REPORT OF THE JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION OF THE STATE OF, NEW YORK TRANSMITTED TO THE LEGISLATURE FEBRUARY 14, 1916 ALBANY J. B. LYON COMPANY, PRINTERS 1916 DOCUMENTS DEFT. REPORT OF THE JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION OF THE STATE OF NEW YORK TRANSMITTED TO THE LEGISLATURE FEBRUARY 14, 1916 ALBANY J. B. LYON COMPANY, PRINTERS 1916 '*' * **' I DOCUMENTS DEFT. CONTENTS Introduction PAGE Joint resolution establishing a Committee 2 Problems facing the Committee 3 General scope of the Committee's investigation 4 Procedure of the Committee 5 Part I. The Revenue Situation 9 CHAPTER I. THE STATE 9 1 CHAPTER II. UP STATE CITIES -. 11 NEW YORK CITY 13 CHAPTER III. THE TOWNS 20 Part II. The New York System of Taxation 21 CHAPTER I. PECULIAR FEATURES OF THE NEW YORK TAX LAW 21 CHAPTER II. THE FAULTS OP THE NEW YORK SYSTEM OF TAXATION . 23 CHAPTER III. WHY THE PRESENT SYSTEM CANNOT BE RELIED UPON FOR THE ADDITIONAL NEEDED REVENUE 26 Part III. The Failure of the Personal Property Tax 31 CHAPTER I 31 History of Tax in Europe 31 Failure in the United States 32 Report of the Commission of Taxation, Massachusetts, 1908 .... 32 Report of Maryland Commission, 1888 35 Report of Kentucky Special Commission, 1912 36 Report of Virginia Tax Commission, 1911 37 Report of National Tax Association, Vol. IV 37 Summary of reports of New York Commissions 38 Report of 1872 39 Report of 1893 40 Report of 1900 40 Report of 1907 40 CHAPTER II. CAUSES OF THE FAILURE OF THE PERSONAL PROPERTY TAX 41 CHAPTER III. INJUSTICE OF THE PERSONAL PROPERTY TAX 43 As between tangible and intangible personalty 44 As between the poor and the wealthy 44 Concerning widows and orphans and trust estates 45 As between farmers and owners of other forms of wealth 47 Comparison of taxes on manufacturing and farms in California. 48 Table showing comparison of aggregates and percentages of investments in manufactures and agriculture in Minnesota ... 50 Injustice as between various types and classes of enterprise .... 54 [iii] 679528 CONTENTS PAGE Part IV. Failure of the Personal Property Tax in New York 55 CHAPTER I. GENERAL SCOPE OF THE COMMITTEE'S INVESTIGATION. 55 CHAPTER II. PERSONAL INVESTIGATION IN THE Six COUNTIES 59 CHAPTER III. DECLINE IN THE PERSONAL PROPERTY ASSESSMENT IN NEW YORK STATE 66 CHAPTER TV*. PERSONAL PROPERTY ASSESSMENT IN NEW YORK CITY. 68 CHAPTER V. PERSONAL PROPERTY ASSESSMENT IN OTHER CITIES AND TOWNS 69 CITIES 69 TOWNS 71 Part V. Failure of Section 12 (Introduction) 73 CHAPTER I. WHAT SECTION 12 Is 73 CHAPTER II. IMPOSSIBILITY OF ENFORCING SECTION 12 77 CHAPTER III. INVESTIGATION OF 2,500 CORPORATIONS 81 CHAPTER IV. INVESTIGATION OF THE COMMITTEE BY MEANS OF VOL- UNTARY RETURNS OF GENERAL BUSINESS CORPORA- TIONS 88 CHAPTER V. FURTHER INVESTIGATION OF THE WORKING OF SECTION 12 THROUGH THE MEANS OF VOLUNTARY RETURNS OF CORPORATIONS 91 CHAPTER VI. How CORPORATIONS ESCAPE THE PERSONAL PROPERTY TAX IN NEW YORK STATE 92 LEGAL MEANS OF ESCAPING TAXATION 96 CHAPTER VII. WHY CORPORATIONS ARE IMPELLED TO EVADE PER- SONAL PROPERTY TAX 101 Part VI. Taxation of Foreign Corporations. 103 The law regarding the taxation of personal property of foreign corporations 103 Failure of the law 109 Investigation of country records 109 Testimony concerning failure of the personal property tax in regard to foreign corporations Ill Why foreign corporations should make a substantial contribution to the support of State and local government 113 Part VII. New York System of Taxing Manufactures 117 CHAPTER I. STATE TAX 117 CHAPTER II. LOCAL TAXATION OF MANUFACTURING CORPORATIONS .. 118 CHAPTER III. NEW YORK MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY AS A TAXABLE BASE 119 CHAPTER IV. YIELD IN NEW YORK 126 CHAPTER V. YIELD OF NEW YORK MANUFACTURING CORPORATIONS UNDER THE FEDERAL INCOME TAX 129 CHAPTER VI. NEW YORK COMPARED WITH OTHER STATES : . . . 130 CHAPTER VII. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS CONCERNING THE TAXA- TION OF MANUFACTURING CORPORATIONS 133 Part VIII. Section 182.. . 137 CONTENTS v PAGE Part IX. The Listing System 143 Report of Oregon Special Tax Commission 144 Report of 1906 Washington Commission 144 Report of New York Special Tax Commission, 1907 144 Drastic laws to secure disclosures have always failed 145 Report of Ohio Commission, 1893 147 Report of Kentucky Special Tax Commission, 1914 ^. 148 Part X. Miscellaneous Business Taxes 149 Part XI. Some Forms of Corporate Taxation Found in Other States. . . . 151 The franchise tax based on the par value of capital stock, such as is found in New Jersey 151 The capital stock tax, such as is found in Pennsylvania 151 The corporate excess tax 153 The Wisconsin Income Tax 155 Part XII. Substitutes for the Personal Property Tax 161 CHAPTER I. THE ABILITY, OB PRESUMPTIVE INCOME, TAX 161 Habitation Tax 161 Occupation Tax 164 Salaries Tax 165 Objections to Ability Tax 167 CHAPTEB II. THE CLASSIFIED PROPERTY TAX 168 CHAPTER III. THE Low RATE OF INTANGIBLES . 170 Arguments for the low rate on intangible property 171 Criticism of the above arguments 172 Pennsylvania low rate on intangibles 172 Results of Pennsylvania experience with 4-mill tax 173 Tax upon corporate loan 174 Conclusions concerning the Pennsylvania low rate on intangibles. 174 The experiment of Maryland with the low rate on tangibles 175 Results of Maryland's experience with the low rate on intan- gibles 176 Where Maryland law has failed 177 Conclusions concerning the Maryland low rate on intangibles. 177 Connecticut's experience with the low rate on intangibles 178 Fiscal results of the tax on choses in action 179 Minnesota's experience with the three-mill tax on intangibles. . . . 180 Conclusions as to the Minnesota tax 181 General conclusions concerning the low rate on intangibles 181 CHAPTER IV. THE INCOME TAX 184 Experience in the United States of America 185 Wisconsin Income Tax 186 General characterization of the tax 186 What is taxable under the Wisconsin income tax 188 What is not taxable 188 Definition of income ; 189 Income of individuals exempted from taxation 189 Rates of Wisconsin income tax 189 Administration 192 Advantages of the income tax , . , 195 vi CONTENTS PAGB Conclusion 206 General conclusions 206 Inheritance tax 207 Apportionment of excise and automobile tax 210 Federal and State subjects of taxation 210 Income Tax Bill 215 Appendices 235 STATE OF NEW YORK No. 26 IN SENATE February 14, 1916 Report of the Joint Legislative Committee on Taxation INTRODUCTION The taxation of personal property in the State of New York has presented a serious problem for the last fifty years. Prior to 1852, because of the low rate, the burden of the tax does not seem to have been seriously felt, nor the inequalities which have since arisen in its administration to have existed. However, in 1872, the rate for state and local purposes had risen to three per cent and the defects and injustice of the taxation of personal property at the general property rate became more and more ap- parent. The situation resulted in the appointment of the Com- mission of 1872, which was one of the first of the many com- missions that have investigated and reported on this trouble- some problem. This problem still remains unsolved. During the last thirty years the State has developed a system of special taxes imposing specific taxes upon certain classes of personal property and businesses, withdrawing them thereby out from under the personal property tax. Thus, banks, trust companies, mortgages and motor vehicles are all free from the local personal property tax and are taxable under special laws. But, except for these particular classes, the great mass of personal property in the State is still taxed locally at the same rate as real estate, and under the same rule as existed a half century ago. This was the situation when, in the year 1911, the Legislature enacted what is known as the Secured Debt Law, under the terms of which certain classes of securities, to wit, bonds, notes, debts secured by mortgage of real property situated in any State or country other than New York, or secured by the deposit of 2 : STATE OF NEW YORK securities under a deed of trust, or any bonds, debentures or notes not payable within a year from their date of issue, were, upon the payment of a tax of one-half of one per cent, exempt from all taxation during the life of the security. The law was, broadly speaking, modeled on the Mortgage Recording Tax Law, but there is this fundamental difference between the taxation of so-called secured debts and of mortgages: the tax on mort- gages is paid by the borrower, whereas the holder pays the tax on secured debts. The Secured Debt Law cannot, strictly construed, be considered a tax measure, for the payment of one-half of one per cent upon a security which may run for fifty years is so light a charge as to amount to little more than a registration fee. The purpose of the law was to exempt, rather than to tax, and unless the general policy of the State can be said to contemplate the relieving from taxation of the great and increasing accumu- lations of wealth represented by securities, credits and other forms of intangible property, this purpose must have run counter to our general policy. The law was not only disappointing as a revenue producer, but in the opinion of many constituted an unfair discrimination in favor of the holders of a particular class of property. The justness of this opinion, and the belief that it represented the sentiment of the majority of the people of the State, led the Legislature in 1915 to repal the Secured Debt Law. Various measures were introduced as substitutes, which contemplated sweeping reforms in the taxation of personal property, and which involved drastic efforts to reach securities and other intangibles. The Legislature, however, felt that the time at its disposal was sufficient neither for a careful study of so important a sub- ject nor for an adequate disposition thereof. It adopted, there- fore, a measure of a temporary character, under the terms of which secured debts, upon the payment of three-quarters of one per cent, could obtain exemption from the personal property tax for a period of five years ; and by joint resolution appointed this Committee to study the subject and to report at the next session of the Legislature. The joint resolution reads as follows : " Eesolved (if the Assembly concur), That a joint legisla- tive committee is hereby constituted consisting of three senators, to be appointed by the president of the senate, JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 3 and five members of the assembly, to be appointed by the speaker of the assembly, to examine the laws of this state and of other states and countries relating to taxation; to investigate generally in respect of systems and methods of taxation, particularly with regard to the best methods of equitably and effectually reaching all property which should be subjected to taxation and avoiding conflicts and duplica- tion of taxation on the same property; and to prepare the needed legislation to carry such methods into effect in this State. " Resolved, That such committee be hereby authorized to sit at Albany or elsewhere within the state, to choose a chair- man from among its own members, to employ a secretary and counsel and such other assistants as may be needed, to take testimony, subpoena witnesses and compel the production of books, documents and papers, and otherwise have all the powers of a legislative committee. " Resolved, That such committee, on or before February first, nineteen hundred and sixteen, report the results of its investigation to the legislature, together with such pro- posed legislative measures as it deems advisable to carry its recommendations into effect. " Resolved, That the expense of such committee, not ex- ceeding fifteen thousand dollars, be payable from the contin- gent fund of the legislature upon the certificate of the chair- man of such committee." In view of the misapprehension which has existed in some quarters as to our functions, we desire to state what we believe those functions to be. The Committee does not understand that it was appointed with a view to developing new sources of revenue for the purposes of the State government, but rather to investi- gate the relative burden borne today by different classes of prop- erty and persons; to devise ways and means of doing away with such inequalities as exist, more particularly in so far as the personal property tax is concerned, both in its application to indi- viduals and to corporations ; and to present to the Legislature such a plan as in its judgment will tend to equalize present, as well as future, tax burdens, by the establishment of a broader tax base and a fairer distribution of those burdens. The reasons which 4 STATE OF NEW YOKE led to the creation of this Committee and the terms of the Reso- lution under which it is created, seem to make this entirely clear. The study of the relative burdens borne by the different classes of property and taxpayers necessarily involved an examination of the financial condition of the State, cities and other localities, while the determination of the best remedies called for a careful study of the tax systems of foreign countries and other American States, and more particularly of the recent reforms which have taken place in many of the latter. The time available to the Committee rendered it impossible to make a complete analysis of all the classes involved. Such investigation would have required the study of (a) Public service corporations, including railways, car companies, telegraph and telephone companies, rapid transit companies, gas, electric light, water and power companies; (b) Financial corporations, including commercial banks, trust companies, savings banks, fire, life and miscellaneous insurance companies; (c) General business corporations, including manufactur- ing companies, mercantile companies and miscellaneous companies. The time required by similar investigations in other states for example: Virginia, one and a half years; Connecticut, two years ; Kentucky, one and a half years ; California, two years - made it clear that it would be impossible for the Committee to undertake the complete task and at the same time to report by February 1, 1916. The CcymTnit.tp.ft felt justified, therefore, in postponing for further consideration if the Legislature deems this to be desirable (a) the taxation of public service corpo- rations, (b) the taxation of financial corporations, etc. The Committee devoted its attention to (a) An investigation of the personal property tax, the causes of its failure, and possible remedies or substitutes, involving a study of systems tried elsewhere ; (b) The reform of the taxation of general business cor- porations, including mercantile, manufacturing and miscel- laneous, involving a study of the principal methods of taxing general business corporations in the principal States of the Union ; JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 5 (c) The revenue to be derived from any new methods of taxation, including (1) The yield of the various substitutes for the personal property tax, such as the 'Classified Property Tax, the Habita- tion, Occupation and Salary Taxes, the Income Tax and Miscellaneous Business Taxes ; (2) The yield of a tax on manufacturing, mercantile and general business corporations, according to methods used in other States. PROCEDURE OF THE COMMITTEE The Committee met for the purpose of organization in Albany on July 9, 1915. Senator Ogden L. Mills was elected Chairman; Assemblyman Frank B. Thorn was elected Vice-Chairman ; Assemblyman H. Edmund Machold was elected Secretary; Charles R. Hotaling was elected Sergeant-at-Arms and William R. Weed was chosen Clerk to the Committee. At a subsequent meeting Bronson Winthrop, Esq., was selected as Counsel-in- Chief, and Walter Lindner, Esq., Henry M. Powell, Esq., and Robert C. Gumming, Esq., were selected as Associate Counsel to the Committee. Professor H. A. E. Chandler was selected as Tax Expert and Advisor to the Committee. Upon the resignation of Frank B. Thorn, Assemblyman William W. Chace was ap- pointed by the Speaker as a member of the Committee and Assemblyman Edward A. Everett was elected Vice-Chairman. The Committee established an office at 9 East 84th street, New York City. The chairman collected all of the important and more recent reports of the special tax commissions appointed in the different states of the Union, and the annual and special reports of the various tax commissions in other states, together with such works as would enable the Committee to familiarize itself with the tax systems of European countries. Letters requesting their advice and suggestion were written to the leading tax experts throughout the country, and to the boards of supervisors, to the boards of assessors of the cities of the State, to the county treasurers, to the mayors of the cities of the State, to the State Grange, to the boards of trade and chambers of 6 STATE OF NEW YORK commerce and merchants' associations throughout the State, to all individuals interested in the subject of taxation in the State and to those who had attended the various New York State Con- ferences. Numerous conferences have been held with tax experts in New York and neighboring states. In addition, specific ques- tionaires were sent to every county and to every city in the State, for the purpose of obtaining information as to the workings of the personal property tax. This was supplemented in six coun- ties by personal investigations. A questionaire was sent to 500 of the leading foreign and domestic corporations doing business in the State, requesting such information as would enable the Committee to determine what property of those corporations was actually liable to personal property taxation and what taxes were actually being paid. In this particular field the Committee received great assistance from the Associated Manufacturers and Merchants Association of the State. The Committee held public hearings in New York City during the month of October, at which city and State officials, real estate owners, representatives of the Merchants Association, of the Chamber of Commerce, of various taxpayers', and civic associa- tions, of the Savings Bank Association, of the Investment Bank- ers Association, leading business men and experts on taxation, presented their views. At the conclusion of these hearings and prior to the hearings held up-State, the Committee issued a state- ment which contained a brief summary of the evidence presented to the Committee, together with the three principal plans which had been suggested as substitutes for the personal property tax, and invited criticism and suggestions on the part of the public. This statement was sent to the various chambers of commerce and boards of trade throughout the State, to the State Grange, and to all the newspapers of the State, with the request that it be published. During the latter part of November and the early part of December, hearings were held in Syracuse, Kochester -and Buffalo, at which the city and county officials, the Secretary of the State Grange, the representatives of the chambers of commerce, the Committee of the Associated Manufacturers and Merchants of JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 7 the State, real estate owners and operators, leading merchants and business men, and Francis M. Lamon, Secretary, Northern New York Development League, were heard. The Committee returned to New York where a brief hearing was held, at which Professor Bullock of Harvard University presented his views to the Committee and explained the tax situa- tion in Massachusetts, and Professor Adams, formerly of the University of Wisconsin and a former tax commissioner of the State of Wisconsin, described the workings of the Wisconsin income tax, and presented his views on the New York situation. At this hearing resolutions were presented on behalf of the Merchants Association, the Committee on Taxation of the New York Chamber of Commerce, and the Special Committee on Taxation appointed by the Mayor of the City of New York, endorsing the income tax as a substitute for the personal prop- erty tax. The Committee desires to acknowledge the assistance it has received, more particularly from Professor E. R. A. Seligman of Columbia University, Professor T. S. Adams of Cornell Uni- versity, Hon. Lawson Purdy, President of the Department of Taxes and Assessments of New York City, Alfred E. Holcomb, Esq., Treasurer, National Tax Association, Professor Charles J. Bullock of Harvard University, and A. C. Pleydell, Esq., of the New York Tax Reform Association. The Committee desires also to acknowledge the assistance which it has derived from the cordial co-operation of the Special Committee on Taxation appointed by the mayor of the city of New York; of the Com- mittee on Co-operation consisting of representatives of the various real estate associations, the Trust Company Association, the Sav- ings Bank Association, the Association of Insurance Presidents, the Merchants' Association and of the New York 'Chamber of Commerce; of the Associated Manufacturers and Merchants As- sociation of the State of New York ; of the Rochester Chamber of Commerce and of the press of the State, which has been of ma- terial aid in presenting to the people the various plans suggested as substitutes for the personal property tax, and in keeping the public in touch with the work of the Committee. 8 STATE OF NEW YORK The Chairman acknowledges the very great assistance he has re- ceived from Professor H. A. E. Chandler in the preparation of this report. Mr. Chandler has been in constant touch with the work of the Committee, has had charge of much of the original in- vestigation 'and has made valuable contributions to the writing of the report itself. PART I THE REVENUE SITUATION The success or failure of the personal property tax is directly connected with the rate of the tax. Given a very low rate, it can be administered more or less satisfactorily and with comparative fairness and equality. Thus when, as in 1852, the rate in this State for both State and local purposes was but 7 mills on the dollar, there was little or no complaint. But let the rate rise to 1% or 2 per cent, and the inequalities and injustice become well-nigh unbearable. Experience has conclusively shown that a personal property tax at a 2 per cent rate is bound to be an absolute and complete failure, and to the extent that it does succeed, grossly unjust. It is pertinent, therefore, to examine the rates in New York State and to determine the likelihood of an increase or decrease by an examination of the financial situation of the State and of the localities. In so far as the latter are concerned, we have con- fined our investigation for the most part to the cities, because it is in the cities principally that we find the largest aggregates of wealth in the form of personal property, and because, broadly speaking, it is in the cities that the tax problem is most acute. CHAPTER I THE STATE The average tax rate in the 'State for the year 1914 was .018995 or approximately $1.90 per $100 of valuation. In the cities the tax rate ran in the year 1914 from .0166 in Geneva to .0655 in Port Jervis. These figures do not include a direct State tax, and yet the steady increase in the cost of State government and the probability that the present indirect sources of revenue have reached approxi- mately their maximum yield, suggest that the direct State tax may well become a permanent part of our revenue system. The expenditures for the general purposes of -State government, exclusive of interest on the canal and highway debts and of the free school fund and sinking and trust funds, have increased from $7,163,831.18 in 1885 to $42,408,488.24 in 1914, or an increase 10 STATE OF NEW YORK of nearly 500 per cent in thirty years. In the meanwhile the population of the State has increased 82 per cent and the assessed value of. real and personal property liable to taxation 274 per cent The per capita cost of government has risen from $2.47 in 1895 to $5.41 in 1914, or an increase of 235 per cent during a period when the population of the State increased but 53 per cent. From 1903 to the present time the net debt of New York State, over and above all sinking funds, has increased from $7,400,000 to over $148,051,000. The funded debt outstanding today is over $186,000,000, and in the last election the people authorized an additional indebtedness of $27,000,000. Thus the per capita net State debt has arisen from 94 cents in 1903 to $15.04 in 1915. The total appropriations for the general purposes of govern- ment, including sinking fund contributions, aggregate for the last five years $263,149,265.50, and exclusive of sinking fund contribu- tions, $225,244,800.77 ; while the income from sources other than the direct State tax aggregates but $211,049,892.59. For the last five years the appropriations for the general expenses of government, exclusive of sinking fund charges, have averaged in round numbers $45,048,960, and including sinking fund con- tributions, $52,629,853.10. The yield of the indirect taxes and of sources other than the direct State tax, has averaged in round numbers but $42,209,978.51 for the last five years. The Comptroller estimates that the debt service for the next five years will cost as follows : 1916-1917 $12,576,684 42 1917-1918 13,155,718 05 1918-1919 13,734,751 68 1919-1920 14,313,785 31 1920-1921 14,892,818 94 To this must be added increased maintenance charges for the State highways and the Barge canal, which, when both are com- pleted, will represent an increase per annum of $2,740,000. Under these circumstances it is hard to escape the conclusion that, unless new indirect sources be devised, a direct State tax for the purposes of the debt service at least must be included in estimating future local rates, even assuming that the most rigid economy be practiced. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 11 That such economy is highly desirable is not open to dispute, and yet in estimating possible reductions in future expenditures for State purposes, it is well to remember that many new func- tions have been assumed by the State government under a policy demanded by the people, a policy which calls not only for in- creased service, but for service of a better quality. Thus, for instance, greater opportunities for education are offered today than ever before; large sums are annually appropriated for the encouragement of agriculture and for the development of scien- tific farming; there has been a large increase in the number of those confined in our penal and correctional institutions and State hospitals, at the same time the construction and reconstruction of hospitals, prisons and other public buildings is paid from current income; huge sums have been voted by the people for the acqui- sition of Palisades Park and for the construction of thousands of miles of improved highways and of a barge canal, the latter two of which add materially to the annual financial burden, not only for interest and amortization charges but for maintenance and repair. Unless, therefore, the people of the State desire a com- plete change of public policy, and are prepared to limit the activities of government, there is little likelihood, with the grow- ing population and with the increased complexities of modern life, of any material decrease, no matter what administrative economies may be effected. This is borne out by the experience of other states and of the Federal government and of all foreign countries that have accepted modern democratic reforms with the new demands which they make upon government. The cost of the Federal government for thirty years prior to 1908 increased nearly 400 per cent, while the population increased but 84 per cent. The average cost of government of all of the states of the Union increased 105.9 per cent from 1903 to 1913, according to the Federal Census, while the population of the states rose only 20 per cent. CHAPTER II THE CITIES Turning now to the cities, we find a similar situation. The cost of government and the bonded indebtedness of almost every city in the State have risen steadily year by year. In the Ap- 12 STATE OF NEW YOIIK pendix will be found tables showing the per capita bonded in- debtedness, the per capita municipal taxes on property, and the per capita expenditures for municipal purposes of the cities of the State in the year 1913, giving the same figures in the case of the 16 principal cities for the years 1902 to 1913. These summaries show that the per capita indebtedness of cities having over 30,000 inhabitants, excluding Amsterdam and Niagara Falls, averaged in 1890, $21.35; in 1902, $47.-05 ; in 1913, $59.82, or an increase in 1913 over 1890 of 180.15 per cent. In Amsterdam the per capita indebtedness decreased 14.5 per cent from 1902 to 1913, and in Niagara Falls increased from 1902 to 1913, 29.2 per cent. In Albany., Auburn, Binghamton, Buffalo, Elmira, Eochester, Schenectady, Syracuse, Troy, Utica and Yonkers, the per capita municipal taxes on property averaged in 1913, $14.64; in 1902, $10.79, or an increase for 1913 over 1902 of 35.72 per cent. The per capita expenditures for muni- cipal purposes for these same cities averaged in 1902, $18.49 and in 1913, $25.11, showing an increase for 1913 over 1902 of 35.81 percent. A careful study of the tables unquestionably shows that there has been a marked upward tendency in practically all of the cities, a tendency so universal that it cannot be fairly attributed to governmental extravagance. In our judgment the explanation will be found in the fact that the increased expenditures have been incurred in response to the demands of the citizens of the localities for better service and for the assumption by the muni- cipal government of duties unthought of by previous generations. Indeed, this was the almost unanimous opinion of those who ap- peared before us. There are but few cities in the State that in recent years have not improved their lighting systems, repaved their streets, constructed new sewers, built school buildings of the most modern type, and in general undertaken a comprehensive \ system of public improvements which, however desirable they may be, and however they may add to the comfort and enjoy- ment of the inhabitants, necessarily mean an increased bur- den to the taxpayers. As a result, the tax rate is so high as to preclude the effective administration of the personal property tax, and the full weight of the increase has fallen on the owners . JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 13 real estate. Without, at this time, discussing the equities of the situation as between the owners of real and of personal property, it is fair to say that, with the possible exception of the City of New York, in most cases the increase in value of real estate has, to a great extent, taken care of these increased taxes. This is still the case as far as we can ascertain in the majority of the up-state cities, but if the cost of government continues to increase during the next decade at the rate that it has in the last, these cities will unquestionably face as serious a situation as now confronts the owners of real estate in the City of New York, unless in the meanwhile some measure can be devised to compel the owners of personal property to contribute their share. The increase in the debt of the City of New York since Decem- ber 31, 1905, is shown in the following table: Gross Funded Debt (exclud- Dec. 31, 1905 Dec. 31, 1915 Increase ing General Fund Bonds) $565, 056, 512 $1, 155, 479, 156 $590, 422, 643' Net Funded Debt (held by the public) 424, 675, 900 979, 750, 749 555, 074, 848 Amount of Gross Funded Debt which is self-sus- taining (not included in computation cf debt limit) 27,113,879 322,525,502 295,411,623 This net increase of $590,000,000 in the gross funded debt is due principally to the initiation and construction of the new dual subway, the Catskill Water Supply System, and exten- sions to the city's other systems of water supply. The bonds issued during this decade on account of the new subway amount to $112,500,000, and on account of the construction and exten- sions of the city's greater water supply system $182,910,000; the amount issued for dock development during this same period has been $64,150,000, making a total of $359,560,000 for rev- enue producing purposes. In addition, there were issued $27,- 500,000 of assessment bonds which will be redeemed from the assessments collected. The other large items of increase in the city debt -are $84,250,000 for streets, sewers and the elimination of grade crossings; $79,850,000 for public buildings; $73,450,000 for schools, libraries and sites, and $45,300,000 mainly for bridges crossing the East river so that the four boroughs 14 STATE OF NEW YORK be physically connected and the Greater City become one city in fact. During the ten years under review, the city has redeemed $135,000,000 of its funded debt. The city debt, however, will not increase in any such ratio during the next decade. The adoption of the " pay-as-you-go " policy and the determination of the present city administration to curtail new authorizations of corporate stock as evidenced by the authorizations of 1914 and 1915 have already checked the growth of the city's debt. The average annual authorizations and allotments of corporate stock throughout the 10-year period, 1906 to 1915, for revenue and non-revenue producing purposes are shown below : AVERAGE ANNUAL AUTHORIZATIONS OF CORPORATE STOCK Distribution Administration Period Amount McClellan 4 yrs. $102, 417, 114 63 Gaynor 4 yrs. 87, 951, 998 46 Mitchel, 1914... 1 yr. 14,594,67048 Revenue Producing $51,663,423 62 56,311,014 23 5, 636, 583 30 Non-Revenue Producing $50,753,691 01 31, 640, 984 23 8,958,087 18 Mitchel, 1915... 1 yr. 11,585,98169 3,545,07056 8,040,91113 Administration Period McClellan 4 yrs. Gaynor 4 yrs. Mitchel, 1914... 1 yr. Mitchel, 1915... 1 yr. AVERAGE ANNUAL ALLOTMENTS OF CORPORATE STOCK Distribution Revenue Non-Revenue Amount Producing Producing $64, 871, 366 72 $23, 978, 468 18 $40, 892, 898 54 79, 164, 221 21 42, 575, 322 26 36, 588, 898 95 62, 234, 689 52 40, 823, 620 55 21, 411, 068 97 57, 226, 931 38 40, 378, 105 56 16, 848, 825 82 The 1916 budget, excluding the direct State tax, is $198,981,- 155.81, a net decrease of $8,630.71 below the budget for 1915, and an increase of $82,175,655.44 above the 1906 budget. The budget for 1916, including the direct State tax of $13,975,021.73 is an increase of $96,150,687.17 over 1906. The two following tables show in summary form the budget for 1906 and 1916 and the city's population, together with the amount and percentage of increase : JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 15 BUDGET Item No. 1906 1916 1 Expenses of city government, exclud- ing charitable institutions $53', 240, 226 84 $78, 075, 306 43 2 Education 23, 938, 006 69 41, 107, 19& 32 3 Charitable institutions 3, 456, 056 44 5, 483, 875 00 4 Total City Government $80, 634, 289 97 $124,666,37975 5 Total County Government 4, 151, 360 50 7, 101, 565 95 6 Debt service 31,116,20721 63,213,21011 7 Tax deficiencies 4, 000, 000 00 8 Direct State Tax.. 903,632 69 13,975,021 73 9 Grand Total $116, 805, 490 37 $212, 956, 177 54 Population 10 Population 4, 166, 556 5, 742, 999 COMPARISON 1916 WITH 1906 Increase Item Average Annual No. Amount Per cent Per cent 1 $24,835,07959 46.647 4.665 2 17,169,19163 71.724 7.172 3 2,027,81856 58.674 5.867 $44,032,08978 . 54.607 5.461 5 2,950,20545 71.066 7.107 6 32,097,00290 103.152 10.315 7 4,000,00000 13,071,38904 1446.538 144.654 $96,150,68717 82.316 8.232 Population 10 1,576,443 37.836 3.784 The above tables show that the average annual increase in the total expense of city government has been 8.23 per cent, whereas the average annual increase in population has 'been 3.784 per cent. The average annual increase in the expense of city government would more nearly approximate or possibly be even less than the average annual increase in population were it not for the fact that until recent years, commencing about 1910, many of the current maintenance charges of city government were not paid from the tax budget but from the proceeds of the sale of corporate stock. The budgets from 1910 to 1916 inclusive, contain appro- 16 STATE OF NEW YOKK priations in substantial amounts for a number of debts which formerly were not included in the annual tax budget. The chief example is the Department of Docks. Prior to the year 1910, all annual maintenance charges for that department were charges against corporate stock. In order to correct this unsound method of financing, the first appropriation in the tax budget for the department was made in the 1910 budget in the amount of $2,821,932, and the amount in the 1916 budget for this depart- ment is $1,501,549. Although the cost of administrative departments under the jurisdiction of the Mayor and the Board of Estimate for 1916 has been decreased by $3,125,904.29 since 1914, the total of the budget has increased, and according to the testimony of the Mayor and the Comptroller of the city before this Committee, will con- tinue to increase principally on account of the adoption of the " pay-as-you-go " policy. The Comptroller estimates that the budget for the next three years will be approximately as follows : 1917 $204,439,623 1918 207,233,298 1919 221,299,848 Mayor Mitchel's estimates are' somewhat higher. He estimates- that the city will have to raise, exclusive of the direct State tax, for the purpose of interest on serial bonds, redemption of serial bonds and the quota of public improvements, and beginning with 1918 interest on subway bonds, the following amounts, which are additional to its present budget of $198,989,786.52 for 1915: 1917 $10,137,000 1918 19,400,000 1919 34,719,000 1920 34,554,000 Bearing In mind that New York City realty is assessed at practi- cally full value, if to this burden be added a direct State tax, there is no question that the tax rate will 'soar to a height rarely known in this country. The consequences of this no man can fore- see, but, in any event, they cannot with safety be minimized or brushed aside. It is only fair to say that the estimated increase will not be due to any increase in the general cost of administra- tion, but will result principally from the adoption of what is- JOISTT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 17 known as the " pay-as-you-go " policy a method recently adopted as a more scientific and proper way of financing public improve- ments. The testimony of the experts in many lines of trade and com- merce all points unmistakably to the fact that this great and increasing burden has been borne largely by one class of in- dividuals, to wit, the real estate owners and their tenants. When- ever the real estate owner is able to shift the tax to the tenant, it falls with the greatest weight on those least able to pay, because of the fact that a much larger percentage of their income is paid for rent by the poor than by the rich. If, on the other hand, the owner of real estate is unable to shift the tax, the new burden may amount to a decrease of his income, and therefore to a fall in the capital value of the real estate. At the New York hearings it was the opinion of those most familiar with real estate in ]STew York City that this class of property was overtaxed, that its value was in danger of being seriously impaired, and that the situation, generally speaking, was critical. For example, Mr. Alfred Marling testified: " I can say without any hesitation, based on my 38 years ex- perience as a real estate broker, appraiser and manager in this city, that real estate is down on its back, and it cannot stand any more burden absolutely none. There is no doubt whatever on that point in my mind. (Q) If these new taxes were imposed, what would be the effect? (A) Trouble, distress of all sorts. It would be practically confiscation to the poor property owner. He is gasping, breathless, now. (Q) You consider the situation serious? (A) I certainly do." The facts and figures submitted by the real estate men are interesting and significant: it was shown that the tax levy for 1915 upon real estate, including land, buildings, special fran- chises and real estate of corporations, amounted to 77 per cent of the 1915 budget, while personal property paid but 3.3 per cent. One group of 11 parcels of real estate paid 30 per cent of net income in taxes. Another group of seven paid 41 per cent in taxes. The average percentage of net income paid in taxes by the entire Astor estate in Manhattan was in 1885, 29.3 per cent ; 1904, 31.6 per cent ; 1909, 30 per cent and 1914, 3*. per cent. 18 STATE OF NEW YORK Their property in Manhattan represents an assessed value of over fifty million dollars, and consists of parcels located all over the borough, and used for all kinds of purposes, from business to residential. An investigation made by Mr. Stewart Browne, who appeared before the Committee, shows that 400 parcels paid 30 per cent more in taxes than ten years ago, while rentals decreased 25 per cent. The same gentleman estimates that the aggregate net income received on improved property in Manhattan does not exceed 3% per cent on assessed valuations and 4% per cent in outlying boroughs. Equally significant was the testimony with reference to the borough of Brooklyn. We quote from the testimony of Mr. William M. Greve: " We have taken into consideration 133 dwelling houses, 49 flats, 88 stores and flats, and 7 stores, for the period of 6 years. Our net return is 4.2 per cent. Of our net return we pay 36 per cent', in taxes ; that is the average tax paid. On dwellings it runs from 31 per cent, in 1909, 32 per cent, in 1910, and in 1911 when the valuations or assessments were increased we paid 60 per cent. It would run in the 6 years on dwellings from 31 to 40 per cent.; on flats it has run from 28 to 39 per cent; on stores and flats it has run from 29 to 38 per cent; and on stores it has decreased, according to our holdings, but that it attributed to the fact that we owned one very large piece of real estate that the rental was more than doubled after the expiration of an old time lease. But I think it is fair to say that in the six years the increase in taxes of the net has been at least 10 per cent." All the real estate experts agree that real property is to-day paying all that it can possibly afford ; that additional taxes could not be shifted to the tenants, who are to-day paying all that they can; that an increase, therefore must come out of the capital value of real estate ; that such an increase would necessarily wipe out the equities of thousands of owners and might precipitate a panic. In so far as mortgages are concerned, it is well to remember that the insurance companies, savings banks, etc., whose investments represent largely the savings of the poorer classes, are the largest investors in real estate mortgages. The mortgages held by sav- JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 19 ings banki aggregate $1,017,493,000 out of a total investment of $1,739,000,000, or 53 per cent, and there are no less than 3,450,000 depositors in the savings banks of the State. Mr. Pulleyn, representing the Savings Banks Association, testi- fied as follows : u Any increase upon real estate holdings in the city of New York, probably in the State of New York, beyond the present figures, would tend to reduce the equities in the investment of $1,017,000,000 of real estate loans that are held at the present time by savings banks. We have seen the indication in the last year in the depression of real estate. We have seen the hand- writing on the wall. We believe, those of us who look at the real estate investment as seriously as savings banks must, that this increase of assessed valuation and increased rate is hurting us very, very seriously hurting our investment. u Q. That is to say, putting it plainly, it is reducing the margin of equity? A. It is reducing the equity in each one of our loans, and will continue to reduce the equity, because whilst there is an increase of a few mills in taxes, it means quite a per- centage on the face of the loan. " Q. There is a point beyond which of course you cannot go ? A. Yes. " Q. A point beyond which your borrowers cannot go, in realiz- ing the increase of taxation out of rents, is there not? A. Exactly. " Q. You feel that that point is very nearly reached ? A. Since there are two ways we have to look at it One is this. In the reappraisal of our investment loans in real estate we take as a basis income. Our income is reduced. It reduces values and when values are reduced, we come under the law of the State which says savings banks shall not lend any more than 60 per cent, of the price value. " Q. Then you have got to call for a scaling down of loans ? A. We have got to call for a scaling down of loans, which we have been unable to do. We are able, of course, to call, but the owners are unable to meet the demand." From the great volume of testimony presented to the Com- mittee with reference to New York Citv. the following conclu- sions may be drawn: 20 STATE OF NEW YORK (1) That real estate is paying* the bulk of the taxes and that personal property, comparatively speaking, is escaping almost entirely. (2) That material increases have taken place in the past dec- ade in the city's bonded indebtedness, the annual tax budget and the tax rate. (3) That in view of the new "pay-as-you-go" policy, adopted by the present city administration, there is likely to be a further material increase during the next few years in the total budgets (due to the increased appropriations for retarding and reducing the city's debt) and consequently material increase in the tax rate. (4) That from the standpoint of equity, real estate alone should not bear the full weight of increased taxes, and that if such a plan is attempted, serious consequences may ensue. (5) That so far as New York City is concerned, therefore, it is imperative that the tax base be broadened so as to include that property and those persons that are not contributing to-day in proportion to their ability to pay taxes. CHAPTER III THE TOWNS As already stated, the Committee's investigation of rural con- ditions was by no means as thorough or as complete as that of the cities. We are in a position to say, however, that, generally speaking, in rural districts the assessed value of real property is higher and nearer to true value than it was a few years ago; that the xate at which it is taxed is higher, and that personal property, in so far as taxation is concerned, has almost ceased to exist. Nor is there any likelihood of there being any material change in either one of these respects. Our conclusion, then, as to the entire State is, that the tax rate is altogether too high to permit the successful taxation of personal property at the general property rate, and that the future financial needs of the State and of its subdivisions, are such as to deny the hope that the tax rate can be reduced to the point where such taxation becomes comparatively successful or even possible. PART II THE NEW YORK SYSTEM OF TAXATION CHAPTER I PECULIAR FEATURES OF THE NEW YORK TAX LAW The New York tax system contain several peculiar features that differentiate it in a striking manner from nearly every other tax system in the United States. Several of these peculiari- ties are of special interest because they are unquestionably account- able for some of the weakest spots in the present tax law. (1) In the first place the theory of intrastate situs of tangible personalty is quite different in New York from that of most other States, and this difference results in much unfairness, not only between different classes of individuals, but also between different communities within the State. In most states there has been a tendency more and more to tax tangible personal property of residents where located ; but in New York State all tangible as well as intangible personalty is taxable only at the legal domicile of the owner, whether it be an individual or a domestic corpo- ration. The extent to which this peculiarity is responsible for tax evasion will be pointed out in the following chapter dealing with the faults of the New York system. (2) The second peculiarity of the New York system is found in the debt exemption feature. The custom as to the exemption of debts varies in different states. In some states the taxpayer is permitted to deduct only certain debts from credits; in other states all debts may be deducted from credits. In most states the deduction of debt feature under the general property tax is troublesome. In New York State, however, the debt deduction difficulty is accentuated because of the peculiar privilege which permits the total deduction of all debts not simply from credits, but from all personalty. In the next chapter will be pointed out how this privilege enables corporations to escape from personal property taxation. The whole question of debt deduction, whether limited to credits or not, presents one of the insuperable difficul- ties of the present property tax. 22 STATE OF NEW YOEK (3) The third peculiarity is that public service corporation franchises, or so-called " special franchises/ 7 are treated as real estate. This whole question of special franchises is a large one, deserving treatment at another time. This feature, of course, is not responsible for the failure of the personal property tax. (4) The fourth peculiar feature is found in the absence of the so-called listing system. New York is the only state in the Union that has not had a complete listing system. It is true that corpo- rations are theoretically required by law to render a complete list of all property subject to taxation, but as a matter of fact the law is a dead letter. New York, however, never has had, even in theory, the rule that individuals should list their personalty, tangible and intangible, for purposes of taxation. To this, peculiarity a few tax reformers with a little knowledge of ex- perience in other states, have attributed the failure of the personal property tax. It can be said, however, without fear of contra- diction that no one acquainted with the results of the listing system in other states has the slightest confidence in this con- tention. The uniform experience of other states has been that the listing system, even with drastic attempts at enforcement and heavy penalties, has failed absolutely to secure an enforcement of the personal property tax. Indeed, it might be added that were the listing system successful in enforcing this unjust tax, it would to that degree achieve a most regrettable success. It is not be- lieved that this peculiarity in the New York law is in any consider- able way responsible for the present inequities. (5) The next peculiarity which is of considerable importance grows out of the phraseology of the New York law. In most states the law declares all property, read and personal, subject to taxation. It then defines real property, and defines personalty as all property not included in real estate. The New York law, after declaring all property, real and personal, subject to taxation, proceeded to define personalty, not in the usual way, but through the method of enumerating the various types of property included within the term. For some reason, good-will was not included in the enumeration, and the courts have declared it to be untax- able. As will be explained in full in the next chapter, this peculiarity has rendered it impossible to reach a large part of the JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 23 earning power of some of the wealthiest corporations in the State. (6) The New York system of taxing corporations is the most complex of its kind in the United States. In the case of certain types of corporations, the aggregate tax burden is split up into so many different taxes levied at varying rates and upon different bases, that it has been impossible to determine the relative burden borne by various classes of wealth. In regard to the taxation of general business corporations, the law is especially complex and confused. It has been called the most illogical corporation law in America. It is so ambiguous that it baffles the best tax at- torneys in the State, and in many cases it is utterly impossible for the corporation that wishes to pay its full share to know what that share is. It is an interesting fact that under this law many cor- porations, through their inability to understand it, have actually paid more taxes than they were liable for. (7) The last peculiarity of the tax law to be mentioned here is section 12, covering the taxation of the personal property of corporations. This feature is dealt with at some length in the chapter covering the failure of the corporation personal property tax. It is sufficient here to say that there is yet to be found in this State one man, either among the tax officials or the corpora- tions taxed, to commend the law. While it has proved practically unenforceable all over the State, it has been a source of great annoyance to corporate business in general. CHAPTER II THE FAULTS OF THE NEW YORK SYSTEM OF TAXATION In the previous chapter it was pointed out that many of the features which differentiate the New York system from those of other states constitute not only its peculiarities, but also its faults. The faults of the system, however, are not limited to its peculiari- ties. New York, like every other state in the Union, has suffered the same inequities that arise from the outgrown general property tax. (1) The most conspicuous defect, therefore, of the New York system is found in the utter failure of that part of the personal property tax that is still left under the general property system. 24 STATE OF NEW YOKK While it must be admitted that New York has in part reformed her personal property tax through the substitution of her system of special taxes, and to this extent is better off than many of her sister states, nevertheless, it is doubtful whether in any other State in the Union that part of the personal property tax still left under a general property scheme is a more lamentable failure than in New York. And this statement is applicable with rein- forced emphasis both to the personalty of individuals and to the personalty of corporations. For the details of this failure, the reader is referred to Part IV of this report. It is sufficient here to conclude with the statement that all familiar with the New York system of taxation, however they may disagree as to the correct reform, are unanimous in the conclusion that the present personal property tax should be eradicated from our system as soon as possible. (2) The second great fault in the New York system of tax- ation is to be found in its lack of adequate provisions for the ad- ministration of the tax law. As is well known to all those in- formed upon tax matters, the present law was designed to deal with conditions that no longer exist. The framers of the law lived in a world different from our own. They designed a law to deal with a simple society in which most property was tan- gible and in which ability to pay was roughly measured by the amount of tangible property owned by each. It was designed for business units of local scope. Since that time has come the great revolution in American industry, and with it the great state-wide and nation-wide corporation. Any system which leaves in the hands of the local assessor the assessment of that part of nation-wide business enterprises that happens to be located in, or to traverse his little district is, of course, nothing short of mediaeval. All authorities agree that so long as we leave the assessment of the personalty of great corporations in the hands of the local assessor, we must remain in the dark ages of taxation. In the matter of administration, New York can make no claim to leadership in taxation. For a number of years, while New York was developing her system of special taxes, this State was looked to for guidance in tax reform. That time is past and JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 25 many states have progressed far beyond New York. Upon this point there seems to appear no difference of opinion among the authorities on taxation either in this or other states. All agree that the next reforms in taxation must come in the form of im- proved and more centralized administration. In whatever direc- tion reform in the 'New York system of taxation shall come, it is clear beyond the shadow of a doubt that to be successful it must be accompanied by improved administration. (3) The next most striking fault of the -New York system is to be found in its peculiar form of intrastate situs of personal property. This peculiar feature has been explained in the pre- vious chapter. It remains here to illustrate how subversive it is of all equity as between localities, and to what extent tax eva- sion is possible under this theory. Personal property, both tangible and intangible, is taxable under the New York law only at the legal domicile of the owner. This principle works with especial unfairness with regard to business men generally, whether carrying on their business as in- dividuals or as a partnership or in corporate form. An individual merchant residing in the town of Brighton, Monroe county, may own and operate a large store in the city of Rochester. Or that same mercantile business may be incorporated and the corporation may select the town of Esopus as its principal place of business, though the latter town has no connection whatever with the busi- ness. In either one of the instances mentioned, it would be im- possible under the law for the city of Kochester to tax either the individual merchant or the corporation on the large stock of goods carried by the store in the city of Rochester, while it is highly improbable that any considerable tax would be paid either to the town of Brighton or to the town of Esopus. In other words, the locality that supplies lire and police protection, as well as other advantages, is required to yield the right to tax the property so protected to other localities supplying none of these protections, while the individual merchant or the corporation doing business and actually residing in the city of Rochester, to continue our illustration, is obliged to meet, in so far as local trade is con- cerned, the competition of a rival who is free from all the taxa- tion on personal property. 26 STATE OF NEW YORK This peculiarity of the New York law is such a prolific source of tax evasion that considerable attention will be given to it in those sections of this report dealing with the failure of section 12. (4) The next important fault of the New York system is found in the needless complexity and ambiguity of the method of taxing corporations both for State purposes and for local pur- poses. As this phase has been briefly touched upon in the pre- vious chapter, and as it will be elaborated to some extent in a special section of this report, we shall only mention here that it comprises a very acute fault which demands immediate and radi- cal reform. (5) The last important fault to be dwelt upon in this chapter, because of its far-reaching consequences, deserves special atten- tion. It may be summed up in one statement that not only do large groups of wealth escape taxation entirely, but many in- dividuals most able to pay taxes and enjoying great privileges within the State cannot be reached under the present law. The effect of this evasion has both important direct and indirect results. The direct effect is that in escaping their fair share, these sources transfer their share of the burden to those already heavily taxed. The indirect effect, which is perhaps of greatest importance, is that the knowledge of this wide-spread evasion sows discontent and in many cases dishonesty in the minds of those who would otherwise be willing to pay their full share. From the results of a wide investigation, it appears beyond doubt that the average person, both individual and corporation, would be will- ing to pay his fair share of taxes, were the burdens more equitably and evenly distributed. CHAPTER III WHY THE PRESENT SYSTEM CANNOT BE RELIED UPON FOR ADDI- TIONAL NEEDED REVENUE To anyone familiar with the working of the general property tax in New York State, it is inconceivable that the communities of the State should continue to raise additional revenue by increasing year after year the rate of the direct tax. There are not less than four important reasons why it would be inequitable as well as unwise from the point of view of the stability of certain lines of business to place additional burdens upon that property bearing the general property rate. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 27 (1) In the first place, a horizontal raise always accentuates existing inequalities. The existing inequalities of the present system are altogether too great to permit any degree of accentua- tion. This fact would be true were the horizontal raise applied to all taxes, but under our system, the situation is even worse because a horizontal raise is always limited to only part of the taxable base. Under our system of special taxes, a large number of sources have been taken out from under the general property tax. Included in this part of the tax base are banks, trust companies, insurance companies, savings banks, mortgages, etc. The rates upon them are fixed and remain the same every year regardless of the rise in the cost of government. This system throws upon the remaining sources, viz., real estate and that small part of personalty that is actually reached, a burden which in many cases is already too heavy to bear. Much can be said in favor of our special taxes and in no place does this report suggest the return to a general property system. It must be admitted, however, that when the bank and trust com- panies those forms of wealth which according to the returns of the internal revenue department yield the largest profits of any American business when these are unaffected by the increased cost of government, it is unfair to continue to heap burdens upon that wealth coming under the general property rate. Of course all lines of business in so far as they own real estate are reached by the general, property rate. However, many of those branches which are most able to pay have a small propor- tion of their capital invested in real estate. The large element of intangible personalty which represents such an important part of the earnings of American business is not reached by an in- creased tax rate under our present system. (2) The second reason why the present system should not be relied upon for additional revenue is, that great masses of wealth are now escaping, in part or in whole, from paying their fair share of taxation; and furthermore, that these sources cannot be reached under the present system. And in this connection it should be noted and emphasized that the present high rates of the general property tax are due principally not to the unusually great expenditures of money in the State of New York nor to 28 STATE OF NEW YORK great extravagance, but to the fact that so much wealth is totally- escaping from taxation. In other words, the part which escapes has loaded its burden upon the part that is caught. Were the people of New York once aroused to the full extent of evasions under the present law, another year could not pass without an important tax reform. What are the principal sources that are now escaping? We have already mentioned intangible personalty. Under this term is grouped the greatest earning power, and therefore, the greatest ability to pay taxes in America. And yet under our present law it is impossible to reach an important part of this wealth. It is a well-known fact that the more complex our business world grows, the larger the amount of income that is not directly derived from real property. Our present law is based upon the theory that earning power is fairly represented by property and especially real property. However, a superficial knowledge of business of today discloses the fact that quite the contrary is true. As a result of this inconsistency between the law and the fact, we have permitted an important part of our well-to-do citizens to grow up and enjoy large incomes, and therefore large tax-paying ability, without actually requiring them to bear their share of the burden. Another fruitful source of tax evasion is found among those wealthy citizens of New York who shift their legal residence for the purpose of evading taxes. While they may not be reached under our present law, they represent a large taxpaying ability which ought to be reached and which could be reached under other forms of taxation suggested in the latter part of this report. A still more important source that escapes almost all taxation is that of foreign corporations doing large amounts of business in the State of New York. It is argued by some that foreign cor- porations ought not to be taxed to any extent in this State. How- ever, a careful study discloses the fact that most of these corpo- rations are foreign only in name, and that in reality they are domestic corporations with many of their plants located in the State. In fact, many of these foreign corporations now own and control property located in this State which formerly was owned and controlled by domestic corporations. In other words, large groups of wealth legally and fairly subject to taxation in the JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ox TAXATION 29 State of New York have been by virtue of a legal fiction trans- ferred to another jurisdiction. This is a subject of greater importance for New York State than for any other State in the Union. In addition to the above, there are several other groups of wealth that are escaping from paying their fair share. Space does not permit the discussion of these in detail. In summarizing, however, it is sufficient to say that were proper and thoroughly possible means taken for reaching the sources which now escape, it would not be necessary to consider the doubtful results of increasing present rates. Present rates would not be increased; they would be decreased materially. (3) The final reason why we cannot rely upon the general property tax for additional revenue lies in the fact that any con- siderable increase would threaten to disturb important business conditions. In this connection the real estate situation in New York City and other localities is already such as to cause appre- hension. This statement should not be misunderstood. Much confusion has been injected into the discussion by the exaggerated claims of the real estate men, on the one hand, and of a group of radical social reformers, on the other. It should be noted that nothing but confusion can result from talking of real estate in the aggregate. In some localities certain sections of the real estate field are in a very prosperous condition and any reasonable in- crease in the tax rate would be taken care of by the normal increase in the value of property. In such cases comprising possibly one-third of the entire State, it is foolish to speak of the unbearable burden of the general property tax. This condition represents important parts of the city of New York. On the other hand, there are large sections of the city of New York, as well as parts of the State at large, where an increase in the tax rate might constitute nothing short of confiscation. Indeed, the present high rates upon real estate have already, through the reduction of net income, actually destroyed capital value. In proof of this fact we have abundant evidence. In a large number of cases the value of the real estate has not increased as the tax rates increased. Indeed, in many cases while the tax rates have increased, the actual value of the property has 30 STATE OF NEW YORK decreased. And, moreover, this has taken place during a period when the tax officers have been pushing the assessed value nearer and nearer to the market value. They have, in fact, actually pushed the assessed value beyond the market value in some cases. The cases presented as sworn testimony at the New York City hearings of the Joint Legislative Committee serve to illustrate how inequitably the present general property rate bears upon real estate. And it should be carefully noted here what great varieties of tax-paying ability are grouped under the term " real estate owners." Our single-tax friends are fond of talking of certain well-known wealthy New York families and give the impression that most of New York real estate is monopolized by the few rich holders. It is greatly to be regretted that they have created a false impression by centering public attention, not upon the nor- mal condition, but upon the unusual and abnormal. A careful examination of the real estate situation, not only in the State at large, but in New York City itself, will disclose a surprising number of small holders of real estate, who depend upon the income from this property for living. In many in- stances the head of the family before dying has invested his earnings in real estate in the hope that either the increased value or the increased earning of the property would be sufficient to take care of his wife and partly educate his children. Cases are now frequent in which those who owned the property pay out a large part or nearly all of the income in taxes. The situation of the small salaried man who desires to own his own home is even more serious, in fact the high rates constitute a positive deter- rent to home building. In summarizing, therefore, it should be clearly borne in mind that the injustice of the present system lies not in the fact that it bears heavily on all real estate owners, but rather in the fact that it fails to discriminate and sometimes bears with such crushing force upon those who are least able * pay. PART III THE FAILURE OF THE PERSONAL PROPERTY TAX CHAPTER I HISTORY OF TAX IN EUROPE We would like, did space permit, to trace the history of the personal property tax from mediaeval times down to the present day; to show how it was once in use in practically every country in Europe ; how, as the earlier and simple economic structure gave way to modern complex development, its weakness and defects became apparent, so that one by one these countries abandoned it until to-day Switzerland is the only country in Europe where the general property tax still remains. \Ve cannot do better in this connection than to quote briefly from Seligman's Essays on Taxa- tion, page 61 : " Historically, the property tax was once well-nigh universal. Far from being an original idea which the Americans instinctively adopted, it is found in all early societies whose economic condi- tions were similar to those of the American colonies. It was the first crude attempt to attain a semblance of equity, and it at first responded roughly to the demands of democratic justice. In a community mainly agricultural, the property tax was not unsuited to the social conditions. But as soon as commercial and industrial considerations came to the foreground in national or municipal life, the property tax decayed, became a shadow of its former self and, while professing to be a tax on all property, ulti- mately turned into a tax on real property. The disparity be- tween facts and appearances, between practice and theory, almost everywhere became so evident and engendered such misery, that the property tax was gradually relegated to a subordinate position in the fiscal system, and was at last completely abolished. All attempts to stem the current and to prolong the tax by a more stringent administration had no effect but that of injurious reac- tion on the morale of the community. America is to-day the only great nation deaf to the warnings of history. But it is fast near ing the stage where it, too, will have to submit to the inevitable." 32 STATE OF NEW YORK FAILURE IN THE UNITED STATES The personal property tax has had a fair trial in nearly every State in the Union, and has everywhere proved a failure. This is the practically unanimous verdict of the many able commis- sions that have made a careful study of the tax in the various states. To quote from all of these reports, however impressive the evidence would be, would be merely cumulative. We give therefore, but brief extracts from five of the most important, which may fairly be said to be typical and representative. REPORT OF THE COMMISSION ON TAXATION, MASSACHUSETTS, 1908, Pages 22-24, 25, 26-28, 33-34 " This method of taxation is frequently described as peculiarly American and democratic, and it is supposed to be a method which, if fully carried out, would oblige every man to contribute to the support of public charges in proportion to his ability to pay. But, as a matter of fact, the system is neither distinctively Ameri- can nor democratic, and it is admitted that, however excellent the intent of the law, the practical result has never been that all citizens do contribute in proportion to their ability to bear the charges of government. " The general property tax was once in nearly universal use in Europe, and was brought to Massachusetts by the early settlers, who merely introduced here a system with which they had been familiar in the country from which they came. In England, as in most other countries of Europe, the principal form of direct taxation had long been a general levy upon property. In the seventeenth century this tax was known as the subsidy, and in practical operation produced the same results as followed its in- troduction in the 2sTew World. Personal property always man- aged to escape taxation in whole or in part, so that complaints about the inequality and injustice of the system were almost as common as they are in Massachusetts in our own time. In 1592 one writer stated that not more than five men in London were assessed upon goods exceeding 200, and in 1601 Sir Walter Ealeigh complained that l The poor man pays as much as the rich/ About the middle of the seventeenth century the subsidy became so unsatisfactory that it was replaced by a new tax, JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 33 known as the monthly assessment, which was, however, but the same thing under another name. The immediate result of the change was a somewhat more complete assessment of property; but before long personalty began to evade taxation as before; so that in 1692 the monthly assessment was abolished, and re- placed by a new tax designed to reach the true yearly value of all lands, tenements, offices and personal estates. This new tax was but another property tax in a somewhat different form, and it soon fared as badly as its predecessors. During the eighteenth century personal property disappeared from the assessment rolls as rapidly as ever before, so that by 1798 over nine-tenths of the levy fell upon real estate, and less than one-tenth upon offices and personal estate. By this time, in fact, the tax had generally come to.be known as the ' land tax.' In some towns, we are told, the whole tax was assessed upon land and houses and personal estates wholly escaped. " In 1798 an act was passed by which the land tax became virtually a fixed charge upon the land, and since that time no further attempt has been made in England to levy a general property tax. The national revenues are now derived from an income tax, taxes on inheritances and the usual indirect taxes; while local revenues are drawn chiefly from a tax levied upon occupiers of land, houses and trade premises. "And in most of the other countries of Europe the result has been the same. * * * " It is equally erroneous to call the general property tax a dem- ocratic form of taxation. It is not found in such ultra-demo- cratic communities as the Australasian States; nor, with the ex- ception of Switzerland, is it found in those countries of Europe in which democratic ideas have taken deepest root. It was brought to America from England in the seventeenth century, when democracy existed neither in the mother country nor the colonies, and has been fastened upon us rather by historical acci- dent than because of its inherently democratic qualities. * * ' The history of the general property tax in Massachusetts is not materially different from its history in other States. From 1651 to the present date complaints that personal property evades taxation are met at every hand. During the last thirty-five years 2 34 STATE OF NEW YORK four commissions or special committees, exclusive of the present, have heen appointed to study the question ; and their reports dis- close the fact that the taxation of intangible property is the weakest point in the entire system. There is reason to believe that the administration of the law by Massachusetts assessors has been considerably better than the administration of the laws of many other States. The taxation of intangible property has not been such a complete farce with us as it has been elsewhere ; yet we find no one who supposes that we are now taxing more than 10 or 20 per cent, of the money, credits and securities taxable under our present law. After careful study of the subject, our commission is forced to the same conclusion that was reached by the commission of 1897, which we reproduce here: " e It is obvious, however, that this method of taxation en- counters, as to intangible property, exceptional and indeed al- most insuperable difficulties. There are no such external indi- cations of taxable liability as appear in the case of live stock, vessels, stock in trade or machinery. General repute as to the possession of large means, or a mode of life indicating an ample income, do not necessarily signify any thing as to taxable securi- ties. The investments of a person of means may be in real es- tate within or without the State, or in Massachusetts stocks or mortgages, or in bonds of the United States. An ample income, indicated by general expenditure, may be derived either from such sources already taxed or not taxable, or from trade and pro- fession, or from taxable securities, these last two being taxable, but 'taxable at very different rates. The assessors hence must rely on their knowledge and judgment in estimating the taxable property of this form. In a great and complicated society, with a mass of investments ramifying in all directions the assessors are here confronted with a task which the best of them could not execute satisfactorily. Even the most capable, most experienced and most conscientious assessors could not have sufficient knowl- edge and judgment. But only average capacity can be expected; experience is often lacking; and, even for conscientious assessors, the temptations to laxity are in many cases irresistible. Conse- quently, the taxation of this form of property is in high degree uncertain, irregular and unsatisfactory. It rests mainly on guess- JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 35 work; it is blind, and therefore unequal. Here is its greatest evil, though not its only evil. It is haphazard in its practical working, and hence demoralizing alike to taxpayers and to tax officials.' " KEPORT OF MARYLAND COMMISSION, 1888, PAGES 101, 103, 151 " The truth is, the existing system is so radically had, that the more you improve it the worse it becomes. This lies in the nature of things and nothing any Legislature can do can alter this condition of things. Experience and reason alike teach this, and in my opinion place it beyond controversy for all those who have eyes to see what it passing about them every day of their lives." ( The reason why our present system of taxation does not operate satisfactorily can be stated in a word; although it is on the face of it fair and simple, it is found in practice to be an impracticable theory, for a large portion of property escapes tax- ation, and that the property of those best able to bear the burdens of government, namely, the wealthy residents of cities. On the one hand, it is impossible to find this property, and to force men to make returns under oath, results invariably in perjury and demoralization, without discovery of property; on the other hand, federal laws over which our States and municipalities have no control, enable many to escape taxation by investments, often temporary, in federal bonds, exempt from taxation. " Personal property is sometimes discovered in its entirety, but it is then nearly always the property of the comparatively helpless, namely, widows and orphans, whose possessions are a matter of public record. Less often a burden is imposed upon the conscientious. Thus, I happen to know of one wealthy town >f a few thousand inhabitants, where three men of conscientious sonvictions with regard to a man's duty to the commonwealth, pay taxes on their personalty, although they have as good an op- portunity to escape as others. This state of things naturally produces dissatisfaction on the part of farmers and other hard working people, who feel that personalty ought to bear a share of the burden of taxation. On this account they suggest various :hings, like taxation of mortgages, and a more vigorous search 36 STATE OF NEW YORK for hidden property. Their aim, as I have said, is commendable, but to attempt to reach the desired goal by direct means, under existing laws, or any laws which do not imply a change of the system of taxation, is as Utopian as the dream of the most radi- cal socialist. If we desire to accomplish a purpose we must use means adequate to the end in view. * " Another aspect of this case is presented by the facts of com- petition in business. Those who escape the payment of a fair share of business taxes have an advantage in business which en- ables them to undersell their competitors, and when a business man sees ruin staring him in the face because his dishonest neighbor makes false returns and pays taxes on only a fractional part of his property, the temptation to do likewise is almost irresistible, except for moral heroes, and moral heroism cannot be made the basis of governmental action." KEPORT OF KENTUCKY SPECIAL COMMISSION, 1912, PAGES 83-84 " In 1904 the total roll was $630,795,464, and monies, credits and securities were assessed at $68,829,446, or 10.9 per cent. " In 1911 the total roll was $846,450,020, and monies, credits and securities were assessed at $83,468,030, or 9.8 per cent. " In 1906 the ratio was 10.8 per cent. " In 1907 the ratio was 11.5 per cent. " In 1908 the ratio was 10.1 per cent. " In 1910 the ratio was 9.5 per cent. " As we said in our preliminary report : The State of Kentucky received more revenue for the year 1912 from its dogs than it did from all the bonds, monies and stocks in the State." " When finally we note that money, credits and securities taxed in 1910, the year of the census, were $79,000,000 or only $34 per capita, the necessity for further research seems to disappear. " Nobody can seriously maintain that all monies, credits and securities are taxed or any substantial part. " In the opinion of the Commission, the present methods of taxing money and credits are ineffective in producing revenue and highly unjust in their operation on individual taxpayers. They constitute one of the gravest problems connected with our JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 37 system of taxation, and until they are changed our tax laws will remain vitally and fundamentally defective." REPORT OF VIRGINIA TAX COMMISSION, 1911, PAGES 69-70 ' To summarize, it has appeared that inequalities and under- valuations of every sort appear in our taxation of personal property. How extensive these are can only be surmised; how iniquitous they are can merely be imagined. Viewing the situ- ation as a whole, the writer believes that it would be better to remove the tax on personal property altogether and seek other sources of revenue, than to perpetuate the frauds, inequalities and undervaluations which now encumber the administration of our tax laws. "A law which permits these things is unquestionably a failure, and it behooves those interested in the problem to ascertain why and wherein the law has broken down. Examination has shown that the failure of the property tax in Virginia may be traced to four things. These are, first, the attempted enforcement of a law under industrial conditions which render it inoperative of necessity and invalidate the theory upon which it is based; second, the failure of many commissioners of the revenue to en- force the existing laws; third, certain defects in the law which make deceit and injustice easy; fourth, the growth of a feeling among our people that there is nothing dishonorable or discredit- able in ( dodging taxes.' ' REPORT or NATIONAL TAX ASSOCIATION, VOL. IV, PAGES 309^- 310 " To sum up, your Committee finds : ' That the general property tax system has broken down ; ' That it has not been more successful under strict administra- tion than where the administration is lax; 1 That in the States where its administration has been the most stringent, the tendency of public opinion and legislation is not towards still more stringent administration, but towards a mod- ification of the system; ( That the same tendency is evident in the States where the administration has been more lax ; 38 STATE OF NEW YORK " That the States which have modified or abandoned the gen- eral property tax show no intention of returning to it ; " That in the States where the general property tax is required by constitutional provisions, there is a growing demand for the repeal of such provisions. " We conclude, therefore, that the failure of the general prop- erty tax is due to the inherent defects of the theory ; " That even measurably fair and effective administration is unattainable; and that all attempts to strengthen such adminis- tration serve simply to accentuate and to prolong the inequalities and unjust operation of the system." SUMMARY OF REPORTS OF NEW YORK COMMISSIONS The New York authorities are all to the same effect. "A more unequal, unjust, and partial system for taxation could not well be devised.' 7 (First Annual Report of the State As- sessors, 1860, p. 12.) " The defects of our system are too glaring and operate too oppressively to be longer tolerated." (Comptroller's Report, 1859.) " The burdens are so heavy and inequalities so gross as almost to paralyze and dishearten the people." (Assessor's Report, 1873, p. 3.) " The absolute inefficiency of the old rickety statutes passed in a bygone generation is patent to all." (Assessors' Report, 1877, p. 5.) " The hope of obtaining satisfactory results from the present broken, shattered, leaky laws, in vain." (Report Association of Taxes and Assessments, 1876, p. 52.) " The system is a farce, sham, humbug." (Assessors' Report of 1879, p. 23.) ' The present result is a travesty upon our taxing system, which aims to be equal and just." (Comptroller's Report, 1889, p. 34.) The general property tax is a reproach to the State, an out- rage upon the people, a disgrace to the civilization of the Nine- teenth Century, and worthy only of an age of mental and moral darkness and degradation when " the only equal rights were those of the equal robber." (Comptroller's Report, 1889, p. 34.) JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 39 The above quotations from the ^ew York reports are taken from Seligman's Essays in Taxation. REPORT OF 1872 The report of the Commission of 1872, of which Mr. David A. W T e!ls was chairman, was one of the ablest tax reports ever writ- ten. We, therefore, quote from it at some length : " In the case of New York, no one, either officials or citizens, is satisfied with the existing system or its administration ; and so apparent, moreover, are its defects, that the necessity of reform is almost universally acknowledged. But the Commissioners, who have made the system a matter of special study and inquiry, go further, and unqualifiedly assert that, as it exists to-day it is more imperfect in theory and defective in administration than almost any system that has ever existed, and that its longer recog- nition and continuance is alike prejudicial to the material interest of the State and the morality of its people." Real property being visible and tangible, presents no inherent difficulty in the way of assessment, and the system might be rea- sonably supposed to work with some degree of uniformity and equality, yet they found it impossible to find any two contiguous towns, cities or counties in which the valuation of real estate approximates in any degree to uniformity. "It is evident that the law in this respect has become a dead letter and wholly inoperative. The attempts to tax personal property under the same system are infinitely more farcical and disgraceful." The reasons for the failure are as follows: In the first place, a large part of personal property " is incor- poreal and invisible, easy of transfer and concealment, not ad- mitting of valuation by comparison with any common standard, and the situs or locality of which for purposes of assessment and taxation, involves some of the oldest, most controverted and yet unsettled questions of law. * * * It is obvious, therefore, that the law contemplates the doing of an act * * which cannot be done without the fullest co-operation through com- munication of information, of the taxpayer himself; and yet for the imparting of which the two most powerful influences that can 40 STATE OF NEW YORK control human action, viz., love of gain and the desire to avoid publicity in respect to one's private affairs, co-operate to oppose." REPORT OF 1893 The taxation of personal property is " unsatisfactory and un- just, and if no better plan of administration be devised and carried into effect than that now in existence, it is idle and worse than useless to attempt the taxation of personalty, however ob- jectionable the alternative." (Report of Counsel to Revise the Tax Laws of the State of New York, 1893.) REPORT or 1900 The Joint Committee on Taxation for the year 1900 likewise found that the personal property tax was a failure, and did not believe any reform would remedy the situation unless the listing system were adopted. This, however, the committee was unwilling to recommend. It found that while the first returns were ap- parently good under the listing system, it eventually drove capital out of the State. REPORT OF 1907 " The principal difficulty connected with our system of local revenue is the taxation of personal property. * * It is a universally accepted maxim that direct taxation of the citizen should be nearly as possible in proportion to his ability to pay. The actual situation in New York involves in practice the very inverse of this principle." As a result of its study the committee concluded : " (1) That there has been gradual and steady increase in the value of real and personal property ; " (2) That personal property escapes paying its share of the burden ; "(3) That the greater the amount of personal property placed on the rolls, the larger the cancellations or reductions ; " (4) That the burden falls heaviest on the residents of our State and the smaller taxpayer ; " (5) That the nonresidents have almost ceased to pnv taxes; " (6) That the collection of the personal property tax has be- come more and more difficult." JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 41 CHAPTER II CAUSES OF THE FAILURE OF THE PERSONAL PROPERTY TAX Briefly stated, the objections to the personal property tax and the reasons for its failure are as follows : (1) Inequality of assessments. (a) As between towns. It is notorious, and the facts to be submitted later will show beyond question, that in some towns personal property is assessed at something like true values, whereas in others no attempt whatsoever is made to reach the personal property of either corporations or individuals, or if it is reached, it is assessed at a value insignificant as compared with true value. This has a tendency to produce throughout the State " isles of safety " or residential districts desirable from a tax standpoint for both individuals and corporations who, by establishing a nominal residence, and by the payment of a small or nominal tax, in one town, are enabled to escape their proportion of the taxes in the town in which they actually reside. Thus, the one town is enabled to increase its tax base and lower its rate, while the other is deprived of large amounts of taxable property and is obliged to tax that which remains within its juristiction at a higher rate. (b) As between citizens of the same town. The system is practically one of self -assessment, under which the dishonest man who is willing to swear off his taxes, does so at the expense of the honest man whose conscience does not permit him to do so. (2) The personal property tax at a general property rate, let us say 2 per cent, is confiscatory and an actual incentive to dis- honesty. Two per cent is the equivalent of 50 per cent of the income of a 4 per cent bond, and no country in the world in normal times has or can successfully impose a 50 per cent income tax. The taxpayer will not submit to it, particularly when he knows that thousands of fellow citizens, in many cases with in- comes much larger than his own, are actually evading its payment. (3) The theory underlying the general property tax is that both real and personal property should be taxed at the same rate and on the same basis. Without at this time discussing the sound- ness of this particular theory, as a matter of practice, real estate bears practically the entire burden, while personal property, 42 STATE OF NEW YORK though theoretically liable, fails to contribute its share to the support of government. (4) The deduction of debts invites fraud and evasion, yet not to allow deduction of debts is in some cases double taxation. As has been said, " Individuals should be taxed on what they own, . not on what they owe." This, of course, is not true in the case of many corporations that obtain most of their working capital by issuing bonds. (5) The personal property tax is unequal as between different grades of property. It falls with equal weight upon unproductive property, on property yielding comparatively small income, and on property bringing in a very large return. (6) Under modern conditions, property no longer represents the true test of ability to pay. In a simple agricultural com- munity, where personalty is for the most part tangible and visible, property furnishes a fairly equal measure of a man's ability to contribute to the support of government ; but under modern busi- ness development this is by no means the case. Take the case of the merchant with a large turnover and a comparatively low profit. His ability to pay taxes is by no means the equal of that of the merchant with a small stock of goods, a rapid turnover and large profits; yet under the personal property tax the former rather than the latter will pay the larger tax. Take the case of the manufacturer. The one may own a very large plant with complicated, expensive machinery, and the necessities of his business may require him to carry a large inventory. He may earn but a small return on his investment. Another manufacturer in another line may have a smaller plant, much less valuable ma- chinery, a comparatively light inventory, and yet because of the nature of his business may have a greater income. Here again the ability of the latter to contribute is greater than that of the former, yet the former under the personal property tax pays the heavier share. As between individuals, the lawyer earning $50,000 a year pays nothing on the taxable ability represented by these large earnings, while the widow or the retired busi- ness man or wage-earner with $500 a year derived from accumu- lated savings of $10,000 is compelled to turn over $200 of it to the tax gatherer. The investor who makes an unwise invest- ment from which he gets little or no return pays as much as the JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 43 fortunate individual enjoying fat dividends; the man with a large unearned income and extravagant habits gets off scotfree, while the thrifty one who in spite of a lower earning capacity and less ability to pay taxes manages to lay something aside is taxed on the evidences of his thrift. (7) Personal property under modern conditions consists for the most part of securities, credits and other intangibles, easy of concealment and which cannot be discovered without the co-operation of the taxpayer himself, a co-operation which the taxpayer declines to furnish, and which experience has demon- strated cannot be compelled. Moreover, the large accumulations of wealth in form of intangibles are usually concentrated in the great cities under conditions which make it well-nigh impossible for the assessors to locate the owners a complete change from the conditions under which the personal property tax was adopted, when life was simple, wealth fairly equally distributed, when people lived in villages or small towns, and when each man knew not only what his neighbor owned, but what property of his was assessed. Even in so far as tangible personalty is concerned, con- sider the difficulty which confronts the average assessor who may be required to assess accurately anything from a Rembrandt pic- ture to a large modern industrial plant. The fact is that, at the wages paid which in many instances do not exceed three dollars a day it is impossible to obtain any man with a sufficient accumulation of knowledge to enable him to deal successfully with a field so wide as to include within its range practically every form of property found in a complicated society. (8) The great number of exempt securities makes it possible for the wise investor lawfully to escape personal property taxation, leaving the tax to fall on those not sufficiently fortunately situated to obtain wise legal advice and on those ignorant of the law. CHAPTER III INJUSTICE OF THE PERSONAL PROPERTY TAX All semblance of justice and equity has long since left the personal property tax, which has been suffered to remain on our statute books because of the widespread apathy and ignorance of the public in regard to taxation, and because of the fact that it has not, generally speaking, been enforced. 44 STATE OF NEW YORK (1) As Between Tangible and Intangible Personalty. Tangible property can be seen; intangible property cannot be seen. Tax assessors find it comparatively easy, therefore, to discover tangible property, while they have the greatest difficulty in locating in- tangible property. Everywhere the result is the same not only is a much larger proportion of tangible property reached for the purposes of taxation, but that proportion reached bears a much higher rate of taxation as a result of the escape of intangibles. The inequity is further accentuated by the fact that those most able to pay have their wealth largely invested in intangibles and that those least able to pay have their wealth largely invested in tangibles. The magnitude of this' injustice will appear as we examine the effect of this tax upon the rich as compared to the poor, upon the widows and orphans, upon the farmers as compared with owners of other forms of wealth and upon the struggling business as compared to the well-established business. In every case the inequity increases with the inability of the particular classes to bear taxes. 2. As Between the Poor and the Wealthy. Not only do the poor and those in only moderate circumstances have their wealth invested in easily seen and easily taxed tangibles, but the kind of tangible personalty in which the poor man invests his money, whether it be in his household effects or in his small business, is of such nature that the ordinary tax assessor is familiar with it and can therefore assess at well-nigh its true value. This is true as well of the tangible personalty that makes up the small business concern as of the tangible personalty included in the household goods and other personal effects. In the case of the wealthy man, however, the case is a very different one. Not only is a large part of his wealth ordinarily invested in intangibles, but much of his tangible personalty, whether that of his personal ef- fects or that of his business, is of a kind that the ordinary assessor (in his daily life) is unfamiliar with, and it is also of a kind that is difficult of valuation. This is true not only of the wealthy individual but of the wealthy corporation as well. In regard to the former, the valuation of such property as jewelry, works of art, books, etc., require a knowledge and skill not possessed by the average assessor. In regard to the rich corpo- JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 45 rations, such as mercantile corporations, carrying large stocks of fine fabrics, jewelry, etc., and those manufacturing corporations having machinery of great value as well as large stocks of products in the process of manufacture, the experience of forty-eight states of the Union discloses with unmistakable clearness that the average assessor does not and cannot assess these subjects with any degree of fairness. When we come to investment in securities, a large investor usually has the knowledge, or can obtain such advice, as will enable him to invest in tax-exempt securities, while the small investors, particularly women, are apt, through ignorance, to invest in taxable bonds. 3. Concerning Widows and Orphans and Trust Estates. If there is one group of property which should escape with reasonable taxation, it would seem to be that property the income from which is set aside for the .support and education of those who have been deprived through death of the head of the family, viz., the widows and the orphans. When the chief bread-winner dies, a record of his property must be filed in the probate court, where it is easily accessible to the tax assessors. Here it is caught and taxed, while similar property held by others is untaxed. Were it taxed at only a fair rate, it would still be questionable whether this property ought not to be partially exempt. However, it is not taxed at a fair rate, but at a rate which makes the personal prop- erty tax in this case one of the most barbarous to be found in any country. Cases are frequent where as high as 25 to 50 per cent of the total income set aside for the support of widows and orphans is taken by this tax. How serious the situation is was well ex- emplified by investigation made by one of the witnesses who ap- peared before the Committee. He stated that he found that in one county (not in the State of New York) the roll showed that about 20 to 25 per cent of the personal property taxes were paid by women. It will, of course, be readily agreed that women do not own anything like 25 per cent, of personal property in any state. Another witness told us of a woman whose husband had died leav- ing an estate all invested in 4 per cent bonds. The woman was assessed by !N"ew York City's Tax Department for the full value of the bonds. There was no possibility of getting the tax re- 46 STATE OF NEW YORK duced. Counsel advised her to change her investments, but she refused to do that because her husband had made them, so she was obliged to leave the city and change her residence. A simple example will illustrate how this tax works. Assume that a prudent head of a family had been able to save $15,000 which had been invested in municipal bonds yielding four per cent. The annual income to the widow would be $600. At a tax rate of 2 per cent, on the value of this personal property, the widow would be compelled to surrender $300 to the tax authorities or one-half of her total income. In some localities tax rates have risen as high as three or four per cent, and cases are not unknown where, had the tax law been enforced, the widow would have been deprived of her entire income. Indeed, cases are known where the tax has not only absorbed all of the income, but has compelled the owner to pay an additional amount. In the 1915 New York Tax Conference, Mr. Lawson Purdy cited such a case. Before the December, 1915, hearings of the Joint Legislative Committee on Taxation, Professor Charles J. Bullock of Harvard University testified that cases of such gross injustice amounting to the taking of from one-third to one-half of the income of widows and orphans were not infrequent where the general property rate was applied to personalty. Upon this point, the Report of the Massachusetts Tax 'Commission for 1908 speaks as follows: " The situation is made worse by the fact that the local tax rates throughout the country are so high that they take from the holder of good securities an excessive proportion of his income. According to the United .States census, the average rate levied upon property assessed for local taxation in the United States in 1902 was about 2 per cent, of the capital value thereof, or as tax rates are usually reckoned in Massachusetts, $20 on each $1,000 of the assessed valuation. In many places real estate was so far undervalued that a tax of 2 per cent, upon the assessed value may not have amounted to more than 1 per cent, or even one- half of one per cent, of the true value of the property. But per- sonal property, if returned for taxation, must be valued usually at its true cash value; and it is clear that a tax rate of 2 per cent, may take from the holder one-third or one-half of his in- come. Under such circumstances few persons can or will make JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 47 returns of their personal estates ; and the usual result is that this property is taxed by the method of arbitrary estimate, or ' doomage ? . When returns are made they come usually from trustees and executors of small estates, who cannot easily evade the law, and have less inducement to do so. Thus it comes about that the mx on personal property bears with exceptional severity upon widows and orphans, the most helpless class in the commu- nity, and is most easily evaded by the rich and powerful, who can best afford to pay it. Instances have come to the attention of members of the present Commission in which widows are paying upon small estates taxes that take as much as 40 or 50 per cent, of the income; whereas in the same communities men whose tax- able property would probably amount to millions are paying a few hundred dollars of personal taxes upon merely nominal assess- ments. These conditions are not peculiar to Massachusetts, they have been repeatedly disclosed by the reports of tax com- missions in other States; and among students of American taxa- tion it has become a mere truism that our present taxes upon personal property actually fall upon the taxpayers in inverse proportion to their ability to pay." 4. As Between Farms and Oilier Forms of Wealth. That the farmers bear a disproportionate share of taxation is gen- erally known and accepted by most of the informed throughout the United States. It is not generally known by the farmers or the public at large, however, to what an extreme degree this dis- proportion is carried. It is, of course, well known that most of a farmer's personalty is in a tangible form, and that it cannot be hidden from the tax assessor. Wherever the law is enforced the farmers' machinery and implements, his stock and other tan- gibles not; only pay a much higher rate than their share, but a rate out of all proportion to the earning power of such property. This disproportionate rate is, of course, largely made up of that part of the tax burden that is evaded by other forms of wealth. The full significance of this inequity cannot be grasped without comparing the rates upon agricultural property and in- come with that of the other principal industries of the State. A study of California in this regard is of much value to New York. A few years ago a very careful investigation was made 48 STATE OF NEW YORK of the relative tax burdens borne by the various classes of wealth in California, and the results of this investigation were set forth in the 1906 California Tax report. Most of the statistics given immediately below are either copied from that report or represent computations based upon the data there set forth. The following table taken from page 68 of this report is a comparative statement of manufacturing industries and agriculture in respect to the capital investment, percentage of total capital value invested in realty and personalty, and percentage of each taxed: COMPARISON OP TAXES ON MANUFACTURING AND FARMS IN CALFORNIA Percentage of total capital Aggregates Manufac- Agricul- Manufactures Agriculture tures ture Capital total $205, 395, 025 $796, 527, 955 100.0 100.0 Land 34, 735, 416 \ 630, 444, 960 16.9 79.0 Buildings 22, 562, 385 77, 468, 000 11.0 9.7 Machinery, resp. imple- ments 62, 440, 759 21,311,670 30.4 2.7 Other assets 85,656,465 67, 303, 325 41.7 8.5 Assessed value 63, 500, 000 474, 731, 497 31.0 65.0 Taxes 1, 049, 932 9, 030, 000 .51 1.14 Gross produce 302, 874, 761 131, 690, 606 147.0 16.5 Net product 52, 172, 862 91, 419, 866 25.4 11.5 Taxes of gross .346 6.86 Taxes of net product 2.01 9.88 This table discloses some very interesting facts; and these facts are of considerable interest to New York, because they illustrate a condition in California very similar to the one now prevailing in New York 'State. At least this is true in so far as they illustrate the inequity existing between farm property and that of other forms of wealth. It should be remembered, how- ever, that the actual inequity as between these two forms of wealth is probably greater in New York than in California. The above table shows that while agriculture pays 6.86 per cent of its gross product in taxes, manufactures pay only .34 per cent or one-third of 1 per cent. In other words, measured in terms of gross product, the tax burden upon agriculture was about twenty times as heavy as that upon manufactures. In terms of net product, the disproportion, though not so extreme, is still very large. The table shows that while manufacturers pay JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 49 2.01 per cent of net products in taxes, agriculture pays 9.88 per cent in taxes. In other words, the tax burden measured in terms of net product is nearly five times upon agriculture what it is upon manufacture. It should be noted here that this statement is based upon the assumption that manufactures pay approximately 2 per cent of net income in California. This rate is probably higher than that borne by manufactures in New York State. Statistics such as those gathered by the Federal Census indicate that the proportion borne by manufactures in New York is less. These facts are brought out in more detail in part VIII of this report which deals with the taxation of manufacturing corporations. The following table summarizes the tax burdens borne by Cali- fornia farms : Per cent of taxes to true value 1 . 14 Per cent of taxes to gross returns 6.86 Per cent of taxes to net returns, including farmer's own compensation and certain expenses 9 . 88 The following tabulation compares the percentage of tax paid by farms and manufactures : Ratio of farm taxes to manufac* Farms Manufactures turing taxes Percentage paid on capital value 1.14% 1/2 of 1% 3 to 1 Percentage paid on gross income 7.00% 1/3 of 1% 20 to 1 Percentage paid on net income 10.00% 2 % 5 to 1 In regard to the comparative burdens borne by various kinds of wealth in New York State, no study similar to that of Cali- fornia has been made with the same degree of care and thorough- ness. The New York problem is much more complex than that of California. The multiplicity of corporation taxes at varying rates and upon different bases makes the difficulties of a similar study for New York almost insurmountable. We have, however, sufficient data to justify a rough comparison between New York and California and between New York and states like Minnesota and Michigan that have also made studies similar to that of California. These comparisons all indicate that the disparity as between agriculture and other forms of wealth is even greater in New York. An examination of Minnesota's experience is pertinent. The 50 STATE OF NEW YORK following facts are gathered from the experience of Minnesota as it appears in the 1908 Report of the State Tax Commission of Minnesota (pp. 54-5) : " The special commission on revenue and taxation of 1906 ap- pointed by the governor of California declared that the per- centage of taxes to the gross products for manufactures in that state was .346, or about one-third of 1 per cent; for agriculture the relation of taxes to total product was 6.86 per cent. On the net product of manufactures the commission found the relation of taxes to be 2.01 per cent, and for agriculture 9.88 per cent. The basis of these figures is the United States census of 1900. Applying the same methods and the same data to Minnesota, a somewhat different result is obtained. Expressed in the terms of product, the percentages of taxes to the returns secured from manufacturing and agriculture are as follows : " Taxes to gross product Manufacturing 3223% Agriculture 4.7200% " Taxes to net product Manufacturing 2 . 0480% Agriculture 6 . 8850% " TABLE SHOWING COMPARISON OF AGGREGATES AND PERCENTAGES OF INVEST- MENTS IN MANUFACTURES AND AGRICULTURE IN MINNESOTA Aggregates Percentages Capital Items Land Manufactures $29, 548, 954 Agriculture Manufactures $559,301,900 17.810 110,220,415 11.980 30,099,230 22.886 89,063,097 47.324 Agriculture 70.90 13.97 3.83 11.30 Buildings . 19, 850 136 Machinery 37, 953, 943 Other assets 78 479 213 Total capital $165, 832, 246 $788, 684, 642 100 . 00 100 . 00 " The assessed value of manufactures was $32,509,514, and of agriculture $299,567,765. Reduced to percentages, the rela- tion of the assessment of manufactures to capital was 19.6 per cent, and of agriculture, 37.9 per cent. The manufactures paid $846,570 in taxes and agriculture $7,609,021; in other words, .51 per cent and .96 per cent, respectively, of their capital values. The gross product of the manufacturers of the State amounted to $262,655,881, or 158.3 per cent of the capital in- vested in manufactures, and the agricultural product was $161,- 217,304, or 20.4 per cent of the capital invested. In the case of the net product, the manufactures of the state earned $41,318,- JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 51 363, or 24.9 per cent on their capital, and agricultural interests $111,050,884, or 14.08 per cent. " Manufacturers pay a little more than 2 per cent on their net product, and farmers pay more than three and one-third times as much as when measured on the same basis; and on the basis of gross product the farmer pays more than eleven and one-half times the amount turned in by the manufacturer for taxes. On a net income basis the manufacturer pays 2 per cent of it for taxes, but the farmer pays nearly 7 per cent of his net income, which includes the benefits he receives from his garden, poultry, etc. And, further, the farmer's net income includes his reward for management as well as interest return. These items make the difference still more marked. " These are eloquent figures. While the commission is not ready to accept them in their full meaning as conclusive, they do show clearly the general situation." The experience of Michigan is also of much value, although the disparity between farms and manufactures is probably not so great as it is in the State of New York. The following table is taken from the 1911 " Report of the Commission of Inquiry Into Taxation of Michigan" (page 9). It gives the rate of taxes per thousand of actual value for farms, banks, residence, railroads, manufacturing corporations, public service corporations and mines. It also gives a comparison of the value and taxes paid by each of these classes except residences : Values Taxes Rate per $1.000 City real estate $14.85 Farms $1, 000, 000, 000 $10, 000, 000 10.00 Banks and trust companies .... 75, 000, 000 1, 250, 000 17.00 Railroads 212, 000, 000 4, 378, 000 20.65 Sleeping car, express, car loaning and telephone and telegraph companies 24, 000, 000 493, 000 20.67 Manufactures 750, 000, 000 3, 938, 000 5.31 Mines 250, 000, 000 1, 750, 000 7.00 Electric railway, power, heat, light and gas companies 130, 000, 000 900, 000 7.00 An examination of this table discloses the fact that manufac- tures bear the lowest rate of taxation of any class of wealth in Michigan, this rate being about one-fifth of that of the public service corporations, about one-half that of farm property and 52 STATE OF NEW YORK about one-third that of city real estate. This table is of value in so far as it throws light upon the disproportion of the tax burden. It should be clearly borne in mind, however, that the dispro- portion between manufactures and farms is very much less than in either California or New York. In view of the great inequality as between the actual assess- ment of farmers and manufacturers, it is of considerable interest to know whether any compensation is found in the difference in their tax-paying ability. The following quotation from page 66 of the 1906 California Report is very clear upon this point: " The same facts may be exhibited in another way. After allowing $2,446,238 for the average annual increase in value of farm property and taking 6 per cent as interest on the value of farm property, the census estimates that the 145,801 persons en- gaged in agriculture earned an average of $499.70 in 1899. The 113,155 persons engaged in manufactures earned an average of $870. " It would seem, then, that from the per capita earnings manu- facturers could afford to pay nearly 75 per cent more taxes than could the farmers. As a matter of fact, however, the farmers pay 10 per cent of their net earnings and manufacturers only 2 per cent of their net earnings." The present personal property tax works a severe hardship upon the property of farmers, irrespective of whether the tax is rigidly enforced or not. If the tax is actually enforced upon the personalty of farmers it obviously lays a highly dispropor- tionate burden upon that part of the farmer's wealth. In an- swer to this statement it is often said that the personal property tax does not discriminate against the farmer inasmuch as the average assessor does not actually assess any considerable amount of the tangible personalty found upon farms. It is true that to the extent that an individual farmer is underassessed by the local tax officer he escapes a certain part of a highly dispropor- tionate burden. It is utterly fallacious, however, to infer that in escaping to this extent the farmer is freed from the inequities of the personal property tax. The greatest injustice to the farmer arises from the indirect results of the almost complete failure of the general property tax as applied to personalty in general. When practically one-half of the tax base escapes in JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 53 the form of personalty, the rate upon the remaining half must be double what the rate would be, were it levied uniformly upon the entire base. To the extent, therefore, that anyone's wealth is composed of real estate, to just that extent does he bear an in- creased disproportionate share of the tax burden. A reference to the above tables from the California report is illuminating at this point. The first table shows that 79 per cent of the total value of agriculture is invested in land and that 88.7 per cent is invested in land and buildings. Manufactures, on the other hand, have invested in land only 16.9 per cent of total capital and only 27.9 per cent in land and buildings. Per- sonalty of manufactures makes up 72.1 per cent, of which not less than 50 per cent is intangible. The significance of these figures must not be overlooked. They show not only that that part of the fair share of personalty escaping taxation is borne to a very large degree by agriculture, but that that particular bur- den is partly accounted for by the failure of the assessors to reach the very large per cent of the capital of manufacturing and other corporations that is represented by personalty. It must not be understood that manufactures represent the only group of wealth that shoves off part of its tax burden upon the farmer. The manufacturing industry has been used for pur- poses of illustration, and did space permit, it could be shown that other business corporations as well as some of the public service and financial corporations fail to bear a tax burden proportion- ately as heavy as that of agriculture. In answer to the above arguments it is often said that the farmer suffers no injustice because as his tax burden increases, the value of his land increases. Wherever the increase in value of his land assumes the form of the so-called " unearned incre- ment ", this fact may be true in those particular cases in which the increment is as large as the tax increase. In those cases, how- ever, where the increased value of the farm has been due to the labor and capital investment of the farmer, it cannot be truth- fully said that the increased value " takes care of " the increase in the tax burden. In any case where the property has not in- creased in value, the increased burden is a heavy one. In summing up the case of the farmer, the evidence is well nigh overwhelming that the general property tax in so far as it 54: STATE OF NEW YORK pertains to personalty, directly or indirectly, imposes on him an increasingly disproportionate burden. 5. Injustice as Between Various Types and Classes of Enter- prises. As the personal property tax is now levied in New York, it constitutes not only a serious impediment to the development of some businesses, but a constant annoyance to many branches of business. It is unjust as between various units of business and types of corporations. It is unjust as between mercantile and manufacturing corporations and it is unfair to corporations within the same group. The extreme to which this unfairness is carried is illustrated by the ridiculous differences in the per- centage of personalty assessment to total assessment in the same counties. In the same type of business, the ratio of personalty to realty sometimes varies from 1 to 2, to 1 to 75. In the same town the personalty of manufactures escapes while the personalty of mercantile corporations is assessed. Moreover, local mercan- tile corporations are taxed upon personalty, while foreign corpor- ations, doing large business next door and carrying large stocks of personalty, are taxed neither in the locality nor at their domicile. The unfairness as between manufacturing corporations of nearby competing towns is often very great. In fact the present investigation discloses the fact that in general throughout the State of New York the personal property tax bears to business the relation of an unmitigated nuisance. Were the law fully enforced, it would drive business out of New York ; with present sporadic enforcement it falls with inequality and injustice. 6. As Between the Various Counties in New York State. Reference to the comparative statistical tables in the Appendix will show with what wide difference personalty is actually assessed in the different counties of the State. When the direct State tax is levied, the inequalities in the assessment of real estate are partly remedied by equalization. With personalty, however, all inequalities remain, because the board of equalization does not equalize personal property, but accepts the returns of the various counties. Thus the more efficient the personal property tax is levied in any county, the higher the percentage of the direct State tax that county is required to pay. In other words, the present law penalizes every county in proportion to its efficiency in enforcing the law. PART IV FAILURE OF THE PERSONAL PROPERTY TAX IN NEW YORK One of the main purposes for which this Joint Legislative Com- mittee on Taxation was appointed was to seek out that property which is now escaping and to recommend changes that would equalize the tax burden by broadening the base. For many years it has been the belief of a large number of tax- payers that the weakest point in our present system is the per- sonal property tax; and this applies both to the individuals and the corporations. For that reason the Committee early deter- mined to make a most careful investigation into the working of the personal property tax. CHAPTER I GENERAL SCOPE OF THE COMMITTEE'S INVESTIGATION At one time or another the Committee has attempted to investi- gate by every known method the success or failure of the personal property tax. In this investigation the Committee approached the subject by not less than eleven different avenues, as follows : (1) An investigation of the assessment of the personal prop- erty tax in the sixty-two counties of the State by means of cor- respondence with local officers, such as the clerks of the board of supervisors, county treasurers, etc. (2) An investigation of the same subject by means of inspect- ing the records on file in the office of the State Board of Tax Commissioners. (3) An investigation in which investigators were sent into a selected list of counties to examine the records in the offices of the town and county collectors, assessors, etc., as well as the records, so far as certificates of incorporation were concerned, filed in the county recorders' offices. (4) An examination of data gathered by an employee of the State Board of Tax Commissioners in regard to the assessment of corporations in a particular county under Section 12. (5) An examination of data furnished by a member of the 56 STATE OF NEW YORK Constitutional Convention in regard to the assessment of the per- sonal property of corporations under Section 12 in another county that had been called to the Committee's attention. (6) An investigation of the records of the Commissioners of Taxes and Assessments of the City of New York for the years 1908, 1909, 1910, 1911, 1912, 1913 and 1914, containing data as to the following points : (a) The tentative personal property assessment of resi- dent personal, estates, corporations resident and corporations nonresident. (b) The amounts cancelled. (c) The amount retained on the final assessment rolls. (7) An examination of three reports prepared within recent years upon the same subject. (8) An investigation into the amount of personal property taxes paid by some two hundred corporations selected at random, information concerning which could not be found in Moody's Manual, Poor's Manual and elsewhere. (9) An investigation into the personal property tax paid by another list of some 250 corporations selected at random by means of statements furnished by the corporations themselves. (10) An examination of the Federal Census Eeports as to the relative percentages of personal property tax collected in New York and other states. (11) An examination of data filed by the State Comptroller and the State Board of Tax Commissioners as to the relative increase and decrease of personal property tax and other taxes, and as to the effect of the method of reaching certain forms of personalty by means of specific taxes upon the yield of that part of the personal property tax assessed at the general property rate. In the first place, the Committee attempted, through the local officers, viz., the clerks of the boards of supervisors, clerks of the county treasurers, etc., to obtain information concerning the success of the personal property tax in the sixty-two counties of the State. At the time of this investigation letters were sent to one or more of these local officers in every one of the counties, and an effort was made at different times to obtain information upon some twelve or fifteen points that might be used in one way or JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 57 another as a basis for an estimate of the success or failure of the personal property tax. The results of the Committee's effort along this line of investigation, after repeated attempts, were very dis- couraging. Some of the local officers attempted by every means to assist the Committee in this investigation, and the Committee is indebted especially to the officers in a number of localities for considerable work and some valuable material. In the hope of obtaining more complete information in regard to the amount of personal property tax collected from resident natural persons, resident corporations, nonresident natural per- sons and nonresident corporations, the Committee investigated the statistical information which is filed in the Department of Statistics of the State Board of Tax Commissioners. 'Section 61 of the Tax Law provides as follows : " Statement of valuation to be forwarded to state board of tax commissioners. The clerk of each board of supervisors shall, on or before the second Monday in December, transmit to the state board of tax commissioners in the form to be prescribed by such state board of tax commissioners a certificate or return of the aggregate assessed and equalized valuation of the real and personal estate in each tax district as the valuation of such real estate has been corrected by such board, and the amount of tax assessed thereon for town, city, school, county and state pur- poses. Also the aggregate assessed valuation of personal prop- erty classified as follows : " 1. Property of resident natural persons assessed pursuant to section twenty-one. " 2. Property held by agents, trustees, guardians, executors or administrators, assessed pursuant to sections eight and thirty-three. " 3. Property of domestic corporations assessed pursuant to section twelve. " 4. Property of nonresident natural persons assessed pursuant to subdivision one of section seven. " 5. Property of nonresident natural persons assessed pursu- ant to subdivision two of section seven. " 6. Property of foreign corporations assessed pursuant to sec- tion seven. 58 STATE OF NEW YORK " In the City of New York such report shall be made by the department of taxes and assessments. " The state board of tax commissioners shall certify to the comptroller, on his request, before the thirty-first of December in each year, such extracts or items, from the returns above men- tioned, as he may desire." Were this law followed, the Committee would be able to obtain a mass of valuable data for purposes of investigating the degree of success of the personal property tax in New York State. For the purposes of this investigation, the Committee's expert went through the records in the Bureau of Statistics of the State Board of Tax Commissioners at Albany. Of the sixty-two counties of the State, it was found that with the exception of four or five counties, none of them filed the complete information required by section 61 of the Tax Law. Of the six groups of informa- tion required by section 61, most of the counties failed to file in complete form most of the information required under subdi- vision 1. A few of the counties filled out sporadically the informa- tion required under subdivision 2. Unfortunately, nearly all of the counties failed to file the information required under subdi- vision 3. Inasmuch as the information required under subdivi- sion 3 relates to domestic corporations assessed pursuant to sec- tion 12, it was impossible to obtain the very data which was neces- sary for purposes of investigating the most important phase of the personal property tax in New York State. The information called for by subdivisions 4 and 5 was also lacking in more than 80 per cent of the counties. It was particularly unfortunate that this data was lacking. One of the important conclusions reached by the Special Tax Commission of 1906, was : (1) That the burden falls heaviest upon the residents of our own State, and principally upon the small taxpayer. (2) That nonresidents find it easier to escape taxation and have almost ceased to pay any tax. The failure of the local officers to return the information re- quired under subdivisions 4 and 5 rendered it impossible in this particular branch of the investigation to determine to what degree the conditions set forth by the 1906 Committee were still true. The data concerning the assessment of the property of foreign JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 59 corporations required to be filed by subdivision 6 of section 61, is also lacking from all but a very few of the reports filed with the Tax Commission. While from these records in themselves it would be impossible to conclude that foreign corporations escape their fair share to a large degree, yet the absence of this data, together with other information obtained, establishes a fair pre- sumption that the foreign corporations are not assessed for per- sonal property in most of the localities. Failing to obtain sufficient data for the purposes of anything like a complete investigation of the personal property tax in New York State, the Committee next resorted to the method of personal investigation. CHAPTER II PERSONAL INVESTIGATION IN THE SIX COUNTIES For the purposes of this report, the names of the counties are not given but are designated as " County A," " B," " C," " D," " E " and " F." The reason for this designation appears as fol- lows : In the time at the disposal of the Committee it was obvi- ously impossible to investigate by means of personal visits the enforcement of the personal property tax in all of the counties. Out of the sixty-two counties it was found possible to send an investigator into only six. Inasmuch as the investigation in these counties disclosed the fact that many of the local officials were not assessing personal property of corporations according to the law, it seemed unfair to give the names of the counties and towns. Were these six counties the only offenders against the law, it might be wise to publish the fact. But inasmuch as they were selected as representative counties, and inasmuch as the practice of the local officers is in all probability no worse in these six counties and the towns contained therein than in the rest of the State at large, it seems only fair to use them as typical of the State without sing- ling them out from the other counties. In justice to the truth, it ought to be said that the six counties discussed below, notwith- standing their deficiencies, actually came nearer to enforcing the law than some other counties which were not investigated by this method. County A. County A contains a large mercantile and manu- facturing city and seven towns, in most of which exist important 60 STATE OF NEW YOEK corporations claiming some town of the county as its principal place of business. An examination of the statistics gathered in this county reveals three striking facts. (1) There is the greatest inequality in the assessment of corporations as between the various localities within the county. (2) Considerable inequality exists as between mercantile and manufacturing corporations, most mercantile corporations being taxed, most manufacturing corporations escaping in whole or in part. (3) The ratio of the real property to personal property varies greatly throughout the county. The facts in regard to this county may be summarized as fol- lows: In one locality every mercantile corporation listed as paying real estate, also pays a personal property tax. (We have no way of determining whether or not the corporations pay all that they ought to pay under section 12.) Nearly every corporation claiming this town as the principal place of business, pays some- thing under section 12. In striking contrast to this locality stand the other seven towns of the county. Some of them contain large and important mercantile or manufacturing corporations. However, not a single one assesses a dollar's worth of personal property to manufactur- ing or mercantile corporations. These seven towns contain eleven mercantile corporations and fifty-seven manufacturing corporations listed as paying real property tax. All of these cor- porations, except fifteen, claim as their principal place of busi- ness one of the towns within the county, and therefore should pay personal property taxes at such place. As' to the exact extent of the evasion of the personal property tax by corporations in the county as a whole, it is very difficult to determine. There is no way by which the Committee, in the time at its disposal, could ascertain exactly what each corporation should pay, or how many corporations were liable for taxation under the law. The following figures, however, indicate that the evasion of the tax is widespread throughout the county. An examination of the certificates of incorporation filed in the JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 61 county clerk's office discloses the fact that only about one corpo- ration in ten claiming some town in this county as its principal place of business, pays any personal property tax. Mne hundred and eighty-two certificates of incorporation were on file with the county clerk. This number includes those corporations that are alive and claim some town in the county as the principal place of business. A large number of these corporations are doubtless practically dead for business purposes, and would have little or no personal property subject to taxation. Of the 982, the in- vestigator estimated that about 400 were actually alive and carry- ing on business, and that the remainder, viz., about 582, though legally alive, are practically dead so far as liability for personal property taxes is concerned. While these figures cannot be relied upon to determine the actual extent to which corporations escape from the personal property tax in County A, still they establish a strong presump- tion that the personal property tax is evaded by a great many corporations that ought to pay it. Conclusions as to County A. (1) It is fair to assume that a large number of corporations, through one means pr another, escape paying their fair share of the personal property tax. (2) It is definitely determined that the greatest inequality exists as between towns. (3) It is definitely determined that in most of the towns of this county no attempt whatever is made to assess the personal property tax upon corporations known to be subject to that tax. County B. In County B the investigator obtained a complete list of all corporations paying taxes of any kind. He did not obtain a list of all corporations claiming County B as principal place of business. The generalizations contained herein are based upon the corporations listed upon the assessors' rolls for either real or personal property tax. Of the fifty-two manufacturing corporations listed upon the assessors' rolls, forty-four claim some town in County B as principal place of business. Of the forty- four manufacturing corporations claiming County B as prin- cipal place of business, only eight pay any personal property tax, and thirty-six pay no personal property tax of any kind. Of the 62 STATE OF NEW YORK twelve towns in the county, ten contain manufacturing corpora- tions claiming those towns as their principal places of business. Of the ten towns, however, only two assess personal property to any corporation. Eight towns containing corporations claiming the town as the principal place of business fail to assess any personal property whatever. The ratio of personal property as- sessed to manufacturing corporations in this county to real prop- erty assessed to manufacturing corporations, is about 1 to 75. In the case of the mercantile corporations in County B, the fail- ure to assess the personal property tax seems to be less flagrant than in the case of the manufacturing corporations. So far as the list could be completed, the facts are as follows : Of the twenty-two mercantile corporations claiming County B as principal place of business, nine pay a personal property tax upon some small amount. Thirteen pay no personal property tax. The ratio between the personal property tax paid and the real property tax is about 1 to 13 for mercantile corporations. This ratio, however, is misrepresentative of the actual assessment. As explained above, some of the mercantile corporations paying personal property tax own no real estate, and therefore in includ- ing the amounts of personal property tax paid by such corpora- tions we obtain a ratio of the aggregate personal property tax to the aggregate real property tax, which is higher than the actual assessment of personal property warrants. In summarizing the investigation of County B, the following conclusions stand out : (1) In most of the localities of the county no effort whatever is made to. assess personal property of manufacturing corporations. (2) Mercantile corporations, although assessed more regularly than manufacturing, are greatly under-assessed. (3) The total assessment of personal property, the situs of which is located in the county, is ridiculously low as compared with the total of real property assessment. County C. The investigation of the assessment of the per- sonal property tax of general business corporations in County C disclosed the following facts : Forty manufacturing corporations claiming some town in County C as principal place of business are assessed upon per- sonal property to the value of $206,800, and upon real property JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 63 to the value of $945,500. The total amount of taxes collected from these corporations was $31,945.45. Of the forty manufacturing corporations claiming some town in County C as the principal place of business, twenty-seven pay a personal property tax and thirteen pay no personal property tax. The ratio of the assessed valuation of corporation personal property to the assessed valuation of corporation realty located in the principal place of business is about 1 to 41/2. Fifty-five mercantile corporations claim some town in County C as their principal place of business. Of the fifty-five, all but six pay a personal property tax. Of the fifty-five, only seventeen pay real property tax. It is assumed that the remaining thirty- eight rent the premises occupied and own no real estate. The ratio of personalty assessment to realty assessment is about 1 to 41/9. In other words, seventeen corporations paying real estate tax actually pay four and one-half times as much tax as the forty- nine pay upon the personalty tax. The ratio of personalty to realty under these conditions is quite unreliable. Summary of County C. In summarizing the results of the investigation in County C, the following points stand out : (1) In County C the officials reach a very much larger pro- portion of both the mercantile and manufacturing corporations than are reached in Counties A and B described above. (2) As between mercantile and manufacturing corporations, no great discrepancy appears in County C. It should be added, however, that the report on County C is limited to one large manufacturing city. Had this county a large number of small manufacturing towns, as in the case of Counties A and B, we might expect to find the same failure to assess the tax in the smaller towns. County D. County D, located in the central part of the State, contains one of the largest cities in the State, with a great many mercantile and manufacturing corporations. The statistics gath- ered cover all of the manufacturing and mercantile corpora- tions listed on the tax assessors' books in the principal localities. They do not include the corporations in six small places, most of which contain no corporations. That part of the data lacking 64 STATE OF NEW YORK would probably not amount to over 5 per cent of the total num- ber of corporations doing business in this county. Of 240 manufacturing corporations actually engaged in busi- ness and claiming County D as principal place of business, 167 paid personal property taxes in the year 1914, and 73 paid no personal property taxes. Of the 150 mercantile corporations claiming County D as principal place of business, 100 paid personal property taxes and 50 paid no personal property tax. From the sources available to the investigator, it was impossi- ble to determine how much personal property tax should have been paid under the law by most of the corporations. It is be- lieved, however, that not only a considerable number of corpora- tions claiming this county as principal place of business pay less than they ought to, but also that a large number of corporations claiming this -county as principal place of business paid no per- sonal property 5 tax whatever. The records appear to be very unreliable. Thirty-four mercan- tile corporations out of 160 doing business in one of the cities have no principal place of business on record in the office of the Secretary of State. Notwithstanding this fact, most of them are paying, a personal property tax in County D. The data collected by the investigator in this county is not of much value for the purposes of determining the extent of the evasion of the personal property tax. It is of value, however, as evidence of the slipshod way in which the records of corporations are kept in this State. County E. County E contains one of the smaller but princi- pal manufacturing cities of the State. This county contains four cities and towns that include mercantile or manufacturing corporations of importance. Of the four localities, only one assesses personal property tax to corporations. Of the eighteen mercantile corporations claiming principal place of business in County E, eleven pay personal property tax and seven do not. Of the forty-one manufacturing corporations claiming County E ,as principal place of business, nineteen pay personal property tax, while twenty-two pay no personal property tax. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 65 From the sources wliich were available to the investigator, it was impossible to determine in the case of most of the corpora- tions whether or not they were paying the full amount for which they were liable under the law. In the few cases where the in- vestigator was able to obtain sufficient data, it was found that about one-half of them paid considerably less than they should have paid. So much of the necessary data, however, was lacking, that it is impossible to make any very positive generalizations. The evidence brought to light, however, would seem to indicate that here, as in the other counties, only a very weak attempt is made to assess the personal property of corporations. Another rough method of ascertaining the inequality of assess- ing personal property as between towns within the county and as between counties, is to compare the ratios of personal property assessment to real property assessment. This is not an accurate method of measuring, and probably in no individual case does the ratio between personal property assessment .and real property assessment express the correct ratio between personal property legally subject to the tax and the real property assessment. The limitations of this method are a3 follows : (1) In some localities there may be a very large percentage of personal property listed for taxation, not because the law is rigorously enforced, but because a larger percentage of the prop- erty in the community is in the name of corporations claiming the locality in question as the principal place of business, while the corporations may have real estate in the form of plants situ- ated in surrounding towns. In this case the apparent high per- centage which the personalty would bear to the realty in the given locality would not indicate necessarily a rigorous enforcement of the law. The facts might be found to be just the opposite. (2) On the other hand, in another locality where there might be a number of plants owned by corporations claiming an out- side town as principal place of business, the ratio of personalty to realty would necessarily be very low, for the reason that the realty of the corporations would be assessed where located, while the personalty located in those towns could not be assessed there. In this case a rigorous assessment of the personal property actually liable to taxation might still show upon the records a very low 66 STATE OF NEW YORK ratio between the personal, property assessed and the real property assessed. Notwithstanding the limitations of this method, we can still gain some very interesting information as to the assessment of personal property in New York State. In our investigation of the five counties we find that the ratio of personal property assessed to real property assessed varies all the way from 1 to 4 to 1 to 75. In one case within the same county we find the ratio of personal property assessed to vary almost as widely as indicated above. In two; counties situated in the same part of the State, each of which has a fair proportion of manufacturing, it is found that in one county where most of the corporations taxed, either for realty or personalty, claim some town in the county as the principal place of business, the ratio of personalty to realty in one city of the first county is 1 to 10, while the ratio for the county as a whole is about 1 to 25. In the other county in which most of the corporations taxed upon realty claim some town in the county as the principal place of business, the ratio of personal property assessment to real prop- erty assessment of manufacturing corporations is only about 1 to 75. While it cannot be said, of course, that the inequality in the assessment of the personal property tax is accurately represented by the above difference in, ratios, it is clear that after discounting for all possible variations growing out of reasons indicated above, still the actual inequality of assessment must be very great. In the case of the mercantile corporations the actual inequality is likely to be much greater than is indicated by the ratio of per- sonal property assessment and real property assessment. Many mercantile corporations rent their premises and are subject to no real property tax of any kind. In those localities having a large proportion of their corporate investment in mercantile corpora- tions, the ratio of personalty to realty ought to be very high. CHAPTER III DECLINE IN THE PERSONAL PROPERTY ASSESSMENT IN NEW YORK STATE Another telling piece of evidence as to the failure of the per- sonal property tax in New York is found in the records of the Federal Census and the annual reports of the State Board of Tax JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 67 Commissioners. These reports contain the records of the per- centage of the assessment of personal property to the total assess- ment for every county of the State from 1840 to 1914. In Appendix A-IV-I will be found the details of these percentages. We give immediately following a brief analysis of this appendix. Appendix A-IV-I includes a statement of the percentage of the assessment of personal property to the total assessment for each county of the State for the years 1840, 1845, 1850, 1855, 1860, 1866, 1870, 1875, 1880, 1885, 1890, 1895 and 1900; (2) includes the same data for the years 1 1903, 1904, 1905, 1906, 1907, 1908, 1909, 1910, 1911, 1912, 1913 and 1914. This table shows that there has been a steady decrease in the percentage of assessed personal property to the total assessment from 1866 down to 1914. This percentage has decreased in practically every one of the sixty-two counties. For the State as a whole it has decreased from 25.5 per cent in 1866 to 3.77 per cent in 1914. During this same period the actual ratio of total personal property in the State to total real property has un- doubtedly increased greatly. It is conceded by all experts that the total amount of personal property probably exceeds that of real property. In examining this table three questions may be asked : (1) Has the percentage of personal property in the State to eal property in the State declined since 1866 ? (2) Has the percentage of taxable personal property to tax- ible real property declined since 1866 ? (3) During recent years the State has segregated certain forms of personal property, such as bank shares, mortgages, vehi- cles, etc., and has devised new special forms of taxation to cover ;hese classes. Has the apparent decline in the percentage of per- jonal property assessed to the total assessment been due to the :*act that these special forms of personalty have been taken out Tom under the general property tax ? In reply to the first question: It is well known that since 1866 he ratio of personal property to real property has increased ffiormously. This is borne out by the best statistical evidence hat we have. As to what is the exact ratio between the two at he present time it is impossible to say. Various estimates have 68 STATE OF NEW YORK been made, some authorities claiming that the personal property is now about three and one-half times as great as real property. Practically all agree that the total amount of personal property is now at least equal to the total amount of real property. In answer to the second question, it also may be said that not- withstanding all exemptions in the State of New York the per- centage of taxable personal property to taxable real property has increased to a marked degree since 1866. In answer to the third question, it must be admitted that in taking away from the general property tax mortgages, bank shares, etc., the amount of personal property actually liable to taxation under the general property tax has been diminished. The table referred to, however, shows that the ratio of assessed personal property to total assessment steadily decreased without regard to the years when these special forms of taxation were introduced. In other words, while the segregation of these forms of personalty did reduce for the time being the actual amount of personalty liable to taxation, it had practically no effect upon the percentage of personalty to reality that was assessed. To summarize: During the last fifty years the ratio of per- sonal property to real property has greatly increased, the ratio of taxable personalty to taxable realty has greatly increased, and the ratio of personalty taxable under the general property tax to the total assessment under the general property tax has in- creased. The actual assessment on the other hand has decreased from 25% per cent to 3.77 per cent. CHAPTER IV PERSONAL PROPERTY ASSESSMENT IN NEW YORK CITY Taking up the personal property assessments in rather more detailed form, we will first consider the situation in New York City from 1907 to 1914, and then take up the personal property assessment as we found it in the other cities and towns through- out the State. The complete New York City figures will be found in Appendix A-V. The tables show that (1) There has been a large decline in the tentative assessments placed on the roll; JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 69 (2) There has been a sharp decline in the final assessment retained on the roll; (3) That there has been a very large increase in the percent age retained, as compared with the original tentative assessment Thus we find that the tentative assessment in Manhattan for the year 1907 was $2,525,084,325 ; that the final assessment was $432,654,158, or 17.1 per cent of the orginal assessment, was retained. In 1914 in Manhattan the tentative assessment was $622,825,820. The final assessment was $287,768,270, or 46.2 per cent of the original assessment. In Brooklyn, in 1907, the tentative assessment amounted to $444,188,425, and the final assessment was $92,866,547, or 20.9 3er cent of the original assessment. In 1914 the tentative as- sessment amounted to $117,426,950, while the final assessment amounted to $39,296,065, or 33.4 per cent of the original assess ment. A similar situation was found to exist in the other boroughs. These figures would seem to indicate that in spite of a greater efficiency on the party of the tax commissioners, as indicated by the percentage retained on the tax rolls, there is, nevertheless, a constantly decreasing amount of personal property actually reached for taxation. CHAPTER V OTHER CITIES AND TOWNS In 1911 Mr. Lawson Purdy presented to the New York State Conference on Taxation the results of his study of the working ;>f the personal property tax in cities and towns of the State Following the lines of his investigation, we have made a further study, and for purposes of comparison have used the identical groupings that he used. Our statistics, which, of course, are brought down to date, completely corroborate his findings. The details of our investigation will be found in Appendix A VI, Arranging all of the fifty-three cities of the State outside the City of New York according to the proportion which their per- sonal property assessment bears to their total assessment In two cities personal assessment was less than 1 per cent. In five cities personal assessment ranged from 1 to 3 per cent. In five cities personal assessment ranged from 4 to 6 per cent 70 STATE OF NEW YORK In ten cities personal assessment ranged from 6 to 8 per cent. In seven cities personal assessment ranged from 8 to 11 per cent. In twelve cities personal assessment ranged from 11 to 13 per cent. In five cities personal assessment ranged from 13 to 18 per cent. In three cities personal assessment ranged from 18 to 20 per cent. In three cities personal assessment ranged from 20 to 21 per cent. In one city personal assessment is greater than 21 per cent. The average per cent of personal assessment to total assess- ment for the fifty-three cities is 7.8 per cent. It must be re- membered that this is the tentative assessment. If we compare the assessments in some of these cities with the assessments in others, the inequalities of the personal property tax become plainly evident. ' Thus, taking Buffalo, Lackawanna, Tonawanda, Niagara Falls, Port Jervis, Kensselaer, Mt. Vernon, New Eochelle, Dunkirk and Lockport on the one hand, and Hudson, Utica, Geneva and Ogdensburg on the other, we find that the ten cities first named have a population of 592,751. Assessed value of real estate $485,267,340. Assessed value of personal prop- erty $30,970,429. Four Cities Population 114,215 Eeal estate $66,554,338 Personal property 15,025,612 The ten cities have approximately five times the population of the four; nearly eight times the real estate value, but only a trifle more than twice the value of the personal property. Omit now Buffalo, Dunkirk and Lockport, and the remaining seven compare with the group of four as follows : Seven Cities Population 133,345 Real estate $135,328,812 Personal property 3,133,893 JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 71 Four Cities Population 114,215 Keal estate $66,554,338 Personal property 15,025,612 The personal assessment in the seven cities is 2.17 per cent of the total assessment, while the personal assessment in the four cities is 18.54 per cent of the total assessment. The per capita assessment of personal property in the four cities is $131.55, and in the seven cities it averages $24.14 and ranges from $7.88 in Lackawanna to $54.48 in Port Jervis. The per capita assess- ment of personal property in the other five is a follows: New Kochelle $10 21 Mt. Vernon 11 12 Rensselaer 15 97 Niagara Falls 38 02 Tonawanda . 52 00 Dunkirk, New Rochelle and Lockport, the three of the original ten cities omitted in the last comparison, have a population of 64,058, a real estate valuation of $51,722,154 and a personal assessment of $2,032,070. Per capita personal assessment, $31.72. Towns. Now let us see what the report shows us as to the conditions of the towns. There are 934 town, and the assessed value of their personal and real property is approximately equal to that of the fifty-three cities : 53 Cities Real estate $1,585,978,451 Personal property 137,505,796 Total assessed value of property 1,723,484,247 934 Towns Real estate $1,536,809,551 Personal property 84,730,979 Total assessed value of property 1,621,540,530 72 STATE OF ISTsw YORK Arranging the 934 towns according to the assessed value of per- sonal property, we have the following : Number Assessed value of personal property of towns Assessed value of personal property $0.00 77 Greater than '$0.00 but less than $1,000 38 From $1,000 to $5,000 136 From $5,000 to $25,000 , 258 From $25,000 to $100,000 213 Over $100,000 212 934 Some of the towns in the first class are Green Island, West Al- mond, Willing, Kirkwood, Binghamton, Olean, Arkwright, etc. The towns of Hamilton and Washington counties, respectively, are relatively most numerous here. Upon examining in greater detail the range of the personal assessments of the towns in the second class, we have : Beekman, $50; Thurston, $100; Ulster, $150; Greenville, $200 ; Richford and Hartsville, $300 each ; about 10 from $300 to $500 and about 20 from $500 to $600. Upon closer examina- tion of the last class, we have the following interesting results : About 75 towns show personal assessments ranging from $100,000 to $200,000; about 55 towns from $200,000 to $500,000; about 37 towns from $500,000 to $1,000,000; and only 6 towns of the 934 show an assessment greater than $1,000,000. These honored six are: Elizabethtown, Batavia, Hempstead, North Hempstead, Oyster Bay, and last but not least, Greenburg (Westchester county), with the greatest assessment of all, $3,225,040. Assuming the rate to be 2 per cent, 509 towns, or 54 per cent of the total number, get anywhere from nothing to a maximum of $500 from the personal property tax; 22 per cent get $2,000 or less, while but 22% per cent get over $2,000. In the language of Mr. Purdy : " What's the use ? " PART V FAILURE OF SECTION 12 INTRODUCTION We shall divide the discussion of section 12 into the following five divisions: (1) a statement of the law; (2) the impossibility of enforcing the law; (3) the results of the Committee's investi- gations into the working of the law; (4) the principal means whereby corporations are enabled to escape taxation upon their personal property; (5) why corporations are impelled to evade personal property tax. CHAPTER I The taxation of the personal property of corporations for local purposes is covered by section 12 of the Tax Law, which reads as follows : " The capital stock of every company liable to taxation, except such part of it as shall have been excepted in the assessment-roll or shall be exempt by law, together with its surplus profits or reserve funds exceeding ten per centum of its capital, after deducting the assessed value of its real estate, and all shares of stock in other corporations actually owned 'by such company, which are taxable on their capital stock under the laws of this State, shall be assessed at its actual value." As is pointed out elsewhere, this law has proved wholly unin- telligible, not only to the tax assessors, but to the tax attorneys and, in part, to the courts themselves. It is, therefore, impos- sible to understand the law without recourse to the court decisions. For purposes of this report, little can be gained, however, by a discussion of these decisions. It is sufficient to state that several attempts have been made by the various taxing boards to inter- pret the law as modified by the court decisions in such language as can be understood by the average tax assessor. The State Board of Tax Commissioners has made the following rule : " From the total assets of the corporation (including full value of real estate and personalty) and both taxable and 74 STATE OF NEW YORK te^ ;? ' non-taxable property, deduct the value of the stock belonging to the State, property exempt, non-taxable property (includ- ing shares of stock of other corporations, patent rights and good will), assessed value of the corporation's real estate, debts of the corporation, and surplus, if any, up to ten per centum of the capital." The most careful attempt to explain the law has been made by the commissioners of taxes and assessments of the City of New York. The following blank schedule is used by the department of taxes and assessments of the City of New York, not for the pur- poses of original assessment but for purposes of reassessment in those cases where the corporation objects to the original assess- ment. This interpretation of section 12, as well as the blank form, have been followed closely by several of the large cities of the State: The (Please state full name of the corporation), a corporation organized under the laws of the State of New York, claiming to be aggrieved by the assessed valuation of its property for the year 1906, makes application by the undersigned, one of the officers of the said corporation, to have the same revised and corrected. Dated, October 1, 1915. STATE THE VALUE OF THE FOLLOWING ITEMS Assets All assets must be scheduled, whether located in the State of New York, or elsewhere, including deposits in banks and debts due from nonresidents. 1. Heal estate $ 2. Machinery, plant, office, furniture and fixtures other than real estate. .-...., 3. Goods, wares and merchandise 4. All other tangible personal property. (This does not include mortgages or credits. ) 5. Cash on hand and on deposit 6. Debts due from solvent debtors. (This includes bonds and all credits, also " secured debts.") JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 75 7. Shares of stock of other corporations. ....... $ 8. Value at which patent rights, copyrights, trade- marks, good will and franchises were taken in payment for capital stock 9. The aggregate of the above assets, 10. Property exempt by law which ^ includes. Deductions Except the items numbered 12, 15, 17 and 18, the value of every item to be deducted must be the sum at which it is included in the above statement of assets. U. S. Bonds, K Y. State and Municipal Bonds ... $ N. Y. Mortgages recorded on or after July 1, 1906, and mortgages on which a registration tax has been paid since May 13, 1907, also " secured debts." (This includes only mortgages and " se- cured debts " owned by the corporation) ....... $ Goods imported by above corporation from for- eign countries on hand in unbroken original packages $ 11. Value at which patent rights, copyrights, trademarks, goodwill and franchises were taken in payment for capital stock. ....... $ 12. So much of the surplus, if any, as shall not exceed ten per centum of the par value of the shares of stock issued $ 13. Shares of stock of other corporations actually owned by the above corporation which are taxable upon their capital stock. ......... $ 76 STATE OF NEW YORK 14. Tangible personal property having a perma- nent situs outside of this State, specifying its nature and location. (This does not include bonds, notes, evidences of debt of any kind, currency, deposits in banks, bills receivable, or any other intangible prop- erty.) 15. The assessed value of the corporation's real estate in this State, including its special franchises. Give Section or Ward and Lot Numbers if in the City of New York 16. Eeal estate outside of this State, specifying its location 17. Indebtedness secured by the corporation's bond and mortgage on real property to which corporation now holds title 18. All other indebtedness of the cor- poration not contracted or in curred in the purchase of non- taxable property or securities, or for the purpose of evading taxa- tion. (The amount owing for goods imported by above corpo- ration from foreign countries on hand in unbroken packages and the capital stock of the corpora- Bonds not secured by mortgage of real estate. Notes .... Open ac- counts . tion must not be included. Itemized as follows : 19. The aggregate of the items set down in answer to questions 10 to 18 inclusive J Additional Information Required a. Total par value of capital stock issued . $ b. Rate of last dividend Date c. Amount of surplus, if any, as shown by the books ...... $ d. Amount of indebtedness for above imported goods; this amount is not included in No. 18 but is an addition thereto. . .... $ JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 77 Gross assets as shown by answer to question 9 .... $ Aggregate of deductions from gross assets as shown by answer to question 19 $ Subtract the deductions from the above assets. . . . Add " secured debts " upon which no registration tax has been paid . The result is the CAPITAL STOCK LIABLE TO TAX- ATION . The principal office or the place of transacting the Financial Business of the said corporation is situated in the Borough of Manhattan, in the City of New York, at !NTo. . . street. CHAPTER II IMPOSSIBILITY OF ENFORCING SECTION 12. In order to understand how utterly impossible is the present system of taxing corporations upon their personal property, it is important to know wherein the law is unenforceable. In the first place, it is framed in such ambiguous terms as to be thoroughly obscure to the mind of the average assessors. It has been called the most ambiguous and unintelligible tax statute in the United States. Without recourse to court decisions it is im- possible to have much idea as to what the law means and these court decisions are not known or understood by the average as- sessor in the State. Indeed, there are very few tax attorneys who pretend to understand the law. . Moreover, we may go fur- ther iand say that the courts themselves have frankly stated that they were in doublt as to what was intended by the language of the law. The 2Tew York Court of Appeals, in the case of The People ex rel. v. Commissioners of Taxes, 95 "N. Y. 554, stated the following: " There is a most extraordinary confusion of ideas in the section * * * ." And again : " Its interpretation has met some difficulty of solution by the very bungling and confused manner in which the statutes, are worded/ 7 78 STATE OF NEW YORK In the hearings of the Joint Legislative Committee on Taxa- tion, held in New York City in November, 1915, there appeared many competent witnesses who testified as to the confusion of this law. In every case the witnesses testified that the law was so ambiguous as to be utterly impossible of enforcement. In the second place, were the law understandable, it would be impossible for the assessors to obtain adequate information for its enforcement. The sections 27, 28 and 29 of the Tax Law attempt to provide means of obtaining this information. Section, 27 reads as follows : " The president or other proper officer of every moneyed or stock corporation deriving an income or profit from its capital or otherwise shall, on or before June fifteenth, de- liver to one of the assessors of the tax district in which the company is liable to be taxed and, if such tax district is in a county embracing a portion of the forest preserve, to the comptroller of the state, a written statement specifying: " 1. The real property, if any, owned by such company, the tax district in which the same is situated and, unless a rail- road corporation, the sums actually paid therefor. " 2. The capital stock actuaHy paid in and secured to be paid in, excepting therefrom the sums paid for real property and the amount of such capital stock held by the State and by any incorporated literary or charitable institution, and u 3. The tax district in which the principal office of the company is situated or in case it has no principal office, the tax district in which its operations are carried on. " Such statement shall be verified by the officer making the same to the effect that it is in all respects just and true. If such statement is not made within twenty days after the fifteenth day of June, or is insufficient, evasive or defective, the assessors may compel the corporation to make a proper statement by mandamus." It is, however, the unanimous opinion of those having to do with the enforcement of section 12 that section 27 is well-nigh useless. While it requires corporations to file certain definite information, this is not the information that is needed for pur- poses of determining the taxable personalty of the corporations JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 79 under section 12. As pointed out in another chapter of this report, in order to assess the personalty of corporations with any degree of intelligence, it is necessary to obtain detailed informa- tion upon no less than twenty-seven principal items of the corpora- tion's financial affairs. The assessor cannot obtain information in regard to these items directly from the corporations, nor can he obtain the information, in most cases, from any public source. An examination of Moody's Manual and of Poor's Manual dis- closes the fact that not one corporation in ten publishes a balance sheet containing any of the necessary information, and very few publish adequate data. In the third place, many assessors have no means of knowing when; a corporation is taxable in their districts. Section 29 of the Tax Law attempts to provide these means. It reads as follows: " Between the first and fifteenth days of June in each year the county clerk in each county of the State, except- ing counties containing a city of the second class and coun- ties wholly situate within the corporate limits of a city, shall prepare from the records in his office and mail to each of the town clerks in his said county, a certified statement contain- ing the names of every stock corporation, whose certificate of incorporation has been filed with him since his last pre- ceding annual statements to said several town clerks, whose principal business office or chief place of business is desig- nated in its certificate of incorporation as being in such town or in any village or hamlet therein, together with the fact of such designation and the names and addresses of the directors of each such corporation so far as said county clerk can discover the same from the certificate of incorporation or from the lastest certificate of election of directors of such corporation filed in his office. Each town clerk receiving such statement shall forthwith file the same in his office and mail a notice of such filing to each of the assessors of his town." The Committee's investigation, however, disclosed the fact that this section is in many localities a dead letter. "No compensa- tion is allowed for this work, with the usual result that the local clerks do not carry out the directions of the statute. 80 STATE OF NEW YORK In the fourth place, even though the law were clear beyond mistake, and even though all necessary information could be obtained with the greatest facility, and even if the assessors were always informed as to the local taxability of any corporation, it would be utterly futile to expect the average tax official to assess the personal property of corporations. This is especially true of manufacturing corporations. The appraisal of a manufacturing plant is a highly technical job. It involves not only wide train- ing in accounting and some engineering, but also a special knowl- edge of the particular branch of business to be appraised. Even a rough estimate of the value of a manufacturing plant involves a thorough understanding of principles of depreciation and ob- solescence. When we add to this the difficulty of assessing large stocks of raw materials and of goods in the process of manufac- ture, as well as finished products, it is seen how utterly hopeless it is to expect an untrained local assessor even to approximate the value of such property. The comparative ease with which the average corporation can keep from the average tax assessor the knowledge necessary to a correct assessment is illustrated by the difficulty which the Committee had in investigating some 2,500 corporations liable to taxation in the State of New York. The Committee had much greater facilities for obtaining correct information than the average assessor. In attempting to deter- mine how much personal property should be assessed to these corporations the Committee had access to Moody's Manual of Corporations, to Poor's Manual, and to several other sources. It employed statisticians and accountants who were trained to do just this sort of work. In the end, however, it had the greatest difficulty in obtaining the necessary information, and was able to obtain sufficient data concerning only about one hundred of these corporations. Even after carefully sifting the doubtful cases, it was still doubtful whether the Committee was able to obtain anything more than a very rough estimate of the amount of per- sonalty taxable to these corporations under the law. In order to do full justice to corporations they were given the benefit of the doubt in every case. While this is the fair thins; to do for purposes of investigation, it would not be the fair thing to mittee is convinced that it is a comparatively easy thing for most do for purposes of taxation. In view of its experience, the Com- JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 81 corporations to keep from the assessor the data necessary to any- thing like a complete assessment. In this respect the New York assessor is in a situation in no way different from that of the other states of the Union that still adhere to the outworn, mediaeval system of local assessment of corporate personalty. The utter fatuity of this system is borne out by overwhelming evidence in every state in the Union. Wherever anything like scientific ap- praisal and assessment of corporation property has been accom- plished, it has been necessary to break away from the local assess- ment. In concluding this paragraph, it is sufficient to say that every tax authority in the United States agrees that it is utterly hopeless and impossible to assess under a corporation tax law such as that now prescribed by section 12 of the New York law. CHAPTER III THE COMMITTEE'S INVESTIGATION OF SECTION 12 In order to obtain a measure of the practical workings of sec- tion 12, the Committee undertook several investigations, the results of which are given below. Investigation of Some 2,500 Corporations. The names of some 2,500 general business corporations actually doing business in the State of New York were obtained. This list was largely made up of domestic corporations, and included mercantile, manu- facturing and other general business corporations. It did not in any case include public service corporations, moneyed corpo- rations or philanthropic and non-stock corporations. The list was selected entirely at random. Some of the names were ob- tained by investigators, who went through the city directories, telephone directories, etc., of various counties. Some of the names were obtained by an assistant who went through Moody's Manual, selecting domestic corporations, without any knowledge as to the purpose for which the names of the corporations were to be used. In ascertaining whether or not the corporations in question were paying all of the personal property tax on which they were 82 STATE OF NEW YORK liable under section 12, the following routine of procedure was followed : (1) An attempt was made to obtain from Moody's Manual or Poor's Manual a copy of the general balance sheet of the cor- poration, with such other detail as to capitalization, bonded indebtedness, etc., as was necessary to determine what the cor- poration should pay. (2) From the Secretary of State's office, or from the county clerk's office, information was obtained as to what town was claimed by the corporation as the principal place of business. (3) An inquiry was sent to the local taxing officer as to the amount of personal property tax paid by the given corporation. Of the some 2,500 corporations, it was possible to locate the names of only about 300 in the corporation manuals. Of the 300, it was necessary after a study of the data recorded to dis- card the names of about 200 corporations. In the case of the latter, either the balance sheet was wholly missing or the report lacked some of the details that were absolutely essential, even to a rough estimate of the amount of personal property which these corporations should pay under section 12. Of the remaining 100 names of corporations listed in the corporation manuals, a care- ful study was made of their balance sheets, and an attempt was made to estimate the amount of personal property which each should pay according to law. An examination of the New York City blank form given above, which contains some 19 principal headings and several sub- headings, will indicate with what difficulty the Committee was able to determine the amount of personal property tax which should be paid by any given corporation. In order to estimate with approximate accuracy the amount of personal property sub- ject to taxation, it is necessary to have quite correct informa- tion in regard to items 10, 11, 12, 13 and 14. From the balance sheets and other data obtained from the corporation man- uals, it was found very difficult to determine in any given case the amount which should be set opposite items Nos. 10, 12, 13 and 14. Wherever in any case doubt existed, the benefit of the doubt was given to the corporation. From the financial state- ments of the corporations it was often impossible to determine JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 83 what percentage of securities held by the corporation should be allowed under item 10. Wherever securities were so listed, a deduction was allowed of the total amount. In regard to item No. 11, it was always impossible to deter- mine what percentage of the value of patent rights, copyrights, trade mark, good will, etc., listed in the general balance sheets of the corporation, was taken in payment for capital stock. Although the value of patent rights, good will, etc., in some cor- porations amounted to as high as two-thirds of their total assets, they were in every case deducted in whole from the taxable assets. In regard to item 13, it was impossible to determine from the financial statements obtained what percentage of the shares of stock of other corporations actually owned by the corporation were taxable upon their capital stock. In every case the corpora- tion was given the benefit of the doubt, and it was assumed that the total amount of shares of stock so held had been taxed else- where and were therefore exempted. Without fairly accurate knowledge of the information called for under item 14, it would be impossible to approximate the amount of personal property in any given case which should be assessed under section 12. It was impossible for the Committee to obtain access to any source that revealed this information, and it therefore resorted to the following four methods of determining the amount of tan- gible personal property having a permanent situs in the State: (1) Where details were given as to the total capacity or out- put of manufacturing plants of a given corporation, in addition to the details of the capacity or output of each plant, it was assumed that the tangible personal property located within the State would bear about the same ratio to the total tangible per- sonal property as the capacity or output of the plants within the State bore to the total capacity or output of all the plants. (2) Where the details of the acreage of the various plants were stated, it was assumed that the amount of tangible personal property within the State would bear about the same ratio to the total tangible personal property as the acreage of plants within the State bore to the total acreage of plants. (3) In the case of mercantile corporations, information was obtained from the Comptroller's office as to the proportion of 84 STATE OF NEW YORK total assets subject to taxation under section 182. This propor- tion of assets was assumed to represent roughly the proportion of tangible personalty situated within the State. (4) In the case of other corporations whose business was known to be done largely in the State of New York, an arbitrary but conservative estimate was made of the proportion of business that was done in this State ; and in the case of such corporations, it was assumed that the percentage of tangible personalty situa- ted in New York would be approximately the same as the per- centage of total business carried on in New York. The results of this investigation will be found in the tabulation given in Appendix D-I. We give below a list of twenty-five corporations taken from Appendix D-I. This group is not selected but includes the names of those corporations about which we were able to obtain data sufficiently complete. The list is as follows : Amount Amount of actual of taxable assessment under Designation of Corporation personalty section 12 A2 $4, 000, 000 $100, 000 A4 2, 100, 000 1,800 A5 8, 541, 000 750, 000 B3 352, 877 B9 1,634,913 C2 350, 524 C3 3,759.361 25. 000 Co 85, 573 150, 000 El 332, 108 E2 5,758,831 E3 1, 000, 000 F2 1, 033, 691 G2 42, 850, 000 1, 100, 000 G3 1,066,714 G6 497, 000 8,000 G7 887,112 G8 78, 356 LI 3,512,752 Ml 9, 608, 055 1,200,000 Nl 1, 027, 488 N9 445,865 S2 301,105 5.000 S3 998. 906 Wl 300, 502 Total . , $90, 522, 733 $3, 339, 800 JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 85 The summary of this list is as follows: Total number of corporations listed 24 Total taxable personalty $90,522,733 Aggregate actual assessment 3,339,800 Percentage of taxable personalty actually paid. ... 3.46% Percentage of taxable personalty legally liable but evaded 9G . 54% Further comment on the above is unnecessary. Important as these results are in disclosing the failure of the personal property tax of corporations, they do not disclose the full significance of that failure. In the first place, corporations are permitted through the peculiar features of the New York Tax Law to escape by thoroughly legal means from paying taxes upon an important portion of their personalty that yields large returns. This investigation, however, attempted to determine not what corporations should pay fairly, but only what they should pay under the generous New York Tax Law. The results dis- closed the fact that even after reducing, through the peculiarities of the law, the amount of taxable personalty to as low as one-fifth or less of the actual personalty owned, the larger part of this one- fifth is usually evaded. Furthermore, reference to the other in- vestigations of the Committee, carried on by means of voluntary returns from general business corporations, shows that the volun- tary reports of the corporations disclosed the failure of the law to a greater degree than the original investigation of the Com- mittee. In order to understand, not only to what extent the law is evaded, but also how the result is very unequal even where the tax law is enforced we may examine the facts in regard to a few of these corporations. Corporation A-4: Has an authorized capitalization of $10,000,000 and capital stock outstanding of $3,000,000. No bonded debt. This corporation has its actual place of business and its only factory located on Long Island, but claims as its principal place of business a little town up in the northwestern part of the State. Its total assets are $3,651,524. 86 STATE OF NEW YORK A careful analysis of its balance sheet results in the conclusion that the minimum amount of personal property, after making all possible deductions according to the law, is $742,630. This cor- poration actually paid upon an assessed value of $1,800. In this case the estimate was less than one-fourth of 1 per cent of the minimum amount taxable under the law. Corporation A-5: A large manufacturing corporation located in the centre of the State, claiming as its principal place of business the city in which its largest plants are located. It is capitalized for $50,000,000 and has a bonded debt of approximately $7,729,000. Its total assets amount to over $73,000,000. After deducting all possible deductions and giving the corporation the benefit of the doubt in every case, there is left $3,655,291 of taxable personal property. A reasonable estimate of this corporation's taxable personalty would be several times this amount, but in order to give the cor- poration the benefit of every doubt the figure given was selected. This corporation pays personal property tax upon the estimate of $750,000, or an amount which is only about 20 per cent of the lowest possible amount subject to section 12. Corporation A-8: A paper manufacturing company with all of its mills located in New York. Capital stock $350,000. No bonded indebtedness. Pays dividends upon its 6 per cent preferred regularly and 20 per cent upon the common stock. Pays no personal property tax. Corporation B-l : An important corporation manufacturing optical goods. Cap- ital stock, $600,000. No bonded indebtedness. Pays a personal property tax upon assessment of $175,000. Impossible to obtain sufficient data to determine whether corporation pays tax upon its total taxable personal property. However, this company would appear to be one of the exceptions, in that it probably pays all that it ought to. Corporation B-5: A large shoe manufacturing company. Capital stock $9,900,- 000. Notes payable $2,336,000. Surplus $285,739. Total as- JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 87 sets over $12,000,000. Good will, etc., about $5,000,000. Under present law apparently no taxable personalty. Here is a con- spicuous case illustrating the inadequacy of the present property tax. A large corporation of great wealth with personalty to the extent of $5,000,000 that would be taxable in other states. In New York, however, the corporation can escape without paying any personal property tax, although it enjoys a large income. Corporation B-7: A manufacturing corporation located in the northwestern part of the State. Capital stock, $1,150,000. No bonded debt. Divi- dends on preferred paid regularly. Dividends on common not reported. This corporation pays upon a total personal property assessment of $25,000. From the corporation manuals and other material at the service of the Committee sufficient details cannot be obtained to determine how large the personal property, assess- ment should have been made. Corporation B-8 : A large furnace company with capital stock of $1,160,000. No bonded debt. Preferred dividends are paid regularly, and com- mon dividends are also paid but not made public. Net earnings average nearly 20 per cent of the total capitalization. Corporation paid taxes upon personal property assessed at $50,000. Here is another case of a large corporation making unusually large divi- dends with a personal property assessment that is insignificant as compared with its total assets and capitalization. Corporation B-10: A by-products company. Capital stock $4,000,000, bonded indebtedness $2,000,000, and total assets of $6,738,000. Under the present law allowing deduction of bonded debt from person- alty the corporation has no personal property liable to taxation. Were the New York Law similar to that of most states, there would be a large item of personalty liable to taxation. 88 STATE OF NEW YOK CHAPTER IV INVESTIGATION OF THE COMMITTEE BY MEANS OF VOLUNTARY RETURNS OF GENERAL BUSINESS CORPORATIONS Another plan of investigating the working of section 12 fol- lowed by the Committee was by means of voluntary returns from general business corporations. For the purpose of this investi- gation the Commitee obtained the names of some 300 representa- tive general business corporations and requested them to fill out a blank form prepared by the Committee. Of the 300 to whom this blank was sent, only a small per- centage made returns, and in many cases the returns were incom- plete. The Committee discarded the too incomplete returns and based its conclusions upon only those complete or nearly complete. In this connection it should be stated that in every case the Com- mittee accepted the returns of the corporation without question. While, for purposes of drawing conclusions, it was unfortunate that a large number of returns could not be obtained, yet it is believed that the data received does not underestimate the failure of section 12. It is only reasonable to assume that those corpora- tions voluntarily returning a statement of their taxable base would be made up of the least offenders under the law. In as- suming, therefore, that the data is typical of the situation we are giving the corporations the benefit of the doubt. In examining the data returned, it is nothing short of surpris- ing to find how completely the personal property tax of corpora- tions has broken down. An examination of Appendix D-IV, which contains a tabulation of the facts gathered from these re- turns, discloses two facts: that a large number of corporations escape from paying taxes upon a large part of their personal property through the bonded debt means or the good will means. But entirely apart from this, it will be noted that most of the corporations there listed also escape from paying taxes, if not entirely, at least upon a large part of their taxable personal prop- erty. The summary of the results brought out by this computa- tion is as follows : Of the fifteen corporations included in the list, six do not pay any personal property tax whatever. These six, however, have a total capital stock outstanding of $19,719,200, and, according to JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 89 their own statements, have a total capital stock liable to taxation of $4,962,003.19. The remaining nine corporations, acec/rding to their own statements, have an aggregate capital stock liable to taxation of $3,019,851.75, and pay on an actual assessment of $1,303,405.50. For the whole group the percentage of capital stock liable to taxation actually assessed varies from O 1 per cent to 121.2 per cent. An examination of the last column of the tabulation in the ap- pendix will explain in part why many of these corporations own- ing millions of personal property are actually liable for such a small percentage under the Tax Law. While the column entitled " Actual assessment, percentage of taxable personalty " will not explain why the system fails so completely, it shows unmistakably what an almost complete farce is this personal property tax of corporations. The following typical cases serve to illustrate this point further: Take, for example, Corporation SS-2, with an outstanding capital of $10,000,000, paying dividends to the amount of $600,000 a year, or at the rate of 6 per cent. This corporation is not assessed for a dollar's worth of personal property and pays no taxes. Corporation AA-1 : This corporation has outstanding capital of $900,000. Total assets, $1,326.617.98. Good will, $50-0,000. Total deductions allowed under section 12, $837,124.58. Personal property liable to taxation, $489,493.40. This corporation pays no personal property tax. Corporation AA-2: This corporation is a manufacturer of engines and boilers. It has a total outstanding stock of $700,000. Total assets, $741,622. Total deductions allowed under the law, $143,005. Personal property liable to taxation under section 12, $598,617. The cor- poration was assessed for $250,650 personal property. This assessment was equal to less than one-half of the taxable personal property. It is, however, unusual for corporations to be assessed up to as much as one-half of their taxable personalty. This case constitutes an exception to the general rule. 90 STATE OF NEW YORK Corporation BB-1: This corporation has total assets of $2,249,655.05 and a capital stock issued of $500,000, The total deductions permitted under the law are $1,521,205.49. The amount of taxable personalty is $628,449.56. This corporation pays no personal property tax. Corporation BB-2: This corporation has an issued capital stock of $7,000,000, a surplus of over $2,500,000, and annual net earnings varying from $860,000 to $1,700,000. It pays upon personal property assessed at $393,220. This corporation has an annual interest charge of over $500,000 upon bonded indebtedness, or in other words has a bonded -indebtedness of approximately $9,000,000. Here is another case where a corporation with a large amount of personal property is allowed to escape with a very small assess- ment as the result of the peculiarity in the New York law which permits deduction of total indebtedness from personal property. Corporation CC-1 : This corporation has capital stock of $150,000 and total assets of $609,346. It pays interest upon bonded indebtedness of $6,315, or in other words has a bonded indebtedness of an average of $500,000. It pays a personal property tax of $374, which at a 2 per cent rate of taxation represents an assessment of $18,700. After allowing for all legal deductions it still has taxable per- sonalty of $58,204. It pays, therefore, a tax upon less than one-third of its taxable personalty. Were it not for the bonded indebtedness the taxable personalty would be several times as great. Corporation GG-1: This corporation is capitalized for $383,600, and has total assets of $1,035,298.52. It has taxable personal property of $695,945, and pays a personal property tax of $106.07. It actually paid upon an assessment of $4,925.28. This assess- ment was less than 1 per cent of its actual taxable personal property. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 91 Corporation HH-1 : This corporation has capital stock of $800,000 and assets of $757,763. It has taxable personalty to the value uf $325,954, and was assessed upon only $45,000. This is a clear case of under assessment, but this assessment represents a much higher proportion of actual taxable personalty than the ordinary assess- ment. Corporation LL-1 : This corporation has a capital stock of $1,600,000 and total assets of nearly $2,400,000. After making all deductions per- mitted under the law it still has taxable personal property to the value of over $1,000,000. It pays no personal property tax of any kind. CHAPTER V INVESTIGATION OF THE WORKING OF SECTION 12 THROUGH THE MEANS OF VOLUNTARY RETURNS OF CORPORATIONS For the data used in this investigation, the Committee is in- debted to the Associated Manufacturers and Merchants Associa- tion of New York. At the request of the Committee the associa- tion undertook to gather from all of the important manufacturers within the State the necessary data. In this way the Committee received sworn statements from thirty-four of the more important business corporations in the State. In appendix D-Y will be found a tabulation of the more important data obtained from these statements. It is not necessary to go into much detail in explain- ing this data. It speaks for itself. The important point to note is, that in so far as it bears upon the failure of section 12, it coin- cides very closely with the results of the other investigations of the Committee. Moreover, it bears out completely the conclusions of the Committee that have been based upon the other investiga- tions. An examination of a few of these returns will serve to confirm our statements. For example, corporation 'No. 252, according to its own state- ment, is liable under section 12 for an assessment of $57,022.20, but was actually assessed for only $1,780. Corporation No. 424 was actually liable, according to its own statement, for a personal property assessment of $785,138.11. It was assessed upon $200,043. 92 STATE OF NEW YORK A still more flagrant case is No. 444. This corporation, accord- ing to its own statement, should have paid taxes upon an assess- ment of $1,232,502.60, and it was actually assessed upon only $59,427. Corporation No. 467 was liable to assessment for $2,071,- 665.76, and was not assessed for personal property. Corporation No. 449 was liable to assessment for over a mil- lion dollars, and paid no personal property tax. Corporation No. 546 was liable to assessment upon $1,830,860, and paid on $15,096.50. On the other hand, there are several cases in which corpora- tions have paid all that they were liable for. The table illustrates, therefore, not only that these corporations as a group are ridicu- lously under-assessed, but that there is an utter lack of uniformity as to the percentage at which the various corporations are as- sessed, some of them being assessed from nothing to ten per cent of their taxable personalty, while others are assessed for one hun- dred per cent. CHAPTER VI HOW CORPORATIONS ESCAPE THE PERSONAL PROPERTY TAX IN NEW YORK STATE In the attempt to construct a scientific and at the same time a thoroughly practical method of reaching that great body of cor- porate wealth that now escapes taxation, the first step is to take notice of the means whereby the present system permits this escape. Under the New York Tax Law there are no less than five important ways through which corporations may escape their fair share of the tax burden. If any system for successfully reaching corporate wealth is to be devised, it must take into account all these methods of evasion. Some of these methods may be classed as illegal, but the means by which the larger part of corporate personalty escapes its fair share may be called thoroughly legal. In other words, the present evasion is due not to the disposition of the corporations to evade the legal requirements of the statute, but to their effort to evade through the legal channels a system of taxation which, if actually enforced, would impose great hardship upon them. This possibility of evasion is not limited to the present system, but is to be found to a more or less extent with some other systems that have been proposed. For purposes of con- JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 93 structive reform it is therefore of utmost importance that we con- sider the means whereby corporations may escape their fair bur- den of personal property taxation. In the first place, the corporation may escape part of its per- sonal property taxation by taking advantage of that feature of the New York Tax Law which permits a corporation to select as its principal place of business any locality in the State. This locality may be where it transacts an important part of its business, or it may be a little obscure place, far removed from the site of any of its business. Owing to another peculiar feature of the New York Law which makes the situs of all personal property for purposes of taxation the principal place of business, the corporation may limit the power of taxing its personalty to the one small locality which it selects as the legal principal place of business. It may have large stocks of goods in the principal cities of the State and enjoy fire protection, police protection, etc., without distributing one cent to the maintenance of the government of those cities. It may have large amount of tangible personal property located in cities where the cost of government is very high, and by trans- ferring its principal place of business to some little obscure town where the expenses of government are very low, it may escape with a very low rate of taxation. More than that, it may, and very often docs, escape without paying any personal property tax in any place. In our investigation of the assessment of the personal property of several hundred corporations, we found a number of cases in which corporations claimed particular towns as principal place of business, while the tax officers were ignorant of the fact and had never assessed them. For the purpose of evading their fair share in the localities where they actually carry on their business and have their tangi- ble assets located, corporations have been accustomed to select cer- tain localities. These localities are notorious either for the low tax rate or for their willingness to assess the corporations only at a nominal amount. Through this means many cities have been deprived of a large amount of their legitimate tax base. The extent of this evil is well borne out both by the testimony of the witnesses before the hearings of the Joint Legislature Com- mittee on Taxation and by numerous investigations. The results 94 STATE OF NEW YORK of the investigation are set forth in the appendix of this report. Appendix D-II and D-III bear upon this point. Appendix D-II contains a list of corporations in a single town that was presented to the New York Constitutional Convention of 1915 from data furnished by the office of the State Board of Tax Commissioners. The summary of this table is as follows: 1. Number of corporations 51 2. Aggregate capital stock $33,257,370 3. Aggregate assessment , 60,700 4. Percentage of aggregate assessment to aggre- gate capital stock . 18% or less than one-fifth of one per cent. While the percentage of assessment to capital stock of any particular corporation does not necessarily reflect the degree of evasion with accuracy, yet in the aggregate the comparison is highly significant. The most interesting fact is that very few, if indeed any, of these corporations, do any business in the town of Esopus. Appendix D-III contains a list of corporations that claim the town of Washington, county of Dutchess, as the principal place of business. The summary of this table is as follows : 1. Number of corporations 43 2. Aggregate of capital stock $52,302,000 3. Aggregate assessment 477,500 4. Aggregate assessment as per cent of aggre- gate capital stock 0.91% or less than one per cent. The conclusions from this table coincide at every point with those of every other piece of evidence presented to the Committee, namely, that corporations select as " principal place of business " towns in which they actually do no business for the purpose of evading the personal property tax. The testimony of the various tax officials, including the Chair- man of the State Board of Tax Commissioners, is completely cor- roborative of the Committee's investigation. Chairman Saxe tes- tified that this evil was of widespread importance. He stated that conditions similar to those of Esopus and Dutchess county JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 95 " obtains in a great many of the so-called desirable taxing dis- tricts, where these corporations locate their principal place of business. You will find in that Esopus list, so-called, a large number of New York city corporations, paying no tax here, and paying a very nominal tax up there, for the privilege of escaping taxation down here." Mr. Joseph C. Wilson, President of the Board of Assessors of the City of Rochester, testified that the City of Rochester loses millions of dollars of taxable base through the custom of corpora- tions to transfer their so-called principal place of business. He testified that many large corporations having their plants and tangible personalty located in the large cities, transfer their so- called principal place of business to one of the smaller towns for the reason that the towns do not assess them, as high in many cases as the cities. Furthermore, he testified that " the town assessors do not know that they [corporations] are located there and they escape without any tax whatever." At the New York hearings, one of the former city comptrollers testified to the same effect. He testified that there are hundreds of corporations incorporated up-state for the purpose of evading taxes which should be paid in New York City. Furthermore, he said, " I am one of them I am entitled to do it under the law, but it is not fair." As to availing himself of the opportunity to escape taxation, he said : " I have two offices in Esopus a tin box in each I know I do it every chance I get, and I suppose every other man does the same thing." A second reason why corporations escape their personal pro- perty tax is found in the failure of the local assessors to assess. As has been pointed out in the previous chapter, this is partly due to the ambiguity of the law and partly due to the fact that the law provides no method for successfully checking up under- assessments. The important point to be considered here, how- ever, is the wide extent to which corporations escape taxation through local favoritism. This is due not necessarily to the dis- honesty of any particular group of tax assessors, but rather to the fact that the system of locally assessing corporate property is one which proves too great a test for human nature, and this statement is as true of every other state in the Union as it is of New York 06 STATE OF NEW YORK State. For thus locally favoring the corporations the assessor is not to be blamed. In so doing he undoubtedly in most cases acts in harmony with the wishes of the community. The com- munities are eager to obtain factories and other corporate invest- ment in their localities, and know that low rates will furnish an inducement to a corporation to locate in their town. This evil is inherent in any system of taxation that provides for the local assessment of corporate personal property, and it can be rectified only by changing the system completely. Legal Means of Escaping Taxation. The most important means by which corporations escape taxation are to be found in two recognized institutions of the New York tax system. To this extent the evasion is accomplished by thoroughly legal means. These means are through New York's peculiar system of deduc- ting indebtedness and of exempting, through omission, good will. In a large number of states of the Union, corporations are per- mitted to deduct debts from credits, but in New York State cor- porations are permitted to deduct total indebtedness from per- sonal property. As a result of this provision it is possible for corporations to create a large bonded indebtedness, and thus to escape entirely from taxation upon personal property. Especially in the cases of those corporations having large amounts of valu- able personal property, these means of evading the personal prop- erty tax have been used. The extent to which this evasion is accomplished was brought out by the Committee's investigation into the relation between the amount of bonded indebtedness and outstanding capital stock of a large number of important New York corporations. In the appendix will be found two tables illustrating this statement. Appendix D-YI contains a tabulation of the bonded indebted- ness and capital stock outstanding of 36 representative domestic manufacturing corporations that were selected at random. Appen- dix D-VI-2 contains a list of 36 domestic mercantile and miscel- laneous corporations that were selected for the purpose of illus- trating the large bonded indebtedness. Appendix D-VI-1 may be said to be representative of manufacturing corporations as a group. Appendix D-VI cannot be said to be representative in- asmuch as those corporations were selected that had the largest bonded indebtedness. However, bot v tables illustrate what a JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 97 large portion of the possible personal property tax base of cor- porations is lost to New York State through these provisions. The amount of taxable base so lost runs up into many hundreds of million dollars annually. This one feature alone deprives the ]STew York personal property tax on corporations of all semblance of justice. The following is a summary of Appendix D-VI-1 : Number of corporations 36 Aggregate bonded debt $161,697,896 Aggregate capital stock outstanding 311,952,286 Bonded debt as per cent, of capital stock 51.8% The following is a summary of Appendix D-VI-2 : Number of corporations 38 Aggregate bonded debt $118,069,207 Aggregate capital stock outstanding 143,191,753 Bonded debt as per cent, of capital stock 82 . 4-% The question naturally arises why the framers of the Tax Law have enacted a provision containing such a large loophole. The question was answered by Professor Seligman at the hearings of the Joint Legislative Committee, as follows: " The whole system of personal property taxes arose be- for there were corporations; and when corporations de- veloped, about the middle of the century, they first began on a large scale in this State, they [legislators] simply slapped that section [debt-deduction section] because they thought it would solve the problem, and they did not realize that the situation was an entirely new one. We therefore go along in the old way, being one of the very few American states which still retain their primitive method of assessing corporations locally." The fallacy of the deduction of bonded indebtedness from personal property is evident to anyone who is familiar with modern corporation finance. Legally, to be sure, funded debt is iebt, but economically it is nothing of the kind. Economically |> 98 STATE OF NEW YORK it is a means of obtaining capital. This fact is recognized by all authorities upon corporation finance and is recognized in the accounting. Bonded indebtedness is but a part of the capitaliza- tion of the corporation, and in the average corporation accounting system, is included with capital stock under the general term of capitalization. A bonded debt is not looked upon by the cor- poration as a handicap, but as an advantage. While it is legally a debt of the corporation and occupies the position of a fixed charge, it is economically a part of the capitalization which provides the revenues of the corporation. Just as the capital stock, through a fiction of accounting, is a liability of the corpo- ration, so the bonded investment, through a legal fiction, is called a debt of the company. The corporation, however, looks upon the debt not as a disadvantage, but as an advantage, and the ques- tion which faces the corporation often is not whether there should be a debt, but as to the proper proportions of the capital which should be obtained through means of bonds and stock. It is clear, therefore, that no sound reason exists for the deduction of bonded indebtedness from personal property. The bonded indebtedness instead of decreasing the earning power of the corporation, in- creases it, and thus, instead of decreasing the ability of the corpo- ration to pay taxes, increases the ability. This fact has been recognized by the best tax commissions that have investigated the taxation of personal property of corporations in other states, and is also recognized by authorities on corporation finance. Another important intangible element that represents large earning power and therefore large ability to pay, is often grouped in the corporation balance sheet under the designation " good will." This item entirely escapes from taxation under the un- usual section of the New York Tax Law pertaining to personal property. In most states good will is not specifically designated for purposes of taxation, but is, however, taxable by implication under the general term " personal property." New York State, however, departs from the usual custom. In designating what personal property is taxable, New York State enumerates those items that are included in the term " personal property." Prob- ably through oversight the term " good will " was omitted from this enumeration. The courts, however, have decided that good will is not taxable under the New York Tax Law. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 99 The unreasonableness of this omission comes out clearly when we consider what the element of good will stands for in the modern corporation. The relation of good will to earning power, and therefore to taxpaying ability, is very clear. In many corpora- tions it represents nothing more than the capitalization of that part of the earning power which is not derived from tangible assets. To the extent that this is incorporated in patents and copyrights, it is of course not taxable legally under the general property tax. Economically, however, it represents taxpaying ability. But entirely apart from that portion of the good will which represents copyrights and patents, the remainder, especially in mercantile corporations, represents, in many cases, a large amount of the real earning power of the corporation. Indeed, it is cus- tomary in many corporations, after apportioning to their tangible assets a part of their income at a reasonable rate of interest, to capitalize the remainder of the income and designate it as good will. In some corporations it is becoming the custom to write off good will. This does not, however, destroy the earning capacity, but only covers it up in a different form. In either case, this intangible asset represents the best taxpaying ability of the corporation. This system deals with various types of corporations very un- fairly. Wherever the law is enforced, those corporations, the nature of the business of which requires a heavy investment in tangible personalty, are subject to a very heavy tax. Those cor- porations, on the other hand, the nature of whose business re- quires a very small investment in tangible assets, escape with almost no tax. For purposes of illustrating this, the Committee compiled a selected list of important domestic corporations having large earn- ing capacity as compared with their tangible assets. This tabula- tion is included in Appendix D-VIII, and contains a statement of the value of the capital stock outstanding, the total assets, and the value of the good will. The value of the good will was taken from the balance sheets of the corporations, as published in Mjoody's or Poor's Manual. In several cases it was found im- possible to determine precisely what proportion of the total assets 100 STATE OF NEW YOKK was made up of good will. In making up their balance sheets some corporations have the habit of grouping one or more items under the term good will. Very often patents, trade-marks, etc., are grouped under this heading. In come of these cases therefore it cannot be said that the total amount set opposite the term good will represents personalty that could be reached for purposes of taxation under any general property system. In most cases, how- ever, it is represented largely by intangible personalty that could be reached were the New York law altered so as to include good will within taxable personalty. And in almost every case it repre- sents a just source of taxation. Reference to Appendix D-VII will show that the 35 corporations there listed have an aggregate good will valued at $287,651,371, while the total aggregate assets of these corporations is only $497,327,898, and the capital stock is $405,569,070. The aggregate good will is 70.9 per cent of the capital stock outstanding and 57.8 per cent of the total assets. A few examples will serve for illustration: (1) The F. W. Company, possessing total assets of about $74,- 000,000, is absolutely untaxable in New York to the extent of $50,000,000. And yet this $50,000,000 represents little more than the capitalization, at a reasonable rate of return, of the very large earnings of one of the most prosperous of New York corporations. (2) Another example is that of X. Y. Z., with a good will valued at $15,000,000 out of a total asset of a little over $21,000,000. (3) Another prominent case is that of P. C. & Co., with total assets of less than $22,000,000, $18,000,000 of which is listed as good will. In conclusion, it should be pointed out that this intangible wealth can best be reached not by a general property tax, nor, indeed, by a classified property tax (for a certain portion of it cannot be reached by either), but by a tax levied according to earning capacity or net income. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 101 CHAPTER VH WHY CORPORATIONS ARE IMPELLED TO EVADE PERSONAL PROP- ERTY TAX In another portion of this report it has been pointed out that a large proportion of the corporations doing business in the State of J^ew York succeed in one way or another in evading entirely or almost entirely their personal property tax. In some cases this is done by making an arrangement with the local assessor whereby the corporation agrees to choose the domicile of that local assessor as ita principal place of business, providing the corpora- tion shall be greatly under assessed. In another case it is ac- complished by secrecy and deceit. In many cases it is accom- plished through a technicality of the law, and in a large number of cases it is accomplishel by legally evading the intent of the law through the means of large bonded indebtedness. The purpose of this paragraph is not to dwell upon the evasions of the law, but to point out the fact that only through evasion can the corporations avoid much injustice in matters of taxation. The present personal property tax law as applied to corporations is one of the most illogical, unenforced and unjust laws that has ever been put upon the American statute books. Were it honestly enforced many corporations would either be forced to leave the State or be forced into bankruptcy. This is especially true in the case of many manufacturing and mercantile corporations. In the case of these types of corporations, the nature of the business of which requires the carrying of a large stock of raw material and partly finished products, or a large stock of finished products, the enforcement of the personal property tax would result in not only great injustice to the corporation but in great injury to the State itself. The present personal property tax of twenty mills is equivalent to an income tax of from 25 to 40 per cent, upon that proportion of the assets embodied in personal property. Were this tax enforced those corporations whose assets were largely made up not of fixed capital but of current assets would be stimu- lated to remove from the State as soon as possible. Those corpora- tions whose assets were largely of specialized and fixed character and thus lacked a ready market would be forced to remain within the State, but in remaining within the State they would be forced STATE OF NEW YORK to compete upon unequal terms with corporations in other states. It is needless to say that new capital would not invest in the State of New York under such unfavorable conditions. Another most unfair aspect of the present personal property tax law is that when enforced it bears with great inequity upon those corporations that are struggling to keep upon their feet. A per- sonal property tax which amounts to 40 per cent, of the income may be paid by a corporation enjoying a, fairly large income, but a tax of this size when imposed upon a corporation that is strug- gling to get upon its feet would mean in some cases ruin. In the latter case it would result not in taking 40 per cent, of income, because there would be no income, but the taking of capital value. In looking up the financial condition of a large number of corporations in the State of New York for the purpose of ascer- taining whether or not corporations were paying the personal property tax according to the present tax law, the Committee found a number of corporations that were approaching dangerously near to bankruptcy. In some of these cases the corporations were forced to carry a large stock of tangible personalty. Had a gen- eral property tax been rigidly enforced upon the later, and had the corporations been unable to evade the law according to some of the well-known methods in this State, some of these particular cor- porations might have been forced to the wall. In considering, therefore, the extent to which the corporations are enabled to, and do, evade the personal property tax, it should always be borne in mind that the corporations are evading a most unjust tax, and moreover it should be borne in mind that the State has imposed upon the corporations in many cases the necessity either of evading this tax, or moving from the State, or going into bankruptcy. The unescapable conclusion is not that the tax should be rigidly enforced but that it is all wrong, out of date, palpably unjust, and should be supplanted by a fair system. PART VI TAXATION OF FOREIGN CORPORATIONS In no other state of the Union do foreign corporations consti- tute such a large proportion of the legitimate tax base as in New York State, and jet it is doubtful if in any other state of the Union these corporations bear such a small proportion of their fair tax burden. The problem of the foreign corporation is of such large importance that the subject calls for a thorough ex- amination. We shall deal with this subject under the following four heads : (1) The law regarding the taxation of the personal property of foreign corporations. (2) The failure of the law. (3) Why foreign corporations in New York should contribute substantially to both State and local government. (4) Foreign corporations as a tax base present yield and potential yield. THE LAW REGARDING THE TAXATION OF PERSONAL PROPERTY OF FOREIGN CORPORATIONS Section 7, subdivision 1, of the New York Tax Law, which applies to foreign corporations, reads as follows: " Nonresidents of the State doing business in the State, either as principals or partners, shall be taxed on the capital invested in such business, as personal property, at the place where such business is carried on, to the same extent as if they were residents of the State." The intrastate situs of foreign corporations, for purposes of assessment for taxation, is only at the principal place of business. (Bay State Shoe and LeatJi. Co. v. McLean, 80 N. Y. 254.) The principal place of business may not necessarily be where the cor- poration carries on its actual business or the larger amount of its business, but at the place named in its certificate filed under sec- tion 16 of the General Corporation Law as its principal place within the State. (Armstrong Cork Co. v. Barker, 157 N. Y. 159.) 104 STATE OF NEW YOEK In the matter of the taxation of foreign corporations, as in so many other sections of the Tax Law dealing with corporations, the exact meaning of the law is uncertain. It is impossible to know what property of foreign corporations is taxable and under what conditions such property is taxable, without referring to the court decisions. These decisions have cleared up the matter to some extent, but still leave considerable doubt as to several im- portant points. In 1915 the Department of Taxes and Assess- ments of the City of New York issued a pamphlet entitled " Memorandum of Examinations on Applications for Correction of Personal Assessments." This pamphlet contains the best short summary of the essential. points affecting the taxation of foreign corporations that has_ appeard. The following brief summary consists largely of extracts from this pamphlet. Recurring to section 7, subdivision 1, of the Tax Law, the question arises as to when capital is invested in New York, and as to when foreign corporations may be said to be doing business within the State. In regard to the question as to when capital is invested, the following may be said. If a, nonresident actually has capital invested in business in the State of New York, the amount of such capital is to be determined by the same rules as would apply to the resident if the resident owned no property other than such capital and had no debts other than debts arising out of the conduct of such business. To determine the amount of the assessment, the aggregate of taxable personal property must be ascertained, and from that amount must be deducted such debts as were incurred in the purchase of such taxable personal property and such debts as affect and lessen the value of the thing subject to taxation, viz., the capital invested here. (Heeler- Jones- Jew ell Milling Co. v. Barker, 147 N. Y. 31.) Section 6 of the Tax Law reads as follows : "All real and personal property subject to taxation shall be assessed at the full value thereof, provided, however, that the owner of personal property shall be allowed a deduction from the full value of his taxable personal property to the ex- tent of the just debts owing by him but no such deduction shall be allowed by reason of the indebtedness of the owner JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 105 contracted or incurred in the purchase of nontaxable prop- erty or securities owned by him or held for his benefit, nor for or on account of any indirect liability as surety, guarantor, indorser or otherwise, nor for or on account of any debt or liability contracted or incurred for the purpose of evading taxation." The prohibition of this section against the deduction of debts incurred for nontaxable property or securities is applicable to the debts of a nonresident. In regard to what constitutes " doing business in the State " the following may be said. If a nonresident corporation is to be subjected to taxation on its capital invested in business in this State, the business must be continuous and permanent and not transitory. No general rule can be given that will make it pos- sible to determine in every case when a business is a permanent one and when it is temporary. It is necessary to examine the nature of the business as well as the intention of the nonresident. The following summary is quoted verbatim from the pamphlet referred to: " The decisions of the courts in particular cases have been somewhat in conflict, but in recent years they have limited the character of a business which may be regarded as perma- nent and continuous. " The law was enacted in 1855, and shortly thereafter in 1861 the case of Parker Mills v. Commissioners of Taxes was decided. (23 1ST. Y. 242.) An extract from the opinion in this case recites the facts as follows : " ' It had a depot and agent in the city of ISTew York, to whom it transmitted nails for sale. Its only business within this State consisted in making such sales, the proceeds of which were remitted at once to the corporation in Massa- chusetts, and where sales were upon credit, the securities received were sent to the corporation for collection. It ap- peared by the testimony of the agent that the sales amounted to about $300,000, and that the value of the nails which he then had in store was $10,00'0. 7 " Nothing is said in this opinion as to whethei or not the 106 STATE OF NEW YORK Parker Mills had a bank account in New York. It is certain that they carried a large stock of goods continuously and per- manently in the city of New York. Nevertheless, it was held that the Parker Mills did not have capital invested in business in the State of New York subject to assessment pur- suant to section 7 of the Tax Law. " On the other hand, a case decided in 1903 on a similar state of fact held that there was capital invested in business in this State. (Dumnd-Ruel v. Wells, 41 Misc. 145 ; affd., 92 App. Div. 622, without opinion.) Durand-Ruel had a stock of pictures of the average value of $75,000. They maintained a continuous bank account here sufficient to pay current expenses, consisting of salaries, rents and import duties. As paintings are sold they are re- placed by new ones. They leased an entire building for $20,000 a year, reserving one floor for themselves, and sub- letting the remainder. " In two recent decisions the fact that a foreign corpora- tion had no bank account in its own name in New York seems to have been an important if not a determining factor in holding that these corporations did not have capital in- vested in business subject to taxation. In one of the cases mentioned, the Tower case, the facts appear from the follow- ing extract from the opinion of the Appellate Division : " ' The relator is a foreign corporation organized under the laws of the State of Maine, in which State it has its principal place of business. Its plant is located in Massa- chusetts, where it carries on the business of manufacturing water-proof clothing. It maintains and had maintained a salesroom in the city of New York for the past five or six years, and at the time of the levying of the assessment had goods on hand at its place of business in the city of New York of the value of $13,490, and the average value of the stock kept on hand in such place of business was about $8,000. The store which it occupies is on the ground floor of 35 Howard street, is about 28 feet wide by 100 feet in depth. In connection with the business it has a manager, JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 107 two salesmen, a typewriter and a bill and shipping clerk. It keeps no bank account in the city of New York and all checks, drafts and other payments for goods sold are remit- ted to Boston for deposit. The manager draws a draft upon the relator in Massachusetts upon an average of once a week for money sufficient to pay the expenses connected with the business, although some money, the proceeds of the business, is kept in the safe at its place of business here and is used to pay running expenses. This sum is never very large. The goods which are shipped to the New York house are mainly reshipped and distributed to various parts of the country, although above one-tenth of the goods received are sold in the city of New York; it sometimes runs above that per- centage. Much of the larger proportion of the goods received are reshipped to points outside the State of New York/ (98 App. Div. 82; affd., 182 K Y. 533.) " The second case was that of A. Leschen & Sons, which was decided by Judge 0' Gorman, on the authority of the Tower case, and the assessment was canceled. The following facts appear from the petition: " ' Leschen & Sons was a foreign corporation organized under the laws of the State of Missouri. Its business was to manufacture wire rope, and its plant was in- the State of Missouri. It had a branch office at 90' West street, in the borough of Manhattan, city of New York, for which it paid $7,000 a year. It had maintained an office in the city of New York continuously for over seven years, and in 1902 had made application to the Comptroller of the State of New York for the usual certificate to do business under the Gen- eral Corporations Law. It maintained a storage room where goods were kept on hand continuously, the average amount being about $14,000. The New York office was advertised as a branch office on the bill heads and office stationery. The majority of the sales orders filled from, stock in New York were sent direct to the main office in St. Louis, but in many cases goods were sold directly from stock in New York, and the proceeds of the sales were received in New York. 108 STATE OF XEW YORK Checks were mailed to the main office in St. Louis, but cash was retained to pay current expenses, and any balance de- posited in the personal account of the manager who remitted checks for these balances to the main office.' " The opinion was printed in the New York Law Journal on February 14, 1910. "A consideration of the Tower, Parker Mills, and Leshcen cases seems to make it clear that there must be a stock of goods kept in E"ew York continuously, and there must be a bank account in the name of the nonresident assessed." In regard to the taxation of tangible personal property, sec- tion 7, subdivision 2, reads as follows : " The personal property of nonresidents of the State hav- ing an actual situs in the State, and not forming a part of capital invested in business in the State, shall be assessed in the name of the owner thereof for the purpose of identifi- cation and taxed in the tax district where such property is situated, unless exempt by law. This subdivision shall not apply to money, or negotiable collateral securities, deposited by, or debts owing to, such nonresidents nor shall it be con- strued as in any manner modifying or changing the law im- posing a tax on real estate mortgage securities." The comment of the New York City Department of Taxes and Assessments upon this section is as follows: " It is understood to have been the intention of the drafts- men of this subdivision chiefly to tax household furniture, pictures, rugs, yachts, habitually kept in this State by non- residents of the State. But the language is capable of a much broader construction, and may be deemed to confer the right to tax as property, and not as ' capital invested in busi- ness/ merchandise and other personal property having an actual situs in this State, owned by a nonresident. So that, in case nonresident merchants have goods, store fixtures and JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 109 other personalty in this State, and yet are not doing business in this State as that expression in section 7, subdivision 1 has been construed by the courts, this subdivision 2 permits of the taxation of such goods, etc., as property just as a resi- dent would be taxed upon it. In taxing under this subdivi- sion, however, no deduction of debts is allowed." Failure of the Law Investigation of County Records. The investigations of the Committee disclose the fact that foreign corporations as a group escape paying taxation upon personal property almost entirely. For the purpose of ascertaining the extent of the evasion of the personal property tax by foreign corporations, the Committee at- tempted to obtain information from the localities as to the taxa- tion of foreign corporations. Section 61 of the Tax Law provides as follows: " The clerk of each board of supervisors shall on or before the second Monday in December, transmit to the State Board of Tax Commissioners, in the form to be prescribed by such Board of Tax Commissioners, a certificate of return of the aggregate assessed and equalized valuation of the real and personal estate in each tax district as the value of such real estate has been created by such board, and the amount of taxes assessed thereon for town, city, school, county and State purposes, also the aggregate assessed valuation of per- sonal property classified as follows: * * * Subdivision 6. Property of foreign corporations assessed pursuant to sec- tion 7." An examination of the statements of the aggregate valuations of personal property pursuant to section 61 of the Tax Law in the several towns and cities in each county, filed in the office of the State Board of Tax Commissioners, disclosed the fact that only eight counties out of the sixty-two in the State returned this in- formation in partial or complete form as required by law. Cor- 110 STATE OF NEW YORK respondence with the clerks of the boards of supervisors and tax assessors of the several counties disclosed the fact that in very few localities is any attempt made to ascertain the taxable personalty of foreign corporations. The data obtained, however, in this in vestigation was too incomplete to determine precisely to what ex- tent the personal property of foreign corporations escaped taxa- tion. The evidence obtained, however, establishes a very strong presumption that less than 10 per cent of the personal property of foreign corporations liable to taxation is actually assessed. In the second investigation the Committee obtained the names of some 250 important foreign corporations known to carry on large business in the State of New York and to have considerable amounts of actual taxable personalty permanently located in this State. To these corporations was sent a printed blank form re- questing information as to the following items : (1) The percentage of the total assets of the corporation in- vested permanently in New York .State. (2) The amount of taxable personalty permanently located in New York. (3) The locality which the corporation claimed as its principal place of business in New York. (4) The assessed value of personal property in New York. (5) The actual amount of personal property tax paid in New York. The failure of the corporations even to acknowledge these re- quests was enlightening. Of the 250 corporations only about thirty acknowledged the receipt of the Committee's communica- tion, and only nine attempted to fill out the blank, and of the nine only four actually filled in the required information. Several of the corporations reported that they paid no taxes, and most main- tained that inasmuch as they were foreign corporations they were not liable to taxation. It is perfectly evident from these replies that the average foreign corporation either believes that it is not liable for taxation under New York law or else knows that it <san escape under the present system. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 111 A great many of the foreign corporations having valuable tangi- ble assets in the State of New York have undoubtedly been ad- vised by their lawyers that their tangible personal property can- not be taxed under the 1902 decision of the Court of Appeals, known as the McLean decision. The relation of this decision to the New York Tax Law was summed up by Mr. Henry M. Powell of the New York Bar in a paper read before the 1915 New York State Conference on Taxation, as follows: " Ever since 1855 there has been a statute on our books by which the property of a nonresident invested in business shall be taxed to the same extent as the property of residents. In 1902 it was held by the Court of Appeals in the City of New York v. McLean, 170 N. Y. 374, that this tax could not be collected by an action in personam. In other words, our remedy must remain one in rem, or against the property. Since that time our statute has not been amended to conform to the opinion of the Court of Appeals and the result has been that property of nonresidents, invested in business, pays only a nominal tax because there is no effective remedy for the collection of the tax. In 1901 before the McLean de- cision, the annual tax collection in the City of New York for nonresidents was about $900,000. In 1913 and for some years prior thereto, it has averaged about $500,000, although population has increased 50 per cent and property of all kinds has correspondingly increased." Testimony Concerning Failure of the Personal Property Tax in Regard to Foreign Corporations At the public hearings of the New York Joint Legislative Com- mittee on Taxation held in the various cities of the State of New York, 1915, the testimony of the tax officials, both State and local, was unanimous in bearing out the statement that foreign corpora- tions escape almost entirely from paying any of the tax burden under the personal property tax. Chairman Martin Saxe of the State Tax Commission was asked to state the effect of the McLean 112 STATE OF NEW YORK decision upon the collection of nonresident taxes. He answered, " Well, it has had the effect of making those taxes practically uncollectible." Mr. A. C. Playdell, Secretary of the New York Tax Eeform Association, testified that there is practically no personal prop- erty of nonresidents collected in the State of New York outside of New York City. Mr. Lawson Purdy, of the Board of Tax Commissioners of New York city, in answer to the effect of the McLean decision, testified as follows: " Since that decision was rendered, the City of New York, in practice, has been without power to enforce the payment of taxes levied pursuant to section 7, Some years ago the amount of uncollectible taxes which had been levied pur- suant to that section was a very serious matter. In recent years, where it has been found impossible to collect taxes from a particular person or corporation, pursuant to section 7, the assessment has been abandoned." In fine, Mr. Pleydell says that there is no personalty of foreign corporations assessed outside of New York City, and Mr. Purdy says that even in New York City the tax is, in the main, unen- forceable. Furthermore, Mr. Purdy testified that he could see no way under the general scheme of the tax laws that now exist to reach foreign corporations. In the city of Rochester, Mr. Joseph C. Wilson, President of the Board of Assessors, in reply to the query as to the amount col- lected from foreign corporations, stated: " Very few can we get. The majority of foreign corporations, particularly the large ones, fix their main office for the State of New York in New York City or Buffalo, mostly in New York City, and in that way es- cape." He further testified that they carried large amounts of goods in Rochester that could not be assessed. From the combined testimony of Messrs. Saxe, Pleydell, Purdy and Wilson, it is unmistakably evident that foreign corporations are escaping substantially tax-free in regard to all of their vast investments in personalty in the State of New Tor*. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 113 Why Foreign Corporations Should Make a Substantial Con- tribution to the support of State and Local Govern- ment. In regard to foreign corporations, New York State occupies a unique position, and this unique position explains in a large part why the foreign corporation question is of so great importance. In order to appreciate the peculiar significance of this problem, it is necessary to examine the relation of New York to the business of the foreign corporation. The first thing to call attention to is the tremendous taxpaying ability of foreign corporations doing business in New York State. And this taxpaying ability is surprisingly large, whether measured by the tangible assets situated in the State, the business transacted in the State, the product produced in the State, or the financial concerns handled within the State. An examination of each of the above discloses the fact that foreign corporations own a large percentage of tangible assets in the State and transact a larger percentage of the total business done in the State than the aver- age citizen has any comprehension of. In this respect the position of New York is unique and in several ways stands out quite apart from most of her sister states. Some comprehension of the vast- ness of this business can be obtained by examining the follow- ing facts : In the first place, the position which New York City occupies as the financial centre of America attracts to it for the transaction of its financial concerns a large proportion of all the important cor- porations in the United States. The importance and indeed even the necessity of transacting the financial concerns in New York City are too well known among business men to call for any elaboration. It suffices to say that out of the privilege of trans- acting financial business in this State come great advantages to those corporations establishing offices here. And these advantages mean larger earnings and greater taxpaying ability. In the second place, New York State possesses within its boun- daries ten million people, or approximately one-tenth the popu- lation of the entire United States. In addition to this, there is another five million people in the cities and towns about New 114 STATE OF NEW YORK York City that technically reside in other States, but actually live within the New York market. The opportunity of reaching such a large population within such a circumscribed area is taken ad- vantage of by almost every important selling agency in America. Several large foreign corporations, each one of which is capital- ized for several million dollars, sell a large part of their product through branch offices scattered throughout the State. They draw tremendous profits from this State and so increase their earnings and taxpaying ability. In the third place, in many lines of industry New York is the selling market of America. Many foreign corporations who have their factories in the New England and Middle States and even in the Western States, find it necessary to come to New York to market their product. A good illustration is the wholesale woolen industry. This industry is largely owned and controlled by foreign corporations. Its mills are scattered all over New England and many other States. Yet the industry is absolutely dependent upon New York for the sale of its goods. The home office of most of these corporations is found in other states, but the selling office is located in New York City. Every year the representatives of these great corporations travel throughout the United States exhibiting their samples, but it is a well-known fact that many of the sales are actually made in New York where the buyers flock every season. To the woolen industry as well as to other big industries the New York market is a. tremendous asset which is reflected in increased earning power and taxpaying ability. In the fourth place, the unrivaled shipping facilities of New York have attracted many corporations that are incorporated in other states. The advantage of New York in this respect is evidenced by the great number of foreign corporations that have in recent years shut down or dismantled their plants in other states, and have built new ones in the tide-water district in New York State, especially on Long Island. One reason, however, why foreign corporations control such a large percentage of New York business is due not to the fact that foreign corporations come to New York, but that the New York plants go to the foreign corporations. In this respect a remarkable JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 115 transition has been taking place during the last few years. Many plants, both mercantile and manufacturing, that were once the property of domestic corporations have become the property of foreign corporations. An examination of Poor's or Moody' s Man- ual discloses part of this very interesting history. As the great trusts and holding companies have developed, they have absorbed many of the smaller corporations. Had these larger companies incorporated in New York, it would have made little difference from the point of view of taxation. Since, however, they have mostly incorporated in New Jersey, Delaware and other states, the effect has been to carry the domicile of much of our wealth over into other states. As a revenue producer it is clear, therefore, that that great mass of personal property belonging to foreign corporations is of little use to New York State. It is impossible to estimate how much New York is losing through the absorption of her domestic corporations by foreign corporations. It has been estimated, however, that the State has been losing not less than a million dollars of revenue every year as a result of the McLean decision. In summarizing the answer to the question why foreign cor- porations ought to make substantial contributions, we must say: In the first place, these foreign corporations enjoy unusual benefits in New York City. The opportunities which these cor- porations avail themselves of, whether they be the financial ac- commodations, the shipping facilities, or the strategic merchan- dising possibilities, all add greatly to the prosperity and the in- come-paying ability. An office in New York for financial or sell- ing purposes is a great asset. These corporations spend millions in advertising annually and from that advertising gain an earn- ing power. The increased earning power, however, which New York contributes, represents in many cases a gift of the city and State. This same increased earning power enlarges their ability to pay taxes. Thus, New York actually adds in an important degree both to the capital value and to the income of these corporations. On the other hand, the privilege extended to foreign corpora- tions cost the citizens of this State large sums. Fire protection, police protection and all the other expenses that are incurred in 116 STATE OF ^\EW YORK keeping up a great trade and financial centre are largely increased by the presence of these foreign corporations. From every point of view, whether from that of the cost of the service, the benefit derived or the ability to pay, the answer is clear ; foreign corpora- tions should contribute liberally to the support of New York State government. PART VII NEW YORK SYSTEM OF TAXING MANUFACTURES CHAPTER I STATE TAX The policy of New York in regard to the taxation of manu- factures for State purposes has-been for many years practically that of exemption. The law governing the taxation of manu- facturing for State purposes is included in sections 182 and 183 of the Tax Law. Section 182 reads, in part, as follows: ff Franchise tax on corporations. For the privilege of doing business or exercising its corporate franchises in this State, every corporation, joint-stock company or association, doing business in this State, shall pay to the State Treasurer annually, in advance, an annual tax to be computed upon the basis of the amount of its capital stock, employed during the preceding year within this State, and upon each dollar of such amount. The measure of the amount of capital stock employed in this State shall be such a portion of the issued capital stock as the gross assets employed in any business within this State bear to the gross assets wherever employed in business." Then follows a detailed statement of the law which is exceed- ingly complex. Manufacturing corporations, however, are exempt, providing 40 per cent, of their assets are invested in the State of New York. Section 183 reads in part as follows: laundering corporations, manufacturing corpo- rations to the extent only of the capital actually employed in this State in manufacturing, and in the sale of the product of such manufacturing, mining corporations wholly engaged in mining ores within this State * * * shall be exempt from the payment of the taxes prescribed by section 182 of this chapter. But such a laundering, manufacturing or mining corporation snail not be exempt from the payment of such tax, unless at least 40 per centum of the capital stock 118 STATE OF NEW YORK of such corporation is invested in property in this State and used by it in its laundering, manufacturing or mining busi- ness in this State." According to the law, it would seem that a large number of manufacturing corporations should be taxable for State purposes. An analysis of the business and financial statements of many im- portant New York manufacturing corporations as given in the corporation manuals, would seem to indicate that an important number of such corporations have less than 40 per cent, of their assets invested in the State. It appears, however, that no very serious attempt had been made to ascertain which of these corpo- rations are not entitled to the exemption of section 183, and that practically all manufacturing corporations, regardless of the amount of their tangible assets invested in New York State, escape paying the general franchise tax on corporations. CHAPTER II LOCAL TAXATION OF MANUFACTURING CORPORATIONS Corporations are taxable locally upon their personal property under section 12 of the Tax Law. This law, with its peculiarities, has been described in Part V of this report. Everything there stated in regard to the inability to enforce the law applies with particular emphasis to the manufacturing corporations. It is sufficient to state here that not only is the law enforced very un- evenly and with considerable inequity as between various manu- facturing centres, but that it yields a comparatively insignificant revenue. The inequity of the present law is well brought out by the statistics presented by Mr. John D. Kernan of Utica. He pre- sented a report at the First New York State Conference on Taxa- tion, and at the request of the Committee, brought the statistics of that report up to date and presented similar facts at the Joint Legislative Committee hearings in New York City. The facts presented in his paper before the New York State Conference on Taxation showed unmistakably that manufacturers in some lo- calities of the State were assessed at ridiculously low percentages, whereas in other localities their personal property was assessed at a fairly high value, thus producing an inequality seriously JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 119 detrimental to the latter business interests. In his testimony be- fore us he summarized his investigation as follows ; and the situa- tion of which he describes in respect to Utica, Home and the neighboring towns is typical of the inequalities which exist throughout the State. " I had this prepared * * * in three tables, first showing the manufacturing corporations that are assessed for personal property in the city of Utica, showing the amount of the personal property assessment in the year 1914; showing the real property assessment for that year, and that being pertiment, in order to determine the rate of taxation as based upon Bradstreet's estimates, and then con- taining Bradstreet's published estimates * * * estimated wealth of each of those corporations. Then I have next done the same thing with all the manufacturing corporations as- sessed for personal property, outside of the cities of Rome and Utica, and then I have prepared a similar table for Rome city * * *. "An examination of the results of the footing of these tables shows that in Utica the manufacturing corporations are assessed upon personal property 25 or 36 per cent, of their estimated wealth as given by Bradstreet. That the corporations in the counties outside of Rome and Utica are assessed from 11 to 15 per cent. * * * That in the City of Rome manufacturing corporations are assessed from 7 to 11 per cent, of their estimated wealth.*" CHAPTER III NEW YORK MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY AS A TAXABLE BASE In considering the possibilities of using the manufacturing industry for purposes of taxation, the first question to ask is, to what extent the tax policy of the State should be altered to con- form with the State's broader economic policy. It is the settled policy of the State of New York, as of nearly every other state in the Union, to attract capital into the manufacturing industries. For this purpose it is necessary to establish no conditions that would in any way tend to drive this industry from the State. The ability of the industry to grow depends upon the relative 120 STATE OF NEW YORK advantages which it enjoys as compared with those competing corporations in other states and foreign countries. The question, therefore, arises, would a material increase in the rate of taxa- ation affect to any appreciable degree the ability of domestic manufacturing corporations to compete in the American and world markets. In regard to foreign competition, it may be said that it is the settled policy of the country that American manu- facturers shall be protected against competition of the foreign manufacturers, and to thisi end the protective tariff shall be levied at a rate which will compensate for the difference in the cost of manufacturing at home and abroad. Whenever taxes are levied by American states, they enter into the cost of the manufactured articles, and to that extent are taken account of in the framing of the tariff schedules. We may, therefore, dismiss from further consideration the effect of New York tax rates upon the ability of the New York manufacturing corporation to compete with foreign manufacturing corporations. In the matter, however, of competition with corporations of other states, the subject cannot be dismissed so quickly. In the United States the American manufacturer enjoys the largest free- trade market existing anywhere in the world. Whatever the con- ditions of the foreign market, it is absolutely necessary that the New York manufacturer be able to compete in this large Ameri- can free-trade market upon equal terms with corporations of other States. To do this it is necessary that New York offer facilities for manufacturing that will enable the New York corporation to produce goods for as low a cost as any other State. If New York should impose a tax rate that would increase the cost of manufacturing to any considerable degree as compared with that of foreign corporations, not only would new capital refuse to come into this State, but capital already invested would leave so far as possible. The whole matter, therefore, hinges upon the relative facilities offered to manufacturing industries in this State as compared to others. We believe that the advantages which the State of New York now offers to manufacturing corporations are so much greater than those of any of its competing states that any reasonable increase in the tax rate would not in any way tend to drive capital from this State. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 121 The principal factors which attract investment of outside capi- tal to the manufacturing industries of the State are (1) Nearness to abundant supplies raw materials; (2) Transportation facilities; (3) Labor market; (4) Power facilities. For purposes of ascertaining the relative advantages of New York in regard to all of these factors, there is no better source than the bulletin of the 13th Census of the United States dealing with manufactures of New York. The advantage of New York in regard to raw materials is set forth as follows : u The geographic position and topography of New York, as well as the abundant natural wealth of its fields, forests, mines, and quarries, have contributed to its industrial de- velopment and have been instrumental in making it the lead- ing manufacturing State of the Union." In regard to transportation facilities, the following: " The Hudson river, the Erie canal, connecting Lake Erie with the Hudson river, and a system of canals which con- nect Lake Ontario with the Erie canal and Lake Champlain with the Hudson river, form a network of inland waterways for the exchange of various commodities within the State and furnish excellent communication by water from Duluth and Chicago in the West and from various points in Canada on the North to New York City, thereby affording an outlet for coastwise and foreign commerce through the most im- portant seaport in the United States. A large majority of the commercial and manufacturing centres of the State are located on these waterways or on the connecting waterways which border the <State. The 8,448 miles of steam-railway trackage within the State also afford excellent transportation facilities." The advantage of New York to the manufacturer in the matter of transportation facilities is fully borne out by the testimony of the manufacturers themselves. Hon. John D. Kernan of Utica, 122 STATE OF NEW YORK in appearing before the Joint Legislative Committee, testified as follows : " The coming opportunities that the State is going to have with the opening of the Barge Canal, The transportation opportunities are going to be greater in the State of New York, when that is opened, through the influence that they will have, not only in the rate that it will give itself, but in the control that it will give over railroad rates, than any other place in the United States. " And again he stated: " New .York State has, over and above Pennsylvania, or Connecticut, or Rhode Island, or any other State, great ad- vantages for manufacturing industries, and this is very well illustrated by the fact that for fifty years the trunk lines have had to maintain a differential of two or three cents a hundred for like service, in favor against New York State, in favor of Philadelphia, Baltimore, Newport News and those Southern ports, etc., New Orleans. Other- wise the natural advantages of New York would draw all the traffic here, and it has not been thought wise by the trunk line people to permit that to be done. Now, that illustrates the situation New York has as to its natural advantages for manufacturing, etc." In regard to labor facilities, it is sufficient to state that New York enjoys the greatest labor market in America. Mention should be made of the important advantages which have come to the manufacturing industries of the State through the large expenditures of New York in recent years for develop- ment of barge canals. For this purpose the State has and is now expending millions of dollars. The importance of these improvements to the manufacturing industry can hardly be overestimated. Indeed, when measures providing for these expenditures were put before the people for ratification, the chief argument advanced at the time was that the construction of these canals would cover the State with manufac- turing towns and cities. A study of the distribution of the im- portant manufacturing cities and of the growth of these cities since these improvements have been made bear out this contention. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 123 In view of the advantages stated above, there appears no reason- able doubt that the manufacturing industry of the State could bear a considerable increase in its burden of taxation without driving capital from the State and with no fear of deterring new capital from entering the State. In this connection it should be noted that in many recent consolidations the larger corporations have shut down their plants located in other states and are now building new plants in New York State. The importance of the manufacturing industry as compared with that of other great industries in New York is so great that an increase in taxation of this industry at a very low rate would yield a large revenue. For the purpose of gauging the potential- ities of the manufacturing industry as a tax base, it is important therefore to consider the extent and growth of manufactures. This can be done in no better way than by quoting some extracts from the brief general summary of the 1910 Census Bulletin deal- ing with New York manufactures. "Although New York has important interests in agriculture and mining, its predominance is most marked in manufac- turing. Since the completion of the Erie canal in 1825, New York has held the foremost rank in this respect. * * * " In 1849 the total value of the manufactured products of New York, including those of the neighborhood and hand industries, amounted to $237,597,249, while in 1909, ex- clusive of the value of the products of the neighborhood and hand industries, it reached a total of $3,369,490,192, or more than fourteen times that in 1849. During the same period the population of the State increased 194.2 per cent. In 1849 an average of 199,349 wage earners, representing 6.4 per cent of the total population, were employed in manu- factures, while in 1909 an average of 1,003,981 wage earners or 11 per cent of the total population, were so engaged. During this period the gross value of products per capita of the total population of the State increased from $77 to $370. " In 1909 the State of New York had 44,935 manufactur- ing establishments, which gave employment to ah average of 1,203,241 persons during the year and paid out $743,- 263,000 in salaries and wages. Of the persons employed, 124 STATE OF NEW YOKK 1,003,981 were wage earners. These establishments turned out products to the value of $3,369,490,000, to produce which materials costing $1,856,904,000 were utilized. The value added by manufacture was thus $1,512,586,000, which figure, as explained in the introduction, best represents the net wealth created by manufacturing operations during the year." The relative importance of the manufacturing industry of New York is further illustrated by the wide diversity in the manufac- turing activities of the State. " With the exception of Penn- sylvania, the diversity is greater in New York than in any other State in the Union." Of the 264 classifications used in the presentation of the 1909 manufactures statistics for the country as a whole, 243 were represented in New York. The size and great wealth of many of these manufacturing cor- porations that are now almost entirely escaping their fair burden of the general property tax, so far as personalty is concerned, is well brought out by the following statistics taken from page 4 of the 1910 Bulletin dealing with manufactures in New York. " The table referred to gives separate statistics for 139 industries or industry groups for which products valued at more than $1,000,000 were reported in 1909. These in- dustries include 12 with products exceeding $50,000,000 in value, 20 with products between $25,000,000 and $50,000,- 000 in value, and 26 with products between $10,000,000 and $25,000,000, making an aggregate of 58 industries with a value of products in excess of $10,000,000 each. The other industries shown separately comprise 30 with products be- tween $5,000,000 and $10,000,000 in value, and 51 with products between $1,000,000 and $5,000,000. " In addition to the industries presented separately in the table, there were 32 other industries in the State which re- ported products in 1909 to the value of $1,000,000 or over, comprising 5 with products exceeding $10,000,000 in value, 2 with products between $5,000,000 and $10,000.000 in value, and 25 with products between $1,000,000 and $5,000,- 000 in value." JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 125 POTENTIALITIES OF THE MANUFACTURING INDUSTRY AS A TAX- ABLE BASE Tlie possibilities of the manufacturing industry as a taxable base will be grasped by an examination of the statistics of manu- facturing published, respectively, by the Federal Census Bureau in 1910 and the Internal Revenue Bureau in 1914. The follow- ing are the principal statistics taken from the Federal census. They are for the year 1909 : Total capital invested in manufacturing in New York $2,779,496,814 Value of products 3,369,490,192 Value added by manufacture 1,512,58,5,850 'Net returns 383.249,162 The following statistics are taken from the 1914 report of In- ternal Revenue Department, in regard to the receipts from the Federal Income Tax: Number of manufacturing corporations re- turning income tax data 12,640 Number of manufacturing corporations whose returns show tax due 6,446 Capital stock of domestic manufacturing cor- porations $6,644,640,357 84 Bonded and other indebtedness. 2,134,031,252 41 Net income 522,666,412 05 In comparing these two sets of data it should be noted that the internal revenue statistics of the capital stock of domestic cor- porations was more than double the census statistics of the total capital invested in manufacturing in New York. This difference is partly to be accounted for by the increase in the growth of manufactures between the years 1909 and 1914, and partly by the fact that the Census statistics undoubtedly underestimated the actual capital investment in manufactures in New York State. It is possible also that the Internal Revenue statistics, in in- cluding the total capital stock of domestic manufacturing corpo- rations irrespective of where the property may be located, thereby 126 STATE OF NEW YORK takes in a larger item than that represented by the capital in- vestment in New York State of foreign corporations, the latter item, of course, not being included within the Internal Kevenue statistics for New York. It is believed, however, that the In- ternal Revenue statistics are fairly representative of the total capital investment in manufactures in the State of New York. CHAPTER IV THE YIELD IN NEW YORK In considering the yield of manufactures as a tax base it is necessary to distinguish carefully between the yields of the fol- lowing separate taxes : (1) The yield of manufacturing taxes for State purposes. (2) The yield of the personal property tax of manufacturing corporations for local purposes. (3) The yield of real estate taxes for local purposes. (4) The aggregate yield of manufacturing taxes, both State and local, for all purposes. ' In regard to the yield of the manufacturing corporations for State purposes, we have shown above that it is insignificant. Likewise, the yield of personal property taxes for local purposes is ridiculously low. The yield of the real estate tax for local purposes represents a large part, and in many cases nearly all, of the total contribution made by manufacturing corporations for all state and local purposes. This fact is of particular signifi- cance for the reason that only a comparatively small percentage of the total investment of manufacturing corporations is found in real estate. In other words, a small part of the total invest- ment of manufacturing corporations yields a very large part of the tax contribution of manufactures. This means, not that the real estate is taxed heavily, but that most of the property escapes. U. 8. Census Figures. Inasmuch as the taxes paid by manu- facturers in the various localities are not segregated in the records, it is impossible to obtain anything like a correct estimate of the amount of taxes contributed in the year 1914 or 1915 for all purposes. The best estimate which we have is that collected by the Federal Census for the year 1909. In this report the Census Bureau collected data as to the total taxes paid by manufacturers, JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 127 both for State and Federal purposes, for every state in the Union. In this investigation the manufacturers were asked to divide their total tax contribution into (a) internal revenue taxes, (b) all other taxes. The item entitled " all other taxes " included the total taxes paid by manufacturers for all purposes of both state and local government. In 1909 the manufacturers of New York State paid $10,844,403. For purposes of appreciating the relative importance of this contribution of the manufacturers it is helpful to look at it from several points of view. We may compare the contribution of manufacturers to the total revenue receipts of the State, or we may compare the contribution of the manufacturers to the total capital investment in manufactures in the State. For the purpose of these comparisons it would be well if we could have the statistics under all of these items for the corre- sponding year. This it is impossible to obtain. However, we have the figures for these various items for periods only four years apart, and they may be used for purposes of these compar- isons. For the year 1912 we have a record of the total wealth of the State of New York, which is $25,011,105,223. For the year 1909 we have the capital investment in manufactures which is $2,779,496,814. For the year 1913 we have the total revenue receipts of the State, which is $330,622,071. And for the year 1909 we have the taxes paid by manufacturing corporations as stated above. In making these comparisons we must compare the capital invested in manufactures for the year 1909 to the total wealth in 1912. The discrepancy in years is not important for two reasons. In the first place, the capital investment in manufactures does not include the total capital investment in manufactures. The census does not include establishments which are idle during the entire year or had products valued at less than $500. It does not contain securities and loans representing investments in other enterprises, and it contained no lands or buildings rented. In the second place, the discrepancy between years is not important because after allowing a reasonable in- crease in the value of the investment between 1909 and 1912, the results for purposes of our comparisons are unappreciable. In comparing the taxes paid by manufactures in 1909 with total revenue receipts of 1913, we are possibly underestimating 128 STATE OF NEW YORK to a small degree the percentage of total revenues contributed by manufacturers. This underestimation, however, is so small that it loses its significance in the comparison made, and moreover it should be borne in mind that the statistics of taxes paid by manu- facturers for the year 1909 included " all taxes paid other than internal revenue." In comparing total taxes paid by manufacturers to the total revenue receipts, we find the following: The total revenue re- ceipts, for the year 1913 were $330,622,071; the total taxes paid by manufacturers in 1909 for all purposes, State and local, were $10,844,403, or in other words, manufactures paid only 3.3 per cent of the total revenue receipts. Bearing this in mind, we may now compare the total capital investment in manufactures in the State of New York to the total wealth of New York. The total capital investment in manufactures in 1909 was $2,779,496,814, while the total wealth in 1912 was $25,011,105,223. The capital investment in manufactures was 11.1 per cent of the total wealth. In other words, while the manufacturing -industry possesses 11.1 per cent of the total wealth of the State, it paid in taxes for all pur- poses only 3.3 per cent of the total revenue receipts. Assuming that the ability of the various classes of wealth to pay taxes was roughly measured by their capital investment, the manufacturers should have paid 11.1 per cent of the total revenue receipts. They paid, however, only 3.3 per cent or less than one-third of their proportional burden. In this connection it should be stated that reference to the statistics published by the Internal Revenue Department concerning the income tax yield of manufactures in New York in the year 1914, would lead us to think that the 1909 estimate of capital investment in manufactures was much below the actual investment. If this suggestion is correct, the dis- crepancy between the percentage of taxes actually paid by manu- facturers and their proportional share upon the basis of capital investment would be even greater. Or, we may look at the matter in another way by comparing the percentage of capital investment paid in taxes by manufac- turers. The taxes paid by manufacturers for all purposes in New York, viz., $10,844,403, is only .39 of one per cent of the capital investment in manufactures in the State. In other words, JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 129 manufactures paid less than 4 mills upon the dollar, assuming always that the figures represent full valuation of the total in- vestment in manufactures. It should be home in mind that the .39 rate is not the rate for State purposes, nor the rate for in- tangible personalty, but the average rate for the total investment including real estate taxes for local purposes. We may assume that the real estate of manufacturing corpora- tions is assessed at the same proportion of its full value as the real estate of other property owners in the localities. We may also assume that the total -real estate investment of manufactures is about one-third of the total capital investment. Under these assumptions the total yield of taxes upon the real estate of manu- facturers should at the average State rate yield approximately from $14,000,000 to $1.5,000,000. We know, however, that the total yield is less than $11,000,000. Under these assumptions we can come to one or two conclusions; (1) either that manu- facturing corporations are escaping entirely from taxation for any purpose upon at least two-thirds of the capital invested, and even upon that fraction are assessed at a lower rate than that of other forms of wealth, or (2) that all property of manufacturing corpo- ations is grossly under-assessed as compared to that of other forms of wealth. CHAPTER V YIELD OF NEW YORK MANUFACTURING CORPORATIONS UNDER THE FEDERAL INCOME TAX In view of the preceding estimates based upon the 1909 cen- MUS figures, it is interesting to note the revenue possibilities for State purposes in the light of the yield of these same sources for Federal Income Tax purposes. The statistics given by the In- ternal Revenue Department in regard to manufacturing corpora- tions of New York State are given below. In comparing the two :.t should be noted that the Internal Revenue statistics have to do, not with capital investment in manufactures in 'New York State as in the case of the census figures, but with the capital in- vestment and income of New York corporations, irrespective of whether the investment is in New York or in other States. While ;hey include the total investment of !New York corporations every- where, they at the same time exclude the investment in New York 130 STATE OF NEW YORK manufactures belonging to all foreign corporations. Further- more, these statistics do not include the capital investment of any New York manufacturing corporation that did not earn a net income in the preceding year. From an examination of the business and financial statements of many important corpora- tions as given in the corporation manuals, it appears that there are a large number of manufacturing corporations that are tem- porarily earning no net income and therefore are not included within the Internal Revenue figures. A further fact should be noted, viz., that a large number of manufacturing plants that were formerly owned by domestic New York corporations are now owned by corporations whose domicile is in another State. Much of the property represented by these corporations would not, therefore, be included within the Internal Revenue statis- tics. For these reasons it is believed that the statistics given by the Internal Revenue Department do not overestimate either the actual capital investment of manufactures in New York State or the earning power of the capital investment in New York State. CHAPTER VI NEW YORK COMPARED WITH OTHER STATES Whenever it is proposed to increase the tax burden of New York manufacturing corporations, we are always met with the argument that an increase in the tax burden will not only hamper New York manufacturing corporations in their compe- tition with the corporations of other States, but that it will both prevent new capital from investing in the State and drive pres- ent capital out of the State. As indicated in another part of this report, it is the belief of the Committee that this argument is utterly fallacious. However, in order to give the manufacturing industry the. benefit of the doubt, we may assume that this argu- ment is sound. Under this assumption it is important, there- fore, to ascertain the relative burden borne by New York manu- facturing corporations and manufacturing corporations of other States. In Appendix E-V of this report is given a statistical tabulation of every State in the Union, including the following items : JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 131 (1) The total wealth of each state. (2) The capital invested in manufactures in each state. (3) The total revenue receipts of each state. (4) The taxes paid by manufactures in each state. (5) The percentage of total wealth invested in manufactures in each state, (6) The percentage of total revenue receipts paid by manu- factures in each state. (7) The percentage of capital investment paid by manufactures in taxes in each state. An analysis of this table brings out some very interesting information. It is worth while to compare the tax burden of w York manufacturing corporations to that of other states from several points of view. From the point of view of percentage of capital investment paid in taxes by manufacturers in each state, the following is interesting: New York State pay .39 of 1 per cent., New Hampshire pays .61 per cent., Massachusetts pays .77 per cent., New Jersey pays .39 per cent., Pennsyl- vania pays .28 per cent., Illinois pays .39 per cent, Michigan pays .73 per cent., California pays .41 per cent. Other states pay from .25 per cent, in Oregon up to .96 per cent, in Mississippi. Vv'ith the exception of Oregon, Delaware and Pennsylvania, in ao other states in the Union do manufacturers pay a smaller per- 3entage than New York State, and with the further exception of N"ew Jersey no other State pays so small a percentage as New York. The percentage paid by manufacturers in many states )f the Union is more than twice as high as that of New York State. A comparison of the percentage of total revenue receipts paid oy manufactures in the various states is not as representative of :he comparative abilities as the previous comparison. However, it orings to light some very interesting things. New York pays 3.3 per cent, of the total revenue receipts of the State. New Hampshire pays 12.2 per cent., Massachusetts, 8 per cent., New Jersey 5.5 per cent., Pennsylvania, 5.6 per cent., Illinois, 5 per cent, Michigan, 8 per cent., Wisconsin, 9'.7 per cent. In Dther words, in no one of the important manufacturing state**, 132 STATE OF NEW YORK do the manufactures pay so small a percentage of the total rev- enue receipts as in the State of New York. In view of the fact that New York State is the leading manufacturing state in the Union, and in view of the fact that 11.1 per cent, of the total wealth of the State is invested in manufactures, this statement is illuminating. In many of the Western States where manufacturing is of relatively small importance, the percentage of total revenue re- ceipts paid by manufacturing corporations is of course very small. With the exception of California, however, in no important manu- facturing state do manufactures pay so small a percentage of total revenue receipts as in New York. A still more interesting and more trustworthy comparison is that of the ratio of the percentage of total wealth invested in manufac- tures to that of the total revenue receipts paid by manufacturers. In no other way is the special privilege of New York manufac- turers in this regard brought out so strikingly. While New York State has 11.1 per cent, of its total wealth invested in manu- factures it pays only 3.3 per cent, of the total revenue receipts. New Hampshire having 21.6 per cent, of its capital investment in manufactures pays 12.2 per cent, of the total revenue receipts. Massachusetts with 20.3 per cent, of its total wealth invested in manufactures, pays 8 per cent, of the total revenue receipts. New Jersey having 17 per cent, of its wealth invested in manufactures, pays 5.5 per cent. Pennsylvania having 17.8 per cent, of its wealth invested in manufactures pays 5.6 per cent. Illinois hav- ing 10 per cent, invested in manufactures pays 5 per cent, of the revenue receipts. Michigan having 10.8 per cent, invested in manufactures, pays 8 per cent, of the total revenue receipts; and Wisconsin having 13.5 per cent, pays 9.7 per cent. It will be noted that with the possible exception of two or three states, the ratio of percentage of total revenue receipts paid by manu- factures to the percentage of total wealth invested in manu- factures is greater throughout the United States than in New York and in many cases the manufacturing industries pay more than double the proportion now paid by New York State. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 133 CHAPTER VII SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS CONCERNING THE TAXATION OF MANUFACTURING CORPORATIONS In the first place, it must be frankly admitted that it has been the policy of the American commonwealths to favor the manufacturing industry, as compared with other forms of wealth, in the matter of taxation. This policy has taken the form, not only of what is equivalent to a lower rate of taxation, but also in many cases of an absolute exemption from taxation. This practice of offering special privileges in the form of tax exemp- tion has been especially common in the New England States, Pennsylvania and a few other states. It has not been limited, however, to these states, but has been extended to practically every state in the Union. To this extent, the policy of the states has been directed toward accomplishing for the industries within the State somewhat the same protection that has been afforded by the Federal government through the means of the protective tariff for American industries in general. In each case the pur- pose of the policy has been to offer special advantages to the manufacturers as opposed to their competitors in other govern- mental districts. The reason why this policy has been so generally accepted by :he American states is not difficult to learn. Nearly all of the principal business interests in any community are benefited by the development of manufactures. The construction of new plants, with the attendant increase in the laborers employed in those plants, not only adds to the value of the real estate, but adds to the profits of the merchants of the community. Since i large number of those influential citizens in any community "Jiat control the policy of the community are interested financially in real estate and in mercantile business, they have naturally been very eager to offer privileges that would attract the invest- ment of capital. In this respect the introduction and develop- ment of manufacturing industries in our communities has followed somewhat the same course as that followed by transportation in the middle and latter part of the nineteenth century. Just as towns and states vied with one another in offering bonuses and ier special privileges to the railroads for the purpose of in- 134 STATE OF NEW YORK ducing the railroads to come through their localities, so have the towns and states competed with one another in attracting capital of manufacturers. From the point of view of the desira- bility of building up communities, it is doubtless true that this* policy of encouragement, to a certain extent, was justified, in] regard to both the railways and the manufacturing industries of | the community. The time came, however, in the development of the railroads when the communities realized that they had gone entirely too far, and that public policy demanded a more COH-! servative course. So in the development of manufactures the question is now being raised in many parts of this country as to whether we have not gone much farther than was necessary in extending special privileges to the manufacturing industry. The present inequality in the matter of taxation as between the manufacturing industry and other industries is very great. In- deed, it is highly doubtful that the people ever intended that the discrepancy as between the taxation of the various forms of wealth should extend to the present extreme. Whenever the facts have become known by the people in general, there has resulted a strong movement for the readjustment of the tax burden. In the matter of inequities as between manufactures and other forms of wealth, the situation is nowhere worse than in New York State, and this point is of added importance when we consider the additional benefits that accrue to the manufacturers from the great investment of the State's wealth in barge canals and other means of transportation. In summing up the injustice of the present system of taxing manufactures, we may say: First, it is unjust as between manufactures and other forms of wealth. Second, it is unjust as between the various manufacturing towns of the State. In the third place, it is unjust as between the manufacturers themselves. And in this connection it should be said that we can make no progress in dealing with the manufacturing situation so long as we group under the same term conditions of such great va- riance as we find in our various manufacturing communities. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 135 In some communities the manufacturing industry is highly pros- perous and is able to bear an important increase in taxation without affecting in any way its ability to compete successfully. In other communities, however, the manufacturing industries are struggling to get upon their feet, and an increased burden at this time would not only be unjust to them, but would be highly unwise from the point of view of public revenue. To add any burden to a new industry before it can be said to be well established, entirely apart from the injustice, would be the greatest mistake that the State could make. Such a burden would impair the capital from which the State might reasonably expect in the future under right policy to obtain a large revenue. In answering the question whether the manufacturing indus- tries of the State in general can afford to bear a considerable increase in the tax burdens if made upon a proper basis, we may say, unquestionably, it can. It can, in the first place, because of the great advantages growing out of public improvements con- structed at State expense. These advantages have increased the earnings of the manufacturing corporations and have given them advantages in the matter of competition not enjoyed to an equal extent by competitors from other states. In the second place, the manufacturing industry can afford to bear a substantial increase of the tax burden because as a group they have been and are earning large dividends. The evidence of this is found in the report of the Internal Kevenue Department concerning the in- come tax. In reply to the question, by what means should the increased tax burden upon manufacturers be laid, we can say unquestion- ably it should be on some basis other than that of property. Neither the cost basis nor the reproduction basis is fair for pur- poses of taxation. As pointed out in the previous chapters, neither of these bases in many cases forms anything like an ac- curate measure of the ability of the corporation to pay taxes. When manufacturing corporations are taxed upon the property basis, the only method of valuation that approaches justice is that of market value. But to determine market value involves a knowl- edge of the business as a going concern. As pointed out in the previous chapters, it is utterly impossible under our present sys- tem for the assessor to determine this value. 136 STATE OF NEW YORK In the final instance it is the opinion of the Committee, after a careful investigation through consultation with a large num- ber of the principal manufacturers in the State, that the manu- facturing industry as a group is thoroughly willing to bear its just share of the tax burden. The widespread evasion which has resulted to date is a direct result of the attempt to enforce a most inequitable tax. The introduction of a fair tax would be equally acceptable, not only to those other forms of wealth now bearing an unjust share of the tax burden, but also to the manu- facturing industry. PART VIII SECTION 182 OR THE FRANCHISE TAX All mercantile and miscellaneous corporations and all manu- facturing, laundering and mining corporations, having less than 40 per centum of their capital stock invested in property in this State and used in their laundering, manufacturing or mining business in this State, are taxable under section 182 of the Tax Law, more familiarly known as the " franchise tax." It is a tax payable annually for the privilege of existing or doing business in an organized capacity in this State. The tax is computed upon the basis of the amount of the capi- tal stock employed during the preceding year within the State. The amount of the capital stock employed in the State is measured by the proportion which the gross assets employed within the State bear to the gross assets of the corporation wherever em- ployed. The rates are as follows : (1) If the dividends amount to 6 or more than 6 per centum upon the par value of the capital stock, one-fourth of a mill for each one per centum of dividends declared upon the par value of the capital stock. (2) If the dividends amount to less than 6 per centum on the par value of the capital stock, and (a) The assets do not exceed the liabilities, exclusive of capi- tal stock, or (b) The average price at which such stock sold during said year did not equal or exceed its par value, or (c) If no dividend was declared, Then each dollar of the amount of capital stock employed in this State, determined as hereinbefore provided, shall be taxed at the rate of three-fourths of one mill. (3) If such dividend or dividends amount to less than six per centum on the par value of the capital stock, and (a) The assets exceed the liabilities, exclusive of capital stock, by an amount equal to or greater than the par value of the cap ital stock, or (b) The average price at which such stock sold during said year is equal to or greater than the par value, 138 STATE OF NEW YORK Then the amount of capital stock, determined as hereinbefore provided to be employed in this State, shall be taxd at the rate of one and one-half mills on each dollar of the valuation of the capital stock employed in this State, but such valuation shall not be less than (1) The par value of such stock, (2) The difference between the assets and liabilities, exclu- sive of capital stock, (3) The average price at which such stock sold during said year. Section 182 must be read in connection with section 193 of the Tax Law, which, reads in part as follows : " If the dividend or dividends amount to less than six per cen- tum on the par value of the capital stock, or no dividend is de- clared, the president, treasurer or secretary of the company liable to pay a tax under the provisions of section one hundred and eighty-two of this chapter, shall, under oath, between the first and fifteenth days of November in each year, estimate and ap- praise the capital stock of such company at its actual value." The franchise tax was originally imposed in 1880. It was based largely on the Pennsylvania system then in existence, but which has since been abandoned by that State. Amended from time to time, substantially the present statute was passed in the session of 1906. Badly drawn in the first place, the various amendments have utterly failed to clear up the ambiguities of this section, and it has always been fruitful of litigation and eva- sions. Nor did the law of 1906 materially improve the situation. The original law levied a tax upon the par value of the capital stock as fixed by the State Board, making the rate one and a half mills if the dividends were less than six per cent, or if there were no dividends at all, and one quarter mill for each one per cent of dividends if the dividends were six per cent or more. The chief 1906 amendments provided as follows : 1. The franchise tax was declared payable in advance. 2. The rule was provided in the statute itself for determining the amount of capital stock employed within and without the State. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 139 3. A method was provided in the statute for determining the amount of capital stock employed within the State represented by stock in other corporations. 4. Corporations paying less than six per cent dividends, or paying no dividends, were re-classified in two divisions so that a different rate applied to them as they fell into one of the other classifications. This last classification has caused the greatest confusion and is generally held to constitute one of the major defects. Corpora- tions paying dividends of less than six per cent whose assets exceed the liabilities by an amount equal to or greater than the capital stock, or in which the average price of the stock sold during the year was par or over, and not included in the classification pro- vided for in subdivision b (infra) pay at the rate of one and one- half mills on the appraised value, but such appraised value shall not be: Less than the par value of the stock, or Less than the difference between the assets and liabilities, or Less than the average price at which the stock sold during the year. The second subdivision of corporations paying dividends of less than six per cent is that class of corporations in which the average price of the stock sold during the year was less than par, or whose assets do not exceed the liabilities, exclusive of capital stock. In either case, the tax to be paid is three-quarters of a mill on the appraised value of the capital stock. There is no minimum valuation in this class and under the appraisement pro- vided for by section 193 the tax may be nominal. It probably was intended by the framers of the amendment of 1906 to take into account a minimum valuation of par for this class of corporations, but the statute did not clearly express it, and after the amendment of section 193 it was decided in People ex rel N. Y. Mail & Trans. Co. v. Gaus, 198 K Y. 250, that the valuation referred to in this part of section 182 by the words " each dollar of the amount of capital stock employed in this state " was the appraised valuation provided" by section 193. Another point of ambiguity which has given rise to litigation 14:0 STATE OF NEW YORK is where corporations pay dividends of less than six per cent and fall under one alternative subdivision of the second paragraph of section 182 requiring it to pay the rate of three-quarters of a mill and also an alternative subdivision of the third paragraph or class of section 182 providing for the rate of one and one-half mills. Under these circumstances, the practice in the State Comptroller's office had been to assess at the higher rate. The legality of this practice was attacked in People ex rel. American Bank Note Co. v. Sohmer, 157 A. D. 1, and the court held that since the reading of the statute discloses an inconsistency under the general principles of interpretation, the taxpayer was en- titled to the most favorable reading and the common stock of the corporation in the case mentioned should be taxed at the three- quarters mills rate. Under the interpretation placed on the statute in the New York Mail & Trans. Co. case, many corporations escape entirely from taxation since their indebtedness exceeds their assets. Many corporations under this decision pay a nominal tax. On examin- ing the Treasurer's report for 1914, out of the first 4,800 cor- porations, 2,079 pay a tax of less than $5, out of the next 4,903 corporations in the report, 2,043 pay a tax of less than $5. The average tax paid by these corporations paying less than $5 is somewhat less than $2. It would not be unfair for corporations whose capitalization was $20,000 or less to pay no tax less than $5 no matter what its appraisement might be, and no corpora- tion whose capitalization was over $20,000 should pay a tax of less than $10 a year, no matter what its appraisement might be. This simp 1 ^ amendment would bring from $50,000 to $100,- 000 additional tax into the treasury every year. As it stands to- day, it does not pay to audit or make out bills in 40 per cent of these cases. These are some of the principal defects in the wording of the franchise tax, but the who'le section is so confused and misunder- stood that no mere amendments can cure it. We cannot do better in this connection than to quote the testimony of Deputy State Tax Commissioner John J. M,erril, for over 21 years chief of the Bureau of Corporations, and who is reputed to be the only JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 141 man in the State who understands this law. He testified as follows : " Section 182 as it is written and construed, I do not believe is understood by a score of lawyers in the State of New York, and of course it is understood less by the taxpayers. It is am- biguous, prolix and as construed does not get anywhere; and it is open to all kinds of evasions * I think it has been a burning disgrace that the Legislature of the great State of New York has allowed this thing to go on impossible of administra- tion; I will say frankly, with all the years of time that I have put on it, there are plenty of cases that it cannot be applied to, that if it should ever come to the courts for review, they will be vacated. I would not want to suggest what kind or character in this public meeting, because it would not be proper. And it is not at all surprising that good lawyers, men of ability who can sit down and distinguish between two sets of conditions, neces- sarily mislead their clients in making their reports. I say that is a burning shame." But assuming that existing ambiguities be eliminated and that the law be so worded as to accomplish what was intended, it would still, in our judgment, be defective. Class I, or corpora- tions paying six per cent dividends or over are taxed one-quarter for each one per cent of dividend on par value of capital stock. This is for all purposes a tax on dividends and open to the ob- jections that can be urged to such a tax, the principal one of which is that it readily permits evasion through the medium of a small stock issue and a large bonded indebtednes. In other words, it tends to encourage financing by means of bonded indebt- edness, which is not desirable from the standpoint of sound busi- ness finance. Nor does it produce revenue commensurate with the corporation's ability to pay. Class II, or corporations whose assets exceed the liabilities exclusive of capital stock by an amount equal to or greater than the par value of the capital stock, or the average price of whose stock during the year is equal or greater than the par value, are taxed at the rate of one and one-half mills, (1) on the value of the capital stock, or (2) the difference between the assets and the liabilities exclusive of capital stock, or (3) the average 14:2 STATE OF NEW YORK price at which such stock sold during the year. Let us consider each one of these methods of valuation separately. 1. The par value of the stock. Here again bonded indebted- ness offers a serious difficulty. The interest on the indebtedness may, in the first place, have reduced the dividends below the six per cent class. And, in the second place, the par value does not represent either the capital invested in the business which con- sists of both stock and bond investment and surplus, or the earning capacity of the property measured by the actual amount of the investment. 2. The difference between the assets and liabilities, exclusive of capital stock. This, of course, tends to correct some of the above-mentioned objections to (1) and was so intended. Thus it takes care of the surplus. But it does not solve the bond difficulty. And it involves, furthermore, the very grave difficulties of valuing assets, some of which have been described in discussing property taxation. 3. The average price at which the stock sold during the year. This is inseparably connected with the outstanding funded debt; and secondly, market value is too dependent on the speculative factor of stock manipulation to make it an accurate basis of valuation. Moreover, any number of stocks not listed on the Stock Exchange have no readily ascertainable market value. Class III. Corporations which would fall under the mini- mum tax on par value. This is open to the objections already enumerated in our discussion of par value valuation. It is, never- theless, justifiable as a fair, if arbitrary, method of imposing a minimum tax on all corporations for the privilege of doing busi- ness in corporate form. In conclusion, we are of opinion that the corporation tax on a dividend capital stock basis is complicated and unscientific, in that it fails to establish an accurate measure of the corporation's ability to pay; and that a net earnings tax is not only more desirable from a taxation standpoint, but from that of revenue productivity as well. PART IX THE LISTING SYSTEM Before taking up the various substitutes for the personal prop- erty tax, we desire to deal with the attempts which have been made actually to enforce the present system. Every state in the Union, except New York State, has had the listing system. It has been common with those acquainted only with the Xew York system of taxation, to suppose that the failure to collect the personal property tax in New York was due to the lack of the listing system. An examination, however, of the results in the states which have the listing system discloses in some of them a condition much worse than has ever existed in ]STew York. According to the laws of these States, every taxpayer is re- quired to fill out a minute inventory, not only of all his furniture and other tangible personalty, but also of all his intangible per- sonalty. Penalties for failure to list property are of great severity. The most stringent laws have been passed to enable the assessors to enforce the complete listing of property. The assessors have had every power necessary to inquire into and to gain knowl- edge of the ownership of personalty. Every inducement has been offered to the assessors and to private citizens to ferret out per- sonal property. Various states have had tax ferrets and boards of inquisition, back-tax commissions, etc., and have paid at times commissions amounting to a large part of the tax collected, yet in every case (with the exception of one or two temporary suc- cesses) the result has been failure to secure honest and complete listing. Most of the states require that the statements shall be filed under oath, and although these statements are sworn to, the greatest lack of uniformity in this regard exists as between state and state and as between localities. The most notable result ob- tained from these drastic measures has been, not the listing of a large proportion of intangible personalty, but widespread perjury. The reports of practically every tax commission, that has in- vestigated the problem disclose the same results, viz., that the listing system in itself is not a remedy for the present difficulty 144 STATE OF NEW YORK with the personal property tax. The following quotations from various reports are sufficient to establish this contention beyond controversy : The Oregon Special Tax Commission reports as follows: " Where the general property tax has been retained, it has been sought to reach personal property by an exhaustive listing system, whereby the taxpayer is compelled to prac- tically assess himself by furnishing a detailed list of all species of personal property owned by him. The system in practice has not been effective. It results in evasion and deception; it is not calculated to reach intangible personal property. * * It works a great hardship upon the person who honestly lists his property." The 1906 Washington Commission reports as follows: " This is the lesson of all history. The oath to make a full and complete return is as sacred as the oath taken by the juror, etc. How well it is observed can be gleaned from the foregoing pages. The oath is a failure." The Commission cites the experience of other States that have attempted, by drastic laws, penalties and the informing system, to enforce the assessment of intangible property. It reports that in no case has the system been successful. The 1907 New York Special Tax Commission sums up the situation as follows: " Two schemes have been discussed by the members of this Commission to remedy the present evils of the personal property tax. One of these consists in an attempt to retain the present personal property tax, but to make its admin- istration more rigorous, and to require some form of listing. To your undersigned Commissioners, this plan scarcely merits any further consideration at all. " To any one who is acquainted with the history of per- sonal property taxation in the various commonwealths of the United States or the different countries of Europe, such a proposition must seem entirely out of place. Every pos- sible attempt has been made to enforce the personal property tax. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 145 " We have had lenient measures and listing bills ; self- assessments and official assessments, general i tax inquisitors ' and ' tax ferrets.' We have had taxation of debts and exemption of debts. It needs no argument in this place to prove what is universally acknowledged by all careful students of the problem that a tax on personal property cannot succeed under any conceivable method of administration. The root of the difficulty lies in the fact that personal property legally follows the residence of the owner, and that it is impossible to localize intangible personalty. * * *. " The sole result of increasing the rigor of the law will be here, as it ha? always been elsewhere, to augment perjury instead of revenue and to breed more inequality while aiming at greater justice. Xo law, however carefully devised, can enforce a system which is out of harmony with the economic facts. The personal property tax has become an anachronism find is hence unworkable under any possible administrative method in our modern industrial centres. " We, therefore, brush aside as undeserving of any serious consideration, the proposition to remedy the present evils of personal property taxation, by attempting to make the law more rigorous." One of the most drastic laws on any statute book was the former law of Ohio, since much softened. The Kentucky law is a good second to that of Ohio for the severity of its language. If any law could compel the owners of intangible property to make a return of their holdings and to pay a tax amounting to one-third or one-half of the income therefrom, it would seem that the old tax law of Ohio could compel them to do so. For many years that State required all taxpayers to make a return of their personal property " according to its value in money," and this statement had to be made under oath. More- over, the law authorized any county auditor to summon recal- citrant citizens before a judge of the probate court, and made it the duty of such judge to punish the citizen for contempt if he refused to answer any question which the auditor might ask concerning his personal property subject to taxation. Nor was this all. 146 STATE OF NEW YORK The auditor might summon any other person, including the cashier of any bank, which he might suppose to have knowledge of any taxpayer's affairs, and might compel him to testify under oath. Such an investigation might extend hack over a period of five years; and the law provided that in case of proved evasion or false statement five years' back taxes might be collected, with an addition of 50 per cent as a penalty. When we remember that the average tax rate in Ohio until very recently was 2% per cent of the capital value of taxable property, it will seem that, with the penalty included, the amount that might be recovered from a man who evaded taxes for a period of five years amounted to no less than 18.75 per cent of the entire value of his property. Under such a law it was discovered twenty-five years ago that the assessment of personal property was decreasing not only rela- tively, but absolutely. In 1887 the Governor of Ohio sent to the Legislature a special message dealing with the question of tax- ation. " Personal property ", he said " is valued all the way from full value down to nothing. In fact, the great majority of the personal property of the state was not returned, but en- tirely and fraudulently withheld from taxation. So far as per- sonal property is concerned the fault is chiefly with the people who list their property for taxation. The idea seems largely to prevail that there is injustice and inequality in taxation and that there is no harm in cheating the State, although to do so a false return must be made and perjury committed. This offense against the State and good morals is too frequently committed by men of wealth, and reputed high character, and of corresponding position in society." To remedy the conditions thus disclosed the Legislature ex- tended to all parts of the State a device which had been tried previously in a few counties. It was provided that the county officials might employ agents to ferret out property escaping taxa- tion, and these agents known as tax inquisitors, similar to the revenue agents in Kentucky, were to receive as compensation a part of the taxes recovered through their efforts. Under the operation of this enlightened and civilized law, some millions of personal property were uncovered and placed upon the tax rolls; but this effect was merely temporary, since JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 147 many wealthy persons were driven out of the State and their per- sonal property was thereby placed beyond reach. Many citizens of Ohio at this time took up residences in the city of Washington, others moved to New York; and it is disputed by no one that the effect of the tax inquisitors law was to drive capital out of the State. In many cases the law is reported to have led to extensive blackmail; and it is a matter of common knowledge that persons with sufficient political influence were able to secure immunity from the tax inquisitors. The conditions have been aptly described by the Ohio Com- mission of 1893 : " It must be perfectly apparent that we do not succeed in getting upon the duplicate any appreciable part of the personal property which is not tangible and which is not in sight The system as it is actually administered results in debauching the moral sense. It is a school of perjury. It sends large amounts of property into hiding. It drives capital in large quantities from the State." More significant still are the figures which show the amount of intangible property assessed under Ohio's severe laws. TABLE SHOWING THE ASSESSED VALUE OF INTANGIBLE PROPERTY IN OHIO Year Money Credits Securities Total 1881 $40, 600, 000 $101, 100, 000 $8, 600, 000 $150, 300, 000 1893 41,600,000 111,200,000 9,700,000 162,500,000 1906 59, 900, 000 77, 200, 000 10, 800, 000 147, 900, 000 From 1910 to 1914, if we exclude the $300,000,000 assessed against one individual which cannot be collected because he is a resident of the state of New York, the percentage of the assessed value of personal property owned by individuals to the total assessment of the State actually decreased from 14.5 per cent to 11.5 per cent, and this in spite of a new system whereby county assessors appointed by the Governor made the assessment, a system admittedly more effective from the administrative stand- point. In Kentucky, after the most vigorous efforts had been made through a listing system to reach personal property, the Special 148 STATE OF NEW YORK Tax Commission of 1914 found that " the state of Kentucky received more revenue from its dogs than it did from all the bonds, moneys and stocks in the State." A story told the Committee by one of the witnesses well illus- trates the workings of the listing system. It seems that a college professor went from New York to Michigan, to a small college town. He took his household goods and family along, and when he was handed one of the listing blanks, took it seriously and conscientiously filled it out. As it turned out, not only was his the highest assessment of anybody in the town, but he was ac- tually assessed for more personal property than everybody else together in the town. The town council, horrified at this treat- ment of a stranger within their gates, actually appropriated enough money to reimburse him, so that his levy would not ex- ceed the general average. The New York Commission of 1872 refers to this system as " a method of procedure which has no parallel except in the records of the Middle Ages and of the Inquisition, and consti- tutes, in itself, a satire of any claim to wholly free and enlightened government." But there is no need to continue to dwell on the shortcomings of the listing system. We are of opinion that it cannot be made to succeed; that its adoption would be highly detrimental to the jest interests of the State; that it is contrary to all our tradi- tions, and that public opinion would not sanction its adoption. PART X MISCELLANEOUS BUSINESS TAXES One of the projects brought to the attention of the Committee was the imposition of a number of stamp taxes on bank checks, bills of exchange, legal instruments, telephone communications, telegraph messages, etc. Such a proposition falls squarely into the category of new sources of revenue for state purposes. In this connection we desire to reiterate what we have already stated in our introduction: That the Committee does not under- stand that it was appointed with a view to developing new sources of revenue for the purposes of the State government, but rather to report " the best methods of equitably and effectually reaching all property which should be subjected to taxation ", an investi- gation in which the question of additional revenue is only inci- dental. The imposition of new and miscellaneous indirect taxes which, while yielding additional revenue, would not reach the great mass of personal property now escaping taxation, or equalize the relative burden borne by different classes of taxpayers and different forms of property, would not, in our judgment, meet the problem submitted to your Committee for solution. Moreover our study has resulted in the conclusion that the problem has become acute in the localities rather than in the state budget. Two-thirds of all taxes are devoted to local purposes, while by far the greater proportion of future needs are likely to be local in character. The State enjoys a considerable revenue from indirect taxes. These are, generally speaking, satisfactory in character, and can, if the necessity arises, be supplemented by a direct tax, which would never exceed a small fraction of the total direct tax for local and State purposes. The localities, however, must rely for the most part on direct taxation, which we have seen falls almost entirely upon one class of property. We are inclined to believe that any new indirect taxes should be for local rather than for state purposes, and the miscellaneous taxes suggested are for the most part unsuited to such a purpose. Nevertheless, the Committee has investigated these miscellane- ous taxes, both as imposed by the Federal government and as im- posed by European countries, and has endeavored to ascertain the probable yield of such taxes if imposed in the State of !New 150 STATE OF NEW YORK York. The results of these investigations will be found in the appendix. Some of the more serious objections to the imposition of these taxes are as follows: (1) It is obvious that the yield would be small, unless the rates were so high and the subjects of taxation so numerous as to result in a serious burden upon the business interests of the State. (2) Formerly only used as emergency war measures, these taxes apparently are to be relied on more and more by the Fed- eral government. (3) Not even from a revenue standpoint their imposition would in no sense solve the personal property problem. Assume that the yield would be four or five millions. The personal property tax yields to-day somewhat in excess of six and a quarter millions of dollars. If it were abolished and the new taxes returned to the localities, the latter would be no better off than they are to-day, in fact somewhat worse off. Moreover, real estate would have to pay, even to a greater extent than under the present system, all future increases in the cost of government. (4) If the new taxes were retained by the -State for state pur- poses, it is quite true that they could be used to reduce the amount of any future direct tax that might have to be imposed. There is, however, very grave doubt as to the wisdom of the further de- velopment of the separation of State and local revenues by the imposition of new indirect taxes. Experience has shown that where local and state revenues are separated and indirect taxes supplant a direct State tax, in the course of a very few years the yield of the former is exhausted and the State is compelled to re- turn to the direct tax under conditions by no means as favorable as those which existed at the time of its abolition. The truth is, that indirect taxes are not as severely felt as the direct. The indirect are open, therefore, to the charge of leading to extrava- gance, rather than economy. (5) To superimpose these new forms of indirect taxation upon our present heterogeneous system might temporarily alleviate, but might also postpone and would eventually impede a proper solu- tion of the already confused problem which demands immediate action, rather than temporizing. PART XI SOME FORMS OF CORPORATE TAXATION FOUND IN OTHER STATES 1. The Franchise Tax Based on the Par Value of Capital Stock, Such as is Found in New Jersey. The objections to a tax based on par value have all been discussed in connection with our analysis of section 182. While the tax is readily ascertain- able, the par value of the stock bears no direct relationship to the actual value of the property of the corporation, nor to its earning ability. Moreover, a small capitalization and a large bond issue make this method of taxation easy of evasion. (2) The Capital Stock Tax, Such as is Found in Pennsyl- vania, where the capital stock is appraised " at its actual value in cash, not less, however, than the average price which said stock sold for during said year, and not less than the price indicated or measured by net earnings or by the amount of profits made and either declared in dividends or carried into surplus or sink- ing funds." This tax has been described as follows: (See " Brief History of Taxation," 1906, p. 66). " The tax on the capital stock of a corporation is a tax on its property and assets and franchises. The corpora- tion is simply a trustee for its stockholders, and they are the real owners of the property, and whether the property is taxed in the name of the corporation or in the name of the shareholders, the ultimate burden falls on the same per- sons. The fact that the tax is called a tax on capital stock is, therefore, not of the essence of the matter; whatever it is called, it is a tax on the property and assets of the share- holders for whom the corporation is simply trustee. The tax is a tax on its property and assets, including its fran- chise, and the question of the actual value in cash is a question of fact which must be determined by considering value of its tangible property and assets of every kind, in- cluding its bonds, mortgages and moneys at interest, and its franchises and privileges; and the amount of the encum- brances on its property and franchises is also a relevant fact 1 52 STATE OF NEW YOKK to be considered, but is riot to be specifically deducted from the valuation so ascertained and determined, and the Su- preme Court has held, in the case of Commonwealth v. N. Y., P. and 0. R. R., 188 Pa. State 169, that it would be a manifest error to hold that the debt should be deducted from the aggregate value of the property, and thereby withdraw tangible property to that extent from taxation." Professor Seligman, in his " Essays on Taxation," page 240, after describing the method of appraisal of the Pennsylvania capital stock tax quoted above, has this to say : " This has led to much litigation. It has been decided, for instance, that the price at which the shares sell in the market is not conclusive; and in a more general way that the actual value in cash is to be determined by ' considering the value of the tangible property, the amount of its busi- ness, the rate of dividends declared, and the extent and value of its good will, franchises, and privileges, as indi- cated by the evidence bearing upon those subjects at that particular time.' The result is that in practice the taxation of capital stock, by such a method of appraisal, does not differ much from the ad valorem system mentioned below." Under this system the full value of corporate property, includ- ing franchise value, is sought, the law undertaking to lay down certain definite rules to be used in ascertaining the value of the said property. It differs from the ad valorem system to the ex- tent that it takes into consideration such important factors as net earnings, dividends and profits carried into surplus. If the tax is to be levied on the capital stock, the value of which is to be based on net earnings, it is hard to see what ad- vantages accrue from a capital stock tax as contrasted with a tax on net earnings. If, on the other hand, in addition to net earn- ings, the assessors must take into consideration the value of the tangible and intangible property, they are compelled to deal with all the objectionable elements and serious difficulties connected with property taxation. It may be urged that a capital stock tax provides for the contingency when there are no net earnings, in which event under the net earnings system the corporation would JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 153 not pay taxes. It must be remembered, however, that the cor- porations would, in any event, pay a tax on their real property, and it is, to say the least, doubtful whether a corporation with- out earnings has real taxpaying ability. Whatever may be true of public service corporations which enjoy peculiar privileges, we believe that in so far as general business corporations are con- cerned, it is fairer and on the whole better public policy to tax them on a net earning basis, and to require them to pay taxes only when they have the income from which to pay them. N. B. Capital stock tax does not apply to manufacturing corporations in Pennsylvania. (3) The Pennsylvania Mercantile and License Taxes. This tax is paid by retail and wholesale merchants and is based on their gross sales. The Pennsylvania tax committee of 1911 found that this tax was unequal, in that it was the same for the merchant who made a large profit as for the one who made a small one. The committee thought that " full realization of an ideal system had been attempted in the Winconsin income tax law," but found that without constitutional authoiity no such progressive tax could be laid in Pennsylvania. The criticism of the Pennsylvania committee is obviously sound. A tax on gross sales is not a fair tax, because gross sales have no controlling relationship with actual or net profits and are therefore not a reliable index of ability to pay. (4) The Corporate Excess Tax. Massachusetts claims to have originated this form of corporate taxation. Business corporations make an annual return to the State Treasurer, from which he estimates the full value of the capital stock, in the estimating of which debts may be deducted unless incurred for the purpose of avoiding the tax. From the estimated full value of the capital stock are deducted the assessed value of real estate and machinery locally taxable and also such property as is located and taxed in other states. The balance, or corporate excess, is taxed at the average rate of taxation for cities and towns during the preceding three years; providing, however, that the corporate excess shall never exceed 20 per cent of the value of the real estate, machinery and merchandise and taxable securities ; nor is the tax to be less than one-tenth of 1 per cent of the market value of the capital stock. The tax has, in the main, received the approval of the 154 STATE OF NEW YORK various Massachusetts commissions that have studied its work- ings. It is, nevertheless, fairly open to the following criticism : (1) It favors corporations with a large bonded indeted- ness. This means inequality. One Boston corporation, which as a firm has been assessed locally for $837,000, paid as a corporation no tax, either to Boston or to the State. (2) The market value of stock is fluctuating and uncer- tain, and it cannot be applied to closely held corporations whose shares are not dealt in widely, and these last must be taxed on the basis of net assets. The tax thus becomes a tax on property rather than on capitalized earnings, and is open to the objection of taxing property without consider- ing its income-bearing character. Moreover, it is based on a valuation that does not take account of debts, since cor- porations enjoy the privilege of deducting debts and by this means frequently escape taxation entirely. (3) Corporations that have a large part of their capital invested in real estate and machinery, pay practically no corporate excess tax, and do not pay on whatever other prop- erty they may own. This is likewise true of corporations the value of whose merchandise exceeds the value of the corporate excess; whereas corporations whose property con- sists largely in intangibles and whose earning capacity as compared with their tangible assets is relatively greater, pay a large tax which they would not pay at all were they individuals. These corporations, it was found, were rapidly adopting foreign charters, and the 1903 amendment re- ducing the maximum of the corporate excess tax to 120 per cent of the value of the property was adopted for this reason. (4) The tax is not proportional to the earning capacity. " It would seem fair to conclude that the taxation of business corporations is proportional neither to property nor to income. It is not an adequate means of reaching either tangible or intangible property. It is not levied with re- spect to taxpaying ability as measured by capitalized earn- ings. The merits of the system lie rather in its superiority to the general property tax, in its administrative efficiency JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 155 and in its approximation to the ideal system of taxing net earnings directly or indirectly." (The Taxation of Corpora- tions in Massachusetts, by Harry G. Friedman.) The corporate excess tax is administered in Massachusetts by a central board. Where it is administered locally it is by no means as successful. (5) The Wisconsin Income Tax. Returns are made for the calendar year, though in cases where this rule would cause hard- ship the Commission may allow the business year to be substi- tuted. In its principal results and conclusions the return should conform to the report made to the Federal government. INCOME INCLUDES 1. All rent of real estate. 2. All dividends, and all interest. 3. All profits derived from the transaction of business or from the sale of real estate or other capital assets; provided that of the profits derived from such sales only such proportion shall be taxable as the time between January 1, 1911, and the time of sale bears to the entire period of ownership. 4. All royalties derived from mines or the possession or use of franchises or legalized privileges of any kind. 5. All other gains, profits or income of any kind derived from any source whatever, except such as are specifically exempt. DEDUCTIONS ALLOWED 1. Wages and salaries paid in the production of such income. The name, address and amount paid to each employee who re- ceives over $700 to be reported. This is true whether corpora- tion is liable to tax or not. The Commission may disallow the deduction if the amount is excessive or not paid in the production of income, or if the corporation has failed to file the name, etc. 2. Ordinary and necessary expenses paid out of income in the maintenance and operation of its business, including a reasonable allowance for depreciation, and in the case of mines and quarries an allowance for depletion of ores; and including interest paid on its bonded or other indebtedness to an amount of such indebted- ness, not exceeding its paid-up capital stock outstanding at the close of the year ; provided that the amount of such capital stock 156 STATE OF NEW YORK shall in no case exceed the clear value of its assets over and above all indebtedness and liabilities. Additions or improvements are not " ordinary or necessary re- pairs/ 7 nor are renewals or replacements which are covered by depreciation. Depreciation is limited to deterioration or exhaustion by " use, wear and tear," and does not cover fluctuations in market value. Depreciation of merchant's stock is not allowed. 3. Losses actually sustained within the year, and not covered by insurance or otherwise. Loss cannot be deducted unless profit from transaction could have been taxed as income. This rule prohibits the deduction of losses sustained in business without the State. 4. Taxes wherever paid, if upon the source from which the income is derived. Taxes paid upon idle property or unimproved real estate cannot be deducted. Income taxes paid in cash may be deducted as " necessary expenses." Taxes paid by corporations cannot be al- lowed as deductions from the income of the stockholder. Special assessments cannot be deducted. 5. Dividends received from any corporations, joint-stock com- panies or associations, partnerships, etc., i. e., that proportion of the income upon which the tax has already been paid. 6. Dividends received from state banks, national banks, mutual savings banks and trust companies, none of which pays an income tax. APPORTIONMENT OF INCOME " In determining taxable income, rentals, royalties and gains or profit from the operation of any farm, quarry, or mine, shall follow the situs of property from which derived, and income from personal service and from land contracts, mortgages,- stocks, bonds, and securities, shall follow the resi- dence of the recipient. With respect to other income, persons engaged in business within and without the state shall be taxed only upon such income as is derived from business transacted and property located within the state." Two methods are provided for dealing with this last class of income a separate accounting or an apportionment. Mercan- JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 157 tile establishments and a few other special classes make a special accounting. All others, unless exempted by the Commission, have their income apportioned according to the following rule: " In determining the proportion of capital stock employed in the state, the same shall be computed by taking the gross business in dollars of the corporations in the state and add- ing the same to the full value in dollars of the property of the corporations located in the state. The sum so obtained shall be the numerator of a fraction of which the denominator shall consist of the total gross business in dollars of the corporation both within and without the state, added to the full value in dollars of the entire property of the corporation both within and without the state. The fraction so obtained shall represent the proportion of the capital stock represented within the state." Gross business consists of at least two elements: the business of production and that of distribution or sale. The former is measured by costs of production, the latter by gross sales minus costs of production. It is believed that the word " property " as used in the appor- tionment fraction means property from which apportionable in- come is derived, i. e., the full or book value of property other than or excluding farms, mines, quarries and property yielding rents and royalties (income of which follows the situs of the property), and land contracts, mortgages, stocks, bonds and securi-- ties (the income of which follows the residence of the recipient). KATES. On the first $1,000 of taxable income or any part thereof, 2 per cent. On the second $1,000 of taxable income or any part thereof, 2% per cent. On the third $1,000 of taxable income or any part thereof, 3 per cent. On the fourth $1,000 of taxable income or any part thereof, 3% per cent. On the fifth $1,000 of taxable income or any part thereof, 4 per cent. 158 STATE OF NEW YORK On the sixth $1,000 of taxable income or any part thereof, 5 per cent. On the seventh $1,000 of taxable income or any part thereof, 6 per cent. On all taxable income in excess of $7,000, 6 per cent. ADMINISTRATION The State is divided up into assessment districts. An assessor of income for each assessment district is appointed by the Tax Commission. ' Every corporation, whether liable to the tax or not. must make a sworn return. In case a false or fraudulent return is made, the additional amount is taxed at double the normal rate. In case of failure to make the return, the Commission may estimate the income and impose the double rate upon the income so fixed. In addition, a penalty of not less than $100 or more than $5,000 can be im- posed at the discretion of the court, and the officer of the com- pany making the false return is also fined not to exceed $500, or imprisoned for more than a year. The State Tax Commission appoints three resident taxpayers of each county to serve as a board of review, which is particularly charged with the duty of examining and deciding upon the facts of disputed cases. An appeal from its decision can be taken to the State Tax Commission. APPORTIONMENT The taxable income once computed shall be assessed, and taxes at such rate, shall be paid, in the several towns, cities and vil- lages in proportion to the respective amounts of income derived from each, counting the income derived without the State as belonging to the locality of residence. The proportion may be determined according to gross income, investment or, preferably, by an exact allocation of net income. Ten per cent goes to the State, 20 per cent to the county and 70 per cent to the town, city or village. Personal property tax may be offset against income tax. REPORT OF COMMISSION, 1912 The total income tax assessed amounts to $3,501,161, of which $2,392,454, or 68.3 per cent is assessed against corporations and JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 159 $1,108,707, or 31.7 per cent against firms and individuals. The average rate upon firms and individuals is 1.96 per cent and upon corporations 5.4 per cent. The total taxable income amounted to $100,845,862. The taxable income of corporations amounted to $44,311,315, and of individuals $56,534,547. " These figures are noteworthy in many respects. It has repeatedly been charged by critics that although a number of American states have experimented with the income tax, in no case has it proved a success. The answer has been that the income tax has never been given a fair trial by any American state. This answer now proves to be essentially correct." The reduction by reason of the personal tax offset was not known at the time the report was written and was merely esti- mated. In twelve selected counties, excluding the corporations whose income tax is entirely offset by the personal property tax, we have 1,055 corporations with an assessed income of $7,520,776, paying a tax of $411,611. They formerly paid a personal prop- erty tax of $71,473. Increase, $340,138. The cost of administration in the first and most expensive year will be only $45,000 over and above the former cost of the supervisors of assessment. Total cost $100,000, probably the cheapest tax of a general kind collected in the United States. The Wisconsin tax has, on the whole, encountered very little difficulty with the large interstate corporations. " The large interstate corporations usually keep their books in such a way as to make it possible to apportion or allocate fairly to the State of Wisconsin its share of earn- ings. Their stock is frequently listed on the exchange and their financial operations are publicly reported. Moreover, these corporations are above petty deception. These cor- porations have dealt quite as fairly with the Wisconsin income tax as any other class of taxpayers. It is just as easy to assess the big interstate corporations under the in- come tax as it is under the property tax a fact that will be appreciated if one stops to think how ' property ' gets its value, and the degree to which our state laws insist that 160 STATE OF NEW YORK ' franchise/ ' corporate excess ' and all ' intangible proper- ties ' of corporations shall be assessed and taxed under prop- erty taxes. Yet nobody proposes to do away with the state taxation of the property of the interstate corporations." EEPORT OF COMMISSION, 1914 In 1914 the income assessed rose to $126,979,330, and the tax to $4,140,571. The actual cash collected amounted to $1,935,846, which represents the excess over the personal property tax collected. It must be noted first that collections have been slow owing to litigation, and, second, that the income tax assess- ment machinery has resulted in an extraordinary increase in the personal property assessment. The tax is largely one on success- ful business concerns. Corporations paid 65.6 per cent and in divi duals 34.4 per cent. The rate for corporations was 5.21 per cent, for individuals 1.9 per cent. Eighty-five per cent of the corporation tax is assessed on manufacturing and mercantile cor- porations, and the former are by far the largest contributors. " There is no reason why manufacturing concerns should not contribute to the state when they are prosperous and have reached the dividend-paying stage. There is every reason why they should contribute. On the o.ther hand, the new and struggling enterprise, the expirimental industry, the weak and small producers, need and deserve protection; and it would be well, in the opinion of the Commission, if such concerns could be exempted from the personal property tax and not be called upon to contribute to the state until their taxpaying ability had been definitely proven." The income tax law exempted from the personal property tax Moneys, credits, household goods, farm machinery, and other minor personal property, but much personal property, including merchants' and manufacturers' stock, still pay the personal prop- erty tax. These last " baffle the efforts of the best assessors " and the Commission recommends that they be included in the exemp- tion list. PART XII SUBSTITUTES FOR THE PERSONAL PROPERTY TAX We now come to the three plans most seriously urged by wit- nesses before the Committee as best possible substitutes for the personal property tax: (1) The Ability, or Presumptive Income, Tax. (2) The Classified Personal Property Tax. (3) The Income Tax. CHAPTER I THE ABILITY, OR PRESUMPTIVE INCOME, TAX. " The ability tax, so-called, is a tax on the abilities of those who profit from the opportunities afforded by the State of New York. Conceding that the fairest test of ability to pay is income, and assuming that a direct income tax is- unattainable, the proposition is to get at the income indirectly and by outward signs utilizing certain definite facts of expenditure as affording some indication of rela- tive income. The ability tax, as a presumptive income tax, would therefore be composed of three parts: A. A habitation tax; B. An occupation tax; C. A salaries tax; which provisions by which only one of these taxes would be payable by any particular person. A. THE HABITATION TAX '" The habitation tax is to be levied upon individuals occupying houses or apartments for residential purposes. It proceeds upon the theory that what a man spends for rent is a rough indication of his ability to contribute to the public burden. Inasmuch as the ratio of house rent to in- come decreases as the amount of rent increases, it is ob- vious that, in order to secure approximate justice', the tax must be rather sharply graduated. The tax is accordingly based upon a progressively graduated scale. The tax is so 162 STATE OF NEW YOKK calculated that the taxpayer will pay a sum that is about; equivalent to 1 per cent of his income, as indicated by hia house rent. As a rental increases it is multiplied by a con- tinually increasing figure in order to reach the presumptive income, and only the excess of this over $2,000 is considered the taxable income. Moreover, in order to prevent miscar- riages of justice, it is provided that if any one finds that the tax amounts to more than 1 per cent of his actual in- come, he shall have the right to declare and prove his actual income and to have his tax reduced to 1 per cent of his in- come. Where a man lives in his own house the rental value shall be calculated at 7- per cent of the assessed value of the property. Provision is also made for people who live in hotels or apartments and the tax is applicable to those who have occupied the apartments continuously for at least three or four months. " Several criticisms might be urged against this scheme. It might be alleged that the tax is a tax on the poor man. In reality the opposite is the case. All rentals below $50 a month, that is $600 a year, are exempt. This corresponds to a total expenditure of from $2,500 to $3,000. Every one, therefore, with a presumptive income under this amount, pays no tax at all. Moreover, the amount of the tax on slightly higher rentals is exceedingly moderate, while on very high rentals the tax is much greater in proportion. This will be seen from the following scale: " On rentals from the tax is $600 to $700 $5 00 1,000 to 1,100 30 00 2,000 to 2,100 87 00 4,000 to 4,100 226 00 6,000 to 6,200 426 00 10,000 to 10,200 796 00 25,000 to 26,000 4,400 00 In other words, the occupier of a house of $6,000 rental pays about eighty times as much tax as the occupier of a house of $600 rental, although his rent is only ten times as JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 163 great. If we compare the occupiers of houses of $1,000 and $25,000 rental, respectively, we find that the latter pays about 146 times as much tax as the former, although he pays only twenty-five times as much rent. " The habitation tax thus entirely exempts all those with incomes under about $3,000 and imposes an insignificant burden upon those between $3,000 and $6,000, while it con- siderably increases as the income augments. The habitation tax is not a tax upon the poor man, and not an appreciable burden upon those in moderate circumstances, while even for the rich man the tax cannot exceed 1 per cent of the actual income. " In the second place, it might be alleged that the habita- tion tax falls upon the real estate owner, for the reason that a prospective tenant of, let us say, a $650 apartment would insist upon having his rent reduced to $600 in order to escape the tax. This argument, however, is, to a large ex- tent, fallacious. In the first place, the $650 tenant will never secure the owner's consent to a reduction of $50 in rent in order to enable the tenant to save $5 in tax. The same would be true of somewhat higher rentals, because, ac- cording to the scale proposed, a reduction of every $100 in rent would involve a saving of only $5 in tax. So that even at the very worst, it would only be at the margin of each class of tenants that there would be any pressure at all to demand any reduction of rentals. But even this would not be true. The only way in which a landlord could be induced to grant a reduction of rent would be through the fear of having his apartments vacated. But if the tenants of a particular grade of apartments would actually be in- duced to move to a lower-priced apartment because of the tax, the places vacated by them would be instantly filled by the influx of the tenants from the next higher grade of apartments, who would, in like manner, be induced to seek lower-priced apartments. Therefore, what might possibly be lost in one way would be gained in the other; and the only apartments which might suffer a possible reduction of rentals because of a threatened disappearance of their ten- ants would be the highest-priced apartments in the city. 164 STATE OF NEW YORK But as these highest-priced apartments are occupied by the wealthiest classes, the amount of tax to which they would be subject would be such an insignificant proportion of their entire income as in all probability to lead to no such transfer at all. " Thus it will be seen that the argument that the habita- tion tax falls on the real estate owner, is fallacious. If it is shifted at all to the real estate owner, only an exceedingly small part will fall on him and the rest will still be paid by the tenant. " The habitation tax is therefore not a tax on the small man nor is it a tax on the real estate owner. It is a tax on the presumptive income of everybody who resides in New York City. Its chief value as compared with our present system of taxation is that it reaches the man who is not in business as well as the rich man who, although living here, now escapes taxation by claiming residence outside of New York. " The habitation tax will, however, affect those who earn their living in New York but who do not live here. They, too, possess an ability which ought to be reached. These it is proposed to reach by: B. THE OCCUPATION TAX " The occupation tax is a flat tax on the premises occupied for business or for securing a livelihood. It is levied on the basis of the annual rental value of the premises. The tax is 7 per cent of the annual rental value, with a reduction of $25 in every case. Where a man occupies his own building for business purposes or for -purposes of a livelihood, the rental value is estimated, as in the case of the habitation tax, at 7 per cent of the assessed valuation. The occupation tax is not a tax upon the small business man. Business premises are liable to the tax only when the rent exceeds $600 and as the tax is- levied at the rate of 7 per cent only on the rental exceeding that sum, the amount of the tax is in- significant. On even the more moderately successful busi- ness man, whose business rentals are $1,000 a year, for in- stance, the tax is only $50. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 165 " The occupation tax, although concededly not ideal, is far better than a tax on the stock-in-trade and assets of the business man. Any attempt to enforce the present personal property tax or even to levy a new low-rate tax upon his stock in trade and assets would be both more onerous and less equitable than the occupation tax. No one, more- over, will be held to both the habitation tax and the occu- pation tax. The habitation tax will hit large classes who do not pay the occupation tax; the occupation tax will hit large classes who do not pay the habitation. In both cases, any tax paid on personal property may be deducted. " In the case of the occupation tax also, the objection might be raised that the burden will be shifted to the owner of the real estate. As has been pointed out above in the case of the habitation tax, this argument is fallacious. Even, however, if it were true in part, and if a portion of the tax were to remain on the real estate owner, it must be remem- bered that the whole project is to be regarded as an alterna- tive to the general property tax, the chief burden of which notoriously falls on real estate. The choice lies between an increased rate of the general property tax (in actual fact an increased rate on real estate) on the one hand, and the ability or indirect income tax on the other. Even if, as is most unlikely, a small part of the occupation tax should be shifted to the real estate owner, it nevertheless would prove as to the unshifted part a corresponding relief to real estate. As a matter of fact, the tax will be borne, not by real estate, but by the business and professional classes. C. SALARIES TAX " The third part of the project is a tax on all salaries paid or received in the State of New York except salaries paid by the Federal government. The exemption is in all cases $2,000 and the tax is graded from 1 per cent up to 5 per cent, the last rate being levied on the excess of salaries over $30,000. Provision is made for the reporting of sal- aries by employers, and for withholding by them of the tax at the source. 166 STATE OF NEW YORK " The salaries tax is not a tax on the small man. Since all salaries under $2,000 are exempt, the recipient of a $5,000 salary would pay only $30 a year. On the higher salaries like those of the more successful professional men and of well-paid corporation officials the tax is graded ac- cording to a progressive scale. The salaries tax is, there- fore, in reality a tax on large incomes derived from per- sonal exertion. It is a tax upon the wealthier class, not upon the poor man. " Moreover, it would be equally false to state that sal- aries are taxed while other incomes are not taxed. Just the reverse is true. Business incomes are reached by the occu- pation tax; other incomes in general by the habitation tax. ~No one is to pay more than one of these taxes. The object of the salaries tax is not to single out for taxation people with salaries; but on the contrary, to prevent people with large salaries, but living outside of the State and who carry on no other business in the State from escaping justice. " The salaries tax, instead of being an unequal tax on a special class, is an attempt to secure equality of taxation by reaching those who would otherwise escape. t( In considering the ability or presumptive income tax, it must be compared not to any ideal scheme, but with the present methods. The general property tax is concededly an absurdity. The low rate tax on intangibles would do more harm than good. In New York there remains only a direct income tax or a presumptive-income tax. The pre- sumptive income tax is the ability tax. " It is, indeed, quite true that neither the habitation tax nor the occupation tax is in exact mathematical proportion to the taxpayers' income. We must remember that a fairly rough approximation of justice which is administratively simple, and workable, may be better than some ideal scheme which does not work out in practice. The ability tax would be exceedingly easy to administer by either state or local officials, and the revenue would be very large. In the City of New York alone, at rates suggested, the revenue would be from twenty to twenty-five million dollars a year. In the JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 167 other cities of the State the revenue would be proportionate. Under our present system vast classes of the population escape and a small proportion bears the burden. Under the new scheme many classes will be reached who now are not reached. While ideal justice will not be attained, a great step forward will have been taken. As in every question of taxation reform, we must consider the proposition not from the point of view of ideal justice, but from that of substan- tial progress." The above was prepared and submitted to us by Professor Seligman, Chairman of the Executive Committee of the Now York City Special Committee on Taxation. His Committee last year recommended such a tax for the City of New York, but has since declared its preference for the State income tax. The business tax part of this plan has been in force in some of the Canadian cities for a number of years, notably in Winni- peg and Montreal, where in lieu of a personal property tax a business tax is levied, based upon the annual rental of the prem- ises occupied, in Winnipeg at the rate of 6% per cent, and in Montreal at 7% per cent. Judging by the reports of the Can- adian commissioners, the tax is a most successful one and gives general satisfaction. The system of business taxes in the City of Toronto and other Ontario cities is somewhat different, the amount of levy depend- ing not only upon the value of the real estate occupied, but also upon an arbitrary classification applied to the different lines of business, running from 25 per cent on some lines of business to 150 per cent on others. This system appears to offer many more difficulties and complications than the simpler one prevailing in Winnipeg and Montreal. France and other European countries have used the habita- tion tax and the business tax in different forms. In fact it is still an integral part of the French system. However, the whole tendency in Europe has been to rely more and more on a direct income tax. The Ability Tax has many advantages. We do not feel, how- ever, that we can recommend its adoption as a State-wide sub- stitute for the personal property tax. It is primarily an urban 168 STATE OF NEW YORK tax. While rental value may in a large city be on the whole a fairly accurate measure of the taxpaying ability of large classes of taxpayers, the test would by no means hold good in the rural districts. Thus it is well known that in the smaller towns and villages, the habitation occupied is not an accurate test of the wealth of the occupant. Moreover, the plan is frankly one to reach income by indirect means. Professor Seligman, in describing the tax, says : " Con- ceding that the fairest test of ability to pay is income, and assuming that a direct income tax is unattainable the proposition is to get at the income indirectly, and by outward signs utilizing certain definite facts of expenditure as affording some indica- tion of relative income." Now, it is quite proper to assume in the case of a single city that an income tax is unattainable be- cause for rather obvious reasons a single city could not hope successfully to administer such a tax. But this is not true of the State; and if one of the main arguments for the ability or indirect income tax is based on the unattainability of the direct income tax, this reason disappears when the latter is attainable. In the second place, if income be the fairest test of ability to pay, why resort to outward signs, to approximations, to the in- direct means of ascertaining the income when it is possible to do so by the direct method ? As between the indirect income tax and the personal property tax there is much to be said for the former, but as between an indirect income tax and a direct one, the advantages are clearly with the latter. CHAPTER II THE CLASSIFIED PROPERTY TAX This tax is based upon the theory that real estate, tangible personalty and intangible personalty, respectively, rest upon dif- ferent economic bases, and that it is unjust to tax all three classes at the same rate. Furthermore, that whenever a tax upon personalty exceeds an amount equivalent to a 7 or 8 per cent income tax, the average taxpayer will not pay it, if he can evade it. Professor Bullock in describing this system gives the following threefold classification : JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 169 (1) Real estate at the general property tax rate. The heaviest burden will fall here, but this is greatly alleviated by the fact that whenever real property changes hands, existing taxes are capitalized, so that the purchaser buys upon what is practically a tax-exempt basis. (2) Intangible personalty a rate of three to four mills is a safe limit for intangibles. The experience of Pennsylvania, Mary- land and Minnesota would seem to bear this out. This rate is equivalent to a 6 per cent income tax on a security paying 5 per cent interest. (3) Tangible personalty. The rate on tangible personalty can be about double that on intangible personalty, for the reason that capital employed in trade is presumed on an average to yield the ordinary trade profit, which is about twice the rate of simple interest. Therefore six or eight mills seem to be a fair rate for tangible property. This would be equivalent to an income tax of 6 per cent upon intangible personalty yielding an income at about 10 per cent. ARGUMENT FOR CLASSIFICATION OF PROPERTY FOR PURPOSES OF TAXATION "All successful legislation is based upon a reasonable discrim- ination between the classes of things with which it deals, and laws that ignore necessary distinctions between classes prove in- effectual or pernicious in their results. " Uniform regulations for the transfer of all classes of prop- erty, a uniform penalty for all crimes, and absolute uniformity in the treatment of persons, without discrimination of age, sex, or condition, would be no more unreasonable than a uniform rate of taxation for all property, irrespective of its nature or class. " Diversification of rates of taxation agrees with the ordinary business principle of adjusting charges and prices to ' what the traffic will bear.' No railroad charges as much for carrying logs as for carrying furniture; but the discrimination in favor of logs, by enabling that traffic to move, contributes to the revenue of the road and decreases the charges upon furniture and other traffic of higher grade. " When the average rate of taxation was fifty cents per $100, it was possible to tax all property at a uniform rate because the 170 STATE OF NEW YORK tax was not higher than any important class of property could bear; but under modern conditions the rate of taxation is high that it is necessary to classify property and adjust methot and rates of taxation to the needs of each important class. " Reasonable discrimination between the objects of taxation is the principle upon which our customs tariff and internal taxes upon commodities are now adjusted. We tax beer at one rate, spirits at another, and tobacco at another, and no sensible man would propose to tax all three commodities at a uniform rate. Our tariff taxes cut diamonds at the rate of 10 per cent and levies upon sugar a duty equivalent to 60 per cent ad valorem. This discrimination is both just and expedient, since a duty of 60 per cent upon diamonds would lead to so much smuggling as to produce little revenue; while the duty of 10 per cent yielded, in 1905, $2,500,000. " This illustration not only makes clear the necessity of ad- justing taxation to ' what the traffic will bear/ but points to the reason therefor. The duty of 10 per cent can be collected from any dealer in diamonds, because the government succeeds in col- lecting it from practically all dealers. If the duty were raised to 60 per cent, and a few dishonest dealers were tempted to evade payment of it, the honest dealers, who would have no objection to paying duties uniformly collected upon all persons engaged in their trade would have no choice but to resort to smuggling or go out of business. Evasion of taxation, when it becomes general, is not due to dishonesty on the part of the average taxpayer, but to the sheer inability of the honest man to pay his taxes when other persons succeed in evading theirs." (C. J. Bullock.) CHAPTER III THE LOW RATE ON INTANGIBLES This plan represents, in part, the scheme for a classified prop- erty tax as proposed by Professor Bullock, except that the advo- cates of this single scheme do not include Bullock's suggestion in regard to a low rate for tangible personalty, but deal solely with intangibles. The theory upon which this tax rests is : (1) That the general property tax has been a failure as ap- plied to intangibles, because the rate in most states amounts to JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 171 a sum which represents from 40 to 50 per cent of the entire in- come from an average high-grade investment. (2) That taxpayers refuse to pay a confiscatory rate, but that they would voluntarily pay a rate consistent with the low rate of income derived from such property. CLASSIFICATION OF SYSTEMS OF LOW RATE UPON INTANGIBLES ( 1 ) The registration plan a simple payment f OT a term of years upon the face value of the debt, without any attempt to reach the real value. (a) Exemption from other taxation for a period of years upon the payment of a definite amount, but not for the life of the security. Example : Connecticut exemption for five years. Exempt locally in the hands of the holder. (b) Exemption for the life of the security. Example: New York Secured Debt Law before amendment of 1915. (2) Annual tax based upon full value of the security. (a) At flat rate for State or apportioned for local pur- poses. Examples : Pennsylvania, Minnesota and Iowa. (b) Combined local rates plus State rates. Example: Maryland. Local: uniform rate of 3 mills. State: general property rate, averaging about 1.8 mill. Total rate about 4.8 mills; now, 1915, 4.5 mills. ARGUMENTS FOR THE LOW RATE ON INTANGIBLE PROPERTY The principal arguments for the tax were presented by one of the Massachusetts committees as follows : (1) That it will impose upon the classes of intangible personalty subject to it a rate of taxation proportionate to the incomes which they yield; (2) That it will reduce the temptation on the part of owners of money and taxable securities to conceal such prop- erty and evade the payment of taxes; (3) That it will put a stop to the concentration of in- tangible personalty in certain towns; (4) That it will tend to make residence in this State more attractive for wealthy property-holders ; (5) That it will relieve the present inequality in the dis- tribution of the tax burden between personalty and realty 172 STATE OF NEW YORK by bringing a larger amount of the former upon the as- sessors' lists; (6) That it will do away with the general demoralization attendant upon the working of the present system. CRITICISM OF THE ABOVE ARGUMENTS It is true that most of the above hold, in part at least, for the low rate on intangibles. However, these arguments would hold to the same extent if applied to almost any other scheme that would reduce the tax rate to the equivalent of a 6 to 8 per cent income tax. The above arguments represent not simply the strength of the so-called " low rate on intangibles," but rather the strength of the general and broader idea that the tax rate should be adjusted to all classes of personalty according to the income-bearing capacity. PENNSYLVANIA LOW RATE ON INTANGIBLES The Pennsylvania system has two parts: (A) The tax on intangible personalty other than corpo- rate loans; (B) The tax upon loans of (1) Counties and municipalities; (2) Business corporations doing business in Pennsyl- vania. (A) TAX ON INTANGIBLES OTHER THAN CORPORATE LOANS, APPLIES TO (1) Money at interest; (2) Money owing by solvent debtors; (3) Mortgages; (4) Public securities not exempt from taxation and not included under the corporate loan tax; (5) -Shares of stock in all corporations other than cor- porations subject to taxation upon capital stock or business in Pennsylvania. Method of Assessment The tax upon intangible property other than corporate loans is assessed by the county officials upon the basis of returns made JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 173 by the taxpayers. The law requires every person to make a return of all taxable money, credits and securities ; and these state- ments must be made under oath. Upon the refusal or failure of any person to make the required returns, the assessors are au- thorized to make an assessment from the best information they can obtain. In most of the counties of the State, this arbi- trary assessment law is not rigidly enforced. * Yield According to Classified Sources (1) Mortgages a very large part of the tax, possibly 50 per cent, is collected from mortgages on real estate, since the law makes rigorous provision for ascertaining the ownership of this class of property. (2) Trust companies a considerable amount is paid by the trust companies upon personal property which they hold in trust. (3) The remainder, about 30 per cent, is paid by individuals, assessed by a sworn return or arbitrary estimate. Results of Pennsylvania Experience with 4:-Mill Tax From the point of view of amount of intangible personal prop- erty listed, the Pennsylvania system undeniably has been suc- cessful. The following statistics, expressed in round numbers, indicate the striking growth in the amount of intangibles listed from 1885 to 1915: 1885 $14-5,300,000 1888 429,000,000 1891 575,000,000 1894 613,000,000 1897 , 073,000,000 1900 722,000,000 1903 847,100,000 1906 932,000,000 1907 1,014,000,000 1909 1,141,000,000 1910 1,184,000,000 1912 1,266,000,000 1913 , 1,402,000,000 174 STATE OF NEW YORK It must not be inferred, however, that the local assessors dis- cover all intangible property subject to taxation and list it at its true value. As a matter of fact, the administration of the Pennsylvania law is far from rigorous, and except in the case of mortgages and personal property held in trust by trust companies, there is more or less evasion. As brought out later on, the field in which Pennsylvania has been most successful has been that in which the State has not relied upon the self-assess- ment of the individual taxpayer. (B) TAX UPON" CORPORATE LOANS This tax is deducted by the treasurers of the counties, mu- nicipalities and business corporations when paying interest upon loans and is paid directly into the State treasury. It was the original intention of this law to levy the corporate loan tax upon the bonds of all domestic corporations, as well as upon other bonds held in the State. The Supreme Court of the United States, however, decided (1) That a corporation cannot be required to deduct a tax from interest paid to nonresident bondholders; (2) That a foreign corporation doing business in the State cannot be required to deduct a tax from interest disbursed in another State. The result of these decisions has been to limit the tax to Pennsylvania corporations and to only those bonds of Pennsyl- vania corporations owned by residents of Pennsylvania. Although limited in its operation to bonds owned by residents of Pennsylvania, the yield of the corporate loan tax has steadily increased at a satisfactory rate. From 1886 to 1890 the receipts average $300,000 per year, this amount being somewhat less than the usual, because considerable sums were withheld by cor- porations pending the outcome of litigation. From 1891 to 1895 the receipts averaged $1,130,000. From 1896 to 1900 they averaged $1,260,000, and from 1901 to 1905 they averaged $1,530,000; 1906 $2,352,000. CONCLUSIONS CONCERNING THE PENNSYLVANIA LOW RATE ON INTANGIBLES (1) The system is a decided improvement upon the old, dis- reputable general property tax. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 175 (2) The success of the Pennsylvania system is most marked (a) Where it is collected at the source, as in the case of the corporate loans by methods which make evasion very difficult ; (b) Where it is collected from mortgages on real estate, in which case the law makes rigorous provision for ascer- taining the ownership of this class of property ; (c) Where it is collected from trust companies upon per- sonal property which they hold in trust. (3) The weakest part of the law is that part dealing with in- dividuals who list their intangibles. As pointed out above, the experience of Pennsylvania in regard to this class is quite far from satisfactory. (4) The experience of Pennsylvania seems to show that a four mill rate on intangibles will not drive this class of property out of the State. At least in the case of corporate loans, even though it is collected only on securities held in Pennsylvania, the four mill tax does not drive this property out of the State. In recent years corporations have often voluntarily assumed the payment of the tax in order to be able to advertise their bonds as being nontaxable in Pennsylvania. THE EXPERIMENT OF MARYLAND WITH THE LOW RATE ON INTANGIBLES For nineteen years Maryland has taxed certain forms of in- tangible personalty at approximately four and eight-tenths mills. It has imposed a uniform rate of three mills for local purposes, and for State purposes the general property rate, which has varied between 1.6 mills and 3.1 mills. By recent amendment, adopted this last year, Maryland now imposes a uniform rate of three mills for local purposes, and also a uniform rate of one and five-tenths mills for State purposes. WHAT THE LAW APPLIES TO It is important to note that the law applies only to certain forms of intangibles, including the following: (1) All bonds and certificates of indebtedness issued by corporations (except State, county and municipal bonds). 176 STATE OF NEW YORK (2) Stocks of foreign corporations, only on the condition that interest is paid during the year. WHAT THE LAW DOES NOT APPLY TO (1) Shares of Maryland corporations; (2) Ordinary mortgages; (3) Book accounts of merchants; (4) Holdings of savings banks; (5) Deposits in banks; (6) State, county and municipal bonds; (7) Holdings of domestic corporations under certain con- ditions ; (8) Holders of nonproductive bonds and foreign stock. KESULTS OF MARYLAND'S EXPERIENCE WITH THE Low KATE ON INTANGIBLES The success of Maryland with the low rate tax has been very marked in spots. The following figures, indicating the amount of intangible personalty brought upon the books, are instructive: They include the assessment of interest-paying bonds, certifi- cates of indebtedness, stocks of foreign corporations, in Baltimore city, in round numbers. 1896 $6,000,000 1897 58,700,000 1900 65,700,000 1902 89,900,000 1905 104,000,000 1907 151,000,000 1910 158,000,000 1912 179,000,000 1914 192,000,000 N. B. It must be noted, of course, that this success was at- tained under a rate (three mills) which is only a fraction of the general property rate, and that it was attained in Baltimore city under the direction of an unusually efficient public servant (Judge Leser), and under more favorable conditions of administration than existed for the State at large. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 177 The yield of the tax of course has not been in proportion to the increase in the amount of the intangibles listed as a result of the low rate. WHERE THE MARYLAND LAW HAS FAILED The Maryland tax officials have reported utter failure in some counties. The reason given for this failure is weak adminis- tration. The lamentable lack of success in some of the rural counties as compared to the city of Baltimore was one of the principal arguments which led to the creation of the tax commis- sion with centralized power. Moreover, " nearly one-third of the revenue from this three mill tax in Baltimore comes from a few railroads that are incorporated under the laws of Maryland and own the shares of companies outside the State." (Stenographer's Minutes, p. 1044.) It must be remembered also that Maryland taxes under this law the holdings of insurance companies. CONCLUSIONS CONCERNING THE MARYLAND Low RATE ON INTANGIBLES (1) As compared with the old, broken-down general property tax, the Maryland plan represents an unqualified improvement. (2) However, Maryland's experience indicates that even a rate as low as three mills cannot be collected under decentralized administration. The local assessors cannot be depended upon, unless closely supervised or controlled by a centralized body. (3) It can be enforced with success in a city like Baltimore, under a high type of personnel. (4) The securities of foreign corporations can be listed where administration is of high type. FAILURE OF Low RATE ON INTANGIBLES IN MARYLAND (Quoted from 1913 Maryland Report of Special Tax Commission, pp. 27 and 28.) " Maryland taxes the stock of domestic corporations * * * differently from the stock of foreign corporations, and our dis- cussion here refers only to the corporate bonds and the certifi- cates of indebtedness of all corporations and the stocks of all cor- 178 STATS OF NEW YOKE porations now taxed under Article 81, Section 214, at the full state rate and a uniform local rate of 30 cents. " We realize that this method of classification and the imposi- tion of the 30-cent local rate has been the subject of favorable comment by students of taxation, and many reports have cited this State as an example of a low rate producing more revenue than a high rate by reason of the fact that greater assessment is thereby obtained. " This conclusion is correct only in part. When this class of property was taxed the full local rate (prior to 1896) Baltimore City had $6,000,000 assessed, whereas it now has $179,412,676 on the books. The result throughout the State has not shown anything like this change. Even now, but a small part of this kind of property is assessed in Baltimore City and less in the counties. " The amount of securities taxed in each county is shown in another part of this report. Four counties of the State, viz., Calvert, Caroline, Garrett and Worcester, have not a single as- sessment against this class of property. " !N". B. It is a well known fact that a large part of the wealth of our people at the present time consist of securities subject to this rate of taxation, and there is no doubt that in every community a vast amount of this class of property escapes taxation." CONNECTICUT EXPERIENCE WITH THE LOW RATE ON INTANGIBLES Connecticut's tax on choses in action has been in existence since 1889, the rate being at first two mills, and since 1897 four mills. The substance of the law is as follows : Any person may send to the office of the Treasurer of the State any bond, note or other chose in action, and pay a tax of 2 per cent on the face amount for five years, or for a greater or less number of years at the same rate. " The Treasurer shall thereupon make an endorsement upon said bond, note, or other chose in action, or shall give a receipt for the tax thereon, de- scribing said bond, note or chose in action," certifying that the same is exempt from all taxation for the period of five years, or for such longer or shorter period for which a proportionate tax JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 179 has been paid. The Treasurer shall keep a record of endorse- ments, together with the name and address of the, party present- ing them, and the date of registration. The Treasurer annually sends to the town clerk of each town a description of all such bonds, etc., registered by persons residing in such town, indica- ting that such bonds, etc., are exempt from all taxation in the state for the period during which the tax is enacted. FISCAL RESULTS OF THE TAX ON CHOSES IN ACTION (STATED IN ROUND NUMBERS) Number of Amount of Year 1908 notes, etc. 35, 000 notes registered $38, 000, 000 Tax $160, 000 1909 35, 000 37, 000, 000 161, 000 1910 37, 000 41, 000, 000 167, 000 1911 36, 000 39, 000, 000 159, 000 1912 37, 000 40, 000, 000 161, 000 1913 44, 000, 000 176, 000 1914 61, 000, 000 244, 000 1915 . 100, 000, 000 400, 000 As indicated above, the yield of this tax is not strikingly large, but on the whole the tax seems to have been fairly successful. The Tax Commission of 1911-1912 speaks of the tax as follows: " The present statute permits the registration of choses in action in the treasurer's office by the bearer, and does not require the owner's name to appear on the records in that office, nor to be sent to the town clerk of the town in which the owner resides. It is customary for banks and trust com- panies to pay the tax on a large amount of securities owned by the different clients; the registration of the same being in the name of the bank instead of in the name of the origi- nal owner. " Section 2325 requires the state treasurer to send to the town clerks the list of choses in action so registered in the name of the bearer, but not of the owner. " This makes it difficult for the assessors to check the tax- ation of bonds under this procedure in the name of the 180 STATE OF NEW YORK MINNESOTA'S EXPERIENCE WITH THE THREE-MILL TAX ON INTANGIBLES In 1911 Minnesota enacted a law which provides for the sepa- rate listing of the following: (2) Promissory notes; (3) Bonds, other than mortgages on Minnesota real estate ; (4) Muncipal bonds; (5) Book accounts; (6) Annuities; (Y) Royalties and all claims and demands for money and other things of value. The law does not apply to the following: (1) Money and credits belonging to incorporated banks; (2) Shares of stock; (3) Mortgages secured within the state (the latter con- tinuing subject to the registry tax) ; (4) Municipal bonds (which are exempt). COLLECTION AND APPORTIONMENT OF THE TAX The return of moneys and credits is made on a separate sched- ule, and it is specifically required that the taxpayer make oath as to the correctness of his return. The tax is paid into the county treasury, as other taxes, but is apportioned as follows: One-sixth to the revenue fund of the state ; One-sixth to the county revenue fund ; One-third to the city or town ; One-third to the school district in which the property is DEDUCTION OF DEBTS Under the old law, deductions for debt were allowed as an off- set to credits, but under the 3-mill tax no deductions for debts are allowed. RESULTS OF THE LAW Minnesota's experience with the low rate tax on intangibles is similar to that of other states. As a means of bringing upon JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 181 the tax rolls a large amount of intangible personalty, it has proved successful, but as a revenue producer it cannot be said to have been a huge success. The following table indicates its success in listing property: Year 1910 Number assessed 6 000 Total assessmen 1 $13 000 000 Per cent in- crease from 1910 1911 41 000 115 000 000 730 1912 50 000 135 000 000 873 1913 57 000 156 000 000 1 027 1914. 73 000 196 000 000 1 309 FISCAL RESULTS The foregoing statistics, indicating the striking increase in the total assessment of intangible personalty, are entirely mislead- ing, unless one refers to the actual revenue producing results. Minnesota's revenue in 1910, the year preceding the enactment of the three-mill tax, was approximately $379,000. In the fol- lowing year, when the total assessment was increased more than tenfold, the actual yield of the tax was only $347,000, or a net loss to the treasury of about $32,000. Since 1911 the yield of the tax has gradually increased. From the point of view of public morals, the Minnesota low rate on intangibles may be considered a success, if we mean by " success " the listing of a large amount of intangible personalty formerly escaping taxation. However, judged from a revenue point of view, the success has been by no means as great. It is true, however, that the tax base has been broadened, more tax- payers have been reached and thus there is a better distribution. Rhode Island and Iowa also have a low tax on intangibles. The Rhode Island Commission expresses itself as well satisfied with the results. In Iowa under a five-mill tax the revenue at first showed a marked falling off, but seems now to have reached the yield formerly received from the personal property tax. GENERAL CONCLUSIONS CONCERNING THE LOW RATE UPON INTANGIBLES (A) ECONOMIC JUSTICE. Most tax authorities agree that the present low rates of 3 to 5 mills upon tangibles are in accord with economic justice. The application of the general 182 STATE OF NEW YOKK property rate in the various states of the Union has in no single instance administered justice either as between intangible and tangible personalty, as between personalty and realty, or as between classes within the community. The general property rates, where enforced, have been confiscatory, but the present rate of 3 to 5 mills with few exceptions is adjusted to the income- bearing capacity of the property. (B) EFFECT UPON PUBLIC MORALS. As to the degrading effect upon public morals of an attempt to enforce the general property tax, all authorities agree. When members of the com- munity are invited by an unjust law to beat an unjust tax, they naturally fall into the habit of attempting to beat all taxes. In Baltimore, where Judge Leser has had large opportunity to notice the effect of the low rate tax, the general attitude of the tax- payer, not only in regard to the tax upon intangible property, but also in regard to all other taxes, seems to reflect a much more wholesome condition. (C) SUCCESS AS A REVENUE PRODUCER. The success of the low rate tax has been remarkable rather for the large amount of intangible property put upon the books, than for the actual net increase in the yield of the tax. However, in Maryland and Pennsylvania, where peculiar conditions exist, there has been a substantial increase in the revenue produced. (D) CONDITIONS NECESSARY TO ITS SUCCESS. Whenever the low rate has succeeded, either one or all of the following conditions have prevailed: (a) A large degree of central administration or supervision ; or (b) A type of tax official more zealous and more efficient than the average; (c) A provision for reaching the source without reliance upon self -assessment (and this has been possible only in the case of particular classes of intangibles). The Committee has given serious consideration and much thought to the low tax on intangibles plan, not only because of its own intrinsic merit and superiority over the present system, but because of the earnestness with which it was pressed by its advo- cates. Nevertheless, while conceding its good features, we do not believe that this tax system will solve our New York problem. We base this judgment on the following grounds: JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 183 (1) While the low rate will, to a great extent, do away with the temptation on the part of taxpayers to evade the tax, never- theless it is idle to hope that any great amount of personal prop- erty will find its way on the rolls unless the owner he compelled either to produce or to disclose his holdings. A three or a four mill rate is, of course, much lower than the present one, yet even so, it represents a fairly high rate on income, and in the case of some securities anywhere from 6 to 10 per cent. A 10 per cent tax on income is sufficient to inspire the average man with a desire to escape therefrom. There are two well-recognized methods of compelling disclosure. The first is to require the taxpayer to fur- nish the assessor with a list of his taxable property. But even a modified listing system is so contrary to our traditional public policy and so obnoxious to the great majority of our citizens, that we do not believe that public opinion would sanction its adoption. The second method is that of voluntary registration, such as is found in Connecticut. This plan contemplates the retention of the personal property tax at the general property rate, but per- mits the taxpayer to register his securities annually, to pay the two three or four mill tax, as the case may be, and so to exempt his property from the local personal property tax. The difficulty with this scheme is that the threat of the enforcement of the per- sonal property tax at the general property rate can never be made severe enough to compel all of the property, or even the greater part of it to pay the lower tax. Indeed, under the circumstances, there is hardly incentive enough on the part of the local assessor to induce him to make any very strenuous effort to furnish the compelling force. (2) In the second place, the experience of all the states that have tried it show conclusively that the low rate on intangibles cannot be made a success unless the administration be taken away from the local assessor and placed in the hands of the State Tax Commission, or some other central administrative body. This is frankly admitted by the advocates of the plan. This in itself is an insuperable objection to its adoption in New York, because under the terms of our present Constitution the function of as- sessing personal property, even at a lower rate, cannot be taken away from the local assessor. 184: STATE OF NEW YORK (3) The application of the tax would be necessarily much more limited than in some of our sister states, because of the great number of securities at present exempt which could not be reached even under the new tax. Thus, for example, it is hardly likely that mortgages would be included, or the securities held by insurance companies, or savings banks. It was estimated by two well qualified witnesses who- appeared before our Committee that the exempt securities in the State of New York amounted to no less than three billion dollars. When we add to these facts the knowledge of the j)eculiar conditions in New York City that render it so easy for the taxpayer to change his residence, it is clear that sufficient revenue could not be obtained greatly to alleviate the burden borne by real estate and other forms of tax- paying property. The State of Pennsylvania is the only one of the states having the low tax on intangibles where general conditions are in any way analogous to those existing in New York, and in Pennsylvania it has been found that, except where the tax is collected at the source, it is not particularly successful. (4) The low tax on intangibles is a property tax, and the whole modern tendency, particularly in the business world, is to get away from property as a basis of assessment, and to look more and more to income. (5) The low tax on intangibles would in no sense solve our corporation tax problem. In fact, Mr. Alfred E. Holcomb, who is one of those who must strenuously urged its adoption before our Committee, admitted that when we come to general business corporations, it would be necessary to supplement the measure by some such tax as the Canadian business tax. CHAPTER IV THE INCOME TAX The first step in the construction of any scientific form of taxation is a careful consideration of the fundamental principle underlying all sound public finance. Our studies have led us to the conclusion- that no fairer principle of taxation can be adopted than that each man shall be called upon to contribute to the support of government in proportion to his ability to pay. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 185 Adam Smith laid down as the first canon of taxation that the " sub- jects of every state ought to contribute towards the support of government as nearly as possible in proportion to their respec- tive abilities; that is, in proportion to the revenue which they respectively enjoy under the protection of the state.' 7 This canon, as enunciated, has stood the test of more than a century of criticism, and today comes as near universal acceptance as any principle of taxation. As ability best represents the proportion which each man is called upon to pay, so, in turn, ability to pay itself is best determined by the income or revenue which a man enjoys. Taxes are paid out of income. All taxes have to be paid either out of income or capital. To pay them out of capital is to destroy the future source of income, both to the individual and the state and if persisted in over a long period of time, to wipe out capital itself. This principle has repeatedly been recognized in our various taxes. In taxing property we have done so in the belief that, in the main, it was a fair criterion of taxable income ; and this was true when our property tax system was originally adopted in a simpler state of society. But to-day property alone is not a complete measure of the total income enjoyed, and if the above enunciated principle be sound, it is necessary to abandon the in- direct property method of reaching income, and to tax income directly. This conclusion has received widespread recognition. There is hardly a civilized country to-day where the income tax does not make up an important part of the tax system. Thus it is in use in nearly every country in Europe, notably in Germany, England, France, Austria and Italy. At one time every one of these countries had a personal property tax, but as its failure became recognized it was abandoned and to-day they all resort to the income tax. EXPERIENCE IN THE UNITED STATES From time to time various states in the Union, more particu- larly the Southern States, have enacted income tax laws (of one kind or another) but no really successful attempt has been made to enforce them. The failure which has attended their efforts has given rise to a misconception as to the possibility of enforcing an income tax in this country. It might as well be noted here that 186 STATE OF NEW YORK the income tax is not likely to be any more successful than the personal property tax unless adequate means of enforcement are provided. This fact was conclusively demonstrated by the earlier experiences in this country. However, the Wisconsin experiment proved beyond controversy that the income tax could be adminis- tered with complete success under a centralized system of adminis- tration and with reasonable provisions for its enforcement. In this respect it merely confirmed what had amply been demonstrated in Europe. The Wisconsin income tax was devised as a substitute for the personal property tax, the inequalities and injustice of which were felt even more keenly than in New York. WISCONSIN INCOME TAX The principal facts in regard to the Wisconsin income tax have been clearly set forth in the annual reports of the Wisconsin Tax Commission and in papers presented before the National Tax Association. The following data has been largely quoted from these sources: History Adopted in 1911. Has been collected in 1912, 1913 and 1914. General Characterization of the Tax The Wisconsin income tax differs in several important particu- lars from any other income tax ever adopted in this country. It is, therefore, important to note the following salient features: (a) It is not an additional tax, but a substitute for the tax on certain classes of personal property and particularly moneys and credits. (b) Any personal property tax which a person pays is subtracted from his income tax. This is popularly referred to as the " personal tax offset." (c) It is not a tax on the whole income of persons en- gaged in business within and without the State, but is con- fined practically to income derived from property located and business transacted within the State. (d) It is not a state tax. Seventy per cent of the tax goes to the *own, city or village in which it is collected, 20 JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 187 per cent to the county, and ten per cent to the state. Out of this ten per cent, the State pays practically all the expenses of administration. (e) The rates imposed upon individuals differ materially from those imposed upon corporations. The rate upon individuals and co-partnerships is 1 per cent on the first thousand dollars of taxable income; 1*4 per cent upon the second thousand dollars, and rises gradu- ally to 6 per cent, where it stops. The rate upon corporations, up to a year ago, was deter- mined by the relation between the taxable income and the assessed value of the property used and employed in the ac- quisition of such income. (For detail of present law, see supra.} (f) The principle of collection at source has been exten- sively applied. Thus the corporation pays on its total profits, and the individual stockholder is not taxed upon his dividend. So also the interest paid upon bonds of corpora- tions subject to the Wisconsin income tax is, for practical purposes, taxed directly to the corporation and exempted to the individual bondholder. (g) The administration of the law is centralized in the Tax Commission and is not left to local officials. The as- sessors of income are appointed after civil service examina- tions and are entirely independent of local influences. Enacted as a Substitute for the General Property Tax on the Following Forms of Personalty (a) Intangible personalty. Coincident with the passage of the Income Tax Law, the general laws were amended so as to exempt from taxation ( 1 ) Moneys, (2) Stocks and bonds, (3) All debts due from solvent debtors, whether on ac- count, note, contract, bond, mortgage, or other security, or whether such debts are due or to become due. (&) Tangible Personalty. In order that the owner of tangible personal property should not be placed at a disadvantage as com- pared with the owner of intangibles, the Income Tax Law pro- 188 STATE OF NEW YORK vides that the receipts for general taxes paid on personal property may be used as cash in paying for the income tax. This is called offsetting. What is Taxable Under the Wisconsin Income Tax General rule all income derived from (a) Persons, (b) Property, (c) Business, having an actual or constructive situs in the State. In detail all income, other than by statute exempt ; (a) which residents of the State receive from within or without the State, (b) as well as that which nonresidents receive from within the State, is taxable. Where a resident receives income partly from within and partly from without the State (other than income derived from rentals, stocks, bonds, and securities, or evidence of indebtedness), said resident is taxed on a proportion of the total income, to be de- termined by the amount of property from which it is derived, located or to be acquired within the State and by the business transacted within or without the State. In determining taxable income, the general rule is followed that income from property which is taxable at its situs also fol- lows the situs of the property, and income derived from property- taxable at the domicile of the owner also follows the residence of the recipient of the income. Thus the resident is not taxable on income from rents or royalties arising in another State, but he is taxable on that derived from securities, regardless of their origin ; while rents and royalties arising in Wisconsin are taxable to nonresidents. What Income Is Not Taxable (a) Residents are not taxable on rents or royalties arising in another State, or, in other words, on any income derived from prop- JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 189 erty having its situs beyond the jurisdiction of the State of Wis- consin. Definition of Income Incomes includes " rent, interest, wages, dividends, profits, and royalties, and all other income." !N". B. It also includes " esti- mated rental of resident's property occupied by one thereof." Income of Individuals Exempted from Taxation (1) (a) To an individual income up to and including $800 ; (b) To husband and wife, $1,200 ; (c) For each child under the age of eighteen years, $200; (d) For each additional person, for whose support the tax- payer is legally liable and who is entirely dependent upon the taxpayer for his support, $200 ; (e) The aforesaid exemptions do not apply to incomes de- rived from sources within the State by nonresidents thereof, nor to firms, copartnerships, corporations, joint-stock companies, nor associations. In computing the exemptions and the amounts of taxes pay- able, the income of a wife is added to the income of her husband, and the income of each child under eighteen years of age to that of its parent or parents, when said wife or child is not living separately from said husband, parent, or parents. (2) Income of any mutual savings or loan and building asso- ciation, or of any religious, scientific, educational, benevolent, or other association or individuals not organized or conducted for pecuniary profit. (3) Incomes derived from property and privileges by persons now required by law to pay taxes or license fees directly into the treasury of the State in lieu of taxes, and such persons shall con- tinue to pay taxes and license fees as heretofore. (4) Income received by the United States, the State, and all counties, cities, villages, school districts, or other political units of the State. Rates of Wisconsin Income Tax Individuals. On taxable incomes of individuals, firms, or co- partnerships * 190 STATE OF NEW YORK Rate True rate on per cent whole amount On the first $1,000 or portion thereof 1 l . second 1% 1.125 third 11/2 1.25 fourth 1% 1.375 fifth 2 1.5 sixth 21/2 1.6667 seventh 3 1 . 8571 eighth 3i/ 2 2.0625 ninth 4 2.2778 tenth 4V 2 2.5 eleventh 5 2 . 7273 twelfth 5y 2 2. 7582 twentieth 6 4 . 175 All additional amounts 6 Deductions from Incomes of Individuals and Co-partnerships In the case of individuals, firms and copartnerships the follow- ing deductions from the gross income are allowed : (1) Necessary expenses, including salaries or wages, of less than $700. (2) Salaries or. wages of $700 or more, providing the name and address of the employee is reported. (3) Uninsured losses during the year. (4) Dividends received from other persons whose income has been taxed by the State, providing the amount of said dividends has been reported by the person taxed at the time of the assess- ment. (5) Interest received from bonds or other securities exempt from taxation under the laws of the United States. (6) Amount paid in taxes, other than inheritance taxes, and paid upon the property or business from which the income to be taxed is derived. (7) All inheritances, devises, and bequests on which inherit- ance tax has been paid. (8) Life insurance received to the amount of $10,000, if the taxpayer was legally dependent on the decedent. (9) Current interest paid on existing indebtedness, providing taxpayer reports the name and address of the creditor. (10) Compensation or pensions received from the United States. " JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 191 Income from Interstate Business The following quotation from the Wisconsin Income Tax Law explains how incomes from interstate business are apportioned: (1) "In determining taxable income, rentals, royalties and gains or profits from the operation of any firm, mine or quarry shall follow the situs of the property from which de- rived, and (2) income from personal service and from land contracts, mortgages, stocks, bonds and securities shall follow the resi- dence of the recipient. " With respect to other income, persons engaged in busi- ness within and without the State shall be taxed only upon such income as is derived from business transacted and prop- erty located within the State, which may be determined by allocation and separate accounting for such income when made in form and manner prescribed by the Tax Commission, but otherwise shall be determined in the manner specified in subdivision (e) of subsection Y of section I770b of the statutes as far as applicable." The section of the statute referred to authorizes a computation by taking the (1) gross business in dollars of the corporation in the State and adding the same to the (2) full value of the property of the corporation located in the State. The sum thus obtained is used as the enumerator of a fraction the denominator of which is to consist of the (1) total gross business in dollars of the corporation, both I within and without the State, added to (2) the full value of the property of the corporation within and without the State. The quotient of the enum- erator divided by the denominator is a decimal which indi- cates the proportion of the whole net income which should be apportioned in Wisconsin, i. e., such proportion of total income as gross business within the State and value of prop- erty within the State is to local gross business anywhere and total property owned. * 192 STATE OF NEW YORK II. ADMINISTRATION The distinguishing feature of the Wisconsin Income Tax Law is the prominence given to the scheme of administration. Of the seventeen closely printed pages which contain the law in pamphlet form, about two-thirds are devoted to the methods by which law is to be administered. It was realized that the failure of all State income taxes in the past was directly attributable to lax methods on the part of the local officials, and this danger was sought to be avoided by securing a higher degree of centralization. To this end the administration of the law was placed wholly in the hands of the permanent State Tax Commission. For purposes of ascertaining the amount of income to be assessed, the taxpayers are divided into the following classes : (a) Individuals; (b) Guardians, trustees, executors, agents and receivers; (c) Firms and partnerships; (d) Corporations; (e) Farmers and dairymen; (f ) Wage-earners, salaried men and other individuals deriving their income from personal services. Returns Individuals. All returns of income by firms and individuals are made to the income tax assessors. Upon receipt of these returns, they are carefully edited, and the assessors make an assessment of the tax in each case. If the assessor has reason to believe that the return is erroneous, he .can increase the amount upon which the tax is based, upon giving written notice to the taxpayer. A board of review of three persons is appointed by the Tax Commission of each district. An appeal lies from the decision of the assessor to the board of review, and then from the board of review to the Tax Commission. Use of Information at Source in Wisconsin When the forms for income tax returns are given out, they are accompanied by blanks upon which the taxpayer is required to JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 193 fill out the name and address of every person to \\ horn a salary or wages to the amount of $700 or more has been paid during the year and the amount paid in each case. There is an additional blank for corporations upon which the names and addresses of all stockholders to whom dividends have been paid, together with the amount paid or given, are shown. In like manner, claims for interest paid on indebtedness must be accompanied by a statement of the name and address of the person to whom such interest was paid. The information thus obtained by the Tax Commission is classi- fied and arranged so as to be furnished to the assessors of the respective districts where the recipients of the wages or dividends reside. Threefold Check 1. The above data shows whether any excessive salaries are being paid to officers of the corporation. 2. It enables the Commission to test the correctness of the corporate deductions for wages, salaries and^ dividends paid. 3. It calls attention to any omission on the part of individuals to report the full amount received by them as interest, wages or dividends. Centralized Control and Income Tax Assessors The Income Tax Assessors. The success of the income tax as applied to individuals is ascribed principally to the work of the assessors of incomes. These assessors are selected through the Civil Service Commission without reference to political considera- tions, and are relieved of that local pressure which in so many places has brought about the failure of the general property tax. Cost of Administration The cost of administering the Wisconsin income tax is very small, indeed. The first year it cost 1.31 per cent, and the second year only 1.11 per cent. Comparing these figures with the cost of collecting other forms of taxes in this country, or in other countries, discloses the fact that the income tax is one of the least expensive direct taxes collected anywhere in the world. The only possible exception to this statement may be found in the case of 7 194 STATE OF NEW YORK license fees and similar taxes taken directly over the counter of the public treasury without any difficult assessment work to be performed. The latter are, of course, the least expensive forms of revenue known to modern governments. The cheapest kinds of taxes collected in the United States are internal revenue taxes of the Federal government. However, it cost the state of Wisconsin less proportionately to collect the income tax than it cost the Federal government to collect the internal revenue taxes. Delinquency The experience of Wisconsin for the first three years indicates that from 2 to 4 per cent of the income taxes are delinquent. Of the total amount of delinquency, it is estimated, in the opinion of the assessors of incomes, that about 50 per cent could be collected, that about 25 per cent are noncollectible, and the re- maining 25 per cent doubtful. In other words, with efficient and vigorous collection on the part of the local treasurers, only about one and one-third per cent should be finally lost. Success of the Tax The Wisconsin income tax is generally regarded as being highly successful, and in our judgment tha.t opinion is well justified by the results. The report of the Wisconsin Tax Commission for the year 1914 has this to say: " .Such were the ideals and objects of the income tax. Whether it would accomplish the desired results was dis- tinctly problematical. Income taxes had been employed in this country continuously from the seventeenth century. But they had not, particularly in recent years, worked well. In theory the income tax was generally admitted to be the ideal substitute for the tax on moneys, credits and perhaps all forms of personal property. But experts doubted whether it could be made to work as a state tax, and in particular they doubted whether it would yield reasonable large revenues, whether it would not prove exceedingly expensive to administer, and whether the average taxpayer would co-operate with the authorities in returning sufficiently accurate and truthful re- ports upon which to base a fair and adequate assessment. Three assessments have now been made under the income tax JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 195 law and a body of experience and data has been accumulated sufficient to answer with some certainty the doubts and ques- tions properly raised by the experiment with the incomei tax." It then goes on to say what results have been accomplished, which may be summarized, as follows : (1) The income tax has yielded a very substantial revenue, and one well in excess of that received from the personal prop- erty tax. Thus, in 1912 the tax amounted to $3,482,145; in 1913, $4,084,497; and in 1914 to $4,140,571. It is to be noted, however, that this does not represent actual cash collections, be- cause under the Wisconsin law the man paying a personal prop- erty tax may offset it as against his income tax. (2) It has succeeded in reaching large classes of property and groups of individuals that were escaping under the personal property tax. (3) It has reached those groups in proportion to their ability to pay. (4) It has proved from an administrative standpoint one of the cheapest taxes known, costing both in the years 1913 and 1914 less than a hundred thousand dollars. It should be noted, however, in this connection, that in this amount there is included $34,000, representing the cost of the supervisors of assessment, leaving $45,197.59 as the net cost of the income tax for the year 1913-1914. On this basis, therefore, the income tax cost to assess and administer the first year 1.31 per cent, and the second year 1.11 per cent. Advantages of the Income Tax The income tax reaches everyone in accordance with his ability to pay. It is the one tax that will most fairly' and equitably reach the professional and salaried men who earn large incomes. They now entirely escape taxation except on such property, as they may have accumulated and which very obviously is no fair indi- cation of their ability to contribute to the support of government. This is likewise true in respect to the great wealth, represented by the securities and credits of all kinds and by the various forms of intangible property, which is now escaping taxation. One of the most interesting facts to be gained from a study of the Wis- consin results is, that the classes of occupations, of professions * 196 STATE OF NEW YORK and of property-owners that most successfully escape in ISTew York, are the very ones that pay the larger part of the Wisconsin tax levied upon firms and individuals. In ISTew York State the following classes are able to escape taxation in a large degree: Bankers and capitalists, brokers, lawyers, merchants and jobbers, manufacturers, physicians and surgeons, and other professions. We quote in this connection from the Report of 1914, which reads as. follows : Occupation Bankers and capitalists 982 $116.33 8.00 1.61 4.76 Estates, guardianships, etc 977 82.42 5.98 1.60 3.76 Lumbermen 346 81.27 1.97 .57 1.32 Manufacturers 2, 920 78.26 16.01 4.80 11.36 Lawyers 1,202 59.26 5.02 1.97 4.18 Miners 80 38.89 0.22 .13 .18 Eetired 3, 263 37.24 8.51 5.36 6.93 Merchants and jobbers 11, 838 24.13 20.01 19.45 23.55 Physicians and surgeons 1,642 22.78 2.62 2.70 3.30 Brokers, real estate men, etc .... 5,338 20.86 7.80 8.77 8.72 Public officials 555 16.05 0.62 .91 .93 Mechanics and tradesmen 5,768 12.63 5.10 9.48 6.17 Professions miscellaneous .... 2, 359 12.30 2.03 3.88 2.96 Professors and teachers 2,372 10.40 1.73 3.90 2.08 State and public employees 1,203 8.15 0.69 1.98 .99 Public service employees 2, 870 7.96 1.60 4.72 2.07 Farmers 7, 225 7.66 3.87 11.87 6.40 Bookkeepers, stenographers, etc. 4, 148 4.96 1.44 6.82 2.54 Laborers 882 2.91 0.18 1.45 .34 Other occupations 4,336 20.25 6.15 7.12 6.78 Unknown 554 11.71 0.45 .91 .68 All occupations 60, 860 23.46 100.00 100.00 100.00 " Certain important conclusions may, however, be drawn with safety. For instance, the census statistics make it plain that there are not less than 165,000 farmers in the state, from which it follows that certainly less than five per cent of the farmers of the state are subject to the income tax. Similarly, it is certain that considerably less than one per cent, and probably less than one-half of one per cent, of the JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 197 laborers of the state are assessed for income taxes. Of the bookkeepers, stenographers and clerks, the statistics indicate that something less than six per cent were assessed for in- come tax in 1914. " On the other hand, it is practically certain that more than fifty per cent of the bankers and capitalists, lawyers and physicians and surgeons were subject to the individual income tax, to say nothing of the amounts which these per- sons pay indirectly through the tax on corporations. It is interesting also to note that probably not less than 20 per cent of the public officials, public employees and public laborers of the state were assessed for income tax. The federal census for 1910 shows 7,338 employees in the public service, not elsewhere classified, including guards, watch- men, doorkeepers, firemen and laborers. Table IV shows that 1,758 public officials and employees were assessed for income tax in 1914, or somewhere between one-quarter and one-fifth of the number recorded in the census. There can- not be a very large number of public employees classified elsewhere than in this group. " Perhaps as good a measure of the relative burden of the tax as could be secured is found in the figures showing the average tax per taxpayer. The various occupations are arranged in the order of the size of this average tax in Table VI. The highest per capita tax, $116.33, is paid by bank- ers and capitalists; the lowest by laborers, $2.91. The tax was evidently highest upon investors and allied classes, those drawing their incomes largely in the form of interest. Next it touches the extractive and manufacturing industries lumbering, manufacturing and mining though it should be remembered that in these classes a relatively large pro- portion of the tax is offset by the personal property tax. Merchants and jobbers follow closely, among whom also a large part of the tax is offset by personal property taxes, and thereafter come the professional classes. The lawyers it will be observed are above the other professional classes, standing between manufacturers and miners. The tax on the professional classes generally is additional or supple- 198 STATE OF NEW YORK mentary. It is not offset by the personal property taxes and no equivalent tax was collected from these classes be- fore the income tax was introduced. The statistics indicate that the income tax is performing exactly the service for which it was introduced drawing a larger contribution from the investing and professional classes and from those elements of the manufacturing and commercial classes which are usually prosperous and subject to higher income than personal property taxes." This conclusion is further emphasized when we remember that the largest accumulations of so-called intangible personal prop- erty are found in our great cities, and that the income tax is, strictly speaking, an urban tax. In Wisconsin, the first year over 40 per cent of the entire tax was charged in Milwaukee County and more than 80 per cent in the 17 counties having the larger cities of the state, while 20 per cent was charged in the remaining 54 counties containing about 50 per cent of the popu- lation. The urban character of the tax is shown in another way by the returns from Dane county in which the capital is located. In the county there are six times as many farmers as there are pub- lic employees, " yet only sixty-eight farmers in Dane County as contrasted with six .hundred twenty-four public employees and professors will pay an income tax; and the farmers will pay an income tax of $877.35, while the public officials, professors and teachers will pay $7,224.44, more than eight times as much." " The income tax is primarily an urban tax. Milwaukee county, for instance, contains only 8.56 per cent of the population of the state, but 42.55 per cent of the total in- come and 47.12 per cent of the total income tax are assessed in that County. The fifty-four rural counties, on the other hand, contain nearly fifty per cent of the population but pay less than one-fifth of the tax. " The marked urban character of the tax comes out in other relationships. For instance, the total income tax as- sessed in 1914 amounts to $1.77 per capita. But the per JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 199 capita tax in Milwaukee City is $4.50, and in the rural coun- ties only 53 cents. Again, the average rate of taxation paid is 3.61 per cent in Milwaukee County, but only 1.95 per cent in the rural counties of the state. Finally, in Milwaukee County 4.69 per cent of the population is subject to the tax on firms and individuals, while in the rural districts only 1.71 per cent of the population was assessed. In short, a smaller proportion of the people pay, and they pay lower average rates on smaller average incomes, in the country than in the city." As has already been shown, the property tax falls with the greatest weight on the man of small means, on ths widow, on trust estates, on young and struggling business concerns, and, generally speaking, on those least able to bear it. Under the income tax these people contribute their proportion, but their proportion is relatively small as compared with that of the wealthy and prosperous, who enjoy large incomes and are, there- fore, better, and with much less sacrifice, able to shoulder the tax burden, and yet who to-day are practically free from taxation, except in so far as they own real estate. We cite again the Wisconsin results for purposes of illustration : " This table contains some very significant data. Of those assessed in 1914 for income tax, 41,732 had taxable in- comes under $1,000. This group of small taxpayers con- stituted 68 per cent of the total number, but paid less than 11 per cent of the total tax. The average tax in this group is 3.74. " On the other hand, 315 taxpayers having incomes of $15,000 or more, and constituting about one-half of one per cent of the total number of taxpayers, were assessed for practically forty per cent of the aggregate tax, and the aver- age tax on each person in this group is $1,794. This group of 315 taxpayers constitute less than 2/100 of 1 per cent of the population of the State. The two upper groups of taxpayers 667 in number constitute less than 3/100 of 1 per cent of the entire population but contributes nearly one-half of the income tax." 200 STATE OF NEW YOKK Classified by amount groups of income Num- ber assessed Per cent of each group to total Taxable income Per cent of each group to total Tax Per cent of each group to total Average tax per indi- vidual Total 60,560 100.00 $73,969,905 25 100.00 $1,427,923 13 100.00 $23 46 Under 1,000... 41,732 63.57 15,545,782 60 21.02 156,202 53 10.94 3 74 1,000 to 1,999. 10,528 17.30 11,004,276 71 18.93 152,871 09 10.71 14 52 2, 000 to 2, 999. 3,855 6.33 9,210,837 07 12.45 110,348 59 7.73 28 62 3,000 to 3,999. 1,691 2.78 5,760,689 61 7.79 75,436 33 5.28 44 61 4,000 to 4,999. 908 1.49 4,027,847 43 5.44 57,906 82 4.05 63 76 5,000 to 9,999. 1,479 2.43 9,820,371 30 13.28 182,901 61 12.81 123 70 10,000 to 14,999 352 0.58 4,245,486 58 5.74 127,168 00 8.91 361 26 15,000 and over. 315 0.52 11,354,613 95 15.35 565,087 56 39.57 1,794 00 As a further illustration we may give an example of the amount that would be contributed by the highest and the lowest classes of tax-payers under the terms of the bill attached to this report. 72,345 people having incomes less than $3,000 would pay a total of $287,587.15, while 82 people having the larger incomes in the State would pay a total of $1,809,649. The result is almost startling, and yet the 82 would be paying only their share. But neither for the wealthy man nor for the poor man would the burden be a heavy one, for a low rate running from one-half of 1 per cent to a maximum of 2 per cent on indi- viduals would satisfy all our needs. Under this rate, with an exemption of $1,500 to a single man and of $2,000 to the average family, the family man with an income of $3,000 would pay but $5 per annum, while the man with an income of $100,000 would pay somewhat less than $2,000 per annum. Could either one of them fairly complain? Nor, under such circumstances, would there be any real incentive to escape. No man will willingly pay a two per cent tax on capital value, which amounts to taking from 30 to 50 per cent of his income. Experience has shown, however, that he will pay so reasonable an amount as 2 per cent on income, par- ticularly when he knows that all who should are contributing their share. Under our present system the conscientious tax- payer is not only asked to pay a confiscatory rate, but he is asked to do so with the full knowledge that nearly everyone in the community is dodging the tax in one way or another. Most men are honest. Most men, we believe, are willing to pay a fair and reasonable tax, but there is a point in taxation where it is dangerous to test human nature too far, and where the honesty JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 201 of the average citizen is forced to give way to the instinct of self- protection. Turning now to general business corporations and to individ- uals and partnerships engaged in business, we find that in so far as these classes are concerned, the personal property tax is illogical, burdensome, unequal and therefore inequitable; that the great majority of business houses escape taxation, but that those that do pay are taxed at a rate altogether too high, a fact which puts them at an unfair disadvantage as compared with their competitors; that, in brief, the personal property tax is, in the main, a failure, and to the extent that it does succeed, grossly unjust. ' We find, moreover, that the assessment and valuation of property gives rise to all manner of difficulties, particularly in the case of cor- porations where it is necessary to include the franchise value as part of the gross assets or of the capital stock value ; and that ulti- mately the assessors find that the fairest way to reach the capi- tal value of the property is through the capitalization of net earnings. Few, if any, of these difficulties arise when individuals engaged in business and general business corporations are taxed on a net-earning basis. As has been well said by Dr. Ely in the report of the Maryland Tax Commission : " Furthermore, it is of moment that the income tax does not make it more difficult for a poor man to begin business or to continue business. Its social effects, on the contrary, are beneficial, because it places a heavy load only on strong shoulders. Even for men of large means engaged in busi- ness it is a tax to be strongly recommended, fur such men will in some years make little or nothing, or even lose money. !N"ow, our property tax is merciless; it exacts as much in a year when a business man is struggling to keep his head above water as in a year of rare prosperity; whereas the income tax exacts much only when much can be given without finan- cial embarrassment. If it were practicable to substitute an income tax for the whole of the property tax it would save many a man from bankruptcy. I will repeat, with some 202 STATE OF NEW YOKE modification, in this connection, words I used in my special report as member of the Baltimore Tax Commission: " t It is the fairest tax ever devised ; it places a heavy bur- den when and where there is strength to bear it, and lightens the load in case of temporary or permanent weakness. Large property does not always imply ability to pay taxes, as taxes should come from income; even when assessed on property it is only an indirect device for estimating income. An income tax spares the business man in season of distress and helps him to weather the storm, but asks a return for the consideration shown in days of increasing prosperity. 7 ' Moreover, as we have repeatedly stated throughout this report, property is not a fair test of ability to pay, and this is particu- larly true in the case of merchants and manufacturers. We again desire to emphasize, that the amount of stock of goods on hand or the capital value of the property does not adequately measure earning capacity for the purpose of taxation, and that we know of no fairer way of determining what should be the proper contribu- tion of an individual corporation than by considering its net earnings. This is all the more true when we consider that it takes, in some instances, several years for a business to develop to the point that it* can pay a return upon the original invest- ment. It is neither good policy nor sound finance to overtax an infant industry, nor, for that matter, even an established industry, in bad times. Taxes are paid out of income, and one of the great advantages of an income tax as a business tax is that it levies tribute only when there is an income from which to pay it. That the income tax is the best way of taxing both individ- uals engaged in business and general business corporations, was the opinion of practically every business man that appeared before our Committee, and of the Tax Committees of such repre- sentative commercial bodies as the Chamber of Commerce of the City of Kochester, of the Merchants Association of the City of "New York, and the Chamber of Commerce of the City of New York. The income tax is the only tax that will reach that great class of people who do business in New York City, enjoying all of its JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 203 commercial and other advantages on the same basis as a citizen of the State, and who, under the present law, pay no taxes whatso- ever. One of the chief difficulties of our present system is the vary- ing rates in different localities which tend to produce grave inequalities as between towns and between the residents of differ- ent towns. The tendency, of course, is for taxpayers to establish a real or fictitious residence in that locality where the rate is lowest, and this inevitably results in injustice to the other less fortunate towns and their taxpayers. By the establishment of a uniform rate throughout the State, the income tax will do away with this situation entirely. " Isles of safety " and favorite places of residence will disappear, and individuals and corporations will all meet on an equal and fair basis, subject to a just burden, and with the full knowledge that it is common to all and that there are neither a fortunate many nor an unfortunate few. To equalize the burden is the principal function for which this Committee was appointed. Certain classes of property are to-day paying too much, others too little. No equality can exist until those paying too little are compelled to pay their share. It seems to us that the income tax meets these requirements. The Committee has caused to be made various estimates as to the possible yield of an income tax in the State of New York. Different methods have been used, and a number of experts have made various estimates based on these different methods. The results in each case are not far apart. All tend to indicate that a corporation tax as outlined in the attached bill would yield in 1916, at a one per cent rate, approximately, $9,000,000 ; at two per cent, approximately, $18,000,000; and at three per cent, approxi- mately $27,000,000. In the year 1917, at one per cent, approxi- mately, $9,000,000; at two per cent, approximately, $19,000,000; and at three per cent, approximately, $29,000,000. The estimate of the yield from the individual income tax at the rates contained in the attached bill is as follows: 1916 $18,000,000, approximately 1917 19,000,000, approximately 204 STATE OF NEW YORK From these amounts would have to be deducted, however, the present revenue derived under section 182 from the corporations that would be subject to the income tax, which corporations, by the terms of the attached bill, would be relieved from payments under section 182. The State would then, out of the total amount collected, retain a little over $2,000,000, plus the cost of ad- ministration; and the balance, under the terms of the bill, would be returned to the localities. This balance, in 1917, would amount to over $44,000,000. In considering the net gain to the localities over the present system, we would have to take into consideration the loss of approximately $6,000,- 000, at present derived from the personal property tax. After allowing for all these deductions there would still be a net gain of $38,000,000, to be distributed to the localities with a view to equalizing the present burden of taxation by relieving real estate and such other forms of wealth as are now contributing more than their share. We give in the appendix a table showing the amount which would be received by each county if the $38,000,000 were distributed on the basis of the assessed values of real estate for the year 1914. This table shows beyond any question that there is not a county in the State that would not be infinitely better off than it is to-day. The suggested method of distribution according to assessed values in each county is novel, but it has these advantages: 1. It will avoid the difficulty which would arise if each locality were permitted to retain the tax paid by residents of that district. Under this latter method some districts, where many rich men have established a residence, or where many prosperous corpora- tions are located, would have more revenue than they could use, while others, whose inhabitants enjoy smaller incomes, would receive little or no revenue. 2. The new method will tend to encourage the raising of real estate assessments to a point approaching true value. 3. It will meet the criticism made of an income tax to the effect that, although the rate is usually low at the start, there is a con- stant temptation to raise it in order to obtain more revenue. Under the proposed system there will be no temptation on the JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 205 part of the Legislature to raise the rate, inasmuch as the State will not profit, while it is hardly probable that all of the localities, or even a majority of them, will unite at one time in demanding an increase, or at least such a situation will not occur unless the increase is fully warranted by the general circumstances. It is sometimes said that the income tax is inquisitorial, but it will be noted that the bill hereto attached makes it possible for the taxpayer to file with the State authorities a return which is, for all practical purposes, a duplicate of the information already fur- nished to the Federal government, together with such additional information as may be necessary for State purposes. We hear little or no complaint to-day as to the inquisitorial features of the Federal income tax. People have become accustomed to it. Nor do we feel that there will be any great reluctance to disclose to the State authorities information already furnished by the Federal government, particularly under a law which provides severe pen- alties for the disclosure of any information by the public officers. Again others object to a state income tax on the ground that there is already a Federal income tax. But let us analyze the ob- jection. There is no question that, in addition to the Federal income tax, personal property must contribute its quota to the sup- port of the State government. Is it better to impose a 2 per cent property tax on capital value, or to impose a 2 per cent tax on net income? We can hardly assume that the State will continue to allow the personal property tax to remain on the statute books and to permit its evasion. And so the choice does not lie between no tax and some new form of taxation such as the income tax, but be- tween a continuance of the present hopeless system, and some better and more equitable way of raising revenue. If such a latter plan can be devised, are we to reject it because it is already employed by the Federal government, and in order to avoid dupli- cation, continue to tax the same property in a manner which we admit ourselves to be inequitable, and to be a failure ? Finally, it is often said, that while theoretically sound, the in- come tax will not work in practice. This may have been true prior to the enactment of the Federal Income Tax Law, but this law is of immense help to any state desiring to impose an inctrae 206 STATE OF NEW YOKK tax; and for two reasons. In the first place, many people are already accustomed to it, they understand its workings and will not resist its enforcement; and in the second place, the fact that the Federal government requires a return, and has the machinery to check up that return in a strictly accurate manner, makes the evasion of the State income tax a matter of no little difficulty and danger. In so far as corporations are concerned, the Federal law to-day permits a state to examine the returns. A similar provi- sion in so far as individuals are concerned, could probably be ob- tained from the Federal government. But in the meanwhile it seems to us highly doubtful whether any individual having already filed a correct statement with the Federal government would be foolhardy enought to file an incorrect duplicate with the State authorities. The income tax will work in practice. It has been successfully administered in practically every European country for a great number of years. The Federal income tax works, and the Wis- consin experiment has conclusively demonstrated that with a good administration a state income tax does work. There seems to be, moreover, a strong movement in favor of such a tax throughout the country. Connecticut and West Virginia both adopted an in- come tax in so far as corporations are concerned last winter, while the people of Massachusetts, by a vote of almost three to one, adopted at the last election an amendment which permits the im- position of such a tax in the State of Massachusetts. Practically every witness that appeared before our Committee and the list included representatives of leading commercial and business or- ganizations, as well as tax experts, business men and individuals from many walks of life advocated the abolition of the per- sonal property tax and the substitution therefor of the income tax. CONCLUSION The Legislature submitted to this Committee the question: " How can the State most equitably and effectually reach all property which should be subjected to taxation and avoid conflict and duplication of taxation on the same property ? " Without passing upon the broad questions of public policy in- volved in the adoption of a new tax system, which questions JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 207 should more properly be decided by the Legislature as a whole, this Committee, in answer to the specific question submitted to it, desires to state that all the evidence presented and all our investi- gations, the results of which are presented in full in this report, tend to show that the end sought for will be accomplished best by : (1) the abolition of the present tax on personal property; (2) the withdrawal of general business corporations from the provisions of section 182 of the Tax Law; and (3) the imposition of an in- come tax on individuals and general business corporations, in- cluding manufacturing corporations. To illustrate the general outline of what is involved in the sub- stitution of income taxation for the personal property tax, and to furnish a concrete basis for criticism and suggestion on the part of the public and the Legislature, we attach to this report an income tax bill. There is some difference of opinion among the members of the Committee as to the details of this measure and the advisability of some of its provisions. In view of this differ- ence, the Committee as a whole submits this specific bill to the Legislature merely for the purposes of illustration. We emphasize that such a bill does not contemplate the imposi- tion of an additional tax but a substitute for a hopelessly bad system, that it is not advanced as a means of raising additional revenue for State purposes but rather to equalize local burdens. Again, it is advanced because of all the many reforms and new methods of taxation adopted in other states of the Union and in foreign countries, it seems to promise the closest approximation to the ideals of equity and equality. It does this by taxing each man in accordance with his ability to contribute to the support of the government which protects him, his property and the social structure of which he is a part. If the Legislature intended that this Committee should make a complete survey of our tax system, the work is by no means finished. For example, the study of the taxation of public service and financial corporations could not even be begun in the time at our disposal, and though consideration has been given to the many amendments to the Tax Law submitted by the State Tax Commis- sion and by others 7 we find it impossible to report definite con- clusions as to them at this date. If a complete study of the tax 208 STATE OF NEW YORK laws is desired, the time of the Committee should be extended to February 1, 1917. We are in a position, however, at present, to make one or two suggestions in addition to our main recommendations. The inheritance tax as it stands is, generally speaking, of satis- factory character. It is regarded as a fair and equitable law, while the progressive feature is almost universally acknowledged to be sound. Nevertheless, from a revenue standpoint the tax is a disappointment. The Comptroller informs us that the normal income to be expected therefrom is between seven and nine mil- lion dollars, an amount well below what had been anticipated. In order to make the tax more productive, the Comptroller recommends that the law be amended in the following particu- lars: (1) The present inheritance tax law as amended in 1911 ex- empts from taxation in this State intangible property belonging to nonresidents, such as shares in New York corporations, and money and securities kept on deposit here. The Comptroller would restore the provisions which existed prior to 1911, and tax the intangible property of nonresidents. The Committee does not feel that it can agree with this recommendation. This prop- erty has a situs and is taxable at the decedent's residence. As nearly all states have inheritance tax laws, the taxation by New York is double taxation. When originally adopted, few states had inheritance tax laws, and the question was not, therefore, serious, as it has since become. Aside from the unfairness of a double tax of this character, we do not believe that the amend- ment would result in a greatly increased revenue, but rather in driving property from the State and in preventing residents of other states investing in New York corporations. The evil results of an unwise law are well exemplified by experience in connection with the 1910 amendments to the inheritance tax law. " The law of 1910 established high graded rates with prac- tically no exemption, and so greatly increased the tax to which such investments were liable that it attracted attention through- out the United States and Europe. Investors residing outside the State were warned by circulars from banking houses and by the JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 209 newspapers of their liability to taxation under the New York law, of which many of them had been unaware, with the result that millions of dollars of investments and deposits were with- drawn from the State, and more withdrawals were in contempla- tion. "Attention was called to this situation by the State Comptroller in his report of 1911. The Comptroller said: " ' Instances have lately been brought to my attention in which foreign capital, seeking investment in New York through bank- ing houses, which, by reason of their connections, would, under normal conditions, have invested it in stocks of domestic corpora- tions, has, by reason of the hardship of this law, been diverted from the natural course and invested in the stocks of corporations domiciled in other states. No argument is needed to show the effect which a continuation of the present law will have upon the corporations domiciled here. " ' The great custodial institutions incorporated under the bank- ing law of the State to care for the property of its citizens are likewise suffering loss of patronage due to the severity of this law.' " After the law had been in operation eight months it was esti- mated that the withdrawal of securities and investments in this State had amounted to $400,000,000. (2) The Comptroller further suggested that a tax should be collected on the amounts bequeathed to educational and charitable institutions in other states which are now exempt. The wisdom of such an amendment is open to the gravest doubts, and we can- not recommend its adoption. The exemption from taxation of religious, charitable and educational institutions has long since been recognized as a permanent policy in the State of New York. If such institutions are to be encouraged, we do not know why this principle should be limited to our own State. As a matter of broad public policy, New York's interest in the development of educational and charitable enterprises in other states should be second only to her interest in the development of such enterprises within her own border. Men should be encouraged to make be- quests to institutions devoted to the public good, not discouraged, 210 STATE OF NEW YORK no matter where those institutions may be located. Any other point of view is narrow and provincial, unbecoming to a great State, and will inevitably lead to retaliation. (3) The third amendment contemplates the bringing of the various groups or classifications closer together, so as to lower the point at which the higher rates are applicable. The rates remain unchanged, but the progression is made somewhat more rapid and sharper. The Comptroller estimates that such an amendment will add $2,500,000 to the annual yield of the tax " without imposing any appreciable hardship upon those whose immediate interests in property would be affected thereby." We are in accord with this suggestion, which appears to be a sound and proper one, though we do not agree to all the details of the amendment as contained in his report. Should the last recommendation be adopted and the State's revenue increased $2,500,000, it would then be possible to give some measure of relief to the localities pending a more thorough reform, through the division between the State and the locality of the increase in the excise tax, should that increase be made permanent, and of the automobile license tax, with the under- standing, however, that as to the latter both the State and the county should continue to devote their respective shares to the maintenance of highways. There is no novelty involved in such a division. It is in line with the policy adopted in the past as exemplified by the division of the excise taxes and of the mort- gage recording tax. In conclusion, it is pertinent to call attention to the fact that if the Federal government is to abandon its traditional policy of relying upon indirect taxation, and is to look more and more to direct taxes for its support; if Federal income tax rates are to be raised and a Federal inheritance tax imposed, it will be necessary to revolutionize our systems of State taxation. The Federal government is much better able to effectively impose indirect taxes, such as custom duties, excise, etc. These have been and are its natural sources of revenue; while the states are of necessity compelled to rely for the most part on direct taxes. Time and space do not permit the adequate discussion of so large JCINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 211 a topic. We cannot refrain, however, from pointing out the utter folly of building up side by side two independent and totally un- related systems of taxation, without conference, mutual under- standing or an intelligent endeavor to determine the limits of the fields of taxation to be assigned, respectively, to the Federal government and to the states. OGDEN L. MILLS, Chairman, ARCHIE D. SANDERS, EDWARD A. EVERETT, H. EDMUND MACHOLD, WILLIAM W. CHACE. While I concur in the majority report of the committee, believ- ing that all the testimony taken points irresistibly to the conclu- sions reached, yet I most strongly disapprove of many features of the Income Tax bill attached to the report, the details of which are not at all in accord with my views of such a measure. WILLIAM W. CHACE. DRAFT OF LAW FOR INCOME TAX [213] * DRAFT OF LAW FOR INCOME TAX AN ACT To amend the tax law, in relation to imposing an income tax. The People of the State of New York, represented in Senate and Assembly, do enact as follows: Section 1. Chapter sixty-two of the laws of nineteen hundred and nine, entitled "An act in relation to. taxation, constituting chapter sixty of the consolidated laws," is hereby amended by adding a new article to be article sixteen, to read as follows: AETICLE 16. TAX UPON AND WITH RESPECT TO INCOMES. Section 340. Definitions. 341. Tax upon and with respect to incomes. 342. Definition of " income." 343. "Net income" and "taxable income" defined. 344. Deductions to persons other than corporations. 345. Deductions to corporations. 346. Specific personal deduction. 347. Income exempt. 348. Persons not subject to income tax. 349. Income within and without the state. 350. Rate of taxation. 351. Administration and assessment. 352. When returns to be made. 353. Consolidated return from certain corporations. 354. Powers of tax commission; revision of accounts. 355. Penalties. 356. Certification of assessment to comptroller. 357. Notice of assessment. 358. When payable. 359. Warrant for the collection of taxes. 360. Action for recovery of taxes; forfeiture of char- ter by delinquent corporations. [215] 216 STATE OF NEW YOEK Section 361. Distribution of the tax. 362. The tax on salaries paid to non-residents to be with- held by employers. 363. Persons acting in a fiduciary capacity. 364. Tax commission authorized to make such regula- tions and to collect such facts as are necessary to enforce this article. 365. :Secrecy required of officials. Penalty for violation. 366. Persons subject to the income tax exempt from the personal property tax and from the provisions of sections twelve, one hundred and eighty-two and one hundred and ninety-two of the tax law. 340. Definitions. For the purpose of this article and unless otherwise required by the context: 1. The word " person " or the word " taxpayer " shall be deemed to include individuals, firms, copartnerships, representa- tives and corporations as hereinafter defined. 2. The word " corporation " shall be deemed to include corpo- rations, joint stock companies, associations and those trusts whose property is represented by transferable certificates or by capital stock divided into transferable shares. For the purpose of this act corporations shall be deemed to reside within the state under whose laws they were organized and erected. 341. Tax upon and with respect to incomes. A tax is hereby imposed upon every person residing within the state, and shall be collected and paid annually upon and with respect to his entire net income from all sources except that from property located or from any business, trade or profession carried on without the state as hereinafter provided ; and a like tax shall be collected and paid annually upon and with respect to the entire net income from all property located and of every business, trade or profession carried on in this state by persons residing elsewhere. Such tax shall first be collected and paid in the year nineteen hundred and seventeen upon and with respect to the taxable income for the year ending December thirty-first, nineteen hundred and sixteen. 342. Definition of income. 1. The term " income " as used in this act shall comprise all gains, profits and income derived from any source whatever, including the income from but not the value of property acquired by gift, bequest, devise or descent. It shall include but shall not be limited to: JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 217 a. Salaries, wages, fees and compensation for personal service of whatever kind and in whatever form paid. b. Interest, dividends, and rent, including royalties from mines or the possession or use of franchises or legalized privileges of any kind. c. Gains, profits and income derived from securities, or from professions, vocations, businesses, trade, commerce or sales, or from transactions growing out of the ownership or use of or inter- est in property. d. So much of any debt or account due to the taxpayer and col- lected after January first, nineteen hundred and sixteen, as has been written off as worthless at any time prior to such collection. 2. Income shall not include the proceeds of life insurance policies paid upon the death of the person insured; nor amounts paid by the insured on a life insurance, endowment, or annuity contract when returned to him upon the maturity or surrender of the contract, but the amount by which the sum received exceeds the sum paid shall be included as income; and so much of any annuity as is composed of an interest return upon the principal sum paid therefor, shall also be included as income. 3. Of the gain derived or loss sustained from the sale of real estate, stocks, bonds, securities or other property acquired before January first, nineteen hundred and sixteen, not regularly bought and sold by the taxpayer, only such proportion shall be included as the time between January first, nineteen hundred and sixteen, and the date of sale bears to the entire time between the date of acquisition and the date of sale. 343. "Net income" and "taxable income" defined. The term " net income " shall mean the excess of income as herein- before defined over and above the deductions and exemptions here- inafter authorized. As applied to persons residing within the state, the term " taxable income " shall mean all net income ex- cept that from property located, or from any business, trade or profession carried on, without the state. As applied to persons residing without the state, the term " taxable income " shall mean the entire net income from all property located, and of every busi- ness, trade or profession carried on, within the state. 344. Deductions to persons other than corporations. In com- puting net income of persons other than corporations there shall be allowed as deductions from the income as above defined : 1. The necessary expenses actually paid in carrying on any business, not including personal, living or family expenses. 218 STATE OF NEW YORK 2. Interest paid within the year except as provided in sub- division eight of this section. 3. Taxes paid within the year upon or with respect to income subject to this tax, including federal income taxes thereon when separately stated in the return, and including also license taxes, privilege taxes and other taxes upon business or property the income from which is subject to this tax; but not including assess- ments for local improvements, taxes imposed by article ten of the tax law or other inheritance taxes wherever imposed. 4. The following losses when actually sustained during the year and not compensated for by insurance or otherwise: (a) Losses resulting from fire, storm or other casualty, and from theft or property used in connection with the business or profession of the taxpayers. (b) Losses incurred in trade or transactions entered into for profit, to the extent that a profit therefrom, if realized, would have been taxable. 5. Debts due to the taxpayer arising in the course of business, charged off within the year and not theretofore ascertained to be worthless. 6. A reasonable annual allowance for the exhaustion, wear, tear and obsolescence of property arising out of its use or employ- ment in the business, and based upon its cost in cash or the equivalent of cash ; but no deduction shall be made for any amount of expense of restoring property or making good the exhaustion thereof for which an allowance is or has been made; and no deduction shall be allowed for any amount paid out for new buildings, permanent improvements or betterments made to in- crease the value of any property or estate. 7. Any salary received by a non-resident, the tax upon which has been withheld and which has been paid or is to be paid by an employer or payor under the provisions of section three hun- dred and sixty-two of this article; and any income received by a beneficiary which is taxed or taxable to his representative under the provision of section three hundred and sixty-three of this article. 8. No deduction shall be made for expenses chargeable to resi- dence property occupied by its owner, nor for the depreciation thereof, taxes paid thereon, nor for interest paid upon indebted-* ness secured thereby; and the annual value or estimated rental thereof shall not be included in the income subject to taxation. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 219 9. Dividends received from stock in any corporation and profit received from an interest in any copartnership subject to this tax, provided that when only part of the net income of the corporation or copartnership from which such dividend or profit was paid shall have been taxed under this article, only a corresponding part of such dividend or profit shall be deducted. 345. Deductions to corporations. In computing the net income of any corporation there shall be allowed as deductions from the income as above defined: 1. All the ordinary and necessary expenses paid within the year in the maintenance and operation of its business and prop- erties including rentals or other payments required to be made as a condition to the continued use or possession of property. 2. The following losses when actually sustained during the year and not compensated for by insurance or otherwise: a. Losses resulting from fire, storm or other casualty, and from theft of property used in connection with the business or profession of the taxpayer. b. Losses incurred in trade or transmissions entered into for profit, to the extent that a profit therefrom, if realized, would have been taxable, 3. Debts due to the taxpayer arising in the course of business charged off within the year and not theretofore ascertained to be worthless. 4. When duly entered on the books of the corporation, a rea- sonable annual allowance for exhaustion and depreciation by use, wear, tear and obsolescence of property, based upon its cost in cash or the equivalent of cash ; but no deduction shall be made for any amount of expense of restoring property or making good the exhaustion thereof for which an allowance is or has been made; and no deduction shall be allowed for any amount paid out for new buildings, permanent improvements or betterments made to increase the value of any property or estate. 5. Interest paid within the year on its indebtedness to an amount of such indebtedness not exceeding the sum of its paid up capital stock and one-half of its interest bearing indebtedness as both stood at the close of the year, or if no capital stock, the amount of interest paid within the year on an amount of its indebtedness not exceeding the sum of its net worth and one-half of its interest-bearing indebtedness as both stood at the close of the year; provided, that in case of indebtedness wholly secured by collateral the subject of sale in ordinary business of such cor- 220 STATE OF NEW YORK poratioB, the total interest secured and paid by such corporation within the year on any such indebtedness may be deducted as a part of its expense of doing business ; and provided that the above limitation upon the interest deduction shall not apply to so much of the interest paid by any corporation as is shown to be taxable to other persons under the provisions of this act. 6. Taxes paid within the year upon or with respect to incomes bubject to this tax, including federal income taxes thereon when separately stated in the return, and including also license, privi- lege and other taxes upon business or property the income from which is subject to this tax; but not including assessments for local improvements, taxes imposed by article ten of the tax law or other inheritance taxes wherever imposed. 7. Dividends received from stock in any corporation subject to this tax, provided that when only part of the income of the corporation from which such dividend was paid shall have been taxed under this article, only a corresponding part of such dividend shall be deducted. 8. Any income received by a beneficiary which is taxed or taxable to his representative under the provisions of section three hundred and sixty-three of this article. 9. Amounts distributed to patrons in any year, in proportion to their patronage of the same year, by any corporation doing business on a co-operative basis, shall be returned as income by said patrons but may be deducted by such corporation as cost, pur- chase price or refund; provided that no such deduction shall be made for amounts distributed to the stockholders or owners of such corporation in proportion to their stock or ownership, nor for amounts retained by such corporation and subject to distribu- tion according to stock or ownership as distinguished from patron- age. 346. Specific personal deduction. In lieu of all personal or domestic expenditures and losses, persons other than copartner- ships and corporations shall be allowed the following specific de- ductions from net income : 1. To an individual fifteen hundred dollars. 2. To husband and wife living together eighteen hundred dol- lars. 3. For each child under the age of eighteen years one hundred dollars; but the total exemption to husband, wife and children under eighteen years of age residing together as members of a familv shall in no case exceed two thousand dollars. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 221 4. In computing said exemptions and amount of taxes pay- able by persons residing together as members of a family, the income of the wife and the income of each child under eighteen years shall be combined with that of the husband or father, or if he be not living, with that of the head of the family and taxed to him. The tax thereon shall be payable by such husband or head of the family, but if not paid by him may be enforced against any person whose income is included in the assessment. The member of the family who pays the tax shall have a legal right of reimbursement against each other member of the family in the proportion that the net income of such other member bears to the combined net income. The wife may elect to make an independent return of income, in which case she shall be entitled to an exemption of nine hundred dollars, and the husband to an exemption of nine hundred dollars plus an allowance of one hun- dred dollars for each child under eighteen years of age who lives with him ; but the total exemption to husband, wife, and children living together shall in no case exceed two thousand dollars. 5. When part of the net income of any person entitled to a specific deduction is excluded as being derived from sources with- out the state, said deduction shall be proportionately reduced. 347. Income exempt. The following income shall be ex- empt from taxation under this act : 1. Pensions received from the United States. 2. Compensation received for injury or incapacity under any compensation law of this or any other state, or of the United States, 3. Salaries, wages and other compensation received from the United States by officials or employees thereof. 4. Interest upon the obligations of the United States or of its possessions, and upon the obligations of this state or of its polit- ical subdivisions. 5. Income received by the United States, the state, or any political subdivision thereof. 6. Income of any corporation or association organized exclu- sively for the moral or mental improvement of men and women or for religious, Bible, tract, charitable, benevolent, fraternal, missionary, hospital, infirmary, educational, scientific, literary, library, patriotic, historical or cemetery purposes, or for the en- forcement of laws relating to children or animals, or for two or more of such purposes, if such income be used exclusively for 222 STATE OF NEW YORK carrying out one or more of suck purposes. But no such cor- poration or association shall be entitled to any such exemption if any officer, member or employee thereof shall receive or may be lawfully entitled, to receive any pecuniary profit from the opera- tions thereof, except reasonable compensation for services in eifecting one or more of such purposes, or as proper beneficiaries of its strictly charitable purposes; or if the organization thereof for any such avowed purposes be a guise or pretence for directly or indirectly making any other pecuniary profit for such corpora- tion or association or for any of its members or employees, or if it be not in good faith organized or conducted exclusively for one or more of such purposes. 7. Income of any officer of a religious denomination or of trusts received for any of the purposes mentioned in subdivision six preceding, subject to the same condition and exceptions as control the exemptions according to the corporations or associa- tions included in subdivision six preceding, but nothing herein shall be construed to exempt the fees, stipends, personal earnings or other private income of such persons. 8. Income of labor, agricultural and horticultural organiza- tions, business leagues, chambers of commerce or boards of trade and civic leagues or organizations, not organized or conducted for profit and no part of the net income of which inures to the bene- fit of the private stockholder or individual. 9. Interest received during the exemption period of five years specified in chapter four hundred and sixty-five of the laws of nineteen hundred and fifteen, from secured debts which have been recorded and taxed under the provisions of said chapter. 348. Persons not liable to income tax. The following per- sons shall not be liable to the income tax herein provided for : 1. Building and loan associations. 2. Banks whose stockholders are taxable under the provisions of section thirteen of the tax law. 3. Persons liable to the taxes imposed by sections one hundred and eighty-four, one hundred and eighty-five, one hundred and eighty-six, one hundred and eighty-seven, one hundred and eighty-eight, one hundred and eighty-nine and one hundred and ninety-one of the tax law; but nothing herein shall be construed to exempt income received by any such person as trustee or repre- sentative. 349. Income within and without the state. For the pur- pose of determining taxable income, income and deductions shall be divided or allocated in accordance with the following rules : JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 223 1. Income from and deductions allowable with respect to ren- tals, royalties and the operation of any farm, mine or quarry shall follows the situs of the property from which such income was de- rived. 2. In the case of individuals having a permanent office, or a permanent place of business or employment at which their trade, occupation, or profession is exercised, salaries, wages, fees and compensation for personal service shall be allocated to the state in which such office, or place of business of employment is located. In the case of traveling salesmen and persons practicing itinerant trades or occupations and having a permanent office or place of business or employment to which they report or return, such in- come shall be allocated to the state in which such office or place of business is located. In the case of other individuals such income shall follow the residence of the taxpayer. The provisions of this subdivision shall not apply to income received by copartnerships and corporations for personal service rendered to others by their officers and employees. 3. Income from and deductions allowable with respect to stocks and securities, and profit or loss from ownership thereof or dealings therein, shall in the case of copartnerships be allocated to that place of business of the taxpayer at or from which his financial concerns and operations are transacted or directed. In- come from any deductions allowable with respect to securities and profit or loss from ownership thereof, or dealings therein, shall in the case of corporations be allocated to that place of business of the taxpayer at or from which its financial concerns and opera- tions are transacted or directed. Income from and deductions allowable with respect to stocks and profit or loss from ownership thereof, or dealings therein, shall in the case of corporations be allocated to the place where the physical property represented by such stock is located. In the case of other persons such income shall follow the residence of the taxpayer. The word " securities " as used herein shall be deemed to include bonds, debentures, notes, certificates or other evidences of indebtedness or obligation for the payment of money or its equivalent, which obligation by its terms is payable one year or more from its date. 4. Other income and deductions shall be allocated to the state ' where the property is located or the business transacted, from which such income was derived. The tax commission shall pre- scribe for different classes of taxpayers appropriate regulations! for enforcing this rule. Until such regulations are issued and 224 STATE OF NEW YORK in the case of any industry or class of taxpayers for which it may be impracticable to allocate or localize income and the corre- sponding deductions the following process of apportionment shall be applied: There shall first be excluded from the computation the income; and deductions governed by the preceding subdivisions of th'.a section and the property or assets from which such income was derived. Of the remaining net income such a portion shall be taxed as the remaining gross assets employed in any business within the state bear to the remaining gross assets wherever em- ployed in business. 5. Whenever by reason of loss or otherwise the entire net in- come for the year is less than the taxable income only the smaller amount shall be taxed. 350. Rate of taxation. Corporations shall pay annually a tax of three per centum upon and with respect to the entire tax- able income. Persons other than corporations shall pay annually upon and with respect to the entire taxable income, the amounts set forth in the following schedule : When the taxable income exceeds The annual tax shall be $0 but does not exceed $200 $1 00 200 but does not exceed 300 1 50 300 but does not exceed 400 2 00 400 but does not exceed 500 2 50 500 but does not exceed 600 3 00 600 but does not exceed 700 , . 3 50 TOO but does not exceed 800 4 00 800 but does not exceed 900 4 50 900 but does not exceed 1,000 5 00 1,000 but does not exceed 1,100 6 00 1,100 but does not exceed 1,200 7 00 1,200 but does not exceed 1,300 8 00 1,300 but does not exceed 1,400 9 00 1,400 but does not exceed 1,500 10 00 1,500 but does not exceed 1,600 12 00 1,600 but does not exceed 1,700 14 00 1,700 but does not exceed 1,800 16 00 1,800 but does not exceed 1,900 18 00 1,900 but does not exceed 2,000 20 00 f $20 plus two per centum upon and 2,000 -{ with respect to all taxable income in excess of two thousand dollars. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 225 351. Administration and assessment. Except as otherwise provided herein the state tax commission shall administer and en- force the tax herein imposed, for which purpose it may divide the state into districts, in each of which a branch office of the commis- sion may be maintained in charge of an agent. Unless limited by order of the tax commission, each such agent shall have power to receive and audit returns of income and, when so designated by the comptroller, to collect income taxes, and shall perform such other services as are required by the tax commission. 352. When returns to be made. 1. On or before the first day of March, nineteen hundred and seventeen, and annually there- after, every corporation and copartnership subject to this tax and every other person having a taxable income or having gross in- come in excess of fifteen hundred dollars for the income year, shall render to the tax commission a true and accurate report of income for the preceding calendar year. Such returns shall so far as may be set forth the same or similar items called for in the blank forms of return prescribed by the United States com- missioner of internal revenue for the enforcement of the act of congress of October third, nineteen hundred and thirteen, together with such other facts as may be necessary for the proper enforce- ment of this act. There shall be annexed to such return the affi- davit or affirmation of the president, vice-president, secretary, ou treasurer of the corporation, of two members of the copartnership, or of the person making the return, to the effect that the statements contained therein are true. Blank forms of return shall be fur- nished by the tax commission and its agents upon application, but failure to secure the form shall not release any person from the obligation of making the return herein required. 2. Corporations and copartnerships which customarily close their annual accounts on a date other than B'ecember thirty-first, or which customarily estimate their income or profits on a basis other than of actual cash receipts and disbursements, may, with the consent of the tax commission, return for taxation the income earned during the business year for which the accounts of such persons are customarily made up. In the case of persons author- ized to make return on the basis of a fiscal year other than the calendar year, the first return shall cover the income from Jan- uary first, nineteen hundred and sixteen, to the close of his fiscal year ending in nineteen hundred and sixteen; and such income shall be returned and taxes paid upon and with respect thereto, as in the case of other persons. Thereafter each such person shall A. 226 STATE OF NEW YORK make return within sixty days after the closing of his fiscal year, and shall pay the tax to the state comptroller within thirty days after receiving notice of the amount of tax assessed, in accord- ance with regulations to be prescribed by the tax commission. 3. In case of neglect to make return occasioned by sickness or absence of any person required to make said return, or for other sufficient reason, the tax commission may allow such further time for making and delivering said return as it may deem necessary. 353. Consolidated return from certain corporations. In thq case of any corporation which owns all of the stock of another or subsidiary corporation, or more than nine-tenths of such stock, a consolidated return shall be made, including the income, de- ductions and other required data for both parent and subsidiary corporation or corporations, provided that such corporations con- stitute a single business entity or enterprise, and provided further, that in determining net income for their own purposes no recog- nition in the accounts is made of the subsidiary corporations as distinct operating units. In the case of any corporation which distributes or sells its goods or products through another corpo- ration, and such goods or products are sold or transferred to such other corporation at conventional or fictitious prices or on terms other than those which would ordinarily obtain between independ- ent corporations, the tax commission shall require such corpora- tions or either of them to furnish a consolidated return of income, or to make such an accounting as shall accurately show the true net income subject to the tax herein imposed. 354. Powers of tax commission; revision of accounts. 1. If in the opinion of the tax commission any return of income is in any essential respect incorrect it shall have power to revise such return, or if any person liable to taxation under this article fails to make return as herein required, the commission is author- ized to make an estimate of the taxable income of such person from any information in its possession, and to order and state an account according to such revised return or the estimate so made by it for the taxes, penalties and interest due the state from such person. The tax commission shall also have power to examine or cause to have examined, in case of failure to report or in case the return is unsatisfactory to it, the books and rej- ords of any such person, and may hear testimony and take proofs material for its information. In case any return is revised 01 any taxable income estimated, the tax commission shall notify JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 227 the taxpayer of its action and of a time and place at which. oppor- tunity will be given to be heard in respect thereof. Such notice may be mailed to the postoffice address of the taxpayer. The determination of the tax commission shall be subject to review by certiorari in the manner prescribed in sections one hundred and ninety-nine and two hundred of the tax law. Subject to the rights of notice, appeal and hearing herein provided, the tax com- mission may revise returns or make estimates of taxable income and on the basis of such returns or estimates audit and state ac- counts for taxes for a period of three years next preceding that in which such revision or estimate is made. 2. The provisions of section one hundred and ninety-eight of the tax law are hereby made applicable to the revision and readjust- ment of accounts for income taxes; and credits in favor of any taxpayer resulting from such revision may be assigned to any other person subject to the income tax in the same way and with the same effect as though the credit had originally been allowed in favor of such assignee; provided that applications for such revi- sion may be made within three years from the time any such ac- count shall have been audited and stated. 355. Penalties. 1. Any person required by law to make re^ turn of income, who shall fail or refuse to make such return be- fore the time at which accounts for income taxes are required to be certified to the comptroller, shall upon conviction be fined not less than twenty dollars and not more than five hundred dol- lars, at the discretion of the court. 2. If any such person shall fail or refuse to make a return of income at the time or times hereinbefore specified, but shall voluntarily make a correct return of income before the time at which accounts for income taxes are required to be certified to the comptroller, there shall be added to his tax five per centum of the amount otherwise due, but such additional amount shall in no case be less than two dollars nor more than five hundred dollars. 3. If any person liable to taxation under this article fails to make a return as hereinbefore required, or if in any return he wilfully omits or understates any item of income, or wilfully overstates any deduction or loss, or makes any statement with false or fraudulent intent, and an additional amount is discovered to be taxable, the amount so discovered shall be subject to twice the ordinary rate of taxation. The amount so added to the tax shall be collected at such time and in such manner as may be 228 STATE OF NEW YORK designated by the tax commission. This penalty shall be addi- tional to all other penalties in this or any other act provided. 4. Any person required by law to make, render, sign or verify any return, who makes any false or fraudulent return or state- ment, with intent to evade any tax imposed by this act, shall upon conviction be fined not to exceed five hundred dollars or be imprisoned not to exceed one year, or both, at the discretion of the court, with the cost of prosecution. 356. Certification of assessment to comptroller. On or before the first day of September in each year the tax commis- sion shall audit and state the account of each person reporting income for the calendar year, shall compute the tax thereon and forthwith certify the same to the state comptroller for collection. 357. Notice of assessment. Every return of income shall contain the post office address of the taxpayer and lines or spaces upon which the taxpayer shall enter the net income which he believes to be taxable under the provisions of this article and the amount of tax due thereupon or with respect thereto. If such amount is accepted by the tax commission as correct no further notice of assessment need be given, but in case of revision the taxpayer shall be notified and given opportunity to be heard as provided in section three hundred and fifty-four. Such notice may be sent by mail to the post office address given in the re- turn, and a record that such notice has been sent shall be pre- served by the tax commission or its agent. 358. When payable. 1. The tax herein imposed shall be paid to the state comptroller or to the authorized collecting agents of such comptroller, and except as hereinbefore provided for per- sons computing income on a basis other than the calendar year, shall be paid on or before the first day of October of each year. The comptroller is authorized at his discretion and with the con- sent of the tax commission to designate the agents mentioned in section three hundred and fifty-one as collectors for the purpose of collecting income taxes, and may require bond from such officers. The cost of such bond shall be audited and paid as are the other expenses of such agents, but no such agent shall be entitled to any additional salary, fee or compensation for service rendered in the collection of such taxes. 2. If the tax imposed by this article be not paid on or before October first, or in the case of additional taxes, at the time designated by the tax commission, the person liable to such tax- shall pay to the state comptroller in addition to the amount of JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 22*9 such tax ten per centum of said amount, plus one per centum for each month the tax remains unpaid. Each such tax shall be a lien upon and bind all the real and personal property of the person liable to pay the same from the time when it is payable until the same is paid in full. 359. Warrant for the collection of taxes. If the tax im- posed by this article be not paid within thirty days after the same becomes due, unless an appeal or other proceeding shall have been taken to review the same, the comptroller may issue a warrant under his hand and official seal directed to the sheriff of any county of the state commanding him to levy upon and sell the real and personal property of the person owing the same, found within his county, for the payment of the amount thereof, with the added penalties, interest and the cost of executing the warrant, and to return such warrant to the comptroller and pay to him the money collected by virtue thereof by a time to be therein specified, not less than sixty days from the date of the warrant. Such warrant shall be a lien upon and shall bind the real and personal property of the person against whom it is issued from the time an actual levy shall be made by virtue thereof. The sheriff to whom any such warrant shall be directed shall proceed upon the same in all respects, with like effect, and in the same manner as prescribed by law in respect to executions issued against property upon judgments of a court of record, and shall be entitled to the same fees for his services in executing the warrant, to be collected in the same manner. In the discre- tion of the comptroller a warrant of like terms, force and effect may be issued and directed to any agent authorized to collect income taxes, and in the execution thereof such agent shall have all the powers conferred by law upon sheriffs, but shall be entitled to no fee or compensation in excess of actual expenses paid in the performance of such duty. 360. Action for recovery of taxes: Forfeiture of charter by delinquent corporations. Action may be brought at any time by the attorney-general at the instance of the comptroller, in the name of the state, to recover the amount of any taxes, penalties and interest due under this article. If such taxes be not paid within one year after the same be due, and the comptroller is sat- isfied the failure to pay the same is intentional he shall so report to the attorney-general, who shall immediately bring an action in the name of the people of the state, for the forfeiture of the charter or franchise of any corporation, joint stock company or * 230 STATE OF NEW YORK association failing to make such payment, and if it found that such failure was intentional, judgment shall he rendered in each action for the forfeiture of such charter and for its dissolution if a domestic corporation and if a foreign corporation for the an- nulment of its franchise to do business in this state. 361. Distribution of the tax. Of the revenue collected under this article twenty per cent, shall he paid into the state treasury to the credit of the general fund and the residue on or before the first day of February in each year, shall be distributed and paid by the state comptroller to the treasurers of the several counties of the state, in proportion to the aggregate amount of assessment for each county as found by the state board of equaliza- tion in the last preceding state equalization of assessment. As to any county included in the city of New York such payment shall be made to the receiver of taxes in such city and be paid into the general fund for city purposes. The county treasurer shall ap- portion the amount so received among the several towns and cities within the county in proportion to their valuations as equalized by the board of supervisors at its last annual meeting, and shall credit the amount apportioned to each city or town against the county tax payable by it. If in a county not wholly included in a city, the amount of such credit to a city or town exceeds the county tax from such city or town, the excess shall be paid to the supervisor of the town or fiscal officer of the city and be by him credited to general town or city purposes. 362. The tax on salaries paid to non-residents to be with- held by employers. 1. The word " salary " as used in this sec- tion shall be deemed to include salaries, wages, fees, commissions, gratuities, emoluments, perquisites and other compensation of whatever kind and in whatever form paid, received, or earned and subject to taxation under the provisions of this article. 2. Every employer or person (hereinafter called "payor") who shall in the year nineteen hundred and sixteen or in any subsequent year pay or become liable to a non-resident (herein- after called " payee ") for a salary or salaries at a rate exceeding fifteen hundred dollars a year, shall, on behalf of said payee de- duct and withhold from the payment the following sums: One-half of one per centum upon all amounts paid at a ra,te exceeding fifteen hundred dollars but not exceeding twenty-four hundred dollars a year. One per centum upon all amounts paid at a rate exceeding twenty-four hundred dollars, but not exceeding thirty-six hun- dred dollars a year. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 231 Two per centum upon all amounts paid at a rate exceeding thirty-six hundred dollars a year, and upon all salaries the rate of which reckoned on a yearly basis is uncertain or unknown. Said amounts shall be withheld at the first time of payment after the approval of this act upon the salary previously paid in the year nineteen hundred and sixteen, and thereafter shall be withheld upon each payment when it is made. 3. Every payor required by this section to withhold any por- tion of any salary shall, between the first day of March and the first day of April of the next succeeding year, pay to the state comptroller all sums required to be withheld which he has not returned to the payee in accordance with the following subdivi- sion of this section, retaining one per centum thereof for the expense and labor of collection, and shall within the same period make and file with the tax commission or its proper agent a return under oath, in such form as shall be prescribed by said commis- sion, setting forth the name of every payee from whose salary he is required to make such deduction, the receipts of such payees as have filed returns on their own behalf or satisfied the require- ments of the law as hereinafter provided, and such other informa- tion as shall be required by said commission. 4. Any such payee may between the second day of January and the first day of March file with the tax commission or its proper agent a full and complete return of income ; and upon the accept- ance and approval of such return shall be furnished with a state- ment that no tax is due or with a tax bill reciting the amount of income and the tax due thereon, as the case may be. Such tax shall be computed at the rates prescribed in section three hundred and fifty of this article. Immediately thereupon said payee shall be entitled to pay said tax to the state comptroller and receive his receipt therefor. In the payment of such tax, said payee shall be entitled to a deduction for prepayment of two percentum of the amount of tax due. Upon the presentation and surrender of said receipt or statement that no tax is due to said payor, the payee shall be entitled to receive all the sums withheld by said payor on his behalf ; and said statements or receipts shall be filed with the tax commission or its proper agent, as hereinbefore provided. 5. Any non-resident payee subject to state or local income tax at his domicile upon any salary as herein defined, shall upon proof thereof made in the manner and form prescribed by the tax 232 STATE OF NEW YORK commission, be charged for only one-half the tax that would be otherwise due under the provision of this section. 363. Persons acting in a fiduciary capacity. 1. The word " representative " as used in this section shall be deemed to in- clude guardians, trustees, agents, receivers, assignees, executors, administrators, committees and all persons acting in any fiduciary capacity, residing within this state or appointed by a court of this state. The word " beneficiary " as used in this section shall be deemed to include any and all persons whom such representative succeeds or for whom he acts. 2. Every such representative shall make and render to the tax commission a verified return of the income received by him in his representative capacity together with all income, if any, re- ceived during the year by a ward, deceased or incompetent person, and shall be liable to taxation therefor subject to the deductions and exemptions authorized in this article; provided that every executor or administrator shall be allowed the deductions and ex- emptions to which the deceased would have been entitled had he lived, and provided further that in the case of any ward having a parent living the specific personal deduction shall be limited to one hundred dollars, and provided further that no deduction or exemption shall be allowed which has been otherwise claimed by or for any beneficiary. Income received by a trustee shall be taxed or not according as the beneficiary resides within or without the state; but nothing herein shall be construed to exempt from taxation income derived from property located or business trans- acted within the state. 3. The provision of this section shall not apply to trusts whose property is represented by transferable certificates or by capital stock divided into transferable shares, and such trusts shall make return of income and be taxed as corporations. 364. Tax commission authorized to make such regulations and to collect such facts as are necessary to enforce this article. The tax commission is hereby authorized to make such rules and regulations, and to require such facts and information to be re- ported, as are necessary to enforce the provisions of this article. Without limitations of the general powers herein conferred, said commission is specifically authorized at its discretion: A (a) To require every person within the jurisdiction of the state, whether subject to this tax or not, to furnish or return at prescribed intervals, a list of the payments for rent, interest, JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 233 wages and other specified purposes which he has made during such intervals, or copies of receipts for such payments, particu- larly when made to or to the credit of persons subject to this tax; and (b) To require every such person buying or accepting for col- lection or deposit any coupon or interest order to secure from the owner thereof and transmit to the tax commission at prescribed intervals, an ownership certificate stating the name and address of the owner, and such other facts as may be helpful or necessary in determining whether such interest or income is subject to this tax. Information required under the provision of this section may, when authorized by the tax commission and at the option of the respondent, be returned on copies or duplicates of the forms prescribed by the commissioner of internal revenue for the en- forcement of the act of congress of October three, nineteen hun- dred and thirteen. 365. Secrecy required of officials. Penalty for violation. 1. It shall be unlawful for any tax commissioner, agent, clerk or other officer or employee to divulge or make known in any manner whatever not provided by law the amount or source of in- come, profits, losses, expenditures, or any particular thereof, set forth or disclosed in any return of income, or to permit any such returns or copy thereof or any book containing any abstract or particulars thereof to be seen or examined by any person except as provided by law. Nothing herein shall be construed to pro- hibit the publication of general statistics so classified as to pre- vent the identification of particular returns and the items thereof, or the publication of delinquent lists showing the names of tax- payers who have failed to pay their taxes at the time and in the manner provided by section three hundred and fifty-eight to- gether with any relevant information which in the opinion of the comptroller may assist in the collection of such delinquent taxes; or the inspection by the attorney-general or other legal represen- tative of the state of the income return of any taxpayer who shall bring action to set aside or review the tax based thereon, or against whom action or proceedings have been instituted in ac- cordance with the provisions of section three hundred and fifty- five or three hundred and sixty of this article. 2. Any offense against the foregoing provision shall be pun- ished by a fine not exceeding one thousand dollars or by im- prisonment not exceeding one year, or both, at the discretion of the court; and if the offender be an officer or employee of the 234 STATE OF NEW YOEK state lie shall be dismissed from office and be incapable of holding any public office in this state for a period of five years thereafter. 366. Persons liable to income tax exempt from personal property tax and from, the provisions of sections twelve, one hun- dred and eighty-two and one hundred and ninety-two of the tax law. After the first day of January, nineteen hundred and seven- teen, persons liable to the income tax shall not be assessed for taxation on personal property as defined in article one of the tax law, but bank stock and rents taxable as personal property under the provisions of section eight of the tax law, shall be assessed and taxed as heretofore. After the fifteenth day of January, nineteen hundred and seventeen, corporations liable to the income tax shall not be assessed or taxed upon their corporate stock as provided in section twelve, nor shall they be required to pay th< franchise tax imposed by section one hundred and eighty-two, n( to make the report called for in section one hundred and ninety- two of the tax law. For the purpose of this section every person shall be deemed to be liable to the income tax who is not specifi- cally excepted from such liability by the provisions of section three hundred and forty-eight. Nothing herein shall be con- strued to impair the obligation to pay franchise taxes due on or before the fifteenth day of January, nineteen hundred and seven- teen, or taxes on personal property or corporate stock assessed in the year nineteen hundred and sixteen, whether payable in that year or not. 2. Invalidity of part of this act not to affect the remainder. If any clause, sentence, paragraph or part of this act shall for any reason be adjudged by any court of competent jurisdiction to be invalid, such judgment shall .not affect, impair, or invalidate the remainder of said act, but shall be confined in its operation to the clause, sentence, paragraph, or part thereof directly involved in the controversy in which such judgment .shall have been ren- dered. 3. Except as otherwise provided herein this act shall take effect immediately. APPENDICES [235] APPENDIX All REVENUE RECEIPTS OF STATES, COUNTIES AND INCORPORATED PLACES (INCLUDING TOTAL REVENUE RECEIPTS, GENERAL PROP- ERTY TAXES AND SPECIAL PROPERTY TAXES, BUT NOT THIR- TEEN OTHER CLASSES OF REVENUE RECEIPTS LISTED BY CENSUS) * STATES Population Total Per capita General property taxes Special property taxes Total 97,163,330 $1,845,901,128 $19 00 $1,082,971,468 $83,960,118 States 96 815 253 $367 585 331 $3 80 $139 750 303 $67 675 933 Counties Incorporated places . . 85,738,717 45,682,236 370,043,046 1,108,272,751 4 32 24 26 282,077,069 661,144,096 805,419 15,478,766 Alabama 2,238,614 $16,675,494 $7 45 $9,410,110 $142,940 State 2 238 614 $5 966 208 $2 67 $3 500 148 $96 472 Counties 2,238,614 5,175,597 2 31 4 , 203 , 525 46 468 Incorporated places 410,707 5,533,689 13 53 1,706,437 Arizona 230,808 6,294,701 27 27 4,561,146 173 State 230,808 $1,539,147 $6 67 $1,252,573 $173 Counties Incorporated places 230,808 70,021 3,398,239 1,357,315 14 72 19 38 2,741,182 567,391 Arkansas 1,659,859 10,579,487 6 37 7,306,567 221,115 State 1,659,859 $3,454,081 $2 08 $2,737,926 $221 115 Counties 1 , 659 , 859 4,037,669 2 43 3 , 293 , 668 Incorporated places 217,381 3,087,737 14 20 1,274,973 California 2,667,516 123,195,750 46 18 69,433,033 3 273 158 State 2,667,516 $19,775,003 $7 41 $1,361,887 $3 237 158 Counties .... 2,226,521 42,997,382 19 31 34,825,081 Incorporated places 1,689,400 60,423,365 35 77 33,246,065 Colorado 883,276 19,161,098 21 69 12,950,354 280 701 State 883,276 $2,727,954 $3 09 $1,578,697 $280 701 Counties 645,391 5,900,076 9 14 5,081,575 Incorporated places 442,586 10,533,068 23 80 6,290,082 Connecticut 1,181,793 25,545,578 21 62 13,531,984 5,072,233 State 1,181,793 $5,497,195 $4 65 $4 256 021 Counties 1,181,793 673,305 57 $261,368 Incorporated places Delaware . . ... 1,058,117 208,036 19,375,078 2,790,438 18 31 13 41 13,270,616 1,494,235 816,212 27 494 State 208,036 $713,348 $3 43 $26,662 Counties . . . 208,036 735,223 3 53 $620,250 Incorporated places District of Columbia 100,627 348,077 1,341,867 14,438,046 13 34 41 48 873,985 5,557,090 832 Incorporated places 348,077 $14,438,046 $41 48 $5,557,090 Florida 825,420 12,101,112 14 66 7,360,475 $31,681 State 825,420 $2,980,334 $3 61 $1,478,479 $2 295 Counties 810,899 5,071,256 6 26 3,916,582 29,386 Incorporated places 236,640 4,049,522 17 11 1,965,414 Georgia 2,736,737 26,293,393 9 61 16,269,128 State 2,736,737 $5,778,440 $2 11 $4,037,908 Counties 2,736,737 9,956,971 3 64 7,109,105 Incorporated places 573,057 10,557,982 18 42 5,122,115 Idaho 378,818 6,734,155 17 78 4,207,142 $97,887 State 378,818 $1,936,279 $5 11 $1,004,830 Counties 378,818 3,012,221 7 95 2,363 656 Incorporated places 81,718 1,785,655 21 85 838,656 237] * 238 STATE OF NEW YORK APPENDIX All Continued STATES Population Total Per ca-pita General property taxes Special property taxes Illinois 5,904,043 $118,579,747 $20 08 $67 821,281 $1 612 818 State Counties 5,904,043 5,904 043 $14,025,769 15 873 765 $2 38 2 69 $8,091,832 12 374 734 $1,612,818 Incorporated places 3,710,769 88,680,213 23 90 47,354,715 2 760 792 43 767 765 15 85 27 906 304 170 585 State 2 760 792 $8 425 385 $3 05 $6 182 813 $170 585 Counties 2 , 760 , 792 11,652,870 4 22 8,698,167 Incorporated places 1,214 030 23,689 510 19 51 13 025 324 2,222,472 36,428,647 16 39 24,233 876 280,733 State 2,222,472 $6,098,459 $2 74 $3,658,488 $280,733 2 222 472 16 564 437 7 45 11 403 433 Incorporated places 711,662 13,765,751 19 34 9,171,955 Kansas 1,762,573 24,164,614 13 71 16,395,281 170,234 State 1,762,573 $5,379,229 $3 05 $3,310,048 $170,234 Counties 1,685,621 7,432,155 4 41 6,525,401 522 478 11 353 230 21 73 6 559 832 2 336 277 26 722 060 11 44 15 733 715 461,956 State 2 336 277 $7 688 194 $3 29 $4 318 990 $461,956 Counties 2,336,277 8,607,899 3 68 5 , 246 , 650 Incorporated places 574,890 10 425 967 18 14 6 168 075 1,745,658 22,739,066 13 03 14,515,346 207,004 State 1,745,658 $7,096,702 $4 07 $4,386,920 $207 , 004 1 389 700 6 013 822 4 33 4 187 527 523 214 9 628 542 18 40 5 940 899 Maine 757,936 12,966,150 17 11 7,366,586 275,318 State 757,936 $5,063,526 $6 68 $2,498,591 $275,318 757 936 879 012 1 16 674 172 389 364 7 023 61? 18 04 4 193 823 Maryland 1,330,209 26,029,645 19 57 15,156,991 725,166 State 1,330,209 $5,294, >f6 $3 98 $2,129,364 $525,426 Counties 755 , 634 5,700,921 7 54 4 , 156 , 772 31,023 Incorporated places 677,147 3 548 705 15,034,448 124 350 892 22 20 35 04 8,870,855 69 173,958 168,717 12,278,551 State 3,548 705 $25 742 902 $7 25 $6 252,161 $5,056,514 2 761 574 3 435 938 1 24 2 727 983 Incorporated places Michigan 3,294,319 2,936,618 95,172,052 52 979 446 28 89 18 04 60,193,814 36,461,096 7,222,037 889,621 State 2,936,618 $12,806,666 $4 36 $10,875,862 $628,831 2 936 618 8 642 466 2 94 6,045,366 253,527 Incorporated places Minnesota 1,431,059 2,181,077 31,530,314 44,089,229 22 03 20 21 19,539,868 23,221,369 7,263 1,080,115 State 2 181 077 $14 033 962 $6 43 $4 201 828 $714,905 Counties Incorporated places Mississippi 2,181,077 914,301 1 876 987 8,245,936 21,809,331 14 612 702 3 78 23 85 7 79 5,843,122 13,176,419 8,383,108 241,788 123,422 44,907 State 1,876 987 $3 694 027 $1 97 $2,325,705 $44,907 1 876 987 7 719 846 4 11 4 308 549 217 561 3 198 829 14 70 1*748' 854 Missouri 3,353,983 58 555,630 17 46 30,825,369 1,141,124 State 3 353 983 $8 243 849 $2 46 $3 , 222 , 363 $479,517 Counties 2,630,636 11,051 008 4 20 7,830,979 Incorporated places 1,465,008 39,260,773 26 80 19,772,027 661,607 JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 239 APPENDIX All Continued STATES Population Total Per capita General property taxes Special property taxes 419,174 $12 803 151 $30 54 $7 864 865 $25 004 State 419,174 $2,642,075 $6 30 $905 746 $20 036 419,174 6 259 720 14 93 5 258 998 4 968 Incorporated places 141,253 3,901,356 27 62 1,700,121 1,233,122 17 998 117 14 60 12 194 263 137 131 State 1,233,122 $3,761,392 $3 05 $2 187 597 $71 872 1,233,122 6 597 146 5 35 5 757 843 65 259 Incorporated places 321,770 7 , 639 , 579 23 74 4,248,823 Nevada . ... 94 722 2 967,919 31 33 2 118 933 * State 94 , 722 $970,540 1 $10 25 $601 948 Counties 94 , 722 1,692,809 17 87 1,331,012 Incorporated places 15,434 304 , 570 19 73 185,973 436 740 7 054 912 16 15 4 655 153 $483 344 State 436 740 $1 793 881 $4 11 $1 178 347 $220 601 Counties 436,740 756,701 1 75 552 , 535 Incorporated places 262,907 2 749 486 4,504,330 68 684 931 17 13 24 98 2,924,271 39 613 391 262,743 758 599 State 2 749 486 $15 425 547 $5 61 $9 877 039 $748 086 Counties Incorporated places New Mexico .... 2,749,486 2,056,856 370 185 11,653,749 41,605,635 3,104,833 4 24 20 23 8 39 9,108,329 20,628,023 2,232,145 10,513 32 503 State.. 370,185 370 185 $797,423 1 765,421 $2 15 4 77 $529 , 143 1 408 799 $28,078 4 425 Incorporated places 48,124 541,989 11 26 294,203 New York 9 712 954 330 622 071 34 04 201 342 295 28 399 306 State 9 712 954 $52 013,706 $5 36 $6,187,819 $22 183 580 Counties . , 4,514,066 17,721,855 3 93 12,694,846 Incorporated places North Carolina 7,755,439 2,307,809 260,886,510 14,212,398 33 65 6 16 182,459,630 9,386,831 6,215,726 5,265 State 2 307 809 $3 294 223 $1 43 $1 969 056 $5 265 Counties 2,307,809 6,445,604 2 79 5,011,003 339 758 4 472,571 13 16 2,406,772 North Dakota 660 , 849 10,024,589 15 17 6,317,386 State 660 , 849 $3,251,350 $4 92 $1,240,338 Counties 660 849 5,010,319 7 58 4,122,970 66 620 1 762 920 26 46 954,078 Ohio 4 965 169 95 , 669 , 743 19 27 51,473,265 $1,922,998 State 4,965,169 $13,877,036 $2 79 $2,916,282 $1,895,094 4 965 169 28,812,212 4 80 15,646,094 27,904 2 864 526 57 980 495 20 24 32,910,889 1 938 761 18,391,968 9 49 12,252,427 5,572 State 1,938,761 $3,358,843 $1 73 $2,206,205 $5,572 1 938 761 6 920,032 3 57 5,429,713 366 947 8 113 093 22 11 4 616 509 Oregon 756,988 24,613,582 32 52 15,420,281 262,138 State 756,988 $3,847,371 $5 08 $2,541,696 $262,138 756 988 7 970,054 10 53 7,377,705 Incorporated places 350,709 12,796,157 36 49 5,500,880 Pennsylvania 8,107,942 137,280,510 16 93 70,197,242 18,876,538 State 8,107,942 $28,571,882 $3 52 $1,256,609 $18,876,538 6 475 986 17,640,063 2 72 12,552 663 Incornorated daces 4.878.522 81.068.565 18 67 56.387.970 240 STATE OF NEW YORK APPENDIX All Concluded STATES Population Total Per capita General property taxes Special property taxes Rhode Island 579,665 $13,627,651 $23 51 $8,065,197 $535,032 State 579 , 665 $3 018 385 $5 21 $843 319 $534 825 Counties Incorporated places South Carolina 557,768 1,572,285 10,609,266 9,295 371 19 02 5 91 7,221,878 6 154 648 207 122 575 State.. 1,572,285 1,572 285 $2,375,236 3 515 661 $1 51 2 24 $1,654,659 2 766 600 $122,575 Incorporated places South Dakota 237,836 643,121 3,404,474 9,782,158 14 31 15 21 1,733,389 6,016,784 9,781 State 643,121 $3 151 538 $4 90 $1 547 545 $9 781 643 121 4 600 068 7 15 3 128 460 Incorporated places 80 , 789 2 030 552 25 14 1 340 779 2 238 128 22 191 231 9 92 12 794 563 91 268 State.. 2,238,128 2 238 128 $4,639,769 9 210 586 $2 07 4 12 $1,733,782 6 888 484 $91,268 Incorporated places 467 , 588 8 340 876 17 84 4,172,297 Texas 4,171,997 44,015,367 10 55 28,780,156 541,971 State 4,171,997 $12,598,297 $3 02 $6,328,327 $541,971 4,171 997 13 100 016 3 14 11 063 779 Incorporated places 1,032,272 18,317 054 17 74 11,388,050 Utah 404 , 735 9,551,375 23 60 5,802,191 317,271 State 404,735 $2,715,919 $6 71 $1,883,377 $317,271 404 , 735 2 307 108 5 70 1 849 235 Incorporated places 189,769 4,528,348 23 86 2 069,579 Vermont 359,957 4,408,670 12 25 1,922,661 746,547 State.. 359,957 359 957 $1,952,770 30 359 $5 43 08 $184,319 25 623 $746,547 Incorporated places 171,510 2,425,541 14 14 1,712 719 2,129,003 20,734,314 9 74 11,175 929 412,588 State 2,129,003 $7 , 176 , 220 $3 37 $2 , 539 , 343 $412,588 1,674 340 3 557 591 2 12 3 013 324 Incorporated places 511,324 10,000,503 19 56 5,623,262 1 344 686 44 984 021 33 45 23 701 723 186 231 State 1 , 344 , 686 $7,174,313 $5 34 $3,333,336 $186,231 1,344 686 13,152 882 9 78 11 833 558 Incorporated places 726,144 24,656,826 33 96 3 , 534 , 829 1 306 345 10 609 218 8 12 6 314 812 587 735 State 1,306,345 $2,772,722 $2 12 $304 , 756 $587,735 1,306,345 3 975 059 3 04 3 697 582 Incorporated places 252,095 3,861,437 15 32 2,312,474 2,419,898 40,352,935 16 68 25 , 857 , 592 1,003,771 State 2,419,898 $11,380,681 $4 70 $6,818,729 $924,736 2,419,898 8,319,451 3 44 6 006 871 79,035 1 066 688 20 652 803 19 36 13 031 992 Wyoming 163,325 3,125,248 19 15 2,041,191 11,436 State 163 325 $1 063 277 $6 51 $573 573 $316 Counties 163,325 1,250,566 7 66 1,112,196 11,120 45 455 811 405 17 85 , ; * . 355 422 ' * f >' fr 0. ' * Abstract of Special Bulletins, Wealth, Debt and Taxation, 1913, pp. 36-42. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 241 APPENDIX A I 2 ASSESSED VALUE OF ALL PROPERTY, REAL AND PERSONAL, SUBJECT TO AD VALOREM TAXATION IN STATES, 1912.* GEOGRAPHIC DIVISION AND STATE ASSESSED VALUATION OF ALL PROPERTY SUBJECT TO AD VALOREM TAXATION Total Real property and improvements Personal property Other property Total $69,452,936,104 $51,854,009,436 $12,135,880,928 $5,241,114,687 New England Maine $416,891,264 439,683,132 221,530,142 - 4,803,078,625 619,010,208 1,041,334,019 11,131,778,917 2,490,490,534 5,068,802,988 6,481,059,158 1,898,307,218 2,343,673,232 2,317,561,634 2,466,636,793 1,474,585,315 992,092,597 1,860,087,956 293,048,119 354,278,413 463,371,889 2,746,900,291 93,814,011 1,235,457,607 359,932,253 864,962,621 1,168,012,658 747,500,632 291,531,003 842,358,342 212,887,518 1,031,174,033 625,686,792 566,807,488 411,551,004 427,473,108 550,517,808 1,193,655,846 2,532,710,050 346,550,585 167,512,157 180,750,630 422,330,199 72,457,454 140,338,191 200,299,207 101,087,082 1,005,086,251 905,011,679 2,921,277,451 $329,614,002 299 , 333 , 340 157,967,927 3,216,714,460 426,968,806 880,054,721 10,684,290,188 1,880,407,662 4,821,764,111 4,335,665,521 1,221,410,854 1,648,500,546 1,649,105,370 1,723,425,870 1,154,269,735 547,544,903 1,187,413,981 199,070,599 264,163,184 319,049,627 1,798,339,960 89,541,628 1,151,374,665 330,322,487 538,924,546 633,747,633 382,775,963 152,052,298 431,329,671 140,200,555 636,774,911 447,552,416 342,648,441 240,104,986 298,828,900 368,449,430 719,703,439 1,650,198,381 179,892,897 132,531,537 81,270,500 280,766,698 34,682,427 84,328,045 109,625,848 83,667,525 729,751,400 674,866,639 2,163,020,203 $87,277,262 80,314,189 63,562,215 1,032,985,395 192,041,402 161,279,298 447,488,729 291,003,421 247,038,877 2,145,393,637 676,896,364 473,402,700 429,589,039 356,629,923 320,315,580 282,536,401 481,443,865 93,977,520 55,917,277 88,937,396 517,350,932 4,272,383 New Hampshire $60,035,603 Massachusetts Rhode Island Connecticut 553,378,770 Middle Atlantic New York "97!i48!398 New Jersey East North Central Ohio Indiana "22i;769;986 238,867,225 386,581,000 ' 72!6iii293 191,230,110 'si,' i97] 952 55,384,866 431,209,399 ""84;682;942 "isi 1689; 857 295,028,419 121,098,098 43,359,299 138,021,114 34,279,204 189,130,112 99,675,906 "'66,'i6i!652 Illinois Wisconsin West North Central Minnesota Missouri North Dakota South Dakota Nebraska South Atlantic District of Columbia . . 29,609,766 194,948,218 239,236,606 243,626,571 96,119,406 273,007,557 38,407,759 205,269,010 78,458,470 224,159,047 111,344,966 128,644,208 119,595,699 214,142,358 527,552,200 98,176,389 West Virginia North Carolina South Carolina Georgia Florida East South Central Kentucky Tennessee Mississippi West South Central 62,472,679 259,810,049 354,959,469 68,481,299 34,980,620 51,513,534 61,011,609 20,771,379 31,938,240 43,470,332 Texas Mountain Montana Idaho Wyoming Colorado 47,966,596 80,551,892 17,003,648 24,071,906 47,203,027 17,419,557 117,949,520 118,228,542 313,534,205 New Mexico Arizona Utah Pacific Washington 157,385,331 111,916,498 444,723,043 Oregon California.. * Abstract of Special Bulletins, Wealth, Debt and Taxation, 1913, page 16. 242 STATE OF NEW YORK 05 I 1:0 p. hH M I I II 8538 ' rH t-COCD rHOSCO rH :8 2 :; COCOON! t^t-iOCO OS N 00 CO CO CO 1C rH CO t^ 00 CO t^ (N O CO CO os co o T< co co a> rHCO r}N O(N -b- -CO 18 aSS IM O5 1 ic >c (N <N t^o i >OT}<COb- COCO< I OOSt- COCO- ,t^rH rHrHt^< >ICOOCOCOO< * (N d Tf( Tji rH COOOCO 1C 00 CO (N <N C W 00 rH O *< t^ O CO rHOOCOOt-O 1C CO CO t^ Oi O5 OS i -t- co^* t^ -CO rH i-HOO CO" OSO*rH OO OS <N (N rH T}< CO o t^- o T-H o r* co CO O 00 CO CO "5 CO I OOCO iCCOOO>fl CO CO OS t^ CO I C 00 ^ *< CO C CO rHOCO O5 CO<N<N< CO<NCO rHrHCO r IN C t^* 00 f* CO C^ O OS t>- CO O5 C N 00 !> rH CO OS O O5 O *O rH <COOOCO rH N-COCOI>1> t^OSOiCOSO^O OS'tCOOS'* O CO OS t^ i-< 00 OS COCOOOOSOO rH 1C Tj< 00 1^ t^ OO COlCTt<t~CO 00 CO 1C rH O OS t- nd re ts d I5:::ri] eS ' :-S- : Ijltiatijiii-iiUfiJj i ^^^ rth nes h D h D ask H Z d ,2 W o ig ^PH^ g> ^5 ; ia.S.2 Illllll IIII Ullll !l!ll!l I !,-. f . ! W JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 243 6* m co o m <N I-H & S- O i-l CO <N CO i-H i-l t- 00 O 00 I-H O S S So oo co H .-i COW (NCOCOCiCi 1-1 t>. 1C O 1-- i-l * ICO Ol>COCOb. - 00O 1C . S J K%%< ooo c> 10 oc>e<i t^OO -COCO i-l 00 O CO lO T}< C O N -COO C CD CO * (N CO (N t- ,-I -i-tt^ CO ij< TjH CO CO *n O l t^C II <COI> O O O <f> t~ -H O5 OS )i-ieo oo * ic oo 1-1 o oo ^< >OOO O 00 * TJ< <D CO l> O ^ T C 1-1 DTf I'tTjHO'* 5(NOOCO(N 500Oi-HCO 1000 oo <N O5 t> gf-H < coi >t-O( CO CO CO i-l O C<I Tt< 1 <Jt CO N r-l O i-l i-l rH iM CO CO t~ O CO C 00 b I-H CO Oi CO lO i-l Ol OO W O t- Oi "5 O H rH O> * t^ CO C H tH iC T}< t CO CO CO n'eo'iccooorco'oo'oo' CO i-l t>. i-H co.1 ! ! tvT^oTor ^ N O -i CO t~ 00 iO 1-1 co <N in c<i i> CO C C< irfiCOi-H-i >OcOOS ' t>O5OO5 COOOi-H lOSOSOO-^ OOOCO S fe-2.2'S^ja ja'B'S <l|ll|sl8l .uQSQ^^^ccOfe ' a; 03 1^ r/i r* i .sljlFJ^l 111 -* 244 STATE OF NEW YOKK APPENDIX A II 1 TABLE SHOWING THE ASSESSED VALUATION OF KEAL AND PER- SONAL PROPERTY AND THE AGGREGATE STATE AND LOCAL TAXES FROM 1840 TO 1914, INCLUSIVE * YEAR Real Personal including bank stock Aggregate taxes levied 1840 $517,723,170 $121 447 830 $3 088 408 22 1841 531 987 886 123 311 644 3 173 355 97 1842 504,254,029 116 595 233 4 246 487 78 1843 476,999,430 118,602,064 3 965 180 14 1844 480,027,609 119 612 343 4 243 101 81 1845 486,490,121 117 988 895 4 170 527 95 1846 496,483,411 119,880 236 4 647 461 88 1847 509,496,855 121,162,201 4 843 575 60 1848 526,624,853 125,663 318 5 295 458 23 1849 536,162,901 129 926 625 5 548 981 28 1850 571,690,807 153,183,486 6 312 787 33 1851 888,237,812 196,538,263 6 759 438 26 1852 946,467,907 221,802,950 7 007 688 08 1853 ,015,762,791 249 720 727 9 326 763 97 1854 ,091,514,033 272,638,110 9 638 279 63 1855 ,107,272,715 294 012 564 11 678 015 69 1856 ,112,133,136 316,506,930 12 743 179 73 1857 ,111,551,629 319,897 155 15 166 309 62 1858 ,095,403,134 307,049,165 15 426 593 20 1859 ,098,666,251 315,108,117 16 353 301 38 I860 ,119,933,484 320,617,352 18,956 024 50 1861 ,121,134,480 313,802,682 20 402 276 51 1862 ,113,779,352 314,111,034 19,456 288 40 1863 ,161,750,000 339 , 249 , 877 23 046 800 66 1864 ,158,327,371 392,552,314 39,873,945 56 1865 ,196,403,416 334,826,220 45 961 440 62 1866 ,237,703,092 426,404,633 40,568,244 69 1867 ,327,403,886 438,685,254 46 518 921 62 1868 ,418,132,855 441,987,915 44,298,435 90 1869 ,532,720,907 434,280,278 46 161 531 50 1870 ,599,930,166 452,607,732 50,328,684 21 1871 ,641,379,410 447,248,035 45,674 486 92 1872 1,692,523,071 437,102,215 63 511 936 12 1873 1,750,698,918 418,608,955 51,444 536 27 1874 1,960,352,703 407,427,399 57 811 381 92 1875 2,108,325,872 357,941,401 56,926 470 69 1876 2,376,252,178 379,488,140 52 148 368 37 1877 2,373,408,540 364,960,110 50,237,164 06 1878 2,333,669,813 352,469,320 48 047 241 97 1879 2,315,400,526 322,468,712 47 148 475 04 1880 2,340,335,690 340,921,916 49,117,782 18 1881 2,432,661,378 351,021,189 49,286,772 55 1882 2,557,218,240 315,039,085 47,573 820 07 1883 2,669,173,011 345,418,361 50,936,788 95 1884 2,762,348,218 332,383,239 52,372,707 00 1885 2,899,899,062 324,783,281 57,265,650 02 1886 3,035,229,788 335,898,389 58,110,078 96 1887 3,122,588,084 346,611,861 57,331,191 58 1888 3,213,171,201 354,258,556 60,639,806 72 1889 3,298,323,931 385,329,131 60,183,803 78 1890 3,397,234,679 382,159,067 60,624,473 09 1891 3,526,645,815 405,095,684 60,417,409 52 1892 3,626,645,093 491,675,158 63,795,261 80 1893 3,761,679,384 540,708,935 67,274,029 22 1894 3,841,582,748 562,193,379 66,977,889 35 1895 3,908,853,377 541,621,122 72,400,944 11 1896 4,041,826,586 544,311,557 79,193,647 07 1897 4,349,801,526 649,364,694 80,645,206 34 1898 4,413,848,496 758,581,839 63,950,072 98 1899 4,811,593,039 742,959,229 102,940,006 33 1900 5,093,025,771 672,715,703 100,099,372 77 1901 5,169,308,069 960,152,352 105,656,212 21 1902 5,297,754,482 926,871,017 104,107,361 08 1903 6,749,509,958 1,152,169,443 94,989,856 45 1904 7,051,455,025 1,104,370,798 103,676,463 63 1905 7,312,621,452 1,172,456,705 106,441,726 08 1906 7,933,057,917 1,069,967,682 111,340,919 44 * Report of the N. Y. State Board^of Tax Commissioners, 1914, pp. 53-54. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 245 APPENDIX A II 2 TABLE SHOWING AMOUNT OF MONEY RECEIVED DIRECTLY AND INDIRECTLY FOR STATE PURPOSES * YEAR Direct State tax levied for State purposes Receipts from indirect sources for State purposes 1867 . . $12 647,218 71 1868 10,243,317 01 1869 10,463,179 33 1870. . 14,285,976 55 1871 11 613 943 51 1872 19,850,882 30 1873 . . . 14,800,903 38 1874 15,727,482 08 1875 14,206,680 61 1876 8,529,174 32 1877 8,726,511 01 1878. 7,941,297 94 1879. . . 7,690,416 34 1880 9,232,543 33 1881 6,032,826 31 1882 6,820,023 29 1883 9,334,886 31 1884 7,762,572 78 1885. . 9,160,405 11 1886 . . . 9,512,812 91 1887 9,075,046 81 1888 9,089,303 85 1889 12,557,352 74 1890. . . 8,619,748 17 $3,237,575 31 1891 . . 5,196,666 40 5,593,968 69 1892. 7,784,848 16 4,797,209 73 1893. .. 10,418,192 08 5,887,706 55 1894 9,600,231 79 4,817,250 80 1895 13,906,346 22 5,411,654 50 1896. . 11,751,837 71 9,262,884 89 1897.. 12,033,651 80 9,204,395 44 1898 10,189,110 93 9,749,688 52 1899. . 12,640,228 09 10,463,265 71 1900. . . 10,704,153 39 13,226,849 80 1901 6,824,306 01 15,611,498 62 1902 748,072 05 16,051,353 90 1903 761,085 02 22,341,802 97 1904 968,041 89 23,473,046 23 1905 1,191,677 51 23,869,423 44 1906. . . 32,077,393 48 1907 34,474,999 76 1908 33,253,796 17 1909 30,828,532 08 1910 37,130,151 19 1911 6,072,766 48 35,400,611 10 1912... 11,022,986 91 43,707,582 95 1913 6,460,093 12 43,971,846 54 1914 42,588,417 81 * Report of the State Board of Tax Commissioners 1914 (N. Y.) p. 54 246 STATE OF NEW YORK APPENDIX A II 3 RATIO OF PERCENTAGES USED IN STATE EQUALIZATION TABLES EROM 1896 TO 1915 * COUNTIES Ratio? of per- cent- age, 1896 Ratio of per- cent- age, 1897 Ratio of per- cent- age, 1898 Ratio of per- cent- Ratio of per- cent- Ratio of per- cent- age, 1901 Ratio of per- cent- age, 1902 Ratio of per- cent- age, 1903 Ratio of per- cent- age, 1904 Ratio of per- cent- age, 1905 .75 .70 .75 .70 .78 .73 .78 .73 .78 .73 .78 .73 .80 .75 .80 .75 .80 .75 .81 .75 Allegany Broome .73 .70 .69 .68 .68 .73 .66 .67 .55 .60 .71 .70 .78 .70 .60 .60 .72 .92 .58 .80 .68 .60 .70 .67 .70 .70 .73 .73 .69 .69 .69 .73 .60 .72 .55 .70 .71 .70 .82 .70 .60 .63 .72 .92 .58 .83 .68 .60 .70 .67 .70 .70 .73 .80 .74 .90 .70 .73 .60 .78 .80 .76 .72 .70 .83 .75 .73 .71 .73 .92 .93 .83 .68 .80 .70 .70 .80 .70 .74 .78 .74 .90 .70 .73 .55 .78 .82 .75 .71 .69 .81 .74 .73 .71 .72 .90 .91 .83 .68 .79 .70 .68 .80 .72 .65 .64 .81 .81 .85 .75 .67 .77 .73 .73 .77 .80 .78 .63 .81 .85 .70 .70 .80 .72 .76 .80 .82 .74 .75 .77 .75 .80 .75 .69 .90 .72 .80 .74 .78 .74 .90 .70 .73 .52 .78 .82 .75 .71 .68 .81 .74 .73 .71 .72 .90 .91 .83 .68 .79 .70 .68 .80 .72 .65 .67 .81 .81 .85 .75 .67 .77 .73 .73 .77 .80 .78 .66 .81 .85 .70 .70 .80 .72 .76 .80 .82 .74 .75 .77 .75 .80 .75 .69 .90 .72 .73 .74 .78 .74 .90 .70 .73 .50 .78 .82 .75 .71 .68 .81 .74 .73 .71 .72 .90 .91 .83 .68 .79 .70 .68 .80 .72 .65 .67 .81 .82 .85 .75 .67 .77 .73 .73 .77 .80 .78 .67 .81 .85 .69 .70 .80 .72 .76 .80 .82 .74 .75 .77 .75 .80 .75 .69 .90 .72 .73 .74 .78 .74 .90 .70 .73 .50 .78 .82 .75 .72 .67 .81 .74 .73 .71 .72 .88 .91 .83 .68 .79 .72 .68 .80 .72 .65 .67 .81 .82 .85 .75 .67 .77 .73 .73 .77 .80 .78 .70 .81 .85 .69 .70 .80 .72 .76 .80 .82 .74 .77 .78 .75 .80 .75 .69 .90 .74 .73 .74 .78 .74 .90 .70 .73 .50 .78 .82 .74 .72 .67 .79 .74 .70 .71 .72 .83 .90 .83 .68 .79 .72 .68 .80 .71 .62 .67 .81 .80 .84 .75 .68 .77 .73 .73 .77 .81 .78 .75 .80 .85 .68 .70 .78 .72 .76 .80 .80 .74 .77 .78 .75 .80 .75 .69 .90 .74 .73 .74 .78 .74 .90 .70 .73 .50 .78 .82 .74 .72 .69 .79 .74 .70 .71 .72 .83 .90 .84 .89 .79 .72 .68 .79 .71 .62 .89 .81 .80 .83 .75 .70 .77 .73 .73 .77 .89 .78 .90 .80 .85 .68 .70 .78 .72 .76 .80 .80 .74 .77 .78 .75 .82 .75 .69 .90 .74 .73 .74 .78 .74 .90 .70 .73 .50 .78 .82 .74 .73 .70 .79 .74 .70 .71 .72 .81 .90 .84 .89 .77 .74 .68 .79 .71 .52 .89 .81 .79 .85 .76 .70 .77 .71 .73 .77 .89 .79 .90 .79 .85 .68 .70 .78 .72 .76 .80 .80 .69 .77 .78 .75 .80 .75 .69 .90 .74 .73 Cattaraugus Cayuga Chautauqua Chemung Chenango Columbia Cortland Delaware Dutchess Erie Essex . . Fulton Greene Herkinaer Kings Livingston Madison Monroe Montgomery New York .63 .75 .60 .85 .78 .62 .78 .71 .59 .72 .50 .80 .50 .58 .84 .60 .69 .80 .65 .79 .80 .62 .70 .75 .55 .71 .80 .75 .71 .51 .65 .65 .63 .75 .60 .85 .78 .66 .80 .71 .62 .72 .65 .80 .50 .58 .84 .60 .70 .80 .70 .79 .80 .55 .70 .75 .55 .71 .80 .75 .71 .51 .70 .70 .63 .83 .86 .85 .75 .67 .77 .73 .70 .80 .80 .79 .62 .85 .85 .70 .70 .80 .72 .77 .80 .90 .75 .75 .75 .75 .80 .75 .71 .90 .70 .73 Niagara Oneida . . Ontario .... Orleans Otsego Queens Richmond Rockland Saint Lawrence Saratoga Schenectady Schoharie Schuyler Seneca Steuben Suffolk . Sullivan Tioga Tompkins Ulster Warren Washington Wayne Westchester Yates ::: * Ratio of percentages adopted for Equalization Tables are based upon Assessments of previous years. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION APPENDIX A II 3 Concluded 247 COUNTIES Ratio of per- cent- age, 1906 Ratio of per- cent- age, 1907 Ratio of per- cent- age, 1908 Ratio of per- cent- age, 1909 Ratio of per- cent- age, 1910 Ratio of per- cent- age, 1911 Ratio of per- cent- age, 1912 Ratio of per- cent- age, 1913 Ratio of per- cent- age, 1914 Ratio of per- cent- age, 1915 Albany .85 .75 .85 .75 .90 .75 .90 .75 .90 .75 .90 .75 .90 .72 .90 .70 .90 .65 .91 .83 .70 .75 .74 .76 .74 .50 .80 .80 .58 .80 .77 .56 .60 .68 .72 .70 .70 .66 .80 .91 .71 .75 .80 .75 .75 .55 .91 .70 .75 .82 .71 .62 .61 .80 .77 .75 .89 .86 .89 .61 .77 .72 .82 .80 .65 .77 .75 .62 .45 .80 .80 .75 .50 .78 .72 .81 .70 .71 .87 .70 .92 .83 .70 .75 .72 .77 .72 .50 .78 .77 .58 .80 .75 .58 .60 .65 .74 .65 .65 .70 .80 .92 .71 .75 .80 .78 .70 .52 .93 .68 .75 .82 .73 .60 .80 .79 .77 .71 .89 .89 .89 .68 .77 .68 .75 .77 .65 .77 .75 .65 .40 .80 .77 .73 .60 .78 .75 .75 .74 .71 Bronx .78 .78 .76 .90 .73 .73 .50 .80 .84 .74 .80 .72 .80 .76 .71 .72 .72 .81 .90 .84 .89 .77 .78 .76 .80 .75 .62 .89 .81 .81 .88 .76 .70 .77 .80 .76 .79 .89 .79 .90 .79 .85 .68 .73 .78 .72 .80 .80 .80 .69 .85 .78 .75 .80 .75 .72 .90 .76 .77 .78 .78 .76 .90 .73 .73 .50 .60 .84 .68 .85 .74 .60 .65 .75 .72 .72 .85 .90 .84 .89 .77 .82 .76 .82 .75 .62 .89 .81 .81 .88 .76 .70 .77 .80 .75 .79 .89 .79 .90 .79 .85 .68 .78 .79 .74 .80 .80 .75 .60 .85 .78 .83 .67 .73 .72 .90 .76 .77 .78 .78 .78 .90 .73 .73 .55 .84 .86 .68 .85 .76 .60 .65 .75 .77 .72 .85 .90 .84 .89 .77 .82 .85 .85 .77 .62 .89 .81 .81 .88 .76 .75 .77 .84 .75 .79 .89 .83 .90 .79 .85 .68 .78 .82 .74 .85 .80 .75 .60 .85 .83 .83 .67 .73 .75 .90 .76 .80 .78 .78 .78 .85 .73 '.77 .55 .84 .86 .68 .85 .76 .62 .65 .75 .77 .74 .75 .90 .84 .89 .77 .82 .85 .85 .77 .65 .89 .81 .81 .88 .76 .75 .77 .84 .77 .79 .87 .85 .88 .80 .85 .70 .78 .85 .75 .85 .82 .70 .60 .85 .83 .83 .65 .78 .75 .90 .76 .80 .80 .78 .78 .80 .74 .77 .55 .84 .82 .68 .85 .76 .62 .65 .75 .77 .74 .75 .85 .80 .89 .77 .82 .83 .85 .77 .65 .89 .75 .81 .88 .76 .72 .74 .81 .77 .79 .87 .85 .88 .80 .80 .75 .78 .85 .75 .82 .82 .70 .60 .82 .83 .83 .65 .78 .75 .85 .76 .80 .83 .74 .78 .80 .74 .74 .55 .84 .82 .68 .85 .80 .62 .65 .75 .77 .70 .75 .85 .80 .91 .77 .82 .83 .85 .77 .65 .91 .75 .81 .88 .76 .75 .74 .81 .77 .79 .89 .90 .89 .88 .80 .75 .82 .80 .70 .82 .82 .70 .55 .82 .83 .80 .60 .78 .75 .85 .76 .80 .83 .74 .78 .80 .76 .74 .55 .82 .82 .68 .85 .80 .62 .65 .75 .75 .70 .75 .82 .80 .91 .77 .82 .83 .85 .75 .65 .91 .75 .81 .88 .76 .70 .74 .80 .77 .79 .89 .90 .89 .88 .80 .75 .82 .80 .70 .82 .82 .70 .55 .82 .80 .80 .60 .78 .75 .85 .74 .75 .83 .70 .78 .77 .76 .74 .50 .82 .82 .62 .82 .80 .60 .62 .70 .75 .70 .75 .64 .80 .91 .75 .78 .83 .80 .75 .60 .91 .75 .81 .85 .76 .70 .70 .80 .77 .79 .89 .90 .89 .88 .80 .75 .82 .80 .70 .82 .80 .67 .50 .82 .80 .80 .55 .78 .75 .85 .74 .75 Cayuga Chenango Clinton Cortland Dutchess Erie Essex Franklin Fulton Greene Herkimer Lewis Nassau New York Oneida Ontario Oswego Richmond Saratoga Schoharie Schuyler Steuben Suffolk Sullivan Tioga. Ulster Warren Washington Wayne Westchester Wyoming , Yates 248 STATE OF NEW YORK APPENDIX A IV 1 STATEMENT OF PERCENTAGE OF PERSONAL TO TOTAL ASSESSMENT FOR THE YEARS 1840, 1845, 1850, 1855, 1860, 1866, 1870, 1875, 1880, 1885, 1890, 1895, AND 1900 * COUNTIES Percentage of 1 personal to total, 1840 |i Percentage of personal to total, 1850 Percentage of personal to total, 1855 Percentage of personal to total, 1860 ss IS* Percentage of personal to total, 1870 Percentage of personal to total, 1875 Percentage of personal to total, 1880 Percentage of personal to total, 1885 Percentage of personal to total, 1890 Percentage of personal to total, 1895 Percentage of personal to total, 1900 N Albany Allegany Broome Cattaraugus... Cayuga. . 26.36 3.48 17.23 4.03 12.37 25.29 2.51 10.07 2.50 13.57 21.44 5.90 9.74 4.44 16.20 19.40 7.52 12.53 5.56 14.75 21.17 9.55 11.76 6.62 18.90 19.39 10.09 13.00 8.52 21.41 16.34 9.80 10.34 7.42 19 99 10.25 7.05 7.29 8.08 12 18 7.37 7.75 6.87 8.82 10 32 8.09 8.35 10.09 7.83 10 89 7.46 8.25 8.56 9.40 12 39 8.34 10.48 8.27 9.11 11 45 9.39 12.09 8.46 8.61 9 21 Chautauqua... Chemung Chenango Clinton. Columbia 6.99 12.20 12.97 15.91 26 36 7.30 9.85 11.86 4.48 25 14 11.86 13.37 13.09 3.68 OQ OK 11.77 14.55 15.73 10.75 29.33 12.64 13.82 14.62 12.08 30.86 15.89 18.90 15.59 15.33 24 35 11.62 12.36 12.66 12.86 20 22 8.47 8.63 11.11 11.80 29 36 10.54 3.63 14.18 11.30 17 95 9.53 5.44 11.07 12.52 16 26 9.20 8.54 10.50 10.96 13 42 fc8.76 7.10 10.16 10.20 12 27 7.69 5.37 12.54 10.89 11 02 Cortland Delaware 10.90 11.27 6.63 9 36 8.54 17 43 9.02 13.26 10.15 13.52 15.19 16.71 12.16 13.18 9.75 13 54 11.91 12 34 10.98 10 94 9.52 10 59 8.11 9 55 9.73 11 21 Dutchess Erie. 26.72 8.49 26.67 4.79 26.03 9 15 25.95 13.54 26.77 12.70 28.48 18.43 27.25 15.82 18.18 10.97 16.15 7 99 14.88 7 28 16.27 6 55 11.27 5 95 12.17 4 16 Essex Franklin Fulton Genesee Greene 10.49 2.01 18.39 5.64 18.20 5.82 10.13 14.77 7.53 19.92 14.42 8.78 17.12 11.38 24.36 11.93 8.37 16.87 11.41 16.84 10.65 9.22 14.08 14.75 17.57 9.85 13.66 16.85 17.19 19.27 9.16 12.94 13.40 15.72 17.28 7.43 12.09 11.72 14.93 11.37 6.49 14.07 9.60 14.75 9.92 7.13 14.38 6.99 12.39 12.62 7.06 11.58 8.03 12.32 10.12 7.75 10.17 7.74 11.64 10.26 8.33 10.15 11.21 13.08 11.22 Hamilton Herkimer Jefferson Kings .35 14.91 8.82 12 25 .13 12.63 12.21 13.13 1.14 13.99 15.43 11.23 .93 18.08 18.86 11 31 .79 20.68 18.76 11.20 2.07 16.55 17.67 16.47 2.02 15.70 18.36 9.24 .44 12.38 17.10 7 36 .17 10.77 12.73 4 82 .14 9.87 10.94 S3 46 .37 10.22 9.57 3 14 .10 9.25 11.40 14 18 .69 10.19 10.94 6 31 Lewis Livingston Madison Monroe 11.85 6.94 11.09 8 91 13.35 9.34 10.78 10.65 6.96 12.57 14.45 11 12 12.25 13.12 16.94 11.28 11.81 16.62 20.02 15.95 10.08 14.82 22.01 16.08 10.06 14.61 16.11 10.61 10.51 8.99 13.75 5.53 11.02 10.22 12.24 4 44 fS.98 10.31 10.21 5 17 7.88 11.42 9.10 5 84 17.82 12.07 8.07 5 34 12.14 11.15 9.74 6 93 Montgomery. . . Nassau 11.83 10.26 12.15 11.37 7.56 13.47 7.93 5.42 7.03 6.14 10.70 11.24 10.93 6 93 New York Niagara Oneida 25.78 3.49 18 36 26.16 6.77 19 66 27.58 7.57 22 97 30.80 8.48 17 71 30.95 14.51 18 15 35.00 15.14 14 14 29.14 13.55 12 93 19.73 6.99 11 10 17.59 6.59 10 51 14.78 7.30 9 39 13.61 8.09 8 65 i8. 39 7.71 9 16 15.35 5.01 19 10 Onondaga Ontario Orange Orleans 11.86 14.20 18.01 5 30 11.28 13.67 19.89 7.73 11.68 16.96 21.56 10 58 14.62 16.19 23.61 12.10 13.32 19.65 23.83 11.43 14.83 19.08 27.94 10.34 13.55 19.46 24.50 10.84 10.90 11.58 20.94 7.21 10.62 10.85 15.79 9 73 8.98 11.06 14.13 10 24 8.03 10.75 12.06 9 35 6.36 10.19 10.70 8 78 9.13 10.16 9.92 9 97 Oswego Otsego 9.82 15 79 6.95 13 64 10.10 16.68 9.94 19.23 13.03 18.91 16.00 18.22 10.53 14.54 9.64 11.60 5.54 12 46 3.81 10 29 5.96 9 77 5.62 10 28 11.91 12 96 Putnam Queens Rensselaer Richmond Rockland Saint Lawrence Saratoga Schenectady . . . Schoharie... Schuyler Seneca Steuben Suffolk Sullivan Tioga Tompkins Ulster Warren Washington.... Wayne 16.38 29.51 27.88 13.69 19.23 2.67 16.28 24.64 8.08 n.ii 5.41 19.09 5.46 17.04 21.29 16.15 3.74 16.58 7 62 15.37 30.32 29.92 13.24 21.57 9.53 15.95 18.28 8.70 6^87 20.29 4.49 15.67 17.53 14.80 2.42 13.40 4 77 21.97 32.32 29.74 14.06 20.65 4.02 19.03 24.14 16.35 8^47 20.44 9.40 17.15 18.61 16.25 4.25 17.13 8 56 16.09 26.57 26.41 17.59 16.43 9.30 20.01 15.68 12.91 7.36 14.40 16.34 22.78 11.56 13.73 11.57 14.53 15.94 17.59 29 00 19.46 24.80 27.64 10.64 18.45 10.06 23.53 14.02 14.02 7.05 15.22 15.70 19.32 11.32 16.07 19.09 15.82 16.43 20.39 12 29 27.92 26.55 21.40 9.66 24.67 11.13 22.60 11.55 12.65 14.75 15.04 11.44 19.16 6.81 20.06 20.74 24.07 20.47 20.29 15 65 22.26 22.17 26.41 8.74 17.85 9.41 22.57 10.54 12.06 10.63 13.94 10.95 18.32 5.15 12.94 18.73 17.97 17.82 20.61 11 90 17.12 13.50 18.23 7.17 9.79 8.78 12.32 9.22 11.55 10.81 12.29 9.15 15.81 6.56 7.71 10.99 14.38 18.88 17.99 10.15 18.08 6.24 14.45 4.67 20.35 7.45 8.44 10.46 10.96 9.76 11.83 8.82 13.00 3.97 6.66 12.40 13.96 17.00 13.71 7 71 18.32 7.49 12.59 2.79 11.31 8.36 7.12 6.43 11.11 7.33 12.27 7.97 11.79 2.85 6.66 11.26 11.58 16.44 13.36 8 45 13.47 4.67 10.20 2.17 9.20 8.93 7.28 5.87 11.37 10.12 12.28 8.10 10.89 2.50 7.20 10.97 10.10 15.00 11.92 9 35 11.44 4.08 9.17 .64 6.98 8.23 6.16 8.35 10.38 8.91 11.12 7.66 9.25 2.41 7.87 8.60 8.69 20.05 16.56 8 80 14.88 5.00 9.61 12.78 5.23 9.87 6.38 8.98 11.66 9.38 10.84 7.40 6.97 4.37 9.70 11.61 8.55 19.18 12.67 8 54 Westchester... Wyoming 27.05 30.33 4 77 38.84 7 31 17.56 11 32 16.57 10 37 16.16 12 78 14.46 12.60 9.93 9.11 6.42 9 45 4.96 10 64 3.52 10 76 3.03 10 31 8.79 12 07 Yates 4.57 7.59 11.62 10.48 13.10 13.36 11.60 10.41 9.42 9.49 9.14 8.45 7.68 State 18.93 19.48 21.05 20.95 22.24 25.50 22.05 14.86 12.70 10.98 10.12 12.16 11.66 * Report of the N. Y. State Board of Tax Commissioners, 1914, pages 51-52. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 249 APPENDIX A IV 1 Concluded STATEMENT OF PERCENTAGE OF PERSONAL TO TOTAL ASSESS- MENT FOR THE YEARS 1913 TO 1914, INCLUSIVE COUNTIES SScc P s |t! 3S* |15 2 3 3*5 }l! g5 I* 2 Percentage ot personal to total. 1906 Percentage of personal to total, 1907 Percentage ot personal to total, 1908 Percentage of personal to total, 1909 Percentage of personal to total, 1910 SB- |1| 3 Percentage of personal to total, 1912 'S-Sc* ||S ill N Percentage of personal to total, 1914 |j Albany 7 87 6.81 6 15 6 65 5 65 5 44 5 42 5 15 4 30 4 42 5 71 5 86 Allegany 8.25 8.29 7.55 7.84 6.62 5.77 5.221 4.90 4.14 3.95 3.68 2.69 Bronx Broome 5 62 '5.52 4 93 5.50 5 ii 4 75 ! '4 36! 4 20 3 JJl 3 63 2 92 .86 2 70 Cattaraugus 6.24 6.09 5.58 6.03 5.03 4.49 4.16 3.57 2.85 11.21 2.68 2.16 Cayuga 6.97 6.97 6.40 6.12 5.23 4.73 4.32 4.12 3.47 3 19 2 98 2 75 5 57 5 47 5 28 5 15 4 71 3 77 3 26 2 84 2 54 2 37 2 35 1 99 Chemung Chenango Clinton 2.81 7.81 15 96 3.84 7.70 6.35 4.28 7.01 5 89 5.62 6.93 4 78 5.28 5.99 5 08 5.16 5.47 4 13 4.79 5.25 3 64 5.63 4.64 3 19 5.28 4.36 2 87 5.38 4.00 2 60 3.26 3.80 2 46 1.53 3.50 2 47 Columbia Cortland '7.23 5.66 12 13 6.97 5.20 12 21 7.00 4.61 8 21 7.19 4.52 8 66 7.15 3.78 6 58 5.85 3.33 5 89 5.29 3.08 5 09 4.53 ' 2.60 4 25 4.07 2.19 3 88 3.72 1.91 3 38 3.63 1.87 2 99 3.34 1.59 2 75 Dutchess Erie Essex 8.89 2.79 8.49 7.50 2.97 8.38 7.93 2.77 5.36 8.61 2.61 5.22 8.52 2.39 4.53 8.23 2.30 4.39 8.46 2.16 4.19 7.69 2.15 3.87 6.26 1.98 3.58 5.92 1.90 3.68 5.60 1.85 3.34 5.59 1.90 2.89 Franklin Fulton 6.43 13 33 6.14 13.10 5.94 5 75 5.83 5 64 5.15 5 00 4.41 4 75 4.24 4 99 3.79 4 53 3.68 4.17 3.49 3 99 3.06 3.32 2.75 4 88 Genesee Greene . . . 12.43 6.88 9.27 6.44 9.04 6.18 8.67 5.58 6.74 5.15 5.94 4.71 6.07 4.23 5.92 3.82 5.49 3.44 3.66 3.06 3.51 2.83 4.72 2.49 65 55 61 53 68 49 42 19 .16 44 .15 16 Herkimer Jefferson 6.29 8.40 5.66 7.99 5.66 7.38 5.32 6 78 5.43 5.89 4.40 5.29 4.10 4.86 3.50 4.44 3.40 4.20 3.17 4.41 3.04 4.22 2.79 4.11 10 48 8 94 8 81 7 56 7 28 5 88 6 22 4 05 3 20 2 82 2 68 2 29 Lewis Livingston . 11.48 8 83 11.15 8.92 9.80 8 73 8.79 8 52 6.84 7 72 6.12 7 36 5.78 7.02 5.28 6.49 4.87 6.00 4.79 5 62 3.96 5.44 3.77 5.10 Madison 6.91 6.58 6.35 6.63 5.81 5.45 5.26 4.84 4.77 4.32 3.96 3.59 Monroe Montgomery 4.86 5 82 4.99 5 68 4.79 5 12 4.65 4 72 4.54 4 37 4.20 3 76 3.99 3.25 4.31 2.90 3.96 2.73 3.65 2.28 3.50 2.37 3.15 2.51 Nassau 7.70 7.48 8.22 10.97 8.29 7.62 6.70 3.59 3.27 2.74 2.42 2.24 New York ... 13.14 11.72 12.49 9.44 8.53 6.32 6.81 5.51 4.96 4.81 4.48 5.29 3 47 3 44 2 93 3 17 2 33 1 95 1 77 1 87 1 53 1.42 1.39 1.22 Oneida Onondaga 10.51 5.26 12.03 5 74 8.78 5 13 9.03 5 15 9.15 4.54 9.29 4 37 9.46 4.28 9.06 3.94 7.84 4.11 7.65 3.48 7.70 3.30 7.20 3.11 Ontario Orange Orleans 10.94 6.25 7 74 9.27 5.98 7 13 8.64 6.67 5 26 8.23 6.49 5 11 7.38 5.75 4 14 6.92 5.63 3 33 6.69 5.33 2.84 6.20 5.23 2.66 5.61 4.97 2.26 5.13 5.04 1.86 4.67 4.65 1.65 6.12 4.54 1.23 Oswego Otsego 6.35 9.06 6.79 9.39 5.67 9.14 5.63 8.99 4.53 8.08 4.48 7.67 4.61 7.01 10.81 6.40 3.34 5.98 5.57 5.35 3.77 5.07 4.71 4.83 9 47 9 21 9 69 8 39 7 86 8.36 10 02 9 57 8.16 7.17 7.53 6.53 Queens 7.59 5.38 6.08 5.73 4.89 3.23 3.13 1.57 1.18 1.38 1.39 1.19 Rensselaer 5.84 12 27 5.63 11 58 5.46 10 96 5.47 9 24 5.16 7.12 5.03 4.48 4.80 4.69 4.80 3.14 4.33 2.37 3.97 2.18 3.88 2.13 3.86 1.85 Rockland Saint Lawrence Saratoga 3.44 11.42 4 24 2.74 8.16 3 53 2.99 7.81 3 26 2.56 7.86 2 87 2.67 6.90 2.47 3.50 6.38 2.64 2.60 5.86 2 54 3.32 5.36 2.08 2.17 5.06 1.91 2.87 5.01 1.62 2.67 4.82 1.32 1.76 4.34 1.25 Schenectady Schoharie Schuyler 6.42 11.86 8 12 7.42 11.21 7 61 5.59 7.68 7 53 5.00 8.43 6.87 5.21 6.55 6.23 4.76 5.81 5.85 4.43 5.41 4.29 4.29 4.57 3.57 4.04 4.51 2.76 4.42 3.92 2.45 4.01 3.46 2.29 3.70 2.93 2.09 Seneca Steuben Suffolk ' Sullivan Tioga 7.83 6.46 6.68 2.93 8.43 7.18 6.24 6.32 2.73 8.04 6.16 5.69 6.37 2.53 8.34 6.15 5.76 5.86 4.05 7.84 5.33 5.0 4.78 1.93 7.05 4.72 4.23 4.29 1.68 6.41 4.19 4.08 4.10 1.45 15.07 3.97 3.68 3.53 1.59 4.07 3.56 3.90 5.14 1.69 3.67 3.13 4.12 3.30 2.18 3.25 2.66 3.33 3.01 2.15 3.07 2.54 3.07 2.26 1.82 2.76 Tompkins 8.02 7.49 7.24 6.68 5.82 5.00 4.44 4.20 4.82 4.86 4.65 3.99 Ulster Warren 3.39 13 96 3.1 13 63 2.83 13.71 2.89 10.89 2.82 9.3 2.46 5.39 2.36 4.93 2.20 4.61 2.32 4.16 2.07 3.94 1.68 3.69 1.50 2.73 Washington Wayne . . 8.52 7.03 8.10 6.74 8.00 6.54 7.55 6.18 6.84 4.40 6.32 3.85 5.84 3.51 5.43 3.12 5.18 2.73 5.05 2.66 4.62 2.17 3.46 1.74 Weetchester 6 82 6 5.85 5.12 4.1 3.82 3.53 2.98 2.93 2.76 2.21 2.01 Wyoming Yates . 9.43 8 58 8.94 7.1 9.02 8.22 8.62 6.92 6.9 5.44 5.77 4.87 5.38 4.58 4.68 4.76 4.18 4.55 4.33 4.70 4.33 4.63 3.51 3.63 State 10.82 9.7 10.04 8.07 7.3 5.6S 5.65 4.76 4.19 4.01 3.73 3.77 1 Report of N. Y. State Board of Tax Commissioners, 1914, pp. 49-50. 250 STATE OF NEW YORK APPENDIX A IV 2 TOTAL ASSESSED VALUE OF PERSONAL PROPERTY AND ASSESSED VALUE OF PERSONAL PROPERTY NOT TAXABLE LOCALLY FOR STATE PURPOSES, 1914 * COUNTIES Total assessed value of personal property, 1914 Assessed value of personal property, not taxable locally for State purposes, 1913 Albany $15,535,573 $7 112 237 Allegany 2,170,165 1 581 656 Broome 3 021 108 1 626 868 Cattaraugus 3 657 088 2 879 600 Cayuga 2 414 094 1 241 260 Chautauo.ua 4 141 603 2 896 354 Chemung 1 743 950 1 204 605 Chenango 2 229 284 1 631 010 Clinton 1 435 485 1 181 130 Columbia 2 314 499 1 393 967 Cortland ... 1 248 591 973 596 Delaware . . . . 1 977 678 1 532 441 Dutchess .... 7 096 777 3 186 327 Erie 27 968 682 20 051 456 Essex 993,262 550 160 Franklin 1,699,670 1,332,910 Fulton 3,188,265 2,342,492 Genesee 1,965,728 575,000 Greene 1,084,666 748,541 Hamilton 8,199 Herkimer 3,493,105 2,488,655 Jefferson 3,621,202 1,629,997 Lewis 710,190 279,957 Livingston 2 078 081 611 836 Miadison 1 544 808 753,008 IMonroe 15 821 817 6,977,492 IVtontgomery 3,120,755 2,351,005 Nassau 4,394 545 1,982,345 New York (Greater) 703,006,714 362,711,154 Niagara .... 3,187,587 2,252,982 Oneida . 13,969,952 7,656,711 Onondaga . 11,452,925 5,570,175 Ontario . 3,520,759 1,184,759 Orange . 6,190,799 3,623,189 Orleans 1,032,997 681,962 Oswego 2,760,984 1,100,989 Otsego 3,290,342 2,059,017 Putnam 1,268,129 309,529 Rensselaer 7,038,300 3,694,650 Rockland 1,417,094 820,622 Saint Lawrence 4,314,935 2,235,845 Saratoga 1,484,807 1,125,452 Schenectady . . . 3,133,534 631,642 Schoharie. . 892,418 538,001 JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION APPENDIX A IV 2 Concluded 251 COUNTIES Total assessed value of personal property, 1914 Assessed value of personal property, not taxable locally for State purposes, 1914 Schuyler $315,611 $171 651 Seneca 865,825 427 100 Steuben 2,941,109 1 559 799 Suffolk 4 427 854 2 293 729 SullivRn 628 502 500 689 Tioga 1,201,814 807 974 Tompkins 1,871,486 1,012 886 Ulster 2,924,144 2,421,074 Warren 1 894,593 1 444 598 Washington 2,092,694 1 358 669 W^ayne . . - 1,783,345 1;201 880 Westchester 12,230,281 4,211,609 Wyoming 1,408,551 688,268 Yates 922,920 484,390 Total $924,149,875 $485,987,900 * Report of the New York State Board of Tax Commissioners, 1914, page 547. 252 STATE or NEW YORK APPENDIX A V 1 TABLE SHOWING THE PERCENTAGE OF TENTATIVE PERSONAL PROPERTY ASSESSMENT RETAINED ON BOOK IN BOROUGHS OF MANHATTAN, BRONX, BROOKLYN, RICHMOND AND QUEENS, FROM 1907 TO 1914 MANHATTAN TAXES OF 1907 Tentative assessment on annual record Canceled Per cent canceled Receiver's book or final assessment roll Per cent retained on book Resident corporations . $1 171 685,000 $1 118 643 620 95 4 $53 041,380 4 5 Nonresident corporations Resident personal 219,152,500 554 511,305 192,044,325 366 033 222 87.6 66 27,108,175 188 478 083 12.3 33 9 Nonresident personal Estates . 223,229,615 356,505,905 157,518,105 258,190,895 70.5 72 4 65,711,510 98,315,010 29.4 27 5 Totals $2,525,084,325 $2,092 430,167 82 8 $432,654,158 17 1 MANHATTAN TAXES OF 1908 Resident corporations $133 829 525 $79 871 030 59 6 $53 958 495 40 3 Nonresident corporations Resident personal 58,723,800 469 401 150 31,745,000 331 294 298 54.0 70 5 26 ,978, '800 138 106 852 S.1 29 4 Nonresident personal Estates 136,240,955 287 984 880 108,091,600 212 808 255 79.3 73 8 28,149,355 75,176 625 20.8 26 1 Tax Law, Sec. 7, Subdv. 2 34,152,150 28,711,645 84.0 5,440,505 15.9 Totals $1 120 332 460 $792 521 828 70 7 $327 810 632 29 2 MANHATTAN TAXES OF 1909 Tentative assessment on annual record Additions Canceled Per cent canceled Receiver's book or final assessment roll Per cent retained on book Resident corporations Nonresident corporations. . . Resident personal Nonresident personal Estates Tax Law, Sec. 7, Subdv. 2.. $135,443,200 55,924,750 370,695,507 77,423,975 278,962,905 18,581,255 $1,589,200 108,275 1,324,075 136,615 7,610,000 383,000 $70,467,325 26,477,150 241,373,523 52,231,695 211,360,570 14,069,860 51.4 47.2 64.8 67.3 73.7 74.1 $66,565,075 29,555,875 130,646,059 25,328,895 75,212,335 4,894,395 48.5 52.7 35.1 32.6 26.2 25.8 Totals $937,031,592 $11,151 165 $615 980 123 64 9 $332 202 634 35 MANHATTAN TAXES OF 1910 Resident corporations .... Nonresident corporations. . Resident personal Nonresident personal Estates Tax Law, Sec. 7, Subdv. 2. Totals... $127,801,800 47,218,600 407,801.322 86,024,045 282,887,810 7,252,895 $522,650 193,300 166,810 139,900 962,367 $56,797,250 20,749,950 291,311,331 67,262,955 223,408,430 3,411,100 44.2 43.7 71.4 78.0 78.7 47.0 $71,527,200 26,661,950 116,656,801 18,900,990 60,441,747 3,841,795 8: 28.5 21.9 21.2 52.9 $958,986,472 $1,985,027 $662,941,016 68.9 $298,030,483 31.0 JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 253 APPENDIX AVI Continued MANHATTAN TAXES OF 1911 Tentative assessment on annual record Additions Canceled Per cent canceled Receiver's book or final assessment roll Percent retained on book Resident corporations Nonresident corporations. . . Resident personal Nonresident personal Estates Tax Law, Sec. 7, Subd. 2... Totals $118,129,600 30,344,500 299,469,091 27,401,215 178,368,250 4,272,295 $212,500 74,400 68,600 16,000 219,800 2,000 $43,720,500 6,049,600 182,202,944 12,612,215 122,896,040 705,700 37.0 19.9 60.8 46.0 68.9 16.5 $74,409,100 24,294,900 117,266,147 14,789,000 55,472,210 3,566,595 62.9 80.0 39.1 53.9 31.1 83.4 5657,984,951 $593,300 $368,186,999 55.9 $289,797,952 44.0 MANHATTAN TAXES OF 1912 Resident corporations Nonresident corporations.. . Resident personal Nonresident personal $124,989,300 37,959,000 267,603,527 19,755,050 135,804,695 3,939,595 $24,800 106,000 9,569,390 $48,505,500 12,188,450 142,139,360 6,005,030 99,600,905 144,800 38.8 32.1 53.1 30.3 73.3 3.6 $76,483,800 25,770,800 125,464,167 13,750,020 36,203,790 3,794,795 61 1 67.8 46.8 69.6 26.6 96.3 Estates Tax Law, Sec. 7, Subd. 2... Totals 11,800 348,000 $590,051,167 $10,059,990 $308,584,045 52.2 $281,467,122 47.7 Resident corporations .... Nonresident corporations. . Resident personal Nonresident personal Estates Tax Law, Sec. 7, Subd. 2.. Totals Resident corporations Nonresident corporations. . . Resident personal MANE $145,944,000 43,342,200 302,902,280 47,527,500 154,064,500 4,096,200 [ATTAN TA] $170,000 22,200 404,300 4,300 348,900 27,000 tES OF 1913 $55,367,700 13,704,300 201,162,945 31,187,700 130,430,000 511,700 37.9 .31.6 66.4 65.6 84,6 12.4 $90,576,300 29,637,900 101,739,335 16,339,800 23,634,500 3,584,500 62.0 68.3 33.5 34.3 15.3 87.5 $697,876,680 $976,700 $432,364,345 61.9 $265,512,335 38.0 MAN $153,216,900 34,872,000 260,727,120 38,600.200 131,308,700 4,100,900 [ATT AN TA $76,400 109,000 271,200 11.000 556,400 27,200 XES OF 1914 $53,105,800 8,458,700 151,137,250 20,030.200 101,702,300 623,300 34.6 1 24.2 57.9 51.8 77.4 15.1 $100,111,100 26,413,300 109,589,870 18,570,000 29,606,400 3,477,600 65.3 75.7 42.0 48.1 22.5 84.8 Nonresident personal Estates ... Tax Law, Sec. 7, Subd. 2... Totals. . . . $622,825,820 $1,051,200 $335,057,550 53.7 $287,768,270 46.2 BRONX TAXES FOR 1907 Tentative assessment on annual record Canceled Per cent canceled Receiver's book or final assessment roll Percent retained on book Personal $29,611,697 3,294,025 36,347,450 $17,875,473 2,233,695 35,028,305 60.3 67.8 96.3 $11,736,224 1,060,330 1,319,345 39.6 32.1 3.6 Estates Corporations < Total $69,253,172 $55,137,473 79.6 $14,115,699 20.3 BR Resident personal ONX TAXES $24,518,688 . 3,511,116 3,932,790 FOR 1908 $15,553,540 2,308,642 2,560,730 63.4 65.7 65.1 $8,965,146 1,202,474 1,372,060 36.5 34.2 34.8 Estates Resident corporations . . Totals $31,962,592 $20,422,912 63.9 $11,539,680 36.1 254 STATE OF NEW YORK APPENDIX AVI Continued BRONX TAXES OF 1909 Tentative assessment on annual record Additions Canceled Per cent canceled Receiver's book or final assessment roll Per ceni retained on book Resident personal Estates $42,088,686 4,568,429 $117,455 $30,493,990 3,569,924 72.4 78 1 $11,594,696 998 505 27.5 21 8 Resident corporations Nonresident corporations. . . 2,937,940 196,200 9,330 1,681,880 105,790 56.5 53.9 1,276,060 90 410 43.4 46 Totals $49 791 255 $126 785 $35 831 584 71 9 $13 959 671 28 BRONX TAXES OF 1910 Resident personal Estates Resident corporations Nonresident corporations.. . Totals $16,500,599 4,111,498 2,446,860 148,410 $11,047,284 3,247,563 1,137,120 58,850 66.9 78.9 46.4 39.6 $5,453,315 863,935 1,309,740 89,560 33 21 53.5 60.3 $23,207,367 $15,490,817 66.7 $7,716.550 $2,539,225 978,070 1,395,600 74,000 33.2 44.7 21.9 54.9 76.6 Resident personal B $5,678,475 4,461,235 2,541,300 96,500 RONX TAXE $16,600 3,800 17,600 S OF 1911 $3,139,250 3,483,165 1,145,700 22,500 55.2 78.0 45 23.3 Estates Resident corporations Nonresident corporations.. . Totals $12,777,510 $38,000 $7,790,615 60.9 $4,986,895 39 BRONX TAXES OF 1912 Resident personal $2,760,325 $665,710 24.1 $2,094,615 75.8 Estates 4,395,570 3,486,387 79.3 909,183 20 6 Resident corporations 2,548,400 1,034,600 40 6 1,513,800 59.4 Nonresident corporations 81 400 3 800 4 6 77 600 95.3 Totals $9,785,695 $5,190,497 53 $4,595,198 46.9 Resident personal Estates Resident corporations .... Nonresident corporations. . Totals. BRONX TAXES OF 1913 $5,200,115 3,980,183 2,665,500 146,000 $31,700 10,500 2,500 $2,850,790 3,070,848 923,100 53,000 54.8 77.1 34.6 36.3 $2,349,325 909,335 1,742,400 93,000 45.1 22.8 65.3 63.7 $11,991,798 $44,700 $6,897,738 57.5 $5,094,060 42.4 BRONX TAXES OF 1914 Resident personal $7,793,600 $10,200 $5,305,300 68 $2,488,300 31.9 Estates . 4,448,900 4,100 3,451,600 77.5 997,300 22.4 2 896 400 738 400 25 4 2 158 000 74 5 Nonresident corporations. . . 127,000 2,000 9,400 7.4 117,600 92.6 Totals. $15,265,900 $16,300 $9,504,700 62.2 $5,761,200 37.7 BROOKLYN -TAXES OF 1907 Tentative assessment on annual record Canceled Per cent canceled Receiver's book or final assessment roll Percent retained on book Personal $195 152,905 $124 213 130 63.6 $70,939,775 36.3 Estates 41,775,220 26,798,810 64.1 14,976,410 35.8 Resident corporations 201,565,300 195,619,368 97 5,945,932 2.9 Nonresident corporations Nonresident individuals . 4,275,000 1,420,000 3,534,670 1,155,900 82.6 81.4 740,330 264,100 17.3 18.6 Totals $444,188,425 $351,321,878 79 $92,866,547 20.9 JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 255 APPENDIX AVI Continued BROOKLYN TAXES OF 1908 Tentative assessment on annual record Canceled Per cent canceled Receiver's book or final assessment roll Per cent retained on book Resident personal Estates $192,343,855 42,117,955 $126,380,285 31,227,163 65.7 74.1 $65,963,570 10,890,792 34.2 25.8 11,716,750 5,887,580 50 2 5 829,170 49 7 Nonresident corporations Tax Law Sec 7 Subd 2 . . 898,870 264,100 288,930 109,500 32.1 41.4 609,940 154,600 67.8 58.5 Totals $247,341,530 $163,893,458 66.2 $83,448,072 33.7 BROOKLYN TAXES OF 1909 Tentative assessment on annual record Additions Canceled Percent canceled Receiver's book or final assessment roll Percent retained on book Resident personal Estates $192,745,180 39,328,510 $221,535 $125,684,600 28,942,210 65.2 73.5 $67,060,580 10,386,300 34.7 26 4 Resident corporations Nonresident corporations. . Tax Law, Sec. 7, Subd. 2. 12,751,135 921,700 225,000 41,850 12,900 6,617,325 323,700 71,500 51.9 35.1 31.7 6,133,810 598,000 153,500 48.1 64.8 68.3 Totals $245,971,525 $276,285 $161,639,335 65.7 $84,332,190 34.2 Resident personal Estates Resident corporations .... Nonresident corporations. . Tax Law, Sec. 7, Subd. 2. Totals. Resident personal , Estates , Resident corporations Nonresident corporations. . , Tax Law, Sec. 7, Subd. 2., Totals. . . Resident personal Estates Resident corporations Nonresident corporations. . Tax Law, Sec. 7, Subd. 2. Totals. Resident personal . Resident corporations Nonresident corporations. . Tax Law, Sec. 7, Subd. 2. Totals. . . BROOKLYN TAXES OF 1910 $196,524,830 39,264,415 13,650,550 1,061,250 $62,100 98,300 210,800 $152,910,810 30,877,960 6,909,550 523,400 77.8 78.6 50.6 49 3 $43,614,020 8,386,455 6,741,000 537 850 22.1 21.3 49.3 50 g 153 500 101 000 65 8 52 500 34 2 $250,654,545 $371,200 $191,322,720 76.3 $59,331,825 23.6 BROOKLYN TAXES OF 1911 $106,895,800 38,905,805 10,533,150 811,500 $18,050 2,500 105,400 $67,309,455 30,652,934 3,151,400 219,800 62.9 78.7 29.9 27 $39,586,345 8,252,871 7,381,700 591,700 37 21.2 70 72 9 52,500 9,500 18.1 43,000 81.9 $157,198,705 $125.950 $101,343.089 64.4 $55,855.616 35.5 BRO( $90,173,995 38,084,771 11,362,100 731,800 45,000 DKLYN TAX $15,850 500 25,800 ES OF 1912 $56,568,700 30,869,181 4,095,400 110,400 62.7 81 36 15 $33,605,295 7,215,590 7,266,700 621,400 45,000 37.2 18.9 63.9 84.9 100 $140,397,666 $42,150 $91,643,681 65.2 $48,753,985 34.7 BRO< $63,190,195 37,708,890 13,351,100 1,228,000 45,000 DKLYN TAX $64,000 300,000 16,300 45,000 ES OF 1913 $32,671,840 31,265,595 5,152,000 562,200 51.6 82.2 38.5 44.1 $30,582,355 6,743,315 8,215,400 710,800 45,000 48.3 17.7 61.4 55.8 100 $115,523,185 $425,300 $69,651,615 60 $46,296,870 39.9 256 STATE OF NEW YORK APPENDIX AVI Continued BROOKLYN TAXES OF 1914 Tentative assessment on annual record Additions Canceled Per cent canceled Receiver's book or final assessment roll Per cent retained on book Resident personal Estates $63,975,710 38,740,340 $26,250 3,200 $40,776,235 31 945 350 63.7 82 4 $23,199,475 6 794,990 36.2 17 5 Resident corporations Nonresident corporations. . . Tax Law, Sec. 7, Subd. 2.. 13,809,000 856,900 45,000 15,000 1,900 5,231,400 167,900 10,000 37.8 19.5 22.2 8,577,600 689,000 35,000 62.1 80.4 77.7 Totals $117,426,950 $46,350 $78,130,885 66.5 $39,296,065 33.4 RICHMOND TAXES OF 1907 Tentative assessment on annual record Additions Canceled Per cent canceled Receiver's book or final assessment roll Per cent retained on book Personal . . . $7,799,950 $4,939,890 63 3 $2,860,060 36.6 Estates 1 279,350 414 315 32 3 865 035 67 6 Corporations . ... 10,210,000 9,872,890 96 7 337,110 3.3 Totals $19,289,300 $15,227,095 78.9 $4,062,205 21 Resident personal RICE $4,873,000 [MOND TAX ES OF 1908 $2,755,055 724,128 358,370 56.5 53.6 52.5 $2,117,945 626,272 323,180 43.4 46.3 47.4 Estates 1,350,400 681,550 Resident corporations Totals $6,904,950 $3,837,553 55.5 $3,067,397 44.4 RICHMOND TAXES OF 1909 Resident personal Estates $4,756,500 1,720,750 $1,900 $2,805,815 863,075 58.9 50 1 $1,950,685 857,675 41 49.8 599 500 254 700 42 4 344 800 57 5 Totals $7,076,750 $1,900 $3,923,590 55.4 $3,153,160 44.5 RICHMOND TAXES OF 1910 Resident personal $22,530,275 $8,375 $18,409,500 81.6 $4,129,150 18.3 Estates 4,298,500 3 866,120 89.9 432,380 10 Resident corporations 1,464,950 23,000 22,200 693,200 20,000 46.6 86.9 793,950 3,000 53.3 13 Totals $28,316,725 $30,575 $22,988,820 81.1 $5,358,480 18.9 RICHMOND TAXES OF 1911 Resident personal Resident corporations Nonresident corporations. . Totals... $2,000,740 2,207,450 549,500 60 000 $4,000 2,500 1,500 $985,200 1,664,705 233,000 $4,817,690 $8,000 $2,882,905 49.1 75.3 42.2 0.0 59.7 $1,019,540 545,245 318,000 60,000 $1,942,783 Resident personal Estates Resident corporations Nonresident corporations. . Totals. . . RICB $1,161,200 1,909,835 500,500 65,000 MOND TAX ES OF 1912 $286,500 1,454,050 141,000 4,500 24.6 76.1 28.1 6.9 $874,700 455,785 359,500 60,500 :::::::::::: $3,636,535 $1,886,050 51.8 $1,750,485 JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 257 APPENDIX AVI Continued RICHMOND TAXES OF 1913 Tentative assessment on annual record Additions Canceled Per cent canceled Receiver's book or final assessment roll Per cent retained on book Resident personal Estates $2,240,400 2,921,485 $1,395,650 2,390,010 37.7 81 8 $844,750 531 475 62.2 18 1 Resident corporations Nonresident corporations. . . 447,500 72,500 111,500 7,500 24.9 10.3 336,000 65,000 75 89.6 Totals $5,681,885 $3,904,660 68.7 $1,777,225 31.2 RICHMOND TAXES OF 1914 Resident personal $1,368,450 $650,150 47.5 $718,300 52 4 Estates 1 390 275 977 700 70 3 412 575 29 6 Resident corporations Nonresident corporations. 465,000 60,000 101,000 21.7 364,000 60,000 78.2 100 Totals $3,283,725 $1,728,850 52.6 $1,554,875 47.3 QUEENS TAXES OF 1907 Tentative assessment on annual record Additions Canceled Per cent canceled Receiver's book or final assessment roll Per cent retained on book Personal $16,979,400 $8,449,700 49.7 $8,529,700 50.2 Estates 5,382,323 3,866,876 71.8 1,515,447 28 1 Corporations 40 303 150 39,157,035 97 1 1,146,115 2 8 Totals $62,664 873 $51,473,611 82.1 $11,191,262 17.8 QUEENS TAXES OF 1908 Resident personal Estates Resident corporations . . . Totals... $13,912,325 2,993,547 $5,935,505 1,901,272 42.6 63.5 $7,976,820 1,092,275 57.3 36.4 2,262,500 1,422,765 62.8 839,735 37.1 $19,168,372 $9,259,542 48.3 $9,908,830 51.6 QUEENS TAXES OF 1909 lesident personal Estates lesident corporations. . . Nonresident corporations. Totals... $15,650,375 6,088,800 2,044,800 20,000 $735,275 2,550,000 73,925 $8,151.500 4,783,450 1,175,925 20,000 52 78.5 57.5 100 $7,498,875 1,305,350 868,975 47.9 21.4 42.5 0.0 $23,804,075 $3,359,200 $14,130,875 59.3 $9,673,200 40.6 QUEENS TAXES OF 1910 lesident personal Cstates lesident corporations Nonresident corporations. Totals. . . $22,538,650 4,298,500 $8,375 $18,409,500 3,866,120 81.6 89.9 $4,129,150 432,380 18.3 10 1,487.150 23 000 22,200 693,200 20,000 46.6 86.9 793,950 3,000 53.3 13 $28,347,300 $30,575 $22,988,820 81.1 $5,358,480 18.9 QUEENS TAXES OF 1911 lesident personal Estates leaident corporations. . . Nonresident corporations Totals... $17,152,000 3 085 880 $13,300 $13,470,425 2,500,280 78.5 81 $3,681,575 585,600 21.4 18 9 1,502,200 129,000 20,000 500,500 58,000 33.3 44.9 1,001,700 71,000 66.6 55 $21,869,080 $33,300 $16,529,205 75.5 $5,339,875 24.4 258 STATE OF NEW YORK APPENDIX A V 1 Concluded QUEENS TAXES OF 1912 Tentative assessment on annual record Additions Canceled Per cent canceled Receiver's book or final assessment roll Per cent retained on book Resident personal $10,732,250 $1,000 $6,752,500 62.9 $3,980,750 37 Estates 2,680,000 1,400 1,596,700 59.5 1,085,300 40.4 Resident corporations Nonresident corporations.. . 1,807,000 146,000 14,500 616,800 20,000 33.8 13.7 , 1,204,700 126,000 66.1 86.3 Totals $15,385,850 $16,900 $8,986,000 58.4 $6,390,750 41.5 QUEENS TAXES OF 1913 Resident personal Estates $13,953,700 6,230,300 $1,800 $9,562,300 5,48$, 050 68.5 88 $4,391,400 744,250 31.4 11.9 Resident corporations 1,953,800 190 000 1,800 474,600 64,000 24.2 33.6 1,479,200 126,000 75.7 66 3 Totals $22 327 800 $3 600 $15,586,950 69 8 $6,740,850 30.1 QUEENS TAXES OF 1914 Resident personal Estates. Resident corporations . $14,078,200 3,208,850 2,257,000 $8,400 38,600 $10,706,100 2,445,100 627,700 76 76.2 27.8 $3,372,100 763,750 1,629,300 23.9 23.8 72.1 150 000 150,000 100 Totals $19 694 050 $47,000 $13,778,900 ' 69.9 $5,915,150 30 APPENDIX A V 2 SUMMARY OF MANHATTAN PERSONAL PROPERTY ASSESSMENTS, 1907 TO 1914 YEAR Tentative assessment Amount canceled Per cent canceled Final assessment roll Per cent retained 1907 $2 525,084,325 $2,092,430,167 82 8 $432,654,158 17.1 1908 1,120,332,460 792,521,828 70.7 327,810,632 29.2 1909 948,182,757 615,980,123 64.9 332,202,634 35.0 1910 960,971,499 660,941,016 68.9 298,030,483 31.0 1911 657,984,951 368,186,999 55.9 289,797,952 44.0 1912 590,051,167 308,584,045 52.2 281,467,122 47.0 1913 697,876,680 452,364,345 61.9 265,512,335 38.0 1914 622,825,820 335,057,550 53.8 287,768,270 46.2 JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 259 APPENDIX A VI 1 TABLE SHOWING AMOUNT OF PERSONAL PROPERTY ASSESSMENT, AMOUNT OF TOTAL PROPERTY ASSESSMENT AND PERCENTAGE PER- SONAL ASSESSMENT Is OF TOTAL ASSESSMENT, FOR THE CITIES AND TOWNS OF THE STATE. ClTIES AND TOWNS ARE ARRANGED ACCORDING TO THE PERCENTAGE OF PERSONALTY TO TOTAL AS- SESSMENT, THE HIGHEST PERCENTAGE RANKING FIRST ClTY Personal property assessment value Total property assessment value Percentage former is of latter Rank of city Johnstown $1,237,317 $4,982,681 24.5 1 Hudson 1,305,277 6,321,686 20.7 2 Ogdensburg 1,440,149 5,635,896 20.3 3 Plattsburg 908 461 4,461,271 20 3 4 Norwich 876,217 4,378,823 19.9 5 Port Jervis . . . 521,091 2,669,271 19.5 6 Utica 10,777,686 57,678,518 18.7 7 Olean 2,088,803 11,513,711 18 8 Gloversville Geneva 1,834,324 1,502,500 10,127,999 10,503,701 17.8 14.3 9 10 Little Falls 1,139,134 7,897,409 14.1 11 Oswego 1,821,411 13,415,483 13.4 12 Rome 1,470,947 11,271,515 13 13 Middletown 172,163 1,311,334 13 14 Oneonta 787,100 6,268,972 12.8 15 Newburgh 1,802,122 14,204,094 12.7 16 Beacon 967,348 7,468,300 12.6 17 Glens Falls 1,398,400 10,462,925 12.5 18 Hornell ... 918,726 7,378,278 12.3 19 Canandaigua 607,509 4,929,187 12.2 20 Watertown 2,060,650 16,853,970 12.2 21 Batavia 1,298,537 9,939,843 12.1 22 Albany 13,883,272 109,857,472 11.9 23 Ithaca . . ... 1,337,675 11,181,732 11.7 24 Amsterdam 1,600,277 13,457,056 10.7 25 Oneida Jamestown 524,908 1,975,388 5,064,149 18,800,052 10.3 10.1 26 27 Kingston 1,649,235 16,731,354 9.6 28 Poughkeepsie . . . 2,614,027 27,032,935 9.6 29 Trov 5,637,669 58,240,189 9.6 30 Tonawanda 431,138 5,254,320 8.2 31 Lockport 937,644 11,771,573 7.9 32 North Tonawanda 770,932 9,795,407 7.8 33 Cohoes . . . 1,101,862 13,248,573 7.7 34 Buffalo 26,199,127 365,053,595 7.1 35 Fulton 458,140 6,463,628 7.0 36 Binghamton Dunkirk 2,656,576 699,765 34,703,037 10,165,927 6.9 6.8 37 38 Rochester 14,842,409 220,669,819 6.7 39 Syracuse 9,771,210 146,898,597 6.7 40 Auburn. . 1,508,813 22,539,280 6.6 41 260 STATE OF NEW YORK APPENDIX A VI 1 Concluded CITY Personal property assessment value Total property assessment value Percentage former is of latter Rank of city Elmira $1,680,700 $26,857,606 6.0 42 Schen.6ct8.dy 3 081 392 58,264,632 5.3 43 Corning 442 284 9,272,522 4.7 44 Cortland 867,599 19,259,265 4.5 45 Salamanca 206,656 4,826,842 4.2 46 Rensselaer 171,089 5,935,643 2.9 47 Niagara Falls 1,157,684 37,300,349 2.9 48 Yonkers 3,351,672 117,432,358 2.9 49 Watervliet 157,890 5,850,392 2.7 50 Lackawanna 115,450 7,568,669 1.4 51 New Rochelle 394,661 41,231,942 .95 52 Mount Vernon 342,780 39,921,272 .86 53 APPENDIX A VI 2 TABLE SHOWING NUMBER OF CITIES, THE PERSONAL PROPERTY ASSESSMENT OF WHICH is LESS THAN ONE PER CENT, THREE PER CENT, ETC., RESPECTIVELY, OF THE TOTAL PROPERTY ASSESSMENT. 1. Number of cities the personal property assessment of which is less than 1 per cent of total assessment .... 2. Ditto from 1 to 3 per cent 3. Ditto from 4 to 6 per cent 4. Ditto from 6 to 8 per cent 5. Ditto from 8 to 11 per cent 6. Ditto from 11 to 13 per cent 7. Ditto from 13 to 18 per cent 8. Ditto from 18 to 20 per cent 9. Ditto from 20 to 21 per cent 10. Ditto greater than 21 per cent 2 5 5 10 7 12 5 3 3 1 Total. 53 JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 261 APPENDIX B I PER CAPITA COST OF STATE GOVERNMENT IN THE STATES, 1912'* Per State capita Alabama $2 77 Arizona 6 20 Arkansas 1 87 California 7 98 Colorado 3 46 Connecticut 5 58 Delaware 3 15 District of Columbia 35 45 Florida 3 41 Georgia 1 96 Idaho 7 81 Illinois 2 21 Indiana 2 92 Iowa 2 69 Kansas 2 96 Kentucky 3 33 Louisiana 3 92 Maine 5 84 Maryland 5 27 Massachusetts 7 02 Michigan 4 30 Minnesota 6 66 Mississippi 2 29 Missouri 2 27 Montana . . .... 6 66 Per State capita Nebraska $2 90 Nevada 10 45 New Hampshire 3 41 New Jersey 4 88 New Mexico 3 09 New York 693 North Carolina 1 46 North Dakota 4 84 Ohio 2 63 Oklahoma 1 89 Oregon 4 17 Pennsylvania 3 71 Rhode Island 6 32 South Carolina 1 46 South Dakota 4 60 Tennessee 1 84 Texas 2 97 Utah 6 09 Vermont 6 51 Virginia 3 22 Washington 4 47 West Virginia 2 14 Wisconsin 5 27 Wyoming 5 20 Abstract of special bulletin?, Wealth, Debt and Taxation, 1913, pa?os 44-50. 262 STATE OF NEW YORK CD 10 CO CQ 02 W H M S EH 6 2 8 ^ w (2 If 8 2 W QJ H g n PH to H 3 ' H- g S 1 H :!s a o p ,-1 18 ^ g s 1-1 Q p H ^ n w <^ w t? PH O O CO ej .OCO^OSCOCC^ OQO5<NO O< 050!> OOJO OOOM t -oooot^eo <N -rHiH^CC > t^ O5 O "5 g :S2SS O -OOS-^rH co cO'-iioeo ^ -C<lt^ W -(NrH t^Ot^i-li CO (N i-H lO < OOr-(OiOOO5 CO CO t> CO i-l CO SCO CO (NO-* *CO*<NI^ r-t C<I IO CO CO i-l (N 5< CO 3 ffS CO ) io co I) a JrtCO || g o o COIN JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 263 051 e 5 I g D_, ^ O CO 2 O CO O CO CO > -TH 05 ^ Sg^C^C^S CO CO Tt| r-l Tt< i : ;!!:: COt^OOO'N CO t>- CO CT> i-l O CO ^CO OO-* ** : jj Tt< -COCDOl O O5 T^ CO ^ O CO COCOOOOlN C<1 r-i 1> CD O ** : : 2 :ScS$S : O ' O O CO O cot-coo^oo CD Oi CO t- O 00 CO t- CO CO t-H >O i ,-1 O O CO <N ' is-saas 7 a ssw ^ CO rf< !>. rfi CO 00 t-COCDOOOOO -^ O5 CO CO >O O CO OiOiOOO CO COCO COO i-H COt>CO ^H T}< CO O t>- 00 I-H 03 GO O> CD CO CO -^ O5 3 CO *-* CO 40 i CO COr-iiO H 10 CO ^ * r^ 00 o 2 CO ' r-i O <0 -1 ' (-coco coco o rJH 10 CO CO * OCO>O COCOO5 2 :So!5eoS!-!2 M CO 05 CO SSS2S8S8S3B512S8SS c fi "S v=> o oicoto^ I g S^S !1 1 2 1 3 5 2" ll 11 ,5 S3 |1 |; fe '^ ft, rt W o 3 'S'Sco -S g S ^^" ^ ::s tn O O a; IS ai J 264 STATE OF NEW YOKK O 'f^OSOOrH : : : ^SSSSS I OS -OIOOSCO # : : : :^2^22c^ I 'CMI> b-rH rHrHOrH rH rH 00 T}* IO Tjt TJH OS 00 CO OS <N CO -CMt-rHO - -oooot-r-<N r^l^CO I oo -OIOOSCM rH ;CMrHrHr, (N rH CO 00 00 00 (M CM (N rH rH (N IO 00 ^O (NrHCO 02 10 3 8 iSfcSS OS -COOO rH kO rH .i-HrHCM rH CO OS CD t^ Tj< rH CO CO OO 1O CM CO 10 OS (N O rH T}< CM rH (N (M CM CM H <& 02 o 2 O 'b-iOCOCO * -OCOOSOO t>- OS CM CM rH TH IO CO <*< CM t>- Ttl 1 00 -CO>OO5>O t& ' IO T}< rH (N rH CO CM i-H <N (N CM CM HH ' g S .^cgS t~ <M CD CO 00 CM -eMOSCOCMcOO CO hH h-t cb OS (N CM CM CM CM CO PQ tf o 1 S :2^^2 O -OS CDOO-* . -rHlO^OrHOOS -001>I>l>OOO 1 '. ; co 10 10 co co b- CM CM (N CN rH CO H M w 5 HH 02 g Q Tjt -rHOOO * 00 O -* CO b- 00 & \-^ PH tf -(NrHQOOS CSCOOOIOCO po H B 05 T ~ l M -NrHINrH . . . CO CO OS CM 00 IO CM CM CM CM rH CO PH 8 '. PH PH rH rHt>CSOO 10 -iOTt*<NiO SOS050S>OCO CD O> CO t^- "^ M H OS g j^ScOrH j : ! -CMCMCMWCMCO g H rfl O CO OS CO CO t^ lOCOlNOOOOrH b-iOCOCOOCMrHCOt- 2 O 2 CM rH OS O O IO rH (^ _ JH rH CO rH (M COCOCMCMCOiOCMOSt> ' TO W <o t '43 '^3 o 'o'o co COCOrHCOgg coocb^oSc^^cv; llg CM rH OS c^Sc^S^SS 5!^CO^CMCMr^^ ^^"i ^ 22a CO OS O rH rH CO rH 00 O: CO rH CM rH CO rH CM *CO-<*COrHCM<NrHCO & > > !! fc a : ig : ij 144 iliJ !! o c3 * "S Is ^ O^ QJ ^ " " * I iiiu'ii | i-g.J|| JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 265 APPENDIX B II 4 PEE, CAPITA MUNICIPAL, INDEBTEDNESS FOB MUNICIPAL PURPOSES (LESS SINKING FUND ASSETS) OF THE REMAINING CITIES CITY 1913 1902 1890 Batavia $35 33 $1 96 $4 85 Cohoes. 32 18 30 73 11 30 Corning 33 98 18 88 9 45 Cortland 58 03 32 71 3 75 Dunkirk 24 48 28 93 14 31 Fulton 46 78 57 78 38 Geneva 36 56 39 93 Glens Falls 24 42 29 78 15 25 Gloversville 34 97 19 81 11 00 Hornell 39 47 40 63 Hudson 30 66 28 31 28 31 Ithaca 96 98 20 96 4 05 Jamestown 20 75 25 68 7 79 Kingston . . 37 91 43 29 21 59 Lackawanna 27 39 Little Falls 30 51 39 93 34 73 Lockport 37 33 13 59 15 40 Middletown 30 99 33 30 12 81 Newburgh 44 00 25 63 14 47 North Tonawanda . .... 49 52 75 27 Ogdensburg 27 22 16 11 10 80 Olean 30 86 20 62 13 79 Oneida 28 65 35 12 5 10 Oneonta. 33 69 14 55 6 86 Ossining 72 78 23 91 24 06 Oswego. . . 31 85 47 22 39 83 Peekskill 53 11 26 57 14 97 Plattsburg 28 86 25 35 27 51 Port Chester 53 45 15 35 14 41 Port Jervis 14 24 10 03 Poughkeepsie 67 36 72 60 79 74 Rensselaer ... . '. 30 57 34 04 13 60 Rome 42 44 33 84 10 67 Saratoga Springs 40 26 36 34 25 97 Tonawanda 60 55 56 88 17 63 Watertown 41 15 33 78 15 48 Watervliet 23 65 22 89 15 19 White Plains 140 47 155 55 25 48 SUMMARY (The above includes all the remaining cities except Geneva, Hornell, Lackawanna North Tonawanda and Port Jervis, for which data is lacking for certain years.) Average for 1913 ... $43 . 21878 Average for 1902 33.999 Average for 1890 17.2887 Per cent increase for 1913 over 1890 Per ecnt increase for 1902 over 1890. 149.98 96.65 266 STATE OF NEW YORK APPENDIX B II 5 PEE CAPITA TAXES FOR MUNICIPAL PURPOSES LEVIED ON GEN- ERAL PROPERTY IN REMAINING CITIES CITIES 1913 Batavia $11 85 Cohoes 7 89 Corning : 8 09 Cortland 9 95 Dunkirk 7 98 Fulton 10 07 Geneva 10 42 Glens Falls 10 48 Gloversville 8 76 Hornell 10 47 Hudson 7 55 Ithaca 14 12 Jamestown 11 68 Kingston 11 57 Lackawanna 8 69 Little Falls 6 64 Lockport 14 17 Middletown 11 20 Newburgh 12 29 North Tonawanda 13 11 Ogdensburg 5 46 Olean 10 04 Oneida 8 79 Oneonta 9 47 Ossining 12 03 Oswego 12 31 Peekskill 9 55 Plattsburg 7 15 Port Chester 14 93 Port Jervis 9 75 Poughkeepsie 13 35 Rensselaer 9 65 Rome 8 36 Saratoga Springs 15 34 Tonawanda 13 88 Watertown 12 72 Watervliet 8 45 White Plains. . 21 12 NOTE. Data for the years 1890 to 1912 is lacking. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 267 APPENDIX B II 6 PER CAPITA EXPENDITURES FOR MUNICIPAL PURPOSES IN REMAIN- ING CITIES Cities 1913 Batavia $15 78 Cohoes 11 79 Corning 11 42 Cortland 15 09 Dunkirk 15 03 Fulton 28 34 Geneva 18 75 Glens Falls 14 38 Gloversville 14 50 Hornell , 20 49 Hudson 11 31 Ithaca \ . 20 47 Jamestown 13 17 Kingston 15 71 Lackawanna 19 51 Little Falls 13 93 Lockport 19 29 Middletown 19 46 Newburgh 19 63 North Tonawanda 19 62 Ogdensburg 15 39 Olean 18 51 Oneida 14 58 Oneonta 13 26 Ossining 20 31 Oswego 14 64 Peekskill 14 91 Plattsburg 14 95 Port Chester 18 68 Port Jervis 12 89 Poughkeepsie 30 09 Rensselaer 13 90 Rome 13 43 Saratoga Springs f 18 98 Tonawanda 18 13 Watertown ' 17 13 Watervliet 14 60 White Plains 30 16 NOTE. Data for the years 1890 to 1912 is lacking. 268 STATE OF NEW YOEK HH iz O ^ P I g PH So PLH 9 << H S pi 2 PH O O XJ CC H ^ O " S ^ o E cc | ^ I OQ "H o 1^ o-S PQ V ao S-S d .5 S3 -r5lO C*^ Q, Ilsil 8 f^-l I lift I OK Q : iii! H . +JT300 o3 O -d o oj a, llllfSl S a c< 'S 8 -i Its" Poo" QO $** ^3 "s Hi 11 ^ So O OJ 10 fl II ~ s o * i-l 35 53 .2 ^ ^^ ^1 ** -s^ s ^^ II 8 I * CN (M i-Hr-l S * o o ^ 1C CO Ti cir-T r-T Tj< CO <N GO < r^co 1-1 ( <X f JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 269 "o > Bill* 3 S 2 * <Drj5.-H c3 oj als ?3?il s JOTS ^0* **G -5 *131 o - 83 o* O en 05 O >< o>" *21 M a>S * ^1 1 Pdi5i|pi|;|--3|l |il.i.g:,!liii!s fe *-eS-s% s'fcSoirS 84* a i O O^_ liil l|S|g-S ~r>3 S'sflsf ^S 1 I & !! s f|-s i-gj 8 POO o 0355 a a c c LO oooo c c o o 1) J O O O O C fl fl ooo o sss o o< 5555, 55 5555555555 : ooo o :555555 55 00 OOrHOi-loSoSoS 03 t^ O CO O 05 *J -^ -g -u 10 -iooo<n _2 c3 cs ^. . . - . -T3'dT3 ^> " IO C<1 OO O CO .i .3 ^, .,' 00 $St2SS"c"S g Tfl O O S a a t^ 00 55 55 C<> CO fe S i-H OCSJ rt rt rt Tj< 10 COO g g < 3 - * t~-o : : oo" oo" 55 s s CO CO v 55 i"< (" o oo 88 t o oo iO iO OO * CM OO o" co" co'o" :8 (N CO r-t i-H o S 8 S 270 STATE OF NEW YORK i n b p fc&j 1,88 la -3 it i . ''S a ^ o 5 || r, s.S T3 t^i (H ill s O C && lf|| If *f life -s-i^ c s s|^|2 sSlU ill Oil' T5 ^! *& & *rn l&ssa I OH . O Q O 85? Cj O O5 j O Q,) 5 {fiig 50 55 5 - fc 55 55 3t- S CQQQ P JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 271 APPENDIX D II DOMESTIC CORPORATIONS ASSESSED UNDER SECTION 12 OF THE TAX LAW, IN TOWN OF ESOPUS, COUNTY OF ULSTER, WITH THE AMOUNT OF CAPITAL STOCK AS OBTAINED IN THE OFFICE OF THE SECRETARY OF STATE, AND THE PERSONAL PROPERTY ASSESS- MENTS PLACED ON SUCH DOMESTIC CORPORATIONS BY THE ASSESS- ORS OF THE TOWN Capital stock E 100 $5,000 E 101 10,000,000 E 102 300,000 E 103 30,000 E 104 150,000 E 105 150,000 E 106 201,870 E 107 100,000 E108 200,000 E 109 100,000 E 110 40,000 Bill 15,000 E 112 30,000 E 113 200,000 E 114 300,000 E 115 25,000 E 116 120,000 E 117 200,000 E 118 20,000 E 119 1,000,000 E 120 100,000 E121 250,000 E 122 50,000 E 123 50,000 E 124 85,000 E125 1,000,000 E 126 400,000 E127 5,500,000 E 128 160,000 E129 1,500,000 E130 5,000,000 E131 150,000 E 132 1,200,000 E 134 200,000 E135 150,000 E 136 100,000 E137.. 100,000 Assessment under Section 12 $500 1,800 1,500 400 800 3,000 800 800 500 500 500 300 500 4,000 400 400 500 300 300 8,000 800 800 2,000 1,000 1,500 1,000 1,000 2,000 250 500 500 500 500 500 000 300 1,000 272 STATE OF NEW YORK APPENDIX D II Concluded under Capital stock Section 12 E 138 $30,000 $500 E 139 500 500 E 140 100,000 500 E 141 350,000 1,200 E 142 100,000 500 E 143 500,000 1,500 E 144 150,000 1,000 E 145 10,000 500 E 146 250,000 1,000 E 147 150,000 300 E 148 200,000 750 E 149 135,000 800 E 150 100,000 200 E 151 2,000,000 1,500 $33,257,370 $60,700 SUMMARY OF ABOVE TABLE Number of corporations 51 Aggregate capital stock $33,257,370 Aggregate assessment $60,700 Aggregate assessment as per cent of aggregate capital stock . 18% or less than 1/5 of 1% JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 273 APPENDIX D III DOMESTIC CORPORATIONS ASSESSED UNDER SECTION 12 OF THE TAX LAW, IN TOWN OF WASHINGTON, COUNTY OF DUTCHESS, WITH THE AMOUNT OF CAPITAL STOCK AS OBTAINED IN THE OFFICE OF THE SECRETARY OF STATE, AND THE PERSONAL PROPERTY ASSESSMENT PLACED ON SUCH DOMESTIC CORPORATIONS BY THE ASSESSORS OF THE TOWN Assessment Designation of under corporation Capital stock Section 12 D 101 $2,000,000 $100,000 D 102 50,000 1,000 D 103 120,000 3,000 D 104 16,000,000 50,000 D 105 1,000 500 D 106 17,500,000 150,000 D 107 300,000 500 D 108 :... 100,000 5,000 D 109 1,000,000 5,000 D 110 50,000 2,500 D 111 30,000 1,000 D 112 10,000 500 D 113 150,000 1,000 D 114 50,000 1,000 D 115 1,000,000 50,000 D 116 100,000 1,000 D 117 100,000 1,000 D 118 No record 2,000 D 119 1,750,000 30,000 D 120 250,000 5,000 D 121 1,000,000 1,000 D 122 250,000 500 D 123 200,000 5,000 D 124 500,000 500 D 125 1,500,000 500 D 126 100,000 1,000 D 127 50,000 1,000 D 128 180,000 3,000 D 129 i 100,000 10,000 D 130 ** 25,000 500 D 131 50,000 1,000 D 132 400,000 1,000 D 133 1,200,000 500 D 134 1,125,000 500 D 135 1,500,000 15,000 D 136 100,000 10,000 D 137 500,000 3,000 274 STATE OF NEW YORK APPENDIX D III Concluded Designation of corporation D 138 D 139 D 140 D 141 D 142 D 143... Capital stock $400,000 2,000,000 1,000 60,000 400,000 100,000 Assessment under Section 12 $10,000 500 1,000 1,000 500 500 SUMMARY Number of corporations 43 Aggregate capital stock $52,302,000 Aggregate assessment $477 , 500 Aggregate assessment as per cent of capital stock . 91% or less than 1% JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 275 !!! ISsll 11^ 5 3 H K04g o Q H 3- 1 13 I pd W ,*" r^ P^ O H O <J PH < PH PH M P? 6 H 3 tc O H H O o a a H H 8 8 S 1 8 8 8 ii 276 STATE OF NEW YORK ll-'l- Jp-l If fil ! ll^l^ ^3^- iJs^lsllifl' -gT)25-2-g'^^^o-2 PH PH C IP *| ^ -^3is S || s |il a EH EH H '1 o3 ^S2 i^ii 1 1 88 8 88 1 1 JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 2Y7 Jf w M w ; g pll!lfl,Pj:^;ii-i^.!i^^i j|5llllli1|iils|| fflilfllllf ^ , j| o ( ^ H83 ^ 8 S 8 8 278 STATE OF NEW YORK Q w OQ 5 6 o <1 o S S s I t s I! O g u Ifi 28 a -2 O T3 t-i *> o -2r o~" rt -pH< -' as a) lot il Hill i 1J 03 00 <U O< ' - ..0,3 m o I s s 8 8 8 8 Q ^ 1 8 8 8 JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 279 ;i s*ijr aS|Si| Iftlli -S^^3i |3SS3; H 21 llflli Kf'sa'jj 5 4B 3'Js* sJlliS Ss'B'sfcSi *lifiJ SwfcSgo ijjlislli 1 111 11 .-o o fc5 !"-!< o< m ..."S O aa M s a 8 o io-^S, ?-00 - a-- fifflll ^.S a -|^Sg roll m iSII? 5-sIssSs:-|||l^'s| 2 -|gi^ s is H H H "H ' ^ 8 8 i 8 8 | ca i 8 i 8 8 8 8 888 COCOi-H i-HN 280 STATE OF NEW YORK 86? r 28 88 I 8 - 5 If, IP. 38 S 88 41! 888 8 : :8 88 8 888 21 OOOS CNlOCO t^OCO <N~rH 8 8 888 CO t^t Ol ** 00 eoioco JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 281 T3 -2 ^ & Jls 8*1 8 a 8 * o^co^^g SSg-g-g-ggg^a -S < . n ioZ^2 com ._ ~,,jE3 8 a S?2 ^ si ^ifcp^iflg^ig!^ 8 . 00 00 CO C5 CO (N !& &s: c^ oo o o Tj< o ^ . CO t^ D 1C I s * O O B '"i C V Tt< % X s i 8 8 1 ! "<N" CO g 5 ss II o CO ^ 1C co 8 8 8 00 03 00 CO iO N i 00 ~ QO* TH W t2 o M 5 CO 00 eo i I CO g 8 8 8 8 :8 8 8 10 o 2 rH 00* i 8 8 i I 8 8 8 88 8 o o o 8 8 J 00 E 8 CO c * * to l> J ^ y ^ K'S' ^ ,4 03 c 03 2 O303 03 2 i r^ 00 co *fi s CO-* coco CO i CO 282 STATE OF NEW YORK APPENDIX D VI 1 BONDED DEBT OF THIRTY-SIX DOMESTIC MANUFACTURING CORPORA- TIONS TAKEN AT EANDOM Designation of Bonded Capital stock corporation debt* outstanding B.D. 1 $2,000,000 $3,896,000 B. D. 2 433,000 500,000 B.D. 3 3,164,000 9,325,000 B.D. 4 12,067,500 101,485,700 B.D. 5 500,000 500,000 B.D. 6 17,426,234 20,359,000 B.D. 7 .21,399,834 39,849,500 B. D. 8 640,000 789,500 B.D. 9 3,414,500 4,907,000 B.D. 10 41,313,000 34,756,000 B.D. 11 7,743,728 10,000,000 B.D. 12 375,000 500,000 B.D. 13 1,785,000 15,000,000 B.D. 14 822,000 4,000,000 B.D. 15 851,612 500,000 B.D. 16 125,000 500,000 B.D. 17 3,800,000 2,500,000 B.D. 18 3,000,000 7,924,700 B.D. 19 1,038,277 2,000,000 B.D. 20 600,000 600,000 B.D. 21 95,000 328,300 B.D. 22 11,335,100 6,000,000 B.D. 23 500,000 500,000 B. D. 24 614,550 3,135,161 B.D. 25 4,000,000 15,000,000 B.D. 26 225,000 600,000 B. D. 27 2,765,000 1,000,000 B.D. 28 2,080,000 6,800,000 B.D. 29 740,200 2,300,000 B.D. 30 1,497,963 1,600,000 B.D. 31 1,500,000 1,250,000 B. D. 32 5,123,350 8,554,425 B.D. 33 1,500,000 1,000,000 B.D. 34 6,850,000 2,410,000 B.D. 35 100,000 1,011,000 B.D. 36 273,048 571,000 SUMMARY Aggregate bonded debt $161,697,896 Aggregate capital stock outstanding 311,952,286 Bonded debt as per cent of capital stock 51.8% In some cases notes payable are included. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 283 APPENDIX D VI 2 BONDED DEBT OF THIRTY-EIGHT DOMESTIC MERCANTILE AND MIS- CELLANEOUS CORPORATIONS SELECTED Designation of Bonded Capital stock corporation debt* outstanding B. M. 1 $2,700,000 $5,000,000 B. M. 2 19,593,900 10,084,00 B. M. 3 3,550,000 4,000,000 B. M. 4 2,500,000 2,000,000 B. M. 5 5,000,000 5,000,000 B. M. 6 700,000 750,000 B. M. 7 7,540,072 10,457,200 B. M. 8 2,969,500 3,665,800 B. M. 9 1,900,000 1,357,500 B. M. 10 2,000,000 2,000,000 B. M. 11 4,027,000 3,500,000 B. M. 12 10,000,000 2,000,000 B. M. 13 9,200,000 6,000,000 B. M. 14 1,500,000 2,942,750 B. M. 15 1,100,000 9,800,000 B. M. 16 4,193,000 3,000,000 B. M. 17 1,004,871 740,200 B. M. 18 3,025,000 22,755,000 B. M. 19 4,809,958 2,000,000 B. M. 20 2,960,141 248,103 B. M. 21 1,200,000 1,000,000 B. M. 22 2,720,000 2,250,000 B. M. 23 954,633 1,000,000 B. M. 24 446,500 300,000 B. M. 25 3,000,000 1,700,000 B. M. 26 1,857,781 6,900,000 B. M. 27 352,000 375,000 B. M. 28 3,700,950 10,500,000 B. M. 29 750,000 1,000,000 B. M. 30 380,375 565,600 B. M. 31 75,750 198,500 B. M. 32 156,500 249,600 B. M. 33 4,797,215 7,395,100 B. M. 34... 769,000 1,180,400 B. M. 35 487,500 400,000 B. M. 36 3,649,871 6,000,000 B.M.37 220,000 900,000 B. M. 38 2,277,690 3,977,000 SUMMARY Aggregate bonded debt $118,069,207 Aggregate capital stock outstanding 143,191,753 Bonded debt as per cent of capital stock 82.4% * In some cases notes payable are included. 284 STATE OF NEW YORK APPENDIX D VII SELECTED LIST OF DOMESTIC CORPORATIONS WITH GOOD WILL OF GREAT VALUE Designation of Capital stock corporation Good will outstanding Total assets G. W. 1 $15,000,000 $19,300,000 $21,623,840 G. W. 2 600,000 1,000,000 2,115,563 G. W. 3 7,500,000 9,800,000 12,202,852 G. W. 4 5,664,000 9,145,000 14,081,332 G. W. 5 1,000,000 3,000,000 3,937,286 G. W. 6 5,000,000 7,850,000 9,080,957 G. W. 7 15,525,310 22,755,000 31,314,167 G. W. 8 12,000,000 17,000,000 19,084,009 G. W. 9 7,451,448 9,875,000 10,446,802 G. W. 10 500,000 945,000 1,461,654 G. W. 11 7,000,000 10,000,000 10,809,428 G. W. 12 3,874,965 5,800,000 6,002,213 G. W. 13 7,499,600 10,500,000 14,686,162 G. W. 14 3,000,000 7,395,100 12,960,426 G. W. 15 600,000 1,000,000 1,413,786 G. W. 16 4,000,000 6,800,000 8,994,505 G. W. 17 50,000,000 64,000,000 74,444,730 G. W. 18 878,792 1,010,000 1,047,131 G. W. 19 1,080,258 900,000 1,158,728 G. W. 20 386,138 3,034,070 3,651,142 G. W. 21 2,637,309 3,450,000 4,541,708 G. W. 22 3,023,983 8,000,000 10,045,729 G. W. 23 1,524,752 1,000,000 3,937,911 G. W. 24 4,966,365 9,900,000 14,144,547 G. W. 25 9,786,065 14,647,200 19,236,468 G. W. 26 18,000,000 26,000,000 21,936,638 G. W. 27 17,947,142 10,457,200 21,511,644 G. W. 28 1,794,342 2,075,000 3,109,241 G. W. 29 8,025,000 10,250,500 14,980,831 G. W. 30 2,800,000 3,656,526 G. W. 31 1,575,000 7,480,000 8,308,073 G. W. 32 500,000 900,000 2,006,331 G. W. 33 3,000,000 5,000,000 7,188,292 G. W. 34 5,100,000 6,200,000 7,270,292 G. W. 35 58,380,902 89,100,000 94,936,954 SUMMARY Aggregate good will. . . $287,651,371 Aggregate capital stock outstanding 405,569,070 Aggregate total assets. . 497,327,898 Aggregate good will as per cent of capital stock 70.9% Aggregate good will as per cent of total assets 57.8% JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 285 05iCi-liOt>C<>fOOiOO^-lrH05CO>Ot^C01>O-*CDOlT}*l^t>O-*'-HCO(NC>000 CO'OCDTj(tTtlTj<COWC'<i<C3l>CDCC)'*OCOlOTticDC^r}<^'<tl'*tOiOCOOOO CO "5 CO C<J <N 00 O5 riO 00>C(NCO OCO^OJOOrH^T^CO'OOr-iiOCO-^OO'tii-HOCO'-i-rticOCJOCO-^-^'-HO .eooTfo>i>t*iQOoSic5oioeoooo '-'- ^i-iiO(rOO'-iCCOi-l(NOOO^fiCs|-^iO5i-iCCCOiOt^-Tt<l--'COt^Or-i(N'*Tj< 00 ^1 00 M Oi <N (N 00 l> l> rH O <N 05 X t> 10 * O ^H --1 IN 00 <> rH Oi IN iO KCS 3 C<3r^ fl H * T' i-HOi^CO l GCIOC01 (l >-TT'- OOC>if3C300(Nt-rtt03'-l'S<Tt<T}tiOOOOOT-ieOI>CDeCT-iT-i<NCOOO CO C g. g 286 STATE OF NEW YOBK O I > )^HT^C s J l O"<^Tt<l N "00'^O}CDCOi ' *t*l*-Oi 5CO^ T -(OtN.iCcOCO(NCOGOCX)^COfHOOO SSS^S^rqgggrSSSS^^ >i-HCOGOi-H^OOrHOCOCOiO*Cl s '^C^C&'^ "i-T N COi-^OO i : 11 rH N 3 a *o M a 05" c oo Illflll flttl 3 MJ9 : 1* g JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 287 APPENDIX E IV TABLE SHOWING THE AMOUNT OF THE $38,000,000 INCOME TAX THAT WOULD BE RETURNED BY THE STATE TO EACH COUNTY, IF THIS TAX WERE APPORTIONED TO EACH COUNTY ACCORD- ING TO THE RATIO OF THE ASSESSED VALUE OF REAL ESTATE IN THE COUNTY TO THE AGGREGATE ASSESSED VALUE OF REAL ESTATE IN ALL THE COUNTIES. COUNTIES Assessed value of real estate, including village property, real estate of cor- porations and special fran- chises Percentage such assess- ment for each county is of the entire assessment for the State Amount of the $38,000,000 yield of the income tax allocated to each county Albany $135,306,349 Per cent 1 2 $456 000 21 229 483 19 72 200 50 121 967 44 16 720 Cattaraugus 35,174 263 31 117 800 41 389 501 37 140 600 Chautauqua 61,185,310 54 205 200 Chemung 34,595,626 31 117 800 16 472 864 14 53 200 Clinton 10,018,340 08 30,400 26,561 393 23 87 400 Cortland 17 012 221 15 57 000 Delaware 15,738,848 14 53,200 66 010 836 59 224 200 Erie 407 595 886 3 65 1 387 000 Essex 14,851,302 13 49,400 Franklin 13,050 904 11 41 800 Fulton 16 456 624 14 53 200 Genesee 28,040,502 25 95,000 12 737,958 11 41,800 Hamilton 4,916,732 044 16,720 Herkimer . . 34,877,231 31 117,800 46 354 589 41 155,800 Lewis 10,970,233 0.09 34,200 Livingston . . 27,240,601 24 91,200 21,234 613 19 72,200 Monroe Montgomery 271,783,213 29 , 857 , 687 2.43 26 923,400 98,800 105,222 041 94 357,200 New York (Greater) [including Bronx, New York, Kings, Queens and Richmond coun- ties] 8,049,859 912 72 22 27,443,600 Niagara 75,606,856 81,264,851 0.67 72 254,600 273,600 182 864 850 1 64 623,200 Ontario 35,792,695 0.32 121,600 53,978,477 48 182,400 28,078 172 25 95,000 Oswego 33,521,007 0.30 114,000 Otsego 24,256,890 0.21 79,800 Putnam 13,707,606 0.12 45,600 Rensselaer 83,081,895 0.74 281,200 Rockland 33,302,423 29 110,200 Saint Lawrence 45,787,133 0.41 155,800 Saratoga . . . . 28,178,422 0.25 95,000 64,953,520 0.58 220,400 Schoharie 11,724,504 0.10 38,000 Schuyler 6,723,745 0.06 22,800 17,078,374 15 57,000 Steuben 43,480,842 0.39 148,200 Suffolk 92,063,939 0.82 311,600 Sullivan . . 7,119,881 0.06 22,800 288 STATE OF NEW YORK APPENDIX F IV Concluded COUNTIES Assessed value of real estate, including village property, real estate of cor- porations and special fran- chises Percentage such assess- ment for each county is of the entire assessment for the State Amount of the $38,000,000 yield of the income tax allocated to each county Tioga . $13,860,147 Per cent 12 $45 600 Tompkins 20,641,257 18 68 400 Ulster 32,904,296 29 110 200 Warren 16,012 611 14 53 200 20,462,596 18 68 400 Wayne 32,654,979 29 110 200 Westchester 389,896,028 3 49 1 326 200 19,795,811 17 64 600 Yates 11,610,176 0.10 38 000 Total $11,146,271,012 99,734 $37 898 920 . JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION APPENDIX F V ESTIMATE OF POSSIBLE YIELD OF STAMP TAXES ON CHECKS, NOTES, BILLS OF EXCHANGE AND OTHER LEGAL INSTRUMENTS IN NEW YORK STATE For the purpose of estimating the possible yield of stamp taxes in New York State the Committee caused to be made a study of the following : first, the stamp taxes in France, Germany and the United Kingdom; and second, the Federal stamp taxes in the United States (a) during the Civil War, (b) during the Spanish- American War and (c) under the present Federal Emergency Revenue A,ct. With few exceptions, the data obtained concerning France, England and Germany was of little value for purposes of estimat- ing the possible yield of such taxes in the United States. The taxes in these countries are levied upon many miscellaneous sources, and a number of these important sources is already reached in the State of New York by other forms of taxation. With the exception of a few of the German figures the Committee found it impossible to use the foreign figures for even an approximate estimate. Out of the complexity of the German system we may select the follow- ing figures as offering the easiest basis of a comparison. The total revenue receipts from bills of exchange, promissory notes, etc., in all Germany (Federal Tax) are as follows: 1909 $4,661,250 1910 4,684,250 1911 4,670,250 1912 4,865,250 1913 4,780,500 The total revenue receipts from the tax on checks in all Ger- many (Federal Tax) was as follows: 1909 $751,000 1910 890,000 1911 777,250 1912 779,500 1913 784,000 10 290 STATE or NEW YORK Because of the complexity of the German rates it is impossible to estimate even with rough accuracy what such a tax might yield in New York State. In considering the above tables it should, of course, be borne in mind that the amount of revenue in each case represents the aggre- gate for the entire German Empire. In any case New York State could not hope to obtain an amount representing anything like the yield of the German tax upon these particular sources. CIVIL WAR STAMP TAXES During the Civil War, the Federal Government levied stamp taxes upon the following fifteen miscellaneous sources : First: Agreement of contract, 5c. Second: Bank checks, 2c. Third: Bills of exchange, inland, varying from 5e, upon bills of $100, to $1.50 upon bills from $2,500 to $5,000. Fourth : Foreign bills of exchange at approximately same rates as inland. Fifth: Bills of lading, lOc. Sixth: Express company receipts, Ic and 2c. Seventh: Bonds, 50c. Eighth: Certificates of stock from lOc upward. Ninth: Charter party $3.00 to $10.00. Tenth: Broker's note, lOc. Eleventh: Conveyance of deed varying from 50c when con- sideration is less than $500 to $20, when consideration is $20,000. Twelfth: Telegraphic dispatch from Ic to 3c. Thirteenth: Lease, 50c to $1.00. Fourteenth: Power of attorney, 25c. Fifteenth: Probate of will, 50 cents to $1.00. In addition to the above taxes we also levied upon entry of goods at customs house, life insurance policies, marine insurance policies, protest and other legal documents. The yield of these taxes from 1863 to 1870 is given below, in round numbers, and, for purposes of comparison, the yield of the Federal Income Taxes for the same years: JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 291 Year Stamp Taxes Income Taxes 1863 . . . . $4,100,000 $455,000 1864 5,900,000 14,900,000 1865 11,200,000 20,600,000 1866 15,000,000 60,900,000 1867 16,100,000 64,900,000 1868 14,900,000 34,100,000 1869 15,000,000 34,600,000 1870 15,600,000 36,600,000 No record has been kept of the yield of the stamp taxes by states. However, a very rough idea of this yield in New York State may be obtained by comparing it with the yield of other federal taxes in New York State. The following table shows the percentage of the total yield of the Federal Income Taxes and of the Internal Revenue Taxes collected in New York State; Year Income Taxes 1864 33 per cent. 1865 30 per cent. 1866 30 per cent. 1867 31 per cent. 1868 30 per cent. 1869 31 per cent 1870 28 per cent. Internal Revenue Taxes 24 per cent. 24 per cent. 24 per cent. 24 per cent. 22 per cent. 25 per cent. 22 per cent. Average 31 per cent. 24 per cent. From the above it would seem fair to assume that New York's share of the total amount raised by the Federal Government from stamp taxes would be not less than 24 per cent, at that time. This percentage is, of course, of no importance except as it may be used to check up later estimates of the percentage of the Spanish War taxes collected in New York State. 292 STATE OF NEW YORK STAMP TAXES LEVIED DURING THE SPANISH-AMERICAN WAR PERIOD During the Spanish-American War, the Federal Government levied stamp taxes on the following twenty-one miscellaneous sources; bonds, certificates of stock, sales or agreements to sell, bank checks, certificates of deposits, bills of exchange, bills of lading, telephone messages, indemnity bonds, certificates of pro- test, brokers' contracts, conveyances, telegraph dispatches, various forms of insurance, leases, manifests for customs house entry, mortgages, foreign steamship tickets, power of attorney, protests and warehouse receipts. With few exceptions the sources taxed, as well as the rates, were substantially the same as the Civil War taxes. In a few cases the Civil War taxes were higher than the Spanish-American War taxes. The total yield of these taxes for the entire country for the years 1898 to 1901 were as follows: 1898 $724,073 *1899 38,618,081 1900 36,416,082 1901 34,998,836 As in the case of the Civil War stamp taxes, no record has been kept of the yield of the stamp taxes for this period by states. We may, however, roughly approximate the yield of these taxes in New York. In the following tables we give the total internal revenue col- lected in the United States, the amount collected in New York State, and the percentage of the total collected in New York State for the years 1895 to 1903: Internal Revenue Internal Revenue Per cent collected Year United States New York in New York 1895 $143,246,077 $19,090,723 13 per cent. 1896 146,830,615 21,620,471 15 per cent. 1897 146,619,593 18,420,767 13 per cent. 1898 170,866,819 21,058,569 12 per cent. * The taxes went into effect July 1, 1898. JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 293 Internal Revenue Internal Revenue Per cent collected Year United StaUs New York in New York 1899 273,484,573 46,634,981 17 per cent. 1900 295,316,108 46,475,135 16 per cent. 1901 306,871,669 49,789,698 16 per cent. 1902 271,867,990 38,694,831 14 per cent. 1903 230,740,925 26,749,648 12 per cent. An examination of the above table discloses the fact that the total internal revenue receipts increased after the imposition of the war taxes by approximately $100,000,000. . This increased yield was due not only to the stamp taxes, but also to the increased rates upon the normal sources of internal revenue. At best we can attribute not more than $75,000,000 of the increase to the federal stamp taxes. The percentage of the total revenue taxes collected in New York from 1895 to 1903 averaged about 13 per cent. If we assume that this percentage would hold for that part of the internal revenue taxes collected from the stamp taxes the yield of stamp taxes in New York State during the Spanish-American War period would have been about $10,000,000. This estimate is probably too high, and at best it can be said to be only very rough. STAMP TAXES UNDER THE FEDERAL EMERGENCY REVENUE ACT The present Emergency Revenue Law imposes stamp duties on the following fifteen miscellaneous sources : I. Documents Subject to Stamp Duties and Rates 1. Bonds, debentures or certificates of indebtedness on each $100 face value or fraction thereof 5c 2. Sales or agreements to sell per $100 face value. ... 5c 3. Sales of products at exchanges per $100 Ic 4. Promissory notes: Not exceeding $100 2c Each additional $100 2c 5. Express or freight shipments on manifest or bill of lading Ic 6. Telegraph and telephone messages : Where charge is over 1.5 cents Ic 294 STATE OF NEW YORK 7. Indemnity bonds 50c 8. Certificates of profits per $100 face value 2e Of marine damages. . . 25c Of any other description lOe 9. Contract, brokers' note or memorandum of sale of any goods or merchandise, stocks, bonds, etc lOc 10. Conveyances of real property, when consideration is greater than $100 and less than $500 50c For each additional $500 50c 11. Custom house entries when value of goods is less than $100 25c Between $100 and $500 50e Entry or withdrawal of any goods from bonded ware- house 50c 12. Foreign Passage Tickets: Exceeding $10 in value $1 00 Between $30 and $60 300 Greater than $60 5 00 13. Power of attorney or proxy lOe General power of attorney 25c 14. Protest 25c 15. Seats in palace or parlor car le The yield of these taxes for the period beginning December 1, 1914 and ending June 20, 1915 was $20,494,475. This covers of course only seven months. Assuming that the tax will continue to yield at the same rate we should receive for the entire year approximately $35,000,000. Assuming that the New York per- centage of the total internal revenue receipts during the Spanish War period would hold for the present Federal Emergency Revenue Tax, namely 16 per cent., we may estimate that stamp taxes equivalent to the present federal stamp , taxes would pro- duce approximately $5,600,000. CONCLUSIONS TO BE DRAWN FROM THE ABOVE. In attempting to use the statistics of the yield of stamp taxes of France, England, Germany, and the Civil War period in the United States we found so many conditions substantially different from those in New York at the present time that it was necessary JOINT LEGISLATIVE COMMITTEE ON TAXATION 295 to make so many assumptions as to vitiate the value of our esti- mates based upon these sources. We must fall back, therefore, upon the results of the Spanish- American War taxes and the pres- ent Federal Emergency taxes. We find that in 1898, under one of the most drastic stamp duties ever imposed, New York's share of the total collection could not have exceeded $10,000,000. Since stamp duties imposed by the State could never hope to cover such a broad range of items, it would be too much to hope that the State of New York could raise as much as $10,000,000. Should the State duplicate the present Federal Emergency Revenue Act it could not hope to raise more than $5,600,000. 35625 679528 UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA LIBRARY