^^ LIBRARY OF THE UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA. GIKT OF" TAXATION ITS PRINCIPLES AND METHODS TRANSLATED FROM THE "SCIENZA DELLE FINANZE" DR. LUIGI COSSA n PROFESSOR IN THE UNIVERSITY OF PAVIA, ITALY WITH AN INTRODUCTION AND NOTES BY HORACE WHITE TOGETHER WITH A COMPILATION OF THE STATE TAX SYSTEMS OF NEW YORK AND PENNSYLVANIA NEW YORK & LONDON G. P. PUTNAM'S SONS &|je Jlnkherbocbr JJnw 1888 COPYRIGHT, 1888, BY HORACEWHITE. INTRODUCTION. THE author of this treatise kindly sent me a copy of it in the year 1882. I had become interested in his work, through his " Guide to the Study of Political Economy," introduced to English readers by the late Professor Jevons. I, accordingly, had a translation of the Scienza delle Finanze made for my own use, but without any fixed intention of publishing it. The admirable brevity and compre- hensiveness of Professor Cossa's statement of the principles of taxation, and the light thrown on the evolution of the science of public finance, and the want of any short treatise of similar scope in the English language, led me to believe that it would find an appreciative audience in this country. But the time did not then appear to be favorable. During the past three or four years there has been a marked revival of interest in economic dis- cussion, as is shown by the number of new works by American writers that have come from the press in that interval, and by the formation and regular meetings of two distinctively economic so- cieties. Notwithstanding the shaking up that Po- litical Economy has received in recent years, which iv INTRODUCTION. some people think has reduced the whole science to chaos, it is certain that it never had so many active, intelligent and persevering votaries in this country as now. Even those who consider the science a chaos always talk and write as though there were a considerable and pretty firm founda- tion to build on. It is evident, too, that the public are taking a more general interest than formerly in the sub- ject of taxation in all its bearings. Hardly a year passes that some State Tax Commission is not working on the problems of local revenue, while the question of national revenue, or perhaps we might better say national non-revenue, is the ab- sorbing one in Washington City. This work does not deal with customs duties except in their fiscal aspect. The dispute be- tween protection and free trade is not touched upon, since the aim of protection is not to pro- vide means for the support of government, but something quite different. The science of the finances does not deal with things which incident- ally affect the revenue. A dry season may do that, but dryness and wetness are not financial considerations. While the tariff question, as it popularly presents itself, is not touched upon, the effects of taxes on imports, upon different classes in the community, are made sufficiently clear. A few notes have been added to the text in INTRODUCTION. V order to give local application and local interest to the abstract principles stated. For the same reason there has been added an appendix, giving in as brief form as possible the State tax systems of New York and Pennsylvania as they stand to- day. A compilation of the tax systems of all the other States would be interesting and valuable, but I would not advise anybody to undertake the task unless he has a great deal of unemployed time to dispose of. A two-fold evolution is now going on in State taxation. There is a movement in the first place to drop real estate from the list of State taxables, and to remit it wholly to the lesser political sub- divisions, the cities, towns and counties. There is also a movement to discontinue the attempt to tax floating capital, money at interest and the like, and to look only to those things which can always be found and which cannot get away, for the revenue of the State proper. Pennsylvania led the way in releasing real estate from State tax- ation. That State also led the way in adopting scientific rules for the taxation of corporations, although the system is still far from perfect. Further information will be found in the note on Taxation of Corporations. Although the current has always run strongly in this country in favor of the taxation of movable personal property, and even yet affords a favorite vi INTRODUCTION. theme for windy declamation, I am convinced that that particular tax will slowly but surely disap- pear. The State of *New York scarcely pretends to collect the personal property tax, although her laws require its collection. Other States that pretend to collect it meet with little better success, although they do cause a great deal of false swearing and hard feeling. The latest official report on this subject that can be called comprehensive is that submitted by Dr. R. T. Ely, of the Maryland Tax Commission. What he finds and what he says about the taxation of personal property coincides with the views of nearly all the accredited teachers of fiscal science in this country. It is true that Dr. Ely's col- leagues on the Maryland Tax Commission do not agree with him on this point. In the first place, the Constitution of the State of Maryland re- quires that all property shall be taxed equally. But if it were otherwise, the majority of the Com- mission would still be in favor of taxing movable personal property. But they are in favor of ex- empting mortgages from taxation, although this is almost the only form of floating capital that can always be identified and located without any chance of error. The report of this Commission came to hand after the body of this work had gone to press. There was accordingly very little opportunity to INTRODUCTION. Vll avail of its certainly valuable investigations. One novel recommendation of the majority is that Maryland shareholders of foreign corporations be taxed or not taxed on their shares according as the State where the corporation is domiciled does or does not tax her own citizens holding shares of Maryland corporations. This translation of Professor Cossa's Scienza delle Finanze was- made originally by Mr. A. H. Gumlogsen, who is now, I believe, a resident of Chicago. The translator's want of acquaintance with the terms in use in Political Economy made extensive revision necessary. This was kindly un- dertaken by my friend, Mr. S. Dana Horton, to whom my thanks are due in an especial manner. While the work was going through the press, I learned that Mr. Eugene Schuyler and his nephew, Mr. Louis Bedell Grant the latter, United States Consular clerk at St. Gall, Switzerland were translating the same work into English for publica- tion. I at once offered to surrender the honors to Mr. Schuyler together with the work already done, but he declined the offer and kindly undertook to revise the proofs by the help of his own transla- tion, and the same were accordingly forwarded to him for that purpose. In the fourth edition of Professor Cossa's work it is stated that it had already been translated into the German, Swedish, Polish, Russian and Spanish languages. Vlll INTRODUCTION. A few additions have been made to Professor Cossa's Bibliography of the science. I am aware that further additions might be made, especially of works in the English language. Thanks are due to the Hon. Alfred C. Chapin, ex-Comptroller of New York, and to Mr. Frank M. Eastman, law clerk in the office of the Aud- itor-General of Pennsylvania, for quite invaluable assistance in compiling the tax systems of their respective States. H. W. NEW YORK, February, 1888. TABLE OF CONTENTS. Introduction iii PART I. PRELIMINARY CONCEPTS. Chapter I. Idea, Limits and Character of the Science of the Finances I II. Sources, Divisions and Importance of the Science of the Finances 3 III. Historical Data of the Science of the Finances 5 PART II. PUBLIC EXPENDITURES. Chapter I. The Idea of Public Expenditures , II II. Public Expenditure in its Juridical, Political and Economical Aspects 13 III. Classification of Public Expenditures 17 ii PART III. PUBLIC INCOME. Section I. Original Public Income 24 Chapter I. The Idea and Division of the Fiscal Domain 24 II. Administration of the Fiscal Domain 27 III. Sale of the Fiscal Domain 30 Section II. Derivative Public Income 35 Chapter I. Idea, Reason and Form of Fees, Costs and Charges. . . 36 II. Charges arising in Matters of Judicial Cognizance ... 39 i. Court Costs. ..' 39 2. Fees for Certification and Registration 41 3. Collection of Charges arising from Matters of Judicial Cognizance 42 X v TABLE OF CONTENTS. PAGE Chapter III. Charges on the Means of Exchange and Transport. ... 45 i. On Coinage 45 2. On Weights and Measures and on Marking 47 3. On Railways, Posts and Telegraphs 48 IV. Idea, Reason and Rules of General Taxation 50 i. Juridical Rules 51 2. Economic Rules 58 3. Political Rules 60 V. Repercussion of Taxes 62 VI. Classification of Taxes , ". 64 VII. Objective Imposts on the Produce of Real Property. . . 69 I. Imposts on the Produce of Land 69 2. Imposts on the Rent of Buildings 75 VIII. Personal Imposts on Income derived from Movable Property 78 i. Imposts on Income derived from Capital 79 2. Imposts on Personal Income 85 3. Imposts on Industrial Income 88 IX. Indirect Imposts on Transfers of Ownership 92 i. Imposts on Transfers made upon Valuable Con- sideration 93 2. Imposts on Gratuitous Transfers 95 3. Imposts in lieu of Transfer Tax 98 X. Indirect Taxes on Consumption 99 i. Classification of Imposts on Consumption.. . . ... 100 2. Fiscal Monopolies 103 3. Imposts x>n Manufacture and Sale 106 4. Internal Customs Duties (Octroi) 108 5. Customs Duties 109 6. Imposts of Immediate Collection 113 XI. Direct Imposts on Income and on Property in General. 116 i. General Tax on Incomes 116 2. General Imposts on the Entire Estate of the Tax- payer 122 XII. Comparison of Direct with Indirect Taxes ... 125 XIII. Comparison between the Multiple Tax System and the Single Tax System 128 XIV. Local Taxes 133 Note on Taxation of Mortgages 136 Note on Taxation of Personal Property 139 TABLE OF CONTENTS. XI PAGE Note on Taxation of Corporations 143 Note on Taxation of " Land Values " 147 Note on Taxes on Consumption 150 PART IV. THE RELATION BETWEEN PUBLIC RECEIPTS AND EXPENDITURES. Chapter I. General Ideas 153 II. The Public Debt 156 III. Floating Debt 160 i. Classification of the Floating Debt 160 2. Paper Money 164 IV. Consolidated Debt 166 i. Redeemable Debt 166 2. Irredeemable Debt 170 V. Administration of the Public Debt 173 i. Negotiation f . , 173 2. Extinction 176 3. Conversion 178 BIBLIOGRAPHY OF THE SCIENCE OF THE FINANCES 181 APPENDIX. Existing Tax Systems of New York and Pennsylvania 195 New York State 1 196 New York City 201 Pennsylvania 202 The Pennsylvania Tax Commission Bill 211 PART I. TAXATION ITS PRINCIPLES AND METHODS. CHAPTER I. IDEA, LIMITS AND CHARACTER OF THE SCIENCE OF THE FINANCES. MEN unite together and constitute domestic, civil and political society for the purpose of preserving and perfecting their physical, intellectual and moral faculties, as well as of attaining the highest ends of existence. The principal forms of political society are the municipality, the province and the state, each of which possesses a judicial constitution and arrange- ment of its own, and which are severally governed by authorities which represent, defend and promote their interests and provide for the public needs. In order to be able to fulfill such duties the sev- eral bodies politic have need of a sufficient amount of exchangeable material property (wealth) ; they must therefore create a special property or estate (patrimonio), which is called the public estate, from the public character of the bodies that dispose of it. 2 TAXA TIONITS PRINCIPLES AND METHODS. By public estate is understood that portion of the national resources which is set apart by law to provide for the wants of the government and of lesser political societies (the province, the munici- pality). The public estate, which .comprises the fiscal domain and the proceeds of taxation, both general and local, must not be confounded with the property of private individuals, or, in the case of a monarchy, with that of the sovereign. The Science of the Finances is the body of prin- ciples which relate to the public estate {patrimonio). It teaches the best method of establishing, manag- ing and using it. The object of the Science of the Finances is common with that of other financial studies, which also deal with the public estate, but regard it from a different point of view. Such are the history of the finances, financial statistics and positive financial law, which investi- gate the public estate, either through its trans- formations in the progress of time, or in its actual conditions in given times and places, or in the legal relations that belong to it. These studies, which are indispensable for gain- ing a deeper knowledge of the Science of the Finances, consider the public estate in its concrete manifestations, but always conditioned within time and space ; while, on the other hand, the Science of the Finances deals with that which is universal and TAXATION ITS PRINCIPLES AND METHODS. 3 permanent, and in this sense it belongs as much to the past as to the present and to the future. Although the Science of Finances investigates the causes and effects of financial facts (for example: the effects of taxes and loans), its chief office never- theless is to furnish the guiding principles for the proper management of the revenue of the state, of the province, or of the municipality. The Science of the Finances forms a part of the science of public administration, which in its turn is a branch of political science in its wider meaning of the science of government. At the present day, however, the Science of the Finances is generally studied as a matter altogether .distinct from the other branches of administrative science by reason of the importance of its objects, the variety of its sources, and the extended scope of the doctrines which it embraces. CHAPTER II. SOURCES, DIVISION AND IMPORTANCE OF THE SCI- ENCE OF THE FINANCES CLASSIFICATION. THE Science of the Finances does not, as many are still inclined to believe, constitute a mere ap- pendix to political economy. It is by no means restricted to the investigation of the economic con- sequences of fiscal provisions. 4 TAXATION ITS PRINCIPLES AND METHODS. The general principles of law and political sci- ence are sources of the Science of the Finances as well as those of political economy. All financial questions should therefore be considered in the triple aspect of justice, convenience and social ad- vantage. The knowledge of these three branches of study is accordingly an essential requisite to a clear understanding of the elements of the Science of the Finances. There are other branches of learning auxiliary to the Science of the Finances, such as political arith- metic, government systems of account, technology, private economy (domestic and industrial), and notably the history, legislation and comparative statistics of finance, all of which contribute to the science valuable materials for the elaboration of its theories. The Science of the Finances divides itself natu- rally into three parts, which treat of expenditure, of income, and of their relations to each other. It forms a subject worthy of careful special study, by reason of the theoretical importance of its abject as a part of general education, especially politico- legal education, as well as by reason of the prac- tical utility of its teachings. In particular is it useful to those who, either directly (as magistrates, or as members of deliberative or of consultative bodies), or indirectly through the rights of assem- bly, and of petition, or through the press, exercise TAXATION ITS PRINCIPLES AND METHODS. 5 an influence on the government of the State, or of political societies of inferior extent. A necessary complement to the Science and the Art of the Finances is practice, which consists in effective action, and avails itself of the truths of science and of the principles of art, strengthening both with the results of individual experience. Science, art and practice are the complements of each other, and it is a mistake to assume that one can take the place of the other. Science explains ; art guides and counsels ; practice acts and executes. Neglect of any of these elements necessary for the profitable realization of financial thought leads to empiricism and the day-dreams of Utopia. CHAPTER III. HISTORICAL DATA OF THE SCIENCE OF THE FINANCES. THE financial systems of Greece and Rome in ancient times, and those no less notable of Florence and of Venice during the middle ages, must be considered as luminous proofs of practical sagacity, and not as the product of scientific research, which in these epochs has yielded but a few fragments from classical writers (Xenophon and Aristotle), and certain maxims of financial morals buried in the theological, philosophical, political and legal works of the schoolmen. Since the Renaissance various principles of finan- O TAXATION ITS PRINCIPLES AND METHODS. cial policy show themselves, developed with some fullness in the writings of publicists here and there in the fifteenth (Carafa), and so likewise in the sixteenth century, the Frenchman Bodin ranking foremost among the latter, while among the Ital- ians Palmieri, Guicciardini, and particularly Botero, distinguished themselves. These principles were commented upon with more or less prolixity, but with little originality, in many works which saw the light in the seventeenth century, the work being undertaken in some cases from pure motives of erudition (Bornitz, Besold, Klock), in others with a view to administrative interests (Seckendorf and the German and English writers on excise). After a few decades, however, there appeared a number of authors who with greater boldness advocated general or partial re- forms of the system of taxation in the interest of the public treasury (in Spain and Germany), or in that of the taxpayers in the endeavor to bring about a more equitable distribution of burdens (Boulainvilliers, Vauban and Boisguillebert ; Pascoli and Bandini). Of more distinct merit, from the scientific point of view, were certain English writers of the seven- teenth century, among whom Hobbes, Petty, and especially Locke, were the first to discuss, although somewhat superficially, the difficult question of the incidence and the repercussion of taxes. TAXATION ITS PRINCIPLES AND METHODS. 7 As a worthy parallel to these, other writers, also English (Davenant, Hutcheson, Barnard, etc.), ap- peared, who, in the early years of the eighteenth century, examined in its technical details the novel theory of the public credit, which, after the famous experiment of Law, was further investigated by Melon, by Dutot, and by other apologists or ad- versaries of that system. A much wider horizon was opened to financial thought toward the middle of the last century. The little-known, yet methodical and important, treatise on taxation by the Neapolitan, Broggia (1743), was followed by Montesquieu's work on The Spirit of Laws (1748), which, with great penetration, explains the connection between po- litical and financial institutions ; and later came the much-prized political essays of Hume (1752), which, as it were, smoothed the path for the famous French school of physiocrats (Quesnay, the elder Mira- beau, Turgot, etc.), which, with a rigorous logic, derives the fiscal corollary of the single tax on the revenue of landed property (impot unique) from the certainly ingenious yet fallacious theory of " net product" (1758 and following years).* * It was a doctrine of the physiocratic school that since land alone yielded a " net product," i. unf ore- seen. In a somewhat different sense expenditure is called ordinary, the useful effect of which merely concerns the current fiscal year, and extraordinary, that which inures to the benefit of several successive periods. In respect of importance, we distinguish : ist. Necessary expense. 2d. Useful expense. Some do not approve of this distinction, maintaining that any necessary ex- pense is also a useful one, and that any really use- ful one may, in almost all cases, be regarded as necessary. In regard to economic effects, we have to distin- guish : i st. Productive expenditure, which is (a) Either directly such, if it increases the public estate, or, (U) Indirectly such, if it increases that of private individuals. 2d. Unproductive expenditure, in which the wealth consumed is not sufficiently repaid by the usefulness of the services for which it is incurred. We must not confuse the utility of public expen- diture with its productiveness. Unproductive ex- 20 PUBLIC EXPENDITURE. penditure may be useful, or, indeed, necessary, when it satisfies any real and urgent want. Finally, in respect of the purposes for which public expenditure is intended, the following clas- sification may be made, which, however, may be varied in a thousand ways : I. Constitutional expenditure; that is, for (a) The head of the State, Emperor, King, President, etc., and in a monarchy, for his family (civil lists, endowments, appanages, etc.) ; (fr) The representative bodies, national, provin- cial, municipal ; (c) The highest governmental departments with general powers. II. Expenditure of administration; that is, for A. The financial administration, and in particu- lar for ist. The public domain ; 2d. The collection of taxes ; 3d. The public debt (interest and redemp- tion) ; 4th. The treasury and accounts. B. The administration proper ; that is to say, (A A} Administration for purposes of public se- curity, and in particular for 1. External security, and hence, for (a) War and marine ; (<) Diplomacy (missions, consulates). 2. Internal security (justice); hence, for PUBLIC EXPENDITURE. 21 (a) Repressive justice (contentions, civil juris- diction, i. ., law courts for civil causes and penal justice) ; (b) Preventive justice (voluntary civil jurisdic- tion and police). (BB) The administration of public well-being, and in particular, 1. Intellectual and moral well-being; hence, (a) Public worship ; (B) Institutions of education and learning. 2. Material prosperity : (a) Physical (public health) ; (b) Economic; hence, (aa) Charitable and provident institutions ; (bK) Public works ; (ci) Industries (agricultural, manufacturing, com- mercial, etc.). But the practical distinction of public expendi- ture for departments, bureaus, divisions, sections, etc., will never exactly coincide in any State with the scientific classification given, or, indeed, with any other classification. It varies according to the extent, the historical traditions, and the political constitutions of the different States. PART III. PUBLIC INCOME. THE public income by which the State, the prov- ince, the municipality provide for their own wants is divided into ordinary and extraordinary income. The former is collected regularly in every fiscal period ; the latter is intended to provide for casual deficits. The ordinary public income is subdivided into original and derivative, the former governed by the common law and the latter by statute. Not- withstanding notable differences the two coincide in the main, because they resolve themselves into two modes of setting aside a portion of the national wealth for purposes of public utility. The following is a summary of the principal pub- lic receipts : I. Ordinary income, which is : A. Original income, arising from the property of the State. B. Derivative income, and therein : ist. The proceeds of taxation. (a) Special fees, costs and charges. (U) General taxes, commonly so called. PUBLIC INCOME. 2$ 2d. Fines, penalties. 3d. Escheats. II. Extraordinary income, namely: A. The reserves of the treasury. B. The sale of the fiscal domain. C. Increase of taxation. D. Public loans. E. War contributions. PART IV. ORIGINAL PUBLIC INCOME. ORIGINAL public income is that which the State, province and municipality derive directly from their own property, in contrast with the derivative in- come which they obtain indirectly from the obliga- tory contributions of private individuals. The original income constitutes the fiscal do- main, in the fullest signification of the term. CHAPTER I. IDEA AND DIVISION OF THE FISCAL DOMAIN. THE fiscal domain comprises the wealth, mov- able and immovable, possessed by the State, the province or municipality, the profitable rights that they enjoy, and the industries carried on by the same, under the ordinary regulations of law, with a view of obtaining revenue, interest or profit, which are designed to provide for a part of the public ex- penses. In reference to the mode of acquisition, of man- agement and of sale respectively, of the domanial ORIGINAL PUBLIC INCOME. 2$ property and industries, they are controlled by the rules of common law, and of the economic law of competition, which regulates both the cost and the value of the products obtained. Distinct from the strictly fiscal domain, which by its nature is alienable, prescriptible and productive, is the public domain (unproductive, imprescriptible and inalienable) which the citizens enjoy individu- ally and not collectively, and on which the State, province and municipality enjoy no true right of property, but only the right and duty of pres- ervation and of protection. Such, for instance, are the roads, canals, harbors, coasts, fortifica- tions, etc. From the fiscal domain differ also the fiscal monopolies, which are industries exercised by the public authority independently of the ordinary rules of law and of competition, with a view of drawing a net product greatly superior to ordinary profit, and which, therefore, really includes an im- post. From the fiscal domain must further be distin- guished those administrative services which the State, province or municipality undertakes, with or without monopoly, from motives of public useful- ness, with a view of deriving, not indeed a profit, but a simple reimbursement, either partial or total, of the expenses incurred, and constituting accord- ingly a special tax. This frequently happens in 26 ORIGINAL PUBLIC INCOME. the managements of posts and telegraphs, and always in the manufacture of coins. The fiscal domain comprises : A. Property. ist. Immovable (domanial property in a limited sense), namely : (a) The public workshops ; (K) Cultivated lands, forests, mines, etc., owned by the State. 2d. Movable, namely : (a) Corporeal goods, as military implements (arms, ships, horses, etc.), furniture, documents, books, pictures, etc., and, in general, the contents of archives, libraries, picture-galleries, museums, national printing-offices, money in the public chest ; (3) Incorporeal goods, as rights of hunting, fish- ing, etc. B. Industries. ist. Territorial and mining, connected with the ownership of real estate. 2d. Manufactories (as national printing-offices, tapestry, porcelain and arms factories). 3d. Commercial, namely : (a) Ordinary commerce ; this is very rare in the present day; (b) Banking, which in our day is everywhere car- ried on, not by State banks, but by private banks, with or without special privileges, the government being able by means of taxation to exercise super- ORIGINAL PUBLIC INCOME. 2/ intendence over the issue of notes payable at sight or to bearer, and to obtain a fiscal revenue from them ; (V) Posts, telegraphs and railways, when they yield a profit. C. Permits for hunting, fishing, etc. CHAPTER II. ADMINISTRATION OF THE FISCAL DOMAIN. THE administration of the fiscal domain can be regulated by " regie " (direct official management), by contract, and (in the case of real estate) by lease. In the first mentioned, a system once generally prevalent, the proprietor (the State, province or municipality) assumes the care and risk of invest- ment in raw material, manufacture and sale of cer- tain products, and intrusts it to public officers, who are paid by fixed stipends. In this system, which has the object of securing to the proprietor the entire profit of the enter- prise, the lack of personal interest on the part of the administrators is to be regretted, as well as the many drawbacks of a bureaucratic management, which is invariably slow, expensive, intricate, some- times yields no profit, and even results in loss. By the contract or farming system the proprietor 28 ORIGINAL PUBLIC INCOME. withdraws from all risks, and grants to others the use of the property or the exercise of the industries of the fiscal domain in return for a fixed yearly payment in goods or money. In favor of the contract system may be adduced the saving which the proprietor is able to effect in the expenses of administration and supervision ; the greater revenue that is obtained by private, free and diligent management ; the greater security of a payment fixed as to time and amount, the pos- sibility of improvements, and, in general, the in- crease of the gross and of the net produce, which also results to general advantage. On the other hand, stress is laid on the possibil- ity of conflicts of interest between the grantor, who is most concerned about maintaining the property intact, and the contractor, who wishes to derive the greatest amount of produce while the contract lasts ; hence there may arise frequent litigation, and sometimes fraudulent bargains, between the contractors and the agents who are charged with making the contracts and watching over their ful- fillment. To prevent such mishaps, in part at least, there have been established certain precautions respect- ing the choice of the* conTraHoT^yprivate con- tract or aT^puEHc auction)7~also in respect to the duration of 'the contract (at a fixed and relatively long term of duration), to the extent of the grant, ORIGINAL PUBLIC INCOME. 2$ and to the guarantees for the^ strict fulfillment of the contract (bond, inventory, etc.), and concern- ing the regulations (which must not be too many or too vexatious) as to the methods of manage- ment. Different from contract (in the case of real prop- erty) is also the so-called concession^ in which the greater duration of the grant, the obligation of ef- fecting improvements, and the smallness of the payment prove frequently of great advantage to the administration and the betterment of the property of the State, of municipalities and of charitable in- stitutions, which in this manner avoid the trouble and risk of such improvements, and to which more- over is assured a small but safe revenue. Still, under different conditions, the progressive diminution of the payment as equalized to money through the diminished value of the latter the smallness of the payment itself no longer corre- sponding to the produce of the lands together with the many controversies, especially in the case of an excessive subdivision of workable lands, have given rise to a decidedly unfavorable opinion in respect to this system of administration of the fiscal domain. There are also mixed systems of administration. Among these there is the system o^sharing^ in which the fiscal agents are made to participate in * A very long, or perpetual, heritable lease at a fixed rent, (Rom. law.) 30 ORIGINAL PUBLIC INCOME. the profits of the undertaking, in order to stimulate their activity through the hope of obtaining greater profits. In the so-called system of guarantee, which at one time was much in vogue, the fiscal agent, who is paid by a fixed stipend, warrants to the exche- quer a minimum of product, and divides with it any- thing that may be obtained beyond this limit. But it has always been difficult to find persons possess- ing capital and endowed with high administrative capacity who would be inclined to charge them- selves with the fixed burden of this guarantee in the hope of enjoying only a part of the greatest eventual profit. CHAPTER III. SALE OF THE FISCAL DOMAIN. THE various systems of administering fiscal prop- erty and industries have almost always presented very grave inconveniences, which have induced the more civilized States to sell the greater part of the domain. It is plain, if the matter be considered in its legal and in its political aspect, that the possession of a large fiscal domain may produce a conflict of inter- ests between the public authority and the citizens, because the duty of the equal protection of every ORIGINAL PUBLIC INCOME. 31 order of persons and property is often forgotten, and through the system of privilege, private prop- erty and private industry are injured for the bene- fit of the exchequer. Besides this the administration of the fiscal do- main increases the number of public functionaries, heightens the influence of the executive power, and diverts a number of persons from the careers of private life. Nor should we omit to mention the danger contained in the fact that domanial wealth furnishes powerful means of financial resistance to the popular will expressed in the political delibera- tive assemblies. Finally, in case of war the public estate is more easily exposed to devastation and confiscation by the enemy, which produce not only the most serious injuries, but also numerous legal conflicts with the buyers of confiscated property. In the economic aspect the subtraction of a con- siderable quantity of property from private owner- ship constitutes a serious obstacle to industrial progress, and compels the citizens to much greater sacrifices than under a system of taxation would suffice to obtain greater revenues for the treasury. In fact, when we consider the lack of individual interest in the public functionaries, the complica- tions, the slowness, the expenses of book-keeping and of supervision, no doubt indispensable, but frequently inadequate when we consider the im- 32 ORIGINAL PUBLIC INCOME. perfection of the entire bureaucratic management, which is always adverse to reforms, and by its own constitution prevented from speedily effecting those small savings and profiting by those favorable oc- casions which so materially contribute to the in- crease of returns, it is not to be wondered at if the revenues of the fiscal domain prove small, or if at times they disappear entirely and are swallowed up by expenses. But the capital obtained from their sale, the amount of which will bear due relation to the greater revenue which private industry could derive therefrom, may be applied to a much more productive employment, as, for example, when used for the partial extinction of the public debt, the in- terest of which, often very burdensome, stands in marked contrast to the smallness of the income arising from the domain. Hence the sale of the fiscal domain is, in general, to be recommended. It may, however, produce the worse results if it is not made with suitable precautions. It is neces- sary to take heed of, ist. The choice of what is to be sold, and of the regulation of the sale itself, in order that the sud- den offer of a great quantity, especially of real prop- erty, may not result in loss to the exchequer (which would receive a lower price) or to private individuals, whose property might be lowered in value. ORIGINAL PUBLIC INCOME. 33 2d. The territorial extent of the property sold, which should be divided up in such manner as to invite the competition of buyers, due regard being paid to the systems of cultivation in different countries. 3d. The time of the sale, which ought to take place in periods of political tranquillity and of economic prosperity, in order to obtain good prices and to avoid the irreparable loss of a sale at an im- proper price. 4th. The persons to whom sale is made, in order to avoid as far as possible the evils of speculation. 5th. The guarantee offered for the punctual ful- fillment of the contract. 6th. And above all, the use made of the proceeds of the sale, which must always be regarded as capital, to be employed either in the extinction of old debts, or to meet extraordinary expenses, for which it would have been necessary to incur fresh debts. The desirability of making sale of the fiscal domain, which some advocate unconditionally, ad- mits, however, of a few exceptions. It may, for instance, be important to retain the possession of certain public forests in mountainous localities or on the banks of certain rivers and "mountain streams, from motives of public health, and for the protection of private property. Also, from yet different reasons, one may advocate the manufact- 34 ORIGINAL PUBLIC INCOME. ure at the expense of the treasury of objects neces- sary to the civil and military administration, and also, in countries of a less advanced civilization, the maintenance of certain lands and factories for pur- poses of instruction (model farms, manufactories of tapestry, etc.). PART V. DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. DERIVATIVE public income consists of obligatory contributions produced by taxation, those sums which the public authority levies on the wealth of private individuals in return for the ser- vices rendered to them by the administrative in- stitutions of the State, province or municipality. Such contributions are distinguished from the fiscal domain, and from its products, both by their origin and their effects on the national wealth, and also by their character as obligatory loans, with- drawn entirely or partially from the action of com- petition. Taxes are either special or general ; the former being more closely designated as fees, costs and charges, the latter as taxes merely, or as imposts. To the derivative public income belong also fines, pecuniary penalties, and in certain respects also escheats, or unappropriated goods. But by reason of the relatively small importance of the latter in modern financial systems, it may suffice merely to mention them here. 36 DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. CHAPTER I. IDEA, REASON, AND FORM OF FEES, COSTS, AND CHARGES. IN scientific language, fees, costs, and charges are the remuneration for special public services which are rendered to private individuals at their request. They differ, therefore, from ordinary taxes ; ist. By their object, because the former refer to special services that have been voluntarily sought, and the latter to general services that are compul- sorily offered. 2d. By the criterion of the assessment, which, as regards fees, etc., is the amount of expense in- curred, and, as regards taxes, the amount of the property of the tax-payers. As certain institutions that are administered by the public authority, either because essentially per- taining to its competency (as the maintenance of external and internal security, etc.), or because it can manage them better than private industry (mint, post-office, telegraph, etc.), yield two kinds of advantages, the one general and indeterminate to the whole body of citizens, the other special to certain classes and persons, it is conformable to reason that the necessary expenses for the main- tenance of such institutions should be defrayed partly by general taxes and partly by special taxes, which means^ in other words, that these expenses DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. 37 should be defrayed in quotas proportioned to the wealth of the individual contributors, and to the greater expense caused by a portion of them. If- such expenses were defrayed solely from the pro- ceeds of general taxes, or solely from those of spe- cial taxes, there would result privileges favorable to some and injurious to others. In order that any fee be legitimate, the ser- vice rendered must be a real one, and its amount should not exceed certain limits, fixed precisely by the expense occasioned by the one who pays it.* Such is the criterion for the determination of fees in which no heed is taken of the economic condition of the contributors, except in the two following cases : ist. Of absolute poverty, in which case exemp- tion is allowed from certain fees, costs and charges to be paid for services which are certainly special, * The State of Pennsylvania obtains net revenue of nearly $200,000 per year from the fees of court clerks, recorders of deeds, and registers of wills. All these officers are required to report their fees to the Auditor General. When the amount exceeds $2,000 per annum, they are required to pay one-half of the surplus to the State treasury, retaining 3 per cent, of the sums so paid. Notaries public pay 5 per cent, of their fees, and are charged $25 each for their commissions. This method of obtaining a net revenue is incidental, not direct, and is quite unobjectionable. As it is never possible to adjust the fees precisely to the cost of the service rendered, or the ex- pense occasioned, it is fitting that the excess received should inure to the benefit of the State. But the officers charged with the collection of the fees must have a sufficient pecuniary inducement to collect them in full and pay over the State's portion. ED. 38 DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. yet which should always be rendered in the interest of justice (court costs). 2d. In case of straitened means combined with signal merit, where exemption is allowed from cer- tain charges for particular services of mere utility (as school taxes). In the first case it is equivalent to an alms ; in the second, to a prize awarded by the wealthier tax-payers to the poorer ones. If we wish to distinguish special charges in their relation to the several administrative services that may lay claim to special remuneration, we obtain a classification analogous to that already given in the case of public expenditures. We cite from the great variety of special taxes the following merely by way of example : 1. Public security. (a) External (charges for exemption from military service, for passports, consular fees, etc.) ; (ft) Internal: ist. Repressive justice (court costs and official fees, etc.). 2d. Preventive justice (permits for hunting, carrying arms, etc.). 2. Public prosperity. (a) Intellectual and moral (school tax, charges for dispensations from observance of strict conditions with reference to mar- DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. 39 riage, for naturalization, decorations, hon- ors,* etc.) ; (jf) Material (charges on coinage, on weights and measures, for stamping precious metals, on railway service, posts and telegraphs,etc.). CHAPTER II. CHARGES ARISING IN MATTERS OF JUDICIAL COGNI- ZANCE. THOSE charges which require special mention may be divided into court costs and fees for certifi- cation, registration and copies of papers. SECTION i. Court costs. Court costs are charges which are paid in return for certain special services rendered by the State on the occasion of certain acts that are completed in the civil tribunals. These concern lawsuits or litigious civil juris- diction. Their principal justification consists in the par- ticular advantage which these judicial proceedings offer to certain persons, who ought not to be al- lowed to enjoy them at the expense of the mass of * In nearly every country of Europe there is a tax on the orders or decorations bestowed by the sovereign, and on any rise in the official hierarchy, which gives a distinct title. So also on patents of nobility. 4 DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. tax-payers. Another reason, but subordinate and of a political character, is the need of putting some restraint on litigation. Court costs, however, should not exceed certain limits, because otherwise : 1. They would become prohibitive or would greatly restrict the usefulness of judicial institutions, to the injury especially of the poorer classes. 2. They would diminish the very great and uni- versal benefit which we derive from a proper ad- ministration of justice independently of special judicial aid. Court costs have to be paid by the losing party in a suit in due proportion to the expenses which he may have caused. In the absence of any established principle for fixing charges of this kind, rules may be framed indirectly, by reference 1. To the rank and dignity of the magistrates who hear and decide ; 2. To the importance of their judgments ; 3. To the kind of questions brought before them. The objections made by many to court fees are either founded on the false premise that the exist- ence of the civil tribunals is not more useful to the litigants than to other citizens, and that taxes are levied on the oppressed poor and not on the rich oppressors; or are only valid against arbitrary, DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. 41 excessive and badly distributed costs that is, against the abuse, and not the use, of fees or taxes of this kind. SEC. 2. Fees for certification and registration. These fees are paid in return for special services rendered by the State through the compilation, cer- tification, preservation and multiplication of certain documents by means of which a right is established, insured, changed, transferred or extinguished. In fact, both the civil judicial authority (in its non-litigious capacity) and the financial authority, as well as the other administrative authorities, often co-operate toward enhancing the value of such acts, by investing them with certain solemn forms, by as- certaining their date, by inscribing and transcrib- ing them in public registers, and making authentic copies of them. But in this category taxes on business transac- tions or contracts are not to be included, and not even registry and stamp taxes, because they happen to be collected in the same method, which may be identical in form both for official fees and for imposts on the transfer of property. Official fees are essentially different from charges on transfers : ist. By the object, which in the one case is the document and in the other is the property trans- ferred. 2d. By the purpose, because the fees aim at ob- 42 DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. taining a reimbursement of expense, while imposts aim at obtaining a net revenue. 3d. By the criterion of the assessment, which in one case is the amount of expense caused, but in the other is inferred from the nature of the trans- fer, from the value of the property transferred, and from the personal relations between those who make the transfer and those who receive it. In the case of charges for official documents the effort is also made to ascertain the expenses caused by individuals by having recourse to certain in- direct data inferred from the nature and impor- tance of the transactions. The distinction often met with in practice be- tween fixed fees and fees proportioned to the values involved in the document is not a sufficient argument to justify the assertion that the fee has been converted into an impost, because within cer- tain limits the proportion may be an indirect and ap- proximate criterion of the amount of expense incur- red for the special advantage of certain tax-payers. SEC. 3. Collection of charges arising from mat- ters within judicial cognizance. Both court costs and charges for official docu- ments may be collected according to various sys- tems, which are either peculiar to them or are common to a few indirect taxes on transfers and on consumption. The distinction is to be noted between the two DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. 43 systems of direct collection (made by public officers) and of indirect collection (performed through a system of stamps). The direct collection is made : ist. By the obsolete, not very creditable and even dangerous method of so-called perquisites, or payments made by the parties concerned to the public officials, and accepted by the latter as a stipend or an addition to their salary.* 2d. By means of the so-called office charges (diritti di cancellaria), belonging to the public treasury, but collected by public officers, either salaried or remunerated with a share in the pro- ceeds, who simply receive the document or com- pile it or make a registration of it. The indirect collection, which is made by means of a seal or stamp, which in itself is not a tax, * This discreditable and dangerous method of collecting fees and charges is by no means obsolete in the United States. Having been adopted at a time when the fees, by reason of the smallness of the business transacted, amounted to no more than a fair compensation for the officers' time and labor, the compensation increased with the growth of States and cities till in some cases it amounted to a princely revenue. Then it became a source of political corruption. Offices of a merely clerical and perfunctory sort have become prizes of such magnitude that political parties and "bosses" have quartered their favorites and henchmen upon the nominal holder of the offices as the price of nomination and election, and have levied " assess- ments " upon them corresponding to the aggregate amount of the fees. Every attempt to reduce the fees or to turn the excess, over and above a fair compensation, into the public treasury, is fiercely opposed by the poli- ticians who divide the "spoils," but the tendency of opinion and of leg- islation is now strongly in favor of the system prevailing in Pennsylvania, mentioned in the note to page 37. ED. 44 DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. offers the advantage that the contributor is bound to co-operate at his own risk and peril in the col- lection of the fees, that the secrecy is better main- tained, and that the collection is rendered more speedy, less costly and more consonant with the dignity of the public functionaries. The forms in which this collection is made differ as follows : 1. The stamp or seal may be affixed by a public officer upon papers prepared beforehand, in which case we return to the system of direct collection. 2. Stamped paper prepared by the State is sold at a profit by officers expressly appointed, and has to be used for the compilation of certain documents. 3. Separate stamps are manufactured and sold for account of the State that have to be affixed to instruments drawn upon unstamped paper. The adoption of this latter system, which is the most recent, and also the most convenient as well as least expensive, is daily gaining ground, al- though many precautions are required to prevent frauds, consisting in counterfeiting the stamps, de- lay in affixing them, and in affixing the same stamp successively to different instruments. DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. 45 CHAPTER III. CHARGES ON THE MEANS OF EXCHANGE AND OF TRANSPORT. AMONG the charges imposed for administrative services which relat'e to public prosperity, the first place belongs to those on the means of exchange and transport, which serve to defray the expense required for the maintenance of certain economic institutions, which for reasons of public utility re- main in the hands of the State. These comprise charges : 1. On coinage. 2. On the verification of weights and measures and on the marking of the precious metals. 3. On railroads, posts and telegraphs. SECTION i. On coinage. The manufacture of coins, for which the State provides either directly by government manage- ment or indirectly by contract, forms a legitimate title for the exaction of charges to reimburse a part of the corresponding expense. Gratuitous coinage, which would seem to real- ize the idea of what money should be, by creating identity between the value of the metal and the value of the coin, would be somewhat dangerous in practice, because it would continually promote 46 DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. the melting and exportation of new coins, and thus encourage the speculations of goldsmiths, money-changers and bankers to the injury of the public, who would receive only worn and light coin. On the other hand, to extract from the coins a net revenue over and above the reimbursement of the expense of coinage, which was once practiced by systematic alteration of the coins (in weight, fineness and value), must be considered the worst of all taxes, because it nominally raises prices, com- promises the certainty of contracts, injures private creditors who had made bargains in the old coin, and finally ruins the treasury, for whose benefit the impost was intended. The best system is that in which the State is satisfied with a partial reimbursement of the ex- penses of the mint, and which may be effected : 1. By causing an equivalent of the expenses for assaying and coining, to be paid by those who bring metal to the mint to be converted into coin. 2. By turning to account the gain which it de- rives from the minting of the subsidiary coins, to which it will generally affix a nominal value higher than their metallic value. The expense caused by the withdrawal and re- melting of worn coin has, on the other hand, to be borne by the tax-payers (by means of imposts), be- cause it is not in accord with equity that they i> U U I V DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. 47 should be borne wholly by the person who may have received them last. SEC. 2. Charges on weights and measures, and on marking. The authority of the community should provide for the establishment and maintenance of a system of weights and measures which should be generally obligatory, and should satisfy the conditions of in- trinsic merit, of consistency within itself, of appli- cation to the whole territory, and of invariability. For this reason the same authority should be charged with the task of the verification of weights and measures, on which occasion there are also levied certain taxes, originally paid by the manu- facturers, but which are afterward periodically levied on tradesmen. It is only proper that these taxes should be paid by those who have the direct benefit of the official verification, and who, at all events, are able to re- imburse themselves through the price of the mer- chandise sold. The trade in the precious metals (gold and sil- ver) and in the objects manufactured from them becomes sometimes the subject of a charge which is collected by means of the application of a stamp (obligatory or optional) impressed by a public of- ficer who certifies to their weight and fineness. This charge is also provided for by the manufacturers and the tradesmen; but they obtain reimbursement 48 DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. from the buyers, who in this manner are fully guaranteed in respect of the fine metal contained in the articles, which they would not be able to verify for themselves with equal ease and accu- racy. SEC. 3. Charges on railways, posts and tele- graphs. The ownership and operation of railways are by the very nature of things, in fact if not by right, almost wholly removed from the beneficial action of competition. Instead therefore of being branches of industry, they are institutions of public utility, necessarily subject to an effective control on the part of the State, which in many countries assumes the prop- erty of them, and in some even works them. When the State works the railways, reason de- mands that it should obtain the reimbursement of the greater part, if not the whole, of the working expenses and interest on the fixed and floating capital invested, by means of charges which are to be paid by those who avail themselves of the rail- roads for the transportation of their persons and goods, and so derive a special benefit from them. But when, on the other hand, the operation of the railroads is in the hands of companies under State inspection and control, the State usually levies an impost on the persons and things trans- ported, either in express or slow trains, which im- DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. 49 post is anticipated by the companies, which obtain their reimbursement by raising their rates in due proportion. For still stronger reasons the postal, and now also the telegraph service (except the submarine) are becoming almost everywhere concentrated in the hands of the State, which, by means of charges on the transmission of letters and dispatches, ob- tains the total or partial reimbursement of the ex- penses of plant and administration. The system of postal and telegraph charges be- comes every day more simple, uniform and eco- nomical, a process promoted by frequent interna- tional conferences and conventions. Prepayment by postage-stamps, the notable dim- inution and simplification of rates, the introduction of postal and telegraphic money-orders, and the more recent one of postal cards and postal packets, are the most important features of reforms, which, however, admit of still further development. The postal and telegraph charges, in which re- gard is had to weight (for letters) and to the num- ber of words (for dispatches) are now more uni- form, and not, as formerly, graduated according to distances. The latter system was too complicated and costly, as well as incompatible with equity, since it has been ascertained that the element of distance, imperfectly estimated according to the plan of the so-called " postal and telegraphic 3 $0 DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. zones," has in reality but little relation to the cost, which falls off considerably with the increase in number of letters and telegrams, the latter effect being in great measure due to the reforms above mentioned. CHAPTER IV. THE IDEA, REASON AND RULES OF GENERAL TAXATION. A TAX is that part of the wealth of private indi- viduals, which the authority of the State, province or municipality appropriates in order to provide for the public expenses incurred for the advantage of the general body of tax-payers. The reason of a tax is evident. In order to sat- isfy certain collective wants, where it is quite im- possible to decide what are the expenses caused by individual citizens, and where the direct perform- ance of personal services, which would prove to be uncertain, inconsiderable and badly distributed, would be of no use, there will be required a com- mon fund, to establish which voluntary contribu- tions would not be adequate. To the right of the public authority to levy taxes there corresponds the duty on the part of private individuals of paying them. Hence we DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. 5 1 must condemn the tolerance with which certain moralists encourage the selfish aversion which some citizens entertain against payments of this kind, extenuating the offences of those who de- fraud the treasury ; as if such delinquencies were less reprehensible or less injurious than those in private life. The science of finance furnishes a few juridical, economic and political rules for the regulation of imposts. SECTION i. Juridical rules. The tax must above all possess the requisites of legality, of certainty, of legitimacy, of equality and of morality. In fiscal matters, as in others, juridical considera- tions should prevail over economic and political ones. As, however, the rigorous application of the principle of justice meets very serious difficulties, both in the selection and the valuation of taxable objects, and by reason of the incidence and of the repercussion of taxes, which cannot always be ex- actly calculated, it follows that in practice we must be satisfied with an approximation to equity. A tax is legal when it has been decreed by com- petent authority with all the solemnities of legisla- tive enactment, and hence, in free States, with the previous assent of the contributors, expressed either directly by their votes or indirectly through their representatives. 52 DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. It is certain, that is, not arbitrary, when the law with precision and clearness determines its nature (subject, object, extent), the means of determining its distribution, the methods of collection, the fines and penalties in cases of delinquency, the authori- ties that are to decide in practical administration, and ultimately the judicial remedies in case of com- plaints from the tax-payers, etc. It is legitimate when its proceeds are effectively employed for the advantage of the whole body of contributors, an equitable relation between the sum total of the taxes and that of the public ex- penses being thus attained. The equality of the tax relates to the justice of its apportionment among the contributors, and is the fiscal application of the principle of equality of the citizens before the law. The tax will be equal not only in name but in fact, when it is at the same time universal and rightly graduated. The universality of the tax consists in the ex- clusion of every privilege, real and personal, be- cause it is not equitable that any person or corpora- tion should enjoy a share in the benefits of political society, and at the same time be exempt, wholly or partially, from the corresponding burdens. The exemption of the poor from certain taxes is a neces- sity based on a fact, which resolves itself into a special form of public chanty. The graduation of taxes consists in a corre- DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. 53 spondence between the tax and the economic condition of individual contributors. If the tax should be uniform, notwithstanding the economic inequalities between the citizens, it would not only be unjust, but also impracticable, for, con- sidering the smallness of the separate contri- butions, which is necessarily implied by uniform taxes, the revenue derived would be alto- gether insufficient for the needs of modern civil societies. Admitting the justice of graduation, it will be necessary to find an equitable and practical crite- rion to carry it into effect. The criterion of equivalence between the tax and the services rendered individually to the con- tributors is neither just nor possible, because the value of these services cannot be determined even approximately, and because such a system would tend to oppress those who, through weakness, ignorance or poverty, stand in greater need of the protection of society, and accordingly derive greater advantages from it. Nor is it just or possible to set up the criterion of equivalence between the tax imposed and the expenses caused by the contributors individually, or, in other words, the principle, which should gov- ern in the case of fees, costs and charges, etc., be- cause there are a great number of public services concerning which it is impossible to decide what 54 DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. portion of the aggregate expense is caused by each contributor. And, finally, it is neither just nor possible to treat the impost as a premium of insurance for social protection, because the public authority does not limit its action to the defence of property, but extends to personal security also, and^to the promo- tion of moral and intellectual well-being. Even in respect of property, the social authority does not assume any real guarantee, but only binds itself to the protection of private property, and to the pun- ishment of crimes committed against it. We must also consider erroneous the theory of those who, in order to avoid the defects of the criteria of the value of services rendered, of the expenses caused, and of the premium of insurance, declare that the best way of applying these criteria is to apportion the taxes according to the total wealth of the contributors. It is erroneous simply because the hypothesis is wrong which assumes that in this manner services, expenses and pre- mium would become exactly proportional to wealth ; for this theory also leaves out of view the fact that the action of the public authority is not limited merely to property, and that in the matter of insurance the premium must be proportioned not only to the value of the goods, but also to the kind of risks against which the property is to be insured. DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. 55 In accord with the more equitable and prac- ticable scheme of graduation the burden on the con- tributors should be assessed in proportion to their means, estimated, in the opinion of some, accord- ing to their estates ; in the opinion of others, ac- cording to their income. Yet, either of these principles being admitted, the advocates of propor- tional, and those of progressive or graduated taxa- tion differ among themselves as to the methods of actual application. A tax is called proportional, when the relation between one's property and the amount which he pays is invariable for all contributors, so that the individual quotas increase in perfect correspondence with the increase of wealth. On the other hand, a tax is called progressive where its rate varies with the variation of the wealth itselt, so that the quotas increase more rapidly than the wealth increases. >\ The adherents of progressive taxes, who in our time are very numerous, and not all of them social- ists, start from the idea that taxation should, above all other considerations, perform a social function. Taxation, they say, should prevent the accumula- tion of wealth in few hands, or at least should bring it about that the burden should press equally upon the tax-payers; in other words, it should con- sider what is left to the tax-payer and not merely what is paid, and should bear upon what is super- 5 6 DERI VA TIVE P UBLIC INCOME. fluous rather than upon what is necessary. They thereupon seek to prove that fiscal legislation fur- nishes a great many instances of at least the partial application of this system, as when a minimum is fixed of property which is to be exempt from direct imposts, and when rents are taxed progressively ac- cording to rental value.* * The progressive tax system has been in force in the city of Basle, Swit- zerland, upwards of fifty years. Incomes derived from property pay on an ascending scale, viz. : $200 per year, about 2^ per cent. 400 " " 3 & " 600 " " 4 800 " " 4 " 1200 " " 5 and so on to $12,000 per year, when the tax is ten per cent. After this the rate of increase is very slow. Incomes derived from earnings are also taxed progressively at about one-half the rate of income from property. There has been a gradual but steady increase in the progressive feature of taxation at Basle, accompanied by further exemptions of the smaller incomes, until now the returns show that 500 persons, in a total population of 60,000, pay eighty per cent, of the taxes. The democracy of Basle are apparently mak- ing experiments to see how far the progressive principle can be carried without causing a disastrous emigration of capital. It is certain that capital is not now increasing in Basle. There was a slight decrease from 1884 to 1887, but whether this was due to temporary or to permanent causes is doubtful. See London Economist, July 9, 1887. Progressive taxation has been adopted recently in the Canton Vaud, Switzerland, differing in some details from the system in force at Basle, exemptions being allowed in proportion to the number of children in the family. There has been some emigration of capital from Lausanne in con- sequence of the progressive tax, but whether it amounts to a serious loss it is too early yet to determine. The advocates of the progressive tax have scarcely been heard in the United States, all the talent that would naturally be applied to it being ab- sorbed in the effort to enforce the proportional tax by causing personal prop- erty to bear its due share of the public burdens. ED. DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. 57 The advocates of proportional taxation, on the other hand, deny the justice and expediency of any act of the treasury which aims directly at changing the distribution of wealth. They object to the fixing of a progressive scale as being arbi- trary, since its increase, in order not to confiscate the entire fortune of the greater contributors, must necessarily stop short somewhere and precisely at the point where the rigor of the principle would seem to require greater severity in respect of a superfluity of property which has become colossal. They moreover observe that progressive imposts would cause capital to emigrate or to disappear ; that it would discourage saving to the injury of the poorer classes, and that it would be the occasion of many frauds (fictitious sales, divisions and trans- fers), all seeking to elude its rigor. They conclude finally that the alleged partial application of pro- gressive taxes is really a favorable testimony to the system of proportional taxation. And in fact the exemption granted from direct taxes accorded to persons of small means is a compensation for the greater burden to which they are subjected through the faulty distribution of the indirect imposts on consumption ; while, on the other hand, the pro- gressive taxation of rental value is made on the hypothesis that this is the best method of taxing proportionally the wealth of the contributors, which is estimated by its outward indication in 58 DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. order to avoid the serious difficulties of direct investigation. The morality of an impost must not be under- stood in the sense that the taxation of certain arti- cles aims at preventing certain injurious or vicious acts, because in order to reach such a result the im- post would have to be made prohibitory and hence would be devoid of fiscal effect ; but merely in the sense that the impost itself must not be immoral : ist. In its object, as if it distinctly taxed the gains of vice, which should neither enjoy exemp- tion, nor be subjected to any special imposts. 2d. In its effects, as if it should incite to gambling, divert attention from labor, and from habits of saving, or encourage idleness, ignorance and super- stition. 3d. In its application, as when the impost, by its excessive amount or by uncertain, onerous or ex- ceedingly lax methods of collection, offers an in- centive to smuggling, thereby sacrificing the honest to the dishonest tax-payer. SEC. 2. Economic rules. The principal economic rules of taxation are the two following : i st. It should, when possible, tax the income only, whether national or individual, but spare the estate itself. 2d. It should cause the least possible disturbance of the natural development of industry. DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. 59 The former rule indicates the economic limit of the impost, and points at its true source (the in- come) ; for it is bound to protect and not to dimin- ish the property of private individuals, in order that the sources of the public receipts may not be imperiled. The rule, however, has no absolute character, for in normal conditions the imposts must remain a great deal below that extreme limit, while in ab- normal cases the limit may be exceeded in order to avoid greater evils. This principle relative to the source was by some applied to the subject matter, that is, to the basis of the impost, the contention being advanced that imposts should be regulated, not according to property but according to income. This is not true in an absolute sense, because the effects which an impost produces on the property depend on the fact and not on the quality of the impost. In fact a light impost may leave the property intact even when based upon property, while an onerous one may diminish the property even when it is based upon income. The second rule enjoins such an arrangement of the impost as shall cause the least possible disturb- ance in the production, circulation, distribution and consumption of wealth. By this it is not pretended that all injurious effect from the impost can be guarded against, for, by reason of the objects 60 DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. which it taxes, the systems of collection and the guarantees required always produce certain re- straints, that are more or less opposed to the liberty of the citizen. SEC. 3. Political rules. The political rules of taxation refer to its suffi- ciency, to its flexibility and to the means of collec- tion. The tax should in the first place suffice for the needs for which it is intended, and be capable of adaptation to the essentially variable nature of the public expenses. The means of collection is the sum total of tin . acts by which the amounts due by the contributors pass from their hands into those of the fiscal authority. The collections should be made by competent persons, and according to convenient methods. In respect to the persons charged with the col- lection we have to distinguish the two systems of " regie " or direct government management and of contract (farming of the revenue), as also their combinations, among these especially the so-called " co-interested regie," and the collection guaran- teed or executed by the local communities even in case of State imposts. Public opinion in the past was decidedly adverse to the contract system, and is not even now entirely agreed as to its merits. DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. 6l Against this system may be mentioned the ra- pacity, arbitrary acts, scandalous fortunes and un- popularity of the contractors ; whilst in favor of the " regie " system it is maintained that it is nat- urally lenient, not bent on private gain, and that it moreover affords the advantage of showing the cost of collection accurately in the balance sheet. In favor of the contract system, particular stress is laid on the advantage of being able at given times to obtain fixed sums, whilst the profit of the contractors is compensated by the saving of ex- penses growing out of the inducement of profit, which is wanting in the agents of the treasury. It is observed, moreover, that the abuses of the old contract system, although greatly exaggerated, are rather to be attributed to the inherent faults of any tax system than to the particular methods of collection ; for the contract system, when controlled and regulated by wise laws, has even lately yielded excellent results in the collection, notably, of di- rect taxes, and it has frequently been opposed merely from a desire of administrative centraliza- tion. In respect of methods, the collection should cause the least possible inconvenience to either the exchequer or the contributors ; in other words, it should be prompt, safe, economical, and not vexa- tious. 62 DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. The collection will be prompt, when it is so ar- ranged that there are no arrearages left, and that the sums collected are forthwith deposited in the treasury. The collection is safe when it is subject to a system of accounting and to a board of control possessing sufficient guarantees to prevent or at least to promptly detect any mistakes or fraud. The collection will be economical, when a mini- mum of difference is reached between the amount turned into the treasury and that obtained from the contributors. Finally, the collection will not be vexatious : ist. When the convenience of tax-payers is con- sulted in respect of time, place and form of pay- ment. 2d. The process should be simplified as far as possible, useless formalities should be avoided, as well as any abuse of oaths, examinations, exhibition of documents and other practices which cause loss of time to the contributors, undue restrictions of individual freedom, invasion of domiciles and of business secrets. CHAPTER V. REPERCUSSION OF TAXES. WE call the repercussion (riper cussione, rim- balzo, traslazione) of a tax that process through DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. 63 which certain persons affected by the tax succeed, by proportionally increasing the price of their goods or of their services, in getting reimbursed by other persons, who are therefore the real tax- payers. Such a shifting, which is difficult to be deter- mined exactly in individual cases, is variously judged by theoretical writers. Some deny it, or consider it vague and unimportant ; others (pessi- mists) believe "it to be an unavoidable disturbing element in every financial system ; still others (optimists) insist that it is beneficent, and repairs the inevitable inequality in the incidence of taxa- tion. We must not confound that repercussion which has been foreseen and desired by the law-making body, and which allows the adoption of more con- venient methods of collection (e. g., in certain im- posts on consumption), with the shifting of a tax to persons whom the treasury wishes to spare. In this last case justice in the distribution of taxes is really impeded. A good system of taxation should take care, as far as possible, that there should be only that repercussion that is desired and intended, and no other. For repercussion is often very hurtful, be- cause it frequently is effected by concealed means {e. g., by deteriorating or adulterating the goods sold). 64 DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. The displacement of the economic consequences of a tax by means of an improvement in the system of production, which reduces its expenses, is far different from repercussion, and is always benefi- cent in its effects.* CHAPTER VI. CLASSIFICATION OF TAXES. TAXES may be divided into classes according to different criteria, some of which are theoretically and practically important. In respect of the kind of property that the tax to be paid consists of we have to distinguish : i st. Imposts in kind (provisions, merchandise, services), which once were the rule, but now are an exception, and to be avoided as far as pos- sible ; 2d. Pecuniary imposts (in coin, money), which were once the exception, but are now the rule. In respect of the rules of assessment, we have * The question of shifting of taxation is not always sufficiently considered by law-makers, as it frequently enables the manufacturer to make a higher profit. For example, the tax on matches in the United States and England caused each box of matches to be sold at a higher price than the mere addi- tion of the tax would have caused, because the tax was less than the unit of the currency. In France it resulted in a very great deterioration of quality. Similarly with the tax on railway journeys and railway tickets. DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. 65 the distinction, already alluded to, of uniform im- posts and of graduated imposts, whether graduated proportionally or progressively. In respect of the permanent or transitory char- acter of the imposts, we have to distinguish : ist. The ordinary imposts which form an in- tegral part of the financial system, and are con- stantly repeated in every fiscal period ; 2d. Extraordinary imposts that are levied to meet exceptional wants (as, for instance, in war), and which cease with their disappearance. In respect to the nature of the property sub- jected to taxation, we have the well-known distinc- tion between direct and indirect imposts ; a dis- tinction, however, which is variously understood both in science and in practice. Some, in fact, call those imposts direct which, either effectively or according to the intent of the legislator, are a charge upon the person who pays them ; and indirect those that are provisionally paid into the treasury by certain persons, who secure the reimbursement of them from others, that is, from the real contributors. Others again call those imposts direct that are founded on essential and permanent relations be- tween the contributors and the treasury, which provides for their collection at fixed times by means of a roll of names ; and those indirect that are founded on relations merely accidental and 66 DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. temporary, and which, therefore, are usually col- lected by means of tariffs. Others, finally, and, as it seems, with more rea- son, call those imposts direct that are levied on wealth in its immediate manifestations (persons, income, estate) ; and indirect those that are levied on the secondary manifestations of the wealth of the contributors, such as transfers and consump- tion. In respect to the manner in which the sums to be paid are determined, especially in the depart- ment of direct imposts, are to be distinguished : ist. Imposts of apportionment or quota, where the public authority, having first fixed the sum which it intends to exact, distributes it, or causes it to be distributed, among the various subdivisions of the territory (quotas for the district, the prov- ince, the municipality, etc.), and finally among the single contributors, without fixing the individual quotas in advance ; 2d. Imposts of fixed assessment, in which the public authority without more ado fixes the amount to be paid by each individual subject to taxation, without determining in advance the sum to be paid in the aggregate. Where there happens to be available an exact list of property the difference between the system of apportionment and that of assessment is rather a matter of form than of substance. DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. 67 The system of apportionment answers the in- terests of the exchequer better, because it assures a fixed return ; that of assessment seems in gen- eral ^nore conformable to justice, although it opens a wider door to frauds. Direct imposts are divided into : ist. Real (objective, impersonal), when they are levied on property, without regard to the personal condition of the owner, and hence, without taking his debts into account. 2d. Personal (subjective), when they are levied on persons : (a) As such (poll tax). (<$) Or with reference to their economic condi- tion, as a basis for the calculation : (aa) In respect of income, or, (6$) Of property, or, as some less correctly put it, of capital. In respect of the mode of ascertaining the prop- erty, we distinguish : ist. The rigorous or exact systems, which re- quire a precise determination of the value of the thing subject to taxation, which may be made, (a) By the payer (declarations). (b) By the fiscal agent (official appraisements), (r) With the co-operation of both (verified dec- larations). 2d. The approximative systems, that are satis- fied with simple indications, or legal presumptions, 68 DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. concerning the value of the objects subject to tax- ation. In the matter of direct personal imposts on in- come, we may inquire into : i st. The actual income of the last fiscal period (for instance, during a year). 2d. The average income of a short definite period, the variations being thus more or less com- pensated (for instance, the average income of five or three years). Direct objective taxes, and among the personal taxes those on income and on property, may be general or special, that is, relating to all, or only to a few classes of income and of property. In the following chapters we shall inquire into : ist. Direct objective imposts on the produce of real property ; 2d. Direct personal imposts on income from movable property ; 3d. Direct imposts on transfers of property ; 4th. Indirect imposts on consumption ; 5th. Direct personal imposts on income and on property in general. DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. 69 CHAPTER VII. OBJECTIVE IMPOSTS ON THE PRODUCE OF REAL PROPERTY. THE impost on the produce of real property (called also predial, land and territorial Tax) was at one time the most important, and at times the only one, among direct imposts, and still retains to-day an important place in systems of taxation. It is subdivided into the two imposts, on the land and the buildings, which generally are regulated by somewhat different rules. SECTION i. Imposts on the produce of land. The land impost is levied on the gross or net produce of cultivated ground of every kind. In order to determine well the subject of this impost, we must know its nature (quality) and amount (measure). If we consider the nature of agricultural produce, it comprises : ist. The rent, in the technical sense of political economy, that is, what the land yields by itself ; 2d. The product of the capital invested in the land, that is : (a) Of the capital permanently invested in the land for improvements of every kind ; JO DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. (K) Of the working capital which serves for the cultivation, without being inseparably connected with the land (machines, implements, tools, pro- visions, etc.). 3d. The product of the agricultural labor (of the farmer and his hired hands) as such. By summing up the rent and the product of the capital expended in improvements we obtain the so-called proprietary revenue ; by summing up the produce of the active capital and that of agricul- tural labor, after deducting the wages of the labor- ers, we obtain the produce of the enterprise, that is, the agricultural profit. In some systems, especially in those founded on lists of real property (cadaster) the tax on the lands is only levied on the proprietary revenue, whilst the agricultural profit either remains exempt from direct imposts, or is subject to personal imposts on the income of movable property. If we consider the measure of the produce of the lands^ the imposts may be levied on either the gross or the net produce. The former method is the more simple, but unjust, and has now been aban- doned, because it overlooks differences of fertility and of tillage. By the second method we do not inquire into the actual produce of the year, but rather into the average produce of a long period (for instance, of a. decade), and, more frequently still, the usual produce of land cultivated with DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. /I ordinary diligence according to the systems of the country ; the variations are neglected, both as re- gards the quantity of the harvest and the price of the crop, and the debts with which the property is incumbered are subtracted. For the ascertainment of the amount of produce subject to impost, there are three systems, viz., es- timates, lists and declarations. The system of estimates is founded on the datum of an imperfect measurement of the land combined with inferences drawn from the amount of capital employed (plows, animals, seeds,, etc.) ; it is accordingly inexact and exceedingly un- just ; in fact, it became entirely unbearable with the increase of the impost, and by degrees was changed into the system of descriptions and of summary appraisements, which serve as a transi- tion to the more perfect method of cadaster (list, census). The cadaster (by regular survey of parcels) takes as a basis of the impost the exact topo- graphical description of the property, inquires concerning the respective proprietors, and makes a careful estimate of the produce of all the sepa- rate pieces of land. In some countries the cadaster, besides its fiscal and statistical purpose, performs also the juridical service of a basis for the ascertainment and trans- mission of real property. 72 DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. The operations of the cadaster are technical and economic. The technical operations comprise : i st. The measurement of the ground, based on the geodetical survey of the territory in general, or, rather, of the single taxable district. 2d. The topographical maps (plots), which are the graphic exposition of the results of the meas- urement, and which describe the grounds in their several parcels or plots, distinguished according to ownership, collocation, and tillage. 3d. The delineation of the boundaries and the ascertainment of ownership. The economic operations (estimates) consist in the pecuniary valuation of the taxable product. In order to avoid the difficulty of individual esti- mates of the single plots, this is executed accord- ing to a system of classification ; whence, having made the correct estimate of the average produce of a few specimen plots in every census district, and having compiled the relative scale of the prices of crops, the other plots are divided into classes, keeping in view the different kinds of cul- tivation and degrees of fertility. The estimates are thereupon completed : (a) According to the indirect or approximative method, which is based either on the purchase price of the landed property (combined with the datum of the normal rate of interest), or on the DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. 73 customary rental value. These data, however, are very often insufficient, constantly changing, and not always exactly proportional to the prod- uce. (K) Or by the method which some regard as rigorous and scientific, of direct inquiry into the value of the property subject to impost, through es- timates, made by experts, of the average or normal produce. The first instance of this was furnished by the famous Milanese census in the last century. The cadaster with all its documents (maps, reg- isters of property and owners) must be continued ; that is, must be kept up to date according to every change, whether in the persons or the property ; it must also be corrected periodically, in order to show modifications required by the introduction of new elements, by the elimination of old ones, and by the correction of material errors. The basis of the estimate, however, must always be maintained, except in the case of extraordinary re- visions (perequations). But the adherents of the so-called " consolidation of the land tax" raise very grave doubts as to the justice and convenience of these, because they maintain that in progress of time the impost is converted into a rent charge which is no burden to the owners who already have discounted it in a capitalized form in the pur- chase price of the property. The system of cadaster, which in some countries 4 74 DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. was at one time unquestioned, has now strong opponents. They complain of the slowness of the operation ; the excessive expenses ; the inexactness and inequalities caused by the decisions of the ex- perts ; by the different periods in which the opera- tion is performed, and by the uncertainty of the classification ; finally, of the unjust privilege enjoyed by certain owners of real property, the income from which, being augmented by successive im- provements, is subject to relatively trifling imposts. They accordingly desire to substitute for the system of cadaster that of declarations of the prop'rietors, revised by appointed commissions of control, a system which they regard as prompt and econom- ical, having yielded satisfactory results in the impost on buildings, and which, in accordance with the requirements of justice, is levied on the actual income, and not on the normal produce, which is a mere abstraction. In this manner the tax on the land would become a personal tax on the income. But the 7 system of declarations has likewise not a few opponents who fear the bad faith of the con- tributors, the difficulty of control and of applica- tion, especially in countries where property is much divided, where intellectual culture is slight, and agricultural book-keeping imperfect. They main- tain that the system of cadaster is a wise legacy handed down to us by our sires, and if not abso- DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. 75 lutely perfect, at all events does not afford oppor- tunity for arbitrary proceedings; that we are not justified in abandoning this system, considering its many advantages, other than the purely fiscal ones, that well repay the expense it causes, and that finally the revisions made at reasonable intervals diminish its dangers, which are, in fact, unavoidable in any system of taxation. SEC. 2. Imposts on the rent of buildings. The impost on buildings falls on the gross or net revenue of all kinds of structures. The direct impost on the rent of the buildings must be distinguished from the indirect impost on dwellings. The former is levied immediately on the mere income from buildings ; but the latter falls indirectly on any wealth inferred from the evidence of the so-called rental value of the house, whether inhabited by the owner or not. Exemptions, total or permanent, are allowed for buildings, which serve for any purposes of public defence, of worship, of beneficence, and partial or temporary exemptions to new structures. If we consider the nature of the rent derived from buildings, it comprises : ist. That of the ground, perfectly analogous to that of cultivated grounds, and which is extremely variable. 2d. That derived from the construction (from the building in a strict sense), to wit, the interest 76 DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. on the capital invested in the building an element, as a rule, but slightly variable. If we consider the measure of revenue derived from buildings, the impost will fall on either the gross or on the net revenue, which latter is ob- tained by deducting from the gross receipts the ex- penses of repair, insurance, and the yearly fund for reconstruction. In imposts on buildings, the various purposes for which they serve are often kept in view. Hence we should distinguish : i st. Farm dwellings, cottages intended for the use of laborers, for the housing of cattle, for the storage and first manipulation of agricultural prod- ucts. 2d. Town habitations in the more populous centres. 3d. Manufactories, in the case of which we must keep in view the large deductions required for re- pairs, insurance, etc., etc. Farm dwellings are usually subject to the land tax (forming generally a part of the cadaster), be- cause they are considered as intended for the pro- duction of an income from cultivated land. For the ascertainment of the taxable income we may adopt as in the case of the land tax the three systems of signs, official estimates and declarations. The system of signs, although once common, is very imperfect, because it infers the amount of the DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. 77 revenue from the uncertain criterion of the number of hearths, or of rooms, or of openings (doors and windows) toward the street. Even irrespective of the inconveniences which, without any profit to exchequer, the tax on doors and windows may pro- duce, especially in the case of houses inhabited by the poorer classes, it remains certain that the aforesaid elements are anything but correctly pro- portional to the income. In the system of official estimates we may adopt the approximative method, based on the data of purchase price, of cost of construction, or better still on that of the rent ; or the more rigorous method of estimates by experts, simplified as in the cadaster of landed property by means of classi- fication. The houses inhabited by their respective owners which give them a latent revenue (saving of ex- pense) should also be subject to taxation. Also houses, or the parts of them, which are not inhabited, and which do not yield any return, are frequently charged with an impost, because the lack of income is considered as only temporary. The system of declarations, although dangerous and on this account opposed by many theorists, still finds greater favor when it is applied to con- structions and not to the soil.. It is, in fact, to be observed : ist. That for town buildings the declarations of 78 DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. the owners can easily be verified by the datum of the rents. 2d. That when the declarations are revised at certain intervals (leaving aside the abstraction of " normal produce "), the impost may keep pace with the very appreciable variations of the effective income. 3d. That at all events the system of the official estimates, proceeding by classes and averages, under normal conditions at least, presents dangers that certainly are not less than those of the system of declarations. By the system of declarations accordingly the tax on buildings may be entirely or partly trans- formed into a personal tax on income. CHAPTER VIII. PERSONAL IMPOSTS ON INCOME DERIVED FROM MOVABLE PROPERTY. IN a perfect system of direct imposts we should tax the income from personal property, which in our time has greatly increased. This income is divided, in respect of its source, into : DERIVATIVE PUBLIC INCOME. 79 ist. Income from capital. 2 - ^. A I