^ <^l PRACTICAL BANKING WITH A SURVEY OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE ACT BY RALPH SCOTT HARRIS BOSTON NEW YORK CHICAGO HOUGHTON MIFFLIN COMPANY COPYRIGHT, 1915, BY RALPH SCOTT HARRIS ALL RIGHTS RESERVED CAMBRIDGE . MASSACHUSETTS U . S . A • * • • t 111 t « • I t t ' » t « c t « « C « C I , « c i tt c c *■ f c c • ^ I • * 3 J DEDICATED TO MY MOTHER AND FATHER PREFACE In putting this volume before the public, the writer has in mind at least two purposes which he hopes to fulfill: (1) to draw with certain accuracy of detail a plan of the structure — the mechan- ism — of the modern bank in America; (2) to reduce all this to untechnical language and yet include suflficient of exact financial information to enable the "layman" who is interested in the general methods of banking to grasp the subject substantially without laborious and endless effort. There is no subject, not essentially fiction, which yields such stimulating or romantic reac- tions as the study and practice of banking. In- deed, writers on the matter are more wont to use literary imagery than are delineators of science in general. Thus, one speaks of London as "the financial Rome of civilized nations," while an- other says that between the gold reserves on "the face of the earth " there is "the same aflSnity as between the blood corpuscles circulating in the organism." The very words "Wall Street," "Lombard Street," "Threadneedle Street," "The Bourse" suggest the boundless optimism of man, his (often) day-dreams and visions, his plans dashed to fragments or culminating in success. After all, finance is so intimate to every one of us we cannot but find an innate interest in the contemplation of it. The prosperity of nations is closely bound VI PREFACE up in the success or failure of its banking system. Thus a writer, speaking of the necessity of guard- ing in some way the metalHc reserve required for a country's own banking, says: "When a nation, carried away by the bhnd confidence of an already long period of easy credit and great prosperity, neglects more and more the metallic basis and the progress of other nations toward a clearing sys- tem, and thinks it can forever increase credit and exalt speculation, the crisis is at hand and will suddenly appear; then, as the penalty for ignor- ing the necessarily slow processes of evolution, it must submit to the humiliation of asking the world for help." ^ But, curiously enough, finance is blind to such considerations as patriotism and money seeks its best market, be it where it may. This levels the supply of gold in a country to what is necessary and, as Mr. Patron points out, results in an ironical situation often enough. He cites the transfer of two hundred million francs into France as the result of buying the Panama Company. This money, it seems, had largely come to the United States from Japan in payment of war material. France loaned a large part of it to Russia, and we had Japan actually furnishing gold to her enemy. This little volume, however, is not concerned in particular with world finance, but rather with the interior conduct of the average American bank. I have sought to make it intimate and, as far as it was interesting and profitable, to intro- ^ Maurice Patron, The Bank of France, in the National Mone- tary Commission Series. PREFACE vii duce the reader to some of the officers and officials of the bank, acquaint him with their duties, and, in fine, describe the actual conduct of banking from the mechanistic side. There are also several chapters dealing with more general phases of banking, such as that concerning "What is a Bank?" and the chapters on "The Clearing House," "National Bank Currency," "Foreign Exchange," and "The Federal Reserve Act." The writer does not presume to have said the final word on banking; indeed, he only assumes a certain originality as far as his observations and treatment are concerned. On the other hand, he has not altogether depended on his own experi- ence, but has sought the advice of numerous prac- tical banking men in New York and elsewhere, and has, moreover, searched the writers for con- firmation of his theories or for additional infor- mation. A working bibliography on banking is appended to this book. A number of other books, not specially consulted by the author for this book, are referred to in various places throughout the work. Finally, the main object of this work must not be forgotten, namely, that it is intended for the student of finance who wishes a glimpse into the practical conduct of the bank or for the business man who daily has relations with the bank and yet, as is most natural, is unfamiliar with the details of this most important institution of modern civilization. The personal acknowledgments of the author in the preparation of this little labor of love are viii PREFACE many and the obligations real. Without those whose names follow, the book would not have been possible. To Professor John Erskine, of Columbia Uni- versity, I owe most in this undertaking. It was he who first suggested it, and his patient criticism of the structure of the book was invaluable. Mr. John H. Frye, president of the Traders' National Bank, of Birmingham, Alabama, is responsible for several years of discipline and experience, wherein I received a first practical insight into bank meth- ods, and for innumerable courtesies. The late J. H. McEldowney, formerly vice-president of the National City Bank of New York, was of great assistance to my book in its inception. Hon. Oscar W. Underwood assisted me with the com- plete report of the National Monetary Commis- sion and valuable documents relating to the Federal Reserve Act. Mr. H. H. Powell, cashier of the Importers' and Traders' National Bank of New York, and Mr. William Scherer, manager of the New York Clearing House, furnished me with definite information in their respective fields. Mr. William E. Hollo way, banker. New York, read the manuscript and criticized it, as did Professor Charles A. Beard, of Columbia University, Mr. H. E. Davisson, formerly of the Foreign Depart- ment of the National City Bank, New York, and Mr. Olaf Olsen, vice-president of the First National Bank of Boston. The Librarian of Congress provided a bibliography on currency legislation. I am indebted to Mr. F. R. Macau- lay, Columbia University, for suggestions. Mr. Frederic Erb, Supervisor of the Loan Division, PREFACE ix Columbia University Library, was untiring in his courtesies from time to time. I gratefully acknowledge the assistance of Mr. Stanley V. La Dow, New York, in reading the proofs of this volume. Those whose books have proven more than valuable in preparing this work are too numerous to mention and must be looked for in the biblio- graphy. However, I will make particular mention of the following: Charles A. Conant, A History of Modern Banks of Issue; Wesley C. Mitchell, Business Cycles; James G. Cannon, Clearing Houses; and articles by Paul M. Warburg. Ralph Scott Harris. Columbia University, October 2, 1914. CONTENTS I. What is a Bank? 1 n. The Stockholders and the Board of Di- rectors 28 m. The President 35 IV. The Cashier 43 V. The Paying Teller 51 VI. The Receiving Teller 61 Vn. The Loan and Discount Department . 73 Vm. The Foreign Cash Items or Transit De- partment 84 IX. The Collection Department ... 91 X. The Domestic Exchange Department . 97 XI. The Individual Ledger 104 Xn. The Reciprocal or Bank Ledger . .110 XIII. The General Books 118 XIV. The Savings Department .... 123 XV. The Formation and Powers of the Na- tional Bank: 134 XVI. National Bank Notes 146 XVII. The Clearing House 161 XVin. Foreign Exchange 178 XIX. Crises in the United States . . .211 XX. The Federal Reserve Act .... 258 Appendix 289 Bibliography 297 Index 301 PEACTICAL BANKING CHAPTER I WHAT IS A BANK? When one ascends marble steps into some wonder of the American builder's art; as he moves through offices magnificently finished, seeing here a long line of wickets, each manned by a well-kept teller, who waits on the public; behind them a vast crowd of bookkeepers, listers, watchmen, collectors, and messengers; as he sees there desk after desk occupied by suave, sharp-eyed officers and assistants; as he notes with what smoothness, what consummate ease the business is divided and handled, like some huge power-machine, made of the best metal, — he is struck with admiration for a thing so immense, so far- reaching, yet so graceful and perfect. It is diffi- cult to imagine that the science which it is prac- ticing and developing — the science of banking and finance — had a beginning long, long ago, and that in the beginning it was a tiny, rude, undeveloped happening, not even a definite calling. Our task, in this chapter, will be to give, in a brief and succinct sketch, the origin and progress of banking. It is not within our province to go very deeply into the details of this theme, which 2 PRACTICAL BANKING itself might fill several portly volumes. But the intention is to cover generally the historical devel- opment of the bank, touching, however, only the great peaks, and to discuss the modern bank, and particularly the National Bank, in the United States. Those principles which underhe banking or finance, as we know it, have been applied since the first day men began to cooperate with each other. ^ It is the process of obtaining some desired article for an article which can be more easily spared. In those days there was no fixed stand- ard, like our currency, by which articles could be compared. Consequently, nothing like a regu- lar market could be instituted; each transaction stood on its own merit. There was exchange of articles which, on account of their practically equal utility to those trading, were of an equal commercial value. But this exchange was and is the basis of our banking system. As soon as you substitute the abstract for the concrete, the pay- ment or the promise to pay in an accepted medium for actual payment with an article of a practically , equal trading value, you have a modern banking system. In the rudest and most barbarous people of whom we have any historical record, glimpses of the employment of these general laws may be had. At first, it was a very simple exchange. A man had a very desirable dog, slave, or ox which he ^ The ultra-radical would say that they had been applied, not from the day men commenced cooperating, but from that day when the stronger began to oppress the weaker. I refrain from any com- ment on this distinction. WHAT IS A BANK? 3 would trade for a weapon, a skin, or a woman to work for him. Gradually rare substances, because of their comparatively little bulk or weight, be- came the more generally accepted medium of exchange, of which gold, silver, and bronze finally became the most common. That is, instead of a man waiting until his heifer had become a full- grown cow, which he might "swap" for a wife, he took an appropriate quantity of the medium, which he had obtained by digging or trading, and made the exchange. By slow degrees — for these evolutionary pro- cesses, it must be understood, were matters of many centuries of gradual development — people came to feel the inconvenience of carrying around coin or bullion in any quantity. Doubtless this was felt to an extraordinary degree in the city where iron was declared the standard money. So, finally, but with as much tardiness and suspi- cion as that which attended Charles Lamb's Chinese learning to roast pig without burning down a house, they became satisfied to accept, in place of money, the written promise to pay a specified sum at a definite time and place, and they had the genesis of paper currency. This paved the way, ultimately, for the creation of the bank, the check, and the currency bill. The function of banking which has to do with the extending of loans is spoken of in the far depths of history. In the early chronicles of the Hebrews are found injunctions against the taking of usury. But this, undoubtedly, preceded the actual business of lending. Then it was but the occasional lending by any man so inclined to one 4 PRACTICAL BANKING who wished to borrow. In other words, it was not yet a definite calHng. Banking, crude but genuine, may go back as far as a thousand years before Christ. Prior to that we have no assurance. It is probable that no institutional or private banking took place before that date, for, although it is estimated that man has been in his present physical and mental stage for something like 250,000 or 300,000 years, it is only within the last 5000 or 6000 years that he has accumulated enough experience — handed down mostly by tradition — to enable him to begin cooperative institutions. Taking, then, the familiar clock illustration, if the face represents 250,000 years, it has only been possible for banks to exist a httle over a minute now, and the national bank in the United States is not quite a second old. Assyria, as early as the seventh and even the ninth century before Christ, possessed a system of commer- cial instruments, which included promissory notes, bills of exchange, and transfer checks, not unlike the modern bank check. As this system was in operation before the use of coined money, these documents usu- ally stipulated for the payment of a given weight of silver or copper. They were not inscribed on paper, but on small clay tablets about the size of a piece pf toilet soap. After the contract had been written in the soft earth, it was baked so as to render it unalterable and indestructible. Such a form of paper naturally could not be subjected to indorsement or acceptance hke modern commercial paper; but this defect was supplied by the presence of witnesses, usually having a religious or legal authority. The original was placed Jov safe-keeping in either the temple or the record room WHAT IS A BANK? 5 of the city, inclosed in a clay envelope or case, while copies went to one or both of the contracting par- ties.^ Banking flourished in ancient Greece and Rome, though it was not a patrician calling. It exercised nearly all the fundamental functions of later banking, except the issuance of circulating notes. Deposits, payable on demand or at a stipulated time, were received. Sometimes interest was paid on these deposits. Bankers derived most of their profits from the lending of money at a high rate. They also engaged in the exchange of foreign money for that of Athens and Rome, and in the buying and selling of bills of exchange. Many complained of the high rates of interest, but bank- ers declared that they had to charge high interest in self-defense, because of the defective laws, ' ^ Charles A. Conant, A History of Modern Banks of Issue, p. 1. Mr. Conant gives the best account of the history of banking on the market. It is a fantastic and grotesque picture which one gets by mentally comparing the ancient Assyrian with a twentieth-century New Yorker. Say " Presto! " and suddenly discover yourself an interested onlooker in the capital of some old potentate like Tiglath Pileser II about three thousand years ago. Go into one of the Oriental, square, stone houses and see the lender and the borrower. The lender is clothed in shabby pale-yellow robes, unfaced and, alas, unwashed. His beard is that of Shylock and of every usurer who ever lived. He stands weighing out small blocks of silver to an anxious, nervous little fellow, type of the perennial money-borrower. Now, see the skillful fingers of Shylock guiding his cuneus through the wet clay. "Put the note on in two layers for safety," suggests little Lamb, and Shylock glares. Several funereal figures in spotless white have hovered silently by all the time. See them step up, examine the tablet, verify the weight, accept a cash offering for the gods from little Lamb, and carry away the note to bake it and put it in safe- keeping. Is it possible that the priests and Shylock exchange know- ing looks? No matter! Have we changed so much? 6 PRACTICAL BANKING which gave debtors every facility for escaping their obligations. Mr. Charles A. Conant^ has very interestingly pointed out that usurious rates led the plebeians to withdraw to the Sacred Mountain in 494 B.C. and to the Janiculum in 278 b.c. This, however, does not seem to have been the fault of the regular money-lenders at Rome, but of the patricians in their business intercourse with the plebeians. The evolution of banking at Rome was the same as everywhere else. "The argentarii (Roman bank- ers) were first money-changers, then receivers of deposits, then lenders at interest, both of their own money and of that entrusted to them, and purchasers of bills of exchange." After the fall of the Roman Empire in the West comes a gradual retrenchment of banking policy. This was a natural consequence upon the upset economic and trade conditions. Banking, even as it was known then, was dependent upon com- merce. Chaos followed the conquest ; the arteries of trade, the magnificent Roman military roads, fell into neglect, became infested by robbers, and were little frequented. Secondly, the predatory character of the unsettled and low-rumbling cen- turies, known as the "Dark Ages," rendered private property unstable; hence did away with credit security. These conditions inevitably drove metallic money to shelter. Therefore, we find a financial stagnation and chaotic situation in matters of banking until about the year 1100, when, with apparent suddenness, one encounters * Charles A. Conant, A History of Modern Banks of Issue. Mr. Conant cites Gustave Cruchon, Les Banques dans V AntiquiU. WHAT IS A BANK? 7 a reawakening of interest in cooperation and institutions. Now, when banking does revive in western Europe, it is seen undergoing the same process of evolution which took place in Assyria, Greece, and Rome. It began with the money-changers. Many people have called the famous "Bank of Venice" (1171) the first modern bank; but it exercised none of the modern bank's functions. It is thought that the word "bank" in this case simply refers to two forced public loans, which gave rise to this institution as a convenient method of repayment.^ Modern banking, however, may be more directly traced to the money-lenders of Florence, who flourished with a high reputation in the thir- teenth century. In the fourteenth century oc- curred the failure of two of Europe's greatest bankers, and for a time there was widespread dis- trust of the growing profession. But bankers had so far recovered lost ground that as early as the first generation of the fifteenth century there were eighty banks in Florence, although none were under state control. There has been a violent dispute as to the derivation of the word "bank" as we know and use it. Some have contended with much specious- ness that our word comes from the Italian "banco" meaning "bench," and refers to the boards which the money-changers of mediaeval Florence used as counters. These show that when a money-lender failed, his bench was broken in * It must be noted in a moment that the Bank of England originated in a somewhat similar way. 8 PRACTICAL BANKING token of his disgrace. Hence, from the words "banco" and "rotto," "to break," we get our word "bankrupt." Another faction contends, with perhaps even more speciousness, that they have no reference to benches, but mean "pubHc loans," a German word having been substituted for the Itahan.^ Toward the end of the sixteenth century bankers began to issue promissory notes payable to bearer, which passed from hand to hand and had a limited circulation. The institutions put- ting such notes into circulation earned the name of banks of issue. In comparatively recent years, ^ Charles A. Conant, A History of Modern Banks of Issue, p. 8: "The word 'bank' is derived from the public loans, made by Italian towns, rather than from the business of banking as understood in later times. The usual Italian word for a public loan was ' monte,' meaning a joint-stock fund. The Germans, who were influential in the Venetian forced loan of 1171, had a word for joint-stock fund, 'banck,' which meant a heap or mound. This the Italians converted into ' banco ' and used for an accumulation of either stock or money. The word was later adapted for English usage with the indifferent meaning of public loan or stacks of money. Benbrigge, in 1646, speaks of the 'three bankes' of Venice, meaning the three public loans or 'monti.' The issue of paper money directly by the state was spoken of as raising a 'banke' in colonial days in Massachusetts, the word ' bank ' standing for the money rather than the institution." Henry D. MacLeod, The Theory and Practice of Banking, vol. I, p. 259: " It is popularly supposed (Gilbart's Practical Treatise on Banking, vol. i, p. 1) that the word Bank comes from the Italian word banco, a bench or table, because the money-dealers or money- changers kept their money piled on benches or tables, whence it is said they were called banchieri. . . . Nevertheless, there can be no possible doubt but that this derivation is a pure illusion; for the money-changers, as such, were never called banchieri in the Middle Ages." MacLeod quotes Blackstone as follows: "At Florence, in 1344, Government owed £60,000, and being unable to pay it, formed the principal into an aggregate sum, called, metaphorically, a Mount or Bank." WHAT IS A BANK? 9 however, it has come to be more and more gener- ally believed that the issuance of circulating notes should fall within the province of the Govern- ment, or at least of banks under state control. Among the very earliest of these banks of issue was the Bank of Amsterdam, which in the seven- teenth century received deposits of gold or silver bullion, for which it issued certificates or receipts. These receipts passed from person to person and served as a somewhat rude circulating medium. They were redeemable at the bank in the metal which they represented through the payment of a small premium. This very famous bank was formed in 1609 un- der the direction of the city and was governed by a secret municipal committee. It was ostensibly founded to remedy the chaos which prevailed in the city at the time on account of sharply com- peting money-receivers and on account of the confused coinage. Persons were forbidden, by city ordinance, to place their money in the hands of any deposit-receiver save their personal agents. All bills of exchange were required to be negoti- ated through the new bank. The bank professed not to lend, but to retain in its coffers the actual money deposited, charging a small percentage for safe-keeping. These deposits were represented by receipts which were transferable. Later, the bank accepted deposits of foreign coin at their intrinsic value and issued receipts payable in "gulden." Upon this professed basis the bank had a long and prosperous career. However, it had actually violated its charter within a half- century after its foundation by allowing consider- 10 PRACTICAL BANKING able overdrafts, and in the eighteenth century it extended huge loans to the Dutch East India Company. The depositors learned of this in 1790, and in 1794 discovered that it could not pay its liabilities. Its notes fell from a premium of five per cent to a discount of sixteen per cent. It was governmentally dissolved in 1819, and its place was taken by the Bank of the Netherlands, founded in 1814. Banking methods seem to have been introduced into England in the seventeenth century by London goldsmiths, who probably borrowed them from the Dutch. It is related that the goldsmiths or "new-fangled bankers," as they were called, soon gained such a foothold that they were able, at considerable profit to themselves, to supply Cromwell with funds in advance of the revenues. At the time, one Sir Josiah Child violently at- tacked the new profession, though, curiously enough, he later became a banker himself, and his firm, with one other, are the only private houses still in existence which were established earlier than the Bank of England. The Bank of England was organized in 1694 for the purpose of extending a loan of £1,200,000 to the Government for public service. The sub- scribers to this fund were to receive eight per cent per annum as interest, and £4000 per year as running expenses for the bank. How this institu- tion has developed into the greatest financial agency in the world, controlling the discount rates of every English banking house and setting the foreign exchange rate, will be spoken of from time to time in the following chapters. WHAT IS A BANK? 11 In 1619 the Bank of Hamburg, Germany, was formed on the same principles that the Bank of Amsterdam professed- It had good management throughout. In the different German States, banks were formed from time to time under their own pecuHar laws. In 1875 the Imperial Bank of Germany (the "Reichsbank") was authorized, which is the bank of Germany to-day. At present there are about one hundred and forty banks doing business in Germany aside from the government banks. For it must not be thought that the "Reichsbank" is the only gov- ernment bank in the empire, though it is undoubt- edly the controlling financial agency. The five banks having the right of uncovered note issue, with the amounts permitted to be issued, are: — • Imperial Bank of Germany $115,000,000.00 Bank of Saxony 4,000,000.00 Bank of Bavaria 8,000,000.00 Bank of Wurttemberg 2,500,000.00 Bank of Baden. 2,500,000.0 $132,000,000.00 About a century after the founding of the Bank of Hamburg, — 1716, to be exact, — John Law organized the Banque Generate in France. It was favored by the Government and seemed to have in store a promise of financial and economic stim- ulation. But Law undertook to affiliate it with his gigantic "Occidental" schemes, and in 1718 found it necessary to ask for governmental aid. The institution became known in that year as the Banque Royale; its notes were guaranteed by the king. But Law's "Mississippi scheme" was too much, and though advantages were offered to 12 PRACTICAL BANKING those who paid taxes in bank bills, and though cash money was forbidden, confidence so fell that in 1721 the bank was closed, through the influence of Paris-Duverney, Law's bitterest opponent. In 1767, under the eminent economist, Turgot, the bank was revived and existed on a pretty sound basis till it became involved in the issuance of assignats during the Revolution and was closed by the Convention in 1793. No financial institution was again attempted until 1800, when Napoleon founded the present Bank of France. A solid foundation was not se- cured until 1806. Its capital at first was 30,000,000 francs. It made large loans to the Provisional Government and to the city of Paris in 1848, and was near failure. But the Government came to the rescue, allowing it to stop cash payments and declaring its notes legal tender. For nearly fifty years the Bank of France was only one of a number of banks having a note issue. Until 1848 departmental banks of issue existed. These, however, and the Bank of Savoy were absorbed by 1863; since then, the Bank of France has been supreme. Its capital at the pres- ent time is 182,500,000 francs, held by about 30,000 shareholders, of whom about 10,000 do not own more than one share. It has had a vigorous administration and is to-day one of the best regu- lated financial institutions in the world. It has one hundred and eighty-eight branches (comp- toirs) and two hundred and seventy-nine agen- cies. Every class has derived benefit from this bank, but none more than have the agriculturists. This is because the bank accepts bills as low as $1 WHAT IS A BANK? 13 and loans as low as $50. In 1906, it discounted $2,500,000,000 in bills and loaned $500,000,000 on securities. Three names are usually required on bills. This bank's deposits are comparatively small, being only $175,000,000. But it has an enormous note issue — $900,000,000 in 1906. In its vaults (1906) it had $575,000,000 in gold and $200,000,000 in silver. On account of its large cash reserve, it can keep discount rates at a rather uniform level. From 1900 to 1906 the rate (3%) did not change. Bank of France notes are more popular as exchange than checks. With regard to the banking history of the United States, only a few words are necessary here. Before 1776 there was very little attempt at banking for commercial purposes. Many crude attempts were made, but mainly for the issuance of paper money. However, in 1740, this was stamped out by the extension of the "Bubble Act" to the colonies. The first real bank was an institution organized by the citizens of Penn- sylvania to supply the patriot army with rations. Its bills were not more than promissory notes, signed and warranted by the bank's founders. These were supposed to be guaranteed by govern- ment bills on American citizens abroad for $750,- 000. It is doubtful, however, if they could have been negotiated. The attempt was not made. In 1781, Congress authorized William Morris to organize the Bank of North America at Phila- delphia. It took over the business of the Bank of Pennsylvania. There was so much doubt as to the right of Congress to carry on a banking business that the institution was incorporated 14 PRACTICAL BANKING under the laws of Pennsylvania, and so continued until 1863, when it became a national banking association. In the year 1791 the Bank of the United States, with a capital of $10,000,000, was chartered by Congress.^ The United States Government bought one fifth of the stock. Notwithstanding its government patronage, a number of state banks sprang up. But by its superior capital and several branches, the Bank of the United States domi- nated the finances of the country. It refused de- posits of notes of banks which it considered un- sound, and thus tended to keep down "wild cats." In 1811 the charter expired and no vigorous effort was made to renew it. In 1816, however, it was renewed with a capital of $35,000,000, of which the Government took $7,000,000. Presi- dent Jackson, by his veto of the second renewal charter in 1832, practically crushed the bank. From that time state banks sprang up with great rapidity, so that in 1837 there were 634 of them with a capital of $291,000,000, of which $149,000,- 000 was in circulating notes and $127,000,000 in deposits. Loans and discounts amounted to $525,- 000,000. The enormous crop of cotton in 1836 and the subsequent fall of prices came as a begin- ning of the inevitable crash. In 1837 there was suspension of cash payments. By strict laws of Congress and the state legislatures, the country nearly recovered by 1844. ^ ^ It was decided in the famous case of McCulIough vs. Maryland that the Federal Government could operate a bank. 2 Mr. Conant gives a lucid account of this in A History of Modern Banks of Issue. WHAT IS A BANK? 15 The panic of 1837 was the deathblow to the United States Bank. After President Jackson's action, it had operated for a time under the laws of Pennsylvania. Following the downfall of the central bank, the United States adopted the in- dependent treasury system. The New York safety fund plan, upon which our contemporary bank- ing methods in this country are based, was worked out between 1837 and 1844. In 1864, to create a market for its bonds, the United States Govern- ment passed an act providing for the national bank, which was to be a bank of issue. The field was cleared of state banks of issue, as competi- tors, by a prohibitive tax on their circulation. With some alterations, the banks thus author- ized are the national banks of to-day. With regard to state banks, it is hard to find general terms to describe them, since every State has its own peculiar banking laws. They have grown at an amazing rate, notwithstanding governmental favor toward the national bank, until there are to-day upward of ten thousand of them in the country. In general, the state banks are regulated very much like the national banks, and exercise practically the same functions, except in the mat- ter of issuing circulating notes and acting as regu- larly designated federal depositories.! II Fundamentally and largely, the business of the bank is an exchange of credit. Mr. Frank A. Vanderlip, in his Columbia University lecture on ^ See Digest of State Banking Statutes, by Samuel A. Welldon, National Monetary Commission Series. 16 PRACTICAL BANKING the "Modern Bank," says: "The business of a bank is not in the main the reception of money and its safe-keeping, nor is it the lending of money. The money transactions of a bank are, under ordinary conditions, comparatively insig- nificant; almost its entire business consists of receiving, from its customers, their evidences of indebtedness, which have a narrow currency, and giving to these customers in exchange the bank's evidences of indebtedness, which have a wide currency. These evidences of a bank's indebted- ness are then transferred from one individual to another and from one bank to another. And in that way, the credits created serve the purpose of the medium of exchange, by wliich perhaps ninety- five per cent of the exchange transactions of com- merce take place." Then follow these sentences, which will throw rather a new light on the matter for most people: "It is a misconception to suppose that a bank first accumulates deposits and then loans them out to borrowers. The operation is the reverse. The bank first makes a loan to the borrower, and in so doing creates a deposit. The borrower exchanges his evidence of indebtedness for the bank's credit, a deposit balance. The creation of these credits has relation to production; their liquidation is related to consumption. If produc- tion increases, the demand for this exchange of individual credit for bank credit increases; and the indebtedness incurred is liquidated as the ar- ticles upon which the financial credit was based enter into consumption." This, then, puts an aspect on the matter which WHAT IS A BANK? 17 many have not thought of. Doubtless a large percentage of bank customers, without any partic- ular reflection, imagine their deposits represented, as in the old Bank of Amsterdam, by huge bags and trays of money stowed away in the vaults. How a bank makes its money without lending is a question which may not enter these people's minds. They have an idea that, in some mysteri- ous way, all will go well with the bank, that from unknown sources it will be miraculously supplied with funds from which to extend loans. They even conceive that a bank lends them actual money, simply because it offers its credit and promises to redeem in cash, if demanded, any drafts against this credit. As a matter of fact, very few loans are made in cash. This holds true among the larger banks in a greater degree than among the smaller. Just so, it follows that most deposits are not made in cash money, but in discounts or credits of other banks, i.e., checks. And in the same sense it is true that the larger the bank, the nearer it comes to depending entirely on the buying of paper and extending of loans for creating deposits, or, in other words, the "exchanging of the custom- er's credit with a narrow currency for the bank's with a wide currency." It must not be misunderstood that small banks do not receive a large block of their deposits from cash sources, for they do; but averaging the deposits of the banks of the country, it will be found that probably far over fifty per cent of the deposits consists of those created by extension of credit. 18 PRACTICAL BANKING Now, expanding somewhat Mr. Vanderlip's last statement, we may see directly how the crea- tion of credits relates to production, and liquida- tion of debts relates to consumption. Take a merchant who wants to buy a supply, say, of cotton or woolen goods. It may, for many reasons, be inconvenient for him to pay cash for them out of his assets — in fact, he probably keeps most of his cash working; or he may venture somewhat beyond his present assets, in which there is surely nothing illegitimate, for only thus is business progress made. So he goes to his bank, with which he probably has an arrangement for credit, and exchanges his note, or discounts obligations of others in his favor, for a credit on the bank ledger. It should be parenthetically observed here that banks do not ordinarily tie up their credit in per- manent or long-time investments, as they must arrange the maturity of paper so that there is a continual stream of repayment. Now the bank's credit to the merchant has made it possible for the manufacturer to produce the goods. It might have been simpler to have taken the case of the manufacturer in the first instance, but the merchant was chosen to show that it works back to the production in any event. Under normal conditions, the merchant disposes of his purchases in due time, and, with the pro- ceeds, is enabled to liquidate his indebtedness at its maturity. Thus is production directly related to the extension of credit, and consumption to the liquidation of debt. WHAT IS A BANK? 19 III After what has been said, it must be plain that a bank cannot hold cash against the total of its deposits, since so many of its deposits are created by the extension of a credit on its books, in which transaction no cash enters. And if it only received cash deposits, for which it actually held cash in reserve, it could only lend out its capital stock; in which case where would be the necessity of depositors at all? As a matter of fact, a certain volume of cash is held in reserve against all probable demands; for extraordinary demands the bank depends on its ability to call in loans and obtain cash from other banks. All national banks and most state banks are required to carry a certain amount of cash reserve. Cities and towns in the United States under the National Banking Act, are divided into three classes, as regards national banking reserves: (1) central reserve cities; (2) reserve cities; (3) those cities and towns not included under the two previous heads. There are three central re- serve cities — New York, Chicago, and St. Louis — in which, by United States statute, national banks must keep an amount of cash reserve in their vaults equal to twenty-five per cent of their deposits, not including deposits of public money, i.e., federal deposits. Banks in these cities may be used as depositories of a certain part of the reserve of other banks. Banks in forty-seven reserve cities must keep a reserve of twenty-five per cent of their deposits, but one half of it may consist of deposit 20 PRACTICAL BANKING balances in central reserve cities. All other na- tional banks need carry a reserve of only fifteen per cent, of which two fifths must be carried in their vaults, while three fifths may consist of de- posit balances in either central reserve or reserve cities. A national bank's reserve has to consist of gold or silver, or its equivalent.^ From this it may be seen that banks could not redeem all their deposits in cash on demand if there should be a sudden demand for all at one time. This reflects not at all on the institutions, for every customer is in just the same position, else he would not borrow. If every bank should demand immediate payment of all its credits, how many customers could comply.? Since few could, the matter of demand of payment should be cooperative. The customer should be as fair with the bank as he expects the bank to be with him. Too many people cannot understand why perfectly solvent banks are sometimes tempora- rily embarrassed. This lack of consideration is one of the chief reasons. Many a good bank goes down undeservedly because of this lack of cooper- ation. Banks conduct their business — and this is surely a matter of common knowledge — solely for lucrative results. They are not philanthropic institutions. They are selfish and make profits as large as possible. Therefore, it is perfectly reason- able to believe that they will lend as much as possible, still retaining a safe margin for demands. It is not the purpose of this book, however, to * Since reserve requirements will be readjusted under the Federal Reserve Act, it will be well to refer to chap, xx for this information. WHAT IS A BANK? 21 disparage the value of a required reserve. It is one of the most salutary provisions of our banking system. It prevents dangerous inflation, which would most certainly take place unless there were this necessary check. It is by no means advised that every bank customer should trust his banker blindly, or even trust him at all. But the banker ought to be shown every reasonable consideration which one business man looks for from another. To round off this discussion of the reserve, and to give an idea of the comparatively little cash in the country, a few figures are appended. It simply goes to prove our earlier remarks in regard the to the most of our business, which is conducted that iJong lines of credit. Cash, after all, has the same At thfc'ity in business that it has in the clearing house announcecin foreign exchange. It merely represents c^^g^^te^jjjlifference between debits and credits. presume tte figures show the amount of cash money in now after , . Germany aiuitcd States on January 3, 1910: — territory t' KeliCid coin, including bullion in the The Sh Treasury. Of this about one half demned ^g^g jjj j-j^g Treasury to secure gold K^TGse certificates $1,638,108,821 Stat" Standard silver dollars. Of this four fifths was to secure silver certificates. . . 564,334,719 Subsidiary silver 162,801 ,137 Treasury notes of 1890 3,942,000 United States notes 340,681,016 National bank notes 710,354,253 Total .$3,426,221,946 This total was just $2,380,102 less than on December 1, 1909, or about thirty days previous. 22 PRACTICAL BANKING However, January 3, 1910, shows $6,797,402 less in gold than on December 3, 1909. This was prob- ably caused by the redemption of many gold certificates with gold bars and coin. About this time, Americans had to pay an immense lump of dividends on their securities held by foreigners. If the exchange market was short, as it usually is at this time of the year, it was necessary to export gold to pay our debts. Therefore, a major portion of the difference in gold for the two dates was probably exported coin and bullion. But six and three quarter millions is not a great sum for pay- ing our obligations at dividend time, when we read on April 25, 1910, that five New York banks in one day engaged to ship over the ocean $12,- 500,000. The truth is, the six and three quarter millions was merely the difference between our available credits and what we owed abroad. The silver and national bank note accounts gained January 3, 1910, $4,457,800, or just enough to offset the loss in gold, a slight decrease in treasury notes of 1890, and leave the total slump of $2,380,102. The amount of money in circulation of January 3, 1910, was $3,122,154,538, as against $3,092,- 315,703 for January 2, 1909, as against $816,266,- 721 on January 1, 1879. The amount of money held in the Treasury as cash assets of the Govern- ment on January 3, 1910, amounted to $304,067,- 408. This did not include, however, government deposits in national banks amounting to $35,- 324,066.85. WHAT IS A BANK? 23 IV Since the lending of credits is so important a part of the bank's business, it is well to give a little time to an explanation of the principal methods of extending credit, namely, commercial paper and secured paper. With regard to ma- turity there are two divisions, — time and de- mand loans. Probably two thirds of the credit extended in the United States, by and large, consists of com- mercial paper. This is simply the promise of an individual, group of individuals, or corporation to pay a certain sum either on demand or at some definite time. This paper is made in settlement of, or to provide funds for, some commercial trans- action, hence the name "commercial." A note for a stock of dry goods or for a car of wheat would be a piece of commercial paper. Although it is true that a large part of this paper is given with- out collateral security, this should not be taken as a primary distinction. The real distinction between commercial paper * and ordinary loans is that the former is considered a piece of merchan- dise,^ so rendered by the fact that it liquidates itself, while the latter consist(l) of "receivables" taken in the ordinary course of business for debts, and (2) of loans based on collateral. ^ Just what will constitute " commercial paper" under the Fed- eral Reserve Act is in doubt. (See chap, xx.) But genuine com- mercial paper should be self-liquidating, that is, represent trans- actions which will before maturity of the note put sufficient cash in the obligee's hands to pay it. ^ Hence, one occasionally hears it called "mercantile" paper in some banks. 24 PRACTICAL BANKING A secured paper is a note whose payment is guaranteed by collateral, such as stocks, bonds, notes, and, in some cases, mortgages on real estate. It would be safe to say that in this class of loans, the banker depends less on the signer than on the collateral. But this is natural, for such loans are the more important ones, so far as individual amounts are concerned, and individual and personal promises are not usually considered acceptable. The larger the city and the larger the bank, the more impersonal become these trans- actions. The amount loaned on collateral varies as the reputation of the security. It is customary to demand collateral at least twenty per cent in excess of the amount of the loan. Sometimes, as in the case of real estate, more excess is required, while at other times, in such cases as United States gold, interest-bearing bonds, less excess or none at all is required. Under the new Federal Reserve Act, national banks, hitherto denied the privilege, may make loans on farm lands, provided the lending banks are not located in central reserve cities. Generally speaking, however, loans on real estate are con- fined to savings banks and trust companies. It is imperative, as we have seen, that the banker so arrange his paper that it is constantly maturing. To be sure, the credits are immediately reloaned, but for the sake of good banking, repay- ments must be so pouring in that, in case of an unexpected heavy demand, within a few days the bank could gather enough, together with its call loans, to meet the emergency. So it is not custom- ary to make long investments, beyond a certain small percentage. WHAT IS A BANK? 25 The call loan of New York is distinct from that of other parts of the country and yet it probably illustrates the principle of call or demand loans better than any other. The New York call loan represents a sum loaned out, usually on the secur- ity of stocks or bonds. It may be demanded at any time by the lender or paid at any time by the borrower. There is, however, a long-observed custom of neither demanding nor tendering pay- ment after one o'clock of a business day. When there is a financial stringency, it will be observed that the great bankers take more call loans than usual, though it be at a lower rate. They prefer to have the option of immediate col- lection in case of emergency. So the prices charged for call money vary from day to day as there is greater or less demand than supply. Many firms take advantage of the call money market for a part of their borrowing. For in- stance, they carry one third to one half of their line of credit in time loans, and depend on favor- able chances on the call market for the balance, as it is needed. Call loans are made in two ways: first, in pri- vate, that is, at the lending bank; and second, at the "money post" on the Stock Exchange. Of the first, there is nothing to remark beyond the fact that the prospective borrower with his security makes a loan from the bank ofifering the best inducements. The " money post " on the Stock Exchange floor is the place where the representatives of the banks and the brokers meet at eleven o'clock each busi- ness day. Banks have at that time heard from the 26 PRACTICAL BANKING clearing and have calculated whether they can lend or must call in. On the other hand, the brok- ers probably know whether they have a surplus or need to borrow. In about an hour the transac- tions are largely over. However, around two o'clock there is a little bustle, as unexpected money may have come in or unexpected demands have been made. Lending money and issuing circulating notes, then, in a very concrete and tangible way, are the important functions of the bank. These, indeed, are the two functions — and of the two, lending is the greater — upon which the entire banking theory rests. The other functions are merely incidental. As Mr. Vanderlip has shown, banks do not go out and gather in deposits in order to lend; but they make a loan, by which process they create a deposit. Of course, this could not apply to the odds and ends of loans, where a person is paid in cash for the proceeds of his paper, but it is a general rule for the making of loans and amassing of deposits. Deposits are not a bank's desideratum. They are but an incident, a necessary incident, however, to the end of lend- ing more money than the capital stock. Looking back over the centuries which have elapsed since the uncouth savage bartered a wild boar's hide for a robust female to cheer his hut; following the ever-ameliorating attempts at banking among the Greeks and Romans; among the Florentines, who were so honest — it is said — that a ruined banker's bench was broken; among the ever-confiding but wrathful Dutch who were swindled by the Bank of Amsterdam; among the WHAT IS A BANK? 27 suspicious Englishmen, one of whom thought the new-fashioned bankers preposterous, though he consented to become one himself, — up to the present day with its fine science of finance, we are constrained to feel proud of the race for this achievement alone. To-day our banks unite the aesthetic with the practical. Great marble build- ings, showing the result of centuries of architec- tural progress, are the homes of great financial institutions, reflecting the outcome of centuries of advance toward an*ideal for facilitating busi- ness and making comfort and happiness more the province of all. And to-day's accomplishments are but prophetic fingers pointing to a greater and a better future. CHAPTER II THE STOCKHOLDERS AND THE BOARD OF DIRECTORS As we now turn from the foregoing brief account of the beginning of banking and a few of its intricate details to a ghmpse into the different departments, as they are every day, it will be pleasant to fancy ourself^es visiting personally the several officers and employees. With true, financial suavity they will receive us and take great pleasure in explaining the mechanics of their system. It is even possible that occasionally they may take us into their confidence and relate one or two " inside " secrets. But we must not expect too much of this, for, after all, we are on a tour of in- spection of the machinery of banking, and shall not attempt to expose the results of unscrupulous men's tampering with the public trust. Why do men organize a bank.^^ First, to increase the facilities for handling a huge credit business, such as ours, and to improve the service by a wholesome competition. Second, to make money, to use their capital in a fashion that will make it "spin out" the farthest. Both these, after all, resolve themselves simply into the American magic passwords, "Make money." So we may look upon the bank as a selfish, not a benevolent, institution. And oftentimes, alas, it is a clever means of exploiting other people's money. But let us consider it here as a square, honest organiza- tion, formed with some idea of cooperation. STOCKHOLDERS AND DIRECTORS 29 When a group of men set about to organize a bank, capital stock is one of the first considera- tions. The amount of capital is decided upon, and a certain block of it is put on the market for pur- chase by the public. This may be because they are not able to subscribe it all themselves or — which is more probable — it may be because of the desire to popularize the new company. Thus a portion of the capital stock becomes the prop- erty of a scattered number of people. This is one means of exploiting other people's money, for their scattered and unorganized voice is of little avail, even if combined they own more than one half of the stock. Those who subscribe stock in the bank pay either in cash or on short time. Under most banking laws, they may not exercise the functions of stockholders until they have paid for their shares. Almost the only features of the business in which they actively participate are the election of directors and the reception of divi- dends. The first is a duty; the second, a sweet and pleasing reward of duty well performed. Shareholders may authorize the change of name or location of their associations, but this is of little general importance, since the occasion for its exercise rarely arises. They also have the power of allowing the reduction or increase of capital stock. They are liable for all of the debts of the bank, but usually only in the proportion which their stock bears to the total capital. Ordinarily, the meeting of the stockholders for the election of directors takes place once per an- num. This meeting is announced generally in several newspapers, and notices of it are mailed to 30 PRACTICAL BANKING each qualified participant. The meetings are called at some definite time, provided for by law or by the rules of the association. A majority of the stock is required, either by the presence of its owner or by proxy, to elect. After the directors are chosen, the responsibility of the stockholders is removed and they resume their ordinary voca- tions with an eye on the dividend month, hoping to reap the fruit of their wisdom in an abundant income from their stock. But we may assume that the scattered holdings of stock have little voice in these elections; in fact, rarely attend. It may be noted here that, in a great number of instances, a comparatively small coterie of men own a majority of stock; and these men will, of course, constitute the board of directors. The bank is a corporation, — one owned by a large number of people, but actually controlled by a few shareholders, who possess perhaps more than fifty per cent of the stock. However, it is demo- cratic to have the stock distributed among many people; it advertises and popularizes the associa- tion. In the case of a newly organized bank, the first oflBcial act of the board of directors, after taking the oath of office and selecting a chairman, is to draw up a set of by-laws and regulations to govern their own procedure and the conduct of the bank. This is often enough submitted to the stockholders for ratification. As soon as possible must come the selection of officers for the bank, — the board's personal representatives. These officers are a president, a cashier, and whatever others it may be necessary to have. STOCKHOLDERS AND DIRECTORS 31 The general policy of the bank is in the keeping of the directors. They meet every so often, and as they command, the oflBcers must do. Of course, it would be impracticable for the entire board to try to manage the details of the association. In this business, as in every other, the executive power over affairs of everyday routine should be single, not multiform. Yet there is a great variation in the degree of supervision which the directors assume. In some banks they meet as often as three or four times a week, consider every application for credit, and work out in detail plans for the conduct of the business. In others, they are not nearly so active and trust a great deal more to the business ability and integrity of their president. In general, the distinction between the former class and the latter is the distinction between a large and a small bank. However, couched in general terms, the duties of the board are largely "legislative, appointive, supervisory, or advisory." The frequency of its meetings varies greatly in different banks. One meeting a year, or two, at which dividends are declared, officers elected, and the past year's prog- ress reviewed, is considered sufficient in some institutions; in others, as already said, a meeting occurs several times weekly. The larger the asso- ciation, as is evident, the more necessary are these meetings. But it has been the practice of the Comptroller of the Currency to try to make directors really direct, that is, meet regularly and as often as necessary. For their attendance the directors are paid from $2.50 to $20 per meeting. 32 PRACTICAL BANKING In order to insure prompt attendance, some cor- porations place the fees on the table before each director's place; five minutes after the meeting is called to order, those who are present divide the absentee directors' fees among themselves. This plan has been found to have a marvelous effect in insuring prompt attendance on the part of directors. By reason of the trust reposed in him, every director's duty demands that he be absolutely conscientious and that he always act in a manner best calculated to meet the needs of the bank as a whole. The board of directors is the source of all mo- tive power in the bank's operation. Upon the directors, finally, depends whether it will succeed or fail. How important that they be men of in- tegrity and honor ! As a rule, the directors of a bank are men of unquestioned ability. If we were to run through the names of the board of some huge New York institution, for instance, we should probably find railroad magnates, mine operators, professional men of note, and wizards of many branches of commerce and trade. When they se- lect the officers of the bank, the directors employ their best judgment. The attitude, ability, and general experience of the president and cashier will count for nearly everything in the earning of profits. Likewise their honesty and trustworthi- ness in carrying out orders, their fidelity to duty, and their high reputation for reliability will be items of vast importance. Since the bank must exist and subsist on pub- lic patronage, it is not hard to discover that an STOCKHOLDERS AND DIRECTORS 33 officer should either be a man already popular or one hkely to become popular. Other things being equal, a prominent man is preferable. Sometimes a very prominent man, who cannot act, allows his name to be used as president for the prestige it gives his bank. Now, as has been already seen, the power granted the president depends largely on local conditions and the attitude of the direc- torate. Usually, however, the president will be the instrument of the board. He will have much power and much will be left to his discretion, but the board will hedge him in by its resolutions. In selecting a cashier, practically the same requisites are asked for. He must be a man of executive talent and one with practical and eco- nomical views. Also he ought to be willing to subordinate his ideas to those of the president. This insures frictionless running for the bank. Directors are supposed to keep vigilant eyes on the officers for the protection of stockholders and depositors. This vigilance extends to actual auditing, in large banks, at least. The writer knows of many banks, for instance, where every year a committee of directors counts all of the cash in the bank and, approximately, at least, makes it balance with the general bookkeeper's record. The board also watches "Liabilities and Resources," seeing that resources are properly apportioned. For instance, "Loans and Dis- counts" might run above a safe figure and need reducing, or — for some reason — "Reserve" might be too low and need increasing. On the other hand, the executive may sometimes have to be gently prodded for overconservatism, amount- 34 PRACTICAL BANKING ing even to sluggishness. Also the bank may not be growing and expanding as it should, or its serv- ice may not be satisfactory; the board sets about to correct the defects. This may extend even to displacing officers and employees. The directors lend stimulus to the business. Their influence brings desirable patrons and adds prestige to the institution. They give additional security to the depositors; it is harder to find ten dishonest men than one. Their usefulness con- sists in the very diversity of their vocations. Discussion and varied experience will always evolve better general working principles than the reflections of a single mind. They are the repre- sentatives of the stockholders, and act as checks on the conduct and manipulations of the oflBicers. CHAPTER III THE PRESIDENT The primary power in the government of the bank Hes, of course, in the stockholders. But it would be the height of absurdity to contemplate the entire body of shareholders trying to manage the bank personally. The directorate is small; it may be composed of only five men. But even the directors are busy men, engaged so deeply in com- mercial or professional activities that they could not find time personally to conduct the bank's transactions. Further, it is a very well-believed doctrine that many hands in the personal control of an enterprise tend to disrupt it rather than to bind and cement it. These complications are anticipated by our national and state banking laws, which require the election, by the stockholders, of a directorate, and by it, of a suitable number of ofiicers. The directors have general control of the policy of the bank, while the officers personally carry out these policies and work out the details. However, it must be understood that the subordinate officers are under the direct command of the president, who is chief executive and plans the large features of the bank's work. The president is, then, the personal representa- tive and, after a fashion, the mouthpiece of tlie directorate, primarily, and of the stockholders, indirectly. 36 PRACTICAL BANKING There are all sorts of presidents and presiden- cies. They are found in the range from the little two-clerk bank at the cross-roads, through the gamut of town and city banks, to the largest institutions of the metropolis. It is natural that the duties and requirements of a president, the capital of whose bank is $10,000, will differ funda- mentally and in detail from those of the president whose bank is capitalized at $25,000,000. In the little bank, while crops are growing and business is dull, the president is likely to take down his faithful breech-loader and go out for a day's hunt. In the great city, he is constantly at his desk, poring over schemes for making a little shorter cut than a competitor. He carries his business to his home and to his bed. For perhaps a month in the year, he may steal away for a hurried trip to Europe or a scurry over the western wonders of our own land. But even there, he is in constant communication with his institution, and not in- frequently directs some of its important functions. If the bank is new, he organizes the work. He has so many vice-presidents, a cashier, and so many assistant cashiers at his disposal to begin with. Provision is also made for the employment of a suitable number of clerks. He puts the cashier in charge of the clerical force generally. In small banks the president's duties include many of those held by active vice-presidents and cashiers in larger ones. In this case he is much nearer the employees and therefore can attend to many more details of the business. In a nutshell, the president seems to be look- ing out for the growth of the bank along proper THE PRESIDENT 37 and legitimate lines ; seeking to increase the total resources; endeavoring to expand it, making it huge, powerful, and rich. His task is to make a maximum dividend for the stockholders, but by legitimate methods always. It seems that his ability to do this is incompatible with too much devotion to the details of the actual clerical force. It is an old-fashioned idea, now almost eliminated in the largest institutions, that the president should run every wheel in the bank and see that each is properly oiled. Rather, it seems the better plan to have some capable and responsible sub- ordinates who can be trusted to attend to the smaller transactions and to the routine. This idea is prevalent among the great financial houses of the country. In their case, the president simply cannot devote his time to see that every pass- book is properly balanced. In his effort to expand the bank and earn goodly dividends, the president meets his greatest diffi- culty and principal duty — that is, in the grant- ing of loans to banks, corporations, and individ- uals. In the first chapter the different kinds of loans have been explained in some detail. The systems of extending their credit are per- haps the most individualistic and variant features of different banks. In some, the directorate is a powerful and active factor, which passes on every application for credit. In such a case there is a meeting of the directors once, twice per week, or perhaps daily. The chairman of the board becomes a potent officer. In other institutions the direc- torate is much less active, contenting itself with periodic reviews of the bank's progress, giving 38SG00 88 PRACTICAL BANKING general advice to the president and allowing him the power of granting loans. With the first type of association, we have dealt in some detail in the preceding chapter. We shall busy ourselves for the time being with the latter type, i.e., where the president has the loan-granting power. It would be impossible, in a bank of any con- siderable size, for the president to pass on every loan and discount. A large number of these are put in the hands of vice-presidents or cashiers. However, it is considered proper for the president to conduct negotiations on most applications for credit from new customers. Likewise, he feels it incumbent upon him personally to attend to the requests of distinguished or prominent patrons. In the granting of loans, especially to new cus- tomers, the president or his assistant must observe many precautions, for there is no business so haz- ardous as the lending of other people's money. Since there is such hazard, it is necessary that the lender feel amply justified in making the loan, either by virtue of the good credit of the signer or indorser, or because of the excellence of the security. And one who is unknown should never complain if the bank demands plenty of good security of him. It is customary to require gilt- edge security from 100 to 120 per cent on $100, and, of course, the ratio increases as the security offered is lessened in value. Another item! By reason of the hazard of money-lending — which is greater than in most other businesses — it ought not to be held against a bank that it charges a reasonable rate of interest. This rate must necessarily differ as the security THE PRESIDENT 39 and signer are the very best or only medium, or as the discountee may or may not do a large volume of business at the bank. Also the ratio of supply to demand of credit is bound to play an important part in determining the interest or dis- count rate. From A. B. Johnson's treatise on banking, the following excellent commentary is taken : — A banker should possess a sufficiency of legal knowl- edge to make him suspect what may be defects in prof- fered security, so as to submit his doubts to authorized counselors. He must, in all things, be eminently prac- tical. Every man can tell an obviously insufficient security as well as an obviously abundant security; but neither of these constitutes any large portion of the loans that are offered to a banker. Security practi- cally sufficient for the occasion is all that a banker can obtain of the greater part of his loans. If he must err in his judgment of securities, he had better reject fifty good loans than make one bad debt. But he must endeavor not to err on the extreme of caution or the extreme of temerity ; and his tact in these particulars will, more than any other, constitute the criterion of his merits as a banker. Of the credit of a bank, a certain part is in- vested in very short-time and demand loans to provide for extraordinary demands. Most, how- ever, is in two, three, and four months' paper. The amount for longer time than four months will not exceed a very small per centum of the whole, for good banking principles demand a con- tinual process of repayment and relending. If there is any one thing that distinguishes a wise president from a foolish one, it is the manner 40 PRACTICAL BANKING in which he has the maturing paper collected. Stacks of past-due and uncollected paper speak eloquently of mismanagement, of bad loans, per- haps, but more frequently of vacillating and lax methods of enforcing payment. The successful president so orders things that there shall be no dilly-dallying about pressing collection. In cases of aggravated obduracy with regard to payment, the paper is turned over to an attorney for suit at law. Another item which the banker watches most carefully is overdrafts. A certain small percent- age of overdrafts must and will creep in. It is either impossible or impolitic to refuse payment of some checks, even though the account may not, at the time, be sufficient to cover the checks. But the sagacious banker keeps these as low as practicable. An overdraft is equivalent to a loan without interest or security. Most banks have bridged this difficulty by making a temporary loan to cover the overdraft, exacting security where it is feasible. The president of a great bank has no more of a lease on life than the beggar, and although the heavens themselves may blaze forth his death, yet he can no more defer its inevitable coming than an ant. It therefore behooves him to keep his work so ordered that he may leave the bank each night as though it were his last. If he does not, he is not faithful to his high trust, he is not true to himself or to his friends. For a great bank, though it stops to drop a tear on the fallen chief's grave, cannot swerve from its course for its own safety. There are so many things which. THE PRESIDENT 41 if left undone overnight and death should call, could not be adjusted so nicely, if at all. The president represents his institution before the public. Popularly, he is almost conceived to be the hank. He has many means of being useful besides guarding the executive duties of the bank. His personal influence and popularity will be of aid in getting desirable customers for the bank, both corporate and individual. His occasional visit to and personal acquaintance with the larg- est of the bank's dealers are of infinite service. The president's position in the bank may be illustrated by a rather homely simile. He may be likened to one of the pilots on the ferry-boats which cross and recross the Hudson at the lower end of New York City. Through the swirling water, keeping a sharp lookout for craft of every description, blowing the hoarse whistle occasion- ally to warn some little tug, the pilot guides his heavy boat. Above his head are the general rules which he must observe — the United States Government regulations. One moment's neglect of his duty would be sufficient to send his boat crashing into some danger. But day and night, winter and summer, he stands skillfully at the wheel, and brings his boat safely to her destina- tion. The vice-president's position is hard to gener- alize. As a rule, the position is an honorary one. In some cases, however, where the president is an honorary dignitary himself, the vice-president may be the executive head of the bank. In the larger banks, active vice-presidents tend to spe- cialize in certain of the executive functions. For 42 PRACTICAL BANKING instance, the duty of one may be to visit the bank's correspondents or to receive their repre- sentatives when they call to pay their business respects; of another, to act as a specialist in the granting of certain lines of credit — and so on ! CHAPTER IV THE CASHIER The cashier is subordinate in rank to the presi- dent. He has direct charge of the force of em- ployees. If the president's office is the great brain of the bank, certainly the cashier's office is the great arm. Ordinarily, the cashier has only such duties as are necessary to move the machinery of the bank, but, in the absence of the president, he sometimes assumes the highest executive functions. He keeps the men in line, so to speak, and adjusts all local difficulties. To him the men come with their problems. To him they report progress or failure. He personally supervises their work. Often, during the day, things arise to be settled, over which tellers or other clerks have no author- ity, but which do not properly come under the president's duties. The cashier undertakes to adjust such matters. Examples of these may be, the question of cashing foreign checks for persons carrying no account, or the granting of a tempo- rary overdraft to a good customer. In a great banking institution of the metrop- olis, the duties of the cashier become very com- plex and taxing. He has so many tasks crowding in upon him, and so much to look after, that it is necessary to provide him with assistants, who form a grade still nearer the rank and file and have jurisdiction over special phases of the work. 44 PRACTICAL BANKING To take a supposititious case: say one assistant cashier is in charge of the bank's bookkeeping; another of the tellers; a third supervises exchange, collections, and perhaps the note department; a fourth opens accounts and is a lobbyist — that is, he has a desk in the lobby, greeting customers, when it is good policy to do so, and performing other duties which may arise. It should be paren- thetically stated that many banks designate one of the clerical force to open accounts, but in a bank of moderate size, it has proved very satis- factory to attach this duty to the cashier or one of his assistants. In that very important branch of a bank, its relations with other banks, the cashier is always active. He carries on most of, the ordinary corre- spondence with them, makes arrangements for the advantageous handling of items, secures ac- counts and rights differences which may come up between his bank and another. Another duty which requires much time from him and his assistants is the signing of checks and other documents. That common instrument, the cashier's check, drawn by the bank on itself, is so called because it is usually signed by him. This check is used to discharge local debts of the bank, to pay dividends, and is sometimes issued to per- sons who prefer it to other forms of exchange. The proceeds of some loans and discounts are also paid by means of it. Then, too, every draft of a bank on its corre- spondents must be signed by the cashier. These amount to many in a day: remittances sent for cash items received; remittances for banks which THE CASHIER 45 order a part or all of their balance forwarded; checks for people who buy exchange on other cities. In addition to these checks and drafts, the cashier signs various government and state reports, acknowledges remittances of interest or advises credit of same. In controlling the work of the departments, the cashier must pay especial attention to means for preventing fraud. This is likely to come up in more guises than simple forgery or counterfeiting. Stopping payment of checks unnecessarily is often an attempt at fraud. "Kiting" is another form. "Kiting" consists in drawing a check on one bank and depositing it at another; then issuing checks against the account and trying to get them paid before the deposited check is presented at the other bank. Or perhaps, the "kiter" also deposits a check at the other bank on the first one. Then, if the check from the first is sent over to the second, in the confusion, it may be certified, for apparently the "kiter" has a credit balance on the books. Most banks obviate this source of danger by refusing to honor checks on an account opened with a check until that check has been paid. But it does happen in the case of persons who have been carrying accounts and suddenly begin "kiting." Another form of fraud is by means of "dum- mies." These, as the name implies, are fictitious persons in other cities on whom people make drafts for pretended indebtedness. If the luckless teller pays such a one or the cashier authorizes payment, it is simply a question of how great the loss is. 46 PRACTICAL BANKING An important duty of the cashier, one that cannot be overlooked, is the rather frequent auditing of the work of each of the clerks. It is much better to do this often and thoroughly than to let it lag and never know how "crooked" the work of some of the clerks may be. Confidence in men is by no means infallible protection against their dishonesty. No man ever defaults who is suspected at first; his very occupancy of a respon- sible position is proof of confidence. The paying teller's cash is in most instances audited at least once a month. This clerk, unfor- tunately, has had more falls than any other of the subordinate employees of the bank. His tempta- tions are great, and if he is weak and knows that no frequent audits will be made of his cash, he may fall. There is a distinct moral effect in know- ing that his cash is going to be audited carefully rather frequently. Not only should the paying teller's cash be audited, but the ledgers of the bank ought to be checked up every so often. One big bank in New York audits the whole institution once a month. The assistant cashiers take turns in con- ducting the examination. In counting the cash of the paying teller and in other detail, several clerks are taken out of their departments to assist, for which they receive extra remuneration. This same bank — as many banks do — shifts its men from position to position, never letting them fall into ruts in any one place. As a friend of the author's once rather fancifully put it, no bank should ever let an employee think that his posi- tion was "his own horse, and that no one else THE CASHIER 47 could ride it." This habit of shifting certainly lessens the chance of dishonesty. In this particular, I am reminded of how an individual bookkeeper, perfidious and dissatis- fied with his compensation, cleverly contrived a scheme for getting a tidy sum quickly. He selected an account little checked on, and forged a check for $10,000 on it. Next he deposited the check to his credit in a suburban bank where he was not known. When it came through the clearing for payment, he took it from the other checks, posted it to the account and slipped it into the check file, not leaving it to be examined by the persons who looked over the day's checks. After this he went out to his bank and withdrew the $10,000 and had his book balanced. He destroyed his pass- book and the check with which he had withdrawn his balance, and settled back to his position as if nothing had happened. About a year later, the patron whose account had thus suffered ordered his book balanced. He was much chagrined to find a charge of $10,000 against him. Examining the check, he declared it a forgery. The book- keeper stoutly denied any knowledge of the for- gery until the suburban bank, whose indorsement appeared on the back, identified him. He had n't had nerve enough to destroy the check when it came back, or he possibly would not have been caught. The subject of "reserve" has been rather fully discussed in the first chapter, and is only men- tioned here in connection with the cashier's duties. He usually has charge of these funds, if, as in many banks, they are separate from current 48 PRACTICAL BANKING funds. By reserve in this sense is meant not neces- sarily the whole amount of lawful money on hand, but that part, aside from that for daily use, which is kept for extraordinary demands. The cashier sees that a proper amount of reserve is always on hand. A minimum reserve is set for all national and most state banks, but in some localities and under some conditions it is necessary to keep a larger volume on hand than is actually required. In the certification of checks the signature of some oflBcer is usually necessary, though in many places the paying teller assumes this duty. Gen- erally, however, this is done by the cashier or an assistant. It is a very delicate step, as it is abso- lutely necessary to ascertain accurately that the check is "good" before certifying. Whether it be "good" or "bad," it must be paid when once it is certified. Furthermore, the officer in a national association, who certifies a check where there are insufficient or no funds, is liable to federal prose- cution. In a number of banks, usually the smaller ones, the cashier has some loan-granting power. And in a bank where the only other lending officer is the president, it amounts to considerable im- portance, especially when the chief is absent. However, this power does not often extend be- yond discounts for persons having a standing credit, except in the case of certain small loans. But this is not an infallible rule, for in some large banks the cashier has broad loan-granting power. The general and current expense items of the bank are ordinarily subject to the control of the cashier. He does not allow bills of expense to THE CASHIER 49 stand out longer than reasonable — usually not more than a month from the date of the debt's contraction. In the prompt payment of the bank's debts, he lays on one of the small stones which form finally the strong wall of the institution's integrity. Often he receives bids from several good houses on large purchases of supplies and sundries, so that he may obtain the most ad- vantageous rates. He pays the salaries of the clerks. To discharge this duty, he issues checks or cash, or even, in some instances, places a credit on the bank's in- dividual ledgers for the men, against which they may draw. Many cashiers keep or cause to be kept a huge book, on which is entered in the minutest detail every expenditure which the bank makes. This may take the form of a voucher registration when vouchers are used to charge expense items to their proper accounts. This register is divided into sections, showing in vertical columns the amount of expense under appropriate heads, such as "salary," "insurance," and "taxes." In deciding matters of policy with customers or others who ask accommodation of various sorts, the cashier has need of all the firmness he can command. He finds himself importuned at every step by people who must be refused. But they respect him the more for his firmness. A good friend once said to the writer, and he has always remembered it, "A business man often has occasion to act with decision and prompti- tude. And most frequently a firm decision, though erroneous, will be more beneficial than a 50 PRACTICAL BANKING wavering tendency." Sometimes, too, crises come which demand the utmost positiveness. In time of panic every cashier knows what it is to be be- sieged with requests of accommodation for all sorts of emergencies. Sometimes it is wise to as- sent; frequently, however, a refusal, firm and final, must be given. Even with all this necessity for staunch abid- ing by the right course, the cashier cannot afford to lose his consideration for the feelings of others. He never fails to find a reward for courtesy and equanimity. One officer of the writer's acquaint- ance is so affable and hearty to every one that it has been said of him that many people applying for credit had rather be turned down by him than be accepted by another man. In leaving the cashier's desk to take up in de- tail the work of the departments under him, let us remember that he, as the bank's arm, furnishes the power to do the work planned by the bank's brain, the president. CHAPTER V THE PAYING TELLER How many people, when they pass their checks, properly signed and indorsed, through the wicket and receive the amount of cash called for, ever stop to think of the tremendous responsibility of the man behind the counter. Most, we may pre- sume, with a half-envious glance at the stacks of currency and trays of coin, dismiss all thought of the teller and of how his department is conducted. And yet, in importance, his is second to none in the bank. Though we carry on more than ninety per cent of our business by credit, that is, by check or draft, we Americans have not yet reached that state of refinement where we may do away with all cash payments and deal alone in exchange or credits. There is a good deal of the Missouri spirit in the most of us on certain oc- casions. We like to see "the coin." And so, our banks cannot do without the paying teller. Some one has remarked that a bank is the pulse of business generally in a town or community. It may be further said that the paying depart- ment is the pulse of the bank, and faithfully reg- isters whether the management is conservative or radical. Here, as in no other department, an experi- enced, capable man is required. It is almost es- sential that a paying teller should have a good knowledge of bookkeeping, as his duties contin- 52 PRACTICAL BANKING ually bring him in touch with the books of the bank. He should be well acquainted with the general status of as many of the bank's cus- tomers as possible. Also, he must have an accur- ate knowledge of the signatures of customers; he should always have the signatures of the bank's depositors, for reference, in a convenient file. It is obviously impossible for a paying teller to know the status and signature of every customer in a large bank. Some banks have supplied their tellers with sheets on which the approximate balances of customers is entered. Many others adopt the plan of having the checks passed back to the bookkeepers for certification before pay- ment. These methods do not always expedite matters during rush hours. In Australia, I be- lieve, some banks have adopted what appears to be a practicable scheme. Those having checks to cash go to a window where the check is certified after identification and verification. Then they file on to the paying window, where the checks are promptly paid. As the name implies, the primary duty of the paying teller is to pay out money. This primary duty involves many accompanying duties of almost equal importance. The paying teller has charge of the money vaults and safes containing current funds. The reserve, as defined in the foregoing chapter, is usually kept separately in the charge of an officer of the bank. The duty of keeping the money vaults is not a light one, for the teller must at all times proceed most carefully in setting time locks. THE PAYING TELLER 53 He must also keep his money in good order and see that a certain volume is always on hand to meet any emergency. This last duty is also im- posed upon one of the officers of the bank, as it is of prime importance. In the great banks, no one man knows the entire combination to the money vaults, but two or three each know a part of it, so that the presence of all is required to unlock. Some banks employ more than one paying teller. In that case there is a senior teller who has charge of the vaults, and who supplies the assist- ants with a certain amount of money each day. In the paying-out process, our teller must maintain his mental equilibrium if he hopes to be in any way successful. For a man to "lose" his head with a long line of impatient customers before his window is disastrous. Men in this con- dition have made and do make errors that are dangerous ; they may seriously misread the amount of a check involving a difference of many dollars ; they may accept a forged check or one dated ahead; they may fail to require proper identifica- tion or indorsement; they may not catch a check on which payment has been ordered stopped. In fine, the paying teller may soon ruin himself, and perhaps the bank, if he is easily flurried. He must carry on his work easily and smoothly. Numerous incidents occur to irritate him; some- times strangers insist upon the cashing of foreign or even of home checks without identification; people sometimes unnecessarily hurry a teller who is working "tooth and nail"; and some come after hours and ask accommodation when he is busy proving up his work. 54 PRACTICAL BANKING One is reminded of the little old man who comes in every Friday afternoon, just after bank- ing hours, by the side door. He always leaves his book to be balanced, to be sure that "the bank has made no mistake" in his $105 account. Then, to prove for himself that the institution is still solvent, he invariably drops by the paying win- dow to get two dollars and a half in cash. Such incidents from a distance wear a ludicrous air, but the vivid reality often makes them a cause for bitter and impotent grinding of teeth. We have enumerated but a few of the many in- stances which may cause friction between the teller and certain customers. But the successful teller learns to be cool and polite under the most trying conditions. He must pour oil on the trou- bled waters, so to speak. The paying teller is more likely to encounter frauds than any other clerk, and, if heedless, is sure to pay bitterly for napping. Counterfeit cur- rency is a common source of trouble. Now and then, persons, consciously or unconsciously, pass bills in for change, etc., that are counterfeit. And some of this worthless currency is so cleverly ex- ecuted that it is next to impossible to detect it. However, the following are common defects. Either the paper is of an inferior quality, or the engraving is rough, or else there is a slight varia- tion in the frieze. Then, too, there are genuine notes whose value has been raised. Some of these are exceedingly dangerous. The best way for a teller to detect counterfeits is, first, to have an accurate knowledge of the different notes in cir- culation, so as to be able to catch any ordinary THE PAYING TELLER 55 imitation, and then, to keep posted through the secret service of the existence of any fine counter- feits. It is a comparatively easy matter for an ex- perienced teller to detect a spurious coin, since it is usually oversized or under. A bad coin is frequently detected by its ring or by its color. Counterfeit gold coins are more dangerous than silver, for their large value makes it worth while to spend much time on their execution. In one famous case the counterfeiter took a genuine double-eagle and cut its edges to a depth of about a quarter of an inch. He next turned back the sides and removed two thirds of the gold, leaving only the shell of the coin. He filled up the space ¥'ith a foreign metal of about the same density us gold, closed it and covered the split edge with gold to conceal the spurious metal. The gold counterfeit can usually be detected by ringing it on the marble or by examining closely the work- manship. Forgeries are by no means negligible. This kind of fraud is largely of two kinds; namely, forging the signature of a bank's customer, and passing a check signed by a person who has no account. Forging the signature of another person is not an easy matter, but it is rather commonly in- dulged in. This sketch will not permit of an ade- quate discussion of the different methods of forg- ing a bank customer's check. However, one or two clever schemes are worth noting. In a certain Western town, a man, purporting to be a representative of the Government, distri- 56 PRACTICAL BANKING buting certain pamphlets of the Department of Agriculture, approached one of the leading citi- zens to supply him with a copy, requiring only his receipt in a small notebook. The citizen readily signed the notebook and thought no more of it. In reality, under the sheet which he signed was a draft on his bank to which his signature was fixed by means of a carbon sheet. The pseudo- government man filled out the draft for a large amount and presented it for payment. But the teller, suspecting something wrong, held the man pending an investigation of the check. Of course, the forger received his just punishment. The following incident is from an address of Mr. Cullom W. Kay before the American Institute of Banking: — Not long ago, on a busy Saturday, a well-dressed fellow joined the line, and in his turn presented a check for $3500 to one of our tellers. It was recognized im- mediately to be a forgery of the personal or individual signature of a member of a prominent local business firm, and the teller was aware of the fact that he did not keep a personal account, so the detection was easy enough to make. To make the fellow believe he was going to get the money, he was told to wait a moment in order that we might see if the check was good, the teller in the mean time waiting on the customers as they came up to the window one after another and keeping his eye on the fellow and the bank's detective to see that they did not get too far apart. When the assistant teller returned the check and stated there was no account under that name as an individual, the forger was politely asked to go to the office in the rear. Apparently he felt so sure that he would get the money that he did not hesitate to follow the teller to the THE PAYING TELLER 57 cashier's rail, where the teller turned the check over to that official and introduced the forger as an interesting person, who would have to account for having such a check in his hands. The teller sent the detective back to the rear office almost immediately afterward to "stand by," and then went on with his work, and shortly afterwards noticed above the heads of the crowd of customers that the rascal went out with the local detective and was placed in an automobile and taken to prison. The fellow was convicted and is now serving fifteen years in the penitentiary. The cus- tomers did not notice anything unusual, and the teller did not lose three minutes from his work. The effect of this kind of experience to one who handles many checks is that he is worried for days afterwards, and strains his eyes looking for defects in signatures and is very apt to be unusually nervous for some time. In regard to the forging of the name of a person to whose credit there is no money, let it suffice to say that this is frequently done, but the check is usually cashed at a bank other than the one on which it is drawn, or else it is foisted on some luckless shopkeeper. Garnishments are generally served on the cashier or paying teller, and in either case the teller, as well as the proper individual book- keeper, must have a memorandum of them be- fore him in order to prevent payment of checks against the accounts garnished. There are always some people who issue checks and wish to have payment stopped on them. Whether it be that some contract has been vio- lated by the payee or whether, for some strange, unknown, subterranean reason, the maker does not wish his check honored, payment must be 58 PRACTICAL BANKING declined or the bank will be liable for the amount of the check and will, most probably, incur the lasting enmity of the customer. So the paying teller keeps a file of orders stopping payment of checks. As a bank is liable to accumulate a num- ber of persons who more or less frequently stop payment of checks for no good reason apparently, the paying teller should note the ones who make a practice of it, and, after conference with the proper officer, should request that the accounts be closed. After the bank is closed, the teller begins work for his balance. He must count his money, take into consideration any money which he may have distributed to other tellers, and record all home, clearing, and foreign checks taken in by himself. If he has opened new accounts, as he does in some banks, he must have a record of their deposit slips. He probably has taken in all cash deposits from other banks. His balance of cash for the previous day, together with all credit items, such as deposits, new currency put into circulation, exchange collected, general expense credits, items sent to the clearing house, etc., must be made to balance with the present amount of cash on hand, along with all disbursements on checks, general expense, notes discounted, exchange, amount of checks received from the clearing house, etc. It should be noted, however, that many banks have the clearing charged directly to a clearing clerk. But in many others the charges and credits for the same run through the paying teller's book. It has been a popular saying among paying tellers generally that it is impossible to balance THE PAYING TELLER 59 consistently in the paying window *'to a cent"; that is, there is almost always an overage or shortage, great or small. The writer became pay- ing teller imbued with this venerable idea. It so happened that the president of the bank was not a man to be tied down to tradition, and one of his theories was that a teller, as well as a bookkeeper, should be held responsible for an exact balance, despite the fact that, if a teller paid out too much money to a person, he rarely got it back. So a scheme was evolved for balancing exactly, put into practice, and, it must be said, it worked mar- velously well, so well, indeed, that, in one period of nine months, there were only a half-dozen misbalances. After having his theory shattered, the writer began to investigate the records of other tellers more closely and discovered that, in most cases, the teller who balanced ojtenest was the man of whom it was required to balance with a fair degree of regularity. We must pass to a brief consideration of a few of the remaining important duties of the paying teller. He collects all cash after balances and stows it away in the vaults until the following business day. Frequently, in the smaller banks, the paying teller is assigned to the duty of verify- ing dates, signatures, and indorsements on home checks. In the national associations, he some- times receives government and post-office de- posits and sends weekly transcripts of the govern- ment account to Washington. Likewise, if it be a bank under United States supervision, the pay- ing teller must keep his currency segregated. In banks where his duties are more or less light, he 60 PRACTICAL BANKING frequently has some miscellaneous duties, such as control of the record of canceled and outstand- ing cashier's and certified checks, certificates of deposit, etc. CHAPTER VI THE RECEIVING TELLER We need give no formal introduction to the receiving teller, for everybody knows him. In- deed, many people will wonder at a discussion of his duties, for they seem so apparent. Yet there are probably many inside features of a receiving teller's work quite unknown to the average bank customer. We are familiar with the cheerful little man behind the window, who passes a pleas- ant word about business or the weather, while he energetically counts over our currency and veri- fies the check entries on our deposit slips. The functions of his position, to a casual observer, seem quite simple — indeed, just taking in a huge mass of checks, coin, and bills, assorting them quickly, and checking them off the ticket; just adding up the little slips and glancing at the in- dorsements on the checks; just making a hasty entry on your pass-book, and then — "Next!'* But we shall soon see that these primary duties involve a complexity of secondary or incidental tasks. It would be about as easy to discover accurate generalities in describing the receiving tellers in over twenty thousand banks as it would be in discussing, with a few bold and well-selected strokes, "The Growth of the Spirit of Resistance in New England." For in every bank, no matter how inconspicuous, there are certain peculiar 62 PRACTICAL BANKING methods of handling the business, due to the nec- essary adaptation to local conditions. It would hardly be an exaggeration to say that there are individuality and originality in the division and allotment of duties in every bank in the country. Therefore, it will be necessary to construct an ideal receiving teller, one whose clerical obliga- tions include those which appear best to pertain to his office. It may be that some duty of a New York teller may stand side by side with that of a country clerk. There are from one to a half-dozen receiving tellers in a bank, the number, of course, depend- ing on the volume of individual depositing. Save for a head of the department in large banks, who is responsible for the work of his subordinates, the receiving tellers are on an apparently equal footing, and their duties are essentially the same. In many banks, each is assigned to a certain di- vision of the alphabetically arranged bank's cus- tomers. This alphabetical division, however, is not the universal practice. Some one has said that the receiving teller's window is the cleanest clerical position in the bank, because he begins each day on a fresh sheet, with no differences carried over. WTien the bank opens, his trays and money drawers are empty and his record clean. After his proof each day, he turns over his cash to the paying teller, his clearing to the clearing clerk, his foreign items to the transit department, etc., having charged, in each case, the proper amount to the appropriate department. Then he is ready to start another day. THE RECEIVING TELLER 63 But to resume with our ideal teller on an ideal day ! Soon after the bank opens its doors his work begins and continues, with perhaps occasional lulls, until banking hours are over — far longer, probably, but the actual receipt of deposits ends with the closing hour. In the course of the day, many things will arise which require open-eyed attention. Perhaps there is a forged check or one which has some evident informality. These he watches out for. There may be a long line of customers before his win- dow and yet he cannot afford to become excited and so overlook some apparent fraud. As a general rule, it may be said that checks, forged or other- wise invalid, are not as likely to cause actual loss to him or to the bank, as in the case of the paying teller. This is readily seen, for in almost every instance such checks may, on discovery of their invalidity, be charged back to the depositor's account. But to protect the bank and himself against possible loss, he closely watches for all invalid checks, especially those rendered so by lack of indorsement. The latter is important because frequently an unindorsed check cannot be charged back to customers, since it is not known by whom it was deposited. Of course, it can often be traced by comparing check entries on the deposit slips of the day with all lists of checks taken from his window, but this is tedious and uncertain at best. The teller knows too well how common rogues are, and how prolific their handiwork is in the shape of counterfeited money, to be anything short of vigilant. We have shown some of the 64 PRACTICAL BANKING means of detecting counterfeits in the foregoing chapter, and will not discuss them again here. Our teller is successful; therefore, he has a cool head, and a quick and accurate perception. It seems to an old teller that one of the supreme shortcomings of the human race is its inaccu- racy in making out deposit slips. It would take tomes to tell of the thousand and one peculiar and ludicrous mistakes which some bank cus- tomers commit when preparing their deposits. Did we say "ludicrous mistakes".'' Often they smack of tragedy. It may be funny enough to remind a patron that the "$10 in Gold" listed on his slip must be in his vest pocket; but during the tedious process of checking over deposit slips till late at night to find a "balance" in some man's ticket with an item listed wrong, the disappointed teller may feel any way but humorous. His mood may approximate Malvolio's, but certainly not Feste's. It may be argued that a teller should detect all errors as he takes in the deposits, but in a "rush" it is practically impossible to do everything as thoroughly as it ought to be done. It seems to be the better plan to check off the items as carefully as possible and note the indorsements, leaving verification in other particulars for a later hour, if necessary. Too many slips are filled out with one or two very ambiguous figures. In checking items off the ticket rapidly, the teller may easily take such a figure to be what the check reads, when a careful footing up would show that it was added in as something else. THE RECEIVING TELLER 65 Not only does our teller realize the time gained by watching these items, but he is aware of the absolute indispensableness of requiring indorse- ments on checks. Several imperative reasons are apparent for this. First of all, if an indorsement does not appear on the check, the payee may claim not to have received the money on the check and may demand repayment. Second, if the payee makes no complaint, the drawer or maker may refuse to have the check charged to his account unless properly indorsed. It may be remarked here that thousands of purely technical errors in indorsing — where good faith is evident — are corrected by tellers. These are such as leaving the "&" out in "Smith, Jones & Perry." Third, absence of indorsement prevents ready and easy *' charging back " of invalid checks to the proper parties. Exchange charges is an item which may, by strict application, cease to be a source of loss to the bank. So many people cannot understand why, if they keep a hundred dollars on deposit, the bank should not accept foreign checks for them without charge for collection. Waiving the exchange which banks in some cities are obliged to charge on certain checks, on account of clear- ing-house regulations, it is perfectly rational that a bank, accommodating a small depositor on gen- eral principles, — for no one accuses it of making money from him, — should charge an exchange rate on checks which in all probability it will have to pay to get collected. Naturally enough, to a certain class of customers, all checks are accepted at par, so far as it does not conflict with any clearing house rule. 66 PRACTICAL BANKING A knowledge of the signatures of the bank's customers should come within the range of the receiving teller's duties. With this knowledge he is in position to detect many frauds in the at- tempt to deposit bogus or forged home checks. After a day full of nerve-trying experience with irascible patrons, who rage because of collection charges, "not good" checks, or counterfeit notes in their deposits; after an effort to assuage their irritability by the " oil-on-the-water " method; after being interrupted time and again to give some trivial information; after tiring himself out with the exercise of constant wariness to detect frauds and to be perfectly accurate, the teller prepares to try for a balance as quickly as possi- ble. In some banks, where two or more tellers are employed, several balances are taken during the day. The operation is simple. Number one teller, say, closes his window, thus turning his depositors through number two. Number one then quickly balances and gives over his deposit slips and his checks — home, clearing, and for- eign — to their appropriate departments, charges himself with the amount of cash which he has and reopens his window. In other banks, where only one balance per day is taken, the deposits and checks are collected once or twice during hours, listed and carefully verified. When the bank closes, the teller first lists, or has listed, all deposit slips and cash items in his cage. This must be done at once in order not to delay the bookkeepers. After this, he begins the task of segregating and counting his currency. THE RECEIVING TELLER 67 This may be quite an arduous undertaking in many banks, while in others, which receive the vast majority of their deposits in checks and dis- counts, it may not be so taxing. As a rule, how- ever, it may be said that the smaller the bank, the more it caters to cash depositors and the less it depends on lending and discounting to create its deposits. It is quite possible that the teller may do much of this counting, bundling up, and segre- gating at odd moments during the day. By seg- regation is meant not only separation into their respective denominations, but also, and especially so in the national bank, the separation into the different kinds of bills, e.g., gold certificates, silver certificates, national bank notes, etc. It has been found convenient among clearing- house associations to adopt some regular scheme for bundling up the currency bills of its members. Many use the fifty bill standard; that is, each package contains fifty bills of the same denomi- nation. The various denominations are distin- guished by different colored bands with which the packages are bound. The color, then, of the band at once shows what amount is in the bundle as well as the denomination. The banks themselves usually require the teller who counts out the pack- age to initial it. Thus one city has white bands inclosing $50 each for ones and twos; blue bands inclosing $250 each for fives; yellow bands inclos- ing $500 each for tens ; and red bands inclosing $1000 each for twenties. The United States Treas- ury has a custom of putting one hundred bills of each denomination to the package. Coin is counted and put up in two ways. First, 68 PRACTICAL BANKING in trays. These trays are built in varying sizes, generally to accommodate five hundred coins. They are only used for the three highest silver coins, and for gold. In many instances a tray contains five rows of five stacks each of coins, each stack containing twenty pieces. Dimes, nickels, and cents for current use are usually put up in small envelopes containing $5, $2.50, or $1. The second method of putting up coins is in packages. This applies to fractional silver, nickels, and copper coins more readily than to dollars. Gold is not put up in these packages at all. The package is nothing more than a small cylindrical piece of stiff paper fastened about a stack of coins, each containing ten dollars in the case of halves and dollars, five dollars in the case of quarters, and five, two, or one dollar in the case of smaller coins. Coins are kept in stout, canvas bags when stowed away in safes and vaults. It is very interesting to note the parts of the country where coins are most used. In the North and East, coins — especially the large silver pieces — are scarcely used at all. In one large bank, in the author's mind, with deposits far up in the tens of millions, two or three thousand silver dollars and a small amount of subsidiary silver is found to be quite suflBcient for all de- mands. Gold is rarely used except for reserve and for transactions between banks. A glance at the receiving-teller's cage with a scant number of trays poorly filled convinces one that coins are not popular in this part of the country. In the South and Southwest, silver and gold are very much in demand and in evidence. A bank in Ala- THE RECEIVING TELLER 69 bama with a capital of $100,000 will probably keep more silver on hand than a bank in New York with $1,000,000. In the Far West, gold is most popular, and it is related that many of the natives look with great suspicion on paper cur- rency, and that country shopkeepers are likely to refuse it. Where there is much to handle, the counting of fractional coins would be almost an endless task but for the counting-machines which the larger banks use. These machines may be adjusted to count dollars, halves, quarters, and smaller change. By simply dumping the coins into a pan and turning a crank, one may count almost as fast as he pleases. A small indicator registers the number of pieces handled, or one may set a pin to stop the counter automatically when the de- sired number of coins is reached. Street railways, motion-picture theaters, and popular summer at- tractions pour vast streams of small coin into their banks. It is in packages when deposited and for the time is accepted at its face value, but the count must be verified. In the days before the money counting-machine, one bank of my ac- quaintance used to press all of its tellers and some utility clerks into service once a week to count the street-car company's deposited change. After his money is counted, the teller makes an entry on the debit side of his book for its total. Then on the same side he lists the totals of the bundles of checks and other cash items which he has turned over to the individual books, to the clearing clerk, to the foreign department, and those which he still has on hand. On the credit 70 PRACTICAL BANKING side of his record appears the total of deposits and the exchange collected. The problem is to make the footing of the two sides of his book coincide. Some of the stumbling-blocks to a speedy bal- ance are errors in counting money, errors in the addition of deposit slips, and errors in entering items on the deposit slip. Errors in counting money are of three kinds : — First, the money may have been miscounted when the deposit was made. If it was incorrectly entered on the slip, and, in his haste, the teller's count coincided with the amount entered; or, when it was correctly set down, if he changed the entry to agree with his calculation, there is small chance that he will be able to recover a shortage or refund an overage. If, however, the error was committed on the slip of a firm keeping an ac- curate set of books, the difference may often be located. In that instance it is practically always noticed by the firm. But in the case of nine out of ten individuals, the discrepancy would not be noted. Second, the teller may have assorted his paper currency wrong; e.g., put a five-dollar bill in a package of tens. This rather common error ought to be found on a second count of the packages. Mistakes of this kind in counting coins are not frequent, though they sometimes happen. Third, he may have actually miscounted the bills or coins. This is purely a mechanical error which is quickly discovered by the experienced teller. We have spoken earlier in the chapter of the THE RECEIVING TELLER 71 errors of addition in deposit slips, and mistakes in entering items on deposit slips. Transposition of figures, which is easily enough made, is occasionally a source of annoyance. However, the teller has a venerable idea regard- ing transpositions, handed down from generation to generation of bookkeepers, which serves fre- quently to locate this sort of discrepancy. If the difference (the shortage or overage) is divisible by nine, then a transposition is possible. So when he discovers that his difference can be divided by that number, he immediately suspects a transposi- tion, and sets to work to check his deposit slips with his lists of checks. Our teller, being a good one, is not without resource if he is out of balance. Often, stopping to think clearly for a moment, it comes to him like a flash that he has failed to credit the indi- vidual books with a check that was missorted and which was charged to them, or that he has not credited himself with some change in packages which he has that day furnished the paying teller. Sometimes he will be looking over his deposit slips, when out of balance, and suddenly get the impression very vividly that a certain check is listed incorrectly on such and such a ticket. Look- ing it up, he finds his impression correct. Occa- sionally he remembers that he changed the figures on a certain ticket that morning to agree with his computation. He calls up the depositor, inquires about it, and quite often discovers his difference. Then, too, there remain all the ways of checking back items with lists and tickets. After a day as strenuous as we have described. 72 PRACTICAL BANKING one may easily picture our ideal teller lying down to sleep the ideal sleep of the weary. Of course, no clerk could well experience such a vicissitudin- ous day, as we have mentioned most of the possi- ble problems which might arise in the ordinary, day-in-and-day-out performance of his duties. CHAPTER VII THE LOAN AND DISCOUNT DEPARTMENT A bank is a manufactory of credit and a machine of exchange. Horace White. Next to depositing and checking, there is prob- ably no feature of banking more familiar to the public than the lending of credit. In the course of his life nearly every man has occasion to borrow from a bank. Many persons are inclined to tra- duce the usefulness of the bank as a lending agency. Yet it has been the means of more prog- ress, of making more comforts the property of all, of more civilization, probably, than any other institution of modern times. The lending of money or credit is essentially the most vital function of banking. "The Loan Department is not only the most important, but it is the money-making end of the business. If it makes no loans, it will pay no dividends. If, on the other hand, it makes bad loans, it will go out of existence." ^ Not only is it the money-making side of the bank, but it is a source of deposits. In the first chapter we have quoted Mr. Vander- lip to show that banks do not first gather deposits in order to lend, but extend loans, thereby creat- ing deposits. Probably the relation of bank • Humphrey Robinson, A Simple Explanation of Modern Bank' ing. p. 82. 74 PRACTICAL BANKING deposits from credit sources — i.e., loans and discounts — to cash money deposits is as high as 5 to 1. Regarding the creation of deposits by discount- ing, Mr. Horace White, in his work on Money and Banking, has in part quoted Mr. H. D. McLeod as follows : — He — the banker — now begins to discount the commercial paper of his customers running say ninety days at six per cent. When he discounts a bill of ex- change for $1000, he deducts the interest for ninety days ($15) and credits the customer with the remainder ($985) on his books. This $985 is called a deposit, be- cause the customer has the right to draw it out by his check exactly as he could draw out an equal sum of gold deposited by him in the same bank. In the eye of the banker, and of the customer, and of the law, it is a deposit. In ordinary' times it is like any other deposit. That is, the proportion remaining uncalled for at any time will be about the same as the proportion of actual money deposited. Yet it is nothing but a bank credit. Hence the word "deposit," when thus used, is clearly a misnomer, since, by derivation and common under- standing, a deposit means a thing laid away, or given in charge of somebody. Thus, it can be clearly inferred that the pro- ceeds of a very small fraction of the average bank's loans and discounts are paid in cash. The author has one bank in mind which, according to an official, never pays any cash on paper, and but rarely issues cashier's checks for the proceeds of a note. When arrangements are made with a bank for credit, the customer nearly always agrees to keep a certain deposit balance on the books. LOAN AND DISCOUNT DEPARTMENT 75 Assume that a man wishes to open a credit at a certain bank. He arms himself with whatever collateral or evidences of debt due him he may de»ire to offer, and repairs to the bank. There he must conform to one of two methods of proced- ure. Either his application will be considered by the board of directors or by certain officers of the bank. In the latter event those having the power of extending credit to a new customer are the president, vice-president, or the cashier — per- haps all three. Some institutions permit certain clerks to discount paper for those having an established line of credit, but generally speaking, no person, unless he is an officer, has the power of extending the bank's credit. Now our man, who has made application for a credit, has submitted either his collateral or notes which he wishes to discount. If he wishes a credit of say $100,000, the bank may require an average balance of $10,000 to $20,000. Mr. Humphrey Robinson, in his book on the modern bank, says, "In New York the banks generally require a regular customer to keep an average balance of not less than twenty per cent of the loans made him. Most interior banks consider ten per cent about the right proportion." For his own notes the customer probably pledges security. His indorsement on receivables (i.e., the obligations of others in his favor) is sufficient. When the amount of credit, the rate of interest, and the security have been agreed upon, the paper is turned over to the discount clerk, who figures the interest or discount, takes the paper in, and has the proceeds credited to the new customer's ac- 76 PRACTICAL BANKING count. From time to time the customer proba- bly has commercial paper discounted for the credit of his account. He is free to make as many drafts against his bank credit as he pleases, provided his average balance is that agreed upon. The extension of a bank's credit on time loans is based largely on commercial paper. ^ In fact, probably two thirds of the credit in our country is based on commercial paper. When a security loan is made it is customary to require about twenty per cent more collateral than the amount of the loan. If, however, the security be of the very best grade, no excess may be required. On the other hand, if the security, such as real estate, is not easily and quickly convertible, a larger per- centage is required. National banks, of course, may not accept real estate mortgages as security for any loan at the time of making. To prevent loss, they may afterward accept such for loans made in good faith. Bonds of all kinds, stocks, mortgages on real estate and on personal property, and private obligations of other kinds, are deemed legitimate and acceptable collateral. In accepting stocks for collateral, it is important to see that they are properly indorsed with the power of attorney to transfer their title on the stock ledger of the issu- ing corporation. The rate of interest on loans and discounts varies from two to eight per cent. A maximum rate is fixed by statute in nearly all the States. National banks in places where the rate is regu- * See page 23, note, and the chapter on the Federal Reserve Act. LOAN AND DISCOUNT DEPARTMENT 77 lated by the State may charge legal interest; in States where it is not specifically fixed, they may charge seven per cent and no more. Yet the rate is constantly fluctuating as the ratio of supply to demand changes. From the Financial Age of July 18, 1910, the following report of the New York money market is taken : — The feature of the week has been an extensive in- quiry for six months' accommodation. Lenders can now obtain 5j per cent, and even at this rate the supply is not abundant. Higher charges are levied for all periods, although sixty day money is occasionally available at 3^ per cent. The detailed range at the close of the week was as follows: Sixty days, 3| per cent; 90 days, 4j to 4| per cent; four months, 4^ to 4| per cent; five months, 4f to 5 per cent; and for six months 5j per cent. The maximum quotation on call for the week was 3 per cent. The average ruling rate for the week has been a shade over 2| per cent, the minimum 2 per cent. The rate for call money, in New York espe- cially, fluctuates even from hour to hour. This is because there is no definite supply or constant demand, for the call money market consists largely of the overage of banks on the one hand and the shortage of brokers on the other. The necessity for such investment is felt to a very great degree in New York, where all clearing- house banks are required to carry a cash balance on hand equal to twenty-five per cent of their deposits. They do not normally carry much if any more than this, and so a debit of a million or more dollars in the clearing would probably seriously affect their reserve. They must call in. But on 78 PRACTICAL BANKING the other hand, if they have a large credit in the clearing, they find it very undesirable to coop it up inactive in their vaults, and consequently they invest it in call loans. They usually are able to invest it in this manner, since brokers are con- stantly needing large sums of money for short time. It has been argued by some people that banks doing a business of discounting small notes almost exclusively and paying many of them in cash, should be permitted to charge one per cent per month. It is shown that it requires as much time and space to accept and keep a fifty-dollar loan as one of one thousand dollars. The period of the average time loan is probably ninety days. Four months' paper is also much in evidence; five and six months' paper is rarer; and long-time paper is seldom seen in a commercial bank, beyond a small block which may be safely invested to offset somewhat the loss incurred by the bank's entire credit not being extended at certain times. When a note is made payable at a fixed date, it is customary in most instances to deduct for the exact number of days from the day of dis- count to the day of maturity. In some States the banks are permitted to charge interest for the day of discount as well as the day of maturity. The three-days-of -grace rule still exists in some of the States, though its usefulness has long since passed. Interest is charged for days of grace. For computing the day on which a note falls due at so many days from date, charts are used. These charts likewise show the number of days LOAN AND DISCOUNT DEPARTMENT 79 between two dates, making allowance for a holi- day if the note matures on one. Reference to a book in which interest is figured at different rates for any length of time on any amount saves time and insures accuracy. The reduction of the dis- count clerk's work in this particular to a purely mechanical process is certainly a reduction of error. Some note forms contain clauses in which the signer waives all exemption from debt as pro- vided by law, and agrees to the confiscation of any of his property which the bank may hold if he defaults in the payment of the note at ma- turity ; in these notes he also assents to the forced collection of the paper, in default of payment, by an attorney, whose fee he agrees to pay. In addi- tion, the collateral notes provide, in his failure to pay, for the sale of the securities, the proceeds of which may be applied to the face of the note and accumulated interest. If there is anything left, it is paid to the former owner of the securities or his personal representative, appointed in his will or by the law. A banker may demand more or other security at any time if he thinks that which he holds is declining in value, and upon the bor- rower's refusal to comply he may even sell it. All discounted notes are indorsed. Frequently in this class of paper, it is desirable for the in- dorser to waive protest on the note. Why this is so will now be shown. Many a bank customer discounts the note of a man that he knows is per- fectly good for the amount. But there is a possi- bility that he may not be able to meet his obliga- tion on the day of its maturity. Now, if the signer 80 PRACTICAL BANKING is a good patron of the bank customer, it would not be good policy to have the note protested, for even if such action caused immediate payment of the debt, it probably would incur the lasting enmity of the patron ; if it did not cause the pay- ment of the paper, the customer would be liable, not only for the note, but also for the protest fees. So in a large number of cases, commercial paper is taken nonprotestable. Primarily, of course, the maker of a note is responsible for its payment, but in his default each indorser is responsible for a part or all of the note. It must be remembered that these provisions are not necessarily universally observed. For instance, it is not the custom in the Eastern States for notes to contain clauses as to waiver or attorneys' fees. II In keeping record of their notes, banks have different systems. The general bookkeeper has the loan and discount account on his ledger. With this account the notes themselves are balanced every so often. For ready reference many banks use two books which we shall call a register and a ledger. The register is a sort of journal, showing in detail each day's loans and discounts. Columns are ruled off for the number of the paper, the maker, the indorsers, the date of making, the date of discount, the amount, the discount or interest, and any general remarks. This last column may include such information as whether LOAN AND DISCOUNT DEPARTMENT 81 the note is secured by collateral or not, whether the note is a renewal, and whether the signer has in the past been prompt in liquidating his in- debtedness. The ledger is a book which, like any other ledger, has a sheet or space for each customer. On these sheets are entered the notes as they are taken. The ruling is similar to that of the reg- ister. The notes are entered on these books and then filed away till maturity. Banks usually file their notes alphabetically, or, as seems more conven- ient, by the date of their maturity. It is a good plan to get out a month's notes, say ten days before the first one matures. No- tices are sent to the makers of these notes a week or ten days before they fall due. At the time the ensuing month's notes are taken out of the file, it has been found desirable to enter them on a book called the "tickler," according to the dates of maturity. This book need only show the date due, the maker's name, and the amount. It is very handy in making records of notes paid and renewed. A sufficient amount of data can be set down in the latter case to show the number of times renewed and the date of the original loan. Thus the tickler can be used as a quick-reference book, saving the neces- sity of looking up the note. It is also well adapted for making monthly, semiannual, or annual re- capitulations of just what percentage of loans and discounts has been paid, renewed, and unpaid. In many banks, however, this tickler is not run up once a month, but daily. In this case the 82 PRACTICAL BANKING notes are entered on the day that they come into the bank. It may seem that some of these books are use- less, but such a number has proved very conven- ient in many cases. Some banks use more. The writer knows of one bank, for instance, that seeks to have at least three checks on all its work. Since the bank clerk is made of the same fallible dust as everybody else, he will make mistakes, be he ever so accurate. It is unlikely, however, that the same error will be made on two books, and for many practical purposes the books mentioned above will act as checks on each other. Ill Although nearly all banks of any considerable size provide separate departments for the receipt and the collection of loans and discounts, this chapter purports to cover both under the single title. They are closely allied, have many points in common, and therefore it is quite feasible to treat them together. When the notes fall due, the bank's business is to collect them. There is nothing which so elo- quently attests to loose management in a bank as a great stack of past-due notes, uncollected because of the lack of suflBciently energetic efforts. There is nothing which the bank examiner so vigorously insists upon as that overdue paper held an unreasonable time be charged to "profit and loss," and that collection, if desired, be pushed through other channels. Many notes are made payable in some other city than that where they are discounted. They are / LOAN AND DISCOUNT DEPARTMENT 83 forwarded some time before maturity to a bank in that city. That bank collects them, if it can, and remits with a check on a par city, usually deducting exchange and collection charges. This method of collection will be more fully discussed in a subsequent chapter. It is frequently necessary to turn over a paper to an attorney to collect through the courts. He is authorized to bring suit on behalf of the bank and to obtain judgment for his fee as well as for the debt. If a protestable note is not paid on the day of its maturity, it must be protested for nonpayment by a notary, unless it mature on a holiday or a half-holiday, when it is due and payable on the following business day. Failure to protest a note makes the bank liable for its amount, but protest where it is waived makes the bank liable only for the notary's fees, although it might lead to trouble with the indorser or maker. Ordinarily, if protest has been made in due form, the fees must be paid by the maker, or, if he default, by the indorser. CHAPTER VIII THE FOREIGN CASH ITEMS OR TRANSIT DEPARTMENT In every bank there are certain facilities for handling foreign cash items and in a large bank there is a regular, well-organized department with its head and its corps of workers. There may be one or two clerks, or there may be a dozen in the department, depending on the volume of for- eign business handled. In a huge bank of the metropolis, twenty thousand or more checks are daily run through this department. It is neces- sary to keep a night shift in some of the greatest institutions to open mail and "run off" the in- coming checks on the adding-machine. Foreign checks, as referred to here, are usually those drawn against banks situated in places other than the one where the collecting bank is located. The line which defines them most fully seems to be, "checks that are collected by mail, but not on foreign countries." Checks on foreign countries are handled through the "foreign de- partment," and will be discussed in a subsequent chapter. Most people have only a vague idea of the exist- ence of the department under consideration, and many never dream of it, dismissing all thought of how a foreign check is collected the moment they pass it over the counter of the bank. Few, in- deed, realize the actual importance of the transit TRANSIT DEPARTMENT 85 department — how it is skillfully manipulated to throw balances first in one locality, then in another; how it is operated to curtail the heavy expense of domestic exchange; how it is used as the instrument of getting accommodation and courtesies otherwise unobtainable. Suppose, now, that in a bank taking in through its windows alone a thousand foreign checks daily, drawn probably on two hundred banks, an at- tempt should be made to send out each check to the bank on which it was drawn. The exchange would be more than doubled, as banks generally charge as much to collect a single check of five dollars as one of twenty-five dollars. Then there would not be half the efficiency and celerity in getting returns, as the bank does not hurry as much to accommodate an occasional customer as one sending many checks daily. Further, in many cities and towns a bank could get a reduced exchange rate or even a par ar- rangement by throwing all its checks for a certain territory into one association; at least, it could be done by carrying an account in the association in addition to allowing it the collecting privilege for a certain area. The clearing houses of many cities, however, prohibit any special exchange arrangements and establish a uniform rate to be charged by all its members. These provisions of the clearing house, moreover, are usually en- forced by the attachment of a heavy penalty for their violation. For example, the New York Clearing House Association imposes a fine of five thousand dollars upon a member for the first violation of its exchange rules, and pro- 86 PRACTICAL BANKING vides for the forfeiture of membership on second offense. . These foreign cash items come from many sources: from the paying teller who cashes them; from the receiving teller who accepts them as de- posits; from the note department in payment of notes and drafts; from banks depositing them or sending them for collection. Generally it is found wise to collect these items two or three times daily from the several depart- ments, making an adding-machine list of each package to turn over to the appropriate teller. The checks thus collected are "run in" with any foreign checks which may have been held over from the last emission and assorted into pigeon- holes or files, which divide them conveniently for routeing. These items are usually divided into two parts: namely, those sent for "returns," and those sent for "credit." By "returns" is meant that the bank which receives them shall collect and return a draft for the amount, minus exchange charges. These return drafts, as a rule, are on New York, Chicago, or some city whose exchange is accepted at par. By "credit" is meant that the proceeds of the collected checks — deducting exchange, if there be any charged — are to be credited to the account of the sending bank. Now, having collected into a separate package the checks to be sent to each bank, the clerks sit down to write. The letters are printed duplicate forms with instructions at the head, stating whether they are sent for returns or credit, that for a certain amount dishonor of the items is to be TRANSIT DEPARTMENT 87 wired, and that under specified conditions items are to be protested. Below on the blank space each check inclosed is fully described, the name of the bank on which it is drawn, the maker, or, most usually, the last indorser, and the amount of the item being given. Many banks still use the old method of writing these letters with pencil, but most up-to-date institutions use machines, having the essential advantages both' of the type- writer and the adding-machine. By means of these the letters are quickly and neatly written and footed up. Some write their letters on the plain typewriter and sum the amounts on an adding-machine. When the letters are written, it remains to prove them. Very apparently the amount of checks held over from the last balance added to the amount of the checks collected should equal the amount of the letters plus the present hold- over. The matter of balancing may become, in some instances, a very difficult matter, especially if the clerks do not keep their eyes open and their wits alert, for figures on bank checks, contrary to the desideratum, are not always very legible. At least, they are frequently ambiguous to such an extent that an error is quite easy. After the balance, the checks are all indorsed with the bank stamp. Then the original letters, with items inclosed, are mailed to their respective destinations, but the duplicates are put on file for record, the returns being carefully separated from the credits. To insure record of these checks out for collection, the amount sent to each bank is also entered on a sheet or book, the reverse 88 PRACTICAL BANKING side of which is often used to record remittances on letters sent for returns. There is another side of this department not yet mentioned, namely, the receiving of remit- tances. The returns should be demanded in a reasonable time. It is rare that banks are not prompt in remitting for items sent them, as they are usually glad to get the business, but occasion- ally there will be only one bank in a small town, and if facilities are poor for handling its checks except through it directly, one must "pamper it mightily," or it will let one's items be unremitted for during week after week. In many cases it has been expedient, though not on the whole desir- able, to use the express companies to collect such checks. These little banks become very irate if, in order to get better service, resort is had to the express company for collection. In one particular case, for instance, it is related that the bank paid one of the checks thus presented to it in coin entirely, putting the limit of small coin in the bag, and covering the whole with a liberal coat of molasses. But this sort of petty spite is rare, as it is not conducive to advantage, but leads to certain detriment. It behooves the clerk in charge of the transit department to keep an eye vigilant to see that remittances and credits are made promptly. If there appears to be any unwarrant- able delay, he sends a tracer asking why advice has not been forwarded on the items mailed. As fast as the drafts come in for return letters, the duplicates which they represent are taken off the current file and placed on the permanent file. The amount of each letter is entered on a sheet TRANSIT DEPARTMENT 89 for the purpose, sometimes the reverse of the sheet on which the outgoing letters are entered. At the side there is a cokimn in which can be put the amount of exchange charged in each instance. The drafts thus received in payment of items sent to be collected are drawn on New York, Chicago, or some par city. Often, however, checks sent out are unpaid for one reason or another, and are consequently returned. In this case the remittance is relatively smaller. These unpaid, returned checks are charged back to the account of the bank, firm, or individual which deposited them. Usually checks are sent protestable, and if un- paid are to be duly presented by a notary and protested. A failure to protest, when ordered, renders the offending bank liable for the amount of the check. If the bank sending a check pro- testable has no account, the protester can only write and request a remittance to cover the fees. He may be able to compel the payment of fees, but, as a matter of practice, these fees are usually most promptly paid. In the case where the check was deposited, it is easy to charge it and the pro- test fees to the account. In the matter of exchange charges, the clerk in charge of this department has an excellent oppor- tunity, if he keeps his eyes open, to save the bank money. Many little banks take delight in charg- ing exorbitant exchange rates if they are suffered to do so with impunity. However, a letter re- questing the refund of excess charges for exchange is usually a sufiicient reminder to discourage for some time any attempts to overcharge. This may 90 PRACTICAL BANKING appear a small item, but if there are a dozen banks overcharging five cents per hundred dollars for three hundred days in the year, the bank's loss from this source alone may soon creep up to an appreciable figure. Items sent for the credit of a bank's account are handled a little differently. As soon as they are mailed, they are charged on the reciprocal or bank ledger to the institution to which they were sent. The duplicate letters are kept on a current file until advice is received that the items have been credited. They are then transferred to permanent files. CHAPTER IX THE COLLECTION DEPARTMENT As one naturally infers from its name, the col- lection department is that division which collects drafts, checks, notes, and other instruments left with it or sent to it. It must not, however, be confused with the transit department which col- lects items sent as cash. The collection depart- ment is operated for the accommodation of banks and other customers. Yet it would not be quite accurate to say that it was operated purely for accommodation. There is much advantage for the bank to derive from it; reciprocal favors of banks elsewhere, the patronage of companies and individuals, and collection charges. Without the collection department, the hand- ling of items, on out-of-town parties especially, would indeed be awkward. Drafts, notes, checks, - — not sent in cash letters, — etc., would have to be collected in one of two ways : by personal agent in the town of the drawee, or by "putting them through" the transit department as cash items. But to secure a special agent in each case would be impracticable, though no more so than to send them as cash items, since there is express desire neither to have them remitted for before collec- tion, as cash items sometimes are, nor to have them credited to the account of the sender. They are not cash, and are not to be treated as such. Therefore, the collection department came into 92 PRACTICAL BANKING existence to handle just this sort of business, but it probably evolved after most of the other depart- ments were organized. Now, items for collection come to this department in two ways and are payable in two places. They come from out-of- town sources, and are payable either in the city or elsewhere; and they come from local customers, and are payable either in the city or elsewhere. Most that come from out of town are payable locally, and most that come from local customers are payable out of town. First, to take up those items payable locally. A vast number of checks are sent for collection, the proceeds of which are to be remitted as in- structed. Now, as in the transit department, because of better exchange and collection arrange- ments, items are frequently not sent direct to their destination. But direct connection has the advantage of celerity. Checks are sent through the collection depart- ment, first, when payment of them is doubtful and the payees are unwilling to have them credited to their accounts before they are collected. Again they are sent by persons who have no affiliation with a bank by which they can get them cashed before collection is effected. Lastly, checks, sent as cash items from out-of-town banks but dis- honored for insufficiency of funds, are often sent back for collection with instructions to hold them over for a time in case of nonpayment. But checks do not form any large percentage of the items handled through this department. Even more numerous than checks, in this de- partment, are drafts. As some one has said, the THE COLLECTION DEPARTMENT 93 distinction between a check and a draft is that one is a command to pay, while the other is a request to pay. The indebtedness, of which the draft is supposed to be evidence, is generally of three sorts: namely, (1) for goods delivered; (2) for goods deliverable on payment or acceptance of draft; (3) for services rendered. (1) Most drafts for goods delivered are made payable on demand or at sight. These terms are identical, save in those places where the days-of- grace custom still holds forth. There the draft "at sight" is payable three days after sight. All drafts may be sent with or without exchange. If "with exchange," the drawee not only pays the face of the draft, but the exchange charges. Other- wise, the collecting clerk deducts the charges on remitting to the sender, although there are fre- quent inter-bank arrangements whereby no col- lection charges are made. (2) Drafts covering a shipment of goods with bills of lading attached are not always payable at sight on demand, but frequently at thirty, sixty, or ninety days' sight. However, a discount is sometimes offered for the payment of these before maturity. Bill-of-lading drafts, not pay- able at sight, are presented by the collecting bank for acceptance, which is the written agreement to pay them at maturity. When acceptance is ob- tained, the bill of lading is in many cases released, and the draft, which has become as binding as any form of note, is filed away till the day for its collection. But this is a matter regulated by statute and no absolute rule can be laid down. (3) Finally, there are drafts for services rend- 94 PRACTICAL BANKING ered. Quite commonly agents and salesmen draw on their employers for expenses, commissions, and salaries. Usually these drafts are accompanied by orders or itemized expense bills. Not infrequently, also, an oflBcer draws against his company for certain sums which he has need of. Notes are much in evidence, though on the whole not as much as drafts. The notes handled are easily arranged into four classes, as follows: (1) those covering purchases of merchandise; (2) those coming from persons who will not or cannot discount them; (3) those pledged as col- lateral; (4) loans and discounts. (1) Many companies sell vast quantities of merchandise to foreign, that is, out-of-town, buyers. Often, instead of a draft with bill of lad- ing attached, especially if payment is divided into several installments, a note or a series of notes is signed for the debt. These notes are made payable in the place wh^re the signer has his business. The notes are forwarded for collec- tion to some bank in the city where they mature. Thus, if a small merchant buys a cash register for fifty dollars, he may have it broken up into five notes of ten dollars each, payable one per month. The bank to which they are forwarded collects them as they fall due and remits the proceeds to the sender. One may wonder why these notes are not discounted, but are sent direct. Sometimes they are discounted, but they are not always de- sirable to banks on account of their small amount. Likewise, the company usually does not wish to discount them, since, if it carries on an extensive business of this kind, it finds it more profitable to THE COLLECTION DEPARTMENT 95 hold the notes and collect them independently, thus saving a large discount bill. It all depends upon whether they could utilize the capital in- volved to such advantage that it would amount to more than the discount. (2) Many people have good reason for not dis- counting paper which they hold. Possibly they do not need the value of it, and are content to wait till the notes fall due and then present them through collection channels. On the other hand, they may not be able to get them discounted either because of no bank affiliation or because of the poor character of the paper. (3) Banks and others very often accept notes as collateral. These are transferred to the bank or person holding them. In case this collateral matures before the paper it secures, the possessor is generally authorized to make the collection of it, the proceeds to be applied to the secured note. A large volume of this class of collections is handled by every bank. (4) The most numerous class of notes handled through the collection department is that which covers the discounts of other banks. Every bank takes a large amount of paper maturing in other cities. These are presented for payment through the collection department of some bank in the place where they are payable. In this particular the collection department is well-nigh indispens- able, as it insures prompt and energetic attention to matters which otherwise would have to go through endless irregularities. Now, the last class of items handled by the collection department consists of sundry other 96 PRACTICAL BANKING instruments, on which there is a certain sum to be paid before their deHvery. This includes stocks, bonds, mortgages, deeds, etc., to which are usually attached drafts, calling for an amount which is the cost of the stock or bonds with the commission, the face and interest of the mort- gage, or the price of the property which the deed conveys. It must be understood that the collection de- partment not only handles those items sent to it for collection locally, but that it forwards those, payable elsewhere, to the proper banks where they are handled in an identical manner. When collection has been made, it is the duty of the clerk to remit the amount paid — minus the exchange and collection charges — to the sender of the item. Of course, the remittance should be in such exchange that it may be used at par. We may conclude that the collection depart- ment is a necessary division of the bank, organized to facilitate the handling of instruments not sent as cash. Its relation to the transit department is close. They use similar methods of mailing out items to be collected elsewhere; both have partic- ular banks to which they send their letters, be- cause of favorable exchange or collection rates. In nearly every preceding chapter, mention has been made of exchange and exchange rates. This very essential and convenient feature of the banking business is the subject of the next chapter. CHAPTER X THE DOMESTIC EXCHANGE DEPARTMENT This department is operated for the buying and selling of exchange on different parts of the country. "Exchange" is the term which has come to denote the bank's check on some bank in another place, for which you exchange your money or your check. And the name of the city prefixed to the word "exchange" exposes the city on which the check is drawn, not the one which draws it. Thus, Chicago exchange would be a bank's check on some bank in Chicago. Preeminent among exchange cities of the coun- try is New York. It is the financial center of the United States. Wall Street — which is really only a term that represents the aggregate finan- cial interests of the country — controls the policy of national finance. The thirty-eight national banks in New York City, in the year ending Sep- tember 1, 1909, made loans amounting, in round figures, to $926,000,000, or about twenty per cent of all the loans made by national associations in the United States. New York's position as a central reserve city secures her a vast amount of deposits from other cities, for outside national banks may carry from one half to three fifths of their reserve as deposit balances in that city.^ Practically, every bank ^ See chapter xx for the new reserve requirements. In 1914 five or six great New York banks held three fourths of the reserves deposited in that city. 98 PRACTICAL BANKING in the country, from the little one-clerk institu- tion at the forks of the road to the largest urban bank, carries an account in New York. What is true of New York is true in a less degree of Chicago and St. Louis, and, in a still less degree, of Philadelphia, Washington, Boston, and San Francisco. But we shall treat most specifically of New York exchange, as it plays the leading role in this department. In 1912, Congressman Vreeland, of New York, explained New York City's importance as an exchange city as follows : — Under existing conditions the banks of New York are charged with the responsibility of maintaining credit and of maintaining cash payment in the United States. New York holds the ultimate reserves of the country. The surplus money of banks may be de- posited in San Francisco or New Orleans or St. Louis or Chicago, but ultimately those not needed at home find their way to the banks of New York. This is true because New York has the only real call (loan) market in the United States.^ During the last few years Washington has assumed the proportions of an important finan- cial factor, through the action of ex-Secretary Cortelyou, who, during the financial crisis of 1907, distributed government deposits in such a way as to strengthen a large number of banks throughout the country. Some have gone so far as to declare that this custom will ultimately * From a speech in the House of Representatives, February 6, 1912. The next sentence should be borne in mind in regard to what we shall see in chapters xix and xx: "It is a real call market nine years out of ten, but in the tenth year they often call in vain." DOMESTIC EXCHANGE DEPARTMENT 99 transfer the control of finances from Wall Street to the Capitol, and they assert, in their enthusi- asm, that this will be the end of the "money kings'" czar-like tyranny over our finance. But they forget that the Administration is already a powerful factor in national finances, and that it can create, as well as dispel, panics. They also forget that there is just the same potentiality for the "money kings" controlling the situation through Washington as through Wall Street. In the very near future there will be a tendency for national finances — so far as commercial bank- ing is concerned — to cluster around twelve centers, with a central supervision in Washington. We refer, of course, to the effect of the operation of the Federal Reserve System.^ Nevertheless, New York's reserve bank is the largest and will be the most influential for some time to come. At least for the present, the nation's financial offices are still located in the shadow of old Trin- ity Church tower. Banks carrying desirable accounts in New York are able to obtain interest on their daily balances, usually two per cent. Thus, a bank's account in New York for a part of its reserve is a better arrangement than to keep it all lying in- active in its vaults. If judiciously placed, these funds are just as safe ^ as though within one's own safe, and almost as available, for it is rare that a bank is not able to dispose of a large block ^ See chapter xx for a full discussion of the new system. Banking practice regarding exchange and collections will be gradually changed; it will require three years, at the least, for readjustments to be made. * With the exception cited in a previous footnote. 100 PRACTICAL BANKING of New York exchange, if not at a premium, at least at par. But though national banks carry a part of their reserve in New York for the interest, what further condition makes every bank, large or small, keep a certain volume of New York funds? The answer: In a country where ninety-five per cent of all transactions are carried on by check and where a large percentage of these transactions are interurban and interstate, it is necessary to have some common, standard exchange. From the very status rerum. New York exchange be- came the standard. In certain sections, Chicago and St. Louis exchange are also first class. Being prime. New York exchange is theoreti- cally payable at par. But in practice this is a matter of supply arid demand. Sometimes a dis- count must be paid to convert it into cash. This is rare in the case of individuals trying to cash small drafts; but if a hapless traveler chances to be stranded in a village with one bank, he will probably be charged a fee for negotiating his New York check. The discounting of New York exchange occurs somewhat more frequently in the case of inter- bank transactions. The larger institutions usually take in enough New York drafts from their cus- tomers to keep their reserve account more than replenished. Consequently, they sometimes wish to dispose of a block of, say, ten to fifty thousand dollars on New York for cash. Usually they can sell the exchange at par or even at a premium. On the other hand, if the prospective pur- chaser is independent and the would-be seller , DOMESTIC EXCHANGE DEPARTMENT 101 is anxious to get the cash, a discount may be exacted. There are several sources of a bank's supply of New York exchange, aside from outright pur- chase. First, for every cash letter sent out for returns, proceeds are remitted in the form of a New York draft. Sometimes remittances are on banks in other cities, but not as a rule. Then every bank has a number of accounts of other banks, carried for the sake of special accommoda- tions in the matter of exchange charges or credit, or even because of reciprocal accounts. These accounts are replenished by checks, frequently collectible in New York exchange at par, or by direct deposit of drafts on the metropolis. Third, every association receives from its depositors, along with other foreign checks, a large volume of New York drafts. Added to this is the num- ber of checks on the big city cashed through the paying window and received in payment of notes, etc. Now, it may be quickly seen what demands are ordinarily made for New York exchange. First, reciprocally the bank, deducting fees, must remit for cash items, sent it for collection, in the standard exchange. Second, it is necessary to carry accounts with banks in many places and often convenient to make deposits of exchange. Next, depositing banks are liable at any time to request the remittance of a fraction or all of their balance in New York funds. Last, banks and individuals buy exchange constantly. The exchange department is operated because it is necessarily incidental to the conduct of the 102 PKACTICAL BANKING banking business. It is not usually a money- making branch. " It is a fact that an examination of this account — the exchange account — on the books of any city bank almost invariably will show that it is a source of loss rather than profit."^ Yet, properly conducted, a large bank ought to make rather than lose on this department. For it takes in great quantities of New York exchange from its depositors — individual and bank. True, it must pay exchange charges on remittances for a large volume of outgoing checks, but the very volume of these checks enables the bank to make arrangements for cheap collection. Then it sells an immense amount of exchange to its customers at the regular rate. On the other hand, the small bank, unless shrewdly managed, is disadvantageously placed, and stands to lose money. Usually, it cannot make the profitable arrangements for the hand- ling of its items by other banks; it has few bank depositors; its individual depositors supply only a limited amount of New York funds. Conse- quently, it has to buy outright for its New York account or ship currency to the metropolis. In connection with this department in inland banks is usually operated the sale of travelers' cheques. Travelers' cheques, issued by certain express companies and banks, and payable at al- most any point in the world, are a source of great convenience. We are all familiar with the form of this cheque — its line of figures across the face, showing the value in different countries; the line ^ Humphrey Robinson, A Simple Explanation of Modern Bank- ing. DOMESTIC EXCHANGE DEPARTMENT 103 for the buyer's signature, by which he is identi- fied in a strange place. In a subsequent chapter this form of exchange will be more fully discussed. ^ An idea of how New York predominates in the financial world in one respect can be gathered from the following comparisons, arrived at from the Report of the Comptroller of the Currency for 1909. The net deposits in New York national banks were almost three times those in both Chi- cago and St. Louis, the other two central reserve cities; were equal, approximately, to the net de- posits of the other forty-six reserve cities; were equal to one fourth of the entire deposits of all national banks, excluding its own; and were equal to about one fifth of all national bank deposits in the United States. The net deposits in New York national associations, at that time, amounted to $1,179,000,000 in round numbers. Now, state bank deposits have not been concentrated as much in one city, but when we remember that the deposits of national banks equal thirty-nine per cent of all deposits in the country, it is not marvelous that New York's influence is so great. But New York exchange is by no means the only kind dealt in. It is necessary for large banks to keep accounts in many prominent cities to accommodate demands, both private and corpo- rate. Persons who buy exchange of a bank are charged a small fee, usually only a trifle over cost. Naturally enough, however, certain designated customers, by virtue of the excellence of their accounts, are allowed exchange without extra charge. ' Chapter xviii. CHAPTER XI THE INDIVIDUAL LEDGER A BANK ledger of individual accounts is an inno- cent looking book which contains more mischief and hard knocks than the casual observer would believe. It is the simplest of all books, having merely columns for dates, debits, credits, and balances. But the manner in which work must be done in it, as will be shown later, makes it the young bank man's bugbear. Ask any old bank employee what the most thankless job about the institution is, and nine times out of ten he will tell you the individual books. However, we must not therefore infer that they are unimportant, for in this set of books are kept the records of debits, credits, and balances of all the bank's commercial creditors — not including, of course, any accounts of other banks, of States, or of the United States, which properly belong to the re- ciprocal or bank ledgers. The individual ledger must be posted and proved up, as a rule, daily, and a very large num- ber of debits and credits must be entered thereon each day. It differs from the individual ledger of the ordinary business house in that work on it must necessarily be done very rapidly and accu- rately, and that the books must be clean and in balance before the doors of the bank are reopened for business. In addition to posting, which we shall presently THE INDIVIDUAL LEDGER 105 discuss in more detail, the individual bookkeeper must watch and keep an accurate record of all overdrafts allowed, and of new, reopened, and closed accounts. He must likewise furnish the proper officer, at stated periods, with a list of customers who seem undesirable, because of low balances or frequent overdrafts; also, of those who make a frequent habit of stopping payment on checks, of issuing checks dated ahead, or of leaving technical errors in their drafts intention- ally. While there is usually an officer whose duty it is to examine checks at the close of business each day and pass upon signatures, dates, indorse- ments, etc., the bookkeeper is in no way relieved of the responsibility, for he may often detect a discrepancy in time to save money for the bank, while, if it were allowed to wait over till after hours, the chances of remedying the error would be lessened. The individual ledger of to-day is usually a loose-leaf book. The advantages and conven- iences of this form of book are too apparent to require any elucidation. But a great many very large banks use a permanent sheet ledger. The ordinary ledger sheet has space reserved and lined off at the top for name and address. Below, the paper is so ruled that there is a column on the left-hand edge for the date, a wider column next divided into small spaces for amounts of checks in detail, then narrower vertical rulings for checks in aggregate, deposits, and balances. Now twice, and sometimes oftener, during the day, collection is made of home checks from the tellers, the general bookkeeper, the collection and 106 PRACTICAL BANKING the exchange departments, it being so arranged that one of these collections shall be made at the time when the clearing returns are received. At the same time collection is made of all deposit slips. These, being distributed alphabetically, are turned over to the several bookkeepers, who immediately set to work. It must be nip and tuck to finish as quickly as possible; at the same time they are to see that accuracy is maintained both in calculating and in posting to the right ac- counts. A very important feature of posting is to ob- serve due care in putting down dates correctly. This should be done not only as regards the days and months, but as regards the years also. It has come within the experience of the writer to be involved in several complications, always embarrassing, and in at least one instance serious, because a bookkeeper has been careless in this particular. It is also of the utmost importance that care be exercised in placing debits and credits to the proper account. For instance, suppose John W. Smith has this morning made a deposit of four hundred dollars and the bookkeeper hast- ily credits it to the account of John M. Smith. Now, if John M. Smith be an unscrupulous man, nothing is easier than to write a check for the total amount shown to his credit, cash it, and escape. Even if he is caught, it is a question whether he could be handled legally. It is even as important to see that no check is charged to the wrong account, for the double reason that a man mav overdraw his account without his or the bank's knowledge, and that the institution is THE INDIVIDUAL LEDGER 107 extremely likely to lose what may be a valuable account and earn the customer's enmity. When all checks and deposits have been posted and the bank is closed for the day, the time for proving the day's work is at hand. As a prelim- inary step a journal is made of the individual checks and deposits on different sheets. This is done with the adding-macliine, the credits and debits being so di\'ided as to fall into sections cor- responding to the different ledgers. Now, the total of deposits for each section is added to the balance of that section for the previous day; the checks are subtracted. With a total of these bal- ances the amounts on the books must be made to coincide. The summa summarum of these sec- tions should agree with the general bookkeeper's record of the total balance of individual deposits for that day. Then comes the actual proving-up of the ledgers. There are three well-known methods of balancing the ledger; namely, (1) the trial balance; (2) the statement-duplicate; (3) the debit and credit "tab." The trial balance is the oldest system, one that has about suffered natural and eminently satis- factory death. The clerk has a second book by him in which are the names of the customers in his ledger. As he posts, he writes down the bal- ance of each customer opposite his name on the trial-balance book. If, when he has compared an addition of his totals with the balance of his sec- tion as obtained above, there should not be ex- act coincidence of amounts, he must search for the difference even to the last penny. In all cases overdrafts, which are usually brought down in 108 PRACTICAL BANKING red ink, must be subtracted from a list of balances for the day. The statement-duplicate system is different. Here every check and deposit is posted twice daily — each time by a different man in a differ- ent book. In the afternoon the names and bal- ances affected during the day by posting are called from one book and verified on the other. In this event, it is only necessary to prove up the ledger once a week, for it is the rarest thing that two experienced bookkeepers will make the same error. This system has the advantage of making pass-book balancing easy. One merely gets the checks out of the file and enters their totals on the pass-book, for the duplicate record in the ledger can be torn out and used as an itemized statement. The debit and credit "tab" method is perhaps the easiest to handle of all. Placing a debit or credit "tab" in those accounts only that are changed for any one day, the bookkeeper makes a separate list of the balances of these accounts for the present and previous day. Their differ- ence should just equal the difference between the checks and deposits for that particular section on that particular day. The advantage of this method lies in the fact that the possibility of error in adding and checking is reduced and confined to the number of accounts changed for any one day, and only in those accounts need the book- keeper look for his error. Once in a fortnight, however, the entire ledger should be balanced. There remains the simple method of posting the checks and deposits on the regular ledger and then adding up balances to make them, in toto. THE INDIVIDUAL LEDGER 109 agree with the general bookkeeper's record. This is the downright, bludgeon method, taking advan- tage of none of the short cuts. Finally, either in the afternoon following the balance, or before hours on the next business day, all entries of checks and deposits should be veri- fied by a man, other than the one who posted them, for the purpose of detecting errors that may exist of credits or debits to wrong parties. CHAPTER XII THE RECIPROCAL OR BANK LEDGER Every bank which accepts deposits of checks — and all do — receives daily a large number on banks in places more or less distant. These items are sent for collection, as described in an earlier chapter, and unless some definite arrangement exists between the sender and the receiver, no special accommodations are extended and the maximum exchange rate is charged. But every bank has special agreements, and of these this chapter has to treat. Arrangements are based on two things: first, reciprocal agreement by which mutual special privileges are granted; second, the carrying of accounts. The latter naturally includes those ac- counts created by extension of credit. These two methods result in quick and courteous attention, and in minimum or advantageous exchange rates. The reciprocal agreement consists generally of the promise of one bank to handle certain items at a definite exchange rate in return for a similar favor. In this manner banks can mass items on a wide territory into their letters to certain associa- tions, which can handle them conveniently at a rate from one half to one fourth what they would cost if sent direct to each bank. Reciprocall3% the senders handle, for the other banks, checks on institutions which they may collect at a low rate or even at par. RECIPROCAL OR BANK LEDGER 111 This agreement necessitates, as a natural con- sequence, an account on the reciprocal or bank ledger of each bank. On the ledger of the sender a charge to the association to whom the items were sent ; on the receiver's ledger, a credit for the sender. The forming of these accounts is per- fectly incidental and may be only temporary. The second arrangement may consist of the promise of one bank to carry a certain balance in another, in return for which it secures interest on daily balances and favorable collection rates. There may be an agreement to carry mutual accounts, or agreements combining the first method with this one. All of these are reciprocal accounts. "Reciprocal accounts are such accounts as bear only on transactions between banks, the term 'reciprocal' being given these accounts because of the mutual exchange of business." In many associations these are not known as reciprocal accounts, nor is the ledger known as the recipro- cal ledger; they are bank accounts and it is the bank ledger. But reciprocal expresses the mutu- ality of the accounts so well that we shall use it by preference. Unless permanent by agreement, these accounts are cleared by remittance; that is, the collecting bank sends its check on New York or some other city of par standing for the amount of the items, less the exchange. Sometimes the accounts are only remitted for on demand. In other cases the bank having the credit asks its clearance once or twice monthly. At that time it requests the amount to be remitted to it or placed to its credit 112 PRACTICAL BANKING with a correspondent. However, the creditor bank is likely, at any time it may have need of funds, to order a certain amount remitted to it or sent, either in check or currency form, to one of its agents. The book on which reciprocal accounts are kept is no more than an ordinary bank ledger. Its pages are ruled off for the title and appropri- ate information at the top, with columns below for date, amount of credit or debit, and credit or debit balance; for on reciprocal sheets, by their very nature, there need not necessarily be credit balances. If a bank has an amount on deposit in another bank, it has a credit balance there, but if it is keeping in its bank a deposit of the other institution, it has a debit balance there. It is the case of the individual customer and his bank over and over. The bank has on its books a credit for him; he has on his books a debit against it. To be sure, with the individual customers it remains always in this sense, save in the case of over- drafts, while with reciprocal accounts a double- action process is possible; that is, it may be a credit balance to-day and a debit balance to- morrow. It is easy to see how closely this department is allied to the transit department, for most of the checks, drafts, and charges against and to the credit of the reciprocal customers are handled by the foreign cash items men. The innumerable items sent out in cash letters are frequently charged on the bank ledger from the sheet, already described, filled out in the transit depart- ment. RECIPROCAL OR BANK LEDGER 113 The items received by the paying teller, receiv- ing teller, and other clerks, drawn against their own bank by other associations, are charged on their books to the proper banks, to be transferred to the reciprocal ledger by the bookkeeper, or, as seems more regular, to be charged to the recip- rocal bookkeeper, who receives them and makes the proper entries from the original items. Most of these bank accounts are created and maintained by an agreement which offers a cer- tain amount of interest on daily balances. This is in addition to usual arrangements for a line of credit — but that's another story. Two, three, or even four per cent is paid on such accounts. In most cases interest is figured about the first of every month. The method in general vogue of computing the amount of interest due on average balances is to discover the total amount of deposit for one day and figure on such a basis. The old arithmetical rule says, "Multiply the deposit bal- ance for one day by the number of days in the interest period to find a total for one day." But in bank accounts, the balances vary from day to day. So the same result is obtained by simply adding up on the machine the balances for each day. Of course, for holidays, the balance of the previous business day is repeated. "WTien the interest has been figured and verified, it is entered to the credit of the proper bank, and a notification card is sent out to the bank, stating that such and such an amount has been placed to its credit as interest on average daily balances for the month. It is then verified by the receiving bank, and if any mistake has been made, ncgotia- 114 PRACTICAL BANKING tions are commenced for its correction. These difficulties, however, are not usually serious. What is a more arduous task is the reconcile- ment of accounts. By reconcilement is meant the comparing of the two banks' records of their mutual accounts. This is done about the last of the month. There is during the month, if the account be active, a large volume of transactions of the books of the two associations. Suppose A carries an account with B. B is in a large city, and so checks drawn on it are in constant demand. A pays his remittances to banks, sending him collections, in checks on B, subtracting a suitable exchange fee. He also sells a good deal of exchange of B to customers and others desiring it, likewise charg- ing a fee. Possibly he draws on B to place other deposits or to cover the proceeds of a discount, or to transmit funds to the United States Treas- urer. At least, at the end of the month he has made quite a few drafts. So B gets out all the drafts and other charges which have been made against A's account, and discovers whether their total subtracted from the former balance and all subsequent deposits leaves the present balance on the ledger. If so, it pro- ceeds to itemize the deposits and subtract the total of charges on a statement form, which it incloses with the paid checks. Then comes the rub. It maybe claimed, and I think it will be granted, that bank men are very accurate in their work. The nature of their business demands it. But they are heirs to all human fallibility, including the liability to clerical error. Add to this human fail- RECIPROCAL OR BANK LEDGER 115 ing a distance of several hundred miles, the multi- plicity of checks, and the long interval in which no attempt is made to reconcile the accounts, and we have some cause for occasional variance of the two accounts. Further, there is the matter of charge tickets, of which something will be said presently. If a bookkeeper has many accounts to keep and little time, he must work very rapidly. He may post a check erroneously, — that is, to the wrong account, — and if he makes the proper deduction, his balance will not show the discrepancy. This is true of deposits in even a greater degree. The bookkeeper will detect most of his errors of post- ing to the wrong account when he rechecks his work, but if the drafts of the banks involved in such an error are very similar, he may not catch it even then. He may, under these conditions, not detect the mistake in making out the statements, so that one sometimes finds in the checks charged against his bank checks drawn by another bank whose draft form is similar to his. But this rarely occurs. It is quite possible, and sometimes actually happens, that deposits in form of cash letters of drafts and checks fail to reach their due destina- tion. This is in time detected and traced by the credit notification plan. But if the deposit be sent near the close of the month and does not reach its destination, time enough may not have elapsed to take up the matter of failure to receive notifica- tion before the statements are sent out. Let it not be misunderstood, however, that these errors are everyday happenings. In fact, 116 PRACTICAL BANKING expert bookkeepers rarely make them, or, at least, quickly detect them. But they are possible, and occasional mistakes show along what line the bookkeeper has to be most careful. So the statement is made out according to B's ledger and forwarded, together with the drafts, to A. A may find some charges of which he knows nothing, or he may discover some other bank's check among his and charged to him. On the other hand, he may find no trace of what a certain charge stands for, and in that case, barring mathe- matical errors, he suspects some "charge slip" of which he has no record. Or it may be that some deposit has not been credited or has not reached its destination. Anyway, he immediately sets to work, with B's assistance, to locate the error. In the matter of "charge tickets" or "charge slips " a word of explanation is necessary. When a bank sends items for collection and they are immediately placed to its credit pending collec- tion, it is often necessary to charge off some or all of them, because of their subsequent dishonor. This is not done by check, of course, but by a ticket specifying the charge and its cause, and signed by some proper oflBcer. The unpaid items, with a memorandum, are sent to the bank from which they came. Each bank then makes a cross- entry and the affair is closed. The charge tickets are sometimes not included with the checks at the end of the month. So it is possible that some return of unpaid items may have strangely failed of its destination, and the bank to which it was charged does not have a record of the debit. But in most banks, charge slips are returned. RECIPROCAL OR BANK LEDGER 117 There is usually no trouble in reconciling these differences when they do occur. But now and then a hard case will come up. The writer has in mind an instance where a small check, returned for non- payment, was apparently lost in the mails. At least, the bank to which it was directed claimed not to have received it. The statement at once showed a discrepancy. The other bank wrote promptly about it. The item was traced, but no vestige could be found. So the one bank con- tinued in its charge of the check, and the other continued to carry the balance on its book, as though no such charge had been made. Thus it went on merrily for several months, each state- ment being followed by a letter from the irascible cashier of the other bank, demanding that the charge be taken off. At last, the signer of the check, who had meantime made it good, con- sented to issue a duplicate check in its place. It has been seen that the reciprocal bookkeeping department is one of the main arteries of the bank. It caters to a certain kind of customer from whose accounts much general profit can be derived. Through these customers avenues are opened up for getting accommodation and advantageous terms for a large volume of its business. It is just a process — as the name implies — of giving and receiving, of offering certain rates here for certain rates there, of exchanging deposits, etc. CHAPTER XIII THE GENERAL BOOKS It has been shown that each phase of the bank's work is detailed to some particular department — deposits to the receiving teller, disbursements to the paying teller, loans and discounts to the loan clerk. It has also been shown that each daily balances his credits with his debits. But for the sake of convenience, and because good business methods imperatively call for it, there must be some general department where all the transactions of the bank, in compact form, are gathered, compiled, and tabulated. It is ne- cessary to provide means for a general survey or recapitulation of total resources and liabilities. This is accomplished by the use of the general ledger. In addition to collecting one day's trans- actions into one book, the general ledger has some special functions of which we shall speak in the proper place. As a basis for this treatment of the accounts handled on the general ledger, it is necessary to summarize briefly the kinds of business handled by the several departments. The paying teller handles home, clearing and foreign items, cash, loans and discounts, exchange, etc. ; the receiving teller, home, clearing and foreign items, deposits, cash, and exchange. So, we might continue through the whole gamut of bank departments, and probably we should find that the following THE GENERAL BOOKS 119 accounts were necessary on the general ledger: bank, individual and savings deposits, loans and discounts, interest and discount, interest on de- posits, interest from banks, expense accounts, exchange, certificates of deposits, certified and cashier's checks. If to these are added accounts for capital stock, surplus, undivided profits, furni- ture, real property, bonds, and the clearing house, the principal accounts on the general books are named. General accounts, as a rule, do not record in- dividual transactions, but show in aggregate each day's transactions under their proper heads. Although not first in the enumeration, capital stock deserves the first place in a logical discus- sion of these accounts. Capital stock, of course, is the working basis of the bank, subscribed by persons who believe it to be good investment. Before a national bank can open its doors for business, fifty per cent of the capital stock must be paid in. It therefore always owns a credit place on the ledger. From time to time, banks add part of their earnings to a surplus account. This simply in- creases the ratio which assets bear to liabilities and increases the book value of the capital stock. Before declaring each dividend, national associa- tions have to set aside a certain part of their earnings as surplus, until it reaches a figure equal to twenty per cent of the capital. The name "undivided profits" completely be- trays its utility. Credits made to it are transfers from income-bearing accounts, such as interest and discount or bond income. Charges against 120 PRACTICAL BANKING it are usually transfers to the surplus account, and to cashier's checks, the latter of which is in turn reduced by dividend checks for the amount of the transfer. Fluctuating and constantly changing, the loans and discounts account is rapidly filled and refilled with entries. This is caused by the continual liquidation of debts and the relending of the bank's credit. This account will show at a glance just the total amount owing the bank for notes and other discounts. Many banks keep separate accounts of demand and time loans. There are always several deposit accounts. In general, they are public, bank, individual and savings, and certificates of deposit. Public de- posits include federal, state, or county deposits, usually put at interest and not actively drawn against. Bank deposits, steady or temporary, are reciprocal. Individual deposits refer, naturally, to the commercial or checking accounts of per- sons, firms, or corporations. Savings accounts, with certificates of deposit in a slightly different sense, are accounts little drawn against and put at interest. On the ledger there are also accounts to show the debit and credit of cashier's checks, of certi- fied checks, of exchange collected and paid, of interest and discount, of interest on deposits, and of interest received from other banks. A word of explanation may not be amiss in regard to the last-named. The account for interest from banks records the interest for balances carried in those banks. More of this bank interest has been spoken of in the previous chapter. The bond income ac- THE GENERAL BOOKS 121 count, as the name suggests, shows the result of the work which the investment in bonds is doing. The actual account of bonds belonging to the bank is quite another account. In cities where there are clearing houses, the members carry clearing-house accounts on the general ledger, which show just how the bank fared on each day's clearing, whether debited or credited. The best business methods prompt the collection and payment of clearing-house bal- ances each day, so that this account is always balanced off at the close of the day. But in cities where, instead of actual money being paid into the clearing house for balances and collected from it, drafts are issued in favor of credit banks and against debit banks, this account is not always balanced out. Frequently, in such cities, the clearing-house draft is sent through as a clearing check itself. This is not always a sound policy, however. Another clearing-house account is kept on the general books in cities where, as in New York, the associated members carry large amounts on deposit in the vaults of the clearing house. On the national bank ledger is found a five- per-cent-redemption account. It must always show a credit equal to five per cent of the bank's circulation, and must be kept on deposit with the Treasurer of the United States, to cover redemp- tions of the bank's circulation. The methods of general bookkeeping depart- ments are almost as many and varied as there are different banks and different officers. There is the same fundamental organization, the same pur- pose, but the details are worked out to comply 122 PRACTICAL BANKING with local conditions. In describing this depart- ment, therefore, we are endeavoring to give as general an account as possible, selecting for the different features the methods which seem best to accomplish their intended end. On account of the diversity and entirely dif- ferent style of accounts, the general ledger is more engaging work than the individual book. The latter, by reason of its routine, is likely to grow monotonous. In the larger banks several men are employed for the general ledger alone; in the smaller ones, only one. Sometimes the general and bank ledgers are kept by the same man, and, if we but go far enough and look in at the country book- keeper, we may see him driving away at all of the books, general, bank, and individual, with, per- haps, the whole between two covers. Many associations require the general book- keeper to keep a " cash sheet," which shows at a glance how much money the bank has in its vaults on a certain day, the amount taken in and dis- bursed by all the departments, including letters received containing items for collection and credit, notes discounted and paid, remittances made, and exchange. It simply is a convenient method for spreading such information on one sheet as may be necessary to show the transactions of one day. Close akin to this, in one respect, is a loose-leaf sheet, generally kept by the transit department, showing on one side the remittances received for cash letters sent out, along with the exchange paid, and on the reverse side the amount of cash letters mailed on the same day. CHAPTER XIV THE SAVINGS DEPARTMENT As we have seen, the modern bank has grown to be a general exchange mart of credit. It has come to be the medium through which people may expeditiously handle business based on faith in each other. Accounts are formed, by a process of credit, for the purpose of making drafts against them to liquidate other indebtednesses. I But there is a class of accounts which cor- responds closely to those contained in such in- stitutions as the old Bank of Amsterdam, namely, accounts which represent money deposited for safe-keeping. As there is a larger cash basis for them and as they are not actively checked against, they are more profitable to banks, in proportion to their amount, than ordinary commercial ac- counts. This, with the fact that money can al- ways demand a certain percentage of interest outside, has led to the general bank practice of offering interest on savings accounts. There are, of course, institutions which con- duct a purely savings business, but their scope is too broad for consideration here. We shall, there- fore, devote ourselves to a short discussion of the savings department of the commercial bank, though, perforce, frequent reference may be made to savings banks. 124 PRACTICAL BANKING In his Report for 1909, the Comptroller of the Currency says : — Peculiar interest attaches to statistics relating to savings institutions, inasmuch as they are the reposi- tories of the accumulations of wage-earners mainly and an index to thrift. The functions of these institu- tions are essentially different from those of commercial banks, as savings banks are a part of a system the aim of which is the safe and profitable investment of the funds of those who are not so situated as to invest their own money, and in this respect a mutual savings institution is the property of its depositors. From 1820, with 10 savings banks in the coun- try having deposits equal to $1,138,576, or an average of twelve cents per capita in the United States, to 1911, with 1884 savings banks having deposits amounting to $4,212,583,598, or an average of $44.82 per capita in the United States, we made gigantic strides in the development of this important branch of banking. The increase in per-capita savings from 1909 to 1911 was $3.07. This large advance is probably due to the recuperation of savings after the stringency fol- lowing the flurry in 1907. The progress of savings deposits is a tribute to the thrift and energy of American blood. In 1911 there were 9,794,000 depositors, or one in every ten inhabitants.^ But not only is there a vast amount deposited in strictly savings institutions, but a huge num- ber of banks, doing a commercial business, have savings departments. On September 1, 1911, the national banks of our country and island pos- * See Report of the Comptroller of the Currency, 1911. For postal savings figures, which are separate from these, see infra, pp. 131^. THE SAVINGS DEPARTMENT 125 sessions had on savings deposit $659,501,543.90, and the state banks had $574,936,098.65. The total savings in 24,392 banks in the United States and islands amounted to $5,445,724,306.77. This was exclusive of about $1,900,000,000 placed on certificates of deposit. It is natural to wonder why it is profitable to conduct a savings bank or a savings department. At first blush, it would seem less lucrative than a commercial banking business, and perhaps, all and all, it is. Yet a savings bank may be so man- aged as to net large dividends. Savings deposi- tors are steadier — that is, they draw less against their accounts — than those doing a mercantile business. Thus, there is a larger amount per hun- dred dollars deposited that may be looked upon as permanently available for lending. Then, too, since there are fewer transactions, there is a smaller expense incurred in operating than in the commercial department. Last, the savings bank can safely invest a much larger percentage of its deposits than a bank doing a mercantile business. In 1908 the average ratio of cash in savings banks to deposits was 1.25 per cent; in 1909, it was .88 per cent.^ Thus it may be seen that the savings depart- ment is a highly desirable adjunct to any bank. Were there less profit in it, most banks would operate it, nevertheless, in order to supply every demand made upon them by their customers for banking facilities. * Usually no cash reserve is required of savings banks. Usually, too, they may demand sixty days' notice on any withdrawals. See Digest of State Banking Statutes, by S. A. Welldon, National Moni- tary Commission Series. 126 PRACTICAL BANKING The savings department is not intended for and does not appeal to firms, corporations, or even individuals who check regularly against their accounts. It aims, primarily, to cater to those wishing to accumulate, by degrees, with little or no withdrawals, a snug sum. Next, it appeals to treasurers, guardians, and trustees, who have money, not often drawn upon, to put at interest. Then it accommodates many indi- viduals who like to put on interest any surplus which they are holding temporarily, in contempla- tion of a future investment elsewhere. Some banks place a minimum figure for bal- ances, say twenty-five or fifty dollars, since otherwise a "raft" of very small accounts, not worth the cost of handling, will accumulate. This must be contended with by banks which open accounts as small as fifty cents or one dollar. For on the impulse of the moment, many persons will make a resolve to start saving, and will de- posit one or two dollars, after which their zeal cools and they proceed to neglect their account. There it stands on the bank's ledger taking as much space and nearly as much time as a five thousand dollar account. To cater especially to this small depositor, the postal savings bank, which will be discussed farther on, was created. The banks which do seek the very small de- positor sometimes employ a corps of paid solici- tors who scour the community, trying to secure a large number of beginners, hoping to obtain some very desirable accounts by the gradual sift- ing process. These banks have numerous ways of "tempting" the pubhc. They get out beauti- THE SAVINGS DEPARTMENT 127 ful little safes, some containing a register of con- tents; some a clock; others are in the form of neat little books which can be stowed away in the pocket. There are hundreds of different styles of "banks" which are placed in the hands of peo- ple, for the loan of which only a small cash de- posit is required. As a rule, however, the larger the bank, the less desirable are such accounts. Interest on savings accounts varies from two to four per cent. In 1909 savings banks paid an average of 3.72 per cent on savings deposits; na- tional banks, 3.34 per cent; state banks, 3.71 per cent; and private banks, 3.43 per cent. A brief word about certificates of deposit. These certificates are issued by every bank, and read to the effect that such a person has deposited a stated amount, to draw interest if it remains on deposit for a certain length of time. Some banks stop the interest accruing at the end of the speci- fied period unless the certificate is renewed; others will pay interest for the total life of the paper. Still others specify in the body of the certificate that the principal deposited may not be withdrawn until the date of maturity. The total amount of money invested in demand certi- ficates of deposit and time deposits in the United States for the year 1911 was $1,900,000,000. Another form of certificate which is popular with transients is that which shows at a glance what the interest amounts to for a certain time. These certificates are issued on printed forms for twenty-five, fifty, seventy-five dollars, etc. In a space below is given the interest that will ac- cumulate in three months, six months, twelve 128 PRACTICAL BANKING months, etc. In other words, one can tell in an instant the value of his certificate. The name of the buyer of the certificate is filled in and he is required to sign his name in a designated place, by which he may, after the fashion of traveler's checks, be identified. The proper officer's signa- ture validates the certificate. In the case of at least one large bank, these certificates contain, on the reverse side, a list of banks scattered throughout the country which will honor these certificates and pay the proper interest. II The large associations not only have a separate department for the handling of savings accounts, but they also have a force under the direction of a savings manager or secretary. Under this secre- tary are the tellers and bookkeepers. The tellers, whose duties largely involve the receiving of money, have functions partaking both of the paying and receiving tellers, though exactly like neither. As a rule, they do not have to rush through their work like their fellows in the com- mercial department, for, as has been remarked, the transactions on savings accounts, in propor- tion to the amount of deposits, are much fewer than on checking accounts. The result is that the tellers have more time to cultivate that pleas- ant familiarity with customers which is such an asset in a department where women and children and others who like personal notice have to be waited upon. But, like the other tellers, they are constantly on their guard against frauds and mis- takes of their own. A plan, followed by some THE SAVINGS DEPARTMENT 129 banks to check with the ledgers the balances on pass-books, is to have the teller jot down on every deposit slip or check the pass-book balance. This may be compared with the ledger as posting is done. Twice or four times annually interest is cal- culated on each savings account and credited. The most laborious part of the work is saved by tables which show the amount of interest — at the given rate — for one month on all amounts. The calculator only has to discover the average balance for one month, multiply it by the num- ber of months, and he has the sum on which in- terest is to be figured. Reference to the tables speedily shows the amount of interest. Every calculation should be, and generally is, carefully verified by a second man. The interest, once verified, is "run through" the teller's book as a deposit, offset in his cash by a voucher properly signed. It is a simple matter to add the interest to each person's account, but it is not such a simple matter to get it credited on the pass-books. It is always tedious to wait for them to be brought in voluntarily, and, therefore, in many banks, a call is made for them when interest is paid. Ill Like the foreign exchange department, the savings department of a large association is really itself a bank in miniature. It is a means of safe and profitable investment for the wage-earner, for the woman and the child, for trustees, and those having money on hand for temporary de- posit. 130 PRACTICAL BANKING But as we remarked earlier in the chapter, many banks do not encourage very small ac- counts. For some years the matter of the estab- lishment of government banks, to cater to the depositor who wishes to start with little and gradually build up a neat balance, was agitated. The Postal Savings Bank Bill was passed in 1910. Mr. Thomas B. Paton thus succinctly describes the postal savings bank: ^ The Postmaster-General, the Secretary of the Treas- ury, and the Attorney-General are constituted a board of trustees with authority to designate such post- offices as the board may select to be postal savings depository offices to receive deposits of funds from the public. The minimum deposit which will be received is one dollar, and deposits may be of a larger amount in multiples thereof, not exceeding one hundred dollars in any calendar month, and the maximum deposit of any one depositor is fixed at five hundred dollars, ex- clusive of accumulated interest. The bill provides for the sale of adhesive "postal savings stamps" to be attached to a postal savings card in order that smaller amounts may be accumulated for deposit; when such cards contain stamps in amounts of one dollar, or multiples thereof, they are acceptable as deposits. The law provides that interest at the rate of two per cent shall be credited to the depositor each year. It pro- vides that postal savings funds shall be deposited in solvent banks, whether organized under national or state laws, such banks being subject to national or state supervision and examination, and the deposits in banks to bear interest at the rate of not less than two and a quarter per cent per annum, which rate shall be uniform throughout the country. Provision ^ Journal of the American Bankers' Association, July, 1910. THE SAVINGS DEPARTMENT 131 is made that funds received at postal savings deposi- torj'- offices shall be deposited in banks in the same locality. A reserve of five per cent of postal savings funds is to be kept with the Treasurer of the United States. Any person ten years or over in age can open an account in his or her own name; any woman can have an account in her own name and "free from any control or interference by her husband." However, no person may have a deposit in more than one postal savings bank.^ Clearly this act appeals to the small depositor. The savings, national, and state banks of the nation retain practically all their big savings de- positors, a large number of their smaller ones, ^ Perhaps no better idea of how the postal savings bank makes its appeal can be got than from the following letter to the author from the Honorable T. L. Weed, then director of the postal savings sys- tem, dated August 3, 1912: — "While the acceptance of deposits of small amount and the sale of ten-cent savings cards and stamps make the postal savings sys- tem of special value to wage-earners and children, the patronage of the system is by no means confined to those classes. In fact over twelve per cent of the depositors up to June 30, 1911, were engaged in what are classed by the Bureau of the Census as 'proprietary, oflScial, and supervisory occupations,' and nineteen per cent of the remainder followed professional and clerical occupations." The following data, furnished the author by the Honorable A. M. Dockery, Third Assistant Postmaster-General, indicates the official status of the postal savings system on July 21, 1914: — "On June 30, 1914, there were 9(i44 offices with 10,352 deposi- tories (including 708 branches and stations) in operation in the United States and of these 9644 offices 8.505 were of the presidential grade and 11.39 fourth-class. On this date the number of depositors was about 397,000, and the amount on deposit was approximately $43,100,000, or an average of $109 per depositor. Of the $43,100,- 000 on deposit about $31,200,000, or over seven tenths (72.4 per cent), was held in the 271 offices having deposits of $20,000 and over, and about $22,700,000, or over one half (53.9 per cent), in the 45 offices having $100,000 and over. Over one fifth of the total 132 PRACTICAL BANKING and at the same time are able to secure postal deposits at two and one quarter per cent. As the postal savings bank's sponsors claimed, it has drawn a vast amount of money, formerly hoarded, into banks, and is apparently encouraging thrift amount on deposit was held in the four offices (New York, Chicago, Brooklyn, and Boston) having over $1,000,000 on deposit. The offices having $100,000 and over, with the amount of funds held by each, are as follows : — 1. New York City $4,394,059 24. 2. Chicago, 111 2,305,932 26. 3. Brooklyn, N.Y 1.501.446 26. 4. Boston, Mass 1,133,009 27. 6. Portland, Greg 897,498 28. 6. San Francisco, Cal 875.446 29. 7. Cincinnati. Ohio 690,030 30. ' 8. St. Paul. Minn 689.445 31. 9. Kansas City, Mo 586.865 32. 10. Pittsburg, Pa 586,759 33. 11. Columbus, Ohio 668.623 34. 12. Los Angeles. Cal 647.152 36. 13. Detroit. Mich 646.296 36. 14. Philadelphia. Pa 630,964 37. 15. St. Louis. Mo 507,406 38. 16. Milwaukee, Wis 463.956 39. 17. Butte, Mont 408,046 40. 18. Denver, Colo 401.630 41. 19. Cleveland. Ohio 387.223 42. 20. Seattle, Wash 341,170 43. 21. Tacoma, Wash 316,940 44. 22. Washington, D.C 263.978 45. 23. Toledo, Ohio 249.669 Newark, N.J $237,976 Omaha, Neb 234,370 Oakland, Cal 222,291 Louisville, Ky 217,760 Minneapolis, Minn 206.923 Providence, R.I 187,375 Leadville, Colo 183,025 Duluth, Minn 176,048 San Diego. Cal 170,950 Buffalo, N.Y 166,113 Indianapolis, Ind 162.128 Kansas City, Kan 154,284 Dallas. Tex 153,915 Ironwood, Mich 150,080 Memphis, Tenn 133,194 Akron, Ohio 121,645 Dayton, Ohio 121.122 Erie. Pa 111,403 Roslyn, Wash 106.464 New Orleans, La 105,703 Astoria, Oreg 104.100 Bellingham, Wash 100,309 "The $43,100,000 on deposit is exclusive of $4,635,820, which is the sum withdrawn by depositors prior to July 1, 1914, for the pur- pose of buying postal savings bonds. Applications amounting to $872,240 were received for the issue of July 1, 1914, and this amount will be withdrawn in July. "The Postal Savings Act provided that the funds received shall be deposited in solvent banks, and that are organized under national or state laws and subject to national or state supervision and ex- amination, it being stipulated that the word ' bank ' shall! be held to include savings banks and trust companies doing a banking busi- ness. Under these provisions 6715 banks in the United States have qualified to receive postal savings funds, classified as follows: 3627 national banks; 2099 state banks; 347 savings banks; 617 trust companies; 25 'organized' private banks." THE SAVINGS DEPARTMENT 133 in those who either had no facilities or hesitated because of the smallness of their deposits. If one wishes, he may surrender his deposit in sums of twenty, forty, sixty, eighty, one hundred dollars, and multiples thereof, and receive in lieu United States coupon or registered bonds bearing two and one half per cent interest an- nually. CHAPTER XV THE FORMATION AND POWERS OF THE NATIONAL BANK During the Civil War the Federal Govern- ment was financially embarrassed. The gigantic struggle emptied the Treasury more rapidly than the revenues of the country could refill it. To assist the Washington Government, the clearing houses of the East came forward with loans; the Government itself issued bonds, but buyers were few and suspicious. Then, some of the financial geniuses of the time conceived the idea of tempt- ing purchasers by allowing them special privileges in certain instances. The name of Salmon P. Chase is foremost among these astute construc- tive financiers.^ The National Bank Act was the fruit of their ideas. Banks formed under this act were allowed * The National Bank Act, as we now know, did not prove to be a measure which would prevent panics. At best, it standardized bank notes. But then it must be remembered that it was not in- tended primarily as a currency reform, but to provide a market for United States bonds. At the same time it would be unfair to Chase to say that he merely stumbled into a system engendered by the ercigencies of the times. Andrew McFarland Davis, in The Origin of the National Banking System, National Monetary Commission Series, shows that Chase's mind had attacked the financial system of the United States as a currency problem. Had the necessities of the Civil War not intervened as they did, who can tell but what we should have had, from the brain of Chase and his contemporaries, some scheme for providing a currency based on actual business transactions? For the provisions for such a currency, see chapter xx. THE NATIONAL BANK 1S5 circulating notes, to be secured, however, by United States bonds deposited with the Treas- urer of the United States. There was, however, one obstruction to the success of the plan. State banks were issuing circulating notes, and there was no direct power to stop them. To remove this competing institution, therefore, a prohibi- tory tax of ten per cent was placed on all circu- lating bank notes save those authorized by the National Bank Act. Thus, state banks either be- came national banks — and therefore had to pur- chase federal bonds — or gave up the advantage of a circulation. The act has provided a safe currency, but not one calculated to alleviate or prevent periodic financial stringencies. It does not expand and contract to suit the exigency of the season or the general financial situation. True, it has a cer- tain elasticity, but it is only the elasticity "of the old rubber band which may be stretched to a cer- tain extent, but which does not contract again." The act has had many new and helpful provi- sions, however, and we have at last evolved a system which will meet the demands of the coun- try and not cater merely to the convenience of the Government — since that necessity has dis- appeared long ago. A national bank may be formed by a group of persons, not less than five in number.^ ^ "In view of these provisions, it has been the uniform policy of the Comptroller to investigate carefully each application to enable it to be determined whether or not the case is entitled to favorable consideration before definite action is taken by the prospective incorporators. "It has been for some time past the practice of this ofBce to refer 136 PRACTICAL BANKING The first step toward organization is the adop- tion of articles of association, which state briefly the object of the organization, and which also contain provisions necessary for the general con- duct of its business, provided such regulations are consistent with law. A copy of these articles signed by the organizers must be transmitted to the Comptroller of the Currency. Second, an "organization certificate" is drafted which enumerates : — (1) The name assumed by the association (subject to the approval of the Comp- troller of the Currency). (2) The exact location of its offices. (3) The amount of capital stock. (4) The names and residences of the stock- holders, and the number of shares each holds. Upon filing the articles of association and the organization certificate, the bank becomes a corporate body, and has the power : — to national-bank examiners all applications received for the organi- zation of national banks. "Some of the points to be covered in the investigation are: — " (A) The standing of the applicants in the community. " (B) Are the directors to be local men with an active interest in the bank. " (C) In case the question turns on whether or not there is need of another bank, submit a statement showing the amount of 'pur- chased paper' held by the bank or banks in the place, and state the percentage of such ' purchased paper ' to the total amount of loans and discounts of the bank. "(D) In cases where the necessity for another bank is open to question, please state whether or not the bank, if established, would obtain entirely new business or would draw such business from ex- isting institutions." Re-port of the Comptroller of the Currency, 1911, pp. 77-78. THE NATIONAL BANK 137 (1) To have succession for twenty years, un- less otherwise dissolved. (2) To elect or appoint directors, who shall select the president, cashier, and other officers, defining their duties, requiring bonds, and having power of dismissal. (3) To adopt by-laws, not inconsistent with law, for regulating the appointment of oflScers, the transference of stock, and the conduct of the business of the bank. (4) To exercise by its board of directors, or duly authorized officers, the power of carry- ing on business by "discounting and nego- tiating promissory notes, drafts, bills of exchange, and other evidences of debt; by receiving deposits; by buying and selling exchange, coin, and bullion; by loaning money on personal security; and by ob- taining and issuing circulating notes." A very important feature of a bank's organiza- tion is its capital stock, and it must here be some- what explained. Amendments to the statutes in 1900 allow the organization of banks with $25,000 capital in towns of 3000 inhabitants or less; with $50,000 in towns of 6000 inhabitants or less; and with $100,000 in other towns; except that a bank in a city of 50,000 population or more can- not be organized with less than $200,000 capital stock. Before a national bank can begin business, the capital, divided into shares of one hundred dol- lars each, must have been at least half paid up. And at the end of each month after it opens its doors, ten per cent of the whole must be paid, till 138 PRACTICAL BANKING the entire subscribed and authorized capital is paid in. Any association may, upon the vote of holders of two thirds, of the shares, increase its capital stock to any sum approved by the Comptroller of the Currency, notwithstanding any limit fixed by its articles of organization. Likewise, those holding two thirds of the stock may authorize the reduction of its capital to any figure, subject to two conditions : first, that it shall not be under the amount of capital required for organization; and, second, that it shall not be less than the amount of outstanding circulation.^ At elections, the shareholders may vote by proxies, duly au- thorized in writing, but no officer or employee of the bank may act as proxy. No shareholder may vote whose liability is past due and unpaid. In a previous chapter,- we have considered the relation of the directors to the bank in the practi- cal conduct of its affairs. Let us now look for a moment at their technical duties, privileges, and qualifications in the national bank. They are elected annually on such a day in January as may be selected, and hold office for one year. The law requires that at least five di- rectors shall be elected, all of whom must be citizens of the United States, and three fourths of whom must have resided in the State, Territory, or District in w^hich the bank is located for one year previous to their election. All are required to reside there during their incumbency. * Under the Federal Reserve Act, reductions cannot be made without the approval of the Federal Reserve Board. ^ Chapter n. THE NATIONAL BANK 139 Every director must own in his own name ten or more shares of stock, unless the capital of the bank be as low as $25,000, in which case he must be the owner of at least five shares of stock. If he ceases to be qualified in any way, he forfeits his place on the board. All vacancies on the board are filled by appointment by the remaining di- rectors, and the appointee holds ofiice until the next annual election. Upon entering his ofiice, the director, whether appointed or elected, must take oath that he will honestly and diligently perform his duties and will not knowingly violate or permit to be vio- lated any of the provisions governing the bank's organization and regulation. He also swears that he is the owner, in his own right, of the requisite number of shares of stock, and that this stock is unincumbered. Now, the most apparent advantage of organiz- ing a national bank is its ability to issue circulat- ing notes. ^ These notes are delivered to the bank by the Comptroller of the Currency upon the receipt of United States bonds, which, at par value, will cover the notes issued. It must be understood, however, that very little actual profit accumulates from investment in circulating notes. The Report of the Comptroller of the Currency for 1909 contains the following figures : — In October, 1909, the market price (of 2 per cent consols) has fallen to $101,052, when the profit on ' This was a fact until 1913, when the passage of the Federal Reserve Act provided that national banks need not issue circulating notes. Under the new law there are other methods of expanding the currency and investing funds than by issuing circulating notes. 140 PRACTICAL BANKING circulation (on such a basis) increased to 1.334 per cent. Panama Canal bonds were $100,595 in October, 1909, the rate of profit being 1.384 per cent. . . . The profit on circulation secured by these bonds (4 per cent loan of 1925, October, 1909, quotation, $117,320) was 1.211 per cent. Mr. Humphrey Robinson shows the method of ascertaining the profit on circulation.^ He figures on a basis of $100,000 circulation: — Bonds purchased: U.S. registered two per cent bonds to be paid at par in 1930. Price of bonds at 104 $104,000 Par value of bonds purchased 100,000 Money worth six per cent. Income from bonds 2,000 Income from circulating notes loaned at six per cent 6,000 Total income $8,000 Less deductions : — Annual tax on circulating notes $500 Sinking fimd to retire premium on bonds at maturity, amount to be charged ofif each year 181 Expenses (plates, express charges, etc.) 75 756 Net income from circulating notes $7,244 Net income from loaning $104,000 (net cost of bonds purchased) at six per cent 6,240 Net profit on circulation $1,004 On such a basis we see that there is a profit of 1.004 per cent on the amount in circulation, which, however, is a profit of only .965 per cent on the amount invested ($104,000). A Simple Explanation of Modern Banking, p. 104. 1 THE NATIONAL BANK 141 All associations having on deposit, to secure their circulation, United States bonds bearing two per cent interest, including Panama Canal bonds, must pay the Treasurer in January of each year a tax of one fourth of one per cent per half- year on all of their circulation based on such bonds. Banks having on deposit, to secure cir- culation, United States bonds bearing more than two per cent interest must pay semiannually one half of one per cent tax on such notes as are based on these bonds. Every association having circulating notes based on securities other than United States and Panama Canal bonds must pay for the first three months a tax ^ of three per cent per annum on the average amount of such circulation, and after- wards a tax of one half of one per cent per annum for each month until a tax of six per cent is reached, and thereafter a tax of six per cent per annum on the average amount of such circula- tion. This tax is imposed to secure the quick re- tirement of emergency currency issued under the Act of May 30, 1908. The Treasurer at Washington has a deposit from every national bank amounting to five per cent of its circulation. This fund is used as an account against which national bank note re- demptions are charged. Whenever national bank currency, worn, mutilated, or otherwise unfit for use, is presented to the Treasurer, he redeems it in United States money. The banks to whom it be- ^ This tax is meant to apply to emergency currency issued under the Aldrich-Vreeland Act of 1908, but is a reduction, mad(! by the Federal Reserve Act of 1913, of the original tax. For provisions of the Aldrich-Vreeland Act, see page 157 et seq. 142 PRACTICAL BANKING longs are notified, and when redemptions amount- ing to five hundred dollars or more for one bank have accumulated, the bank deposits forthwith with the Treasurer a sum equal to the redemp- tions, and receives new blank currency for the redeemed notes. ^ There are other advantages in conducting a national bank, not the least of which is the des- ignation as a United States depository. Such as are selected by the Secretary of the Treasury receive deposits of public money, which, it is unnecessary to remark, is useful at all times and especially in times of financial flurry. For in- stance, the author remembers one bank, ordi- narily-shaving $50,000 of United States deposits, which received $300,000 during the panic of 1907-08. For the guaranty of the safe and prompt pay- ment of these deposits, United States and other bonds or securities must be deposited in the Treas- ury in amount satisfactory to the Secretary of the Treasury. The Secretary is enjoined by law to apportion these deposits equitably among the States. At such a rate as the Secretary may prescribe — not less than one per cent per annum — in- terest is paid on average monthly balances. This includes special and additional deposits of public money in the regular depositories and such asso- ciations as may be selected as temporary deposi- tories. ^ Under the old National Banking Law, national banks might count the five per cent redemption fund as a part of their re- quired reserve. The Federal Reserve Act repeals this privilege. THE NATIONAL BANK 143 Banks in certain cities in the United States, designated as reserve cities, must carry a reserve equal to twenty-five per cent of their deposits, exclusive of Federal deposits. However, they may carry one half of this as deposit balances in one or all of the three central reserve cities. These central reserve cities — New York, Chicago, and St. Louis — must keep a reserve of twenty-five per cent of their deposits in cash or in certain credits which the Government recognizes. All other national banks need carry a reserve of only fifteen per cent. And of this, three fifths may consist of credit balances in banks, in either re- serve or central reserve cities, while two fifths must be in their vaults. In addition to legal tender, clearing-house certificates, for which law- ful money has been deposited, may be held as reserve by a member of the issuing clearing house. ^ It will be observed that banks no longer are required to hold reserve against their circula- tion, as was originally provided. They base their reserve on the amount of deposits they have, exclusive of federal deposits. A national bank may charge such a rate of interest as is permitted or authorized by the State, Territory, or District in which it is situ- ated. If no state law regulates this point, seven per cent and no more may be charged. This, however, does not preclude the charge of exchange or collection fees on drafts, bills of exchange, and discounts payable elsewhere. ^ Again see chapter xx for reserve requirements under the Fed- eral Reserve Act. 144 PRACTICAL BANKING A national bank may not accept its own stock as collateral for a loan, nor may it buy its own stock except to prevent loss on a debt previously contracted in good faith. In that case the stock must be sold again within six months. National banks may not accept United States notes or notes of national banks as collateral. A national bank cannot accept real estate as collateral for a loan, but there are a few cases in which it may own the title to realty, namely: (1) Property for its own housing and accom- modation. (2) Property that may be mortgaged to it in good faith, as security for debts previously made. (3) That which may be deeded to it in pay- ment of debts previously contracted in its ordinary transactions. (4) Such as it may purchase at a sale under judgment held by itself, or may purchase to secure debts due it. But no national bank may hold longer than five years any mortgage or title taken or pur- chased for the security of a debt. Semiannually, the directors may declare a dividend of the net earnings of the association, but before doing so they must add one tenth of the net earnings of the previous half-year to the surplus fund, until it has reached an amount equal to twenty per cent of the capital stock. The Federal Reserve Act (1913) amended the section of the Revised Statutes concerning what liabilities a national bank may have exceeding in amount its capital stock. These are the obliga- THE NATIONAL BANK 145 tions which it may not have, in amounts greater than its capital stock : — (1) Notes of circulation. (2) Moneys deposited with or collected by the association. (3) Bills of exchange or drafts drawn against money actually on deposit to the credit of the association or due thereto. (4) Liabilities to the stockholders of the asso- ciation for dividends and reserve profits (i.e., dividends on stock in the Federal Reserve Banks.) (5) Liabilities incurred under the provisions of the Federal Reserve Act. From 134 national banks capitalized at $16,- 000,000 to 7488 national banks capitaHzed at $1,056,345,000 is huge progress; it represents the growth of national banks in this country from 1863 to 1913 or during the first half-century of their history. Other figures may be interesting. In 1864, the national banks were in number equal to only 9.6 per cent of the reporting banks of the United States, with a capital equal to 3.7 per cent of the capital of the reporting banks. In 1913, the number of national banks was equal to 28.8 per cent of all reporting banks of the country, and their capital equal to 513 per cent of the re- ported bank capital. Thus, while the ratio of the number of national banks to the whole is 300 per cent of what it was in 1864, the ratio of the capi- tal to the entire capital is now 1360 per cent of what it was in 1864. CHAPTER XVI NATIONAL BANK NOTES In an earlier chapter I have suggested how paper money came, as a matter of convenience, to be substituted for coin or bulHon. This, how- ever, does not explain the security for most of the "paper money" of to-day. For example, on a certain day the Bank of England had issued £51,000,000 of notes, for which £32,000,000 was held in gold; the Bank of France had issued £197,000,000 in circulating notes, against which was held £175,000,000 in coin and bullion; and the Imperial Bank of Germany had issued £98,- 000,000 of notes, for the security of which £49,- 000,000 was held. What, then, is the guaranty for the large "uncovered" portions of these issues.'* For the most part, the discrepancies are represented by loans to the , Government, treas- ury notes, or individual bills rediscounted. But suppose, you say, that every one should suddenly demand gold or silver for his bank notes. ^ Indubitably, that would amount to a ca- 1 The story of the growth of the use of gold and silver as media of exchange is told in a lively, if somewhat inaccurate, fashion in a book, A History of the Precious Metals, by Alexander Del Mar, pub- lished in 1880. The author traces the coinage of the precious metals into money to Phidon of Argos (about the ninth century B.C.), but intimates that the practice may have been prevalent in India at a much more remote date. In fact, much evidence tends to indicate that coined NATIONAL BANK NOTES 147 tastrophe — in a teapot. It would reveal only this, that there is no good reason why we should money was used in countries from Egj^pt to India — Thibet, Lydia, Phry-gia, and Crete — as early as the fourteenth century B.C. The evidence mainly relied upon is the Code of Menes, relating the ratio between gold and silver, which Wilkinson places as early as 2950 B.C. Mr. Del Mar instances the change in the ratio of gold and silver between the fifteenth century B.C. and the nineteenth century A.D., which was from " 1 silver equals 10 gold" to " 1 gold equals 20 silver." Mr. Del Mar had a " purpose," and that was to prove a new inter- pretation of history, namely, one based on the production of gold and silver. Part of his interesting collection of historical items fol- lows. Many Argonautic expeditions existed in antiquity. Jason's was not the first; at any rate, his seems to have been largely piratical. "Sardinia at that time contained rich placers of gold, and it was probably to obtain this metal that Jason and his companions under- took that part of their memorable voyage which carried them west- ward." Then, it seems, the Phoenicians worked the gold sands of Sarabat. About 500 B.C., Darius undertook his conquests for the sake of money. Alexander the Great was a gigantic plunderer and — ac- cording to the author — secured pecuniary results in his campaigns amounting to a billion dollars, in addition to slaughtering several million human beings. The writer continues with an observation that quartz mining was attended with unusual danger and cruelty. He quotes Diodorus, who visited Egypt about fifty years B.C. and found well-nigh intolerable conditions in the quartz mines, where the overseer " lashes them [the miners] severely. Deprived of all hope, these miserable creatures expect each day to be worse than the last; and long for death to end their griefs." Next, Mr. Del Mar cites the constant contests for Spain as a fur- ther proof of his contention that " in the search of gold, whole races of people have been put to the sword, continents subjugated, re- ligions and civilizations destroyed." Then comes the case of the conquest of America by the Spaniards. An interesting side-light may be thrown on the origin of the hesi- tancy of Orientals to exploit natural resources by the author's sug- gestion that the Chinese long opposed the mining of gold and silver because it would force people into servitude. The remarkable conclusion to which Mr. Del Mar comes is that the desire for precious metal has furnished all ages with an " irresist i- ble motive for cruelty, injustice, and oppression. In the Middle 148 PRACTICAL BANKING not represent, in tangible, movable form, other val- ues than those of silver and gold. It would disclose only this "mystery," that merchants and farmers had borrowed small sums — for which they had pledged property of some sort — from their local banks, which had, in turn, indorsed the notes or "bills" and rediscounted them at the central bank of issue. There is no sane argument against issuing circulating notes on the security of such property. Intrinsically, a house or an iron safe is quite as valuable, if not more valuable, than a lump of gold or silver. Abroad this truism has long been recognized and even we Americans have finally come to the conclusion that we may very cautiously pass notes on the basis of other security than the precious metals or bonds. In the United States there is at present approx- imately $2,250,000,000 in coin and bullion, of which $1,300,000,000 is represented by gold and Ages it stimulated the internecine strife into which Europe was for 6ve centuries plunged" and which was terminated only by the dis- covery of America. One takes a deep breath when he finishes this — a breath of relief. To what extent would the author go? He has confused, in his en- thusiasm for his thesis, economics with money, when as a matter of fact economics has been connected only incidentally, when at all, with money. He overlooks such considerations as bread and meat, pasturage, farming land, benign climates, and other impulses to- ward strife. Most of all, he forgets entirely the most frequent im- mediate causes of invasions and wars — namely, greed for power. In the last analysis, even this can be reduced to my first proposition above, namely, a question of livelihoods and comforts. I fear the author has been carried away by the literary appeal of his imposing aggregation of historical (?) personages. What they wanted is what men mostly want to-day — the power over other men's bodies and minds. Money chanced to be the medium through which this desire was manifested. It is no fault of "money" itself, which is well-nigh indispensable, but of man's uncurbed, elemental craving for power. NATIONAL BANK NOTES 149 silver certificates. In addition, there is about $700,000,000 in national bank notes, secured by United States bonds, and about $350,000,000 United States notes, issued on the credit of the Government, against which, however, may be counted almost an equal amount of money held in the Treasury as assets. No one can say our system is not safe. A special chapter will subsequently be devoted to a discussion of how, fraught with politics and urged or retarded by politicians, a new system, which is even now receiving its first practical test, has been evolved from the currency question. For the present purpose, a description of the issue of national bank notes under the original National Bank Act of 1863, with the supplemen- tary scheme of 1908, will suffice. A national bank note is the promise of the issuing bank to pay a certain sum of money on demand, — nothing more. The United States Government guarantees the payment of this cur- rency, but stands to lose nothing, as it is secured by bonds deposited with the Treasurer. If they are simply negotiable I.O.U.'s, why do not state banks, as well as national banks, issue circulating notes .^^ Just because the Federal Congress, in organizing the national banking system, laid a prohibitive tax, as we have seen, of ten per cent on all notes issued by other than national banks. This forced the state bank currency out of exist- ence, since ten per cent is far more than could be earned on the currency issued. On the other hand, it had the tendency of inducing many state banks, which desired the power of circula- 150 PRACTICAL BANKING tion, to become national associations. As we have observed in the foregoing chapter, the act creating national banks was simply a measure to make a ready market for United States bonds. Every national bank is required to issue a cer- tain amount of circulating notes. If the associa- tion's capital be more than $150,000, it need carry only $50,000 in notes; if its capital be $150,000 or less, its circulation must at least be equal to one fourth of its capital stock. The circulating notes are issuable in denomina- tions ranging from five to ten thousand dollars, but not more than one third of the bank's cir- culation may consist of five-dollar notes. No notes larger than one thousand dollars have been issued. When the national bank was organized in 1864, it was provided that notes of less than five dollars value might be issued, but in quantity not to exceed one sixth of the bank's circulation. This provision became inactive upon the resump- tion of specie payments in January, 1879. There are still approximately $500,000 in national bank "ones" and "twos" outstanding. On October 31, 1911, there were in round numbers $740,000,- 000 of national bank notes of various denomina- tions in circulation and in the banks. Before any bank may commence business, it must transfer and deliver to the Treasurer of the United States registered, interest-bearing bonds of the United States in such amount as, at par value, will cover the circulation which it proposes to take out.^ It may deposit, however, Panama ^ The Federal Reserve Act repeals those statutes which require that "before any national banking association shall be authorized NATIONAL BANK NOTES 151 Canal two per cent bonds in lieu of the regular United States bonds. ^ If the market value of the bonds deposited falls below par, bonds in amount sufficient to cover the notes at the market value of the bonds will be required of the association by the Comptroller of the Currency. After depositing bonds, the association is en- titled to receive from the Comptroller of the Cur- rency national bank notes in blank, signed by the Treasurer and the Register of the Treasury. The notes bear the promise of the issuing bank to redeem them in money at its own counter. Below this promise is space for the signatures of the president or vice-president and the cashier of the bank. On the back of the notes there is the declara- tion of the United States Government that they may be tendered in payment of taxes, excises, public lands, and all other dues to the United States except duties on imports; that they are also receivable for all salaries and other debts and demands except interest on public debt and in redemption of the national bank currency. National bank notes sent to the Comptroller of the Currency for redemption are, if they are fit for circulation, sent to the issuing banks upon remittances of lawful money covering them. If to commence a banking business, it shall be required to transfer and deliver to the Treasurer of the United, States a stated amount of United States bonds." ^ It may be of interest to note that on a given date — say in August, 1911 — the profit on issuing national bank notes based on Panama Canal bonds was 1.410 per cent, while that based on the consols of 1930 was 1.393 per cent and on the loan of 1925 1.22G per cent. 152 PRACTICAL BANKING they are badly worn or mutilated, they are de- stroyed by maceration in the presence of four persons, namely, one representing the Secretary of the Treasury, one the Treasurer, one the Comp- troller of the Currency, and one the bank whose notes are thus destroyed. A certificate of the maceration is signed by the witnesses in dupli- cate, one copy of which is filed in the office of the Comptroller of the Currency, and one forwarded to the association. This certificate is necessary, since it would be the height of folly to remit for currency which was only supposed to be de- stroyed, but which might at some future time reappear for redemption. The certificate guar- antees the maceration of the old notes and there- fore protects the bank against any possible loss. In place of the currency thus redeemed and destroyed new notes in blank are sent to the asso- ciation upon receipt of the remittances of lawful money covering them. These notes are secured by the bonds which represented the destroyed currency. There is another sort of national bank which is provided for by the statutes, but which is little heard or known of at large, namely, national asso- ciations for issuing gold certificates. They may be organized under the same general provisions as the other national banks, but bonds which they offer for security of circulation must be United States bonds bearing interest in gold. Notes are issued for only eighty per cent of the par value of these bonds. The lowest denomina- tion is five dollars. These notes specify that they are payable in gold money of the United States NATIONAL BANK NOTES 153 on presentation at the office of the issuing bank. National gold associations must keep a reserve of twenty-five per cent of their outstanding cir- culation in gold and silver coin. In 1910 there was only $75,000 of gold national bank certificates outstanding, so it is apparent that gold banks are not popular, and it is easy to see, from the re- quirements, why they would not ordinarily be so. II The national bank currency has been severely criticized time and again. The old saying is that it will expand under certain arbitrary and artifi- cial conditions and will contract in the same way. The charge is that it does not expand naturally — responding to industrial and agricultural de- mands; nor contract naturally — when these de- mands are satisfied. It has been pointed out time and time again that there is no inevitable rela- tion between the needs of the season and the sup- ply of currency. This irregularity has in effect made our financial panics more disastrous and enduring than they would have otherwise been. The great depression of 1907-08 served to bring the matter to a head. On May 30, 1908, along with the passage of the bill which created national currency associations (described below), a National Monetary Commission was authorized which was required "to inquire into and report to Congress, at the earliest date practicable, what changes are necessary or desirable in the mone- tary system of the United States." This Commission, which was composed of some of the most distinguished men in Congress, 154 PRACTICAL BANKING planned and executed an investigation of mone- tary conditions all over the world and published reports and papers by experts which ran to sixty volumes and pamphlets.^ In January 1912, the Commission, through Senator Aldrich, its chairman, reported its labors complete and submitted a plan for a great na- tional clearing house, tobe known as the National Reserve Association. The plan would have, in general, given unity and centralization to the enactment of 1908 described below. It was never enacted into law.^ One of the great collection of publications of the Commission is of particular interest here. It is a monograph by Mr. Alexander D. Noyes, on the History of the National Bank Currency. In this pamphlet Mr. Noyes has very clearly shown what we have mentioned above, namely, that the expansion and contraction of the na- tional bank currency does not inevitably reflect agricultural and industrial demands. In fact, he states that, so far from moving in the same direc- ^ The personnel of the Commission was as follows: Nelson W. Aldrich, Rhode Island, chairman; Edward B. Vreeland, New York, vice-chairman; William B. Allison, Iowa; Julius C. Burrows, Michi- gan; Eugene Hale, Maine; Philander C. Knox, Pennsylvania; Theo- dore E. Burton, Ohio; John W. Daniel, Virginia; Henry M. Teller, Colorado; Hernando D. Money, Mississippi; Joseph W. Bailey, Texas; Frank P. Flint, California; James P. Taliaferro, Florida; Boies Penrose, Pennsylvania; James Overstreet, Indiana; John W. Weeks, Massachusetts; Robert W. Bonynge, Colorado; Sylvester C. Smith, California; Lemuel P. Padgett, Tennessee; George P. Bur- gess, Texas; Arsene P. Pujo, Louisiana; George W. Prince, Illinois; James McLachlan, California. ^ The suggested remedy of the National Monetary Commission will be discussed more fully in chapter xx, dealing with the steps which finally led up to the passing of the Owen-Glass Currency Bill in 191d NATIONAL BANK NOTES 155 tion as trade, bank-note circulation is likely to operate in an exactly opposite direction. He shows that the operation which requires an expansion of currency tends to make national bank notes scarce. For instance, we have a year of great prosperity and trade activity. There must be an expansion in national bank notes; it means the purchase of bonds by the banks. The same prosperous condition fills the Federal Treasury to overflowing, and consequently, the Government reduces its debt by buying up its bonds. This raises the price and discourages the buying for purposes of security on circulation. In 1879 the government debt was $1,797,000,000. Beginning then, under piping times of prosperity, it redeemed its debt until, in 1887, this was $1,- 021,000,000, and in 1892 was reduced to only $585,000,000. The result was that bonds which sold for 99 in 1879 sold for 121f in 1882. Banks were tempted to sell and make the profit; also to abstain from buying, at these tip-top prices, for circulation purposes. This condition, together with a large amount of "Government 3's" which were called by the Treasury, caused the national bank issue to fall from $361,800,000, in 1883, to $296,500,000 in 1886. In 1891 the issue was only $167,577,000. And this was at a period when the growth of the country demanded a large amount of currency. In fact, in a nutshell, the use for money for purposes of trade, evidenced by the amount of exchanges in the clearing houses, be- tween 1883 and 1891 increased fifty -four per cent, while national bank currency actually de- creased fifty- three per cent. 156 PRACTICAL BANKING On the other hand, as Mr. Noyes goes on to show, the same inconvenience was experienced when a decrease in currency was natural. The crash of 1893 brought down the prices of bonds; the Government, in financial straits, issued $100,- 000,000 in new bonds. They were bought largely by national banks, because the low price made them attractive circulation investments, and they were used as a basis for additional currency. And this at a time when clearing-house exchanges showed a large decrease.^ So that between 1892 and 1894 trade activity had decreased twenty six per cent, while bank notes had increased eighteen per cent.^ Mr. Noyes concludes that there is no "remedy for this abnormal situation except the substitu- tion of some other system for that which pre- scribes the United States government bond as a basis for bank-note issues." This pamphlet was written in 1910. In 1908 a patchwork system had been adopted which, it was hoped, might tend to avert any return of the catastrophe of 1907. This system was outlined and provided for in the so-called Aldrich-Vreeland Act of May 30, 1908, aiming to give relief to the currency strin- * See chapter on "The Clearing House." Also the section ia chapter xix, on the crisis of 1893. ''■ I suppose, as a matter of fact, that this increase in bank notes would relieve the stringency and make money easier to obtain. But the diflSculty is, the flood of money does not come till ajter the panic, which is too bad. Also, in normal times, when trading is dull from no reason such as a panic, the tendency would be to increase the bank-note issue, which, in turn, would encourage risky lending. At any rate, I think Mr. Noyes makes out his case very well. The old national bank notes certainly do not respond to natural demands. 4 NATIONAL BANK NOTES 157 gency during certain parts of the year and during panics by the estabhshment of national cur- rency associations. The main provisions of this act endeavored to create an elastic, emergency currency, to be issued on other security than United States bonds, and to be retired as soon as the "tightness" of the situation had blown over.^ A national currency association, for the issu- ance of additional circulating notes, may be formed by not less than ten national banks, each having an unimpaired capital and a surplus of at least twenty per cent of its capital. But the ag- gregate capital and surplus of the currency asso- ciation is not to be less than $5,000,000. The association can be formed in one State, in parts of one State, or in contiguous parts of more than one State. Any bank within a certain territory, having the necessary qualifications for member- ship, cannot be denied the rights and privileges of the association in that territory. In each of these associations there is a board consisting of one member from each of the asso- ciate banks. This board has the general manage- ment of the association, and, for its control, passes rules, not repugnant to law. It also elects a president, vice-president, secretary, treasurer, and executive committee of five or more members. The executive committee transacts the duties of the general board, except those of electing officers and executive committee, and of passing by-laws. The withdrawal of any bank from the associa- tion does not affect its existence unless the num- * The tax, which would force retirement of these notes as soon as the stringency was past, is mentioned on page 141. 158 PRACTICAL BANKING ber of affiliated banks is thereby reduced below ten. Any bank which is a member of a national currency association may apply through the asso- ciation to the Treasury Department for additional currency, to be based on securities other than United States bonds, including commercial paper. Commercial paper here means notes "represent- ing actual commercial transactions, which when accepted by the association shall bear the names of at least two responsible parties and have not exceeding four months to run." When such security is deposited with the cur- rency association, it makes application to the Comptroller of the Currency, who, after consult- ing the Secretary of the Treasury, issues, if con- ditions warrant it, an amount of circulating notes in a certain proportion to the cash value of the securities, not, however, to exceed seventy-five per cent in the case of commercial paper or ninety per cent in the case of state, county, or municipal bonds. The currency associations take charge of these securities for the United States. The total assets of the several banks in each association are liable for the redemption of the notes issued by any of its members, but each only in the proportion that its capital and surplus bears to the total capital and surplus. The association may at any time require of any bank more or other securities to cover its addi- tional circulation, and if, on ten days' notice, this order has not been complied with, the associa- tion may sell the securities and apply the pro- ceeds to the redemption of its notes. NATIONAL BANK NOTES 159 If, for any reason, it is impracticable for a bank to be a member of a national currency associa- tion, under certain conditions it is not deprived of the right to issue additional notes. If it has a surplus equal to twenty per cent of its capital stock, it can make application to the Comp- troller of the Currency for additional currency to be based on bonds other than those of the United States Government. In this case securities eligi- ble for additional circulation are state bonds and interest-bearing obligations of any county, town, or city which has been in existence for ten years past and has not defaulted in the payment of its obligations. The five per cent redemption fund applies to additional currency issue as it does to the regular bond-secured currency. It was originally pro- vided that there should at no time be more than $500,000,000 of additional circulating notes out- standing, but an amendment passed August 4, 1914, provided that each bank might issue addi- tional circulating notes to an amount equal to 125 per cent of its unimpaired capital and sur- plus. This increased the possible issue to about $1,760,000,000. This act was to expire in 1914, but the Federal Reserve Act extended it to June 30, 1915. Under it, up to August 22, 1913, twenty associations were formed with over $675,000,000 capital and surplus. During the financial stringency of the summer and fall of 1914, the provisions of the act were beneficent, in that a panic was avoided and business was " tided over" until the establishment of the Federal Reserve Banks could be effected. 160 PRACTICAL BANKING The great difficulties with this scheme seem to be: (1) that it lacked centralization, and therefore could not be uniform in its operation nor public in its control; (2) that it exhibited much of the old super-cautiousness of the national bank note based on United States bonds; and (3) that it made no provision for the protection of the coun- try's gold reserve. But it was, after all, only in- tended as a makeshift, put together to safeguard the country's financial interests during a period in which something satisfactory, constructive, and lasting was produced. CHAPTER XVII THE CLEARING HOUSE Some time ago the writer asked a business friend for his definition of a clearing house. He said that he understood it to be a place where associated banks exchanged checks drawn against each other and paid or collected the balances in money. That is about what any man, not in the banking business, would say. As a general defi- nition it is very good. Yet there are some func- tions which the clearing house assumes and some points of interest in its mechanism which may be suggested with profit. Indeed, the most important features of the clearing house are not suggested at all in the average business man's rule. A very simple and sufficient definition for the clearing house in its primary functions is "an association of banks and bankers in some partic- ular locality, organized for the mutual exchange of checks, drafts, and other instruments which may be agreed upon. Settlement for the differ- ence between the aggregate of items delivered and the aggregate of items received is usually paid and received in cash or in some form of certif- icate which the banks accept among themselves as cash." In many cities and towns the clearing house has not accomplished more than such simple functions. But in New York and Chicago, and 162 PRACTICAL BANKING in many smaller cities, its scope has widened until it has become an active means of general cooperation among the banks composing it. Mr. James G. Cannon, in his article on the clearing house, says: ^ But we must go further than this; for, though origi- nally designed as a labor-saving device, the clearing house has expanded far beyond those limits, until it has become a medium for united action among the banks that did not exist even in the imagination of those who were instrumental in its inception. A clear- ing house, therefore, may be defined as a device to simplify and facilitate the daily exchanges of items and settlements of balances among banks, and a medium for united action upon all questions affecting their mutual welfare. . . . The tendency has been marked, especially in recent years, to include within the legiti- mate field of clearing houses all questions affecting the mutual welfare of the banks and the community as a whole. The bankers west of the Mississippi have given to the country the most striking examples of the possibilities of clearing houses exercising various spe- cial functions, while the great associations of the East, and especially that of New York, have exemplified the utility and value of the clearing-house loan certificate. As has been intimated, the clearing houses may be divided, in regard to the mode of settlement for balances, into two types: first, those whose members make settlement in cash or some sub- stitute for cash, agreed upon by them; and sec- ond, those whose members may settle their bal- ances with checks on large banking centers. And it should be noted that there are two classes of * Columbia University Lectures on the Currency Problem, 1908. THE CLEARING HOUSE 163 clearing houses in respect to the functions which they perform; namely, those which simply offer a means of exchanging items, and those which, in addition, have the control of certain matters pertaining to the common welfare of all. New York has the most perfectly developed clearing house in the country, showing every phase of progress in that direction.^ In this sketch we shall deal specifically with it, contenting our- selves with a casual remark on other associations. The New York clearing room is a large square chamber in a beautiful white stone building oc- cupied jointly by the Clearing House and the Chase National Bank. Across one side and ele- vated some fifteen feet is the manager's gallery, where he supervises the making of exchanges. Four long lines of standing desks run up to this end of the chamber. Between each two lines there are a screen and coat rack. The exchanges are made at ten o'clock in the morning of each business day. A few minutes before the hour the messengers from the several banks begin arriving. Each member sends a de- livery messenger who brings the items against the other banks, and a settling clerk, with frequently an assistant, who receives the exchanges from the other banks and remains till a proof is made of the clearing. When he arrives at the Clearing House, every settling clerk furnishes the proof clerk in the gal- lery with a ticket showing the amount brought to the clearing. This is entered on the clearing bal- 1 If we except clearing house foreign departments, which are dis- cussed later in this chapter. 164 PRACTICAL BANKING ance sheet as a credit to the bank. This column for credits, together with one for credit balances, constitutes one side of the balance. The delivery clerks come in with huge boxes and bags filled with their bank's items against its fellow members. The items on each bank are done up in a separate package, upon the outside of which there is a list showing the amount con- tained. At 9.59 the manager, having shortly before entered the gallery, strikes a bell as a signal for the messengers to be in readiness to clear. Every settling clerk takes his desk, with an assistant usually at his side, and each delivery messenger stations himself, box of items in hand, in front of his settling clerk's desk. At precisely ten o'clock a second bell is struck and the delivery messen- gers start moving in a steady line, beginning with the desk next to their own, where they leave the proper package, receive the initial of the settling clerk on their clearing slip, and deposit a ticket in the desk showing the amount of the package delivered. Thus, in regular rotation, they move around the room and, in seven or eight minutes, arrive again at their starting-points. They now take over the items received by their settling clerks, pack them away in their bags, and depart for their respective banks. As soon as all deliveries are made, the settling clerks check back their debit slips — the slips on which they have recorded the amounts of checks delivered to them — with the tickets deposited by the several delivery messengers. Now, they foot up their debit slips and transfer the totals of THE CLEARING HOUSE 165 the items delivered and received to another ticket, finding the balance, which they mark "debit" or "credit" as the case may be. These tickets are passed up to the proof clerk in the gallery, who enters the total debit on the left side of his proof-sheet by the bank's name, and the debit or credit balance on the appropriate side of his sheet. Next he proceeds to add, in order to see that the debit side exactly offsets the credit. In a few minutes he is ready to announce whether a balance has been reached or not. If it has, the clerks are at liberty to leave. Otherwise, they must remain till the error is discovered. In case of misbalance, the settling clerk may have copied down the wrong total from some package as it was delivered to him. In this event he probably locates it in rechecking his work with the slips left in his desk by the several delivery clerks. On the other hand, the proof clerk may have erred in transcribing to his book the amounts from the tickets handed him. He rechecks and can readily tell whether the error has been com- mitted by him. It is possible, of course, to make purely mathematical errors in adding up the dif- ferent sheets. This ought to happen rarely, and ought to be easily found, though the writer re- calls an instance where it was otherwise. One of the settling clerks in a smaller clearing house invariably made an error in footing up his debit sheet. The singular part of it was that he was rarely able to find the error himself, and, after hastily going over his figures, would sit back com- placently and wait for one of the other clerks to locate it. After a few minutes of consternation 166 PRACTICAL BANKING and surprise, one of the clerks would suggest that some one go over this fellow's figures. In a mo- ment or two the difference would be found. As there was a fine attached for errors, the bank send- ing this man soon discovered that it was conven- ient to replace him. In cities where every minute is valuable to banks, especially about the clearing hour, it is imperative that clerks arrive at the clearing house promptly. Most cities impose a fine for tardiness. New York sets this fine at two dollars. It is obviously improbable that any bank's credits will offset exactly its debits. In the New York Clearing House's history it has not hap- pened once, though at one time an exact balance was only missed by ten cents. Every bank carries back items in aggregate amount more or less than it brings; that is, it has a debit or credit balance after the exchange of items. Of course, the total debits of the Clearing House will just equal the total credit balances. By 1.30 p.m. each debtor bank has paid to the Clearing House the amount of its debit balance, and has received a receipt for the same from an appropriate officer. Then the creditor banks receive payment for the amount of their credit balances. But no money is paid to creditor members until every debit bal- ance has been paid in. This is a precautionary measure. For suppose that all save one bank had paid in their debits, and all of this had been paid to creditor banks as they came. It is obvious that some bank or banks would not have received their credits. Now, sup- pose the delinquent bank should suddenly dis- THE CLEARING HOUSE 167 cover its inability to pay its debit. All save one or two members received their balances all right. Those one or two, however, must stand to lose their credits entirely, since it would be hard to find any of the others so philanthropic as to de- sire to divide their credits with them. Under New York's system no such occurrence could take place. In some cities where the clearing houses are smaller and where the proximity of the banks makes it practicable, the clearing-house manager writes checks in favor of creditor banks for their exact balances and drawn against debtor banks in just the amount necessary to cover their bal- ances. These checks are subsequently collected in cash or sent through the clearing on the fol- lowing day. This plan necessitates the "splitting- up" of debits and credits which would, in a large city like New York or Chicago, cause much in- convenience in the collection. This plan has the same disadvantages that the New York plan would have if any creditor was paid before all debtors had settled. But it permits a cheaper means of conducting the clearing-house exchanges. In New York the following are recognized as media for paying and receiving clearing balances : except for fractional amounts — legal tender notes, gold. United States or Clearing House gold certificates, or (in times of financial strin- gency) Clearing House loan certificates. Now, what has happened? Fifty banks from many parts of the city have gathered in the clear- ing room with packages containing items against each other. They have made the exchanges, each 168 PRACTICAL BANKING taking what it is listed with and leaving what it has listed against the others. Hundreds of mil- lions of dollars of credit have been exchanged and only about five per cent — in fact only the balances — have been transferred in cash. The Clearing House's operation saves much time and expense. It provides for the deliberate verifica- tion of the checks as to signatures, dates, amounts, and indorsements. All checks which a bank de- cides not to pay, either for lack of funds, because of payment ordered stopped, or because of in- formality of signature, are returned by messen- ger to the bank which sent them. All checks not accepted purely for lack of indorsement are certi- fied and returned through the clearing the next day to the bank by which presented. When they are properly indorsed, they may again be sent through the clearing and in due order paid. The New York Clearing House is in its sixty- first year. It is composed of thirty-two national banks, eighteen state banks, and the Assistant Treasurer at New York. Besides these there are thirty-odd banks and trust companies which make their exchanges through members of the association. When the organization began its operations in 1853 it had just fifty members. This number has fluctuated, falling as low as forty-six and reaching as high as sixty-seven. All members of the association must keep a reserve of twenty- five per cent.^ The association's officers are a president, a secretary, a manager, and an assistant mana- ^ This provision has been revised in accordance with the Fed> eral Reserve Act. THE CLEARING HOUSE 169 ger. The following are the standing committees : the Clearing-House Committee, the Conference Committee, the Nominating Committee, the Committee on Admissions, and the Arbitration Committee. For the year 1909 the average daily transac- tions were $340,303,113.28, of which $326,505,- 468.45 was in exchanges and $13,797,644.83 in balances. In the first full year of its organiza- tion (1854) the average daily transactions were $20,092,583.00, of which $19,104,504.94 was ex- changes and $988,078.06 balances. The largest day on record was January 3, 1906, when the total transactions amounted to $712,- 467,035.83. The largest balances (paid in cash, of course) were on October 3, 1905, when they came to $42,331,709.02. The total transactions since the Clearing House's inception are (to 1909) $2,123,395,038,959.60. The total balances paid into the Clearing House during the year 1909 were $4,194,484,028.37. They were made as fol- lows : — United States bearer gold certificates $1,292,304,000.00 United States order gold certificates 555,140,000.00 Clearing House gold certificates 1,831,410,000.00 Clearing House note depository certifi- cates for — legal tenders 8,595,000.00 gold certificates 11,145,000.00 silver certificates 11,210,000.00 United States legal tenders and change . . 184,080,028.37 $4,194,484,028.37 ' From Mr. William Shcrer's Report for 1909. Mr. Sherer i.s the third incumbent in the office of manager of the New York Clearing 170 PRACTICAL BANKING II We may now proceed to discuss the more spe- cial functions of the clearing house. It may be said to have the following special facilities in its most highly developed form : — (1) Making loans to the Government in time of need. (2) Fixing uniform exchange and collection House, and has honorably discharged his duties since 1892. The writer remembers most pleasantly two days spent in the Clearing House under the kind courtesies of Mr. Sherer. Attention must here be called to a scheme in operation in Boston whereby checks received by clearing-house members on some six himdred banks throughout New England are handled by clearing- house facilities. The results of this plan have been highly successful since its establishment in 1900, the yearly totals averaging about $575,000,000. The cost of collecting "foreign" checks in this way has been approximately seven cents per one thousand dollars. At- lanta, Georgia, and Kansas City, Missouri, also conduct a "foreign department" in their clearing houses. The best account of the scope and possibilities of clearing houses, an economic expedient as well as an institution of local convenience, is to be found in the volume. Clearing Houses, by Mr. James G. Cannon, vice-president of the Fourth National Bank, New York. It is published in the National Monetary Commission Series. The volume is clear and complete; it is abundant in specific illustrations taken from clearing houses in every part of the country. Mr. Cannon realizes that it is, strictly speaking, impossible to generalize very satisfactorily on the subject, because clearing houses have grown up spontaneously in various cities and often without reference to any particular model. At the same time it is important to note that there is a growing "class consciousness" among clearing houses; that is, they are beginning to realize the existence of a sort of affinity between themselves. They are studying each other's methods and imitating good qualities. The result is the awakening of a spirit of cooperation between clearing houses. This is cleverly outlined and new functions consequently suggested in chapter iv of Clearing Houses, cited above. Mr. Cannon's own lucid expositions of the duties and privileges of clearing-house associations and his very large collection of exact data for comparison have contributed con- spicuously to the development of "clearing-house consciousness." THE CLEARING HOUSE 171 charges ; also regulating the rate of interest which its members may pay on deposits. (3) Mutual assistance of its members. (4) Issue of clearing-house loan certificates. (5) Issue of certificates in form of checks on its members for general circulation. (1) During the Civil War, the clearing houses of the great Eastern cities came to the assistance of the embarrassed Government and helped finance the struggle for the preservation of the Union. It is even possible that the war might have been a failure but for the support of these associations. It is not the purpose of this para- graph to inquire as to whether patriotic or eco- nomic motives, or both, moved the clearing houses to this action, but only to point out the wide potentialities of such associations to the Government in a time of public financial embar- rassment. (2) In many cities prescribing the rate of ex- change charged for handling out-of-town checks has seemed to come within the province of the clearing house. In these places it has proved a source of protection for the members, though it is argued that it keeps a certain amount of busi- ness from such cities. Some clearing houses also regulate rates charged on collections. New York has such an arrangement. Her rates vary from par to one tenth and one fourth per cent on items drawn on the United States or Canada. The penalty for violation of this ruling is a fine of five thousand dollars for the first ofi'ense and possible expulsion from the clearing house for second offense. As to fixing the rate of interest 172 PRACTICAL BANKING payable on deposits, clearing houses have not been so successful as might be expected. Some associations, usually in the smaller cities, have been able to regulate this, with the result that it has been highly satisfactory to all concerned. The difficulty has not been altogether the lack of sup- port of clearing-house members, but the fact that banks outside the association have waged un- relenting warfare on the members by offering higher rates than have been agreed upon in the clearing house. ^ (3) In times of financial anxiety and unrest it often happens that a perfectly solvent bank is temporarily embarrassed. It may be because of some malicious or careless rumor; it may be be- cause of the sudden calling-in of a large block of loans to cover some unlooked-for demand which excites the suspicion of the over-wary. But, be the cause what it may, the depositors are panic- stricken and stampede the bank to withdraw their funds. If the run is uninterrupted by a reestab- lishment of the customers' confidence, the bank may speedily find itself in an exceedingly embar- rassed position, unable to extend any loans, un- able to redeem checks against accounts on its own books. This may not reflect on the bank, since it is impossible to think of carrying an amount of cash anywhere near equaling the deposit liabili- ties of the bank. The banker could not afford to lock up his total deposits in his vaults, even if he were able to turn all the resources representing deposits into cash, which, in a system based as much on credit as ours, is impracticable. He has ^ See James G. Cannon, Clearing Houses, p. 14. THE CLEARING HOUSE 173 to calculate as accurately as possible the probable demand for cash and invest the remainder as safely and profitably as he can. To be sure, he should very much limit the long-time paper, and should arrange to have a constant stream of re- payments flowing into the bank. But in case of an unforeseen run, the bank's assets cannot al- ways be converted quickly enough to supply the demands made upon it. Yet, when it is in good standing, its clearing-house associates are usually willing to assist it over the rough place. This ac- tion is not without its selfish side, for the "easing- up" of the panicky fever among depositors can- not but have a desirable effect upon all the banks. But if the aflflicted institution is in bad manage- ment and is a drag to the association, the clear- ing house is likely to let it go, glad to be rid of a weak member. (4) What is probably the most important spe- cial function of the clearing house is the issue of clearing-house loan certificates. These may be defined as secured loans made by associate mem- bers to other members, by means of which they may pay their clearing balances. Fifty years and more ago. New York bankers devised the scheme of issuing clearing-house loan certificates, and they have served long and faithfully. Since 1860 no less than nine times has the New York Clear- ing House come to the rescue of the banking in- terests of New York City with the loan certifi- cate.^ During these nine times not a single dollar has been lost in this manner. The community has ' There have been approximately $270,000,000 of clearing-house loan certificates issued in New York. 174 PRACTICAL BANKING come to look to these certificates as a source of relief. Since the adoption of this plan in New York, many clearing houses throughout the country have taken it up. By means of these certificates members pay their balances at the clearing house, and so retain cash for demands at the bank. During times of financial disturbance, the New York Clearing-House Association appoints five bank officers from its members who, with the president of the association, form the loan com- mittee. It is the particular duty of this committee to meet each morning and consider the collateral offered by members for loan certificates. These certificates have been issued in amounts varying from fifty to one hundred dollars on one hun- dred dollars' worth of collateral. The certificates have ranged in denomination from one hundred thousand dollars to twenty-five cents. In 1907 the Association realized that the bank- ing interests of the city demanded a larger com- mittee, and accordingly an associate loan com- mittee of five was authorized and appointed to assist the general loan committee. On the loan committee of the New York Clearing House have served some of the country's most brilliant and versatile bankers. Now the issuance of loan certificates through the clearing house is purely a self-preservative measure. Moreover, it is intended to be tem- porary. Thus, it is customary to issue the certifi- cates payable with six per cent interest per annum. The interest is payable by the bank using the certificate and is receivable by the member which THE CLEARING HOUSE 175 accepts it in lieu of cash. The idea is to fix the rate of interest high so that it will be undesir- able to have certificates outstanding after the strain is over. In actual practice they are very promptly retired. When a bank desires to take up any or all of its outstanding certificates, it notifies the loan committee, which fixes a day on which interest shall cease on the certificates and serves notice to that effect on the bank or banks holding them. In due time, they are sent through the clearing for redemption. When the certificates have been retired, the banks issuing them can present them to the loan committee and obtain the collateral securing them. Thus, the loan certificates, while not used and paid out of the bank as cash, have the effect of taking its place among clearing-house members. Actual money is left for the necessary demands on the bank. (5) During the panic of 1907-08, many clear- ing-house associations throughout the country authorized their members to issue certificates in the form of checks payable to bearer, drawn against the bank putting them into circulation. These were equivalent to cashiers' checks, and for a time were used in place of much regular currency. Most were guaranteed by bonds and other securities deposited with the clearing house. Others were unsecured. It was surprising to find how they circulated throughout the country. It was nothing unusual to have certificates presented for payment issued by banks far distant. They were accepted on the same basis as other cashiers' checks, and were handled either as clearing items 176 PRACTICAL BANKING — if they were on local banks — or through the transit department, if they were on out-of-town banks. ^ In conclusion, it may be of interest to observe a few figures on the transactions of clearing houses throughout the country and their relation to population. The first matter which will appeal to the eye is that the population per bank has dechned almost fifty per cent between 1880 and 1909; this will emphasize the rapid growth of banking since that time, particularly when it is remembered that the population in the same 1 This practice was originated in Atlanta, Georgia, in 1893. As Mr. Cannon points out, it was perfected in the same year in Birm- ingham, Alabama. The writer, who was a resident of the latter city in 1907-08 and paying teller in one of the city's banks, well remem- bers how it worked out. Certificates as small as twenty-five cents, payable to bearer, were issued and used, not only to pay off clearing debits, but to honor checks over the counter. At one time the clear- ing house limited its members to the payment of twenty-five dollars in cash weekly to each customer, except, as I remember, in the case of certain pay-rolls. The issuance and circulation of these notes were successful in the extreme. The writer, however, feels that much was due to the loyal support of merchants of the city, many of whom offered five and ten per cent premium on this "scrip" used in pay- ment of merchandise. The question is raised, no doubt, as to how these certificates escaped the federal tax of ten per cent on all currency issued other- wise than as authorized by the national banking laws. Certainly they were used as emergency currency and served every local need for money. Assuredly the practice was radical in so far as it not only rendered mutual assistance between banks, but actually increased the available cash for general purposes many millions of dollars. To tell the truth, the writer suspects that the Treasury Department was willing to make a rather liberal construction of the usage of clearing- house certificates as circulating notes in view of the general financial disturbance of the whole country. The notes seemed "safe" inas- much as from thirty-three and one third to one hundred per cent collateral additional to the face value of the notes were required. Furthermore, they could easily be regarded as cashiers' checks secured by a special deposit of collateral with trustees. THE CLEARING HOUSE 177 period has increased from about fifty millions to about eighty-nine millions. During the same time clearings reported from twenty-four cities with $50,000,000,000 cleared have soared to $165,000,000,000 from one hundred and twelve cities, an increase of two hundred and ten per cent, while the population has increased nearly ninety per cent. It will be interesting to know that New York City has maintained almost the same relation to the total clearing, although the number of cities reporting has increased about three hundred sixty-six per cent. In 1880 New York's clearings were seventy-six per cent of the total, and in 1909 they were sixty-two per cent of the total. 1880 1890 1900 1909 Total number of banks of all kinds 6,532 8,201 10,378 22,459 Number of inhabit- ants to each bank. . 7,678 7,635 7,337 3,934 Number of cities re- porting clearing Amount cleared in the 24 56 87 112 year $50,766,000 $60,623,000 $86,205,000 $165,608,000 » ^ Figures compiled from the volume, Statistics for the United States, JS67-1909, by A. Piatt Andrew, in the National Monetary Commission Series. CHAPTER XVIII FOREIGN EXCHANGE Foreign exchange is that branch of banking, created by and built up through the commercial and financial intercourse of nations. Every year we export manufactured articles, produce, and raw material from this country in scarcely cal- culable amounts. Every year we import measure- less quantities of every product of nature's bounty and man's ingenuity. Our citizens scour the face of the earth and even penetrate its bowels or seek the space above the earth in search of art, recreation, and learning. All these things require vast outlays of credit. The consequence is that for our expenditures we owe creditors across the water, and for their purchases they owe us. The foreign exchange is the medium of settling these international debts. ^ A bill of exchange is a draft against a credit abroad, payable on demand or on a specified date.^ ' * There are, to be sure, bills to create credit, but more of them anon. * Note the lucidity of Mr. Franklin Escher's description of the ultimate basis of foreign exchange: "Not all international obliga- tions are settled by having the creditor draw direct on the debtor. Sometimes, gold is actually sent in payment. Sometimes, the debtor goes to a bank engaged in selling drafts on the city where the obli- gation exists, gets such a draft from him. and sends it. But in a vast majority of cases payment is effected as stated — by a draft drawn FOREIGN EXCHANGE 179 By far the greater part of our exports are to Europe and the greater part of our imports thence or, at least, through bankers there. There- fore, for the purposes of this article, we shall chiefly content ourselves with a discussion of America's dealings with Europe. Now, when we say that New York draws many finance bills, or that Paris bills are a drug on the London market, it must not be imagined that New York, Paris, and London are each a solidly organized market of traders, each threatening the other and trying to outwit him. Quite the reverse is true. These markets are composed of bankers and brokers each competing sharply with his fellow and frequently cutting his next neighbor, though he thereby accommodate a foreign correspondent. So let us not think of New York or London as a compact combination of bankers, but as an aggregation of individuals trying to outdo each other. The rate of dis- count on bills is said to be regulated by the supply and demand of foreign bills of exchange, but there is no general exchange at which rep- resentatives of bankers meet to fix the price. Brokers go from bank to bank getting the prices both on selhng bills to them and buying bills from them. There is, however, no lack of coopera- tion between correspondents in different markets. directly on the buyer of the goods. John Smith in London owes me money. I draw on him for £lOO, take the draft around to my bank, sell it at, say, 4.8G, getting for it a check for $i80. I have my money and I am out of the transaction. . . . The buying and selling and discounting of countless such bills of exchange constitute the very foundation of the foreign exchange business." — Foreign Exchange, pp. 3, 4. 180 PRACTICAL BANKING If Americans have a large amount of credit in Europe, bills of exchange — that is, drafts against these credits — are comparatively cheap; whereas, if our credit abroad does not bear a generous ratio with the demand here for bills against Eu- rope, the price naturally rises. Tabulating, we find that the items working toward an accumula- tion of credit in our favor abroad are, in chief, as follows : — (1) Exportation of cotton, wheat and other commodities, and manufactured goods. (2) The purchase by foreigners of American securities, for the payment of which bills are drawn by American brokers. (3) The payment of interest or dividends on foreign securities, held by American in- vestors. (4) Loans, made to Americans abroad for which bills are drawn. (5) Expenditures of foreign tourists in the United States who draw for funds on home concerns. On the other hand, those items operating against America and tending to raise the price of exchange here are : — (1) Immense importation to the United States, for which Americans must remit in ex- change. (2) The liquidation of foreign loans to America which mature abroad. (3) The enormous sum spent by American tourists and residents in Europe. (4) The purchase by Americans of securities in European markets. FOREIGN EXCHANGE 181 (5) The interest and dividends payable on American securities held by foreigners. Generally speaking, foreign exchange is the means by which individuals or firms on this side pay then* foreign creditors and collect from their foreign debtors. This applies in a similar sense to London, Paris, Berlin, and Amsterdam. If, as is sometimes the case, the supply of foreign bills of exchange is too low for the demands, or if it fails altogether, we pay our foreign debts by exporting gold. If, on the other hand, the de- mand for exchange is small and there is a large amount for sale, we collect our credits abroad by importing gold. It is obvious, therefore, that the highest point to which the price for foreign bills of exchange can, under normal conditions, reach, is the gold export price — that is, the point at which it is as cheap to ship gold to pay one's obligations as it is to buy bills. This is true, for a further advance would simply mean that gold would be shipped to pay debts. On the other hand, the limit to which the market can, under normal conditions, decline is naturally the cost of importing gold. For, with little demand and a large accumulation of exchange credits abroad, the prices fall, but when they reach the point where the loss on sell- ing exchange is just the cost of importation of gold, why, of course, the fall is arrested, for a lower decline would simply mean the importa- tion of gold. Sometimes, however, gold is im- ported when the price is above the import point; ordinarily, this is done when, as in time of strin- gency, there is a more profitable field here for 182 PRACTICAL BANKING gold than for exchange. This was done in 1907, when there was a considerable premium on cur- rency. In his paper on "Foreign Exchange,^ Mr. Albert Strauss thus lucidly describes the exporta- tion and importation of gold : — The pure gold contained in one English sovereign is equivalent exactly to $4.8665 of our gold coins; so that, apart from charges and expenses, $4.8665 of our gold will, when sent abroad, produce a credit of one pound sterling; to this cost must be added freight, in- surance, and other expenses, amounting to about one fourth of one per cent. This brings the cost of one pound through shipment to about $4.88, which is, roughly, the gold-export point for full-weight coin. . . . The British sovereign, if full weight, will when sent here and melted down yield gold for which the United States Assay Office will pay $4.8665; the expense of sending the sovereign, freight, insurance, cartage, and kegs will amount to about one quarter of one per cent, so that the net yield of the full-weight sovereign in dollars will be $4.85f . But between the day on which the banker buys the bill of exchange in New York and the day on which he receives in New York the gold which the bill entitled him to collect in London, there must elapse the time necessary to send the bill to London, plus the time needed to send the gold back, — roughly, fifteen days, — during which time the banker loses the use of the money. This loss of interest must be deducted from the net yield of the imported sovereign, and thus, if money is worth six per cent per annum, the net yield of full-weight sovereigns is brought down to about $4.84j, which is the gold-im- port point for demand exchange when money is worth * Columbia University Lectures, Currency Problem, 1908. FOREIGN EXCHANGE 183 six per cent per annum. Losses by abrasion will bring down this point by perhaps one tenth per cent, to about $4.83f. When money is higher the import point will be lower, and vice versa. There is, therefore, a margin of profit in buying demand bills and im- porting gold sovereigns against the purchase whenever the rate for demand bills falls below the gold-import point. But extraordinary decline in the quotation of foreign bills is speedily stopped, for there is a rush by bankers to buy bills in order to import gold, and this quickly restores the rate to normal. Since London is similarly situated regarding the exportation and importation of gold, there is always an accumulation of foreign gold coins in the vaults of the Bank of England, of which no inconsiderable part consists of United States coin. As Mr. Strauss further points out, these are to be obtained, usually, at a somewhat better price than sovereigns, for it saves the cost of coining just so many pieces. Sometimes one can also get bullion at a favorable rate.^ The buyer has some advantage in taking used United States coin, for he buys them in England by weight and sells them in this country at their face value, unless they be under weight. Thus he gains the ad- vantage of the abrasion. It is curious to see the way gold is shipped from London to America. The British, for instance, put them up in bags whose contents weigh five hundred ounces. The bags will frequently contain foreign gold coin of various kinds, and if the coin do not weigh up ' But any one holding Bank of England notes will get sovereigns unless he makes special arrangements. 184 PRACTICAL BANKING exactly, they throw in some chopped-off frag- ments of coins until the exact weight is reached. When an American banker or broker exports gold, he is liable to lose about one tenth per cent by abrasion if he uses ordinary United States coins, since he can receive value in England only by their weight. But by the payment of a much smaller fee than the loss by abrasion would come to, he is usually enabled to get gold bars from the United States Assay Office, buying them by weight. He naturally prefers this method; the office is willing, since the reduction of the coun- try's circulation would necessitate the coining of more gold at an added expense. In many respects European money markets are superior to ours. For instance, England is what is called an open discount market. English banks buy bankers' or first-class merchants' ac- ceptances and hold them till maturity or, if cash be desired, rediscount them in the open market. There are many houses in London which make a specialty of these rediscounts. Rediscounting has rarely been done in America even in case of first-class commercial paper. But with the ad- vent of the federal reserve system, an almost completely open discount market will be erected.^ Another form of income-earning transaction quite unknown to American banking is the ac- cepting of long drafts, for which a commission is charged. This is common in Europe. The com- mission is, of course, based on the security of the draft, both as regards documents attached and the responsibility of the client for whom it is done. ^ See chapter xx for the provisions of the new system. FOREIGN EXCHANGE 185 In Germany, the Reichsbank has established a system called the "Giro Conto," by which money is forwarded free of exchange for cus- tomers to any places where the Reichsbank has a branch. Since the Reichsbank has branches in every important city in Germany, it is of great value to merchants, most of whom carry ac- counts with the Reichsbank, although no interest is allowed on balances. Two other conveniences of European banking are "Del Credere" and "Bank Post Remit- tances." By "Del Credere" is meant the cus- tom which European bankers have of insuring the pajTiient of time bills at maturity. Rates for doing this vary from one fortieth per cent to one and one half per cent, according to the responsibil- ity of the drawee or according to the time for which the bills live.^ We have nothing equivalent to it in this country. A bank in the United States may accept a cer- tain amount of money from a person to be re- mitted to some one at his particular address in Europe. This brings us to the "Post Remit- tances" of the Continent. The American bank simply sends to its foreign correspondent in the country concerned the name of the person to whom the money is to be remitted, with his exact address. Upon this authorization the European banks turns over the money to the Government, which delivers it to the remittee through the mail service, exacting a small fee for guaranteeing de- livery. This transaction is called the "Bank Post Remittance." ^ See Anthony W. Margraff, International Exchange, p. 190. 186 PRACTICAL BANKING II The foreign department of a bank is in reality a complete bank in itself, having its own tellers, bookkeepers, and officers. Not only in New York, the great financial center of the nation control- ling the foreign transactions in this country, are there banks having foreign departments, but far and wide over the United States large banks have established and are establishing foreign depart- ments with direct relations with the Old World. Why, then, do banks have foreign depart- ments? The reasons have been well tabulated by one writer ^ and in terse form they are : — (1) The foreign department opens means for the general clientele of the bank to transact all their business in the bank. This avoids the possibility of losing good accounts be- cause of the superior facilities offered by a rival bank. (2) It serves as a good advertisement for the bank. (3) It affords the bank oppK)rtunities for plac- ing loans at good rates in Europe's money market by purchases of foreign bills of ex- change for investment, by the purchase of finance bills or bankers' long bills, as they are called. (4) It places a bank in position to subscribe to Euroi>ean national loans, since foreign correspondents usually invite their Ameri- can friends to help underwrite these loans. The foreign exchange transactions are actually * Anthony W. Margraff, International Exchange. FOREIGN EXCHANGE 187 carried on by the drawing and accepting, the buy- ing and selling of bills of exchange. Bills of ex- change are simple drafts against credits abroad, or for the creation of credits abroad. The most common of the forms are the cable transfer, the demand bill, and the long bill. These bills are commonly payable in the currency of the coun- try on which they are drawn. All bills are drawn in duplicate and distinctly marked ''original" and "duplicate," or "first" and "second," of ex- change. Ill As we begin the discussion of bills of exchange, let us bear in mind that the exchange market does not consist alone in liquidating debts con- tracted or in collecting credits accumulated abroad in the ordinary conduct of business. These commercial transactions, however, are the ulti- mate cause of the market. With keen eyes scanning the financial horizon, exchange bankers speculate, buying bills on a city with a large supply and little demand here, and authorizing their agents in other foreign cities, where there is little supply but great de- mand for this particular exchange, to draw against their credit. Competition is sharp among the astute, open- eyed bankers who deal in foreign exchange. This, of course, tends to reduce the percentage of profit on exchange transactions. It is not uncommon to hear of bankers making a purchase on which a profit of only 1-128 per cent can be made. The exchange rates fluctuate constantly. Bankers buy 188 PRACTICAL BANKING at what they consider a good price, and sell their own checks against the credit, established by re- mitting the purchased bill, hoping to obtain a slightly better price than they paid. Since bills are drawn against credits abroad, let us see who, in the ordinary course of events, have them for sale. First, must be mentioned the cotton planter of the South and the wheat-raiser of the West. We undoubtedly export more cot- ton and wheat than anything else. We also export all sorts of manufactured articles and raw goods. So the exporter draws a bill against his purchaser across the sea and offers it for sale. Then finance bills create credits abroad, against which bills may be drawn; these will be discussed a little later. Next, brokers who buy American securi- ties for foreigners make drafts on their clients for the cost of the securities together with their commissions. In this case the securities are in- variably attached to the bill. This class of bill is commonly offered for sale. The demands come from importers of foreign commodities and manufactured goods; from cor- porations remitting interest on American securi- ties held abroad; from bankers who sell cable transfers and other forms of exchange; and from American tourists. As has been already said, the exchange banker scans the world's market closely and seeks to find where the prices are cheap and where the demand is great. By cablegram he is kept in- formed at all hours of the day regarding the foreign market's want and supplies. Now, if he finds in New York a large demand for Amsterdam FOREIGN EXCHANGE 189 bills with but little supply in sight and a large supply of Berlin bills with little demand, he will buy Berlin bills, send them to Amsterdam for credit, and draw his bills against Amsterdam.^ Theoretically, this should work out beautifully with considerable profit, but the market is com- posed of a vast crowd of eager bankers and brok- ers, and the price for Berlin is not likely to fall to the import point, nor does the Amsterdam price soar up to the point of exportation. The very buy- ing and selling prevents either alternative. IV Gold always takes the shortest path to its final destination when it is sent in settlement of dif- ferences. Of course, this is no peculiar virtue of the metal, but is caused by the exchange bankers, who cut every corner and take advantage of every infinitesimal profit. This, however, needs a concrete illustration. Suppose that some year we export a huge crop of cotton to England, but do not buy in return. On the other hand, suppose we buy wines and manufactured goods from France, but do not sell them much. A lumbering process of settlement would be to import gold from London and then export it back to Paris. As a matter of fact, the gold is shipped directly to Paris from London. This is an example on a large scale of what is ac- tually happening in a smaller way perhaps many times a year. It need not be a great crop of cotton which we export or wines which we import; the phenomenon, indeed, may not be caused by ex- ^ This transaction is known as "arbitraging in exchange." 190 PRACTICAL BANKING ports or imports at all, but by the accumulation of debt in one city, caused by finance bills matur- ing, and the credit in another, due to the proceeds of some discounted paper. From this we arrive at a curious but economi- cal scheme, arising not from international charity but from international desire to secure every jot and tittle of profit. Mr. Strauss speaks of " the exchange market as an economical mechanism, automatically making delicate international ad- justments." London is a free gold market, and, to judge from the past, is the only reliable one. Berlin is nominally a free gold market, although it some- times has difficulty in paying in gold. Paris is not a gold market, although it usually remits in gold. However, it reserves the right to charge a prem- ium for gold. New York is also nominally a free gold market and was considered reliable until the panic of 1907 when it proved that the reverse was true. London owes much of her prominence in finance to her free gold market, and New York cannot hope to exert a controlling influence upon the world of finance until it becomes a free gold market, absolutely and reliably. V Demand bills are those payable at presenta- tion. There is nothing complicated about them, so we turn to a discussion of long bills, which offer opportunity for careful study. A long bill is " international credit." If this credit fails, as in panics, resort must be had to FOREIGN EXCHANGE 191 the unwieldy method of paying and collecting by the shipment of gold. We have all read of the slow, irksome process of separating the cotton fiber from the seed in the days before the inven- tion of the gin. It is said that an expert planta- tion hand could separate no more than a few pounds in a day. The modern gin seizes upon the cotton as it is brought from the field and in a short time separates many hundred pounds of seed and fiber. The movement of gold to pay and collect balances is as awkward as the old hand-method of separating cotton. In general, there are two kinds of long bills, namely: Bankers' long bills or finance bills, and commercial long bills. Bankers' long bills, or finance bills as they are frequently called, are simply drafts from an American bank on a foreign correspondent, pay- able usually at sixty or ninety days' sight. Most of this class of bills are drawn on England, and are accompanied in many cases by stocks or bonds listed on the New York Stock Exchange. Such collateral or any at all, however, is a matter of negotiation and it usually happens that, if the drawer is a house of excellent and world-wide reputation, no collateral whatever is required. This class of international loan provides an excel- lent means of leveling world money rates. Bankers make use of them to take advantage of the dif- ference in interest rates between that in their city and that in some foreign city. Suppose that on a certain day, the interest rate in New York is five per cent, while that in London is only three per cent. After paying the 192 PRACTICAL BANKING necessary expenses on a finance bill, such as a bill stamp and commission to the London house for accepting the bill, the New York banker has an opportunity to make his money in two ways, as follows: First, by the investment of the pro- ceeds at a higher rate than he paid, which we assume in this case; second, by buying a demand bill on London at the maturity of his paper at a lower rate than he sold his long bill for. These may conversely prove sources of loss. Say, the New York banker draws a ninety-day bill on his London correspondent for $100,000. Let us figure how much he would probably make on it under ideal conditions. London bankers charge varying commissions for accepting these bills. In this case, say, the commission is one eighth per cent for ninety days. The English bill stamp is one twentieth per cent, and the annual discount rate, as we have assumed, is three per cent. Resolving all these to rates per annum, we have — Commission 5 per cent English bill stamp ^ English discount rate on bill 3 3^ — which is the cost of the bill. Now, if the proceeds can be invested at five per cent, there is a net profit of one and three tenths per cent per annum on the transaction. This, of course, neglects the loss of interest on the discount, which is not, however, consider- able. On $100,000 for ninety days, this net profit would be roughly $325. This assumes that he bought a demand bill to pay his maturing bill at FOREIGN EXCHANGE 193 the same rate at which he sold his finance bill. If he buys a bill to pay his obligation at a lower rate, he makes more profit; if he has to pay a higher price for his demand bill, he makes less, or even loses. Sometimes bankers guard against the possibility of loss in this fashion by arranging in advance for the delivery of demand bills to them just before their long bills mature abroad. The exchange banker is frequently content to make a little outside of the profit on exchange when he can sell his bill at a very high price. He has little doubt that he can buy to meet his obli- gation at a much lower rate, since there is a limit, at least theoretically speaking, to its rise, and since it is likely to fall because of the resultant eagerness to supply the demand. It is a curious fact that when the market is short and there are few bills in sight, the rising price brings out an ever-increasing supply. Mr. George Clare, in his book on Foreign Exchange, describes this rather felicitously: "But the bidding need only be roused a centime or two to tap an almost inexhaustible source of supply — that of bankers' drafts. In other words, if the remitter cannot obtain a ready- made bill, he must only pay a little more and have one made to order." Finance bills present attractive lines of invest- ments to foreigners. They are advantageous in that they keep gold within the country. Mr. Albert Strauss tells of an amusing occur- rence in regard to the issuing of finance bills in 1907. It seems that during the summer English houses grew quite distrustful of American bankers' bills (finance bills), and discriminated against 194 PRACTICAL BANKING them, buying only a very few. In the fall we ex- ported an immense crop of wheat to supply Eu- rope whose crop had failed. As there were com- paratively few outstanding finance bills to be paid, the inevitable happened. American bankers imported great quantities of gold, which did a good turn in helping to alleviate the stringency here. At the same time Americans had additional credit because of the heavy purchase by Eu- ropeans of our securities at the low panic prices. The London bankers had destroyed one of the financial adjusters by their action and were un- protected against huge demands for gold. This system of selling finance bills and buying demand bills to meet them at maturity is the frequent cause of a peculiar situation. Say, a bank has a long bill maturing in London. It often happens that this bank buys the long bill of another bank, for which it charges a rate slightly above the regular discount, since there is a certain element of risk. Sending this pur- chased bill to London and discounting it there, a credit is formed against which it may draw de- mand bills to pay its obligation. At the same time it may be selling its own long bills to another bank in order to invest the proceeds profitably. Thus, with Mr. Strauss, we may conclude that if the exchange and interest rates of a market are high, we have ample reason for increasing the number of long bills. But if the interest rate is about equal in the two markets, exchange is the item whence profit is to flow. If, again, the exchange rates are about equal, interest is to be considered. A cable transfer is nothing more than a tele- FOREIGN EXCHANGE 195 graphic order to a foreign correspondent to pay a certain sum on receipt of the cable instead of on receipt of a bill of exchange by steamer. The rate for cable transfers is somewhat higher than for ordinary demand bills, because the seller loses interest on the sum transferred by cable for the number of days required to send a demand bill across. In abnormal times the rates for cable transfers soar. As a rule those selling cable trans- fers carry substantial credit balances abroad, re- plenished by forwarding demand bills to the credit of their accounts. There is little risk in this kind of business; but the percentage of profit is small. The average profit on this transaction on the New York market is fifteen one hundredths of a cent per pound sterling. ^ Occasionally bankers will be able to sell a cable at a price which warrants the replenishing of their account by buying a cable of some one else. Often enough, too, a cable is sold against balances which have accumulated from deposits of all kinds of bills, such as are herein described. VI Commercial long bills are those which are drawn by persons, firms, or corporations in this country against credits abroad. Like finance bills, they are in most cases drawn for sixty or ninety days. They are accompanied almost invariably by documents such as bills of lading, shippers' invoice, and marine insurance policy. The financier is always alert to employ his capital in some profitable yet safe investment. 1 Franklin Eschcr, supra, p. 73. 196 PRACTICAL BANKING In frequent instances commercial long bills are admirably fitted to fulfill these conditions. Suppose money went begging in New York at three and one half per cent, while in France five per cent could be obtained. Assume that the banker bought a ninety-day bill on some first- class merchant in France. This bill would in all probability have documents attached. On the day of purchase the banker sends the first of ex- change to his French correspondent for accept- ance. He also sends the documents with orders to surrender the same on acceptance of the first of exchange. The banker notes on the remaining second that the first is accepted and held by such and such a correspondent.^ He now files away the second until a short time before its maturity when he takes it out, indorses * Two points must here be noted: First, that documentary com- mercial long bills are of two kinds, "acceptance" and "payment" bills. "Acceptance" bills are handled as described above, while "payment" bills provide that the documents shall not be surrend- ered until payment is made. Bills drawn on banks are always "ac- ceptance" bills. Of coiu-se, an "acceptance" bill may be discounted and converted into cash as soon as accepted, and so, as a rule, bring higher prices than a "payment" bill, which may be allowed to run to maturity without any cash being paid on it. But "payment" bills drawn against shipments of perishable goods must be paid by the drawees before maturity to prevent the merchandise spoiling. This payment is subject to a rebate, which is, however, lower than the discount rate for the time of the bill, and consequently is an ad- vantage to the owner of the bill. An example of a "payment" bill of this kind is one drawn against the shipment of grain. A cotton bill, on the other hand, is usually an "acceptance" bill. See pages 198 and 203. "Payment" long bills can be discounted in the French market. The second point to remember is that some commercial long bills are known as "clean" bills; that is, free from documents. Such bills arise from transactions in which the goods are delivered before the draft is made. FOREIGN EXCHANGE 197 it, and sends it to some foreign agent to collect and credit the proceeds. With the indorsed sec- ond the agent can procure the accepted first and present both for payment at maturity. If the same rate of exchange prevails when the proceeds are credited which prevailed when the banker bought the bill, he makes the interest on the investment. If the exchange rate is higher, he makes more, and if it is lower, his profit is re- duced. Since, however, these bills are usually bought when exchange rates are down, there is not much chance for loss on that score. These bills are very attractive in that, although they are to run for a certain time, they may imme- diately be turned into a credit by discount abroad. The three most desirable kinds of bills to pur- chase are : — (1) Bankers' drafts on foreign agents for cred- its there. These, of course, are accepted on the same basis as any other piece of ex- change drawn by the bank. (2) Bills of merchants accompanied by docu- ments covering a shipment of goods. This shipment should consist of goods that could be easily resold in case of necessity. (3) Bankers' long (sixty or ninety days') bills on their foreign correspondents. The finan- cial status of the drawers of these bills should regulate chiefly the amount of them bought, although in many cases, accom- panying security, such as first-class stocks and bonds, is to be taken into consideration. In the case of acceptance long bills, accom- panied by documents, the attached papers are 198 PRACTICAL BANKING to be surrendered, as before remarked, at the ac- ceptance of the bill. These documents consist of bill of lading, exporter's certificate, marine in- surance policy, and at times consular invoice. Across the sides of these bills frequently is written the name and address of an agent to be notified in case of the refusal of the drawees to accept or pay the bill. By referring it to an agent, the drawer is saved the expense of protest fees, cable charges, etc. VII It is now in order to treat of a special form of merchants' long bill, that accompanied and guaranteed by a commercial letter of credit. A commercial letter of credit is a letter ad- dressed by a bank in behalf of a customer to a foreign merchant, authorizing him to draw on the issuing bank's correspondent in a certain place for a specified amount to be the cost price of goods ordered by the bank's customer. The letter further specifies that all drafts shall be accom- panied by the proper documents. Commercial letters of credit are the source of a good deal of benefit both to the importer and the exporter. (1) They insure for the importer prompt ser- vice; they enable the exporter actually to manufacture goods to order. (2) They permit the importer to deal on a cash basis, while payment is actually deferred sixty or ninety days; they permit the ex- porter to sell his goods practically for cash. These letters are issued in four parts; one sent to the foreign agent on whom the exporter's drafts FOREIGN EXCHANGE 199 will be made, one to the exporter, and one to the importer. The remaining part is kept by the issu- ing bank. Now, if we suppose that a New York merchant has purchased a cargo of coffee in Java, the ex- porter may call upon him to pay before the goods arrive. The importer may not wish to pay cash for these goods before their arrival; in fact, may not be able to do so. It would seem natural that the exporter should simply draw against the im- porter, and this is sometimes done. But usually the bill is drawn on England, for reasons that we shall presently tabulate. We shall assume that the bill for the cargo in question was drawn on England, with documents attached, and in accordance with certain require- ments which are to be brought out later. Now, why was the bill drawn on England.'* (1) The pound sterling has been long and still is the international standard. Also, the most reliable bank in Batavia — where the bill is prob- ably sold — is possibly a British bank. Even though it is not a British bank, it is in closer touch with the London market than with any other. Bankers in the Orient keep in rather inti- mate communication with the English market, while they scarcely know anything of the cur- rent condition of the New York market. These circumstances have resulted in habits of long standing regarding the buying of bills on London, and it is useless to oppose them. (2) The exporter in Java may not care to send his goods if he has to sell his bill on New York, because, upon arrival of the goods in New York, 200 PRACTICAL BANKING the purchaser may refuse to pay the draft on some pretext. In that event the seller has a cargo on his hands in New York but no cash credit. In such a case the cargo might easily prove a loss to him. (3) The importer himself does not desire a bill on him directly, since it would arrive before the goods and would have to be paid. This, then, would defeat the very reason he had for not de- siring to pay in cash. Thus, we have a pretty problem. The Java mer- chant, the Java bank, the American importer find it undesirable to utilize what seems to be the most natural means of transacting the affair. Handling the deal through England, on the other hand, would be satisfactory to all. Happily the problem is solved, by the " commercial letter of credit." The New York merchant, when he contem- plates this purchase, goes to his bank, to get a commercial letter of credit. His bank should be an institution of wide reputation. It authorizes its London correspondent to accept a bill for sixty or ninety days when drawn by the Java exporter and attached to the proper documents such as bills of lading, marine insurance, etc. It then authorizes the Java merchant to draw on London, under certain conditions, for the amount of the credit. This credit is the letter of credit described above. The New York merchant sends this authorization in the form of the bank's letter to the Java merchant with his order. Assume that the Java merchant draws his bill for ninety days on London, attaching all specified documents and the letter of credit. He takes it to his bank, which discounts it for him at the FOREIGN EXCHANGE 201 current rate for London bills. It then forwards the bill to its agent in London, who immediately pres- ents it to the New York bank's correspondent for acceptance. Upon acceptance, the accompanying documents are surrendered. They are forthwith shipped to the New York bank, which turns them over to the merchant in time to receive his cargo. The New York merchant receives, sells, and delivers his goods. With the proceeds he must remunerate the bank in time to pay the bill ma- turing in London in ninety days. The bank, of course, charges for this extension of its credit to the merchant. The commission varies as the value to the bank of the merchant's patronage and as his financial responsibility. As it is a matter of negotiation there is no definite charge. For a moment let us watch the accepted paper in London. It is quite an acceptable and negoti- able paper, being signed by the Java merchant, indorsed by his banker and the London agent, and lastly accepted by the New York bank's London correspondent. With ninety days to run after its acceptance, it is in all probability sold to one of the London discount houses which make a spe- cialty of discounting acceptances. When the bill is sold the London agent credits his Java client, who is thereby reimbursed for the amount which he advanced to the exporter. Just prior to the maturity of the bill the New York bank, which has meanwhile been repaid by the importing merchant, draws its demand bill on London to meet the maturing long bill.^ * The above transaction has been suggested by Margraff, supra, and by Strauss, supra. 202 PRACTICAL BANKING The whole difficulty has thus been overcome. By the New York bank's extension of credit to the merchant, forming a debt for which it does not itself have to answer till the end of ninety days, the merchant has been able to trade on a cash basis. There is no difficulty in getting the bill discounted in London, since it has become a first-class negotiable instrument. What is true of London in the matter of com- mercial letters of credit is also true of Berlin, Paris, and Amsterdam. We might further point out that under cer- tain conditions these long bills discounted by the London, Paris, and Berlin discount houses could be rediscounted at the Bank of England, the Reichsbank, or the Banque de France. These banks control the private discount rate as well as their own, for when too great a volume of bills accumulates they simply raise the discount rate, and further transactions of the kind are stopped. Foreign investments, like the foregoing, how- ever, are not very attractive to Americans. We must conclude that this is because of the enormous resources and the ever-increasing enterprise of the country, and because of the fact that the country is so sparsely settled that most of our capital is invested in home ventures. New York might be able to control the world market at times if there were a greater tendency to make foreign loans. As it is, our harvest frequently enables us to exercise considerable influence on prices. Mr. Strauss says: "Until it [New York] has acquired a vast amount of fluid capital ready to seek temporary investment in the best-paying FOREIGN EXCHANGE 203 market, it will not be a financial arbiter among nations." The Americans have been strangely suspicious in their foreign investments, and yet they certainly possess daring enough for anything, to judge from some of the wild investments made in home enterprises whose stock has been judici- ously watered, etc. Transactions like the dis- counting of the Java bill have never appealed greatly to their fancy. We must again conclude that the virgin resources of our country have proved the attraction which has worked against our having a city controlling in world finance. The provisions of the Federal Reserve Act will undoubtedly tend to encourage foreign invest- ments of the kind just described. Banks and federal reserve banks will discount acceptances based on the exportation and importation of goods. Banks that are members of the reserve system are authorized to accept drafts against them based on the importation and exportation of goods. ^ VIII Merchants or tourists going abroad wish, usually, to have some convenient exchange which they can easily convert into cash, in part or en- tirely. The traveler's check, issued by bankers and express companies, fulfills this demand to a certain extent, but the traveler's letter of credit, issued by many prominent banks in this country, seems at present to be the most popular mode of carrying the desired credit abroad, any part of which may be collected, practically at any place. ^ See chapter on "The Federal Reserve Act," p. 258 et seq. 204 PRACTICAL BANKING The letters are usually drawn in pounds ster- ling, and the drafts against credit are consequently directed to the New York bank's correspondent in London. The following is a form used for travelers* letters of credit : — FIRST NATIONAL BANK OF NORTHPORT, INDIANA. Northport, Ind 19. . No.... Sterling. To the Manager: — This letter will introduce to you M in whose favor we have opened a credit of Sterling, and whose sight drafts to that extent upon Bank of London, we engage shall meet with due honor, if negotiated within. . . months from this date. The amount of each payment please indorse on this letter, and your negotiation of the draft will be considered a guaranty that the requisite indorse- ments have been made. You will observe that all such drafts be drawn against the letter of credit of the First National Bank of Northport, No. . . This letter must be at- tached and remitted with the last draft. Recommending M to your usual courtesy. Very truly yours. To Messieurs, our correspondents, and all other banks or bankers to whom this credit may be pre- sented. FOREIGN EXCHANGE 205 {Reverse side.) Paid by Amount in letters Amount in figures Along with the letter, but usually separate from it, is a list of the agents of the issuing bank throughout the world who will negotiate a part or all of the draft. On this list is a card which introduces its bearer as the holder of letter of credit so and so. It is customary to engage, as one's agents for the purpose of negotiating letters of credit, the foreign correspondents of one's London agent, in- asmuch as all the drafts are to be made payable by him. The London bank is immediately advised of the issue of a letter of credit, is furnished with the signature of the letter's owner, and is instructed to pay drafts signed by this person in certain amounts. The holder of the letter, if he be in Berne, Switzerland, say, goes to the office of the banker noted in his list. There his card of introduction and possession of the letter are sufficient to obtain payment of any part of the draft he desires. The banker pays him the money and receives a draft on the London bank signed by his customer. He then notes on the back of the letter the amount paid and the transaction is ended. When the draft is presented for payment in London, the signature is looked up, and, if cor- 206 PRACTICAL BANKING rect, the draft is paid and charged to the issuing banker's account. It is then forwarded to him. The issuer of the letter of credit charges it against the credit which the purchaser of the letter has created for the purpose. IX Although all the European countries handle American accounts on practically the same basis, there is some dissimilarity of detail. When we glance over the foreign money markets, we have no difficulty in agreeing that England is paramount. There are more trans- actions of bankers through London than through any other city in the world, and, as a natural consequence, Americans keep their most import- ant accounts in London, Therefore the London account deserves first place in our discussion. The great Bank of England is the most power- ful instrument in finance. By its discount rate it has a distinct influence on the whole world. The discount rate of the Bank of England is the lowest point at which it will discount bills for English bankers. It is fixed at a meeting of the board of governors which convenes every Thursday. In times of panic or financial uneasiness, meetings are, of course, more frequent. "This rate acts as the barometer of the financial conditions of the various nations, and any factors of political or financial significance are reflected by its course." ^ In tabular form the discount rate of the Bank of England performs the following important functions : — 1 Margraff, supra. FOREIGN EXCHANGE 207 (1) It protects the gold reserve by an advance in the rate. (2) It regulates the discount rate of the open market in Great Britain on bills. (3) It establishes its own minimum discount rate. (4) It may affect the value of foreign bills in all countries since it may cause a lower or higher exchange rate on sterling drafts, and therefore depreciates or enhances the value of long bills by an increase or reduction of its foreign discount rate. (5) It determines the rate of interest allowed on credit balances in London and the rate charged on debit balances or overdrafts, since these are from one half to one and one half per cent higher and lower than the bank's rates. (6) It fixes the rate of interest of the joint- stock companies on short-time deposits, inasmuch as this is usually one and one half per cent below it. Unlike some of the European countries, Eng- land charges a commission on all business handled except cash items sent for credit and unaccom- panied by documents. There is no definite rate, and, as it is a matter of negotiation, the larger and more prominent the bank, the better arrange- ment it will doubtless be able to make. Documentary payment bills are those long bills from which the documents will not be detached until payment. These may, however, be taken up before maturity by the drawee. In the Eng- lish market such bills cannot be discounted, as 208 PRACTICAL BANKING their liability to be paid makes them undesirable investments. The rate at which the interest on these is rebated, if they are taken up before maturity, is called the "retirement rate of dis- count" in England. It is calculated for the un- expired time of the bill and is usually one per cent below the Bank of England discount rate. Owing to the branch banking system in Eng- land, it is only necessary to open an account with a prominent London bank to have facilities for carrying on business throughout the country. The branch banking system is in vogue rather generally among European countries. If one wishes accommodations in France, one can very well succeed by having an account v/ith a Paris bank of importance. But many large American banks find it convenient to carry ac- counts with banks in more than one city. The same holds true in Germany. The French ac- count is comparatively an expensive one, for besides a commission for handling one's business, overdrafts cost a higher rate than in any other country. Checks drawn against this account are charged on the day that the advice of their issue is received in Paris. There is frequently a con- siderable loss of interest thereby. The French market will discount the documentary payment bills which the English market refuses. The German branch system of "Filialen" insures one of banking facilities throughout the empire if one carries an account with a prominent Berlin bank. Though the Germans do not charge commis- sions for handling accounts, they make amends FOREIGN EXCHANGE 209 for this shortcoming by charging checks to their accounts as soon as advice of their issue arrives, and by beginning the payment of interest on credits from the day after remittances are credited. If a bill is discounted in the German market for M. 10,000 or more, discount is figured at the Reichsbank rate for the last five days of its life; if it be for less than M. 10,000, interest at the Imperial Bank rate is charged for the last ten days of its life. The three foregoing accounts — the English, German, and French — absorb by far the greater part of American business. Our trade with other foreign countries is immense, but is mainly banked through these countries. They have been aptly called the "clearing houses of nations." The fundamental principles of the banking systems of the other European countries, from Denmark and Scandinavia through Holland and Austria to Italy, are the same. Holland offers, by means of correspondents and branches, the same facilities as do Switzerland and Italy with their branch banking. Our exports to Italy are on the increase, and so we frequently accumulate larger credits there than are necessary. These are remitted every so often to some European correspondent, usually the French, where the funds are more serviceable. Italy charges about one fourth per cent for col- lecting bills and remitting the proceeds to Paris. Bills on Russia are not greatly in demand in this country. Indeed, there is no present means of directly supplying such a demand in great quantity, — save by actual deposit of credits 210 PRACTICAL BANKING there, — for we export little to Russia direct, and few American banks have affiliations there. Foreign exchange, then, consists of the results of world intercourse. The more we trade with each other, the more we visit the places of beauty and fame in each other's lands, the more we come to trust and believe in each other, the greater will become this phase of banking. And it is on the steady increase. It has gained such momen- tum now that, though it may be retarded, it may not be stopped. As we approach the world or international epoch in our history, this commer- cial, social, and intellectual intercourse between nations increases. The modern means of rapid transportation and communication both on land and sea are making the lands of the earth, though separated by thousands of miles of ocean, next- door neighbors. We are being brought together by bonds — social and commercial — which can- not be broken. It is not uninteresting, therefore, to have dis- cussed and studied one of the great early pro- ducts of general international intercourse — the foreign exchanges. Their importance to-day is so vast that prominent banks, be they in the center of the country or in one of the great sea- ports, are making affiliations with foreign insti- tutions. Some time in the future it will be just as important that an American bank have its Lon- don agent as it is now that it have its New York agent. CHAPTER XIX CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES To-day, seven years after the last great crisis in the United States, one hears occasional re- echoes of the crash. The country is emerging from the depression succeeding that crisis, and one is tempted to ask: "What are crises? How do they arise? Are they necessary evils, like lightning which comes to clear a torrid atmo- sphere?" These are matters which it is proposed to broach in this chapter, and, together with a succinct sketch of the history of financial disturbances in the United States, to seek some conclusion as to the nature of crises. For our purpose it will be more satisfactory to discuss a few results of in- vestigations into crises and their composition than to launch ourselves bodily forth into an almost illimitable analysis of detail.^ Within the scope of this volume it will be possible only to state the case, as it were, in chapter heads. There is no phase of banking which is more alluring to the historically practical mind than the subject of those mysterious disturbances ^ For those who would study figures and enter minutely Into ana- lytical research, most of the books cited in footnotes in this chapter will offer a tempting starting-point, especially Charles A. Conant, A History of Modern Banks of Issue, and Wesley C. Mitchell, Busi- ness Cycles. 212 PRACTICAL BANKING which have visited us every ten or a dozen years in the form of a contraction of loans, a scarcity (sometimes) of currency, a lost stock exchange equilibrium, a derangement of relative credits, both in domestic and foreign exchanges. Why, in the midst of piping prosperity, need and dis- tress should seize our financial and economic sys- tem — that is the question. It has not been adequately answered. There exists a wide difference of opinion among practi- cal financiers and theoretical economists. But one point has been settled: the old notion that crises are abnormal phenomena is abandoned. "On the contrary, explanations in favor to-day ascribe the recurrence of crises after periods of prosperity to some inherent characteristic of economic organization or activity. . . . The in- fluence of special conditions is admitted, of course, but rather as a factor which complicates the pro- cess than as the leading cause of crises." ^ That is to say, by the very nature of our mode of pro- ducing and consuming, "business" moves in a circle from prosperity to a crisis to a depression; then to prosperous and booming times again. This seems to be the order, although artificial causes may intervene, as, for instance, to bring or end a crisis sooner than would occur under the rule. Then, too, each circle or cycle — consisting of prosperity, crisis, and depression — is different from every other one in circumstances. For ex- ample, in 1837, $100,000,000 worth of new canals in a few years had boomed certain enterprises and investments. In 1873, it was said that ' Mitchell, supra, p. 6. CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES 213 extensive railroad construction contributed to the overextension of credit; in 1893, a wild scramble toward real estate and city development.^ What we are interested in does not compre- hend an economic study of the endless details which enter into the evolution of the three essen- tial elements of a business cycle. Nevertheless, we shall do well to remember that underlying every crisis there are scores of economic forces, which we but little understand, and over which there is, at present, great controversy. This much seems to be settled: prosperity begets a crisis with dramatic resistlessness; a crisis is followed by a period of general depression just as inevitably; finally, prosperity is again brought into exist- ence.^ * Conant, supra, pp. 672-73. ^ Wesley Clair Mitchell, in his book Business Cycles (University of California Press, 1913), has made the most complete, up-to-date study of statistics relating to the course which economic conditions take. He has massed in the beginning a summary of the explana- tions offered by leading writers on the subject, a few of which are here digested to throw some light on contemporary theories : — W. H. Beveridge, in his volume on Ujiemployment, says that busi- ness cycles are due to the "simple and well-nigh universal fact of industrial competition." He says that in times of prosperity com- petition tends to overload, to "glut" the market. When goods can- not be sold, the whole structure of commerce and industry, thus sup- ported, threatens to topple or topples. A crisis is at hand, to be fol- lowed by a period of depression which continues until the demand exceeds the supply, when competition begins in earnest, anew. R. E. May {Das Grundgesetz der Wirtschaftskrisen) explains the "glutting" of the market by saying prices in times of prosperity rise, whereas the growing output of production can only be sold if prices are low. An interesting theory is advanced by A. Aftalion {Essai d'une thiorie des crises gSnSrales et p6riodiques), who sets aside the objec- tion to an "overproduction" theory on a basis of marginal utilities. He says that production increases in good times, but that there 214 PRACTICAL BANKING All the authorities cited below analyze the situation more or less accurately, but none are comes a time when, though all human wants may not be gratified, they are sufficiently gratified from goods on the market to cause the marginal utility of the goods (that is, their potentiality to sell at some profit) to decline. A general fall in prices ensues. So, in good times the rise in prices grows out of the relative scarcity of goods in relation to the community's wants. Then M. Aftalion answers the query, "Why this over- and under-production?" The cause, he says, lies in the awkward methods of capital. Where a promising field opens itself, capital flows in in volumes and prepares to supply the field. High prices prevail. But after the new factories are com- pleted and have begun to produce, the time is short before the market becomes overstocked. Then the crisis appears, followed by a depression. When some machinery has gone out of repair, without replacement, and some factories have closed; in fine, when produc- tion is again less than the demand, good times return. Hobson {The Industrial System) has a theory of "oversaving." Since a considerable proportion of capital invested and wealth pro- duced belongs to a comparatively small class, its income rises more rapidly than its consumption, there always being a limit of consumption, no matter how affluent the consumer. Therefore the reinvestment of this surplus of capital has a tendency to "glut" the market. M. Bouniatian {Studien zur Tkeorie und Geschichte der Wirtschaftskrisen) has a theory of overcapitalization resembling Hobson's oversaving. George H. Hull {Industrial Depressions) maintains an enthusi- astic thesis. It is bristlingly practical. Agriculture, commerce, and finance, says he, fluctuate within relatively narrow limits. Agricul- ture provides the necessities of life; commerce distributes them, and finance pays the accounts. On the other hand, he continues, indus- try fluctuates greatly. Three fourths of industry consists in con- struction. Of this construction two thirds is necessary, the rest optional. Optional construction is undertaken when investors can see a goodly profit in so doing. The necessary plus the optional con- struction causes a boom and prices of construction go up. Shrewd investors then defer contracting for a time; prices tumble. Hull says industrial depressions are caused by high prices of construction and foreshadowed by high prices of iron. He favors the Government collecting and publishing monthly "all pertinent information in relation to the existing volume of construction under contract for future months, and all pertinent information in relation to the capacity of the country to produce construction materials to meet the demand thus indicated." CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES 215 so comprehensive as Mr. Mitchell. His theory of business cycles is so complete that the writer ventures, in order to provide a suitable back- ground for a historical summary of crises in the United States, to give a very brief review of Mr. Mitchell's results. He has conceived his problem to be a quantita- tive one and so has treated his subject statisti- cally. His clue, to begin with, is that "the in- dustrial process of making and the commercial process of distributing goods is thoroughly sub- ordinated to the business of making money." Supposing we start at a point where a revival of trade may be first noticed in the business cycle. The elements entering into industrial and com- mercial intercourse are: low prices, reduced cost of doing business, small profits, large bank re- serves, conservative capitalization, moderate granting of credit, fair stock of goods, and cauti- ous buying. Such conditions will be accompanied by an increase in the physical volume of trade — slow but cumulative. Then it is only a question of time until the momentum of increased trade will convert a period of dullness into one of activ- ity. It would come slowly if left alone, but a bumper crop or an increased demand abroad for home products is likely to accelerate the coming of prosperity. The activity is contagious and spreads through innumerable lines of intercon- nection to industries other than that which may have received the first stimulus. More labor is used, more money is borrowed, profits are higher. The resulting increase in incomes causes an ever- accelerated demand for every commodity. "All 216 PRACTICAL BANKING this while the revival of activity is instilling a feeling of optimism among business men, and this feeling both justifies itself and heightens the forces which engendered it by making every one readier to buy with freedom." Prices rise. Then producers begin to foresee orders exceeding their capacity; this raises prices in advance. "The expectation of its coming hastens the advance. Buyers are anxious to secure or to contract for large supplies while the low level of quotations continues, and the first definite signs of an up- ward trend of quotations brings out a sudden rush of orders." In fine, the cumulative process has converted a revival of trade into intense prosperity. Meanwhile, Mr. Mitchell's thesis continues, there is also a slow accumulation of stresses. There is an increase in the cost of doing business. Higher rates of interest prevail, due to greater demand for accommodation. Salaries and wages go up; equipment must be enlarged and improved. The scarcity of labor, necessitating the acquire- ment of inferior workmen, and overtime labor decrease eflBciency, which, when added to waste in doing a "rushing" business, becomes an ap- preciable item. Then a tension on the bond and money market is felt, arising from the super- abundance of securities and notes offered. The demand for credit is growing beyond the ability of accommodation. Such manufactories as steel mills, iron works, lumber mills, and cement plants feel the strain first. It is because they manufacture industrial equipment for which demand decreases when prices — as controlled CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES 217 by the difficulty of getting loans — rise. Con- structing companies and contractors are also among the first to feel the result of a tight money market. As the interest rate rises and, conse- quently, security for credits decreases, and, moreover, as profits seem to waver, cautious lenders refuse to renew notes. Liquidation sets in. When once this process of liquidation of obh- gations has begun, piping times of prosperity are doomed to give way to a crisis. Liquidation con- tinues, partially because the caution of some creditors is contagious, partially because the pres- sure for payment is passed down the line, as from A to B for B's indebtedness to A, then from B to C for C's indebtedness to B. The question with business men becomes not so much one of profits but of solvency. Since resources have to be care- fully guarded, sales are not pushed. Orders for goods fall off. Business in general decreases; ex- pansion gives way to contraction. Meanwhile, the demand for loans becomes more acute with the inevitable result that discount rates rise and the value of securities falls. Liquidation continues steadily, though with- out any paroxysms, until in the chain some weak link gives way, until there is some conspicuous failure. Immediately (under the old system in the United States) intense alarm reigns; banks are frantically besought for loans and are besieged by depositors. If the banks can meet both de- mands without difficulty, the alarm passes; other- wise it becomes a panic. In the wake of the panic there are suspended cash payments at the banks. 218 PRACTICAL BANKING the issue of clearing-house certificates, hoarding of cash, and premium on currency. Interest rates soar. There are bankruptcies and — what is worse for the situation — rumors of bank- ruptcies. The Government does what it can by deposi- ting Treasury funds with the banks. The banks help themselves to some extent by the slow and uncertain process of increasing their circulation. Very little cash money is in circulation; individu- als and banks alike hoard it. The total result is the closing of many busi- nesses and the partial operation of others. Work- men are discharged, commodities are sold at sacrifice, and the volume of business is greatly contracted. Because of unemployed wage-earners, the de- crease in savings, and the encroachments on the incomes of those most fortunately situated, — because of the impoverished ability to buy, — consumers' demands are greatly reduced. The shrinkage here goes down the entire line during the gradual period of readjustment. Construc- tion is almost at a standstill. Now the con- traction in the physical volume of business be- comes cumulative. Competition is keener because there is a reduced demand. Pessimism reigns supreme.^ When the "market" supply is less than the demand, or rather when the consumption has caught pace with production, — in short, when business has adjusted itself to new condi- 1 It is at tbis time that good Americans begin to vilify Washing- ton, D.C., regardless of the party in power. CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES 219 tions, — the seeds are sown for a revival of ac- tivity.^ II. THE CRISES OF 1814 AND 1819 On the 31st of August, 1814, the banks of Philadelphia suspended specie payments and on the next day the New York banks did likewise. This was the weak link in the chain which ac- companied the first great liquidation of credits in the United States. Owing to the economic result of such govern- mental acts as the Embargo, the trade of the United States had fallen, until the fiscal year ending September 30, 1814, indicated the smallest foreign trade in the nation's history. ^ Also the Government pursued a method of borrowing instead of taxing to carry on the War of 1812, which tended to take investment capital out of circulation. This reacted on the already declin- ing trade. Government expenditures doubling receipts in 1813 and 1814 exercised a bad psy- chological effect on business. But what contrib- uted as much, perhaps, as anything else to the crisis of 1814 was the establishment of a large number of state banks without adequate capital, which emitted floods of poorly secured circulating notes. The growth of these banks was encouraged by the lapse of the charter of the first United ^ Of course, in our limited treatment of the subject, we shall not endeavor to trace all these influences, but shall merely show the principal trend of industry and investment which eventually culmi- nates in a money stringency and a crisis. ^ Theodore E. Burton, Crises and Depressinns, pp. 273-76. The total exports and imports for the fi.scal year 1814 were $19,602,103, as against a total of more than $42,000,000 in 1790. 220 PRACTICAL BANKING States Bank in 1811. The amount of specie in the country would not begin to support the huge volume of credit which was extended by these banks. "A veritable banking mania prevailed for several years in the Middle, Southern, and West- ern States." ^ The country's credit was, as it were, on stilts which but required some extraordinary event to overtopple. This event was the capture of Washington by the British, August 24, 1814. After 1814 the United States had a period in which an unnatural trade growth took place. Im- ports increased to $194,000,000 in 1816, amount- ing to more than twice the value of the exports. But this expansion relaxed when Americans found how impoverished they were. In August, 1819, there were twenty thousand unemployed in Philadelphia, with a similar situation prevail- ing in other cities.^ But while commerce and industry had grown to such proportions — as compared with the year 1814 — bank-note circu- lation had fallen from $110,000,000 in 1815 to $65,000,000 in 1819. This retrenchment had been induced partly by the chartering of the second United States Bank in 1816 and its conservative influence on speculation, and partly by the banks' realizing from their experience in 1814 that there was not enough specie to back the immense bank- note circulation. But the mischief was done. Huge sums were invested in real estate and other speculative enterprises. The contraction of the currency caused a great fall in prices, and ruin followed to those dependent on bank accommo- ^ Conant, A History of Modern Banks of Issue, p. 617. 2 Ibid., p. 618. CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES 221 dation or on the continuance of a boom to realize on their speculations. This crisis — or series of crises lasting from 1814 to 1819 — is to be set chiefly to the score of a defective monetary system. It shows how poorly business and finance were coordinated in those days It has been somewhat improved to-day. In 1814, observe, there was a contraction of busi- ness but a huge supply of wretched currency. Business said, "Go to, we shall avail ourselves of this credit." Note the resulting increase in im- ports. Bankers, influenced by their experience and curbed by the new United States Bank, rapidly contracted their circulation. Thus in 1819 the situation was reversed. There was a large amount invested in business enterprises, but the ability of the banks to finance this in- creased business had disappeared. The banks, for the reasons we have noted, had destroyed their own ability to do so.^ III. THE CRISIS OF 1837 The eighteen years which preceded 1837 — years of international peace — were years of growing-pains with regard to territorial and busi- ness development, including the beginnings of transportation expansion. It was also charac- terized by a leap in immigration figures as well as the negotiation of large foreign loans. Manu- facturing had recovered from the depression fol- lowing the crisis in 1819. ^ These twin crises illustrate, in a simple way, better than any others, how awkwardly business and finance tug at cross-purposes when there is no centralized coordination of resources. 222 PRACTICAL BANKING The Erie Canal, finished in 1825 at a cost of more than seven millions, was but one of a large number of canals; a network of canals were opened in Ohio, Pennsylvania, New Jersey, and Illinios. Railroad building began in 1830. The highways were improved. It was an era of inter- nal improvements. The canals tempted home- stead seekers to forsake the seaboard and plunge inland toward the rich interior farming lands. The Cumberland Road was black with traveling settlers. States sprang into being; population bounded upward at a rapid rate. Between 1820 and 1840, the States of Ohio, Indiana, Illinois, and Michigan increased in population from 792,- 000 to 2,893,000. In this period was laid the working foundation of the United States of to- day. There was an increase in the means of pro- ducing commodities; likewise, an expansion of mineral and agricultural products due to better transportation facilities. This tended to over- speculation and overdevelopment. Land speculation was the underlying cause of the forthcoming crisis. The Government was lenient in exacting payment for lands. Prospec- tive buyers were induced, by the jump in the selling price of the land, to borrow. They found ready accommodation in the banks. It was an easy-money time. Frequently, the Government redeposited the purchase money in the bank from which it was borrowed; the bank then loaned it to another land buyer. It does not require a great power of deduction to suspect speculation. It not only existed, but, under these favoring con- ditions, increased by headlong leaps. In 1837 the CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES 223 Government was still selling land at the early- price of $1.25 per acre. Right up to the crisis, speculators realized immediate profits. The fig- ures are in 1834, 4,659,218 acres were sold; in 1836, 20,074,870 acres.^ Land speculation was not confined to the West, but extended to the cotton lands of the South. Cotton production increased from 536,000 bales in 1833 to 916,000 bales in 1837.2 By the process of redepositing purchase money in local banks, the United States and these banks became involved in a network of credits; banks were established purely to carry on this kind of business, relying solely for their existence on land purchasers' loans. This policy could be pursued the more readily since, for some years past, the Government had accepted bank notes in pay- ment of the public lands. Financial uneasiness began to be engendered by the veto of the bill to recharter the United States Bank. The Jackson Administration had set about to " smash" the Bank; it did so.^ The deposits were gradually withdrawn. On Novem- ber 1, 1836, there were public deposits in eighty- nine "pet" state banks of $49,378,000.* But the causes of the crisis were deeper than the poli- tical creed of Andrew Jackson and his kitchen 1 WTiat an inflation this really was may be gathered from the sales in 1842 after the crisis had subsided. In that year the sales amounted to $14,17,972, or a little more than a million acres. " Davis Rich Dewey, Financial History of the United States. p. 227. * Jaclcson was sincere in his belief that the United States Bank was unsound, saying, when he heard of certain transactions, "I tell you, sir, she's brpke." * Dewey, supra, 210. 224 PRACTICAL BANKING cabinet. As Mr. Conant, in his excellent work, says : — The crisis of 1837 in the United States was one of the results of that discounting of the future in a new country, which results in overspeculation and the sinking of capital in unproductive enterprises. For- eign capital became available in great quantities for the use of the American people after the recovery from the crisis of 1825 in England, and specie imports kept company with an excess of imports of merchandise, amounting in seven years to $140,700,000 as evi- dence of the heavy loans which Europe was willing to make in the United States. The fact that the United States succeeded in wiping out their entire public debt and accumulating a surplus seemed,^ among the finan- ciers of European countries, burdened under millions of debt and annual interest charges, to be a proof of great prosperity. ^ The practice of receiving bank notes in pay- ment of public lands did not appeal favorably to the Administration. On July 11, 1836, the Treasury Department issued a " Specie Circular" in which instructions were given to land com- missioners to receive only specie in payment of public lands. It was believed that this would re- duce or eliminate speculation. It did — some- what. But two factors interfered with the success 1 On January 1, 1837, there was more than $42,000,000 surplus in the United States accounts. Congress voted to distribute, as a loan, among the States according to population, all save $5,000,000. Three of four projected installments were paid when it was found that the Government could only pay in state bank notes, and the distribution was never completed. It was not the intention of Con- gress ever to collect the loan, and until this day the account (some $28,000,000) is carried on the books of the Treasurer. * Conant, supra, p. 624. CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES 225 of the measure: first, speculators were those who would most likely have ready money; second, it cut out the props from many banks in the West, together with their affiliations in many cases in the East. So the speculation continued, though some- what abated, and many banks were weakened. The situation was not helped — rather, embar- rassed so far as the United States Treasurer's ac- counts were concerned — by the distribution of the surplus already alluded to.^ Added to the other complications was a change in the ratio of gold and silver by the Government which threat- ened to take silver out of circulation on account of the premium on it. The crisis was affected to some extent by the failure, in November, 1836, on the London Stock Exchange of the three W's, which had the closest credit relations with America.^ Premonitions of a financial distur- bance seemed to be felt on account of the high prices and expanded loans. Popular meetings of protest were held in New York in the early part of 1837, some degenerating into destructive riots. The stage was set. Everything was ready for the curtain to rise.^ The cue was given in April, 1837. One hun- dred and twenty-eight failures occurred in New ^ For the effect on the South and European investors of the spec- ulations of Biddle, president of the United States Bank of Pennsyl- vania, see Conant, supra, p. 627, and also (there cited) Juglar, Dea Crises Commerciales, etc., p. 402, et seq. ^ The houses of Wilkes, Wilde, and Wiggins. * The crisis of 1837 was aggravated by the failure of the American wheat crop. Exports of wheat fell off a million dollars, while im- ports increased four and a half millions. 226 PRACTICAL BANKING York between April 1 and April 11. Cotton fell fifty per cent in value. On May 10 the banks of New York suspended specie payment and were followed on the next day by banks in large cities throughout the East. Within a few days banks all over the country had suspended specie pay- ments. Suspension of specie payments greatly affected the Government. Its funds were de- posited in the state banks. It could get only bank notes. Besides, its accounts were low; Congress had foolishly distributed a handsome portion of its surplus. Public revenues fell off. On October 12, 1837, Congress met in special session to devise means of assisting the embarrassed Government. It authorized the issuance of Treasury notes, pledging the credit of the nation. President Van Buren advocated an independent treasury, but a bill providing for this was not passed until 1840. The Government's immediate needs cared for, it sought to relieve the general distress by various methods: it gave importers additional time to settle for their duties; it withdrew its deposits slowly; it required no more interest on its de- posits. The distress occasioned by the crisis was deep; it gave the entire country a severe shock. Previ- ous experiences had not compared with this one in magnitude and effect. It was not till the latter part of 1838 that banks in general resumed specie payments. Indeed, the Philadelphia banks had to suspend again and were not reliable specie disbursers before 1842. The Government's rev- enues had, as we have hinted, been ruined. From $35,000,000 in 1835 and $50,000,000 in 1836, they CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES 227 fell to $24,000,000 in 1837. From 1837 to 1844 the Treasury had a deficit, with the exception of the year 1838 when there was a small surplus. Altogether in these seven years there was a net deficit of $38,000,000. This crisis was like the later ones and quite un- like those of 1814 and 1819. The earlier crises were due particularly to monetary disorders. The crisis of 1837 was merely localized in a money situation. It had a great economic development behind it. It even showed symptoms of an in- dustrial complication, a factor which, we shall find, is of supreme importance in the great crises to follow. By 1843 the end of the depression was reached and conditions looked up again. IV. THE CRISIS OF 1857 It may seem inexplicable to those who have become piously resigned to a crisis (usually with that attendant money scramble, the panic) in this country every dozen years to observe that our narrative leaps from 1837 to 1857. Indeed, but for unusual — abnormal, we may say — conditions there would have been a severe crisis about 1848. In that year, there was a financial stringency, but no crisis of any magnitude. It was a year of crisis in Europe, and but for the export of huge food supphes, the United States might have suffered. America is always subject to a reflection of a European crisis; there are so many foreign interests in our securities and bor- rowing. Again, we import so largely from Europe that, granting a crisis abroad and a lull in our 228 PRACTICAL BANKING exports therefrom, we lose considerable gold re- serve. However, in 1848 we were able to offset the effect of the crisis by our exportations. It has been thought that the Mexican War tended to curb that superdevelopment, that optimistic cap- italizing of optimism itself, which eventually leads to a crisis. But the war's effect was prob- ably very slight. Two items, ^ indeed, tended to delay the crisis. One was the discovery of gold, which in the end helped lead to the crisis, in 1848, affording a new source of development along lines which did not strain the financial situation. The other was the Crimean War (1854-55) which caused high prices for American goods. On the whole, the period from 1838 to 1857 was one of remarkable industrial growth and pros- perity, marred only by a couple of economic dis- turbances of no magnitude. As contrasted with canal digging during the period of development immediately preceding 1837, this period was one of great activity in railroad building. In no year before 1849 had railway construction exceeded eight hundred miles, but in 1856 it ran to 3642 miles. 2 The total railway mileage had, in 1857, reached 27,000 miles, of which 21,000 had been built in the previous nine years.^ Consider the financing necessary to construct 21,000 miles of railroad, — and in nine years. Banks had increased in numbers from 715 in 1847 to 1416 in 1857; loans and discounts had risen from approximately $310,000,000 to ap- proximately $684,000,000; bank-note circulation * Cited by Burton, supra, p. 214. 2 Burton, supra, p. 284. ^ Conant, supra, p. 640. CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES 229 had expanded one hundred per cent to $214,- 000,000.^ "At all times the proportion of specie held by the banks to their loans and circulation was dangerously small, even when the most con- servative management was maintained." ^ A de- fective currency was a feature of this period. The introduction of large quantities of foreign capital kept the pot boiling. As one writer puts it, "Foreign capital continued to flow into the United States and the bubble of speculation to be blown to the extremist tension." In addition to the construction of railroads during the period prior to 1857 and, indeed, aid- ing and abetting railroad constructing, the dis- covery of gold in the United States in 1848 played a leading role in developing the acute situation leading to the crisis. The discovery of silver and gold in America soon after Columbus's voyage to the New World had wrought a revolution in the value of money. The gold production from 1492 to 1850 had averaged about $9,000,000 per year; imagine the impetus given trade by the increase to about $133,000,000 per year from 1851 to 1860.^ This great unexpected addition to the gold supply had two effects: it hastened the set- tlement of a proper ratio between gold and silver, and it stimulated commerce to an unusual and ' Conant, supra, p. 640. Circulation fell in 1858, after the panic, to $155,000,000, and the specie held by the banks rose from $58,- 000,000 in 1857 to $74,000,000 in 1858 to $104,000,000 in 1859. ^ Burton, supra, p. 284. * Conant, supra, p. 637. Mr. Conant quotes from Adolph Soot- beer's Bimetallism in Europe. From 1493 to 1850 the estimated gold production of the world was $3,150,000,000, while from 1851 to 1885 it was $4,250,000,000. 2S0 PRACTICAL BANKING abnormal extent. Strangely, it did not act as a strong agency to raise prices, although in a well- developed country this would be the result. The extraordinary effort of the newly discovered pre- cious metal was bent toward a " lateral expansion of commerce in quantity"; that is, the energy was diffused, not concentrated. It was an era of unprecedented expansion in enterprises of all kinds. The effect of railroad con- struction and the discovery of gold, however, led the way toward overinvestment which charac- terized the period. There were indications of a money stringency several times before 1857. New business opera- tions swallowed the credit based on the new gold and asked for more. The crop failure in the West in 1853 tended to arouse anxiety; several banks failed as a result. Lastly, the dearness of silver — due to the great quantities of gold — compli- cated the problem, as we have seen. The signal for the crash was the failure on August 24, 1837, of the Ohio Life Insurance and Trust Company, a corporation with offices jn New York. The liabilities of this concern were about $7,000,000. As we have observed, some conspicuous failure is enough to ignite a train of powder. A panic ensued on the Stock Exchange. Then banking, unprotected by a safe currency or a centralized reserve, took its ordinary course : money was hoarded; loans were procurable only at an excessive interest; deposits disappeared from the banks. A run was made on the banks of Philadelphia in September, and on the 26th of the month they CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES 231 were forced to suspend specie payments. Mean- while, the first part of October had seen several important commercial failures; the Illinois Cen- tral and other railroads were put into receivers' hands. A run followed on New York banks, and they, too, suspended specie payments, October 13.^ The crisis, on the whole, was a financial crisis and was characterized by a large number of failures. Prices of commodities tumbled along with the depreciation of stocks and real estate. But the succeeding depression was not long-lived, as we shall see. This crisis has been frequently attributed to the tariff of 1857 which generally reduced import duties. It is argued that the reduction of duties stimulated importations which had to be paid for in specie and that this drain inevitably brought the panic. It is too much to claim that this widespread shock was due to the tariff of 1857 which had been in opera- tion but for a few months, or even to the tariff of 1846. To be sure, imports had increased and there had been a heavy export of specie to pay for them, but at the same time the production of specie in the United States had been more than enough to cover this de- mand and to leave a generous amount in the country for domestic needs . . . [Also] in connecting cause and effect it must be borne in mind that commercial de- pressions have for a century returned in almost mathe- matical regularity, and that it is hardly reasonable ^ Conant, supra, p. C40, note: "The constitution of the State of New York forbade suspension of specie payments directly or indi- rectly, but the judges of the Supreme Court met and agreed not to grant any injunction unless the bank appeared to be insolvent or guilty of fraud." 232 PRACTICAL BANKING to hold alone responsible a tariff which had appar- ently brought no disturbance during a period of ten years. ^ V. THE CRISIS OF 1873 The depression which followed the crisis in 1857 reached its worst point in 1859, and after that prospects were good for a revival. But an abnormal event — war — caused a liquidation in the latter part of 1860 and 1861, thus delaying the acceleration of business activities.^ On the other hand, the large number of men engaged on the battlefield and the impetus given certain activities prevented a depression. The year 1865 ushered in a period of awakening industrialism — at least, in those sections which had been free from the ravages of war. A pro- tective tariff fostered home manufacturing; the demand in this country for American-made goods was enormous. Agricultural products, of course, were greatly in demand after the exhausting four years, particularly since the South was tempo- rarily disorganized and comparatively unproduc- tive. "The return of much more than a million men seemed to cause no embarrassment. All could find employment. With slight reactions in * Dewey, supra, pp. 264-65. Conant (p. 638) quotes from Von Hoist's Constitutional and Political History of the United States (vol. Ill, pp. 51-52), to show that the tariff had nothing to do with the crisis ; he also cites Max Wirth, who makes no mention of the tariff. * The European political situation in July, 1914, caused a rapid liquidation of securities, so extensive, indeed, that all the stock exchanges in the world closed to prevent the selling of securities in such quantities as to destroy values, and thus, in the United States at least, jeopardize a great portion of bank loans. CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES 233 1867 and 1869, the onward movement continued until 1873." ^ The crisis was preceded by four years of general economic activity. Manufacturing and trans- portation facilities were greatly developed, but, as in 1857, a serious weakness was disclosed in railroad construction. The average increase in railway mileage between 1860 and 1867 was 1311 miles per year; in 1869 it was almost 5000 miles; in 1870, 5690 miles; in 1871, 7600 miles; and in 1872, over 6000 miles. ^ Bonds sold at a heavy discount. Many roads were left partially com- pleted owing to inability to arrange finances; when they were completed, they frequently could not pay such fixed charges as interest on bonds. The capital invested in all varieties of enter- prises in the ten years prior to the crisis was enor- mous. "Facihties for the production of certain commodities had increased beyond consumption." The crisis of 1873 was due; mathematically, it was overdue. Had it not been for the extraordi- nary conditions of war, it probably would have come in 1866 as a reflection of the European sit- uation of that year. The latter part of 1872 and the first half of 1873 saw a continuous stringency in the money market. From September, 1872, to May, 1873, the money "tightness" prevailed, "at times almost prohibiting the sale of new railroad bonds and requiring the issue of large amount of rail- road paper for the prosecution of the several enterprises. Together with this came the failures of quite a number of smaller railroad companies ' Burton, supra, pp. 286-87. ' Dewey, supra, p. 370. 234 PRACTICAL BANKING to pay their interest, causing a feelmg of distrust and aversion toward new railroad bonds, which has been quite perceptible for some months past." 1 The crash came on September 8, when the New York warehouse and Produce Company, which was engaged in the financing of the Missouri, Kansas and Texas Railway, suspended. Kenyon, Cox and Company, who had indorsed $1,500,000 of Canadian Southern Railroad paper, suspended on September 13, the reason being inability or unwillingness to pay that part of the paper maturing on the 15th. On the 18th the house of Jay Cooke and Company failed. This firm was the agent of the Government and the leader of the syndicate handling the refunding of the public debt. This failure was brought about by heavy deposit withdrawals and advances to the Northern Pacific Railroad. The next day Fisk and Hatch, stock brokers, were forced to close because of the depreciation of securities on which they had call loans. A number of stock exchange firms followed this dignified lead. Saturday, the 20th, was a day long remembered in Wall Street. The excitement in that famous lane was unprece- dented. Interest was somewhat centered about the runs on the Fourth National Bank and the Union Trust Company. The former succeeded in meeting all demands. A defalcation on the part of the secretary of the Trust Company, in addition to an important loan to the Michigan * Commercial and Financial Chronicle, September 20, 1873, cited by Professor O. M. W. Sprague, History of Crises under the National Banking System, National Monetary Commission Series, p. 36. CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES 235 Southern Railway, brought the close of its doors. On the same day the Commonwealth Bank closed. Excitement was so high and price-slumping so imminent that the Stock Exchange was closed at eleven o'clock on Saturday, remaining closed until September 30.^ Runs on the banks took place in Washington, Philadelphia, and Brooklyn, nineteen banks and trust companies closing on September 19. "Fail- ures followed each other in quick succession, mills and foundries stopped, production ceased, and for six years the pall of depressed industry lay over the United States. Deposits in the national banks fell from $641,121,775 on June 13, 1873, to $540,510,602 on December 26. Failures for four years showed aggregate liabilities of $775,865,000, and the railway bonds in default on January 1, 1876, amounted to $789,367,655." ^ The Secretary of the Treasury paid out $24,- 000,000 in the purchase of bonds, but little of it reached New York and the Eastern cities ; ' clearing-house certificates were issued, amount- ing in New York to $26,505,000 and in Phila- delphia to $6,785,000. It has been pointed out that the action of the New York City banks in 1873 was quite the reverse, in regard to reserves, of that in 1893 and * This was the only closing in the history of the New York Stock Exchange until July 31, 1914, when, due to the closing of all the important European bourses, it was thought necessary to close in order to prevent the flood of selling orders from Europe overturning prices. The closing of the Consolidated Stock Exchange and the Curb Market of New York followed, as did that of the exchanges all over the country. * Conant, supra, pp. G55-56. ' Ibid. 236 PRACTICAL BANKING 1907. In 1873 the New York banks adopted not only the clearing-house loan certificate, but also a scheme of equalizing reserves, which was devised in 1860. In this way, the New York Clearing House Committee, having charge of the combined reserves, enabled New York banks to continue paying considerable cash to country banks. New York savings banks, and customers, although cash payments had been authorized to be suspended September 24. The legal tender reserve in the clearing-house banks of New York was, on October 14, $5,800,000, having been reduced from $34,000,000 on September 20.^ This bears eloquent testimony to the valiant efforts of New York bankers to make good as the country's reserve agents; their generous disburse- ments differed from bank action in 1893 and 1907. "In making free use of their reserves the Clearing House Committee exhibited a determination and strength of purpose which cannot be too highly praised." ^ Finally, in order to review some of the causes of the crisis, it becomes important to glance at the condition of the national banks. ^ Did they contribute too liberally with loans? Was the proper relation of reserve to loans and deposits disturbed? From 1869 to 1873 the number of national banks increased from 1619 to 1968; capital and surplus increased from $548,000,000 to $662,000,000; and loans from $686,000,000 to ^ Sprague, supra, pp. 155-156. ^ Ibid. ' The analysis above is a summary of that advanced by Professor Sprague in his excellent monograph, supra, p. 4 et seq. National banks were authorized in 1863 and for a time there were compara- tively few state banks. CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES 237 $926,000,000. The increase of thirty-five per cent in loans is not considered unsafe in view of tw6 facts: first, $114,000,000 addition had been made to the working capital; second, eighty-nine per cent of the new banks were established in the South and West, which were poorly supplied with banks. ^ Finally, it should be noted that in New York, where the railroads were largely financed and where the failures occurred which precipitated the crisis, there was strikingly little loan increase [from 1869 to 1873], only $21 ,000,000 — from $174,000,000 to $195,000,000. The conclusion seems clear that the national banks cannot be held very largely responsible for creating unhealthy conditions by an unwise policy of rapid loan expansion during the year immediately preced- ing the crisis of 1873.2 The general causes which led to the disturbances [in 1873] were so plain as to eliminate from attention those exceptional features which are often mistaken for the true causes. There was an enormous absorption of cir- culating capital in fixed capital. Railways, as well as docks, buildings, and factories had been constructed on an unprecedented scale. All the equipment for fu- ture production was increasing at a more rapid pace than ever before. In these expenditures we have the effect of capital invested for objects not immediately remunerative. The opening-up of wide areas of terri- tory in the West for settlement by farmers, while greatly increasing agricultural production, rendered less valuable, in some cases almost useless, very large tracts near to the Atlantic seaboard. . . . Railroads preceded settlement, while in previous eras they had followed it.^ ^ Sprague, supra, p. 4 et seq. * Ihid., p. 4 ef »eg» * Burton, supra, p. 280. 238 PRACTICAL BANKING The depression continued till 1879. It was a period of the blackest despair. The process of readjustment was slow because development had run so far ahead of demand. Production seems to have had a uselessly large expansion. After 1879, however, the country arose, shook off the dust of depression, and, with one or two growing-pains, leaped and bounded until 1893. VI. PANIC OF 1884 AND THE FINANCIAL STRINGENCY OF 1890^ The panic of 1884 was in the nature of a finan- cial spectacle and did not involve all the funda- mentals of an economic crisis. There were num- erous failures and general business was for a time seriously threatened. On May 5, the Marine Bank of New York closed its doors; shortly afterward occurred the failure of the Metropolitan Bank. Great excite- ment and uneasiness attended the exposure of a group of bankers and their methods. Money went to one per cent a day; country banks called for their deposits and it was hard to get credit on any security. Clearing-house loan certificates were successfully used to save the day. The causes for the panic may be found in two situations: first, a general decline in business activity in 1883, following four years of economic expansion. Reductions of stocks and the failure of several railroads were subsequent to the panic. * Whereas, for the purposes of this chapter "panic" and "crisis" are synonymous, "panic" is used in this section because it better describes the financial exhibition. "Panic" is frequently used in the section on the crisis of 1907 to refer to the spectacular money scramble, the details of which are fuller there than elsewhere. CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES 239 Second, the money question. The addition of two milHon silver dollars each month to the circula- tion alarmed many European investors, who sold their securities. The tlnited States exported immense quantities of gold — nearly $30,000,000 in March and April, 1884.^ The successive breaks in the stock market brought the failure of broker- age houses, with their creditor banks in their wake. It was known on May 13 that the president of the Second National Bank had stolen $3,000,- 000 worth of securities. But the New York banks met every demand, with the exceptions noted; the panic was local- ized, and, in a few weeks, past. The crisis in Europe in 1890, characterized by the great Baring failure in London, was converted into a financial stringency in this country. Had it not been for the excess of $68,000,000 of exports over imports that year, which cut down the export of gold to $4,000,000, and the inflation of the currency with silver certificates — had it not been for these two factors, we should probably have had the crisis three years earlier. Secretary Windom, between June 30 and Sep- tember 30, disbursed more than $98,000,000 in redeeming unmatured government bonds. This was his method of relieving the stringency. Fail- ures occurred in November. The Treasury was empty. VII. THE CRISIS OF 1893 During the period of prosperity preceding the 1893 crisis, the country was on fire with "get- ^ Sprague, supra, p. 109. 240 PRACTICAL BANKING rich-quick" schemes involving speculation in mineral and farm lands, oftentimes cases of pure fraud. Suburban development began in the shape of city "additions" which have become familiar to American eyes. Railroads continued to be built, though not to the extent which character- ized the previous period. But electrical develop- ment created a demand for electric street railways. It was a period "booming" with optimism gone wild. Outwardly, the country was very prosperous. The English crisis of 1890 made itself distinctly felt in the United States in 1893. After 1890 Europeans began withdrawing their loans and returning American securities at an alarming rate. Only the exportation of large crops in 1891 and 1892, somewhat offsetting the European balance, deferred the crisis. In 1891 there was, on the international ledgers, a balance in favor of Europe of about $68,000,000, and in 1893 this balance — still in favor of Europe — was about $87,000,000. The withdrawal of this capital — even the mere sus- pension of the process of reinvesting it — meant heavy payments in gold or merchandise to Europe without compensation in returning gold or goods. The with- drawal of a large part of this productive loan (it was estimated at about two billion dollars) was the price the United States were called upon to pay for political manoeuvres which aroused the fear that they would abandon the gold standard and make silver the basis of their monetary system.^ Why did silver play a part? In 1890 the Sher- man Silver Bill was passed, providing for the * Conant, supra, p. 670. CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES 241 purchase, by the Secretary of the Treasury, of 4,500,000 ounces of silver each month, and the issue therefor of Treasury notes of full legal tender value. These were redeemable in silver or gold, at the option of the Secretary of the Treasury. The Treasury interpretation of the law was, redeemable in "gold or its exact equiva- lent." This, of course, obliged the Government to pay practically gold for the redemption of these certificates. At this time the result of Secretary Windom's action in buying unmatured bonds instead of depositing the funds in the national banks was realized. The Treasury was so nearly depleted that it was not prepared to withstand the demands made on it. The Sub-Treasury in New York reversed its custom of paying for its clearings in gold, which had come to be looked upon by the banks as a means of maintaining their gold supply.^ In 1890 the Treasury began paying its clearings with Treasury notes, and in 1891 it " increased the use of the older United States notes and held on to the gold reserve." The result was, the banks presented government notes for redemption in gold.^ 1 Dewey, supra, pp. 443-44. In the fiscal year 1889-90, the bal- ances paid in clearings amounted to $230,000,000, and in 1890-91 to $212,000,000. * Conant, supra, p. 671. The total gold in the Treasury on June SO, 1889, was $303,504,319, of which $186,711,560 was in reserve; on June 30, 1890, the total was $321,612,424, of which $190.2.32,405 was in reserve; on June 30, 1891, the total was $238,518,122, of which $1 17,667,723 was in reserve; on June 30, 1892, the total was $255,577,705. of which $114,342,367 was in reserve; on June 30, 1893, the total was $188,455,432, of which $95,485,413 was in reserve. The reserve continued to decline until June 30, 1894, when it was $64,873,025. The difference between the total gold and the gold reserve represents the gold cerliOcates outstanding. 242 PRACTICAL BANKING The net gold exports from the United States from June 30, 1890, to June 30, 1893, were more than $156,000,000. All this time the Sherman law was causing four and a half million ounces of silver to be bought and placed in circulation each month. A special session of Congress was called by- President Cleveland for August 7 for the purpose of repealing the Sherman Silver Act. It was high time some governmental action were taken regard- ing the situation, as we shall see. It was October 30 before the repeal of the silver law could be forced through the Senate. President Cleveland's appeal to the national banks for assistance re- sulted in more than $7,000,000 in gold being added to the Treasury's reserve in June and July. Meanwhile, Bradstreet's reported 905 failures in April, 1893, as compared with 703 in April, 1892; in May they increased to 969. On May 9, the Chemical National Bank, and on May 11, the Columbia National Bank, both of Chicago and each capitalized at a million dollars, closed their doors. Private and state banks followed; as did business firms and corporations. Credit waw«" paralyzed.^ Banks all over the country refused to pay checks except in certified or clearing-house checks. Currency was at a premium. Philadelphia banks issued clearing-house loan certificates on June 16; New York followed on June 21; Boston and Baltimore, on June 27. New York, Philadelphia, Boston, Baltimore, and Pittsburg together issued ^ Conant, supra, p. 674. CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES 243 $63,000,000 of clearing-house certificates.^ Banks all over the country pursued the same course. There were during the year failures of 15 national banks, 172 state banks, 177 private banks, 47 savings banks, 13 loan and trust com- panies, and 6 mortgage companies. Depositors were tremendously frightened. The clearings were the lowest since 1885. A general depression followed the crisis. The output of pig iron decreased from 9,157,000 tons in 1892 to 6,657,000 tons in 1894. New railroad construction almost ceased. In 1894 there were 156 railways — operating approximately 39,200 miles — in the hands of receivers, among others, the Erie, Northern Pacific, and Union Pacific. One fourth of the country's railway capital was in bankruptcy. The commercial failures increased from 10,344, in 1892, with liabihties of $114,000,- 000, to 15,242, in 1893, with liabilities of $346,- 000,000.2 The problem of unemployment was acute and widespread. Food was distributed to the needy in the large cities. Labor strikes and riots char- acterized the distress in Chicago. The spring of 1894 was one of gaunt want. VIII. THE CRISIS OF 1907 The depression subsequent to the crisis in 1893 lasted three or four years. Industry, indeed, aroused itself feebly in 1895, but it was in 1897 that a genuine revival of activity came. The revival was not necessarily delayed by the presi- dential election in 1896, although the then pre- ' Conant, supra, p. 681. ^ Dewey, supra, p. 446. 244 PRACTICAL BANKING vailing lack of confidence in the retiring ad- ministration may have prevented the upward movement gaining cumulatively. Financiers and manufacturers, however, were generally pleased at the outcome of the election, and their optimism proved to be the stimulus the country needed. Exports of merchandise increased by leaps and bounds, from $882,606,938 in 1896 to $1,394,483,- 082 in 1900, and to $1,743,864,500 in 1906. ^ Imports rose, too; from $8.05 per capita in 1898, imports increased to $16.54 per capita in 1907.^ From 1897 to 1907 the United States experi- enced a corporate expansion hitherto undreamed of. The railroads were a conspicuous example. There was not a great increase in mileage as com- pared with other years, but improvements such as the construction of bridges, double tracks, stations, and the providing of better roadbeds, — new ballasting and grading, — the necessary addition to equipment of more and better engines, sleeping-cars, chair cars, vestibuled coaches, and thousands of new freight cars, — improvements of this kind called for an enormous outlay of capital, additional issues of stocks and bonds. In 1905 the steam railway securities outstanding in the United States amounted to the staggering figure of $12,600,000,000 par value. But the period was also notable for growth of enterprises laterally. Electrical supply plants, waterworks, improved sanitation, the building of great piers and dry docks, the construction of a giant navy, street railways, cotton manufactories, automobile factories, sky-scrapers, the expansion ' Conant, supra, pp. 698-99. ^ Ibid. CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES 245 of the great universities — these required a cor- porate organization themselves and gave rise to a horde of corporations to supply equipment. Manufacturing was promoted and protected, from steel girders to shoe buttons. There was no item of human demand which was overlooked. Jinrickshas were made in the United States and successfully sold in Japan in competition with centuries-old industry. So great was American energy and so astute the manipulation of prices that, under the beneficent provisions of a pro- tective tariff, certain Chicago hams were sold in Johannesburg, South Africa, cheaper than they could be bought here. New York saw a phenomenal real estate de- velopment after 1900; this boom found its way into other parts of the country. Mining and oil exploitation progressed — fortunes were made in legitimate and illegitimate projects. It is esti- mated that shortly before the crisis these inter- ests had outstanding over $3,000,000,000 worth of par value securities, ranging in prices on the market from ten cents per share to two hundred dollars. Gold production increased in the five years preceding the crisis at an average of over $371,- 000,000 per year. In the period from 1890 to 1897, as Mr. Conant observes, the gold output reached a mark more than equal to half the production of the four preceding centuries.^ This, of course, tended to raise prices and encourage speculative ventures. As the number of banks rapidly increases to supply the demand for credit accommodation, ' Conant, supra, p. 703. 246 PRACTICAL BANKING and even — when optimism is running high — precede the demand and further bolster optimism and the capitahzation of prospects, we shall not be surprised to note the increase from 1893, with 9492 banks having a capital of $1,091,800,000 and a surplus of $689,300,000, to 1906, with 17,905 banks having a capital of $1,565,300,000 and surplus of $1,558,900,000. In the same pe- riod bank notes increased from $155,100,000 to $510,900,000, and loans and discounts from $4,368,600,000 to $9,893,700,000. ^ Thus, the total banking capital increased in about the same ratio as loans and discounts. The great demand for credit made the increase in bank-note circu- lation profitable. Although in the case of national banks, the reserves bore a definite and, on the whole, satisfactory relation to gold, the laws regarding state banks and trust companies were lax, permitting, in most cases, an inadequate reserve and a reserve which might even be held in bank notes. As a matter of fact, in the years immediately preceding 1907, the liabilities of state banking institutions increased thirty-five times as rapidly as cash reserves, while bank notes increased two and one half times as rapidly as cash reserves. " As these bank notes are secured by evidences of the public debt and not to any appreciable extent by gold reserves, it becomes apparent how one form of credit was built upon another, until the whole fabric became a house of cards which a zephyr might topple in ruins." ^ ^ Re-port o/ the Comptroller oj the Currency, 1913. The figiires for surplus include also profits. * Conant, supra, p. 707. CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES 247 But after all, the bank conditions are but reflections of the business, commercial, and in- dustrial condition of the country. The fever of enterprise continued to fix capital more and more in permanent investments until a time came when there was no longer capital for expansion; then, to every one's chagrin, there was not enough to supply the demand for a continuance of mer- cantile transactions. Our monetary system did not provide a method for converting mercantile transactions into security for currency; in order to extend credit on mercantile transactions, banks must have a cash reserve or a currency reserve based ultimately on an outlay of cash. It is estimated that in 1905 there were outstanding securities in the United States, including the public debt, equal at their par value to $35,000,- 000,000.^ In the first six months of 1907 not less than $1,279,000,000 of new securities were authorized and put on the market.^ There began to be premonitions of a liquida- tion. Professor F. W. Taussig, in the spring of 1907, delivered an address before the Economics Club of New York on " Panics," in which he de- plored the fact that commercial banks had lost their ideal, which he said was to occupy a "judi- cial position, standing aloof from other business than that of banking proper." He said the tend- ency of the t>anks had been to become associated with investment houses and private firms promot- ing new business ventures, with trust companies and men whose primary business was other than that of banking. In May, Mr. F. A. Goddard, ' Conant, swpra, p. 702. ^ Financial Age, July 8, 1907. 248 PRACTICAL BANKING president of the Fort Dearborn National Bank of Chicago, said to the Missouri Bankers' Associa- tion: "What I want to get at is this: we are in somewhat of an epidemic of money-mad conta- gion and excitement. . . . These prosperous times have brought to the front all kinds of propositions and schemes for investment — some legitimate, some a mere chance, and some fakes." About this time Mr. Eugene V. Debs, the Socialist, pro- phesied an era of financial depression, to be at- tended, he said, "by great railroad strikes." On April 29, 1907, in an editorial, the Financial Age said : — When the course of values on the New York Stock Exchange first assumed a clearly established downward trend, the Financial Age ventured the opinion that a business recession was being discounted. During the past few weeks there has been a growing disposition on the part of commentators to take cognizance of certain happenings which previously they were in- clined to overlook entirely or else treat as matters of little importance. They now observe that several of our large railroad corporations are retrenching in many directions, canceling orders for new equipment, and modifying their plans for terminal and other improve- ments; it is remarked also that reports from iron and steel centers tell of a slight falling-off in the consump- tion of these products, while the market for copper metal is losing some of the remarkable strength that has characterized it during the past year or two. Deal- ers in automobiles and other luxuries, it is also ad- mitted, are doing a somewhat smaller business than formerly, while railroad earnings do not compare at all favorably with those of the corresponding period in 1906. CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES 249 Any of these developments, taken singly, may not indicate any general change in the state of trade, but collectively may quite properly be regarded as fore- shadowing a slackening in the speed with which our business machine has been driven in the last half- dozen years. On May 13 the same paper pointed out that rail- roads could borrow money for improvements only by paying extortionate rates of interest: — It is a striking commentary on the present state of their credit that the railroads cannot raise funds for extensions and improvements and for other purposes by the sale of stocks and bonds the same as in former years. The early months of 1907 saw the disintegra- tion of the real estate boom, especially about New York. Even new buildings were almost without tenants, and second mortgages, usually desirable, went begging. Bankers were warned by the financial papers to reduce their loans based on real estate, as the trying second part of the year would find this kind of security even harder to convert. The situation in the middle of the year was peculiar. Superficially conditions were favorable, there being lower rates for short-time and call money than for some time past. But long-time loans could only be made at high rates. Heavy exportations of gold were made to London and Paris and bank reserves were unusu- ally low as July 1 approached. Tightening money conditions continued throughout June and July. The Treasury withdrew $30,000,000 government deposits. Early July saw a bull effort to " boost" 250 PRACTICAL BANKING certain stocks on the market. About the same time James J. Hill spoke regretfully of national extravagance. The meager increase in savings banks deposits was cited. Some fright was caused in the New York Stock Exchange by the Administration's declaration that "trust-busting" would continue; it was heightened by the attacks on railroads in the South. There were distinct signs of a panic on the Exchange, although, in the face of unprece- dented slumps in prices, there were but three fail- ures on the Exchange in the first six months of 1907. It was felt in every circle that business trem- bled on the edge of an abyss. Wavering public confidence was assigned as the cause, and finan- ciers, as well as financial papers, endeavored by argument and persuasion, to allay fear. Mr. A. Barton Hepburn, then president of the Chase National Bank, said in June that, although credit had been used too freely, the country was in fine condition and that he believed the danger of a disastrous slump was past. Under title of " Two Kinds of Hysteria," the Financial Age, August 19, 1907, assured its read- ers that the hot August days were responsible for the uncertain conditions. It said : — When the silly season has passed and the autum- nal breezes sweeten the tempers of the corporation baiters and ease the brows of the Wall Street pessi- mists, they will realize that this is n't such a bad coun- try after all, and that it still has a good many genera- tions of prosperity ahead of it.^ ^ The attitude of bankers and financiers was sharply divided between those who were " pro- Administration " and those who were CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES 251 Toward the latter part of August, realizing what a strain the continued stringency would prove to business, Secretary Cortelyou began making deposits in banks and accepting as security state, municipal, and railroad bonds. At the same time the Curtiss-Leggett Company, shirt manufacturers, failed, on account of the money stringency, having assets of $3,000,000 against liabilities of only $1,100,000. Beginning with September there was a tone of ill-concealed fright among the most hopeful. The financial papers still attempted to coax investors back into the old confidence. " All will be well in sixty days." During the second week in October call loans in New York ranged from two and a haK to six per cent; time loans from six to seven per cent; commercial paper from seven to seven and a half per cent. In these two weeks there were twice as many failures as in the same period of 1906. According to Dun's Review, there were five times as many manufacturing failures in September, 1907, as in September, 1906. A series of bank failures precipitated the spec- tacular part of the crisis of 1907. The first intimation of a serious upheaval in New York was the failure of the Stock Exchange firm of which Mr. Otto C. Heinze was the head. In an effort to corner the copper market this firm was embarrassed by having cartloads of stock "anti-Administration." Jacob 11. Schiff, of Kuhn, Loeb & Com- pany, said the tightness was due to overcapitalization. Ex-Secre- tary of the Treasury Leslie M. Shaw said that economic legislation had destroyed public confidence. 252 PRACTICAL BANKING delivered to it; it suspended. There was a well- defined suspicion that Mr. F. Augustus Heinze, president of the Mercantile National Bank, was interested in his brother's ventures and that his bank was being "used" in this connection. Heinze's supposed allies — Messrs. E. R. and O. P. Thomas and C. W. Morse — fell into public distrust. Depositors began rapid withdrawals. Seven banks and a trust company, with capital and surplus of $21,000,000 and deposits of more than $71,000,000, were dominated by these inter- ests. Believing them unable to weather the storm the Clearing House Association agreed to help them out if Heinze, Morse, and the Thomases were eliminated. This was done; it was hoped on Sunday, October 20, that a panic had ceased to threaten. On Tuesday, however, the National Bank of Commerce refused to clear any longer for the Knickerbocker Trust Company, whose presi- dent was thought to be allied with the Morse interests.^ The result was a run on the Knicker- bocker Trust Company which — after paying out $8,000,000 in three hours — closed its doors. Runs followed on the Lincoln Trust Company, which was forced to suspend, and on the Trust Company of North America. Following several conspicuous commercial failures, such as some of 1 Some radical writers have suggested that the only trouble with Heinze, Thomas, and Morse was that they had formed a chain of banks too formidable to suit the "Wall Street crowd," and so were punished. Also, that the run on the Knickerbocker Trust Company was part of this plan, which included an effort of the United States Steel Corporation to obtain control of the Tennessee Coal, Iron and Railroad Company. See Twentieth-Century Socialism, by Edmund Kelly. CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES 253 the Westinghouse companies and the closing of the Pittsburgh Stock Exchange on October 23, other banks in New York closed for safety's sake. Meanwhile, the money scramble began. ^ Banks in New York were forced to try to call loans in order to be prepared for the demands of banks and individual depositors. The Secretary of the Treasury had a conference with Messrs. Morgan, Stillman, Vanderlip, Banker, and Rockefeller. The result was the deposit of $35,000,000 in na- tional banks in New York in four days. Stock Exchange prices were veritably collaps- ing. On Thursday, October 24, a syndicate, headed by the late J. P. Morgan, stated that they would stand under the market and placed $25,000,000 on call at ten per cent; on Friday $10,000,000 more was made available at fifty per cent, the high price being fixed to discourage speculation, as money ranged from fifty to one hundred and thirty per cent. Up to this time New York bank reserves had been but little dis- turbed, the government deposits about offsetting withdrawals. But on October 26, the banks began to restrict cash payments; clearing-house loan certificates were issued. The demand for cash started a currency premium the next week, prices, for small denominations especially, going to four per cent. Indeed, this premium continued * See the following news item: "Boston, Mass., Nov. 25, 1907. One of the city's banks made an arrangement with the Harvard Athletic Association to take over all the bills and silver taken in exchange for tickets to the Harvard- Yale football contest. A pre- mium of 3.8 per cent is to be paid which will net something over $1000 by the transaction. The arrangement was a result of the scarcity of currency here." 254 PRACTICAL BANKING the rest of the year. It offered an incentive for withdrawals of deposits. Two large failures oc- curred at this time, the Southern Steel Com- pany, capitalized at $25,000,000, and the Arnold Print Works, with liabilities of $8,500,000, the two employing about ten thousand men. Money stringency was assigned as the cause. On November 9 arrived the first shipment of more than $100,000,000 in gold, imported to relieve the money stringency. The banks had also in- creased their circulating notes at this time. But in the mean time the panic had seized the interior. Banks in most of the cities of over twenty-five thousand population suspended cash payments. The clearing houses stood guaranty on certificates.^ It is estimated that over $500,- 000,000 of substitute paper was issued.^ Those country banks, having no clearing-house affilia- tions, were likely to suffer most. Many failures occurred among them. Shipments of money to the West from New York continued. For the week ending October 19 these amounted to $4,400,000 ; the next week it was $16,300,000; the week of November 2 it was about $17,000,000, November 9 about $17,400,- 000, November 16 about $22,600,000, and so on till the last of December in gradually declining quantities. In the week ending January 4 the tide turned and $5,500,000 was shipped to New York. According to Mitchell ^ this was three 1 See chapter on the "Clearing House." ^ Dr. A. Piatt Andrew. ^ Mitchell, supra. Many of the interesting figures from now on are from this excellent work. CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES 255 weeks later than the usual turning of the tide. The New York banks supplied the country with $125,000,000 between the beginning of the panic and the first of 1908. Nevertheless, the reserves of the Clearing-House banks were never lower than 19.98 per cent of the deposits, the importa- tions of gold and the federal deposits having almost offset the loss of cash. Local drains were the real causes of the drop in reserves.^ Domestic exchange was paralyzed, New York drafts selling from sixty cents discount to ten dollars premium in different parts of the country, and being absolutely unsalable in San Francisco part of the time. As for foreign exchange, the ordinary rules applying were suspended. Drafts on London were bought when the export point had been passed, the reason prompting buyers being their ability to sell gold at a premium. Common stocks fell, as did preferred stocks and bonds, although not to so low a point. By the first of the year securities took a brighter outlook on life. In addition to the $35,000,000 syndicate pool to sustain the stock market, 1 Between September 30 and the first of the year almost $120- 000,000, representing money derived from importations of gold and Treasury deposits, was put into circulation. If this could have been used as a forty per cent cash reserve for emergency currency, further secured by commercial paper, $300,000,000 of new circulating notes could have been added, almost enough, together with $84,000,000 new national bank circulation, to have prevented the necessity of clearing-house loan certificates and the restriction of payments. And this would have been what might have been added merely from the addition to the supply of cash reserve in the banks. Under the new Federal Reserve Act some such arrangement will be possible. It would have had tiie added value of encouraging the discounting of commercial paper which suffered most in New York in the panic. 256 PRACTICAL BANKING New York national banks increased loans and dis- counts some $63,000,000 between August 22 and December 3, 1907.^ This increase was to replace the loans contracted by the trust companies and banks outside the Clearing House, and to prevent a further collapse of securities. Of the $63,000,000 $54,000,000 was of Stock Exchange origin, show- ing, as Mr. Mitchell observes, the lack of liquid- ness of the New York call loan. Reserves piled up in the country banks. Be- tween August 22 and December 3, New York City national banks lost $41,700,000, Chicago, $12,100,000; St. Louis, $5,800,000; and the other reserve cities $27,700,000, while the country banks gained $46,400,000. On December 3 re- serves in New York equaled 20.5 per cent (25 per cent par); in Chicago, 23.1 per cent (25 per cent par) ; in St. Louis, 19.6 per cent (25 per cent par) ; in other reserve cities, 12.9 per cent (12.5 per cent par); and in country banks 9.9 per cent (6 per cent par).^ Perhaps the panic could have been localized had New York bankers been able to meet all demands without restriction. But restriction inspired country banks with a zeal to provide for any disaster. Hoarding followed. In December most country banks had higher reserves than at the beginning of the panic. The question, of course, is, Could the New York banks have con- tinued cash payments? They did, to some extent, in 1873. They did not in 1907. Therefore, the ^ National banks outside of New York contracted loans and dis- counts about $156,000,000. ^ Sprague, supra, p. 305 et seq. CRISES IN THE UNITED STATES 257 practical question each country banker asked himself was. Can I afford to be less cautious than other bankers when I know the psychology of "panics" and "runs" and the like as I do? The failures drop thick and fast when the panic is past. The old financial battlefield is gory with the slain and, what is more, the trampled. And failures after the depression sets in are larger and more important. From 3635 failures in the last three months in 1907, bankruptcies increased to 4909 in the first quarter in 1908. What the depression has been since 1907 is common knowledge and common experience. The year 1914, with its elaborate preparations for currency rejuvenation and with large crops in prospect, and with the iron and steel industry showing distinct signs of " picking up," seemed destined to behold the general return of the country to prosperity. The European war has temporarily and artificially raised the price of provisions and made certain crops like cotton seem less profitable to their prospective owners. But notwithstanding the temporary embarrass- ment of agricultural lines and the shaky securities situation, the ultimate outcome of the European struggle will greatly redound to the benefit of this country. CHAPTER XX THE FEDERAL RESERVE ACT In this chapter our purpose is to indicate some of the more conspicuous currency shortcomings under the National Bank Act; to outhne the plan of the National Monetary Commission, and the Federal Reserve Act; and finally, to introduce criticisms of the new law — to point out what is to be expected of it and, chiefly, its advantages. Up to the time of the passage of the Owen- Glass Currency Bill in December, 1913, there had never been a financial system in the United States worthy of the name.^ The National Bank Act had, indeed, systematized bank notes and raised them to the level of a respectable and reliable currency, but otherwise it had not so worked as to coordinate banking operations; no definite system was produced. There were a few rules looking toward certain uniform practices in banking; the safety of the depositor and the standardization of the bank note were more nearly accomplished; but no scheme had been evolved to place banking in closer touch with agricultural and business activities. In fact, the tendency under the act was to encourage credit expansion on a basis of stock exchange quotations 1 The first and second United States Banks had, indeed, formed the basis of a quasi-systematic financial scheme, but they did not bear suflBciently close relations to banking in general to be alto- gether satisfactory. THE FEDERAL RESERVE ACT 259 rather than on actual business transactions; that is, banking came to have too direct a connection with the capitaHzed earning power (sometimes fancied and represented by speculation) of great corporations and too indirect a relation with pro- duction and consumption. This was a hardship on the corporations themselves, for no method was open to them for the free discount of paper representing the business they carried on. Of course, in times of an abundant money market, they could discount notes given for commercial transactions, but when prosperity had built up so gigantic a trade that money began to be short, as is shown in the chapter on "Crises," they had difficulty. This difficulty would have been obvi- ated could the banks have expanded their ability to extend credit by rediscounting these notes to some bank of issue. But no such bank was avail- able. The only method was the cumbersome pro- cess of issuing new circulating national bank notes, based on United States bonds. These, as we have seen, were less and less profitable to banks as times grew more prosperous. Then again, no satisfactory method was offered for the utilization of reserves. Each bank kept its own reserves. Reserves were individualized and to the extent to which they were deposited in reserve or central reserve cities, they ceased to have, in reality, more than one quarter of their face value, — that is, as actual reserves, — for reserve city banks kept only twenty-five per cent reserve against these deposits. When country banks, ^ in times of financial stringency, demanded * Country banks arc those not located in reserve or central reserve cities. 260 PRACTICAL BANKING their balances, they were hkely to want a large part of them, and, in time of panic, far more than twenty-five per cent of them. In short, reserve in the reserve cities was not a reliable reservoir. This was not because of the unwillingness of reserve bankers to pay, but because of their inability. In New York, for instance, the call loan grew up to provide an investment for funds for which payment on de- mand might be readily pressed. The amazing dis- covery has been that call loans have proved the most inflexible, the most unliquid, of loans. ^ Banks simply cannot afford to demand payment — in times of financial stringency — of all call loans; they support the Stock Exchange; they must not be contracted suddenly or securities would fall, the Exchange would topple to ruin, and collateral for most of the loans made in New York would be impaired beyond reparation.^ ^ Representative Bulkley, in the House of Representatives, Sep- tember 12, 1913, said: "Let us keep clearly in mind the distinction between a fixed investment and a commercial or liquid asset. Cor- porate stocks and bonds, lands and buildings, are fixed investments. However valuable they may be, their conversion into cash depends upon finding some one who believes that under all the circumstances it will be profitable for him to buy them as an investment. Growing crops, goods in process of manufacture or in transit, and mercantile stocks are commercial or liquid assets, generally speaking; certainly they are liquid to the extent that they are products on some stage of the way toward consumption. The sale of such products does not depend upon finding a willing investor and does not have to be forced, but comes about naturally in response to the ordinary neces- sities of mankind. Such assets constantly liquidate themselves, because, of necessity, they must be paid for when consumed." ^ As is shown elsewhere, most of the loans made in New York are based on Stock Exchange security. During the crisis in 1907 call loans were increased by the national banks in New York upward of sixty millions. THE FEDERAL RESERVE ACT 261 We have seen that under the National Bank Act there was no form of domestic loan which offered a means of expanding the currency by simple, direct operation. Currency was more or less fixed; at least, it had no rational relation to the agricultural and commercial needs of the country. The result was that, instead of the cur- rency expanding and contracting to fit the legiti- mate demands for loans, loans had to expand and contract to fit the volume of credit which the given amount of currency justified.^ Under the national banking regime the only kind of loan which tended, in time of financial stringency, to increase the volume of currency was "bills of exchange drawn against the ship- ment of products that may be termed the neces- saries of life, such as cotton, wheat, corn, flour, and other articles, shipped abroad." ^ At other times this category might be supplemented by finance bills and bills drawn for the payment of American securities.^ In the next place, an indictment may be drawn against the system before the passage of the Federal Reserve Act on the ground of making no positive and reliable provision, first, for any busi- ness man who, at any time, had merchantable commercial paper, and second, for the agricul- turist. It is not necessary to go into detail as to the ^ As will be seen from Mr. Noyes's analysis, mentioned in the chapter on "National Bank Notes," this form of currency was not coordinated with the upward or downward demand for credit. ^ From a speech of Senator Knute Nelson, in the United States Senate, December 11, 1913. ' See chapter on "Foreign Exchange."' 262 PRACTICAL BANKING first ground. Every man knows that there are times when the best commercial paper cannot be sold. The failures of many large solvent corpora- tions may be attributed to such situations. The reason is not far to seek and has already been hinted more than once. Business grows apace in times of prosperity until there comes a time when the banks cannot safely extend credit in a greater ratio to lawful money. Clearly, banks must either discontinue the expansion of loans and discounts or increase their cash supply. The only sure method to increase cash supply is by increasing circulating notes, but, as we have seen, the issu- ance of national bank notes is increasingly unat- tractive to the banks as times grow more booming. Plainly, some system was needed which would insure a sale for good, short-time, commercial paper at any time. Now as to the farmer. A member of Congress ^ in 1913 said eloquently: "The agricultural classes have always been compelled to pay a high rate of interest. In my district the farmers never could borrow more than forty per cent of values and the rate was from eight per cent up — mostly up. The poorer the man the higher the interest that is charged. In other words, if he is poor, he is going to be kept poor." But the plight of the farmer was due to the sys- tem. National banks were forbidden to make any loans on real estate. As to accommodation, during crop-moving time, that involved the fail- ure of the national bank currency to respond to seasonal demands. ^ Representative Quin. THE FEDERAL RESERVE ACT 263 Apropos of seasonal demands, Representative Bulkley, computation expert for the House Com- mittee on Money and Banking, said in a speech on September 12, 1913: — It happens that at the seasons when our great agri- cultural crops are harvested and moved, there is need for a larger amount of currency in circulation than is required at other seasons. This is only another way of saying that at these seasons the amount of transac- tions evidenced by the payment of cash or currency is larger in proportion to the credit transactions than it is at other times. It is easy to see that when large amounts of cash are drawn out of the banks to pay farm hands and for other purposes, the amount of reserve money held by the banks is reduced and hence their loaning power is impaired, and this is the explanation of the annual autumn money string- ency. The banks can to some extent protect themselves against paying out their reserve money by the issue of national bank notes, but inasmuch as these notes are based on the fixed amount of United States bonds bearing the circulation privilege, and the profitable- ness of their issue depends to some extent upon their being kept constantly in circulation without reference to the country's demand for currency, it is apparent that there can be no elasticity in the amount of such notes. In other words, the amount of our currency does not rise and fall in response to the need for it. It is most desirable that the amount of our currency should be made more elastic, because the seasonal demand for currency is a perfectly normal and natu- ral thing, and, as has been said, results only from the fact that at certain seasons it is necessary to do a re- latively large proportion of the country's business with currency. 264 PRACTICAL BANKING In summary, the principal defects of the cur- rency and credit system as worked out under the National Bank Act were: — (1) An inelasticity of the currency, bringing in its train all the dire consequences of financial stringencies and money scram- bles. (2) An ineffectual and antiquated use of our gold supply, which could never be concen- trated and moved freely from place to place as occasion demanded. (3) The tendency of bank reserves to dissolve in times of panic. (4) A lack of coordination of the banking oper- ations of the country. (5) The independent treasury system, which often caused millions of gold to lie idle in treasury vaults while business and agricul- tural interests cried for help. II A provision of the Aldrich-Vreeland Emergency Currency Act of May 30, 1908, created the National Monetary Commission, requiring it to make a comparative study of financial systems throughout the world and report to Congress a feasible scheme for the reorganization of the United States currency system. The Commis- sion's report was submitted to Congress on Jan- uary 8, 1912, and included a plan, familiarly known as the " Aldrich scheme," for a centralized coordination of the banking interests of the United States. The bill containing this plan was not passed, but it exhibits a step toward the THE FEDERAL RESERVE ACT 265 Federal Reserve Act of December, 1913, and so deserves a short exposition. The bill contemplated the erection of a Na- tional Reserve Association with fifteen branches, representing fifteen districts into which the coun- try was to be divided. Each district was to be subdivided into local associations consisting of at least ten banks representing at least $5,000,000 capital and surplus. Now, observe how the cen- tral control was to be built up. Three fifths of the directors of each local association were to be selected by member banks polling one vote each; two fifths were to be selected by the banks cast- ing one vote for each share of stock which they held in the National Reserve Association. (Each eligible bank in the country was authorized to subscribe to an amount of stock in the National Reserve Association equal to twenty per cent of its paid-up capital.) Now, the branches of the National Reserve Association were each to have a board of directors, to be elected by the local association in each district as follows : one half to be elected on a basis of one vote for each associa- tion, one third to be elected on a basis of the stock which the members of each association held in the National Reserve Association, and one sixth to be chosen by the directors already selected and to represent "the agricultural, commercial, industrial, and other interests of the district." From this intermediate stage thirty-nine directors of the National Reserve Association were to be elected as follows: fifteen to be elected, one by the directors of each hriincl\;fffeen more to be elected, one by the directors of each branch, fairly rcpre- 266 PRACTICAL BANKING senting the "agricultural, commercial, industrial, and other interests of the district" ; and finally nine more to be elected by the branches on a basis of one vote for each share which member banks held in the National Reserve Association. There were to be seven ex officio members of the "Big Board," the Governor of the National Reserve Association (also chairman of the board of directors), two deputy governors, the Secre- taries of the Treasury, of Agriculture, and of Commerce and Labor, and the Comptroller of the Currency. Now, the governor was to be appointed by the President, from a list of not less than three to be submitted by the board of directors of the Na- tional Reserve Association. He might be removed for cause by two thirds of the board. The two deputy governors were to be appointed by the board. The managers and deputy managers of the branches were to be appointed by the gover- nor and the manager was to be chairman of the board of directors of his branch. Thus it can be seen that a highly centralized authority was to be built up, almost beyond any governmental supervision, although the Govern- ment's funds and credit were to support it. It was this feature, together with the danger of a small clique of banks controlling the whole, which brought down upon the bill unmerciful criticism and led to the eventual construction of another bill along somewhat different lines. The purpose of the Aldrich Bill was, first, to provide an elastic currency based, not on govern- ment bonds, but on business transactions and THE FEDERAL RESERVE ACT 267 representing automatically liquidating assets, such as notes or bills of exchange given for the sale of commodities or manufactures; second, to provide an agency for regulating the flow of gold by discount rates; third, to standardize foreign exchange transactions. These in general are the purposes of the new Federal Reserve Act and will be more minutely discussed below. It is not profitable to go more fully into the details of the Aldrich Bill, as it was never enacted into law. There was a considerable feeling of suspicion on the part of legislators and of the public and a disinclination to entrust the national finances to a private bank; it was feared, with the substantial minority of the directors which "big banks" would be able to elect all the way up the scale, plus the influence which their size would give them in any event, that the bill made potential a "money trust" of the most secure and dangerous variety. It was compared to the well-known "holding company," except that here the " big banks" would hold the "hold- ing company" instead of the "holding company" holding the banks; which, after all, would be the most secure method. In the campaign of 1912 the Democrats went on record as opposed to this type of a central bank. In fulfillment of platform pledges they have enacted the Federal Reserve Act, which, in the large, is the work of Secretary of the Treas- ury McAdoo, Senator Owen, and Representative Glass. It is an improvement on the Aldrich Bill in general and has been hailed as such by a num- ber of leading economists. From the point of view 268 PRACTICAL BANKING of the business man and the farmer and of most banks, it offers immediate prospects of more favorable conditions, and after a few years of readjustment it will be just as advantageous to the reserve city, and, particularly, the central reserve city banks. A great many ideas have been borrowed from the Aldrich plan for the new law, and the striking differences consist in the composition and con- struction of the direction of the system. The Aldrich plan suggested a highly centralized bank- ing system, a highly centralized reserve, a highly centralized note-issuing power — almost entirely under the control of the banks themselves. The Federal Reserve Act provides for decentrahzed administration and decentralized reserves (to a limited degree), with a central supervisory and judicial institution. The Federal Reserve Act designated the Secre- tary of the Treasury, the Secretary of Agricul- ture, and the Comptroller of the Currency as an organization committee to make preliminary plans for the inauguration of the new system. Among their first activities was the division of the country into twelve regions, which should follow as nearly as possible "the convenience and cus- tomary course of business" and not necessarily state lines, and the indication of a city in each district to be the headquarters of the federal reserve bank of that district.^ But reserve and central reserve cities under the National Bank Act are not changed. The act contemplates a simpler system than * See Appendix m. THE FEDERAL RESERVE ACT 269 the Aldrich plan. There are twelve federal reserve banks, one in each of the districts. These banks are independent of each other and each does the actual business of a central bank in its district, rediscounting paper, making collections, carrying on a foreign business, discounting acceptances, and issuing, under the direction of the Federal Reserve Board, circulating notes, based on com- mercial transactions, and limited in amount only by a stated relation to the gold reserve. Federal reserve banks will establish appropriate branches in their districts. Above the federal reserve banks is a sort of supreme court and legislature of the system, the Federal Reserve Board, which super- vises and systematizes operations. The act requires all national banks and allows all state banks, fulfilling certain conditions herein- after recited, to enter the system. National banks failing to comply with these provisions within sixty days after the passage of the act ceased to act as reserve agents and those that failed to com- ply within a year lost their charters.^ Upon vote of fifty-one per cent of the shares of its capital stock a state bank, with sufficient unimpaired capital to become a national bank, may be converted into a national bank, with the privileges and obligations of such, provided it does not contravene state law. The Federal Reserve Board will prescribe further rules for the admission of state banks as members of the federal reserve system. A few provisions have been made by the Organization ' Only twenty-eight national banks failed to come in within sixty days. 270 PRACTICAL BANKING Committee. Applying state banks must observe the capital and reserve requirements for national banks; also the National Bank Law respecting the limitation of liability which may be incurred by any person, firm, or corporation, the prohibi- tion against the purchase of or loan on the stock of national banks, and the withdrawal or impair- ment of capital, or the payment of unearned divi- dends. State banks failing to conform to these regulations after admission to the system shall forfeit membership. Their stock shall be bought by the appropriate federal reserve banks and canceled. Each bank entering the federal reserve system must subscribe a sum equal to six per cent of its paid-up capital and surplus in the capital of the federal reserve bank in its district. Of this, one sixth is payable on call, one sixth in three months thereafter, and one sixth in six months there- after. The remainder or any part of it is subject to call by the Federal Reserve Board. Stock sub- scriptions must be paid in gold or gold certificates. No federal reserve bank can begin business with less than $4,000,000 capital, divided into shares having a par value of $100. If the subscrip- tions to the stock of any federal reserve bank, in the opinion of the Organization Committee, are insufficient, the public may be permitted to sub- scribe in blocks not greater than $25,000 to one subscriber; if they are still insufficient, such a quantity as is necessary shall be allotted to the United States to be disposed of for the benefit of the United States at not less than par. Only stock held by member banks may vote. The shares of THE FEDERAL RESERVE ACT 271 member banks may not be transferred or hypothe- cated. The capital stock of the federal reserve banks will automatically increase or decrease as members are admitted or dropped. The Comptroller of the Currency designated five applying banks in each reserve district to execute the organization certificate of the appli- cant banks. When this certificate was filed and approved, the federal reserve bank of that dis- trict became a body corporate with the ordinary powers of a corporation and others hereinafter mentioned. Each federal reserve bank is to be governed by a board of nine directors to be known as Class A (with three directors) , Class B (with three direct- ors), and Class C (with three directors). Class A and Class B directors are to be selected — by preferential ballot — by the member banks, the sole distinction between these classes being that Class A directors may, and probably will, be bankers, while Class B directors must be ac- tively engaged "in commerce, agriculture, or some other industrial pursuit." Class C directors are appointed by the Federal Reserve Board ; two of each group of three must be men of tested banking experience. Directors of the federal reserve banks hold ofiice three years, provided that the first groups of directors so arrange their terms that one director of each class shall be selected each year. One of Class C directors shall be designated by the Federal Reserve Board as chairman of the board of directors of his bank and as federal reserve agent. Another Class C director shall 272 PRACTICAL BANKING be designated as deputy chairman and deputy federal reserve agent. The federal reserve agent shall maintain a local office of the Federal Reserve Board and shall act as its official representative in performance of the functions conferred on it. He shall receive a compensation, fixed by the Federal Reserve Board and paid by the federal reserve bank.^ For the convenience of business, the federal reserve banks are authorized to establish branches where they seem appropriate. Each branch shall have seven directors, three selected by the Fed- eral Reserve Board and four by the parent bank, one of the latter to be designated as manager. Each group of directors shall hold office during the pleasure of the board appointing it. Federal reserve banks are expressly exempted from all taxation whatever save tax on real estate. After paying necessary expenses of operation, federal reserve banks may pay dividends of six per cent per annum and no more. The remainder of the net earnings shall be divided equally be- tween the bank's surplus account and a franchise tax payable to the United States. When the sur- plus reaches an amount equal to forty per cent of the capital of a federal reserve bank, then the entire net earnings, after paying dividends, shall be transferred to the United States as a franchise tax. To unify the operations of the federal reserve ^ The act is silent concerning the fixing of the salary of the deputy federal reserve agent, and apparently it is to be done by the re- serve bank, although it would seem more regular for it to be fixed in the same manner as that of the federal reserve agent. THE FEDERAL RESERVE ACT 273 banks, there is set up the Federal Reserve Board, with headquarters in Washington. It consists of seven members, namely, the Secretary of the Treasury, the Comptroller of the Currency, and five appointees of the President of the United States, who shall, after the first group is so arranged that one term expires every two years, hold office for ten years. The five appointees receive annual salaries of $12,000 plus actual traveling expenses. The Comptroller of the Cur- rency is to receive $7000 additional for his ser- vices on the board. Appointed members of the board may be removed by the President for cause. That vir- tually means that they hold office, within the limitation of their terms, during good behavior. In Congress a bitter strife was waged over the composition of the board, a certain faction trying to prevent the creation of a "money trust" and another endeavoring to obviate a "political ma- chine." Theoretically, both contingencies have been largely avoided.^ It is provided that the Secretary of the Treas- ury will not lose any prestige. In the first place, he is ex officio chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, and, in the second place, wherever his authority apparently conflicts with some power delegated to the Federal Reserve Board, it is provided that this power shall be exercised sub- ject to his control. ^ It is worth while noting that the Aldrich plan proposed to char- ter the National Reserve Association unqualifiedly for fifty years, while the Owen-Glass Act incorporates federal reserve banks for twenty years unless they be dissolved by Congress or forfeit their charters. 274 PRACTICAL BANKING A novel feature of the system is the creation of the Federal Advisory Council, consisting of twelve members, one elected by each federal reserve bank. The powers of this body include the right "to call for information and to make recommendations in regard to discount rates, rediscount business, note issues, reserve condi- tions, in the various districts, the purchase of gold or securities by reserve banks, open-market operations by said banks, and the general affairs of the reserve banking system." The principal powers of the Federal Reserve Board are as follows : — (1) To examine federal reserve banks and member banks and to publish weekly reports as to the condition of federal re- serve banks. (2) To permit or require, on the affirmative vote of five members of the board, federal reserve banks to rediscount the discounted paper of other federal reserve banks at rates of interest to be fixed by the board. (3) To suspend for not more than thirty days, with possible extensions of fifteen days, reserve requirements. (4) To supervise the issuance and retirement of federal reserve bank notes. (5) To remove any officer or director of any federal reserve bank for cause. (6) To suspend and administer the business of any federal reserve bank for the violation of any provisions of the Federal Reserve Act. (7) To grant national banks the privilege of doing a trust company business. THE FEDERAL RESERVE ACT 275 (8) To supervise and determine the discount rates to be observed in federal reserve banks. The federal reserve banks have, in tabular form, the power : — (1) To receive deposits from member banks or the United States; or, purely for exchange purposes, from other federal reserve banks. (2) To discount, on the indorsement of a mem- ber bank, notes, drafts, and bills of exchange arising out of actual commercial transac- tions; "that is, notes, drafts, and bills of exchange issued or drawn for agricultural, industrial, or commercial purposes," the Federal Reserve Board having the right to define eligible paper, provided no paper based on staple agricultural products or other goods, wares, or merchandise shall be barred and no paper secured by stock or bonds, save United States bonds, shall be eligible. Such discounts shall have not exceeding ninety days to run. But paper issued for agricultural purposes or based on live stock, with not more than six months to run, may be discounted at a rate set by the Federal Reserve Board. (3) To discount acceptances based on the exportation or importation of goods, pro- vided the acceptances have no more than three months to run and are indorsed by a member bank. (4) To buy and sell in the open market cable transfers and bankers' acceptances. (5) To buy and sell the notes and bonds of the 276 PRACTICAL BANKING United States and "bills, notes, revenue bonds, and warrants with a maturity from date of purchase of not exceeding six months, issued in anticipation of the receipt of assured revenues by any State, county, district, political subdivision, or munici- pality in the continental United States, including irrigation, drainage, and recla- mation districts, such purchases to be made in accordance with rules and regulations prescribed by the Federal Reserve Board." (6) "To establish from time to time, subject to review and determination of the Fed- eral Reserve Board, rates of discount to be charged by the federal reserve bank for each class of paper, which shall be fixed with a view of accommodating commerce and business." (7) To buy and sell, through foreign agencies, bills of exchange arising out of actual com- mercial transactions which have not more than ninety days to run and which bear the signature of two or more responsible parties. The act permits the Secretary of the Treasury to deposit all government monies, except the redemption fund for national bank notes and federal reserve notes, in the federal reserve banks, reserving for him, however, the privilege of using member banks as depositories. One of the greatest improvements which the act endeavors to bring about is the issuance of federal reserve notes based on commercial paper. The Federal Reserve Board is to have general THE FEDERAL RESERVE ACT 277 charge of this operation and will pass on applica- tions from federal reserve banks for federal reserve notes. These notes may be issued in denominations of $5, $10, $20, $50, and $100, and the notes of each federal reserve bank shall have a distinctive mark. In the matter of issuing notes, the federal reserve agent in each federal reserve bank shall act as representative of the Federal Reserve Board and receive from the applying bank col- lateral in amount equal to the sum of notes applied for. At any time the Federal Reserve Board may require additional security. The col- lateral eligible are the notes and bills, accepted for rediscount from member banks, covering com- mercial, agricultural, or industrial transactions, and acceptances based on the exportation or importation of goods, all to have not exceeding three months to run. These federal reserve notes are receivable by national and member banks and federal reserve banks, and for all taxes, customs, and other public dues. They are redeemable in gold at the Treas- ury or in gold or lawful money at any federal reserve bank. Behind them is pledged the credit of the United States. Every federal reserve bank must keep a gold reserve of forty per cent against all outstanding federal reserve notes, including such an amount as the Secretary of the Treasury shall deem necessary (though not less than five per cent) to be deposited in the Treasury for redemption purposes. This reserve requirement is the only restriction of the amount of outstand- ing federal reserve notes. 278 PRACTICAL BANKING The notes of one federal reserve bank, when received by another, shall not be paid out again, but shall be sent for credit or redemption to the bank through which they were issued. "Every federal reserve bank shall receive on deposit at par from member banks or from federal reserve banks checks and drafts drawn upon any of its depositors, and when remitted by a federal reserve bank, checks and drafts drawn by any depositor in any other federal reserve bank or member bank upon funds to the credit of said depositor in said reserve bank or member bank.'* The Federal Reserve Board shall from time to time fix collection rates to be charged by mem- ber banks for items cleared through the federal reserve banks. These provisions will be spoken of a little later. The act further provides for the retirement of national bank circulation. The bonds represent- ing this circulation may, in the discretion of the Federal Reserve Board, be allotted to the federal reserve banks in due proportion, which shall form the basis of a note issue for these federal reserve banks, subject to the ordinary conditions for national bank notes. The federal reserve banks, however, may see fit to exchange these bonds with circulation privilege for thirty-year three per cent United States bonds and one-year gold United States notes (three per cent) — not more than half of the amount to consist of the thirty- year bonds. The holders of the one-year gold notes are obligated for thirty years to buy, at each expiration of these notes, an equal amount of one-year gold notes of the United States. THE FEDERAL RESERVE ACT 279 The nature of reserves under the new reserve system will best be comprehended by an examina- tion of the accompanying tables. As will be seen, it is provided that reserves on deposit in reserve city banks under the old National Bank Law are to be withdrawn gradually through three years. During those three years, the difference between what is carried in a bank's vaults and in the federal reserve bank and the amount of reserve required may be carried in reserve city banks, or in the federal reserve banks, or in the member's own vault — all or any part of it. It will be seen that, in the case of country banks and reserve city banks, the amount to be carried as reserve with the federal reserve banks increases from two twelfths to five twelfths and from three fifteenths to six fifteenths respectively. Thus the remainder — or optional part — decreases. These changes take place in periodic installments dur- ing the first three years. At the end of three years, reserves will be arranged as follows: Country banks will carry twelve per cent reserve on demand deposits and five per cent on time deposits,^ four twelfths of which will be in their vaults, five twelfths with their appropriate fed- eral reserve banks, and the remaining three twelfths either in their own vaults or in the Federal reserve banks. Banks in reserve cities will carry fifteen per cent reserve on demand deposits and five per cent on time deposits, five ' " Demand deposits within the meaning of the act shall comprise all deposits payable within thirty days, and time deposits shall com- prise all deposits payable after thirty days, and all savings accounts and certificates of deposit which arc subject to not less than thirty days' notice before payment." 280 PRACTICAL BANKING 'cc eft w O C 0-P.B, 0) u o « Pi ii I- ti CT' a> a> « ^ 53 in CO P5 Q W « B C 1^ H < e w PS C5 o < tn a 5.^ a" -, Cj OI a >.3 rt" 'n ^o£ ^aj_c h > !« a Q) +j 3 v: a O Oj Cj o « u a ei w T tn ore*- O O a +J 4J tn'S ^■^ K? c >i j^ 1—* o n_^ C3 o! O) -, a 3 a a H si a a o o sa 1-1 ££ 4) 0) tn tn jj St ei 10 < o •28 a t. a fl 11 o ■" o nj a) in ^ ■d-d rc en %_'^«— >• 0) CI \fi 00 a^ ^^[^ t— I ei 10 £"s^ o o 4J -^ tn ^■^ ^ a rtd S 3 3 .a a a aj s g ^ fc cS c« o M si H M a ^a? <«." « - "2 >>aj„ 5&2 a oj *j 3 m a o 11 a) UPJU M W CO ^iS^^ n • -M a ■ • CS ^ »," >> -,«•- a " ^ rt aj S-°& a >►.£ rt if .o^ ^^2 a a. .w 3 tn a o % a} OPSO THE FEDERAL RESERVE ACT 281 fifteenths of which will be in their vaults, six fifteenths with their appropriate federal reserve banks, and the remaining four fifteenths either in their own vaults or in the federal reserve banks. Banks in central reserve cities will carry eighteen per cent reserve against demand deposits and five per cent against time deposits, six eighteenths of which shall be in their own vaults, seven eight- eenths with their appropriate federal reserve banks, and the remaining five eighteenths either in their own vaults or in the federal reserve banks. ^ Federal reserve banks may receive as reserve from member banks such paper as it is permitted to discount in the open market, but in amounts not exceeding fifty per cent of any installment. Twice a year examinations shall be held into the condition of member banks. In addition to examiners appointed by the Comptroller of the Currency, the Federal Reserve Board may authorize state banking authorities to examine state banks in the system. The federal reserve banks may conduct examinations into the condi- tion of their members. Once a year the Federal Reserve Board shall cause each federal reserve bank to be examined. On petition of ten mem- ber banks, a special examination shall be held for a federal reserve bank. The two final sections of the act provide, first, for loans by banks other than those in central reserve cities on improved and unencumbered 1 It is provided that, where a state bank or trust company is re- quired by state law to keep a part of its reserve with another state bank or trust company, such state bank or trust company shall be looked upon as a national bank in reserve cities for a period of three years. 282 PRACTICAL BANKING farm land for not more than five years; and second, for the estabhshment, by member banks having a capital and surplus of $1,000,000, of foreign branches. Additional advantages arising out of the new act are: (1) the privilege to member banks of accepting drafts or bills of exchange based on the importation or exportation of goods, having not more than six months' sight to run; and (2) the privilege of organizing national banks without the purchase of United States bonds, which means the ability to organize without having to issue circulating notes. Ill It but remains to round off our resume of re- cent currency legislation with a few practical hints as to the operation of the new Federal Reserve Act. What will be the effect on banking methods? "V^Tiat will be the probable effect on business? These are sahent questions. By way of answer, it is the purpose to supplement our views with a diminutive symposium of writers on the subject. One of the first points noticeable to one familiar with foreign systems is the great dissimilarity of organization of the new American system to that of any foreign bank. We have not set up a central bank at all, and only in a limited way have we set up twelve cen- tral banks. Senator Aldrich was pleased to call his National Reserve Association a great clearing house. At most, the federal reserve system but coordinates and unifies the twenty-five thousand individual banks of the nation — it does not dis- THE FEDERAL RESERVE ACT 283 place them. It was the conscious purpose of the framers of the bill to observe the advantages of individual banking, such as adaptability to local needs, the investment of local capital, the interest of local citizens. Now, the Federal Reserve Act seeks to retain these great, though unobtrusive advantages of flexibility and local interest while securing the advantages of com- bined action in meeting strains. It centralizes reserves, it makes the currency elastic, and it provides for re- discounting of commercial paper; but it does not set up a central bank or remove the present restrictions upon branch banking. Accordingly, as reorganized under the new act, the American banking system will still diflPer from all the great foreign systems. ^ What will constitute "commercial paper"? That is one of the interesting and important ques- tions. Within very general limits the Federal Reserve Board is to define it. Mr. Stoddard Jess ^ thinks that "undoubtedly the Federal Reserve Board will be inclined to give a broad interpreta- tion of the term 'commercial paper' during the period when the banks and business community are adjusting themselves to the Federal Reserve Act, but will gradually narrow down their inter- pretation until only such paper will be accepted as possesses a self-liquidating quality, for only such paper can be considered as within the spirit of the act." We should be inclined to think that the board would accept only "self-liquidating" 1 W. C. Mitchell, "The New Banking Measure in the United States," The Economic Journal, March, 1914. 2 "Probable Changes in Bank Methods under the Federal Reserve Act," Financial Age, January 20, 1914. 284 PRACTICAL BANKING paper from the start, since it alone " can be con- sidered as within the spirit of the act." Some of the changes in banking requirements and practices will be : — (1) A material reduction of reserves, as we have seen, and the division of deposits — for reserve purposes — into demand and time deposits. It is also to be noted that certain parts of the reserves on deposit with the federal reserve banks may be paid in discountable paper within the meaning of section 14 of the act. On the other hand, the reserve requirement for federal reserve banks will be high. (2) The creation of a collection department for "transit" checks. "It seems clear that sections 13 and 16 limit the scope of the collection business of the federal reserve banks to the handling of checks of member banks, of the United States, and of other federal reserve banks." ^ This is more fully discussed later. (3) Loans on farm lands by national banks. (4) Rediscounting by the federal reserve banks. (5) The gradual retirement of circulating notes by national banks. (6) Open market operations by the federal reserve banks. (7) The limitation of dividends of the federal reserve banks and the consequent applica- tion of the reserve banks' energies to bet- tering banking accommodations. ^ Thomas Conway, Jr., " Probable Changes in the Assets of Member Banks under the Federal Reserve Act," Financial Age, June G, iai4. THE FEDERAL RESERVE ACT 285 (8) The provision for the aboHtion of the inde- pendent treasury system, save such part of it as is necessary to care for the redemp- tion funds. (9) The issuance of federal reserve notes based on the actual agricultural, commercial, and industrial needs of the country as evidenced by "commercial paper." (10) The creation of a standard discount rate. (11) The publication by the Federal Reserve Board of weekly reports of the condition of the federal reserve banks, by which business conditions in various parts of the country maybe more intelligently gauged. Under it [the Act] every solvent business man who can provide commercial paper of standard quality should be able to obtain bank loans, whatever be the condition of business, by paying the rate of dis- count. For practically every banking enterprise in the country can qualify to enter the system if it so desires, and every member bank can rediscount the paper it has bought with its federal reserve bank, and the latter at need may rediscount again with one of its fellows in another district.^ A revolution is to be worked in the collection of checks on member banks by the federal reserve banks. Under the old system — as we have seen in the chapters on " The Collection Department " and "The Transit Department" — checks were sent in indirect routes to take advantage of low exchange rates and to accumulate balances in certain cities. ' Mitchell, Economic Journal, supra. 286 PRACTICAL BANKING Checks on all member banks shall be received at par by reserve banks. Reserved banks will also receive at par or at a very slight charge, checks drawn on banks that are mem- bers of other districts, although it is not so stated in the bill. It is implied in the sentence providing that the reserve banks can exchange with one another checks in their respective districts.^ Mr. WoKe forecasts the collection of checks something like this: Member bank A sends its checks to the federal reserve bank for collection; they will immediately be credited to bank A, but will not count as reserve until paid. Checks against bank A will be charged to its account after they pass through the reserve bank to bank A. Bank A is thus saved the necessity of making remittances for checks against it. Unpaid items will be sent directly to the bank which deposited them with the reserve bank and a charge ticket will be sent to the reserve bank. Bank A's account is then credited with the unpaid items and the depositor's account is charged, and the incident is closed. Transfers of balances to and from correspond- ents will simply be made on the books of the fed- eral reserve bank; for banks will still have corre- spondents to collect checks on either member or non-member banks and to collect notes, drafts, etc. The cost of collection through the reserve banks, where it is charged, will be applied in a manner quite the opposite of the present practice. The bank on which a check is drawn will pay the 1 O. Howard Wolfe, "Check Collection under the Federal Re- serve Act," The Chicago Banker, June 20, 1914. THE FEDERAL RESER\TE ACT 287 charges. Mr. Wolfe calculates that the total cost of collection will average about ten cents per one thousand dollars, and in time only haK that. This will prove an enormous saving to banks. As a result of the collection possibilities under the new act, checks, " passing at par or almost at par all over the country, tend to produce an ideal bank note." The last proposition to which we turn is. What effect will this truly "business man's law" have on business.'^ Under the old system, as we have said many times before, banking was too largely dependent on speculation. Rates of discount have been con- trolled, not by the demand for commercial dis- count, but by the call-money market. Further- more, commercial transactions suffered in times of crisis because bankers had to support the then inflexible call loan as far as possible. The Federal Reserve Act seeks to standardize commercial paper and thus to insure a response to the genu- ine industrial needs of the country. Under the heading of " How to take Advantage of the Law," Mr. Henry P. Willis ^ says: — If the business community contents itself with simply continuing its present methods of operations, it will derive great advantage from the law. It will find (1) that local banks will be able, by rediscounting the paper of local enterprises, to provide the funds needed by such enterprises in their operations; (2) that there will be no such wide fluctuations of interest rates, either geographically or from season to season, as now ' " Effect of Bank Act on Business," Rand-McNally Bankers' Monthly, February, 1914. 288 PRACTICAL BANKING exists : (3) that there will be no necessity of emergency measures to safeguard the country from the possible results of financial panic or stringency. [But] to get the full advantage of the system the business man needs to arouse himself to a new concep- tion of his functions and duties. He needs to bring his methods of borrowing and his view of commercial paper into harmony with European practice, to accustom himself to prompt payment of notes and bills without extended renewals, and to the putting of his business upon a short-term cash basis. He needs further to familiarize himself with the idea of banking in the larger senses as distinct from a mere note-shaving and stock-manipulating occupation, and to prepare to share actively in the management of the new reserve banks and their branches, in which important places have been reserved for him. As to what foreigners think of the new system, the Financial Chronicle quotes Mr. Moreton Frewen, a London financial writer : — At the close of 1913 London anticipated a bank rate on discounts of six per cent. It has fallen in a fortnight from five to three per cent. Why.? Why have consols jumped 5 points.'' The answer is the new American currency act. Here is Uncle Sam with the power of a hundred Morgans entering the bill-discounting busi- ness and prepared to do the world's business. There- ifore, every banker knows that stringency and con- traction have disappeared, and that a new day has dawned. The act is a bigger thing by all odds for the world's trade than the Panama Canal. The passage of the measure was a greater discovery than half a dozen African gold fields.^ ^ This quotation is given by B. D. Harris in Rand-McNally Bankers' Monthly, April, 1914, under head of " The Federal Re- serve Act." APPENDIX The following illustrations from the speech of Representative Seldomridge in the House of Represen- tatives, September 11, 1913, indicate, with a few minor changes, how the Federal Reserve Act proposes to lend an elastic currency: — Jones is a merchant who desires to borrow one thousand dollars from his bank in order to purchase goods for his fall trade. Under the operation of this bill he would take his note to his banker and request the loan of one thousand dollars for sixty days. The banker accepts his note and the transaction as far as Jones is concerned is closed until the note matures. Other merchants find themselves in need of funds and they, too, discount their paper with the banker. Later on the banker finds himself unable to meet the demand made upon him for loans, and in order to meet these de- mands, which are legitimate and for commercial purposes, he takes the notes made by Jones and other merchants to the federal reserve bank of his district and offers them for rediscount. The federal reserve bank, finding that the paper presented comes within the provisions of the law, accepts it for rediscount, taking the bank's indorsement as security. If the federal reserve bank finds itself unable to issue cur- rency for the paper without encroaching upon the reserve requirement of this bill, it will take the paper presented for rediscount to the Federal Reserve Board at Washington and request the issuance of Treasury notes (federal reserve notes) to the amount of paper presented. The Federal Board will grant the request if it is satisfied the security is sufficient, and will issue the Treasury notes upon the indorsement of the federal reserve bank. The transaction is a simple one and the borrowers have received the accommodation desired. 290 APPENDIX which has enabled them to purchase the goods for their customers and helped the producer to that extent. Let us take another illustration : It is harvest time in the West; farmers are bringing their wheat to the market and are anxious to secure currency with which to pay their debts which have accumulated during the winter and spring months. The resources of the banks have been taxed to the utmost and many bankers find themselves at the limit of their loaning power. Under the present law there is no place to which they can go for relief except to the large central reserve banks. It is possible that they may be able to find funds with which to supply their customers, but these are often procured at an additional interest cost; or it may be that they will find the funds in the city absolutely unavail- able, and then the cry goes up for help from the Treasury Department. But what will happen in this crop emergency under the present bill? The agricultural bank will find ample facilities for the rediscount of its agricultural paper and the stress upon our banking institutions at times of crop move- ment will be largely relieved. It is a strange paradox that a wealthy nation like ours should find itself annually in a con- dition of financial inability to meet the needs of our agricul- tural sections. The currency which will be issued against the paper described in the bill will have back of it several guarantors; First, it has the liability of the original maker; second, it has the indorsement of the local bank, which carries with it not only all of its assets, but also the double liability of its stock- holders; third, it has the indorsement of the federal reserve bank, which carries with it the assets of all the member banks, together with the double liability of their stockholders and also the assets of the federal reserve bank, including a gold reserve of thirty-three and a third [forty] per cent; and fourth, it has the guaranty of the general Government. II The appended clipping from the New York Times of March 4, 1914, shows how, under the provisions of the new Federal Reserve Act, the withdrawal of required reserves, of federal deposits (if carried out), and the payment of stock subscriptions to the federal reserve banks would affect the national banks of the three classes during the first year. It indicates that none of the three divisions (country, reserve, and central reserve) would, in the aggregate, have to rediscount paper to pay their share into the new reserve banks. COUNTRY BANKS Commercial deposits January 13, 1914 $2,982,076,000 Reserve required against same, 12 per cent $357,849,000 Savings deposits $755,914,000 Reserve required against same, 5 per cent 37,795,000 Total reserve required $395,644,000 Deposit in federal reserve banks, two twelfths of required reser\'e. . $65,940,000 Capital and surplus January 13, 1914, $994,066,000 : 3 per cent sub- scription 29,821,000 United States deposits January 13, 1914 34,264,000 $130,025,000 Withdrawals would be Two fifths from central reserve city banks $52,010,000 Three fifths from reserve city banks 78,016,000 $130,025,000 Present balances with reserve agents $524,688,000 Withdrawals 130,025,000 Leaving balance of $394,663,000 RESERVE CITY BANKS Commercial deposits $1,808,770,000 Less country bank withdrawals 78,015,000 $1,730/755,000 Reserve required against same, 15 per cent $259,613,000 Savings deposits $98,696,000 Reserve required against same, 5 per cent 4,934,000 Total reserve required $264,547,000 Deposit in federal reserve banks : three fifteenths of required reserve $52,!)0(),()66 Capital and surplus $447,856,000 ; 3 per cent subscription 13,435,000 United States deposiU 33,620,000 Payment account of reserve banks $99,970,000 Payment account of country banks 78,015,000 ToUl payments $177,985,000 292 APPENDIX Present cash holdings New requirement, six fifteenths of required reserve . Release Payment made — Cash From reserve agents. Total Present balances with central reserve agents . Withdrawals Leaving balance of CENTRAL RESERVE CITY BANKS $268,681,000 105,818,0 00 $162,863,000 $162,863,000 15,122,000 $177,985,000 $278,098,000 15,122,000 $262,976,000 Commercial deposits January 13, 1914 $1,579,645,000 Withdrawals — Country banks $52,010,000 City banks 15,122,000 Total withdrawals 67,132,000 Leaving $1,612,513,000 Reserve required against same, 18 per cent Savings deposits $1,244,000 Reserve required against same, 5 per cent Total reserve required Deposit in federal reserve banks ; seven eighteenths of required reserve Capital and surplus, $348,195,000 ; 3 per cent subscription United States deposits Payment required for own account Payment required for account of reserve banks. . Payment required for account of country banks . Total Present cash holdings, January 13, 1914 New requirement; eleven eighteenths of required reserve. Release Total payments required Free balance [$272,252,000 62,000 $272,314,000 $105,896,000 10,445,000 8,925,000 $125,266,000 15,122,000 52,010,000 $192,398,006 $429,198,000 166,41 8,000 $262,78bTob6 192,398,000 $70,382,000 RECAPITULATION Banks Capital Reserve U.S. Deposits Total payments Country . $29,821,000 13,435,000 10,445,000 $65,940,000 52,909,000 105,896,000 $34,264,000 33,626,000 8,925,000 $130,025,000 99,970,000 Central Reserve 125,266,000 Total $53,701,000 $224,745,000 $76,815,000 $355,261,000 HOW PAID Banks Country Reserve Central Reserve Total Cash payment By draft on reserve banks None $162,863,000 192,398,000 878,015,000 $355,261,000 $78,015,000 By draft on central re- serve banks $52,010,000 15,122,000 $67,132,000 m SCOPE AND STATISTICS OF RESERVE BANK DISTRICTS 1 District 1. Location of reserve bank, Boston. Capital at organization, $9,931,740; national banks in district, 446; area of district (square miles), 66,465; population of district, 6,557,841. Territory: Maine, New Hampshire, Vermont, Massachusetts, Rhode Island, and Connecticut. District 2. Location of reserve bank, New York. Capital at organization, $20,687,616; national banks in district, 478; area of district (square miles), 49,170; population of district, 9,113,279. Territory: the State of New York. District 3. Location of reserve bank, Philadelphia. Capital at organization, $12,993,013; national banks in district, 800; area of district (square miles), 39,865; population of district, 8,110,217. Territory: New Jersey, Delaware, and all of Pennsylvania east of western boundary of McKean, Elk, Clearfield, Cambria, and Bedford Counties. District 4. Location of reserve bank, Cleveland. Capital at organization, $11,621,535; national banks in district, 724; area of district (square miles), 183,995; population of district, 7,961,022. Territory: Ohio, all of Pennsylvania not in District 3, the counties of Marshall, Ohio, Brooke, and Hancock in West Vir- ginia, and all of Kentucky east of western boundary of Boone, Grant, Scott, Woodford, Jessamine, Garrard, Lincoln, Pulaski, and McCreary Counties. District 5. Location of reserve bank, Richmond. 1 From Trust Companies, April, 1914. 294 APPENDIX Capital at organization, $6,543,281; national banks in district, 475; area of district (square miles), 173,818; population of district, 8,519,313. Territory: District of Columbia, Maryland, Virginia, North Carolina, South Carolina, and all of West Virginia not in Dis- trict 4. District 6. Location of reserve bank, Atlanta. Capital at organization, $4,702,780; national banks in district, 372; area of district (square miles), 233,865; population of district, 6,695,341. Territory: Alabama, Georgia, Florida, all of Tennessee east of western boundary of Stewart, Houston, Wayne, Humphreys, and Perry Counties; all of Mississippi south of north- ern boundary of Issaquena, Sharkey, Yazoo, Kemper, Madison, Leake, and Neshoba Counties; all of the southeastern part of Louisiana east of western bound- ary of Pointe Coupee, Iberville, Assumption, and Terra Bonne Counties. District 7. Location of reserve bank, Chicago. Capital at organization, $13,115,925; national banks in district, 984; area of district (square miles), 176,940; population of district, 12,630,383. Territory: Iowa, all of Wisconsin south of northern boundary of Vermont, Sauk, Columbia, Dodge, Washington, and Osaukee Counties; all of the southern peninsula of Michigan; all of Illinois, north of southern boundary of Hancock, Schuyler, Cass, Sangamon, Christian, Shelby, Cumber- land, and Clark Counties; all of Indiana north of southern boundary of Vigo, Clay, Owen, Monroe, Brown, Bartholomew, Jennings, Ripley, and Ohio Counties. District 8. Location of reserve bank, St. Louis. Capital at organization, $6,219,323; national banks in district, 434; area of district (square miles), 146,474; population of district, 6,726,611. Territory: Arkansas, all of Missouri east of western boundary of Harrison, Daviess, Caldwell, Ray, Lafayette, Johnson, Henry, APPENDIX 295 St. Clair, Cedar, Dade, Lawrence, and Barry Counties; all of Illinois not in District 7; all of Indiana not in District 7; all of Kentucky not in District 4; all of Tennessee not in District 6; and all of Mississippi not in District 6. District 9. Location of reserve bank, Minneapolis. Capital at organization, $4,702,864; national banks in district, 687; area of district (square miles), 437,930; population of district, 5,724,893. Territory: Montana, North Dakota, South Dakota, Minnesota; all of Wis- consin not in District 7; and all of Michigan not in District 7. District 10. Location of reserve bank, Kansas City. Capital at organization, $5,594,916; national banks in district, 835; area of district (square miles), 509,649; population of district, 6,306,850. Territory: Kansas, Nebraska, Colorado, Wyoming, all of Missouri not in District 8; all of Oklahoma north of southern boundary of Ellis, Dewey, Blaine, Canadian, Cleve- land, Pottawatomie, Seminole, Okfuskee, Mcintosh, Muskogee, and Sequoyah Counties; all of New Mexico north of southern boundary of McKinley, Sandoval, Santa Fe, San Miguel, and Union Counties. District 11. Location of reserve bank, Dallas. Capital at organization, $5,634,091 ; national banks in district, 726; area of district (square miles), 404,826; population of district, 5,310,561. Territory: Texas, all of New Mexico not in District 10; all of Oklahoma not in District 10; all of Louisiana not in District 6; and the Counties of Pima, Graham, Greenlee, Cochise, and Santa Cruz in Arizona. District 12. Location of reserve bank, San Fran- cisco. Capital at organization, $8,115,524; national banks in district, 514; area of district (square miles), 693,658; population of district, 5,389,303. Territory: California, Washington, Oregon, Idaho, Nevada, and Utah, and all of Arizona not in District 11. I BIBLIOGRAPHY Address of President Wilson before Congress, June 23, 1913. 63d Congress, 1st Session, House Document 103. Aldrich, Nelson W. Speech before Economic Club, New York, on The Work of the Monetary Commission. 61st Congress, 2d Session, Senate Document 406. Andrew, A. Piatt. Statistics for the United States. National Monetary Commission Series, 61st Congress, 2d Session, Senate Document 570. Andrew A. Piatt. " The Banking Bill as it passed the House.'* Boston Evening Transcript, October 8, 1913. "Another Wilson Victory." World's Work, February, 1914. Bagehot, Walter. Lombard Street. Dutton, New York, 1910. Breckinridge, . "The Relation of State Banks and Trust Companies to the Federal Reserve Act." Trust Companies, May, 1914. Burton, Theodore E. Financial Crises. Appleton's, 1902. Cannon, James G. "The Clearing House." Columbia Uni' versity Lectures on the Currency Problem. Columbia Uni- versity Press, New York, 1908. Cannon, James G. Clearing Houses. National Monetary Commission Series, 61st Congress, 2d Session, Senate Document 491. Clare, George. The A B C of the Foreign Exchanges. Macmil- lan & Company, London, 1895. Conant, Charles A. A History of Modern Banks of Issue. Fourth edition, Putnam's, 1909. Congressional Record, 1913, September 9, 11, 12, 13, 15, 16, 18; November 10, 13, 17; December 8, 9, 10, 11, 12, 13, 15, 17, 18, 19. Conway, Thomas, Jr. "Probable Changes of the Assets of MemberBanks under the Federal Reserve Act." Financial Age, June 6, 1914. ** Currency Bill; how the Bill Operates; the History of the Bill." Outlook, January 3, 1914. 298 BIBLIOGRAPHY Davis, Andrew McFarland. The Origins of the National Banking System. National Monetary Commission Series, 61st Congress, 2d Session, Senate Document 582. Del Mar, Alexander. A History of the Precious Metals. London, 1880. Dewey, Davis Rich. Financial History of the United States. Longmans, Green, New York, 1903. Escher, Franklin. Elements of Foreign Exchange. Bankers' Publishing Co., New York, 1910. Federal Reserve Act. 63d Congress, 1st Session, Public Document 43. Financial Age, July 18, 1910. HamUn, Charles S. The Federal Reserve Act. New York Credit Men's Association, 1914. Harris, Beverly D. "The Federal Reserve Act." Rand- McNally Bankers' Monthly, April, 1914. "High Cost of Efficiency Experts." Banker's Magazine, May, 1914. Hulbert, E. D. "Inauguration of New Banking System In- volves Grave Problems of Control and Administration." Trust Companies, June, 1914. Jacobs, L. M. "The Federal Reserve Law of the United States of America." Journal of the Institute of Bankers, April, 1914. Jenks, Jeremiah W. "Central Reserve Bank with Branches." Rand-McNally Bankers' Monthly, February, 1914. Jess, Stoddard. "Probable Changes in Banking Methods under the Federal Reserve Act." Financial Age, June 20, 1914. Johnson, A. B. Treatise on Banking. Utica, 1850. Kay, Cullom W. Address before the American Institute of Banking, 1910. Koelsch, W. F. H. "Preventing Credit Inflation under the Federal Reserve Bank System." Trust Companies, Febru- ary, 1914. Letter from the Secretary of the National Monetary Com- mission. 62d Congress, 2d Session, Senate Document 243. Lipman, F. L. "Operation of Federal Reserve." Rand- McNally Bankers' Monthly, May, 1914. Margraff, Anthony W. hiternational Exchange. Fergus Printing Company, Chicago, 1903. BIBLIOGRAPHY 299 McLeod, Henry D. The Elements of Banking. Longmans, Green, London, 1891. Mead, Edward S. "The National Currency Bill." Lippin- cotfs, February, 1914. Mitchell, Wesley C, Business Cycles. University of Cali- fornia Press, 1913. Mitchell, Wesley C. "The New Banking Measure in the United States." Economic Journal, 1914. "New American Law; Organization Committee and Reserve Cities." London Times, April 14, 1914. "New York and the Federal Reserve Act." Bankers' Maga' zine. May, 1914. Noble, John A. "Europe favors the Establishment of American Branch Banks." Trust Companies, 1914. Noyes, Alexander D. History of National Bank Notes. National Monetary Commission Series, 61st Congress, 2d Session, Senate Document 572. Pa ton, Thomas B. "Postal Savings Banks." Journal of the American Bankers' Association, July, 1910. Patron, Maurice. The Bank of France. National Monetary Commission Series, 61st Congress, 2d Session, Senate Document 494. Poniatowski, Peter. " Is a Central Bank Inevitable ? " Trust Companies, March, 1914. Post Office Department. Sundry Documents regarding Postal Savings System, 1910-14. Publications of the National Monetary Commission (upward of sixty volumes and pamphlets). Report of the New York Clearing House Association for various years. Reports of the Comptroller of the Currency, 1873-74, 1893- 94, 1907-13. Robinson. Humphrey. A Simple Explanation of Modern Banking. Small, Maynard & Co., Boston, 1910. Sprague, O. M. W. Crises under the National Banlcing System. National Monetary Commission Series, 61st Congress, 2d Session, Senate Document .538. Statistical table. Trust Companies, April, 1914. Strauss, Albert. "Foreign Exchange." Columbia University Lecture on Currency Problem. Columbia University Press, 1908. 300 BIBLIOGRAPHY United States Statutes (National Bank Act, Emergency- Currency Act, Federal Reserve Act). Vanderlip, Frank A. "The Modern Bank." Columbia Uni- versity Lecture on the Currency Problem. Columbia Univer- sity Press, 1908. Vreeland, Edward B. Speech in the House of Representa- tives, February 6, 1912. Welldon, S. A. Digest of State Banking Statutes. National Monetary Commission Series, 61st Congress, 2d Session, Senate Document 353. White, Horace. Money and Banking. 4th edition. Ginn & Company, Boston, 1911. White, Horace. "The Currency Bill in the Senate." North American Review, January, 1914. Willis, Henry P. "Effect of Bank Act on Business." Rand' McNally Bankers' Monthly, February, 1914. Withers, Hartley. Money Clianging. Smith, Elder & Co., London, 1913. Wolfe, O. Howard. "Country Checks under the Federal Reserve Act." Trust Companies, June, 1914. Wolfe, O. Howard. "Check Collection under the Federal Reserve Act." The Chicago Banker, June 20, 1914. Youngman, Elmer H. "First Experience with Government Banking." Bankers' Magazine, May, 1914. INDEX Acceptance of long bills. See For- eign exchange, and Federal Re- serve Act. Aftalion, A., Essai d'une theorie des crises genirales el 'p^ri- odiques, 213, and note. "Aldrich scheme," a plan for a centralized banking system, 264 et seq.; description of con- trol and management, 265, 266; purpose of the proposed sys- tem, 266, 267. Aldrich- Vreeland Act, tax on cir- culation, 141; amendment by Federal Reserve Act, 141, note; passage, 156; notes issuable on other security than United States bonds, 156; national currency association, forma- tion and scope, 157; direction and management, 157, 158; application for additional cur- rency, 158; ratio of currency to security, 158; provisions for non-member banks, 159; total notes issuable under, 159; ob- jections to the scheme, 160. Andrew, A. Piatt, 177, 254. Antiquity of banking practices, 2; contrast of theories of con- servative and radical, 2, and note; Assyria, 4, 5, and note; Greece and Rome, 5, 6; Europe, 7 et seq. Assistant cashier, 43, 44. Auditing bank, 46. Bank, meaning of the word, 7, 8, and note. Bankers' long bills, 191-95; lev- elers of world interest rates, 191; illustration. 191-93; prof- its arising from interest and ex- change, 193-95. Bank functions, antiquity of loan- making, 3 et seq.; a credit ex- changing institution, 15, 16; lending of credit, 73. Banks not philanthropic institu- tions, 20. Banking in France, John Law's Banque Generale, 11; under Turgot, 12; Napoleon and the Bank of France, 12; figm-es for present Bank of France, 12, 13; notes, 146; French accom- modations for foreign corres- pondents, 208. Banking in Germany, Reichs- bank, 11; other banks of issue, 11; notes, 146; accommoda- tions for foreign correspond- ents, 208, 209; Filialen, 208. Banking in Italy, 209, 210. Banking in the United States, be- fore 1781, 13; Bank of North America, its purpose and foun- der, 13; First Bank of the United States, 14, 219; Presi- dent Jackson and the Second Bank of the United States, 14, 223; state banks, 1832-37, 15; death of the central bank under Pennsylvania law, 15; New York safety fund, 15; indepen- dent treasury, 15; national banks, 15; growth of national banks, 145; state bank.s, 1811- 18, 223, 228, 229; national banks and crisis of 1873, 236, 237; New York banks in 1873, 235, 230. Bank of Amsterdam, formation, how governed, nature of assets, 9, 10. Bank of England, formed, 10; notes, 146; its functions, 200- 08. 302 INDEX Bank of Hamburg, 11. Bank of Netherlands, 10. Bank of Venice, origin and func- tions, 7. Bank ledger. See Reciprocal ac- counts. Bank post remittances, 185. Bankrupt, alleged meaning of word, 7, 8. Baring failure, 239. Beveridge, W. H., Unemploy- ment, 213, note. Bibliography, 297-300. Bills of exchange. See Foreign exchange. Bill stamp, 192. Branch banking in England, 208. Bulkley, Representative, 260, note; 263, 291. Burton, Theodore E., Crises and Depressions, 219, and note; 228, 229. Business poorly accommodated under National Bank Act, 261- 63. Cable transfers, 194-95. Canals, 222. Cannon, James G., Clearing Houses, 162, 170, note. Capital stock, general consid- eration, 29; why it should be widely distributed, 29; account on general books, 118; of na- tional banks, 137. Cashier, nature of his functions, 43; signing checks and other documents, 44, 45, 48; loan- granting powers, 48; expense items of the bank, 48, 49; rela- tion to public, 49, 50. Central bank. See Aldrich scheme, and Federal Reserve Act. Centralization of executive pow- er in bank, 35. Certificates of deposit, 127, 128. Certification of checks, 48. Charge slips, 116. Chase, Salmon P., 134, and note; his attack of financial situation a currency problem, 134, note. Checks, stopping payment, 57, 58; informahties, 63, 65. Circulating notes. See National Bank notes. Federal Reserve Act, and Aldrich- Vreeland Act. Clare, George, A B C of the For- eign Exchanges, 193. "Clean" bills, 196, note. Clearing houses, regulation of ex- change rates, 85, 171, 172; clearing-house certificates as reserve, 143; definition, 161; broadest functions, 162; New York Clearing House, 163; a morning's clearing, 163-65, 167; fines, 166; collections of credits and payment of debits, 166, 167; media for payment of balances, 167; statistics for New York Clearing House, 169; more special functions, 170, 171; possibilities, 170, note; loans to government, 171 ; mu- tual assistance of members, 172, 173; clearing-house loan certificates, 173-75, 236; other certificates, 175-76, 176, note; query as to the legality of these other certificates, 196, note; growth of clearing-house activ- ities in the United States, 176, 177. Cleveland, President, and the Sherman Silver Act, 242. Collateral security, 38, 76. Collection department, distin- guished from Transit depart- ment, 91; items handled in, 91 et seq.; utility of, 91; why some checks are sent through for col- lection, 92; indebtedness liquid- ated by drafts, 93, 94; collec- tion department notes, 94, 95; stocks, bonds, mortgages, etc., 95, 96; value of reciprocal ac- counts, 110, 111. Commercial letters of credit, definition, 198; benefits, 198; supposititious case, 199-202. Commercial long bills, nature. INDEX 303 195, 196, note; of advantage to bankers, 196, 197; kinds of bills, 197. Commercial paper, 76, 283, 284. Commissions for accepting fi- nance bills, 192. Conant, Charles A., History of Modern Banks of Issue, 5, 6, 8, 211, 220; 224, 228, 229, 231, 240, 241. 244. Conway, Thomas, Jr., 284. Cooperation between banks and their customers, 20. Correspondence of the bank, 44. Cortelyou, Secretary of the Treasury, 251, 253. Counterfeits, 55. Credit, lending of, the vital func- tion of banking, 73; balances required on lines of credit, 75. Crises in the United States, the- ories, 212-14, 213, note, 214, note; Mitchell's views, 215- 18; panic of 1884 and financial stringency, see under these headings. Crises of 1814 and 1818, govern- ment indebtedness and trade declensions, 219; state bank- ing, 219, 220; trade conditions after 1814, 220; decrease in state-bank circulation, 220; a depression due to defective moneta,ry system, 221. Crisis of 1837, preceded by great territorial and business expan- sion, 221; canals, 222; popula- tion, 222; land speculation, 222, 223; cotton lands, 223; "pet" banks of Jackson, 223; efforts to smash the Bank of the United States, 223; "specie circular," 224; speculation in land the basis of crisis, 224, 225; rapid liquidation from April, 1837, 225, 226; distress, 226, 227. Crisis of 1857, precedent period filled with railroad construc- tion, 227-29; increase in bank- ing facilities, 228-29; discov- ery of gold and increased pro- duction, 229, and note; failure of crops, and great business expansion, 230; crash, 230, 231; suspension of specie payments, 231; causes, 231, 232. Crisis of 1873, accelerated activ- ity after war, 232, 233; in- creased railroad facilities, 233; securities at heavy discount, 233; money stringency, 233; crash, 234; involved railroad companies and security bank- ers, 234; other banks, 234, 235; closing of the Stock Exchange, 235; action of New York banks in pooling reserves, 235 ; clear- ing-house loan certificates, 236; national banks' relation to cri- sis, 236, 237; imprecedented depression, 238. Crisis of 1893, variety of "get- rich-quick" speculations, 239, 240; electrical development, 240; land "booms," 240; Eng- lish crisis of 1890 felt in 1893, 240; part silver played, 240, 241; demand of gold for silver certificates, 241; sub- treasury's action, 241; gold exports, 242; repeal of Sherman Act, 242; bank failures, 242, 243; cur- rency at premium, 242; failures, 243; railroads in bankruptcy, 243. Crisis of 1907, increase in mer- chandise exported, 244; great lateral manufacturing expan- sion, 244; protective tariff, 245; mining "booms," 245; gold production, 245; increase in banking facilities, 245, 246, 257; value of securities out- standing, 247; premonitions of approaching li((uidutions, 247-50; early failures, 251; Mercantile National liank and the Clearing House, 252; run on Knickerbocker Trust Com- pany, 252; other runs, 252, 253; Morgan syndicate places 304 INDEX $35,000,000 on call, 253; cur- rency shortage, 253, and note; other failures, 253, 254; panic spreads to interior banks, 254 ; shipments of money West, 254; paralysis of exchanges, 255; fall in prices of securities, 255, 256; increase in call loans, 256; reserves, 256; New York banks, action contrasted with that in 1873, 256, 257. Davis, Andrew MacFarland, on the national bank, 134, note. Days of grace, 78. Debs, Eugene V., 248. "Del Credere," 185. Del Mar, Alexander, his theory of money, 146; its fallacies, 146-48, note. Demand bills, 190. Deposits, creation of, by lending credit, 16, 73, 74; cash, 17, 73, 74; individual, lOiet seq.; bank, 110 et seq.; accounts on gen- eral books, 118 et seq.; federal deposits, 142. Development of a medium of ex- change, 3; inconvenience of bullion, 3. Dewey, Davis Rich, Financial History of the United States, 223, 233, 241, 243. Directors, their duties and obli- gations, 30, 31; bank's policy in their keeping, 31; variation in activities of directorates, 31 ; novel plan to insure attendance at meetings, 32; motive power of bank, 32; directors of na- tional banks, 138, 139. Directors of federal reserve banks. See Federal reserve banks. Discount rates {see Loans and dis- counts); on finance bills, 192. Dividends, payable by national banks semi-annually, 144; by federal reserve banks, 272. Dockery, A. M., 131, note. Documentary acceptance bills, 196, note. Documentary payment bills, 196, note; 207, 208. Domestic exchange department. See Exchange department. Drafts and checks sent at " cash." See Foreign cash items depart- ment. Drafts and checks sent for "col- lection." See Collection de- partment. "Dummies," 45, 46. Embargo, effect of, 219. Emergency Currency Act of 1908. See Aldrich-Vreeland Act. EngUsh banking, 10. See also Bank of England. Erie Canal, 222. Escher, Franklin, Foreign Ex- change, 178, note. European accounts, England's supremacy, 206; exchange functions of Bank of England, 206-08; the French account, 208; German account, 208-09; other accounts, 209. Exchange charges (see also Ex- change department, and For- eign exchange), 65, 85, 89, 100, 101. Exchange department, signifi- cance of the word "exchange," 97; New York an "exchange" center, 97; reason for New York's preeminence, 97-99; ef- fect of federal reserve system, 99, and note; premium and dis- count on exchange, 100, 101, 255; sources of bank's supply of exchange, 101; can be con- ducted profitably, 102; travel- ers' cheques, 102, 103; value of reciprocal arrangements, 110, 111. Farm loans, 281, 282. Federal Advisory Council, 274. Federal Reserve Act, amend- ment to Aldrich-Vreeland Act, 141, note; limitation of 5 per- cent redemption fund, 142, INDEX S05 note; provision for liabilities ex- ceeding capital stock, 144, 145; national banks not required to have circulating notes, 150, note; open discount mar- ket, 184, and note; condition of currency before passage of act, 258-63; seasonal demand for expansion of currency, 262, 263; reserve requirements, 279, 280, 281 ; does not create a cen- tral bank, 282, 283; "commer- cial paper," 283, 284; changes in banking requirements and practices, 284, 285 ; how it oper- ates, 289, 290; movements of reserves, 291, 292. Federal Reserve Banks, organ- ization, 268; regional banks, 269; banks capable of mem- bership, 269; capital subscrip- tion requirements, 270, 271; directors, 271, 272; branches, 272; exempt from taxes, 272; dividends, 272; powers, 275, 276; deposits of public monies, 276; notes, 276, 277, 278; col- lections, 278, 285-87; retire- ment of national bank circula- tion, 278; reserve requirements, 279-81; examinations of mem- ber banks, 281 ; farm loans, 281, 282; additional powers, 282; federal reserve districts, 293, 295. Federal Reserve Board, promul- gation of rules for regional banks, 269, 270; a supreme court of the system, 273; mem- bership, 273; powers, 274, 275. Filialen, 208. Finance bills. See Bankers' long bUls. Financial stringency of 1890, 2.39. Financial Age, 245, 219, 283, 284. Fisk and Hatch, failure of, 234. Foreign cash items dcpartrnenl, large volume of out-of-town items, 84; use of this depart- ment to reduce exchange charges, 85, 98; clearing-house regulation of exchange, 85; "credits" and "returns," 86; sending letters, 86, 87 ; indorse- ment, 87; remittances, 88; un- pleasant experiences in collect- ing, 88; unpaid items, 89; pro- tested checks and drafts, 89; relation to reciprocal accounts, 112; handled through clearing house, 170, note. Foreign exchange, basis of, 178; settlement of international debts and credits, 178, 179; the market individualistic, 179; items of credit and debit, 180, 181; gold export point, 181, 182, 255; gold import point, 181, 182, 183, 184; buying bul- lion in England and United States, 183, 184; European dis- count markets, 184; accept- ance of long bills, 184; "Giro Conto," 185; "Del Credere," and " Bank Post" remittances, 185; foreign department a com- plete bank, 186; reasons for conducting a foreign depart- ment, 186; "first" and "sec- ond" of exchange, 187; sharp competition in the market, 187; fluctuations on markets, 187, 188; those who have commer- cial bills to sell, 188; demand for exchange, 188; "arbitrag- ing in exchange," 189; illustra- tion of gold's short path to its destination, 189, 190; free gold markets, 190; demand l)ills, 190; long bills, 190, 191; bank- ers' long bills, 191-94 ( see also under Bankers' long bills); ca- ble transfers, 195; commercial long bills (see Commercial long bills); commercial letters of credit, 198-202; travelers' let- ters of credit, 203, 200; Euro- pean accounts (see European accounts); conclusion, 210. Formation of national banks. See National bunks. 306 INDEX Fraud, prevention of, by cashier, 45; by paying teller, 54, 55. Frewen, Moreton, 288. Garnishments, 57. General books, necessity of some recapitulation, 118, 119; gamut , of general accounts, 118, 119; capital stock, 119; surplus and undivided profits, 119; loan and discount account, 120; in- dividual, bank, and public de- posits, 120; cashiers' checks, 120; clearing-house accounts, 120; miscellaneous accounts, 120, 121. "GiroConto," 185. Glass, Carter, 267. -See also Fed- eral Reserve Act. Goddard, F. A., before Missouri Bankers' Association, 248. Gold production, 229, and note; 245. Harris, B. D., 288, note. Heinze, F. Augustus, 252. Heinze, Otto C, 251. Hepburn, A. Barton, 250. Hull, George H., Industrial De- pressions, 214, note. Illinois Central Railroad Com- pany, receivership of, 231. Independent treasury, adopted, 15; abolished (see Federal Re- serve Act). Individual ledger, simple records of individual depositors, 104; speedy work required, 104; collateral duties of individual bookkeeper, 104, 105; nature of individual ledger, 105; fre- quent posting, 105, 106; book- keepers' snares, 105; balancing, three principal methods, 107- 09. Indorsed notes, 79. Inexpediency of 100 per cent re- serves, 17. Interest and discount, 76 ; fluctu- ation in rates, 77; high rates for small loans, 78; charts for computing, 78, 79; interest on savings accounts, 121; charged by national banks, 143. International financial adjust- ments, 22. See also Foreign Exchange. Jay Cooke and Company, failure of, 234. Jess, Stoddard, 283. Johnson, A. B., 39. Kay, CuUom W., 56. Kelly, Edmund, Twentieth-Cen- tury Socialism, 252, note. Kenyon, Cox and Company, fail- ure of, 234. "Kiting," 45. Knickerbocker Trust Company, run on, 252. Ledger. See Reciprocal accounts, and Individual ledger. Letters of credit. See Travelers' letters of credit; Foreign ex- change. Liabilities of national banks which may exceed capital stock, 144, 145. Liability of shareholders in gen- eral, 29. Lincoln Trust Company, run on, 252. Loans and discounts, principal divisions, 23, 24; time of ma- turity, 24, 40, 78; loans on farm lands, 24 ; call loans, 25 ; collat- eral, 39, 76; collection, 40; man- ner of making loans and dis- counts, 73 et seq.\ rate, 76, 77; life of paper, 78; waivers and agreements in note forms, 79; indorsements, 79; protests, 79, 83; bank record of loans and discounts in register, ledger, and tickler, 80, 81; collection of out-of-town obligations, 82, 83, 94, 95; account on general books, 120. Long bills, 190 et seq. I 1 INDEX 307 McAdoo, William G., 267. McLeod, H. D., Elements of Bank- ing, 74r. Margraff, International Exchange, 185, 201. May, R. D., Das Grundgesetz der Wirtschaftskrisen, 213, note. Medium of exchange, develop- ment of, 3; inconvenience of bullion, 3. Meetings of shareholders, 29. Missouri, Texas and Pacific Rail- road Company, 234. Mitchell, Wesley C, Business Cy- cles, 211, 212, 215-18, 254; Economic Journal article, 283, 285. Money in the United States, 21. Money-changers of Florence, 7. Morgan, J. Pierpont, 253. Morse, C. W., 251, and note. Motives for organizing a bank, 28. National banks, 15; a war meas- ure, 134; natm-e of the nation- al bank currency, 135; first steps in organization, 135, 136; Comptroller's inquiries, 135, note; capital stock, 137; in- crease or reduction of capital, 137, 138; participation of share- holders, 138; directors, 138, 139; depository for United States funds, 142; interest on federal deposits, 142; banks classified according to reserve, 143, 279, 280; authorized rate of interest, 143; incapacity to accept its stock as collateral, 144; limited ability to hold realty, 144; dividends, 144; lia- bilities exceeding capital stock, 144, 145; growth, 145; required circulation, 150; not required to have circulating notes under Federal Reserve Act, 150, note; 278; purchase of bonds, 150; in 1873, 230, 237. National bank notes, 135; profit on investment, 139, 140; tax on notes issued under Act of May 30, 1908, 141, and note; security for paper currency, 141, 146, 147; reducing com- mercial values to currency, 147, 148; super-safety of na- tional bank notes, 148, 149; a bank note a guaranteed I O U, 149; state circulation taxed, 135, 149; denominations, 150; receivable for what, 151 ; meth- od of redeeming notes, 151, 152; gold certificates issued by national banks, 152; criticism of national bank currency, 153- 55, 258-60; awkward expansion and contraction, 155, 156; pro- visions for emergency currency, see Aldrich-Vreeland Act. National cmrency associations. See Aldrich-Vreeland Act. National Monetary Commission, its formation, duties, and ac- complishments, 153, 154; its personnel, 154, note; report of Senator Aldrich, 154. New York, exchange center, 97- 99; relative importance of New York in national bank depos- its, 103. New York Warehouse and Pro- duce Company, 234. Northern Pacific Railroad Com- pany, 234. Noyes, Alexander D., History of the National Bank Currency, 154-56, and 156, note. Ohio Life Insurance and Trust Company, failure of, 230. Overdrafts, 40. Owen-Glass Currency Bill. See Federal Reserve Act. Panic of 1884, a financial spec- tacle, 2.38; causes, 238, 239. Paton, Thomas B., 130. Paying teller, his department pulse of the bank's policy, 51; familiarity with signatures and accounts, 51, 52; his charge of 308 INDEX money and vaults, 52, 53; ne- cessity for clear-headed teller, 53; frauds and counterfeits, 54, 55; garnishments, 57; "stop payment" checks, 57, 58; ex- amination of signatures on day's checks, 59; balance, 59. Personnel of bank directorates, 30. Postal savings banks, organized, 130; provides for small deposi- tor, 130; banlcs acting as reposi- tories of deposits, 130, 132, note; interest, 130; character of depositors, 131, note; statis- tics, 131; note, 132, note; con- version of deposits into bonds, 132, note; 133. Powers of national bank. See National banks. Presidencies, range of, 36. President, selection, 35; organ- izes work of new bank, 36; cares for broad development of bank's reputation, 36, 37; his extension of the bank's credit, 37 et seq.; the dangers in lend- ing, 38 et. seq.; collateral secur- ity, 38; legal knowledge, 39; necessity for completing work each day, 40, 41; popular con- ception of president. Promissory note, origin, 8. Quin, Representative, 262. Railroads, 228. Real estate mortgages, 76; abil- ity of national banks to hold, 144. Receiving tellers, nimiber and distribution of work, 62; dili- gence required in discovering check informalities, 63-65 ; common mistakes in deposit slips, 64; ambiguous figures, 64 ; collecting exchange charges, 65; balance, 66-71; counting money, 67-69; hindrances to speedy balances by, 70, 71. Reciprocal accounts, based on mutual exchange of business between banks, 110; favorable exchange and collection rates, 110, 111; accounts cleared im- mediately on demand or pe- riodically, 111, 112; rulings of the ledger, 112; relation to . transit department, 112; checks received from various depart- ments and charged, 113; in- terest on reciprocal accounts, 113; reconcilement of accounts, 114-16; differences in accounts explained, 115-17; "charge slips," 117. Regional banks. See Federal re- serve banks. Relation of lending to production and liquidation to consump- tion, 18. Reserve, nature of, 19 et seq.; re- serve under national bank act, 19, 20, 143; savings banks' re- serve, 125; awkwardness under the National Bank Act, 259. Reserve in 1907 crisis, 256. Reserve under Federal reserve system, 279-81. Reserve banks. See Federal re- serve banks. Robinson, Humphrey, 73,75, 140. "Runs" on banks. See Crises. Savings department, profitable- ness of savings accounts to banks, 123; growth of savings institutions, 124; savings ac- counts in commercial banks, 124, 125; reserve, 125; charac- ter of savings deposits, 126; schemes to induce savers, 126, 127; interest, 127; certificates of deposit, 127, 128; organiza- tion of department, 128, 129; postal savings banks, see under Postal savings banks. Scherer, William, 169, note; and 170, note. Schiff, Jacob H., 251, note. Seldomridge, Representative, 287. INDEX 309 Shaw, Leslie, M., 251, note. Sherman Silver Bill, 240, 241, repeal of, 242. "Specie Circular," 224. Sprague, O. M. W., History of Crises under the National Bank- ing System, 234, 236, 237, 239, 256. Stock exchange and the national bank, 260, 261. Stockholders, 28-30; of national banks, 138. Strauss, Albert, Columbia Uni- versity lecture on Foreign Ex- change, 182, 183, 190, 193, 194, 201. Surplus account on general books, 119. Taussig, F. W., before Economics Club, 247. Thomas, E. R., 252, and note. Thomas, O. P., 252, and note. Three VV's, the failure of, 225, and note. Transit department. See For- eign cash items department. Travelers' cheques, 102, 103. Travelers' letters of credit, uses, 203; form, 204; identification, 205; how charges are made, 205, 206. Trust Company of North Ameri- ca, run on, 252. Undivided profits account on general books, 119. Vanderlip, Frank A., 15, 16, 253. Vaults, 52, 53. Vice-president, 41, 42. Weed, T. L., 131, note. Welldon, Samuel A., Digestof State Banking Statutes, 15, note. White, Horace, 73, 74. Willis, Henry P., 287, 288. Windom, Secretary of the Treas- ury, 239, 241. Wolfe, A. Howard, 286, 287. y !^ RIVERSIDE ESSAYS Edited by ADA L. F. SNELL Associate Professor of English, Mount Holyoke College The purpose of the Riverside Essays is to present to stu- dents of English composition essays by modern authors which deal in a fresh way with such subjects as politics, science, lit- erature, and nature. The close study of vigorous and artistic writing is generally acknowledged to be the best method of gaining a mastery of the technique of composition. In the Riverside Essays the material consists of essays which, with few exceptions, have been printed entire. Othei advantages of the Riverside Essays for both instructor and student lie Vn the fact that the material is presented in sepa- rate volunr.es, each of which is devoted to a single author and contains two or more representative essays. Finally, the series has none of the eaimarks of the ordinary textbook which the student passes on, marked and battered, to the next college generation. The books are attractively printed, and bound, in the Library Binding of The Riverside Literature Series. The student will therefore be glad to keep these books for his own library. PROMOTING GOOD CITIZENSHIP By James Bryce. With an Introduction. Riverside Literature Series. No. 227, Library Binding. 40 cents, net. Postpaid. STUDIES IN NATURE AND LITERATURE By John Burroughs. Riverside Literature Series, No. 226, Library Binding. 40 cents, net. Postpaid. UNIVERSITY SUBJECTS By John Henry Newman. Riverside Literature Series, No. 225 Library Binding. 40 cents, net. Postpaid. THE AMERICAN MIND AND AMERICAN IDEALISM By Bliss Perry. With an Introduction. Riverside Literature Series, No. 224. Library Binding. 40 cents, net. Postpaid. HOUGHTON MIFFLIN COMPANY BOSTON NEW YORK CHICAGO UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA AT LOS ANGELES THE UNIVERSITY LIBRARY This book is DUE on the last date stamped below 4UN6 .19" 9 19^ Form L-9 20m -1.' 42(8519) '-I T ITY OF CALIFORNIA AT L03 ANfiF^I.F.R m A 1601 Harris - H24p Pfftc tioal banking. UC SOUTHERN REGIONAL LIBRARY FACILIT AA 000 593 560 6 HG 1601 H24p