BJisawarafei argoKSSoaeeieEsI Robert E. Gross Colleftion A Memorial to the Founder of the Business Administration Library t/niveriifu M^airMtmt'a Los Angeles PRINCIPLES OF POLITICAL ECONOMY BY WILLIAM ROSCHER, PROFESSOR OF POLITICAL ECONOJtT AT THE UNIVERSITY OP LEIPZIG, CORRESPONDING MEMBER OP THE INSTITUTE OP FRANCE, PRIVY COUNSELOR TO HIS MAJESTY, THE KING OF SAXONY. FROM THE THIRTEENTH (1877) GERMAN EDITION. WITH ADDITIONAL CHAPTERS FURNISHED BY THE AUTHOR, FOR THIS FIRST ENGLISH AND AMERICAN EDITION, ON PAPER MONEY, INTERNATIONAL TRADE, AND THE PROTECTIVE SYSTEM; AND A PRELIMINARY ESSAY ON THE HISTORICAL METHOD IN POLITICAL ECONOMY. (From the French) By L. WOLOWSKI, THE WHOLE TRANSLATED BY JOHN J. LALOP, A. M. YOL. I, CHICAGO: CALLAGHAN AND COMPANY. 1878. Entered according to Act of Congress, in the year eighteen hundred and seventy-eight, By CALLAGHAN & CO., In the oflace of the Librarian of Congress, at Washington, D. C. DAVID ATWOOD, 8TEEE0TTPEE AND PRINTER, MADISOX, WIS. Gross Collection Bus. Adm. Lib. 175 WILLIAM H. GAYLORD, Esq., COUNSELOR AT LAW, OF CLEVELAND, OHIO, TO WHOSE BF.OTHEP.lt CARE IT IS LARGELY DUE THAT I LIVFD TO TRANSLATE TUKM, THESE VOLUMES ARE AFFECTIONATELY INSCRIBED. 1621438 TRANSLATOR'S PREFACE. Our literature is rich enough in works on the principles of Political Economy. So far as the translator is informed, however, it possesses none in which the science is treated in accordance with the historical method. We may therefore venture to express the hope that this translation will fill a place hitherto unoccupied in the literatures of England and America, and fill it all the more efficiently and acceptably, as Professor Roscher is the founder and still the leader of the historical school of Political Economy. Were this the only recommendation of our undertaking, it would not be a useless one. But a glance at Professor Roscher's book will convince even the most hasty reader that its pages fascinate by their interest and are rich in treasures of erudition which should not remain inaccessible to the English student from being locked up in a foreign tongue. The present translation has received, throughout, the revis- ion of the author, and should any imperfections remain in the rendering of his thought into English, the blame is certainly not his, for his revision has been most minute. The three appendices have been supplied by Professor Roscher expressly for this edition. As they are intended to form a part of the work on the Political Economy of Industry and Commerce, on which he is now engaged, he authorizes vi TRANSLATOR'S PREFACE. their publication in English, only by the publishers of this edition of his principles; and only for the purpose of being added to the present translation. He desires especially that their appearance in their present shape should not in any way interfere with any of his rights in his forthcoming volume, and that they should not be translated into any language nor translated back into German. The essay of Mr. Wolowski, on the historical method in Political Economy constitutes no part of Professor Roscher's book, and neither he nor its author, but only the translator, is responsible for its appearance here. In it the reader will find a short sketch of the life of Professor Roscher, brought down to the date at which the essay was written. The trans- lator has little to add to that sketch, all the information he possesses in addition to what it contains being embraced in the following lines from a letter received by him from the author in answer to a request that he would supply the bio- graphical data not to be found in Wolowski's essa}^: "You might perhaps say .... that I have repeatedly declined calls to the Universities of Munich, Vienna and Berlin, but that I have never regretted remaining in Leipzig." The acknowledgments of the translator are due, in the first place, to the eminent author himself, for the revision of the plate-proof of the entire work, and then to Professor William F. Allen, of the University of Wisconsin, for his interest in the progress of the enterprise, and for many val- uable suggestions; also to Professor W. G. Sumner, of Yale College, for some excellent hints as to the best transla- tion of certain words in the Appendix on Paper Money. AUTHOR'S PREFACE. yii AUTHOR'S TREFACE. [1st Edition.] My System der Volkszvirthschaft shall, Deo volenie,he. completed in four parts. The second shall contain the national economy of agriculture and the related branches of natural production ; the third, the national economy of industr}^ and commerce; the fourth, of the economy of the state and of the commune (Gcmcindchaiishalt), While the entire work shall constitute one systematic whole, each part shall have its own appropri- ate title, constitute an independent treatise, and be sold sepa- rately. Of the peculiar method which I have followed in this work, and which will produce still better fruits in the succeeding volumes, I have given a sufficient explanation in §§ 26 if., and all I desire now is to say a few words on the relation the notes bear to the text. The careful reader will soon be convinced that of the many citations in this work, not one has been made from a vain desire of the display of erudition. Part of them serves as the necessary proof of surprising facts adduced, but which are little known. Another part of them is intended to incite the reader to the study of certain questions nearly re- lated to those treated in the text, but which are still different from them. The object of the greater number is to supply information concerning the histor}^ of economic principles. As far as the sources at my command permitted, I have endeav- ored to point out the first germs, the chief stages of develop- ment, the contrasts, and, finally, what has been thus far at- tained in economic science. This sometimes required some little victory over self, inasmuch as I was conscious of having yiii AUTHOR'S PREFACE. independently discovered certain facts, when I afterwards found that some old and long-forgotten writer had made sim- ilar observations. Thus, this work may serve both as a hand- book and as a history of the literature of Political Economy. Students of the science know how little has thus far been done by writers in this direction. And hence I shall be very grateful to those who labor in the same field, if they will, either by writing to me personally, or through the medium of the press, inform me when I have erred in ascribing a truth, or a scientifically important error, to its earliest author. I have already said in the title that this work is intended not for the learned only, but for all educated men, for men of a serious turn of mind, who desire truth and science for their own sake. Like that ancient historian, whom I honor above all others as my teacher, I desire that my work should be useful to those, oao: ^oukjaovzo.c tqju ts yevoixsvcov to aacpez axoTiBtv xat r<3v jitXXovziov ttots av&a; xazd to dud^pcoTzecou tocoutoju xat TrapartXr^auou 'iazad-ac. ( Thucydides I, 22.) University of Leipzig, End of May^ ^Sj^f. AUTHOR'S PREFACE. IX FROM THE AUTHOR'S PREFACES. t2d to nth Edition.] . The preface to the second edition is dated October, 1856; that to the third, April, 1858; that to the fourth, April, 1861; that to the fifth, November, 1863; that to the sixth, Novem- ber, 1865; that to the seventh, November, 1868; that to the eighth, August, 1869; that to the ninth, March, 1871; that to the tenth. Ma}', 1873; that to the eleventh (unaltered), Decem- ber, 1873. Each successive edition, nearly, has been an- nounced as an improved and enlarged one; and the tenth edition contains one hundred and fifty-six pages more than the first, although in places, a large number of abbreviations had been made from previous editions. There are many things in some of the previous editions which criticism induced me, long since, to change. I have considered it my duty to the public, who gave my work so warm and friendly a recep- tion, to take into consideration, in each successive edition, not only my own new investigations, but those also of all others with which I became acquainted, and, whenever possible, to correct statistical illustrations from the latest sources. I have especially, in each following edition, enriched a number of paragraphs with here and there historical, ethnographic and statistical features. Plutarch is certainly right, spite of the fact that pedants may abuse him for it, when he says, that trifling acts, a word and even a jest, are often more important, as characterizing the life of a people or an age, than great battles which cost the lives of tens of thousands of men. I have changed the titles " Ricardo's Law of Rent," and " The Malthusian Law of the Increase of Population," which X AUTHOR'S PREFACE. I formerly used, for others. But I would not be misunder- stood here. I hold it to be a duty of reverence in the learned — as it has long been practiced in the case of the natu- ral sciences — in the sciences of the human mind to call the natural laws, methods etc., in acquainting us with which, some one particular investigator has won very distinguished merit, by the name of that investigator. In the case of the law of rent, the application of this rule would as unquestionably en- title Ricardo to this honor as as it would Malthus in that of the increase of population, spite of the fact that Ricardo may not have succeeded in finding the best possible form of the abstraction, and although Malthus even, in a one-sided reac- tion against a former still greater one-sidedness, was not always able to steer clear of positive and negative errors. Recent science has endeavored, and successfully, to examine the facts which contradict the Ricardoan and Malthusian for- mulations of the laws in question, and to extend the formu- las accordingly. I have myself contributed hereto to the ex- tent of my ability. But, in the interval, it is not hard to com- prehend that, while this process of elucidation is going on, most scholars, those especially possessed more of a dogmatic than of a historical turn of mind, should estimate these two leaders more in accordance with their few defects than with the great merits of their discoveries. If, therefore, I now drop the title " Malthusian law," it is to guard hasty readers from the illusion that §§ 242 seq. teach what the great crowd understand by Malthusianism ; when they might, perhaps, omit that portion entirely. For my own part, I have no doubt that, when the process of elucidation above referred to shall have been thoroughly finished, the future will accord both to Ricardo and Malthus their full meed of honor as political economists and discoverers of the first rank.^ 1 The author's preface to the twelfth edition is confined to pointing out the improvements etc., made in the eleventh. There is no new preface to the thirteenth edition of the original, which appeared in 1S77. — Translator. TABLE OF CONTENTS. PRELIMINARY ESSAY. The Historical Method, pp. 1-48. PRINCIPLES OF POLITICAL ECONOMY. INTRODUCTION. CHAPTER I. FUNDAMENTAL, IDEAS. § I. Goods — Wants. 2. Economic Goods. 3. Three Classes of Goods. 4. Economic Value — Value in Use. 5. Value in Exchange — Free Goods. 6. Alleged Contradiction between Value in Use and Value in Exchange. 7. Resources or Means. 8. Valuation of Resources. 9. Wealth. 10. Signs of National Wealth. 11. Economy (Husbandry). 12. Grades of Economy in Common. 13. Political Economy — Idea of an Organism. 14. Origin of a Nation's Economy. 15. Diseases of the Social Organism. Xii TABLE OF CONTENTS. CHAPTER 11. POSITION OF POLITICAL ECONOMY IN THE CIRCLE OF RELATED SCIENCES. § i6. Political or National Economy. 17. Sciences relating to National Life — The Science of Public Economy — The Science of Finance. 18. Statistics. 19. Private Economy — Cameralistic Science. 20. Private Economy (continued). 21. What Political Economy treats of. CHAPTER IIL METHODS OF POLITICAL ECONOMY. § 22. Former Methods. 23. The Idealistic Method. 24. The Idealistic Method (continued). 25. The Idealistic Method (continued). 26. The Historical Method — The Anatomy and Physiology of National Economy. 27. Advantages of the Historical or Physiological Method. 28. Advantages* of the Historical Method. 29. Practical Character of the Historical Method. BOOK I. PRODUCTION OF GOODS. § 30. Meaning of Production. CHAPTER L FACTORS OF PRODUCTION. §31. Factors of Production — External Nature. 32. The Sea — Climate. 33. Gifts of Nature with Value in Excnange. 34. External Nature (continued). 35. Elements of Agricultural Productiveness. 36. Further Divisions of Nature's Gifts. 37. Geographical Character of a Country. 38. Labor — Classes of Labor. 39. Taste for Labor — Piece-Wages. 40. Labor- Power of Individuals. 41. Esteem in which Labor is held. TABLE OF CONTENTS. xiU §42. Capital — Classes of Goods which Constitute it. 43. Productive Capital. 44. Fixed Capital — Circulating Capital. 45. How Capital originates. CHAPTER II. PRODUCTIVE COOPERATION OF THE FACTORS. § 46. Pi'oductive Cooperation of the Three Factors. 47. The Three Great Periods of a Nation's Economy. 48. Critical History of the Idea of Productiveness. 49. The Doctrine of the Physiocrates. 50. The Same Subject (continued). 51. The Same Subject (continued). 52. Idea of Productiveness. 53. The Same Subject (continued). 54. Importance of a Due Proportion in the Different Branches of Productiveness. 55. The Degree of Productiveness. 56. Development of the Division of Labor. 57. Its Extent at Different Periods. 58. Advantages of the Division of Labor. 59. Conditions of the Division of Labor. 60. Influence of the Extent of the Market on the Division of Labor. 61. Meajis of Increasing the Division of Labor. 62. Dark Side of the Division of Labor. 63. Gain and Loss of the Division of Labor. 64. The Cooperation of Labor. 65. Principle of Stability, or of the Continuity of Work. 66. Advantages of Large Enterprises. CHAPTER IV. FREEDOM AND SLAVERY. § 67. Origin of Slavery. 68. Origin of Slavery (continued). 69. The Want of Freedom. 70. Emancipation. 71. Disadvantages of Slavery. 72. Effect of an Advance in Civilization on Slavery. 73. The Same Subject (continued). 74. The Same Subject (continued). 75. The Same Subject (continued). 76. The Domestic Servant System. XIV TABLE OF CONTENTS. CHAPTER V. COMMUNITY OF GOODS AND PRIVATE PROPERTY. § 77. Capital — Importance of Private Property. 78. Socialism and Communism. 79. Socialism and Communism (continued). 80. Socialism and Communism (continued). 8x. Community of Goods. 82. Organization of Labor. 83. Organization of Labor (continued). 84. Organization of Labor (continued). 85. Right of Inheritance. 86. Right of Inheritance (continued). 87. Landed Property. 88. Landed Property (continued). §89 90 91 92 93 94 CHAPTER VL CREDIT. Credit in General. Effects of Credit. Debtor- Laws. History of Credit Laws. Means of Promoting Credit. Letters of Respite. BOOK 11. CIRCULATION OF GOODS. CHAPTER I. CIRCULATION IN GENERAL. § 95. Meaning of the Circulation of Goods. 96. Rapidity of Circulation. 97. Freedom of Competition. 98. How Goods are Paid for. 99. Freedom of Competition and International Trade. CHAPTER IL PRICES. § 100. Prices in General, loi. Effects of the Struggle of Opposing Interests on Price. TABLE OF CONTENTS. XV § I02. Demand. 103. Demand — Indispensable Goods. 104. Influence of Purchaser's Solvability on Prices. 105. Supply. 106. The Cost of Production. 107. Equilibrium of Prices. loS. Eftect of a Rise in Price much above Cost. 109. Effect of a DecHne in Price below Cost. no. Different Costs of Production of the same Goods. 111. The Same Subject (continued). 112. Exceptions. 113. Exceptions (continued). 114. Prices Fixed by Government. 115. Influence of Growing Civilization on Prices. CHAPTER III. MONEY IN GENERAL. § 1 16. Instrument of Exchange — Measure of Value — Barter. 117. Effect of the Introduction of Money. 118. Different Kinds of Money. 119. Metals as Money. 120. Money — The Precious Metals. 121. Value in Use and Value in Exchange of Money. 122. Value in Exchange of Money. 123. Quantity of Money a Nation Needs. 124. Same Subject (continued). 125. Uniformity of the Value in Exchange of the Precious Metals. 126. The Same Subject (continued.) CHAPTER IV. HISTORY OF PRICES. § 127. Measure of Prices. 128. Value in Exchange estimated in Labor. 129. The Precious Metals the Best Measure of Prices. 130. History of the Prices of the Chief Wants of Life. 131. The Same Subject (continued). 132. The Same Subject (continued). 133. The Same Subject (continued). 134. The Same Subject (continued). 135. History of the Value of the Precious Metals — In Antiquity and the Middle Ages. XVi TABLE OF CONTENTS. § 136. Eifect of the Discovery of American Mines etc., on the Value of the Precious Metals. 137. Revolution in Prices at the beginning of Modern History. 138. Influence of the Non-monetary use of Gold and Silver. 139. Californian and Australian Discoveries. 140. Influence of the Revolution in Prices on National Resources. 141. Effect of an Enhancement of the Price of the Precious Metals. 142. The Price of Gold as compared with that of Silver. 143. The Same Subject (continued;. APPENDIX I. PAPER MONEY. § I. Paper Money and Money- Paper. 2. Advantages and Disadvantages of Paper Money. 3. Kinds of Redemption. 4. Compulsary Circulation. 5. Resumption of Specie Payments. 6. Is Paper Money a Curse or a Blessing .!* BOOK III. DISTRIBUTION OF GOODS. CHAPTER I. INCOME IN GENERAL. i 144. Receipts — Income — Product. 145. Gross, Free and Net Income. 146. National Income — Its Statistical Importance. 147. The Same Subject (continued). 148. The two Phases of Income. CHAPTER II. RENT OF LAND. 1 149. Theory of Rent. 150. Theory of Rent (continued). 151. Theory of Rent — Land Favorably Situated. 152. Theory of Rent (continued). 153. Theory of Rent (continued). 154. Theory of Rent (continued). 155. History of Rent. TABLE OF CONTENTS xvil § 156. Influence of Advancing Civilization on Rent. 157. Influence of Improvements in the Art of Agriculture on Rent. 15S. History of Rent in Periods of Decline. 159. Rent and the General Good. CHAPTER III. WAGES. § 160. Wages of Labor. 161. Minimum of Wages. 162. Cost of Production of Labor. 163. Power of the Working Classes over tlie Rate of Wages. 164. Cost of Production of Labor. 165. The Demand for Labor. 166. Price of Common Labor. 167. Difterence of Wages in diflerent Branches of Labor. 16S. The Same Subject (continued). 169. Effect of the Disagreeableness of certam Classes of Labor en Wages. 170. Influence of Custom on Wages. 171. History of the Wages of Common Labor in the Lower Stages of Civilization. 172. History of the Wages of Common Labor in Flourishing Times. 173. History of the Wages of Common Labor in Flourishing Na- tions. 174. History of the Wages of Common Labor in Declining Coun- tries and Times. 175. Wages-Policy — Set Price of Labor. 176. Wages-Policy — Strikes. 177. Strikes and The State. 178. Guaranty of Minimum of Wages. CHAPTER IV. INTEREST. § 179. Rate of Interest in General. 180. Level of the Rate of Interest. 181. Causes of DiiTerent Rates of Interest. 182. Variations of the Rate of Discount. 183. Effect of Increased Demand for Loans. 184. History of the Rate of Interest. 185. Influence of an Advance in Civilization on the Rate of Interest. 186. Causes of a High Rate in Thriving Commercial Nations. 187. Emigration of Capital. Vol. I.— B Xviii • TABLE OF CONTENTS. § iSS. Effect of a Low Rate en Stationary Nations. 1S9. Interest-Policy — Legitimateness of Interest. 190. Aversion to Interest. 191. Interest- Policy — The Canon Law etc. 192. Interest Policy — Government Interference — Fixed Rates. 193. Efforts to avoid the Evil Effects of a Fixed Rate of Interest. 194. Repeal of the Usury Laws. CHAPTER V. THE undertaker's PROFIT. § 195. The Reward of Enterprise. 196. Circumstances on which the Undertaker's Profit Depends. 196 fa). Having the " Lead." CHAPTER VL COKCLUDIXG REMARKS ON THE THREE BRANCHES OF INCOME. § 197. Influence of the Branches of Income on the Price of Com- modities. 195. Remedy in Case One Factor of Production has become dearer. 199. Influence of Foreign Trade. 200. Influence of the Branches of Income on the Price of Com- modities. 201. Harmony of the Three Branches of Income — Individual Differences in them. 202. Necessity of the Feeling of a Common Interest. CHAPTER VII. DISTRIBUTION OF THE NATIONAL INCOME. § 203. Effect of an Equal Division of the National Income. 204. Moneyed Aristocracies and Pauperism. 205. Healthy Distribution of the National Income. BOOK IV. CHAPTER L CONSUMPTION OF GOODS IN GENERAL. § 206. Nature and Kinds of Consumption. 207. The Most Useful Kind of Consumption. 20S. Notional Consumption. 209. Consumption, the V/ork of Nature. TABLE OF CONTENTS. xix 210. Necessity of Considering what is really Consumed. 211. Production Impossible without Consumption. 212. Unproductive Consumption. 213. Equilibrium between Production and Consumption. 214. Causes of an Increase of Production. 215. Necessity of the Proper Simultaneous Development of Pro- duction and Consumption. 216. Commercial Crises in General — A General Glut. 217. The Same Subject (continued). 21S. Prodigality and Frugality. 219. Eftect of Prodigality. 220. When Saving is Injurious. 221. Limits to the Saving of Capital. 222. Spendthrift Nations. 223. The Most Deti'imental Kind of Extravagance. CHAPTER II. § 224. Luxury in General. 225. History of Luxury — In the Middle Ages. 226. Luxury of Barbarous Times. 227. Influence of the Church and the City. 22S. Luxury in Flourishing Times. 229. Character of the Luxury of the Second Period. 230. Condition Precedent of this Luxury. 231. When the Effects of Luxury are Favorable. 232. Character of Luxury in Declining Nations. 233. Luxury-Policy. 234. History of Sumptuary Laws. 235. Difficulty of Enforcing Sumptuary Laws. 236. Expediency of Sumptuary Laws. CHAPTER III. INSURANCE IN GENERAL. 8 237. Insurance in General. 237 (a). Mutual and Speculative Institutions 237 (b). Economic Advantages of Insurance. 237 (c). Fire Insurance. 237 (d). Requisites of a Good System of Fire Insurance. XX TABLE OF CONTENTS. BOOK V. POPULATION. 1238, 239 240 241 242, 243 CHAPTER I. THEORY OF POPULATIOISr. Increase of Population in General. Limits to the Increase of Population. Influence of an Increase of the Means of Subsistence. Eft'ect of Wars on Population. Tendencies counter to the Increase of Population. Opponents of Malthus. CHAPTER II. HISTORY OF POPULATION. § 244. History of Population in Barbarous Times. 245. Community of Wives — Polygamy. 246. History of Population in highly Civilized Times. 247. The Same Subject (continued). 248. The Same Subject (continued). 249. History of Population in Periods of Decline. 2 qo. Influence of the Sacredness of Marriage on Population. 251. Polygamy — Exposure of Children. 252. Positive Decrease of Population. CHAPTER III. POPULATION-POLICY. 253. Population-Policy — Over-population. 254. The Ideal of Population. 255. Means of Promoting Population. 256. Immigration. 257. Influence of Hygienic Police. 258. Means of Checking Population — Placing Impediments in the way of Marriage. 259. Emigration. 260. Colonizing Emigration. 261. State aid to Emigration. 262. Emigration and Pauperism. 262 (a). Temporary Emigration. TABLE OF CONTENTS. xx'l J 263. Conclusion. 264. Conclusion (continued). 265. Conclusion (continued). APPENDIX ir. INTERNATIONAL TRADE. § I. The TNIei-cantile System. 2. Reaction against the Mercantile System. 3. Further Correction of the ISIercantile System. 4. Partial Truth of the Mercantile System. 5. Advantages of International Trade. APPENDIX III. THE INDUSTRIAL PROTECTIVE SYSTEM, § I. Proximate Economic Effects of the Industrial Protective System. 2. Effect of Export Duties etc. on Raw J»Iaterial — Export Pre- miuins. 3. The Free-Trade School. 4. Further Educational Effects of the Industrial Protective Sys- tem. 5. Free-Trade as a Policy. 6. Why the Protective System -was Adopted, 7. How long is Protection Justifiable.' S. Industrial-Protective Policy in Particular. 9. What Industries only should be Favored. PRELIMINARY ESSAY. THE HISTORICAL METHOD. PEELIMINAEY ESSAY APPLICATION OF THE HISTORICAL METHOD TO THE STUDY OF POLITICAL ECONOMY, BY M. WOLOWSKI, MEMBER OF THE INSTITUTE OF FRANCE. '■'■ Nunquam bene j>ercij>iemus usu nccessarium nisi ct noverimus jus illud usu von nccessarium. Ncxiim est et colligatum alterum alteri. Nulli sunt servi nodis, cur qu-CEstioncs dc scrvis vcxanius? Digna imperito vox." — Cuj., vii, in titul. Dig. De Justitia et Jure.' '■'■Homo sum, JiU7nani nihil a me alienmn puto^ — Terence? '■^ Ista prcBpotens, ac gloriosa fhilosopkia." — Cicero, De Or., I, 43.^ I. It is no foolish desire to make a vain display of citations, that induces us, at the beginning of this essay, intended to point out the results of the application of a new method to the study of Political Economy, to invoke the authority of a poet and moral- ist, of a jurisconsult and of a philosopher. The writer finds in the words just quoted the loftiest expression of the thought 1 II -yYj. shall never thoroughly understand the reason of customary law un- less we also have a knowledge of that which is not custom,ary. The one is connected and bound to the other. We have no slaves; why vex ourselves ^vith questions about slaves.'' — Words worthy of a novice." 2 " I am a man ; I think nothing foreign to me that pertains to man." 3 "That excellent and glorious philosophy." Vol. I.— I 2 PRELI^SIINARY ESSAY which dictates these lines, viz. : that the impartial researches of history, a profound feeling of man's moral and material wants, and the light of philosophy, should govern in the teaching of a science, the object of which is to show us how those things which are intended to satisfy our wants are produced and dis- tributed among the several classes or individuals of a nation ; how they are exchanged one against another, and how they are consumed. The nineteenth century affords us something more than the admirable spectacle of the rapid and fertile development of mechanical power and natural forces. This is but one of the aspects, we might even say but one of the results, of the gen- eral progress of the human mind. The renovation of moral and intellectual studies has served as a starting point for the application to facts of the conquests of thought. Science has preceded art. In the foremost rank of the studies just referred to is -philos- ophy^ which initiates us into the knowledge of human nature, the basis of right, and which translates its legitimate aspira- tions into a language which we can understand; history, that ■prophetess of the truth, as one of the ancients called it, which places before us the faithful picture of times past, not by simply putting together a skeleton of facts, but by following the living progress of events and the organic development of institutions. Such, at least, has been the work of those noble minds who have consecrated their energies to the resuscitation of ages past, in their true shape, and such is the service for w^hich we are indebted to them for the successful accomplish- ment of the reformation of historical studies, which they attempted with such rare devotion and such marvelous sa- gacity. This renovation of history has exerted the most fertile in- fluence in the region of philosoph}^, in that of law, and we believe that it will prove no less useful in that of Political Econ- omy. It has served to put us on our guard against being easily misled by a priori notions. ON THE HISTORICAL METHOD. 3 By exliri:)iting to us the results of the life and of the experi- ence of centuries, by teaching us by what steps the human mind has risen to its present eminence, and what the education given it in the past has been, it has enabled us to ascend from phenomena to the principles which preside over them ; from facts to the kiw ; and it has substituted for arbitrary assump- tions and purely ideal systems, the slow but progressive work of the genius of nations. Not that it turns a deaf ear to the exalted lessons of philosophy, nor that it denies the etonial 7'e- lations residting from the nature of things. Far from it. On the contrary, it supplies a solid basis to intellectual investiga- tions, and, so to speak, an answer for all the moral sciences, to this saying of Roederer: "Politics is a field which has been traversed thus far only in a balloon ; it is time to put foot on solid ground." Neither does history, as thus understood, confine itself to mere description ; it also assumes the office of judge. While it pulls down much that passion and inaccuracy have reared, and thus restores respect for the past, it does not turn that past into a fetish. It looks it boldly in the face and questions it, instead of prostrating itself before it and worshipping it with downcast eyes. Thus, by plainly showing us the many bonds which tie us to it, it escapes at once both the rashness of impatience and the wearisomeness of routine. The impartiality it inculcates is not indifference ; and there is no danger that the justice it metes out to past ages shall de- generate into a vain scepticism or a convenient optimism. The study of history, thus understood, has another advantage ; it accustoms us to those patient and disinterested investigations, to those lengthy labors, the positive result of which at first escapes us for a time, only to burst on our eyes, with so much more brilliancy, when rigorous research has succeeded in dis- covering it. It frees us from the deadly constraint of immedi- ate utility. There is nothinef more fatal to science than the feverish im- patience for results which obtains only too much in our own 4 PRELIMINARY ESSAY days, and which induces people to run after him who is in the greatest hurry, and which leads to hasty conclusions. "Research undertaken from a disinterested love of science," says the learned Hugo, one of the masters of the historical school of law in Germany,^ "that research which at first promises no other advantage but truth and the culture of the mind, is pre- cisely that which brings us the richest rewards. Would we not be behind, in all the sciences, if we had clung only to those principles, the utility of which in practice was already known? Do we not, to-day, from many a discovery, reap advantages of which its author never dreamed? " Doubtless this tendency, unless restrained by other demands, is not exempt from danger. We may be carried away by the attraction peculiar to these noble studies, withdraw into anti- quity and fall into a species of historical mysticism which ends in the affirmation, that whatever has been is true, absolutely, and which, instead of confining itself to the explanation of transitory phenomena, invests them with all the dignity of prin- ciples. We shall endeavor to avoid the peril pointed out by Mallebranche. "Learned men study rather to acquire a chimerical greatness in the imagination of other men, than to acquire greater breadth and strength of mind themselves. They make their heads a kind of store-room, into which they gather, without order or discrimination, everything which has a look of erudition, — I mean to say everything which may seem rare or extraordinary and excite the wonder of other people. They glory in getting together, in this archaeological museum, antiques with nothing that is rich or solid about them, and the price of which depends on nothing but fancy, chance or passion." A display of eruditon may obscure the truth, and bury it un- der its weight, instead of bringing it out into rehef By con- centrating the mind on the material vestiges of the past, it may withdraw it from the intellectual movement of the pres- ent, and give us a race of scholars, of great merit, doubtless, ^ Introduction to the Civilistisches Magazin. ON THE HISTORICAL METHOD. 5 but who move about like strangers among their contempo- raries. Without a sense for the practical, and without ideas of an elevated nature, a person may, indeed, be a man of erudition — he cannot be a historian. As the proverb says, the forest can- not be seen, for the trees. That this noble study may bear its best and most useful fruit ; that is, that it should preserve us against ambitious foi'niiilas and destructive chimeras, we must pursue another way. " The world," says Montaigne, " is incapable of curing it- self It is so impatient of what burthens it, that it thinks only of how it shall rid itself of it, without inquiring at what price. A thousand examples show us that it cures itself ordinarily at its own cost. The getting rid of the present evil is not cure, unless there be a greneral amendment of condition. Good does not immediately succeed evil. One evil, and a worse, may follow another, like Ccesar's assassins, who brought the republic to such a pass, that they had reason to repent the meddling with it." Such, too frequently, is the lot of those who, abandoning themselves to their imagination, and with- out consulting the past, mix together promises of liberty and the despotism of Utopias which they would impose on nations under pretext of enfranchising them. Despising the work of the ages, the}- think they can build upon a soil shaken by des- truction and crumbled, until it may be likened to moving sand. Contempt for the past is associated with a passion for reform. Men think of destroying that which should only be transformed. They condemn everything that has been, unconditionally, and launch out towards a new future. The suffering which has been gone through irritates and troubles the mind. The work of pulling down is so easy, it is sup- posed that the work of building up is equally so. Hence sys- tems rise, as if the world were to begin anew. The pride of liberty and of human action becomes the principle of science; and, like all new principles, it pretends to exclusive and abso- lute dominion. Rationalism governs; abstract philosophy 6 PRELIMINARY ESSAY ignores the traditions and the requirements of the life of nations ; and finds now in it, as in geometry, nothing but piinciples and deductions. The memory of recent oppression causes us to act as Tarquin did, and to level down the higher classes in- stead of elevating the inferior. Liberty and equality then gov- ern by their negative side, instead of exercising the positive and beneficent influence they should have, to develop all forces to their utmost, to ennoble the mind, to give more elasticity to the soul and greater vigor to thought, to give birth to those varied forms and to that moral energ}'-, which should bring us nearer to final equality in the bosom of God.^ We forget that no one is hornyree, and that every one ought to endeavor to become so, Feindlich ist des Mannes Streben Mit zermalmender Gewalt • Geht der Wilde durch des Leben Ohne Rast und Aufenthalt, — Scliiller. and make himself worthy of liberty, by the exercise of manly virtue ! Because the form has been changed, we believe that we have changed human nature. It is easy to understand, why, where these ideas prevail, the study of the past should be neglected and despised. Efforts are made to avoid it. Why, it is asked, revive memories of oppression and misery? The old world is wrecked. It is annihilated. Peace to its ashes! Or else, after it has been destroyed, it is sought for again; and, under pretext of eradi- cating the evils existing in it, an attack is made on the eternal basis on which human society rests, on the laws not made by man, and which it is not given to man to change. The world becomes one vast laboratory, in which the rashest experiments are multiplied in number, in which mankind is but clay in the hands of the potter which every pretended "thinker" may mould at will, by giving him the false appearances of inde- pendence and of an emancipated being. ' Dunoycr, De la Liberte du Travail. ON TILE HISTORICAL METHOD. 7 And, indeed, if the will of man be all-powerful, if states are to be distinguished from one another only by their boundaries, if everything may be changed like the scenery in a play by a flourish of the magic wand of a system, if man may arbitrarily make the right, if nations can be put through evolutions like a regiment of troops; what a field would the world present for attempts at the realization of the wildest dreams, and what a temptation would be offered to take possession, by main force, of the government of human affairs, to destroy the rights of property and the rights of capital, to gratify ardent longings without trouble, and provide the much coveted means of en- joyment. The Titans have tried to scale the heavens, and have fallen into the most degrading materialism. Purely speculative dogmatism sinks into materialism. All is changed, both men and things. Yet we hear the same old style of declamation. There are those who wish to plough up the soil which the harrow of the revolution went over yesterday; and they believe they are marching in the way of progress. They do not see that they have mistaken their age, and that the bold attempts of the past have now come to possess a directly opposite meaning. Without stop- ping to inquire to wiiat side the new world inclines, they re- peat the same words, and swear in verba maglstri, and go the road of destruction, believing themselves to be creating the world anew! Nothing is more natural than that these excesses should produce other excesses, in a contrary direction. Moved by hatred or fear of revolutionary absolutism, nations seek an asylum in governmental absolutism, or they retrograde to- wards the middle ages, and consider the mutual bond of pro- tection and dependence of that period as the ideal and the realization of true liberty. History is no longer the organic development of social life, and man, like a soldier that thoughtlessly and capriciously has gone beyond his place of supplies, is obliged to retrace his steps. The reaction is clearly defined. The past is opposed to the present, not as a 8 PRELIMINARY ESSAY lesson to be turned to advantage, but as a model which must be hastily accepted ; and men become revolutionary in a back- ward direction. However, history, rigorously studied, knows neither these complaisances nor these weaknesses. It does not descend to the apotheosis of a past which cannot return again. The real historical spirit consists in rightly discerning what belongs to each epoch. Its object is, by no means, to call back the dead to life, but to explain why and how they lived. In harmony with a healthy philosophy, it assigns a limit to the vagaries of arbitrary will, beyond which the latter cannot go. It unceas- ingly calls us back, from the heights of abstraction, to positive facts and things. In the creation of systems, only one thing was wont to be forgotten, men, who were treated, in them, like so many ciphers ; for intellectual despotism has this in common with all despotic authority. History teaches us that we can reach nothing great or lasting, but by addressing ourselves to the soul. If the soul decays, there can be no longer great thoughts or great actions. Society lives by the spirit which inhabits it. It may, for an instant, submit to the empire of force, but, in the long run, it hearkens only to the voice of justice. It was thus that the greatest revolution which history records, that of Christianity, was accomplished. It addressed itself only to the soul ; but by changing the hearts of men, it transformed society entirely. The violent struggle between an imperious dogmatism and an unintelligent and mistaken attempt at a retrogressive move- ment is resolved into a higher view, which permits the union of conservatism and progress. ^ Violent attempts and rash en- deavors made, threatened to bring contempt on the noblest teachings of philosophy, and to make them repulsive to man ; and, on the other hand, a blind respect for the institutions con- secrated by history threatened to stifle all examination and all freedom of judgment. But a healthier doctrine has permitted us to understand, that ON THE HISTORICAL METHOD. 9 we are continuing the work of preceding generations ; that we are developing the germs which they successively sowed; that we are perfecting that which they had only sketched, and that we are letting drop that which has no support in the social condition of man. Every thing is connected; each thing is linked to every other; nothing is repeated. The hopes of sudden and total renovation, based on absolute for- mulas, vanish before the touch of this solid study. This shows us how firm and unshaken are those reforms which have be- gun by taking hold of the minds of men, the precise spirit of which had penetrated into the souls of whole nations before they had manifested themselves in facts. Law and Economy constitute a part of the life of nations in the same way that language and customs do. The power of history in no way contradicts the supremacy of reason. II. These two tendencies, the rationalistic and the historical, are everywhere found face to face. They carry on an eternal warfare, which is renewed in every age, under new names and new forms. Accomplished facts and renovating thought divide the world between them. They at one time moderate its speed, and at others, spur it on its way. But these two forces, instead of compromising the destinies of humanity by their opposing action, maintain and balance them, as the con- trary impulses given by the hand of the Great Architect has peopled the universe with worlds which gravitate in space. Victor Cousin, a very competent authority on the subject, has said that the history of philosophy is the torch of philoso- phy itself The remarkable works which have enriched it in this direction are well known. History, on its side, is en- lightened by philosophy. Thus, it teaches us not to despise facts, but at the same time not to be slaves to precedent. It does equal justice to the incredulous and to the fanatic, to too supple practitioners and to intractable theorizers. 10 PRELIMINARY ESSxVY We may doubtless say with Henri Klimrath, who, in con- nection with a few others, had undertaken the work of the restoration of historical study in its application to French law, that there is an absolute, true, beautiful, good and just, the 7'atio recta suinmi Jovis^ the supreme reason founded in the nature of things.^ The eternal truths taught by philosophy constitute the higher law, a law which dates not from the day on which it was reduced to writing, but from the day of its birth; and it was born with the divine intelligence itself '■'■^d non tmn denique incifit lex esse, cum serif ta est, sea turn cum oj^ta est. Orta autem simul est cum metite divinaP^ And Troplong rightly adds : " There are rules anterior to all posi- tive laws. I cannot grant that the action of conscience and the idea of right are the work of the legislatoi-. It is not law that made the family, property, hberty, equality, the idea of good and evil. It may, indeed, give organization to all these things, but in doing so, it is only working on the foundation which nature has laid, and it is perfect in proportion as it comes nearer to the eternal, immutable laws which the Creator has engraved on our hearts. What changes is not the eternal law, the revelation of which comes to man incessantly and by a necessary action, but the form in which humanity clothes it, the institutions which man builds on its immutable foundation."^ We therefore believe in the law of nature, and regret that our opinion is not shared by Mr. Roscher, at least that he does not explicitly enough express his faith in it, nor apply it broadly enough in the beautiful work which we are happ}'' to ren- der accessible to the French public.^ We believe in it in its ' Cicero^ De Leg., i. * Discours Preliminaire du Code Civil. 3 Cicero, De Leg., II, 4. " Legem neque hominum ingeniis excogitatam, nee scitum aliquod esse populorum, sed ZEternum quiddam quod universuni mundum regeret, imperandi, prohibendique sapientia." Ibid. 4 Revue de Legisl. et de Jurispr. (1S41, XIII, p. 39.) Montesquieu says: "The relations of justice and equity are anterior to all positive laws." 5 Mr. Wolowski translated the second edition of Roscher's Principles into OK THE HISTORICAL METHOD. H philosophical sense, aiid not simply in the juridical sense at- tached to it by Ulpian. "Let us not," observes Portalis, " confound the physical order of nature, common to all ani- mated beings, with the natural law which is peculiar to man. We call natural Iazt\ the principles which govern man consid- ered as a moral being, that is, as an intelligent and free being, intended to live in the society of other beings, intelligent and free like himself"^ Ulpian's famous tripartite division, of nat- ural law, the law of nations, and the civil law, is proof, from the meaning he attaches to them, either of a misunderstand- ing or of the imperfect idea which the Stoics had conceived of the essence of natural law. In vain Cujas exhausted all the resources of his noble intellect to explain it.^ French, and prefixed the present essay thereto as a preface. Since Wol- owski's translation appeared, the original work has gone through eleven edi- tions, been largely increased in size, and enriched -svith new notes, the re- sult of nearly twenty additional years of research and thought. The thir- teenth German edition, from which the present translation is made, is larger than the fii-st by one hundred and seventy pages. — Translator's }iote. ' And he adds : " Animals which yield only to an impulse or blir^d instinct, come together only fortuitiously or periodically and in a manner destitute of all morality. But in the case of men, reason is mixed up more or less with every act of their lives. Sentiment is found side by side with desire, and right succeeds instinct. I discover a real contract in the union of the two sexes." It would be impossible to present a more coniplete or eloquent refutation of the definition of the Roman jurisconsults which debases marriage to the level of the promiscuous coming together of animals, and which limits the natural law to the law common to man and beast. "Jus naturale est quod natura omnia animalia docuit; nam jus istud non humani generis proprium, sed omnium animalium qua; in terra, qua; in mare nascuntur, avium quoquc commune est. Hinc descendit maris atque feminoe conjunctio, quam nos matrimonium appellamus, hinc liberorum procreatio, hinc educatio; videmus etenim caetera quoque animalia, feras etiam, istius juris peritia censeri." D. L. I, De Just, et Jure. ^ Comment, in tit. Dig., De Just, et Jure, VII, nth Naples edition. The in- genious argument of the great jurisconsult falls to the ground under the beauti- ful words of Cicero : " Ut justitia, ita jus sine ratione non consistit ; soli ratione utentes jure ac lege vivunt." De Natura Dcorum, II, 62. Virtus ratione constat, brutic ratione non utuntur, cujus sunt expertia, ergo jure non vivunt, et ut rationis, sic jures sunt expertia." Besides, Cujas himself recognizes 12 PRELIMINARY ESSAY It is necessary to draw a distinction between physical law and the law {draii) of intelligent beings. Doubtless the ex- istence of men as well as that of animals is limited by time. They both live and die ; but the soul escapes the necessities of material nature. The moment there is question of rights intelligence governs, reason comes into play, and the science of right and wrong is appealed to as a guide. Hence the natural law of the human species is not the physical law which all creatures obey. It was necessary for us to insist upon these principles. It was necessary for us to show that there is a law independent of positive and local law, a law which is not the expression of an arbitrary will, but an emanation from the nature of things.^ Hence come the features in common which we meet with everywhere, and the variable forms which develop law in har- mony with the special conditions of each civil society. We must descend into the very depths of human nature to discover these eternal and permanent laws; and if the mere eftbrt of the mind should not reach them directly, they might be discovered in the phenomena of the life of nations. His- tory affords us the counter-proof and confirmation of the phil- osophical doctrine. The development of society does not afford a mathemati- cal expression of these higher truths. It gives them a form which is unceasingly modified in the written law. The person who discovers in them nothing but an absolute rule, looks upon the changes as evidences of caprice or error. He alone understands the revolutions of things who knows their cause and the necessity which produces them. how faulty and incomplete was the definition he was defending : " At ne jus quidem naturale, de quo agimus, est commune omnium animalium quatenus rationale, est, sed quatenus sensible est, sensui congruit. Tullius participare hominem cum brutis. eo quod sentit, sed ratione ab eo differre. Et alio loco : jus naturale esse commune omnium Quiritium, veluti ut se velint tueri: sed hoc distare hominem a bellua, quod bellua sensu moveatur, homo etiam ra- tione." ' Rossi. ON THE HISTORICAL METHOD. 13 Solon was right when he gave the Athenians not the most perfect laws, but the best which they could bear. It is not in the attempts contemporary with the infancy of society, or nearly so, that we are to look for the complete reali- zation of the precepts of the natural law ; for principles obey the rule laid down by Aristotle. " The nature of each thing is precisely that which constitutes its end; and when each be- ing has attained its entire development, we say that that is its own proper nature." ^ The ideas of natural law are purified in proportion as soci- ety grows enlightened and free; but the truth appears only successively in the phases it passes through. It allows us to grasp one aspect of itself after another, but does not surrender itself entirely, at an}^ one moment, to the investigations of the historian or the jurisconsult. History and philosophy interpenetrate and complement one another. III. The two schools, that of philosophy and that of history have met in our day, in the field of law. Who is there that does not remember the great and noble contest carried on, about the beginning of this century, between two descend- ants of Frenchmen who had sought a refuge in Germany, and who united in their own persons, and in so marvelous a manner, the different aptitudes of the country they owed their origin to, and of the land that gave them birth, — between Thi- baut and Savigny? It would be difficult to find a scientific question of a higher character, debated by champions more worthy to throw light upon it. The Code Napoleon had appeared. It had, to use Rossi's happy expression, transferred into law the social revolution > Politics, I, ch. I, II. 14: PRELIMINARY ESSAY produced by the destruction of privilege. It was the practical formula expressive of the conquests which had been made. The philosophy of the eighteenth century had previously inspired the Prussian Code. And yet, it was on the question of codification that this memorable controversy was carried on. The two principal combatants, while manfully battling, the one against the other, continued to hold each other in high esteem, and the profound study of law was developed in the midst of the melee. We cannot delay long on this subject, nor analyze the argu- ments advanced by Thibaut ^ and Savigny.^ What interests us at present is not so much the question debated, as the intellectual movement to which it gave birth. Savigny sus- tained the ancient law, Thibaut attacked it. Numerous and distinguished jurisconsults ranged themselves on the one side and the other. A new school grew up which, with the most brilliant success, made law throw light on history and history on law. The application of the historical method to the study of law was productive of the most happy results. Without acknowledging it to themselves, the chiefs of the contending parties were each obeying a political impulse. Savigny was by his birth and his tastes carried into the camp of conservatism ; Thibaut, led by his convictions, into the lib- eral ranks. Nevertheless, the natural elevation of their genius preserved them from all exaggeration. The glorious defender of tradition preserved a liberal spirit, and the ardent advocate of reform desired no upheaval. In what more nearly concerns the question with which we are now occupied, Savigny — while he maintained that law was something contingent, human, national; and while he brought out into relief the practical and exalted character of its succes- sive developments which introduced reform and guarded * Ueber die Nothwendigkeit eines Allgemeinen burgerlichen Rechts fur Deutschland. * Vom Beruf unserer Zeit fur Gesetzgebung, etc. ON THE HISTORICAL METHOD. 15 against revolution — developments which, not confiding in the letter of the written law, unceasingly feed the living and created law, that law called in the energetic language of a great jurisconsult, a law Ccrit es cocurs dcs citoyens — is far from denj'ing the importance of a high and healthy philosophy which directs man in the uninterrupted labor to which he is called, in the sphere of jurisprudence. JNIen can no more renounce law than language, the forms of which last the}' have gradually modified in order to better translate their thoughts into words. The legislator's task is the successive elaboration of obligatory provisions. He will sometimes oppose and sometimes second the natural progress of law ; but, in doing so, it wall ever be necessary for him to ascend to the nature of things, and grasp their relations, if he would not go astray in practice, or lose himself among the successive and partial changes to which the illustrious Berlin professor would confine the legitimate ambition of legislative power. To go beyond this, in an age like ours, seemed to him to be a work of destruction. However, far from den3ang the influence of thought, and therefore of philosophy, acting within its sphere, Savign}'- invokes its fertile aid. Thibaut, on the other hand, with more confidence in the powers of the spirit of modern times, did not believe a good codification to be impossible. His starting point had been a cry for national independence He well knew how much vene- ration was due those institutions which were the slow and pro- gressive work of national genius, and what w\as the power they possessed. He wished, therefore, to reform, not to abolish them. He well understood that the greatness of the Code jVa~ ■poleon itself, and the respect w^hich it inspired were due to the fact that its roots ran deep into the soil of the past, even while the modern idea it contained shone like a bright light in the world of things. Hence, without contesting the value of his- tory, he refused to acknowledge its right to exclusive reign.^ 1 In one of his latest productions (Ueber die sogennante historische und nicht historische Rechtsschule, Archives du Droit Civil, Heidelberg, XXI 1G PRELIMINARY ESSAY The life and activity prevailing in the study of law^, and the brilliant successes that study has recently achieved, are due, in great part, to the illustrious representatives of the historical school. We may add, here, that the French historical school, which has so worthily inherited the spirit of Montesquieu, has not achieved less in this direction than the older German school. It has reconciled the opposing but not mutually hos- 183S) the veteran of the philosophical school, resuming a debate begun a quar- ter of a century before, energetically defends himself against the erroneous in- terpretations which it was sought to give to his thoughts. " Does it follow," he inquires, " that because a man is desirous of reform, he must surrender the study of the past? And if there be new laws to construe, how could his evil genius deter him from the necessary knowledge of ancient laws? Is there a single jurisconsult, who, in the hope of a better future, despises the meaning and spirit of that which still exists? I do not know even one And when I am accused of passing by the institutions of the past with cold- ness and hatred in my heart, because I was one of the first to express the hope of a better future, a charge is laid at iny door which is perfectly incom- prehensible .... I am reproached with despising the history of law. It is a slander on me. Although I have only laughed at these reports, one man's mistake grieved me; for that man's name was Niebuhr When he [Niebuhr] returned from Italy to devote himself entirely to science, in his retreat at Bonn, he passed through Heidelberg, where he remained five or six days. During a great part of that time we came frequently together. He was at first a little cold ; but Cicero made us friends. After a happy word let drop concerning that writer, he asked me what I thought of him. I answered laconically: 'If they were burning all the Latin authors, and I were permited to grant a pardon to one of them, I should say, without hesitation: Spare the works of Cicero.' He joyfully exclaimed: 'I have at last found a man who judges rightly of Cicero. I share your admiration for him, and that is the reason I have given my boy the name of Marcus.' The ice was now broken, and he frankly told me that he could not under- stand how I could be an inveterate enemy of Roman law and of the history of law. I gave him to understand that I had simply been slandered, and I added, that, in order to live entirely with the classics, I had always refused to give legal advice, or act as a counsellor, although I might have made a fortune in that way. I told him that I owed my gayety and vigor, in great part, to my love for the classics of all ages, even those outside the domain of jurisprudence; but that I held, above all things, to the good qualities of the German nation, and that I did not hesitate to say with Facciolatus: 'Expedit omnes gentes Romanis legibus operam dare, suis vivere.' " When he heard those words of mine, he exclaimed with his usual energy ON THE HISTORICAL METHOD. 17 tile, tendencies of Savigny and Thibaut. It has conscien- tiously scrutinized facts to show their concatenation, and to allow their meaning and bearing to be clearly grasped. A French jurisconsult, who is at the same time our highest au- thorit}' in the natural law, opened the way by his excellent es- says on the necessity of reforming the historical studies appli- cable to law ; on the influence of the legists on French civiliza- tion ^ etc. ; and by his prefaces, equal in value to whole works, on hypothecation, sales, loans, partnership, charter-parties etc. He may truly be said to have renewed the ancient and prolific alliance of history and law. Instead of pursuing a pure abstraction, this historical school has confined itself to the knowledcfe of the life of man and the evolution of society. It has applied to law, with what success is well known, the principle which has regenerated the social sciences, philosophy, letters, history. Political Economy, — sci- ences which are, so to speak, different provinces of one intel- lectual empire, which interpenetrate one another without being confounded one with another, between which no jealous bar- rier should be raised, and between which reciprocity of ex- change should be encouraged by the suppression of factitious duties, which have existed only too long. and vivacity : ' Habes me consentientem, labcs mc consentientem.' From that moment all coldness between us Avas at an end, and we approached, without any embarrassment, a host of questions in one conversation in which I endeavored, as I had before, to learn from him. "Thus I receive with sincere gratitude, all the worses, both useful and pro- found, which have appeared in our day on the history of law. It would be folly in me to deny the impetus which the study of positive law has re- ceived. New sources have been discovered. Their newness and import- ance have excited the zeal of many scholars who have studied them pro- foundly ; a fact which made a review of the older sources, still by far the most important, necessary. These two circumstances soon rendered it im- perative to proceed to the making of scrupulous dogmatic researchc'^. Thus there now is a new life among jurisconsults, and a great activity, which, it is my hope, may continue long." ' Revue dc Legisl. et de Jurisprudence, 1834-35. Vol. L— 2 18 PRELIMINARY ESSAY IV. We need not dwell any longer on the character of the his- torical method as applied to law, nor on the services it has already rendered. On this point, there can be no two opinions. And, if any one wonders that we should speak of it at all, in a work on Political Economy, we can only say to him, that we have done so to call his attention to an instructive precedent, and for the further reason that the same method is peculiarly well adapted to the study of Political Economy. Its advantages are the same here, its tendencies the same, and the same mo- tives exist to induce us to use it here. In describing the suc- cessive phases of the question in the case of law, we have performed an important part of the task we had imposed upon ourselves, of vindicating the employment of the historical method, in the sphere of Political Economy. The study of history is the best and most powerful antidote against social romances and ideal fancies. Francois Beau- douin was right when he said: " Cceca sine historia jurisfru- dentia;'''' and we are very sure that, without history as an element in it, Political Economy runs a great risk of walking blindfold. The human mind has need of being able to know where it is at any moment, surrounded, as it is, by so many roads, run- ning in so many different directions. It ought to account to itself for its progress, its deviations from the right path, and for its mistakes.^ JHistory alone can throw any light on ques- tions which are not simply intellectual curiosities, but which, rather, are most deeply concerned with the vital interests of society. It confirms the noble teachings of philosophy, by showing how our life is made up of one unchanging tissue of relations, and how man, even if he may vary their colors, and change their design, cannot renew their texture. It teaches us to admire nothing, and to despise nothing, be- ^ Rossi. ON THE HISTORICAL METHOD. 19 yond measure. It enlightens us concerning questions of a very complicated nature. Witnessing the evolutions of hu- manity, following the development of social facts and theories, we better discern principles, and grow wary in relation to the alchemists of thought, who imagine that society may be made to undergo a transformation betw^een the rising and the setting of the sun. As there is a natural law, so, too, there are certain princi- ples of Political Economy which emanate from philosophy, and may be reduced to one supreme principle ; that of liberty and responsibility. The domain of Political Economy is the labor of generations. But we reject with all our strength, the ma- terialistic doctrine which, inexplicably confusing matters, en- deavors to assimilate ideas so distinct as intelligence and things ; and which would descend so low as to employ the dynamometer to measure the creative force of man and its re- sults, and which sees only figures where there is a living soul. Man is an intelligent being, served by organs,^ by -personal organs, with which the Creator has endowed him, by giving him a body provided with marvellous aptitudes, by external organs which he finds in nature subjected to his power. Man was created in the image of God, say the Scriptures, and these words contain a deep meaning. He alone, of all terres- trial beings, possesses a spark of divine intelligence. He alone has been called to pursue the magnificent work of creation, by giving a new face to a world to which he cannot add so much as an atom. Labor is nothing but the action of spirit on itself and on matter.^ Hence its dignity and grandeur. Hence, also, the difficulties in the way of economic studies; since, to consider them only as concerned with questions of material production, is to forget that the products of industry are made for man, not man for industrial products; to ignore the close relation- ' M. de Bonald. ^ M. C<>?^«'« has brought this out in an admirable manner in his lectures on Adam Smith. Cours de Philosophie Moderne. 20 PRELIMINARY ESSAY ship between their fruitful investigations and the whole circle of the moral sciences ; to debase them and to mutilate them. From the moment that science concerns itself with man only, and the action of the mind ; from the moment that its end becomes not simply material enjoyment, but moral elevation, the questions it discusses become indeed more complex, but the answer, when found, is more prolific in results. Wealth, then, is treated only as one of the forces of civilization. Other interests than purely material ones occupy the first place. This matter-of-fact philosophy which, according to Bacon's precept, seeks to improve the conditions of life, bears in mind, that the most fruitful source of material development lies in intellectual development. It humbly recognizes that it is not the first-born of the family, and draws new strength from this avowal. From the moment that it is the mind which -produces and which governs the world, intellectual and moral perfection become the cause and effect of material progress. " But seek ye first the kingdom of God and his righteousness, and all these things shall be added unto you." The increase of production, then, appears an instrument of elevation in the moral order,^ It is energy of soul, intelligence and manly virtue which constitute the chief source of the wealth of nations ; which create it, develop it, and preserve it. Wealth increases, declines, and disappears with the increase, decline and disappearance of these noble attributes of the soul. Labor is the child of thought. Nothing happens in the ex- ternal world which was not first conceived in the mind. The hand is the servant of the intellect ; and its work is successful, beautiful or useful in proportion to the activit}'^ and develop- ment of the intellect, and in proportion as the just, the beauti- ful and the good exert their power over it. Production is, therefore, not a material, but a spiritual, work. How, then, can acts and their morality be separated? How not understand that the market of labor has its own distinct ' Chantiins^. ON THE HISTORICAL METHOD. 21 laws, and that education, even from a material stand-point, be- comes the highest interest and the most important duty of society, since on it depends the efficiency of labor? From the time that, after a long series of years, the doctrine of Christianit}^ had permeated the law of the civilized w^orld; from the time that the teaching of Paul, that all men are chil- dren of one Father, took form and body, and that the principle of the equality of all men before their Maker, was supple- mented by the doctrine and by the practice of that equality before the laws, the thinking masses have endeavored to dis- cover the wherefore of their actions, and the why of their suf- ferings. They have called the past to account, and inquired why they have obtained so limited a share. The people, therefore, think; and it is, therefore, a matter of im.portance that they should think aright. It is of importance, that they should be guarded against fallacious Utopian prom- ises. Henceforth, there is no security for the stabiUty of the world but in the contentment of minds. There is no rest for mankind, unless men will understand the conditions of their destiny ; unless, instead of running, " Tovijours insatiable et jamais assouvis," after the intoxicating cup of material enjoyment — for wants not governed by the intellect and the heart are infinite in num- ber, and the gratification of one gives birth to another — they submit to the law of sacrifice, and give play to the noblest faculty with which the Creator has endowed us, moral empire over self. "We shall meet on this road, hard of ascent, not only peace of soul, but goods, more real and more numerous, than those with which the allurements of error would dazzle our eyes. The greatest obstacles to be overcome are not material ones, but moral difficulties. As Franklin says, in substance, he that tells you you can succeed, in any way but by labor and econ- omy, is a quack. But labor is more productive in proportion as it is more in- 22 PRELIMINARY ESSAY telligent, as hand and mind keep pace with each other, as good moral habits generate order and voluntary discipline. Economy is sacrifice, binding the present to the future, widening the horizon of thought, inspiring foresight, lengthen- ing the lever of human activit}-, by providing it with new in- struments. Life ceases to be a worry about how the body shall be sus- tained, and the material world becomes the shadow of the spiritual. The former is made to serve the latter, and man's free effort lifts him into a higher region of thought, and into a larger field of action. The more mind there is put into a piece of work, says Channing, the more it is worth. We, men of to-day, are lookers-on at a marvelous spectacle. Steam furrows the earth. Industry has taken an immense start. Mechanical force bends the most rebellious materials. Chemistry, physics and the natural sciences are discovering a new world. But whence all this? What is the principle of this new life? We answer: intellectual and moral progress. Mind has grown ; the soul has been expanded. God has per- mitted man to be free, and furnished him with the means to be so. Thus man, as Mignet has said, becomes that Inighty creature to whom God has given the earth for the vast theater of his action, the universe as the inexhaustible object of his knowl- edge, the forces of nature for the growing service of his wants, by allowing him, by ever increasing information, to obtain an ever increasing amount of well-being. Man is free. — 1 789 put in action the sublime precept of the gospel. He holds his destiny in his own hands. But the rights which he enjoys impose new duties on him. If equality be the sentiment which predominates in our day, we should take care not to confound it with the leveling of Communism. Nor is it externally to us, but within ourselves, that it should be developed, by intellectual and moral culture. History preserves the student from being led astray by a too servile adherence to any system. It exposes the folly of the ON THE HISTORICAL ISIETHOD. 23 " social contract," and of the idyllic dreams of the advantages of savage life. It shows that nature, instead of being prodigal of her treasures, distributes them with a niggardly hand, and that it is necessary to conquer her by labor, intelligence and pa- tience before we can control her. It shows us human liberty growing stronger every day, thanks to moral and intellectual progress, supported by the two powerful props of property, the complement of man, the material reflection of his spiritual power; and capital, the fruit of abstinence, the symbol of moral power and the result of enlightened activity. History w'alks with a firm step, because it feels secure in a knowledge of the laws of human nature, and in its experience of the sucessive manifestations of social life. Instead of the vagueness of ideal conceptions, it allows us to grasp and to appreciate what is real in life. It does not confine itself to the study of man. It makes us acquainted with men, whose wants extend and are ennobled in proportion to the perfection of their faculties. The feelings and the intellect are simul- taneously developed in man. The savage is the most egotis- tical of men. Hence, we believe that Political Economy cannot dispense with the services of morals and philosophy, of history and law; for these are branches of one common trunk, through aU of which the self-same sap circulates. V. The isolation of the theory of Political Economy is peculiar to our own day. In more remote times, we find this study confounded with the other moral sciences, of which it was an integral part. When the genius of Adam Smith gave it a distinct character, he did not desire to separate it from those branches of knowledge without which it could only remain a bleached plant from the absence of the sunlight of ethics. 24 PRELIMINARY ESSAY We must renounce the singular idea,^ that thousands of years could pass awa}^ without leaving any trace of what en- lio-htened men had thought and elaborated in the matter of Political Economy, among so. many nations, and that people should never have thought of cultivating this rich intellectual domain, while in every other direction, it is easy for us to as- cend by a road already cleared up to the most remote antiquity. It has already been acknowledged, that the classic domain^ fertilized by intellectual culture on a large scale and on a small one, was exceedingly rich in valuable indications, although they do not present themselves under the distinct form, which later affected the different branches of public life. As to the pretended ■primitive simplicity of the middle ages, which it is claimed, prevailed during that period, a species of economic vegetation, those who maintain it forget the long series of communistic theories which, at near intervals, found expression in many a bloody struggle, and whose repression re- quired the combined efforts of Church and State. Doubtless, it is not in their modern forms that the elements of politico-economical science are to be found, in the past. But when we succeed in reuniting the scattered and broken parts; when we have made our way into the customs, decrees, ordi- nances, capitularies, laws and regulations of those times ; when, so to speak, we come, unaware, upon the life of nations, in the most ingenuous and confidential documents which reflect it most faithfully because most simply, we may well be astonished at the results obtained. Where we expected, perhaps, to find only erudition, we reap a rich harvest of lessons which are all the more valuable for being disinterested. Legislative and administrative acts frequently develop real economic doctrines. It is easy to discover in them the onward course of a theory which plunges directly into practical appli- cations. What results might we not expect from these efforts, if the ' Knies. Die politische CEkonomic vom Standpunkte der geschichtlicheu Methode, Braunschweig, 1853. ON THE HISTORICAL METHOD. 25 genius of investigation and of di^'ination, which has so ele- vated historical studies in our da}^ should have an observing and penetrating eye in this direction! How limited was the field on which Gu6rard erected the scientific monument which he has left us in his Polypiquc d'' Irminon; and how precious are the lessons he leaves us, since we have here to do, not W'ith the histor}- of professed doctrines or unlooked-for events, but with the historical development of economic society which shows us the living march of principles. VI. Political Economy is not, as we have just said, a new sci- ence. It has been a distinct science only a short time. Until the eighteenth century, it was confounded with philosophy, morals, politics, law and history. But it does not follow, that, because it has grown so in importance, as to deserve a place of its own, its intimate relationship with the noble studies which had until then absorbed it should cease. There is an- other consequence also to be deduced from this. From the moment that Political Economy ceases to be considered a new science, it finds a long series of ancestors behind it, since it is compelled to investigate a past to which so many bonds unite it. This duty may increase its difficulties, but, at the same time, it singularly adds to the attractions of a study which, in- stead of presenting us onl}^ with the arid deductions of dog- matism, comes to us with iill the freshness and all the color of life. We may allow those who make Political Economy simply a piece of arithmetic to ignore these retrospective studies and their importance; for mathematics has little to do with his- tor}'. But it is otherwise with the life of nations. These would discover whence they come, in order to learn whither they are tending. The}^ are not obeying a vain interest of curiosity, as J. B. Say supposed, when, in sketching a short history of the prO' 26 PRELIMINARY ESSAY gress of Political Economy, he said: " However, every kind of history has a right to gratify curiosity." It is a thing to be regretted, that this eminent thinker could thus ignore one of the essential elements of the science to which he rendered such great and unquestioned services. A sense for the his- torical was wanting in him. " The history of a science," he writes,^ " is not like the narration of things that have happened. What would it profit us to make a collection of absurd opin- ions, of decried doctrines which deserved to be decried ? It would be at once useless and fastidious to thus exhume them in case we perfectly knew the public economy of social bod- ies. It can be of little concern to us to learn what our pred- ecessors have dreamed about this subject, and to describe the long series of mistakes in practice which have retarded man's progress in the research after truth. Error is a thing to be forgotten, not learned." As if that which was once to be found in time is not to-day to be found in space ; as if there ever was an institution that did not have its raison d'' etre and had not constituted a resting place in the search after a higher truth or of a more intelligent and salutary application of an old one! There are a great many actual S3^stems and a great many present facts which can be understood only by the help of history; and how frequently would not an acquaintance with history serve to keep us from taking for marvelous in- ventions the antiquated machinery of other ages, whose only advantage and only merit are that they have remained un- known. How much of the pretended daring of innovators has been old trumpery which the wisdom of the times had cast off as rubbish. Besides, as Bacon has said: "Verumtamen s^pe necessarium est, quod non est optimum." ' Cours Complet d' Economie politique, II, 540, ed. Guillaumin. ON THE HISTORICAL METHOD. 27 VII. It is not the result of mere chance that the greatest econo- mists have been both historians and philosophers. We need only mention Adam Smith, Turgot, Malthus, Sismondi, Droz, Rossi and Leon Faucher. It is too frequently forgotten that the father of modern Political Economy, Adam Smith, looked upon the science as only one part of the course of moral phi- losophy which he taught at Glasgow, and which embraced four divisions: 1. Universal theology. — The existence and attributes of God; principles or faculties of the human mind, the basis of religion. 2. Ethics. — Theory of the moral sentiments. • 3. Moral principles relating to justice. — • In this, as we learn from one of Adam Smith's pupils in a sketch preserved by David Stewart, he followed a plan which seems to have been suggested to him by Montesquieu. He endeavored to trace the successive advances of jurisprudence from the most barbarous times to the most polished. He carefully showed how the arts which minister to subsistence, and to the accumulation of property, act on laws and governments, and are productive of advances and changes in them analogous to those they ex- perience themselves. In the first part of his course, as we learn from the same authority, he examined the various political regulations not founded on the principle of justice but in expediency, the object of which is to increase the wealth, the power and the prosperity of the state. From this point of view, he consid- ered the political institutions relating to commerce, finance, the ecclesiastical and military establishments. His lectures on the different subjects constitute the substance of the work he after- wards published on the wealth of nations. A pupil of Hut- cheson, Adam Smith always applied the experimental method, " which, instead of losing itself in magnificent and hazardous 28 PRELIMINARY ESSAY speculations, attaches itself to certain and universal facts dis- covered to us by our own consciousness, by language, litera- ture, history and society."^ Before taking the professorship of philosophy, Adam Smith had taught beUeslettres and rhet- oric in Edinburgh, in 1748. He had written a work on the origin and formation of languages; and it was because he had profoundly studied the moral sciences that it was given to him to inaugurate a new science and to become a great economist. Mr. Cousin has laid great stress on Adam Smith's taste and talent for history. " Whatever the subject he treats, he turns his eyes backward over the road traversed before himself, and he illuminates every object on his path by the aid of the torch which reflection has placed in his hand. Thus, in Political Economy, his principles not only prepare the future but renew the past, and discover the reason, heretofore unknown, of ancient facts which history had gathered together without un- derstanding them. It is not saying enough to remark that Adam Smith possessed a great variety of historical informa- tion ; we must add that he possessed the real historical spirit." Thanks to this eminent faculty of his, the Glasgow philoso- pher acquired great influence over minds. In 1810, when the French empire had reached the zenith of its greatness, Mar- witz wrote : " There is a monarch as powerful as Napoleon : Adam Smith." We need not recall Turgot's historical re- searches. Malthus' chief title to distinction, his work on Population, is as much a historical work as a politico-economical one ; and it is not sufficiently known that he was professor of history and Political Economy in the college of the East India Com- pany at A3'lesbury. We need say no more on this subject. The works of the other writers whom we have mentioned are too well known to permit an}^ one to think that they excluded history and moral science from the study of Political Economy. Hence ' Cousin. ON THE HISTORICAL METHOD. 29 the school which has risen up in Germany/ and which is en- deavoring to do for Pohtical Economy what Savigny, Eich- hom, Schrader, Mommsen, RudorlT, and so many other ilhis- trious scholars have done for jurisprudence, cannot be rightly accused of rashness. It has done nothing but unfurl the noble banner borne bv the most venerated masters of the science. VIII. At the head of this school stands William Roscher, profes- sor of Political Economy at the University of Leipzig, whose excellent work. The Principles of Political Economy, in which he follows the histoj'ical tnethod,, we have just translated. William Roscher is (1857) scarcely forty years of age. He w'as born at Hanover, October 21, 1817. His laborious and simple life is that of a worthy representative of the science. " You ask me,"' he wrote us recently, '• to give you some in- formation concerning the incidents of my life. I have, thank God, but very little to tell you. Lives whose history it is in- teresting to relate are seldom happy lives." He confined himself to giving us a few dates which are, so to say, the landmarks of a career full of usefulness. Roscher, from 1835 to 1839, studied jurisprudence and philology at the univer- sities of Gottingen and Berlin. The learned teachers who ex- ' We here append an extract from Hcinrich ContzerCs Geschichte, Liter- atur, und Bedeutung der Nationalokonomie, Cassel und Leipzig, 1S76, p. 7: " Roscher .... is rightfully considered the real founder and the principal rep- resentative of the historical school. This school is continually gaining in extent, and has found, both in Germany and in France, the most distin- guished disciples — men who honor Roscher as their teacher and master, the leader whose beacon light they follow. Roscher combines the richest posi- tive learning with rare clearness and plastic beauty in the presentation of his thought. These are conceded to him on every hand; and it does not de- tract from him, or alter the fact that he possesses them, that, here and there, an ill-humored or maliciously snappish critic calls them in question." It should be borne in mind here that Wolowski wrote in 1S57; Contzen, like Wolow ski, a politico-economical -writer of mark, in 1S76. — Translator's note. 30 PRELIMINARY ESSAY ercised the greatest influence on his intellectual development were the historians Gervinus and Ranke, the philologist K. O. Mliller and the Germanist Albrecht. It is easy to see that he went to a good school, and that he profited by it. He was made doctor in 1838; admitted in 1840 as Privat-docent at Gottingen; appointed in 1843 professor extraordinary at the same university, and called in 1844 to fill the chair of titular professor at Erlangen. Since 1848 he has acted in the same capacity in the University of Leipzig, where he was for six years member of the Poor Board, where he teaches also in the agricultural college. His fame has grown rapidly. Many of the German universities have emulated one another for the honor of possessing him, but he has not been willing to leave Leipzig. His first remarkable work was his doctor's thesis: De historiccB doctrincB a^iid sophistas majores vestigiis, written in 1838. In 1842, he published his excellent work, which has since become classical : " The Life, Labors and age of Thu- cydides." ^ From that time, important works, all bearing the stamp of varied and profound scientific acquirements, and of an erudition remarkable for sagacity and elegance, have fol- lowed one another without interruption. In 1843, he treated the question of luxury ^ with a master hand, and laid the foun- dation of his great work — only the first part of which has thus far appeared — at the same time tracing on a large scale the programme of a course of Political Economy according to the historical method.'' In 1844, he published his historical study on Socialism and Communism,* and in 1845 and 1846, his ideas on the poHtics and the statistics of systems of agri- culture. He is, besides, author of an excellent work on the » Leben, Werk und Zeitalter des Thukydides. "^Rail's Archiv., Heidelberg. This remarkable essay has since appeared in Roscher's Ansichten der Volkswirthschatt vom geschichtlichen Standpunkte, j86i. — Translator'' s note. 3 Grundriss zu Vorlesungen iiber die Staatswirthschaft nach geschichtlichet Methode. ■* Berliner Zeitschrift fiir allgem.-Geschichte. ON THE HISTORICAL METHOD. 31 corn-trade ;^ of a remarkable book on the colonial system.;'' of a sketch on the three forms of the state f of a memoir on the re- lations between Political Economy and classical antiquity;* of a work of the greatest interest, on the history of economic doctrines in England in the sixteenth and seventeenth centu- ries — a work full of the most curious researches;^ of a book on the economic principle of forest economy," and lastly, of the great work, the first part of which we have translated, under the title of The Principles of Political Economy, and which is to be completed by the successive publication of three other vol- umes, on the Political Economy of Agriculture, and the related branches of primitive production, the Political Economy of Industry and Commerce, and one on the Political Economy of the State and the Commune. This work, when completed, will be a real cyclopedia of the science^ Side by side with William Roscher, we must mention a ' Ueber Kornhandel und Theuerungspolitik, 3d ed., 1S52. 2 Untersuchungen tiber das Kolonialwesen. 3 Umrisse zur Naturlehre der drei Staatsformen (Berliner Zeitschrift, 1847- 1S4S). ■* Ueber das Verhiiltniss der Nationalokonomie zum klassischen Alter- thume (K. Sachs Akademie der Wissenschaft, 1S49). Also to be found in Roscher's Ansichten etc. — Translator. 5 Zur Geschichte der englischen Volkswirthschaftslehre im 16 und 17 Jahrh. * Ein nationalokonom. Princep der Forstwirthschaft. "^ Roscher'' s complete work he calls "A System of Political Economy." It embraces the four parts above referred to; but each of these parts constitutes an independent work. The first part, or the Pi-inciples of Political Economy, covers the ground generally covered by English treatises on Political Econ- omy. Besides the works above mentioned, Professor Roscher has written Ansich- ten der Volkswirtbschaftaus dem geschichtlichen Standpunkte, 2d ed., Leip- zig, 1861 ; Die deutche Nationalokonomik an der Grenzscheide de,s sechs- zehnten und siebenzehnten Jahrhunderts, Leipzig, 1862 ; Griindungsgeschi- chte des Zollvereins, Berlin, 1S70; Betrachtungen iiber die geographische Lage der grosscn Stadte, Leipzig, 1871; Bcrtrachtungen iiber die Wjihrungs- frage der deutschen Mijnzreform, Berlin, 1872 ; Geschichte der National- okonomik in Dcutschland, Munich, 1874; Nationalokonomik des Acker- baues, Sth ed., Stuttgart, 1875. — Translator'' s note. 32 PRELIMINARY ESSAY young economist, Knies, formerly professor at the University of Marburg, but whom political persecution compelled to ac- cept a secondary position at the gymnasium of Schaffhausen, for a time, and who fills, to-day, in the University of Freiburg, in Breisgau, a position more worthy of his great talent. We hope, in a work which we intend to publish, on Political Economy in Germany, to make the public acquainted with the works of this writer. They deserve to attract the most seri- ous attention. We know of few works which equal his Polit- ical Economy, written on the historical method.^ We shall also have something to say of another economist, formerly professor at Marburg, a victim, also, of the power of the elector of Hesse, Hildebrand, now professor at the Univer- sit}'- of Zurich. His National-CEkonomie ^ is a book replete with interest, and we have nowhere met with a better criti- cism of Proudhon's system, than in its pages. If the new school had produced but these three men, it would still have left its impress on the history of the science. Other works, no less important, will claim our attention in the book to which we have already devoted many years of •labor. If we carry out our intention, we shall review the works of a great many scholars, of great merit, whose names only are, unfortunately, known outside of Germany. The works of Rau, of Hermann, of Robert Mohl, of Hannsen, Helferich, Schlitz, Kosegarten, Wirth etc., are a rich mine, from which we hope to draw much valuable information. Nor shall we neglect the original productions of J. Moser, the Franklin of Germany, nor the quaint, but sometimes striking, ideas of Adam Miiller. Lastly, our learned friend. Professor Stein of Vienna, will afford us an opportunity to show forth the merit of important ana extensive works, animated by the philosophic spirit. For the present, we must confine ourselves to a view of the application of the historical method to Political Econom}'-. ' Die politische CEkonomie vom Standpunkte der geschichtlichen Methoda * Die National CEkonomie der Gegenwart und Zukunft. ON THE HISTORICxVL METHOD. 33 There is a rather widespread prejudice existing against this order of works, a souvenir of the struggle carried on formerly, between Thibaut and Savigny, which inclines people to sup- pose that the historical school leans towards the poHtical doc- trines of the past, and that it is hostile to the liberal spirit of modern times. Nothing can be farther from the truth. The names of Roscher, Knies and Hildebrand are sufficient to remove this prejudice. Their works, inspired by an enlight- ened love for progress, do not allow of such a misconstruction. The historical point of view does not consist in the worship of the past, any more than in the depreciation of the present. It does not view the succession of phenomena as a fluctuation of events without unity or purpose. On the contrary, the histor- ical method harmonizes wonderfully well with the w^ants of genuine progress. The changes accomplished bear testimony to the free and creative power of man, acting within the limit permitted to it by the degrees of intelligence reached, of the development of morals, and of individual liberty. The philos- ophy of Political Economy, which is the result of this calm teaching, free from the passions of party — for science ac- knowledges no adherence to party — is like that of law, op- posed to the, more or less, ingenious or rash dreams, which build the world over again in thought. In showing how, at all times, humanity has understood and applied the principles which govern the production of wealth, it ma}^ sa}^ with the Roman jurisconsult: "Justitiam namque colimus .... £Equum ab iniquo separantes .... veram nisi fallor philosophiam, non simulatam aftectantes." "The human mind," says Rossi, " endeavoring to attain to a knowledge of itself, estimating its strength, taking a method, and applying it with a conscious- ness of its mode of procedure to the knowledge of all things ; such is philosophy. Without it, there is no science in any branch of human knowledge." Thus do we rise, with the aid of a critical mind, by careful investigation and great sagacity, to the truths founded on observations made. Vol. I.— 3 34 PRELIMINARY ESSAY IX. There is another method, which, starting out from prin- ciples, evident of tliemselves, develops science by way of conclusions drawn, after the manner of the geometricians. The apparent severity and simplicity of this method are very seductive, and very dangerous, when we have to deal not with figures, but with men; when the varied, complex and delicate exigencies which accumulate when human nature comes into play do not exactly square with the formula ; and, when in- stead of dealing with abstractions, we have to tackle realities. One of our venerated teachers, the illustrious Rossi, thought he might remove the difficulty by drawing a distinction be- tween -piire Political Economy and afflied Political Economy. It is not without a certain amount of hesitation that we dare differ with so high an authority ; but confess we must, this dis- tinction is far from satisfying us. The doubt it has left in our mind has been the principal cause which has inclined us to the historical method. "Rational Political Economy," says Rossi, " is the science which investigates the nature, the causes and the movement of wealth, by basing itself on the general and constant facts of human nature, and of the external world. In applied Political Economy, the science is taken as the mean. Account is taken of external facts. Nationality, time and place play an important part." Let us for a moment accept these definitions; what is the consequence ? That there are two sciences, the one of which, purely speculative, has more to do with philosophy than with the permanent conflicts which agitate the world; the other of which could not alone furnish us with rules in practice, nor with a formular}" for the measures to be taken in a given case, since such a pretension would be both vain and ridicu- lous, but which would inform the practical judgment of men charged with the solution of the numberless difficult and com- plicated questions which come up every day. If pure science refuses to interfere in the affairs of this world ; if, as the learned ON THE HISTORICAL METHOD. 35 originator of the doctrine we are just now considering gives us to understand, it would compromise the solution of ques- tions by the intoxication of logic, and the ambition of perfect S3^stem; if, consequently, it is to be worshipped like a mo- tionless and inactive divinit)^, how could this platonic satisfac- tion suffice us? Would not the opponents of economic doc- trines be disposed to acknowledge all the principles, provided the consequences to be drawn from them were left to them- selves; and would they not come to us, bristling with argu- ments drawn from the circumstances of nationality, time and space, to refute the possibility of applying pure science? On ne vaincra jamais les Romains que dans Rome. This, therefore, is the ground we must explore. We must develop applied Political Economy which takes cognizance of external circumstances. To do this, no one will question that the best and most decisive of methods is the historical, which concerns itself with time, space and nationalit}-, and which leads to proper reformation where reformation is wanted. Moreover, principles will be no less firmly established by historical induction than by dogmatic deduction, and, more- over, science will be inseparable from art. We are not of those who deny principles, or who challenge them. What we desire is, that they should not be worshiped as fetiches, but that they should enter into the very life-blood of nations. Further: the abstract deductions of pure science do not leave us without disquietude, since they treat man much more like a material than like a moral force. Under the vigorous procedure of speculative mathematics, man becomes a constant quantity for all times and all countries, whereas he is, in real- ity, a variable quantity. All the elements put in play are ideal entities, the reverse of which we find in poetry, where Tout prcnd un corps, una ame,un esprit, un visage! and where everything loses the character of life, and is trans- formed into inanimate units. Man is something different from 36 PRELIMINARY ESSAY the sum of the services he maybe made to render, and from the sum of enjoyments which may be procured for him. We must not run the risk of lowering him to the level of a living tool; and from the moment that we are required to take his moral destiny into account, what becomes of abstract calcula- tion? X. We have been wrong, says Rossi, in reproaching Quesnay for his famous laisscz faire, laissez -passer^ which is pure sci- ence. We, also, are of opinion that the reproach was ill founded, for it proceeded from a wrong conception of the principle itself But it seems to us that, far from condemning this doctrine in its serious application, the historical method may serve to explain and to justify it. Employing less of rigidity and dryness in form, it reaches consequences more in harmony with social life. But it is not to be imagined that we do not meet in this way with many ancient and glorious precedents. The great principles of industrial liberty, as well as those of commercial liberty, originated in France. For- bonnais was right when he said: "We may congratulate ourselves on being able to find, in our old books and ancient ordinances, wherewith to vindicate for ourselves the right to that light which we generally supposed to have been revealed to the English and Dutch before us." The further Forbonnais carried his researches into our annals, the greater the number of traces of opposition to the prejudices in favor of exclusion and monopoly, so long made principles of administrative pol- icy, did he find.^ The famous axiom, laissez f aire, and laissez -passer^ the sub- versive tendencies of which people affect to condemn, was not invented by Quesnay. He only gave a scientific bearing to what was the inspiration of a merchant called Legendre. The latter, consulted by Colbert on the best means of pro- ' Recherches sur les Finances de France. ON THE HISTORICAL METHOD. 37 tecting commerce, dropped these words which have since be- come so celebrated. We must not lose sioht of their real meaning^ nor misun- derstand the intention which dictated them. What Quesnay said was this: "Let everything alone which is injurious, neither to good morals, nor to liberty, nor to property, nor to personal security. Allow everything to be sold which has been produced without crime." And he added : " Only free- dom judges aright ; only competition never sells too dear, and always pays a reasonable and legitimate price." Far from being the absence of rule, liberty is the rule itself. To laisser fairc the good is to prevent evil.^ There is need of institutions to complete the exercise of the independence acquired by labor, and of laws to regulate that exercise. The laisser f aire and laisser fasser of economists is, in no way, like the absolute formula, which some have de- nounced and others sought to utilize, as relieving authority of all care and all intervention. To understand this maxim aright, we must go back to the oppressive regime of ancient society. Quesnay's formula was, first of all, a protest against the restraints which hampered the free development of labor. But it did not tend to abrogate the office of legislator, nor to deprive society or the individual of the support of the public power which watches over the fulfillment of our destiny. It may have seemed convenient to find in the gravity of a politico-economical principle, an excuse for the sweets of legis- lative and administrative_/?7r niente^ but it is generally conceded that the role of authority has grown, rather than diminished, under the regime of the liberty of labor. The task is, in our days, a hard one, both for individuals and nations; for liberty dispenses its favors only to the masculine virtues of a labori- ous and an enlightened people. Liberty is not license. It refuses to bend under the yoke, FrdiUric Passy, de la Contrainte et de la Libert^. 38 PRELIMINARY ESSAY but it submits to rule. The mission of authority is not to con- strain, but to counsel; not to command, but to help accom- plish ; not to absorb individual activity, but to develop it. It does not pretend to raise a convenient .indifference on the part of government, nor the indolent withdrawal of all protective influence to the dignity of a principle. To say, on the other hand, that the laisser fairc and laisser passer of the economists means: Let robbery alone; let fraud alone etc., is to amuse one's self playing upon words, and to argue in a manner un- worthy of any serious answer. Under pretext of painting a picture of economic doctrine, we are given its caricature. Such has never been the system, to the elaboration of which the purest hearts and noblest intellects have devoted them- selves. A negation does not constitute the science of Political Economy. It is very convenient to inclose humanity within a circle of action, drawn with rigorous precision, and to govern move- ments seen in advance. But such artificial conceptions muti- late the activity of man. To guaranty man all liberty, and prevent its abuse — such are the data of the problem. The work is a great and difficult one. Far from yielding in point of elevation to ideal systems, it is superior to them in extent and variety of combinations. Those who ignore its bearing, yield, it may be, to a certain indolence of intellect. Restrained within its natural limits, the famous laisser fair e and laisser ■passer of the Physiocrates deserves even to-day our respect and our confidence. It ought to be preserved in the grateful memory of men, side by side with the maxim which Quesnay succeeded in having printed at Versailles, by the hand of Louis XV himself: "Pauvres paysans, pauvre ro3^aume; pauvre royaume, pauvre souverain." ^ ' Poor peasantry, poor kingdom; poor kingdom, poor sovereign. ON THE HISTORICAL METHOD. 39 XL To return to the question of method. Rossi made use of an ingenious example to explain his thought:^ "Are," he in- quires, " these deductions [of pure science] perfectly legitimate ; are these consequences always true? It is incontestably true that a projectile, discharged at a certain angle, will describe a certain curve; this is a mathematical truth. It is equally true, that the resistance offered to the projectile by the medium through which it moves modifies the speculative result in practice, to some extent; this is a truth of observation. Is the mathematical deduction false? By no means; but it supposes a vacuum. I hasten to acknowledge it. Speculative economy also neglects certain facts and leaves certain resistances out of account." Now, from the moment that we have to deal with human interests, it is not possible to suppose a vacuum, to neglect the most vulgar facts, and the most common instances of resistance, nor to lose one's self in abstraction. The correct- ives of applied Political Economy either may not wipe out this original sin, or else they run great danger of covering up the principles themselves. In balistics, again, we may measure the resistance which the medium in which we are obliffed to operate, makes the force of impulsion and the target both obey the same law, and yield to the same process of calcula- tion. But is it thus when 3"ou touch upon man's innermost and most sensitive part ? Is there not danger that the hypoth- eses may be deceitful, and that you may be accused of toiling in a vacuum? We well know the solid reason that may be opposed to sarcasm of this nature; but is it expedient to lay one's self open to it? Moreover, the consequences are not great enough to war- rant us to expose ourselves to the danger. The principles of pure science are very small in number. They might even, be easily reduced to one, of which M. Cousin has been the elo- * Cours d' Econ. polit., 2e., Lc9on, I, p. 33. 40 PRELIMINARY ESSAY quent interpreter — human libert3^ This liberty has no need of Political Economy to shine with the luster of evidence; nothing can prevail against it. "We can prove that it is as fecund as it is respectable; but if the science of wealth should endeavor to demonstrate the contrary, the primordial bases of societ}^, libert}^, property and the family would not be less sacred nor less necessar}^, for they are the right of humanity. They could not be put aside, even under pretext of any mech- anism which would claim to produce more.^ These sovereign principles of economy flow from the moral law, and they have no reason to dread the power of facts, for the prosperity of na- tions depends on the respect with which they are surrounded and the guaranties by which they are protected. We have spoken of the moral law ; and, indeed, in our opin- ion, it is impossible to banish it from the domain of public economy. Any other point of view seems to us too narrow. And when we see eminent men go astray in the pursuit of an ideal which fails to take the human soul into account, and which finds nothing but equations where there are feelings and ideas, we cannot help thinking that they are unfaithful to the thought of the founder of the science, Adam Smith. Man is not simply a piece of machinery. He does not blindly submit to external impulse. Rather is he himself, the greatest of im- pulses. But to govern things, he must first learn to conquer himself Personal interest is the powerful motive which he obeys. Man does not live alone, in a state of isolation, in the world. VcB soli! He lives in society and profits by the rela- tions which he forms with other beings, intelligent like him- self, and for whom he has a natural feeling of sympathy. The good that comes to them yields satisfaction to him, and the evil that befalls them falls on him likewise. He cannot turn back entirely upon his own personality. Besides his own in- terest, he feels and shares another interest — the interest of all. Personal interest is perfectly legitimate. The love of self can- ' This would be : Propter vitiam, vitae perdere causas. ON THE HISTORICAL METHOD. 41 not be condemned. The Savior himself has enjoined us to love our neighbor as ourselves. To love him more than ourselves is a very high and beautiful virtue. It is the self-abnegation which inspired Christian heroes. But heroism is rare, and can- not be imposed, nor taken, as a rule. Personal interest is a powerful stimulant, and the superior harmony of social rela^ tions makes it contribute to the general good. What must be condemned is a fatal deviation of this senti- ment which destroys its effect and narrows its actions. What we need to prevent is the degeneration of personal interest in- to an egotism which parches, instead of fertilizing, and which compromises the future by the exclusive search after present advantage; for egotism is short-sighted. On the other hand, the broader and more p^enerous feelinc: which inclines us to sympathize with our fellow beings in their sorrows, and to unite our destiny to theirs ; that is, the feeling of the general interest, has a limit too. It would be falsified if it absorbed the individual; if it des- troyed the most powerful motive-force by drying up the abund- ant source of activity ; if it attacked moral energy by enervat- ing responsibility ; if it extended the circle of results obtained to such an extent that scarcely any one should feel the rebound. The evil produced by egotism, that sad travesty of personal interest, appears under a form quite as formidable when the general interest takes the form of communism. The cooper- ation of personal interest and of the general interest is always necessar}'-, both for individual profit and social advantage. There is as much danger in annihilating the individual as in exalting him. History furnishes us with memorable examples of this. It does not allow us to go astray in the narrow ways of a peevish and jealous personality, nor to lose ourselves in the vague labyrinth of a chimerical and false communism. The latter would destroy what constitutes the power and dig- nity of man. It would wipe out the most prominent features of his noble nature, by destroying the support of energy and activity and the food of moral force. 42 PRELIMINARY ESSAY XII. But, we are told, Political Economy is only the science of selfishness ; Adam Smith is the prophet of individualism ; grow rich -per fas et nefas is its ultimate teaching. Such a judg- ment is evidence of much levity and little enlightenment. How could the man who conceived the study of human in- terests on so large a scale, the philosopher who acknowledged Hutcheson as his master and gave his ideas a still more ex- pansive character, be the apostle of egotism ; and how can the science which he founded be its gospel? There is here an error of fact and a defect of appreciation. Hutcheson had based moral philosophy on the feeling which, according to him, engendered all the other virtues, on benevolence, which is disinterested, busied with the welfare of others, with the public weal and the general interest. Adam Smith went fur- ther, and sought to base it on a still more energetic feeling, on sympathy. The first sentence of his Theory of the Moral Sentiments, which is a full resume' of his theory, is as follows: "How selfish soever man may be supposed, there are evidently some principles in his nature which interest him in the fortune of others, and render their happiness necessary to him, though he derives nothing from it, except the pleasure of seeing it." And this is no empty declaration on his part. It is the thought which of all in his book is nearest to his heart ; and hence he energetically assails those philosophers who look upon self- love and the refinements of self-love as the universal cause of aU our sentiments, and seek to explain sympathy by self-love. La Rochefoucauld, Mandeville and Helvetius never met with a more determined or energetic adversary. Nowhere have the sweet and amiable virtues, such as ingenuous conde scension, indulgent humanity, and the respectable and severe virtues, such as disinterestedness and self-control which sub- ject our movements to the requirements of the dignit}^ of ouf ON THE HISTORICAL METHOD. 43 nature, been better understood or interpreted. " Adam Smith is the philosopher of sympathy.^ His theory triumphs over the cowardly and shameful egotism which concentrates the moral life of the individual in himself, and separates it from the life of the human race of the outre stoicism which refuses the aid of sentiment to reason." '^ According to him, the law of private morals is sympathy; the law of natural jurispru- dence, justice ; the law of the production of wealth, free labor. But while he defended this principle with energy, he did not become guilty of a real recantation by worshiping the idol he had just overthrown. He would have been culpable of the strangest of all contradictions if he had made the vice which he had just lacerated the very pivot of another part of his teaching. We regret that this essay, which has already very much exceeded the limits we assigned it in the beginning, will not permit us to reproduce here Knies' beautiful demonstration, in which he so learnedl}^ and eloquently vindicates Adam Smith from this strange imputation, thereby placing Political Econ- omy on its true basis, the basis of morals, by removing in a decisive way, all pretext of error and all means of subterfuge. This part is one of the best features in his most excellent work on " Political Economy, from the historical Point of View." We shall return to this matter. XIII. What is there that political economists have not been charged with? They have been accused, above all, of a cold hearted- ness and cruelty, and the sentence passed on them has been resumed in these words: " Political Economy has no bowels!" Indeed, the representative of the science, who has been most attacked and who has been held up as a picture of impassible insensibility ; on whom have been heaped the most bloody out- ' Cousin, loc. cit, p. 276. '^ Ibid., 214. 44 PRELIMINARY ESSAY rages, is Malthus. Let us hear him. He tells us in his work on Political Economy, that if a country had no other means to grow rich, except by seeking for success in the struggle with other countries, at the cost of a reduction of the wages of labor, he would unhesitatingly say: Away with such riches; that it is much to be desired that the working classes should be well remunerated, and this for a reason much more import- ant than all the considerations relating to wealth ; that is, the happiness of the great mass of society. And he goes on to say, that he knows nothing more detestable than the idea of knowingly condemning the laboring classes to cover them- selves with rags, to lodge in wretched huts, to enable us to sell a few more stuffs and calicoes to foreign countries. Cer- tain it is, that no defender, however determined, of the laboring classes, has said anything stronger or more deeply felt. The reason is, that nothing was more foreign to Malthus' ideas than the systematic rigidity of mathematical theories of wealth; that, a minister of the Gospel, he had meditated on its high precepts. His whole doctrine is based on the moral idea. " He was profoundly convinced that there are principles in Political Economy which are true only in as far as they are restricted within certain limits. He saw the principal diffi- culty of the science in the frequent combination of complicated causes, in the action and reaction of causes on one another, and in the necessity of setting limits or making exceptions to a great number of important propositions." ^ Here we are ever brought back to the undulating ground of living science, instead of having to follow the rectilineal way traced out b}^ the dead letter. We are always driven back, whatever may be pre- tended to the contrary, to the realities of which history alone possesses the secret. The idea of wealth cannot absorb every- thing when there is question of judging and enlightening men. To do this, it is necessary to know the various phases of social housekeeping, what nations have thought of economic interests ' Ch. Comte, Notice tur Malthus, XXVII. ON THE HISTORICAL METHOD. 45 which have never ceased to interest them greatl}^, what they have attempted and what they have attained. Hence, we must turn over the leaves of the book of the past, and study its economic aspect, as we have studied its political and literary aspect. We must follow living nations through their divers periods of development, and fathom the causes of the destruction of those that are dead. When we are dealing with the comparative study of the economic destinies of na- tions, our investigations are limited to a small number of indi- vidual nations — a further reason not to omit any, and above all, to scrutinize, as an anatomist would with his scalpel, the principle of life of those which are no more. We may, by accounting to om^selves for the immense variety of phenomena which are brought to light by the application of principles to facts, and in which nothing is absolute or permanent, in which, on the contrary, everything is relative and successive, acquire that sureness of touch and correctness of vision which are among the most valuable conquests of science. It would be a mistake to suppose that theory simplifies prac- tical solutions. Far from providing us with a sort of formu- lary, it teaches us to put our finger on a number of difficulties. It brings to the surface the many aspects and fertile and varied considerations, the examination of which is the mission of the real statesman and legislator. In this way, the action of thought and the power of the moral idea are revealed with most eclat. Man ceases to be an inert element, and manifests himself as a sensible being, and the sublime thought of Pascal: " Human- ity is like one man who lives and learns always," is verified by the result. The wish to violently abdicate the past, it would be vain and rash to attempt to realize. The lessons it trans- mits to us are as instructive as the picture it unrolls before our eyes is attractive. We have no longer but to see and hear, to be cured of the most generous impatience with what is, and to retreat from the most perilous attempts. 46 PRELIMINARY ESSAY XIV. The unvarying testimony of ages affirms the continued and gradual amelioration of man by individual energy and moral thouiiht.^ Want and suflerin^ have urcjed him forward. Foresight, labor, sacrifice and virtue have in part redeemed him. No right has been lessened or usurped, and every step in civilization has been a step in the way of freedom. Instead of making the latter responsible for a material and moral wretchedness which it is called upon to cure, we may prove, that, in proportion as real liberty and legal guaranties increase, evil diminishes. We do not desire to yield to a convenient optimism, and de- ny the sufferings which weigh only too heavily on the world. We are far from having reached the end assigned to our ef- forts ; but let not the hope we entertain of further progress blind us to that which has already been accomplished. This latter shows us that we are on the right road, and that we have not done unwisely in giving free rein to the human faculties. Sudden changes are made only in theaters. In the real world, the march of progress is slow and laborious. It may be ac- celerated by a happy hit ; but it would be vain to try to hurry it. Man still suffers. No one desires to deny the evil, but only to estimate its extent. Yet it cannot be gainsaid that its fatal empire is narrowing instead of enlarging. Especially is it the progress accomplished in the higher regions of intellect and of the feelings which here exerts its beneficent influence. On our moral greatness depends our material power. The eleva- tion or debasement of character, the energy or debility of the will — such is the first source of good or evil. The world, a Chalmers rightly says, is so constituted that we should be materially happy if we were morally good. Industrial progress helps, we have said, towards moral per- fection. It is not the source of that perfection, but its instru- ' FriiUric Passy: De la Contrainte et de la Liberte. ON THE HISTORICAL METHOD. 47 mcnt; for ignorance and misery, its habitual attendants, are poor advisers. Political Economy shows how the goods of this W' orld are multiplied. It shows how modest comfort may become more and more general, and thus an impetus be given to all noble virtues without awakening a blind passion for riches. It teaches moderation instead of exxiting covetousness, nor does it come in conflict with the sublime words of Saint Augus- tine : " The family of men, living by faith, use the goods of the earth as strangers here, not to be captivated by them or turned away by them from the goal to which they tend, which is God, but to find in them a support which, far from aggravating, lightens the burthen of this perishable body which weighs down the soul." XV. Looked at from below, all things diverge. Looked at from above, all things run into one another and combine with one another. It is one of the great merits of the historical method, that it raises the point of observation and gives the observer the support of tradition and good sense, that master of life; that it prevents a divorce between different branches of knowl- edge of the same order, whicli constitute but one intellectual family, which there is no question of confounding, and which it would be dangerous to isolate. Aristotle, that universal genius, had discovered Political Economy, and it was the historical method which revealed it to him. Be it added, that the great philosopher had seen but one phase of the science, chrematistics, and that his ideas here bear the impress of the age in which he lived. Aristotle, however, distinguished this science from all others and from domestic economy, which is so akin to it. Doubtless, he did not found the modern study of Political Economy, but his powerful intellect gave him a presentiment of it. The honor of producing at once, Adam Smith, Quesnay and Turgot belongs to the eighteenth century. It was in the 48 PRELIMINARY ESSAY. course of philosophy at Glasgow that this study found a defi- nite place. The illustrious founder of the science of Political Economy did not contemplate dissolving the ancient alliance between it and the moral sciences, history, philosophy, juris- prudence, belles-lettres — all of which he had explored and studied profoundly. Let those whose ambition it is to walk, even at a distance, in the footsteps of Adam Smith, not forget what was the cradle of the noble study to which they have devoted their intellects. L. WOLOWSKI. THE PRINCIPLES OF POLITICAL ECONOMY. INTRODUCTION FUNDAMENTAL PRINCIPLES. INTEODUCTIOK CHAPTER I. FUNDAMENTAL IDEAS. SECTION I. GOODS— WANTS. The starting point, as well as the object-point of our science is Man,^ Every man has numberless wants, physical and intellectual.'' * Wants are either necessaries, decencies (Anstandsbedurfmss,c) or luxuries. The non-satisfaction of necessary wants causes disease or death; that of the wants of decency endangers one's ' Schaffie, Deutsche Vierteljahrsschrift (iS6i), emphasizes this. Adam Smith, Wealth of Nations (1776), very characteristicallj, begins with the yearly labor of the nation; y. B. Say (Traite d' Economie Politique, 1802), with richesses; Ricardo (Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, 1817), with the idea of value. ' The sum total of the wants {Bedarf) of the Bavarian people, for a whole year, is estimated by Hermann, Staatswirthschaftliche Untersuchungen (2d ed., 1S70, p. Si), at 177,000,000 florins for food (77 millions for wheat and po- tatoes, 69 millions for meat, 15 millions for milk etc., 16 millions for eggs, vegetables, salt and spices); 50 millions for clothing, 45 millions for shelter, 37.5 millions for fuel, 60 millions for beverages. *The original adds: deren Gesammtheit sein Bedarf heisst ; the aggregate of which is called his [man's] Requisite {Bedarf). There being no exact equivalent in English for the Avord Bedarf m. this connection, this note is ap- pended. — Translator. 52 INTRODUCTION. [Ch. I. social position.^ The much greater number, and the longer continuance of his wants are among the most striking dif- ferences between man and the brute:* wants such as clothing, fuel,^ tools, and those resulting from his much longer period of infancy; which last, together with other causes, has con- tributed so largely to make marriage necessary and universal. While the lower animals have no wants, but necessities, and w^hile their aggregate-want, even in the longest series of generations, admits of no qualitative increase, the circle of man's wants is susceptible of indefinite extension.^ And, indeed, every advance in culture made by man finds €;;^pres- sion in an increase in the number and in the keenness of his rational wants. No man who distinguishes himself in an}^- thing, but feels spurred thereto by a peculiar want ; and this want is both the cause and the effect of the power which is peculiar to him. No one but the poet feels the want of poet- izing; no one but the philosopher, of philosophizing. In every particular, intellectual or physical, in which the man is in advance of the child, he experiences new wants unknown to the child. Our education consists, for the most part, in awakening wants and providing for their satisfaction. 2 According to Boi-sguillebert (ob. 1714) Traits des Grains, I., c. 4, the wants necessaire, commode, ddlicat, superjlic, magnifiqne, arise in successive order with increasing welfare or prosperity, and are surrendered in a reverse order, witli increasing need. Tucker distinguishes necessaries, comforts, and conveni- ences of the respective conditions, elegancies and refinements, and lastly, "grand and magnificent." (Two Sermons, 1774, 29 ff.); F. B. W. Hermann, loc. cit., ist, ed., 1S32, 68; necessary goods (Giiter der Nothdurft), goods that contribute to pleasure and recuperation, to culture and splendor. ^Compare Tucker, On the Naturalization Bill (1751 seq.), IV, note. 5 No people without fire (Prometheus !) ; and it seems that broiling was the earliest mode of preparing food; then followed baking in heated cavities, and lastly came boiling in vessels. {KIcmm, Allgemeine Kulturgeschichte, I, 180, 343.) s There is an interesting attempt by Fauchcr, in the Vierteljahrsschrift fur Volkswirthschaft und Kulturgeschichte, 1S6S, III, 148 ff., to determine the relative place of our various wants according to their capacity for extension or contraction. Sec. I.] GOODS — WANTS. 53 Goods arc anything which can be used, whether directly or indirectly, for the satisfaction of any true" or legitimate human want,^ and whose utility, for this purpose, is recognized. Hence, the idea goods is an essentially relative one. Every change in man's wants, or knowledge, is accompanied by a rapid, corresponding change, either in the limits of the circle * of goods, or in their relative importance. Thus, the tobacco plant has, probably, existed thousands of 3'ears. It became goods, however, only from the time that man recognized its use for smoking, snuffing, etc., and experienced the want of it for these purposes. In a similar way, the limestone of the Solenhofen quarries has become goods, of considerable importance, only since the invention of lithography ; decaying bones, only since that of bone-dust manure; caoutchouc since about 1825, and gutta-percha, only since 1844. On the other hand, charms,^" philters, and even rehcs, since the decay of faith in their efH- cacy, have lost the quality of goods. If the aggregate in- come of all mankind were, by some sudden revolution, to be equally divided among all, diamonds, for instance, would '' The qualification " true," excludes from the circle of goods, not only all those things which might satisfy only irrational or immoral wants (compare MiscJilcr, Grundsatze der Nationalokonomie, 1S56, I, 1S7), but also vindicates the fundamental idea of the whole system of Political Economy, as a subject of moral as well as of psychological investigation. 8 Even Aristotle (Eth. nicom. V, S), considers that all things intended to enter into commerce, should be susceptible of comparison with one another, and that the measure of this comparison is ■want, which is the foundation of all association among men. ' An Arab helped pillage a caravan, and carried away, as his share of the boot}', a chest of pearls. He thought it a box of rice, and gave them to his wife to cook, but finding they did not boil tender, he threw them away. (Niebiikr, Beschreibung von Arabien, 3S3). See a similar anecdote in Ammian. Mar- cell, XXII. Compare Strabo, VIII, 381. 't^ As soon as the Persians renounce the superstition thai the daily contem- plation of a turquoise is a talisman against the "evil eye" {K. Ritter, Erd- kunde, VIII, 327), that precious stone will lose much of its value. On the other hand, the amulets of antiquitv, although they have long lost the qual- ity of goods as objects of superstition, have now a real value for the arch«- ologist. 54: INTRODUCTION. [Ch. I. greatly decline in value, for the reason that it is dependent, in great part, on the wants generated by vanity, or by the desire of outshining others. Beer, tobacco etc., would rise in the scale as goods, because the circle of those to whose wants they minister would have been very greatly extended. On the whole, advancement in civilization has uniformly the effect, of itself, to increase the quantity and number of goods, the wants and knowledge of men being thereby increased. We should reach the ideal here, if all men experienced only true or legitimate wants, but these completely; if they could see their way, clearly, to the satisfaction of them, and find the means of satisfying them with just the amount of effort most conducive to their physico-intellectuai development.^^ SECTION 11. GOODS. — ECONOMIC GOODS. By economy ( Wtrf/isc/ia/i( =h.usbRndry or housekeeping), we mean the systematized activity of man, to satisfy his need {Beda?y= requisite) of external goods.-^ This treatise is con- cerned only with economic goods (ends or means of econo- my).^ The greater the advance of civilization or human cul- ^' Since observation sliows, that, as time runs on, matter tends more and more to become goods, the bhnd forms of motion in nature to become useful labor and useful sustenance, impersonal and objectless existence to be trans- formed into personal property and personal culture, ScJiiiffle inclines to the belief that the whole mechanism of unconsciously governing nature is des- tined ultimately to aid in the realization of moral good, which alone is really valuable. Das gesellschaftliche System der menschlichen Wirthschaft, III, Auff., 1873, I, 3. 1 Hermann, loc. cit, ist ed., i, calls internal goods whatever each of us finds in himself, the free gift of nature; also that which we develop in our- selves by our own free action; and external, whatever we create or obtain, through the external world, as a means of satisfying our wants. The internal goods of one man may be external goods to another, as, for instance, when the former conveys them directly to the latter to be enjoyed, by words, de- meanor, etc., or indirectly, in combination with other external goods. ^ The exclusion of all else, has, indeed, been called one-sidedness and ma- Sec. II.] ECONOMIC GOODS. 55 ture, the less apt are men to pursue the satisfaction of their wants, isolated from their fellows, or, in other words, to carry- on their economies or husbandries apart from one another. The more numerous the wants of men, and the more different in kind their faculties are, the more natural does exchange^ be- come. Since all goods derive their character as goods from the fact that they are destined to satisfy human wants, the very possibility of exchange must greatly increase the possi- bility of things to become goods. Think of the machinist, whose products are used only by the astronomer, while the latter is never in a way to manufacture them for himself. {Hiifeland.) Commerce is the series of combinations, created by the interchange of services: "a living net of relations, which wants and services are ever weaving and unweaving." {Hermann^ As a rule, with an advance in civilization, there is an increase in the number of goods, which become economic goods, and in the number of economic goods which become commercial goods (objects or means promotive of commerce)."^ But this is to be considered a real advancement only to the extent that that which is obtained is superior to that which was possessed before, in consequence of the specialization of callings or the greater division of labor (§ 48 ff.). When a little street Arab exacts money from a stranger for pointing out the way, we rightly censure him ; but no one would find terialism. But, as Senior says, no one blames the writer on tactics, because he confines liis attention to mihtary subjects ; nor is the objection raised, that by so doing, he is encouraging eternal war. On the other hand, J. B. S torch (1815) devoted a special division of his work to the consideration of "internal goods " (health, knowledge, morality, security, leisure, etc.). See RaiCs trans- lation of his Manual, II, 337 ff. Compare Gioja^ Nuovo Prospetto delle Scienze economiche, 1815 ft'. VIII. 3 The inclination to exchange is, according to Adam S?mtli, one of the most important marks which distinguish man from the brute. (Wealth of Nations, I, ch. 2). But see Busch, Geldumlanf (1780), I, § 29, on exchange among the lower animals. * Observed by Aristoi. Polit. I, ch. 6. 56 INTRODLXTION. [Cii. I. it improper if he should first fit himself to play the part of a guide, and then live by his calling.^ SECTION III. GOODS. — THE THREE CLASSES OF GOODS. All economic goods are divided into three classes: A. Persons o?' fersonal sei'vkes. It is entirely repugnant to the feeling of humanity to regard a man's person in its entirety as an instrument intended to satisfy the wants of another.^ 5 The efforts of political economists to select from among the infinite num- ber of goods, those which should constitute the subject of their investigations, have taken two directions in recent times. Bastiat liere confines himself too exclusively to commerce. The political economist should concern himself only with wants and satisfactions, where the labor, which is the connecting link between them, is undertaken by some other person for a consideration. Thus the ordinary act of respiration lies outside the circle, that of the diver, which is paid for, does not. (Harmonies economiques, 1850, 68 ff.) But even Robinson Crusoe had his own system of economy. Are the products which the farmer consumes in his own home, the work he does himself, any the less matters of economic inoment than the products he sells, or the labors of his servants.? ScJiafflc is right when he says that ordinary respiration is no economic function, because it is an unconscious necessity of nature. But his definition is too broad, inasmuch as he places the essence of the economic character of goods or of an act, in the conscious adaptation of means to human ends. (Tiibinger Progr. z. 27 Sept. 1862, 9, 24 seq.) To take a walk is no economic operation, although it may be the best means to a very important end, — health. The same goods or the same act may have, fre- quently, according to the end proposed, an economic or non-economic char- acter. The beauty of the human bodj^, for instance, however systematically made use of for purposes of vanity, is not economic goods. But it is an economic speculation, base though it be, when a man relies on his handsome figure to secure a Avealthy wife, or, for purposes of gain, allows her to pose as a model to artists or to take part in tableaux vivants. According to C. Men- ger, Grundsatze der Volkswirthschaftslehre (1871) I, 51 ff., there are no eco- nomic goods, but those the disposable supply of which is, at most, equal to the quantity that is required. But is not the largest navigable stream, even in the most thinly populated country, an economic good.? ' Hegel, Rechtsphilosophie, § 67. Even the use of a corpse as manure, or for any mercantile purpose, is repugnant to our feelings, "because of the dig- Sec. III.] THREE CLASSES OF GOODS. 57 Yet this happens wherever slavery exists ; in its coarsest form, in cannibaHsm. Among civilized nations, we can speak, under this head, only of individual services or capabilities of persons ; or, indeed, of the aggregate of the services rendered by them during a time determined at pleasure, or a short time.^ B. Things, both moveable and immovable.^ C. delations to persons or things which may frequently be estimated just as accurately as material goods. (The res in- nity of personality." {Sckafflc, National CEkonomie, i860, 28.) In this re- spect, pi-ostitution is a remnant of slavery. Scliajfle is right, when he says that to repay personal services with material commodities which do not aiford as much food, etc., as the former have cost in expenditure of vital energy, is a slow and frequently a very cruel kind of cannibalism. (Kapitalismus und Socialismus, 1S70, iS). "^ Bornitz^ De rerum Sufficientia in Republica procuranda, 1625, gives in this encycloptedia of political science, together with a dissertation on agricul- ture, commerce and manufactures, a complete survey of the ministeria. Several modern writers refuse to look upon personal services, or the ability to render such services, as elements of wealth: compare Kaufmann, Unter- suchungen im Gebiete der politischen CEkonomie, 1S30, II, Heft I. They demonstrate, however, no more than this, that that class of goods has some- thing very peculiar. Thus MaltJius, Principles of Political Economy (1S20), chap. I, sect. I, objects that they cannot be inventoried or taxed; but can ma- terial goods be so completely.'' Can all the parts of the wealth of a nation be so inventoried and taxed.? Ran, Lehrbueh der pol. CEkonomie (1826)1, g 46, remai-ks that the personal aptitude to perform services dies with the person, and that personal services cannot be stored up (.?), etc. I appeal simply to the definition I have given above of economic goods, and which applies equally to services of eveiy kind which can be performed for other people. Besides, those who oppose this view are unable to give a satisfactory explanation of all the phenomena of commerce. Of course, the qualification "recognized as useful" is of the utmost importance as a mark to determine what is goods. But a prima donna, or a world-renowned physician, cast na- ked by shipwreck on the shores of North America, is certainly, better off than a blind beggar, his fellow sufferer. Compare Storclt, Handbuch II, 335 ff. and his Considerations sur la Nature du Revenu National. ^Ad. Muller compares persons, so far as they render any kind of service, to things, and, so far as they are required to be preserved in their individuality, to persons. The children in the "status " of a country gentleman, for instance, are treated more as persons, and domestics, more like things ; the land par- takes of a species of personality, but not the implements of labor. (Noth- wendigkeit einer theolog. Grundlage der Staatswissenschaft, 1S19, 48.) 58 INTRODUCTION. [Ch. I cor^oralcs of the Roman law.) I need only mention what is called good-wiU, which freely, and to the advantage of custom- ers themselves, but still with a limited amount of certainty, attaches to certain localities, and for which tavern-keepers, sometimes, as in theaters, depots and clubs, pay so enormous a rent.^ When a newspaper is sold, the purchaser frequently buys nothing but the existing relations between his colaborers, subscribers etc. No small part of the value of a good busi- ness firm consists in the confidence with which it inspires all who deal with it, thus sparing them a world of care and trouble.^ A general may be of incalculable value to an army which he has himself helped organize. In another, or in the service of a country not his own, he might be entirely value- less, incapable of accomplishing anything.^ With the progress of civilization, as man becomes more social, the number of valuable relations increases, while that of legalized monopolies is wont to decrease. {Schajle.y ^The privilege of selling refreshments in the garden of the Palais Royal ■was formerly let for 38,000 Irancs a year. 5 See the cases cited by Hermmin^ Staatswirtsch. Untersuchungen, 6 fF. and by Be7'nouilli^ Schweiz. Archiv. fiir Statistik und N. CEkon. II, 55. Think of the firm of J. M. Farina! In Athens, good stands were leased at a very high rent, even where there was no investment of the lessee's capital. {Demos- thenes, pro. Phorm., 948; adv. vSteph. I, mi.) There is, again, the sale of in- ventions, while they are still " mere ideas." According to Schdffe, Theorie der ausschliessendnen Verhaltnisse, 1867, II ff., the value in exchange of these relations depends on the extra income \Ahich is assured in fact, or in law, against diminution, by the exclusion of competition. He, therefore, recom- mends, instead of the word "relations," "custom," or "publicum." But these words, by no means, exhaust the meaning expressed by " relation." Thus, the good administration of public affairs, although it has no value in ex- change, is one of the most valuable economic goods Avhich a people can possess. ^ The relation mentioned above of a general to an army may even have great value in exchange. Instance, the Italian condottieri in the fifteenth century ! ^Relations which take from one man, as much as they afford to their possessor, arc of value as components of a man's private fortime, hut not of the wealth of the nation. To this class belong debts due from persons or Sec. IV.] VALUE IN USE. 59 SECTION IV. OF VALUE. — VALUE IN USE. The economic value of goods is the importance they pos- sess for the purposes of man, considered as engaged in econ- omy (housekeeping, husbandry.^) Looked at from the point of view of the person who wishes to employ them in his use directly, doubtless the oldest point of view, value appears first as value in use ; and here, according to the difference of subjective purposes it is intended to sub- serve, we may speak of production value or enjoyment- value; and of this last, in turn, as utilization-value, or consumption- value. The value in use of goods, is greater in proportion as the number of wants they are calculated to satisfy are more gen- eral and more urgent, and in proportion as they are gratified by them more fully, surely, durably, easily and pleasantly.^ Hence, it is seldom possible to find an accurate mathematical expression of the relation which exists between the value in use of different goods.^ Thus, it is possible to estimate the from things, compulsory custom or good-will of every description; as for in- stance, the seventy -two places of the agents de change in Paris, each of which was worth more than a million of francs; or the right of navigating the Elbe as far as Magdeburg, which, about the beginning of this century, was worth in every instance about 10,000 thalers. {Krug^ Abriss. der St. OSkonomie, 62.) ' Schafflc, N. Qi^konomie, 10. In the German language, this same word is used to designate utility, and sometimes useful objects (so called values). A clear distinction, however, should be made between utility and value in use. Utility is a quality of things themselves, in relation, it is true, to human wants. Value in use is a quality imputed to them, the result of man's thought, or of his view of them. Thus, for instance, in a beleagured city, the stores of food do not increase in utility, but their value in use does. Com- pare ScJiiiffle^ System, III, I, 170. ^ Genovcst^ Economia civile (1S69), II, I, 7. L. Say, De la Richesse indi- viduelle et de la Richesse publique (1827), 29, estimates the value of goods according to the degree of discomfort attendant on the privation of them. "^ Fricdldndcr has, however, made a general attempt in this direction. Theorie des Werthes (Dorpat, 1S52). But says Th. Fix (Journal des Econ- 60 INTRODUCTION. [Ch. I. nutritive power of different kinds of goods, the value of wheat or of hay for instance, but not the goodness or quality of their taste, of the attractiveness of their appearance, etc. But, the more men become used to comparing the aggregate of human wants, and the aggregate of the goods which minis- ter to the satisfaction of these wants, as if they were two great wholes, gradually shading each into the other, the more does the value in use of the different kinds of goods assume, for purposes of social rating or estimation, a fungible character/ If a new kind of goods be produced or discovered, which sat- isfies the same wants in a more complete manner than an- other, the latter, although it has suffered no change, generally loses in the value put upon it, especially if the new goods can be produced in any desired quantity. An instance of this is the change effected in the value of the dyers weed, woad, by the introduction of indigo. Things present in quantities greater than the amount necessary to supply the want they satisfy, preserve their lull value in use, to the limit of that want, after which they are simply an element of possible future value, dependent on an increase of the want ; but they have no value for present use.^ The economic valuation of goods, however, is by no means exhausted, so far as the isolated individual house- keeper is concerned, by the mere establishing of its value in use. As the systematic effort of every rational individual in omistes, 1S44, IX, 12) : " It is as impossible to establish a scale of values, as it is to find an exact mathematical and permanent measure of our wants, pas- sions, desires, tastes and fancies." 4 Compare Knies, Geld und Credit, 1S73, I, 126 ff. The very respectable attempt made by A. Satnter, Sociallehre (1S75), with the idea society-value {Geselhchaftsxverth) covers too nearly the idea of value in exchange. Fur- ther research will here have to be made, with the idea of "impotent need," inasmuch as, from a high ethical, national-dietetical point of view, the ques- tion is asked whether, to what extent, and how, " impotent need " may be made a potent one. ^ Friedldnder, loc. cit., 50. If too many copies of the very best book be published, there is a certainty that a number of them will remain little better tlian waste paper. Sec. v.] value IN EXCHANGE. Qi his household management is directed towards the obtaining, by a minimum of sacrilice of pleasure and energy, a maxi- mum satisfoction of his wants, even an Adam or a Crusoe is, in his economy, compelled to estimate not only what the goods to be acquired accomi:)lish (value in use) but also what they will cost — cost-^'alue. Even the most indispensable kind of goods, for instance atmospheric air, is considered to have no value, when it can be obtained in sufficient quantity, without any sacrifice whatever.^ SECTION V. VALUE. — VALUE IN EXCHANGE. The value in exchange of goods, or the quality which makes them exchangeable against other goods, is based on a combi- nation of their value in use with their cost-value, such as men in their intercourse with one another will make.^ Without A'alue in use, value in exchange- is unthinkable. But there are many, and even indispensable goods which are not at all susceptible of being exchanged; for instance, the light and heat of the sun, the open sea etc.^ Other goods, ^ Sclidffie, System, II, aufl., 55. See also his Kapitalismus unci Socialismus, 1S70, 31. 35> 43- ^ Thus Klcin-wiichtcr (Hildebrand's Jahrbiicher fur N. Oek. und Statistik, 1S67, II, 31S), defines value in exchange =: value in use + costliness. Ac- cording to Schaffle, it is " a covert comparison between the cost- value and the value in use of the two kinds of goods to be exchanged." (Kapitalismus und Socialisinus, 35.) * An intermediate dealer can, so far as he is himself concerned, attribute value in exchange to goods only to the extent that they have use for the last person who has acquired them. Hence, Storch calls value in use immediate, and value in exchange^ mediate value. As the English are always wont to express the immediate in words of Germanic origin, and the mediate in words borrowed from the Latin, Loche calls value in use " worth," and value in ex- change, simply " value." {K, Marx, Das Kapital. Kritik dcr politischen CEkonomic, 1S67, i, 2.) 3 It is, of course, otherwise when, for instance, a beautiful sea view, or a desirable position as regards air and sunshine, is connected with a piece of land. 62 INTRODUCTION. [Ch. I although capable of being exchanged, have no value in ex- change, because they exist in superabundance, and may be obtained by everyone, without trouble and without reward; for instance, drinking-water in most places, ice in winter, and wood in the primeval forest.^ Moreover, the idea of such " free goods " is in great part relative. The water of a river may, for drinking purposes, be " free " goods, and yet, for pur- poses of irrigation, have great value in exchange. {John Stuart Mill). But, goods, to obtain value in exchange, must, in addition to their value in use, a value which must be recognized^ by a certain number of persons, at least , have the capacity of be- coming the exclusive property of some one individual, and therefore of being alienated or transferred; and this alienation or transfer must be desired because of the difficulty to become possessed of them in any other way.^ ■* In Ravenna a cistern had greater value in exchange than a vineyard : Martial^ III, 56. In Paris, too, drinking water, vs^hich is transported only with considerable trouble, costs i Y^ thalers per cubic meter. We may also men- tion snow and ice in summer, which last sells in the capitals of southern Europe at 0.34, silber groschens per pound. According to Carcy^ " utility " is the measure of man's power over nature, " value," the measure of nature's power over man. He very inaccurately adds, that both are always in an op- posite direction. (Principles of Social Science, 1S61, VI, ch. 9.) 5 Hence Ad. Miiller calls value in use, individual value, and value in ex- change, social value. The Germans call the value of goods whose value in use is recognized by only one person, Affedtonszuerth, (affection-value) a value which influences its value in exchange only when the individual who holds it in high esteem is not himself the possessor of the goods. An instance of this latter is a piece of paper covered with notes, intelligible only to the maker of them. *The very important difference between value in use and value in ex- change was recognized even by Aristotle. Arisiot. Pol. I, 9. Hutchinson, System of Moral Philosophy (1755), II, 53 ff. The Physiocrates speak very frequently of valetir usuella and vdnale, on which, according to Duj^ont, Physlocratie, CXVIII, the difference between Mens and richcsses is based. La valctcr d'un sefUer de bid., consider^ comme richesse ne consiste que datis son p'ix. {^Hcsnay, ed. Dairc, 300.) Turcot distinguishes between '■'•valeiir estimative'''' and '■'■ echangeable or apprdciative ;'" the former designating the relation between the amount of energy, physical and mental, which one Sec. VI.] ALLEGED CONTRADICTION. ' 63 SECTION VI. VALUE. — ALLEGED CONTRADICTION BETWEEN VALUE IN USE AND VALUE IN EXCHANGE. Recent, and Especially socialistic,^ writers have alluded to the great " contradiction " between value in use and value in exchange. This contradiction, however, vanishes when the above idea of economy, and the two sides or aspects, which economic value presents, are kept steadily in view. It is said, for instance, that a pound of gold has a much greater value in exchange than a pound of iron; while the value in use of iron, is incomparably greater than that of gold. I question is willing to spend in order to obtain the goods, to the sum total of his ener- gies, physical and mental ; the latter the relation between the aggregate like energy of two persons which they are willing to spend in order to procure each of the goods to be exchanged, and the sum total of their energies in general, (^''aleurs et Monnaies, p. 87, seq., 6d. Dair.e.) Ad. Stnith, in his Wealth of Nations, I, ch. 4, shows that he knew the difference between value in use and value in exchange ; but he afterwards drops the consideration of the former, altogether. In this respect he has had only too faithful and one-sided followers among his countrymen, so that Ricardo, Principles, ch. 28, asks what value in exchange can have in common with the capacity of commodi- ties to serve as food or clothing. (See, however, ch. XIX seq.) Many " free traders " would have no objection to interpose, if a people should abandon the cultivation of wheat, etc., to devote themselves exclusively to the manu- facture of point lace, provided the latter had a greater value in exchange. The two degrees of the idea of value have been examined with much thor- oughness by Hufdand in his Neue Grundlegung der Staatswirthschaftskunst (1807), I, 118 ff.; Lotz, Revision der Grundbegriffe (iSii ff.), I, 31, ff.; Storch, Handbuch, i ; Raii^ Lehrbuch, I, 56, ff. ; Thomas^ Theorie des Verkehrs, I, p. 11; /iTw/c.?, Tubing. Zeitschr. 1S55; Bastiafs declaration (Harmonies, p. 171 ff.) : that " valour " (by which Bastiat means only value in exchange),=/e rap- fort dc deux services ec7ia7}gds, contains a two-fold error: the ambiguity of the word services, which applies equally to a yielding or affording of utility, as to useful labor, and the error that the labor necessary to produce a com- modity, and of which the purchaser is relieved, alone determines its value in exchange. Compare tjifra §§ 47, 107, no, 115 ff., and Knies, loc. cit., p. 644 ff. ^Proudhon, Systfeme des Contradictions economiques, 1S46, ch. 2. 64: INTRODUCTION. [Ch. I this latter statement. True it is, that the need of iron is much more universal and urorent than the need of opold. On the other hand, a pound of gold yields satisfaction to the want of that metal, much greater than is yielded by a pound of iron, to the want of iron. We may speak of a contradiction between value in use and value in exchange, at the farthest, only in case the existing quantity of an article in trade, which can be done without, is not estimated correspondingly lower than the whole existing supply of a thing which is indispensable. But this is a case which cannot often occur. When, for instance, wheat is very dear, as in years of scarcity, people prefer to pay a very high price for it rather than to dispense, even in part, with its use ; and so of all the necessaries of life. As people progress in economic culture, they become more expert in adapting the value in exchange of related goods, not only to their cost- value, but also to their value in use." ^ The lower the state of a nation's economy, the more isolated men live from one another, the greater is the prominence given by them to value in use, as compared with value in exchange, a fact which makes a valuation of resources, which shall be universally applicable, a more difficult matter.* ^^ ^ In France, according to Cordicr (Memoire sur I'Agriculture de la Flandre Fran9aise), the wheat harvest yielded, in 1S17, forty-eight million hectolitres, with a value in exchange of two thous- and and forty-six million francs ; in 1818, fifty-three million hectolitres, with a value in exchange of one thous- and four hundred and forty-two million francs ; in 1819, sixty-four million hectolitres, with a value in exchange of one thous- and one hundred and seventy million francs. A rise in the value in exchange of wheat, such as was witnessed in 1S17, is synonymous with a decline in the value in exchange of money, and of all those goods whose money price has not risen. It is no objection to the views here advocated, that when the necessaries of life are vei-y scarce, the want of clothing, furniture, articles of luxury etc., is not felt so keenly as at other times, and that the value in use of these commodities really falls ; and vice versa. 3 Compare B. Hildebrand^ N. CEkonomie der Gegenwart und Zukunft; 1848, I, p. 316 fF. Kvics, loc. cit. * The greater importance attached, in our days, to value in exchange, than Sec. VII.J RESOURCES OR MEANS. 65 SECTION VII. RESOURCES OR MEANS (VERMOGEN). Resources^ or means, in the sense in which we here use the term, are the aggregate of economic goods owned by a phys- ical or legal person, after deduction is made of the person's debts, and all valuable and rightful claims have been added.^ Hence, there are private resources, corporative resources, municipal resources, etc., state resources, national resources and the world's resources. In estimating the resources of a whole people, it is, of course, necessary to make deduction of the debts due by the individual members of the nation to their fellow countrymen.^ to value in use, is seen especially in the attitude which the buyer, who is pos- sessed of the more current commodity (money), assumes toward the seller, — an attitude not unlike that of a patron towards his client. In the interior of Africa, the possessor of money, as such, would scarcely look down on the possessor of the means of subsistence. The South American Indians are ready to render an amount of service for a little brandy, which it would be in vain to ask them to perform for ten times its value in gold. (Ausland, Jan. 15, 1S70.) The miser estimates the possibility of being able to procure for himself, for one dollar, a hundred difterent articles worth a dollar each, to be worth one hundred dollars. ' When the wants of a person or of a people change, it is possible for the value in use ot one kind of goods, which had the greater prominence before, to take the place occupied previously by its value in exchange ; and vice versa. Thus, the youth sells the plaything he used in childhood; the man, the educa- tional apparatus of his earlier years ; the old man, the implements that enabled him to acquire wealth, and which he can no longer use except with great effort. (Mciiger, Grundsatze, I, 220 ff.) * Rau (Lehrbuch, I, § 61 ff.) distinguishes between the concrete or quanti- tative value which a certain kind of goods may have for a certain person, under certain circumstances, and the abstract or species-value which a whole class of commodities may have for men in general. But F. y. Neumann, (Tubinger Zeitschrift, 1S72, p. 2SS ff.) objects, that even the abstract value of a commodity always suggests the relation of a definite number of concrete men to a definite quantity of goods; else, by the expression, value of goods, is to be understood not what it is generally meant to signify, but only the capacity to satisfy a single want. ' Storch, Ueber die Natur des Nationaleinkommens (1S24, 1825), 5, defines Vol. I.— =; 65 INTRODUCTION. [Cn. I. SECTION VIII. VALUATION OF RESOURCES. It has often been made a question, whether the valuation of resources should be based on the value in use, or the value in ex- change of their constituent parts.^ The latter has, of course, no interest, except in so far as we are concerned with the possi- bility of obtaining the control of part of the resources, or means, of another, by the surrender of a part of one's own goods. In estimating the value of private resources, which require to be made continually an object of trade, this point is, of course, of the greatest importance. If certain of their com- ponent elements, lands, for instance, belonging to a fclci coin- inissjtiu, are incapable of entering immediately into the market, at least the revenue they yield is measured by its value in ex- change. It is quite otherwise, even with the resources of a whole nation. Such resources are, evidently, much more independ- ent, and have much less need of being exchanged against their equals, than private resources. The foreign commerce, of the greatest and most advanced nations, has, hitherto, been but a small quota of their internal commerce.^ A valuation, resources ( Vcrmogen) thus : a source of income, permanent in its nature, and capable of being transmitted, the possessor of which does not need to work, on its account. Hence he does not approve of the expression " the people's resources " ( Volksvermogen). 1 See especially Lord Laudeydalc, Inquiry into the Natvire and Origin of Public Wealth, 1804, ch. 2. Siorc/i, loc. cit. ^ Morcaii de yonnhs, Le Commei-ce au 19. Siicle (1S25) I, 114 ff., says that the United States imported from abroad 9.6, France 6, and Great Britain 5.8 per cent, of their annual consumption ; and exported respectively 10.4, 6.2, 9.8 per cent, of their annual production. The recent free trade tendencies, and the improvement in the international means of transportation, have cer- tainly increased the relative importance of foreign commerce. In the king- dom of Saxony (1S53), Engel estimates that 1^ of the whole production of the country was destined for foreign counti-ies, and that \^ of the consump- tion was imported. I Sec. VIII.] VALUATION OF RESOURCES. 67 therefore, based on value in exchange, however interesting it might be to enable us to determine how property is shared by the diticrcnt classes and persons that compose the nation, would atlbrd but little information concerninh. Memor., IV, 2, 37, seq. CEconom. II, 2 ft".). Plato, on the other hand, as the socialists are wont to do, looks to the excess over that possessed by others. (Legg. V, 742, seq.). Xenophoii' s observations, Hiero, 4, on the nature of wealth, are many-sided and beautiful. Aristotle distinguishes between natural and artificial wealth : ~?J^&o:; opyducou olxovo [JLccxibv xal 7ZO?.cT(Xcov — 7:}Jj&0^ iyOijlaixazoQ. (Polit., i, 3, 9, 16.) Compare Cicero, Parad. YI. The dominant idea of the so-called Mercantile System is thus expressed in a Saxon pamphlet of 1530 (Miintzbelangende Antwort, etc.): "Money is the real watchword ; where there is much money, there is wealth, it is clear." Compare Lutlier, Werke, Irmisch edition, XXII, p. 200 seq. See some ex- cellent remarks in opposition hereto, in the Saxon pamphlet, Gemeyne Stim- men von der Muntz, 1530. Schroder, Furstliche Schatz-und Rentkammer, 1686, ch XXIX. "A country grows rich in proportion as it draws gold or money, either from the earth or from other countries ; poor, in proportion as money leaves it. The wealth of a country must be estimated by the quan- tity of gold and silver in it." See a very passionate argument against this view in Boisguillebert, Dissertation sur la Nature des Richesses, written some- time between 1697 and 1714. Berkeley, Querist (1735), Nos. 562, 542. Among Englishmen, the correct view was prevalent much earlier, especially among the founders of the American colonial empire. See HacMttyt, Voy- ages (1600), III, 22 ft". 45 ft". 152 ff. 165 ft". 182 K 266 ft"; but especially the work 70 INTRODUCTION. [Ch. I SECTION X. WEALTH. — SIGNS OF NATIONAL WEALTH. We should have a very imperfect idea of the wealth of a people (§ 8) if we should estimate it at the value in exchange "Virginia's Verger" in "Purchas Pilgrims " (1625), IV, p. S09 ft". Howevei", several Spaniards vrere led by hard experience to adopt a view opposed to the Midas-view (compare Aristotle, Polit. I, ch. 3, 16), by which the first American explorers were carried away: Garcilasso de la Vega (1609), Com- ment, reales II, ch. 6; Saavedra Flixardo, Idea Principis christian! (1640) Sjmb. 69 : potissimcB diviticc ac opes terrte fructus sunt, ncc ditiores in regnis fodincc, quaiii agricultitra; plus emoluiiieiiti, acdivia montis Vesuvii laiera adve- rujit, quam Potosus mons. Contemporary with those Englishmen, was the Italian, Giov. Botero, who called attention to the fact, that France and Italy were the countries of Europe richest in gold, although they possessed no mines of the precious metal themselves: Delia Ragion di Stato (1591) p. 83 ff. Also Sully, who called agriculture and cattle-breeding the breasts of the state, the real mines and pearls of Peru. (Economics royales I, ch. Si. See however, II, p. 3S1). Montchr6ticn, Traite d'Economie politique (1615) 81, 172 seq. According to Sir D. NortKs Discourses upon Trade, 1691, wealth is synonymous with freedom from want, and the ability to procure many comforts, while Temple (ob. 1700, Works I, 140 seq.) looks entirely at the subjective side of wealth. Pollcxfcn, " England and East India inconsistent in their Manufactures" (1697), considers gold and silver as the only real wealth. To this definition Davenant (ob. 1714), opposes another. Wealth, according to him, is whatever places prince or people in a condition of superabund- ance, peace and security. See his Works, I, p. 3S1 seq. He even reckons intellectual powers, alliances etc., among the national wealth. Compare W. Reseller, Zur Geschichte der englischen Volkswirthschaftslehre 1S51, in the acts of the royal Saxon Academy of Sciences, vol. III. Vauban (Dime royale 1707), Daire's edition, says: "The real wealth of a people consists in an abundance of those things, the use of which is so necessary to sustain the life of man, that they cannot at all be dispensed with." By the wealth of a people Galiani, Delia Moneta II, c. 2, understands the aggregate of all lands, houses, movable property, money, etc. which belong to them, but, that the chief element of wealth, and the condition precedent of all others, is men themselves. Hence, the process of the impoverishment of a people in their decline, takes the following course : money first emigrates, next, population diminishes, afterwards, the housos fall in ruin, finally, the land itself becomes n waste. According to Broggia,wQs.\t\i is nn avanzoosia valorcdi tiitto cio clie avanza al propria consume c bisogno, Delle Monete, 1743, IV, 307, 314; Cust.) Paltnieri {oh. 1794), also says: il superjluo constitiiiscc la richezza. (Publica Sec. X.] SIGNS OF NATIONAL WEALTH. 71 of the sum^-total of the component parts of the national re- sources. By the following signs, however, an approximative notion of the value in use of the resources of a nation may be obtained : A. When, even the lower classes, who compose everywhere the greatest portion of the people, are comfortable, in a con- dition worthy of human beings. Thus, C. Dupin is surprised at the great quantities of meat, butter, cheese and tea entered on the accounts of the poor-houses in England, and the great Felicita.) According to Turgot, Sur la Formation et Distribution des Richesses 1771, § 90, the wealtli of a nation consists in the net proceeds of landed prop- erty capitalized at the ordinary price of land, and then of the aggregate of all the movable property of the country. BtlscJi, Geluumlauf III, § 27, consid- ers a certain duration of the produce or revenue as an essential element in the idea of Avealth. Lauderdale, Inquiry, ch. II, distinguishes national wealth and private wealth; the former embracing all that man covets as agreeable or desirable; "while it is one of the mai^ks of the latter, that there should be no general superfluity of it on hand. Several modern English economists call wealth only that, the production of which cost human labor. Thus, Malthus, Definitions (1S27) p. 234. Torreiis, Production of Wealth, 1S21, ch. I. When Rossi, Cours d'Economie politique, 1S35, L. 2, says: tout chose fropi-e i^s expression, loc. cit., which it is not difficult to misconstrue, the feeling of the common interest manifests itself, both as law and force. And, in reality, it is necessary that, in order not to permit the droivsy con- 76 INTRODUCTION. [Cn. I, to " the Kingdom of God " ' as it grows larger. And yet, all these circles respectively condition one another. Cosmopol- itanism or chmxh-zeal, without love of countiy; patriotism, without fidelity to the community in which one lives, or love of one's family, are more than suspicious. The reverse is also true. This is a chief connecting link between the great apparent opposites.^ ^ science to fall too far behind self-interest, -which is always awake, it should create lasting institutions and regulations above and beyond the caprice of the individual or of the moment; for instance, in the family, marriage, educa- tion etc. ^ The more private interest ceases to be momentary, and becomes life- longandeven hereditary, the better does it harmonize with the feeling of the common interest. ^ Perin says (i, 93), that the conflict of interest is reconciled in the seeking for the attainment of the supreme good, that is God, " who gives himself to all in equal measure, and yet always remains the same, and out of whose ful- ness all may draw, and yet no one's share grows less." But the same is true of all ideal goods, and of every fonfi of the feeling for the common interest, the highest of which is, indeed, religiousness. 8 According to Kant, Anthropologie, p. 239, the desire of comfort and well-being, and the inclination to virtue, when the former is properly re- strained by the latter, produce the highest degree of moi-al, united to the highest degree of physical, good. It Is well known, that during the middle ages, in all countries except Italy and, even up to the seventeenth century, the moral sciences were under a one-sided theological influence, whose as- cetic condemnation of self-interest may have been well enough during a period of violence. By virtue of a very natural reaction, and as a protest of individualism against the constraint of absolute monarchy, the materialists of the eighteenth century endeavored to discover, even in the most exalted phenomena of human society, only the expression of an enlightenod self- interest. See Mandevillc's Fable of the Bees, or private Vices public Vir- tues (1723), but especially, Hclvdtius, De I'Esprit (175S). Voltaire says, that,' in all the celebrated maxims of De Rochefoucauld (1665) there is but one truth contained, ijiie Vaiiiotii' fropre est le mobile de toutcs. nos actions. (But see, per contra, Pufcndorf Jus Naturrc ct Gentium, 1672, II, 3, 15.) This ten- dency was opposed, especially by the English, who could not be blind to the influence exerted in public life by the feeling for the common good. David Hume, Treatise on Human Nature (1739), HI, 54, is of opinion that the in- terests of others are, on the whole, in the case of nearly every man stronger than even his own self interest. Hutcheson, System of Moral Philosophy (^755)1 speaks of the innate principle of benevolence. Man is not a perfect Sec. XII.] GRADES OF ECONOMY. 77 SECTION XII. ECONOMY. — GRADES OF ECONOMY. Thanks to this feeling for the common weal, the eternal and destructive war — the hcUum omnium contra omncs — which an unscrupulous self-interest would not fail to generate among men engaged in the isolated prosecution of their own economic interests, ceases in the higher, well-ordered organization ^ of society. On it are based the various forms of economy in common : family-economy, corporation or association-economy, •whole ; a part belongs to his own person, part to his family, part to the na- tion, part even to all humanity. Burke, Inquiry into the Origin of our Ideas of the Sublime and Beautiful (1756), distinguishes two fundamental prmciples of action, that of self-preservation and that of society. On the former is based the sense of the sublime; on the latter, of the beautiful. Accord- ing to Ferguson^ History of Civil Society, (1767), I, 3, 4, the "sense of union" is frequently strongest where the advantage drawn from the con- nection is smallest ; for instance, it is weakest in highly cultured commercial countries. Adam Smith, Theory of Moral Sentiments (176S), has been as one-sided in reducing everything to "sympathy," as he has been in his Wealth of Nations in reducing everything to "self-interest;" but not with- out the consciousness, that to explain the reality, it is necessary to take both ihto consideration (Buckle). It would, indeed, be just as preposterous to base economy on self-interest alone, as to base marriage merely on the sexual appetite. Recently, Hermann, Staatswirthschaftliche Untersuchungen, ist ed., part ist, discovers in self-interest, and in the feeling for the common good, the two springs of all economy. He would even base the so-called theoretic Political Economy, on the study of self-interest, its practice in that of the common good. M. Chevalier, Cours d'Economie politique, 1S44, •'■•'^> 412 ff., understands something very like this by the contrast between liberty and centralization. The antagonisme and aseodaiiojt of Bazard, Exposition de la Doctrine de Saint Simon (1S29), p. 144 if. Closer investigation will show, however, that self-interest, which must not be confounded with egotism, and the common interest, are neither coordinate nor exhaustive opposites. Compare the beautiful contrast drawn by Goethe (Pocket edition of 1S33, '^'ol 46, 97), between "Pietat" and " Egoisterei." ^ Paul, I. Corinth. 12, gives the most beautiful model description of a social organism. Compare, however, the fable of Menenius Agrippa in Livy, II, 32. 78 INTRODUCTION. [Ch. I. municipal economy, and national economy.^ And these forms of economy in common are so essentially the condition and complement of individual economy, that the latter, without them, could either not be maintained at all, or, at least, only in the very lowest stage of civilization. Although the higher science of Political Economy has, nearly always, been conceived^ as treating of the aggregate national activity of a people, there have been many, recently, who consider Political Economy as no real whole, but only as a mere abstraction. This is true, especially of many uncon- ditional free-trade theorizers, partly from a repugnance toward the governmental guardianship of private businesses or econ- om}^ It is true, also, of certain philosophers who consider the idea, " the people," as merely nominal.^ There are, how- * Excellent beginnings of a general theory of economies in common in Schdfflc^ N. CEkonomie, II, Aufl., 62 ff., 331. ff. ^The French and English, with their strong political bias, use the expres- sions respectively economie politique and Political Economy. In Germany, Avhere the terms the people ( Volk) and the state (Slant) are much less nearly coextensive, the Avords Volks-Mirthschaft and ]Sl ationalokonomie are preferred. But even Hufeland, who first gave currency to the term Volks-virthschaft (Grundlegung, I, 14), called attention to the peculiarity " that the term econ- omy suggests that there is one who economizes and guides, an economist in chief, and that such a one is, even according to the most correct opinion, wanting in the public economy of a people. 4 According to Th. Cooper, Lectures on the Elements of Political Economy, (1126), I, 15 ff. 117, the wealth of society is nothing but the aggregate wealth of all the individuals that compose it. Each individual looks out best for his own interests, and, hence, that nation must be the richest, in which each indi- vidual is most completely left to himself (If this were so, savage nations would be the richest!) Cooper goes so far as to disapprove of the protection afforded to commerce on the high seas by a national navy ; no naval war is worth what it costs, and merchants should protect themselves. He says, too, that the word " nation " is an invention of the grammarians, made to save the trouble of circumlocution, a nonentity ! Adam Smith is, as might be ex- pected, far removed from such absurdities. (Compare Wealth of Nations, IV, ch. 2, and the end of the fourth book.) But, even he is of opinion that men, in the study of their own advantage are led " naturally, or rather necessarily" (IV, ch. 2), to the employment which is most useful to society. But here Adam Smith overlooks the fact, that every individual nation strives after earth- Sec. XII.] GRADES OF ECONOMY. 70 ever, two things necessary to warrant us to call a thing made up of a number of parts, one real whole : the parts and the whole must have a reciprocal action upon one another, and the whole, as such, must have a demonstrable action of its own. {Drobisc/i.) In this sense, " the people " is, unquestionably, a \y immortality, and is, in consequence, frequently compelled to make imme- diate sacrifices for the sake of a distant future, a thing -which can never be to the private interest of the mortal individuals who compose it. And thus, D. North, Discourses upon Trade (1691), 13 seq., says, that in commercial matters, different nations stand in precisely the same relation to the ^vhole •world, that individual cities do to the kingdom, and individual families to the city. Similarl}-, Boisguillchert, Factum de la France, ch. 10, 327, Daire's edition. ^c///rtw/« i^;-rt«Z-//« (ob. 1790), Political Papers, § 4. And J.B.Say\ Traite d' Economic politique (1S02) I, 15 : e\ery nation is, in relation to neigh- boring nations, in the situation of a province in relation to neighboring pro- vinces. Unfortunately, such doctrine is only too palpably refuted by every ■war! y. Bcntham^s saying: Lcs interets Individ ucls sont Ics sculs iniereis rids (Traite de Legislation, I, 229). Infra § 98. Among those who, in antiquity, most energetically maintained that the idea of national economy is not a merely nominal one, is Plato (De Republ., IV, 420, I, 462); more recently, Fichte (Der geschlossene Handelstaat, iSoo), although, in general, the socialists attach as little importance to nationality as their most decided opponents. Adam Miiller is a writer who deserves recog- nition for his advocacy of national economy, and of the state as a whole, par- amount to individuals, and even generations. He gives war the credit of causing the scientific knovrledge of the state to cast deeper roots, and of en- lightening individuals in the most forcible way, that they are parts of one great whole. (Elemente der Staatskunst, 1S09, 1, 7, 113). He calls public econ- omy, as a whole, the product of all products. W'hat, he inquires, is the use ot all wealth, if it does not guaranty itself.^ And this, it can do, only through the organization of the whole people, that is, through the nation (I, 202). ■ Adam SmiWs theory of labor would be correct if it considered the entire na- tional life of a people itself as one huge piece of labor. (II, 265). And so, Miiller directs his polemics against Adam Smith's premise of a merely mer- cantile world-market. (II, 290). Similarly, the protective tarift" theoreticians, t?cw;V7/, Theorie de I'Economie politique (1S22), II, 19S fl". and Fr. List, Na- tionals System der politischen Oek. (1S42), I, 2408'. Colton, Political Econ- omy of the United States, 1853. Sismondi, Nouveaux Principes (1819), I, 197, ridicules the opinion which resolves the public interest into merely pri- vate interests : It is A's interest to rob B ; B, the weaker, is equally inter- ested to let himself be robbed, that he may fare no worse. But the state — ? ! 80 INTRODUCTION. [Ch. I. reality, and not alone the individuals who constitute the " peo- ple." Besides, it is truly said that all husbandry or economy supposes a will ("systematized activity" etc., sufra^ § 2). Such a will is ascribed to individuals, to legal persons, to the state, but not, however, to " the people," as a whole. But this will need not be an entirely conscious one, as is plain from the case of the less gifted and less cultured individuals engaged in household economy. The systemization in the public econr- omy of a people finds its clearest expression in economic laws, and in the institutions of the state. But it finds expression, also, without the intervention of the state, in the laws estab- lished by use, and b}^ the opinions of jurists or courts, in com- munity of speech, of customs and tastes etc.: things which have an important economic meaning, which depend on the common nature of the land, of race and history, and which influence the state, at least as much as they are influenced by it.^ ^ The most that can be said, at present, so far as an economy of mankind, or a world-economy, is concerned, is, that it may be shown that important preparations have been made for it. We are approaching more nearly to it by the ways of the more and more cosmopolitan character of science, the increas- ing international cooperation of labor, the improvement in the means of transportation, growing emigration, the greater love of peace, and the greater toleration of nations etc. * National wars are really no inere operations of the will of the state ! Since iSoo, Ireland, and, since 1S58, even British India, constitute one state with England, and yet how different are the economic tendencies of these different countries of Avhich the individual husbandman or business man must take cognizance ! * One might also deny the reality of a stream, considered as a whole, since its bed, no one calls a stream, and its watery contents change every moment. And yet, it is well known to scientific geography that every stream has its own individual character. Sec. XIII.] THE ECONOMIC ORGANISM. 81 SECTION XIII. POLITICAL ECONOMY. — THE ECONOMIC ORGANISM. The idea conveyed by the word o)-gn)i/siu, is doubtless, one of the most obscure of all ideas; and I am so far from de- siring to explain ^ by that idea, the meaning of public or na- tional economy, that I would only use the word organism as the shortest and most familiar expression of a number of problems, which it is the purpose of the following investiga- tion to solve. There are two points, especially, of importance here. In the motion of any machine, it is possible to distinguish with the utmost accuracy, between the cause and the effect of the mo- tion: the blowing of the wind, for instance, is simply and pure- ly, the cause of the friction of the mill-stones in a wind-mill, and is not in the least influenced or conditioned by the latter. But, in the public economy of every people, patient thought soon shows the observer, that the most important simultaneous events or phenomena mutually condition one another. Thus, a flourishing state of agriculture is impossible without flourish- ing industries; but, conversely, the prosperity of the latter supposes the prosperity of the former, as a condition precedent. It is as in the human body. The motions of respiration are produced by the action of the spinal cord ; and the spinal cord, in turn, continues to work only through the blood, that is, ' This would be to be guilty of explaining igtiotnm per ignotiiis. And yQt, there arc a great many modern writers who imagine that they have said something all-sufficient, Avhen they have told us that the state is an organ- ism. As early a writer as H iif eland {^ . Grundlegung, I, 113), enters his pro- test against such abuses. The person who would operate with this notion, should, at least, have read the acute observations, so well calculated to dissi- pate preconceived opinions, made by Lotze^ in his Allgemeine Phy-siologie des korperlichen Lebens, 1-165. The organic conception of national life, the life of a whole people, Avliere the individual organs are free and rational beings, is evidently a much more difficult one to form than that of the animal or human body. Vol. I.— 6 S3 THE ECONOMIC ORGANISM. [Ch. I by the help of resph'ation. In all cases like this, we are forced, when accounting for phenomena, to move about in a circle, un- less we admit the existence of an organic life, of which every individual fact is only the manifestation.^ ■'' It is, also, undeniable, that human insight into the operation and utility of a machine must always precede the existence of the machine itself. This human insight is parent to the plan, and the plan, in turn, is parent to the machine. The very re- verse of this is true in the case of organisms, those " divine machines " as Leibnitz called them. Men had digested food and reproduced their kind, thousands of years before physiol- ogists had attained to a true theory of digestion or reproduc- tion. I do not, indeed, by any means, pretend, that the public economy of nations is governed by natural necessity, in the same degree, as for instance, the human body. We shall find, however, that the minute arbitrary variations usual here and there in the course of its development, generally compensate for one another, in accordance with the law of large numbers. Here, too, we find harmonies, frequently of wonderful beauty, which existed long before any one dreamt of them ; innumer- * I first called attention, in my work on the life-work and age of Thucydides, to the fact that that great historian always accounts for causes in the follow- ing manner: A. is produced by B., and B. by A. {Roschcr, Leben Work und Zeitalter des Thukydides, 199 ft". ; compare especially Thucyd., I, 3, 7, seq.) Such a circle is not a vicious one. All first class historians have thus ex- plained historical phenomena. The one-sided deduction of A. from B., and B. froin C, etc., which the so-called pragmatic writers like Polyhins, for in- stance, is the result of overlooking all recij^rocal action. Scialoja, Principii (1840), p. 60, makes a somewhat similar observation for Political Econoni}-. 2 Whether we call the unknown and inexplicable ground back of all analy- sis, and which our analysis cannot reach, vital force, generic form, spirit of the nation, or God's thought, is for the present a matter of scientific indifter- cnce. All the more necessary are the self-knowledge and honesty, in gen- eral, which admit the existence of this background, and which do not, by denying it, deny the connection of the whole, which is, for the most part, much more important than the analyzed parts. But I must at the same time, enter my energetic protest against the imputations of heresy made by those who do not comprehend the sacred duty of science, by never ceasing investi- gation, to push farther back the bounds of this inexplicable background. Sec. XIII.] THE ECONOMIC ORGANISM. 83 able natural lavjs^ whose operation does not depend on their recognition by individuals, and, over which, only he can ob- tain power who has learned to obey them. (^Bacon.) ^ "^ '' But *When Ilildebrand, for instance, objects to the application of the expres- sion " natural law " to the economic actions of man, for the reason that it conflicts with human freedom and man's capacity for progress ( Jahrbiicher derN. CEek. und Statistik., 1863, Heft., I), I cannot agree with him. I use the expression " natural law " wherever I observe uniformity, explicable in its broader connections, and not dependent on human design. That there are such uniformities there can be no question. I need only mention the philo- logical law of the so-called "permutation of consonants," which individuals follow when speaking — certainly not through compulsion, — and, by means of which, the progress of the speaking aggregate is made manifest. Or, I might call attention to the well known fact, that, in populous countries mar- riages and crimes, which are for the most part free, are divided among the different age-classes in a proportion much more uniform, fi-om year to year, than are deaths, which are not free. I adhere all the more firmly to the ex- pression " natural law," because no one takes offense at or objects to the ex- pression, " nature of the human soul." But to this very nature of the human soul belong the freedom and responsibility of the individual, as well as the capacity of the species for progress. Compare A. Wagner, on Law in the Apparently capricious Actions of !Man {Die Gesetzindssigkcit hi den scheinhar tvzllkiirlichen mejisclilicjicn Handhtngcn^ 1864, p. 63 seq.), in which, how- ever, he only goes so far as to show that law and freedom coexist side by side as indubitable facts, while the seeming contradiction between the two remains. DrobiscKs Moralische Statistik und die menschliche Willensfrei- heit, 1867, is an important contribution to the literature of this question. ^Whately^ in his fourth lecture (Lectures, 1831), shows in a very clear way, Jiow London is supplied and provisioned by men with no object in view but their own personal interest, each of whom is possessed of but a very limited knowledge of the aggregate wants of its inhabitants, and yet they work into one another's hands, in the interests of the whole, purely instinctively, and infinitely better, perhaps, than the operations of the most skillful governmental commission, organized for the same purpose. 6 Alphonsus of Castile, the king astrologer of the thirteenth century, is reported to have said, that the universe would have been much better consti- tuted, if the Creator had asked his advice beforehand. Astronomers like Newton and Gauss have, certainly, judged otherwise. "• MacCulloch remarks, that there is an essential difterence between the phys- ical and the moral and political sciences in this, that the principles of the form- er apply in all cases, those of the latter, only in the greater number of cases — a thought very ably developed by K)ties,\oc. cit., fasst'in. If, with N'e-i'inarcl:, (London Statistical Journal, 1S61, p. 460 seq.), wc could gi"ant, that there is no 84 INTRODUCTION. [Ch. I. it should never be lost sight of, that the natural laws govern- ing the public economy of a people, like those of the human mind, are distinguished in one very essential point from those of the material world. They have to do with free rational be- ings, who, because they are thus free and rational, are respon- sible to God and their conscience, and constitute in their ag- gregate a species capable of progress. SECTION XIV. ORIGIN OF A NATION'S ECONOMY. The public economy of a people has its origin simultane- ously with the people. It is neither the invention of man nor the revelation of God. It is the natural product of the facul- ties and propensities which make man man.^ Just as it may be shown, that the family which lives isolated from all others, contains, in itself, the germs of all political organization,'^ so may it be demonstrated, that every independent household management contains the germs of all politico-economical activity. The public economy of a nation gi'ows with the nation. With the nation, it blooms and ripens. Its season of blossoming and of maturity is the period of its greatest strength, and, at the same time, of the most perfect develop- " law," except where it is possible to predict each individual occurrence under it, there would be no such thing even as the " laws " of the probability of life. The word " element," also, means something very different in Political Econ- omy from Avhat it does in chemistry: a combination which might be broken up, but which that science leaves it to other sciences to do. The "element" of Political Economy is Man. Compare Ptckford, Einleitung in die poli- tische CEk., iS6o, 17. • It is in this sense that Aristotle (Polit., I, p. i, 9 Schn.) says: (po.V£pbv^ ore Tcou ; Schmtilz, Handbuch der Staatswirthschaft, iSoS. More recently, Hcniiamt, Staatswirthschaftliche Untersuchungcn, 1S32. In France, the expression 6co7iomie de Vela/, is very seldom used. Gavard, Principes del'E. d'Etat, 1796. s Politz, Staatswissenschaftcn im Lichte unserer Zeit„II, 3. Compare Lotz^ Handbuch der Staatswirthschaft (2d ed., 1S37), I, 10 ft". 92 INTRODUCTION. [Ch. II. one which uninterruptedly and irresistibly acts on all others, out of consideration.* By the term folicc^ we mean the state power whose office it is, without mediation, to prevent all disturbances of external or- der among the people.^ It may extend its action into all the domains of national life mentioned above, whenever external order is there threatened, or calls for protection ; but its action is important especially in the domains of law and economy. The science of the -poUcc -pozucr^ therefore, of all those doctrines resulting from investigation into national life, takes up only one phase of each of them ; and the phases of doctrine thus taken up, it combines into a whole, for practical ends. Its rela- tion to those sciences is like that of surgery to the medical sci- ences, or like the science of legal procedure to the science of law. ^Our view of Political Economy holds a rniddle place between opposed ex- tremes. The view expressed by Whately^ Lectures on Political Economy (1831), No. I, and covered by the proposed term " catalactics," is by far too narrow. Similarly, Macleod^ Elements of Political Economy, 1858, I, 11. A like objection may be raised to the earlier title of Prifz-wltz's book : Die Kunst reich zuwerden, — the art of growing rich. On the other hand, Dun- oyer, Liberte du Travail (1845), L. IX, ch. I, goes too far altogether: "not only in what manner a nation grows rich, but according to what laws it best succeeds, in the execution of all its functions." And so SforcJi, Handbuch, translated into German by Rau, I, 9. Many modern writers define Polit- ical Economy simply as the theory of society ; for instance, Sctaloja, Principj. dell'Economia sociale, 1840. Cibrario, E. polit. del medio Evo, III, 1S42. 5 For the many and various definitions of the police power, see von Berg, Handbuch des Polezeirechts, I, 1-12; Butte, Versuch der Begriindung eines System der Polezei (1S07), 6 ff. ; Rosshirt, Ueber den Begriff der Staatspolizoi (1817), 34 ff. One of the principal difficulties is, that the practical domain of the police power is, in consequence of the successive grades of civilization through which a people passes, subject to greater modifications than any other state power. We call attention especially to the expressions " without mediation, to prevent," and "external order," in our definition. The church, the school, the administration of justice etc., act mediately towards the pre- vention of such disturbances; and there are many other institutions which offer immediate protection to order of a higher and more intellectual nature. Sec. XVIII.] SCIENCES RELATING TO NATIONAL LIFE. 93 SECTION XVIII. SCIENCES RELATING TO NATIONAL LIFE.— STATISTICS. Statistics we call the picture or representation of social life at given periods of time, and especially at the present time, drawn on a scale iu accordance witli the laws of development discovered by means of the theoretical sciences above named ; as it were, a section through the stream. {Sc/ilozcr calls them: history standing still.)^ Statistics, as thus defined, are as far removed from sa3dng too much as from saying too little. To give a complete tableau of their object, statistics should, of course, take in the life of a people, in all its aspects. But they should look upon such facts only as their own property, the meaning of which they are able to understand; that is, such only as can be ranged under known laws of develop- ment. Unintelligible facts are collected only in the hope of penetrating into their meaning in the future, by comparing them with one another. In the meantime, they are to the sta- tistician only what unfinished experiments are to the investi- gator of nature. The view is daily gaining ground, that statistics should be occupied — without, however, confining themselves to them — with present facts, with " facts afiecting society and the state, which are susceptible of being expressed in figures." ^ The more deceptive the immediate observation of an individual, isolated fact is, in cases where a great number of simultaneous ' See the great number of earlier definitions collected in R. von Moltl, Gesch. und Literatur der Staatswissenschaften III, pp. 637 fi". There are two prin- cipal groups of them, the one of which considers it as the science of things of political note, the other as the science of actual or past conditions. ^ See Du/(uf, Traitd de Statistique, 1840; Morcau de yi3/;//^5, Elements de Statistique, 1S47; Knics^ Die Statistik als sclbststandige Wissenschaft, 1S50. B. Hildcbnmd, in his Jahrbiichern, 1S66, I etc., but especially .^«c/r/f2?'5 works. For the contrary view, see Fallati, Einlcitung in die Wissenschaft der Statis- tik der St., 1S43; yoitak, Theorie der Statistik, 1S56, and Hecreii, in the Gott^ Gelehrten Anzeigen, 1S06, No. S4, 1807, 1302. 94: ■ INTRODUCTION. [Ch. II. or scattered individual isolated facts of national life should be observed, the more important it is to discover proper numeri- cal relations, by noting all the like acts or experiences of men, the time and place in question, and the relation of the aggre- gate of these phenomena, to the sum-total of the population, or to the sum-total of corresponding phenomena in other places. When this is done, and the focts are completely enu- merated and correctly recorded, there is no danger of sub- jective error. And this species of " political and social meas- uring," as Hildebrand calls it, may be applied, not only to quantities, bnt to all qualities accessible to the observation of the senses; since the individual or isolated qualities of the things enumerated, may be again made objects of enumera- tion. Without doubt, this mode of numerical procedure is the most perfect for all those divisions of statistics in which it can be followed; and hence, it should be our endeavor to make the numerical side of statistics as comprehensive as possible. But, one side of a science is not a science itself As there-is no natural science proper called microscopy, embracing all the observations made by means of the microscope, so care should be taken n-ot to deduce the principle of a science from the chief instrument it employs. There wiU always be many and important facts in national life which can not be subjected to numerical calculation, although they may be established with the usual amount of historical certainty. Were statistics to be limited, in the manner mentioned above, they would re- main a collection of fragments, and instead of being a science, properly so-called, become a method.^ Besides, it is evident, that, of statistics in general, economic 3 So thinks v. Rilmclin (Tiibinger Zeitschr., 1S63, 653 ft") ; and he recommends in place of statistics an independent brancli of learning bordering on historj and geography, to be called demography. His statistics is a science auxil- iary to all the experimental sciences ofman, justas criticism and hermeneutics are a methodological science auxiliary to many sciences, otherwise different. It would be difficult to justify the use of the name statistics for such a science, as such a science corresponds to neither of the two meanings of the word status (state — condition). Sec. XIX.] CAISIERALISTIC SCIENCE. 95 Statistics constitute a chief part, and precisely the part most accessible to numerical treatment. As these cx:onomic statis- tics need to be always directed by the light of Political Econ- omy, they also furnish it with rich materials for the continuation of its structure, and for the strengthening of such foundations as it already has. The}', are, moreover, the indispensable con- dition of the application of economic theorems to practice. SECTION XIX. PRIVATE ECONOMY — CAMERALISTIC SCIENCE. The meaning of the term cameralistic science {Canicralvjiss- aisc/uift) can be explained only by the history of the cam- eralistic system.^ From the end of the middle ages, we find, in most German countries, an institution called the Council {KajHincr) whose province it was to administer tlie public domain, and to watch over regal rights. At first, a mere governmental commission, it was not long betbre it developed into an independent board. This change had taken place in Burgundy as early as the year 1409. It was in that country that the emperor Maximilian became acquainted with the in- stitution ; and by the erection of the aulic councils at Innspruck and Vienna (1498 and 1501), he gave the principal impulse to the imitation of it in Germany. As, at that time, the division of labor was very little developed, and personal and collegial authority all the more developed in consequence, it is easy to 1 The ancients understood by the term xapApo. camera, covered places such especially as -were .vaulted, also vaults of the most varied kind. Com- pare Herod. I, 199; Diod., II, 9; Strabo, XI, 495; Arrtan. Exp. Alex., VII, 5, 55; Dio Cass. XXXVI, 32; Sallusf, B. C, 55; Cicero, ad Q. fratrem III, i; riin., II. N. XXX, 27; Seneca, Epist., S6; Tacii. Hist. Ill, 47; Sueio», Nero, 34. During the middle ages, the meaning treasure-chamber (Schatzhammcr) became predominant: camera est locus, in qnem thesaurus rccoiUigitur, vel cofi- clave, in quo fecunia reservatur {Ocham, Cap. Quid sit Scaccarium). It gradu- ally became synonymous with finance, — from the time of Charlemagne, or at least since Louis II. (Charter of S74). See Ducange, Glossarium, v. Camera, and Muratori Antiquitt. Ital., I, 932 ff. • 96 INTRODUCTION. [Cir. II. conceive that a great part of all the new and rapidly increas- ing business of police administration was confided to these councils. They were charged especially with what is known to-day as economic police ( Wirthschaftspolizei) and an import- ant part of the administration of justice, in its lower depart- ments, was turned over to their subordinates. The most eminent men who wrote, in the seventeenth century, on cam- eralistic matters, laid great stress on the point, that it was the duty of the aulic councils to entertain not only fiscal questions, but that it was within their province also, to determine ques- tions of economic police.^ The interest of absolute princes must have greatly favored these cameralistic institutions, for they were in their hands docile tools, which escaped the an- noying intervention of the states of their realms. By degrees, the knowledge necessary to these council officials, and which found no place in the lectures on law, were formed into a special body of doctrine. After such men as Morhof and Thomasius had prepared the way,^ Frederick William I., himself a clever cameralist, and author of the mas- terly financial system of Prussia, took the important step of founding, at Halle and Frankfurt on the Oder, special chairs of economy and cameralistic science ; which, considering the time, were very ably filled by Gasser and Dithmar. (1727.) ' " A husbandman must plow and manure his land if he would reap a har- vest from it. He must fatten his cattle if he would glaughter them; and furnish his cows with good fodder if he would ha^'e them give good milk. In like manner, a prince should begin by assuring his subjects healthy and abundant food, if he would take anything from them :" von Schroder^ Fiirstl. Schatz-und Rentkammer (1686), preface, § 11. Von Horneck before him, Oesterreich iiber alles wann es nur will, p. 220, ed. of 1707, had expressed the idea that the watchful solicitude for the public economy of the country was no farergon^ no afpendix^ to the council (Kammer)^ but its real basis, and that it embraced many subjects which had nothing in common with the cameralia C" Cameralien "^. ^ Morhof ^ Polyhistor (168S), III. Thomasius, 1728, Cautelse circa prxcog- nita Jurisprudentite (17 10), ch. 17. (Cautelae circa studium occonomicum.) Also, in his lectures on Sechendorff^s " Teutschen Fiirstenstaat." Compare Roschcr, Gesch. der N. CEk. in Deutschland, 328 IT. Sec. XX.] PRIVATE ECONOMY. 97 There was thus formed in the German universities a dis tinct school of cameralists, which, through Jung, Rossig and Schmalz, reached to the nineteenth century. The term camer- alistic science, the creature of chance, was used, it must be said, with very various limits to its meaning.* However, Political Economy in Germany developed out of the science of law and the cameralistic sciences, while in Eng- land and Italy it had its origin chiefly in the study of questions of finance and foreign commerce. SECTION XX. PRIVATE ECONOMY. (CONTINUED.) If we abstract from cameralistic science as it was understood in the last century, what it has in common with all economy,^ and therefore with public economy, next that which belongs to the aggregate of governmental economy, there remains only a number of rules, such as those which govern the principal branches of private business, and which indicate how they are to be carried on with the greatest advantage to those who en- gage in them. Such are forest and rural economy, mining science, technology, including architecture, and all that con- cerns founderies, and commercial science. Now that the ex- pression cameralistic science is altogether obsolete, the aggre- * While Dithmar (1731) distinguishes economy -police and canneralistic sciences and restricts the latter to finance and taxation; Darjes (1756) com- prises under the name of cameralistic science, economy (municipal and rural), and police, as well as cameralistic subjects in the strict sense of the term, that is, the public domain and regal rights. While Nau (1791), in his " Ersten Linien der C," treats only of the branches of private economy, Schmalz^ [I'jg'j) treats also of national or public economy, and liosst'g- (1792) divides cameralistic science into the doctrine of the public demesne and regal rights (cameralistic science in the narrower sense), and the doctrine of taxa- tion and police. ' Thus, for instance, all that concerns domestic economy, book-keeping and private financial administration. Vol. 1.— 7 98 INTRODUCTION. [Ch. II. gate of these might be designated by the name private economy. Obviously, we should have here, neither a simple nor pure sci- ence, but only a compilation of natural-philosophical and eco- nomic lemmas. Thus, in agriculture, for instance, a knowl- edge of the different kinds of soil, of the tillage of land, of the different plants and animals etc., belongs to the domain of nat- ural science; while all that relates to the cost of production, the employment of capital, the wages of labor, the exchange of products, net product and the price of land, are purely politi- co-economical. The political economists also require a knowl- edge of the natural side of the cameralistic sciences. Such a knowledge is indispenable to every detailed and living theory, and especially to the application of economic science to prac- tice. The great difference lies in this, that the cameralist inter- ests himself in the production of material goods for their own sake, while the political economist regards them only in their relations to national life.^ It would seem, moreover, that political economists, especial- ' John Stuart Mill, Principles of Political Economy (1848), I, p. 25, draws a distinction between the physical conditions which influence the economic situation of a people, and the moral and psychological conditions; which last have their origin in social institutions or in the fundamental principles of hu- man nature. Only the latter belong to the domain of Political Economy. According to J. B. Say, Traite, Introd., this science embraces at once agri- culture, mauufactures and commerce, but only in their relation to the increase or diminution of w-ealth, and does not concern itself with the means employed to reach the desired end. As a rule, says Arndt (Naturgemasse Volkswirth- schaft, 1851, p. 16), it takes into consideration not so much things themselves as their exchange value. Lotz (Handbuch, I, p. 6 seq.), in like manner, defines Political Economy — the science of the one activity which constitutes the basis of all industries etc. F. G. Schulze (Ueber volkswirthschaftliche Begrundung der Gewerbswissenschaften, 1S26), characterizes Political Econ- omy as the science of the fundamental conditions of the well-being of a peo- ple, in so far as they lie in human nature. When Adam Smith (book IV, c. II) says that the government in respect to matters of economy is inferior to the first best person engaged in industrial pursuits, he is right only from a technic point of view. And when Stezvart, on the other hand, vindicates for the state the office of a pater-familias (book II, ch. 13), he evidently means only in national economical matters. t>EC. XXL] WHAT rOLITICAL ECONOMY TREATS OF. 99 h' in Germany, have attached too much importance to putting formal bounds to their special science. Why not rather fol- low the example of the students of nature who care little whether this or that discovery belongs to physics or chemis- try, to astronomy or mathematics, provided, only, very many and important discoveries are mader^ SECTION XXI. WHAT POLITICAL ECONOMY TREATS OF. Political Economy treats chiefly of the material interests of nations. It inquires how the various wants of the people of a country, especially those of food, clothing, fuel, shelter, of the sexual instinct etc., may be satisfied ; how the satisfaction of these wants influences the aggregate national life, and how in turn, they are influenced by the national life. (Gospel of Matth., 4, 4.) This alone suffices to enable us to estimate the importance of the science. The relation of virtue to wealth is likened by Bacon to that of an army to its baggage. In Xenophon's opinion, wealth is really useful only to him who knows how to make a good use of it. From an economic point of view, the happiest man is he who has accumulated most, honorably, and used it best.^ That, even in a material sense, the intellect of a people is their most important element, is evi- dent from the example of the Chinese, who were so long ac- quainted with printing, powder, and the mariner's compass, without, by their means, attaining to intelligent public opinion, forming a good army, or coming to an understanding of the art of navigation, to any great extent. The undervaluing of economic matters, for which ages of inferior cultivation, our own middle ages for instance, are now 3 See also Ran (Ueber die Cameralwissenschaft, Entwickelung ihres Wesens und ihrer Thcile, 1S25); ^«K;«5/rt/'>t (Cameralistische Enclycopadie, 1S35). ^Xcnopk. fficonom. I, S fT. Cyrop. VIII; 2, 23. He saw with equal clear- ness the moral light and shade of wealth. CEcon. XI. 9. Conviv. 4. Memor. 1,6. Cyrop. VIII, 3, 35 ff. IIiero4.) 100 INTRODUCTION. [Ch. IL praised and now blamed, was really a rare exception even during these ages.^ Other kinds of acquisition and enjoyment then occupied the foreground; but there never was a time, when gain and enjoyment in general were not favorite objects of pursuit, and held in high esteem. The physical wants of uncultured men cry out much louder than intellectual ones. (§ 2, 14.)^ On the other hand, in over-cultivated ages, when decay begins, an over-estimation of material things is wont to become general.* The mere servants of mammon, whether as political economists or as private individuals, may see their depravity faithfully reflected in communism as in a mirror. We should not overlook the fact that it is with whole nations * Thomas Aquinas values earthly goods according to the end they are inade to serve ; when used for a good purpose, they have a mediately true val- ue. Hence it was an error of the stoics to despise them under all circum- stances. (Summa Theol. II, 2. Qu., 50, 3. 58, 2. 59, 3. 125, 4.) * Whateley considers the savage much beneath th e materialist, instead of superior to him. The latter possesses, although he frequently abuses it, the faculty of self-control and forethought, which is entirely wanting in the former. (Lectures, No. 6.) Dunoyer, De la Liberte du Travail, liv. IV, ch. I, 8, an apology for the moral wholesomeness of civilization, since promotive of military prowess, favorable to the development of the sciences, and even poetical. BatidriUart, Manual d'CEkonomie politique, 1857, 24. See Fallati, Ueber die sogennannte materiellen Tendenz der Gegenwart, 1842. * See the inscription on the tomb of Sardanapalus : vaUT ^'j/^f^t oaa i(pajov xac i(pu^pcaa xai fxsr iqcovo;; rsqm ena&ov. {Strabo, XIV, 672.) Isaiah, 122, 13, 56, 12, and the book of wisdom (2) characterizes the view of the fallen Jewish people. In Greece, the Cynic and Epicurean schools were only different phases of the same degeneration. " Thirst, for money, and nothing else, will be the ruin of Sparta!" (Cicero, De Offic, II, 22, 77.) See the magnificent description by Demosthenes, in which he shows the over-estimation of material things to be the principal cause of the decline of Athens, and in which he lays great stress on the fact, that Athens, on its decay, had a larger population, more wealth, ships, and evidences of external power, than in its golden age. (Phil., Ill, 120 seq.) Also Phil., IV, 144, cautions us against the Manchester criterion of national prosperity. See Plato, De Rep., VIII. In Rome, the principle ommia venalia esse was a chief element in the total decline and fall of the republic. (Sallust, Cat., 10 ff.. Jug., 8 ff.) In an age when people think they can do everything with money, the ruin of all things is the last end of mercantile, financial and political specu- lation. (Co7idillac, Le Commerce et le Gouverment, 1776, II, 18.) Sec. XXL] WHAT POLITICAL ECONOMY TREATS OF. IQl as with the individual man who amasses his own fortune. He reaches the cuhiiinating point of his weahh generally after he has passed the prime of life. The most flourishing period of a nation's existence is wont just to precede its decay, and to introduce it.^ Hence, here nothing could be more untrue, as Macchiavelh has remarked, than the general opinion that money is the sinew of war.* * Under Pericles, the Athenian treasury of the state contained at most 9,700 talents. (Thucyd. II, 13.) On the other hand, Alexander the Great had a treasure of iSo,ooo talents accumulated in the citadel of Ecbatana. {Sirabo, XV, 731); Ptolomy II. left after him 740,000 talents. [Apfian. pra;f. 10, Droyscii, Geschichte dcs Ilcllenismus II, 44 ff.) In Nero's time there was man}' a freedman's daughter who owned a looking glass worth a greater sum than the senate had appropriated as a doAvry to the daughter of the great Scipio. {Seneca, Qua?st. Natur. I, 17. Compare Cons, ad Helviam, 12.J McCnllock says that an intelligent despotism can enrich a nation as well as freedom. (In his Discourse on the Rise, etc. of Polit. Econ., 1825, 77 seq.) ^ Bacon (Sermones, 56) says that youthful states distingui sh themselves specially by their warlike instincts; mature states in literature; old and de- caying ones in industry and commerce. JDavenant very happily remarks, that the development of commerce among a people has an ambiguous value. It, indeed, increases wealtli, but, at the same time, it may introduce luxury, covetousness and fraud, destroy virtue, do away with simplicity of manners and.customs, and then it inevitably ends in internal or external slavery. (Works II, 275.) The simplicity of the patriarchal state, however, cannot last always, if for no other reason, because of the emulation of foreign na- tions, (i, 348, ff.) The impoverishment of even the wealthiest nation is certainly inevitable when its morality dfclines. It is especially h-ue, that the public economy of a people can be prosperous only where political liberty obtains, and this, independent of the fact that wealth without freedom has no value. (II, 336 ff., 3S0, fi'., 2S5.) According to Ferguson, private wealth, hon- estly acquired, used rightly and with moderation, :nanaged with a sense of independence, may be to those who possess it, an element of self-confidence and of liberty, provided they loosen their purse strings not through vanity or for their personal gratification, but for commendable party purposes. But in periods of decay, even a greater amount of wealth is very far from pro- ducing these results. (History of Civil Society, VI, 5.) W/iatcly, on the contrary, maintains that only personal wealth — never national wealth — has a disastrous influence on morals. Lectures, No. 2. 102 INTRODUCTION. [Ch. III. CHAPTER HI. THE METHODS OF POLITICAL ECONOMY. SECTION XXII. FORMER METHODS. The methods' which would apply to any science of national life, principles borrowed from any other science, are now gen- erally looked upon as obsolete. This is true, especially, of the theological method which prevailed, almost exclusively, during the middle ages,'^ and of the juridical method of the seventeenth century. It would be much more in harmony with the intellectual tendencies of the time, to adopt a mathematical mode of treat- ment in Political Economy, involving, as such a mode of treat- ment does, not the matter of the science, but only a formal ' " The method of a science is of much greater importance than any indi- vidual discovery, however wonderful." (Cuvicr.) 2 Thus, for instance, G. Bid (ob. 1495), the " last of the schoolmen," gives us his doctrine of Political Economy, in a work on Dogmatic Theology, in the chapter on Penfince, his starting point being the inquiry, how the eco- nomic damage caused by the sinner may be repaired. Jioscher, Gesch- ichte der Nationalokonomik in Deutchland, 1074, I, 23. The Melittothe- ologia, Arachnotheologia of later times! A recent attempt in this direc- tion has been made by Ad. Miiller, Nothwendigkeit einer theologischen Grundage der gesammten Staatswissenschaften und der Staatswirthschaft insbesondere (1819), i. e., " necessity of a theological basis for all political sci- ence, and especially lor Political Economy." He divides political science into two parts : the science of law, and the science of wisdom, embracing under the latter denomination, politics. Political Economy, etc. Law ema- nates from God, as supreme judge; the science of Avisdom from God, as our Supreme Father. Sec. XXII.] FORMER METHODS. 103 principle. That which is general in Political Economy has, it must be acknowledged, much that is analogous to the math- ematical sciences. Like the latter, it swarms with abstrac- tions.^ Just as there are, strictly speaking, no mathematical lines or points in nature, and no mathematical lever, there is nowhere such a thing as production or rent, entirely pure and simple. The mathematical laws of motion operate in a hypo- thetical vacuum, and, where applied, are subjected to important moditications, in consequence of atmospheric resistance. Some- thing similar is true of most of the laws of our science ; as, for instance, those in accordance wath which the price of com- modities is lixed by the buyer and seller. It also, always sup- poses the parties to the contract to be guided only by a sense of their own best interest, and not to be influenced by second- ary considerations. It is not, therefore, to be wondered at, that many authors have endeavored to clothe the laws of Political Economy in algebraic formulai.^ And, indeed, wherever mag- 3 Abstraction is indulged in on a large scale, when a number of elements which are always found combined in life, are here separated and examined apart. It is precisely thus that anatomy proceeds, dissecting each member of the human frame, separating the bones, ligaments and muscles from one an- other, thus becoming the necessary preparatory school to physiology. ^Thus, for instance. Canard^ Principes d'Economie politique (iSoi). Also Kronche^ in several of his works, and Count Buqitoy, in his Theorie der Na- tionalwirthschaft (1816), p. 333 iT. ; Lang, Grundlinien einer politischen Arithmetik, Charkow, 181 1, and more especially v. TJiUnen, Der isolirte Staat, vol. I (1842), vol. II, 1S50. See my criticism of his method in Birn- 5rt«/rt'5 Georgika, 1869, 77 ft". Von ThUnciCs fii'st volume is an essay towards a geometrical exposition of the science. See also Rau, Lehrbuch I, § 154, ap- pendix; von Mangoldt, Grundriss der Volkswirthschaftslehfe (1862); Cazaux, Elements d' Economie privee et Principes mathematiques de la Theorie des Richesses (1S38); F. Fuoco, Saggi economici (1827) II, 61 ft". Walrus, Ele- ments d' Econ. p61itique pure (1874). jfcvons has recently endeavored to give Political Economy a mathematical basis by reducing the objects of which it treats to the calculable feelings of pleasure (4-) and pain (— ). The duration of a feeling is tjeated as an abscissa, its intensity as the ordinate of a curve, and its quantity as the area. Future feelings are reduced to present ones, by allowing for their distance, and the uncertainty of their occurrence. All this, however, is rather curious than scientifically useful. 104 INTRODUCTION. [Ch. III. nitudes and the relations of magnitudes to one another are treated of, it must be possible to subject them to calculation. Herbart has shown that this is so in the case of psychology;^ and all the sciences which treat of national life, especially our own, are psychological.^ But the advantages of the mathemat- ical mode of expression diminish as the facts to which it is ap- plied become more complicated. This is true even in the or- dinary psychology of the individual. How much more, there- fore, in the portraying of national life! Here the algebraic formulce would soon become so con plicated, as to make all further progress in the operation next to impossible.''' Their employment, especially in a science whose sphere it is, at pres- ent, to increase the number of the facts observed, to make them the object of exhaustive investigation, and vary the com- binations into which they may be made to enter, is a matter of great difficulty, if not entirely impossible.^ For, most assured- ly, as our science has to do with men, it must take them and treat them as they actually are, moved at once by very differ- ent and non-economic motives, belonging to an entirely definite people, state, age etc. The abstraction according to which * Herbart^ Ueber die Moglichkeit und Nothwendigkeit, Mathematik auf Psychologic anzuwenden ; Kleinere Schriften, II, 417. * How detrimental it is to ignore the psychological nature of Political Econ- omy is evident from the errors of Karl Marx, who personifies things in a manner almost mythological. Thus, according to him, modesty should be ascribed to a coat which exchanges for a piece of linen, and purpose to the linen, etc. (Das Kapital, 1S67, I, 19, 22, seq.) The greatest fault of this in- telligent but not very acute man, his inability to reduce complicated phenom- ena to their constituent elements, is greatly increased by his way of thus looking at things. ^ Compare 5^. B. Say, Traite I, introd. Thus, it would be certainly possi- ble to describe every individual's physiognomy by means of a very compli- cated mathematical formula, and yet there is no one who would not prefer the usual mode of taking pictures. The simple motions of the heavenly bodies, on the contrary, are always treated mathematically. [Loize, Arige- meine Physiologic, 322 fl.) 8 When Favjcett says that all " principles of Political Economy are describ- ing tendencies instead of actual results" (Manual of Political Economy, 1863, p. 90), our method, the historical, would give also the theory of the latter. Sec. XXIL] FORMER METHODS. 105 all men are by nature the same, different only in consequence of a difterence of education, position in life etc., all equally well equipped, skillful and free in the matter of economic pro- duction and consumption, i-s one which, as Ricardo and von Thiinen have shown, must pass as an indispensable stage in the preparatory labors of political economists. It would be especially well, when an economic fact is produced by the co- operation of many different factors, for the investigator to men- tally isolate the factor of which, for the time being, he wishes to examine the peculiar nature. All other factors should, for a time, be considered as not operating, and as unchangeable, and then the question asked. What would be the effect of a change in the factor to be examined, whether the change be occasioned b}' enlarging or diminishing it.'^ But it never should be lost sight of, that such a one is only an abstraction after all, for which, not only in the transition to practice, but even in fin- ished theor}', we must turn to the infinite variety of real life.^ There are two important inquiries in all sciences whose sub- ject matter is national or social life: i. What isF (What has been? How did it become so? etc.) 2. What s/iould dcP The greater number of political economists have confounded these questions one with the other, but not all to the same extent.^" *This was lost sight of by most writers during the second half of the eighteenth century, because they looked upon that equality as the really oldest condition, and its restoration the ideal to be striven for. How much of this still clings to the present free-trade school; see in Roscher^ Gesch. der N. Oi^k. in Deutschland, 10 17 ff. "> Thus, for instance, Ricardo examines, almost exclusively, the actual con- dition of things, while the socialists confine themselves, still more exclu- sively, to the investigation of how things should be. It has been very usual in Germany since Rau wrote, to draw a distinction between theoretical and practical Political Economy. There are many who think that a good man- ual of practical Political Economy, dropping the introduction, demonstrations etc., would be also a good code of law, of universal application. Mercicr de la Riviere has said that he wished to propose an organization which should be necessarily productive of all the happiness which can be enjoyed on earth. (Ordre essentiel et naturel (1767), Disc, prelim.) Compare, also, Sismondi^ N. Principes, I, ch. 2. 106 INTRODUCTION. [Ch III.. When a careful distinction is made between them, the contrast between the (realistic) hysiological or historical, and the ideal- istic methods is brought out.^^ SECTION XXIII. THE IDEALISTIC METHOD. Any one who has read a goodly number of idealistic works treating of public economy (the state, law etc.) cannot have failed to be struck by the enormous differences, and even con- tradictions, as to what theorizers have considered desirable and " The word method is used in an essentially different sense, when the in- quiry is, whether the inductive or deductive method is followed in Political Economy, y. S. ISIill calls Political Economy, and, indeed, all " sociology," a concrete deductive science, whose a priori conclusions, based on the laws of human nature, must be tested by experience, either by comparing them with the concrete phenomena themselves, or with their emperical laws. It, in this, resembles astronomy and physics. (System of Logic VI, ch. 9. Es- says on some unsettled questions of Political E., No. 5.) According to this, an economic fact can be said to have received a scientific explanation only when its deductive and inductive explanations have met and agreed. " Only those principles which, after they have been obtained by the one, are con- firmed by the other method, can be said to have a scientific basis." (von Mangoldt^ Grundriss, 8.) While I agree to this view, it seems necessary to me to mention points wherein caution is necessary : A. Even the deduc- tive explanation of economic facts is based on observation, namely, on the self-observation of the person accounting lor them, who, consciously or un- consciously, must always inquire: If I had experienced or accomplished the same fact, what should I have thought, willed and felt.' The man who can- not translate himself into the souls of others, will give a wrong explanation of most economic facts. In the question, for instance, of the determination of the price of an article, the person who can look into the mind of one of the contracting parties only, will give a one-sided explanation of the facts. B. Moreover, every explanation, that is, satisfactory connection of the fact seeking explanation with other facts which are already clear, can be only provisional. The wider our horizon grows, the deeper should our solution of all questions become. A hundred years hence, should science increase in the mean time, the solutions which are satisfactory to us will be looked down upon by our posterity, as the speculations of our fathers antecedent to Adam Smith's time are looked down upon by us. Sec. XXIV.] THE IDEALISTIC METHOD. 107 necessar}-. There is scarcely an important point which the highest authorities may not be cited for or against. We must not close our eyes to this fact. " The giddiness that comes from contemplating the depths of knowledge is the beginning of philosophy, as the god Thaumas was, according to the fa- ble, the father of Iris." {Plato.) In a precisely similar man- ner, the student of public economy (politics, the philosophy of law etc.) must familiarize himself with the variations that have taken place in what men, at different periods of history, have required of the state and public economy, until he is lost in wonder at the contemplation. SECTION XXIV. THE IDEALISTIC METHOD. (CONTINUED.) It is impossible to fail to notice at once that those ideal de- scriptions wdiich have enjoyed great fame and exerted great influence, depart very little from the real conditions of the pub- lic economy (of the state, law etc.) surrounding their authors.^ This is not mere chance. The power of great theorizers, as, indeed, of all great men, lies, as a rule, in this, that they satisfy the want of their own time to an unusual extent ; and it is the peculiar task of theorizers to give expression to this want with scientific clearness, and to justify it with scientific depth. But the real wants of a people will, in the long run, be satis- fied in life," so far as this is possible to the moral imperfec- ' Tanquam e vinctilis sermocinantu}\ says Bacon (De Dignit. et Augm. Scient., Ill, 3), of those who have written in a not non-practical -way on the laws. Hugo, also (Naturrccht, 1S19, p. 9), calls attention to the resemblance of the so-called laws of nature, to the positive law in force at the time. As to polit- ical idealism, see Roscher: De historical doctrintc apud sophistas majores vestigiis (Gdtt. 1S3S, 26 ff.). The only exceptions to this rule are the eclec- tics, who form their own system from the blossoms of all foreign ones, a sys- tem, indeed, without root, and which therefore must soon wither. ' In this place, naturally, such an assertion can be made only as a pro- gramme to be carried out, the proof whereof is to be sought in the rest of the 108 INTRODUC-ilON [Ch. III. tion of man. We should at least be on our guard when we hear it said that w hole nations have been forced into an " un- natural" course by priests, tyrants and cavilers. For, to leave human freedom and divine Providence out of consideration entirely, how is such a thing possible? The supposed tyrants are generally part and parcel of the people themselves ; all their resources are derived from the people. They must have been new Archimedeses standing outside of their own world. (Compare, however, infra^ % 263.) It is true, that if the result of the growth of generations be to gradually produce a different people, these different men may require different institutions. Then a struggle arises be- tween the old and those of the younger generation ; the former wish to retain what has been tested by time, the latter to seek for the satisfaction of their new wants by new means. As the sea always oscillates between the flowing and ebbing of the tides, so the life of nations, between periods of repose and of crisis: periods of repose, when existing forms answer to the real substance of things, and of crisis, when the changed sub- stance or contents seeks to build up a new form for itself. Such crises are called reforms when they are effected in a peaceful way, and in accordance with positive law. When accomplished in violation of law, they are called revolutions.^ That every revolution, it matters not how great the need of the change produced by it, is as such an enormous evil, a seri- work. By " the people," we do not mean the governed, to the exclusion of the governing classes, but both classes together. We attach to the expression the most extensive meaning possible. We do not limit it to the present gen- eration, but intend it to cover all the generations from the beginning of a people's history to its end. 3 The custom, Avhich has become general, of calling all democratic move- ments, and them only, revolutions (thus Staid: Was ist Revolution.? 1852, and many other writers of an entirely opposite tendency, especially in France), is not warranted. It is true that democratic (and imperial) revolutions are more frequent than others in our times, just as aristocratic revolutions were in the middle ages, and monarchical at the beginning of modern history. The essence of revolution, however, is in the operation of change contrary to positive law, acknowledged as such by the consciousness of the people. Sec. XXIV.] THE IDEALISTIC METHOD. IQO ous, and sometimes, fatal disease of the body politic, is self- evident. The injury to morals which the spectacle of victorious wrong almost always produces can be healed, as a rule, only in the following generation. Where law has been once tram- pled on, the "right of the stronger" will prevail; and the stronger is, to some extent, the most unscrupulous and reck- less in the choice of the means to be employed. Hence, the well-known fact, that in revolutionary times the worst so fre- quently remain the victors. The counter-revolution which is wont to follow on the heels of revolution, and with a corres- ponding violence, is a compensation only to the most short- sighted. It allows the disease, the familiarizing of the people with the infringement of law, to continue, until the hitherto sound parts are attacked. Hence, a people should, if they would have it go well with them, in the changes in the form of things which they make, take as their model Time, whose reforms are the surest and most irresistible, but, at the same time, as Bacon says, so gradual that they cannot be seen or observed at any one moment. It is true, that, as all that is great is difficult, so also is the carrying out of uninterrupted reform. Its carrying out, indeed, supposes two things: a con- stitution so wisely planned as to keep the doors open both to the disappearing institutions of the past and to the coming institutions of the future; and, among all classes of the people, a moral control of themselves, so absolute that, no matter w^hat the inconvenience, or how great the sacrifice, legal ways shall alone be used. In this manner, two of the greatest and ap- parently most contradictory wants of every legal or moral person, the w-ant of uninterrupted continuity and that of free development, may be satisfied. 110 INTRODUCTION. [Ch. Ill SECTION XXV. THE IDEALISTIC METHOD. (CONTINUED.) It is doubtless true that all economic laws, and all economic institutions are made for the people, not the people for such laws and institutions. Their mutability is, therefore, by no means such an evil as mankind should endeavor to remove, but is wholesome and laudable, so far as it runs parallel with the transformation of the people, and the changes which their wants have undergone.^ Hence, there is no reason why the most various ideal systems should contradict one another. Any one of them may be right, but, of course, only for one people and one age. In this case, the only error would be, if they should claim to be universally applicable. There can no more be an economic ideal adapted to the various wants of every people, than a garment which should fit every individual. The leading-strings of children and the staff of age would be great annoyances to the man. " Reason becomes non- sense cind beneficence a torment." Hence, whoever would elaborate the ideal of the best public economy — and the greater number of political economists have really wished to do this — should, if he would be perfectly true, and at the same time prac- tical, place in juxta position as many different ideals as there are different types of people.^ He would, moreover, have to revise his work every few years; for, in proportion as a people change, and new wants originate, the economic ideal suitable to them must change also. But it is impossible to accomplish this on so large a scale. Besides, to appreciate the present thus instantaneousl}^ and to perfectly feel the pulse ' Compare, especially, the first pages of Sir y. Stcxvarf, Principles of Polit Economy. * See Colton, Public Economy of the United States, p. 28, who, indeed, un- wai-rantedly, refers to the whole of Political Economy, what properly belongs to its precepts. Sec. XXVI.] THE HISTORICAL METHOD. m of time thus uninterruptedly, requires a species of talent difler- ent from what even the most distinj^uished scientists are wont to possess ; talents of an entirely practical nature, such as become a great minister of the interior or of finance. And it is an acknowledged lact, that ev en the cleverest of such prac- ticioners, as the younger Pitt said of himself, generally feel their way instinctivel}', and do not see it with the clearness necessary to indicate it to others. SECTION XXVI. THE HISTORICAL METHOD. — THE. ANATOMY AND PHYSI- OLOGY OF PUBLIC ECONOMY. We refuse entirely to lend ourselves in theory to the con- struction of such ideal systems. Our aim is simply to describe man's economic nature and economic wants, to investigate the laws and the character of the institutions which are adapted to the satisfaction of these wants, and the greater or less amount of success by which they have been attended.^ Our task, is, therefore, so to speak, the anatomy and physiology of social or national economy! These are matters to be found within the domain of reality, susceptible of demonstration or refutation by the ordinary op- erations of science ; entirely true or entirely false, and, there- fore, in the former case, not liable to become obsolete. We proceed after the manner of the investigator of nature. We, too, have our dissecting knife and microscope, and we have an advantage over the student of nature in this, that the self- observation of the body is exceedingly limited, while that of mind is almost unlimited. There are other respects, however, in which he has the advantage over us. When he wishes to ' Je ii'imfose ricn, je 7ie frof>ose mime ricn : f expose. {CIi. Dunoyer'). CJier- bulicz, Precis de la Science cconomiquc, 1S62, p. 7 ff., has exaggerated this idea in a strangely non-practical manner. That the historical method docs not differ essentially from the statistical as recently recommended, see Reseller^ Gesch. der Nat. CEk., 1035 seq. 112 INTRODUCTION. [Ch. III. Study a given species, he may make a hundred or a thousand experiments, and use a hundred or a thousand individuals for his purpose. Hence, he can easily control each separate ob- servation, and distinguish the exception from the rule. But, how many nations are there which we can make use of for purposes of comparison ? Their very fewness makes it all the more imperative to compare them all. Doubtless, comparison cannot supply the place of observation; but observation may be thus rendered more thorough, many-sided, and richer in the number of its points of view. Interested alike in the dif- ferences and resemblances, we must first form our rules from the latter, consider the former as the exceptions, and then en- deavor to explain them. {Infra^ § 266). SECTION XXVII. ADVANTAGES OF THE HISTORICAL OR PHYSIOLOGICAL METHOD, The thorough application of this method will do away with a great number of controversies on important questions.^ Men are as far removed from being devils as from being angels. We meet with few who are only guided by ideal motives, but with few, also, who hearken only to the voice of egotism, and care for nothing but themselves. It may, therefore, be as- sumed, that any view current on certain tangible interests which concern man very nearly, and which has been shared by great parties and even by whole peoples for generations, is not based only on ignorance or a perverse love of wrong. The error consists more frequently in applying measures wholesome and even absolutely necessary under certain circumstances, to circumstances entirely different. And here, a thorough in- sight into the conditions of the measure suffices to compose the differences between the two parties. Once the natural laws of Political Economy are sufficiently known and recognized, > Storck, Handbuch, II, 22 2. Sec. XXVIII.J HISTORICAL ISIETIIOD. 1;13 all that is needed, in any given instance, is more exact and reliable statistics of the fact involved, to reconcile all party controversies on questions of the politics of public econom}', so far, at least, as these controversies arise from a difference of opinion. It may be that science may never attain to this, in consequence of the new problems which are ever arising and demanding a solution. It may be, too, that in the greater number of party controversies, the opposed purposes of the parties play a more important part even than the opposed views. Be this as it may, it is necessary, especially in an age as deeply agitated as our own, when every good citizen is in duty bound to ally himself to party, that every honest party- man should seek to secure, amid the ocean of ephemeral opin- ions, a firm island of scientific truth, as universally recognized as truth as are the principles of mathematical physics by physicians of the most various schools. SECTION XXVIII. ADVANTAGES OF THE HISTORICAL METHOD. (COXTIXUED.) Another characteristic feature of the historical method is that it does away with the feeling of sell-sufliciency, and the braggadocio which cause most men to ridicule what they do not understand, and the higher to look down with contempt on lower civilizations. "Whoever is acquainted with the laws of the development of the }:)lant, cannot fail to see in the seed the germ of its growth, and in its flower, the herald of decay. If there were inhabitants of the moon, and one of them should visit our earth, and fmd children and grown people side by side, while ignorant of the laws of human development, would he not look upon the must beautiful child as a mere monster, with an enormous head, with arms and legs of stunted growth, useless genitals, and destitute of reason? The folly of such a judgment would be obvious to ever}^ one; and yet we meet with thousands like it on the state and the public economy of Vol. I.— S 114 ' INTRODUCTION. [Ch. III. nations when in lower stages of civilization, and this, even amonfj the most distiniruished writers.-^ We may, indeed, make a critical comparison of different forms, each of which answers perfectly to its object or con- tents; but such a comparison can possess historical object- ivity, only when it is based on a correct view of the peculiar course of development followed by the people in question. The forms of the period of maturity may be considered the most perfect; earlier forms as the immature, and the later as those of the acje of decline.^ But it is a matter of the great- est difficulty, accurately to determine the culminating point of a people's civilization. The old man believes, as a rule, that the times are growing worse, because he is no longer in a way to utilize them; the young man, as a rule, that they are growing better, because he hopes to turn them to account. It is, however, always a purely empirical question ; and in the solution of it, the observer's eye may acquire a singular acute- ness by the comparative study of as many nations as possible, especially of those which have already passed away.^ Could anyone contemplate the history of mankind as a a whole, of which the histories of individual nations are but the parts, the successive steps in the evolution of humanity would of course afford him a similar objective rule for all these * Ad. Milllcr, an essentially mediceval mind, is guilty of this same brag- gadocio in an opposite direction, when he calls the " present with its political disorders simply an intermediate state, — the transmission of the natural or unconscious wisdom of the fathers, through the inquisitiveness of their chil- dren to the rational acknowledgment of that wisdom by their grandsons." (Theorie des Geldes, iSi6, pref.) 2 Thus, for instance, it can not be said that a model university is better than a model public school ; and yet the former is higher, because the age to which it is adapted is doubtless intellectually higher. 3 Kntcs (Polit. CEk., 256 seq.) remarks, that it would be a great mistake, and it is the mistake of the majority, to consider what has been achieved or striven for in the present, as the absolute von fins tiltra, and thus to look upon all future generations as called upon to play the parts of apes and ruminators ; a remark ^Yorthy to be taken to heart. I Sec. XXIX.] HISTORICAL METHOD. 115 points in which whole peoples permanently differ from one another.* SECTION XXIX. THE PRACTICAL CHARACTER OF THE HISTORICAL METHOD IN POLITICAL ECONOMY. Before I close, I must refer to a possible objection which may be made to historical or physiological Political Economy: that it may indeed be taught, but that it cannot be a practical science. If it be assumed that those principles only are prac- tical, which may be applied immediately by every reader, in practice, this work must disclaim all pretensions to that title. I doubt very much if, in this sense, there is a single science susceptible of a practical exposition.^ Genuine practitioners^ who know life with its thousands of relations by experience, will be the first to grant that such a collection of prescriptions, when the question is the knowledge and guidance of men, would be misleading and dangerous in proportion as such prescriptions were positive and apodictic, that is non-practical and doctrinarian. Our endeavor has been, not to write a practical book, but to train our readers to be practical. To this end, we have sought to describe the laws of nature which man cannot con- trol, but, at most, only utilize. We call the attention of the reader to the different points of view, from which every eco- nomic fact must be observed, to do justice to every claim. We would like to accustom the reader, when he is examining the * I have, myself, no doubt, that up to the present time, mankind, as a whole, has, from the beginning of historical knowledge, always advanced. In indi- vidual cases, their movement has been interrupted by so many pauses, and even by so many occasional retrogressions, that great care must be taken not to infer superior excellence from mere subsequency. ' Buckle ^vTitcs of people whose knowledge is about limited to that which they see going on under their eyes, and who are called practical, only because of their ignorance; and he adds that, although they assume to despise tlieqry, they are in fact slaves of theory, of others' theories. 116 INTRODUCTION. [Ch. III. most insignificant politico-economical fact, never to lose sight of the whole, not only of public economy but of national life. We are very strongly of the opinion, that only he can form a a correct judgment and defend his views against all objections, on such questions as to where, how and when certain liens and charges, monopolies, privileges, services etc., should be abolished, who fully understands why they were once imposed or introduced. Especially, do we not desire to impress a cer- tain number of rules of action on those who have confided themselves to our guidance, after having first demonstrated their excellence. Our highest ambition is to put our readers in a way to discover such rules of direction for themselves, after they have conscientiously weighed all the facts, untram- meled by any earthly authority whatever.^ ^ 2 Compare this whole chapter with RoscJicr, Leben Werk und Zeitalter des Thukydides, 1S42, pp. 25, 239-275; Roscher^ Grundries zu Vorlesungen uber die Staatswirthschaft nach geschichtlicher Methode, 1843, preface; Roschcr Geschichte der Nat. CEk. in Deutchland (1874), 882 f., 1017 seq., and D.Vier- teljahrsschrift, ff. See also J. Kautz's learned and accurate Theorie und Ge- schichte der N. CEkonomik, vol. I, 1858, II, 1S60. I find no real contradic- tion between the views here expressed and those of Kautz, when he (I, pp. 313 ff.) introduces history and ethico-practical reason with their ideals as sources of Political Economy, to the end that the science may be something more than simply a picture, namely, a model of economic life. Apart from the fact that it is only the ethico-practical i-eason that can understand history at all, the ideals of a period constitute one of the most important elements of its history. The aspirations of an age find in them their best expression. The historical political, economist as such, is certainly not disinclined to form plans of reform, nor can it be said that he is not adapted to the per- formance of such a task. Only, he will scarcely recommend his reforms as absolutely better than what they are intended to supplant. He will confine himself to showing that there is a want which may, probably, be best satisfied by what he proposes. See Sartorius, Einladungsbliitter zu Vorlesungen iiber die Politik, 1793. 3 " There is a book which youth may use to grow old, and the old to remain young — History." {K. S. Zaccharia). BOOK I. THE PEODTJCTION OF GOODS. CHAPTER I. FACTORS OF PRODUCTION. SECTION XXX. MEANING OF PRODUCTION. To create new matter is more than it is given to man to do. Hence, by the term production, in its widest sense, we mean simply the bringing forth of new goods — the discovery of new utilities, the change or transformation of already existing goods into new utilities,^ the creation of means for the satis- faction of human wants, out of the aggregate of matter origin- ally present in the world. {Prodiicercf) We confine ourselves, however, in this to economic goods, as defined in § 2. In a secondary and more limited sense, production is an increase of resources, in so far as the goods produced satisfy a greater human want, than those employed in the production ^ it- self.^ 3* ' Especially when natural science begins to be " a practical science." {L. Stein). 2 The difference between the broader and narrower sense of production, corresponds essentially with that of gross and net income (§ 145). Compare also §§ 206, 2 1 1 ff. ^Von Mangoldt distinguishes the coming into existence of free values of the production vindertaken for an economic purpose. (Grundriss, 9.) ■* Gioja, Nuovo Prospetto dellc Scienze economiche (1S15), I, 49 ft". Besides positive production, there is a latent production, which prevents the decay of goods. It is not possible to make as exact an estimate of the latter as of the former; and much more depends in the latter case than in the former? on continuity and proper extension. Hence, latent production is especially a stiite concern. (Kfiics, Telegraph als Verkehrsmittel, 1857, 232.) 120 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. I It would, however, be an error to suppose, that the crea- tion of certain utilities for the producer himself, or for oth- ers, constitutes the only end of economic production. The more perfect economic production becomes, the greater grows the pleasure the producer feels in his products, which pleasure is at once the effect and the cause of his success. Hence, production is to a great extent its own end. That this is so in the case of artists is well known. " If you want only progeny from her, a mortal can beget them as w^ell. Let him who rejoices in the goddess, not seek in her the woman," says Schiller. There is not a really clever workman but has something artistic in his mode of production. And even the meanest productive activity, provided it is neither over-driven nor misdirected, must of itself exert a good influence on the physical and moral development or preservation of the pro- ducer. An idle brain is the devil's workshop.^ SECTION XXXI. THE FACTORS OF PRODUCTION.— EXTERNAL NATURE.> The division of natural forces which formerly obtained, into organic, chemical and mechanical, is of no great importance in Political Economy. The tendency is more and more to re- solve organic forces partly into chemical and partly into me- chanical. Between mechanical and chemical forces, again, the boundary is not fixed, heat being always capable of producing motion, and motion always of producing heat. Hence, it is all the more important for us to find a division of the economic gifts (matter, forces^ and relations) of external nature, into such 8 See Schdffie, in the Tiibinger Univ. Programm, September 27, 1862, on the disastrous effect on the community of idleness. The leading of a happy life the Greeks called very appropriately, euTTpdzTeiV. {Garvc). ' We use the expression " external nature " through the whole of this work in contradistinction not only to the soul, but also to man's body, designating his entire physico-intellectual activity by the term " labor-force " (Arbeits- kraft). * By the expression " natural forces," we designate the economically useful Sec. XXXII.] EXTERNAL NATURE. 121 as are capable of acquiring exchange value, and such as are not. (See §5.) A. Those gifts of nature which, because they cannot be appropriated by any one, or which at least are inexhaustible as compared with the wants of man, and therefore never have a direct value in exchange, belong either to the class oi free goods, in the fullest sense of the word, as, for instance, sunlight and the atmosphere {supra, § 5);^ or they constitute, by rea- son of their peculiar and intransmissible connection with the whole country, an essential element of the national resources. SECTION XXXII. EXTERNAL NATURE. — THE SEA. — CLIMATE. To the last category belongs, for instance, the sea, the only natural boundary of a country, which from a military point of view, constitutes a protection to it, without, at the same time, disturbing peaceful traffic. {Riedel.) Here, also be- long ocean currents, especially when uniformly supported by regular winds,^ the ebb and flow of the tides, which consti- changes of matter, changes of place as well as of composition, which are made without man's cooperation ; for instance, the gigantic machinery which supplies the greater part of mankind with water to drink, for domestic and other purposes — the evaporation of the sea, the formation of clouds, rain, springs, rivers etc. See Basitat, Harmonies, 277. Thus the sun's rays are indirectly the cause, not only of vegetation, but also of all wind and steam forces. * Spite of this " freedom," it may well happen that these gifts of nature can be utilized, in many cases, only on condition of some expenditure. The pho- tographer can compel the sunlight to work for him only by means of a camera obscvira, and the smithy the atmosphere, only by means of a bellows. But neither will ever successfully make an item, in their accounts with their cus- tomers, of the services of the sun or air. 'The most important ocean currents may be explained by two causes: the flowing of the water from the polar seas to the equator (polar current), and the revolution of the earth about its axis (equinoctial current); besides •which, there are the reflex currents produced by the horizontal form of the 122 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Cii. I. tute a piece of commercial machinery of the very greatest importance, particularly when they affect the waters of rivers to a great distance.^ In this age, when the love of travel is so great and so universal, what prices are paid in many places by strangers for the beauty of a landscape, to its owner. Special mention should be here made of climate, and of its heat or moisture. The lines called isothermal, that is, lines of equal annual heat, are, therefore, of greatest importance to public economy, because the " zones of production" depend mainly on them.^ However, we are concerned here, not only coast-lands. Thanks to these natural ocean highways, England is nearer to almost all the important mercantile coasts of the world by 300 geographical miles than the Eastern States of the American Union. The only exception is the Atlantic coast of America north of the Equator. North Americans to pass the line, or to double one of the two great capes, are obliged first to traverse the ocean as far as the Azores. On the other hand, the western coast of South America is very widely separated from Mexico, for instance, by its ocean currents. The colonization of America by Europe, instead of by China, is a consequence of the direction of ocean cun-ents, as is also the fact that America has now the fairest prospect of influencing the civilization of China and Japan. What an influence the warm gulf stream has on the mild climate of north-western Europe ! 2 While the Mississippi has no ebb or flow whatever, the influence of the ocean is felt in the Hudson, which is 60 geographical miles long, a distance of 29 miles from its mouth. 2 Thus, A. 2'oung, Travels in France I, 293 if., has defined, with approxi- mate accuracy, the limits within which the vine, maize and the olive grow. And so von Cancrin, Dorpater Jahrbuch IV, i, distinguishes the ice zone, the reindeer-moss (a lichen on which the reindeer live in winter) zone, the forest zone, the zone within the limits of which cattle are raised; that in which the culture of rye begins, that in which it becomes permanent; the wheat, fruit- tree, vine, maize, olive, sugar cane and silk-worm zones. The United States arc divided into cattle-raising, wheat-raising, cotton-raising, rice-raising and sugar-raising zones. Even in Europe, beyond the 60th parallel of north lati- tude, wheat can scarcely be cultivated; the polar limits of rye raising extend, at most, six or seven degrees farther. Towards the north, barley extends sometimes as far as the 70th degree. Here agriculture almost ceases, and the inhabitants are compelled to confine themselves to animal substances for food. On the other hand, these three cereals are not adapted to a tropical climate, while the bread-fruit tree, for instance, does not thrive at more than Sec. XXXII.] EXTERNAL NATURE. 123 with the average temperature of the whole year, but espe- cially with the distribution of heat among the several parts of the day and the different seasons of the year, and the maxi- mum summer heat and winter cold (the isothermal and iso- cheimenal lines). Coast lands are wont to have a milder winter and a cooler summer than continental ones with an equal av- erage yearly heat. This produces a great difference in vege- tation, because there are a great many plants which can endure the winter's cold very well, but require a hot summer; and vice versa.^ Were it not for this fact, in connection with the winter-sleep of plants, a large portion of the north would be entirely uninhabitable. Besides, the temperature of a place does not depend exclusively on its latitude, or on its height 22 degrees from the Equator, nor the banana at more than 35. Compare Griscbach, Die Vegetation der Erde nach ilirer kUmatischen Anordnung. II, 1871. ^ Thus rje and Avheat thrive in many parts of Siberia (lakutzk) at an an- nual temperature of — 7-50, "vvhile in Iceland no cereals ripen at an annual temperature of +4°. But in the former place the summer heat is + 16.2° ; the •winter cold, —39.2°; in Iceland, +12° and —1.6°. In England, the myrtle, laurel, camelia and fuchsia stand the winter well ; while the vine no where ripens. On the other hand, Astrakan and Hungary are vine growing countries, although the former is as cold in winter as North Cape, and although the cold is more intense in Hungary than in the Faroe Islands, where neither the oak nor the beech grow any longer. No good wine is produced on the western coast of France, north of 47° 20' north latitude; in Champagne, north of 49°, or in the Rheingau, north of 51°. In Norway, the average heat is greater on the coast than in the heart of the country where, however, grain ripens, while it does not on the coast; for the mildness of the winter, no matter how great, can make no compensation for the want of heat. On the other hand, the cattle on the coast can remain inuch longer out of doors, and the sea seldom freezes in such a way as to interfere with the fisheries. Blom, Norwegen I, 39. Boiissingtiault (Economie rurale consideree dans ses Rapports avec la Chimie, II) has made some interesting attempts to calculate by a mathematical process the amount of heat necessary to vegetable, during the period of vegetation. Thus, for instance, Avheat requires about 12° (Reaumur) of heat during 140 days; that is, nearly 140 x i2°=i6So° Reaumur. In Venezuela, the sugar cane requires a longer time to gi-ow in a higher and therefore cooler position than in a lower and warmer, and the length of time required is in proportion to the height. 124 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. L above the sea-level.^ The humidity of the climate is, as a rule, great in proportion to the quantity of water in its neighbor- hood, and to the height of its temperature; although, for in- stance, in Europe, the number of rainy days increases, the further we advance towards the north.^ Although the dis- tance of a place from the equator and its height above the level of the sea have, in many respects, a similar effect (verti- cal, horizontal isothermal lines and zones of production), moun- tainous regions are uniformly distinguished by a greater degree of humidity, which makes them better adapted for pasturage and forest-culture. But the flora of a locality, be- ing the resultant of all its conditions, affords us a much better criterion of the value of the climate for economic purposes, than the most accurate thermometric observations. Other things being equal, the productive force of nature operates, doubtless, with most energy, in warm climates. The more remote a country is from the equator, the more is its fertility confined to its lowest parts.'' Greater heat will, as a rule, ripen the same product sooner, and thus permit the same land to be used several times in the same year.^ Each individual ^ Hence it is that the isothermal lines are not parallel with the equator or with one another. The greater number of these have two northern and two southern summits; the former on the western coasts of Europe and America, and the letter in eastern North America, and in the interior of Asia. ^The quantity of rain which falls every jear is, at St. Petersburg and Pesth, from i6 to 17 inches; at Berlin 19, Mannheim 21, Tubingen 26: in the interior of France 16-24; on the French coast 25, on the eastern coast of England 24, on the western coast 35, in Milan 36, Genoa 44, on the coast of most tropical lands 70-120. On the political-economical influences of most climates, see Gobbt, Ueber die Abhangikeit der Populationskrafte von den einfachen Grundfstoffen, 1842. ' The snow limit at Mageroe in Norway is 2,200, in Iceland 2,900, in the northern Ural 4,500, in the Alps 8,200, in the Caucasus 10,400, and Quito 14,850 feet high. Hence it is that mountainous countries which produce nothing in the north, make magnificent vineyards in warmer countries. *In central Germany, even a second crop can be produced after the com harvest. In Arabia, the same seed produces three harvests, because the grain which falls at the time of harvesting to the ground, germinates immediately and suffices for new seed. [Niebuhr, Beschreibung, 154.) Sec. XXXIL] EXTERNAL NATURE. 125 harvest, as a rule, is more abundant,'^ and the products better in many respects. The fruit, for instance, and wine, contain more sugar,^° and oleaginous plants contain more oil. Lastly, since nature in warm countries is so much more generous, it may be utilized by man with less regard for consequences. There is less need of extensive woods, of large winter sup- plies, especially for animals ;^^ fewer buildings are demanded, and there is also less demand for human and brute labor, since the work of plowing, sowing etc., extends over a greater por- tion of the year.^^ It is true, on the other hand, that also the 9 Thus in the northern states of the American union, -wheat yields a return of only from four to five times the amount sown ; in France, 5-6 times (La- voisier): in Chili, 12 times; in northern Mexico, 17 times; in Peru, iS and 20 times; in southern Mexico, 25 and even 35 times; in Germany, maize seed yields at best one hundred fold, while in the torrid zone there is a return of from three hundred to four hundred fold, generally. 1" Andalusian corn produces in the mill only one-half as much bran-waste as Baltic wheat produces. Bourgoing^H^^A&7)^x de I'Espagne, II, 155. Bal- tic wheat contains 6-7 per cent, of azote, and Algerian, 20-25 per cent. (KabscJi, Pflanzenleben der Erde, 1S65.) " In Europe the blossoming season is retarded four days for each degree of northern latitude. (SchUbler.) As we advance towards the north, the dif- ference becomes less noticeable, but more so as we go towards the south. In mountainous countries a similar difference is observable, produced by a like climatic influence. It is from about 10 to 12 days, for a heighth of from 500 to 600 feet. ( Wolff, Naturgesetzliche Grundlagen des Ackerbaues I, p. 332 ft") In the cantons, in which the Swiss confederation had its origin, the pasturage of the Alps lasts generally thirteen weeks, but in the higher Alps it lasts only from six to seven weeks. (Dusingcr, C. Unterwalden, p. 52.) '■' In central Italy, winter wheat may be sown in October, November or De- cember ; summer Avheat, in February or March. (Sismondi, Tableau de I'Ag- riculture Toscane, p. 35.) In Judiea, it was possible to harvest figs ten months in the year. (Josefh, Bell. Jud., Ill, p. 10.) On the other hand, there is Jemtland, where the peasant in many places surrounds the northern portion of his cornfield with lagots, and lights them in August when the north wind blows, to protect his land from the fi'ost; and where the expression "green years" is used to designate those in which the harvest has to be reaped before it is ripe. {Forsell, Stntistik you Schwedcn, 24.) In the valu- ation made of the lands of the kingdom of Saxony, for assessment purposes, the cost of supporting a yoke of oxen in the lowest country is estimated at only three-fourths of what it is iu tlic highest localities, because in the for- mer, 200 work days can be calculated upon in the year, in the latter only 159. 126 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Cii. I. destructive force of nature is greater in warmer than in colder countries. (§ 209.)^^ SECTION XXXIII. EXTERNAL NATURE. — GIFTS OF NATURE WITH VALUE IN EXCHANGE. B. Those gifts of external nature which may become ob- jects of private property, and at the same time possess suffi- cient relative scarcity to give them value in exchange, are either movable, and exhaustible in a given place, or firmly connected with the land. The first category embraces, for instance, such wild animals and plants as serve some useful purpose, minerals, above all, fossil combustible matter^ — the In central Russia, the greater part of the labor of agriculture, sowing and harvesting, has to be finished within the space of four months. In central Germany, they are spread over seven months. Other things being equal, seven horses and ploughmen are needed in Russia where only four are called for in central Germany, {von Haxthausen^ Studien I, 174.) On the impedi- ments put in the way of agriculture by the climate of eastern Prussia, see Meit- zen, Boden und landwirthsch. Verbal tnisse des preussichen Staats, 1868, I, Abschn., 6. '3 " In both hemispheres, the zone in which the temperature decreases most rapidly lies between the 40th and 50th degrees of north latitude. This cir- cumstance must have a happy influence on the culture and industry of the nation inhabiting the neighborhood of that zone. Here is rhe point where the regions of the vine touch upon those of the olive. Nowhere in the world, do the products of the vegetable kingdom, and the most varied won- ders of agriculture, follow with such rapidity on one another. The great va- riety of products enlivens the commerce and increases the industrial activity of agricultural nations." {Htunboldt!) It is true, however, that tropical countries possess, also, in their mountainous parts, the tierra fria, tonplada and caliente, superimposed the one on the other. 'The aggregate coal supply of Great Britain (1869) was 2,180 millions cwt.; of Belgium (1862), 207 miUions; of France (1868) 256 millions; of Prussia (1870), 600 millions, of Austria (1870), including brown lignite coal, 158 mil- lions ; of Russia (1868), only a little over 9 millions. The great English coal field, in the counties of Durham and Northumberland, embraces 732 English square miles; that of South Wales, 1,200, with a depth of 95 feet, so that the geographical square mile contains here 679 millions of tons, each of twenty Sec. XXXIIL] EXTERNAL NATURE. 127 "black diamonds," coal, of which, with its canals, Franklin said that it had made England what it is. The economical effect of their moveable character is best seen, when the use made of an ordinary stratum of coal is compared with that of a protracted subterranean fire in a coal mine.- The latter can be directly useful only to those in its immediate vicinity. Every lower layer of the burning coal would be less useful. An increase of its actual power by accumulation in time or place is scarcely possible. In all these respects, the movable coal is incomparably better adapted to the satisfaction of man's WMnts. It may be said that the capacity of heat for drying, distilling, melting and hardening purposes, of imparting rapid motion to heavy objects by the production of confined steam, is, at least, a thousand times as great when a thousand bushels of coal are consumed as when one is consumed. In most cases even the concentration of a large quantity of coal will increase, the result not only absolutely, but relatively. ^ ■* cwt. To obtain the same quantity of combustible material as was furnished to Prussia, in 1865, by its coal, it would be necessary to use up 6,331 square miles of forest. (vo7i Dechen, in EngeVs Zeitschrift, 1867, 25S.) The supply of coal is, of course, exhaustible while, for instance, turf-fields replace them- selves by slow degrees. Compare Gnesbacfi, iiber die Bildung des Torfs, in the Gottinger Studien, 1S45, vol. I. The importance of the coal-fields of the United States, which are twenty-two times as large as those of Great Britain, in the distant future, cannot be over-estimated. ^ I need only call attention to the earth-fire (Erdbrand) for the purpose of forcing the growth of garden plants in the neighborhood of Zwickau, which is said to have existed since 1505. 3 Thus, in Watt's steam engines of the larger kind, an hourly consumption of ten pounds of coal is needed to produce a force equivalent to that of one horse, while in the smallest machines of only one horse power, twenty-two pounds are needed. See Prccktl, Technolo. Encyklopadie, III, 669. •* It is easy to see that it is the most important substances needed in indus- try which are mentioned in this section. Many political economists have considered the principal difference between agriculture and the industries and economies of towns to lie in the contrast here referred to. Thus, A. Serra, Sulle Cause che possono far abbondare li Regni d'oro c d'argento, dove non sono miniere, 1613, I, 3. See the description of the diflerence be- tween land and machines in Malthus, Principles, III, 5; Senior, Outlines, 86. But it is nothing more than a difference of gradation. Even in the most 128 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. I SECTION XXXIV. EXTERNAL NATURE. (CONTINnKD.) The materials, forces and relations or conditions of external nature, immovably connected with parts of the land, even when in themselves exhaustless, either allow only of a definite amount of economic utilization, as, for instance, the mechanical force of a given waterfall, which can drive only a definite num- ber of miUs of a definite size ; ^ or their increased utilization is accompanied by difficulties which increase with stiU greater rapidity. This last is the case, especially in the employment of land for agricultural purposes. It is, according to Senior, one of the four fundamental axioms of Political Economy, that additional labor, spent on a given quantity of land, produces, as a rule, a relatively smaller yield ; assuming, of course, that the art of agriculture remains the same.^ It is not possible to active of businesses there is a limit which the accumulation of means of production cannot pass without a relative diminution of the income. This boundary is imposed by the limited nature of those organic beings which must contribute to production either actively or passively. Thus, for in- stance, a manufacturing establishment or commercial business can be en- larged with advantage only so long as it is still possible for one superintend- ent to conduct it. And so, when cattle are furnished with very abundant and substantial food, a pound of meat costs the producer a much higher price than when they are more moderately supplied : sometimes in the ratio of 1.95:0.98. Bousstiigaiilt, Economic rurale, II. Where there is absolute over-feeding, the producer must suffer loss. But, even inorganic nature im- poses its own limits here ; as, for instance, when ships, machines etc., on ac- count of the insufficient sfa-ength of the materials of which they are made, cannot be constructed beyond a certain size. But all these limits are much narrower than those imposed by the quality of immovability. ' Senior, Outlines, 26, 81 ff. See Ste-wart, Principles, II, ch. 11 ; Orles, E. N., I, 18, II, 18 ft'. This most important principle in Political Economy is thus illustrated by yohn Stuart Mill, Principles, book I, ch. 12. "The limi- tation to production from the properties of the soil is not like the obstacle opposed by a wall, which stands immovable in one particular spot, and offers no hindrance to motion short of stopping it entirely. We may rather com- pare it to a highly elastic and extendible band, which is hardly ever so vio- Sec. XXXIV.] EXTERNAL NxVTURE. 129 determine either generally, or in particular cases, the precise point at which agriculture should stop, to prevent relatively smaller returns from increased expenditure of labor and capi- tal. Improvements in the art of agriculture may remove it a great distance. But, that there is such a point admits of no doubt. No one will believe that an acre of land can be made to produce a quantity of the means of subsistence sufficient to support all Europe, no matter what the amount of seed used, or of manure etc. employed.^ This is most apparent in forest- economy, where the absolute increase of the so-called wood- capital becomes, after a certain time, smaller from year to year.^ lentlj stretched, that it could not possibly be stretched any more, yet the pressure of which is felt long before the final limit is reached, and felt more severely the nearer that limit is approached." This is, if possible, more ob- vious in building than in agriculture, both as to the construction of new stories and the excavation of deeper cellars. ^ Ad. Mayer, Das Diingerkapital und der Raubbau (Heidelberg, 1S69), sees the only conditions of production which man cannot increase at will exclu- sively in the sun's rays, the employment of which also depends on the quan- tity of land. Thus would he explain Senior^s law. ^ See the tables of increase in Coda, Anweisung zum Waldbau, p. 22S. Count Biiquoy, Theorie der N. Wirthschaft, p. 54, ridicules the absurd pro- cedure of a great many farmers, as if by forcing the ploughshare deeper into the soil, they could compel it to produce a double return, and asks : if one should dig a square foot of land to the center of the earth and manure it, who would take it off his hands.' As to the effect of manure, KuJilmaiui's investi- gations have shown that 300 kilograhimes of guano produced in three years an increase per hectare in the yield, of 2,469 kilogrammes of hay ; while 600 kilogrammes produced an increase of only 2,870 kilogrammes. Schiiblcr, found that where salt had been used for manuring purposes, 40 kilogrammes produced a maximum of fertility from which point forward every increase in the amount of salt was attended by diminished returns, and finally led to complete barrenness. See Wolff, Naturgesetzliche Grundlagen, I, 40S, 412, 502. Constantly increased irrigation would convert the land into a swamp instead of indefinitely adding to its fertility. Nor can abundant sowing be of any use when it reaches such a point that the plants stand so closely to- gether as to interfere with their proper development. Vol. I. — 9 130 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. I. SECTION XXXV. EXTERNAL NATURE. — ELEMENTS OF AGRICULURAL PRODUCTIVENESS. In treating of the agricultural productiveness of a piece of land, it is necessary to distinguish three things, — its bearing- capacity, its capacity for cultivation, and its direct capacity to afford food to plants.^ Plants grow by drawing a part of the elements which enter into their composition from the atmos- phere, and a part from the earth through the agencies of sun- light and of water. While the air, the sun's heat, and in most parts of the world, water, are free and inexhaustible goods, the earth's supply of food for plants must be considered as an- alogous, so far as its exhaustibility and capacity to be appro- priated are concerned, to the beds of coal and of ore etc. which occur in mining districts. This is certainly true, with a few important differences, however, as for instance, that, as a rule, it is impossible, except through the cultivation of plants, to ob- tain from the earth the stores of plant food which it contains ; ^ and that it is possible to husbandry to replace the portion of these stores taken from the earth by the harvest, through the agency of manures.^ Incomparably more important in the economic valuation of a piece of land is its capacity for cultivation, because this de- ' These differences correspond with the differences in the kinds of deterio- ration to which land is liable from rivers, floods, lava, etc., soiI-exhausti:)n, and the growing wild of the land. 2 From a technic point of view, it would, perhaps, be practicable, in most instances, to obtain the phosphoric acid immediately from the land and transfer it to other land ; but the relation of the cost to the result makes it impossible from an economical point of view. 3 It most certainly is always an uncommon advantage that certain kinds of soil, rich in kali and decayed vegetable matter, yield a long series of har- vests without the addition of manure, provided, always, that a short interval is allowed to the process of decay to replace the exhausted plant-food. Thus in many volcanic regions. Compare on similar districts in the Deccan: Rittcr, Erdkunde, V, 714. Sec. XXXV.] EXTERNAL NATURE. 131 pends much less on the good or bad quality of the husband- man's art. I mean here the so-called ph3'sical constitution of of the vegetable soil; its water-holding power, its consistency (light or heavy soil) on which the difficulty of working it de- pends; its ability to dry, in a shorter or longer time, and its accompanying diminution in volume ; its ability to draw mois- ture from the atmosphere and to absorb the various kinds of gases; its heat-absorbing and heat-containing power (hot, warm and cold soils).^ Much depends here on the depth of the vegetable soil and on the constitution of the sub-soil, which, for instance, when it is very permeable, improves a very moist soil, but in the form of meadow iron-ore ( Wicsen- erz), works great injury. The vertical form of the land is also a very important element in estimating the natural fertil- ity of the soil. In mountainous districts, the quantity of land w^hich can be used (and with what labor!) is wont to be rela- tively smaller than in low lands. Hence it is, that the form- er become too small for their inhabitants; who, therefore, swarm over the plains lying before them either as settlers or conquerors.* In the eastern hemisphere, the northern slopes * According to Schiibler, the absorption of water by loo parts of earth is, in the case of quartz-sand, 25 per cent, of its weight; for clay, 70 per cent.; for calcareous earth, 85 per cent. ; humus, 190 per cent. ; and for 100 parts of their value, respectively, 37.9, 66.2, and 69.2 per cent. The consistency of the four kinds of earth, in a dry state, is in the proportion of 0.100, 5, 8.7; their adhesion in a moist state, to iron agricultural implements, is in that of 0.17, 1. 12, 0.65, 0.40. ,Of 100 parts of water mixed with these kinds of earth, the evaporation in four hours, at a temperature of iS° 75' (centigrade) is 8S.4, 31.3, 28 and 20.5 per cent, respectively. The diminution of volume when the moist earth dries, under the same degree of temperature, is, o, 18.3, 5 and 20. Their relative absorption of atmospheric moisture for 48 hours is as o, 24, 17.5 and 55; their absorption of oxygen in 30 daj-s is respectively 1.6, 15.3, lo.S and 2.03 per cent; and, lastly, their heat-holding power is in the ratio of 95.6, 66.7, 61.S, 49. 5 In Austria, below the Enns, only 3.8 per cent, of the soil is barren ; in the Tyrol, 29 per cent. ; in Dalmatia, 48.1 per cent. (Springer). In the French Pyrenees, 43 per cent, is considered incapable of cultivation ; in tiie Alps, in Landes and Morbihan, 42 per cent. ; in the departments of Nord and Sommc, 1.3 per cent. (Schnitzlcr). Franscini considers 36 per cent, of Switzerland 132 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. I. of mountain regions are most unfavorably situated, although the southern slopes are frequently subjected to more trying and more sudden variations of thawing and freezing weather.^ But all these more special qualities of the soil must be dis- tinguished from their general basis, the bearing or carrying ca- pacity which land possesses as a mere superficies, and which the most naked rock (Malta!), and the bed of a flowing stream (the floating gardens of China!) possess to some ex- tent, since there is a possibility of establishing a plant-feeding surface on them. This bearing capacity, which in most in- stances is given only by nature, and which can be added to only to a very limited extent and at great outlay, is wont, when the population is very dense, to acquire considerable ex- change value in the vicinity.''^ unfit for tillage. The idea "barren" is a very vague one, and hence a com- parison of different countries on this point should not be made without great caution. * Wolff', loc. cit, 353 ff. As to the manner in vrhich soil and climate mutually improve or injure one another, see Schiverz, Prackt. Ackerbau I, 12. "^ In this respect, also, the fundamental difference between agriculture and industry is very important, inasmuch as the products of the former, equal in value to those of the latter, require a very large supporting or bearing sur- face ; those of industry, a very small one. If JVobbe's " water-cultivation " should ever come to assume any great practical importance, agriculture would approach to industry in this respect. 8 Wolkoff has called special attention to mere emplacejncnt : Lectures d'Economie politique rationelle (1861), pp. 90 seq., 157 seq. Bastiafs rather broad and enthusiastic assertion, that no mere product of nature possesses value (in contradistinction to utility), an exaggeration of his very honorable contest with the socialists (1848!), is refuted by daily experience, as when, for instance, discoveries are made accidentally of metallic veins, coal-fields etc., which immediately acquire great exchange value. Sec. XXXVI .1 EXTERNAL NATURE. 133 SECTION XXXVI. EXTERNAL NATURE.— FURTHER DIVISIONS OF NATURE'S GIFTS. The gifts of nature, we further divide into those which can be directly enjoyed and those which are of use only indirectly, by facilitating production. (Natural means of enjoyment, — means of acquisition.)^ An extreme superfluity of the former is as disastrous to civilization as a too great scarcity of them. How simple the economy of a tropical country! A banana field will support twenty-five times as many men as a wheat field (/r. Ritter)\ and with infinitely less labor; for all that is needed is to cut the stems with their ripened fruit, to loosen the earth a little and very superficially, when new stems shoot up.^ At the base of the mountains of Mexico, a father needs labor only two days in the week to support his family. Hence, nothing so much excites the wonder of the traveler there as the diminutiveness of the cultivated ground surrounding each Indian hut.^ But in these earthly paradises, ' Aristotle distinguishes between dazolauaTUa and xdp7lC[ia. (Rhet., I, 5.) ' Humboldt^ Essai politique, sur la N. Espagne, IV, 9, in which he estimates ihe relation of the culture of the banana to that of wheat, in respect of mere quantity, to be as 4,000 to 30, — " probably the best gift of nature to awaken- ing man, and the object of the most ancient cultivation." ^ It was said that in Easter Island, three days' labor sufficed for a man's maintenance through the whole year. A similar gift of nature to tropical lands is the date tree. It is turned to so many different uses that the Arabs of the coast of the Persian Gulf say that it is possible to construct a ship, rig it, supply and freight it, from date trees. Houses are built of palm wood, covered with palm leaves, furnished with palm mats, lighted with palm chips, and heated with palm coals. The whole architecture of these countries is fash- ioned by the date tree. Date wine is the favorite intoxicating beverage. There is a proverb current there that a good housewife can vary the preparation of the date for her guests every day in the month. Even the pulp is eaten. Each tree yields an average of 50-250 lbs. of dates; and a tree may last over 200 years. An acre may contain more than 200 trees. The labor of cultiva- tion is very slight, although it demands more care than the banana. Com- pare Ritter., Brdkunde, XII, 763. An acre planted with the sago-palm yields 134 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. I. where, as Byron said, even bread is gathered like fruit, the powers of man slumber as certainly as they grow torpid in polar deserts.* The sentence : " In the sweat of thy brow shalt thou eat bread," has been a blessing to mankind. Athens was not only the literary and political, but also the economic capi- tal of Greece ; and yet Attica was one of the most sterile coun- tries in the world.^ Unfortunate Messina, on the other hand, was the most fertile province of Greece. In modern times, no countries of equal extent have produced as many great captains, statesmen, savants and artists as Holland, whose securest por- tions are as unfertile as those which are fertile are threatened by the sea. On the other hand, how lately and imperfectly has the so-called black-earth of southern Russia fallen under the influence of civilization ! ^ as much nourishment as 163 acres of wheat land. (Reise der Frigatte No- vara, II, 113. *See D. Hume, Discourses No. I (On Commerce), While in hot coun- tries " the sun does more work for man, it diminishes human strength itself." (M. Wirth.) That, however, such people, to their surplus of the natural means of enjoyment and the consequent laziness and absence of care, add the bright side of a joyous disposition, is well shown by Goethe, Werke (16 mo., 1840), XXIII, 246. 5 Noticed even by Thucyd., I, 2. See also Euripides' comparison of Sparta and Messina, in Strabo, VIII, 366. •^ We find, in a great many countries, that their northern portions are en- dowed more sparingly by nature with means of enjoyment (Genusstnittcln) than southern portions, but more abundantly with means of acquisition. (Er- iverbsmittcln.) Hence, the former are latest to develop ; but once developed, they assume a much higher place in civilization than the latter. This is true of Italy, Spain, Portugal, France, the Netherlands, and the United States, and of North America in general, as compared with South America. Some- thing similar may be seen in the contrast between Austria and Prussia. The latter is colder and less fertile, but far superior to the former in extent of coast, in rivers, and fossilized combustible matter. Sec. XXXVII.] EXTERNAL NATURE. 135 SECTION XXXVII. • EXTERNAL NATURE. — THE GEOGRAPHICAL CHARACTER OF A COUNTRY. The geographical character of a country is, as a rule,^ most intimately connected, not only with its flora and fauna, but also with the character of its people. One of the crowning glories of the progress of modern science is, that it has recognized anew the power of this wonderful organism, and that it has made geography an explanatory medium between nature and history. The conditions most favorable to the development of civilization are found in a well developed country which slopes gradually through a series of intermediate terraces from a mountain summit to a plain; especially when they are con- nected with one another by a good system of streams ; since here the opposite peculiarities of the populations of the high- lands and coast-lands ^ tend to produce a nationality both one and varied. Where the transitions are too abrupt, as for in- stance, in New Holland, they easily impede inter-communica- tion ; and, still more, where the several parts of the country are of very great extent; as, for example, the desert of North Africa, the plateau of South Africa or that of Central Asia. Europe is favored above all other parts of the world by the happy combination of mountain and plain.^ "We might pur- sue the parallel existing between the soil and the character of a people into the minutest details, and discover, even in the * The rule is not without its exceptions. Thus, for instance, Borneo and New Guinea are physically very like each other, but zoologically two dif- ferent worlds ; the former belonging to India and the latter to Australia. * Even language, which is the most general and most accurate expression of the intellectual genius of a people, presents a strikingly analogous con- trast in mountainous and coast countries. Thus, compare the Ionic, Latin, Low German, Danish and Portuguese, with the Doric, Oscan, High Ger- man, Swedish and Spanish. ^ See Strabo^ II, 136. seq. 136 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Cn. I. difference between Spanish, French, German and Hungarian wines, a reflection of the different characters of the people.* But whence is this? Can it be that dead nature has thus irresistibly affected the living mind? We do not need to give a materialistic answer to the question.^ Almost every people has migrated at some period of its existence. Urged on by their peculiar tastes and tendencies, they settled in the places most in harmony with their character. A higher hand was over them; one which, we should unreservedly trust, placed them in such external circumstances as were most favorable to the development of all their faculties. But the influences of man on nature are no less notable than those of nature upon man. The greater number of domestic animals and plants which Europe posesses to-day, it has been obliged to introduce from other parts of the globe.^ In the interior of Gaul, the vine rarely ripened, at the time of Christ.' On the other hand, Mesopotamia, formerly one of the gardens * The most striking instance, illustrative of the manner in which the na- ture of a country influences the character of a people is afibrded by the dif- ference in the development of the Aryans in India and Persia, especially when their sojourn in the territory of the Indus before that near the Ganges is looked upon as an intermediate stage. * French writers, especially, have exaggerated the influence of nature over man. Thus, Bodin, de Repub. (1584), V, i; Alonicsquicu, Esprit des Lois, XVII, 6. XVIII, 1,18. Cadatiis, Rapport du Physique et du Moral de I'Homme (1805), IX, Memoire, Influence des Climats. Comie, also, Traitede Legislation (1827), is of opinion that " the degree of civilization which a peo- ple may attain does not depend on the degree of development of which they are capable by nature, but on that which their geographical situation permits them to attain." See, aho, Herodot., Ill, 106; Hippocr., De -^re etc., 71; Euripid., Medea, 820 fF. ; Plutarch, DeExilio, 13. The proper mean has been found by E. M. Arndt, in his Anleitung zu historischen Characterschilder- ungen (1810), and by Ritter^ and his school. See, also, K. S. Zacharice, Idee einer volkswirthschaftlichen Geographic als Grundlage der praktischen N. CEkonomie fur jedes einzelne Volk: Vierzig Biicher v. Staate, II, 79. See, also, Turgot, Geographic politique, 1750, CEuvres (ed. Daire, II, 611 fl'.); Lucder, Nationalindustrie und Staatswirthschaft, III, 1800 fF. * Maltc Brun, Precis, de la Geographic universelle, VI. pr. "^ Strabo, IV, 178. On the climate of ancient Germany, see Tacit.^ Germ, 2. Sec. XXXVIII.] LABOR. 137 of the world, is now covered with dried-up canals, filled a little below the surface with heaps of brick and broken vases, the remains and other vestiges of a once dense population. Its former rich alluvial soil, now almost calcined, produces at present scarcely anything except a few saline plants, mi- mosas etc.^ The higher the civilization of a people, the less does it depend on the nature of the country. SECTION XXXVIII. OF LABOR. — DIVISIONS OF LABOR. Man's capacity for most economic labor is so closely con- nected with the exquisite articulation of the human hand, that BulTon could say without exaggeration that reason and the hand made man man.^ But it is true of economic labor, as of all other labor, that it is more efficient in proportion as mind predominates over matter. The best division of economic labor is the following:^ A. Discoveries and inventions.* B. Occupation of the spontaneous gifts of nature, as, for in- ^ Praser, Travels in Koordistan and Mesopotamia, II, 5. See, also, the description of ancient Susiana in Strabo XV, 731, with that of the new one by AfKinncir, Geogr. Memoir of Persia, 92. ' Labor is not to be confounded with activity, which is always present even in enjoyment. " Thus, Galenus, De Usu Partium Corporis humani, L. I. The animal nearest to man mentally, the elephant, is also possessed of a member more like the human hand than any other animal. Its trunk was called manus by the Romans. Hence the Indians call the elephant, the animal gifted with a hand. Bttffon^s view is exaggerated by Helvetius in the interests of mate- rialism. Aristotle^ (De partt. anim. IV, 10), opposes the saying of Anaxagoras : OM TO yziqa^ h^ziv ipooviixcbraTOV zlvru zcou ^cocou dud^ocoKOv. Compare Bell, On the human Hand, 1836. 2 As to the imperfection of the ordinary division into agricultural, indus- trial and commercial labor, see yo/in Siuc.ri Mill, I, ch. 2,9. The division of all labor into mental and physical, is not more satisfactory ; for even the basest labor is not wholly physical. See Buckle, History of Civilization, vol II. * Dioscorides and Galen were acquainted with, at most, 600 plants ; Limtceus, 138 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. I. Stance, of wild plants, wild animals, and of minerals.^ Where this is the only kind of economic labor, man is necessarity de- pendent on nature in a high degree. C. The production of raw materials; that is, a direction given to nature in order to the production of raw materials, by stock-raising, agriculture, forest-culture etc., but not by mining. D. The transformation ( Verarbeitung) of raw material by means of manufactories, factories, the trades etc. E. The distribution of stores of goods among those who are to use them directl}^, whether from people to people or from place to place (wholesale), or among the individuals of the same place (retail).® To this class also belong leasing, renting, loaning, etc. F. Services, in the more limited sense of the term, which embraces personal as well as incorporeal goods ; as, for in- stance, the labors of the doctor, teacher; virtuoso, of the states- man, judge, and of preachers, whose office it is, by way of eminence, to produce and preserve the immaterial wealth, known as the State and the Church. The order followed in the above classification is that in which the different classes of labor are wont to be historically developed. with 8,000. About iSi2^ about 30,000 had been described; in 1S37, about 60,000; in 1849, about 100,000. BucMc, History of Civilization etc., II, p. 359. ^Industrie extractives, according to Dunoyer. When nature's spontaneous g ifts are exhausted, this occupation readily becomes production. * Industrie voituridre, according to Dunoyer; industria traslocatrice in oppo- sition to trasforniatrice, according to Scialoja. Ortes distinguishes only lour classes: agricoltori, artejici, dispensntori and administratori, or raccoglitori, manifattori, and difensori di bene (E. N. I, 2; III, 14). A. Walker, Science of Wealth (1S67), p. 34, knows only three classes: transmutation, transforma- tion, transportation. ' This is not to be understood in the sense, that there ever was a period in ■which these sciences were unknown. We need only mention the position occupied by the priest and knight in the middle ages. But, looked upon as economic labor, intended only for purposes of free commere, they have become Sec. XXXIX.] LABOR. 139 SECTION XXXIX. LABOR. — TASTE FOR LABOR. — PIECE-WAGES. Man's taste for labor is conditioned especially by the extent to which, and the security with which, he may hope to enjoy the fruit of his labor himself. Hence it is that, as a rule, the slave (§71, if.) and socager work least willingly, the day la- borer with less industry than the piece-worker,^ who is at the same time more satisfied with himself, and gives most satis- faction to his master,^ since he acquires more both for himself and for his master. The superiority of piece-paid labor is very important onlj within a relatively recent period of time. Thus, for in- stance, there was in Lower Austria, in 1866, one lawyer or notary to every 6,569 inhabitants; in Bohemia, to every 14,860; in Galicia, to every 22,361 ; in the whole of Cis-Leithanian Austria, 12,259. I^i 1865, there was in Prussia, one to every 11,149; in Bavaria, to every 7,350; in Hanover, to every 4,946; in 1862, in Baden, one to every 4,992; in 1867, in Saxony, one to every 3,048. Hildebrand' s Tagebuch, 1868, I, 234. There was in Prussia, in 1871, one doctor to every 3,230 inhabitants; in Berlin, to every 1,100; in Heldesheim, to 1,803; in Cologne, to 2,120, in Marienwerder, to 7,240; in Gumbinnen, to 10,047. Engcl^ Preuss. Statis. Zeitschrift, 1S72, 376. The verb "to plow" is, according to comparative philologists, of more recent origin than " to weave." (Lassen^ Indische Alterth. I, 814 ft") And yet agriculture, in the sense above indicated, undoubtedly precedes industry. ' Observed by Geiler v. Kaiscrsberg. Compare Schmoller in the Tiibinger Zcitschr., i860, 483. Hour wages occupy a middle place between day wages and piece wages. ' Thus the introduction of piece wages into lower Silesia has increased the daily earnings of workmen by one-third, one-half, and even more. EngcVs Stastist. Zeitschr. (1868), p. 327. The investigations of the German agricul- tural congress on the condition of agricultural laborers in the German em- pire (report of v. d. Goltz, 1S75) show that in all Gerrnany on an average, the daily earnings of a contract workman {Accordlohner) is to the daily sum- mer wages of a day laborer as 15: 10 (1420). On the other hand, Brassey, in the construction of a railway, found that the same workmen engaged in grad- ing, digging, etc., cost 18 pence per yard when paid by the day, and 7 pence when paid by the piece. (Work and Wages, 266.) Swiss experience is, that production became 20 per cent, cheaper under the piece wages system. (Bdhmert, Beitr., 109.) 140 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. I. greater in proportion as the workman calculates his own ad- vantage. It is, therefore, smallest in the case of ingenuous un- educated workmen, and in that of the really conscientious.^ The fear of seeing one's condition grow worse, through want of industry, exerts an influence precisely similar to the hope of improving it. In both respects, free competition (§97) must be considered one of the principal means of furthering the taste for labor.* Among the causes which have contributed to make Eng- land the first country in the world, viewed from a politico- economical stand-point, English writers on Political Economy have pointed out as one of the principal, the prevalence there of piece-wages.^ Payment by the piece should, of course, be 2 According to v. d. Goltz's EnquSte, the earnings of workmen by the piece, compared with the wages paid workmen by the day in summer, is especially high in middle Franconia (16.5:10); in the Leipzig circle of the German empire (16.6), in the Braunschweig plain (16.8), within the jurisdiction of Hildesheim (18.1), of the Bavarian Palatinate (18.6), in Rhenish Hesse (23.2), especially low in Stettin (13.2:10), in Stralsund (12.4), in Schleswig Holstein (12), in Osnabriick, (11.7.) ■* According to v. Flotovj^ Anleitung zur Fertigung der Ertragsanschlage, I, 80, four days of serf labor are equivalent to only three of a free day laborer. According to v. Jacob, Ueber die Arbeit Leibeigener und freier Bauern (1815), 21, two day laborers are equal to three serfs, and one farm horse is equal to two employed by serfs. It is as impossible to obtain accurate general esti- mates here, as in the case of slave labor. As a rule, hope is not only a more humane but a sharper spur to action. But if force is employed at all, there is no doubt that the greater it is, the more effectual it is. Wherever the right of corporal punishment has been taken from the masters, the technic value of serfdom has uniformly decreased. In the English West Indies, formerly, philanthropic masters who treated their negroes with unwonted gentleness, obtained from them, as a rule, very poor economic results. While each of the slaves expressed the greatest indignation at the idleness of the others when they had " so good a master," they were all equally and excessively lazy. The weekly production of a plantation sank rapidly under this system from thirty-three hogsheads to twenty-three, and finally to thirteen. Math. Levis, Journal of a West India Proprietor, 1834; Edinburg Review, XLV, 410. For the same reason, the negroes in the Spanish colonies, who were treated much more gently than those owned by other European nationalities produced much worse work. See, however. Columella, De Re rust., I, S. 5 According to Hovjlctt, The Insufficiency of the Causes to which the In- Sec. XXXIX.] LABOR. 14-1 practiced, only in cases in which the work may be broken up into a series of isolated tasks, and is completed by such a se- ries. Hence, it is not applicable where a great many differ- ent things are required of the same workman; nor in rela- tions in which continuity, as, for instance, of the inclination or disposition of the workman is the chief thing.^ The fur- ther the division of labor is carried in our day, the greater the part money plays in our social economy, and the more lasting relations are dissolved, the more general becomes piece- work, which, with all its material advantages, has, speaking morally, its dark side. {Atomism /^ In a great many branches crease of our Poor Rate have been ascribed (17SS), piece wages had become usual " a few years ago." Very recently the trades unions have again re- stricted the system of piece wages (§ 176). * This system is inapplicable in the case of domestic servants {Gcsinde) who are a part of the household, and who afford to their masters, besides their ser- vices, the advantage of having a person at their disposal always about them, and whose wages are therefore in great part their board and lodging. Still less can it apply to the case of the family physician, whose services consist not simply in writing prescriptions, but who is also the professional family friend. The same may be said of the state official, clergyman etc., from ■whom it is demanded that he should sacrifice his entire life to the service of the public. Against adopting piece wages in the case of state officials, it may be further urged that no case at law, no act of public life is precisely similar to any other. It cannot be applied to that of soldiers, because they are called upon for action only after a longtermof peace, during all of which they must keep themselves in readiness for war. (Schdffle, N. CEk., II, 3SS.) It has also been the practice of courts, until recently, on account of their dignity, to pay their mechanics not by the piece, wherever that was practicable, but by a fixed salary. An able professor in a university is of use to it not only by his lectures, but by his reputation and example etc. ; hence, here, a cornbina- tion of piece wages and of a regular salary is preferred. As to services, the permanency of which constitutes their essential character, remuneration is also wont to be permanent or hereditary, as in the case of very many public officers, while civilization is as yet unadvanced. Later, in proportion as the progress of civilization makes itself felt, this hereditariness is wont to be confined to the sovereign. For an opposite view, see BoxJiorn, Institutt. po- litt. (1663), 41. ■" Thus, the Chinese, who, by a ridiculous exaggeration bordering on carica- ture of many of our recent tendencies, may aftbrd us a warning reflection of ourselves in our present state of civilization, rarely labor efficiently when not 142 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. 1, of manufactures it has been relinquished because the excellence of his work suffered from the workman's haste, and because he could not be properly controlled.^ It is rather the quan- tity than the quality of work which increases with piece- work, and where the quality of the work is what is desired, this system has not the same field. And where it obtains, as, for instance, in the case of ordinary type-setters, resort is had to payment by the day for compositors engaged on mathemat- ical treatises, fac-similes, inscriptions etc. On the side of the workman, it is generally only the idle and awkward who op-« pose piece-work on principle. It is a subject of regret that the best and most industrious workmen are carried away b}'' it to an extent detrimental to their health.^ However, many watched. Only by means of piece wages or the share-system can they be induced to do good work. R. M. Micking, Recollections of Manilla and the Phillippine Islands, 1851. , * Day laborers, for instance, must be watched over during the harvest, to prevent their idling away their time, and piece-workers to prevent their con- tinuing to work in spite of wet weathei", binding sheaves, for instance, which causes the sheaves to rot. In England, it is considered almost an impossibil- ity to induce laborers to cut wheat close enough to the soil. {Sinclair, Code of Agriculture, 102.) The haste of piece-workers, in the harvest of the rape, occasions great loss, by the fall of the seed. In Russia the removing of the hide from animals is paid for by the piece, and the laborers injure a very large number of skins in their haste. Sieinhaus, Russlands industrielle und commercielle Verhaltnisse, 425. Piece-wage-s are to be entirely dis- countenanced in the reeling of silk. See ^er;/c>?^z7/?', Technologie, II, 215. A yearly salary is to be recommended in the tending of cattle, because here a certain connection {Anschluss) with individuals is desirable. In building trades, contractors in England prefer a regular salary ; but they employ model workmen, the so-called " bell horses," to whom they pay a large salary, and who keep the others on the sh'ain by their example, and who on that account are very much hated by their colleagues. * Adam Stnith, W. of Nations, I, ch. 8. HoTvlett, also, 1. c, thinks that piece-wages increase the earnings of workmen, but at the expense of their capacity for constant labor. Count Gortz^ in his Reise, 328, relates with what fatal effect piece-work in Demarara tells on white laborers and their horses. After the February Revolution, Parisian workmen demanded the abolition of piece- wages, and obtained it in several manufactories. Revue des deux Mondes, March 15, 1S4S. Sec. XXXIX.] LABOR. 143 of the deficiencies of the piece-wage principle may be removed by agreements made with whole groups of workmen; pro- vided, always, that the groups are not too large to prevent the mutual knowledge and surveillance of their members.^" The quantity of work is greatest, its quality best, and the mate- rial" employed used most sparingly, when the workman works on his own account, or has a share in the profits. This last is proper only in those branches of the business the success of which depends on the quality of the work. To compel the workman to share in the profits alone will not do, because he is generally too poor to run any risk or to do long without his earnings. The system of paying " commissions," therefore, is to be recommended all the more strongly, since it is a combi- nation of fixed wages with a share in the profits. This sys- tem is very prevalent in North America, where a great deal has to be confided to the workmen. It is practiced, also, in the whale fisheries, and on the Greek ships in the Levant en- gaged in coasting, where much more depends on the care of- the sailors than on the ability of the captain.^^ It presupposes '" In several Swiss factories, understrappers receive a salary, while viontettrs work by groupe-contract. (Bohmert, Arbeiterveraltnisse und Fabrikeinricht- ungen der Schw., II, 70.) Sub-contracting, where the contract is generally made with only one person, for the most part of more than average capacity, and this latter contracts with other workmen on his own account entirely, is considered by philanthropic employers of labor as one of the worst kinds of remuneration. The more democratic system of gang-contract is much better, although even here, it is very easy for the weaker members of a good gang to overwork themselves. (Edinburg Review, October, 1873, 365-) '^ Especially important in chemical factories. The expense of greasing on the Rhenish railways fell, through premiums offered as rewards for saving, from 27,000 thalers to S,ooo, in spite of an increase in the amount of traffic. (v. Mangoldt^ Volkswirthschaftslehre, 349.) This was, besides, the most ef- fectual way of controlling the theft of material. '^ In the cachelot fishery, the captain receives one-sixteenth, the master, one twenty-fifth, the second master, one thirty-fifth, the boatswain, one- sixtieth, each sailor, one eighty-fifth of the profit. (Humboldt, N. Espagne, IV, 10.) This system is very common in North America. See Carey in J, S. MilVs Principles, V, ch. 9, 7. In heathen Iceland, mariners were 144 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. I. good workmen, equal almost to their master in education,^^ for instance, in the case of overseers of labor ; since every bet- ter inducement to the taste for labor which is not only juster but more complicative, is not only a condition but also the ef- fect of higher culture. But if the economy of a people is ripe for share-wages, and masters begin to introduce them in earn- est in individual cases, the work produced will be improved to such a degree that it can not be long before all others will be necessitated to follow them." If, howerer, workmen are to enjoy the fruit of their indus- try, it is necessary, first of all, that public order should be se- cure. Even the most industrious become discouraged where despotism or anarchy prevails. On the other hand, even the greatest security is no sufficient incentive to a nation of fa- talists." always paid a certain quota of the profits. Leo, in Raumer's historischem Taschenbuch, 1835, 524. The same was often the case in China. McCullocJi, Comni. Diction, v. Canton. In England, its employment was rendered very difficult by the laws of partnership, which made each individual, except in great chartered societies, responsible for all kinds of debts contracted by the rest of the firm. J. S. Mill, B. IV, ch. 7, 5. '3 The house painter Leclaire,.in Paris, obtained very high results in this respect. Leclaire, Repartition des Benefices du Travail, 1842. He retained for his own services as contractor the sum of 6,000 francs, and paid each workman the salary he had hitherto received. What remained was, at the end of the year, equally divided among all. Leclatre assures us that he was always satisfied with the system. The paying of a proportion of the general pi-ofits to laborers is advisable only in case their ability of sur- veying the whole is not much inferior to that of their employers. Where a special proportion is paid, in special branches of business, it is sufficient if their supervision extends over that particular branch. But a sharing in the profits of business always supposes a corresponding supervision of the business itself, and also the keeping of accounts. '* A very good remedy against indigence among the lower classes. (Umf- fcnhach. National CEkonomie, 1867,214.) But whether it will ever be possi- ble to make the remuneration of the navvy or that of a type-setter depend on the final success of his work, qticere. '5 Toiirnefort, speaking of the fatalism of the Turks, says that they always and everywhere leave the world as they found it. According to their own proverb, no grass grows again where the Osman has set foot. Sec. XL.] LABOR. 145 SECTION XL. LABOR. — LABOR-POWER OF INDIVIDUALS. The average labor-power of individuals varies very much in different nations.^ The reason of this is, in part, doubtless a difference in natural endowments. Thus, for instance, no people surpass the English and Anglo-American in energy, none the German in intelligence in work or the French in taste. Where we can assume that the same meaning is attached to the expression, " military capacity," by the different recruiting bu- reaus, important conclusions as to the physical labor-power of different localities may be di^awn from the ratio existing be- ' The experiments made with the dynamometer in iSoofF. show that the av- erage _/brce maniieUc of an inhabitant of Van Dieman's Land is to that of an inhabitant of New Holland, of Timor, of a French marine, and of an English colonist in Australia, in the ratio of 50, 51, 58, 69, 71 kilogrammes. Peron, Voyage de Decouverte aux Terres australes, 2d ed., II, 417. It was found more recently in the American army, that the average lifting-power of white soldiers was 314 to 343 lbs; of white marines, 307; students, 30S; ne- groes, 323; mulattos, 348; and Indians, 419. Gould, Investigations in the Military and Anthropolog. Statistics of American Soldiers, 1S69, 458, scq. Ac- cording to English manufacturers, an English laborer accomplishes almost as much again as a French one( .^), and the latter in turn more than an Irishman. An English contractor, who had worked in French manufactories, expressed his opinion concerning the French to this effect : " It cannot be called work they do; it is only looking at it and wishing it done." Senior, Outlines, 149. Thus, for instance, a good English spinner with a machine of 800 spindles could produce 66 lt)S. of yarn. No. 40, while a Frenchman could produce only 48 lbs. {M. Mold, Reise durch Frankreich, 535; compare Dingier, Polyt. Journal, I, 63 seq.) That the Americans also are inferior to the English in strength and dexterity is attested by the American Hevjitt. See Brcntano, Arbeitergilden, II, 231. A Berlin wood-sawyer accomplished as much in ten days as a West Prussian from Labiau in twenty-seven days. J. G. Hoff"- mann. English farmers on the Hellespont prefer to pay Greek laborers £10 prer year "besides their keep," rather than £3 to Turkish laborers. {Lord Carlisle, Diary in Turkish and Greek Waters, 1S54, P- 77 ^eq.) In Paulo- pinang, the Malayan agricultural laborer receives $2j!^ per month, the Malabar, $4, the Chinese, $6 ; for which compensation they work respect- ively 26, 28 and 30 days. Riitcr, Erdkunde, \, 54. Vol, I. — 10 146 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch I tween the number of those fit for military service and those who are legally liable to military duty.^ But these conclusions are greatly modified by the state of civilization and that of society. Where the laboring classes are despised and paid in a manner unworthy of human beings, the badness of their work will be in keeping with the esti- mation in which it is held. The reverse of this, also, is usually true under different circumstances. (§ 173.) Thus, it has been noticed in France, that native workmen, provided with as sub- stantial food as English workmen, are scarcelv inferior to the the latter in the technic value of their labor .^ A Mecklen- burg day laborer eats almost twice as much as a Thuringian workman, but then he accomplishes almost twice as much. Hence, employers gain in the long run by paying their workmen well. As civilization advances, the same number of workmen become, not only more industrious and more capable, but the same quantity and quality of labor becomes, as a rule, cheaper.* * Little light can be thrown on this subject by a comparison of different countries. Thus, in France, there are 614 persons in every i,ooo examined fit for military service; in Bavaria, 705; in Denmark, 523; in Austria, 49S; in Prussia, 284; in Saxony, 259; in England, where the conscription is from among the lowest classes, 665 ; and in Wiirttemberg, 490. ( Wappaus, Allg. BevOlkerungsstatistik, II, 71, 140. Massy, Remarks on the Examination of Recruits, 1S54. [Memminger, Wiirt. Jahrb., 1S43, 103.) The comparison of different parts of the same state is much more instructive. Thus, in Saxony, cities afford only 197, and the flat country only 265 per 1,000 (Sachs, statist. Ztschr., 1856, No. 4 ff.); and in France there are among those of illegitimate birth a very large number unfit for military service. (Journ.des Econ., 1850, XXV, 69.) According to the Austrian Annual of military statistics, there Avere in 1870, on an average, throughout the entire monarchy, 211 per 1,000 of those liable to enter the ranks of the military, fit for service; in the Inns- bruck command, 325; in Lemberg, 179. ^M. Chevalier , Cours, I, 115. Adam Smithy B. I, ch. 8, noticed the great in- dustry of well paid workmen. Among the imcducated, labor must almost necessarily be repulsive in proportion as it is illy remunerated. ^Thusvl. Young remarked that wages in Ireland are wretchedly low, while labor is far from being cheap. In his " Evidence in Respect to the Occupa- tion of Land in Ireland," II, 135, he says that a Scotch day laborer at is. per day is cheaper tlian an Irish day laborer at |^s. According to McCulloch, "Statis. Account of the British Empire," I, 666, industrial labor in Germany Sec. XL.] LABOR. 147 The moral culture of a people exerts the greatest influence here. In every private undertaking, a great part of the ex- pense attending it, and in every state, a great part of the ex- pense of its police system, and of its system of administering justice, is occasioned only b}' the dishonesty of men. If all this expense could be dispensed with, and full confidence placed in individuals, it would be possible to devote much more time and energy to positively useful labor.^ In estimating the labor- power of ditTerent nations or different periods of time, the di- vision of population according to age is also of importance. As a rule, the labor-power of males is greatest from the age of twenty-five to the age of forty-five. The more numerous, therefore, the class of the population between these ages is, the more favorabl}^ other things being equal, is it situated as regards labor." "^ But, as a rule, the relative number of full- grown people is greatest in highly civilized nations. (§ 248.)^ and France is dearer than in England, because in the former countries there are, ceteris paribus, twice as many laborers employed in most manufactures. See Senior, Lectures on Wages, 1S30, 11, and the reports of the committees of parliament, /rt5«/« on French manufactures (1825). The same has been experienced in the agricultural history of Schleswig-Holstein. Sej Haiiss- en, Archiv. der Politisch. CEk. IV, 421. /,« main d'tvuvre est clih'c en Russic des qiCil s'agit d'line ccrtainc capacite et d'lm certain dcgrd d^instruciion pro- fessionellc, tandis que ccllc de Vouvricr ordinaire n'est mdle part aussi bas, (Tdgoborsky.) * Thus even Columella, R. R. I, 9. y. S. Mill, Principles, I, ch. 7, 5. 8 Thus, for instance, the Lex Visigoth., VIII, 4, 16, graduates the fine to be paid by the murderer according to the age of his victim. It increases up to the 20th year in the case of males, and diminishes after the 50th. In the case of females, the maximuin is attained between the ages of 15 and 40. Simi- larly even Afoscs, Book III, 27. ' As to what concerns the two sexes, thejbrce rdnale of adult males is twice that of females in the human species. The difference between them in youth is not so great. The force mantiellc of the two sexes at the age of 30 is as 9:5. (^udtelct, Sur ITIomme II, p. 73 ff.) The numerical ratio of one sex to the other varies but little among those nations which have attained a certain degree of civilization. See infra, § 245. 8 It is of great importance to calculate here the number of days in the year in which the laborer is compelled to be idle on account of sickness. Fengcr, 148 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. 1. SECTION XLI. LABOR. — EFFECT OF THE ESTEEM IN WHICH IT IS HELD. As civilization advances, labor becomes more honorable. All barbarous nations despise it as slavish. Pigrum et iners videtur stidore adqidrcre quod Rossis sanguine -par'are : has been the motto of all medieval times. In heathen Iceland, the owner of a piece of land might be deprived of it by an adver- sary who could overpower him in single combat. This mode of acquisition was considered more honorable than purchase. It was Thor's own form of investiture. The ideas of the Romans on rightful acquisition may be inferred from the word mancipmm (manu capere).^ Pure Christianity, on the other hand, preached the honorableness of labor from the first (Thess. 4, ii; II. Thess. 3, 8 seq. ; Eph. 4, 28). And so in the time of the Reformation,^ when Christendom was return- ing to its primitive purity. In keeping with this is the fact, that the most cultivated (Quid faciant astas annique tempus ad frequentiam et diuturnitatem morbo- rum, Hafnise 1S40), finds the following result: Between 15 and 19 years, 7.2 days. Between 35 and 39 years, 7.8 days. " 20 and 24 years, 10.3 days. " 40 and 44 years, 8.3 days. " 25 and 29 years, 9.5 days. " 45 and 49 years, 11. 6 days. " 30 and 34 years, 7.6 days. " 50 and 59 years, 14. i days. According to Villerme, in the Annales d'Hygiene, II, At 60 years 16 days. At 67 years 42 days. At 65 years 31 days. At 70 years 75 days. The latter table is the result of a comparison made of the tables of seventy Scotch mutual aid societies. Compare Divgler^ Polyt. Journal, XXIV, 16S. ' Tacii., Germ., 14. Leo, in Rau»ier''s Taschenbuch, 1S35, 41S. Maxime sua esse credebanf, qncc ex hostibus cepissent. (Gajiis IV, 16.) Roman auction sub hasta! Similar views obtained among the Thracians. See Herodot., V, 6. In Sparta, even in the time of Agesilaus, economic labor was considered un- worthy of a free man, (Plutarch, Ages, 26) ; while the Athenians, from the time of Solon, punished idleness, and from that of Pericles " knew no other festival but attending to their business." Thucyd., I. 70. For some happy observations on this subject, see Rielil, Die deutsche Arbeit, 1S61. 2 Compare Erasmus CoUoq. (ed. Stallb), 21 ff., 213 ff., 392 fF. Sec. XLI.] LABOR. 149 nations, and the same may be said of individuals, value time most highly. " Time is monc}'." {Boijaiiiin FranMin^ An English proverb calls time the stulT ot* which life is made." While in negro nations, individuals do not even know their own age; while in Russia, there are very few clocks to strike the hours, even in the towers of churches, in England, a watch is considered an indispensable article oi apparel, even for very young people and for some of the lower orders of society.* Railroads operate in this respect as a kind of na- tional clock. The introduction of machinery and the more minute division of labor, make punctuality a necessity. While South Americans and West Indians are frightfully careless in their every movement, a carelessness ^vhich betrays itself even in their drawling speech , ^ the life of a New Englander has been compared to the rush of a locomotive. In the markets of Central Asia, nothing strikes the European with so much surprise as the little value put upon time by the merchants of India and Bucharia, who are fully satisfied when, after endless waiting, they succeed in obtaining a somewhat higher price for their wares.^ ' Temple learned from the Dutch of his own age that the time of industri- ous men is the greatest home commodity of a country. (Works 1, 129.) "A trader's time is his bread." (Sir M. Decker, Essay on the DecHne etc., 1744, 24.) JValpoIc, in his Testament poHtique II, 3S5, speaks of the inferiority of the Roman Church in this respect. I Avould allude to the medieaval prohi- bition " to sell time " as one of the chief grounds of the prohibition of usury. (See RoscJier^ Gesch. der N. CEk. in Deutschland, 7.) Economia di temfo eqiii- vale a prolimgamcnto di csistenza. (Scialoja.) * DouvillCy Voyage au Congo I, 239. See v. Haxthausen, Studien, II, 439; W. yacob, Production and Consumption of the precious Metals, II, 209. The division of the day into hours dates from the time of the sun dials of Alexandria. It was not known in Rome until after the year of the city 491. (Mominsen, Romische Geschichte, I. 301.) ^ Pinckard, Notes on the West Indies, 1S06, II, 107. In Spain it looks as if no one in the streets was in a hurry. W'hat a contrast between the sans souci gait of persons at bathing places and the resorts of pilgrims and the precipitate haste in commercial centres! ^ Mejendoi^',yoyage d Boukhara, 246. 150 PRODUCTION OF GOODS, [B.I, Ch. I. SECTION XLIL OF CAPITAL. — THE CLASSES OF GOODS OF WHICH A NATION'S CAPITAL IS MADE UP. Capital ^ we call every product laid by for purposes of further production. (§ 220).^ ' The history of this idea aftbrds a remarkable example of the confusion produced by the employment of scientific terminology in daily life. Until within a short time every possible meanmg of the word capital was to be found in the dictionary of the French Academy, its scientific politico-eco- nomical meaning alone excepted. During the middle ages, the Latin capitale was used to signify both loaned money and cattle. (Diicaiigc^ s. v.) When culture was at its highest in Greece, Demosthenes entertained very good ideas of the nature of capital which he sometimes calls aifopuin. sometimes epauo^, the meaning of which he extends also to the incorporeal capital of a good reputation. (Adv. Mid., 574; pro Phorm, 947.) The same may be said of the Roman in conception o{ feciiUuin. See Hildcbrand's Jahrbb., 1866, I. 338. On the beginnings of the present idea of capital among the later schoolmen, see Funck, Tiibinger Ztschr., 1869, 149. The diary of Lucas Re)>2s, 1491-1541 (ed. Greiff, 1S61), calls commercial capital, in most instances, the chief good {Hauptgut) p. 37; also Cavedal. The words money and capital, interest and the price of money are now confounded in daily life, as they were formerly by most writers. In the 17th century. Child and Loche may be mentioned as instances. Hobbes had some faint notion of the productive power of capital. See Roscher, Zur Geschichte der englischen Volkswirthschaftslehre, 49, 60, 102. Thus, also, in the iSth century, La^v, Sur rUsage des Monnaies, 697; Trade and money (1705) 117; Mdlon, Essai politique sur le Commerce, 1734, ch. 22; (?«//'««/, Delia Moneta, IV, i, 3; Blachstone^ Commentaries, 1764, II, 456; Gcnctvesi, Economia civile, II, 2, 18, 13; Sietvari, Principles, IV, i, ch. IV; Verri, Meditazioni, XIV; BUsch, Geldumlauf, V. 14; A. Toung^ Political Arithmetics (1774), i, ch. 7. Hume, on the other hand, Discourses (1752), No. 4 (on interest), shows, that the rate of interest is dependent, not as Loche supposed, on the abundance or scarcity of money, but on the state of profit and on the relation between the demand and supply of capital. Similarly, J. Massie, An Essay on the governing Causes of the Rate of Interest (1750J. ^uestiay, Dialogue sur le Commerce, 173 (ed. Daire), shows that he had a very clear conception of the operation, and of the principal component parts of capital. Turgot, Sur la Formation et la Distribution des Richesses, § 14, 54-79, came very near the truth, and yet missed it. He recognized the necessity of advances which, as a rule, are the result of saving, in every case of production. He also distinguishes in the product of the soil, besides the produit net and the subsistance du labourcur. Sec. XLII.] CAPITAL. 151 Hence, the capital of a nation consists especially of the fol- lowing classes of goods: the profit of the hitter. He hkewise points out a great number of differences between the " price of money " considered in its rehition to trade, and in its relation to loans. He explains tlie interest on capital, as Scliroiicr, in his Schatz-und Rentkammer, 231, and Benjamin Franklin^ in his Inquiry into the Nature of a Paper Currency (1729) had done before, by the fact that the owner of capital can purchase a piece of land with his capital, and thus draw an income without working. Money, he said, was indeed not productive, but neither was any other thing that could be loaned or leased, with the ex- ception of land and cattle. Adam Smith deserves the greatest credit for his analysis of the idea of capital, although he opposes " capital " to what the Germans call capital-in-use, the "stock for immediate consumption." When Canard, Principes d'Economie politique (iSoi)' and J. B. Say^ Cours pra- tique, 1S28, I, 285, included man's power of labor in capital, they took a ret- rograde step. " Labour is Capital, primary and fundamental." Colton^ 275. Every grown-up individual, says McCulloch, Principles, 1S25, II, ch. 2, may be looked upon as a machine which has- cost several years of con- tinued care and a considerable sum for its construction. It is only anoth- er side of this same perversity, when McCulloch seeks to force the results produced by animals and machines into the definition of labor. ScJdozcr, Anfangsgriinde (1S05), I, 21, goes so far as to call the soul, raw material, which receives productive power from the labor of the teacher! For a calculation of the money value of man in the different ages of life, see Statis. Journ. XVI, 43 ft". See, on the other hand, Malthus, Definitions, ch . 7; and Rossi, in the Journal des Economistes, VI, 113. Nor does the view of Gaiiilh, Systemes d'Economie politique (1S09), I, 243; of Ad. Miillcr, Con- cordia, 93 ff., 211; of //c/";«rt««,. jStaatswirth, Untcrsuchungen, No. 3; of Dunoyer, Liberie du Travail, L. VI; of Bastiat, Carey and others, who include pieces of land in themselves under the head of capital, seem to be better founded. Hermann defines capital the durable basis of every utility possessed of value in exchange. Scfiaffle reckons land as nature offers it to us, among free goods. From the moment that labor and capital are spent upon it, it becomes immovable capital, but he concedes that it still pre- serves many essential points which distinguish it froin other capital. (N. CEk. Theorie der ausschliessenden Absatz verbal tnisse, 1S67, 65 ff., 89 ff.) These differences appear to me to be still more important than that which land and capital have in common ; especially as the historic development of their relations proceeds for the most part in opposite directions. Thus, for instance, as civilization advances, land is wont to become dearer and capital cheaper. How difficult would it be to introduce clearness into the ideas of intensive and f.\-/e'W5?rc agriculture, if land were accounted capital! And it is not only always theoretically, but also very often, in practice, possible to 152 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. I. A. Soil-improvements, for instance, drainage and irrigation works, dikes, hedges etc., which are, indeed, sometimes so far part of the land itself that it is difficult to distinguish them from it.^ To this class belong all permanent plantations. B. Buildings, which embrace workshops and storehouses as well as dwellings ; also artificial roads of all kinds. C. Tools, machines and utensils of every description ; * the latter especially for personal service, and for the preservation and transportation of other goods. A machine is distinguished from a tool in that the moving power of the former is not com- municated to it immediately by the human body, which only directs it; while the latter serves as a species of equipment, or as a better substitute for some member of man's body.^ To be of advantage, these three kinds of capital must save more labor or fatigue than it has cost to produce them. Tools are, however, older than machines. The aborigines of Australia used only a lance and a club in hunting; the somewhat more civilized American Indians, the bow and arrow; Europeans use firearms : in all of which a gradual progress is observable. Of the blind forces which communicate motion to machines, water was the first used, then the wind, and last of all, steam.^ separate the value of a given piece of land from the most durable capital- improvements {Kapitahndiorationen ) made on it. It is only necessary to call to mind the area of buildinjjs. 2 Marx makes a very arbitrary assertion when he says that only the capital operating in trade, and even only that operating in trade where money is used as the instrument of exchange, can properly be called capital ; and that, therefore, the modern biography of capital dates only from the i6th century, (Das Kapital I, io6 ff.) ^ See, on the other hand, Wolkoff, Lectures d'Economie politique ra- tionelle, 167. ■* Hermann (II ed., 238 if.) distinguishes especially f7-eparatory contrivances auxiliary to labor, such as stationary structures etc., vessels, tools, machines and instruments for measuring etc. ^ Thus, for instance, the plow and the gun are machines, the spade and the blow-pipe are tools. A hammer may be considered as a hard, insensible jfist; the bellows as a pair of very strong and durable lungs. Tongs take the Sec. XLIi.] CAPITAL. 153 D. Useful and labor i)ig animals^ in so far as they are raised, fed and developed by human care. E. Materials for transformation ( Verwandlungsstoffc) : either the principal material which constitutes the essential substance of a new product, the yarn of the weaver for instance, the raw wool, silk or cotton of the spinner ; or the secondary ma- terial which, indeed, enters into the work, but only for pur- poses of ornamentation, as gold-leaf, lac, colors etc. F. Auxiliary substances, which are consumed in production, but do not constitute a visible part of the raw product,''' as coal in a smithy, powder in the chase or in mining, muriatic acid, in the preparation of gelatin, chlorine in bleaching etc. G. Mea)is of subsistence for the producers, which are ad- vanced to them until production is complete. H. Commercial stock, which the merchant keeps always on hand to meet the w^ants of his customers. I. Money as the principal tool in every trade that is made. K. There is also what may be called iiicorporeal capital (quasi-capital according to Schmitthenner), which is as much the result of production as any other capital, and is used in pro- place of fingers, just as a spoon does of the empty hand, and the knife the place ot the teeth. A great number of machines, on the other hand, may be compared to a complete workman. Thus, the action of the mill -which grinds grain has very little resemblance to the blowing of the wind or the running of the water, whereas the rising and falling of the pestle in the small mortar for throwing grenades corresponds to the motion of the arm. (Hctu, Lehrbuch I, § 125.) The infinite number of functions of which our members are capable is related to their inability to attain alone the greater number of their ends. Hence animals which require no tools can undertake to achieve very few things. " Man is a tool-making animal." (B. Franklin.) * This is seen most clearly in the history of the grinding of corn. In the time of Moses, and even of Homer, there were only hand-mills, and originally only mortars. Later, mills set in motion by horse-power were employed. Shortly after Cicero's time, mills driven by water-power came into use. Brunck, Analecta, II, 119, Ep. 39. Mills built on pontoons do not date farther back than the time of Belisarius. Wind-mills have been known since the. ninth century; Dutch wind-mills, only since the middle of the i6th century. See Beckman^ Beitrage zur Geschichte der Erfindungen II, I flf. ' Compare Plato., Polit., 2S0. 154 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch I. duction, but which, for the most part, is not exhausted by use. There are species of this kind of capital which may be trans- ferred, as for instance, the good will of a well-established firm. Others are as inseparably connected with human capacity for labor as soil-improvements with a piece of land; c. g,^ the greater dexterity acquired by a workman through scientific study, or the greater confidence he has acquired by long trial.^ The state itself is the most important incorporeal capital of every nation, since it is clearly indispensable, at least indi- rectly, to economic production.^ The greater portion of the national capital is in a state of constant transformation. It is being continually destroyed and reproduced. But from the stand-point of private economy, as well as from that of the whole people, we say that capital is preserved, increased or diminished according as its value is preserved, increased or diminished.^" Prctiimi succedit in lo- ciim roi ct res in locum -pretii. " The greater part in value of the wealth now existing in England, has been produced by hu- man hands within the last twelve months. A very small pro- portion indeed of that large aggregate was in existence ten years ago; of the present productive capital of the country, scarcely any part except farm-houses and a few ships and ma- *Thus, Gantl'i, Theorie de I'Economie politique I, 133, calls the knowl- edge, talents and probity of meixhants, as well as their reputation, valuable parts of their capital in trade. See, also, Moser^ Patriot. Ph. II, 26. See some happy observations on the intellectual capital of nations, as consisting of " known and unknown preparatory labor through their history," in Lotze, Mikrokosomos II, 353 scq. ^ Compare Dictzel, System der Staatsanleihen (1S56), 71 ff. And, earlier yet, Ad. Miiller had looked upon taxes not in the light of an insurance pre- mium, but as " the interest of the invisible and yet absolutely necessarj' in- tellectual capital of the nation." (Elemente, III, 75.) Of course, the State is much more than a species of capital; just as a Gothic cathedral is some- thing more than a piece of masonry, but does not on that accout cease to be a piece of masonry. '" 'J. B. Say, Traite d'Economie Politique I, ch. 10. Only think of what is known in physiology as the change or transformation of matter (Stoffvjcchsel I). Sec. XLIII.] CAPITAL. 155 chines; and even these would not, in most cases, have sur- vived so long, if fresh labor had not been employed within that period in putting them into repair Capital is kept in existence from age to age like population, not by preserva- tion, but by reproduction." {y. S. 31ill.) SECTION XLIII. CAPITAL. — PRODUCTIVE CAPITAL. Capital, according to the employment that can be given it, may be divided into such as affects the production of material goods, and such as affects personal goods or useful relations. The former, under the name of productive capital, is, in recent politico-economical literature, usually opposed to capital in use.^ Evidently any one of the two kinds of capital mentioned above, may be used for both purposes.^ Indeed, the two classes are, in many respects, coincident. Thus, a livery-stable carriage or a circulating library is productive capital to its proprietor, and capital in use* {Gcbranchskapital^ to the nation ' Productive capital lias been rendered into German by the word Erxverb- stainm, by the author of " Staatswirthschat't nach Naturgesetzen," 1S19. Aldlthus, Definitions, ch. 10, and Ran, Lchrbuch, I, § 51, call productive cap- ital alone, capital. According to M. Chevalier^ goods lose their quality of capital as soon as they come into the hands of a consumer. ScJidffle, N. CEk., II, aufl., 59, calls capital in use Genussvermogen (resources intended for enjoyment) and productive capital, Kapitalvermogen (capital-resources). On the other hand, J. B. Say, Traite, I, \y, McCtdloch, Principles, II, 2, 3; Her- mann, Staatswirthschaft. Untersuchungen, p. 60 ft*., and v. Mangoldt, Volks- Avirthschaftslehre, 122, divide capital into capital in use and productive capi- tal, according as it provides the possessor with that which he may tm-n to account directly or indirectly by becoming the owner of goods through its ineans. Aristotle distinguishes between 0(>yava and XT'/jptaza^ the former relating to Tioir.ac:;; for instance, a shuttle; the latter to Tzod^:^^ as, for in- stance, bedding and articles of dress. (Polit., I, 2, 5.) "Thus, for instance, class A embraces parks and forests; B, theaters, churches, manufactories, arsenals, granaries, public walks and roads. Walks can, besides, be used for the cultivation of fruit, and roads for pleasure trips. * Translated "capital de consommation " by W^olowski, p. 96 of his Rosch- er's Principles. — Translator's note. 156 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. I. in general; although the circulating library from which an Arkwright obtains technic information, or the livery-stable vehicle which carries a Borsig to his counting-room, has cer- tainly been used in the production of material goods. Almost all capital in use may be converted into productive capital, and hence, the former might be called quiescent capital, and the latter working capital.^ One of the principal difterences between productive capital and capital in use is, that the for- mer, even when most judiciously employed, does not so imme- diately replace itself, as the latter, by its returns.* On the other hand, the real dividing line between capital in use, and objects consumed which are not capital, is, and it is in complete har- mony with our definition of capital, that the latter are subject not only to a more speedy destruction and one which is always contemplated, while in the case of the former, its destruction is only the unintended reverse-side of its use. Among a highly civilized people, a great amount of capital in use, as compared with the productive capital of the country, may be considered a sure sign of great wealth. When this is the case, the people, without losing the desire of further ac- quisition, think that they have enough to richly enjoy the present. I need only call to mind the munificence displayed by the middle classes in England, in their silver plate and other domestic utensils. But the people of Russia, and Mex- ico also, can make no mean display of silverware.^ Here lux- ^ Dead, or better, dormant capital is such productive capital as, for the time being, remains unvised, and -which, therefore, does not yield even personal en- joyment. The sum total of this kind of capital is very much diminished by the agency of savings banks. Loaned capital which has been employed un- productively evidently constitutes no longer a part of the wealth of a people. See infra^ § 189. * Wolhoff is so far right, when in his Lectures, p. 142, he calls the return of capital in use not revenii., but ddstruction graduclle. ScJtdffle is right, too, and entirely so, when he says that only such an increase of the property, in- tended for enjoyment simply, is anti-economic, as does not make the per- sonal capacities of labor ( Arbeit svermogcn) as much more productive than they would otherwise be. N. Oik., II, aufl., 224. ^ Humboldf^ N. Espange, II, ch. 17; v. Sc/dozcr, Anfangsgrliiule, II, 109. Sec. XLIIL] CAPITAL. 157 ury is only a symptom of the disinclination or inability -of the inhabitants of the country to use their capital in the production of wealth. How much richer would Spain be to-day, if it had employed the idle capital spent in the ornamentation of its churches in constructinfj roads and canals!" Most nations in a low state of civilization suflerfrom the absence of legal guar- anties. Each one is compelled to turn his property into a shape in which it can be most easily transferred from one place to another and hidden. This is the principal reason why Ausland, 140, No. 313. On the extraordinary wealth of even Russian peas- ant women in pearls, see v. HaxtJiausen, Studien, 87, 309. ^ Tozvnsend, '^oum^y in Spain, I, 115, 310. In the patriarchal age of the Jews, there was a relatively very large quantity of ornamental objects in gold and silver: Mkhcclis, Dc Pretiis Reruni apud Hebrreos, in the Comm. Soc. Getting., Ill, 151 il, 160. Conservative Sparta, in the middle age of its history, was certainly not rich, and yet it had more gold and silver than any other Grecian state: Plato, Alcib., I, 123. Accordjng to St. John, The Hellenes, III, 142, the ancients had relatively much more of the precious metals in the form of objects for ornament than the moderns. The Romans, with their usual good sense, did not make use of silver as an article of lux- ury until they had attained great wealth. See Cato, R. R., ch. 23, and Sen- eca, De Vita bcata, ch. 21. Then the Carthagenian ambassadors railed at their hosts because they found the same pieces of table silver in all the houses to which they were invited. The younger Scipio, even, did not possess more relatively than 32 pounds of silver ware. Mommsen, ROmische Geschichte, II, 383. The relatively great importance of the stores for domestic use, never- theless, runs through the whole of Roman history. The title ffc /aus, Handbuch der Geographic, I, 310. For proof that the clergy by preaching self denial contributed largely to the crea- tion of capital in the earlier part of medieval history, see Giidrard, Polyp- tiques d'lrminon Pref., 13. s On the inevitableness of slavery, where capital is needed, and no one cares to save, see de Mctz Noblet, Phenomcncs economiques, I, 306. Vol. I. — n 162 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. I. fra^ § 68. Where civilization is at its highest, the inclination to save, as a rule, is very marked.' It begins to decline where a people are themselves declining in civilization, and especially where legal guaranties have lost their force. But capital may be increased even without personal sacri- fice ; as for instance, by mere occupation, as of certain goods, not hitherto recognized as such. Thus, also, by the establish- ment of valuable relations, the advantages of which either be- come the common good of all; or which, because at the exclusive command of one individual, obtain value in ex- change. The progress of civilization itself may increase the value of existing capital. Thus, for instance, a house, consid- ered as capital, may double in value if a frequented street be opened in its neighborhood. To this category belong all im- provements in the arts which enable existing capital to achieve more than it could before. The invention of the compass in- creased the value of the capital employed in the merchant marine to an extent that cannot be calculated.^ The increase of capital effected by saving soon finds a limit unless such limit is widened by the progress of civilization.^ ^*' ' The origination of capital by " social connexions " ( gcsellschaftliche Zus- ammenhdnge) Lassalle (Bastiat-Schultze, 92, 98) exaggerates into the absurd- ity that no capital was ever saved. This is in part related to his confounding land with capital (103 seq.). On the other hand, P. L. (v. Ltlienfeld), Ge- uanken iiber de Staatswissenschaft der Zukunft (1S73), distinguishes between the external and internal creation of capital in human society ; the latter based on the condition of evei'y organic being, by virtue of Avhich the present is generated by the past, and generates the future. The intercellular substance of plants, the honey-comb of bees, and the blood in the animal body, corres- pond to the capital of a nation. ^ Hermann^ St. Untersuchungen, 2S9 ff. ; List^ System der politischen CEkonomie, I, 325 fF. Thus, for instance, capitalization among a race of hunters may be continued longest by the creation of herds; that of a race of shepherds by the building of houses, and by land-improvements; that of an agricultural people by the establishment of trades, artificial roads, etc. As to how, in general the accumulation of goods to any great extent, supposes exchange, and as to how, first of all, with exchange through the existence of a superabundance wealth may originate, see Hermann, loc. cit., II, Aufl., 25 flf. Sec. XLVI.] PRODUCTIVE CO-OPERATION. 1G3 CHAPTER II. CO-OPERATION OF THE FACTORS. SECTION XLVI. THE PRODUCTIVE C0<3PERATI0N OF THE THREE FACTORS. All economic production generally demands the coopera- tion of the three factors: external nature, labor and capital. But with the political economist, labor is the principal thing; and not merely because all capital presupposes labor, nor be- cause every combination of the three factors is an act of labor ; ^ The annual increase of the capital of France during the later years of Louis Philippe's reign, Avas estimated at from 200 to 300 million of francs ; during the best years of Napoleon Ill's reign, at 600 million. Journal des Econ., Nov., 1S61, 170. The capital of the British empire, judging from the statistics of the income tax, increased from 1843 to 1853, in Great Britain alone, at least £42,000,000 yearly; from 1S54 to 1S60, in the whole empire, at least £114,000,000; and in 1S63 alone by £130,000,000. London Statis. Jour- nal, 1864, iiS ff. A war carried on on English soil would doubtless be more destructive of capital than one waged in Russia; but Russia would recover from one like that of 1854-55 with much gi-eater difficulty because of the small tendency of its people to amass capital. In countries in which the middle classes preponderate, the influence of the amassing of capital on for- eign politics is one that favors peace. In despotic or democratic countries, it may as readily favor war. '•^ The " absolute formation " of capital above described is, of course, the only one in the general economy of mankind. In the economy of individuals, we frequently meet with another which is only " relative," as when the increase of one's resources is attended by as great or even greater decrease of anoth- er's. This is the case, for instance, where privileges or monopolies are granted. The same phenomenon is found also in the intercourse of economies of differ- ent nations. S//J>>-a, § 64. 1(3-1, PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. II. but, in general, because " the human mind's idea of means and ends makes all goods goods for the first time." {Huf eland.) Leaving the free forces of nature, surrounded by which we live and work, out of consideration, and also the fact that all raw material is due to nature, land is the indispensable found- ation of all economy. But how little can unassisted nature do to satisfy human wants! How much less to produce goods possessed of value in exchange! A virgin forest, for instance, sold in its natural state, has, indeed, value in exchange, but only because it is taken into account that it can be cleared, and that there are means of transportion already existing.-^ The greater part of the forces of nature are latent to nomads and nations of hunters. When labor develops, they are set free to assist it.^ It is very seldom that any thing can be pro- duced without capital. Even the poorest gatherer of wild ber- ries needs a basket and must be clothed.^ Were there no capital, every individual would have to begin at the very be- ginning every moment. Life would be possible only in a tropical climate. No man, since the days of Adam, has been able to labor, except on the condition that a considerable ad- vance of capital had been made upon him. There is not a nail in all England, sa^'-s Senior, which cannot directly or in- ' Thus Cieero^ De Oft", II, 3, 4. Nature may indeed produce mere value in use without the cooperation of labor, in the narrow sense of the word ; as, for instance, a forest which protects a district from avalanches etc. But " every- thing which has been ti-ansformed into goods tends constantly to return to its natural state, and to withdraw itself from the life of goods. Stchi, Lehrbuch. * Compare List, System der Polit. CEkon. But see also the very fine dis- cussion of y. S. Mill, Principles, IV, ch. VI, 2, on the dreariness of nature, when taken exclusive possession of by man; "with every rood of land brought into cultivation which is capable of growing food for human beings; every flowery waste or natural pasture plowed up ; all quadrupeds or birds which are not domesticated for man's use, exterminated as his rivals for food; every hedgerow or superfluous tree rooted out, and scarcely a place left where a wild shrub or flower could grow, without being eradicated as a weed, in the name of improved agriculture." 3In Paris, in 1820, the necessary tools of a rag-gatherer cost 6^ francs. Gamier, Elements d'Econ.-polit., 43. Sec. XLVIL] PRODUCTIVE CO-OPERATION. 1G5 directly be traced back to savings made before the Norman conquest,* SECTION XLVIL PRODUCTIVE CO-OPERATION OF THE THREE FACTORS. THE THREE GREAT PERIODS OF A NATION'S ECONOMY. The relation of the three factors to one another is necessari- ly very different in different branches of production. For in- stance, in the case of cattle-raising on a prairie, labor does very little, land almost everything. Hence an extensive, thinly populated country is best adapted to this species of produc- tion. But where land is scarce, as in wealthy and populous cities, human activity should be directed into those branches of industry which need capital and labor, as manufactures and the trades. (§ 198.) ^ Looked at from this point of view, the history of the de- velopment of the public economy of every people may be divided into three great periods. In the earliest period, nature is the element that predominates everywhere. The woods, waters and meadows afford food almost spontaneously to a scanty population. This is the Saturnian or golden age of which the sagas tell. Wealth, properly speaking, does not exist here, and those who do not possess a piece of land run the risk of becoming completely dependent on, or even the slave of a land owner. In the second period, that through which all modern nations have passed since the later part of the middle ages, the element, labor, acquires an ever increas- ing importance. Labor favors the origin and development of cities as well as exclusive rights, the rights of boroughs and guilds by means of which labor is, so to speak, capitalized. A * It is not to be overlooked that all labor expended for a distant end also falls vinder the head of capital. See Droz^ Economic politique, 1S29, 1, 6. 1 For a good exposition as to how England has need of more agi-icultural products, the East Indies of more capital, and the West Indies of more labor, see Fa-Mcett, Manual of P. E., 1 10. IQQ PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Cil. II. middle class is formed intermediate between the serfs and the owners of the soil. In the third period, capital, if we may so speak, gives tone to everything. The value of land is vastly increased by the expenditure of capital on it, and in manufac- tures, machine labor preponderates over the labor of the hu- man hand.^ The national w^ealth undergoes a daily increase; and it is the " capitalism " which first gives an independent existence to the economic activity of man; just in the same way that law is, as it were, emancipated from land-own- ership, from the church and the family only in the consti- tutional state {Rechtsstaaf).^ But, during this period, the middle class with its moderate ease and solid culture may de- crease in numbers, and colossal wealth be confronted with the most abject miser3\* Although these three periods may be shown to exist in the history of all highly civilized countries, the nations of antiquity, relativel}^ speaking, never advanced far beyond the second, even in their palmiest days. A great part of that which is accomplished among us by means of cap- ital and of machines, the Greeks and Romans performed by the labor of slaves. Leaving Christianity out of the question, nearly all the minor differences between the public economy of the ancients and that of the moderns may be reduced to this fundamental distinction.^ ^ ° It is a very significant fact, tliat, at present, in certain European countries, in Germany for instance, the laborer is called a taker, and the capitalist a giver of work. The expressions employed by Canard, Say and Hermann, teach a similar lesson. ^ Schciffle, Kapitalismus und Socialismus, 124 seq. ■* It is evident, that, absolutely considered, the predominating factor of an earlier period may continue to increase during the following : and, as a rule, it does continue to increase. ^ I need cite only the instance of the slaves, Avho called out the hours, thus performing the functions of a clock: Martial, Ylll. 6'j; ^Kvcnal, X. 216; Petron. 26; of the turning of water wheels, in Egypt and Babylon, by hu- man hands. Strabo, XVI. 738, XVII., 807. Among the ancients, it re- quired one shepherd, and shepherd boys besides, to take care of twenty sheep. (Geopon. XVIII, i.) In highly cultivated regions, the number ran up to fifty. (Demosth., adv. Euerg. et Mnes., 1155.) It seldom passed eighty Sec. XLVIIL] CRITICAL HISTORY. 107 SECTION XLYIII. CRITICAL HISTORY OF THE IDEA OF PRODUCTIVENESS. In this chapter, the dogma-historical (dogmcngcschichtUche) part is of the utmost importance, because it treats of the con- (Varro^ De re rust., II. lo, lo. 2, 20), or one hundred (Caio, R. R. c. 10); ■while, recently, five men are sufficient to take care of eighteen hundred sheep. See Rosckcr's discourse on the relation of Political Economy to classical antiquity, in the reports of the Royal Saxon Science Association, May, 1S49. Also D. Ilujiie, Discourses, No. 10. ^The productive power of each of the factors of production has been over- estimated by some schools. After Gratian (c. i, C. XIII. qu. 1), had clearly recognized the necessary cooperation of the three elements, there was in the one-sidedness with which the Reformers emphasized God's blessing as the only source of wealth, a great over-estimation of the factor nature. The Mercantile System over-estimated the factor capital, in one of its most obvious component parts, money. In later times again : " La terre est la source on la viatiere cVaii V on tire la rickcssej le travail de Vhomme est la forme qui la froduit. Tons Ics homines d'lin dtat subsistent et i enrichissent aux depens dcs fropridtaires des terres. (Cantillon, Sur la Nature du Commerce, i75S) !• 33> 55.) La terre est V unique source des richesses. (^uesfiqy, Maximes gdnerales de Gouvernement, 1758, ch. 3.) In another place, indeed, the same writer says: les revenus sont Ic prodiiit des terres et dcs hoinmes (Grains^ p. 276, Daire), and Mirabeaii frequently laid stress on the necessary cooperation of labor and capital. (Landwirthschaftsphilosophie, translation by IVichmann, I, 5.) Turgot^ Sur la Formation et Distribution des Richesses, § 7. For an excellent refutation of this " Physiocratic " one-sidedness, which, if all men are endowed by nature with equal rights, leads to socialism, see Canard^ Principes, 6. According to Gioja, N. Prospetto, I. 35, the part played by la- bor, in the production of Parmesan cheese, is a thousand times as great as that played by the soil; and in the production of a Dutch tulip, a hundred thousand times as great. The English are wont, similarly, to over-estimate the relative power of labor. {Po7wcratie, after Ancillon, Essais philosoph- iques, 1817, II. 327.) "Commerce and trade first spring from the labour of men." {North, Discourses upon Trade, 112.) Thus, Locke {i6cp), Of Civil Government, II, 5, 40 ff., is of opinion, that, at least f"^ of the value of the products of the soil, useful to man, are to be ascribed to labor, and, in the case of most, even ■^-^■^. And so, Berkeley (1735), Querist, No. 38 seq. This view is advocated in its boldest form, — a thing unusual in the case of the independent disciples of a great master — by McCulloch, Principles, II, ch. i, that it is to labor, and to labor alone, that man owes everything that possesses 168 PRODUCTION OF GOODS, [B. I, Ch. II. nection between the deepest fundamental notions and the prin- cipal branches of practical life. It is clear that eveiy political economist must construct his exposition of productiveness on his prior notions of goods and value. We must, therefore, draw a distinction between expositions which are logical but altogether too narrow, and wholly erroneous ones.^ any value in exchange. Similarly, y. Mill, Elements (1S24), III, 2. The consequences -which socialism might drav from these premises are £elf-evi- dent. KarlAIarx's whole system, for instance, i-ests, without any attempt at demonstration, on the assumption that the Ricardo school is rrght. Much more moderate views are met with earlier. Thus, Hobbes, De Give, XIII, 14, and Leviath., 24 (1642 and 1651), calls labor ei farsimonia necessary sources of wealth; froventus terrce et aquce useful ones; and Petty, On Taxes (1679), 47, says: "Labour is the father and active principle of wealth, as lands are the mother. Land and labour together are the sources of all wealth ; without a competency of lands there would be no subsistence, and but a very poor one without labour." Harris, Upon Money and Goins, 1757, P. I. Adam Smith, also, in spite of the well known passage at the be- ginning of his Avork, very frequently lays stress on "the annual produce of land and labour." (See the passages collected in Leser, Begriff des Reich- thums bei A. S., 97.) According to Leibniz, regionis fotentia consistit in ter- ra, rebus, Jiominibus. (ed. Dutens, IV. 2, 531.) Ricardds school is wont to bring capital under the head of labor, as saved-up labor. This is about as correct as to say, that all that a grown man does, his parents had done. ( Umpfenbach, Nat. CEk., 64.) There is only one way in which labor, and even then the expression is not exactly correct, can be looked upon as the only factor in production ; and that is to presuppose the forces of nature as mat- ters of course (als sich von selbst verstehend), and to call the aggregate use made of them by the human mind, labor. Or we might say with old EpicJiarmos, that the gods sell all goods for labor. (Xenoph., Memor. II. i.) Moreover, even in purely intellectual productions, in poetical productions for instance, nature, labor and experience, the culture inherited from former ages (a kind of intellectual capital) uniformly cooperate. But how almost completely valueless in literature are all entirely pure (empty!) productions of the fancy ! 1 Before the predominance of the Mercantile System, Mo7itchrHien very cleverly called all trades : farcelles ct fragments de cctte sagesse divine que Dieu nous communique far le moyen de la raisen. By means of the three es- tates ; labourers, artisans, merckattds, tout etat est noiirri; far eux tout projii se fait. Vutilitd regie les rangs des arts. (Traite, 12,45,66.) The tQZ.(±.- ing o{: P. Gregorius Tolosanos (ph. 1597) on the different classes of society and the different callings of men, is still more in keeping with the presentdoc- Sec. XLVIII.] CRITICAL HISTORY. 169 Thus, the Mercantile System admits every mode of ap- plying the three factors of production, but considers them really productive only in so far as they increase the quantity of the precious metals possessed by the nation, either through the agency of mining at home, or b}^ means of foreign trade. This view stands and falls with the altogether too limited idea of national wealth before mentioned (§9), which this system advocated.^ The majority of the followers of the Mercantile System ascribe more power to industry to attract gold and sil- ver from foreign parts, than to agriculture, and to the finer kinds of industiy than to the coarser; to active and direct trade", more than to passive and indirect trade. trine of production; only, in the moralizing tone of the time, he speaks ratlier of tlieir dignity than of tlieir influence in creating wealth : De Rep. I, 195. See, also, the earlier views of Franc. Patricias (ob. 1494), De Rep. I, 4, 7, S. ^ Compare A. Serra^ Breve Trattato delle Cause die possono far abbondare i Regni d' Ore d' Argento, 1613. Th. Man., England's Treasure by foreign Trade, 1664. Ch. King^ British INIerchant or Commerce Preserved, 1721. But, particularly, A. C. Leib^ Von Verbesserung Land und Leuten etc. (1708), Avho, from the point of view of the Mercantile Sj'stem, draws a very clear distinction between the productive and unproductive classes. See, also, infra, § 116. • First thoroughly refuted by W. Petty, Political Anatomy of Ireland, 67, 82. Quantulumcunque concerning Money (1682). D. North, Discourses upon h-ade (1691). See Roschcr''s Geschichte der englischcn Volkswirthschaftslehre, 77, 88, 138. And later, especially. Ad. Smith, W. of N. IV., ch. I ft". Adam Smithes doctrine of productive and unproductive labor is to be found already, in this period, in Petty, Several Essays, 127 If. Political Anatom}', 185 fF; also, in the anonymous work, A Discourse of Trade, Coyn and Paper Credit, London (1697), 44, 159. 170 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. II. SECTION XLIX. CRITICAL HISTORY OF THE IDEA OF PRODUCTIVENESS— THE DOCTRINE OF THE PHYSIOCRATES. The doctrine of the Physiocrates is to be explained in part by a very natural reaction from the narrow-heartedness of the Mercantile Sj^stem, and at the same time, by a presentiment, misunderstood, of the true theory of rent. (§ 150 ft'.). Of the six classes of labor mentioned above (§ 38), those only are called productive which increase the quantity of raw material useful for human ends. All the other classes, it matters not how useful, are called sterile, salaried, because they draw their income only from the superabundance of land-owners and the workers of the soil. Tradesmen, in the narrower sense of the term, produce only a change in the form of the material, the higher value of which depends on the quantity of other mate- rial consumed for the purposes of the tradesman's labor. If any of this material is saved, the value of their products sinks, although to the advantage of the economy of the whole nation. In any case, industry could create no wealth, but only make existing wealth more lasting. It might, so to speak, ac- cumulate the value of the quantity of food consumed during the building of a house in the house itself ^ ^nesnay, Dialogue sur les Travaux des Artisans, 210 ft"; S89 ed Daire; Turgot, Sur la Formation etc., § 8; Dtcpont', Correspondence avec J. B. Say, 400, ed. Daire. B. Franklin^ Letter to Dr. Evans (1768), and Positions Con- cerning National Wealth (1769), Works ed. Sparks, VII and II. Similarlj even Aristotle^ Oec, I, 2, says, that commerce, wage-labor and war win from men, with or without their will ; but that only agriculture obtains booty fro:n nature. And so Cicero says of merchants : nihil projiciunt, nisi admodum mentiantur. De Off., I, 42. The same view seems to have prevailed during the middle ages. See Thotn. Aquin., De Rebus publicis, II, 3, 5 seq. Luther entertained a like notion (Vom Kaufhandel und Wucher, 1524), He prefers agriculture to the trades. Seethe Irmischer edition of his works, XXII, 284; XXXVI, 172; LXI, 352. C<2/w« considered commerce both useful and hon- orable ; so that ex ipsius mercatoris diligentia atque indiistria, its profit may be greater than that of agi-iculture. (0pp. ed. Amstelod, 1664, IX, 223.) Asgill, Sec. XLIX.] CRITICAL HISTORY. 171 But if tradesmen really earned, in the value of their pro- ducts, only what they had consumed during their labor, it would be difficult for them to find employers to provide them with capital. Everyone will acknowledge, that a Thorwaldsen and an ordinary stone-cutter, with the same block of marble, the same implements, the same food, would necessarily, after the same time, turn out exceedingly different values.^ And, even in the case that industry should add to the raw^ material only precisely the same amount of value as had been consumed by the workmen, can it be said that the work ceases to be pro- ductive simpl}" because it is consumed by the Avorkmen them- selves? If that were so, agriculture even, would, in most countries with a low civilization, be unproductive.^ Commerce, according to the theory of the Physiocrates, only transfers already existing wealth from one hand to an- other. What the merchants gain by it is at the cost of the nation. Hence, it is desirable that this loss should be as Several Assertions proved in order to create another Species of Money than Gold (1691): "what we call commodities is nothing but land severed from the soil ; man deals in nothing but earth." Concerning Cantillou., compare § 47, note 4. How violent an innovation the Physiocratic theory was in its time may be inferred from what Zincke writes in the Leipzig Sammlungen, X, 551 ff. (1753), p. 20, XIII, S61. ^ ^ncsnay, 1. c, 1S9, does not ignore that many workmen earn more than the cost of their necessary subsistence; but he claimed that this was a result of a natural or legal monopoly of the same. The dearer labor was, the more productive it seemed. Per contra, see Dohm on the Physiocratic system, in the Deutsch. Museum, 177S, II, 313 ff. 2 Gournay (comi^are Turgot^ Eloge de G., in Guillaumin's edition, I, 266, 271 if.), as well as Raynal^ Histoire des Indes, vol. X, Livre 19, spite of the similarity of their and Quesnay's views, acknowledged on this account, the productiveness of industry. For some remarkable examples illustrative of how it may increase the value in exchange of raw material, see the anony- mous work. Paying Old Debts without New Taxes, London, 1723. See also Algaroiti (ph. 1794), 318, in 0«/(P^/, Economisti classic! italiani, Parte moder- na, I. Thus a cwt. of coarse cast iron is converted, in a Berlin manufactory, into 88,440 shirt buttons worth 6^^ silver groschens each. Hence the value is raised from 1-2 thalers to 19,653 thalers. The increase of the value in use by industrial labor is self-evident. 172 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. II. small as possible. Hence sterility!^ But, the more important branches of business, especially wholesale trade, are connected with a transportation of goods ( Verri), either from one place or from one period of time, into another. Here the genuine merchant speculates essentially on the difference of the values in use which are afterwards greater than before.^ The ice shipped yearly from Boston to tropical lands met a much more urgent and wide-spread want there than it would if it had remained at home. And thus the storage of grain in large quantities after a bountiful harvest withdraws, indeed, an object of enjoyment from the comsumption of the people ; but its sale, after a bad harvest, undoubtedly increases their enjoyment in a much greater degree than it was before dimin- ished. Besides, the condition of both parties to the contract is usually improved in all normal trade. {Condillac.y No one parts with exchangeable goods unless they are of less use to him than the ones he receives in return."^ And so, the value in use of a nation's resources is really increased by commerce. To the other attributes of goods it adds one of the principal condi- tions of all use, accessibility {Ktidler), with which it either newly endows them, or which it increases in degree. To this end, the merchant makes use of tools, just as the manufacturer ^ ^testiay, Dialogue surle Commerce. ^ Recognized very early by Ad. Contzen, Politicorum, Lib. VIII, C. lo (i629)._ ^This did not escape the notice of Frederick II. Von Raumer, Hohenstau- fen, III, 535.. " Condillac acknowledges the productive power both of industry and of commerce ; and that the service rendered by the state is at least economically indispensable. (Le Commerce et le Gouvernment, 1776, 1, 6, 7, 10.) Beccaria, Economia pubblica (1769 ff.), IV, 4, 24. Boisgtnllchert (ob. 1714), Sur la Nature des Richesses, illustrated the utility of commerce by the picture of a number of men bound to pillars, one hundred steps apart, one with a superabundance of food but naked, a second with a superabundance of fuel, a third with a superabundance of clothing etc. ; all of whom perish, because unable to ex- change their respective surpluses with one another. According to Lotz^ Re- vision, I, 217, "buying dear," apart from real fraud, means only a decrease of possibCe gain. Sec. L.] critical HISTORY. 173 does. What spinning-wheels, looms and workshops are to the latter, ships, warehouses, cranes etc., are to the former. If production be not complete until the thing produced is made fit for its last end, consumption, commerce may be looked up- on as the last link in the chain of productive labor. It, at the same time, constitutes a series of intermediate links ; as with- out it no division of labor is possible, and without a division of labor, no higher economic productiveness.^ How com- merce may increase the value in exchange of goods, and with- out in any way injuring the purchaser, needs no further illus- tration.^ SECTION L. THE SAME SUBJECT CONTINUED. Even Adam Smith called services, in the narrower sense of the term (§ 3), the grave and important ones of the statesman, clergyman and physician, as well as the " frivolous " ones of the opera singer, ballet-dancer and buffoon, unproductive. The labor of none of these can be fixed or incorporated in any ^Verri, Meditazioni, XXIV, instead of calling the merchant productive, calls him a mediator between producers and consumers. It would be just as reasonable to call the shoemaker a mediator between the production and consumption of leather; or the cloth merchant, who cuts the material froin the piece, an assistant preparatory to the tailor. The labor of commerce is especially like that of the fisherman or the turf digger, because they produce only in so far as they transfer goods from inaccessible to accessible places. See, however. Ran, Lehrbuch, I, § 103. See the demonstration of the pro- ductive power of commerce in general, as well as of what is, by way of pref- erence, called industry, in Ad. SmitJi, W. of N., IV, ch. 9. A much more fundamental refutation of the Physiocratic Principle is to be found in Jacob^ N. CEk., 204 flf. 9 In 1S43, about 55,000 tons of ice were shipped from Boston. Less than 25 cents, per ton was paid for the ice in the first instance. When packed on board ship, it was worth $2.55 per ton. The ultimate sale brought $3,575,- 000. Ausland, 1S44, No. 27S. The ancients were acquainted with a similar production of ice, the value in exchange of which might be almost entirely reduced to the labor of commerce. See AV/^(7///., Memor., II, 1,30; Athen. Ill, 97; Proverbs of Solomon, 25, 13. 174: PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. II. particular object. ^ ^ But how strange it is that the labor of a violin-maker is called productive, while that of the violin- player is called unproductive; altliough the product of the former has no other object than to be played on by the latter? {Garnicr.) Is it not strange that the hog-raiser should be called productive, and the educator of man unproductive {List); the apothecary, who prepares a salve which alleviates for the moment, productive, the physician, unproductive, spite of the fact that his prescription in relation to diet, or his surgi- cal operation, may radically cure the severest disease? If the productiveness of an employment of the factors of production be made to depend on whether it is attended by a material result, no one will deny that the labor of the plow- man, for instance, is productive ; and no one, of Adam Smith's school, at least, that that of the clerk, who orders the raw material for the owner of the manufactory, is. They have participated indirectly in the production. But, has not the servant of the state, who protects the property of its citizens, or the physician, who preserves the health of the producer, an equally mediate but indispensable share in it? The field- guard who keeps the crows away, every one calls productive ; why, not, then, the soldier, who keeps away a far worse ' W. of N., ch. 3. See, however, Gartner's French translation of Ad. Smith, Pr^f. p. IX and V, note 20. Similar!}^, MaUJius, Principles, ch. i, Lect. 21. Definitions, ch. 7, 10. "^ Bacon had already said of the nobility, clergy and literateurs : sor/z' m- fiiblicce nihil addtint (Serm., 15, 29); in opposition to which, Hobbes justly re- marks, that even human labor may, like other things, be exchanged against goods of all sorts. (Leviathan, 24.) In the work, Discourse of Trade, Coyn and Credit, p. 44 flf., and p. 156, the absolute necessity of "head-work" as well as bodily labor, is conceded ; but it is insisted that physicians, clergymen and jurists can never enrich a country, and that a relatively large number of them would even conduce to national poverty. (See Rosc/icr, Geschichte der englischen Volkswirthschaftslehre, 138.) David Hume considers merchants as productive, but says that a doctor or lawyer can grow rich only at the ex- pense of some one else. (Discourses, No. 4, On Interest.) Ferguson very cleverly compares such a valuation of national wealth to that of a miser. Hist, of Civil Society, VI. I. Sec. L.] critical HISTORY. 175 enemy from the whole land? {JMcCiilIocJi^ But the entire division of business into two branches, the one directly, and the other indirectly productive, can be defended only as re- spects certain kinds of goods. {Sckniitthcnncr^ The labor of the judge, for instance, is only indirectly productive in the manufacture of shoes, inasmuch as he guarantees the payment of the shoemaker's account. On the other hand, the shoe- maker contributes only very indirectly to the general security which the law affords, by protecting the judge's foot.^ Nor can any effectual inferiority of service be claimed, simply because the productive power of one branch of busi- ness is, measured by the duration of its results, greater than another.* What is more perishable than a loaf of bread bought for dinner? What more imperishable than the mon- luncntiim mx pcrcmiius of a Horace ? The labor expended on persons and on relations ( Verhaltnisseti) is, both as to the ex- 3 Similarly Lauderdale, Inquiry, 355; Z,o/^, Handbuch der Staatswirth- schaft, I, § 39, and Ran, Lehrbuch I, § 195, concede only indirect productive- ness to commerce. It may be shown, in a great many instances, that such productiveness exists side^by side with direct productiveness, on account of the thousand ways in which all economic threads are interwoven with one another. Thus Paley remarks in his work on the Principles of Morals and Politics, that a tobacco manufacturer even may contribute indirectly to the cultivation of grain ; an actor, to industry etc. •*Thus Sismondi, Nouveaux Principes, II, ch. i, and, earlier, Mcngotti Col- bertismo, 317. (Cust.) See, on the other hand, Hermann, Staatsw. Unter- suchungen, 34 ft'. Even J. B. Say does no manner of justice, in this respect, to personal services. He speaks oi produits qui ne s'attachent d, rien qui s'dvan- ouissent cb mdsure qiCils naisscnt, qu'il est impossible d'accuinuler, qui ri'ajoutent rei7i ci la richesse nationalc. Compare Catechisme (3d ed.) 52 ff., 174 ft". On the other hand Dunoyer, Libert^ du Travail, L. V., remarks that here labor and its result are made to change places; the former like all labor is very perishable, the latter as lasting as in the case of other kinds of labor. In the one case the utility is fixed in things, in the other in persons. Ad. MUller, Elemente der Staatskunst passim, calls special attention to how the kinds of labor, called unproductive by Adam Smii/i, preserve the state, and in that way, all individual exchangeable goods. Similarly, Storch, Handbuch, I, 347 ; Steinleiu, Handbuch, I, 460. Lauderdale (443), however, is correct when he says, that the continued duration of the product of labor depends, usually, more on the caprice of consumers than on the nature of the labor. 17G PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. II tent and duration of its results, much less capable of being estimated than any other; but its capacity of accumulation and its power of propagation are greater than any other. It is in the domain of the "'immaterial," that man is most "cre- ative." {Lticdcr.) ^ Finally, neither should the greater indis- pensablenss of the more material branches of business be too generally asserted. Agriculture produces grain which is in- dispensable, and tobacco which is not; industry, cloth, as well as lace; commerce draws from the same part of the world rhu- barb and edible bird's-nests ; and so, to services belong the in- dispensable ones of the educator and judge, as well as those of the rope-dancer and bear-leader, which can be dispensed wath.® Indeed, the dividing line between material and intel- lectual production cannot, by any means, be closely drawn.' SECTION LI. • THE SAME SUBJECT CONTINUED. The greater number of recent writers^ have, therefore, come to be of the opinion that every useful business which minis- 5 Gamier calls attention to the fact, that there is a great quantity of mate- rial products, such as laces, perfumes etc., that can scarcely be ever used in further production, and, generally speaking, one's resources for the most part are not kept in lasting goods, but are preserved by the change of technic forms in production. Hermann,!, Aufli., 115. f When ScJion, Nat. ffikonomie, 33, ridicules the idea of the productive- ness of personal services, by citing the instance of prostitution carried on as a trade, he forgets that many material goods also may conduce to the moral damage of the purchaser of them. It is said that there are in France 3,500 retailers and colporteurs of immoral Avritings and pictures, who sell yearly nine million numbers or pieces, at a cost of six million francs ! (Moniteur, 9 Avril, 1S53.) ' Compare Schafflc, Theorie der ausschliessenden Absatzverhaltnise, 1867, 135. seq. 1 Many of the socialists take a retrograde step in this respect, in as much as they consider only manual labor productive. Fourier's school particu- larly, declaim passionately against the unproductiveness of commerce and of most personal services. Compare V. Considdrant, Destin^e sociale, 1S51, 1,44. Sec. LL] CRITICAL HISTORY. 177 ters to the whole people's requirement of external goods pos- sesses economic productiveness.^ But it makes a great dit- ference to science, whether a view is considered true because no one has suggested a doubt of its correctness, or because all doubts as to its truth have been triumphantly removed. ' Besides the above, see Gioja, N. Prospetto, I, 246 ff. ; Scialoja, 42 ; y. B. Say, Traite, I, ch. 2; Huf eland, N. Grundlegung, I, 42, 54; Gr. Sodcn, Nat. GEkonomie, I, 142 ff. Hermann, St. Untersuchungen, 20 ft", distinguishes three politico-economical points of view; that of the producer, that of the consumer, and that of the whole nation's economy. The producer calls his labor productive, in case he receives back his outlay of capital with the rate of profit usual in the trade of the country. To this point of view, there- fore, every service which is paid for, according to wish, seems productive. On the other hand, the consumer ascribes productiveness to all those kinds of labor the achievements of which he may use, and which he can obtain at a convenient price. Whenever, therefore, he pays for a service voluntarily, he acknowledges its productiveness. Lastly, from a national-economical point of view, all labor is considered productive which increases the quan- tity of goods exposed for sale in the market; and this, personal services do. The technic productiveness, which depends on the execution of the technic ideas floating before the mind of the workman, must be distinguished from this economic productiveness. It is possible that, technically labor may be very productive, and yet cause economic loss; for instance, the fine arts and the so-called master pieces of the trades! See Seneca, De Benef, II, 33. H. (33) furnishes a very good refutation of the doctrine that a great deal depends on whether the labor has been paid from capital or from income. Eiselen, Volkswirthschaft (1843), 27 ff, remarks, that the laborer, for instance, who grows corn, must besides look after his health and the preservation of his house; this is a part of his necessary aggregate labor. "Why, then, should it be called unproductive when such secondary labor is performed by particu- lar persons.'' Otherwise the farmer would have no time whatever for his principal business! Edinburg Review, 1S04, IV, 343 ff.; Wakefield, An Essay upon Political Economy, 1804, who is concerned mainly with the theory of the productiveness of labor. L. Lauderdale says, that when the nation's wealth is estimated according to its value in use, all useful labor is productive ; and that when estimated according to its value in exchange, all labor that is paid is productive. (Inquiry, ch. 3.) Stein (Lehrbuch, 68; Tiib. Zeitschr., iS68, 230) conditions the notion of productiveness by the presence of a superfluity of values. But, it may be asked, does a family, which does no more than support itself, labor unproductively .? (Compare, however, § 30.) J. S. Mill took a surprisingly retrograde step in the doc- trine on this point, in his Principles, I, ch. 3. Compare his Essays on some Vol. I. — 12 178 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. II SECTION LII. IDEA OF PRODUCTIVENESS. It should never be lost sight of, that the public economy of a people should be considei-ed an organism, which, when its growth is healthy, always develops more varied organs, but always in a due proportion, which are not only carried by the body, but also in turn serve to carry it. The aggregate of the wants of the entire public economy etc., is satisfied by the aggregate activity of the people. Every individual who em- ploys his lands, labor or capital for the whole, receives his share of the aggregate produce, whether he contributed or not to the creation of the kind of produce in which he is paid. Thus, in a pin-manufactory, the workman who is occupied solely in making the heads of pins is not paid in pins or pin- heads, but in a part of the aggregate result of the manufac- ture, in money. Every department of business, therefore, for the achievements of which there is a rational demand, and which are remunerated in proportion to their deserts, has labored productively. It is unproductive only when no one will need what it has brought forth, or when no one will pay for it; but, in this case, what is true of the writer without readers — that he is unproductive — and of the singer with- out hearers, is equally true of the peasant whose corn rots in his granary, because he can find no sale for it.^ unsettled Questions of Political Economy, No. 3. A still more surprising exaggeration in de Augustinis Instituzzioni di Economia sociale (Napolii S37), ivho goes so far as to call a person guilty of arson a productive person be- cause he has produced for himself " the pleasure of destruction " ! More recently, von Mangoldt distinguishes between economic labor and the labor of culture : the latter is incorporated into the man himself, the former one employed on the external world, in order to transform it in a way corres- ponding to human wants. Viewed from the stand-point of Political Econ- omy, the latter only is productive. (Volkswirthschaftslehre, 1S65, 26 ff.) ' We might, indeed, compare original production, that which preceded all other, to eating; the trades, to digestion; commerce, to the movements of the Sec. LIII.] CRITICAL HISTORY 179 SECTION LIII. THE SAME SUBJECT CONTINUED. In this matter, again, there is an important difference to be observed between private or individual economy and econ- omy in its widest sense, in the sense of a world-economy. The productiveness of labor is estimated in the case of the for- mer, according to the value in "exchange of its result; in the case of the latter, according to its value in use. There is a great number of employments which are very remunerative to private individuals, but which are entirely unproductive, and even injurious, so far as mankind is concerned; for the reason that they take from others as much as, or even more than they procure to those engaged in them. Here belong, besides formal crimes against property, games of chance,^ usurious speculations (§113) and measures taken to entice cus- tomers away from other competitors. Again, scientific ex- periments, means of communication etc., may be entirely un- productive in the individual economy of the undertaker, and yet be of more profit to mankind in general, than they have several members of the body; personal services to inspiration, and yet all are equally necessary to the hfe of the body! Thus, GajniUi com- pares agriculture to the root of a tree of which the service rendered by the state is the top. The growth of tlie latter conti'ibutes, as well as that of the former, to the nutrition of the ^J.•hole, and is far removed from exhausting the tree. Theorie de 1' E. P., II, 46 if. '^Natural pro- duction" would, indeed, accomplish very little without the legal protec- tion guarantied by the state, or witliout the tools furnished by industry etc. But it is, besides, in most instances, a distortion of the truth to speak ot productive and unproductive men or classes of men. These expressions are proper only when applied to individual kinds of labor. See Murkard^ Ideen iiber Nat. CEk., SS ft'. Persons seriously ill are temporarily unproductive, and children who die early, are unproductive for their Avhole life. 1 Not, however, in the case in which the loser estimates the pleasure of the play higher than the loss. ISO PRODUDTION OF GOODS. [B. 1, Ch. II. cost the former.^ In this respect the nation's economy holds a middle place between individual economy and the world's economy.^ Strictly speaking, only those employments should be called productive which increase the world's resources. Hence, the work of government should be called so, only in so far as its expenses are covered by the taxes paid willingly by the more reasonable portion of the citizens ; and also only in so far as its work is really necessary to the attainment of its end.'* The productiveness of an employment supposes, also, that it is not carried on at the cost of other employments which it is more difficult to do without. In a healthy nation we may, in this matter, rely, to a certain extent, on the judg- ment of public opinion, which knows how to appreciate, at their just value, professional gamblers, pettifoggers and the luxury of soldiers. The greater, freer and more cultivated a nation is, the more probable is it that the productiveness of private economy is also national-economical productiveness, and that national-economical productiveness is world-econom- ical productiveness.^ SECTION LIV. IMPORTANCE OF A DUE PROPORTION IN THE DIFFERENT BRANCHES OF PRODUCTIVENESS. Much always depends on the due proportion of the differ- ent branches of productiveness to one another. Thus, Spain, for instance, has remained poor under the most advantageous 2 y. B. Say, Traite, I. ch. i. ^v. Cancrin, CEkonomie der menschlichen Gesellschaften, 1S45, 10, speaks, in this case, of privative production. Among the Socialists, Bazard's ex- pression V exploitation de Vkomine far Vhovime, has found loud echo; instead of which only V exploitation du globe far Vhoinme should be allowed to obtain. (Exposition de la Doctrine de St. Simon, 24.) But von Schroder had already- warned the world of " imagined food " which led only to idleness. (F. Schatz- und Rentkammer, 191, 363.) ■» Therefore, there should not be too many nor too highly salaried offices. See Storch, Nationaleinkommen, 33 ff. 5 See V. Mangoldt, Volkswirthschaftslehre, 29 ff. Sec. LIV.J DUE PROPORTION. 181 circumstances in the world,^ because it allowed a dispropor- tionate preponderance of personal services. The character of the Spanish people has always given them a leaning towards aristocratic pride and economic idleness. Tradesmen, in that country, sought, as a rule, to amass merely enough to enable them to live on the interest of their capital; after which they, by way of preference, removed it into some other province, where they might be considered as among the nobility; or they withdrew into a monastery. Even in 1781, the Madrid Academy thought it incumbent on it to propose a prize for the best essay in support of the thesis : " The useful trades in no w^ay detract from personal honor." ^ During the century in which the country was in its greatest glory, the whole people were bent on being to all Europe what nobles, officers and offi- cials are to a single nation. " Whoever wishes to make his fortune," said Cervantes, " let him seek the church, the sea (i. e., go as an adventurer to America) or the king's palace." Un- der Philip III., there were in Spain nine hundred and eighty- eight nunneries, and thirty-two thousand mendicant friars. The number of monasteries trebled between 1574 and 1624, and the number of monks increased in a yet greater ratio. A great many of its manufactories, much of its commerce, and not a few of its most important farms were controlled by foreign- ers, especially by Italians. There were, it seems, in 1610, one hundred and sixty thousand foreign tradesmen living in Cas- tile. In 1787, there were still 188,625 priests, monks, nuns, etc.; 280,092 servants; 480,589 nobles; 964,571 day labor- ers; 987,187 peasants; 310,739 mechanics and manufacturers; * Remained, and not become, poor, as is generally supposed ; for the enorm- ous wealth of Spain, under Ferdinand and Isabella, as well as during the early period of Charles V. is only a. fable convcnue. Charles V. said : France has a superabundance of everything, and Spain is in want of everything. See also the embassy report of Navagero (1526), Viaggio fatto in Spagna e in Francia (Venct., 1563), and Rankc, Fiirsten und Vdlker, I, 393 ff. 2 The prize was won by Arrcta dc Moiitcseguro. The author of the history of Portuguese Asia, translated by Stevens, is of opinion (III, ch. 6), that commerce is not a proper subject for serious history to treat. 182 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. II. 34,339 merchants.^ As a counterpart to this, the United States had, in 1840, about 77.5 per cent, of its population engaged in agriculture, 16.8 in manufactures and mining, 4.2 in ship- ping and commerce, 1.3 in the learned professions.^ 2 There is a very fine description, of this spirit in Clcuard, Epist. I, ad Lat- omum (1535 ff.) Compare Jovellanos^ in Laborde, Itineraire descriptif, IV, 176. Toxvnsend^ Journey throvigh Spain, II, 207, 117. ^kc^-/c, History of Civilization, II, ch, I. Tlie census of 17SS gave the number of priests and monks, soldiers, mariners, nobles, lawyers, tax-gatherers, authors, students and domestics, at 1,221,000, in a total of 3,800,000 men; from -which number tliere was a multitude of beggars, vagrants etc. to be deducted. Laborde, Itineraire, II, 32 ff. The seventeen universities and the numberless small Latin schools, with their gratuitous instruction, and their many scholarships, misled a disproportionately large number to engage in study. At the begin- ning of this century, there were at least 200,000 priests, nuns (Geistliche), etc., in a population of from three to three and a half millions only. (Ebe- ling, Erdbeschreibung von Portugal, 66.) Senior shows that the poverty of the Osman is caused by too many state employees, tax-farmers and retail merchants. (Journal kept in Turkey and Greece, 1S57-58.) Thus, also, y. Tucker, Four Tracts, 1774, 18, conti-asts men engaged in industry with rich idlers, Avhose increase,, possibly by immigration, w'ould make the people a nation of "gentlemen and ladies, footmen, grooms, laundresses etc." Schmitthcncr, N. CEk., 656, calls a condition such as that of Spain, " national- economical phthisis." 4 Tucker, Progi-ess of the U. S., 137. The following data also will serve for a comparison: In Belgium, in 1856, it was estimated that, leaving persons sans professio7i out of consideration, 45.6 per cent, were agriculturists, 37.2 in- dustrials, 6.7 in commerce, 2.8 in the liberal professions, \.i^ force fiibliquc, 2.1 ■propridtaires, rentiers, pensionnes, 3.7 domesticity. In Prussia, in 1871, of the entire male population, 28.6 per cent, were engaged in agi-iculture, forest-cul- ture, hunting and fishing : 32.3 per cent, in mining, industiy, building, and in founderies: 8.56 in trade and commerce; 20.3 in personal services and handi- work not belonging to any of the groups above mentioned ; 2.3 in the army and navy; 3.7 in other callings; 2.7 were renters, pensioners, and persons who lived by selling or renting houses, reserving lodgings for themselves there- in, and persons who gave no account of their calling. (Preuss. statisc. Zeitschr., 1875, 32. ff.) It is, however, surprising that EttgcVs Amtl.Jahrbuch, III, 1867, gives only 48 per cent, as belonging to the first category, and 25 to the second. In the kingdom of Saxony in 1861, 25.1 per cent, of the population were agriculturists and foresters; 56.1 were engaged in industry; 7.7 in trade and commerce ; 6.8 in art, science, the service of the state and of private per- sons; while 4.1 percent were Avithout any particular calling, or returned none. Bavaria, in 1S52, had 67.9 per cent, of its population engaged in agi-iculture. Sec. LIV.] DUE PROPORTION. 183 We might be tempted, in view of this contrast, to return once more to the unproductiveness of personal services. It is not, however, the direction given to the forces of production, but the squandering of them, that is injurious. When the Magyar, through mere vanity, drives a yoke of from four to six horses where two are enough; or when, as in 183 1, Irish agriculture employed 1,131,715 workmen to produce a value of thirty-six million pounds sterling, while that of Great Britain ^ produced one hundred and fifty millions a year, and employed only 1,055,982 workmen, these causes are as sure to impoverish the country, as the waste of the Spaniards in sup- porting such an army of clergy and servants. Of course, the temptation to waste wealth on parks is greater than to waste it in vegetable gardens! The probability that a man will ruin himself by keeping too many servants is greater than that he 22.7 in the trades and in manufactures ; 5.5 per cent., persons living on the interest of their money, and by performing the higher class of personal ser- vices; 1.9 in the army; and 2 per cent, of listed poor. In Hermann^ Beitriige 2ur Statistik des Konigreichs Bayern. In France, according to the official reports, there -were: 1851 1S66 AgricuUeurs 61.46 per cent. 51.49 per cent. Industricls et commergants 25.95 " 32-78 " Professions libirales 9.73 " 9.4S " To which it must be added, that, in 1S51, there were 2.86 sans profession on dont Ics frofessions 7i'ont fu ctre constat ics; and that, in 1866, on the other hand, there were 2.87 per cent, in frofessions se rattachant d V agriculture^ iit- dustrie et commerce. (Legoyt.) In England and Wales, leaving the domestic class out of consideration (women without an independent means of employ- ment, school children, servant girls etc.), and also the "indefinite class," there were, in i86i, 25.3 per cent, of the population engaged in agricultural pursuits ; 60.7 in industrial ; 7.8 in commercial ; and 6.06 in professional pur- suits. In Italy, omitting housewives, children and infirm persons, there were, in 1862, 57.4 per cent, of the population engaged in agriculture; 22.9 in industrial pursuits ; 4 in commerce ; and 3.9 per cent, in the army and iii the liberal professions. (Annali univ. di Statistica, Febbr., 1866.) On Hol- land, in the middle of the 17th century, see J. de Wit, Memoires, 34 seq. 8 Csaflovics, Gemalde von Ungarn II, i. Torrens, The Budget: On com- mercial and colonial Policy, 106 ff. 184 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. II. will do the same by employing too many operatives.^ ' And all the more, as there are many and especially important ser- vices which regulate their own remuneration: thus, as a rule, those of the statesman, those of the military in times of war, and those of the priest in the age of superstition.^ SECTION LV. THE DEGREE OF PRODUCTIVENESS. Concerning the degree of productiveness, it may be re- marked that that application of the factors of production is most productive, which, with the least expenditure of means, satisfies the greatest want in the economy of a people. Here, there is a continual change, corresponding precisely to the change in wants and faculties. After a bad harvest, for in- stance, the labor which procures grain from foreign countries or the supplies of former years, is most productive; and, after an earthquake which has destroyed a large city, the labor of the builder. Agriculture is, as a rule, the more productive * Precisely as there are more people ruined by spirituous liquors than by bread. Time thieving is also more frequent among servants. There is scarcely anything in agriculture analogous to the lazzaroni who wait all day to help a gondola to land, to unload a coach, etc. There is is more in the chase, in the fisheries, or in the cattle raising. 'Compare Basiiat, Harmonies economiques, ch. 17. Hence ^zVwwwif/ ac- counts it one of the chief merits of the constitutional state, that in it, the fof Illation gardienne does not regulate its own remuneration. (N. P., 1, 144.) Saint Sinw7t, indeed, says that the French members of the Chambre, in his time, drew a revenue from the state, three times as large as from their own resources, and were, therefore, deeply interested in increasing the budget. (Vues sur la Propriete et la Legislation, iSiS.) I would call attention also to the national over-estimation and over-crowding of learned callings from which Germany suffered, even as far back as the time of Louis XIV. (v. Schroder, Fiirstl. Schatz-und Rentkammer, 302 fF.) ; to the disproportionate number of keepers of public houses, which is related to the system of popu- lar assemblies, and is a regular attendant upon Democracy (Bro?iner, Der C. Aargau, I, 451.) Taxation-legislation may here become a good means of popular education. Sec. LV.] DEGREE OF PRODUCTIVENESS. 185 labor of undeveloped nations, and industry of highly developed nations.^ ~ ' This was recognized very early by Grcgor. Tolsan, 1, c. Ad. Muller, Elc- mente, II, 255. Sto)-ch, Handbuch, II, 229 ff. (ScJileiermacJicr., Christ. Sitte, 66S.) A. Smith, W. of N., II, ch. 5, ascribed greater productiveness to agri- cultural than to industrial labor; in the former case, not only human labor ■was put in operation, but the forces of nature were compelled to cooperate with them. Similarly, Afalikus, Additions (1817) to the Essay on the Princi- ple of Population, B. Ill, ch. 8-12. Principles of P. E., 217 ff. Both thus explain the rent of land, and so far as products, which have only value in exchange are concerned, they are right. Hence it is all the more surpris- ing that Carey, the zealous advocate of a protective tariff and opponent ot rent, comes back in this to Adam Smith. Principles of Social Science, 1858, II, 35, and passim. Compare also y. B.Say, Traite, II, ch. 8; Sismondi, N. P., II, ch. 5. For the best refutation of this view, see Jiicardo, Principles, ch. 2,3. Does not all labor put the force of nature in operation.'' Ad of era nihil aliiid fotest lioino^ quam ut corpora naturalia admoveat, rcliqua natura in- tus transigit. (Bacon.) Similarly, Ferr/, Meditazioni, III, i. An expression escapes even Ricardo himself (ch. 7), to the effect, that capitalists are the producing class. ' ^ Relying on very superficial statistics of England and France, Ganilh ad- vocates a theory of the productive forces of the several branches of economy the very reverse of Adam Smiih^s. He places foreign trade first; then follow wholesale trade, industry and agriculture. (Theorie, I, 240 seq.) 186 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. III. CHAPTEB III. THE ORGANIZATION OF LABOR. SECTION LVI. DEVELOPMENT OF THE DIVISION OF LABOR. The larger a tree grows to be, the more boughs and branches does it put forth. The more perfect any species of animal is, the more does it stand in need of a special organ for each special purpose. And thus the division of labor has de- veloped and kept pace with the development of human society. While Crusoe was obliged to provide for all his wants by his own labor, we find that in the wildest Indian family the male is employed in war, the chase, in fishing, in the manufacture of arms and boats, and in the transportation of the latter during long marches ; the female, on the other hand, in the prepara- tion of food, in the hewing of wood, the curing of skins, the sewing of clothes, in the building and preservation of the wig- wam, the care of children, and the carriage of baggage when on the march.^ These occupations, at first entirely domestic, ^ Ausland, 1846, No. 54. Expressions still used in Europe, such as Spin- delmagen (spindle-relation), Kunkellehen (apron-string-hold) etc., for instance, suggest this most ancient and purely family division of labor. The lower classes of the population, even in the most civilized countries, are wont to preserve some of the peculiar customs of very primitive times. Hence it is that among proletarians, the division of labor between males and females is still very small. The employments usual at different stages of life among men, and the costumes worn by them are much more uniform than among the higher classes. See Richly Die Familie, 1S55, passim. Sec. LVII.] DIVISION OF LABOR. 187 became, by degrees, separate industries, which are constantly subject to turther subdivision.^ SECTION LVIL DEVELOPMENT OF THE DIVISION OF LABOR.— ITS EXTENT AT DIFFERENT PERIODS. In the middle age of a people, the division of labor is not carried to any great extent. The courtiers of King Frotho III. advised him to marry, " since otherwise his majesty's rag- ged linen would never be mended." Saint Dunstan, although he occupied a high position in politics and in the Church, was an excellent blacksmith, bell-founder and designer of ladies' robes. Chriemhild in the Nibelungenlied was an industri- ous and skillful milliner. In the corresponding period of Gre- cian and Roman history, we find Penelope and Lucretia at the loom, Nausicaa, a laundress, the daughter of the king of the Lestrigons, fetching water from the spring, Odysseus, a carpenter, a queen of Macedonia as a cook, and finally the distaff" of Tanaquil.^ In the highlands of Scotland, in 1797, there were a great many peasants all of whose clothing was home-made, with the exception of their caps; nothing coming from abroad except the tailor, his needles and iron tools gen- erally. But the peasant himself was the weaver, fuller, dyer, tanner, shoemaker etc. of his own family:- every man jack of aU trades.^ ^ As Dani'zvarcK shows, the jus civile of the earhest Roman time is based on the condition of isolated labor, the later y«5 gentium^ on the division of labor. N. CEk. und Jurisprudenz, 1857, Heft. I. 1 Saxo Gramm., Hist. Dan. V, 101. Turna; Hist, of the A. Saxons B. VII, ch. II. Nibel., 351 if. There is a French proverb: die temps que la rcitic Berthe filait. Queen Bertha was a mythic daughter of Charlemagne. It may be that the character meant is the old German spinning gooddess Berchta. Concerning the daughter of Otto the Great, see DitJimar, Merseb. IL /f<>;«^;',Od.V, 31 ff.; X, 106; XXIII, iSpff. I/erodot., YUI, i^'j. Livy, 1,57- 2 Edefi, State of the Poor I, 558 ff. In the interior of Peru, the priest is 1S8 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. Ill In present England, on the other hand, the manufacture of watches is divided into one hundred and two branches which have to be specially learned; only the so-called "watch-finisher" carries on other branches besides. In Wolverhampton, it may happen that a man, emplo3'ed in the manufacture of keys, may not be able to make a whole key after an apprenticeship of ten years, for the reason that during all that time he may have been engaged only in filing.* In English agriculture there are, according to German notions, very few complete wholes. A weU-marked distinction exists there between the cultivators of corn and breeders of cattle; and the latter are again divided into breeders of young cattle, into fat- teners of cattle etc. Its industries are, in large part, sepa- rated into provinces. Thus, linen manufactures are confined almost exclusively to Leeds and Dundee, woolen manu- factures, to Leeds, ^ cotton manufactures, to Manchester, also usually a shop-keeper (Poppig^ Reise, II, 365) ; in Canada, as in many of the villages of the Alps which are not often visited, a hotel keeper. In coun- tries with an unadvanced civilization, the little division of labor that exists is also very awkwardly regulated. Thus in Russia, weak children are very frequently put to work on farms, while powerful men are found in the city oft'ering all kinds of eatables and the pictures of saints for sale. (StorcJi, Gemalde des russischen Reichs II, 364. v. Haxthausen, Studien I, 335.) ^ Babhage, Economy of Machinery, 1S33, 201. L. Faucher^ Angleterre II, Ch. '■'■la Ville des Serruriersr The industrial statistics of Paris, furnished \>y H. Say in 1S47 and 1S4S, show that in that city alone there are 325 different branches of indusby, 17 of which are concerned with the production of food; 21 with building; 32 with the manufacture of furniture; 21 with that of clothing; 36 with that of thread and tissues; 7 with skins and leathers; 14 with vehicles, saddlery, and military equipment; 33 with chemicals and pottery; 33 with working in metal, glass etc.; 35 in that of the precious metals and jewels; 27 with printing, engraving and paper; 15 with that of wooden-ware and wicker- ware ; 34 with articles de Paris. Journal des Economistes, Janv., 1853, 107. According to the industrial almanac of Birmingham, there are in that city manufacturers of buttons in gold, silver, metal, mother-of-pearl etc; manufacturers of hammers, ink-stands, coffin- nails, dog-collars, tooth-picks, stirrups, fish-hooks, spurs, pack-needles etc. ^ And so with the subdivisions. Flannel is manufactured almost exclu- sively in Halifax, woolen blankets between Leeds and Huddersfield etc. ^The same division of labor was developed among the Dutch in the 17th Sec. LVIII.] ADVANTAGES. 189 and Glagow, pottery to Staftbrd, coarse iron to South Wales, hardwares to Birmingham, cutlery to Sheffield. And so in the different quarters of the city. Thus, in large towns, the banks, stores, offices etc., are found in one portion, with scarcely any intervening dwelling houses. On the division of labor depends all differences of estate and class, and all human culture. It cannot be claimed that a division of labor does not exist among animals f but those ani- mals among which something analogous to a division of labor among men exists, are raised far above all others by their hu- man-like economy and the relative importance of their achieve- ments.'^ SECTION LVIII. ADVANTAGES OF THE DIVISION OF LABOR. The advantages of all suitable division of labor, consequent upon the natural differences of human faculties and disposi- tions, are the following: century, and excited then the wonder of the English. See Sir W. Temple, Observations upon the U. Provinces, 1672, ch. 3. Works, I, 128, 143. In 1615, Montchretien held up the Flemish as a model to the French, in this re- spect. *0n the bees, see Virgil, Georg. IV, 15S. ' The principle of the division of labor was known to the ancients : Xcno- j)Iion, Cyri Discipl., VIII, 2,5. Plato, de Rep., 11,369, III, 394, IV, 443; Isocrat., Busir., 8. Aristot., Polit., II, 8, S. Among the more modern writers, compare Thomas Aquin., De Reg. pr., I, i, II, 3. Luther (Works by Walch, I, 388), in his Commentary on Genesis, 3, 19. Petty, Several Essaj'S, 16S2, p. 113. Considerations upon the East India Trade, London, 1701. Roschcr, Geschichte der englischen Volkswirthschaftslehre, 118. Mandevillc, The Fable of the Bees, enlarged edition of 1723, p. 411. Berkeley, Querist, 1735, No. 415, 430, 520 ff., 586: "What is everybody's business is nobody's." Harris, on Money and Coins (1757), I, 16. J. J. Rousseau, Emile (1762), L. III. Ttcrgot, Sur la Formation et la Distribution des Richesses, § 3, p. 50, 62, 66. Diderot, EncyclopGdie de I'Art, s. v. Art. J. Tucker, Four Tracts (1774), p. 25 ff. Bozcaria, Economia pubblica, I, i, 9. But the author to whom we owe most on this score is undoubtedly Adam Smith. To him we are indebted almost entirely for our knowledge of the natural laws developed in § 59 seq. 190 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Cir.-III. A. The greotc}' skill of the worhnan. Even physically, many capacities are, by an indefinite number of repetitions of the same operation, enhanced to an extraordinary degree; which, however, renders the performance of other operations more difficult. Thus, the man who has developed his mus- cles and hardened his hands working in a smithy, renders himself incapable of becoming a violin-player or an operating- oculist.^ Here belongs especially the possibility of turning every kind of labor-power to greatest account. Even chil- dren ^ and old men may be made, in this way, to play a part in the production of goods. It becomes practicable, too, to relieve men endowed with superior faculties from common labor, and allow them to devote themselves exclusively to the development of the peculiar powers with which nature has gifted them.^ B. A great saving of time and trouble. The simpler the operation performed by a single workman, the more easily is it learned; the smaller is the price paid for apprenticeship, which depends on this, at least, that beginners perform poorer work and are paid more poorly. "The shortest way to the ' According to Adam Smithy a nailer can make 2,300 nails (Rati says 3,000 shoemaker's tacks in the Odenwalde) per day ; a smith who is only occas- ionally employed in the manufacture, from 800 to 1,000; and smiths who never made nails before, from 200 to 300. A clever filer makes 200 strokes in a minute ; a skilled comb-maker can make in a day from 60 to 70 combs of such fineness that there are from 40 to 48 teeth to the inch in them; eight Liege brick-makers, working together, produce 4,800 bricks per day ; children employed in a needle manufactory, in making the eyes of needles, grow so skillful at it that they can make a small hole in the finest hair and draw an- other hair through it. Rati, Lehrbuch I, § 115. The old proverb, "practice makes perfect," is followed even by thieves in their great division of labor. See Thiele^ Die jiidischen Gauner I, 87. Fregier^ Des Classes Dang^reuses. 2 Children, with their thinner fingers, can point twice as many needles in the same time as a grown person. 2 The manufacture of English needles demands, on the part of workmen, degrees of skill so different that their pay varies from 6 pence to 20 shillings per day. If the most skillful workman were to manufacture whole needles alone, he would partly be obliged to be satisfied with one-fortieth of what he misfht otherwise receive. Babbacftii{s. {^la'jiiilrai/, XII, I.) And so Garve, Versuche, IV, 51 fF., expects from the political elevation of citizenship, of those possessed of the right of citizens, not only usefulness in a particular direction but the development of the whole man, a thing hitherto expected only of the nobility. Sec. LXIV.] CO-OPERATION OF LABOR. 203 ness produced by a high division of labor consists in the ex- tension and many-sided employment of leisure time, both of which are made more easy l)y the same high civilization which always accompanies the division of labor.® SECTION LXIV. THE CO-OPERATION OF LABOR. The cooperation or combination^ of labor must, however, always correspond to the division of labor. Both are but dif- ferent sides of the one idea of social labor; the separation of different kinds of labor, in so far as they would disturb one another, and the union or combination of them so far as they help one another.^ The vintner or grower of flax would neces- * As one's peculiar calling does not take up all his Hie, we must draw a clear distinction between the one-sidedness of labor and the one-sidedness of life. (vo7i Mangoldt^ Volkswirthschaftslehre, 227.) Only the last is to be avoided at all hazards ; and we find it in the middle ages, with its limited di- visions of labor, perhaps more frequently than where civilization has at- tained a higher stage. During the middle ages, it was not unusual to make feelings which every one should cultivate at times, if only temporarily, the lasting calling of some. Thus one prayed his whole life long, or was en- gaged in contemplation, and relieved others of the necessity of performing these duties. The consequence was, that the latter sank as deeply in world- liness and want of tlie interior spirit as the former were plunged in idleness and hj'pocrisy. But, on the other hand, when, in our day, the printer re- lieves the writer of a portion of the labor which might be his, the personal development of neither suffers. ^ L''uomo euii' tal potcnza^ chetcnitaalV gltra nonfa un eguale alia soinina, ma al qiiadraio delta somina. (Gcnovesi.) As to how the action of every individu- al man is a species of division and union of different kinds of labor, see Siein, Lehrbuch, 24. * Compare Ad. Miiller, Elemente der Staatskunst, III, 1809. Fr. List, Sys- tem der polit. CEkonomie, 222 ff., 409 ff. IVakcJield, in his edition of Adam Smith, distinguishes two degrees of cooperation, simple and complex. In the case of simple labor, the same sort of work is performed at the same time and place by several individuals, as, for instance, by a lot of hod-carriers in building. In the other case, there are different kinds of work performed at different times and places, but all intended for the one greater end. Agri- 204 ^ PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Cii. III. sarily die of hunger if he could not certainly count on the grower of corn. The workman in a pin-factory, who prepares only the heads of pins, must be sure of his colleagues who sharpen the points, if his labor would not be entirely in vain. The la- bor of the merchant is not even thinkable without that of the different producers between whom he mediates. Where the production of a certain article depends on the services of six different kinds of labor, one of which, however, demands thrice the time, and another twice the time of the rest, it is clear, that, in order that the business may be properly carried on, so many workmen should be employed that their number divided by 9 should leave no remainder. (Ran.) The union or com- bination of different kinds of labor is most perfect when the workmen live nearest together ; when, therefore, they are not separated by great difficulties of, transportation ; or in different countries, in which case, a war might tear all to pieces. SECTION LXV. THE PRINCIPLE OF STABILITY, OR OF THE CONTINUITY OF WORK. Cooperation in time is of equal importance : the principle of the stability, or of the continuity of labor. When a workman dies, it is necessary to be able to calculate on a substitute. It is well known that it is much harder to begin a business, than it is, afterwards, to improve and enlarge it ; and this, the more complicated it is. A new enterprise will take root easily, only where there are several similar ones already in existence ; a new manufacturing establishment, for instance, where by the existence of other such establishments, the requisite habits of the workmen, of capitalists and of the public in general, have been previously developed. The skill of workmen is propa- gated especially by observation and the personal emulation of culture aflbrds room for the first especially, and it is known also to a great number of animal species. Sec. LXV.] PRINCIPLE OF STABILITY. 205 the young; whence it is, that the introduction of new indus- tries is best made by the immigration of skilled workmen.'^ Hence the baleful influence of such interruptions, as for in- stance, the repeal of the edict of Nantes. Hence too, it is, that despotism and the reign of the populace are so unfavor- able to the economy of a country, where there can be no guar- anty of a consistent observance and development of the laws. To the best applications of the principle of the continuity of labor belong the church-building of the middle ages, the national canals, the street and fortification systems of modern times ; all of which have been created only by the cooperation of several generations to the same end." The most striking means by which such a cooperation has been advanced in modern times is public credit, " a draft on posterity ; " yet, all saving is, in principle, the same. The most powerful element in the cooperation in time of labor is the economy in common of the family, although it differs in degree, according to the diflerent kinds of family inheritance. Where, as among the English middle classes, it is customary to secure the business property of the family to one child by will, and to entrust the conduct of the business, during the life of the father, to the devisee, to provide for the other children by insurance, by sav- ings etc., made from the surplus of the business, there may be old firms which remain always new, however ; because they combine the experience of age with the energy of youth, and are never broken up by a division of the inheritance. But the * Flemish weavers in England, French refugees in Protestant countries ; German miners in Spain, Scandinavia, Hungary and America. * This, so very largely developed in Egypt and India, Avhere the principle of caste obtains, is very little developed in the despotisms of Asia. The great princes, in the lattei covintries, build largely from vanity only. Hence their successors seldom complete their works, and scarcely repair them. Nowhere else are there so many half completed and yet decaying buildings. Klcmm, Kulturgeschichte, VIII, 86. Rtedel, N. CEkonomie I, 259, very correctly re- marks that such kinds of cooperation as contribute most to the propagation of skill, both in commerce and manual labor, have less real division of labor, and vice versa. 206 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. Ill compulsory equality of heirs,which actually obtains in France, compels almost ever}'- new generation to begin with a new firm. (See § 85 seq.) ^ SECTION LXVI. ADVANTAGE OF LARGE ENTERPRISES. On the results of the division and cooperation of labor rests the superior advantage of all great undertakings, and they are, therefore, smaller in agriculture than in industry. "It is harder to acquire the first thousand than the second million." Abstraction made of the conditions of capital and of the mar- ket, the limit up to which the growing magnitude of an enter- prise becomes more advantageous, lies in the increasing difficul- ty of superintendence. Numberless commercial improvements, such as the post-ofiice, railroads, telegraphs, exchange, banks etc., have operated powerfully to extend these limits. It is frequently possible, even in small enterprises, to secure the ad- vantages of large enterprises, by association among those con- cerned. They must, of course, possess the necessary capital. If they have not got it, as property, they must borrow it. It is, of course, peculiarly difficult here to preserve the neces- sary unity, without which the cooperation of labor becomes the confusion of labor. The more moral and intelligent the participants are and the simpler the business, the more exten- sive may it become, and the more probable will be its suc- cess. (§ 90.) ^ ^ ^ 8 Compare Leplay, La Reforme sociale en France (1864). 1 Concerning association in general, see M. Chevalier^ Coi'.rs, III, Le^on, 24, 25. On this subject so much talked of in our day, see, more in detail, con- cerning its application to agriculture, my work, Nationalokonomik des Ackerbaues, 4, § 39,470".; 68, 133 ff.; on its application toindustryj especially where there is question of the relation of handiwork and manufactures to large factories; see Roschcr, Ansichten der Volkswirthschaft, II, Aufl., 1S61, Ab- handlung, IV, V. ^Adam Stnith remarked that the laws of the division of labor obtain also in intellectual works ; and indeed, among all nations in a very low grade of Sec. LXVII.] THE ORIGIN OF SLAVERY. 207 CHAPTER IV. FREEDOM AND SLAVERY. SECTION LXVII. THE ORJGIN OF SLAVERY. An institution like that of personal bondage, which, it can be shown, has existed, among all nations of which history gives civilization, the germs of all art and science are found connected with theol- ogy; and later, the germs of all poetry and history -with the epic. The ex- pression : non. defiiit Iioiiiiiii, sed scicntice, quod ncscivit Saliiiasiiis, is a clear proof of the insignificance of the science of the time. Think of the increase during the last hundred years of the branches of study in our German uni- versities. There are now thirty -four regular professors in the Leipzig philosophical faculty, where then there were only nine. But here also the principle proves true, that an excessive division of labor, where the broader connection and the deeper foundation of all sciences disappear from the con- sciousness, undermines intellectual health and freedom. And the injury here is greater and more irreparable than in the domain of mere physical labor. See Hufelandy N. Grundlegung,I, 207 ft'. If we have just become Alexandrians, we have, however, no Aristotle to hope for. Jurisprudentia est divinarum atquc Jiumanarum rerum notitia,jusii atque injusti scientia (Ulpian). It is re- markable that nations who possess no real national literature of their own, when they once get beyond the bounds of utter barbarism, learn foreign lan- guages etc., most easily. 3 The socialistic Utopia of Ch. Fourier (The^orie des quatre Mouvements, 180S. The'orie de I'Unitd universelle, 1S22. Le nouveau Monde industriel et societaire, 1S29) are based upon the following fundamental ideas. A. The present civilization is that of a topsy-turvy Avorld, especially in so far as it ascribes a " moral " (a word always used by him in an ironical sense) self- 208 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. IV. US information, at one time or another, must have very gen- eral causes. Among these may be mentioned especially sub- jection through war. It is not possible to calculate how much the principle, that it was proper to reduce the man to slavery government to man. In Fourier's world, on the other hand, every man is supposed, at all times, to give free rein to every ^assioti; and the play of these gratifications constitutes the hannonie^ in which the poorest find more enjoyment than do kings at the present time. (See § 207 of this work.) B. The main thing to further this is a radical reform in the division and co- operation of labor as they exist at present. Instead of the present villages and cities, we should have only phalansteries, each with 2,000 inhabitants, and situated in the center of the land cultivated by them. Instead of the present nations and states, we should have a universal confederate republic, hierarch- ically graded, with French as the universal language. According to the diQ- mands of the passion ^a/illontie, each one should carry on the most different kinds of business side by side, and each one of them at most two hours per day ; i. e., every one should be a dilletante, no one a master, and everything should be done as badly as possible. Proud/ioii, Contradictions economiques, ch. 3, objects to this, that a workman must, in some way, be held responsible for his Avork. Fourier himself calculates that, in his Iiarmonie all pleasures are productive labor; and that by this constant change, one might be satisfied with from 4 >^ to 5>2 hours of sleep, and that even children 2}^ years old might take part in the work. Thus, there would be a great rivalry be- tween apple-growers and pear-growers, so great " that more intrigues in at- tack and defense [passi'oti cabaliste\ would arise there than in all the cabinets of Europe," in the settling of which the growers of quinces would act as in- termediaries. There are, in addition to all this, wonderful aids ; a fructifying crown of light rises over the north pole; oranges bloom in Siberia; the sea becomes as delicious as lemonade ; dangerous animals die, and in their stead anti-lions and anti-whales come into being, animals useful to man, which draw his ships for him during calms. These ideas are by no means retracted in Fourier'' s later works. See Nouveau Monde (Oeuvres) IV, 447. The prop- ositions of Robert Ozven^A. new View of Society (1812), have much similarity with those of Fourier. They differ only in the absence of the French bar- rack-like character of the phalanxes, and the fantastic character of the pre- sentation of the doctrine. He would have all the land divided into districts of 1,000 acres each; each district to have a four-cornered town with 1,000 inhabitants, following a system of production and consumption in common, but not with full equality; carrying on both agriculture and other business. A principal feature here is an entirely new system of education. The author says that man has hitherto been the slave of an execrable trinity: positive re- ligion, personal property and indissoluble wedlock. (Declaration of mental independence.) Skc. lxvil] the origin of slavery. 200 whom it was considered right to kill, contributed to make war less blood}^ in an uncivilized age.' A nation of hunters is al- most compelled to grant no quarter; the conqueror would be obliged either to feed his prisoner or to put arms in his hands. It is certainly a great humanitarian advance, when this state of things is superseded by slavery among nomadic nations.^ In times of peace, economic dependence is the result of pov- erty, excessive debt etc.^ Where there is no division of labor, the individual has no means of supplying his wants, except by cultivating a spot of ground. But, how can the poor wretch who has neither capital * nor land exchange anything of value for either? Such an advance, where there is no security in law, can be made only on the credit of a verj- important pledge. But the man who is destitute of all property can ofler nothing but the productive power of himself or of his family.^ And ' Compare Tacitus, Histor., II, 44. ' See Isclin, Geschichte der Menscheit (1764), III, 7. Bazard, Exposition de la Doctrine de Saint Simon, 1S31, 153. Among negro nations deprivation of freedom is one of the most usual punishments for crime ; but the criminal has the option of substituting his wife or child for himself. L.A. de Olivetra Mcndez, in the Memor. econom. of the Rojal Academy of Lisbon, vol. IV, I, 1S12. As to slavery on account of crime among the Germans, see Grimm, D. Rechtsalterth., 32S seq. 3 Loss at play was a frequent cause of slavery among the ancient Germans. Tacit., Germ., 24. For the principal causes of slavery among the Israelites, see the books of Moses, II, 22, 3; III, 25, 39; IV, 21, 26 seq.; among the In- dians, Laws of Menu, VIII, 415. The first serfs of Russia were prisoners of war and their children. The laws of Jaroslaws recognize, besides, the fol- lowing causes: insolvency, contracting marriage with a slave, the illegal breach of a contract for service, flight, unconditional contract for service. Karamsiii, Russ. Gesch., II, 37. * At least seed and tlie means of subsistence until harvest time. 5 Cases of voluntary slavery to escape famine. Pafencordt, Geschichte der Vandalen, 186; Victor, Chron., V, 17; Tur., VII, 45; Lex Bajuv, VI, 3; L. Fris, XI, I. According to the Edictum Pistense (a., S64), c, 34, one could free himself again by paying back the purchase money and 20 per cent, in addition. It freqviently happened that people spontaneously ac- cepted the condition of a vassal in order to enjoy the protection of a power- ful personage. See Stiivc, Lasten des Grundcigcnthums, p. 74. In 1S12, a young Himalayan offered himself to the traveler Moore: oft as a slave in or- VoL. I. — 14 2.10 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch IV SO it is with the small landed proprietor who has lost all his capital ; ^ for, considering the superabundance of land, the part which he possesses has value in exchange only to the extent that it is joined with the certainty of being cultivated; and here is the origin of the glcbcB adscriftio. The hereditary transmission of the relation to the children seems to be equal- ly useful to them ; or who, were this not the case, would think of providing them with food? It also frequently happens that poor parents prefer to sell their children to seeing them starve.'' Hence the strange fact that most nations have the most rigid system of slavery precisely at the time that the soil produces food most readily. We need only cite the instance of the South Sea Islands,, at the time of their discovery. In many negro countries, where the people have not yet learned to use animals for transportation, the lowest classes, although they enjoy a nominal liberty, are used as beasts of burden.^ der to obtain food during the famine. K. Ritter, Erdkunde, III, p. 999. The same fact occurred, but in greater proportions under Joseph in Egypt. Moses, I, 47, iS seq. 6 CcBsar, B. C, VI, 13. ' Solon was the first to prohibit tliis commerce in Athens. Kindlinger, in his Geschichte der deutschen HOrigkeit, p. 621, speaks of a child promised as a slave before its birth, bj its parents, as a species of farm-rent. (See the Edictum Pistense, in Baluz, II, 192.) In Chili, the poorest country people "who Avere not entirely white, sold their children in the towns, where they grew up with the families of their masters, and were then kept as servants in a state of semi-serfdom. There is, it is true, no law governing this condition of things. (Popfig, Reise, I, 201 ff.) ^Ritfer, XIII, 727. For instance, men in South America used for the purpose of riding. M. Chevalier, Cours, I, 251; LcEzvenstcrn, Le INIexique, Souvenirs d'un Voyageur (1S43); and Sfcfhens, Travels in Yucatan (1S41), show how, even yet, in Central America, although the Indians are legally free, yet, by their senseless way of running into debt, a number of legal re- lations, amounting virtually to glelxe adscriftio, arise. But compare, how- ever, Humboldt, Neuspanien, IV, 263. This condition of things has been produced in Peru, also, by the payment of one or two years' wages in ad- vance. (Popp'g, Reise, II, 225.) Sec. LXVIII.] THE ORIGIN OF SLAVERY. 211 SECTION LXVIII. THE SAME SUBJECT CONTINUED. In all very low stages of civilization, the greatest absence of the feeling of wants, and the greatest indolence, are wont to prevail, and in the highest degree. As soon as their merest necessities are provided for, men begin to look upon labor as a disgraceful occupation, and indolence as the highest kind of enjoyment. (§41, 213 It.) Sustained and voluntary efforts, in any number, then become possible only by the creation of new wants ; but these new wants suppose a higher civilization. Escape from this sorry circle is then effected in the most hu- mane manner, through the agency of foreign teachers; inas- much as the representatives of a more highly cultivated people (missionaries, merchants etc.), by their own example, make the nation acquainted with more wants, and at the same time help toward their satisfaction.^ But, in the case of nations whose civilization is completely isolated, or having intercourse only with others equally low, progress is the creature of force exclusively. The barbarous isolation of families ceases when the strongest and most powerful force the weaker into their service. It is now that the division of labor really begins : the victor devotes himself entirely to work of a higher order, to statesmanship, war, worship etc. ; the very doing of which is generally a pleasure in itself. The vanquished per- form the lower. The one- half of the people are forced to labor for something beyond their own brute wants. And it is, here as elsewhere, the first step that costs. ^ (§ 45.) ' Thus Fo}-bonnais, Elements du Commerce (1S54) ^1 3^4> ^^J^ of trade with savages : il fait nciUre dans ccs nations le go{it du snferfa ct dcs commcdiids, qui midtifJie la iclianges ct leur donne le goUi du travail. • In vcr}' uncivilized nations, among whom serfdom is not known, we gen- erally find the slavery of woman and the temporary bondage of the son-in- law in order to secure the daughter in marriage. This is still the case among the Laplanders. Klcmfii, Kulturgeschichte III, p. 54. Slavery was unknown 212 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. IV. SECTION LXIX. ORIGIN OF SLAVERY. — WANT OF FREEDOM. It is not to be supposed that slavery, at this stage, is so oppressive even to those who have been deprived of their freedom. The feeling of moral degradation which slavery, abstraction even made of its abuses, awakens in us, is unknown in a very uncivilized age.^ The child willingly obeys the orders of strangers, and is hired out to service by his parents etc. The want or craving for liberty keeps pace with the in- tellectual growth of a people. The systematic over-working of servants or slaves, in the interest of their masters, is scarcely thinkable in an uncultured age, when, in the absence of com- among the Greeks in the very earhest times. Herod., VI, 263. F. A. Wolf, Darstell. der Afterthumswissenschaft, iii, doubts whether any great advance in the higher development of the mind would have been possible without slavery. ' In Russia, where free peasants and serfs lived side by side, it has been remarked that the latter were never so rich and never so poor as the former. (Kohl, Reise durch Russland II, S, 300.) The Livonian peasants have be- come poorer since their emancipation. (Cancrin, CEkonomie der mensch- lichen Gesellschaften, 41). Many of the serfs refused to accept emancipation. (Biisch, Geldumlauf, Einleitung, § 6.) And so Martius, Reise in Brasilien II, 553 ff., assures us that the negro slaves in Brazil are as a rule a very merry set. He is also of the opinion that they are better clothed, lodged, fed and employed than in their own country. For the remarkable official defense of North American slavery directed by Calhoun, to Lord Aberdeen, see the Allg. Zeitung, 1S44, No. 145. In this document, we find a compari- son instituted between the free negroes of the north and the slaves of the south. In the north, there was one deaf-mute, a case of blindness and of in- sanit}' in every 96; in the south, in every 672; a pauper, invalid and prisoner in every 6 at the north, in every 54 at the south. In Maine, -ji^th of the negroes were afflicted by disease; in Florida, jyV^th (.'). The fiict that the slave population of the United States increased, between 1S40 and 1S60, from 2,873,698 to 4,441,830, while the free negro population of Jamaica, between 1833 and 1843, underwent a frightful decrease, is to the same purport. How- ever, too much must not be inferred from all this, as the negroes in America are very far from being the children of the soil. Sec. LXIX.] THE ORIGIN OF SLAVERY. 213 mercial intercourse, every family consumes what it produces.^ The only thing which Ihe slave has to fear is an occasional outburst of tyranny on the part of the master, a thing which is far from unfrequent in all the relations of low civilizations. Fear restrains masters to a certain extent; for, in those early days, how few were the institutions of state which could pro- tect them aijainst the vengeance of their slaves! ^ * * The servants in the Odyssey who cared for hogs and cattle etc. were cer- tainly in a better condition in many respects than the peasants of Attica, who were free, but buried in debt until the time of Solon. Concerning the mildness of the treatment of slaves ifi very early Roman times, see Plutarch, Coriol., 24, and Cato, I, 3, 20 fF. ; Cato, de Re rust, 5, 56 ft'.; Alacroh., Stat. I, 10 ff. On the state of the serfs among the Germans, see Grimm^ Deutsche Rechtsalterthiimer, p. 339 if. ; among the ancient Scandinavians etc., Dahl- maUy Geschichte von Danemark, I, 163. See Tacit., Germ., 25. * Compare Landnamabok, I, 6. * The opinions of the ancients for and against slavery are found in Arist. Polit. I, 2. See especially the beautiful passages in Philemon : Meineke, Comi- corum jr., 364, 410. Aristotle even thinks that there are cases in which master and slave might be brought together by a mutual -want, each of the other. The former wants hands to execute the work of his brain ; the latter a guiding brain for his hands. Where the degree of dependence corresponds exactly to the diflerence of ability, Aristotle, leaving its abuses out of the ques- tion, declares slavery to be just. See, also, Eth. Nicom., VIII, 11. Similarly the Pythagorean Bryson in Stobceus, Florid. LXXXV, 15. But Aristotle would hold up emancipation to all slaves as a reward they might have in prospect. Polit. VII, 9, 9; OEcon. I, 5. It is characteristic of the many testa- ments of philosophers, found in Diogenes Laeriius, that they contain declar- ations giving slaves their freedom. The Essenes and Therapeutics con- demned slavery under all circumstances. Philc, Opp. II, pp. 45S, 4S2, Opp. I. See Seneca, De Benef. Ill, 20. The Jus naiurale of the age of the Caesars recognized the freedom and equality of man. Digest, XII, 664., L. 1 7, 32. The New Testament does not reject it absolutely, but would sanctity- it as well as all other relations in life. Compare Luke, 17, 7; Eph. 6 5 ff. ; Coloss. 3, 22 ; Tit. 2, 9. More especially, I Timothy, VI, i ft". It was not until the ninth century that the opinion that slavery was anti-Christian be- cause men were all made in the image of God, arose. Planck, Geschichte der kirchlichen Gesellschaftsverfassimg, II, 350. Sachsenspiegel, III, 42. A writer as recent as Pufendorf explains slavery as arising from a free con- tract ; _/i;c;V/;«, tit dcs. Jus naturtc (1672) VI, 3. More recently Linguct, Theorie des Loisciviles (1767), V, ch. 30, and Hugo, Naturrecht, § 1S6 ft", have en- deavored to prove that slaves are in a condition preferable to that of poor free 214 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. IV. SECTION LXX. EMANCIPATION. As States grow greater and men's manners gentler, the ranks of slavery are less and less liable to be recruited through the agency of war.^ It then becomes necessary to have recourse to the family to keep up their number, which makes their condition much more endurable, and which supposes that it has been made more endurable in other respects beforehand. jNIodern states, are, as a rule^ larger than the anci-ent were. The Gei"mans had, long before the time of Charlemagne, treated prisoners of war of German origin more mildly than those of Gallic or Slavic origin.^ The condition of the latter even improved from the time that nations began to think of making permanent conquests. Since the Slavic wars of the tenth century, certainly since the Lithuanian contests, it seems that prisoners of war were not reduced to slavery.^ Chivalry, men. And so Moser Patriot Phantasien, IIvP- 154, seq. Those who with Thaer separate the element of production, " labor" from that of " inteUigence," justify slavery on the same principle that Aristotle did, without knowing it. Per contra, see F. G. Schultze^ N. CEkonomie (1856), 418. ' Turgot^ Sur la Formation etc., § 21. The universal empire of the Ro- mans demonstrated this. Then it was, for instance, that during the wars of Lucullus, a slave cost only four drachmas. {Aj>J>ian., Bell. Mithr., 78.) Sar- di venules: on account of the glutting of the market with Sardinian slaves, made through the victory of Tib. Gracchus, 177, before Christ. Many of the lesser wars of the Romans can be looked upon only as slave-hunts. But the great wars also were followed by uprisings of slaves on account of the many new slaves which they made. Thus 198 in Latium, 196 in Etruria. {Bilcher., Aufstande der unfreien Arbeiter von, 143-129, v. Chr., 1874.) During the relatively peaceful periods which preceded many of the Roman revolutions, pirates delivered over great masses of slaves. It frequently happened that several thousand slaves were led to Delos and sold in a single day. (Sirabo, XIV, 668.) As emancipation was a measure which people could not make up their minds to adopt, these pirates satisfied a "want" for a time, and this partly explains the otherwise incomprehensible forbearaece of tlie state to- wards them. ^ Greg or. Turoii., Ill, 15. * Grimm, D. Rechtsalterthiimer, 323. It is a strange fact that prisoners of Sec. LXX.] EMANCirATION. 215 and allowing prisoners to go free, on their word of honor, contributed largely to this result. The more productive agriculture is, the more numerous the wants of land owners, the more extensive the division of labor and commercial intercourse become, the easier it is for a large class of the community to obtain support for themselves and families without cultivating land of their own. (Wages.) When exchanges through the medium of money become cus- tomary, the chief argument for slavery disappears; and the strong, rich and able man can, without having recourse to force, command the labor of other men. Every further ad- vance in economic culture must necessarily help forward in this direction. Thus, without the plow, for instance, we should all be really only so many glehce adscri^ti. It is due especially to the ever increasing perfection of tools, machines and opera- tions, that the slave of antiquit}" was transformed into the serf of the middle ages, and afterwards into the day laborer of modern times.* It is more particularly to be remarked, that machines, since 1750, "first made the constitutional liberty of many, instead of the feudal freedom of a few, possible." {ScJiafflc>j war were in several remarkable instances sold as slaves in Italy during the fifteenth century. {Sismoudi^ Hist, des Republiques italiennes, IX, p. 312 seq.; XI, p. 13S seq.) And even in the sixteenth century, the pope allowed those of states opposed to him to be treated in this way. Stsinoiidi, sup-a, XI, 251 ; XIII, 4S5. Raynold, Ann. eccl., 1506, § 25 ff. *This graduation of slave, serf and workman, has been carried out espe- cially by Saint Simon, Oeuvres, 328 ff. Even Proudhon admits tliat the con- dition of the lower classes is better now than formerlv. (Conti-adictions economiques, ch. X, 2.) Compare M. Chevalier, Cours, I. Le90ns i and 2, where he shows that our productive power has increased during the last four or five centuries in the production of iron in the proportion of i to from 25 to 30; in the preparation of flour since the time of Homer in the proportion of i : 144; in the production of cotton during the last 70 years in the proportion of i : 320. Aristotle predicted, long ago, that " when the shuttle would move of itself, and plecfa-a of themselves strike the lyre, we should need no more slaves." Polit., 2, 5. Every step of true progress brings us nearer the fulfillment of the prophecy. 216 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. IV. SECTION LXXI. DISADVANTAGES OF SLAVERY. Slavery promotes the division of labor only in the very beginning. The more dependent the slave is, the worse he works. Whatever he spoils or allows to go to waste injures only his master. Hence it is that slave-husbandry is only one degree removed from what the Germans call Raiibbaii^ and which means, as nearly as we can translate it, the most thoughtless and wasteful management possible.^ Whatever he consumes is simply so much gain to himself. Industry and skill are injurious to him, because, if remarkable for these qualities, his master exacts more work from him and is more adverse to setting him at liberty. Instead of the num- berless incentives of the free workman: care for the future, for his family, honor and comfort, the slave is generally moved by one — the fear of ill-treatment, and to this he grad- ually becomes insensible.' The division of labor demanded by manufactures, and which is to be found for the most part only where each person is at liberty to choose his own avo- cation, is scarcely supposable where slavery, in the strict sense of the word, prevails. The same is true of the spirit of inven- tion and improvement.^ And even where the milder glebcB ' The North American planters employed coarse tools rather than fine ones, mules rather than horses, because their slaves took so little care of them. 2 It can never obtain as much labor from the slave, as the fear of losing his situation and of not being able to obtain another, will from the free workman. (Hume.) Afarlo, Weltcekonomie, 1S4S, I, 2, 38, grants this to be true only where all the forces of nature are appropriated by occupation, and the number of workmen is greater than the want of workmen. 2 Even in Brazil, only free men are, as a rule, employed as sugar refiners, distillers, teamsters etc. (Kostcr, Travels in Brazil, 1S16, 362.) StorcJi, Russland unter Alexander I, Heft, 23, p. 255, cites the opinion of an eminent Russian manufacturer, that it would first be necessary to liberate the serf factory-hands. Masters have generally give^i up employing their own serfs in manufactures, allowed them to seek work for themselves, and only re- Sec. LXXI.] DISADVANTAGES OF SLAVERY. 217 adscriftio obtains, the division of labor is much hindered. Hence, competent judges all agree on the badness of slave labor ;^ which, as for instance in the United States, was used only where the slaves were crowded together in large num- bers and could therefore be easily superintended. And not only are the slaves themselves indolent, but their masters as well; more particularly in slave countries where all labor is considered disgraceful. What must be the national husbandry of a people, one half of whom refuse to do anything that is right and proper, through malice, and the other half through pride ! As soon as, on account of increased population and conse- quent increased consumption, this enormous waste of force can be endured no longer, free workmen become more profit- able, not only to themselves and to the whole community, but to the greater number of the individuals who compose it.^ On the Bernstoff estates the quantity of rye harvested before quired them to pay them a species of tax. When this plan was adopted, it Avas found that they worked much better, (v. Haxthausen, Studien I, 6i, 1 16.) It was a consequence of slavery that, in antiquity, the very wealthy purchased so little: omnia domi nascuntur ! (Pctron.^ 3S.) ■* Thus Homer, Od. XVII, 322, in whose time even there were day laborers, "d^YiTB^ or eqt&oc. (Od. IV, 644; X, 85; XI, 490; XIV, 102. //c5w^, Opera, 602.) And Varro, De Re rust. I, 17, advises that difficult labor should be performed rather by day laborers. Colt rtira ab ergastulis fessununi est et qm'dquid agitur a desfcrantibus. Plin., H. N. XVIII, 7. Omne genus agri tolcrabiliiis sub liberis colo?tts, quam sub villicis. (Columella, De Re rust I, 7.) It has been estimated, that, in the West Indies, a negro slave performed only one-third of the work performed by an Englishinan in his own country. (B. Edtvards, History of the British West Indies, II, 131.) During the one afternoon, in every week, in which the negroes were allowed to work on their own account, they accomplished as much as on other entire days. Edinburgh R. IV, 842. Compare Bentham, Traitd de Legislation I, 319. Ch. Comte, Traite de Legislation, 1827, Livre V.; Cairnes, The Slave-Power, its Character, Career and probable Designs, 1862; Olmsted, Journeys and Explorations in the Cotton Kingdom, 1861. 5 While the older tyrants had prohibited idleness, Draco and Solon even under pain of degradation (see places in BuchscnschUtz, Besitz und Erwerb, 260). Socrates called the dpfta the sister of Freedom (Aelian, V. H. X, 14), and the ay.o}y] the most beautiful of all professions 218 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. IV. and after emancipation was as 3:8j^; of barley-corn as 4:9^^^; of oat- grain as 2^:8.^ The owners of serfs, especially, are apt to be very wasteful of their labor, because they imagine that they obtain it gratis. Tucker has made a curious calculation tending to show that when civilization reaches a certain point, the master's self-in- terest leads to emancipation. In Russia, where there are seventy-five persons to the English square mile, it seemed to him that serfdom was still a good economic speculation. In western Europe, where there were one hundred and ten per- sons to the square mile, freedom, in all relations of master and servant, he considered more advantageous to all parties. Eman- cipation began in England in the fourteenth century, when that country had a population of forty to the square mile, and was completed in the seventeenth, when the population was ninety- two to the square mile."' Tucker concludes, that the turning point comes, when the population is relatively to the number of square miles as 66: i.^ Such a calculation cannot, of course, be universally true. The free workman can usually command a much larger portion of the sum total of economic profits * B. Franklin, Observations concerning the Peopling of New Countries etc., 1751. 'Monument erected to Bernstorjfhy his peasants, 8, 15. The Zamoisl-t estates yielded, 17 years after emancipation, three times as much as they did when serfdom prevailed. Coxe, Travels in Poland, I, 22. The transformation of the serfs into hereditary farmers cost Count Bernstorf 100,000 thalers; but the revenue derived from his lands increased in consequence, in twenty- four years, from 3,000 to 27,000 thalers. An English mower can mow a field two and three times as gi-eat as a Russian mower in a given time. If the former receives daily wages equivalent to seventy pounds of wheat, and the latter to only twelve, the Englishman's labor is still the cheaper; for he turns out 100 pounds of hay while the latter turns out only eight. Jacob, 43 seq. But the hiring out of serfs in the large cities of Russia yielded less to their masters than in the interior. Storch, Handbuch, II, 286. 8 Tucker, Progress of the United States, 1843, pp. iii ff. We need not call attention to the inaccuracy of these figures, nor remark how little servicea- ble for our present purpose an average obtained from the density of popula- tion in different parts of Russia, where such densities are themselves so very different, would be. Sec. LXXII.] CIVILIZATION AND SLAVERY. 219 than can the slave or serf, who must be satisfied with the min- imum necessary to support life.^ Hence, free labor is more profitable to masters only when production in general is so much enhanced thereby that a greater quantity of goods falls to their share also. But this will always be the case where workmen are capable of development.^" SECTION LXXII. EFFECT OF AN ADVANCE IN CIVILIZATION ON SLAVERY. At the same time, the same degree of servitude becomes more and more oppressive to the bondman as civilization ad- vances. The greater his intellectual progress, the more does he feel the want of liberty, and the more keenly he experiences the degradation of his condition. The development of luxury digs a gulf between master and servant which grows wider every day. (§ 227 ff.) As commerce extends, it becomes more profitable for the master to exact excessive work from his slave. In the West Indies, it was a problem which every slaveholder solved for himself, whether, by immoderately in- creased production, which cost the lives of many slaves, the gain in sugar was greater than the loss occasioned by the 3 The Spartans seemed to have counted on an adult free man for twice as much coarse food as a bondsman. (Thucyd.^ VI, 16.) 1* Stcxvar-t, Principles, I, 7, in accordance with historical data, says, that the peasantry in our days work for other people, because they have wants which can be satisfied only in this way ; because " they are slaves of their own wants." The unquestionable superiority of free to slave labor, in point of economy, has been dwelt upon especially by Turgot, Sur la Formation et la Distribution, § 28, and by Adam Smith, Wealth of Nations, I, S, III, 2. But see J. B. Say, Traitd, I, ch. 19, and Storc/i, Handbuch, II, 1S4. When Hume, Discourses, No. 11, Populousness of ancient Nations, demonstrates the greater cost of slavery from the fact that the master of slaves must either breed or buy them, he forgets that in the case of free workmen he is obliged to provide also for the support of the workman's children. Only, the slave- holder has, indeed, to advance the whole at once. 220 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. IV consequent death of the negroes. ^ When, with the advance of civilization, the state guaranties to all more certain protection of their rights than they enjoyed in a less advanced stage of social improvement, the last check on masters, the fear of the vengeance of their slaves, is removed.^ Demoralization natu- rally increases in the same proportion ; and that of the master as well as that of his servants. ^ SECTION LXXIII. THE SAME SUBJECT CONTINUED. This explains why it is that, in all countries, the power of the state, in a period of transition towards a higher civiliza- tion, has endeavored to render slavery milder. Great credit is due the Church in this regard. It soon extinguished slavery entirely in Scandinavia,^ and in portions of Europe it abolished at least the sale of prisoners to foreign countries." The ^ Hutnboldf, Cuba, I, 177. Aslnvortk, Tour in the U. S. Cuba and Canada, iS6r. The slaves in Louisiana were so overworked that they Hved, on an average, scarcely seven years. Edinburg Rev., LXXXIII, 73. Even the Stoics were not agreed, whether it was right, in case of shipwreck, to sacri- fice a cheap slave in order to save a valuable horse. (Cicero, de Oif. Ill, 23.) Whether the self-interest of masters is an inducement to the mild treatment of their slaves depends on the price for which fresh slaves may be obtained. This is a strong reason why a high degree of civilization, where there are not counteracting influences, must make slavery less endurable. The more valuable slaves are, the worse is their condition. In the unfertile Bahamas, the price was £21; in Demarara, £86. In the former place they were re- quired to do little work and were well fed and well clothed. Hence their numbers have increased there, while in Demarara they have decreased. (Edinburgh Rev., XLVI, 496, iSo.) 2 Proverb: quot servi totidem liostcs. (Macfob., Sat. I, 11, 13.) 3 ycfferson, Notes on Virginia, 212. The chastity of both parties especially suffers. The letio of ancient comedy was a slave trader! Compare L. 27, Digest, V, 3. In the English negro colonies, it was not unusual for the guests of the planters, even in the best families, on retiring, to ask the accompanving servant for a girl, with as little concern as they would in En- gland for a light. (Negro Slavery, or a Creed of that state of Society as it exists in the United States and in the Colonies of the West Indies, Lon- don, 1S23, 53.) 1 Even the law of Upland forbade the sale of Christians. The children of Sec. LXXIIL] THE CHURCH AND SLAVERY. 221 Concilium Agailieiisc, in the year 506, decreed that serfs should not be killed by their masters at pleasure,^ but that they should be brought before a tribunal of justice. (The manorial tribu- nals of more recent times.) Moreover, the numberless holi- days of the church operated greatly in favor of the bondmen. Pope Alexander III. recommended their gradual emancipa- tion.^ One of the principal steps in the way of progress was made when they could no longer be sold singly, but only with the village or on the estate to which they belonged.^ The feudal aristocracy improved the condition of the bondmen by reducing a great number of freemen to their level.^ This a slave and of a free person -were born free. Emancipation ^vas considered a Christian act, to be performed for "the salvation of one's soul." Voluntary slavery was prohibited in 1266, and Magnus Erichson forbade slavery gener- ally from the year 1335. See Gcijcv, Geschichte von Schweden, pp. 157, 185, 273. Estruj>, in Falcks N. Staatsburg Magazin, 1837, 179, fl". *L. Alam, 137, i. L. Fris., 17, 5. Decree of 960 concerning the aboli- tion of the trade in Christian slaves between Germany, Italy and the Byzan- tine Empire. Tafel nnd Tltomas^ Urkunden der Staats-und Handelsgesch- ichte von Venedig, I, 18 ft". 3 Tacit. Germ. 25. In the Legg. Wallire 206 (Wolton) we read : " Hero eadem fotestas in serviiin smwt ac in juinentumr 4 The council of London in 1 102 forbade men to be sold like beasts. (Con- cil., ed. Venet. 1730, XII, iioo, No. 27.) Gudrard, Polyptiques d'lrminon, Prolegg., 220, describes a pedagogical model emancipation by the Church of its own serfs. On the whole, the church contributed more towards the eman- cipation of the serfs of others than of its own. See ch. 39, C. XII, qu. 2 ; c. 3,4; De Rebus eccl. 5 In Flanders since the end of the twelfth century. Warnl-oni^, Fland- rische Staats und Rechtsgeschichte (I, 244). * In what relates to Germany, compare SuffenJtcim, Geschichte der Aufhe- bung der Leibeigenschaft in Europa, 1861, p. 350 ft". The destruction of the old manorial system (Hofxvesot) in the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries, was often unfavorable to bondmen and favorable to serfs. Maiircr, Gesch. der Frohnhofe, II, 92. In Poland, where all were originally equal land-owners, many sank gradually through poverty to the condition of the so-called kmetes, who, although personally free, were not very far removed from slaves. Beginning Avith the thirteenth century, a great number of immunities, after the model of those accorded in Germany, were granted, by means of which they lost, for the most part, their direct subjection to the emperor and the empire alone. This was soon followed as a consequence by their personal 222 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. IV could not be effected without a real amelioration of slaver}^; and, later, when the feudal aristocracy declined, the older serfs were, with those who had been formerly free, raised from their abject condition. The sense of chivalry would not permit a lord to be served by a bondman. The old adage " the serf lives to serve and serves to live," by degrees, lost its force. Serfs were required to perform certain tasks on the lands of their master and to pay him a certain quantity of the produce of their own. Heriots (mortjiarhmi), which became usual from the 8th century (y. Grimm )^ may be considered evi- dence that even bondmen were permitted to acquire and hold property in their own right. Thus was one of the chief dis- advantages of slavery, in an economic sense, removed.'^ It may be affirmed, as characteristic of the aristocracy of feudal times, that they treated those, who like the serfs were entirely at their mercy, with much more consideration than those who were free, and, although dependent on them, had certain rights guarantied by contract. The absolute monarchy found in oppression. (Ropell, Geschichte von Polen, I, p. 30S seq., and p. 570 seq.) In Bohemia, the old form of serfdom had so far disappeared in the fourteenth century, that it might be said it was known only to history. But during the reign of the weak king, Ladislaus II, a new species of serfdom came into vogue, the result of the preponderance of the aristocratic element. Palacky^ Gesch. von Bohmen, II, p. 33 seq.; Ill, 31 seq. Aristocratic Denmark, be- fore the peasant war of 1255-1258, subjected the free peasantry who had been leaseholders for a term of years to unlimited socage duty. Waldemar III, reduced to the same kind of service the land-owning peasantry, which es- pecially from the date of Margaret's reign, developed into a species of gle- icp adscriftto. From the sixteenth century, Avhen the royal power almost dis- appeared, these public privileges were abandoned to the nobility to such an extent that, in 1650, there were scarcely 5,000 free peasants. Dalilmaini, III, p. 73 seq. However the sevei-ity of traeldom made way in the fourteenth century for the vornedskaf (modified bondage), a milder species of vassalage. See Koldcrup Rosenvinge, Grundriss der danischen Rechtsgeschichte, § 94. ' The French expression mainmorte comes originally from the deprivation of the right of inheritance. In Beaumanoir's time, 12S3, it was customary, after a number of serfs had lived together for a year and a day, for their chattels movable to become the common property of the community. (Warnkomg, Franzosische Rechtsgeschichte, II, 157.) Sec. LXXIII.] THE CHURCH AND SLAVERY. 223 nearly all nations, at the opening of modern times, was forced by its struggle with the mediaeval aristocracy to favor the emancipation of the serfs and of the lower classes. Even in Russia, Iwan III. (1462-1505) seems to have restored to the peasantry the right of migration, of which they had been de- prived by the invasion of the Mongols, nor did they lose it again until the great troubles at the beginning of the seven- teenth century, which gave the ruling power to the nobility.^ Where civilization has reached its highest development, the irresistible power of public opinion, governed by the ideas of the universal brotherhood of man and of democratic equality, causes the abolition of all irredeemable and of all hereditary relations of servitude .^ ^^ ^' * In France, Louis X. made it a fiscal speculation to sell serfs their liberty in whole districts, even against their will. His edict, Ordonnances, I, 583, recognizes that all men are by nature free, and that France is not without reason called the land of the Franks etc. Even in 129S, Philip IV. had ex- changed the serfdom to the crown of several provinces for a land duty. The last ruler of Dauphiny gave all the serfs of the crown their liberty gratis, in 1394. (Sugenheim^ p. 130.) When the so-called coutitiiies were written, there were only nine provincees in Avhich by local law serfdom was permitted. The defeat of the jacquerie injured the cause of emancipation in France in the same way that the suppression of the war of the peasants did in Ger- many. About 1779, mainmorte was abolished in all lands of the crown, and its proof made almost impossible in all others. (Wanikdiiig, II, 151 seq.) Yet it is said that there were 150,000 serfs de corps in France in 17S9. (Cos- sagfiac, Causes de la Revolution, III, li.) Koloman, who died in 11 14, for- bade the slave trade in Hungary, and labored to raise all Christian slaves to conditionarii (renters). But the right of migration was abolished in 1351. King Sigismund, and still more, Matthias Corvinus, restored it, after the suppression of the war of the peasants, but in 1514 it was again lost until 1586. Further progress was aiTested until the Urbarium of Maria Theresa. 9 In Italy, Frederick II. liberated all the serfs of the crown. (Constitutt. Regni Sicil., 164.) A model instance of emancipation at Bologna in 1256. The serfs of the state were simply set at liberty ; the freedom of those of private persons Avas purchased Avith the money of the state, and a small corn-tithe laid on the emancipated as a compensation for the expense in- curred in their behalf. In the future, there Avas not to be a bondman on Bologna territory. The motives which led to this measure are a strange admixture of Christianity and Democracy. (Muzzt^ Annali di Bologna, 224 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. IV. SECTION LXXIV. THE SAME SUBJECT CONTINUED. It cannot be doubted, that an entirely direct leap from com- plete servitude to complete freedom may be attended by many 1S40, I, 479.) Italy, at the end of the fourteenth century, was entirely free from Christian serfdom. (Miii-atori, Antt. Ital., I, 79S.) In the canton of Berne, Switzerland, slaverj* was gradually abolished, the process commenc- ing about the beginning of the fifteenth century. It continued, however, in the case of ordinary masters until 1798. Sugenheim, p. 530 seq. In England, Alfred the Great's eftbrts towards the gradual abolition of slavery ( Wilkins, Leges, 29) remained without result. The steps taken by William I, towards a much narrower end, however, seem to have been more success- ful. (Leges Will. Conq., 225, 229; Turner, Hist, of England, I, 135.) From the time of the Norman conquest, prisoners of war ceased to recruit the ranks of slavery. Under Henry III and Edward I, socage tenants became more and more frequent; but, before long, their duties became less onerous, and might be discharged by others hired for the purpose, instead of by them- selves. The first remarkable vestige of a class working for wages is met with in the law of 1351, which may be considered an effort made by the nobility to opjfose the tendencies in. favor of emancipation, which were a consequence of the development of cities. (Eden, State of the Poor, I, 7, 12, 30, 41,) Infra, § 175. Although the peasant war under Wat Tyler and Straw, who wished to abolish servitude at a blow, failed of its object, we find that there were a gi-eat many instances of emancipation by individuals in the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries when death or sickness overtook them, in which they declared the moral unfitness of slavery. (Wycliffe: "When Adam dalve and Eve span, who was then the gentleman.?") Elizabeth lib- erated the last serfs of the crown. Compare 12 Charles II, ch. 24, 1660. Emancipation in the lowlands of Scotland was completed in 1574. (Tytler, Hist, of Scotland, II, 260.) '" Modern Emancipation Laws: in Pru&sia, 1719, 1S07, 1S19; Lausitz; 1S20, Westphalia; in Austria, 1781 (Bohemia and Moravia), 1782 (other German countries and Galicia); 1785 (Hungaria); Schleswig-Holstein, 1804, after many of the landed gentry had voluntarily emancipated their own serfs; in Bavaria, in 180S; in the kingdom of Westphalia, in 180S; in Hessen-Darm- stadt, in i8ii; in Wiirttemberg, in 1S17; in Baden, in 17S3, 1820 in newly acquired countries; in Mecklenburg, in 1820; in the kingdom of Saxony, in 1832; in Hano\«er, in 1833. The laAV of 1702, abolishing sei-fdom in Den- mark, was evaded until 17SS, and in part, even until iSoo bv the Schollband Sec. LXXIV.] EMANCIPATION. 225 evils. No man is " born free,"^ but only with a faculty for freedom; but this faculty must be developed. The knowl- edge and respect for law, and the self-control, which are the conditions and limits of freedom, are never acquired without labor, seldom without the making of grave mistakes, and never except through the practice of them,. As a rule, both parties, masters as well as servants, would like to get rid immediately of all the inconveniences of the former condition and yet con- tinue to enjoy its advantages. The servant, for instance, will now yield no more the specific obedience of former times, but demands still specific mildness from the land-owner, or loaner of capital, his former master. It is inevitable that there should be complaints on both sides.- But in the higher stages of eco- nomic culture, the relation of paternal protection and childlike (clod-bond) introduced in its stead. The only Christian people in Europe, Avho, until recently, kept serfs, was the Russian. The serfs of Russia, in 1S34, numbered 22,000,000, i. e., about 40 per cent, of the entire population In the meantime, the law of FebruarA'- 19, 1S61, passed after four years of preparation, fixed the date of emancipation at the beginning of the year 1S63. Slavery has been abolished in the United States since January i, 1S63; first of all in all portions of the country engaged in rebellion. " There is a very interesting discussion in the Journ. des Economistes for June 1S63, of the question whether the owners of serfs are entitled to com- pensation on their emancipation, by Laboulaye, WoloivsM^ Lavcrgne^ Garnier, Simon and others. In the United States it would have required $2,000,000,000 to fully compensate the slave-holders for depriving them of their slaves. (Quart. R., Jan., 1S74, 142.) Compare my view, RoscJicr, Nationalokonomik des Ackerbaues, § 124. ' Leave a new-born child to its " natural freedom " for t^venty-four hours, and it will in all probability be dead at the end of the time ! "^ Compare Edinburgh Review, LXXXIII, 64 if., April, 1S51, 333. Klein's Annalen XXV, 70, ft". Even in the fifth book of Moses, 15, 13, ff., we see that experience had taken into consideration that a freed serf without capital or landed property might very readily be in a worse condition than he was before. In the United States, the anticipation that the emancipated negroes might diminish in numbers has not been realized. The census of 1870 showed a negro population of 4,880,000, nearly ten per cent, more than in 1S60. The increase of the number of churches, schools and savings banks also bears testimony to the prosperity of the negro. (R. Somers, The South- ern States since the War, 1871.) Vol. L— 15 226 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ck. IV. obedience between the different classes of the people, which, even in medieval times, never obtained in all its purity, is cer- tainly unrecallable. Hence it is, that all hope of a better con- dition of things is based only on this, that the lower classes may as soon as possible attain to true independence.^ SECTION LXXV. THE SAME SUBJECT CONTINUED. Even in antiquity, the principal nations of the world could not keep the humanizing influence of civilization from mak- ing itself felt on their slaves. And if they did not go so far as to bring about the total abolition of slavery, it is unhesi- tatingly to be attributed to their religious inferiority.^ In Athens, during the Peloponnesian war, it was almost impossi- ble to distinguish the slaves from the poorer freemen by their looks or dress. Their treatment was mild in proportion as desertion was easier by reason of the smallness of the state or the frequency of war. It was forbidden to beat them; and only a court of justice could punish them with death.^ Eman- cipation, in individual cases, was very frequent, and the names of Agoratos and of the law-reviser Nicomachos show how great a part an emancipated slave might play in the nation.^ 3 y. S. Mill, Principles, lo, ch. 7. 1 As to the Jews, see Ezvald, Geschichte von Israel, I 2, p. 198. In general, see H. Wallon, Hist, de TEsclavage dans I'Antiquitd, II, 1S47. 2 Thucyd. IV, 27; XetwJ>h. De Re. rep. Art. I, 10 if., Arisfoph. Nubes, 6; Antipli. De Caede Herod, 727. In the "Frogs" of Aristophanes, the rela- tion between the slave Xanthias and his master is eloquent testimony to the good treatment he received. Slaves enjoyed great freedom of speech. (De- viosth. Phil. Ill, III.) Concerning masters accused of cruelty, see Demosth. ISIid. 529, 7. Athen. VI, 266. The slave who had been ill-treated might seek refuge in a temple, after which his master was compelled to sell him. (ScJiol. Arisioph. Equitt. 1309. Phdarcli, Thes. 36.) ' Slaves might purchase their own Ireedom with their fectdiiun. See Petit. Legg., Art. II, 179. There were many who lived entirely on their own ac- count, paying a certain duty or tax to their masters, and who were well able Sec. LXXV.] EMANCIPATION. 227 The helot system of the Lacedemonians preserved much longer a great deal more of medieval barbarism; but even here, we may infer from the frequent uprisings and emanci- pations of the helots, from their services in war etc., that their lot was made less hard than it had been.* Among the Romans, with whom war and conquest were so long considered ^ the principal means of acquisition, slav- ery was relatively very hard.^ But, later, there came to be several different grades of slavery (scrvi ordinarii and medias- tini etc.) ; and in slavery every, gradation denotes some ameli- oration of condition.''' The slave obtained the right to pos- sess resources of his own (fccidium)? In addition to this, to make savings, i?. i?'. //crwz«««, Privatalterthiimer, § 13, 9, 58, ii ft". See the instance in Plato, De Rep. VI, 495, where a slave who had grown wealthy asks the daughter of his former master in marriage. Moreover, there was a general indisposition to hold Greeks as slaves. (Pliilostr. Apoll. VIII, 7, 12.) The case cited in Demosth. adv. Nicostr. 1249 ft'., is all the stronger on this account. 4 Under Cleomenes, many purchased their freedom with their own means. Plutarch, Cleom. 23. At an earlier period, men like Lysandros, Gylippos, Kallikratidos had belonged to a class composed of the children of slaves brought up as citizens. 5 Cicero, pro Mursena, IX, 22. 6 Think of the subterranean ergasiula, the fettered door-keepers and the gladiatorial exhibitions. '' Even from the time of Plant us, the servi honcstiores were wont to keep -7'- carios, or subordinate slaves. Plant. Asin. I, 4, Seneca De Tranq. Anim. S. Compare Cicero, Farad. V, 2. Of the slaves of the state, the public scribes were sometimes found in excellent circumstances. *The peculium was fully developed in the time of Plautus and Terence. Compare Terent., Phorm. I, i. It was customary to promise slaves their freedom as soon as they had acquired a certain peculium. (Dionys. Hal., Antt. Rom., IV, 24. Tac, Ann., XIV, 42.) Humane masters permitted their slaves to dispose freely of their ;peculium by will. (Plin., Ep., VIII, 16.) There were many of the Romans who gave their slaves a fixed salary, from which they could make savings. (Scnec, Epist., 80, 7.) Shepherds raised some sheep for themselves alone. (Plaut., Asin., Ill, i, 36; Varro, R. R., I, 17,7.) Premiums were offered for certain products (Athen.,Yl,2^i^d^, and there were cases even in which businesses were farmed out to slaves. (Corp. Inscr. Gr., No. 4,713 f) The servi puhlici had the right to dispose of the half of what they owned, by will. (Ulp'au, XX, 16.) Contracts of loan 228 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. IV emancipation became much more frequent in the later repub- lic; so much so, that Augustus considered it necessary to pass laws taxing frivolous emancipation. (L. Aclia Scntia and Fiiria.) ^ Where men like Terence, Roscius, Tiro, Phccdrus and the father of Horace rose from the condition of slav- ery, the treatment of slaves cannot have been entirely brutal- izing.^° Under the emperors who oppressed the free citizens, legislation was directed more than ever towards the protec- tion of the slaves.^^ Instead of permanent slavery, a condition of things was introduced and became more general every day, one in which the bondman might contract a legal marriage, have property of his own, and in which he was protected against an arbitrary increase of the quota he had to pay his master, whether in money or produce, although he still re- mained bound to the land. This class was formed not only of the oi'iginarii, or those born into it, but also of a large number of impoverished freemen, barbarian prisoners of war etc.^^^^ were sometimes made between master and slave. (Plnt.^ Cato, I, 21, L., 49, § 2, Digest, XV, I.) ^Compare Tacit. ^ Ann., XIII, 26 seq. During the time from 356 to 211 A. C, it seems tliat there were, on an average, 1,380 slaves emancipated yearly. (Diireau de la Malle, Economie polit. des Remains, I, 290 fF.) ■0 Concerning the highly educated slaves of Atticus, of the like of whom the Greeks had formerly few examples, see Drumann, Geschichte Roms., V, 66. The high prices, 100,000, and even 200,000 sesterces, paid for slaves, suppose a very high degree of education. (Martial, I, 59; III, 62; XI, 70; Seneca, Ep., 27.) But even Cicero Avas ashamed of his affliction over the death of an exceptionally clever slave. (Ad. Att., I, 12.) '1 At an earlier period, even the censor had punished cruel masters. But most of what was done to prevent the arbitrary condemnation to death of slaves, their castration etc., and to give them rights against their masters for libidinous acts towards them, for cruelty and insufficient support, or the fur- nishing them with bad food, was done after the time of Hadrian. (Compare Scncca,de. Benef, III, 22; de Ira, III, 40, Siieton., Claud, 25, Dom., 7; Sj>ar- tian., Hadr., iS; Gaius, I, 53; L., i, § 2, Digest, I, 6; L., i, § 8, D., I, 12; L., I, § 2, D., XLVII, 8; L., i; Cod., IX, 14; Contra, see Dio Cass, I, V, 17.) However, the vitce necisque fotestas existed in the time of Justinian. (Zim- mem, Geschichte des rom., Privati-echts, I, 2, 661 ff.) ^'^Salvian, De Gubern. Dei, V, 8. Theod., Cad. V, 4. Eumenis^ Paneg. Sec. LXXVI.] THE DOMESTIC SERVANT SYSTEM. 229 SECTION LXXVI. (APPENDIX TO CHAPTER IV.) THE DOMESTIC SERVANT SYSTEM. In most countries the servant system developed itself grad- ually out of serfdom, or of some condition of tutelage analo- gous thereto. This is seen most clearly in the long continuance of forced service, by which the subjects of the lord of the fee were compelled to allow their children to remain in the court of the lord as servants, either without any remuneration what- ever, or for very low wages fixed by long continued custom.^ Here, also, belongs the right of correction, so generally ac- corded to masters in former times. In the higher stages of civilization, the whole relation is wont to be resolved more and more into freedom of competition ; and this process is wont to take place earliest and most strikingly in the cities. Where vast numbers of men are brought together, demand and sup- Coast. 8, 9. Trebell, Poll. Claud., 9. yustin. Cad., XI, 26, 47. Compare v. Savigny, Ueber den romischen Colonat. Berliner Akad., 1S22-23. "The figures given in ^l///c«., VI, 103, concerning the number of bond- men in Greece are almost incredible. For Attica alone, the estimates vary between 110,000 (Lclronne, in the Mem. de I'Academie des Inscr., 1822, 192, ff.) and 400,000 (Athen. 1. c), while the free men are estimated at from 130,000 to 150,000. In Rome, during the time from the e pulsion of the kings until the destruction of Carthage, the number of the slaves remained about the same. (Blair, State of Slavery among the Romans, 1S33, 10, 15.) On the other hand, Durcaic de la Malle is of opinion, that in 576 B. C, the number of slaves was to the number of free men as i to 25, and in 225 B. C. (including the metics), as 22 to 27. (Economic polit. des Romains I 270 ff., 296.) Com- pare Cato, de Re. rust. I, 3, IV, X, i XI; i, XVII, XVIII, i. In Germany, the number of bondmen, from the eighth to the tenth century, was estimated to be at least as great as that of free men. (Grimm, D. Rechtsaltherthiimer, 334.) Among the Anglo Saxons, before the Norman conquest, it Avas much higher, even three-fourths of the entire population. (Turner, Hist, of the A. S., VIII, 9.) Compare on the subject of this whole chapter my paper in the Archiv. der polit. CEkonomie, N. F., IV, 30 ff. 1 Klontrtipp, Abhandlung der Lehre vom Zwangsdienste, iSoi. Frequently, the lord had only a right of preference in case the children of the tenant de- sired to abandon the parental roof and take service elsewhere. 230 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Cii. IV. ply of services meet most easily. The nearer in the course of this development the servant system approaches to piece-wages and day-wages, the shorter does the customary (presumptive) duration of the contract last / the more voluntary is the period of leave-taking by both parties ; ^ the more does the entire re- lation tend to be limited to single acts of service agreed upon in advance (§ 39), and the more frequently do both parties en- deavor to supply the place of the domestic servants by work- men who receive wages and live outside of the family.* The extreme of this direction at present is the servant-institutes in cities, the more movable and more democratic character of which finds expression in this, that they have extended the use of personal services to a lower circle of consumers than could previously have thought of employing them. In Eng- - In Adam SmiWs time, in England, the presumption was that a servant had been hired for a year. (I, 2, 15 ed., Bas.) Frederick the Great's ordi- nance of 1769, on this subject, forbade any one to enter into service for a sliorter time than this (II, § i ff.), while the Saxon ordinance of 1835, on the same matter, allowed engagements by the month, in cities. Darjes, Erste Griinde der Cameralwissenschaften, 2d ed. (176S), p. 432, demands that ser- vants should always hire themselves for at least four or five years, and that their masters should have, during the whole of this time, the right to enforce the contract. In North America, however, service by the month has become customary and general, and no notice of th-e dissolution of the contract is, as a rule, required. (Deutsche Vierteljahrsschrift, 1S53, II, 191.) In Switzerland, contracts for service by the week are frequently made even by country serv- ants. (Bokmeri, Arbeiterverhh., II, 157.) 3 In the south of England, farm hands were used to change service only at Michaelmas. The choice of such a date made farmers very dependent on them, as it fell in harvest time. (Marshall^ Rural Economy of the Southern Countries, II, 233.) A similar complaint in Cleves. (Schiverz, Rheinisch- westphalische Landw., 21 if.) In jUlich, a half year's notice was required, during which time the servant who had received it, performed his work with disgust, and stirred up his fellow servants against their master. (Sclnverz, n, 87.) 4 The families of day laborers, to whom the owner of the land gives the use of a house, small garden, a cow etc., constitute such a transition ; and also, workmen Avho are fed. In Brandenburg, in 1644, only married persons or widowers with children were permitted to work as day laborers. (My- UuSy C. C. March., V, 1, 3, 11.) Sec. LXXVI.] the DOMESTIC SERVANT SYSTEM. 231 lish agriculture this transition was completed mainly in the third decade of this century. The change was unquestionably favorable to the improvement of the art of agriculture, but it was frequently damaging to the social relation existing be- tween the rich and the poor in the country.^ In Germany, the sale of the public domains, conscription and Landwehr duty have operated in this direction.^ Hence it is, for instance, that in Prussia, the servants, in 1816, were 15.18 per cent, of the entire male population over 14 years of age, and 17.84 per cent, of the entire female population over 14 years of age. In 1861, on the other hand, there were only 11.88 and 12.93 per cent., respectively, while the number of day laborers and work- men, in the same time, increased from 16.29 P^^ cent, males, and 10.87 psr cent, females, to 20.95 and 16.65 P^^ cent., re- spectively.'' In most civilized countries, the grade of society 5 Wakefield, Swing Unmasked, or the Causes of rural Incendiarism, 1S31. * By means of the former, the number of independent small householders was much increased in the country. Masters feel indisposed to hire young men liable to be subjected to military duty, because they may be called away at the moment their services are most needed. The returning soldier, as a rul£, feels above doing menial service. (Schtverz, passim, I, 191 ff., 236.) On this account, servants' wages in Cleves rose much higher than those of day laborers. (194-) In Belgium, a farm hand cost, on an average, 400 francs a year ; a day laborer, counting 300 working days to the year, only 339 francs. (Horn, Statist. Gemalde, 175.) In the Palatinate, day labor- ers who receive nothing but their wages cost their masters less than those who receive only their food ; and servants are the dearest of all. (Hanssci/., Archiv der Politischen OEkonomie, N. F. X, 243.) If servants were rela- tively more poorly paid in 1813 than day laborers (Lofz, Revision, III, 147), it was because of the at least temporary retrogression of civilization which every great war causes. "> Engel^ Preuss. Statist. Jahrb., II, 261. Services which contribute to per- sonal convenience are naturally committed much less frequently to inde- pendent day laborers than those which aid in production proper. Hence it is, that, as civilization advances, house-servants, especially of the female sex, constitute an ever-increasing portion of the total number of servants. In Prussia, in 1816, the number of servants who ministered to personal comfort was only 4.19 per cent, of the total number of servants engaged in industry; of female servants, it was 13.4 per cent. In 1S61, on the other hand, the percentages were 8.4 and 37.2. In Great Britain, of the total number of 232 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. IV. from which servants are recruited grows lower and lower as the spirit of independence extends to the deeper strata of hu- manity.^ The servant class may continue a long time yet to be a school of development for those of the lower classes, who, ripe in body, are not intellectually independent; just as the duty of bearing arms has been a school of improvement for all male youth. Life-long servants are as seldom to be desired as life- long soldiers. In most places, the long transition period from complete bondage to free competition was governed by a police system of wardship, which was very unfavorable to the servant class. Such especially was the provision that all young people of the lower classes, who could not expressly show that they were employed under the paternal roof or at some trade, should be compelled to seek some outside or inland work;^ such also was the strict prohibition of "usurious" wage-claims, and the " decoying " of servants from their masters.^'' Besides, a servants over 20 years of age, only 2 per cent, were engaged in personal services. In 1841, they were 3^ per cent. (Alcidmger.) In France, in 1S51, 2.5 per cent, of the whole population were in domestical. (Stat, off^) * In England, now more especially, out of farm-hand day laborers : Edin- burgh Rev., April, 1S62. 9 A chief element in the earlier " organization of labor." So, also, in the Magdeburg Gesindeordnung (service-i-egulation) of 1789. 't* Saxon Landcsordnungoi of 1482 and 1543. Cod. August. I, 3, 23. The Gcsindeordninig (service regulation) of Frederick the Great, threatened with the house of correction the receivers, and under certain circumstances also the givers of wages higher than the fixed rate ofwagesjbutas a "matter of course," the payment of wages less than this was permitted. (V, § 7.) Great care was taken that wages greater than the law allowed should not be evaded by the payment of arrha or payment in produce. The same law forbade the deprivation of the servant of his right to determine the service by making of loans to him on long time (II, § 7.) Even v. Berg., Handbuch des deutschen Polizeirechts, calls it a duty of the public authorities charged with the protection of property and of the public security, to see to it that there be no lack of good servants, and that the public (as if those who sell their services were not a part of it) should not be made the victims of exor- bitant demands in the matter of servants' wages. Jung., more humane, de- Sec. LXXVI.] THE DOMESTIC SERVANT SYSTEM. 233 great many provisions relating to servants, and based on views belonging to an older economic condition, were intended to throw obstacles in the way of farm hands and country serv- ants ^^ becoming servants in towns ; and, on the other hand, to facilitate the speedy abandonment of service in all cases in which the servant desired to marry.^^ All these preferences in favor of one class of contractors, and at the cost of another, are radically opposed to the modern political spirit. The laws relating to servants are wont, in our day, to have but one ob- ject, the prevention, by registration with the police, of fraud and breach of contract, and of all strife and litigation by the legally formulating of the conditions which are very frequently tacitly understood. The ideal of the relation of master and servant is attained when it is considered by both as a part of the life of a Christian family.^^ Hence, benevolence on the one side and devoted- ness on the other, fidelity on both sides, disinterested care for the present and future interests each of the other tanqiiam sua\ and especially for each other's eternal future. Whether this state of mutual feeling is best furthered by the patriarchal system, by a police system, or by free competition, it is scarcely possible to say. It may, however, be affirmed that it depends upon a mutual and continued denial of self not easy to attain. mands that the authorities shall protect, especially, the weaker party. (Grund- lehre der Staatswirthschaft, 1792, 700.) In Prussian legislation, the Silesian rescript of March 13, 1S09, is the beginning of the new order of things. (Rabe, Samml. preuss. Gesetze, X, 59 ft") The Obertribunal, or high court, decided, in 1S74, ^^'^^^ the bringing back of absconding servants by the police, which the law concerning servants of 18 10 provided for, should not be al- lowed to occur any more. " Ordinance of the elector of Saxony of 1766, prohibiting the inhabitants of cities to take an apprentice from among the peasantry, unless he had served at least four years as a farm hand, beginning with his fourteenth yeai*. Sim- ilarly, in Prussia in 17S1. 12 In Berlin, even before the " populationistischen " period : Fidkin, Histor. diplom. Beitrage zur Gesch. der Stadt Berlin, I, loi. (From the year I397-) 13 1 Peter, 2, iS ft".; I Timoth., 6, 12; Ephes., 6, 5; Philem., 15 ft". 234 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. IV. Where it really prevails, all the advantages of the piece-work system are obtained in a worthy and organic manner, and without its atomistic drawbacks.^* '* In the German colonies of Mennonites in Russia, every youth serves a few years in the family of some other peasant. This is considered a sort of school. Wages are of course very large, and the treatment very mild. v.Haxthauscn^ Studien, II, 1S5. Southwestern Germany where small landed proprietors are many, something very analogous to this continues, (v. d. GoUz, loc. cit., 452.) Sec. LXXVII.] CAPITAL. 233 CHAPTER V. COMMUNITY OF GOODS AND PRIVATE PROPERTY. CAPITAL — PROPERTY. SECTION LXXVII. CAPITAL. — IMPORTANCE OF PRIVATE PROPERTY. As human labor can attain its fiill development, only on the supposition that personal freedom is allowed to develop to its full economic importance and dimensions, so capital can de- velop its fuU productive power only on the supposition of the existence of the freedom of personal property. Who would save anything, that is, give up present enjoyment, if he were not certain of future enjoyment?^ The legitimacy of private property has, since the time of Locke," been based, by the greater number of political economists, on the right inherent in every workman, either to consume or to save the product of his labor. But it should not be forgotten here that, at least in the higher stages of the economy of a nation, scarcely any work or saving is possible without the cooperation of society. And society must be conceived not only as the sum-total of the now living individuals that compose it, but in its entire 1 For a masterly exposition of the doctrine that the right of prescription or limitation is related to the politico-economical necessity of property, see John Stuart Mill, Principles, 3, II, ch. 2, sec. 2. ^ Locke, On Civil Government, II, § 25-51 ; and so L. Mendelssohn^ Jerusa- lem (17S3), 32; Thiers, Du Droit de la Propriete (1S49). 23(5 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. V. past, present and future, and also as being led and borne on- ward by eternal ideas and wants.^ 3 Modern writers, in their attempt to find a philosophical basis for the right of propertj^, have taken two principal directions, the first a juridical, the sec- ond a political one. The axiom, res nnllius ccdit primo occupanti (compare L. 3, Digest, XLI, i), explains only the smallebt part of the relations of prop- erty, and that only because of a very fortuitous circumstance. According to Hobbes (Leviathan, 24), property has its origin in the recognition of it by the power of the state, by the autorite pullique^ the goiivcrnanent (Bossuet, Po- litique tiree de I'Ecriture, Sainte, L. 3, 4), or as Montesquieu (Esprit des Lois XX VL, 15) more mildly expresses it, in the laws. The application of this principle would, on account of the extreme changeableness of the laws of everj^ state, lead to most extreme insecurity, and to a steady oscillation from one Utopia to another, from one revolution to another, if it were not, at the same time, recognized that each one had a just title to the acquisitions he had made, not because the law, for the time being existing, acknowledged the right, but because they were the product of his labor and saving. The theory which bases the right of property on contract cannot be objected to with as much reason. Thus, Hugo Grotiiis, Jus Belli et Pacis, II, 2, who even justifies the occupation of things without an owner, on the supposition of the existence of an implied contract. It is very characteristic of the En- glish, that in their political language, the words " liberty " and " property " are so frequently found in each other's company. In one of his classic speeches made by Fox in 17S4, he gives a definition of liberty which be- gins with the words, " It consists in the safe and sacred possession of a man's property " etc. The recent doctrine, not unfrequently to be met with, that every man has a right to an amount of property corresponding to his wants, may be used to sanction all kinds of socialistic inferences. An entirely be- wildered and bewildering description is to be found in ProudhoiCs Qu'est ce que la Propriete, 1S48, as the precursor of which BrissoVs Recherches phil- osophiques sur le Droit de Propridte et le Vol, may be considered. In me- dieval times, there are always a multitude of other titles to property besides production and saving. The title which is held in highest esteem for the time being is always because of this very extreme vis-a-vis of all other titles, strengthened and made general. Sec. LXXVIII.] SOCIALISM AND COMMUNISM. 237 SECTION LXXVIII. SOCIALISM AND COMMUNISM. In opposition to this, the idea of a community of goods has found favor, especially in times when the four following con- ditions met:^ A. A xvcll-dcfincd confrontation of rich and -poor. So long as there is a middle class of considerable numbers between them, the two extremes are kept, by its moral force, from com- ing into collision. There is no greater preservative against env}?- of the superior classes and contempt for the inferior, than the gradual and unbroken fading of one class of society into another. Sf crate miser i^ cavcte f dices! In such a state of social organization, we find the utmost and freshest productive activity at every round of the great ladder. Those at the bottom are straining every nerve to rise, and those higher up, 1 The word socialism brought into use by L. Rcyhaud is as ambiguous as the Avord communism is simple and intelligible. But most socialists agree that actual " society " (which is indeed to be distinguished from the state) is, together with its foundations, the existing relations of property and the family, entirely wrong. A radical reconstruction, they say, is needed to remove forever the chief evil of this system, viz. : the glaring difference be- tween the rich and the poor, the educated and the uneducated. The differ- ence between the doctrines of the socialists and of Political Economy does not, by any means, consist in this, that the former concerns itself more with the welfare of the lower classes, or even that it gives wider scope to econ- omy in common. But socialism is, indeed, a living or housekeeping in common (Geineinivirthschaft)^ Avhich goes far beyond the feeling for the com- mon interest (^Gtvwe/w.s/ww^. Such economy in common is always opposed to freedom, and, at its first introduction, contrary to law. It can guaranty no compensation to those who have suffered from violence or force, because it leads to a thoughtless and wasteful exhaustion of the nation's resources, in- asmuch as it weakens the incentive to industry and frugality. Political Econ- omy, on the other hand, recommends an expropriation when the incentives to industry and frugality are thereby strengthened; and the increased re- sources thus obtained serve it, as full compensation to those whose property has been exj>roj>riated. 238 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. V. not to fall below. But where the rich and the poor are sepa- rated by an abyss which there is no hope of ever crossing, how pride on the one side and envy on the other rage! and especially in the foci of industry, the great cities, where the deepest misery is found side by side with the most brazen- faced luxur}^, and where the wretched themselves conscious of their numbers, mutually excite their own bad passions. It cannot, unfortunately, be denied, that when a nation has at- tained the acme of its development, we find a multitude of tendencies prevailing to make the rich richer and the poor, at least relatively poorer, and thus to diminish the numbers of the middle class from both sides; unless, indeed, remedial in- fluences are brought to bear and to operate in a contrary direction.^ B. A high degree of the division of labor ^ by which, on the one hand, the mutual dependence of man on man grows ever greater, but by which, at the same time, the eye of the uncul- tured man becomes less and less able to perceive the connec- tion existing between merit and reward, or service and re- muneration. Let us betake ourselves in imagination to Cru- soe's island. There, when one man, after the labor of many months, has hollowed out a tree into a canoe, with no tools but an animal's tooth, it does not occur to another who, in the meantime was, it may be, sleeping on his bear-skin, to contest the right of the former to the fruit of his labor. How differ- ent this from the condition of things where civilization is ad- vanced, as it is in our day; where the banker, by a single stroke of his pen, seems to earn a thousand times more than a day-laborer in a week ; where, in the case of those who loan money on interest, their debtors too frequently forget how laborious was the process of acquiring the loaned capital by the possessors, or their predecessors in ownership. More es- pecially, we have, in times of " over-population," whole masses ■^ See RoscJicr, Betrachtungen iiber Socialismus und Communismus, Ben liner Zeitschrift fiir Gcschichtwissenschaft, 1S45, III, 422 ff. Sec. LXXVIII.] SOCIALISM AND COMMUNISM. 039 of honest men asking not alms, but onl}^ work, an opportunity to earn their bread, and yet on the verge of starvation.^ C. A violent shaJciiig- or -pcrflcxing cf ■public opinion in its relation to the feeling of Rights by rczvlidions^ especially when they follow rapidly one on the heels of another, and take oppo- site directions. On such occasions, both parties have generall}'- prostituted themselves for the sake of the favor of the masses ; and the latter have become conscious of the changes which the force of their arms may effect. In this way, it is impossible that until order is again entirely established, the reins of power should not be slackened in many ways at the demands of the multitude. In this way, too, they are stirred up to the making of pretentious claims which it is afterwards very difficult to silence. In every long and far-reaching revolution, whether undertaken in the interest of the crown, the nobility or the middle classes, we find, side by side with the seed it intended to sow, the tares of communism sprout up. D. Pretensions of the lozver classes in consequence of a demo- cratic constitution. Communism is the logically not inconsist- ent exaggeration of the principle of equality. Men who al- ways hear themselves designated as " the sovereign people," and their welfare as the supreme law of the state, are more apt than others to feel more keenly the distance which sepa- rates their own misery from the superabundance of others. And, indeed, to what an extent our ph3'sical wants are deter- mined by our intellectual mould ! The Greenlander feels com- fortable in his mud hut, with his oil-jug. An Englishman in the same condition would despair.^ ^ 2 Vivre en travaillant ou moiirir en comhattant — the device on the flags of the mutinous silk-weavers at Lyons, in 1S32. 4 We are so assured by Vmihan (Dime Royale, 34 seq.), of the later years of the reign of Louis XIV., that nearly -^^ of the French people begged, that y^^ could give no alms, because they Avere themselves on the very brink of indigence; -^^ were fort malaisis^ embarassds de defies ct de frocks; scarcely one per cent, could be said to he fort d, leiir aise. How much better off is the present Parisian Avorkman ! And yet, at that time, there was not the least spread of communistic doctrines. It is indeed seldom that com 240 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. V. SECTION LXXIX. SOCIALISM AND COMMUNISM. (CONTINUED.) What has just been said will serve to explain why, in the following four periods of the world's history, socialistic and communistic ideas have been most widespread: among the ancients at the time of the decline of Greece,^ and in that of the degeneration of the Roman Republic f among the mod- pletely doAvn-trodden men react against their wretchedness with great en- ergy. 5 " If my caj>rtce be the source of law, then my enjoyment may be the source of the division of the nation's resources." StaJil, Rechtsphilosophie, II, 2, 72. • Tliat the socialism of Plaio, De Repub., V, was no mere fancy, is proved by the polemic which Aristophanes directs against it in his Ecclesiazuses. See also Aristot., Polit., II, 2, Schn. In the contemporary practice of the Greeks, with the increasing democratization of the state, it became more and more usual for it to bear the expense of the outlay for the means of subsist- ence of the great crowd. (See PlutarcJi, Cimo, 10.) Every act of public life was paid for. Citizens were paid for attending popular meetings three oboli per day, while the pay of the soldiers was six, and that of the sailors three. (Thucyd., Ill, 17; VII, 27; VIII, 45.) The pay of the commonest day lab- orer was from three to four oboli per day. Aristophan., Eccl., 310, and Pollux, VII, 29. The number of magistrates was very large, in order that as many as possible might participate in this species of remuneration. Thus, in Athens, when it had only about 20,000 inhabitants, there were 6,000 judges. In addition to all this, there were numberless feasts, plays, banquets etc., which were offered to the people gratis. The wealthy who were compelled to meet all the expense thus incurred, lived in such a state of terror of the populace, that they considered their own impoverishment as a species of deliverance. (Xenoph., Conviv., 4, and Lysias^ pro Bonis.) Isocrates called it much more dangerous to be rich than to commit a crime, since in the latter case one might obtain a pardon or a mild punishment. (De Permut., p. 160.) (Ly- sias, De Invalido, de sacra Olea, seq.) There is little difference between this state of things and a semi-community of goods. Only that, indeed, the great mass of the slaves were excluded from enjoying them. The contrast which somewhat later distinguished the Cynics from the Cyreno-Epicureans af- fords a striking analogy to that which, in our own times, exists between the pure socialists and the worshipers of mammon after the fashion of Doctor Ure. Concerning the Utopia of lamdulos, see Diodor., II, 55 ff. ''■ Our sources of inlbrmation concerning the division of tlie Roman repub- lic into a moneyed oligarchy, and the proletariat are very numerous. Com Sec. LXXX.] SOCIALISM AND COMMUNISM. 0^1 erns in the age of the Reformation,^ and again, in our own day.* SECTION LXXX. SOCIALISM AND COMMUNISM. (CONTINUED.) We thus see, that the attempts made by socialism and com- munism are, by no means, phenomena unheard of in the past, pare vi/ra, § 205. The speeches of the Gracchi (e. g. Pint., T. Gracchus, 9), and still more the violent discourses of Catiline's conspiracy (Sallusi, Cat., -Oj 23, 37-39), remind us very forcibly of the shibboleths of modern social- ism. We very frequently meet with the expression of a longing desire to return to the most uncivilized and hoary past, when there was no money and no wealth — an aspiration which lies at the very foundation of communisjii. Thus Virgil, Geo., I, 125, ff., Tibiill. I, 3, 35, ff. Propert. II, 13, III, 5, 11; Seneca, Epist., 90; Soicc., Oct. II, Hippol., II, ■2\Plin., H. N. XXXII, 3. On the other hand, the practice of supporting the populace at the expense of great candidates or of the state, was developed to a very great extent. The masses lived very largely by the sale of their right of suffrage to the highest bidder. At the election of consuls in the year 54, 500,000 thalers were oftered to the century called on to vote first. (Cicero, ad Quintum II, 15; ad. A. H. IV, 15.) Even Cato had a part in such bribery. (Siieton., Caes., 19.) In the social reform of the younger Gracchus, besides the limitation of large land- ownership, the principal points were the following: the sale of wheat under the market price, but only to the inhabitants of Rome itself; the construc- tion of great highways in Italy ; colonization at the expense of the state, and the increase of soldiers' pay. (Ritsch, Gracchen, 392 if.) The socialistic plans of RuUus went much further. Were his agi-arian laws put in execution, he Avould have confiscated very nearly the entire country in the interest of the poor, and of their demagogues ! (Cicero, De Lege agrar.) Rome twicx; ex- perienced a social revolution of the most frightful character, one by which a great portion of all private goods fell into the hands of the propertyless (sol- diers), who knew nothing of how to turn it to account or to invest it — under Sulla, and then under the later Triumviri. (Compare Appian, Bell, civil., V, 5, 22.) Complaints concerning the latter, in Horat., Epist., I, 3, 49; Virgil, Buc, IX, 28; Tibiill. I, I, 19, IV, 1, 1S2; Propert., IV, i, 129. The elder Gracchus had promised compensation to the last possessors. Tabula: novce of Cinna, Catiline, Ca;lius, Dolebella. Clodius introduced the distribution of wheat, which according to Cicero pro Sext., 25, ate up almost one-fifth ot the public revenues. About 320,000 persons were, in this way, supported for a long period of time (Sueton., Caes, 41, Dio C, XLIII, 21; L. LV, 10), but only in such a manner as to keep them from starvation. (Sallttst, 26S ed. Vol. L— 16 212 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Cn. V. and peculiar to modern times, as the blind adherents and op- ponents of them would have us believe. They are rather dis- Bip.) To all this was soon added distributions of salt, meal and oil, also free baths, numberless public plays, colossal banqueting, payment of one year's rent etc. Panem ei circenses! (Juvenal, X, So seq.) The mere distribution of money under Augustus, in Avhich from 200,000 to 320,000 men participa- ted, cost each time from 2,500,000 to 6,000,000 thalers. (Monum Ancyr., 373 Wolf.) Exti-aordinary assistance was, by way of preference, accorded to col- onies of the poor. (Sueton.^ Caes, 42.) Concerning this entire policy, see Plin., Paneg., 26 fF. Even in Constantinople, at the time of its foundation, large distributions of bread were made at the expense of Egypt, although there could scarcely be any real pauperism in that new and flourishing city. (Theod., Cod., XIII, 4, XIV 16; Socrat.^ II, 13. I can only allude to the plan proposed by the emperor Gallien by the neo-platonist Plotin, to found a city in which the ideas of Plato's republic should be carried out. (Porphyr., V, Plotin., 8.) 3 During the two centuries of which the Reformation constituted the mid- dle point, the transition from the peasant system of agriculture to the large farming system of modern times bore very heavily on the inferior classes. Such, too, was the operation of the fall in price of the precious metals. (§ 140.) The suppression of the many monasteries caused an increase in the wretchedness of the poor; and the numerous poor-laws enacted in England, Spain etc., were not sufficient to supply a remedy. The feeling of the peo- ple during this period of tribulation found expression in the War of the Peasants, in the sect of Anabaptists, in the many reformations and counter- reformations, in the revolt of the Netherlands, in the conflicts for the crown in France and England etc. In Italy, the conti-ast ex-isting between the moneyed oligarchy and the proletariat had been developed several centuries, but from the middle of the sixteenth century, it had become much more op- pressive by reason of the universal impoverishment of the country. For an account of the pantheistic " Brethren and Sisters of the Free Spirit," with their community of goods and of women, see Ullmaim, Reformatoren vor der Reformation, II, iS fF. They were very numerous from the thirteenth to the fifteenth century in Italy and France, as well as in Germany, and lead us to the Adamites in the Hussite war. (Aschbach^ Geschichte K. Sigis- munds. III, 109.) Earlier yet, we have the sect of the Giovannali, who had their property and women in common, and who, in 1355, had won the third of Corsica, but who were afterwards suppressed by Genoa and the Church. (Lebret^ Geschichte von Italien, VI, 20S flf.) The coarse socialist, John Balle, bears about the same relation to Wyclifle, that Miinzer and Bockholt did to Luther. (Walshigham^ Hist. Anglia; in Camden^ Scriptt.-, 2.^ <,) Hans Boheim of Wiirzburg, 1476, seems to be the direct precursor of Miinzer, (Ullmann, I, 421 ff.) It was almost as usual in Luther's time, as in 1S4S, or Sec. LXXX.] SOCIALISM AMD COMMUNISM. £43 eases of the body social, which have affected every highly civilized nation at certain periods of its existence. If the in our day, to hear of the deep demoralization of trade — the Fuggerei of the Germany of the time — and of the universal system of fraud that pre- vailed. See the citations in Hagen, Deutschland's Verhiiltnisse im Reform- Zeitalter, II, 313 ft". Miinzer's fundamental principle: Omnia simul commu- nia! Sebastian Frank, Chronica, Zeytbuch und Geschychtbibel etc., 1551, fol. VI, 16, 27, 116, 194, 414, 433. John Bockholt's life presents us with a striking contrast. While they were bringing his perfumed -women, sparkling with jew- els, to his rose-covered bed, hung with curtains of gold cloth, on which he was reclining, his subjects were a prey to the horrors of famine, to such an ex- tent that they were compelled to salt the bodies of children who had died of starvation. How frightful the end of this cominunistic benefactor of man- kind! Libertine community of goods and women. (Calvin, Instructio adv. Libertinos, cap. 21.) English communists in the age of the reformation. (J. Story, Comment, on the Constitution of the U. S., I, 36.) Even under Cromwell, there were many Englishmen who believed that farmers were no longer obliged to pay rent to land-owners. On the sect of Levellers, see Walker, History of the Independency, II, 152. Even in Erasmus, \;e find some sympathy with communism. (Enchirid. milit. Christ, 80.) Contra, see Mclanchthon, Prolegg. in Cic. de Off., Corp. Reform, XVI, 549 ft". The most remarkable systematic works of this period are Thomas Mare's, Utopia, 1516, and Campanelld! s Civitas, solis, 1620. Thomas More bluntly says that all ex- isting governinents are in fact only permanent conspiracies of the rich to further their OAvn interests under the mask of the common good, and to de- spoil labor. The abolition of money, which should be continued in use only to carry on foreign war, Avould, he contends, remove all misery. There was no really private property in his Utopia. There should be a rigid superin- tendence of all work by the public authorities, whose duty it should be to see to it, that no one should abandon agricultural pursuits. All should eat at a common table and dress after the same fashion. Internal commerce should give way to a mutual exchange of gifts under the supervision of the state. Camfanella, besides a community of goods, recommends continually varying occupation, to last not more than four hours daily ; education in common, especially by means of pictures, popular encyclopedias etc., all under the su- preme guidance of a despotism to be composed of the wise, some secular and some spiritual, operating through the confessional. Socialists nearly always succeed better in the critical part of their works than in the positive. Compare R. Mohl, Geschichte und Literatur der Staatswissenschaften, § i, 165 ft". ^ Considering the aversion exhibited against private property by J. J. Rousseau, and the unlimited power which he accords to the majority for the time being in the state (Contrat Social, 1761, IT, ch. 4), it cannot 24:4: PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Cii. V. body be too weak to react healthily and curatively (§ 84), the evil is very apt to lead to the decline of all true freedom and be denied that his freedom and equah'ty contain, to say the least, germs of communism by no means insignificant. But, he would, in the present state of civil society, have a feeling of respect for the rights of property implanted in the mind. of the child very early, and even before the feeling of liberty is developed. (Emilef 1762, Livre II.) About the same time Morelly published his Basiliade ou Naufrage des lies flottantes, 1753, a political romance in the interest of communism. See the same author's Code de la Nature, 1755. JMably, in his two works, Doutes proposes aux Economistes, 1768, and La Legislation ou Principesdes Lois, 1776, recommended the abolition of all ine- quality and a real community of goods. The introduction of property seems to him, unefaute qii'il dtait j>resque impossible de faire. Even Bcccaria calls property a dreadful but perhaps a necessary right which has left to the un- fortunate nothing but a naked existence. (Dei Delitti e delle Pene, 1765, cap 22.) The French Reign of Terror came pretty near carrying these ideas into effect. We need only refer to the abolition of the census, the payments made to the workingmen who attended the section meetings, two francs per diem, the enormous extension of confiscation, requisitions and forced loans, the revolution effected in the fortunes of individuals by the system of issuing as- signats, the maximum affixed to the price of all the necessaries of life, the abolition of indirect taxes, and of what remained of the economic institutions handed down from the middle ages. According to St. yust: V opulence est une infamie; il ne faut ni riches ni fauvres. The Cahier des Pauvres de- mands, first of all, that salaries " should no longer be estimated in accord- ance with the mui-derous principles of unbridled luxury." See Forster's letter dated November 15, 1793. (Sammtl. Schriften, IX, 125.) On the conspiracy of Baboeuf, who was executed in 1796, and who wanted to see the completest equality and community of labor, of enjoyment and education, the abolition of large cities etc., see Buotiarott{,'L,2t. Conjuration de.B., 182 1. This book contributed powerfully towards the revival of communistic ideas after the July revolution. Among modern communists who are to be distinguished from the more ancient, especially by the industrial coloring given to their theories, Cabet, Voyage en Icarie, 1840, II, holds a very prominent place. He declares the abolition of religion, of the family and of the state, to be open questions, and desires to bring the practice of a community of goods to a successful issue only through the peaceful channel of convic- tion. Compare Reybaud, Etudes sur les Rdformateurs contemporains ou Socialistes modernes, 1840. L. Stein, Der Socialismus und Communismus des heuti- gen Frankreich. See, also, the learned history of socialistic systems in Mario'' s WeltOkonomie, I, 2, 435 ff. ; and in what concerns the most recent time, R. Meyer, Der Emancipationskampf des vierten Standes, II, 1S74, seq. : Sec. LXXX.] SOCIALISM AND COMMUNISM. 245 order. The communist, viewing all other things, especially the organization of the state, only as instruments to supply his material and absolute wants, considers the liberal either as a fool who is ever pursuing the phantoms of the brain, or as a knave who covers his own selfishness under the mask of the public welfare.^ Hence the adherents of communism are sat- tisfied with any form of government which seems to ofTer them most, and this a ruthless despotism can do, at least, for the moment. And, although they are ever ready for any revolu- tion in the form of government, and easily to be won "over to it, they are most readily captivated by a despotic revolution. On the other hand, when communism seriously threatens all that constitutes the wealth of a people, the owners of that wealth are compelled to fly to any refuge which holds out the promise to protect them from it, although by seeking that same refuge they may destroy their own political fi-eedom." The Achean league, which under the leadership of Aratos, the "enemy of tyrants," had come into existence, promising so much hope, beheld itself later, and mainly through fear of the contagious effects of Spartan socialism under Cleomenes, com- a book which, in £pite of its many defects, both doctrinal and journalistic, is as rich in thought, and in the knowledge of the subject it treats of, as it is permeated by a love of truth regardless of consequences. Among the op- ponents of socialism and communism, Malthus, On Population, B. Ill, ch. 3, and B. Hildebrand, Die Nationalokonomie der Gegenwart und Zukunft, vol. I, 1S48, hold a very distinguished place, y. S. Mill, Principles, II, ch. i, 3, calls attention to the fact that hitherto the principle of free property has never been consistently carried out. The first social arrangement of modern society was almost everywhere the result of conquest and violence, large ti-aces of which yet remain. Things have always been made property which ought not to be property. Governments have endeavored to intensify the darkness of the dark side of property, and favored the concentration instead of the diffusion of wealth etc. Hence, no one can claim that the social wrongs, so-called, had their origin in property as such. ScJidffle^ Kapitalis- mus und Socialismus, 1S70, has made a very note- worthy effort to recognize whatever of truth there is in socialism, and to combat its errors. ' Saint Simoii's reproach to the liberals, that their fundamental principle was : 6ie-toi de Id, que je tn^y mette, is well known. ' Compare Malthus, Additions to the Essay on Population, 1S17, IV, ch. 7 246 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ck. V. pelled to unite with the Macedonians, that is, to give them- selves up entirely. (§ 204). SECTION LXXXI. COMMUNITY OF GOODS. We now, for the present, turn our gaze from the frightful revolution, destructive of all civilization, which would neces- sarily precede the establishment of a community of goods,^ and inquire what would be the consequences. Among angels (" gods and sons of gods " of Plato) and mere animals, a com- munity of goods might, perhaps, exist without producing in- jury. And so, too, it might exist among men bound one to the other by the bonds of the truest love. The life of every model family is accompanied by a species of community of goods.^ But in more extensive social organizations, this love is never found except as an element of the most exalted relig- ious enthusiasm, which, as a rule, is of very short duration; of which the Acts of the Apostles (II, 44 ff, 32 ff, V, I, II) aflbrds us the best known and most beautiful example." ^ The travatlleurs igalitaires wished to murder not only the king, the court, and the ministry, but also the Liberals and all owners of property. ^ As soon, indeed, as this true love disappears in the married state, the com- munity of goods even there degenerates only too easily into a spoliation of the better party by the worse. 3 The community of goods of the first Christians at Jerusalem, so frequently cited and extolled ( James^ I, i), was only a community of use, not of owner- ship (Acts IV, 32), and, throughout, a voluntary act of love, not a duty (V. 4), least of all, a right which the poorer might assert. Spite of all this, that com- munity of goods produced a chronic state of poverty in the church of Jeru- salem. Hence, Paul had collections taken up for them on all sides, without, however, anywhere establishing a similar institution. (Romans, 15, 26; I. Corinth., 16, i.) Compare Alosheim, De vera Natura Communionis Bonorum in Ecclesia Hierosol., in his Dissertatt. ad Histor. Eccles. pertinentes, II, i ft". As to -whQihQr Ba7'nabas (Epist., 19) desired to say anything more, compare Epist. ad Diognetum, 5. For a real recommendation of a commuuity of goods, on economic grounds, see yoh. Clirysosfom., in Acta Apost., Hom. XI. Also Cle- mens Rom. c. 2 C. 12, qu. I. Community of goods among the Essenes: Pkilo. Sec. LXXXI.] COMMUNITY OF GOODS. 247 Where this love does not exist, each participant in the com- munity of goods will, as a rule, seek to do the least and enjoy the most possible.* In a society of one hundred thousand Opp. II. 457 ff. Joseph. Bell, Jud., II. 8. Bcllcrmamiy Geschichtliche Nach- richten iiber die Essener. (1S21.) In many monasteries, there has been and is a species of community of goods. There ^v■as once a singular contest on this subject, carried on between the Minorites and tlie Pope, in tlie time of Louis of Bavaria. The Minorities claimed that property was a thing, so much to be condemned, that even food, at the moment of eating it, did not belong to the person using it. The Pope taught on the other hand, that even Christ and the Apostles possessed property, part personal and part in com- mon. (Raynaldi, Ann. eccL, XV, 241, 2S5 ff.) Community of goods of the Homiliates, later of the Brothers of Common Life, after the manner of the monks, but of a much higher kind. ( Ullinaiin, Reformatoren v. d. Reform, II, 62 ft") The first settlers of New Haven, Connecticut, held their proj^erty in common. Land was divided among families in proportion to the number of persons in them, and of the number of cattle they had brought with them; and all sales and purchases were made on account of the whole community. And so in Massachusetts during the first seven years of the colony's exist- ence. (Ebeliuff, Geschichte und Erdbeschreib. der Vereinigten Staaten, II, 391, 1, 557.) Hcrrnhut community of goods in Pennsylvania, from 1742 to 1762, but which was done away with when the number of colonists became too great. (Rbeling, IV, 717.) Community of goods of the Shakers and Lu- theran Rappers. (Bucl-tnff/iain,^di?,\.QYn. States, 11,214, 4'7- Prinz Netnvied, Reise in Nord Amerika, I, 136, ft'.) Russian sects with community of goods. (v. Haxthatisen, I, 366, 407.) Harlcss, christliche Ethik § 50', distinguishes very well between the "anti-christian" and "pseudo christian" stand point, from which it is sought to establish the doctrine of a community of goods. The Christian view of this subject (compare Ephes., 4, 28, I; Thess., 4, ii,II, 3, 12; Matth., 6, 24 ; Pet. 4, 10 ; Matth., 26, 7-1 1) is accused of hypocrisy by many so- cialists. It is very easy, they say, when one is himself in comfortable cir- cumstances, to represent to the poor that their poverty is a school for heaven, and to preach a contempt for riches etc. They entirely forget, that the first promulgation of the Gospel was made at a time when the worst kind of pau- perism prevailed ; and that even the Master Himself, and the greater number of His Apostles belonged to theloAvest stratum of society. Luke,% 58. Many of the Fathers of the Church, however, in their exhortations to benevolence, used language in which modern Socialists have found a rich mine which they have sedulously worked. ('Compare Villegardcllc, Ilistoire des Idees so- ciales, IS46, 61 ft".) ^ Even Aristotle says that what is common to many is a matter of little concern to any one. (Polit., II, i.) Bastiat remarks: "We compete to-day to see who works most and best. Under another regime, we should emulate 248 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. V. members, each individual would be interested in the results of its aggregate frugality only indirectly, and only to the extent of a one-hundred thousandth part of the whole ; that is, practi- cally, not at all.^ Individual selfishness would expend itself entirely on the division of what the whole community pro- duced. It would, consequently, and almost always be detri- mental to the whole, and to the other individuals of the society; whereas, at present, it does so only in exceptional cases. When Louis Blanc, as Mably had before him, recom- mended that the -point cV homicur should take the place of the interet -personnel, as a spur to production, and a check on con- sumption, and cited the army as an illustration of its workings, he forgot, among other things, the thirty cases in which the one another to see who should work least and worst." (Harmonies Econ., ch. VIII.) When the first settlers of Virginia, in 1611, gave up the system of common labor and of joint-stock companies, as much work was performed in a day as formerly in a week, or as much by three workmen as formerly by thirty. (Purchas, Pilgrims, iv, 1S66. Bancroft, History of the United States, I, 161.) Even in New England, therefore among men both steady and accustomed to labor, who for conscience sake had sacrificed so much, a community of goods was accompanied uninteruptedly by famine. A change for the better took place, for the first time in 1623 with the introduction of the institution of private property which was followed in 1624 by the right of inheritance. (Bancroft, I, 340.) The military colonies of Algeria, also, in which husbandry in common was carried on, begged, at the end of a year, that the system should be abandoned, for the reason tliat it was good for nothing but to generate idlers ; and yet, these colonists were all powerful men of about the saine age, and accustomed to order and service in conmion. They were, moreover, assisted by the nation with pay and food. Compare Bugeaud's account: Revue des deux Mondes, June i, 1848. "The French associations (after 1848), whose object was labor in common, have nearly all died out." M. Chevalier in the Journal des Debats, Feb. 3, 1851. In the United States, sixteen phalansteries of Fourierites, founded between 1840 and 1S46, had all collapsed in 1S55. (D. Viertcljahrsschrift, October, 1855, 205 fi".) 5 Even in New Harmony, the members considered the task which they had to perform to obtain food, clothing and shelter, as villeinage in the worst sense of the term. (H. Bernliard v. Weimar, Nordamerikan. Reise, V, 134 ft". ; 151, 310, ff".) It is very inconsistent in socialists to continue the propri- etorship and heirship of the state. To be consistent they should give both these rights only to mankind as a whole. Compare Kiraly, Ueber Socialis- mus und Comm., 1S6S, 35. Sec. LXXXI.] COMMUNITY OF GOODS. 249 code viiliiairc pronounces sentence of death on the violators of its provisions. And, as a matter of fact, the Miinster x\nabap- tists could not help punishing with death every transgression of their communistic precepts.*^ If, in a community in which the principles of communism were rigorously carried out, all the burthens and enjoyments of life were equal, and equally divided according to the ideas of the crowd, men like Thaer, Arkwright, and others of their class, who now provide bread for hundreds of thousands from their studies and laboratories, would then be able, at most, with a rake and shovel, to provide food for three or four. The division of labor, with its infinite amount of productive force, would, for the most part, cease. Nor would the consequence be that the humbler classes would be freed from work of a coarse, mechanical, unintellectual and severe nature; but that the higher classes would be dragged down to engage in it likewise. And what an increase there would be in the number of consumers at the same time! Every man would, with a light heart, follow the most impe- rious of human impulses if the whole community were to educate his children. But we have seen that a community of goods is desired most urgently in times of over-population. Hence, here it would make the evil greater yet, by increasing consumption and diminishing production. Where there are now one thousand wealthy persons, and one hundred thousand proletarians, there would be, after one gen- eration, no one wealthy and two hundred thousand proleta- rians. Misery and want would be universal." For the purpose ^ It would not be entirely fair to take a partisan view of the ateliers naiion- aiix of 1S4S, and claim them as a practical refutation of socialistic Utopias, since no serious experiment was made with them. Compare E- Thomas, Histoire dcs Ateliers nationaux consider^s sous le double Point de Vuc polit- ique et social, 1S48. ' Socialists generally overlook the fact, that the greater number of enjoy- ments from which the poorer classes are excluded, by the right of property, would not exist at all were it not for that very right. (Spiitler, Politik, 356 ft'.) This remark may also be made of Hugo's ingenious objections. (Naturrecht, § 20S ft".) One of the most effective pieces of socialistic declamation is 250 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. T, Ch. V. of giving the crowd a very agreeable,^ but rather short-lived period of pleasure, a period simply of transition, almost all that constitutes the wealth of a nation, all the higher goods of life, would have to be cast to the waves, and henceforth all men would have to content themselves with the gratifications afforded by potatoes, brandy and the pleasures of the most sensual of appetites. And then, the equal education of all, demanded by the communists, would have no result but this, that no one would acquire a higher scientific training.^ But, after all, there lurks concealed in communism much more of envy than is generally supposed. that the lower classes have a much shorter average of life than the upper. Hence the institution of private property is charged with being a species of spoliation of the poor of so many years of life, and the entire " present soci- ety " condemned oft that account. Here again it is not borne in mind, that a few centuries ago the general average of life was probably still smaller ; and that it was precisely the growth and development of " present society " that lengthened the days of the poorer classes erven, although it may have lengthened those of the rich in a still greater proportion. See § 246. s But a community of goods would not, by a great deal, accomplish as much as is generally supposed. In Prussia, for instance, in 1867, only about three per cent, of the entire number of families in the community had a yearly income of 1,000 thalers; only nine per cent, had 500 thalers or more, and only 6,465 returned an income of more than 4,000 thalers, while only 590 i-eturned one of 16,000 thalers. (Preuss. statist. Ztschr., 1S68, 83. Held., Die Einkommensteuer, 197 ft'.) How little, therefore, could the poor here gain by the spoliation of the rich! Besides, the parely personal consump- tion of the rich is, after all, not so great; and if all luxury were abandoned, an innumerable number of men would lose their gains. (Compare Ad. Smith, Wealth of Nations, I, ch. 11, 2.) It would be to kill the hen that had hitherto laid the golden egg in order to divide its flesh a little more equally. 5 Babeuf declared all arts and sciences to be evils. He would have no one learn anything but Reading, Writing, Arithmetic, and a little of the Geog- raphy of France ; and have the strictest censorship enforced to keep every one within these limits. Compare the able criticism of Proudhon^ Contra- dictions, ch. 12. Sec. LXXXIL] THE ORGANIZATION OF LABOR. 251 SECTION LXXXIL THE ORGANIZATION OF LABOR. Most theoretical adherents of the doctrine of a community of goods, feeling^ more or less the weight of the above ob- jections, have supplemented it witli the idea of an organization of labor ^ or the centralized superintendence of all production and consumption, either by the government already existing, or by one to be created anew. Such a government would be, of course, a despotism such as the world has scarcely yet seen, a Caesaro-Papacy, usurping both tlie place and power of Father of the universal Family.^ But the evils mentioned above would be entailed none the less. Every incentive which now ^ According to Umpfenbach, Nationalokonomie, .201, where a community of goods obtains, there can be but the alternative, viz. : whether eacli person or each family shall receive just the same amount. (The former would be more in harmony with principle, but what an over-population would be the conse- quence!) Precisely so, too, if each person were to come and take his own portion (anarchy !), or if it were parcelled out to each by a board of distrib- utors (despotism !). ^ This expression came into vogue, principally, through L. Blanc, Organi- zation du Travail (1S41), the leading ideas in which work ai'C the following: The suppression of competition by the establishment of state industries; equality of remuneration for labor; equality and legislative determination of the rate of interest; the choice of superintendents by the workmen. With many modern socialists, the shibboleth is not so much liberte as solidarite. Besides, Fielders Naturrecht (1796), and his geschlossener Handelsstaat, are, without doubt, among the most remarkable works favoring an " organization of labor." They aim at the destruction of the present social system, which, at most, needs only to be reformed and rejuvenated; and to galvanize the dead body into a new and different life (Medea's magic cauldron !). Compare Corvaja, Bancocrazia o il gran Libro sociale, 1S40. 2 Cabet's Icarian colony in America numbered 29S adults and only 107 children. Yet spite of this condition, so favorable to production, it did but a very sorry busmess. Its government was very similar to that of a house of correction or a penitentiary. Even in religious matters, spite of all pretended toleration, those members who did not agree with Cabet were described in the official weekly paper as des infames on dcs avcuglcs. (D. Vierteljahrs- schrift, 1855, October, 205 ff. 252 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch V moves man to industry or frugality would disappear, and noth- ing remain but universal pliilanthrophy ; or, if you will, but pat- riotism, virtues which are not wanting even now. Even guard- ianship of the government newly created would be carried on in a very loose manner; for it would be exercised without any feeling of personal interest, even in the most favorable case supposable. It is well known and easily understood, that state industries are never engaged in, in the long run, with the same zeal, nor crowned with the same same success, as com- peting private industries. It is well known, too, how intimate the connection is between the political freedom of a people and their economic production ; that, for instance, England's greater wealth, as compared with that of Turkey, depends, most largely, on the freedom that obtains in the former country and the servitude that prevails in the latter.^ And we may in- quire just here, what the result would be, if the despotism of government should go ten times farther that it has ever gone in Turkey, when, moreover, the despot who led the state, was not an individual with his few officials, but the whole crowd, with its million eyes and million hands. It would, practicall}'', be to give every producer an escort of a policeman and a rev- enue agent, as if he were- a prisoner. And where would be the gain? A division of wealth which would seem unjust to many would exist now as well as before, because the idle and the unskillful would receive the same reward as the most industrious and skillful.^ The op- position of one class of society to another, so much complained •*An eastern sage says, that land possesses the ideal of legal security through which a beautiful woman, decked with pearls, might travel without danger. What would such a sage say of a European country, in which even orphan children have their property not only preserved to them, but find it increased from having been placed at interest, as soon as they reach their majority.'' (Barrovj.) 5 " The equality of communism is the worst species of inequality, because it guaranties to one for two hours of poor labor as n:iuch as it does to an other for four hours of good work." (Basiiat, Harmonies dconomiques, ch. S.) Sec. LXXXIIL] THE ORGANIZATION OF LABOR. 053 of, would continue. The only difference would be, that whereas, it now comes from the weak, it would then come from the strong." Compulsory association is certainly more prolilic in strife and crime than is a state of society in which everybod}^ manages his own affairs. A journey on foot, in company with others, is allowed, on all hands, to be a very good test of friendship. But, a com- munity of goods would, in the strictest sense of the word, be a journey on foot through the whole of life with number- less "friends." Here, every one would believe himself enti- tled to possess whatever pleased him. And, who would de- cide; since so many communists preach the dissolution and extinction of all government, and the reign of anarchy? Be- sides, there can be no doubt, that the difference of human talents and human wants, would soon, spite of every law, lead to a difference in property again. Hence, that first revolution would have to be repeated from time to time — a real Sisyphus labor! No sooner have the bees produced anything, than the drones come, and divide anew! SECTION LXXXIIL THE ORGANIZATION OF LABOR. [COXTISrED.] Experience, however, teaches us, that, in all the lower stages of civilization, a community of goods exists to a greater or lesser extent.^ The institution of private property has been more fully evolved out of this condition of things, onl}^ in pro- portion as well-being and culture have been developed as cause and effect of such well-being. Thus, among most nations of hunters and fishermen, the idea of private property was un- ^ Proudhon^ Qu'est-ce que la Propriety, 2S3, says, very justly, that "a com- munity of goods is the spoliation of the strong by the weak." ' Called a negative community of goods, by Zaccharici, Vierzig Blicher vom Staate, IV, 146, in contradistinction to the positive and universal community of gain, as desired by the communists. 254 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. V. known when these nations were first discovered. This is, indeed, very natural. Their chief spring of production flows as if of itself, apparantly inexhaustible ; and the hunter can hardly think of such a thing as saving any of his booty .^ And, among nomadic nations, the land is a great meadow held in common; and the industry of plunder is considered, as it is in all inferior stages of civilization, especially honora- ble.^ The conqiiistadores of Peru found there something very like a community of goods, under the despotic guardianship of the state, viz.: a yearly division of all lands among the people, in proportion to their rank; the cultivation of these lands in common, under the superintendence of the state, and to the sound of music. But, at the stage of civilization that Peru was then in, land is about the only resource possessed. The results were the usual ones. A country like Peru, with '^ Comirlunitj of goods and of women among the Ichthyophages on the Red Sea, who lived in caves, went naked for the most part, plundered all ship- wrecked people, and never reached an advanced age. Diodor.^ Ill, 15 if. Peripl.^ Maris Erythr., 12. Concerning the Scythians, see Strabo^ VII, 300; the Spaniards, P/^i/rtrc/;, Marius, 6; the Rhetians, ZJw Cass. LIV, 23; the Triballi, Isoa\, Panath., § 237; the Kilici, Sext.^ Empir. P^'rrh. Hypot. Ill, 24. Community of goods among the Caribs who performed all their work in common, and had, at least in the case of males, a common table and common stores with supplies. (Petr. Martyr., Dec. VII, i. Rockefort, II, c. 16. B. Edtvards., History of the West Indies, I, 43 ff.) Among the Kus- kowimers of Russian America, all the able-bodied men of the tribe live to- gether. ( V. Wrangell., Nachrichten, 129.) Among the inhabitants of the Aleutian islands, at least in times of scarcity of food, the produce of the fisheries is divided according to their need. (V. Wrati£-ell, iS^.) The or- ganization of labor is rigidly enforced among the Otomacs, on the banks of the Orinoco, and they are, nevertheless, more civilized than their neighbors. (DeJ>ons, Voyage, I, 295.) A community of goods must, however, be con- sidered an advance, in the case of an isolated people ; and it is an error to look upon it as the most primitive condition, as does, for instance, Avidrosiits, De off. Minist. I, 28, and Frederick //, in the preface to his general code. (Allgemein. Gesetzbuche, 1231.) The hospitality of the inhabitants of the Friendly Islands borders on a community of goods. (Mariner, Freund- schaftsinseln, 75, Si. Klemm, Kulturgeschichte, IV, 398.) Concerning the beginnings of property among the Esquimaux, See Klemm, II, 294. (Didytn., ad Odyss. II, 73, IX, 252.) Sec.LXXXIII.] the organization of labor. 255 only one city, no beasts of burthen, no plows, no trades and no commerce, cannot possibly be rich.* That the constitu- tion of L3'curgus established a sort of community of goods among the Spartans, is well known. I need only recall the public education, the meals in common, the authorization of stealing,^ the prohibition of trade, of the precious metals and fine furniture, the equal division of property and the inaliena- ble character of the land " etc. With such laws, Sparta could neither be, nor desire to become, wealth}-. Of all Greek states of any historical importance, it preserved longest the economic peculiarities belonging to a low stage of civiliza- tion. Among most modern nations, the fundamental idea of their land laws, which had their origin in the middle ages, is, that each family is only the usufructuary, and that the com- munity is the sovereign proprietor of the soil. This community of landed possession finds expression, among other things, in the vast extent of communal woods and pasturages, in the varied intersecting of parcels of land one by the other, W'hich, indeed, change proprietors from time to time, and in the com- * In Mexico, the Spaniards found land ownership among the most distin- guished of the natives, but only a species of possession in common and common store houses among tlie peasantry. (Robertson^ History of Amer- ica, § VII.) Hence, tlie agriculture of the country -was so unimportant that the little army of the conquistadorcs frequently produced a fa^iine by their marches. 5 The Tcherkesses considered robbery honorable provided the robber was not caught in flagrante. Compare Koch, Reise in den kaukasischen Isth- mus, I, 370 ff. Bell, Journal of a Residence in Circassia, I, 181, II, 201. The organized robber bands of ancient Egypt, when it was so highly civil- ized (Diodor., I, 80) may, on the other hand, be accounted for by similar con- ditions actually existing in the large cities of our own day. "'What a frightful organization of labor we find in Sparta, combined with a community of goods ! Let us recall the exposing of children authorized by law, the mode of education which must have cost the life of all whose constitution was weak, the cryftia, the stern hierarchy of age etc. Pint., Inst. Lac. 2, appreciates the bad taste of the black broth at its true value. The Cretan community of goods was based chiefly on the unnatural rela- tion created by the authorities known as paideraslia ; and which was a very efficient means to prevent over-population. (Plat., De Legg, 1, 636. Artsi., Polit. II, 8.) 256 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. V mon working of the land, carried as far as possible etc' In all medieval times,^ not only the individual is considered an owner of the land, but, over and above him, the family. At the same time, we are wont to find existing an amount of mortmain property in the hands of corporations, monastery lands, crown lands and domains of very great importance.^ All these institutions have declined in number and shown a disposition to disappear, in proportion as national husbandry or economy has grown more productive. SECTION LXXXIV. THE ORGANIZATION OF LABOR. [CONTINUED.] To this tendency we find, indeed, another, and a no less powerful one, opposed. Everywhere as civilization advances, the sphere of action of the state grows larger, and the ends it serves more numerous. In its origin, government was established to preserve only the external security of its subjects. By degrees, it comes to look after their internal legal security, b}" enforcing internal peace, prohibiting revenge for bloodshed etc. It next extends its care to the well-being, the culture, and even to the comfort of the people. But the claims of the state must grow in the same proportion as the service it renders. While Lowe, in 1822, estimated the yearly net income of the British people at '' Remarkable reasons therefor in Cc^sar, Bell. Gall., VI, 32. 8 There are, especially in Russia, a multitude of such institutions among the inhabitants of the country still. See Roscher^ Nationalokonomik des Ackerbaues, § 71 ft". ' In the Corpus Juris Canonici, that crown of medieval theology, politics and jurisprudence, the ideal of a community of goods occupies a place almost as prominent as in the works of modern socialists. The only difler- ence is, that in the former the opposition to private property arises from a one-sided religiousness and contempt of the world, while, in the latter, it arises generally from irreligiousness and over-estimation of worldly goods. Sec. LXXXIV.] THE ORGANIZATION OF LABOR. 257 £25i,ooo,cxxd; the government expenses,^ in 1813 and 1814, averaged £106,000,000, and these sums were vohmtarily de- voted to public purposes by parliament. And so, between 1685 and 1841, the population of England more than trebled its numbers, But, in the same period of time, the outlay of the state increased forty fold. (Macaiilay.) Simultaneously with this development of things, it becomes more and more usual by the exercise of the power of eminent domain and others like it, to sacrifice private rights, acquired by the very best of titles, to the preponderating common good. We may allude, further, to the duty, imiversally imposed in modern times, of performing military service, to the national systems of public instruction in so many countries; to the large number of societies, joint-stock companies, popular holi- days; but particularly to the associations for insurance of every description. And so it may, indeed, be claimed that we have come nearer to a community of goods than could have been dreamed of a hundred years ago.~ And yet, these are, for the most part, institutions in which we find reflected the peculiar strength and solidity of our age. Whoever wishes to compare the power of one people with that of another, must take into account not only the elements which constitute their intellectual and physical force, but especially their inclination to permit these elements to cooperate for public purposes.^ 1 This does not include the cost of the schools, churches and benevolent in- stitutions. "^ According to Lassallc, System der erworbenen Rechte, 1S61, § 259, his- tory shows that law, as civilization advances, curtails more and more the proprietary sphere of private individuals, inasmuch as it tends more and more to place a greater number of objects outside the circle of individual ownership. 3 Saint Simonism is a warning example of this tendency. Saint Simon never lost an opportunity to give vent to his utter contempt for the liberals, and for constitutional government — ce bdtard du regime fiodal et dii regime indiistricl; and to counsel the crown, after the example of Louis XL to place itself at the head of the working class, and in opposition to the middle class. (Oeuvres de Saint Simon, €d. 1S41, 44, 14S, 209.) Bazard, Exposition, 76, de- manded that all antagonism between the temporal and spiritual powers, all Vol. I.— 17 25S PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Cii. V. We may now inquire: At what point does this increasing community cease to be a gain? This is as easily determined generally, as it is difficult to say what the limit to it is in par- ticular instances. Progress in the direction of a community of interests of this nature is beneficial, only so long but cer- tainly as long as it corresponds with the feeling entertained by the community, that they have interests in common. Hence it is, that such a noble kind of communism reigns in art and lit- erature, one which causes the stronger to willingly labor for the weaker, and with the greatest success.^ And so, too, the chris- tian care of the poor, even were it carried to the height of the Gospel counsels (Luke, 3:11), would be no direct obstacle in the way of the development of a nation's public economy, pro- vided it were given, and accepted, only as christian benevo- lence. Every approximation towards a community of goods should be effected by the love of the rich for the poor, not by the hatred of the poor for the rich. If all men were true Christians, a community of goods might exist without danger. But then, also, the institution of private property would have no dark side to it. Every employer would give his work- men the highest wages possible, and demand in return only the smallest possible sacrifice.^ ^ opposition for the sake of freedom, tu^fauce organisee of parliaments, and all competition, should cease. Even education he would have bestowed according to capacity, which he would have determined by the c/iefs Ugitimes de la socidti (280). To the criminal court should be referred all cases of delicts, that is, all inopportune acts, even in the scientific and artistic departments. They should be tried after the manner of the "courts of trade; " that is, in a sum- mary way, without appeal, and by experts (317 fF). All the relations of prop- erty should be determined by the decision arbitrale des chefs d Industrie (326). Bazard everywhere insists that the reign of genius and of self-sacrifice on the one hand, and on the other of confidence and obedience, is the only true pol- icy (330). Saint Simonism was nearly related to Bonapartism. "^Schdffle, Nat. CEk., Ill, Aufl., I, 61. 5 If we remove in thought, all injurious elements from a community of goods, and add to it all the incentives and restraints necessary to be added, we shall have a state of things entirely similar to that in a nation whose pub- lic and private affairs arc carried on in accordance with the principles of a Sec. LXXXV.J THE RIGHT OF INHERITANCE. 259 SECTION LXXXV. THE RIGHT OF INHERITANCE. The right of inheritance to resources has its origin in a com- bination of the idea of the family with the idea of property. And, indeed, this combination of ideas is a very natural one. The larger portion of mankind consider the pleasures of the family as the highest attainable, and endeavor, whenever their economic means make it at all possible, to secure them. At the same time, the selfishness of most men is not confined to their own persons, but extends also to their posterity. Hence it is that bed and board, connubimn and commercium, have, from time immemorial, been considered correlative ideas; and, to all the more logical socialists, a community of wives (or celibacy) ^ is as dear as a community of goods.^ (§ 245.) And in practice, the greater number of nations of hunters, who, according to our conceptions, have no knowledge of a real family and no knowledge of property, have a custom of bury- ing with the dead the things they used, to kill their cattle etc., or to deprive minor children of their inheritance.^ healthy system of Political Economy as understood to-day. (Edinburgh Review, January, 1851.) ^ How true freedom is accompanied by what Bastiat calls " true Saint Simonism and true communism," see infra, § 210. ' The experiments of a community of goods, which have proved successful in practice, were all based on the more or less complete celibacj^of the mem- bers of the societies. Compare Hermann, Staatsw. Unters., II, Avifl., 45. ^ Thus Proudhon (Contradictions, ch. 5) says that the many socialists, who would construct their societies after the type of the family, as the inohcule organique, are all wrong. The family has a " monarchical, patriarchal" char- acter. In it, the principle of authority is formed and preserved. On it, an- cient and feudal society was based ; and " precisely against this old patriarchal constitution, modern democracy protests and revolts." Fourier calls mar- riage, tin groiife essenticllement faux : faux far le nombre borni d deux, far I ''absence de libertd et par les dissidenccs du goTit, qui iclatcnt des le fremier jour. (Nouveau Monde, 57.) 2 On the Indians of North America, see 6'c//w//'({/?, Information respect- ing the Indian Tribes of the United States, II, 194; on the South American 260 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. V. SECTION LXXXVI. ECONOMIC UTILITY OF THE RIGHT OF INHERITANCE. The certainty, that the material welfare of their children de- pends, in great part, on their industry and frugality, is one of the most powerful incentives to good, in the case of most men. And this is the basis of the economic utility of the fam- ily right of inheritance.^ There is scarcely any other institu- tion which opposes over-population with such efficiency, for the reason, that the obstacle placed in its way here is placed very directly, at the point where it can make itself felt most, viz. : in the life of the family itself. The weaker the family feel- ing, the less does the abolition of the right of inheritance inter- fere with the economic interests of a nation. Hence, for in- stance, it is, that taxes imposed upon legacies, bequests, testa- mentary gifts etc., are less objectionable in proportion as they affect only those in the more remote degrees of relationship in which inheritance is something merely accidental. While, when a nation is yet in the intermediate stages of civilization, the family right of inheritance seems to be very strong, especially as regards landed property, a consequence of the fact, that a superior kind of title to such property is recog- nized to exist in the family; at a period, when individualism becomes more developed, the liberty of devise by wiU is wont to prevail more and more.^ Then the right of inheritance be- d^Orb{g}iy,Yoya.ge^ IV, 220, and passim, on the South Sea Islanders, theNo- vara- Reise, II, 418; on the ancient Albanians, Sirabo, XI, 503. ' The hereditary transmission of property to posterity has an obvious ten- dency to make a man a good citizen. It ranges his passions on the side of duty, and induces him to make himself profit the common good, and it as- sures him that his reward shall not die with himself, but that it shall be handed down to those to whom he is joined by the dearest and most tender feelings. (See Blackstone's Commentaries, II, 11.) Without the right of in- heritance, credit is scarcely possible, since with the death of the debtor the only stay of the creditor would cease. = Testamentary freedom (which obtained in places there about the begin- Sec. LXXXVL] RIGHT OF INHERITANCE. 261 comes, so to speak, a more elevated species of personal prop- erty, a prolongation of the same beyond the grave. Should testamentary freedom be too much hampered, selfishness v^ould manifest itself in a way much more detrimental to economic interests, viz. : in the consumption of wealth, during the life- time of its owner. Every man would be but a life annuitant of his own property. But, at the same time, in periods of moral decline, complete freedom may degenerate so as to produce evils equally great. The wealthy Boeotians, in the later days of Hellenic history, were wont to form themselves into dissolute drinking com- panies ; and not only the childless, but even fathers of families made over their property to these companies, limiting their offspring to a portion which it was made their duty to let them have. It was so in Rome, also, in Cicero's time, when every acquaintance of standing took it very ill if not remembered in the will of the testator, and where Octavian, for instance, in the last twenty years of his reign, received about 70,000,000 thalers through legacies left him by his "friends."^ Here, ning of the eighteenth century) prevails completely in England at present, contrary to the principle of the Roman law requiring an obligatory portion (la legitime) to be left to the heirs, which is still binding in France, but in a very much developed form. The consequence is that last testaments are as frequent in England as they are rare in France. There were, in Paris, in 1825, 7,649 judicial, and only 1,081 testamentary partitions of property. (Mou- nter.) In Great Britain, in 1838, the number of testamentary alienations of property taxed stood to those in which there was no will, in the proportion of 8:3; and the values of the alienated property as 10:1. (Porter.) Among a people noted for their high moral tone, testamentary freedom is a powerful means of strengthening paternal authority on the one hand, and of keeping alive, in the minds of parents, on the other, a sense of responsibility for the future of their children. Compare Helferich, Tiibinger Zeitschr., 1854, 143, fi. ^Polyb., XX, 6. Hence it was, that all {?) the wealth of Thebes, when it was destroyed by Alexander the Great, was only 440 talents. (Athen., IV, 148.) Drumann, Gesch. Roms. etc., VI, 333 ff. Cicero, Phil., II, 16. Hoeck, Rom. Gesch., I, 2, 118. Siceton., Octav., 66. An especially scandalous instance in Petron., 140. For a masterly theory of legacy - hunting, see Jlorat., Sat., II, 5. Compare Lucian, Dialogues of the Dead, 5-9. Peironitts speaks of a turba h(Bredipetarum. (124.) 262 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. V. the repeal of the law making it obligatory on testators to leave a certain proportion of their wealth to their children would remove the last safe-guard of their material welfare.* SECTION LXXXVIL LANDED PROPERTY. As land, in its uncultivated state, has neither been produced by man, nor can be entirely consumed by him, the above de- monstration of the necessity of private property cannot with- * Even the revolutionary shibboleth, faterniid, really means nothing more than the equal right of inheritance of all, i. e., the abolition of the right of in- heritance! (R. Meyer.) The strongest attack, from a scientific point of view, made on the right of inheritance in more recent times, comes froin Saint Si- monism. The founder himself, after a life rich in experience but poor in ac- tion, spent in the search of inuch but in the finding of little, succeeded only in arraying the industrial and proprietary classes against each other, in de- claring the poorest class to be the most important of all, and in basing the r\e^\ .religio?i of love on the emancipation of labor. His disciples went fur- ther. In order to abolish all the privileges of birth, Bazard, Exposition de la Doctrine de Saint Simon, 1831, p. 172, ff., taught that it was not enough to dis- tribute public employments according to merit, and in the interest of the people generally, but that the distribution of property should be made in accordance with the same principle. The inequality of ownership should correspond with the inequality of merit. Every one may, during his life, keep what he had acquired himself, but give it to the state at death. Thus would a reconciliation be effected between the general interest and private interest; and the public revenue, supplied in this Avay, might easily be em- ployed in place of the revenue raised by such taxation as weighs most heavily on the inferior classes. F. Huei, also, Le Regne social du Christian- isme, 1853, III, 5, would have all private property, after the death of the owner, fall igalement d, tous les jeunes travailleurs. The practical consequen- ces of this system may now be seen in Turkey. There, the principal mili- tary fiefs are held in this way. Hence it is, that the Turkish owner of such a fief builds as little as possible. When one of his walls threatens to fall, it is kept standing by means of props. If it falls in fact, the only consequence is that there are fewer rooms in the house, and the owner settles beside the ruins. (Denon,l,p.ig2) ^^ the Butan, there exists a species of practical Saint Simonism. liodinson, Descriptive Account of Assan, 1841. Sec. LXXXVII.] LANDED PROPERTY. 2G3 out any more ado, be extended to land.^ Hence, individual property in land is everywhere much more recent than indi- vidual property in capital." But a certain expenditure of capital and labor is necessary that land may be used productively, and, in most instances, this employment of capital and labor is of long duration, irre- vocable in the very nature of things, and one the fruits of which can be reaped only after some time has elapsed. Now, this cooperation of capital and labor is such, that no one would undertake to employ them in the cultivation of the land, had he not the strongest assurance of possessing it. Hence, agri- culture in its most rudimentary stage supposes ownership of the land, at least from the time that it is " tickled with the hoe," until it " smiles with the harvest ; " or, to express it more accurately, all the time intervening between the work of the plow and the labor of the sickle. The more, afterwards, popu- lation and civilization increase, the more products must be wrung from the soil. But this can be accomplished only by means of its more intensive cultivation (higher farming), by lavishing a greater amount of capital and labor on it, and, as a rule, by extending the circle of agricultural operations by means of combinations more and more artificial. Hence, the progress of civilization demands an ever increasing fixity, and a more pronounced shaping of landed propert}^ (the sfccif ca- tion of jurists), in the interests of all w' ho share in this progress, and even of those who own no landed property themselves. Were there no property in land, every one would find it more * It was chiefly fear of the consequences of the declamations of the socialists and their declamation against "monopoly " that induced Bastiatio reduce all the value of landed property to that of the capital employed in its manuring, improvement etc. (Harmonies, ch. 9.) We may, however, unreservedly grant him that, as a rule, until the time of its original possession by man, land had no valeiir whatever (278). *Art«i! thinks the very contrary: Metaph. Anfangsgriinde der Rechtslehre, (Werke, IX, 72 ff). Contra, Groiius, J. B. et P., II, 2. Gi-asruinkel, in his Schriften fiir die Freiheit des Meeres, 1652 if., in Laspeyrcs, Geschichte der niederlandischen N. CEk., 12. Hiifdaud, Neue Grundlegung, I, 307. 264: PRODUCTION OF GOODS. ; [B. I, Ch. V difficult and laborious to gratify his want of agricultural pro- ducts ; ^ and the products themselves would be of an inferior kind. Thus, for instance, in Camargo, the lackmus was formerly prepared from plants to be had " free " in the woods. It was then, however, much dearer than it is now that the plants are artificially raised on landed property.* It is otherwise with the fisheries. The appropriation of rivers or seas would not tend to increase the abundance of their products, and hence this appropriation is, on the whole, rare.^ SECTION LXXXVIII. LANDED PROPERTY. (CONTINUED.) Whenever this admixture of capital and labor with land has taken place to no great extent, private property in land is not found developed in any degree. Thus, there are even now many half-civilized countries in which the land is forfeited be- cause not tilled for many years, and where it may be occupied by the first person who will cultivate it.^ In Europe, common ^ " A district of Tartary of ten square miles, in which several hordes pas- ture their flocks, may contain between 400 and 500 shepherds, who find em- ployment in this mode of production." In Brie, in France, on the same area, 50,000 peasants who own no land, live and draw their sole income from their labors in the fields (J^. B. Say). *Schubcri^ Reise durch Frankreich und Italien, I, 1S8. 5 " Without labor, the earth bestows nothing on man but a stopping place. Hence, the reasons for private property do not extend so far as to prove that the great land and water highways should not be reserved as common prop- erty, and as a home to every man." (Zacharid^ vom Staate, VII, 43.) ' This is the practice in Taway. Ritter, Erdkunde, V, 130. And so in ancient Germany, y. Grimm, Rechtsalterthiimer, 92. Right of the "dead fire" in Spain and Portugal during the middle ages. S . Rosa de Viterbo : Elucidario das Palavras etc., I, 470. In many parts of Persia, the land be- longs to anyone who has provided it with water by canals or wells. (Fniscr, Journey in Chorasan, ch. 7.) Especially after the Mongolian devastation about the beginning of the fourteenth century, it was decreed that land Sec. LXXXVIII.J LANDED PROPERTY. 265 possession of forests and pasture lands asserted itself miieh longer than that of arable land, because, in the case of the former, labor and capital play a much less important part in the management of them. And yet, even in the case of arable land etc., and, in the highest stages of civilization, the property- quality is yet less developed than the property-quality of capital. How seldom do vv^e find jidei commissa of capital, or capital juridically tied up. We find that the law of all ancient nations drew a marked distinction between moveable and immoveable property, and that the power of disposing of the former by sale, pledge, in dowry, partition etc., was a much freer one. And even now, the police power which may be exercised over moveable property is much more restricted than that over houses and land.^ The justice of the exclusive right of possession to what one has earned and saved is obvi- ous to every one. On the other hand, the appropriation of " original and indestructible natural forces" has its basis not so much in justice as in the general good; and the state has always considered itself entitled to attach to the " monopoly of land," which it accorded to the first possessor, all kinds of limitations and conditions in the interest of the common good, Avhich had remained uncultivated for a long time should belong to the per- son who made it productive. (d^Ohsson, Hist, des Mongols, IV, 418.) Simi- larly, in the time of the ancient Persians (Polyb., X, 28, 3), the harvest for the first five years belonged to the person who first irrigated the land. On the upper Euphrates, likewise, the land is very often neither sold nor leased. Anyone who will till it and pay one-tenth of the produce to the bey may have it for nothing. (Rittcr, X, 669; compare VIII, •468; IX, 900.) So, too, among the Fulah and Mandingo negroes, and even among the Tschcrkessans. (Klemm, Kulturgeschichte, III, 337 fl:'.) As the latest stages of development so often present instances of a reversion to the earliest, we find that Theo- dosius and Valentinian decreed that the agri deserti should, after two years' cultivation, belong to the possesser. L. 8, Cod. Just., XI, 58. 2 Thus anyone may burn his own coat or throw it in the water ; but no one may set fire to his own house or drown his land \iy the destruction of a dam. Even the non-user of a large area, in a thickly populated region, would scarcely be permitted. The taking of property by the state, at the present Hay in times of peace, is confined almost exclusively to land. 266 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. V. and sometimes to consider private property in land in the light of a semi-public function.^ I may instance the feudal princi- ples of the latter portion of the middle ages, which are so far removed from our ideas of private property in land; and yet, of which many echoes are heard, even in our day, and are not without their influence in practice. Thus, further, for instance, even in England, the greater number of the poor-rates, of taxes for the support of the established church, the main- tenance of public highways etc., are heaped upon the rent of land. Many socialists have proposed to make the state the sole proprietor of the soil,* sometimes adding the condition, that the previous private owners should be compensated in capital, when it would be at least supposable that private cap- ital might be enticed to cultivate it, if long and sure leases of it were made. This would be a " good " demesne-husbandry, extending over the entire country. We need only glance at those kingdoms in which something analogous is to be found, ^ Thus P. V. Arnim, in a work entitled " Ideen zu einer voUstandigen land- wirthschaftlichen Buchfiihrung, 1S05, a treatise on "agricultural book-keep- ing," considers the farmer as a state official who should cultivate whatever he believed in conscience, or what the state declared to be, most necessary. He suggests that the state should subject all new purchasers of land to an examination to ascertain whether they are rich and noble enough to act in this way. *Thus, for instance, Herbert Spencer, Social Statics, 1S51, 114 ft", and to some extent Spinoza, Tract, polit., VI, 2. There are now in England several Land-Tenure-Reform-Associations, some of which would " expropriate " all land and vest the title in the state. The programme of the others embraces not only opposition to the right of primogeniture, to family fidei commissa and the assertion of the right of freedom of trade in land, and of a more democratic use of common lands, but also the appropriation by the state of the increase in the rent of land which is caused by no labor of the landlord, but solely by the increase of population and of the wealth of the community or of the nation. Ne-wmarch, on the other hand, very correctly remarks, that since it is impossible to draw a line of demarkation showing the increase of the value of land growing out of the increase of population etc., the owner of land in making improvements would never know whether he made them for himself or for the state. (Statist. Journal, 1S71, 488 ff.) Compare Wolkojf, Sur la Rente fonci^re, 1854, and H. H. Gossen, Entwickelung der Gesetze des menschlichen Verkehrs (1854). Sec. LXXXVIIL] LANDED PROPERTY. 0(]7 especially the despotisms of the east,^ to divine that such a system does not suffice to insure the real productiveness of a nation's economy.'' * In Congo and on the gold coast of Guinea the land, in whole villages, is tilled in common and the harvest distributed among the families per capita. Wherever absolutism reigns, the prince is also the owner of all the land. (Klanin. Ill, 337.) In China, where the original tenure in common of the land by all was broken through in the third century before Christ, all the land of the country now belongs, strictly speaking, to the state ; and the pos- sessor of land who permits it to go untilled is jiunished. (Plath, in the phil.-hist. Sitzungsberichten der Miinchener Akad., 1S73, 793 ft") In Corea, private property in land is unknown ; arable land is divided by the state ac- cording to the number in a family. (Ritter, IV, 633.) The example, on the largest scale, of a country without private property in land is the British East Indies. Compare the paper by Ch. Campbell^ in the Essays published by the Cobden Club; System of Land Tenure in various Countries, 1870. ^The legal and economic difference between property in land and property in capital is well defined by J. S. Mill, Principles, II, ch. 2, 6. " The reasons which form the justification, in an economical ])oint of view, of property in land, are only valid in so far as the proprietor of the land is its improver. In no sound theory of private property was it ever contemplated that the proprietor of land should be merely a sinecurist quartered on it." He here alludes specially to Ireland. The Fourierist, Considcrant, distinguishes ac- curately between the capital produced by labor and saving, and the increase of the value of land caused by capital and labor, and its original value. Only the first two elements can justly be made property. But as, for pru- dential reasons, it is necessary to grant individuals the right of private prop- erty in land, those who are not such proprietors must, as a compensation for the common property which they have lost, be guarantied the right to labor. (Theorie du Droit de Propriete et du Droit au Travail.) In England, the opinion that the compulsory supjiort of the poor was inti'oduced in compen- sation to them for the establishment of private property in land has met with considerable favor. Bishop Woodxvard, On the Expediency of a Regu- lar Plan for the Maintenance of the Poor in Ireland, 1775. Compare Eden, State of the Poor, I, 413. However, the poor rates, in a country like Eng- land, are much more than an equivalent of what its soil could produce with- out the assistance of capital. 268 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Cn. VI. CHAPTER VI. CREDIT. SECTION LXXXIX. CREDIT IN GENERAL. Credit^ is the power of disposition over the goods of an- otlier,'^ voluntarily granted in consideration of the mere prom- ise of the counter-value.^ As Franklin says : A good pay is master of another man's purse. Hence, it is evident that whoever would obtain credit must be believed to possess the ability as well as the intention to fulfill his promise. Where ' The principal classical work on this subject is Nebenius, Der oftentliche Credit, 1S20, 2d ed., 1S29. Previousl}', Salmasius, De Mode Usurarum, 1639; and even Demosthenes^ adv. Dionysiod, 12S3. Compare further Schdffle^ in the Deutsch. Vierteljahrsschrift, No. 106, II, 2S9 ft'. ' Compulsarjr loans by the state, for instance, occupy an intermediate posi- tion between taxes and credit-operations, properly so called. 3 Besides loans proper, all payments in advance, or delays made in the pay- ments of earnest-money, all leases and lettings, which Courcelle-Seneiiil calls nn mediocre degrd de crddit, insurances and even all contracts foi' wages Avhere the payment is delayed for a long period of time, are species of credit. For a nice distinction between leasing (Pacht) and letting (MtetJie), see Knies, Tubinger Ztschr., i860, 180 ft"., and the Freiburger Univ. Programm., 9. September, 1S62. D. Wakefield^ Essay upon Political Economy, 1804, 35, distinguishes between "loan-credit" which is given to a poor man in the hope of his paying it by means of his labor, and " exchange-credit," or credit between property owners. CieszkoTvski's definition : le cridit c'est la metamor- fkose des capitaux stables et engagis en capitaux circulants et d6gagis. (Du Credit et de la Circulation, 2d ed., 1847.) According to Knies^ Tubinger Ztschr., 1859, 568, every credit-operation is an exchange or sale of services, one of which is to be performed in the present, and the counter-service of the other party in the future. According to Macleod, it is " a sale of debts." Sec. LXXXIX.] CREDIT IN GENERAL. 269 this belief is based simply on the opinion entertained of the person of the debtor, we speak of personal credit/ in contra- distinction especially to the credit based on bailment, pledge, hypothecation etc. The longer the time between the making of the promise and the period fixed for its fulfillment, the less certain is the latter, where the security is simply the person of the debtor. It is chiefly in very uncivilized nations and also in nations in their decrepitude, and during periods of an- archy, and in despotisms, that personal security stands higher than any other. The same is true, though for other reasons, in very energetic civilized nations, where the people put a high estimate on the element of labor in their econom}^, among whose members legal security is, indeed, found, but where the peculiar sensitiveness of speculation would be too much ham- pered by the more sluggish nature of other credits; as, for instance, in North America, and even in ancient Rome. Civ- ilized nations that have reached the stationary economic state, on this account much prefer the greater security and the ab- sence of care which accompany non-personal credit.^ In esti- mating the ability of the debtor to meet his promise, we must take into account, especially, the disposable character of his resources; otherwise it would be impossible to understand ■* Personal credit, of course, preponderates in commerce. Hence it is, that in mercantile life, information concerning the personal status, reputation etc. of his colleagues, plays so important a part with the merchant. This infor- mation was made more accessible in England by the Lloyd institution. On similar North American institutions, see Tellkamfj^ Beitrage, I, 51. Credit given on security is a modification, sometimes of personal and sometimes of real credit. Compare, infra^ the theory on bankers, brokers etc. ^ In despotisms, credit is almost entirely personal. Montesquieu Esprit des Lois, L. v., 15. In New York, says M. Chevalier, a merchant with resources worth 200,000 francs, can do a business of from 1,000,000 to 1,500,000 francs. In Paris, under similar circumstances, the same man would find it difficult to be credited to the extent of 500,000 francs. In Holland, two hundred years ago, a person who hypothecated his property was obliged to pay a higher rate of interest than in business (Becher, Polit. Discurs, 1763, 699), while the stationary period, one hundred years ago, made personal credit extremely difficult. In Zurich, it was encouraged by the prohibition of loaning money out of the country. (BiiscJi, GedUnnlauf, III, 40.) 270 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. VI. why the merchant may so frequently obtain a loan on his stock equal to its whole value, while the owner of land can place it as security only to the extent of half its value. Credit, on the whole, grows in importance with an advance in civilization, and this is true especially of credit intended for productive purposes. This is a consequence of the greater division of labor which causes unfinished products to be put on the market more and more frequently, — products which come to have a value only after some time, but which, when that time has elapsed, have present value. And, indeed, as the world advances and civilization grows, it becomes much easier to forecast the future with certainty. The future, also, then be- comes more a source of solicitude, and fixed capital, as a con- sequence, plays a part which grows daily more important. The limit to the development of credit is this : it is safe only when the debtor invests his borrowed goods in the production of, to say the least, their equivalent. This is why the person- ality of the state, clothed with immortality and with a formally boundless power of taxation, is so often seduced into engag- ing in transactions of credit which are never self-discharged." The social diseases of panics and of extravagant enterprises stand in the same relation to credit that unbelief and super- stition do to true religion.''^ (ScJmffle.) SECTION XC. CREDIT— EFFECTS OF CREDIT. As regards the effects of credit, we may remark, that it is as powerless directly to produce new capital as is the division of labor to produce new workmen. To every credit of the ^Sdidffle, Nat. CEk., II, Aufl., 112. "^ Sclidffle, according to the purpose which it is intended to subserve, divides credit into production-credit (investment of loans in immoveable property and in moveable property engaged in industrial operations), consumption- credit and clearing-credit, or loans made to pay respited purchase and earnest money, inheritances etc. (Kapitalismus und Socialismus, 552.) Sec. XC] CREDIT. 271 creditor corresponds a debit of the debtor. As Turgot said: Tout credit est un cmprunt} ~ "^ But, on the other hand, credit ^ Pinto, Traite de la Circulation ct du Credit, 1771, considers loans bearing interest as new portions of the resources of a country (p. 161), and that gov- ernment loans not made in excess of its powers are urte alchyniie rdalisde dont souvent eux tncines qui V ofbrejit w' ciitciident ^as tout le mystire, (p. 338.) Sim- ilarly and earlier, v. Schroder, F. Schatz-und Rentkammer, 238 ff ; Mdlon, Essai politique sur le Commerce, 1734, ch. 6; next, Hamilton, Report to the House of Representatives on the subject of Manufactures, I?cc. 5, 1791; Von Strucnsce, Abhandlungen, iSoo, I, 259. See infra, § 210. More re- cently, St. Ckamans, Nouvel Essai sur la Richesses des Nations, 1824, S3 ft". To some extent, even Dietzel, System der Staatsanleihen, 1S55, 200. This is a dangerous error, since to every credit there is a set-off in the nature of a debit of an equal amount; and the evidences of debt are nothing but claims on the future revenue of the state. This was fully recognized by Cantillon, 291 ff. One of the principal advocates of that view among writers on Polit- ical Economy is the vivacious, acute and practically not unskillful, but sophistically superficial Madeod. (Elements of Political Economy, 1858, ch. 3, Dictionary, 1862, v. Credit.) The creditor's assignable right of demand, he considers immaterial capital. While bills of lading, warehouse receipts, dock yard receipts etc., only represent goods, the bank note is new goods. Even metallic money has only a credit-value, inasmuch as it can be used only to effect exchanges. To the — of the creditor may correspond a -f of the debtor; but the latter is negative only in the sense that we speak of negative electricity, a negative thermometrical degree. When an estate is leased, the owner has, in his demand for rent, a vendible flus; but the lessee no corre- sponding minus. (Not so. To the same extent that the proprietor has his future payments on the lease discounted, the present sale-value of his estate is diminished ; or if it is not sold, the last party obtaining the discount has made his available capital as much less by the advance as that of the lessor has been increased.) The " discounting of the future," that is, the apparent capitalization of hopes, so much in vogue at the present time, may be a great spur to production as it may also be to baseless extravagance. - Many theoreticians ascribe a direct creation of new capital to credit, in so fur as the capacity of the evidences of debt to circulate as a medium of ex- change effects a real saving, and permits the former very costly and intrin- sically valuable instruments of exchange to be used in some other way. (§ 123.) Compare Ricardo, Proposals for a secure and economical Cur- rency (1817). y. S. Mill, Principles, II, 174 and 36. McCuHocJi, Commercial Dictionary, art. Credit. And so it was in the first four editions of this book of mine. But here, too, there is, immediately, only a transfer of already ex- isting capital. The person, for instance, who accepts a bank note for pay- ment, loans a part of his capital to the bank ; and the advantage to the whole 272 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [C. I, Ch. VI. facilitates the transmission of the elements of production, especially of capital, from one hand to another.* When, therefore, the debtor employs the capital thai he has borrowed, more productively than the creditor would have done, the whole country is a gainer; as it is a loser, on the contrary, when a person engaged in industry advances to the idler, the frugal rnan to the spendthrift, the solid man to the wild speculator. In declining nations, where every new development hastens decay, the Matter alternative may be the prevailing one ; and, especially here, may the usurious giving of credit by the shrewd to the simple lead to ruinous debtor-slavery. Among a vig- orous and energetic people, thp former is apt to govern, as it is only by the productive employment of the loans made that they are permanently enabled to pay interest. Here credit is an invaluable means, not only of putting idle capital in motion, and of making active capital still more active, but especially of concentrating capital, by which it may gain as much in produc- tive power as labor does by the cooperation of labor. This is effected, very frequently, by means of joint-stock companies, the principle of which recommends them especially in en- terprises where stationary capital is required rather than cir- culating capital, and where capital generally plays a greater part than labor; and where this labor can be subjected to pro- visions which may be accurately laid down beforehand; as, for instance, in the case of docks, insurance companies, banks,^ community of such credit-operations consists chiefly in this : that so large a quantity of cash-capital which lay idle in banks etc., may be used more productively. 2 When Roesler says that credit is capital, the product of saving, and very serviceable in further production (Grittids.^ 300)^ he confounds credit itself with the foundations of credit, which are, indeed, in large part material or moral capital. ■* Compare Discourse on Trade, Coyn and Paper-Credit, London, 1697, 72 ff. ^Compare Buron, Guerre au Credit, 1S68. Schdffle, Tiib. Ztsch., 1S69, 296 fF. With a thorough understanding of its politico-economical hearing, O. Michaelts, (Berliner V. Jahrsschr. 1S63, IV, 121,) says: The capital-value of my credit is not equal to the nominal value of my evidences of indebtednes? Sec. XC] CREDIT. 070, etc. Banks, then, become real reservoirs of capital, provided they are properly and judiciously established and managed; real reservoirs which receive in one place the capital which is superfluous elsewhere, in order to supply some other place with that which is necessary to it. The more conlidence in- creases, the more are even the smallest driblets of capital awakened from their slumbers, and made active and produc- tive. It is only by means of credit that the help of foreign capital can be obtained for home production. Indeed, credit, considered as an exchange of probable future goods against actually existing goods, is one of the principal functions of the temporal solidarity of the economy of nations. (Schdffie.) "Without credit, there would be very little place for specula- tion proper. We may see how the possibility of giving and receiving cred- it promotes wealth,by contemplating the poorer classes, whose poverty, both as cause and effect, is very closely related to the absence of credit. And here we have a suggestion of the re- verse to the bright side of the picture of credit, analogous to that mentioned in § 62 of the cooperation of labor, viz.: that it tends to intensify inequality among men. The man who is distinguished by the amount of his wealth, or by his po- sition is naturally known to a much wider circle than others are. From which it follows, that he may, by the way of cred- it, increase his power, already so much greater in the econom- ic world, by a much larger multiplier.^ Hence, it need not [notes etc.], but to the capitalized amount of the extra surplus which I have obtained in my business by means of credit, after deduction is made of the costs and of the risk-premium. 6 We shall, in the books to follow this, inquire with great care, what are the means best calculated to remedy this dangerous tendency. We need only remark here, that it is to be found in a judicious association of small capitalists, and also in the capitalization, so to speak, of personal qualities. A well organized society of work-men, without capital, may indeed obtam credit, as for instance, the Schultze-Delitsch societies, the Russian artel- schnicks (market-aid societies) etc. prove. (Friikanf, Die russ. Artels in Faucher^s Vierteljahrsschrift, 1S68, I, 106 fl'.) We may also mention the greater credit accorded to a land-owner the moment he becomes a member Vol. I.— 18 274 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. VI. surprise us, that the great obtain credit from those in a lower position, at least as frequently as they give them credit in turn. On the side of the creditor, the possibility of making loans is a powerful incentive to frugality. Were there no credit, those who were not in a condition to employ their capital pro- ductively would make savings only within veiy narrow limits.'' SECTION XCI. DEBTOR LAWS. Private credit is always conditioned, and in a great many ways, by the situation of the whole nation's business ; in other of a land-loan association as compared with what he could obtain before he had joined it. The popular belief of the ancient Egyptians afforded them a very great instrument of credit in the pledging of the remains of their an- cestors. (Herodot., II, 136.) ' B. Hildehrand is of opinion that the Political Economy of the future may be characterized as credit-economy, in the same way as the EcoruDmy of the present may be called money-economy, and that of the past as barter- economy of barter. (National CEkonomie der Gegenwart und Zukunft, I, 276 ff.) Hildehrand^ s view is correct in so far as that, with every advance in civilization, credit comes to have absolutely and relatively an ever increasing importance, although in the middle ages, especially under feudal forms ( Lchensformcn), there Avere numberless operations in credit. Otherwise, however, Hildehrand' s three kinds of economy are, by no means, coordinated. While barter and purchase through the instrumentality of money, in every instance, entirely exclude each other, it is impossible to imagine a credit- transaction of which the promise of a barter-performance or of a money -per- formance does not constitute the base. During a "money-economical (geldwirtJisckaftlicIien) period " [i. e., one during which money is the medium of exchange, and not notes; and when barter does not obtain. — Translator.'] the service rendered by money as a medium of exchange may, for the most part, be supplanted by credit. Money, as a measure of value, still remains the substratum of credit itself. (See Knies in the Tiibinger Ztschr., 1S60, 154 ff. ; and in the Freiburger Programm^ 9 Sept., 1862, 19.) Earlier yet, A. JFag-ner, Beitr. zur Lehre von den Banken, 1857 ff. Among the most prac- tical propositions of Saint Simonism is that oi a. systhnc general des haftques, intended to administer all the goods of the nation, and to loan them to indi- viduals engaged in production. (Bazard, 205 ff.) Sec. XCI.] DEBTOR -LAW. 275 words, by their politico-economical situation. It is especially in the higher stages of civilization, that one bankrupt may easily drag numberless others down with him ;• and where the laws are bad or powerless, not even the wealthiest man can predicate his own solvency for any length of time in advance. One of the most important conditions of credit is the certainty that, if the debtor's good will to meet his obligations should fail, it shall be supplied by the compulsory process of the courts. Hence, the importance of a judicial procedure, at once impartial, enlightened, prompt and cheap.^ The more vigorous the laws relating to debt are in preventing dishonesty on the part of the debtor, the more advantageous are they to honorable and honest debtors. Adam Smith has rightly said, that in countries in which creditors are not completely pro- tected by the courts, the honorable man who borrows money is in the same condition as the notoriously dishonest man or the spendthrift, in better governed countries. He finds it more difficult to borrow and is obliged to pay a higher rate of in- terest.^ Rigorous debtor laws, on the other hand, diminish in ' It is destructive of credit to allow the ddator to await several decrees or judgments before his liability is established; to allow him, on easy terms, dekiys, reversals of judgment, the costs of the case etc. The term within which a creditor might bring in his claim before the meeting of creditors in the Amsterdam Boedel-chamber was formerly thirty-three and a third years. (BUsck, Darst. der Handlung, Zusatz, 82.) In the presidency of Bengal there were, in 1S19, Si,ooo cases in arrears, and in 1829, 140,000. Westinin- ister Review, XIX, 142. ^ And yet Melon is of opinion that the state should favor the debtor as much as possible. (Essai politique sur le Commerce, ch. 12, iS.) This was the view entertained on this subject by the older practitioners. In Bengal, the dJiura, a species of "judgment of God," in which the party who could hold out longest against hunger was declared the victor, was the only means to compel a debtor to pay his debt. As a consequence, the Bengal peasant could not borrow money at less than 60 per cent, per annum. Edinburgh Review, XXII, 67. On the damages attending the credit-laws and credit- courts of Russia, by which all foreign goods are rendered exceedinglv dear, see_ V. Sternberg, Bemerkungen iiber R., loo ff. In a country in Avhich a great many powerful personages are above the laws, an incorporated loaning bank may be an indispensable necessity. (StorcJi, Handbuch, II, p, 23 ff.) 276 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Cn. VI. the whole nation the amount of " bad debts," that is, a not in- significant portion of the cost of production. They, at the same time, promote, as far as it is in the power of laws to do it, national honor and the mutual confidence of man in man. The excellence of their debtor laws, in their most flourishing period, was one of the principal elements which contributed to make Athens and Rome of such importance in the history of the world.^ SECTION XCII. HISTORY OF CREDIT LAWS. In the history of laws relating to credit, we may distinguish, in a great many countries, three stages of development. A. The laws, in the first stage, are very severe. In the Germanic middle age the insolvent was disgraced. He be- came the slave of his creditor (zti Hand und Halfter), who might imprison him, fetter him (stocken und blocken), and probably kill him. A Norwegian law allowed the creditor, when his debtor would not work and his friends would not ransom him, to take him before the court, and "to lop olTfrom his body what part he will, above or below." ^ To judge of In Naples, even as recently as 1804, no debtor could be arrested during the last six months of the queen's pregnancy. At a previous period, one might fail in business there and escape all punishment by exposing the hindermost part of himself in a nude state publicly before a column of the Vicaria. (Rehfues, Gemalde von Neapel, I, p. 203 seq., 222.) In Schwytz, the rate ot interest is so high, because the law allows the debtor to pay his creditor, whether the latter will or not, in articles of household furniture, clothes etc., estimated at a very high value. (Hermann^ Staatsw. Untersuchungen, 202.) It has now become quite usual in the United States, on account of the many delays granted to the debtor by " democratic " laws introduced there, instead of mere mortgage, to give full warranty deeds when capital is loaned. By this means, the creditor is in danger, when misfortune overtakes him, to see himself compelled to let his property go at one-fourth of its value. ' See the Heliast oath in Detnosih'., adv. Timocr., 746. The Roman sys- tem of credits in the time of Polybius was much better than the Cartha- genian. Polyb., VI, 56, XXXII, 13. ' Sachsenspiegel, III, 39. y. Grimtn, Deutsche Rechtsalterthiimer, 612 fF. Sec. XCIL] HISTORY OF CREDIT LAWS. 277 these provisions correctly, it is necessary to bear in mind the many ways in which family resources were at this time bound and tied up , and not forget " the power of defiance in these iron natures." "^ (JViehuhr.) B. The canon law introduced milder principles. Gregory the Great had already prohibited the holding on to the body of the debtor.^ On this account, during the latter portion of the middle ages, it was customary to stipulate by contract that the provisions of the ancient law should govern in this matter, to submit to imprisonment etc.* The influence of the Roman law made it gradually more usual, in the case of insolvent debtors, to demand no more from them than the assignment of their property for the benefit of their creditors. This, how- ever, led to numerous frauds ; and these became more frequent in proportion as the laws governing the property of parties while the marriage relation existed between them, and as ex- ecutions against landed property etc. were defective. C. Hence, in more highly civilized times, there has been a return to the severity of earlier ages. Persons engaged in commerce, especially those whose capital is so volatile, and to whom time is a thing so precious, can scarcely dispense wil- lingly with personal imprisonment for debt. Hence, legisla- tion on bills of exchange, sanctioned especially by imprison- ment of the person, plays a very important part in the com- mercial cities of the seventeenth century, as it did, naturally, much earlier in Italy and the Netherlands.^ Modern laws in Dahlinann^ Danische Gesch., II, 245, 339. Hermann^ Russ. Gesch., Ill, 357. On slavery for debt among the Malays, see Ausland, 1845, No. 157. ^ Beauj'our, Tableau du Commerc en Grfece, II, 176. ^C. 2 X. De Pignor. An appropriate provision in a priestly govern- ment. Diodor., I, 79. * Staying in a place by the debtor until the creditor is satisfied, and other degrading stipulations, which, however, were prohibited by the police regu- lations of the Empire in 1548, art. 17. ^ Mai'teii's Ursprung des Wcchselrechts, 1797. .Statuta Mediol., 14S0, fol. 238 ff. The municipal law of Florence unconditionally imprisoned the father or grandfather for the debt of the son, when the latter engaged in in- dustrial pursuits with their consent. (Stat. Flor., I, 201) In Bologna, the 27S PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Cii VI, many cases punish the bankrupt whenever an examination of his books, kept after approved methods, does not demonstrate his innocence.® The great facility of fraudulent bankruptcy, where commerce has attained a high degree of development and complication ; the absence of honor shown in engaging in speculation for one's own gain with a stranger's capital, and without the real owner's knowledge; the comparatively small number of blameless and irreproachable bankruptcies,'' cer- tainly justify these provisions.^ ^ bi-others of a bankrupt who had constituted one household with him were held responsible for his debts. (Statuti dell' Universita de Mercantati della Citta di B., 1550, fol. no.) The law of Geneva excluded from all positions of honor the son who had left his father's debts unpaid. Montesquieu, E. des Lois, XX, 16. The consequence was, that among the higher classes not a creditor lost anything for centuries. (K. L. v. Haller, Restauration der Staatswissenschaften, VI, 519.) Compare the "Nurenberger Reformation" of 1479, fol. 61 and 68 of the edition of 1564. fi Compare the R. P. O. of 154S, art. 22. And so, by the Code de Com- merce, III, 4, I, even the simple bankrupt in contradistinction to the fraudu- lent bankrupt is punished, and every person unable to pay his debts is de- clared a simj>le bankrupt, who, among other things, has made excessive household expenses, or lost considerable sunas by play etc. Compare Sully, Mdmoires, Livre XXVI, who declares it to be his most wholesome law, that fraudulent bankrupts should, like thieves, be punished with death, and that all their fraudulent assignments, gifts, etc., should be declared void. Fur- ther, Ordonn. de Louis XIV., sur les Failletes, art. 11 ; y. de Wit, Mfimoires, 77 if; V. den Heuvel, Sur le Commerce de la Hollande, iioff. Frederick William I., in 1715, threatened with the galleys all light-headed bankrupts, and, in 1723, all those who, knowing their insolvent condition, should effect further loans. Mylius, Corp. Const. March. II, 2, 31, 40. For China, see Davi?, The Chinese, i, 247 ff. Gr. Sodcn, Nat. Oek., Ill, 231, demands that, in case of doubt, the guilt of the bankrupt should always be presumed. ' In England only one-tenth of the number of bankrupts are considered innocent. Elliott, Credit the Life of Commerce, 1845, 50 ff. ^ The contrainte far corps of debtors was abolished in France in 1792, but restored in 1797. Even Turgot remarked that since slavery had ceased there was no further fear ( .^) that the poor would be oppressed by imprisonment for debt. (Sur le Pr^t d' argent, § 31.) According to Droz, the question is not one of weighing " freedom " against " miserable money," but the depriva- tion of a few of that freedom and the non-fulfillment of obligations entered into, that is against the destruction of public confidence. • A similar development among the Greeks : Sec. XCIII.] MEANS OF PROMOTING CREDIT. 279 SECTION XCIII. MEANS OF PROMOTING CREDIT. One of the most efficient means of promoting credit con- sists in legislation intended to dry up the somxe of bad debts, by placing obstacles in the way of reckless or usm^ious credits A. Rigorous slavery for debt, Avhich Kypselos moderated at Corinth. (Pausan.,Y. 17, 2), and Solon abolished in Athens. (Plutarch, Sol., 15. Dc- mosth., de fals. Legat., 412.) B. The reckless creation of debts as seen in Aristophanes; while outside of Athens slavery for debt lasted yet a long time. (Hermann, Griech. Pri- vatalterth., § 57, 20.) In the time of Demosthenes, the merchant in arrears in the payment of his debts -was cast into prison, and the bottomry-debtor who deprived his creditor of his security might be punished with death. (Demosth. adv. Phann., 922, 95S), and this although the cessio honorum was introduced. Hermann, § 70, 3. Compare Xenofh., Vectigg., 3, Demosth. adv Apat., 892 ; adv. Lacrit., and and adv. Dionys. In Corinth, the state superin- tended expenses made by parties. This was part of its credit-policy. (AthcencEus, VI, 227) For a remarkable Rhodian law relating to debts, see Sext. Emp., Hypot. I, 149. In Rome : A. The chief characteristic of the ancient law in this matter was the eventual sale of the person of the debtor on the getting of the loan (nextim) ; the power of the creditor to put the addictus to death or to sell him in foreign parts ; finally, the in partes secanto, in the concourse of creditors. Without these rigorous provisions, the borrower might easily have evaded his debts, by the emancipation of his son and turning over his property to him. (Nic- bithr, Rom. Gesch., II, 770 ff ; Savigny in the Abb. der Berliner Acad., 1S33. Ztmmern, Gesch. des rbm. Privatrechts, III, 131 ft". B. Later, we find nothing of the execution of the debtor, or of the sale ot his person ; but he might be compelled to do slave labor for his creditor Avithout any protection against ill-treatment. Slavery for debtAvas restricted by the Lex Poetelia. (Niebnhr, III, p. i"]^; Mommseu, 111,494.) The Praetorian laAV introduced the custom of putting the creditor in possession of the goods of the debtor, Avith poAver of sale, Avhich proceeding rendered the debtor in- famous. See several passages in Walter., Rom Rechtsgesch, 763 ft" ; Tcrf/dl., Apol., 4; Tab. Herac. I, 115 ft". Later, Cresar's Lex Julia permitted the hon- est debtor to escape imprisonment by the assignment of his goods. C. The moneyed oligarchy Avhich prevailed in Rome catised the adoption of exceedingly severe measures against delinquent debtors. (Plut.,'L\xc\\\\., 20. Cic., ad. Att. V. 21, VI.), although its members themselves incurred 280 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. VI. for objects of luxury or pleasure, to bad customers.^ But the application of these laws should be clear and simple as to their matter, and require no inquiries, relating to the person, impracticable for a business man to make.^ Thus, for in- stance, a short period of limitation established by statute in the matter of advances made for ordinary money-claims is a beneficial restraint, as well on the creditor as on the debtor, since it prevents the accumulation of a multitude of small debts which almost imperceptibly but at the same time irre- sistibly overpower the debtor under their weight.^ Another debts in the most reckless manner. C^sar, in the year A. C. 62, excluding his active (acit'veu), owed debts to the amount of 25,000,000 sesterces; M. Antonius, in the year 24, 6,000,000; in the year 38, 40,000,000; Curio, 60,- 000,000; Milon, 70,000,000. (Mommsen, Romische Geschichte, III, 486.) Compare Gelltus, XX, i, XV, 14. ' Whenever a new shop-keeper, who sells goods on monthly credits, set- tles in a district, the number of poor persons invariably increases. (McCul- lock, Commercial Dictionary.) The ruinous credit given by the Jews to the Westphalian peasants begins with an account for the goods which they have succeeded in pressing upon them., after five or six years have elapsed. The Jew seldom sues accounts at law; but he besieges the debtor and discovers where his last head of cattle and his last little supply of provisions are to be found. As he is willing to accept everything that has any value, sometimes in payment of arrears, and sometimes in payment for some new piece of trash, he is sure to obtain his dues in the end, but not until his victim, who is sunk deeper and deeper in the abyss of debt by every " accommodation," is entirely ruined. (Schmerz, Rheinish-Westphal. L. W., 396 ft") - In the lower and middle stages of civilization, we find a multitude of laws by which minors, students etc., but especially land-owners are limited to a minimum of credit, which, however, varies very much with the person, and is subjected to a number of embarrassing forms, the consent of a third person, for instance etc. (Compare Bayerische L. O. von 1553, fol. 83.) Such laws, however, give as much room to the play of dishonesty as they take away from that of want of reflection. ^ On the municipal regulations (Slddteoydtiungen) oi the 14th and 15th centuries, which compelled Jewish creditors especially to have their evi- dences of indebtedness redeemed within from every two to five years, see Stobbe, Juden im Mittetalter,_ 129. Compare further the Wiirtemberg L. O. of 1515, Statut. Ferrar, ed. 1650, lib. II, rub. 37, 289. According to the other provisions of the laws in North America, some book accounts were re- quired to be sued on within six and others within seventeen years. (Ebeling^ Sec. XCIII.] MEANS OF PROMOTING CREDIT. 281 efficient means is associations of business men to circulate lists of bad debtors, and to prosecute their own demands in com- mon.'* On the other hand, experience has shown that impris- onment for debt, as a means of enforcing a creditor's claim, where the amount of the debt is very small and such as only- very poor debtors are apt to incur, is of little service. It is even injurious, because a great many sellers would rely on that means of compelling payment in the future instead of de- manding it immediately, as they should do in the interest both of themselves and of their customers. As a rule, it is only rich creditors who can resort to it with success, a class who compel payment through this means by wringing it from the debtor's relations more frequently than from the debtor him- self. The working out of debts in correctional institutions seems, for the same reasons, to fail of its object, since even well governed institutions scarcely cover their current ex- penses from the income derived from this source.^ The in- equitable character of imprisonment for debt lies in this, that it punishes the unfortunate debtor as severely as it does the malicious one. It must be clearly distinguished from the im- prisonment recognized by the courts as a punishment for reck- less or fraudulent bankruptcy ."^ We must pass a judgment Gerchichte und Erdberchreibung der v.Staaten, 11,247, 298.) The Prussian law of March 31, 1S38, provides a period of limitation of three years for all ordinary commercial debts. A similar law was passed in the Kingdom of Saxony, in 1846. In London, there has been found a great number of hat- ters, tailors, boot and shoe dealers etc., whose books showed credits of more than £4,000, most of them not to exceed over £10. How much of all this must be lost entirely, and how that loss must increase the sums paid for boots, shoes and hats by the prompt payer! (McCulloch^ v. Credit.) We find, even in Athens, that the period of limitation was shortened in the in- terest of credit, and that in the case of minors, it did not exceed five years. (Demosth. adv. Nausim., 989.) Security for a debtor not over one year. (Dcmosth., adv. Apatur., 901.) The prohibition of Zaleukos to issue any ev- idences of debt whatever goes much farther. (Zetiob., Proverb. V, 4.) 4 Compare the report of the Dresden Handelskammer, 1864, 11. ^ A. Mayer, in Fauclier''s Vierteljahrsschrift, 1S65, IV, 65. 8 We learn from the debates in the English parliament of February 9, 282 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Cii. IV. similar to tliat on the imprisonment of the person of the debtor on the seizure of his wages not yet due, so far, at least, as an amount absolutely necessary to save himself and family from want, is not excepted. The prohibition of such seizure, be- yond this, would amount to a declaration that all workmen without capital, even the best, should be considered un- worthy of credit.'^ We may also include in this category such laws as except from execution the necessary tools of a tradesman, since to deprive him of them would be to pre- 1827, that, in two years and a half, there were, in London and its environs, 70,000 cases of imprisonment for debt, tlie costs of which were from £i5o,ooa to £200,000. In 1S31, there were in one debtors' prison 1,120 prisoners, who owed on an average £2 3s. 2d. (AlcCidloch, 1. c.) Tliere was, in 1792, a case of a woman who, for a debt of £19, remained in prison 45 years, and others like it. (See Archenholtz, Annalen, IX, 87 ff; X, 169 ft, XIII, 125.) In En- gland in 1844, arrest for sums less than £19 was prohibited. Johnson had al- ready proposed a similar provision. (Idler, 1758, Nos. 22 and 38.) Impris- onment for debt was abolished in France, England and Austria in 1867; in the Nortli German Confederation, on the 29th of May, 1S68, but arrest for se- curity's sake was retained. Sismondi finds fault with nearly all laws in the premises, because they attack the person of the debtor rather than his per- sonal property, and his personal, rather than his immovable, property. He would have all this just the contrary of what it is. The first interferes with the very source of wealth, the productive power of labor; the second causes goods to be sold much below their value. Neither of these evils attends the last. (N. PrincipeSy I, 250.) ' A law of the North German Confederation allows the pledging of future wages, only in the case of public officers, and those holding permanent places in the service of private parties, whose salaries are over 400 thalers per an- num. The original draft had excepted only the things necessary to workmen and those directly depending on them ; while the law as passed makes the prohibition general. This was undoubtedly done for the convenience of em- ployers as well as of courts ; as for instance in the circuit of Dortmund, there were, in one year, 10,000 cases in which wages were garnisheed. (An- nalen des N. D. Bundes und Zollvereins, 1869, 1071 ft".) But the recklessness of those workmen whose wages are below the average, might have been just as well guarded against without dragging those whose wages are above the average down to their level, if a distinction had been made between pro- duction-credit and consumption-credit, and the latter had been limited by pro- viding that no suit should be instituted for supplies made to public houses, taverns etc. Sfx. xciv.] letters of respite. 283 vent his employing even his labor to satisfy ^ his creditors' claims. SECTION XCIV. letters of respite (SPECIALMORATORIEN). special letters of respite (S-peciahnoratorien) are a suspension of the laws relating to debt, made in favor of an individual. (^linquennalia.) They were intended to protect not onl}^ the debtor, but also the aggregate of creditors against the sVort-sighted severity of one of their number. They were wont to be given especially when the debtor showed that im- mediate execution would not only have the effect of ruining himself, but of sending his creditors away empty handed; while, if time were given him, he would be able to satisfy every one.^ But the granting of such letters has, in recent times, been prohibited ^ in nearly all countries as arbitrary, and 8 In the second book of Moses, 22, 25 fF., and the fifth, 24, 6. A very old Norman law provides that in actions for debt, execution should not issue against effects of the debtor which are indispensably necessary to him to maintain his position, such as the horses of a count or the armor of a knight. (Dialog, de Scaccario.) Magna Charta extended this provision so as to in- clude the agricultural implements and cattle of the peasanti-y. The moment tliese laws, in consequence of a false principle of humanity, except anything but what is absolutely necessary, they injure credit. Thus, for instance, in Brazil, a law of 1758, providing that nothing immediately employed in or directly necessary to the production of sugar should be seized on execu- tion, caused great injury to the production of sugar. (Koste>\ Travels in B., 1S16, 356 ff. ' § 2, Cod. De Prec. Imper. Off., I, 19. The diets of the Empire had granted such letters in the fourteenth century. (WacJisniutli, Europ. Sittengesch., IV, 690.) They were granted, as a rule, only with the previous knowledge of the Emperor, by the police ordinances of the Empire of 1548, art. 22. 2 So in Austria, Saxony, Brunswick, the electorates of Hesse and Baden. In Prussia, they could be granted only after a juridical decree to that effect; and an appeal to a superior court was allowed to reverse or affirm it. Com- pare Mittermaier in the Archiv. fiir civilist. Praxis, XVI, and also P. de la Court, Aanwysing der politike Gronden en Maximen van Holland etc., 1669, I, ch. 25. Niirnberg obtained as a privilege, in 1495, that no moratorium 284 PRODUCTION OF GOODS. [B. I, Ch. VI. as a species of cabinet-justice. Nor should the granting of them be compared with the pardoning power. In the case of a pardon, the oflended State forgives. In this case it sacrifices the unquestionable right of one party to the very doubtful ad- vantage of another. Where such letters are granted in great numbers, credit cannot fail to suffer. " ^uinquinnellen gehoren in die Ho lien I " Yet in troublous times, when a great many debtors are in- solvent at the same time, the question of modifying the laws relating to debt, temporarily, has been mooted. It has been urged on such occasions, that it would be a matter of enor- mous difficulty to treat, lege artis, thousands as bankrupts a\ Qnce ; that thousands of businesses would have to be closed, their stocks cast upon the market at mock prices, and their em- ployees thrown out of employment. But, if certain privileges were to be accorded to all who should declare themselves un- able to meet their obligations before a certain day, it would be known, at least, that the others were in a solid condition; and this would have the effect to strengthen the credit which had been before universally shaken. We must, however, leaving all cases of abuse out of the question, remember, that a really unrightful favor, granted to the debtor, may possi- bly entail the ruin of his creditor. Besides, the uncertainty of the law would have a much worse eflect on credit than uncer- tainty as to the personal status of individuals.^ Where, as is the case generally in inferior stages of civilization, debtors and creditors form two distinct classes, the question of right is not, indeed, changed, but there is a solid basis afforded for the political admeasurement of opposing interests. In another should be valid as against its citizens. (Rotk, Geschichte des Niirnb. Han- dels, I, 86.) ^ Compare the discussions in the French National Assembly, in the month of August, 1848. It is much less disadvantageous in times of great commo- tion, when all business is brought to a stand still, to extend the time in which bills of exchange etc. are payable. Such a measure prevents a number of bankruptcies which the real balance of debts due to one and owing by him does not render necessary. Sec. XCIV.] LETTERS OF RESPITE. 285 work I have shown how, after great w^ars, land owners, who became involved in debt, have been protected against cap- italists. (See Roschci'^ Nationalokonomik des Ackerbaues, * In the persecution of the Jews in the middle ages, tlie so-called Brief - tddteti (letter-killing), or the destruction of titles, was very common. In iiSS, the French government released all crusaders from the payment of in- terest on their debts, and granted them an extension of three years' time to pay oft' the principal. (SisDwiidi, Hist, des Fran9ais, VI, 82.) Similar com- pulsory measures were provided against the Jews and usurers in 1223 (Ibid, VI, 539 ff.); and in 1299 (Ordonnances, I, '1331), on the formal request of the nobility. (Ordonnances, II, 59.) Again, in 1594, there was a release of one- third of the interest on all national and private debts. (Stsmondt, XXI, 318.) The general moratorium of the Milanese for a term of eight years, introduced in 125 1, after their war with France, was of an essentially different character. (Sismondi, Geschichte der italienischen Republiken, III, 155.) The same is true of the general indidt granted by Philip II. in Belgium. (Boxhorn^ Dis- quisitt. politicnc, 241 ff".) ^ The abolition or release of debts, so frequent in ancient revolutionary times, reminds us, in many ways, of the crises precipitated in modern times by paper money and produced by the state. The ancestors of Alcibades and Hipponikos laid the foundation of an immense fortune, in Solon's time, by purchasing land in large quantities with money borrowed from several citizens, a short time before the abolition of debts. (Plutarch, Sol., 15.) BOOK II. THE CIECULATION OF GOODS. CHAPTER I. CIRCULATION IN GENERAL. SECTION XCV. MEANING OF THE CIRCULATION OF GOODS. The more highly developed the division of labor is, the more frequent and necessary do exchanges become. While the hermit engaged in production thinks only of his own wants, and the mere housekeeper of the w^ants of his household, the man w'ho is part of a nation and who plays a part in its gen- eral economy, must bear in mind the market in which goods of one kind are exchanged against goods of other kinds. The greater, more various and more changeable the conditions of this market are, the greater are the intellectual faculties de- manded to engage in it successfully, and to the advantage of everybody concerned in it.^ Goods intended to be exchanged ' Enormous consumption of wax in the churches of the middle ages. In the cathedral of Wittenberg alone, a short time before the Reformation, more than 35,000 pounds of wax candles etc. were burned yearly. At the same time, honey was generally used instead of sugar. Haw much more important, therefore, at that time must bee-culture have been, considered from the point of view of circulation as compared with what it is to-da\-. And so in Catholic countries, a difference in the external manifestation of re- ligion causes the relative importance of the consumption of fish to increase and decrease. In 1S03 there was little demand in France for ivory crucifixes, rosaries etc. In 1844, the demand for them and iov;prie-Dieu for the bed-room etc. was increased. (Mohl, Gewerbwissenschafliche Reise, loi.) To engage successfully in the sale of sugar in Persia, it is necessary to know that in that Vol. I. — 19 290 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Cii. I are called commodities. By the circulation of commodities is meant their going over from one owner to another.^ Among the principal causes of circulation, we may mention the differ- ence in the nature and civilization of countries and peoples, the distinction betweenxity and country, the division of people into classes etc.^ The rapidity of circulation depends, on the one hand, on the quantity of commodities, and on the other, on the degree to which the division of labor has been carried. In both respects it is, therefore, an important indication of the wealth of the nation, and of the world. Different commodities have very different degrees of capac- ity for circulation (Circidatiotisfahigkeit)^ that is, of certainty of finding purchasers, and of facility of seeking purchasers. The smaller, compared with its value, the volume and weight of a commodity are ; the longer and more conveniently it can be stored away; the more invariable and well-known are its value in use and value in exchange: the more readily does it go from one place to another, the more easily is it transmitted from one period of time to another and from the possession of one person into the possession of another. Thus, for instance, the precious metals circulate more rapidly than industrial pro- country it is liked only in little hat-shaped lumps, which are used only as semi- voluntary gifts ; and that, in such case, custom fixes the number of lumps. (Steinhatcs, Russlands commercielle etc. Verhh., 151.) In the Levant, workmen prefer bars of iron which are small and of varied form because they find it difficult to manipulate the large ones. The English bear this in mind much better than the Russians. (Steinhaiis.) A merchant sending wood to Southern France must be acquainted with the form of the staves used in the manufacture of barrels there. Compare BUsch, Geldumlauf, VI, 2, 2. '^ The circulation of goods compared to the circulation of the blood : by Mirahean., Philosophie Rurale, ch. 3. Turgot, Sur la Formation etc. § 69. Canard., Principes, ch. 6. 3 Eiselen, Volkswirthschaftslehre, 98 ff. If in ancient times commerce played a much less important part than it does among the moderns, it was, as Montesquieu says, because the whole commercial world was then more uni- form in climate and the character of its products than it is nov;^. (Esprit des Lois, XXI, 4. Sec. XCV.] MEANING OF CIRCULATION. 291 ducts; these in turn more than raw material,^ and immovable property circulates least rapidly of all. An improvement in the means of transportation naturally increases the capacity of cir- culation of the entire wealth of a people, and especially of those commodities which were not before transferable as well as of those of which the cost of transportation constituted a pecu- liarly large component part of the price.^ The greater the capacity for circulation of any kind of goods, the greater is the power of control of its owner in the world of trade. If we compare two men, each of whom possesses a million of dol- lars, but one of whom has that million in money and the other in land, we shall find that the former is able, for present pur- poses, such as loaning to the state in case of need, aiding a conspiracy etc., to command resources much more readily and efTectively than the latter. Under the ordinary circumstances of a nation's economy, we find that the owner of money is very seldom in want of bread, fuel or clothing, whereas very many owners of other property may be in want of money.^ True, resources which may, so to speak, take the offensive most energeticalh^, offer less resistance to unforeseen misfor- tune. The possessor of such resources is in a condition to lose his all on the turn of a single die. As civilization advances, the circulating capacity of a nation's wealth increases.''' ■* Of the successive steps, sheaves, corn, flour, bread, — flour has the great- est capacity for circulation. And, indeed, the last operation of labor on a great many goods, because of their consequent more narrowly specialized utility, is accompanied by a decrease in their capacity for circulation. As an illustration, we may mention ready-made clothing as compared with cloth. The capacit}^ for circulation of a commodity is very much advanced when the demand is wont to increase with the supply, as is the case with gold and silver, but not with learned books, optical instruments etc. Many commod- ities have but little circulating capacity, because no one desires to purchase them but at first hand. See Menge>\ Grundsatze, I, 245 ff. 5 K7itcs., Die Eisenbahnen und ihre Wirkungen, 1853, 79. ^ Compare Schmittheiiner, I, who calls attention and with reason to the im- portance of loans on chattel mortgages. But Berkeley, Querist, No. 265, remarks that a squire with a yearly income of £1000 can, " upon an emer- gency," do less good or evil than a merchant with £20,000 ready money. ' A very important difterence between Russia and England. 292 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. I. SECTION XCVI. RAPIDITY OF CIRCULATION. With an advance in a people's public economy, we find an increased rapidity of circulation connected, both as cause and effect. Every improvement, every thing which shortens the process of production, must facilitate and accelerate the circu- lation of commodities. And so, the perfecting of the means of transport of commodities, of the media of exchange and of credit, an increase in the number of middlemen who make it their business to purchase in order to sell again. On the other hand, the more rapid the circulation of wealth, the more can it promote production. The more rapidly, for instance, the manufacturer of cloth exchanges his wares for money, the more rapidly may he employ the money in the purchase of new tools and the hiring of new labor; and the sooner may he appear in the market with new cloth. It is here precisely as it is in agriculture, which is more productive where the seed returns several times in a year (several crops ^) to the hand of ' SiorcJi, Handbuch, I, 273 ff. There is also a useless circulation which is not calculated to promote the division of labor, but to employ idle time or idle capital, as in the case of games of hazard, speculation in stocks, wheat etc. Even impoverishing consumption may produce rapidity of circulation, as in Germany during the war years 1812 and 1S13. (F. G. Scliulzc^ N. Qikonomie, 1856, 667.) Relying on this fact, Hume (1752) on Public Credit, Discourses, No. 8, argues in favor of the old opinion, that all circulation is wholesome and to be encouraged. Boisgttillcberf, Traite des Grains, I, 6, went so far as to laud war because it accelerated the circulation of wealth. On the necessity of a circulation sans i'e^os,see ibid., II, 10. In a similar way, Law, Trade and Money, 1705, and Dutos, Reflexions "Politiques sur le Com- merce, over- valued the circulation of wealth as such. Concerning the Mer- cantile System, see § 116. Darjes, Erste Griinde der Camerahvissenschaft, 1768, 531. And even Biisc/i, Geldumlauf, I, 29, 32 ff.. Ill, 96, who in other places nearly always overlooks real production and sees only the circula- tion of money caused thereby. Thus he calls the poor when they are helped in money, and spend it, useful members of society! (IV, 32, 39.) Similarly, v. Stfuensee, Abhandlungen, 1800, I, 2S2 ff., 400 ff. Sec. XCVII.] FREEDOM OF COMPETITION. 293 the peasant than it is where this liappens only once. The nearer the members of the commercial organism are to one another, the more rapid is circulation wont to be. Hence, it is more rapid in industry than in agriculture ; in retail trade than in wholesale; in large cities than in the country; among a dense population than among a sparse population. The regularity of circulation increases with economic cul- ture. Its concentration at large terminal points, its interrup- tion by bad seasons of the year, belong to the lower stages of the political economy of a people; although bad harvests, floods, wars, revolutions etc. may, at any time, lead to a slug- gishness or to an arrest of circulation. SECTION XCVII. FREEDOM OF COMPETITION. But it is especially the freedom of circulation that increases with an advance in civilization, and this advance, like the two preceding, first aflects the home or inland circulation. Free- dom of competition, the freedom of commerce and industry, technical expressions used to designate freedom in general in the domain of a nation's economy, is the natural conclusion drawn from the principles of individual independence and of private property. Hence its development is as slow as the development of these, and attains its fuU growth only in high- ly cultivated nations, their colonies and dependencies. In very low stages of economic development, the circulation of goods is hampered by the absence of legal security ; later, by priv- ileges accorded to a great number of families, corporate bodies, municipalities, classes, etc., and later yet by the mighty guardianship which the state exercises by its power of legis- lation and even of education.^ Each one of these epochs con- ' As, for instance, happened in France in 1577, when all commerce, and in 1585 all industry, were declared to be de droit domanial. Louis XIV. was of opinion that the king ^^•as absolute master of all private property of priests 294 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Cn. I. stitutes the end of the preceding one, and is milder than it was. Finally comes the period of complete freedom, when every man is permitted to manage his own affairs even with injury to himself, provided the injury is confined to himself; The later times of the Roman Empire are the best illustra- tion of how, with the decline of the conditions which must pre- cede freedom of competition, that freedom itself decays.^ Freedom of competition unchains all economic forces, good and bad. Hence, when the former preponderate, it hastens the time of a people's grandeur, as it does their decline where the latter gain the upper hand.® We may say of economic free- dom what may be said of all other freedom, that the removal of external constraint can be justified and produces the greater good of the greater number only where a stern empire over self takes its place. Without this it would not prevent or avoid idle- ness, usury or over-population. Freedom must not be simply negative. It must be positive. If on account of the immatur- ity or over-maturity of a people, there be no sturdy middle class among them, unlimited competition may become what Bazard calls a general $aitve-qtn-peut (let the devil take the hindmost); what Fourier designates as a 7norcellement indus- iriel, and a fraude commerciale ; what M. Chevalier denomi- nated " a battle-field on which the little are devoured by the and people. (Mdmoires histor. de Louis XIV., II, 121.) Compare Duclos, Mdjnoires, I, 14 ff. * Compare Theod. Cod., V, 9, i ; Just. Cod., X, 19, 8; XI, 47, 21, 23; XI, 50, 51, 52, 55, 58. How full the really classic period of the Roman jurists was of the idea of freedom of competition, we see in Paullus: L. 22, § 3, Dig. XIX, 2. The provisions concerning Icesio enormis appear first in the time of Diocletian. (Just. Cod., IV, 44, 2.) '^Benjamin Franklin says that the freer the form of government is, the more the people show themselves in their true aspect. Ancient Rome, with the early development of its rational disposition, soon learned to favor free- dom of commercial intercourse. Compare Mommsen, Romische Geschichte, I, passim. This was, certainly, an element of its greatness, but also of the proletarian evils developed in it an early date, and which were weighed down only by the absolute growth of the state and the development of its eco- nomic interests during centuries. Sec. XCVIL] FREEDOM OF COMPETITION. 295 big;" and in such case, as Bodz-Reymond says, the word competition, meaning simply that each one is permitted to run in whatever direction he may see a door open to him, is but another and a new expression for vagabondizing. But here the evil does not lie in too great competition, but in this, that on one side there is too little competition.'* The opposing prin- ciple of competition is always monopoly, that is, as John Stuart Mill says, tlie taxation of industry in the interest of indol- ence and even rapacity; and protection against competition is synonymous with a dispensation from the necessity to be as industrious and clever as other people. A protection of this nature, sufficiently effective to attain its end, would not fail to arrest the efforts of those who had ac- complished something, and even to turn them backward. That freedom of competition is a species of declaration of war,^ among men considered as producers, is certain ; but, at the same time, it makes all men considered as consumers mem- bers of one society, in which all the members are equally in- terested, a fact too much overlooked by socialists.® It is the means especially by which the greatest and ever increasing portion of the forces of nature are raised to the character of the free and common property of the human race.''' " Man is not the favorite of nature in the sense that nature has done everything for him, but in the sense that it has endowed him with the ability to do everything for himself. The right of freedom of competition may, therefore, be considered both * Nor must it be forgotton that competition raises prices as well as lowers them. The expressions higher price and lower price denote only different sides of the same relation. M. Chevalier is of opinion that our present breathless competition is characteristic only of a period of transition prolific in new inventions, a competition soon to be followed by peace. (Cours, II, 450 ff.) ^ 'Ayad-Yj lore > Hesiod.^ Opp., 10 fF. « " Whoever speaks of competition suppresses the existence of a common aim," says Protidkon, although he adds, after Bilcatiis way, that to cure the evils of competition by competition, is as absurd as to lead men to liberty by liberty, or to cultivate the mind by cultivation of the mind. ' Compare Bastiat, Harmonies dconomiques, ch. 10. 296 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. I. the protection and the image of this provision of nature. (Zacharid.f The person, therefore, who claims or asserts an exception from the rule of free competition, has to prove his position in every individual case, since the burthen of proof is on him. But the duty of interference on the part of the state is posi- tively pointed out where any interest common to the whole people is not in a condition to assert itself; and negatively, v/hen the custom which hitherto had prevented an undoubted abuse has grown too weak to continue to perform that service. In both regards I would call attention to the protection of fac- tory children against the concurrent selfishness of their parents and masters.^ ^'^ Supra, § 39. ^ If all classes were protected against competition, no class would derive anj advantage from it, since a " universal privilege " is an absurdity. If only certain classes or individuals are protected, it is done at the cost of all others. ^ The question should not be formulated thus: " Caprice or rule.^" but "Rule of morals, or rule of law.'"' Schmollcr against v. Trcitschhc in Hilde- brafid's Jahrbb. i'" Concerning the arguments by which the commercial restrictions of the middle ages were defended, see below. They were, for the most part, well founded for the age in which they were advanced. A judicious education will often be compelled to provide limitations, but always with the intention, by this means, of making possible a really greater independence. Thus the current of commerce may be too weak in a poor and thinly settled country in order that supply and demand should always and everywhere meet and be satisfied. Under such circumstances, their artificial concentration at certain points is among the most efficient means of promoting the economy of the whole people. The policy of freedom of commerce was recommended even in the seventeenth century by J. Child, by North and Davenant. W. Roscher, Zur Geschichte der englisch. Volkswirthschaftslehre, 65 ft'., 85 ft", 113 ft"., 143 ft". And earlier yet, in Holland, by Salmasius, De Usurus, 163S, 583 and dela Court. Compare Tiibinger Ztschr., 330 ft". Thus Bots^uillcdo-t says: /I fiy avait qii'd, laisscr fairc la nature et la libcrtd, qui est Ic commissionaire de cette meme nature. (Factum de la France, 1707, ch. 5.) See, also. Dissertation sur la Nature des Richesses, ch. VI; Detail de la France, 1697, II, ch. 13; Tr. des Grains, II, 8. For the most part dictated by a reaction against Colbertism. See further, Milon, Essai Politique sur le Commerce, 1734, ch. 2. M. Decker, Essay on the Causes of the Decline of Foreign Trade, 1744, 31 fF, 106 ff. y. Tucker, Essay on the advantages and disadvantages which re- spectively attend France and Great Britain with regard to Trade, 1750. Sec. XCVIIL] HOW GOODS ARE PAID FOR. 297 SECTION XCVIIL HOW GOODS ARE PAID FOR. — THE RENT FOR GOODS. Payment for goods (§ i K) of any kind can be made only in other goods.^ ~ Hence, the greater, more varied, and the bet- Forhonnais^ Elemens du Commerce, 1754, I, 63. Gcnovcsi, c. I, 17, 3, is of opinion that at least in case of doubt, commerce stood more in need of free- dom than of protection. Verri, in his Meditazioni, goes still farther. The Physiocrates, with their laissez oiler and laissez faire recommend competition as the best means to increase the net income of a people. According to Du- font, 147 if, ed. Daire, the province of legislation is confined to declaring the laws of nature. His motto is: liberie and fropricte. Adam Smith asks that the state should do only three things: insure protection against foreign states, the administration of justice at home, the establishment and mainte- nance of certain institutions of advantage to the whole coinmunity, but which private interest could not establish for want of means to cover the ex- penses attending them. (Wealth of Nations, V, ch. i, 2.) Hence he de- mands (III, ch. 2) the abolition of all kinds of fdci commissa, of royalty in mines (I, ch. 11, 2), of all corporate and exclusive privileges, of all protective duties etc. (IV, ch. i ft"), but especially of the colonial policy hitherto in vogue. (IV, ch. 8.) The attacks of the Socialists on freedom of competition were begun by FicJitc, Geschlossener Handelsstaat, 126, in which it is called a robber-sj'stem or system of spoliation. He would have the state have more solicitude for human industry than if men were so many swallows. See further, Sisinoiidi, N. Principes, passim, who everywhere demands the protection of the gov- ernment for the weaker. Fourier, N. Monde industriel, 396, who thinks that Ic moHofole gdndral is always a freservatif contrc Ic commerce. Bastiat, Har- monies economiques, ch. 10, has a very valuable refutation of these follies. Recently, Rodbertus, Hildebrand's Jahrbiicher, 1S65, II, 272, is of opinion that " social individualism " has ever had in history the task of dissolving decaying societies, as, for instance, under the Csesars. ' Whoever would sell to others must purchase of them. (Child., Discourse of Trade, 358.) Similarly Temple, Wovks III, 19, and Bccher, Polit. Discurs, 1547. This view seems to have become the national one first in Holland. Compare also ^esnay, 71 and Mirabcau, Philosophic rurale, 1763, ch. 2. * We often hear it said: " nothing sells because there is no money." But the real cause here is, in most instances, not a want of money, but a Avant of other goods which might serve as a counter-value. In bad times, for in- stance, there is many a weaver who would consider himself fortunate, even if he could get no money for his cloth, to obtain instead, meat, bread, wood, 298 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Cii. I. ter adapted to satisfy wants, production is, the more readily does any product find a remunerative market; more readily in England, for instance, in spite, or rather, because of, the great competition there, than in Greenland or Madagascar. From this it follows that, as a rule, a person is in a better condition to purchase more goods in proportion as he has produced more himself. According to official accounts, the average value of a harvest of wheat and potatoes in Prussia was for- merly 332,500,000 thalers. In the year 1850, however, it was only 262,000,000 thalers. As a matter of course, the country people in that year could not purchase from the cities as much as in ordinary years, by a diflference of 70,000,000 thalers. This illustrates how every class of people, who live by finding a free market for their products, are interested in the prosper- ity of all other classes. As Bastiat says: " All legitimate in- terests are harmonious." The more flourishing a city, the better olT are the towns around it, which furnish it with pro- visions; and the richer these towns, the more flourishing is the industry of the city which ministers to their wants.^ It is important that this fact should be borne steadily in mind, especially in times of advanced civilization, when the feeling that we all have interests in common, is too apt to grow dor- mant. Nothing can better serve to awaken it again when it has become so. A nation, sa37s Louis Blanc, in which one por- tion of the people is oppressed by another, is like a man raw material etc. If money only were wanting, that might easily be as fa- vorable a symptom in commerce, as Avhen there are not enough shops, steamers etc., to carry on the business of the country. Compare Nortli.^ Dis- courses upon Trade, 1691, 11 seq., but especially J. B. Safs celebrated theory of Markets, traitd I, ch. XV. 3 See Humholdf s observations as to how, in Spanish America, agriculture in the vicinity of the mines increases and decreases with the wealth of the latter. (N. Espagne, III, 11 ff.) See also Harriiigton (ob. 1677), On the Pre- rogative of a Popular Government, I, ch. 11; Cantillon^ Nature du Com- merce, 16. And so ^^e/w., Lehrbuch, 122 seq., points out how great enter- prises produce especially for the consumption of the small householder with- out capital, and how, therefore, the flourishing condition of the one deter- mines that of the other. Sec. XCIX.] FREEDOM OF COMPETITION. 299 wounded in the leg. The healthy limb is prevented by the sick one from performing its functions.* SECTION XCIX. FREEDOM OF COMPETITION AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE. Does the same rule apply to the commercial intercourse of nations? Where the feelinfj that all mankind constitute one vast family is stronger than that of their political and religious diversity; where the sense of right and the love of peace have extinguished every dangerous spark of ambition for empire and all warlike jealousy; where, especially, their economic interests are rightly understood on both sides, a real conflict between the interests of two nations must always be a phe- nomenon of rare occurrence, and an exception to the general rule, which should not be admitted until it has been clearly demonstrated to exist.'^ Highly cultivated nations generally * Those indeed who Uve by the spohation of others, as robbers, deceivers etc. are interested in the economic prosperity of the latter only so long as their spoliation of them is not endangered. Only to this extent can it be claimed with I^r. List that the nobility of the Middle Ages, in obeying the selfish calculation which led to the oppression of the peasantry, engaged in as bad a speculation as a manufacturer of our day would who should feed his steam-engine with nothing but saw-dust or scraps of old paper. The cities of the middle ages had a much more undoubted economic interest in the emancipation of the peasantry as a class than the nobles or the clergy. ' Such exceptions there certainly are, even if it were not true " that the most godly cannot rest in peace unless he is acceptable to his ungodly neigh- bor." Nations that furnish the same products as we do may, indeed, " spoil our market," just as at home the selfish shoemaker may desire the prosperity of all wearers of shoes, that is of all other industries, but not that of all other producers of shoes. The view that long prevailed, that one man's gain was always some other man's loss {Th. Moms., Utopia 79, ed. Colon. 1555; Baco., Sermones ndeles, cap. 15; quid-quid alicubi adiiciiur, alibi detrahiturj M. Montaigne, Essais I, 21: les froujicit de Vun est le dommage de Vautye) prevailed much longer in international affairs where observation is much more difficult than in national affairs ; although even here, P. de la Court, Maximes politiques, 1658, contrasts the economic interest of Holland with that of the rest of the Netherlands and prefers it to theirs. Even Voltaire- says : " The 300 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch I. look upon the first steps in the civilization of a foreign people with a more favorable eye than they do on the subsequent progress which brings such nations nearer to themselves.^ • Yet the realization of the above mentioned conditions on all sides is something so improbable, unpatriotic "philanthropy" something so suspicious,* the greater number of mankind desire of the greatness of the Fatherland includes the desire of evil to our neighbor. Evidently no country can gain except what another loses." (Diet, philosophique, v. Patrie.) Compare, however, the feid-etre in his Histoire de la Russie,!, i, on the occasion of the English-Russian treaty of commerce. Similarly, Galiani, Delia Moneta, I, i, IV, i ; Verri, Opuscoli, 335, and re- cently V. Cancrin who says that " in every-day life, property is acquired only at some other person's expense." (Weltreichthum, 1S21, 119. Ookonomie der menschl. Gesellschaft, 1S45, 23.) The cosmopolitan view {Xcnoph., Cyrop., Ill, 2, 17. Hier., 10) which prevails in Adam Smith's school was introduced by Hume^ Essays,i752, On the Jealousy of Trade, ^uesnay, Encyclopedie, v. Grains, 294, ed. Daire; A. Smith, Theory of moral Sentiments, 1759, p. 6, sec. 2, ch. 2. Pinto, Lettre sur la Jalousie de Commerce, 1771, and jf. Tucker, Four Tracts on commercial and political Subjects, 1776, 34 ft" and 42 IT. " The system of states exercises no influence whatever on the world's com- merce." (Lotz, HandbuchI, 11.) More recently, R. Cobden, in his Russia, Edinb., 1S36, among others argued, that the conquest of Turkey by the Rus- sians would be useful to England, because then more (.?) English products would probably be sold there. Russia would become no stronger thereby, as conquests always injure the conqueror more than they benefit him. The idea of European equilibrium is therefore a chimera, because no state can be prevented from having an internal growth, as great as may be. Thus, in the summer of 1S53, "^^e heard the London Times sometimes preach tliat every cannon-shot fired by the English at the Russians might kill an English debtor or an English customer. The Venetians entertained a similar view at the beginning of the fifteenth century. Compare AI. Sanudo in Muratori, Scriptores, XXII, 950 ft'. See above, § 12. Moreover, Malthus had recognized that there were natural rivalries be- tween nations which produced exceptions to Tucker's laws. (Principles, Preface.) Similarly Garve, in Cicero's Pflichten (17S3), III, 146 ft". '^ B. Franklin, Works, vol. Ill, 49. Sisnwndi claims for all civilized nations the right of interfering with the governments of other nations with whom they have or might have commercial relations, and of insisting that they shall have a good government under which commerce may freely develop. (N. P. VII, ch. 4.) ^ As for instance when the ami des honunes says that he felt towards an En- glishman or a German as he did towards a Frenchman with whom he was not acquainted. Mirabeau, Philosophic rurale, ch. 6.. Sec. XCIX.] FREEDOM OF COMPETITION. 301 SO incapable of development except under the limitations of nationality, that I should observe the total disappearance of national jealousies only with solicitude. Nothing so much contributed to the Macedonian and Roman conquests as the cosmopolitanism of the later Greek philosophers.'* As all commerce is based on the mutual dependence of the contracting parties, we need not be surprised to find interna- tional commerce so dependent. But this dependence need not, by any means, be equally great on both sides. Rather is the individual or the nation which stands in most urgent need of foreign goods or products the most dependent. Hence, it seems that, in the commercial intercourse between an agri- cultural and an industrial people, in which the former furnish food and the raw material of manufactures, and the latter manufactured articles, the latter are the more dependent. In case of war, for instance, it is much easier to dispense for a long time with manufactured articles than with most articles of food.^ However, this condition of things is very much modified, for the better, by all those circumstances on which the dominant active commerce of a nation depends. It is, for instance, much easier for the English, on account of their greater familiarity with, and knowledge of the laws and nature of commerce, on account of their business connections, their capital, credit and means of transportation, but more particu- larly on account of the greater capacity of circulation of their national resources, to find a new market in the stead of one that has been closed to them, than it is for the Russians with their much more immoveable system of public economy.® It "•Thus, for instance, the Stoic, Zeno: Plutarch. De Alex, fort, i, 6. ^ Compare even Lauderdale, Inquiry, 274 if. ^ How well, for instance, the English sustained Napoleon's continental blockade, the evils produced by which were intensified by several bad har- vests. Its worst time did not, indeed, coincide with that of the struggle with the United States. The ancient Athenians, during their contest with Philip of Macedon, considered the question of the supplies from the Bosphorus etc. as one of life and death. But this can be looked iipon only as a cogent proof of the small development which their commercial talents had received 302 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. " [B. II, Ch. I. is true, however, that an effective blockade, which excluded both of these nations from all the markets of the world, would be much more injurious to England than to Russia. at the time. How easily might they not, according to our ideas, have ob- tained corn from Sicily or Egypt, Sec. C] prices IN GENERAL. 303 CHAPTER II. PRICES. SECTION C. PRICES IN GENERAL. The price of a commodity is its value in exchange expressed in the quantum of some other definite commodity, against which it is exchanged or to be exchanged. Hence, it is possible for any commodity to have as many different prices as there are other kinds of commodities with which it may be compared.^ But whenever price is spoken of, we think only of a compar- ison of the commodity whose value is to be estimated, with the commodity which, at that time and place, is most current and has the greatest capacity for circulation. (Money.) ^ When two commodities have changed their price-relation to each other, it is not possible, from the simple fact of such change of relation, to determine on which side the change has taken place. If we find that a commodity A stands to all other commodities, C, D, E etc., in the same relation as to price as 1 According to the acute analysis of language made by F. y. Neumann, Tiibinger Ztschr., 1872, 317 fF., the word "price" has reference to an actual purchase or sale, "while the expression " value in exchange," generally called simply value, is based upon a valuation, or intimates in a general way that an object possesses value; value in exchange is, so to speak, the average of sev- eral price-determinations. Price, according to Schdfflc, is the external con- sequence of value in exchange, a means of representing the latter. (N. CZk., Ill, Aufl., I, 218.) Only through the difference between value in exchange (universal possibility) and price (special reality) is the laesio enormis of the jurists possible. (Schmitthenner, Staatswissenschen, I, 416.) ■■^ By market price, prix courant, is meant the money-price of commodities, determined by competition. 304 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch.II. before, while commodity B, compared with the same, has changed its place in the scale of prices, we may infer that B, and not A, has left its former position.^ The words costly and dear, as contradistinguished from common and cheap, both indicate a high price. We, how- ever, call a commodity costly whose price, compared with that of other similar commodities, is high. On the other hand, we call a commodity dear when we compare it with itself, and with its own average price in other places and at other times.^ In individual cases, the price of a commodity is determined most usually, and at the same time most superficially, by cus- tom; people ask and pay for a commodity what others have asked and paid for it. If we go deeper and inquire what originated this customary price and may continually change it, we come to the struggle of interests between buyers and sellers. And if science would analyze the ultimate elements of the incentives to this struggle and the forces engaged in it, it is necessary that it should keep in view the entire economy of the nation, and even all national life. SECTION CI. EFFECT OF THE STRUGGLE OF OPPOSING INTERESTS ON PRICE. No where in the public economy of a people are the work- ings of self-interest so apparent as in the determination of prices. When the price of a commodity is once fixed by the conflict of opposing interests,^ the self-seeking of every indi- vidual dictates that he should thereby gain as much as possible ^ A problem very similar to that of the motion of bodies in space. 4 Lofz, Handbuch, 50 ff., calls those commodities costly which are obtained only at a high cost of production, and dear, those whose price is above the cost of production. * Compare Canard, Principes d'Economie politique, ch. 3. Almost simul- taneously, H. Thornton, 1802, Paper-Credit of Great Britain. Sec. CI.] OPPOSING INTERESTS ON PRICE. 305 of the goods of others, and lose as little as possible of his own. In this struggle, the victory is generally to the stronger, and the price is higher or lower, according to the superiority of the buyer or seller." But \vho, in such case, is the stronger? Political or physical superiority can turn the balance one way or another only in veiy barbarous times, and especially in times when legal security is small.'' As a rule, it is the party in whom the desire of holding on to his own commodities is strongest, and who is least moved by the want of the wares of others. As in every conflict, confidence in self, sometimes even unbounded confidence in self, is an important element of success. A party to a contract of sale or barter, who con- siders his immediate position decidedly stronger than that of the other party, will scarcely depart from his demands. Hence it is, that in exchange, one party so frequently holds back until the other has expressed his terms.'* How different is the * See yacksoii's Account of Morocco, 2S4, for cases in which, in the Sahara, when the burning -winds of the desert had dried up the water in the leathern bottles of the caravan, a drink of water cost from $10 to $500. ^ The North American aborigines very frequently consent, in their ex- changes, to take any offer made to them by their equals, however insufBcient it may be, because they fear revenge. ScJioolcraJt, Information etc., II, 17S. As to the efiects of cunning, the Tungusi, when they get a glass of brandy from the Russians, grow almost idiotic, and give away their goods at mock- prices in drink, (v. Wrangell, Nachrichten, I, 233.) In the higher stages of civilization, on the other hand, very distinguished people are, by no means, privileged because of their position, in the struggle for prices. In modern times, claims (reclamen) have taken the place of greater physical or political power. Compare E. Hcrmaini, Leitfaden der Wirthschaftslehre 1S70, 91 ff. ^ Thus Galiani says, that before one of the two parties has expressed his want to buy or to sell, the pans of the scales are in equilibrium. The first that speaks breathes on one of them, and it drops. (Dialogue sur le Com- merce des Bleds, 1770, No. 6.) This has been verified in a striking manner in California, where the most valuable commodities were often purchased at auction at the lowest prices, while when purchased from merchants and even the most wretched shopkeepers, they were sold enormously dear. (Gcrstackcr, in the Allg. Zeitg., May, 1850.) Thus there wtre harvested in France, in 1817,48,000,000 hectolires of wheat, valued at 2,046,000,000 francs, m 1820, 44,500,000 hectolitres valued at 895,000,000 francs. (Conlier.) This Vol. I. — 2Q 306 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. II. price of the same pieces of land which a new raih-oad enter- prise is compelled to pay and the prices it would get for them, from the adjoining owners, in case of the dissolution of the company. But the struggle to raise prices or to lower them, which is always going on, undergoes modifications of every description among all really commercial nations, partly through the in- fluence of the public conscience, which brands as inhuman and blameworthy the spoliation of the opposing party by acts which the laws do not reach. And this consideration by the public conscience is all the more severe in proportion as real competition in the article sold is w^anting.^ But the chief mod- ification in this struggle is produced by the fact, that where civilization has advanced farthest, every commodity is offered for sale by a great many and wanted by a great many.^ As soon as several seek the same object, there naturally results a rivalry among them, which induces each to attain the desired end, even by the making of greater sacrifices than others. vast difference in price existed, because in iSi 7, the whole world was still trembling under the impression made by the failure of the crops in 1S16, while in 1820, the feeling of comfort and security caused by the rich year 1819, siill prevailed. Low prices at forced sales under decree etc. See be- low, § 5. That travelers are so frequently taken advantage of in effecting changes of money is explainable partly by their urgent wants, which are well known to the opposite party, and partly by their supposed ignorance in the matter. And so, at auction sales, out-bidding one another has something very seductive in it for ignorant or hot-headed purchasers. ' It was considered immoral by his contemporaries, when William the Con- queror introduced the custom of farm-letting to the highest bidder. (A. Thierry^ ConquSte de I'Angleterre, II, 116, ed. Bruxelles.) It is repugnant to poetic and delicate minds to think that everything has a price exactly fixed. (§2.) I need only refer to the picture of Helen which Zeuxis exhibited for money, which act of his Avas characterized, by his cotempora- ries, as a species of prostitution. Val. Mac, III, 7. yEltan, V, 4, IV, 12. Socrates judgment on the payment of the sophists. Xenoph., Memor., I, 6, 13- * Competition has only a negative influence on prices, inasmuch as it mod- ifies the extreme operation of the other grounds of their determination. Thornton, Paper Credit. Lotz, Revision, 181 1, I, 74 fl", 241 ff. \ Sec. CI.] OPPOSING INTERESTS ON PRICE. 307 The greater the supply of a commodity is, as compared with the demand for it, the lower is its price; the greater the de- mand as compared with the supply, the higher it is. And, indeed, there is question here, not only of the mass of things supplied or demanded, but also of the intensity of the supply and demand.''^ If the exchange-force of both contractants be equal, or, in other words, if both, with equal knowledge, are interested in the completion of the exchange, there results from this atti- tude of the parties toward each other, what is called an equit- able, or average price, in which both meet with their deserts. Here each is a gainer, since each has parted with the com- modity which was less necessary to him, and received in exchange the commodity which was more necessary to him. Looked at, however, from the stand-point, not simply of a nation's but of the world's economy, the value given and the value received are equal. ^ ^ ■"The expression, " intensity of demand," in Malthus^ Principles, ch. 2, sec. 2. As early a writer as Sir J. Ste-ivart calls attention to the difference between large and high and small and low demand. A high demand will always raise the price, as when, for instance, tAvo wealthy virtuosi compete at an auction. Paucorum furore frctiosa^^% Seneca says. An English penny of the time of Henry VII, once sold, on such an occasion, for £600. In 1868, at the Lafitte auction, seven bottles of wine sold to Rothschild at 235 francs a piece after the Maison dorde had offered 233. (N. freie Presse, Dec. 17, 1868.) A great demand has frequently no result but to increase the supply, and the price rises only in so far as the demand is too sudden to permit a parallel growth of the supply. (Principles, Book II, ch. 2, 10.) The present price of tea could not remain unaffected, if ten different private merchants, com- peting one with another, or the agent of a privileged commercial society, should send orders to China for an eqvial quantity of tea. ( Verri, Medita- zioni, IV, 8 ff.) 8 Immense weight laid on the cequalitas fermutaiioiiis (after Aristot., Eth. Nicom., V. 7,) in the ethics and economics of the scholastic middle ages, and in the time of the Reformation. Compare Melancthon^ in Corp. Ref , XVI, 495 ff, XXII, 230. ' A very barbarous theory of price in Xcnoj>Ii., De Vectigg., 4. The an- cients made little progress in this respect, although there are not wanting in- genious observations on certain phenomena of prices. (See Art'sfoi., (?) 308 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Cn. II. As a rule, the price-relation of two commodities is deter- mined by this relation of demand and supply, — by the desire to possess and the difficult}' of obtaining them. We must, therefore, examine on what deeper relations supply and de- mand themselves depend.^" In the case of the purchaser, the Oecon. II; Cicero, De Oft". Ill, 12 ft'.) Mariana, De Rege et Regis Institu- tione, 1598, III, explains price as the relation of value to quantity. Accord- ing to Locke, the price of a thing is determined by the relation between "quantity" and "vent": the increase or diminution of its useful qualities in- fluences it only so far as it alters that relation. (Considerations on the Con- sequences of the Lowering of Interest etc, 1691, Works II, 20 ft".) Law, on the contrary, says that the "vent" can never be greater than the "quantity," but that the " demand " may be. Wherefore, he proposes the formula : quan- tity in proportion to the demand. (Trade and Commerce considered, 1705, ch. I.) In chap. 6, La-v distinguishes three elements in price: quality, quan- tity and demand. The expression " quantity " is, eertainly, very unsatisfac- tory. How many examples does not Tooke (Thoughts and Details on the high and low Prices of the last thirty Years, 1823, part IV) give to illus- trate how, when the supply was smallest, prices were lowest and vice versa! It was so almost always after the market was over-filled, when a great many speculators had lost and no one dared to purchase anew. Montanari (ob. 1687) furnishes us with an excellent theory of prices. (Delia Moneta, 64 fF., Custodi.) And a still better one, Sam. Pufendorf, Jus Nature et Gentium, 1672, V. I, who must be considered the best authority on the laws of prices before Ste-vart. Boisguillebert, Traite des Grains, II, i, 10. Galtatii, Delia Moneta, I, 2, knows only the factors utilitd, and raritci, although in his expo- sition of the latter, he discusses many points which would be called the cost of i^roduction in our time. The wisdom of Providence has granted us the most iiseful things in the greatest abundance to make them cheap. Stetvart, Principles II, 2, 4, rendered a great service to the theory of prices, tracing back supply to the cost of production, demand to want and ability to pay ; and his deserves to be called the immediate predecessor of Hcrmami's re- markable theory. (Herniatm, Staatsw. Untersuchungen, 66 ft'.) For a pe- culiar theory of prices, see Paganini, Saggio sopra il giusto Pregio delle Cose, 189 ft* Neri, Osservazioni, 1751, 127. Gust. Menger, Grundsatze, I, 179 fF., has made an interesting attempt to explain the formation of prices in its simplest shape, in the supposition of a monopoly in the seller, and by then going over to the subsequent modifications introduced by the competi- tion of many sellers. " " Instead of sejiarating, in the same matter, the points of view of the buyer and seller, we may distinguish the consideration of the thing to be acquired and the thing to be given by one and the same person." (Ran.) Sec. CII.] DEMAND. 309 value in use of the commodit}- and his own ability to pay con- stitute the maximum limit of its price, which price may, how- ever, be modified by the cost of producing it^^ elsewhere or at another time. In the case of the seller, the cost of produc- tion is the minimum limit, which may, however, be extended by the cost of procuring the commodity by the pmxhaser at another time or place.^^ SECTION CII. DEMAND. The pmxhaser in his demand is wont to consider principal- ly the value in use of a commodit}-, according as it, in a higher or lower degree, ministers to a necessary want, to a decency or to a luxury. The difference of opinion as to which of these categories any given want belongs depends not only on the nature of the country and the customs of its people, but, for the most part, also, on the prejudices of class and on per- sonal individuality.^ A reasonable man will employ only the The possessor of the more cun-ent commodity appears especially as demand- ing, that of the less current as offering or supplying, (v. Mangoldt.) " This is for free goods=0, for monopolized goods=l-. ''^ The obvious fact that every price supposes a comparison of two com- modities, and that every buyer is, at the same time, a seller, has been over- looked by only too many writers. And hence Dutofs opinion, that, as all men buy and few only sell, the state, in case of doubt, should favor the buyer. (Reflexions sur le Commerce et les Finances, 1738, 962, dd. Daire.) And so the often-mooted question whether imiversal dearness or cheapness is more useful : the latter advocated, for instance, by Herbert^ Police gendrale des Grains, 1755; Verri, Meditazioni, V; the former by BmsgiiUlebert., Traitd des Grains, I, 7,11, 9; and by the Physiocrates. (^/ccs/tay, ISIaximes gdndrales, Nr. iS ff., I, Probleme &onomique; also by ..-I. 2'auiig, Polit. Arithmetics, ch. 8.) The laity in Political Economy understand by dearness only the gen- eral cheapness of the medium of circulation or exchange, and vice versa. ' Thus, even a poor man in Naples sometimes requires a glass of ice-water. The introduction of the extensive use of snow into Sicily improved the con- dition of the public health. (Rehfiies, Gemiilde von Neapel, I, 37fF.) On the other hand, furs, in the far north, are articles of prime necessity. Newspapers in a free country sastisfy a want much more urgent than in countries which 310 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. IL surplus of the first cla'ss in the satisfaction of wants of the second, and again only the surplus of the second in the satis- faction of wants of the third.- If the value in use of a commodity rises or falls, and sur- rounding circumstances remain unchanged, its price also rises or falls.2 ^ are not free. And so, Senior says that shoes are " necessaries " to all Eng- lishmen, since without them, their health would suffer. To the lower classes of Scotland they are " luxuries." Custom permits them to go barefoot with- out hardship or degradation. For the middle classes of the same countiy, they are " decencies." Shoes are worn there, not to protect the feet but one's civil position. In Turkey, tobacco is a decency and wine a luxui-y. The re- verse is the case in England. (Outlines, 36 ff.) ^ As to the relativity of the opposites of " temperance " and " excess," every person should attend to the following points : a, not to exceed one's income ; b, to provide for one's self and one's family ; c, to lay by something for a rainy day; d, to place one's self in a position to care for the poor; e, to in- dulge in no pleasure injurious to body or mind; f, to give no bad example. (Tucker, Two Sermons, 29 if.) Mcngcr, Grundsatze, I, 92 ff., endeavors to compare the value in use of difterent commodities from the point of view, that the means of gratification of a less urgent want, when the more urgent wants of the present are satisfied completely, should be preferred to the means of over-gratifying the latter. *Thus the price of many dark articles of apparel rises in a moment of un- expected universal mourning. A very remarkable case in Paris, at the death of Henry II. (Alontanari, Delia Moneta, 85, Custodi.) On the other hand, a change of fashion inay greatly depress the price of many commodities. Such a change may take place even in the case of precious stones; as, for instance, now in Loudon, a perfect emei-ald is most highly prized. (King, Precious Stones and Metals, 1S71.) The rise of many drugs in times of cholera, and of leeches, for example, in Paris, 600 per cent. Rise of the price of powder, horses etc. at the outbreak of a war, and of the price of iron caused by extensive railroad building. In Circassia, a good shirt of mail was formerly worth from 10 to 200 oxen : but since it was discovered not to be a protection against cannon balls, its price fell 50 per cent. (Bell, Journal of a Residence in Circassia, I, 403. ■• On " connected " (connexen) goods, the use of one of which supposes the use of the other, as, for instance, sugar and coffee, wood and stone used in the construction of buildings, see Schdffie, Nat.-Oek, II. Aufi., 179. Sec. CIII.j INDISPENSABLE GOODS. 311 SECTION cm. DEMAND. — INDISPENSABLE GOODS. When the supply of articles of luxury diminishes, the price of them, it is true, rises. But as now there is a number of purchasers no longer able to pay for them, the demand for them also decreases, and their price, as a consequence, rises in a less deo-ree than mioht be inferred from the amount and con- dition of the supply merely. And so, on the other hand, an increase of the supply which lowers the price is wont, in the case of pleasures capable of a wide extension, such as are min- istered to by fine roots, vegetables, etc., to produce an increase of the demand, and this operates to arrest the falling price. It is quite otherwise, in the case of indispensable goods, as for instance, wheat. When there is a want of such an article, men prefer to dispense with all other articles, to some extent, rather than to practice frugality in bread ; and all the more, as bread is not so much used as consumed rapidly, while clothes and metallic articles last a long time. And even after an over- abundant harvest, leaving voluntary waste out of the question, consumption is increased by a finer separating of the flour, an increase in the amount of corn fed to cattle, and the distillation of spirits. Hence, demand and supply by no means nin in parallel lines at every moment; and indispensable articles tend to greater perturbations in price than those which can be dis- pensed with.^ ^ The price of grain, especially, varies in a ratio ' Observed by JVecker, Sur la Legislation et le Commerce des Grains, 1776. Compare RoscJier, Ueber Kornhandel und Theuerungspolitik. 1S53, i ft". In Athens, for instance, the medimnos of wheat cost ordinarily five drachmas, but during the siege by Sulla it rose to looo drachmas. (Demosth. adv. Phorm., 91S. Plutarch^ Sulla, 13.) Compare II. Kings, 6, 25, 7, i. In Paris during the siege by Henry IV. it rose to 5000 per cent, of the ordinary price. (Lauderdale^ Inquiry, 60 ft") During the siege of Breisach, in 163S, a mouse ■was finally worth i florin, the quarter of a dog, 7 florins, a quarter of Avheat, 80 thalers. (Rose, Leben H. Bernhards, M., :i, 269.) Compare Strabo, V, 248 seq. ' Wheat is still more indispensable than meat. Hence, in the ten principal 312 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. II. very different from the inverse ratio of tlie amount of the harvest ; ^ although a formula therefor expressed in figures, like that of Gregory King, can never be applicable universal- ly.* Farmers must everywhere and always withhold a certain amount of their harvest for seed, for home use etc., from the market. Only absolute necessity can induce them to draw on the quantity thus laid by. But the ratio of this part to the whole is very different in different countries.^ In the higher stages of civiHzation, where payment in money has taken the place of payment in produce, and all other kinds of payment, and where the cultivator of the ground pays the wages of his markets of Prussia, the price of rye rose much more from 1811 to i860 than the price of beef; the former between 0.32 and 1.03 silver groschens and tiie latter between 2.32 and 4.94 silver groschens. (Annalen der preussischen Landwirthschaft, 1869, No. 9.) And so in the Rhine district, the wine harvests have undergone much greater changes in price than the prices of must, al- though the years differed very largely in the quality of the yield. Thus the crop of 1830 was only 225, that of 1S68, 10,845 pieces, and yet the mininium price between 1831 and 1865 was only from 3 to 58 flr. per ome. (Engcl^ Preuss. Statist, Ztschr., 1871, 16S ff. 3 In England, the price of wheat has not unfrequently risen from 100 to 200 per cent, when the harvest Avas from one-sixth to one-third imder the average, and when a supply from abroad ' had modified even this condition of things. (Tooke, History of Prices, I, 10 ff.) Tooke is of opinion that in a country with poor-laws like those of England, a deficit of one-third in the wheat crop, if there were no stores remaining and no importation from abroad, would cause the price of wheat to rise, 500, 600, and even 1000 per cent. (p. 15.) *See Davenant, Political and Commercial Works, London, 1771, II, 224. Tooke was somewhat acquainted with Davenant. According to this law, a deficit in the harvest of 10 per cent, would raise the price of corn 30 per cent. ; one of 20 per cent, would raise the price of corn 80 per cent. ; one of 30 per cent, would raise the price of corn 160 per cent.; one of 40 per cent, would raise the price of corn 280 per cent. ; one of 50 per cent, would raise the price of corn 450 per cent. * In England, it is 3S.8 per cent, of the supply that comes to the market. (Quart. Review, XXXVI, 425.) In Belgium 40, and in Saxony at least 50 per cent. (Engel, Jahrb. der Statistik etc. von Sachsen, i, 276.) In Ger- man}', the farmers consume on an average two-thirds themselves, (v. Vie- bah?i, Zoll.-v-Statist., II, 958.) With this Plato, De Legg., VIII, agrees re- mai-kably well. Sec. civ.] PURCHASER'S SOLVABILITY. 313 laborers almost exclusively in money, so that they, like all others, purchase what bread they require in the market; a given deficit in the harvest must be spread over a much larger market supply; and prices, therefore, remain much less affect- ed than in the lower stages of civilization.*' And so, it is clear that a like bad harvest must aflect prices very differently, if there be a large importation or exportation of the means of subsistence, and if several bad harvests, or several harvests yielding more than the average have preceded. In another respect yet, the price of indispensable commodi- ties is very sensitive, because here the mere fear of a future want of them has a far deeper and wider influence, than has the fear of want of articles of luxury. No matter how good the wheat crop may have been, if the weather afterwards interferes with its harvesting, the price of wheat, in countries in which the spirit of speculation is on the alert, will certainly rise, because the prospect of the future crop then becomes somewhat doubtful.'' SECTION CIV. INFLUENCE OF PURCHASER'S SOLVABILITY ON PRICES. The purchaser, besides the value in use of the goods he de- sires to buy, considers his own solvability ( Zahluiigsjdhigkeii^ ability to pa}'). It is only solvent demand which can influence prices.-' For instance, among a people made up almost en- * On the difference in this respect between England, Germany and north- western Norway, see Hermann, p. 71. ■" Hence it not unfrequently happens that grain grows dear not from any real •want of it, but because it is generally supposed that such want exists. For an explanation of why it is that wheat and similar commodities have an al- most invariable price, when the average is taken of a long series of years, sec infra § 129. > Case in Naples in which after a poor harvest the price of corn remained very low, because the oil-harvest had also failed, and the poor could earn nothing in that industry in which they were largely employed, and vice vorsa. (Galliani, Delia Moneta, II, 2.) Thus Adam Smiifi^ Wealth of Na- 314 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Cii- II. tirely of proletarians, there will be a great many cases of starvation and death after a bad harvest, but the price of corn will undergo only a slight increase.'^ But where the greater number of inhabitants own property, and where the wealthy come to the help of the poorer classes by means of poor-rates and acts of benevolence, it is scarcely possible to assign limits to the increase of the price of corn. By a necessary connec- tion, when indispensable articles grow dear, the demand for articles that can be dispensed With generally decreases, and vice vc7'sa? Every merchant, engaged in an extensive business, is interested in knowing in advance the results of the corn crop. The higher the price of a commodity rises, the nar- rower, of course, grows the circle of those who can pay for it. '' 5 tions, I, ch. 7, distinguishes between "effectual" and "absolute" demand. Similarly J. Stenarf, Principles I, ch. iS. Care should be taken to distin- guish in this respect between desire and demand. ''^Thus, in the famine in Ireland in 1S21, during which potatoes rose to fab- ulous prices, but wheat scarcely at all, and had therefore to be exported. " In Tooke, History of Prices (2d edition of the Thoughts and Details etc.), we meet repeatedly with the assertion that when the price of wheat rises, the price of colonial products and manufactured articles sinks, and vice versa. Thus, in England, the price of the evidences of national debt increases from two to three per cent, in fruitful years above what it is after a bad harvest. ( Lauderdale, Inquiry, 93.) The British nation paid for the cotton it needed for their own consumption in 1845 over £19,500,000; in 1S47 only £9,500,000. (Banfield, Organization of Industry, 162.) ^ Hence y. B. Say has said that the disposable wealth of a people is like a pyramid, with the scale of prices of the various commodities inscribed on its side. The higher a commodity is in this scale of prices, the smaller is the corresponding section of the pyramid. Compare Sir IV. TeiJiJ>le, Essay on the Origin and Nature of Government, Woi-ks I, 23 ff. 5 This fact, in connection with the preceding, explains the well known puz- zle, why the remnant of a piece of goods is comparatively cheaper than the whole piece, while a small share in the public debt is dearer than a large one. (Lauderdale^ ch. i.) Secs. CV, CVI.] SUPPLY. — COST OF PRODUCTION. 315 SECTION CV. SUPPLY. In the case of isolated chance exchanges, the seller, too, takes into consideration, first of all, value in use, and compares the satisfaction which the commodity to be parted with and that to be received are able to afford. It is true that in making this estimate, he is subject in the highest degree to error and deception.^ In the well ordered trade of a nation whose economy is highly developed, the seller, who had this very trade in view in his production, is wont to consider almost ex- clusively the value in exchange of his commodity. SECTION CVI. THE COST OF PRODUCTION. As no one is willing to lose anything, every seller will con- sider what his goods have cost him, and the cost of produc- ing or procuring them as the minimum price to be asked for them.^ At the same time, the idea covered by the expression 1 Rhode Island Avas, it is said, bought from the Indians in 163S for a pair of spectacles. (B. JF'?-a?iklin, FoMtical . . . Pieces, 1707.) According to Chalmers, it was bought for 50 threads of coral, 12 hatchets and 12 overcoats. (Political Annals of the U. States.) Compare Ebeling, II, 108. Holland cloths and opium were exchanged for a long time at Sumatra for gold dust worth ten times their value. (Saalfeld, Geschichte des holl. Koloniahvesens, I, 260.) The Hudson Bay Company realized, it is said, at the beginning of this century, in trading with the Indians, a profit of 2000 per cent. (Anderson, Origin of Commerce, a. 1751.) When Altai was discovered, the natives gave as many sable-skins for a Russian kettle or boiler as could be crammed into it. With 10 rubles in iron it was an easy easy matter to gain 500-660 rubles. Siorch, Gemalde des russ., R., II, 16; K. Rittcr, Erdkunde, II, 557. Similar cases among the Germans : Tacit., Germ., 5. 1 A seller not actually engaged in the business of selling for a livelihood, and w^ho has not purchased or produced with the intention of selling, is apt to consider instead of this the market price, towards the determination ot 316 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. II. cost of production, although it always embraces whatever dis- appears from the resources of the producer to enter into pro- duction, varies very much according as it is considered from the point of view of the individual's, the nation's or the world's economy. An individual who pays taxes to his government, and who has rented land and employed labor and capital to engage in production, must indeed, besides the capital he has used in such production, call all his outlay in interest, wages, rent, and taxes, by the name of cost of production;^ since, unless they all come back to him in the price of the commodity, the entire enterprise can only injure him.^ He will, of course, add an equitable prolit to remunerate him for his enterprise, since without such profit, he would not be able to live or produce ; or else, he would be compelled to consume his capital. The moment the current rates of taxation, interest, wages and rent change in a country, the cost of production is also changed in the case of the individual engaged in production, however unaltered the technic process may remain."* But taking the ^vhich those actually engaged in trade have cooperated. Somewhat inaccu- rately', the amount of the cost of production is called by Adam Siiitfh and Ricardo, " natural price," by J. B. Say, pnx naturel, also prix originairc, be- cause the commodity at its first entrance into the world cost so much. Sis- mondi and Storch call it prix necessaire, and Lotz, Kostcnpreis. P. Cantillon, Nature de Commerce, 33 ft", understands by the prix intrinsique of a com- modity, the amount of land and labor, taking the quality of both also into consideration, necessary to its production. ^ The cheapest cotton thread is numbered from 60 to So. The coarser is dearer on account of the quantity of raw material in it, and the finer because of the greater amount of labor in it. (Babbagc.) For similar reasons, the Venetian chains cost per braca'o, No. o, the finest, 60 francs; No. i, 40 francs; Nos. 2 and 3, 20 francs ; No. 24, coarsest, 60 francs. (Ra7(.) 2 If a person engaged in production has himself furnished certain of the elements of production ; if, for instance, he has worked with his own hands, emplo^'ed his own capital etc., he is wont to charge as much for these as they would be worth, if he hired himself out or loaned his capital. •*The greater number of political economists consider the cost of produc- tion only from the standpoint of the individual engaged in production. Thus Darjes, Erste Griinde, 218 seq. ; Ad. Smith, Wealth of Nations, I, ch. 6. y. Sec. CVI.] COST OF PRODUCTION. 317 nation, or all mankind into consideration, we must not lose sight of the fact that these three great sources of income, as well as taxation, are not, rightly speaking, sources from which income flows, but rather channels through which the aggre- gate income of the nation or the world is distributed among individuals.'^ Hence the wages of labor, for instance, which afford the means of living to the greater part of the popula- tion, cannot possibly be looked upon simply as a factor in eco- nomic production. The people considered in their entirety have the soil gratis. All saving made from rent, interest on capi- tal, or wages, is nothing but a change of the proportion in which the results of production were distributed hitherto among couperators in production. Such a change may be either advantageous or the revese ; but it is not a diminution of the amount of sacrifice which the people in general must make for purposes of production. Hence, in a politico-economical sense, to the cost of production, belongs only the capital necessarily expended in production, and which has disappeared as a part of the nation's resources, abstraction made of the personal sacrifices in behalf of production.^ The value of the circulating capital which in the proces is entirely used up, must, B. Say calls even production an exchange in Avhich the productive services of natural forces, of labor and of capital are parted with in order to obtain products. The estimate put upon the value of these services is the cost of production. For some interesting examples as to how the cost of production, in this sense, is calculated, see Hermann, I ed., 136 ff. 5 yacob translated by Say, 1S07, II, 450. Hit-f eland, N. Grundelgung, I, 309. 5 Compare L. Lauderdale, Inquiry, 124, against the Physiocrates. (Rtedel, Nat.-Oekonomie, 1838, I, 68.) A country which possesses advantages over other countries, in respect to the cost of production of a commodity, can ofter it in the market cheapest. Where, for instance, with the employment of the same amount of capital, a specially large quantity of wheat can be produced, whether it be because of the unusual fertility of the soil, or because of the extensiveness of agriculture (farming over a large area), wheat will, the de- mand being the same, be specially cheap, whatever the proportion of the three branches of income may have been. If relatively a great number of work- men have been employed in its cultivation, each will receive smaller wages, and vice versa. 318 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Cn. II. of course, be entirely restored in the price, that of the fixed capital used only to the extent that it has been used.'^ The risk, which the producer runs until the commodity produced is actually consumed must also be borne in mind.^ There are things which are a real risk in small enterprises that by the intervention of an insurance company, or where the enterprises are large and insure themselves, become a more or less variable portion of the cost of production. The price of the product, in the latter instance, rises, by this means, very regularly. In the former case, the rise depends partly on the feeling of the people whether their pleasure in gain is greater than their grief over a corresponding loss.'' Those enterprises which necessarily produce different pro- ducts at the same time deserve special consideration.^^ Here we may speak of " Jinited costs of production," and all that is needed is that the aggregate of these costs should be covered by the aggregate price of both products. This complicates to a certain extent the calculations which the seller must make to determine his minimum demand for each product. To as- certain this, he must subtract from the united costs of produc- tion the amount of value which he expects with certainty for the other product.^^ ' Copper and steel engraving affords an example of the different kinds of wear of fixed capital, and the influence it may have on prices. Canard, Prin- cipes, ch. IV, considers that one of the most important elements in the cost of production is the length of time that capital must " stagnate" for the sake of production. 8 On this risk depends, for instance, the high price of vanilla (Humboldt, N. Espagne, IV, lo,), sparkling wines and articles of fashion. '^ Mangoldt, Lehre voni Unternehmergewinn, 1855, ^i ff. Compare v. Thiinen, Der isolirte Staat, II, i, 80 ff. '" Wool and mutton, brandy and fattened cattle, calves and milk, honey and wax, gas and coke, hens and eggs etc. " Ada?n Stniih himself remarked that all artificial lowering of the price of skins or avooI must necessarily raise the price of the ineat, and vice versa. (Wealth of Nations, I, ch. 11, 3.) For a very elaborate theory on this sub- ject, see y. S. Mill, Principles, III, ch. 16, § i. Thus Australian wool did not rise as inxich in price as the production of gold there might have led us to suppose, for the reason that mutton rose to an exceedingly high price. Sec. CVII.] EQUILIBRIUM OF PRICES. 319 SECTION CVII. EQUILIBRIUM OF PRICES. Goods whose cost of reproduction,^ that is, the highest neces- sary cost of reproduction is the same, have uniformly the same value in exchange. Every deviation from this level immedi- ately sets forces in motion which endeavor to restore the level, just as the water of the sea seeks its level, notwithstanding the mountains and abysses which the winds bring forth from its bosom. ^ ^ ' It is an important and correct remark of Carcy^s^ that the price of a com- modity depends much more on the cost of producing its like than on its own cost of production, which already belongs to the past. "^ Compare J. S. Mill, III, ch. 3, § i. A much too high price, caused by speculation, or a much too low one, by depreciation, is regularly followed by an ebb or flow just as much too great. (Tooke, History of Prices, III, 55.) And Latv, Trade and Money, 41, remarks that the price of a commodity always tends to coincide with the " first cost." This fact Adam Smith ex- presses by saying that the cost of production is the center about which the market price always gravitates, fl, ch. 7.) But here there is still the error lurking, that the producer's profit is a part of the cost of production. Com- pare Malihus, Definitions, ch. 6. * The English view, one very chai-acteristic of the people, is that the equi- librium of prices depends on this, that all commodities should have a value eqvial to that of the labor they have cost. (Compare Aristot., Eth. Nicom., V, 5,) The same doctrine is to be found in its germinal state in Hobbcs, Leviathan, 24, 165 1, and Rice Vaug/iaii, Discourse of Coin and Coinage, 1675. More exhaustively in Petty, Treatise of Taxes and Contributions, 1679, 24, 31,67. (Compare Locke, Civil government, II, § 40 ff. ; B. Franklin^ Inquiry into the Nature and Necessity of a paper Currency, 1729; Works, ed. Sparks, vol. II.) Adam Smith admits this to be true only of the first beginnings of society, before the origin of property in land and in capital. (Wealth of Nations, I, ch. 5.) Most largely developed in Ricardo, Principles, ch. I, 4, 30. Marx, Zur Kritik der polit. Gi^konomie, 1S59, 6, endeavors to improve on this by calling all values in exchange " a determinate quantity of thickly curdled working-time," meaning by work an averaged qualitdtslose, social work of production. Per contra, compare Iluf eland, N. Grundlegung, I, 134, 156 ff.; and Malthus, Principles, ch. 2, sees. 2, 3, who claims very earnestly that price is not determined by the cost of production, but by the relation existing between demand and supply, the cost of production influ- 320 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. II. SECTION CVIII. EFFECT OF A RISE OF PRICE MUCH ABOVE COST. If the market price rises high above the cost of production, producers make a profit greater than the average profit made in the country. This induces them, by the appropriation of new land and tlie employment of new labor and capital, to increase their business. Other parties also engage in this profitable department of trade. This competition not only makes the means of production dearer, but must eventually, by increasing the demand, reduce the price of the product to the ordinary level of profit, that is to an equilibrium with other commodities.^ Hence, in the beginning, every diminution of encing it only to the extent that it influences this relation. He calls atten- tion to the poor-rates bj which the cost of production of labor is i-aised, but its wages decreased; also to the case of bank notes etc. (Tooke, History of Prices, V, 49 ff; y. S. Alill, Principles, III, ch. 16, 2.) For a very marked case of reaction against Adam Smith and Ricardo, see Macleod^ Elements, ch. 2, who, however, is much too one-sided in considering only the amount necessary to the purchaserj and his means. Even Condillac had said: une chose 11' a fas une valeur^ farccqiCclle coute, mat's elle coute (du travail ou de rargent),farcequ'eUe a une valcur. (Commerce et Gouvernement, 16.) Ri- cardo's doctrine is more tenable than appears at first blush. We need only to interline his theory of rent, admit that capital is accumulated labor, sub- tract all objects constituting a natural monopoly, and not forget that the intrinsic value of labor is one of the causes of the difference of price of diflerent sorts of labor. Ricardo does justice to value in use even en fassant. A strange effort by McCtiUoch to make labor the cause of the non-use of capital. (Principles, III, ch. 6, 2.) McCnllocJi has not unfrequently exagger- ated the half-truths of his doctrines to such an extent as to produce unwit- tingly a reductio ad abstirdum. According to Torrens, before any separation of capitalists from workmen, price dejiends entirely on the work done, and afterwards on the capital expended, inasmuch as wages, rent etc. are covered by the capital of the person who engages in the enterprise. (Production of Wealth, ch. i.) ^ Ce que V on appclle chereti^ c'est V unique remede d la chercte. (Dupont de Nemours.) Tenders of division in common, in England, increase and de- crease according to the higher or lower price of corn during the preceding year. (Tooke, Thoughts and Details, III, 105 ff.) The cotton famine after Sec. CVIII.] EFFECT OF A RISE OF PRICE. 32] the cost of production ^ turns to the advantage of the producer ; but afterwards and permanently to that of the consumers : an economic law exceedingly benelicent in its operations, and not unlike the action of positive legislation in the matter of patents. There is no greater stimulus to the making of improvements than the certainty of reward to the person who first intro- duces one. The moment, however, that the improvement is imitated by all producers, the advantage gained by it becomes the common good of the whole nation.^ These are, as J. B. Say says, conquests made over the gratuitous productive force of nature. As a consequence, the value in use of a people's resources increases; generally, also, their value in exchange, in so far as the production of the now cheaper goods increases in a degree greater than their cost of production has dimin- ished.* As to the alternative so frequently discussed, whether it is preferable to make a large percentage of profit on the sale of a small quantity of goods, or a small percentage on a large quantit}', we find that, in the lower stages of civilization, the lS6i increased the price of flax-yarn in a short time fifty per cent., although the raw material of flax did not rise in price, but only because care was not taken to increase the number of flax-spinners. (Aiislaud, I, 1865.) How- ever, there were in 1S64, 490,000 flax-machine spindles in course of election. (Report of the Chemnitz Chamber of Commerce, 1864, loi.) ^ By the discovery, for instance, of new natural forces, the invention of machines, improved division of labor, improved roads etc. In France, in consequence of techmc improvement, a quintal of saltpeter fell from 100 to 9 francs. See a similar instance in CJiaftal^ De 1' Industrie fran^aise, II, 64, 70. 434- ^ Hermami^ Staatsw. Untersuchungen, 212. ■'The highest but unattainable ideal of such progress would consist in this, that all products should be obtained without cost. If this ideal were attain- able, evei-y one would be infinitely rich and all wealth would be free, like the air and the sunshine. (Compare J. B. Say^ Traite, II, 2.) The complete victory of mankind over nature would consist in that all men should be free and all the forces of nature the slaves of man. (Smitthenner.) Carey inti- mates something similar when he says that, with the advance of civilization the tendency is for men to become more and more valuable and commodi- ties to have less of "value." Vol. I.— 21 322 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. II. > former is preferred, and the latter in the higher.^ And, indeed, the latter is not only more humane, but, in the long run, it is more profitable to the person who adopts it as his rule in busi- ness. In the case of commodities, he now runs but little risk from a change of fashion, because the fashions of the masses change much less rapidly than those of the upper circles of society. In the case of indispensable goods, on the other hand, he may now calculate with more certainty on the increase of population, and, therefore, on a future market for his wares. Competition, which in former times, devoted all its efforts to bringing about the exclusion, by law, of all rivals, is now en- gaged, principally, in devising means of surpassing them by superiority of workmanship, and in thus increasing the power of the real sources of a nation's wealth. ^ We niight here speak of an aristocratic and democratic principle of the determination of prices. The greater utility of the latter is advocated in the Discourse of Trade, Covn and Credit, London, 1697. Bacon has a good word to saj for the maxim: "Light gains make heavy purses; for light gains come thick, Avhereas great come now and then." Similarly, Gurnay in CJiquot de Blci-vaclic, Considerations svir le Commerce etc., 175S, 48, 54. As to how Morrison, the celebrated merchant, became rich by adhering to the principles : " to sell cheap as well as to buy cheap," and " always tell the truth," see CJtadtvick, in the Statistical Journal, 1S62, 503. Com.pare the related opinion of Adam SmitJi's continuator in an ethical direction, Garve, zu Cicero's Pflichten, III, 100. The contrary principle, the cunning of the Judaeans, according to Strabo, XVII, 800, was followed by the Dutch East India Company, when it, in 1652, caused the greater number of the vegeta- ble roots on the Moluccas to be desti'oyed. Saalfeld, Geschichte des hol- landischen Kolonialwesens, I, 272. Also, when great quantities of roots were destroyed by burning in the East Indies. (Huysers Beschryving der Oost- indischen Etablissmenten, 1789, 22.) For a clever argument against such practice, see de la Court, Anwysing der heilsame Gronden, 1663. The prin- ciple similar to that of the patent, mentioned in the text, works at the same time democratically and aristocratically, both words understood in their best sense. Sec. CIX-l EFFECT OF A DECLINE OF PRICE. 303 SECTION CIX. EFFECT OF A DECLINE OF PRICE BELOW COST. If the market price sinks below the cost of production, tlie producer naturally suffers a loss, and diminishes his stock as soon as possible. That whole establishments engaged in in- dustiy should forsake a branch of it which is suffering from depression and enter a flourishing one, must ever remain a rare exception.^ But the discouraged manufacturer may de- lay renewing his stock on hand,^ replacing his machinery by new machinery; he may dismiss some of his workmen and diminish the number of days during which the others shall work. Moreover, most industries are operated by means of borrowed capital, capital which must therefore, be returned to the lender. Under certain circumstances, however, the indus- try may be continued for some time, even at a real loss,^ so long as the loss of interest etc., which would follow the entire suspension of the work, exceeds the loss produced by the low- ' This is true, first of all, in those industries which are intimately connected with one another, or of those which are carried on with scarcely any fixed capital ; also in lower stages of civilization, where the lights and shades caused by a highly developed division of labor are not very intense. On the numer- ous difficulties overlooked by Ricardo in every other case, see Sismondi, N. P., II, ch. 2. The workman thereby loses his former skill, that is his prin- cipal capital, and can certainly not wait until he has acquired other and dif- ferent skill. 2 When a lowering of prices is expected, demand is less than consumption : " postponed demand ; " whereas, an expectation that the price will rise, pro- duces "anticipated demand." Tooke, History of Prices, II, 155. 3 Thus, for instance, if the workmen were exposed to starvation, or were likely to take their departui-e; if great stores of raw material were in danger of spoiling; if fixed capital of great value were engaged in one industry and could not be easily h-ansferred to another. The first and third causes are fre- quently met with in mining, and give rise to the mode of carrying on the operation known as Zubusgriiben^ that is, a species of working mines upon shares. In England, after the spring of 1S62, cotton yarn was not so much dearer than raw cotton, that the loss caused by the decline could be made up. (Atisland, 24 Sept., 1862.) 324: CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. II. ering of price, but hardly any longer. If the supply of the commodity the price of which has fallen has been diminished, the subsequent result depends on the causes which, in the first place, brought about the fall in price. If the diminution in price was caused solely by a too great supply, when this super- abundant supply is gotten rid of, the price will rise again.* If it were produced by a decrease in the value in use of the com- modity, the diminution of the supply can restore the former state of things only in so far as at least a part of the purchas- ers ascribe to the commodity the same value in use as before.^ Lastly, if the lowering of the price came from a decrease in the number of bu3'ers, or from a decrease in their ability to pur- chase, the former price will be restored when production has been adapted to a correspondingly smaller circle of consum- ers.® This last is true especially when the price, without hav- ing suffered any absolute change, has become relatively too low, on account of an increase in the cost of production.''^ * Besides, in the time immediately following, the price lowered by too great a supply, may produce a species of desperation among producers, which would lead them, in the hope of covering their losses, to increase the supply still more, until many of them were ruined. Generally, when a time of high prices is followed by a time of low prices, we find an interval during which sellers endeavor to defend themselves against the decline, and during which, as a consequence, scarcely any business is transacted, while high prices are nominally continued. And so vice versa. Tooke, History of Prices, II, 62. ^ Thus, for instance, when the change of fashion brought about the disuse of long periwigs in every-day life, their price did not cease to fall until they had entirely disappeared. But, if a person wishes to have one made to-day for a masquerade, for the stage, etc., he would pay as much for it as its former price. On the other hand, the price of whalebone has never been again as high as it was in the time when hooped petticoats were worn. ®The great plague in the time of Edward III. caused during the first year, on account of the decreased consumption, an extraordinary cheapness of provisions. In the following year, however, they became alarmingly dear, berause there were few producers, especially among the humble classes. A quarter of wheat cost in 1348, 4s. 2d.; in 1349, 5s. 5d.; in 1350, 8s. 3d.; in 1351, IDS. 2d. ; while in 1346 and 1347, its average price was 6s. 8^d. Rogers, History of Agriculture and Prices, I, 232. ' As for instance when new taxes or excises are imposed. Generally when the cost of production has largely increased, purchasers do not wait until a Sec. ex.] DIFFERENT COST. 325 SECTION ex. DIFFERENT COST OF PRODUCTION OF THE SAME GOODS. JNIost goods are produced at the same time, but under dif- ferent circumstances, at a very different cost. In order to estimate the influence of this fact upon price, we must distin- guish between those commodities the cheapest manner of the production of which may be extended at pleasure, and those in the production of which it is necessary, in order to satisfy the aggregate want of,. them, to call in the dearest mode of pro- duction to aid the cheapest. In the former instance, the price of commodities is naturally regulated by the least cost of production. The person who is unable to sustain this competition permanently, would do a great deal better to abandon the industry altogether; for it is not in his power to raise the price by diminishing the supply; more powerful rivals would then only need to correspondingly increase theirs.^ If the same law were applicable, in the latter case, producers decrease of competition among sellers compels them to exact higlier prices, but meet them half waj^ especially when many greatly desire the commodity, and the increase of the cost is only small. (Rati, Handbuch, I, § 163.) ' Under this rule fall, according to § 33, most products of industry prop- erly so called. " If we lose a market for a year, we generally lose it for all time," said an experienced manufacturer before the parliamentary hand-loom weavers' committee, 1840-42. Of course the cost of transportation as far as the market must be estimated as part of the cost of production. In conse- quence of this, as well as of the difference of taxation duties etc., the superi- ority of one producer to another may be more than overcome. In the case of colonial commodities, which go into the interior of a country from differ- ent sea-ports, the territory supplied from each port is determined for the most part by these data. Thus, in Switzerland, for instance, we find the dis- tricts supplied by Havre, Genoa and Rotterdam ; in Austria, the districts supplied by Hamburg and Triest contiguous, but the boundary line subject to many changes. (liaii, Lehrbuch, I, § 164.) It mvist be understood that we do not here speak of abnormal expenses made by producers individually, whether in consequence of want of skill or because of accident. 326 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. II. placed in a less favorable situation would be compelled to im- mediately abandon the market. The market, in consequence, would no longer be able to provide for the aggregate need; and the price of the commodit}' would continue to rise until the producers who had been driven from the market returned to it again. Hence, here, price in the long run is determined by the cost of the production of the commodity, produced under the least advantageous conditions, while such produc- tion is necessary in order to satisfy the aggregate need. The person engaged in production under more advantageous con- ditions receives in the same price of the goods, which are cheaper to him, an excess of profit; one \thich is greater in proportion as his situation, vis-a-vis of production, is superior to that of his less favored competitors. ^ ^ ^ This is true especially of agricultural production, in which, as a rule, be- side the most fertile and most advantageously situated land, the worse rriust be used. What Whaicly calls " surplus-profit " appears here in the form of rent, whereas, in other cases, it takes the shape of unusually high wages, or profit on capital. This is very beautifully and systematically developed by Schdffle^ N. CEk., II; Aufl., 192 fF. According to Senior, Outlines, 15, the price-relation of two commodities to each other depends not on the quanti- ties of them which come to market, but on the relative j^ower of the diffi- culties which stand in the way of an increase in these quantities. If the same producers can pursue the cheaper mode of production which does not suffice to supply the market, as well as the dearer, we have, generally, a price which is the mean between the two costs of production. The same is true in the case of " smuggled " goods which ought to have paid duty. (Her- mann, loc. cit., 83, seq.) ^ To this section belong the secrets of production Avhich may be taken ad- vantage of either ad libitum or within certain limits. In agriculture, advan- tages of production can seldom remain secret. Compare, however, the case mentioned in G«r«/Vr'5 ti-anslation oi Adam vS^wzV//, V, 119, and that of the orchards Avhich yielded £i,ooa yearly for every 32 acres, and which Avere a result of the recent introduction of the culture of the cherry in Kent, in the reign of Henry VIII. (Anderson, Origin of Commerce, a, 1540.) There is therefore, a certain odium attached by agricultural producers to keeping se- cret a means of agricultural improvement. Sec. CXI.] DIFFERENT COST. 327 SECTION CXI. DIFFERENT COST OF PRODUCTION OF THE SAME GOODS. (CONTINUED.) Hence the price of a commodity and the ratio between its supply and demand mutually condition each other. On the height of the price depends, in great part, how many pur- chasers shall resolve to make an effectual demand; but, at the same time, to what amount of cost of production, sellers shall extend their supply.^ We can speak of an equilibrium between supply and demand only w^hen the former corresponds with the wish of those who are ready to make good the full cost of production. (Malthus.) It has been asked, indeed, whether it were more natural and better that demand should precede supply or supply demand.^ But the inquiry is an illogical one, when expressed in so general a manner, since supply and 1 Compare Boisguillebert^ Traits des Grains, II, ch. 3. yohn Stuart Mill speaks of an equation : the price of a commodity in a given maket is always high enough to produce a demand corresponding to the present supply, or to an expected supply. The price of such commodities only which may not be increased to any desirable extent depends on supply and demand. In the case of all others, on the other hand, demand and supply depend on the price, and this on the cost of production. Supply and demand ahvaj-s tend to an equilibrium which is never really attained where the price is high enough to cover the cost of production (.?). (Principles, III, ch. 2, § 4; ch. 3, § 2.) Scliaffle's theory of prices is topped by the proposition that all com- peting sellers and all competing buyers, after an economic fashion, do not wish to sell below individual cost-value, nor to rise above individual value iii use, in purchasing. Hence, in a throng of competition of supply the cost- liest productions step out of the field of competition in a descending cost- value series; and in a throng of competition of demand, the most wearied cravings in an ascending value-in-use series; until the quantities offered in supply and asked for cover each other without loss, and have placed each other in quantitative equilibrium. (N. CEk. Aufl., I, 1S8 ff.; compare 173, 185.) It is, however, to say the least, an instance of baseless solicitude, when Wade, History of the middle and working Classes, 214, says that one un- employed workman might depress the aggregate wages of labor, almost ad injimtum. - Huf eland, N. Grundlegung, I, 78; Eicardo, Principles, ch. 31. 328 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. II. demand are only two sides of the same transaction. But, we may say that in the case of indispensable goods, the want of them (demand) is always felt sooner than the excess of them (supply), and that in the case of goods which may be dis- pensed with, including, originally, money, the reverse is true. Besides, a person engaging in the production of any kind of goods, can, as a rule, only seldom directly investigate the re- lation between supply and demand. Generally, he can do no more than compare the market price of the commodity with the cost at which he can produce it. Many mistakes are in- evitable here ; but the making of them is the necessary sacri- fice which must be endured to purchase the more than coun- terbalancing advantages of free competition.^ SECTION CXII. EXCEPTIONS. The rule that goods which have the same cost of produc- tion have also equal value in exchange, is applicable only to the extent that it is possible to transfer the factors of produc- tion at will from one branch of production to another. Where this really free competition does not exist, the price depends entirely on the quantity of the supply, compared with the solvability or capacity to pay of the purchaser; and hence, it may sometimes rise far above the cost of production (monop- oly-price), and sometimes sink far below it (forced price, or under-price).^ Such hindrances to competition depend, in part, ^ Du7ioye>% Liberie du Travail, VIII, ch. 4; Rati, Lelirbuch, I, § 15S. * For a good classification of monopolies, see Senior, Outlines, 103 ft". Menger, Grundsiitze, I, 195, shows that no monopolist can arbitrarily deter- mine the extent of the market for his inonopolj-product when the price is fixed, nor when the extent of the market is known, the height of the price. Moreover, the price may remain longer above than under the cost of production, for the reason that it is easier to abandon a business than to begin one, and that the fear of loss is more frequently an incentive to action than the hope of gain. Hence the price of corn, when everything else is \ery dear, is more apt to vary from the average price, than in times when Sec. CXIL] EXCEPTIONS. 320 upon natural causes. Thus, in the case of the works of art of a deceased artist, which cannot be increased in number;- or in that of living celebrities who cannot extend their mental acti\ity in the same degree that their reputation has grown. So, also, in the case of precious stones, which are sometimes found free, and therefore cost nothing, but which, at the same time, have a high price.^ Many valuable agricultural products are, together with their production, limited to a detinite and sometimes very small district.* It is to be re- garded as a modification of such natural monopolies when sub- stitutes for a kind of goods which diminish, at least in part, the demand for them, are found, at a cheaper price; for in- stance, ordinary table-wines in the stead of fine wines. The rule applies much more strictly to those goods which, on account of their greater quantity, can replace inferior ones,^ than it does to those where this is not possible. everything is very cheap. For instance, the Munich prices from 1750 to iSoo sliow tliat its highest price was 147 per cent, above, and its lowest 47 per cent, below the average of twenty years. (Ran, Lehrbucli, § 162, 1S2.) 2 Chance plays a great part here. Thus, Murillo's Conception which Mar- shal Soult had oftered several times for 150,000 francs, but in vain, was sold in May, 1S52, for 586,000 francs. Paul Potter's young bull at the Hague, which cost 625 florins in 174S, was valued before the middle of the nineteenth century at 200,000 florins. (Dethmar.) 2 The purchaser resolves to do so because it would, in all probability, cost him more to go to India or Brazil in search of precious stones. Besides after the working of the Brazilian mines in 172S, and again after the French Revo- lution, the price of diamonds fell greatly; in the one case, from an in- crease of the supply, in the other from a decrease of the demand. (Ritto; VI, 355, 365-) ■* Thus, the Champagne and Johannisberg grapes, when transplanted to the Crimea, lost most of their native taste. On China's practical monopoly of tea culture, and Ceylon's, especially in its southwestern part, of cinnamon, at least so far as the peculiar aroma is concerned, compare Rttier, Erdkunde, VI, 123 ft". The small deer of Angoi-a no sooner leave the little district of Asia Minor to which they belong, than they are in danger of degenerating. (Revue des deux Mondes, May 15, 1S50.) Indian birds-nests cost no more than 1 1 per cent, to gather, dry etc., of the market price. (CrazifurJ, East India Archipelago, III, 432 fl:'.; Hogendorp^ Sur I'lle de Java, 201.) * Poor material for fuel, poor day-laborer work — dwellings, medical attend- ance. (Mctigcr, Grundsiitze, I, 116.) 330 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. II. The principal cause of forced or under-prices (Schlciider- frcise) is the facility with which the product deteriorates, and must, therefore, find a quick sale, especially when its storage or transportation is attended by further difficulties.^ But, very durable commodities are also subject to under-prices, and es- pecially those which last longest, because the supply of them can be diminished only very slowly. Thus, for instance, houses, in a declining city. Distress-prices are found most usually in the case of such commodities as are produced with- out any intention to produce them, as for instance, rags and excrementitious substances. The more the mere forces of nature preponderate in production, the less can the supply be increased or decreased at pleasure, the more frequently, as a consequence, do we find monopoly-prices and under-prices. (Compare § 131 ft'.) Thus the production of wheat is invariably connected with the order of the seasons. Between seed-time and harvest, there are a number of months which neither capital nor skill can shorten to any extent. The cultivation of land, to be very much greater and more lasting, supposes so many conditions precedent, increase of live stock, buildings etc., that it can be attained only after a series of years. Hence it happens that wheat, much more than manufactured products, is subject to oppressivel}'' high prices and oppressivel}'^ low ones, during a long period of time. No matter what the influence of the forces operating in the opposite direction may be, the ^Thus sea fish, oysters etc. were formerly much cheaper during the sum- mer than during the winter, at Ostend and Scheveningen, because during winter they could be sent to a distance. At Billingsgate market, in the mackerel season, fish cost per himdred 48 to 50 shillings at 5 o'clock in the morning, 36 shillings at 10 o'clock, and 24 shillings in the afternoon. (H. Schidze^ Nat.-CEkonomische Bilder aus England, 1S53, 241.) In the Rhine country, the price of fruit does not vary so much as in Saxony, because it is customary there to employ the surplus in the manufacture of cider, of pre- serves etc., thus making it transportable and durable. Frequently, after a very abundant crop of gi-apes or olives, under-prices prevail, sometimes on account of a want of vessels, cellar-room etc. ; they must, therefore, be sold rapidly. Sec. CXIIL] EXCEPTIONS. 331 price of wheat depends most largely on the result of the last crop." SECTION CXIIL EXCEPTIONS. (co:s'nNUED.) Other impediments in the way of freedom of competition have their origin in social conditions. The rule governing prices applies only where the vendor and purchaser are equal- ly ready to exchange. But in every case in which the pro- ducer carries on his business, not for the sake of free gain, but simply to obtain a means of livelihood, it may be subject to many important exceptions.^ The richer a seller is, the longer can he wait for a favorable opportunity to sell. Thus, for in- stance, wheat is somewhat lower in price at times when pay- ments are universally made than at other seasons of the year, because a great many country people are then compelled to sell. Where the country population are universally needy, it sinks after a harvest to an unusually low figure, and in spring rises again ver}'- high. Sometimes price is aflected by the agreements of the pur- chaser or seller, but most readily by those of middlemen be- '' Compare Adam Smithy Wealth of Nations, I, ch. 7. ; Tooke, History of Prices, I, 97. Furs vary very much in price, sometimes 300 per cent, in a year, because, in the case of this entirely natural product, every tiling depends on the stores of them, on the temperature etc. (McCulloch, Commerc. Diet., s. \.) On the other hand, the price of coffee usually varies only after periods of a number of years, because new plantations produce only after a lapse of years. (Ibid.) Pigs vary much more than cattle in price, because the former may be made ready for the slaughter house in one-third of the time required for the latter. (Thaei\ Rationelle Landwirthschaft, IV, 374.) ' Thus the rent of farms, where a numerous proletarian population will live exclusively from agriculture, depends on scarcely anything but the number of people and the extent of the land. (J. S. Mill, Principles, III, ch. 2.) In retail trade, where personal want comes in question, prices are much more subject to be modified by small circumstances, than in wholesale trade, Avhero both parties are only intent on " doing business." (J. S. Mill, III, ch. i, § 5. Tookc, II, 72 f.) 332 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Cii. II. tween consumer and producer.'^ Customs peculiar to whole classes may exert the same influence, and such customs are especially powerful in the lower stages of business and in- dustrial development. They, even at the present time, take the place, frequently, of freedom of competition in retail busi- ness, in the book business, and in the determination of lawyers' and doctors' fees, as well as in the distribution of a nation's income among the three great branches of its general econ- omy,^ deciding, instead of competition, how much shall go to each. Wherever there are guilds, communities, castes etc. W' ith legal privileges ; wherever there are difficulties placed in the way of exportation and importation; wherever preemption rights or monopolies,'' in the strict sense of the word, exist, the leveling ebb and flow of the elements of production may be still more seriously interfered with. Legislation ^ of this sort injures the non-privileged portion of the population more than it helps the privileged portion. (See § 97./ The word tismy, so arbitrarily used in every-day language, should be admitted in science only to designate a famine-price, fraudulenth^ and intentionally caused or intensified. ■^ Hucksters, butchers, dealers in corn, inn-keepers etc. A remarkable case where Parisian dealers in hare-skins attempted to ruin the new fashion in silk hats bj distributing a great number of them among the rabble, at mock- prices. (Hermann, ist ed., 91.) The author witnessed a similar but unsuc- cessful attempt in Berlin in 1S3S-39, bj the tailors against the so-called Mac- intosh coat. On the conspiracy of the English dealers in second-hand goods against auctions, see Athteneum, Dec. 5, 1S63. It is one of McCtdlocKs characteristic exaggerations, that he says that conspiracies to raise the price of a commodity by artificial means, are broken just as soon as they begin to obtain their object by the interest of the individual members to profit by the advanced prices. (Edition of Adam Smith, Edinb., 1S63, p. 59.) 3 J. S. Mill, Principles, II, ch. 4. * Monopolies universally prohibited: L. un. C. De Monopol. (IV, 59.) Po- lice-order of the Empire, 154S, tit. iS. * Privileges which the purchaser voluntarily accords to the seller are wont to be useful to both parties. (Hermann, loc. cit. 155, 158.) ^ Besides, guilds, castes, corporations etc. may, when the vent diminishes, produce vinder-prices as readily as they may monopoly -prices when the vent is very good. (See Adam Smith, Wealth of Nations, I, ch. 7. Secs. cxiv."i prices fixed by government. 333 SECTION CXIV. PRICES FIXED BY GOVERNMENT. No power can, of course, fix the price of a commodity in the long run, which cannot at the same time fix the relation of supply and demand. Hence, set prices fixed by govern- mental authority can be made to play a part in practice only in so far as the}^ do not establish a price in opposition to the real state of things, only to the extent that they give un- doubted expression to it in a manner in harmony with natural conditions. With this restriction, set or fixed prices may, in the absence of real competition, which can always best deter- mine prices, be useful to both parties; otherwise one party would at one time, and the other at another, profit by an un- just advantage; but it would not be long before both would suffer from the perturbation caused thereby in all commercial transactions. How pleasant it is for a traveler in Switzer- land, or even in Italy, to find set prices established there.^ Especially where competition is prevented by state privileges, the establishment of set prices by the state for the protection of the public may be necessary.^ It is more difficult to fix a 'Thus, for instance, the traveler who wanted to cross a stream, -would find himself delivered over to the tender mercies of the ferry-man, without pro- tection of any kind against his demands. But repeated impositions in the matter of prices would have for efiect to bring a point into disrepute as a place of crossing, and would induce the public to seek another. Similarly in the case of hackney-coachmen and carriers in large cities, and in that of innkeepers, at hotels and postal termini etc. * Fixed prices by governmental authority were soonest attempted after bad harvests, but, indeed, with a strange ignorance of the natural grounds of the increase in price of bread-stufis. Thus in the time of Charlemagne. (Cap- itul. a, 805 ; Baliiz, I, 423.) Similarly in the case of other articles of uni- versal necessity, when oppressively but necessarily dear. (See § 175.) During the last centuries of the middle ages, -svith their multitude of actual monopolies, and at the beginning of the modern era, fixed prices became more and more general. The earliest instance in the history of England of a fixed price for bread was in 120:: (v. Raumcr, Ilohenstaufen, V, 372), and 334: CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. IT. set price for a commodity in proportion to its complexity and to its variableness in quality; and where there are different grades of quality of the same commodity, and the transition from one grade to another is almost imperceptible, such price is easily evaded.^ In the case of every enterprise carried on in 1266, 51 Henrj III. The earliest in Prussia was in 1393. (Voigi, Geschichte von Preussen, II, 659.) Many instances of fixed prices in the Rliine provinces of Austria in 1530. In Mylius, Corp. Const. Marcli, V, 2, 587 ff., we find an ordinance of 1653 fixing prices in Berlin, and including 72 industries. There is a very complicated system of fixed prices in the police ordinance of the electorate of Saxony of 1612, and in the decree concerning the coin of 1822. As to how, in Saxony in 1578, an attempt was made to ascertain the cost of the production of shoes by shoemakers, see JoJi. Faike, Gesch. des Kurf. August in volkswirthschaft. Beziehung, 1S6S, 252. There was an enormous extension of governmental fixing of prices under Philip II.; one of the principal causes why Castile was so far behind Aragon eco- nomically. (T(nvnsc)id, Journey through Spain, II, 221.) Sometimes these measures were adopted to prevent distress-prices ; as in Hochheim, in favor of the vintners. (Becker, Polit. Discurs, II, 1652.) Tlie predilection especi- ally of German authorities for the fixing of prices by governmental power, in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries is ver^' remarkable. Thus Luther, vom Kaufhandel und Wucher, 1524; Calvin, Leben Calvins, by He7iry, II, Beilage, 3, 23; Bornitz, De Rerum Sufficientia, 1625, 246; Sechcndorff, Teut- scher Fiirstenstaat, 5th ed., 1776, 210; Becker, II, 1823 ft"; Horncck, Oester- rich iiber Alles, wenn es will, 16S4, 123; Leibniz ed. Dutens, VI, I, 250; Thomasius, Gottl. Rechtsgelahrtheit, 1709, 209; even Frederick the Great, Mylius, N. Corp. Const. March, I, 190. Similarly, Mariana, De Rege et Regis Institutione, III, c. 9. Compare, however, III, c. 8, and Bacon, Serm., 15; Historia Henrici, 1037, 1040. On the other hand, Ckild, 1690, and Nortk, 1691, reprove all such measures. Roscker, Zur Geschichte der englischen Volkswirthschaftslehre, 65, 90 f. Earlier yet, Salmasius, who would allow the ix&& fori ratio to govern. (De Usuris, 163S, 5S3.) For a very rigorous price-tarriff in the old Indian laws, by which, inter alia, the price of provis- ions was to be fixed anew every foiirteen days, see Menu, Laws, VIII, ch. 401 ft". 2 Where trade is free, the filet de hoeuf, for instance, is worth four times as much as the flesh of the ox's neck or throat; but prices fixed by a govern- ment can scarcely take cognizance of the difference. How easily might not a fixed price for beer, for instance, be evaded by diluting that beverage with water, or fixed prices for inn-keepers by dealing out portions smaller in quantity or of an inferior quality. Moreover, as early a writer as De la Court, Polit. Discoursen, 1662, c. 4, remarks that the establishment of fixed prices by governmental authority raises the average price of all commodities Sec. CXV.] CIVILIZATION ON PRICES. 335 by many in common, where no competition is possible, it is necessary to supply the defect by means similar to the estab- lishment of fixed prices; as in the case of government, by fees for governmental services, and the cooperation of a cham- ber of deputies in the imposition of taxes and the determina- tion of official salaries etc/ SECTION CXV. INFLUENCE OF GROWING CIVILIZATION ON PRICES. On the whole, prices become more and more regular as national-economic civilization advances. Progress in civiliza- tion tends to bring the parties engaged in the struggle for prices that is buyers and sellers, nearer to one another, in so far as it uniformly decreases the cost of production, and increases the purchaser's ability to pay.-^ (See §101.) The more universal di- vision of labor makes commercial intercourse more necessary to every one, at the same time that it makes it more of a hab- it to him; and hence exchange ceases more and more to be a matter of caprice or chance. The better means of transpor- tation and communication render it easier, in every way, for supply and demand to meet. With the advance of general en- lightenment and education, an acquaintance with commodities also becomes more general, and every purcliaser is on a bet- ter way to be able to estimate the cost of production which the seller has to bear. Hence, fraudulent prices and prices founded rather than lowers it, for the reason that the few who are sellers bj trade can do more to influence the authorities than the many buyers, whose inter- ests are divided among numberless different commodities. *Schdffle, Nat.-CEkonomie, II, 384 f. ^ 13 at! f eld, Organization of Industry, 120. "Where the economic life of a people is still undeveloped, and the production of one enterprise is not from the first based on the estimated consumption of another, the circulation of goods brings with it great profits and great losses ; Avhereas, profits and losses grow smaller, but at the same time more uniform and regular, in proportion as the circulation of goods increases in rapidity and regularity. (Siei/i, Lehr- buch, 212.) 336 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. II. in error become less frequent ; and all this is helped forward by the greater accuracy of weights and measures. The in- crease of population makes competition more active in all branches of trade, while at the same time, with the greater freedom of circulation, a number of causes which previously operated to produce very high prices in one place and very low ones in another are removed.^ But especially, the growth of a distinct class of merchants leads to a uniformit}^ in price. This class are incited by their own interest to purchase at low prices and sell at high prices. Thus, their competition in the former case raises prices, and lowers them in the latter.^ In all low- er stages of civilization, the custom of making offers and beat- ing down in price pla3^s a great part, while where culture is higher, the system of fixed prices (but not by government) gains ground continually. Here Turgot's principle is appli- cable, viz.: that the current price of an article is tacitly under- stood when one asks a merchant the price of his wares.* 2 In Belgium, during the last forty years, the price of wheat has become more constant every year, while the price of rye has become more variable; for the reason that rye has gradually ceased to be an article of popular con- sumption, and therefore to be an important article in trade, and is consumed almost entirely and directly by its producers. (Horn, Statist. Gemalde von B., 1S53, 185.) Rodbertus rightly conjectures that the price of wheat was much more variable in ancient times than it is with us. (Hildcbra7id''s Jahrb., 1S70, I, 36.) That it was so may be inferred from the surprisingly large family supplies which were laid in, as appears from Digest, XXXIII, De Penu legato. 3 In Wiirtemberg even officials etc. buy their own wine almost always direct- ly from the vintner. This causes prices there to be exceedingly variable, fre- quently from hour to hour. (y. Redcti, Statist. Zeitschrift, Nov. 1847, 1008.) How greatly the mere presence of a regular market has contributed to make prices more constant, may be seen in the suburbs of Hamburg, Avhere fish offered for sale on the street are sold in the evening for one-third of the price asked for them in the morning. Besides, purchases made with a view to spec- ulation may increase the variations of price, if the speculation is unskillfuUy conducted, especially when a low rate of interest, and of the profit of the person engaged in it, has produced a blind race among the speculators. Here the price of a commodity rises, not from any natural cause, but because it once rose before, and vice versa. (Senior, Outlines, 17 ff; Hermann, 90 ft") * That fixed prices suppose that men are engaged in the production of the Sec. CXV.J CIVILIZATION ON PRICES. 337 This proposition is tnie in the case of individuals, as well as of classes and of whole nations.'' It is plain, that under a system of fixed prices we can more certainly discover wliat the equit- able price is, than in the heat of higgling which besides con- sumes a great deal of precious time. Lastly, one of the princi- pal requisites of a well developed scale of prices is national hon- or, and this, doubtless, increases in the higher stages of civiliza- tion, not only because of the greater moral culture which commodity in question, as their calling in life, see Garve^ Zu Cicero's Pflich- ten, III, 64 fl'. Chess-like commerce of colporteurs, and in caravans etc. Concerning the dreadful higgling of the Bedouins, see Wdhtcd, Reise in Arabien, Rbdigcr\'i translation, I, 147; and the still ^vorse bantering in Cash- mere, -where the merchant, in the first place, always denies that he possesses the desired commodity, then begins to search for it, in order to discover what value the purchaser puts upon it etc. (K. Ritter, Erdkunde, m, 475.) On the practices in Indian fairs, see Th. Skinner^ Excursion in India, 1S33, I, ch. 6; on the bazaars in Asia, Andree, Globus XII, 7, 211. Herberstein says of the Russians in the sixteenth century : mercantur fallacissime et dolosissime ncc ^aucis verbis . . . 7nercatores nonnunquam non uno tantum ant alter' o vtcnse sicspensos deiitic7it, verum ad extremam dcspcrationem ferducere solent. Hence the great variations in prices and commodities. (Rerum Moscov. Commentt., ed. Starczewski, 39 f) Similarly also, in 1674, according to KiU burger: BUsching's Magazin, III, 249. But, on the contrary, it is said of the Plescovers, educated by intercourse with the Hanse; tanta integritas . . . in conirach'bus, ui nno tantum verba res ifsas indicareni omni verbosi- tatc in frattdcm emptoris omissa. (Herberstein^ 52.) In the England of the present day, the custom of marking each piece of goods Avith its price is very general. Concerning the rapidity and the paucity of words with which prices are settled in that country, where business men do not even salute their customers, nor customers the business man, see C. G. Simon, Observations recueillies en Angleterre, 1835, I, 129 f. The Athenian laws (.-*), that fixed prices should be asked, and that sellers should not sit down that that they might sell more rapidly, points to something similar. (Aiheri., VI, 226 f. Plato, De Legg., XI, 916 f.) Athenian law prohibiting mendacity in the markets. (See DemostJt., Lept., 459.) ' Thus the German book-trade has fixed prices. Many merchants never make an offer to their educated customers who are wont to do so with peas- ants etc. ; because they are aware that tlie latter purchase only after they have compelled the seller to come down greatly from his first proposed price. Among the Quakers it has been a rule from the beginning, never to ask more for their wares than they were determined to accept. (Hume, History of England, ch. 62.) Vol. 1. — 22 338 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. II. then prevails, but also and especialty because that which con- stitutes a people's real and best interests is better understood." Among declining nations, many of these developments take a retrogressive road. The very great distinction between rich and poor, between educated and uneducated, again produces great fluctuations in price. A proletarian people who have sunk so low as to live on potatoes will suffer much more from variations in price and of the means of subsistance than a people who live on wheat ; for the reason that it is so diflicult to export or to preserve '^ potatoes. Nor can it be doubted, that the greatest possible constancy of prices is the most beneficial condition that the general economy of a people can be in. Where prices change while the cost of production remains the ^ Sir William Temj>le, Observations upon the Netherlands, Works I, 134, compares honor in trade to diseipline in an army. Similarly, Latv, Trade and Money, 209 f. Ferguson^ History of Civil Society, III, 4. Where the seller is not obliged to make known the existence of certain defects in his wares to the purchaser before sale, there is always scope for fraud. Com- pare Digest De Edict, aedilit., XXI, I. On the meaning of the German legal maxims : Hand muss Hand ivahren^ and Ein JVorf, ein Mann^ see £/5e«//ar/, Deutsches Recht in SpriichwOrtern, 311 f., 319 f. It is a principle in matters of business, that the person who through malice or carelessness recommends a man of whose probity there is already some doubt, should bear the damage caused by his recommendation. (Martens, Grundriss, des Handelsrechtes, 24 fF.) Many attempts at dishonesty are prevented by laws which in important contracts, especially in sales of land etc., require the presence of witnesses, and this particularly in the lower stages of civiliza- tion. {Meier and ^c/zow^ww, Attischer Process, 522; Roman, Emancipatio; Grimm, Deutsche Rechtsalterthiimer, 608 f.), or even a public proclamation before the assembled community, at least written documents invested with all legal formalities as practiced among civilized peoples. On Greek laws of this nature, see especially, Theophrast., in Siobaeus, Sermon., XLIV, 22. Very remarkable in Sparta. Schol. Aristopkan., Aves, 12S4. ''Compare Lotz, Revision, I, 255 fi". In England the price of wheat scarce- ly ever varied more than from i to 2. In Ireland the price of potatoes var- ied from I to 6. (McCtdloc?/, Comm. Diet., v. Potatoes.) Compare Engcl, Jahrbuch fiir Sachsen, I, 491 ff. The custom of asking enormous prices with the expectation of being beaten down, is usual in Italy and carried to a frightful extent, and related to the bad custom prevalent there of begging a little after-payment to every little gratuity or drink-money which has been received. Sec. CXV.] CIVILIZATION ON PRICES. 339 same, one person can only gain what the other has lost. But such unmerited crains and undeserved losses have an invari- able tendency to destroy the deepest roots of a people's eco- nomic activity ; and intentional speculation based upon such change usually assumes an immoral character, (Stock-job- bing./ Even if Macleod be right, that an increase or decrease in prices is to be regarded as a warning of excess, the former of excess of consumption, the latter of production, no one will doubt that it is the interest of every organism to confine pain within the smallest possible limits, even if its consequences are so beneficial to the preservation of the whole body. ^Storck, Handbuch, I, 311. 5^. B. ^oy, Traite I, ch. 16. As to how com- merce, when fully developed, is wont to be more moral than when only half developed, see Garve, loc. cit., and Versuche IV, 149 if. How fortunate for the public economy of nations that the prices of corn especially have been growing more steady all the time since the middle ages. See Jiosc/ier, Ueber Kornhandel, 56, 6i. 340 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. III. CHAPTER III. MONEY IN GENERAL. SECTION CXVI. INSTRUMENT OF EXCHANGE. MEASURE OF VALUE. BARTER. Wherever the division of labor is very highly developed, the continuance of barter, or the direct exchange of one ob- ject of consumption for another, presents difficulties well nigh insurmountable. How difficult it would be always to find the person who could supply us with precisely what we wanted, and at the same time have need of what we had a surplus of .^ But how much less frequently would it happen that one's ' Trade by barter was very general in several states of the American Union about the close of the eighteenth century. In Vermont, for instance, it was usual for a doctor to exchange his medicines against a horse, and for the prmter to buy corn, butter etc. with a newspaper. (Ebeling^ Geschichte und Erdbeschreibung, II, 537.) In Maryland, the Assembly fixed' by law the rel- ative proportions at which tobacco, pork, corn and wheat should be ex- changed the one against the other. (Ebeling, V, 435 ff. Douglas, Summary of the British Settlements in N. America, 1670, V, 2, 359.) Even as late as 1815, children were wont to run the streets of Corrientes, crying: " Salt for candles, tobacco for bread etc." It was commerce with England that first led to trade by money in the United States. (Robertson, Letters on South America, 1843, I, 52.) Similarly in Rhokand until the end of tlie eighteenth century, where the cities, as a consequence, presented the appearance of a fair the whole year round. In the beginning of this century, the khan in- troduced the use of copper money made from Persian cannons; and much later yet, there were scarcely a million rubles in money to a million men. (Ritter, Erdkunde, VII, 753.) Basil Hall found the uncivilized inhabitants of the Loo-Choo Islands ignorant of the use of money. (Voyage of Dis- Sec. CXVI.] INSTRUMENT OF EXCHANGE 34X want and another's surplus would coiTCspond exactly the one to the other in quantity ; that, for instance, the manufacturer of nails, desirous of exchanging his nails for a cow, should meet a cattle-dealer who should want exactly as many nails as a cow is worth ! Here there is one chief difficulty in the way, viz.: that there are so many commodities which cannot be divided without causing a dimunition or even a destruction of their value ; and that others cannot be stored away in any quantity without becoming a very heavy burthen to their owner. How useful it would therefore be, if there was one commodity which should be acceptable to every person, at all tin>es, especially if in addition to this, it possessed the qualities of durability, capacity for transportation and for being stored up and preserved. Any person who possessed a proper supply of this one commodity would then be certain of being able to obtain all other exchangeable commodities through its instru- mentality; and every seller would be satisfied to exchange what he had to dispose of against this " universal commodity." If two values are equal to a third, they are equal to each other. It is, therefore, a simple matter to use this most cur- rent of all commodities, with which all others are most fre- quently compared, as a measure of the relative values of all other exchangeable commodities. There is need of such a measure, and it is analogous to the want experienced by the mathematician who has a column of fractions to sum up, and who does it by first reducing them all to a common denomi- nator. (Storch.) ^ A person entrusted with the duty of as- covery, 1S18.) Concerning h-ade by barter in the Homeric age, see the Iliad, VII, 472 ff. A supposed law of Lujcurgus prohibited the use of money in purchases, and allowed barter only. (Justin., Ill, 2.) According to Pau- sail., Ill, 12, only barter existed in India (.?) in his time. 2 The person who has been used to paying for four pounds of meat with twenty pounds of bread, and is asked to give twenty pounds of bread in ex- change for some other article, must of course have some unit of measure in his mind to serve as a means of comparison between the value of that article and that of four pounds of meat. In Denmark, during the rule of the aris- tocracy, there were fixed prices sanctioned by the tradition of long usage, in 342 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Cii. III. sessing the values of two hundred different articles would be obliged, if he had no such measure to use, to burthen his memory with at least 19,900^ different ratios. With it, he need carry only 199 in his head. Such a commodity, universally in favor, and which, on that account, is employed as an intermediary in the effecting of exchanges of the most varied nature, in the measuring of all exchange-values and as a value-carrier ( Werthtr'dger) in time^ and space, we call money. (Merce tmiversale: Berri; 'produit prefer e : Ganilh; marchandise inte7'mediare : Bastiat.)^ accordance with which the prices of all commodities were estimated in rela- tion to a ton of barlej' or rye — a natural consequence, apparently, of the want of a common measure to govern in the greater number of transactions. Bergsoe, Archiv der Polit. CEk., IV, 314; Gratigaii's Icoiandic Code contains a remarkable fixed price of this nature in the supplement to the Kaiij>a-Balkr or Commercial Code, I, p. 500. Similarly among the ancient Persians. Reynier^ Economic publique des Perses, 30S. 200 X f200 l) 3 That is, -^ -• Compare Rau in Storch, Handbuch, III, 253. The " at least " has reference to the fact, that in barter, the many different kinds of most commodities has to be borne in mind. (Kiiics, Geld und Credit, I, 218.) * This ti-ansportation of values supposes an equality of values of the inoney in two places, while the transportation of goods supposes different values of the same kind of goods in both places. (Knies, Geld und Credit, I, 218.) * While the words j>ecunia, danarOy dinero, and argent, are all derived from unessential qualities, the German word for money, Geld, corresponds with the essential quality of money, since it denotes that which is of value every- where (gilt). On the other hand, niimnms and VOfjicopLa from VOp.O(;, (Bceckh. Meti-olog. Unters., 310.), moneta (the English, money), are from the temple of Juno Moneta, in which the Roman coins were for a long time stamped. In old German, the word for money. Geld, means everything that is paid by any one. (Grimm, D. Rechtsalterth., 382.) The present meaning of the word is to be met with in a very old document of 1327. (Arnold, z. Geschichte des Eigenthums in den deutschen Stadten, 89.) 5 The wrong definitions of money may be divided into two classes : those which convey the idea that it is more than a commodity, and those which imply that it is less. This was a point which was contested even among the Greeks. There were many who claimed that wealth consisted exclusively in the possession of much money ; as we find, for instance, in the pseudo-Platonic dialogue Eryxias ; while others insisted that money was something purely imaginary Sec. CXVL] INSTRUMENT OF EXCHANGE. 34.3 The more enlightened portions of every business com- munity gradually come to require payment in the commodit}' (^?.7jOO^^, and the creation, exclusively, of hunian laws. (ArisioL, Polit., I, 3, 16, Schn.) Nofxcajxa aofifioloi' r^c oJMiyy^:; iusxa. (Plato, De Rep., II, 371.) Anacharsis compares money to counters. (Plutarch, De Profectt. in Virtute.) Aristotle, himself, subscribed to the second opinion, although he saw clearly, that only useful and current things {^qdav S.\)llzZO.'/tlotazov 7:00^ TO t^p) could be used as money. (Polit., 1, 3, 14 ff. Eth. Nicom., V, 5, 6, Rhet., II, 1 6.) Xenophon ascribed properties to money which no other commodity possessed; especially when he said that it could never be too plentiful, and ihat its price could never fall. (De Vectt. Ath., 4.) The finest ancient explanation of the nature df money is that of the jurisconsult Paullus, L. I ; Digest, XVIII, i ; and it well deserves the long commentary devoted to it by P. Neri, Osservazioni etc., in Custodt, P. A., VI, 324, ft". Among the moderns, Melandhon., Corp. Ref., XVI, 49S, and Seb. Frank, Chronik., 760, consider money as a mere symbol. On the other hand, the over-estimation in which the precious metals were held by the adherents of the Mercantile System was owing, without doubt, to their very superior util- ity as money ; for we very frequently find that the adherents of that school insist that the precious metals must circulate. (See § 9 and § 210.) v. Schroder, Fiirstl. Schatz - und Rentkammer, 1 1 1 f., considers new copper coins as an increase of the national wealth, but not other copper which is merely a commercial commodity. He frequently calls money, the pendulum aommercii, and expresses ideas concerning it as enthusiastic as they are ob- scure (p. 86.) Horncch, in his Oesterreich iiber Alles w-enn es will, 1864, calls gold and silver " our best blood, the very marrow of our sti-ength," and " the t\v;o most indispensable universal instruments of human activity and existence." (p. iSS.) Th. Mun, England's Treasure by forraign Trade, 1664, (ch. 2) considers cash-money and resources as synonymous in every way. Only, he says (ch. 4) that it is sometimes advisable to allow one's money to remain in foreign countries, and to use bills of exchange, banks etc., at home, as a substitute, y. Gee, Trade and Commerce of Gr. Britain, edition of 173S, laments the " stift'-necked folly of those who think money a commodity like any other." It is one of the most common demands of the adherents of the Mercantile System that the home mines of gold and silver should be v/orked at no matter what sacrifice, since the money employed in working them con- tinues to remain in the country and the newly coined precious metal is clear gain. Compare Schroder, loc. cit. 109 ff., 181. Ilorncck; loc. cit. 173. Brog- gia, Delia Monete, 1743, cap. 33; v. Justi, Staaatswirthschaft, I755, I, 246: Forbonnais, Finances de France, 175S, I, 14S. Ulloa, Noticias Americanas, 1772, ch. 12. We seldom meet -with the correct view on this subject in the seventeenth century. Sully, of whom Henry IV. said that he never found anything to be possessed of beauty which cost double its real value, had it at 34i CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. Ill, which has for the time being the greatest circulating capacity. If to this be added the sanction of the government, and if the times. (Economies royales, LXXIII.) So had v. Seckendorff, Teutscher Fiirstenstaat, 1655, 5th edition. It is in accordance with the usual course of human development that the exaggerations of the Mercantile System led to a reaction characterized by an exaggeration in the opposite direction. Even Davanzati, Sulle Monete, 15SS, traces the value of money back to human convention and refuses to find it in nature. A natural calf, he thinks, is ^iu nobile than a golden one ; al- though he elsewhere expresses his admiration of the precious metals, calls them ca^ioni seconde delta vita beata, and lauds them because they procure us tutVessi bent (20, 21, Cust.) Montanari (ob., 1687) demonstrates from the use of leather money etc., that the authority of the state is the only power which gives money its character as money. (Delia Moneta, 35.) Davenant (ob., 1714) carries his inclination to call money "the servant of trade, meas- ure of trade," so far as to compare it to a ticket or counter. (Works, I, 355, 444.) Strongly as Laiv^ himself, opposes the convention theory (Trade and Money, ch. i; Sur 1' Usage des Monnaies, 1720, p. 1.), his disciple Dutot, in his Reflexions polit. sur le Commerce et les Finances, 1738, 905, ed. Daire, contrasts not only paper money but also gold and silver as repre- sentative wealth, with real wealth. Berkeley, Querist, 1735, teaches that the real notion of money is not that of a " commodity, standard, measure, pledge, but [No. 23] ticket or counter, entitling to power and fitted to record and transfer such power." (441,475.) Even if the names, //we, shilling etc., remain, and the metal is dropped, evei-y article may still as well as before be counted and sold, industry promoted and the course of commerce preserved. (p. 440.) According to Montesquieu, Esprit des Lois, XXI, 22, gold and sil- ver are a ricliesse de fctiott ou de signe. Compare Lettres persanes, II, 18. Benjamin Franklin also maintains that the value of gold, for instance, is principally a credit-value. Remarks relative to the American Paper-Money, 1765, Works, II, Sparks' edition. Forhomiais, Finances de France, I, 86 f, calls money, simply a means to put commodities, which alone have value origmally, in circulation. Hence it is, in itself, a matter of indifierence whether, for a given quantity of coin, a person gives one thaler, or ten. In the Elements de Commerce, I, 11, II, 67 ff., he draws a distinction between richesses naturelles (raw material), artificicllcs (manufactured products), and ricliesses de convention (money.) von Schlozer, Aufangsgriinde, 1805, 100, 138, calls money somethmg imagined; and Th. Smith, Essay on the Theory' of Money and Exchange, 1807, asserts, that true money is only an ideal ineasure of value, of which coins in turn are only the representatives. Compare, however, Edinb. Review, Oct., 1808. Oppe7iheim, Die Natur des Geldes, 1855, grants that in the beginnings of trade, money possessed the character of a commodity; but says tliat as soon as the services of circula- Sec. CXVI.] INSTRUMENT OF EXCHANGE. 345 government itself recognizes this same " universal commodity" as the means of payment of all debts, or as " legal tender" tion of the money-commodity prevailed over its services in consumption, it lost all its importance for the latter purpose, and that all relations dependent thereon ceased. At present, he claims money is only the representative of commodities, but no commodity itself. See, on the other hand, Roscher's critical analysis in the Literarisches Centralblatt, 1855, December. The true doctrine was advocated in a classic form by Nicolaiis Oresmiiis (ob. 13S2). See his Tractatus dc Origine et Jure nee non ct Ivlutationibus Monetarum, newly edited by Wolov:ski: Paris, 1864. See Roscher^s essay in the Comptes rendus of the Acadvimie des Sciences morales et politiques, vol. dz^ 435 If. Based on the latter we have Gabr. Bid (ob. 1495), Dc Monetarum Potestate simul et Utilitate, 1542, and G. Agricola^ De Re metallica, 1556, I, 4 fi. This true doctrine was acclimated earliest in England and Holland, and before the mercantile system invaded them. Compare Ilobbes, Leviathan, 24, in which the concoctio honorum is described by means of money, and the full and clear. chapter I3 of Salmasius, De Usuris (1630J, who, among other things, shows how Midas, who turned everything into bread, died of thirst. Petty shows very clearly that national wealth does not consist exclusively nor mainly in money. Every country, he says, needs a certain quantity of money to carry on trade. It would be a waste to increase the former, the latter remaining the same. But the precious metals, by reason of their dura- bility and universally recognized value, possess the character of wealth in a higher degree than other commodities. On the whole, the use of money in a nation is like the use of fat in the individual. (Quantulumcunquc concerning Money, 1682.) Compare Rosdicr, z. Geschichte der eng. Volkswirthschaftslehre, 80 f. Davanzati and Hobbes had compared it to the blood, as has recently Schmitthennery Staatswissen- schaften, 1839, I, 459. North calls money a commodity of which there may be an excess as well as a want. (Discourse on Trade, preface and postscript.) Compare Locke, Considerations on the Lowering of Interest, 1691, Works II, 13 ff., 19. Galiaiit, 1750, Delia Moneta, IV, holds a very happy middle place between the alchymists and the philosophic contemners of gold. See, further, ^uesnaj, id. Daire, 64, 75 if. Ttirgot, Sur la Formation des Richesses, § 30 fF., had many clear views on this subject. Verri, Meditazioni, 1771, II, I, calls money the universally current commodity. The expressions, meas- ure of value, pledge, representative of all commodities might be true also of all other wares. It cannot, however, be denied that most modern political economists have not borne sufficiently in mind the peculiarities which dis- tinguish money from all other commodities, as is apparent from the doctrine of the balance of trade prevalent in Hume's and Adam Smith's time. To this extent, therefore, the semi-mercantilistic reaction instituted by Gatitl/i, Thdorie de I'Economie politique, 2822, II, 380 fF., 426; St. C/iamaus, N. Essai 3^6 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. III. (puissance liheratoire)^ where no other is expressly agreed upon, the "universal commodity" in question then becomes money in the fullest sense of the idea conveyed by the word.® sur la Richesse des Nations, 1824,011.3; and Colton, Public Economy for the United States, 1849, 203 ff., who bring into relief the difference between "money as the subject" and "money as the instrument of trade," was not wholly unfounded. Ad. MUller exaggerates a correct thought, and causes it to degenerate into a species of mystic pleasantry, when he calls every in- dividual in the state and every commodity that possesses value, in exchange or a social character, money. The highest object of the state is to develop this money-character more and more. (Elemente der Staatskunst, II, 194, 199.) The statesman, he says, should be money. (Ill, 206.) A very valuable monograph on this subject is M. Chevalier's De la Monnaie, 1850, constituting the third volume of his Cours d' Economic polititique. Knies^ Geld und Credit, 1, 1873, is here most thorough and acute, especially in keeping separate, by well defined lines of demarcation, the five different functions of money : measure of value (bv proper division into parts: price-measure), instrument of exchange, means of transportation of values, and means of storing up and preserving values. 3 Knies shows how the making of money legal tender by the state, al- though of only secondary importance, is by no means an irrelevant matter, since persons must then have it, even if they do not want it for purposes of use or exchange, to discharge their liabilities thereby etc., etc. (Tiibinger, Zetschrift, 1858, 272.) In all these cases, barter-economy (Naturalwirthschaft) meets with greater and greater difficulties as civilization advances. How, for instance, could 50 days annually of socage-service or labor be redeemed by the achievement at one time of 1,000 days of socage-service or labor.? The rich man requires money principally as a means of payment, the poor man as a medium of ex- change. The requirement or need of a people of media of payment is much more susceptible of extension or contraction, than thai of media of exchange, made especially so by the intervention of claim-rights instead of mone}'. (KnieSy loc. cit., 200 ff.) Ravit, Beitr. z. Lehre, vom Gelde, emphasizes this feature of money altogether too much after the manner of a jurist. But he is entirely right in adopting the exclusion of the rei vindicatio against the honest possessor as necessary to the completion of the idea of money. Sec. CXVII.] INTRODUCTION OF MONEY. 347 SECTION CXVII. EFFECT OF THE INTRODUCTION OF MONEY. By the introduction of money, most exchanges are divided into two halves: purchase and sale.^ We may also say with Schlozer, that by its means, exchange, for the first time, be- comes a sale, and obscure value in exchange, clear and defi- nite price. (Permatio vidua emtioni). Were there no money, the party to an exchange, occupying the most advantageous economic position, would possess a much greater superiority over the other than he does now. Many a bread-buyer, espe- cially, would be half starved before he could agree with the seller on the quantity of bread to be received in exchange for the commodity he had to dispose of. The producer of the means of subsistence would here possess an extreme advant- age, since the urgent necessity of the exchange for the one party, and the power of the other to postpone it, would make the determination of the price an entirely arbitrary matter.'* Hence, the development of money as the instrument of trade, keeps pace with the development of individual liberty. Pay- ment of wages in money makes the workman more responsible for his husbandry etc., but at the same time, freer, than payment in produce. Now, also, a higher division of labor becomes pos- sible; for the easier it is to obtain everything else for money, the easier it is for each person to devote himself exclusively to one branch of business.^ Without money, too, only ready '^ Sismondi, N. P., I, 131, very rightly remarks that this has made practice as much easier as it has theory more difficult. 'Zaw, Trade and Money, 19. Hence, before the invention of money, scarcely anything but the things most indispensable to existence were pro- duced. Were there no money, there would be very few scholars, artists etc.; for the classes who produce most of the things indispensable to existence make but few demands for them. BuscJi, Gcldumlauf, I, 11 fl'., 36, II, 54. ' Turgot.^ Formation et Distribution, § 4S fF. Commodities which perish rapidly could be produced by persons devoting themselves to their production 348 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. III. commodities could be exchanged one against another. Only when money has become the instrument of trade, is it possible to separate the net from the gross returns, and, therefore, to manage income properly. (Sdmffle). Now, also, it becomes for the first time really remunerative to produce more than one needs for his own use, and to save. Without money, the owner of any one kind of capital, who could not employ it himself, would be obliged, if he desired to loan it, to find not only a person who was in need of capital, but one who needed the very kind of capital he had. For instance, the person who had one horse too many, would be obliged to look for another who was in need of one etc. And how difficult a task it would be to determine the amount of interest, if it had to be paid in pro- duce or kind, and even to make a return in produce or kind of capital which had been presumably used. (Storch). Moveable property or resources can attain importance only after the in- troduction of good money, since, previous to such introduction, it was by reason of its great variety,^ and of its perishable na- ture, immensely inferior to landed property. Hence it is, that money, in a nation's economy, is what the blood is in the life of the animal. It is, so to speak, the common reservoir in which all food is first dissolved, and by which, at a later stage, the elements of nutrition and preservation are distributed to the several organs.^ There is, indeed, no machine which has as a business only after the invention of small coin. (Lueder, N. CEk., 1820, 283.) ^ Compare Kntcs, Geld imd Credit, I, 219. ^Compare Schmitthenner, loc. cit., I, 457. One of the principal advantages of money consists in this, that every producer can discover what there is an over-supply or under-supply of in the nation, by means of the relation of the price in money of his products to the cost of producing them, estimated in money, (v. Thiinen^ Isolirte Staat., II, 2, 235.) ^ Hence it is that so many socialists attack money TJi. More assures us that with the simple abolition of money, vice and misery would, for the most part, disappear of themselves. Hence in his Utopia, criminals are bound in golden chains and the chamber-pots are made of gold and silver in order to make these metals contemptible. (Ed. 1555, if., 197 if.) Similar views among Sec. CXVII.] INTRODUCTION OF MONEY. 349 saved as much labor as money. (Lauderdale). It is true that the shadows which wealth is wont to cast, extravagance, av- arice and inequality of every kind, may readily grow longer and darker in consequence of the introduction of money.*^ But may not the knife which, in the hands of the surgeon, does so much for life, become an instrument of danger in the hands of a child ? The invention of money has been rightly compared to the invention of writing with letters.' We may, however, call the introduction of money as the universal medium of ex- change (money-economy),^ in which goods intended for use are exchanged against money ^ — instead of barter (barter econ- omy), which is a system of public economy (Sch'dffie)^ in an, as yet, very little developed form, man being there less socia- the over-cultured Romans. (Compare § § 79, 204.) Auri sacra fames. Vir- gil^ ^neid, III, 56. Pliny, too, -would recall the days of trade by barter. (H. N., XXXIII, 3.) Even in Botsguillcbcri, Factum de la France, ch. 4, we find, together with many con-ect views on the nature of money, passionate decla- mation against it because of its darker side. Argent criminel. (Detail de la France, 7. Dissertation sur la Nature des Richesses etc.) More recently this darker side has been dwelt upon by F. Moser, Patriot. Phant., I, 2S; Ortcs, Economia nazionale, II, 17, and the would-be restorer of the middle ages, Ad. MiiUer. While the latter writer lauds the feudal system as a " sublime fusion of person and thing " (Elemente I, 221), the present system of wages, because it is a system of compensation, he blames, and prefers the feudal for the opposite reason ( .'). " The only merit which the state recognizes in our day is one of serviee." (Ill, 259.) Kosegarten^ Geschichtliche systematische, Uebersicht der N. Oek., 1856, 146 ff., is no friend to the economic system to which money gives a distinctive character. Per contra., compare Bastiaty Maudit Argent, 1849. "^Mirabeau, Philosophie rurale, 1763, ch. 2, adds as the third great inven- tion the tableau 4conomiqiie of the Physiocrates. For a comparison of money and language, see Hamann, Werke, II, 135 ff., 509. Ile/iti, Kulturpflan- zen und Hausthiere, finds it characteristic of the race, that wine, writing with letters, and money, all owe their origin to the monotheistic stem of the Sem- itic people. 8 Where every man becomes a merchant, and the society itself a commer- cial society. Ad. Stnitk, Wealth of Nations, I, ch. 4. "Just as descriptive is the German word billig (equitable) for cheap. Here it is plain that language takes sides with the possessor of money ! 350 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. III. ble with his fellow men — one of the greatest and most be- neficent advances ever made by the race.^° '"The contrastbetween barter-economy and money-economy is of great and fundamental importance. It repeats itself with so much regularity in the his- tory of every highly developed nation, that political economists gifted with perception for the historical, could not possibly overlook it. Thus, Arisiotle, for instance, establishes with the utmost care and accuracy the difference between OCXOUO^ixh and yoT^tjiatKTTCXTJ, that is, between natural economy and artificial economy, corresponding to the difference between value in use and value in exchange. (Polit., I, 3, Schn.) Similarly Z>. Hume, who allows a period of luxury, culture, industry, of trade and manufactures, of freedom and circulation of money, to be preceded by one in which the feeling of wants is not awakened, in which coarseness and idleness prevail, one in which agriculture is alone pursued, and monetary economy and freedom decline, and trade by barter obtains. (Discourses, passim, especially On Interest and on Money.) A similar contrast we find frequently, and as one of his fundamental thoughts, in J^. Steuart. As to how the transition from barter-economy to monetary-economy is generally effected, see J. G. Hoffmann, Lehre vom Gelde, 1S3S, 176 ff. In the Tvrol, as late as 1820, the greater portion of purely mechanical work, such as that of the smith, the carpenter, and the washerwoman, were purely feudal duties. On the other hand, payment in money was the rule, in the beginning of the fourteenth century. (J. Beidermanv, Technische Bildung in Oesterreich, 3.) Yet, for a long time after, the functions of a measure of value were performed by pieces of. land, and those of an instrument of ex- change by cattle and natural products. (Arnold, Gesch. des Eigenth., 207.) In France, money-economy, i. e., trade by money, had grown to importance earlier. ("iViVic//., Ministerialitat und Biirgerthiuu, im 11. und 12. Jahr., 143.) Even in the time of Mary Stuart, the Scotch estimated the rent of land in "cauldrons of victuals." (Moryson, Itinerary, 1617, III, 155.) In ancient Italy, during the first three centuries of Rome, there was, with the exception of the Greek colonies, only trade by barter. Mommsen, Romische Gesch., I, 293, shows that the oldest ases were not money in the higher sense of the word, but belonged rather to the stage of barter-economy. On the other hand, we find in the time of the classic jurists, much as slavery had limited the sphere of action of money, the principle : pecunicB nomine non solum nu- merata fecunia, scd omnes res, tarn soli quam mobiles, et tarn corpora qua?n j ura coiitincntur. (L. 222, Digest L. 16; compare 4,5, 178.) Similarly in Cicero, Top. 6. De Invent., II, 21. De Legg, II, 19, 2I; III, 3. Compare Diofiys. Hal, N. R. IV, 15. Sec. CXVIII.J DIFFERENT KINDS OF MONEY. $f,l SECTION CXVIII. THE DIFFERENT KINDS OF MONEY. Very different kinds of commodities have, according to cir- cumstances, been used as money; but uniformly only such as jDOssess a universally recognized economic value.^ On the whole, people in a low stage of civilization are wont to employ, mainly, only ordinary commodities, such as are calculated to satisfy a vulgar and urgent want, as an instrument of ex- change. As they advance in civilization, they, at each step, choose a more and more costly object, for this purpose,^ and one which ministers to the more elevated wants. ' Were money nothing but a measure of values in exchange, it should on that account, if on no other, have value in exchange itself, as a measure of length must necessarily have length itself. (We measure time on a clock by means of the revolution of the hands on the dial.) Again, value in exchange supposes value in use. The so-called "money of account," such as the East Indian lac de rouptes, the Portuguese reis, and the earlier English found sterling are no imaginary magnitudes, which would disappear with the figures of our system of counting (see Hufclattd, N. Grundlegung, II, 33, in reply to Struensec, Abh., Ill, 501); but real coin-values which can not he represented by only single pieces of coin, units of value for the most part no longer recognized by the state, but which the people still retain. See M. Parkas (Travels, 27) refutation of the fable circulated by Montesquieu, Esprit des Lois, XXII, 8, that the regular standard money of the Mandingo negroes was a mere imaginary standard. Ilobbes, Leviathan, 24, exhibits a very good knowledge of this subject. 2 Compare P. Neri, Osservazioni, 1751, VI, i. Lord LiverJ>ool, Treatise on the Coins of the Realm, 1S05. The person who takes money as such must always harbor the hope of being able to dispose of it again as money. Hence, such an acceptance always supposes the existence of a certain amount of commercial confidence. The savage Goahiros, between Rio de la Hacha and Maracaibo, are too " distrustful " to take anything in trade but commod- ities fit for the most immediate use. (Depons, Voyage dans la Terrefirme, I, 314-) Similarly in the twelfth century, the heathen Laplanders. (Arndt, Liefl. Chronik, II, 3.) Commodities which barbarians can consume imme- diately are objects of the first necessity, whereas more civilized people, who are in a condition to undergo greater expense, look more to the technic quali- ities of money, such as divisibility, capacity for transportation and durabil- 352 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Cii. III. A. Races of hunters, at least in non-tropical countries, usually use skins as money; that is the almost exclusive pro- duct of their labor, one which can be preserved for a long period of time, vv^hich constitutes their principal article of clothing and their principal export in the more highly devel- oped regions.^ B. Nomadic races and the lower agricultural races,* pass, by a natural gradation, to the use of cattle as money; which supposes rich pasturages at the disposal of all. If it were otherwise, there would be a great many to whom payments ity. V. Schecl shows in a very happy manner how, as commerce increases, money comes to be, as it were, subjected to a process resembling that of dis- tillation: first mere increase of stores for use, next preponderating values in exchange, lastl}' mere orders for the same possessing no independent value. (Hildebrnnd^s Jahrbb., 1866, 1, 16. 2 The last circumstance continues to be one of great importance for a long period of time in the frigid zones. Thus, the beaver-skin continues still to be the unit of measure of trade in much of the territory of the Hudson Bay Company. Three martens are estimated to be equal in value to one beaver, one white fox to two beavers, one black fox or a bear to four beavers, a rifle to fifteen beavers. (Ausland, 1S46, No. 21.) The Esthonian word, raha, money, means in the related language of the Laplanders, fur. (Krug, 2ur Miinzkunde Russlands, 1805.) Concerning skin-money in the middle age of Russia, see JVcsfoi; Sclilozcr^s translation. III, 90. The old word kttng, money, means marten. By degrees it came to pass that instead of wliole skins, only two " snouts "were given or other pieces of leather about a square inch in size, which were probably stamped by the government and redeemed in whole skins at the government magazines. Hence, there is here supposed a species of assignats, and of disturbances of credit. The Mongolian con- querors would not recognize them, and they therefore became suddenly val- ueless. In Novgorod and Pskow, the system continued some time longer, for the reason that these places had little trade with the Mongols. In the rest of the kingdom it now became necessary to iatroduce silver money, and in the north to return to real squirrel and beaver skins. Karamsin^ Russ. Gesch., I, 203, 3S5; I, 96, 191 f. Voyage de Rubruquis, in Bergeron^ Voy- ages I, 91. Hcrbcrstem, Rer. moscov. Commentt., 58 if. Even in 1610, a Russian military chest was captured by the enemy, and in it were found 5450 silver rubles, and 7000 fur rubles. (Karamsin^ XI, 183.) •* When the Danes progressed so far as to practice agriculture, they used grain instead of cattle, in quantities corresponding to the value of one cow or one sheep, for money, to the end that their idea of a unit of measure might not become obscured. (Ravit, Beitrage, 3.) Sec. CXVIII.] DIFFERENT KINDS OF MONEY. 353 of this kind had been made, who would not know what to do with the cattle given them, on account of the charges for their maintenance.^ 'Homeric determination of prices in oxen. Iliad, II, 449; VI, 236; XXI, 79; XXIII, 703 ff; Odyss., I, 431. Compare, however, II, VII, 473 ff. In Draco's time, money-fines were imposed in cattle (Pollux, IX, 60 ft"), and in Athens, before Solon's time, even the metal coins were, for the most part, stamped with the figure of an ox. Plutarch, Theseus, 25. Bockh., Metr. Uuntcrsuch., 121 ft". Among the most ancient Romans (Cicero, de Rep., II, 35) the imposition of fines in property, the coins first stamped by Servius, bourn pviumque effigie (Plin., H. N., XVIII, 3, Cassiodor., Var., VII, 32), and the words j>ecunia, peculium, feculatus, derived from fecus, point to some- thing analogous. (Varro, De L. L., V, 19; De Re rust., II, i; Cicero, De Rep., 11,9; Ovid, Fast, V, 2S1; Plutarch, Publicola, 11.) Old German fines in cattle, in Tacitus, Germ., 12, 21; Lex Ripuar, 36, 11; Lex Saxonum, 19. Ulfilas translates aoyuoiOV doovo.l (Marl; 14, 11), faihu gibaii. Very old German documents, of the seventh and eighth centuries, name horses as purchase-price. (Grimm, Deutsche Rechtsalterth., 586 f.) Otho the Great imposed cattle-fines. (Widuk Corb., II, 6.) Similarly, in King Stephen's laws of Hungary (Wachsmuth, Europaische Sitturgesch., II), in the old Irish Brehon laws (Leland, History of Ireland, 36 ft".), as well as in the Scotch collection of laws, Regiam Majestatem,oi 1330. (Honard, II, 263 f, 537.) Fz"f«/^c?ndl ^&i'& equal in value to one milch cow or six inilch sheep, or two and a half ounces of silver. (Leo in Raiaiicr^s histor. Taschenbuch, 1835, 515.) That the ancient northern mode of valuation, by the Vadhmdl and in cows is older than by the markis shown by Wilda, Gesch. des deutschen Strafrechts, I, 331. The cod-fish money used by the Icelanders was, on account of its great commer- cial importance as an article of export, an advance upon the use of the Vadhmdl. Among the CafRrs, besides cauris, mats, javelins, glass corals, but particularly brass rings, are used as money. From three to four hundred of these rings arc strung together, and two such strings are equal in value to one cow. (Klemm, Kulturgeschichte, III, 308, 320 f.) Ivory used as money in the neighborhood of the Portuguese colonies in Africa. (Martins, Reise, II, 670.) In Logone, Dc7iham (1822) if., had met with pieces of iron as a medium of circulation; but on the other hand, Barth (1849), with small strips of cotton from 2 to 3 inches in breadth, and shirts for larger sums. (A. R., Ill, 274, 297, 53S.) In colonies, money of this nature is continued for a long time. Thus cod-fish used in Newfoundland, sugar in the English 358 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Cn. III. cultivated nations ^ as the instrument of exchange, depends on the greatness and uniformity of their value in exchange, but especially on their durability and pliancy as to form. This value in exchange is great, because their beauty, which consists in their luster and their sonorous ring,^ gives them great value in use ; and because, at the same time, their rarity in nature makes the supply of them relatively small,^ and not susceptible of increase at pleasure.* As they contain so large West Indies (Adam Smithy I, ch. 4), tobacco in Maryland and Virginia. (Douglas^ V, 2, 389; Ebeling, V, 435 ff.) The last was related to the inspec- tion and storage of the tobacco intended for exportation. Payment was made in orders on the stored and inspected tobacco, even as late as the end of the eighteenth century. In 1618, the forced circulation of tobacco was decreed in Virginia, and under severe penalties. (Gouge, Histoiy of Paper- Money and Banking in the United States, ch. i.) ' When the caravans no longer touched at the oasis Agades, gold and sil- ver money fell into disuse, and grain, stuffs etc. did service as instruments of circulation. (Barih, Reisen und Endeckungen, I, 144.) ^ Ad. Miiller says very pertinently, but in a very inystical vein, that the precious metals combine in a very high degree and yet in a very simple man- ner, the principal qualities in which man's greatness finds expression : rarity, flexibility, uniformity, mobility, durability and beauty. (Elemente, II, 266.) In another place, he says, the highest ideal good is God, the highest material good, gold! (111,65.) The mysticism of gold was most highly developed am.ong the alchymists of the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries. ' Iron beds are worked only when they contain at least iS per cent, of metal. Generally it is estimated that the furnace should yield 30 per cent. In the copper inines of Mansfield, Norway, Agordo and Venice, it goes as low as from one to three per cent. On the other hand, silver inines which yield 0.17 per cent, of metal are considered worth working. Lastly, gold is so rare that generally it can be extracted only from time to time by the oi'dinary mining processes. As a rule, men are content to gather it where nature has charged itself with its refining. The extreme limit of the working of gold appears, according to Plattner and Haussmarm, at Goslar, to be reached when in 5,200,000 parts of mineral earth there is one of gold. Spite of this, however, by reason of their great ductility, the precious metals have been able to pen- etrate even into the meanest huts in one form or another. It has been esti- mated that a silver leaf may be attenuated by beating to a thickness of only o.ooooi of an inch, and a gold leaf to 0.0000035 of an inch. An ounce of gold spread on a silver thread may attain a length of 13,000 English miles. (Mc- Culloch.) * How easily, for instance, could leather-money, such as was used by the Sec. CXX.] THE PRECIOUS METALS. 359 a value in so small a volume, they are adapted to transporta- tion from one place to another, with but little difficulty — a matter of the greatest importance in an instrument of ex- change.^ Hence, it is much easier to keep the demand for them and the supply of them at a level all over the world, than it is the demand and supply of most other commodities. And this all the more as there are not dilierent kinds of gold and silver, but only different qualities of their fineness.^ It also contributes to the uniformity of their value in exchange, that they minister mainly only to wants of luxury. The most indispensable commodities are subject to the greatest varia- ancient Galls (Cassiodor.^ Varia, II, 32,) be increased to any desired quan- tity, and thus its price brought down. ^ Engcl^ at the usual tariff for land and railroad freight (10 and 5 ffomigs per inile and hundredths of a mile) estimates the enhancement of the price of the following commodities, for one mile of transportation of a custom- hundred-weight (ZoHcefitjier) at the following percentage of their average value : Commodities. Value, fcr civf. By Land. Railroad. German lieichsthaler. Gold, - - - 47610 0.000007 0.0000035 Silver, - - - 3000 o.oom 0.00055 Cotton, - - - 45 0.074 0.037 Tin, - - - - 0.1389 0.0694 Lead, - - - 8 0.416 0.20S Iron, - - - 2-S 1-333 0.666 Rye, - - - 2 1.666 0.833 Potatoes, - - 0.6 5-S.SS 2-777 Coal, - - - 0.12 27.777 13.8S8 Then- great specific gravity, also, makes the precious inetals easy of trans- portation. Thus Cazeau calculates that a given value of gold is 17,223 times as easy to transport as the same value in wheat. But as, where the weight is the same, the labor of transportation is inversely as the volume, this num- ber must be multiplied by 26, and we therefore have 447,773 times. In the case of silver, the relation to wheat is as i : 15,554. Concerning copper, see Siorch, Ilandbuch i, 48S. Chevalier, Cours, III, 17 ff. 6 This, at bottom, is also true, of the various kinds of copper; only, here, complete refining is impracticable on account of the relation between the cost of production and the product-price. 360 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. III. tions in price (see § 103), whereas, in the case of the precious metals, the diversity of uses to which they may be turned contributes greatly to render their value, as instruments of ex- change, more equable. If the supply of them be small, gold and silver vessels are less in demand; a part of the old ones are melted down, and vice versa. In durability, the precious metals surpass almost all other commodities. They are not at all affected by air or water, and they can be corroded only by very few fluids. Fire may, indeed, change their form, but scarcely in any degree the value of the material of gold, and that of silver very little, and then only when it is subjected to a very powerful blast or draught of air. '^ ^ Hence, while by laying them by, they sufier virtually nothing at all (a most valuable article is an article to deposit savings in), their wear and tear from use may be very much decreased by an admixture with other metals in the proper proportion.^ This durability contributes largely to keep the price of the precious metals more uniform. By the time that the wheat crop is rightly harvested, the great bulk of the previously stored wheat is, as a rule, consumed; and, therefore, the supply of wheat depends almost entirely on ' On the other hand, copper, and still more zinc, tin and lead lose much of their value in the fire. Pearls may lose their entire value by fire, and dia- monds more than half of it. '^ Aqua-regia, a mixture of nitric and muriatic acid, dissolves gold. Chlo- rine and bromine attack it. It has been noticed to vaporize at a very high temperature. A gold thread vaporizes when a strong electric current is passed through it. A small ball of gold gives off a great deal of vapor if placed between two carbon points and subjected to the action of a powerful galvanic pile. (K. F. Nmimajin.) ^ Compare HatcJieti, Experiments and Observations of the various Alloys, On the specific Gravity and comparative Weight of Gold, 1863. The French five-franc pieces wear away, on an average, in a year, 0.00016; the English crown, o.oooiS; the half crown, about 0.00173; and the shilling, about 0.00456. (L. Liverpool, Treatise on the Coins, 204; M. Chevalier, Cours, III, 12S if.) The wear fron> use of the south German gulden is 0.292 per 1,000. (JRau, in the Archiv. N. F. X, 256.) According to yacob, the average wear of coin is 2.38 per 1,000. (Historical Inquiry into the Production and Consumption of the Precious Metals, ch. 23.) Sec. CXX.] THE PRECIOUS METALS. 361 the yield of the last crop. On the other hand, it is probable that there is many a piece of money, the raw material of which was dug from Thracian gold mines in the time of King Philip or from tlie silver mines of Spain during the reign of Hannibal, in circulation to-day. Compared with the immeasurable stores of gold and silver which have gone on accumulating for thou- sands of 3'ears, the new yield of them, in any one year, is lost like a drop in a bucket. Hence, only w4ien the yield of the mines has continued for a very long time, or when it is exceedingly great or remarkably small, can the price of their products change to any great extent.^° Even during the revolution in prices, between 1492 and 1560, the yearly decline in their prices was only one-half of one per cent, per annum. Their great pliability of form has, too, very important ad- vantages for our purpose: first, that they can be divided very accurately into very small parts, and that the volume of every part corresponds exactly to the value of the part ; ^^ and sec- ondly, that they take an impression at very little cost, an im- pression which is an authoritative and trustworthy expression of their weight and quality, thus saving the commercial public the perilous trouble of weighing and testing them every time they are used. ^^^^^'' This duty the state, as a rule, assumes. ^^ Adam Smith, Wealth of Nations, I, ch. 11, Digr. '^^ Solera, Sur les Valueurs, 1785, 271 ff. : Custodi. Half an ox, for instance, is worth half the value of a whole one only for a few well defined purposes. As to how much the value of the diamond varies with the size etc., see Du- frenoy, Traite de Mineralogie, II, 77 f. On the other hand, the separated parts of a piece of metal are verj' readily reduced to a whole. '^ In the case of the ox, it is impossible to imagine a mark which might not be eluded by its losing flesh. 13 The cost of coinage since 1849 has been 3/ of i per cent, in the case of silver, and in that of gold not quite 2 per 1,000. (M. Chevalier, Cours, III, no.) '* Platinum possesses many of the properties necessary to an instrument of exchange in as high a degree as gold and silver, — great value in exchange, great specific gravity and great durability. On the other hand, its pliability as to form is very small, and therefore the cost of coining it would be high. The conversion of platinum coins into utensils, and of utensils into coin, 3(52 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Cn. III. (Coinage.) When its authority, however, is not recognized, as is generally the case in international trade, gold and silver bars are even now used, and have, therefore, to be weighed and tested. ^^ ^"^ ■svliich would contribute to the supply of money when needed, and to a diminution of that supply when the demand decreased, would be much more difficult on this account; and also because of the small degree of beauty possessed by that metal, which renders it little adapted to purposes of luxury. Under these circumstances, the rarity in nature of the metal is a great draw- back ; for the discovery of a new mine would create a great perturbation in prices. For this reason, the Russian platinum coins have been generally very much undervalued since 1S2S in the commercial world, and the whole experiment was given up in 1845-46.. Compare J. ScJion, National OEkono- mie, 1 28 ff. Aluminum, discovered by Wohler, and which can be prepared from argillaceous earth, is capable of manipulation in a very high degree (malUable et ductile d feu prhs sans limite^ excessivetnent fusible), almost as in- destructible as the precious metals, but easily distinguished from silver by a fine bluish color, which has been compared to that of tin; by its small spe- cific gravity, from 2.5 to 2.67, and its ring like that of iron. Hence it is very doubtful whether aluminum can be made to play the part of a substitute for silver, and still more so whether it can be used for coining. 15 Lingot, bullion. In India, beyond the Ganges, and in China, bars are very much used. (Sycee.) In the latter country, besides these bars, there is no coinage except that of a mixture of copper and lead, for small change. (Th. Smith, An attempt to define some of the first Principles of Political Economy, 31. Timkoxuski, Reise nach China, III, 366.) Concerning Bra- zilian trade by bars, see Sj>ix und Afartius, Reise, I, 346 f. They are stamped with the national coat of arms, the sign of the mint, the number by which registered, that of the year and of the degree of fineness. Concerning the Persian bars, the laries, see Noback, Handbuch der Munzverrh., Ill, Taf. 29. '* Concerning the utility of the precious metals for purposes of money, see Pliny, A. N. XXXIII, 3 ; Oresniius, De Mutatione Monetarum, ch. 2 ; La-w, Sur r Usage des Monnaies, 683 f. Daire, where we read that before the in- vention of money, silver had served all kinds of useful purposes, but that now it served its most important purpose, namely the making of the best material for money on many accounts. Yet Law's book. Money and Trade considered (1705) is based mainly on the idea that pieces of land are much better adapted for purposes of money than the precious metals (185)! Galliani, Delia Moneta, 1750, I, 3, 4, and P. Ncri, Osservazioni, 1751 ft"., Cust., have very correct ideas on this subject. Sec. CXXI.] VALUE IN USE AND EXCHANGE. 363 SECTION CXXI. VALUE IN USE AND VALUE IN EXCHANGE OF MONEY. The original value in use of the precious metals, to satisfy certain wants of luxury in the most esthetic and the most sub- stantial manner, continues still; but with the advance of civ- ilization, the employment of gold and silver for this purpose has fallen farther and farther behind the more recent employ- ment of these metals as the best material for money. And since now the services rendered by money may be divided into two classes: storing up or preservation, and the transmission (division, concentration) of values,^ the former always plays a greater part in the earlier states of the development of trade by money ; and the latter plays the larger part in the later stages of the same development. We may best compare money to the other machines or instruments of commerce.^ The person who, in times when there is a< dearth of goods, and especially of capital, complains of a want of money, com- mits the same error as if he ascribed a scarcity or absence of grain, when it exists, to a too small number of wagons to carry it, or to the narrowness of country highways. The inference may, indeed, be sometimes well-founded, but certainly only by way of exception ; and yet it is generally the first which politi- ' North, Discourses upon Trade, i6. The capacity of money to act as a storer of wealth has been as much over-estimated by the so called Mercantile System, as its capacity to transfer wealth has been by the so called currency- school. * Adam StKtth compares money to a large wheel, by means of which a due share of the means of subsistence and of enjoyment is distributed to each member of society. Elsewhere he compares its utility to streets and roads. (Wealth of Nations, II, ch. 2.) Hume, On Money, Pr., prefers to compare it to the oil with which the wheels of circulation are greased. Sisiiiondi com- pares money to porters. (N. Principes, II, ch. 2.) " Money is to commerce what railways are to locomotion, a contrivance to diminish friction." (y. S. Mill.) According to Schmitthenner, 455, it bears the same relation to other commodities that the written language of a people's literature does to their dialects. 364 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Cii. III. co-economical quacks think of in practice.^ Like all tools or instruments, money constitutes a part of an individual's of a nation's, or of the world's capital. Considered from the point of view of private business or economy, money is circulating capital, but from the point of view of the world's economy, it is fixed capital.* ^Latv's views on money are, in part, excellent. Thus, for instance, he says that the debasement of the coin from financial necessity is as great a folly as it would be to try to enlarge a piece of goods too small for the pur- pose for which it was intended, by diminishing the length of the yard-stick. (Sur rUsage des Monnaies, 697.) A country entirely isolated from all others could get along as well with one hundred pounds sterling as with a million. (Money and Trade, p. 8S.) Elsewhere, he confounds money and capital to such a degree that he considers every increase of the amount of money in a country as an enrichment of the people, a means to give employment to the poor, to carry on manufactures etc. (Money and Trade, 23, 26 fF., 16S.) A given quantity of money is capable of giving employment at most only to a certain number of men. (21.) A nation's power and wealth depend on the population and its stores of goods, these on commerce, and commerce in turn on the amount gf money, (pp. no, 220.) The advice given, in 1848, to the National Assembly of France, but which it had the good sense to reject, to overflow all France with the so-called bons liypotMcaires, is akin to Law's practical propositions. M. Chevalier^ Cours, III, 8, rightly ridicules the literal construction of the words : Vargent est abondant, when merchants find it easy to obtain credit, and considers it as well grounded as it would be to infer from the maxim : Vargent est le nerf de la guerre^ that rifles and bullets were made of silver. ■^ Adam Smith was not entirely clear, in his own mind, on this point. Thus inconsistently enough, he calls money unproductive — " dead stock," for the reason that it leaves no material traces behind it of the goods which it has transferred from one hand to another. (II, ch. 2.) Is not the same true of trade itself .'' And yet Adam Smith calls trade productive. His error is doubtless a remnant of the Physiocratic doch-ine, to which Smith still held. Compare ^ucsttay, 94, ^d. Daire. Even Tiviss says that money employed as money is unproductive, but that, when employed as a commodity, it is pro- ductive. (View of the Progress of Political Economy, since the sixteenth Century, 1847.) Besides it is not a peculiarity of money alone, that, after it has served the purposes of production, it comes out of the product unaltered. The same is true of quicksilver employed in amalgamation. (Hermann, 2nd edition, 302.) Sec. CXXII.] VALUE IN EXCHANGE OF MONEY. 3G5 SECTION CXXII. VALUE IN EXCHANGE OF MONEY. The value in exchange of money is said to be high when all other commodities estimated in money are cheap ; and low in the opposite case. We have here to do with the applica- tion of the most general of all laws of price ; therefore, with the demand and supply of money. The demand for it de- pends on the wants and the means of payment of its purchas- ers. Therefore, if a country has little trade, it will, on this ac- count, need only few instruments of trade, that is, of little money to efTect exchanges. If it be poor in other goods, it will get little money in exchange. In the former respect, there is a beneficent principle of equalization or compensation which de- creases the price-variations of money, no matter of what kind, in the necessity, when the number of business transactions re- mains the same and money becomes cheaper, to use more of it, and less when it becomes dearer.^ The supply of money is, in the long run, dependent chiefly on the cost of production. But since the cost of production in different mines is very dif- ferent, the value in exchange of the precious metals is deter- mined by the cost of producing them from the poorest mines which must be worked in order to supply the aggregate want of them. (See § i lo.) ^ The more unfavorable the con- ^ Senior, Three Lectures on the Value of Money, 1840, is, in so far, not ■wrong when he says that the value in exchange of the precious metals is still ultimately determined by the want of such commodities as are luxuries. This last determines to what extent the production shall be extended by the working of the poorest mines, whereas the wants of circulation can be met as well by small as large quantities of the metals. ' The good or bad result of this production depends on many different ele- ments which may compensate on another. In California and Australia gold is to be found in large quantities, and is easily mined; but the workmen make large demands which the nature of the country renders it difficult to meet. In the Harz mines, where the cost is scarcely covered, (Lehzen, Han- nover's Staatshaushalt, 1853, I, 139), the shafts are sometimes I75>^ fathoms, []QQ CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Cii. III. ditions of their production are, the greater is the quantity of commodities which must be given for a pound of gold, sil- ver etc. ; that producers may not be deterred from the prose- cution of their work. The extremes of the value in ex- cliange of money are dependent on the use for which it is in- tended. That value cannot rise higher than to the point at which single pieces of money become inconvenient on account of their smallness, nor sink lower than the point at which a similar inconvenience is produced by their too great size. In both instances, it would become necessary to have recourse to other instruments of exchange. SECTION CXXIII. THE QUANTITY OF MONEY A NATION NEEDS. How great the amount of money needed in the entire economy of any state is, cannot be always rightly determined, either by the am.ount of the national resources, or by the number of the population.^ It is a very easy thing to refute the opinion, that the aggregate amount of cash money in a deep, but this is made up for in a measure by the moderate demands of the ■workmen and their skill in mining. Among the Mandingos, the auriferous material is so rich that i^ per i,ooo of the weight of the sand is washed out in- to pure gold in ten minutes (M.ParA, Journal, 53 ft", addenda, XIX), while in Europe, where the proportion is only jJq per 1,000, mines are still considered Avorth working. But then, what workmen there are there! In Peru, the burdensome height of the mines above the level of the sea and the want of combustible material more than counterbalance many favorable advantages, while in Norway the cheapness of wood compensates for a great many dis- advantages. Another thing which contributes towards the uniformity of the price of the precious metals is the circumstance that the great amount of fixed capital required in the greater number of mining enterprises, post- pones for a long time the working of good mines as well as the abandon- ment of poor ones. ' Older writers have estimated the amount of monej' necessary in a coun- try at -^j ^-^ ( Petty )^ ^5j,and even J^ of the yearly income of a people. (Adam Siiiiili, II, ch. 2.) According to Cantillon^ Sur la Nature du Con' merce, p. 73, it is from \ to -^^ of the annual gross production of a nation. Sec. CXXIII.] THE MONEY A NATION NEEDS. 367 country constitutes an equivalent of the aggregate amount of all other commodities to be found there at any time, in such a way that the two pans of this great scales (Locke) hang al- ways in a state of equilibrium, and that an increase of the amount of money, the, am.ount of all other commodities re- maining the same, must be productive of an exactly corres- ponding decrease in the value of each piece of money .^ Think ^ Davanzatt, Lezione sulle Moneta, 15SS, 32 ft", Cust., thinks that all terres- ti"ial things ■svhich serve to satisfy the ^vants of men are, by virtue of agree- ment, equal in value to all the gold, silver and copper; and that the parts comport themselves as tlie whole. The price of a commodity is based on this, that men find in it as much of their beatitiidiiie as is afforded them by a given quantum of gold etc. Similarly, Montanari^ who adds as a limitation the quantity of money spcndibile in csmmercio. (Delia Moneta, 45, 64, Cust.J The same opinion leads Locke to the singular conclusion, that, as there is now in the world, ten times as much silver as there was previous to the dis- covery of America, each single piece of silver, separately considered, and taken in relation to such commodities as have not varied, is worth only one- tenth of what it was then. Locke, here, starts out with the gi'oss assumption, shared even by GaniUi, Theorie, II, 3S6 ft", that in the case of money the de- mand is always, relatively speaking, equally strong and just as great as the supply, or as the amount in the market. (Works, II, 23 ft'.) Further, Mon- tesquieu, Esprit des Lois, XXII, 7, 8. Per contra, however, see Moiitesquieti, ibid. XXII, 5, 6, and Hume, On INIoney and on the Balance of Commerce, Essays II, 1752. Hume knew perfectly well, that only circulating money and circulating commodities operated on price, but failed to take the rapidity of circula- tion into account. Similarly, Forbonnais, Elements du Commerce, II, 212; even Canard, Principes, ch. 6; Fichte, Geschloss. Handelstaat, 93 ft"., and Stein, Lehrbuch, 58. Contested by La-v, Trade and Monej' considered, 140, a work directed especially against the Mercantilistic essay, Britannia languens ; 16S0, by M6lon, Essai politique sur le Commerce, ch. 22 ; Gcnovesi, Econo- mia civile, 1764, II, 1, 15; Stcuart, Principles, II, ch. 28; Vcrri, Meditazioni, XVII, 3 ft".; BUsch, Gedlumlauf, II, 40. The simple taking of an inventory of most private resources which possess so much greater value in other com- inodities than in money is enough to demonstrate the error of DavanzaiPs doctrine. Thus, in France, in Necker's time, the cash money in the kingdom was estimated at 2,200,000,000 livres, and the average value of the wheat crop alone at 1,000,000,000. Neckcr, Legislation et Commerce des Grains, 1776, I, 215. Recently, Michel Chevalier, estimated the amount of money in France at irom ^tYz to 4 milliards, while the official estimate of its immovable property alone was over 83 milliards. 368 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. III. only of the great many commodities which are obtained and consumed without any exchange whatever ! Rather does the amount of money necessary to keep the value in exchange of the money emplo3^ed in a people's public economy unaltered,^ depend on the cooperation of the following conditions: A. The number and extent of such coinniercial transactions as are ejfected by means qfmoneyi^a. relation which, evidently, increases (see § 56, ft'.) with every advance in the division of labor. Hence the transition from serfdom and socage service to free labor, from domestic-servant labor to day-labor and piece-work, from feudal military service to that of paid and standing armies, from land-privileges and allowances in pro- duce, such as fire-bote etc., to the payment of officials in money, from dues in produce to taxes in money, and regular lease-hold interests, from requisitions to loans of money; in a word, from the barter-economy (Naturalwirthschaft) of the middle ages to the trade by means of money in the higher stages of civilization, that is, from the " feudal " to the " com- mercial " system must, of itself, increase the money-need (Geld- bedarf) of a people. B. The rabidity of the circidation of money; because, in most commercial transactions, one dollar which circulates ten times a year really performs the same service as ten dollars which go from hand to hand once in a year; just as the economic use of a ship employed in the transportation of commodities does not depend on its commdiousness alone but on its rapidity also.^ The economic use of money does 3 When money becomes dearer, less of It is of course needed ; and when cheaper, more, for the same purpose. * In contradistinction to presents, acts of spoliation, but especially to barter. 5 The discoverer of this truth is supposed by many to be Banditti, Discorso economico, 1737, 141 f., Cust. Berkely, however, in the Querist, 1735, 477 f., writes: "A sixpence twice paid is as good as a shilling once paid." Much earlier yet, in 1797, Boisguillebert, Detail de la France, II, 19, had the germ of this doctrine, but he confounds circulation with consumption. Kx\6.Locl:e, Considerations, II, 13 ff., presented it in 1691 with great clearness, although he did not always remain true to his theory. Compare ^uesnay, 6d. Daire, 64; Cantillon, 159^., 382. Sec. CXXIII.] THE MONEY A NATION NEEDS. 359 not depend on its amount simply. Says Sisiiiondi: " The amount of the medium of circulation in a state must be equal to the sum of the payments made in it in a given time, di- vided by the sum of the times the former has, on an average, changed owners within that time."^ Under given economic circumstances, the rapidity of the medium of circulation is, taken all in all, not by any means an arbitrary matter. It will happen very seldom that one man will purchase or con- sume a commodity in order that another may not want money.''' Were the greater number of money-earners (and in nations with a healthy economic life this number is always made up of men noted for the good management of their own affairs) inclined to pay out the money which they had taken in, rapidly, a very active production w'ould prevail everywhere; and this, in turn, supposes general commercial freedom and great legal security. The less these conditions are developed, the more difficult it becomes, not only to lay out the money received to-day productively to-morrow, but the more imperative!}" does a proper foresight demand, that a reserve-fund should be maintained for times of necessity. (See § 43.)^ Even in the same age and among the same people, money moves most slowly under the influences of troublesome and critical epochs; for the dangers of war and sedition, of impending burdensome taxation, commercial gluts and numerous cases of bankruptcy uniformly operate to make the possessors of money hold anxiously to their present supply.® In less civilized countries, the same condition of things leads ^ If the nvimber of annual exchanges effected by i dollar = u; the total number of dollars in the store of money = m ; the rapidity of circulation, that is the number of exchanges effected on an average by each dollar in a ..u • u u year, = s : then is u = m s, s = — , m = — m s ' Since good money is so easily stored away and preserved, no one is in haste to get rid of it. St. Chanians., N. Essai sur la Richesse des Nations, 122 ff. * Among the Kurds, all the money in their camps is used for head-orna- ments for their women. (K. Rttter, Erdkunde, X, 887.) 'Thus, Sir David Xorth^ Discourse on Trade, 1691, Postscr. Vol. I.— 24 370 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II., Ch. III. the people even to bury their money-treasures. In large cities, the circulation of mone}^ is generally more rapid than in the country districts ; in a thickly populated than in a thinly populated country; and in trade than in agriculture.^*^ Every improvement in the means of intercommunication tends to facil- itate it. The rich man possesses, as a rule, less money, rela- tively speaking, than the poorer man. Hence, a more equable division of a nation's resources among the people would in- crease the amount of money needed,^^ While the concentra- tion, as to time, of circulation into few great terms of payment is calculated of itself to cause a large sum of money to remain idle in the interval,^^ its concentration in space in large com- mercial cities must dispense with the necessity of a great num- ber of instruments of exchange. In England, it is customary for every man in comfortable circumstances, as soon as he re- ceives any money, to deposit with a banker, and to make all his payments by means of checks upon the latter. Cash money is now emplo3^ed by Londoners only in pa3'"ment of ^'^ Lotz^ Handbuch, 377, is of opinion that even in England £100,000 em- ployed in trade in land can scarcely effect exchanges to the amount of £1,- 000,000 in a year. The same sum employed for the same purpose in London, in stocks and in the trade in commodities, will effect exchanges to the amount of £160,000,000. '1 Cernuschi^ Mecanique de I'Echange, 1865, 132 ff. '^Thus Petty (ob. 16S7) is of opinion that England needed as much money as ]/i of all its ground-rents amounted to, as the J^ of all house-rents, and ■j'j of all the wages of labor for a year; for the reason that ground-rents are paid semi-annually, house-rents quarterly, and wages weekly. (Several Essays, 179; Political Anatomy of Ireland, 116.) Locke, on the other hand, assumes -^^ of the wages of labor, ^ of all the revenue of land owners, and 5^;,- of the amount cash money taken in in a year by merchants. Of these Umounts, there should be always, at least, one-half in ready money on hand, if commerce would not be brought to a stand-still. If leases were to be paid for on short terms, a great saving of money would be possible. (Works, II, 13 ff.) Pinto, Traite du Credit et de la Circulation, 34, calls special attention to the case of Tournay, in which the commandant, during the siege of 1745, made 7,000 florins serve him for seven weeks to pay the garrison; by bor- rowing that sum anew every week from the inn-keepers etc. ; which they, again, had received from the soldiers. Sec. CXXIIL] THE MONEY A NATION NEEDS. 371 •wages, and in trade between retail dealers and consumers. The banker is there the common cashier of a great number of private individuals, and is in a condition to make their pay- ments for them with a much smaller amount of money, espe- cially when they are to be made by one of his depositors to another.^^ This " union of money-chests " (Kasseiivereimgung) has been effected also on a larger scale ; inasmuch as bankers, in greater or smaller numbers, are wont to have one bank as a center ; and the country banks, in turn, to be in constant rela- tion with the great moneyed institutions of London, subject to a species of general superintendence by the Bank of England. These great monetary institutions have, so to speak, a common rendezvous at the Clearing-House, where the greater part of their payments are made by a mere off-setting of debits and credits;^* and this bank is, as it were, the cashier-in-chief of the nation, and in possession of almost the entire cash stores ^^ of the English people.-'^ '2 If all were to commit their payments to the care of the same banker, it would be possible to do with almost no money. But even now, if lOO sep- arate merchants were obliged to keep each 3,000 dollars in their money-chests for unforseen contingencies, a banker might accomplish the same for them with 50,000 dollars, because it is not probable that the unforseen contingen- cies in question would occur to all at the same time. '*In the London Clearing-House, in 1839, £954,401,600 were paid by means of the use of £66,275,600 as a circulating medium, for the most part notes of the Bank of England. ('Zbf/^e, Inquiry into the Currency Principle, 27.) From May, 1868, tin til May, 1869, £75068,078,000. (Statist. Journal, 1869, 229.) The New York Clearing House, in 1867, effected payments to the amount of £5,735,031,900 (Ibid., 1867, 577), and in 1868, $30,880^00,000. (Hildebnmd's Jahrb., 1869, II, 168.) '5 This system began in the middle of the seventeenth century. (A Dis- course of Trade Coyn and Paper Credit, 64.) As early a writer as Sir y. Child^ N. Discourse on Trade, 46, says, that for some time, every man who had from £50 to £100 in money, sent it to his banker, and that since that time, all the money flowed towards London and the country was de- prived of it. (127 ff.) As a rule, the goldsmiths were also bankers. One such smith had at the time of the Great Fire of 1666, emitted £1,200,000 in notes. (A Discourse etc., 67.) The Bank of England, as a money center, dates froin 1694. The London banks developed into intermediaries princi- 373 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. III. C. The quantity and rabidity of circtdation of the representa- tives of money. These, in so far as they are worthy of the name here given them, depend on the credit of those who issue them ; that is, on the certainty that they shall, at the time fixed, be redeemed in money. To this category belong the paper money of the state which bears no interest, and the treasury- notes of the state which do bear interest, bank notes, bills of exchange, promissory notes, book-credits of private persons, sometimes even certificates of the storage of goods in public stores. It is estimated, that, at the present time, nine-tenths of all the payments made in Great Britian are effected with- out the aid of money, or even of bank-notes.^® The capacity of a person to make purchases does not depend simply on the pally before the time of the French Revolution. (Thornto7i^ Paper-Credit of Great Britain, 1802.) This remarkable institution had grown to vast dimen- sions even in Thornton's time, although it has been much enlarged since 1825. (Tooke, History of Prices, 152 f.) Similar conditions among almost all highly civilized peoples. Thus in Greece, compare Becker, Charicles, I, 294. Concerning a person who had 14 talents' worth of resources, 26 minae, and therefore three per cent, in cash, see Lysias, adv. Diog., 6. In Rome, compare Polyb., XXXII, 13. Cicero, pro Font., I, i. For Italian analogous cases, part of which may be traced back as far as the twelfth century, see Lobero, Memorie storiche della Banca de S. Georgio, 1832; or the Dutch " cassiere " Richesse de Hollande, I, 376, ff. In France an ever increasing centralization of the money-trade is to be noticed in Paris (M. Chevalier, Cours., Ill, 418); and now of the money-trade of Germany in Berlin. 'fi Compare Fullarton, On the Regulation of Currencies, 1845. Among the Dutch, the custom of using all commercial commodities as much as pos- sible, as a basis of the circulating medium, was much earlier developed. (Child, Discourse on Trade, 65, 264 f) In Great Britain, the aggregate amount of bills of exchange put in circulation was, in 1S39, £528,000,000, which sum has been increased annually at the rate of about £24,000,000. (Tooke, Inquiry into the Currency Principle, 26.) Between 1828 and 1847, there circulated at the same moment, on an average, £79,127,000 in bills of exchange in England, and in Scotland, £17,380,000 (Athenaeum, 1850, No. 175), and in Great Britain and Ireland, from £180,000,000 to £200,000,000. (Tooke, History of Prices, VI, 588.) According to Macleod, the bills of exchange and promissory notes together amounted to £500,000,000; bills of exchange, bank-notes and bank-credits, to over £600,000,000. (Elements, 12, 325.) Macleod calls the currency the sum total of all debts due by every individual in the country. (Elements, 43.) Sec. CXXIV.] THE MONEY A NATION NEEDS. 37p, amount of money he possesses, but on his credit likewise. The person who buys on credit, contributes as much to raise the price of commodities as the person who buys for cash ; with this exception, however, that when the former eventually fails to redeem his promise to pay, the price raised by him quickly falls again." And, indeed, all the various forms of credit, mentioned above, agree essentially in this, however they may differ from one another in costliness and rapidity of circulation. SECTION CXXIV. THE QUANTITY OF MONEY A NATION NEEDS. (CONTINUED.) Of the three conditions above mentioned, it is evident that the first operates on the amount of money needed, in a direc- tion opposite to that of the other two. The usual course of development is this: among an advancing people, the number of money transactions increases at first; later, when education has become general, and the people have grown habituated to the giving and receiving of credit, the circulation of money is accelerated, and an increase of the substitutes for money efTected. Hence, it is perfectly natural that the money-need of a people whose public economy is only half developed, should, in proportion to the number of inhabitants, be greater, not only than that of a people whose economy is wholly unde- veloped, but also, than that of a people whose public economy has been carried to the highest point of perfection.^ ^ " A case in England, in 1857, in which a liouse -with £10,000 capital failed with liabilities amounting to £900,000. (Report of the select Committee on the Bank Act, 1S5S, XV.) Or where a speculator with £1,200 made pur- chases on credit to the amount of £80,000, and then failed with a deficit of £16,000. (Faivcett, Manual, 442 f.) 1 Remai-ked by as early a writer as Davenant, Works, IV, 106 ff. Com- pare, however, II, 23S. ^uesnay, €d. Daire, 75 ff. Lord King, Thoughts on the Effects of the Bank Restriction, 1804, 17 ff. Exhaustively treated by Chevalier^ Cours., Ill, 397 ff. He very much laments the fact that the cus- 374 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. III. SECTION CXXV. UNIFORMITY OF THE VALUE IN EXCHANGE OF THE PRECIOUS METALS. The peculiar properties of the precious metals described above (§ 120), explains satisfactorily enough, why, at the same toms of France cause it to need from 3^ to 4 milliards of cash money, while England does a much larger trade with 1,200 millions. (I, 207 ff.) In France, it is said that the amount of money, in 1S12, was 1,500,000,000 francs(.''). (Peuchet, Statistique elementaire, 473.) In Prussia, in 1805, it was 90,000,000 thalers. (Krug^ Betracht. iiber den Nationalwohlstand des preuss. St., I, 244.) The annual amount of production in the former coun- try was, 7,036,000,000 francs ; in the latter it was estimated at 261,000,000 thalers, so that in Prussia the relation of money to national income was, as 1 : 2.9; in France, as i : 4.69. 2 It is scarcely possible to determine exactly the amount of money in a country ; for the reason that, outside of the suppositions of bankers etc., there is no authority which can be safely relied on, unless it be the reports concerning the coinage, and of the emission of paper money. The informa- tion, no less necessary, to be derived from the statistics of the importation and exportation of money, the melting down of coin by gold smelters etc., can never be exactly obtained. In England, at the end of the sixteenth cen- tury, the circulating medmni was estimated at £4,000,000 (Hume, History of England, ch. 44, App.) ; under Charles II., at £6,000,000, when the popula- tion was 6,000,000. ('jPe//}', Several Essays, 179.) About 171 1, Davenatit, New Dialogues, 11 fF., mentions £12,000,000 as the amount; and Ajiderson, Origin of Commerce, a., 1659, £16,000,000 in 1762. The circulation of gold, shortly before 1797, was estimated by Rose at, at least, £40,000,000; by Lord Liver;pool, at £30,000,000; by Toohe, at only £22,500,000. (History of Prices, V, 130 ft") Morcau de Jonnis, 1S37, assumed £43,500,000 (Statistique, I, 329), and Helferich (Schwankungen der edlen Met., 1843, 147), £45,000,000. Sir Robert Peel, estimated the amount in 1S45 at £59,000,000, to which was to be added an average of £28,000,000 in bank notes, after deduction made of the metallic reserve. According to yevons, the amount of British money is now £80,000,000 in gold, £14,000,000 in silver, £1,000,000 in copper; the sum total, including bullion and bank notes, after the deduction of their metallic repre- sentatives, £134,000,000. (Economist, December, 186S, July, 1869.) In France, Vauban, Dime royale, 104 (Daire), estimated the cash money at about 500,000,000 livres, over 750,000,000 francs, with which Voltaire, Siecle de Louis, XIV, ch. 30, agrees so far as the year 16S3 is concerned. In 1730, Voltaire, assumes the amount to be 1,200,000,000 of the coins of that time. Sec. CXXV.] VALUE IN EXCHANGE. 375 time, but in different countries, they liave more nearly the same value in exchange than any other commodity whatever. Like a fluid in tubes which communicate with one another, the precious metals seek the one same level of value the whole world over.^ O^ly^ it must not be supposed that every abso- lute or relative increase of the amount of money in a country must produce immediately a corresponding diminution of the value of money; and in addition to this cause an exportation of money. ^ If the number of trade-transactions increases in the same proportion as the amount of money, the value of money remains entirely unaffected.^ The same thing occurs when the increased influx of money, instead of overflowing the channels of circulation, only swells the volume in the Nechcr, Administration des Finances, III, 66, estimated it, in 17S4, at 2,200,000,000 livres; MolUen, about 1806, at 2,300,000,000. The valuations in Louis Philippe's time varied from 2,400,000,000 to 2,500,000,000 (Chamber of Deputies, April, 13, 1S47), and 4,000,000,000. (Blanqui.) The valuations of 1S70 were, according to Wolovjshi^ 4 milliards; and to Bonnet^ from 5 to 6 milliards. Compare 1Voloxvsh\ L'Or et 1' Argent, 3S3 ff., Euqu6te, 42. The German Zollverein is said to have had, at the beginning of 1870 (Soetbeer) 480,000,000 or 520,000,000 thalers (WcibezaJtn) cash money. In Wirtemberg, Mcmmiiiger, 1S40, estimated the resources of the country at 1,600,000,000 guldens, of which 36,000,000 were cash; and the yearly gross income at 179,000,000 guldens; so that the money Avas 20 per cent, of the latter and 2}^ per cent, of the former. The annual sales = 226,000,000. Therefore the coin currency must have circulated on an average between six and seven times in a year. In the electorate of Hesse, there were fer capita 4 thalers, 18 sgrs., 9 hellers, metallic money, and 3 thalers, 9 sgrs., 4 hellers, paper-money. (B. Hildehrand^ Statist. Mitth., 1853, 1S5.) The amount of money in Naples, in 1840, was estimated at 42,000,000 ducats. (Scialoja.) It has been estimated that, in 1S30, Spain possessed 1,725,000,000 francs. (Bar- rego von Rottenkamp^ 330-) ' Montatiari, Delia Moneta, 52 if. ^ David Huine's very In^uQntxaX essay on the balance of ti-ade does not give expression to this error, but he certainly was the occasion of making a great many of his disciples advocate it. It is related to the error mentioned in § 123. S^ucsuay, loi (Daire) saw this point in a much clearer light. So did Graumann^ Gesammelte Briefe vom Gelde (1762), 12 ff.; 73 If. 3 This is seen, for instance, when paper money is issued, in times when trade is thriving, and is withdrawn when this conjuncture ceases. 376 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. III. ready-money reservoirs. By means of these stores of ready money, very large payments may be made by one nation to another, without changing the circulation, or, therefore, the value of money, in the slighest degree, on either side. * If, indeed, such payments should continue for a long time to flow in the same direction, they would certainly influence the circu- lation, and then produce a cui-rent in the opposite direction. However, it may happen, that the value of money in difTer- ent countries may be permanently different, when there are lasting difficulties in the way of the leveling influence of the incoming or outgoing current of money. Thus, the precious metals mantain a high value in those countries especially which can obtain them only by giving commodities difficult of trans- portation for them. If, for instance, an Englishman, anxious to take advantage of the high value of money in Poland, ^ Very well elaborated by Fullarton^ On the Regulation of Currencies, 71 ff., 139 ff. Compare, however, ^ecana, Economica publica, IV, 4, 27. When England on the occasion of the removal of the bank restriction in 182 1 and 1S22, caused £9,520,759 and £5,356, 7S8 to be stamped, this powerful demand scarcely affected the gold-agio in Paris. (M. Chevalier^ Cours, III, 157.) And, on the other hand, the system of assignats, developed during the first French Revolution, on so large a scale, had no influence on the price of sil- ver in the rest of Eui-ope. (Lord King, Thoughts on the Bank Restriction, 1804.) And so, Tooke, History of Prices, I, 205, describes a very large in- crease of the medium of circulation, after which the prices of commodities remained unchanged, corn fell, colonial products rose in price, both as they had done before, and from causes inherent in the commodities themselves. During the first years of the bank restriction, 1799-1S01, grain rose very rap- idly in price, while all trans-Atlantic products sank. (Tooke, I, 332 if.) The unusually large importation of wheat from January i, 1846, to January 14, 1S47, was paid in France by a decrease of the bank metallic reserve (encaisse) to the extent of 172,000,000 francs. (M. Chevalier, Cours, III, 470.) An ex- perienced practitioner in England is of opinion that an increase of bank notes to the amount of about £5,000,000 would not raise prices nor increase the tendency to speculation, but only enlarge the deposits of the bankers. But, if on the other hand, £5,000,000, by any sudden contingency, were to be put into the hands of the working classes, this money would, for the most part, enter immediately into circulation ; the price of commodities would, there- fore, rise and continue to rise until that amount had come into closer fists, as it would after some time. (Tooke, III, 156 fl'., II, 323.) i Sec. CXXV.]- VALUE IN EXCHANGE. 377 should cause Polish articles, such as wheat, wood, wool etc., to be imported into England, they would reach their destina- tion very much increased in price, because of the great cost of transportation. Whether Poland or England would have to bear this cost depends on the relations of supply and de- mand. Certain it is, however, that the migration of money is hereby rendered exceedingly difficult, forbidden even within the hmits of certain value-diflerences, especially where the means of communication are universally bad. And so, the smaller the number of countries which minister to the want of commodities of precious-metal districts, the more must other nations obtain the money they need only at second and third hand; by means of which, naturally, money itself is made dearer each time. Now, it is, as a rule, nations in a low stage of civilization, that engage in the exportation of raw material, and they are the worst adapted to engaging directly in the carrying on of trade. When, therefore, they do not possess gold or silver mines themselves, money-value is, as a rule, highest with them ; especially as the absence of legal security and protection, which generally obtains there, makes the value in use of the precious metals one of great urgency to them. ^ ^ Direct legislative or governmental provisions may operate in the same direction; as, for instance, the Japanese embargo laws which, not long since, limited all foreign trade to two * This explains the high price of gold in Farther Asia, which was formerly separated from America, the principal source of supply of the precious metals, by a journey around the earth, the then usual course of the world's trade. The precious metals are generally higher in country places than in large cities, and in the interior than on the sea-coast. Since the public highwaj's etc. in Germany have been so much improved, the difference in the value of money in upper and lower Germany has almost disappeared. (Raii^ in the Archiv der polit. Oek., Ill, 338.) 5 Happy begirning of this doctrine in Huinc, On the Balance of Trade. Further, Thoinion, The Paper Credit of Great Britain, ch. 11. Adam Smith, on the other hand, claims that gold and silver, because they arc costly super- fluities are uniformly paid most dearly for, in the richest countries. (Wealth of Nations, I, ch. 11, 3: Digr.) 378 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. 11," Cii. III. foreign nations. "^ I intend to treat of the influence of taxation on the value of money, in a future work to be written by me, on the Political Economy of the State. SECTION CXXVI. UNIFORMITY OF THE VALUE IN EXCHANGE OF THE PRECIOUS METALS. [CONTIKtTKD.] Most nations can satisfy their want of the precious metals, only through the medium of foreign trade. Hence they very naturally look upon the cost of production of the articles of export by the exchange of which they obtain the precious metals either directly or indirectly, as the cost of production of these metals themselves. But, the rule that all commodities of equal cost of production have equal value in exchange is ap- plicable only within the limits of the same economic territory (§ 107), for it is frequently physically impossible, and still more frequently rendered difficult, by laws, customs and states of mind to transfer factors of production from one country to another simply on account of the more advantageous market they would there find. Thus, for instance, when England exchanges its cotton and woolen goods, and steel instruments for Mexican silver, the cost of production of the two equiva- lents may be very different, and the one party in this trade may permanentley make a larger profit than the other.^ Ac- cording to § loi, that party will be most favored in whom the desire of holding to his own commodities is farthest from be- ■' Similarly in China, and even in Upper Egypt, the China, so to speak, of antiquity! Compare Herodot, II, 112 flf; Homer, Od., IV, 354 ff. The relig- ion of the Egyptians prescribed to them a mode of life which was scarcely practicable in foreign parts. They were sj'stematically inspired with a horror for everything foreign. They had a strong antipathy for salt, fish and pilots. In Egyptian mythology, Osiris represents the Nile, Typhon the desert and the sea! (Plutarch, De Iside, 32.) ' The other party, of course, makes a -profit also. He is in a better condi- tion than if he wished to produce the desired commodity in his own counhy. Sec. CXXVI.] VALUE IX EXCHANGE. 370 ing out-weighed by his desire to obtain the other. But, at bottom, silver is no very indispensable article. Especiall}^ in highly civilized commercial communities, it is easiest to ob- tain substitutes for it, while the principal articles of English export are, for the the most part, objects with which to satisfy wants rather urgent in their nature, very general, and of rapid growth; and which, besides, are not, to any extent, diflicult of transportation. It is not a matter of surprise, therefore, that English commodities, in silver countries, are generally sold above the mean price between the English cost of pro- duction and the Mexican, for instance, or the cost of procur- ing them elsewhere ; and that silver, on the other hand, is sold in England, under the same. But this lowers the price of the precious metals of the latter country in general. Hence a change in the channels of international trade, which in most countries is the only source of gold and silver, may make the price of the precious metals dearer in one place and cheaper in another, even when the conditions of the production of mines remain entirely unaltered.^ In an isolated country, any ^The first clear germ of this doctrine, which is one of the inost important theoretical principles of international-trade politics, is to be found in David Hume, On Interest ; Cantillon, Nature du Commerce, 226, 369 ff. Bicardo, Prin- ciples, ch. 7. " Gold and silver having been chosen for the general medium of circulation, they are, by the competition of commerce, distributed in such proportions amongst the different countries of the world, as to accommodate themselves to the natural traffic which would take place if no such metals existed, and the trade between countries were purely a trade of barter." Rehenius, OefF. Credit, I, 29 if. Still further developed, especially by John Stuart Mill, Elements, 1821, III, 4, 13 f ; Torrcns, The Budget, 1844. J^^'"' Stuart Mill, Essays on some unsettled Principles of Political Econom_y, 1844, No. I, and Principles, III, ch. 19, § 3, 5th ed.: "The opening of a new branch of export trade from England ; an increase in the foreign demand for English products, either by the natural course of events or by the abrogation of du- ties ; a check to the demand in England for foreign commodities, by the lay- ing on of import duties in England, or of export duties elsewhere; these and all other events of similar tendency, should make the imports of England, bullion and other things taken together, no longer an equivalent for the ex- ports ; and the countries which take her exports would be obliged to ofter their commodities, and bullion among the rest, on cheaper terms, in order to 3S0 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. III. amount of gold and silver whatever would, finally, as soon as the people had grown accustomed to it, suffice for all the wants of circulation. But, in commerce with the rest of the world, the greater quantity and greater cheapness of the precious metals, that is of those commodities which are most current and are possessed of the greatest amount of economic energy, must, without fail, be of the greatest advantage to a country; and this irrespective of the fact that they are under certain circumstances the symptom of an especially highly developed public economy. If we suppose two nations, A and B, equal in every other point, but that A has twice as much money as B, and that prices are twice as high there as in B; yet, with the same effort or sacrifice, A could levy twice as many taxes as B. In case of a war between them, A might pay in ready money for the necessities of an army which had invaded B, with one-fourth the sacrifice which B would have to make to support its army in A, if we reverse the case, and suppose that B had invaded A.^ re-establish the equation of demand; and thus England would obtain money cheaper, and would acquire a generally higher range of prices." Obscurely surmised by Beccaria^ E. P., 3, 18, and even by Galiant, Delia Moneta, II, 2. Sem'or^s admirable work, Three Lectures on the Cost of Ob- taining Money, 1830, follows up the thought that every country obtains in- digenous and foreign products at a cost which grows smaller in the same proportion as the productiveness of its people's labor is large. This would, certainly, explain why it is that perhaps one hundred English days' work in cotton manufactui-es will exchange against as much silver as is produced by two hundred days' work in Mexican mines and foundries. This would not, by any means, produce a lowering of the price of the precious metals rela- tively to other English commodities, but the mfluence would be felt equally by all the products of English national industry. •'To be found in germ in Canii/lon, Nature du Commerce, 1755, 249 ff. 307. Bilsch, Geldumlauf, 14. Kaufmann^ Untersuchungen, I, 75 ff. Many of the doctrines of the so-called Mercantile System, of which I shall treat in my projected work on the Political Economy of Commerce, have given ex- pression to this truth in an inexact and exaggerated way ; but they were not entirely erroneous, as is supposed by the adherents of Hume and Smith. However, J. S. Mill, Principles II, ch, 19, § 2, does not fully admit the de- gree of the cheapness of money in England usually assumed. According Sec. CXXVIL] MEASURE OF PRICES. 381 CHAPTER IV. HISTORY OF PRICES. SECTION CXXVIL MEASURE OF PRICES, — CONSTANT MEASURE. If we had a measure of prices with the same universality of application and the same unchangeableness as the measure of length, which is determined by astronomical calculation, we should be able, not only to clearly understand all the data relat- ing to value, that is to say, a not unimportant portion of histori- cal science, but we should, moreover, have a practical means to condition and fix even perpetual annuities, in such a way, that they would always afford the same economic and purchasing power to the person receiving them. No wonder, therefore, that political economists since Petty's time have zealously labored to find a constant measure of prices.^ If by this we understand a species of goods such that it should always main- tain equal exchange-power, as compared with all other com- to him it is wants of luxury (luxury-wants) become such through habit, that produce " the dearness of living in England." ^ Petty considers the search for a nieasure which could be applied both to land and labor as one of the principal problems of Political Economy. (Po- litical Anatomy of Ireland, 62 ft") Sir J. Stciiarf, Principles, III, ch. i, took the matter very easy by considering the so-called "coin of account," for instance, "bank-money," as an invariable value-magnitude. Compare Jacob, Grundsiitze der National CEkonomie, II, 441 if. Cazaux, Economic politique ct pnvee, 1825, 16 ff., has a not uninteresting study on this subject; but he goes, throughout his argument, on the assumption that the rate of interest is the price of money! If the rate of interest in two countries := I and i, the prices of the same commodity =:P and p, the true thing- values, V and v; then we have v: V:: i p: I P! 3S2 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Cn. IV. modities, the idea of a " constant ■' measure of prices is un- thinkable. We would have to suppose here, that not a single kind of goods varied in its price; since, otherwise, at least as compared with those that varied in price, the measure of prices would itself be variable.^ But we may, indeed, search for a kind of goods such that its inherent elements and the ele- ments peculiar to it, so far as it is itself concerned, and which go to determine price, should exert the same uniform influence at all times. If there be such a kind of goods, and its value in exchange as compared with other kinds of goods were to vary, we should be certain, at least, that the cause of the change was not in it, but in them; that it had not grown dearer or cheaper, but that they had grown cheaper or dearer. Such a kind of goods would have these two char- acteristics: x\. A given amount of it would, under all cir- cumstances, have the same value in use for the same num- ber of persons. B. It would require, under all circumstances, the same cost to produce it, and therefore the supply might always keep pace exactly with the number of those who de- manded it,^ In this way the supply and demand of this kind of goods, abstraction made of the quantity of counter-values, would preserve forever the same invariable relation. SECTION CXXVIII. VALUE IN EXCHANGE ESTIMATED IN LABOR. Adam Smith is of opinion that different kinds of goods, no matter how far removed from one another they may be in '^ Lav.\ Trade and Money, iSi. Before him, and quite correctly, Mon- tanari, Delia Moneta, I, p. 84 fF., compares the means employed of measuring one commodity by another, to the means used to estimate time in terms of space, as when it is measured by the revolutions of the hands of a clock, and again, space in terms of time. 2 The solvability or capacity to pay of buyers cannot be taken into considera- tion here, because it is synonymous with the amount of counter- values which are to be measured. Sec. CXXVIIL] VALUE IN EXCHANGE. 3S3 time or space, have equal value in exchange, when an equal quantum of human labor may be purchased by their means. He adopts, because of the great diflerences in work, the aver- age work of the common manual laborer. One work-day, and the sacrifice of " rest, freedom and happiness " therewith con- nected, are, under all circumstances, attended with the same inconvenience (value). If at one time this day's labor will ex- change for more, and at another for less, of any kind of goods, it is only because the price of the latter has fallen or risen.^ But w^e may ask whether the same sacrifice of liberty is as great a hardship to a Russian as to a Bedouin ; or whether the sacrifice of an equal amount of rest is as hard for the New Englander as it is for a Turk, or as difficult to endure on a hot day in July as in the cold of winter. Besides, we have ^Adam Smith, Wealth of Nations, I, ch. 5. Similarly Luther, vom Kauf- handel : Werke, ed. Walch, X, 1098 f. B. Franklin considered the labor em- ployed in the production of wheat as the best measure of prices. (Letter to Ld. Karnes: Works, ed. SfarJiS, VIL) As Adam Smith, so also Sisinandi, Richesse commerciale, I, 371 f.; Kraus, Staatswirthschaft, I, 84; v.Schlozer, Anfangsgriinde, i, 41. Also Malthus, in the second and succeeding edi- tions of his Principles, ch. I, 6, and Definitions, ch. S, 9. The Measure of Vakve, 1S23. Zacharia, Vierzig Biicher, VII, 53 f., maintains that, at least within the limits of every separate nation, the average labor-power of one man is invariable. Assuming this principle, therefore, to be true, the means of subsistence necessai-y to support a laborer for one work-day constitutes, in- directly, a measure of prices. Toohe, History of Prices, I, 56, says that the amount of a day's wages is always a better measure of the price of the pre- cious metals than the price of wheat. Even in 1750, Galiani, Delia Moneta, II, 2, had denied the impossibility of an entirely invariable measure of price in this Avorld of change, but he considered man himself the least variable of measures, and in a country where slavery prevailed, slaves. He thought that the maada of the negroes were a part of the average price of slaves. Practically, Adam Smith's proposed measure was used in the French consti- tution of 1791, in as much as it provided that participation in primary assem- blies should depend on the participant's paying an annual tax equal to the wages of three days' work, and eligibility as an klecteur, on the possession of an income equal in value to the wages paid for two hundred days' day-labor. Oiven endeavored to base the value of the paper money in circulation in his Utopian commonwealth, not on any metal of a certain weight or stamp, but on hours of labor as the unit. (Reybatid, Reformateurs Contemporains, I, 255.) 3S4 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Cii. IV. here to do primarily only with value in exchange ; and that value in the case of day-laborers' work is subject to very great fluctuations. The elements on which the demand and supply of labor depend are not, in themselves, invariable, nor do their varia- tions usually compensate for one another. In progressive na- tions, the value in use of day-laborers' work increases as well as the capacity of their employers to pay them; but, at the same time, as a rule, and at least relatively speaking, the sup- ply of labor diminishes on account of the increase in the cost, of production of workmen. Precisely the reverse of this hap- pens in nations in their decline, and in over-populated nations. The workman is subjected to the necessity of accepting dis- tress-prices for his work, and especially of accepting them for a long space of time.^ How often it happens that, if onl}'^ trans- itorily, when wages are declining, work improves, and vice versa? Ricardo's school employs, as the measure of the price of various kinds of goods, the quantity of work by which the goods themselves are produced.* It is evident that the same ^ The wretched condition, until within a short time since, of the Irish work- ing class, is well known; how they dwelt in mud cabins without windows, board-floors or chimneys etc., in the same apartment with their pigs ; how they lived almost exclusively on potatoes, and went about in rags. These same Irish, coelum,, non animtim mutantcs, received in North America for the coarsest kind of labor^ 50 to 75 cents wages, besides wheat bread and meat three times a day, coflee and sugar twice a day, butter once, and seven or eight glasses of whisky or brandy. M. Chevalier, Lettres sur I'Amei-ique du Nord, I, 159.) ^ Thus in Mauritius, the immigration of the coolies has produced a decrease of negro wages, but an increase of negro industry. In the Barbadoes, the negroes are more industrious and their wages lower than in Jamaica. The Avages of good workmen, as for instance during the commercial crisis in Man- chester, often sink, while the wages of bad workmen rise ; as, for example, in a village through which a railroad is made to pass. Compare Lauderdale Inquiry, ch. i; Sartorius, Abhandlungen, 1806, I, 16 ff. ; Lotz, Revision, I, 99 IT.; M. Chevalier, Cours, III, 88 f. * Besides the passages cited in § T07, compare also Harris, On Money and Sec. CXXIX.] MEASURE OF PRICES. 385 amount of common labor produces very different results, ac- cording as it is well or badly conducted. Hence Ricardo must have used the word labor in the sense of labor ideally adapted to its end. But in this way it would be impossible to reduce all the different kinds of labor to a common denomi- nator.^ Nor could the peculiar effects of capitalization, or the influence of the natural or artitlcial limitations of competition be estimated in terms of such a measure. (See §§ 47, 107, 189./ SECTION CXXIX. THE PRECIOUS METALS THE BEST MEASURE OF PRICES. It is no more possible to find a constant measure of prices than it is to square the circle. ( J. B. Say.) If the two mag- nitudes to be compared are separated from each other in space but not in time, the precious metals constitute not only the best measure of their prices, but also a very good one. But the precious metals are subject to very sensible and acci- dental variations in price in long periods of time. If, there- fore, we would compare sums of money belonging to different times with one another, we must first construct a price-cur- rent list of all the more important articles of commerce for the time in question, and in the quantities they are needed in every Coins, II, 1757 f.; Jacob also preceded Ricardo. See the German translation of Say, II, 435, 507. 5 The introduction of the words "the socially necessary time of labor" into the formulse does not make the measure any more practical for political economists or for socialists. 6 Cantillon, who reduces all the cost of production to land and labor, con- siders the " at par " between these two to be this : that the labor of the mean- est slave corresponds to the quantity of land which the owner is obliged to employ for his support, and the support of the slave and of the children who are to take his place. (Nature du Commerce, 42.) The Physiocrates thought that the internal (innere) value of two commodities stood in the same relation to each other as the area of land directly or indirectly neces- sary to their production. Schlettwein, Grundfeste der Staaten, 1792, 230. Vol. I.— 25 3SG CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. IV. day life. We would next have to Ctilculate the average of these mean prices, and thus to determine the relative value of the amounts to be estimated.^ The person who should limit his comparison to a few species of commodities, says von Mangoldt, would lose in exactness what he gained in com- prehensibility. In every such list, the wages of a day would occupy a very important place. The desire of exerting an influence over the lives and actions of other men, and the desire of relatively greater social distinction as compared with the social distinc- tion of others, is very general ; and there is scarcely any better evidence that it has been attained than the possession of the power of controlling a large number of days' Vv^ork. The man who can keep one thousand day laborers is certainly,, in a po- ' The so-called Sacli-Merth (thing- value, real-value) of Hermann, St. Unter- suchungen, loi ff. Thus Poidett Scrofe recommended a " tabular standard," to be officially established and renewed from time to time, to serve as an anchor to those persons who wished permanently to fix their money in such a manner as to make it exchangeable for an equal value in things. (Principles of Political Economy, 1833, 406.) Something of this kind was tried for 50 commodities, between 1S33 and 1S37, by Porter, Progress of the Nation, ist ed., II, 236 ff., then for 40 commodities by Jevons in the Statistical Journal, 1S65. Of course, all commodities of a given price are not equally important in this respect. Thus, for instance, a fluctuation in the price of diamonds would have no effect on the thing-value or real-value of a day's wages, but it certainly would on the thing-value of a princely income. There are some excellent re-marks on this very important subject in Lorve's work, On the Actual Condition of England, chs. 8 and 9. The controversy carried on between Jevons, A serious Fall in the Value of Gold, and its social Effects, 1863; Statist. Journal, 1865; and Laspeyres, Htldebrand's Jahrb., 1S64, 81 ff. ; 1S71, I, 296 ff. ; in which the former recommends the geometric mean of the relative prices of separate commodities at different points of time, in order to calculate the average relative price; and the latter, as usual, the arithme- tical mean, is very thoroughly reviewed and criticised by DroUsch, who shows that neither of these methods is sufficient, but that the quantity of every separate commodity must also be taken into account, for which he furnishes practical formulae. (Math. phys. Berichte der K. Siichs. Gesellsch., 1871, I, 143 ff., 416 ff.) It is certain that a fixed income in money could maintain its real value or thing-value (Sachwcrth) just as little if the cwt. of bread rose by as many dollars as the cwt. of pepper had fallen ; as if the increasing price of bread depended on a decreasing price of pepper. Sec. CXXIX.] MEASL'RE OF PRICES. 387 • litico-economical sense, an important personage. Besides, the height of day-wages has the most direct influence on the price of many other commodities.^ No less important is the price of wheat, or rather of the principal article of food of the people, for the time being, with which the price of inland raw material — in so far as it can be produced from the same soil alternately with wheat — and, in the long run, also the wages of labor, are so essentially con- nected.^ The same indispensable necessity of wheat which causes its price to fluctuate so largely from year to year, and from month to month, promotes the uniformity of its aver- age price,'* when many years are taken into the account.^ *^ ^Senior, Outlines, 1S7. In addition to this, we may draw from the thing- value of a day's wages a right conclusion as to the economic condition of the majority of the people ; and assuming the customary division of the national wealth, also as to the degree, to which the people have subjected tlie forces of nature to their service. ^Jiicardo, ch. 22, refuted, indeed, only the view that an increase in the Avages of labor produced by the higher prices of corn, would necessarily make all goods or products of labor, correspondingly dearer. * Compare § 103. In Paris, in 1S17, the sefier of wheat cost March 5, 55^ francs; April 2, 57 fr.; April 23, 60 fr.; May 14, 63 fr. ; May 21, 66 fr. ; May 28, 75 fr.; June 4, 82 fr.; June 11, 92 fr. (Tooke, History of Prices, II, 17.) ^ Locke, 98. When Condillac asserts that wheat is the best measure of prices, he adds, when free ti-ade in wheat obtains. (Commerce et Gouverne- ment, i, 23.) PicJite, on the other hand, while advocating the despotic guid- ance of all trade by the state, would employ wheat as the fundamental mea- sure of prices. (Geschl. Handelstaat, 47 fF.) That grain does not afford a good measure of prices in very highly cultivated nations nor in barbaric on«s, see Hermann, II, Aufl., 451. •^ The average price must be based on the prices of a great many years, since crops vary not only from year to 3'ear in price, but from decade to decade. See Roschcr, Nationalokonomik des Ackerbaues, § 152, and Roscher, Kornhandel und Theuerungspolitik, 47 ff. Great wars are wont to disturb agriculture in such a manner that the price of corn is very much in- creased by them. Hence, it is not unfrequently possible to use the prices of grain as a species of barometer to determine the real pressure of a war upon the economic life of a people. Judging by this standard, England suffered much less from the War of the Roses in the fifteenth centur}^, than from the civil wars in the seventeenth ; and less than France from the religious wars of the sixteenth. The war year 163^, in which Gustavus Adolphus and the 388 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. H, Cir. IV (Malthus.) If, by reason of great progress made in the art of agriculture, the cost of the production of wheat should fall to one-half of what it was, a large increase of population would certainly not be delayed long. And so, on the other hand, there would be a decrease of population if, by the destruction of artificial means of irrigation, or other steps in the direction of a retrogressive civilization, the cost of the production of wheat were to be permanently increased. But even the average price of wheat, during a long series of years, is not entirely invariable. The increasing consump- tion compels the nation, as a whole, to provide for its require- ment of wheat from less fertile sources, w^hich increases its price generally. It is true that the progress of the science of agriculture and of the corn-trade counteract this tendency, retard the advance of the price of wheat, and may, for a time, produce an opposite tendency. It is true, also, that the people are induced by their most general and vital interests to take advantage of this possibility. But spite of the frequency of exceptions to it, the rule remains.''^ If, therefore, we wished to so fix a perpetual annuity that it should always be worth emperors had to spare the country, must have been far less oppressive for Saxony than the later Swedish campaigns. Roscker, in the Tiibinger Zeit- schrift, 1857, 471. ' Most countries go through these successive periods in their corn trade • in the first, exportation preponderates ; in the second, there is an equilibrium ; in the third, importation preponderates. (M. Chevalier, III, 74 ff.) Compare Tacit., Ann., XII, 43. Omitting the two dearest and the two cheapest years, the Prussian provinces were circumstanced as follows : Price of Population Rye, Per Sq. Mile, 1816 to i8jj. ^8^7- The Whole Kingdom - - 40. silver groschens. 2,776 Prussia . - . . 32.2 " " 1)827 Posen 34.3 " " 2,i8o Brandeburg, Pomerania - 38.4 " " 2,093 Saxony 40.3 " " 2,366 Silesia 38.0 " «' 3,612 Westphalia .... ^^y.y " <; 3,600 Rhine Province - - - 49.4 " " 5)078 I Sec. CXXX.] HISTORY OF PRICES. 389 as much money as a certain quantity of wheat had cost, on an average, during the three preceding decades, the thing- value of tliis annuity would, on the whole, rise with an ad- vance in civilization.^ To obtain something that would re- main the same, it would be necessary to combine wheat with at least one chief commodity, the intrinsic basis of the price of which had a development independent of the price of grain; but the whole to be made payable in money. The precious metals are, in many respects, so diametrically opposed in prop- erties to wheat, in their dispensableness, transportable char- acter and durability, for instance, that these two classes of commodities are best adapted to act as counter-balances to each other.' SECTION CXXX. HISTORY OF THE PRICES OF THE CHIEF WANTS OF LIFE. The higher civilization advances, the dearer all those com- modities in the production of which the factor nature with Rau, Lehrbuch, I, § 1S3. As to when it may be assumed that the price of corn has remained unchanged, see Hermann, loc. cit., 125 ff. 2 Petty recommended the average daily food necessarily required by one man as the measure of price, estimated on the basis of the cheapest means of subsistence. (Polit. Anatomy of Ireland, 62 ff.) T/uiey used as such a measure the smallest day's wages; as he supposed, expressed in rye, that is, ^ of the Prussian scheffel. Similarly, Maltkus, in his first edition, and Buquoy, Theorie der Nationalwirthschaft, 240. But this is simply to substi- tute for wheat an arbitrarily determined quantity and quality of the same as a measure of prices. For practical experiments of this kind, made by the depreciation of paper money during the French Revolution, see M. Chevalier, Cours, III, 98; and Constitution de 1795, V, 68, VI, 173. Count Soden, Nat. CEk., II, 338 r, demands that all taxes, salaries of state officials etc., should be regulated in accordance with the price of corn. This same view has been suggested recently in many German States. ' Recognized generally by Locke, Considerations 24. Further, Galliani, Delia Moneta, II, 2; Adam Smith, I, ch. 5. Sclidffle, N. CEk., II, Aufl., 127, maintains that a constant measure of price, such as would enable a person to stipulate for a salary for instance that would bo ahvays of the same value, is impossible. Similarly, Hildcbrand's Jahrb., 1871, 315 ff. 390 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Cii. IV value in exchange predominates are apt to become; and the cheaper, on the other hand, all those in which labor and cap- ital play the principal productive part.^ This is accounted for, not only by the almost unlimited capacity of labor and capital to be increased, while the natural forces which have value in exchange are susceptible of increase to so small an extent; but also, and especially, because new additions of labor and cap- ital are wont to cause relatively smaller results in the produc- tion of raw material, and relatively larger ones in industry and commerce. (§ 33, ff).'^ Hence, from the relations the prices of the different classes of commodities bear to one another, we ma}^ draw important conclusions as to the degree of civilization which a country has attained. The above law also affords an explanation of the fact, that a young nation, which has made no great strides in the way of development, and in which, of course, the produc- tion of raw material preponderates, draw their commercial and manufactured necessaries, by way of preference, from 1 Compare J. Tucker, Four Tracts on political and commercial Subjects, 2S ff., who maintains that it is a rule, alniost without exception, that "oper- ose or complicated manufactures " are cheapest in rich countries ; " raw mate- rials," in poor ones. Thus, for instance, corn (.''), garden products in the former; cattle, wool, milk, skins, flesh-meat, in the latter. Ships and mov- able property are cheaper in the former, whereas wood may be said to be almost the free product of nature here. See especially Adam Smif/i, Wealth of Nations, ch. 11, Digr. ^Senior, Outlines 119 f., makes the following calculation: Of the 15 d. which a loaf of bread costs in England, 10 d. goes to buy the wheat, the other 5 d, to the miller, baker etc. If now, Ave suppose, that in consequence of an increased demand, and therefore of increased production under more unfa- vorable circumstances, the price of wheat should rise to 20 d., the cost of pro- duction would possibly, because of an improved division of labor, come down to 3^4 d., and hence the price of the loaf of bread would be increased to 23^d. It is quite the reverse in the case of lace, because here a piece of raw ma- terial worth only 2 shillings may, by reason of the labor expended on it, be- come worth as much as £105. If the consumption of lace should increase so that the value of the raw material rose to 4 shillings, the simultaneous decrease of the cost of manufacture to the extent of one-quarter of the ag- gregate price, would leave the price of the manufactured article £78, 19s. Sec. CXXXI.] HISTORY OF PRICES. 391 precisely the most highly civilized foreign nations. The latter are in a condition, and accustomed, to give the largest quan- tity and the best qualit}- of manufactured articles for a required quantit}' of raw material ; and, of course, rice versa. Hence, in this intercourse of nations, the most urgent want, and the completest and easiest possibility of satisf3'ing it, meet.'' Only very highly civilized mother-countries can hold fast to colo- nial possessions in our day. SECTION CXXXI. HISTORY OF THE PRICES OF THE CHIEF WANTS OF LIFE. (CONTIKUED.) A. In the case of a great many raw materials, we repeat- edly find the following to be the course of development. In the lower stages of civilization, they grow of themselves, and in such quantities that a small amount of labor, and that only the labor of occupation, more than suffices to satisfy the small demand for them. Here, naturally enough, the price of raw materials is very low. After this, it rises with every advance made in civilization, for two reasons: first, because the de- mand becomes greater and greater; and then, because the naturally free sources of production, called into requisition b}^ other wants, now flow less and less abundantly.^ This rise in price continues until the point is reached at which it becomes customary, instead of the mere occupation of the free gifts of nature, to bring forth the commodities in question by the more 8 When, for instance, the inhabitants of the Baltic coasts, by way of pref- erence, kept up their relations with the Hanseatic cities, the Dutch and En- glish, that is with the most important industrial and commercial nations in their own sphere, they in all this pursued only their own interest. As to how this intercourse between " old " and " new " countries is susceptible of the very highest development, sec Torrens, The Budget: On Commercial and Colonial Policy, 1S44, and earlier, Wahefield^ England and Amciuca, II, 1S23. 1 The clearing up of primeval forests, the cultivation of natural meadows, etc. 392 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. IV- laborious process of production proper. From this time for- ward, the usual seeking of prices for a level requires that our commodity should, like all others which suppose an equal sac-, rifice of the means of production, claim an equal value in ex- change. If from any peculiar causes, the production of this commodity is not at all possible, or if it is capable of no great extension, its price, which would under the circumstances, be limited only by the purchasing power of the buyer, might attain the utmost extreme reached in prices under the spur of vanity or of the mere love of the commodity itself. The latter is true especially in the case of venison ; ^ the former, in the case of the tame cattle,^ fresh-water fish,* and wood. ^ ^ ^ In Hungary, during the sixteenth century, the choicest venison was con- sumed by plebeians and nobles alike. Herberstein^ Rer. Moscov. Comm., 97. In Russia, even the lowest classes not unfrequently partake of roast hare and duck etc. KoM^ Reise in Russland, II, 3S6. Still, in St. Petersburg, wild- fowl game rose between the time of Peter the Great and Alexander I. 600 per cent, in price. (StorcJi, Handbuch, I, 36S.) In Pittsburg, in 1807, mutton, beef and veal cost from 4 to 6 cents a pound, and game only from 3 to 4 J^ cents a pound. (Melish, Travels through the United States, II, 57.) The more the game laws are enforced, the longer does the low price of game con- tinue, especially when it is not easy for the poor to procure them. The moderns have seldom thought of raising game artificially ; among the Romans, arti- ficial raising was confined to the hare and fieldfare. (Varro, R. R., Ill, 12 ff.; Columella, R. R., VIII, 10.) Hence, the enormous prices paid for game, of which Pliny, H. N. X., 43, relates an example from the time of the emperors. On the other hand, Polybius assures us that, in his time, game was to be had as good as gratis in Lusitania. XXXIV, 8, 7. 2 In Buenos Ayres, in the nineteenth century, beggars on horseback were to be seen. (Robertson, Letters on South America, II, 294.) In Krasno- jarsk, in 1770, i^ rubles was the price of an ox, 1 ruble of a cow, from 2 to 3 of a horse, from 0.3 to 0.5 of a sheep; 0.15 of a deer. (Pallas, Sibirische Reise, III, 5, II 12.) According to the Tables of Prices in Sir F. M. Eden, State of the Poor, Append, i, and Rogers, History of Agriculture and Prices (1866), I, 245, 361, the following prices obtained in England; in, (On an average.) 1125-26, one ox, I shilling. One quarter of wheat, 20 shillings, 1260-1400, " " 13 " i;4fd. " " 5 " io|^d. 1406 " " g% " " " ^Yz " • 1463 •' " 10-20 " " " 17^-4% " Compare Hume, History of England, a. 1327. Under Henry VIII. veal, I Sec. CXXXII.] HISTORY OF PRICES. 39J SECTION CXXXII. HISTORY OF THE PRICES OF THE CHIEF WANTS OF LIFE. [CONTIUrED.] B. The rise in prices is observed earliest in that class of goods in question which by reason of their small volume and beef, mutton and pork were food for the poor in England, and cost on an av- erage i^d per pound; while wheat cost from 7 to 8 shillings a quarter. (24 Henry VII, c. 3. Price, Observations, II, 148 f.) The same appears from the " reasonable prices " which Charles I, in 1663, had established by sworn juries viz.: that the different kinds of meat were much cheaper compara- tively than corn in our days. (Ryincr, Foedera, XIX, 511. Anderson, Ori- gin of Commerce, a. 1633.) In many places in the highlands of Scotland, in the middle of the seventeenth century, one pound of oat-bread cost as much or more than one pound of the best meat. The union of Scotland with more highly civilized England soon changed the relation, so that in Adam SmitJi's time, good meat, in nearly all parts of Great Britain was worth from 2 to 4 times as much as the same weight of wheat bread. (Wealth of Na- tions, I, ch. II, I.) The Thomas Hospital in London paid, on an average, for good beef per stone weight : 1701-1710, ------ IS. 7.9d. 1764-1773, IS. 3.7d. 1794-1S03, - - - - - - IS. 5.d. 1S04-1S21, --..--- IS lo.gd. 1S22-1S42, ------ IS. i.5d. (Porter, Progress of the Nation, III, 112.) Among the most certain proofs of the high degree of economic civilization attained in upper Italy about the close of the medieval times is the fact, that the price of cattle, compared with that of wheat in the thirteenth and fourteenth centuries, varies very little from what it is to-day. (Cibrario, Economia politica del medio Evo, III, 335-3S3.) Compare Rau, Lehrbuch I, § 1S5. In Athens, the cost of a 7ne- diinnos of wheat was as great as that of a sheep in Solon's time. In the age of Demosthenes, it cost only half as much. (Bockh, Staatshaushalt der Athener, I, 107, 132.) It is obvious, however, that the price of meat com- pared with that of corn, was lowered by the great extension of the artificial cultivation of meadows; for, when the former has reached its maximum, it becomes a great spur to the promotion of the latter. Thus, in England, the price of meat, at the beginning of the sixteenth century, was on an average, higher than in Adam SmiWs time. (loc. cit.) To the same cause is to be ascribed the state of things in Prussia mentioned by v. Podeivtls, Wirth schaftserfahrungen, II, 15. 394: CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. 11, Ch. IV their comparatively great value, and by reason of the greater capacity to be kept in a state of preservation for a longer time, are best adapted to seeking a more favorable market. This applies particularly to the skins, fleece, hair, feathers, As a common basis for such calculations, the following may be accepted. It is plain that meadows, pasturages and forage-fields must yield as much in meat, as corn-fields of the same dimensions of equal goodness, and situated as favorably, in corn. According to Block, a Prussian acre (Morgen) of the best quality, used as a meadow, produces a hay-value equal to i,ooo pounds, a clover-value equal to 2,420; as a vegetable field, a beet or potato-value equal to 6,050-6,930 pounds. V. Lengerke's Q.h^\vi\'3X& is that no pounds of cattle- fodder expressed in terms of iiay, produces on an average 40 pounds of milk, and from 3_J^ to 4 pounds of meat. This would, at most, give 36, SS and 220- 252 pounds of meat. The yield of -wheat, v. Lengerhe estimates, on the best soil, and on an average, at 14 Prussian scheffels (at 80 pounds, i. e. 1,120 pounds) yearly per acre (Motgen). The three periods in the history of the prices of cattle were clearly recognized by Thaer, Landw. Gewerblehre, 1S15, 100. ^ It is a very characteristic fact, in relation to the river fisheries, that the fable that servants formerly stijDulated not to eat salmon except twice a week is to be found in so many places. Thus on the Elbe and the Rhine. Com- pare Thaarup, Danische Statistik, I, 112. In Scotland, about the end of the seventeenth century, the story in places ran, that it was five times a week. (Walter Scott, Old Mortality, ch. 8.) In England, fish seems to have been a tid-bit among the poorer classes in the fourteenth century. (Rogers, I, 606.) It was dearer especially during Lent. (Statist. Journ., 1S61, 544 ff".) The artificial production of sea-fish seems to have been tried only by the ancient Romans. On the whole, Adam Smithes law that a ten-fold demand can, as a rule, be met only by a greater than ten-fold labor, applies here. (I, 370, ed. Basil.) But this relation is obscured to a certain extent, from the fact that the source of the production of sea-fish, the ocean, which may be claimed at any time by occupation, is, practically, boundless. Here, therefore, the improve- ments made in nautical science, and the progress of geographical knowledge, may yet for a long time compensate for the exhaustion of the nearer seas, and even more than counterbalance it. ^ Among a great many nations in a low stage of civilization, agriculture consists in the burning down of the forest. In 1594, the Lauenforder forest produced 1,110 thalers' worth of food for hogs, and wood to the amount of 44 thalers. (v. Berg, Staatsforstwirthsch., 213.) The Harzgerode woods, at the ducal line of Anhalt-Bernburg, were estimated at 6,000 thalers. A hun- dred years later, they brought in yearly 70,000 thalers, although, in the mean- time, very little progress was made in the science of cultivating them, (v Justly Staatswirthschaft, II, 211.) We may form a notion of the relativity of Sec. CXXXII.] HISTORY OF PRICES. 395 teeth, horns, etc., of animals, in which, in the breeding of stock, etc. people in a low stage of civilization are much more apt to speculate than in their meat. Here it is considered, and rightly so, to be much more profitable to raise many animals which are badly cared for, than a few, that are well cared for ; for the care bestowed on animals has, as a rule, much more in- fluence on the body itself than on their covering.^ In fisheries, the idea of the clearness of wood from the fact that in Bavaria, for instance, in 1S40, there was a great deal of complaint, that in the disti-ict of Isark the price rose from 6 to 9 florins ; in the districts of Regen and the lower Maine, from II to 14 florins to from 15 to 18; in the Rhine district, from 20 to 26 florins per cord (Klafter). (Rau, Lehrbuch, III, § 150, a.) Besides, the price of wood in the forest rises, Avith an advance in civilization, much more rapidly than it does in the market; in which last, labor and capital play a greater part. fTiA?/, I,§ 3S5.) ^ Plan for the artificial pi-oduction of pearl oysters. (Novara-Rcise, I, 303.) Ostriches seem now to be ceasing to be objects of mere occupation, and to be becoming objects of breeding. (Ausland, 1S69, § 13.) ' Thus Wolff's experiments made at Mockern have shown that in the case of sheep fed with hay, the wool becomes much heavier and the flesh leaner than those of sheep fed with a more concentrated food. While it is estimated in England, at the present time, that the wool of South-Down sheep is worth scarcely one-tenth what their flesh is (yacob, On Corn Trade, 166), mutton, from the year 1260 to 1400, was, on an average, worth 17 pence; and this even at a time when prices were gradually rising; but the wool of one animal (i lb., ']'^ ounces), 5J4f pence. (Rogers, I, 362, 395.) Even under Anglo-Saxon kings the fleece was worth 40 per cent, of the val- ue of the whole sheep. (David Hume.) And so W. Macann, Two Thou- sand Miles Ride through the Argentine Provinces, 1S53, I, 151, says that in the interior of Buenos Ayres, he purchased S,ooo sheep at iS pence a dozen, and after a march of 200 English miles, sold the skins for sixty pence a dozen. In Goya, formerly, a live horse cost 3 pence, its skin on the coast i3 pence ; and the slaughtering of the beast cost 3 pence, the removal and clean- ing of the skin 3 pence ; and 3 pence were paid for transportation. (Robert- son.) In Ireland, in 1763, it not unfrequently happened that the skin and tallow of an ox cost as much in a commercial city as the whole ox had cost in the nearest market town. (Temple., Works III, 13.) In England, from 1260 to 1400, the average price of a whole cow was 9s. 9d.; of the hide is. 8d., and cows were cheapest in the first decade, i. e., 6s. 2d., and the hides dearer than they were generally afterwards, i. e., by from i-g^d. (Rogers., I, 361, 451.) In Saxony, according to Engcl (1853), the average price of homed cattle was 396 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. IV. caviar, sturgeon- bladders, oil and whalebone;^ and in forest- about 46 thalers; of their hide, 4 thalers and 21 silver groschens. Russia ex- ported, 1S42-1847, 72,636,166 silver rubles worth of tallow, 1,832,137 silver rubles worth of horse hair, 10,811,735 worth of bristles (Borsten), 7,387,140 of uncured skins, 36,159,452 of sheep's wool, but flesh-meat only to the amount of 370,363 rubles, and entire animals to the value of 6,853,241 rubles. (P. Slorch, Der Bauernstand Russlands, 289 ft'.) Tallow is there ten times dearer than the same volume of wheat. (Steinkaus, Russlands industrielle und commercielle Verhaltnisse, 294 ff.); while in Saxony, according to Engel (1821), a pound of wheat cost on an average 7. ^pfennigs, and a pound of tallow 30 f. However, Russia's recent progress in civilization has had for effect: that the exportation of tallow (1833 = 4>^ million fiids; 1S69 = 2% mill.) has greatly fallen oft' ; while that of butter and live stock has increased. (v. Lengefeld^ R. im 19. Jahrh., 220 ft". In England, during the fourteenth century, a pound of meat cost, on an average, 34fd. ; of lard, from ij^ to 2. (Rogcrs^l, 411.) On the other hand, from 1848 to 1856, the average January price of beef from America was no shillings; of tallow from St. Petersburg, 48s. iid. per cwt. (Nevjtnarcli.) And so, in the time of Pallas^ the Cossacks chased the deer of their steppes only for the sake of its skin and horns. (Pallas, Reise, III, 524.) While the Greeks got horn from Macedonia and Thrace (Herodot.^ VII, 156), it is a striking proof of high civilization that at Athens (.?), about the time of the hundredth Olympiad, an ox-hide was worth only 3 drachmas, and the whole ox 77 drachmas. (Bockh, Staatshaushalt, I, 105 ft") As the ox is primarily serviceable as an object of food and an instrument of labor, and the sheep on the other hand, only an instrument to produce wool, it is easy to understand why, with the further advance of civilization, the price of oxen rises comparatively much more than the price of sheep. In Athens, during the time of Solon, an ox was equal in value to five sheep. (PlutarcJi, Solon, 23.) So also in countries with a low civilization in the time of Polybius. (Polyb., XXXIV, 8; Gell., XI, i.) Why the same was the case in Rome at the beginning of the Republic.^ (Plut., Popl., 11). In England the proportion between the price of an ox and that of a sheep was, in : Tear As Year As 927 6:1 (Henry.) 1229 8:1 (Eden.) 1125 3:1 126-1492 (av.) 9.2: 1 ('i?<7^.^ 1182 6.3:1 1497 10:1 I197 9:1 1500 11.6:1 1511 8:1 At present the proportion may be from 10 to 20: i. In Saxony, it is as 48 thalers to 5.27. (Engel.) " About 1793, Russia exported 10,000 rubles worth of fish, 452,000 of stur- geon bladders, 188,000 of caviar. (Siorch, Russland, II, 1S4.) But this had Tear As 1528 10: I I.S29 12.8: 1 1531 9.4:1 1551 10.6: I 1597 8.2 : I (Eden.) Sec. CXXXII.] HISTORY OF PRICES. 397 culture, pitch, tar, potash and, to some extent, building mater- ial etc., play the same part.'^ Conversely, the price of those portions which are most dif- ficult of transportation, by reason of their volume or of the difficulty of preserving them, rises latest. To this category belongs milk, the production of which in a fresh state can be made an object of economic speculation, only where civiliza- tion is at its very highest, and especially in the vicinity of large cities.* It is indeed possible by its transformation into butter or cheese to preserve milk and make it capable of undergone a great change even in 1S50. x\t present, there are 64 per cent, of sturgeon bladders, 27 of caviar, and 7 of whole fish. (Steinfiaus, Russland's industrielle und commercielle Verliiiltnisse, 102, 36S.) Yet the Astrakan fishermen still throw the greater number of the sturgeon they catch back into the water. (Pallas, Reise im sUd. Russland, i, 1S9; Stcinhaus, 99.) Salt fish are adapted for transportation to a distance not only because they can be preserved, but also because they may be caught and prepared on the great highway of the water. Athens got from the Black Sea besides wood, tar, wool, hides, cordage, honey, wax and slaves, also salt fish. (Wolf, z. Demosth. Leptin., 252; Bockh, Staatshaush. I, 51.) The latter from Sardinia, Egypt and Spain. (Pollux, VI, 48.) * The principal countries that produce potash are Russia and North Amer- ica. It is estimated that a cwt. of potash requires, on an average, 480 cwt. of wood. (Pfeil, Grundsatze der Forstwirthsch. in Bezug. auf National- Oekon. etc., I, 128.) From iSoo to 1S40, wood for fuel in Wiirtemberg trebled its price; for building material the price increased 1.6 times. (Deutsche Vierteljahrsschrift, 1847, No. 4, 104.) * Whereas barbarous nations take little trouble to turn the milk from their cows to account (Roscher, Ideen z. Politik und Statistik der Ackerbausys- teme, Archiv. der politische CEkonomie, neue Folge, III, 202), Rcuning, in 1844, calculated that the milk from all the cows in Saxony amounts to a value of 10,000,000 thalers, their meat to over 2,000,000, and the labor performed by them in various ways to 3,000,000. In Silesia, in the last decade of the eighteenth century, a quart of milk was estimated to be worth 2 pfennigs (Festschrift der deutschen Landwirthschaftsversammlung, 1869, 343), where- as now it is sold almost every where for \2 ffennigs. (Schmoller.) In the rather high state of civilization which Saxony had reached at the end of the sixteenth century, when game was already dear, and the prices of other meat were almost as high as in 1800, a shcffel of rye was worth 44 measures (Mass.) of milk, and recently 82^ measures. (Schmoller, Tiibinger Ztschr., 1871. 336 ff.) 398 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Cii. IV. transportation. But to carry on such a business for the pur- poses of trade, a care and a cleanliness are needed which are national characteristics only of a highly civilized people (§ 229) and the preparation of a superior quality of cheese, which is al- w^ays a very long process, is conditioned by the employment of capital long in advance of a return, and which no poor nation is in a condition to make.^ Cows are primarily milk- producing animals.^ Hence their price, as a rule, rises later than that of oxen, but, in the higher stages of civilization, it rises much more surprisingly. Something analogous is true of those products which result from what remains after the production of other goods or commodities. As long as this alone supplies the demand, the cost of production of the former commodity is almost nothing, and hence its price is very low. For this reason hogs are relatively cheap in two very different periods of a people's national economy, in a very low stage of civilization where forests are plentiful and they are fattened on acorns and the nuts of the beech, and also when they may be considered as a collateral product of some great industry, such as distilleries and dairy-farming; and w^hen raised by a numerous, especially a rural population of small means and laborers, in order to turn to advantage, in the former instance, the remains of production, and in the lat- ter of consumption.'' Where neither of these two reasons ob- '■ The principal cheese-producing countries and cities are Holland, Lim- burg, Switzerland, Gloucester, Chester, Ayrshire etc. Compare HoscAer, loc. cit., 195 if. ^In England, in the year looo, a cow was worth only as much as two sheep. (Afiderson, Origin of Commerce, a., 979.) The best butter was worth only id. per pound in 1550, while pork was worth 1%, veal and mutton, i_J^, and beet; 2 J^^d. The price of butter was exceedingly variable in the sixteenth century. (Eden.) ' During the middle ages, pork constituted the most usual animal food even of the best classes. ('^«.sc//2'«_^, Ritterzeit und Ritterwesen, I, 164.) Immense importance attached to pork by the Lex Salica. (Tit., II, XIV; Emendatt. Caroli Magni, II, i ft'.) The archbishop of Cologne used every day 24 large and 8 medium-sized hogs, and four more on the three great festivals. The abbot of Corvey used daily five fat and one lean hog, besides two young ones. Sec. CXXXII.] HISTORY OF TRICES. 399 tains, the price of hogs is wont to increase largely with an ad- vance in civilization.^ ^^° (See Roscher, Nationalokononiik des Ackerbaues, §§ 177 ff.) (Kindlin'^cii, Miinsterische Beitr., Urkunden, 147, 126.) In 1345, at the court of Dauphiny, there were used annually for 30 persons, 30 salt and 52 fresh hogs ; whereas, in modern Paris, with 800,000 inhabitants, only 32,000 hogs are consumed yearly. (Roquefort^ De la Vie privee des Fr., I, 310 f.) Com- pare herewith the place occupied by the swine-herds in the Odyssey in Greece's age of chivalry. In England, in the time of William I., woods were taxed according to the number of hogs they might feed. At present, there is an enormous production of hogs in Servia, which, in many places, consti- tutes the only source of ready money to the agricultural population. And about the end of the eighteenth century, it is said that Servia re- ceived from Austria alone 1,300,000 florins yearly for hogs. (liaii/ce, Serb. Revolution, 95.) In 1S64, Servia's total exports amounted to 62,500,000 pias- ters, of which 28,162,260 were for hogs, 7,043,000 for wool, 7,662,000 for the skins of sheep and deer, 5,732,000 for cattle, 1,222,400 for tallow. (Kaniiz, Serbien, 59S ft") Great production of hogs also in the Moldau and in Wal- lachia, in the United States and Mexico, where, instead of butter, only lard and suet are used; also in Lombardy, the Prussian Rhine province, Belgium, the English milk-producing districts, Gloucester, Wilt, Dumfries, Galloway and the districts where agricultural proletarians abound — Ireland and York- shire. It is a consequence of the same law that, among the South Sea Is- landers, the hog was the principal domestic animal, as it still is among the Chinese. Similarly in tlie whole of Asia, beyond the Ganges (Ritter^ Erd- kunde, IV, 938, iioi); in semi-barbarous upper Italy in the time of Polyhios (II, 15); in Gall itself, in the time of Augustus. (Strabo, IV, 192, 197.) The America of the ancient Greeks, Sicily, exported hogs, mainly, in the time of Hermippos. (Athen.^ I, 27.) And even among the Romans, the consumption of pork was much greater than the consumption of beef. (Marqicard- Becker, Handbuch, V, 2, 39.) 8 In the cities of Prussia subject to a tax for the privilege of maintaining slaughter houses, a pound of beef cost on an average, in 1S46, from 2 silver groschens, 5 ffennigs^ to 3 s. gr. 4 pf. ; pork, from 3 s. gr. 2 pf. to 4 s. gr. 4 pf. (Dictcn'ct.) In Moscow, also, the latter is dearer at present. Before the time of Peter the Great, it was cheaper. (Siorc//, Handbuch 1, 364.) It was a sign of high civilization, too, that in Florence, in the fifteenth century, veal cost, on an average, 2j4 soldi; mutton, 2^ soldi; but pork, 4 soldi. (Pagnini, Saggio sopra il giusto Pregio delle Cose, 325 f., Cust.) It is especially the lower middle class who ask for fat meats. The very fat English sheep are taken not to London, but into the manufacturing districts. (Lauderdale, In- quiry, 322 f.) As to whether the relatively high price of pork, and the fact that in the later times ot Rome, the wild boar was the most fashionable dish, compare Becker, Gallus,II, 1S6. 400 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. IV. SECTION CXXXIII. HISTORY OF THE PRICES OF THE CHIEF WANTS OF LIFE. (CONTINUED.) C. Those raw materials which, from the very first, have been obtained by the means of production properly so called, maintain a much greater uniformity in price. In the lower stages of civilization, they are never found permanently in excess; and as the economy of a people advances, the grow- ing dearth of natural forces may be more or less counter- 9 The production of fowl is similar in this, that they are frequently fed from remains of consumption; only their production is not adapted to un- civilized countries, because it is difficult to protect them there. In Texas, it is said, it costs more to raise ten chickens than to bring up ten children. (Kennedy, Czarnkowski's translation, 1846, 115.) The independent breeding of fowl is advisable only where there are a great many rich consumers ; for the reason that they are naturally a delicacy. Enormous production of pi- geons in Cambridge, Huntington etc. (McCulloch, Statistical Accovmt, I, 189.) In Paris the consumption of pork and fowl has gained somewhat since the Revolution. (M^ Chevalier, Cours. I, 113.) '" According to Schuckburg; Philosophical Transactions of 1798, and Kraus, Vermischte Schriften, I, tab. I, the prices of the following species of animals rose in England between 1550 and 1795: horses, 904 per cent; oxen, 896 per cent.; sheep, 876 per cent; cows, 2050 per cent; hogs, 1964 per cent; geese, 300 per cent; butter rose from 5d. per pound to 11^ d.; beer from id. per gallon to 2^4^d.; agricultural day wages from ^s. to is. S/i^-'i "wheat 326 per cent. Compare, however, Edinburg Review, III, 246 ff. In Germany also, cows and hogs have increased much more in price than horses and sheep. (Tiibinger Ztschr., 1S71, 342.) Diitot, Reflexions, 946 if., ed. Daire, says that the value of the precious metals in France decreased in value be- tween the times of Louis XII. and Louis XV. in the ratio of 3^f : i. On the other hand, the prices of difterent commodities rise in very different de- grees : Fat sheep from 7 sous - - - to 10 livres. - " 5 " - - to 25— 35 Lean " " 5 Hogs " 10 Capons " I Hens " 1% Pigeons " ^y^ Deer " i^ 10 sous. to 12 (( " 6 « " 3 « " 15 « Sec. CXXXIII.] HISTORY OF PRICES. 401 balanced by the greater cheapness of capital and labor. This is true, especially of wheat. (See § 129, and Roscher, Na- tionalokonomik des Ackerbaues, p. 43.) ^ D. In the case also of those raw materials which are objects of occupation, and never of real production, as, for instance, minerals, a progressive public economy, by altering the differ- ent elements of price in an opposite direction, may leave their price on the whole unchanged. Here, indeed, the discovery of new and especially of rich natural stores may exert an incal- culable influence ; but such " accidents " underlie the laws of human development only to the extent that those ages which are intellectually most active are those also which are most in- dustrious and fortunate in the discovery of their natural re- sources. ^ ' Thus, in Thuringia, the average price in silver of corn from the sixteenth century until the period 1S48-61 increased in the ratio of from i to 3-4; the price of the different kinds of animals, on the other hand, from i to 5-10. (Knics^ in Hildebrand''s Jahrbb., 1863, 78.) The price of the different kinds of corn as compared with one another may, however, be modified by many different circumstances. Thus the Capitulare Saxoniie of 797, c, 11, esti- mated the prices of rye, barley and oats to be to one another as 30: 30: 15; while the Magdeburg Chamber of 1S04 estimated them to be as 17: 14: 8. In the kingdom of Saxony, in 1841-9, the average prices of wheat, rye, barley and oats stood to one anotlier in the ratio of 144: 100: 75 : 47 (Engel); while, in the middle ages, Avheat, rye and oats were as 9:6:3 (Gersdorf^ Cod. Depl. Sax., II, p. XXXIV); under Prince August, corn, barley and oats were as 24: 22: 12 Assuming the price of rye to be equal to 100, the cost was: At Brussels, in the i6th century, - At Brussels, in the 17th century, At Brussels, in the iSth century, - At Brussels, 1815 — 1844, At Brussels, 1841 — 1850, At Berlin, 1 7S9 — 1S18, At Berlin, 1819— 1832, (Rail, Lehrbuch, I, § 183.) To understand this, it is necessary to bear in mind the relatively great increase of wheat bread, beer made of barley, and horses, as objects of luxury. The unusually low price of oats in North America, as compared with the price of wheat, is dependent on the facility Vol. I.— 26 Of Wheat. Barley. Oats. 126.7 80 50 13S.8 82.9 51-9 H7 86. 7 55-3 156 153 82.7 51 135 74.8 54 H3-S 74-9 52 402 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. IV. SECTION CXXXIV. HISTORY OF THE PRICES OF THE CHIEF WANTS OF LIFE. [CONTINUKD.] E. The products of industry become cheaper and cheaper as economic culture advances; whereas, for instance, in Eng- land, towards the end of the middle ages, a single shirt was considered of importance enough to be made not unfrequently an object of testamentary bequest.^ And, indeed, the price of industrial products sinks lower the more important the part played in their production by capital and the division of labor is as compared with the part played by the raw material.^ of exporting the latter. In Florence, in the fifteenth century, the price of wheat was 22^, of rye, 12, of barley, 8 soldi. (Pag)iin{, Sopra il giusto Pregio delle Cose, 325.) ^ The English so called custom-house prices (Zollhaus^rcise) correspond to the market prices of 1696. If tliese are assumed = 100, the price In 1826. In i8ji. Of steel and iron was, - - - - S3 56 Of coal was, ----- 47 4^ Between 1S35 and 1850, Scotch iron had already become cheaper by one- half (Mcidmger, 387), and coal in London by one-third (Porter). ^ Rogers, History of Agriculture, I, 67. -In England, in 1172, an ox cost 2 shillings; in 1175, green cloth cost per ell, 2 II shillmgs; red cloth, 5^ shillings. (Eden.) In the western states of North America, the farmer gives two poimds of coarse wool for one pound of woolen yarn ; he sends 4 bushels of wheat to the miller for the flour of three bushels (Ausland, 1843, No. 68), while in Ravenna, in the thirteenth century, the miller's fee was -^^ (von Raicmcr, Hohenstaufen II, 437); accord- to the fixed prices in Fantazzi, (Monumen. Ravennet.); in Germany, during the last centuries of the middle ages, % (% Grimm, Weisthiimer, III, 8) ; at the end of the sixteenth century from -J- to ^ (Coler, Oeconomia, II, 3); in modern Germany, generally Jg- of the raw material, and in the steppes of southern Russia, when the wind is still, in summer, even the half (Mitth. der freien okonom. Gesellsch. zu Petersburg, 1S53, 85.) In Guiana, in 1806, a very ordinary saddle and bridle could not be had under 10 J4 guineas. (Pinchard, Notes on the West Indies, III, 1806.) Count Gortz was obliged to pay 2 dollars, in Demarara, for the cleansing of rifle, and another person for the oiling of a carriage, 5 dollars. (Reise um die Welt, 1864, 327.) A lady's dress in Mobile costs four times as much as in London or Paris. (C/i. Sec. CXXXIV.] HISTORY OF PRICES. 403 On this account, in recent times, fine cloths have grown, rela- tively speaking, much cheaper than coarse ones/' Lead, which during the middle ages in England was much cheaper than iron, because of the difficulty of mining the latter, has be- come much dearer in our days.* Conversely, where raw material plays the most important part in manufactures, the price of the manufactured article may increase with an ad- vance in civilization. Hence, articles made of wood are pro- cured at the cheapest rates in mountainous countries, where the division of labor is not carried very far, but where the raw material is cheap.^ Lyell^ Second Visit to the United States, II, 70.) In Athens, articles of cloth- ing, even for the poorer classes, were never as cheap as they are in civilized countries to-day. Compare Plutarch^ De Tranquill. Anim., 10.) * In Upper Italy, between 1261 and 1400, a lady's chemise and the making of it cost 14.77 lire; Rheims linen, 7.04; ordinary mourning cloth, 0.45 ; black cloth from Moriana, 2.83; cloth from Mecheln, 43.S3; from Ypres, 47.04; scarlet cloth, S0.44 per ell. (Cibrario, 1. 1.) On the other hand, to-day, in the Leipzig m.arket, the difterence in price of the dearest and of the cheapest cloth will scarcely surpass the ratio iS: i. Even Scariiffi, SuUe Moneta, 1679, 163, Cust, remarks that hemp-linen and similar coarse articles had increased much more in price than brocades ; but he ascribes this circum- stance to the disordered state of the coinage. It is much better accounted for by Adam Smithy Wealth of Nations, I, 3S6, ed. Basil. * Before the plague in the fourteenth century, the cwt. of lead was worth ioj'2d.; of iron, 4s. id. (Rogers, I 599.) On the other hand, between 1S4S and 1S56, the average January price of bar-iron was £7, lis.; of lead, over £20. (Ne-Minmxh.) '■' Thus, in England, the price Tear Tear 1826. J831. Of glass was, ----- 387 369 per cent. Of leather was, - - . - 285 123 per cent. Of silk goods was, - - - - 158 249 per cent, of the price of the same articles in 1796. (Ran.) Of 29 chemical products of the Parisian manufacture, the wages of labor is on an average only 7.4 per cent, of the selling price; and, in some cases, only from i to 2 per cent. (Ckabrol, Richerches Statistiques sur la Villa de Paris, 1821 ; Hermann, Staatsw. Untersuch., 137.) In Buschtiehrad, between 1670 and 1870, barley rose from i to 4.8; hops to 6.52 ; fii-e wood to 6.14; the excise to 6.54; but beer only to 2.81; although wages increased ten fold. (Inama Sternegg, Gesch. dcr Preise im ostcrreich. Ausstellungsbericht von 1S73, 43.) 404 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Cii IV. F. But the price of commodities decreases, especially in the higher stages of civilization, to the extent that it is dependent on commerce.'' Here capital and human labor almost exclus- ively are effective, and the modern improvements of communi- cation, legal security and competition are especially striking^ G. Since personal services are, as a rule, performed and received only by individuals, the principle in accordance with which labor in general becomes cheaper in the higher stages of civilization, does not apply to them to any great extent.^ Yet we may claim that advancing civilization has pretty universally a twofold influence on the price paid for personal services. In the first place, freedom of competition, with the more accurate and equitable determination of price which it produces (in con- tradistinction to servitude, privilege and custom) always tends ® A bilk cloak lined with fur cost in the time of Charlemagne, 400 schefFels of rye, one not so lined 200. (HUlhnann, Finanzgeschichte, 213 ff.) In Florence in the fifteenth century, one pound of sugar was equal in value to 15 pounds of mutton. (Pagm?ii, 326.) In Turin, in the fourteenth century, I pound of pepper was equal in value to 28 pounds of salt. (Cibrarto, III, 359) 362.) As late as the middle of the fifteenth century, the court of Duke William of Saxony paid for one pound of sugar i thaler and 8 groschens, while ducal fees paid to servants and workmen seldom exceeded 2 gr. Hence, even at a princely meal, often scarcely j-^ a pound was consumed. (Busckiiig, Ritterzeit, I, 137 f.) ■> Charlemagne's capitularies suppose a merchant's profits to be from 100 to 200 per cent. (a. 809, c. 34.) And even in our own day, merchants in the markets of Cabul are frequently not satisfied with a profit of from 300 to 400 per cent. (K. Rttier, Erdkunde, VII, 244), and the caravans which leave Ma- roc for the Soudan are wont, in exchange for commodities amounting in price to 1,000,000 piasters, to return with a supply of other commodities worth 10,000,000. ('6'/««-W^«//««-?, Handbuch, Africa, 33.) According to Busck, Geldumlauf, II, 10, the price of East Indian products in Hamburg was some 70 per cent, higher than at home, wlyle Pliny, H. N. IV, 26, speaks of a price one hundred times (.?) as high; and its spices, at the time of Portuguese dominion, were sold at a profit of at least 600 per cent., in Europe. (Craw- furd, History, VII, 360; Ritter, Erdkunde, V, 872.) 8 When Humboldt found a missionary near Cumana who paid 7 piasters for a cow, and was obliged to pay 17 piasters for blood-letting, rather unskil- fully performed, he found an illustration of one of the peculiarities of colo- nial life — to have all the wants of higher stages of civilization but not the means of satisfying them. (Relation historique, I, 374.) Sec. CXXXV.] HISTORY OF VALUES. 405 to obtain the upper hand; and further, by the growing combi- nation of labor and of use (§§ 56, {l\ 207), a better and better and more clearl}^ defined gradation between ordinary services and those of a higher order is effected. When the latter cannot be increased at pleasure, the price paid for them may, as the wealth of consumers increases, become, fi-om motives of van- ity or of custom (^Gcbrauchsgrmiden)^ almost unlimited. The dancing maid, to whom Herod (Mark, 6, 23) promised even the half of his kingdom, is both in a politico-economical and in a moral sense a warning example to over-refined nations.® SECTION CXXXV. HISTORY OF THE VALUES OF THE PRECIOUS METALS.— IN ANTIQUITY AND IN THE MIDDLE AGES. It is impossible to write a real history of the values of the precious metals in ancient and medieval times : the sources of ^Enormovis payments made to distinguished virtuosi, actors, sophists and hetares at the time :n question, also to Appelles, Aristides etc., for works of art. (Plin., XXXIV, 19, 2, XXXV, 36, 19.) The actor Aesopus (see § 233, note 6) had a fortune worth 20,000,000 sesterces, while Pompey, for instance, had 70,000,000. Roscius received from the state for every day he played, 2S6 thalers, and earned 43,000 a year. ( Mommsen, Romische Geschichte, III, 483, 547.) Compare Cicero, pro Roscio Comoedo, 10, and Plin., H. N. IX, 59, X, 72. The zither-player, Amoebaeos, received one talent for each appear- ance. (Athen. XIV, 623.) According to Pliny, H. N. XXIX, 5, the Roman frincipes gave the most distinguished doctors yearly 250,000 sesterces, and even more as an honorarium. At the end of the eighteenth century, the greatest Parisian actors received from 4,000 to 5,000 francs per annum. Now 100,000 is considered a moderate income for one. ( Journ. des Economistes, May, 1854, 279.) It is said that Frederick Hase earned $30,000 in America in ten weeks. (Leipz. Tagebb., 15 Jan., 1871.) Steuart, Principles, II, ch. 30. Adam Smith frequently represents it as a rule, that superfluous goods like gold and silver, are dearest among the richest nations, necessary goods among the poorer, and vice versa. But the supply has much more to do with the permanent price of a comm.odity than the demand for it has. And the principle above mentioned applies only in so far as the supply is here an un- limited and there a limited one. Hence, the comparison of silver with paint- ers' and sculptors' works is not an apposite one : in the case of these there is a natural monopoly, while the former, on account of its durability and capacity for transportation, may, on the contrary, be increased almost at pleasure. 406 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. IV. information are too few. But it does seem possible to sug- gest some fragments and something of the development of that history/ at least in outline. Thus, for instance, the supply of the precious metals fur- nished by the mines, in the earlier times of ancient history, was kept from entering the market by the system which then prevailed everywhere, of hoarding treasure by the state, by the temples etc., and later by great reserves of treasure kept by individuals.^ The revolutions in prices in ancient times were produced as frequently by the sudden opening of such reser- voirs, as by the discovery of richer sources. Thus, for in- stance, such events as the dissipation of Pericles' treasures, the subsidies of the Persian kings, the spoliation of many temples in consequence of declining religiousness, the distribution of Persian treasures by Alexander the Great,^ had a vast influ- ence on the undeniable rise in the price of Greek commodi- ties in the century succeeding the Peleponnesian war.* Later, it is said that in Rome, the price of pieces of land was doubled ' Besides Bochh.^ Staatshaushalt der Athener, 1S17, Book I, compare Ar- buthtot^ Tables of ancient Coins, Weights and Measures, 2d ed., 1754, Reit- mcyei\ Ueber den Bergbau der Alten, 1785, and Michaelis, De Pretiis Re- rum apud veteros Hebrseos, in the Comment. Societ. Gottingensis, vol. III. The principal sources of information among the ancients are Diodor.^ V ; Strabo, III, V; Plin., H. N., XXXIII. -The money revenue of the Persian king, to the amount of 14,560 talents yearly, was transformed into bars and thus deposited in the treasury. Hero- dot.^ Ill, 95 f. Even the little vassal prince Pythios of Celzcnje had a treas- ure of 2,000 talents of silver and 4,000,000 pieces of gold. (Ibid, VII, 26 f.) On the money stores of private persons, see Plin., H. N., XXXIII, 47. 2 An ox vi^as worth, in Solon's time, 5 drachmas; in 410 B. C, 51 dr.; 374 B. C, 77^ dr.; a medimnos of wheat in Solon's time, i dr., about 390, 3 dr., under Alexander the Great, on an average, 5 dr. (Bochh., I, 102, f.) The usual amount of ransom paid for a prisoner of war, in Kleomenes' time, was 2 minse (Hcrodot., V, 77, VI, 79) ; under Dionys., I, 300 m. (Aristot., Oeconom, II, 21); under Philip of Macedon, from 300 to 400 m. (Demosth., De fals. Legat., 394); under Demetrios Poliorketes, 1,000 for a free man, 5 for a slave. (Dtod., XX, 84.) 4 This booty for Susa alone amounted to fi'om 40,000 to 50,000 talents; for Persepolis, to 120,000; for Pasargadse. to 600. Curtius, V, 2, 6; Strabo, XV, 731 ; Justin, XI, 14; Arnau, III, 16; Dwd., XVII, 66, 71 ; Plutarcli, Alex., 36. Sec. CXXXV.] HISTORY OF VALUES. 407 by the influx of Egptian war-booty/' It is a remarkable proof of the undeveloped condition of trade in the earlier pe- riods of ancient history, that the perturbations in prices were, apparently, at least, so entirely local. Phccnecia, Palestine etc., must have experienced, in the age of Solomon, a formal deluge of the precious metals, while Greece, for instance, was then, and for centuries after, extremely poor in them.^ It is not, on the whole, to be doubted, that the value in exchange of the precious metals was on a continual decline until the most flourishing time of the Roman emperors.''^ During the middle ages, it seems to have stood much higher again; be- cause the great loss of treasure caused by the migration of nations etc., the almost complete cessation of production at the mines, and the slowness of the circulation of money, played a much more important part than the decrease of trade.^ ^ * Of'os., VI, 19; £>to, C, LI, 21; Suet, Aug., 41. Decline of the value of money under Constantine the Great, when the precious objects of the heathen temples were coined. (Monitio ad Theod., Aug. de inbidenda Largitate, T/ies., Antt. Renn., XI, 1415; Taylor, ad Warm. Sandvic, 38.) 6 Compare I Kings, 10, 14, 27 fF.; I Chron., 22, 2 fF.; II Chron., 9, 15 f., 12, 10 ff. On Ophir: K. Ritter, Erdkunde, XIV, 407 f ; on the wonders of the discovery of Spain: Herodot., IV, 152. Aristot., De Mirab., 146; Diodor, V, 35 ft". On the other hand, of Greece, Athcn. VI, 19 ff. ' Compare Plin., H. N., XIV, i. Yet the value of money in the time of the Caesars seems to have stood much higher than it is now, as is proved, for instance, by the endowments by Trajan (16 sesterces per month for boys, and 12 sesterces per month for girls), as the alimenta furnished them accord- ing to Digest XXXIV, i, embraced their entire support. Compare the ex- cellent essay on this subject by Rodhertus, in Hildebrand's Jahi-bb., 1S70, I. 8 The conquest of the Avares seems to have temporarily produced a consider- able cheapness of the precious metals. (Gudrard, Polyptiques, I, 141.) In- crease of the value of money in Scandinavia, during the later part of the middle ages. (Wilda, Gesch. des deutschen Sti-afrechts, I, 323 if.) ^ In England, from 1279 to 1509, there were coined on an average only 6,86S>^ pounds sterling; from 1603 to 1830, on the other hand, 819,415 pounds sterling. The average in the time of George IV., per annum, was 4,262,652. Jacob, ch. IV.) An evidence of the uncertainty of the history of prices in the middle ages is, that Jacob, ch. 12, infers, from the price of corn, that the price of silver remained rather stationary from 1120 to 1550, while Adam Smitli, I, ch. II, 3, infers from the same fact, a remarkable rise in the 408 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Cii. IV. SECTION CXXXVI. c EFFECT OF THE DISCOVERY OF AMERICAN MINES ETC. ON THE VALUE OF THE PRECIOUS METALS. The discovery of America influenced the market of the precious metals less by the peculiar wealth of the mines in that part of the world than by their ahuost incredible number.^ The sources of wealth that the conquistadores first lighted upon were, however, much over-estimated.^ The production of the American mines first assumed great importance after the discovery of Potosi, in 1545, which was soon followed by the working of the American mines at Guanaxuato. (1558.) price of silver from 1350 to 1570, Concerning the latter, see Leber, Fortune privde au mojen. Age, 16 f. Tooke-Neivmarch^ History of Prices, VI, 391 ; whereas i?c^er5. Statist. Journ., 1S61, 544 ff., finds that in England, between 1300 and 1532, there was no change whatever in the pi-ice of silver. Accord- ing to Soetbeer, Forschungen zur deutschen Geschichte, VI, 94, wheat and rye were, as compared with silver, worth during the Carolingian period, about one-fourth of its value, between 1750 and 1S50. //^?o-c/, Shassburger Chroniken, II, 1012, ascribes to gold over 2|^ times as great a puixhasing power in the 13th and 14th centuries as in the 19th century; and to silver, a purchasing power about three times as great. ' The silver ores of Peru and Mexico yield, on an average, only from 2 to 3 per 1,000 of metal; those of Potosi, at present, scarcely i per 1,000; those of Mexico, according to Humboldt, on an average, from 3 to 4 ounces per cwt. ; so that many of the European ores are decidedly richer. While the veins of the Saxon mine, Himmelsfurst, have a breadth of only from 0.2 to 0.3 meters ; the Veta-Madre of Guanaxuato, is in few parts less than 8, and it is sometimes even 50 meters broad ; and the Veta-Grade of Zacatecas is from 5 to ID meters in breadth. In Pasco there are veins of silver ore which have 114 and even 123 meters. Tschudi, Reise in Peru, K., 12; Chevalier, Cours, III, 184 flf., 241 lY. According to Humboldt, Essai sur la Nouvelle Espagne, III, p. 413, eleven times as many miners are needed at Himmels- fiirst as at Valenciana to obtain the same quantity of silver. ^ Thus, for instance, the celebrated ransom-money of Athahualpa (even ac- cording to Garcilaso de la Vega) amounted to only 5,000,000 thalers, while the French King John, after the battle of Poitiers, in 1356, had to pay 41,000,000 francs for his ransom. (Leber, Fortune privde au moyen Age, 121 ff.) Sec. CXXXVI.] EFFECT OF NEW DISCOVERIES. 409 Coincident with this was the extraordinaiy " chance " of Medina's invention, in 1557, by means of which, it became possible to separate silver from foreign elements by the cool process of amalgamation, instead of melting it as had hither- to been done ; an invention all the more important in America, for the reason that in that country, where there is so much rich ore, there is scarcely any fuel, in the neighborhood ^ of where it is found. During the first hundred years the mines of Peru occupied the most prominent place; whereas they were afterwards completely overshadowed by the Mexican.'^ According to Humboldt,^ the annual export of gold and silver from America to Europe, between 1492 and 1500, amounted to 250,000 piasters; between 1500 and 1545, to 3,000,000;^ from that time to 1600, to 11,000,000; in the seventeenth cen- tury, to about 16,000,000; during the first half the eighteenth century to 22,500,000; during the second half, to 35,300,000. The production of gold in Brazil began to be important after the commencement of the eighteenth century,''' and the working of the Mexican silver mines of Valencia, Biscaina etc. from the middle of the same century. In the beginning of the nineteenth century, Mexico produced, annually, 537,512 kilo- grammes of silver, and 1,609 kilogrammes of gold; Peru, 140,078 and 782 of silver and gold respectively; Buenos Ayres, 1 10,764 and 506; Chili, 6,827 and 2,807 '■> New Granada, 4,714 kilogrammes of gold; Brazil, 3,700 kiUogrammes of ^Compare M. Chevalier, III, 190 ff. Discovery of the quicksilver mines of Guancavelica, 1567. ^ The yield of Potosi amounted from 1545 to 1638, to 395,619,000 pesos. ( Ulloa,Wa.^Q, II, I, 13.) Up to the present time, the aggregate yield there has been estimated at from 6,000 to 7,000 million francs. ^ On the worse grounded assumptions of former writers, see Humboldt, N. Espagne, IV, 237. * There was really introduced into Spain, about 1525, not much over 2,000,- 000 francs annually; and after 1550, six times as much. (L. Ranke, Fiirstcn und Volkcr, I, 347 ff.) Compare Humboldt, Ueber die Schwankungcn der Goldproduction, in the Vierteljahrsschrift, 183S, IV, iS. 1 On the Brazilian exports of gold in the iSth century, see Sddfcr, Gesch. von Portugal, V, 192 ff. 410 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [C. II, Cii. IV. gold; the whole of America together, 795,581 kilogrammes of silver and 14,018 kilogrammes of gold, worth about 60,750,000 thalers.^ During the uprisings between 1810 and 1825, which separated Spanish America from the mother country, the production of the mines diminished as surprisingly as it had increased in the previous generation by reason of the great- er liberality of Spanish colonial polic3\^ Since that time, a certain increase has, indeed, been noticed, which, however, had not immediately before the discovery of the gold mines of California by any means attained the height reached in 1808, but only an annual production of 701,570 kilogrammes of sil- ver, and of 15,215 kilogrammes of gold, with an aggregate value of more than 56,000,000 thalers.^" In Europe, also, the obtaining of the precious metals dur- ing the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries took a great stride, especially in Germany ;^^ but, on the other hand, the Spanish gold and silver mines were closed in 1535 by a law. In the seventeenth century, there was another lull, followed, at the end of the eighteenth, by a second period of activity which has not yet closed. The great development of the production of gold in the Ural mines since 18 19, and in the Altai mines since 1829,^^ the revival of the production of silver in the old Spanish 'According to Humboldt., N. E., IV, 218, the amount up to the beginning of tliis century Avas 17,000 kilogi-amnies of gold and 800,000 kilogrammes of silver. ' Thus, for instance, Mexico, during this period yielded, on an average, 65,000,000 francs, instead of the former amount of from 130,000,000 to 140,000,000. In Carro de Potosi, there were, in 1S26, of the former 132 pool- , works only 12 in operation. Compare Adams., The Actual State of the Mexican Mines, 1S22. Jacob assumes that about 1830, the quantity of money in Europe and America was ith less than in 1809. (Ch. 28.) ^'^ Of this, 1,800 killogrammes of gold from the United States. " Fischer., Geschichte des deutschen Handels, 2d ed., II, 616 ft'., 673 ff. But the Schwaz mines, in the Tyrol, are said to have produced, until 1523, 55,000 marks annually; the Freiberg silver mine, from 1542 to 1616, 16,000 marks annually. Compare von Langen, Kurfiirst Moritz, II, 56. '^The Russian gold ores, quite insignificant before the year 1814, have made very great progress since 1840. Their aggregate yield, between 1814 and 1861, not taking into account the amount embezzled, amounted to 37,000 Sec. CXXXVIL] REVOLUTION IN PRICES. 411 mines shice 1835,^^ and Pattinson's discovery, by means of which the poorest lead ores containing silver may be refined, are here of great importance.^^ Shortly before 1848, it was estimated that all the mines of the old world produced annu- ally about 274,cxx) kilogrammes of silver, and 56,000 kilo- grammes of gold, with an aggregate value of over 69,000,000 thalers." ^^ SECTION CXXXVIL REVOLUTION IN PRICES AT THE BEGINNING OF MODERN HISTORY. The mere discovery of new and richer mines need not, of itself, lower the price of the precious metals. Their price de- pends on their cost of production; and it may be very much increased, even under the most favorable natural conditions, by the unskillfulness of labor, the dearness of the means of fuds, the ;pud being equal to 16.3 kilogrammes. The best year, 1847, gave a yield of i,^c^'j fuds; 1852-1861, an average of 1,556 /«(/.?/ 1S61 alone, 1,442 j>itds, of which 1,041 came from the private Siberian gold-sand washings. (Walcher^ in Faucher's Vierleljahrsschrift, 1S69, II, 115.) "Spanish silver production yielded, in 1845, over 184,000 marks; in 1850, over 291,000. (Willkomm^ Halbinsel der Pyranaen, 1855, 537.) '■* Annales des Mines, X, 831 fl'. '^ Of this amount, there came to Europe, not including Russia, 150,000 kilogrammes of silver, 2,650 kilogrammes of gold; to Russia, 24,000 kilo- grammes of silver and 30,000 kilogrammes of gold (embracing the quantities probably withdrawn without the knowledge of the custom's authorities) ; to the rest of Asia, 100,000 kil. of gold; to Africa, 4,000. (M. Chevalier.) '^ According to Humboldfs assumption before the time of Columbus, Eu- rope had a circulation of 170,000,000 piasters; about 1600, of 600,000,000; about 1700, of 1,400,000,000; in 1809, of about 1,824,000,000. Up to 1803, there Avas produced in America, 9,915,000 marks (Spanish) of gold, and 512,700,000 of silver. (N. E., 245.) (?«//«;?/"« estimates that, before Columbus, there were 1,600,000,000 francs; in 1830, in Europe and America, from 22,000,000,000 to 27,000,000,000 francs. (Considerations on the Currency and Banking System of the United States, 1831.) According to M. Chevalier, 1850, all the silver which America produced had a volume of only 11,657 cubic meters ; and all the gold of only 151 cubic meters. The latter, there- fore, would not even fill the half of a French gentleman's salon. 412 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. IV. subsistence, of machinery and of auxiliary substances, by inse- curity to property or to the person ; by war, oppressive taxes^ etc. The new mines can produce a decline in the price of the precious metals only to the extent that, for the same amount of capital and labor expended, they, spite of all such deduc- tions, produce a greater result. ~ I opine that the price of metallic money, since the discovery of America, has diminished until the present time in the ratio of from three to four to one. * The prices of wheat in France, ' All the more in favor with governments because they affect principally foreign consumers. Thus, the Spanish government at first imposed a tax of 50 per cent, of the gross yield of the raw material, on the purchaser of sil- ver; since 1503, under Orando, of 33 J^ per cent,; and later yet, of 20 per cent. This last tax was therefore in full force under Cortes. This tax was reduced in Mexico, in 1725, and in Peru in 1736, to 10 per cent, and later, in the case of gold, to 3 per cent. Heavy taxation of Russian gold ore (35 per cent, of the raw material), by virtue of the ukase of April 14, 1849. Compare M. Chevalier, III, 274. * Cantillon, Nature du Commerce, 215, 236, shows very clearlj"- how the in- crease of the price of commodities was produced, in the first instance, by the increased consumption of the possessors of gold, and how it, therefore, first affected those commodities which they especially desired. * This is the opinion of Adam Smith. Similarly of David Hume, On Money. According to Letronne, Considerations sur I'Evaluation des Monnaies Grec- ques et romaines, 119, and Bockh, Staatshaushalt, I, 88, the average value of wheat in relation to silver was, in Athens, 400 B. C, as 1 : 3146; in Rome, 50 B. C, as i: 2681; in France, shortly before 1520 after Christ, as 1:4320; in the nineteenth century it is as 1 : 1050. Th. Smith, De Republ. Anglorum, I, assumes that the price of silver, from the age of chivalry to 1625, decreased in the ratio of 120: 40. The Spaniard, Moncado (1619), says as 6: i. (Jacob, ch. 19.) Jacob, himself, in comparison with his own time, as 7: i (ch. 15.) Much more moderate is JVewmarch in Tooke's History of Prices, VI, 345 ff., who assumes an increase in the prices of commodities of about 200 per cent. The estimated value of tithe-wine (Zehntivein) about doubled in lower Aus- tria, during the sixteenth century. (Oberleitner, Finanzlage N. Oesterreichs im 16 Jahrhundert, 36.) According to the important researches of Mantellier, Memoires de la Societe Archdologique de 1' Orleanais, vol. 1, 103 ff.; extract of Lespeyrcs in Hildebrand' s Jahrb., 1S65, 1, i, the purchasing power of silver as compared with the average value of twenty-seven commodities, assuming it to have been i from 1750 to 1850, was, from 1350 to 1450, 2.9; from 1450 to 1550, 2.8; from 1550 to 1650, 1.5 ; from 1650 to 1750, 2.1. According to Rogers, the prices of corn in relation to silver were from 1596 to 1636, at most 2.3 Sec. CXXXVII.J REVOLUTION IN PRICES. 413 from 1800 to 1850, were about seven times as great as in the second half of the fifteenth century; and in England about six times as great. But, it is not to be overlooked here, how wheat may have grown dearer in itself (an sich) and how gold declined considerably less than silver. True, this decline of the precious metals was not an entirely steady one. We meet at the beginning of the modern era with a real revolution in prices. The prices of rye, in lower Saxony, from 1525 to 1550, were twice as high as fi-om 1475 to 1500. According to Gamier, the French prices of wheat, from 1450 to 1500, were, on an average, 4.08 francs of the present time per sctkr; from 1501 to 1520, 5 francs; from 1522 to 1540, 11.26 francs; from 1541 to 1560, 11.69 francs; from 1561 to 1580, 21.33 francs; from 1581 to 1600, 32.51 francs; during the first half of the seventeenth centur}-, 22.77 francs; in the second half, 26.83 francs; from 1701 to 1750, 19.64 francs. Similarly in England, where wheat cost, from 1560 to 1600, 2.64 times as much as from 1450 to 1500.* times as high as from 1260 to 1400; from 1637 to 1700, 2.6 times; from 1701 to 1764, 2.1 times; from 1726 to 1S20, 3.2 times. (Rogers, I, iSo.) * In Germany, the rise in prices was first observed in the price of foreign groceries, which partly rose 400 per cent. Popular opinion looked for the cause in the evil disposition of the large commercial houses. In order to facilitate the competition of the smaller houses with the larger, the Reichstag, in 1522, prohibited all companies with a capital of more than 50,000 florins; and, in 1524, the royal treasury Avished to bring suit against the violators of this law. But the cities contrived to avert the blow. (L. Ranke, Geschichte der Reformation, II, 42 ff., 134 fl'.) In Spain, the government, especially be- tween 1550 and 1560, endeavored to oppose the growing dearness of goods of all kinds, by prohibiting the exportation of the most important commodi- ties, and by putting obstacles in the way of retail trade. The lower classes in England ascribed the rise to the suppression of the monasteries (Percy, Reliques of ancient Poetry, II, 296), while Henry VIII. endeavored to im- prove the condition of things by laws against luxury, the governmental establishment of fixed prices, the expulsion of foreign merchants etc. (21 Henry VIII.) The first writer who seems to have clearly seen the true cause of the changes in price was Bodhitis, Response aux Paradoxes de Mr. de Malestroit touchant I'Encherissement de toutes Choses et des Monnaies (11568). This work was translated into Latin by H. Cotiring^ 1671; and done 4:14: CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. IV. Now, the increased production of the mines cannot be the only cause of this great perturbation in prices. It commenced, in most countries, at a time when the supplies from America were still too small to account for such an effect. One of the chief causes of the phenoinenon was, that precisely at this pe- riod, there was in so many nations a transition from a sluggish circulation of money, made still more sluggish by the custom which everywhere prevailed of hoarding treasure, to a rapid circulation, which was inade still more rapid by the use of all kinds of substitutes for money. (§ 123).^ In the earliest ripe fruit of European civilization (Italy), this transition had long been accomplished; and, on that account, the value in ex- change of the precious metals was there, for a long time pre- vious, comparatively low.'' From the second third of the seventeenth century, the value of the medium of circulation seems, on the whole, to have re- mained stationaiy,''^ Tooke seeks to demonstrate the steady over in the Avoi-k: Discours sur les Causes de I'extrSme Chertd, qui est aujourd'hui en France (1574). Next, Ave have the English author W. S., A Compendious or briefe Examination of certayne ordinary Complaints of divers of our Countryinen of these our Daj's, London, 1581. In BefohVs Vitoe et Mortis Consideratio politica, 1623, 13 f., we have a right explanation of the caritas sine inopia which is to be considered as the common property of his time. 5 Similarly ^ues>tay, 77, Daire. Sir ji^. Stetvart^ Principes, ch. 3. Kraus, Vermischte Schriften, II, 131 ft". Hennan7t, Staatsw. Unters., 127. Hclferich^ Von den periodischen Schwankungen im Werth der edlen Metalle, 1S43, 70 f. ^ According to Cibrario, a hectoliti-e of wheat was worth, in Turin, from 12S9 to 1379, on an average, 905 gr. of fine silver; that is, about three times as much as in Paris before the discovery of America, and as much as in Paris from 1546 to 1556. In Turin, from 1825 to 1835, it was worth about 1702 gr. In the fifteenth century even, the foreign embassadors complain of the enormous cost of living there. So, for instance, Ratimer's histor. Tasch- enbuch, 1833, 162. Compare also, Carli, Del Valore della Proporzione dei Metalli monetati con i Generi in Italia prima delle Scoperte dell' Indie, 1760, in which he, indeed, exaggerates the matter, and seeks to prove his views by the coarsest sophistry. ■" The chief result of HelfericKs excellent researches. (HelfericJt, loc. cit.) The general opinion, indeed, is that this statu quo of the value of the pre- Sec. CXXXVIL] REVOLUTION IX PRICES. 415 decline of the value of money until late in the eighteenth cent- ury, from the fact that the wages of labor increased during that time; but I should rather connect the latter phenomenon with the simultaneous elevation of the classes engaged in manual labor. And so Adam Smith infers a rise in the price of money after the beginning of the eighteenth century, from the prices of wheat ;^ but it would be better to consider the cause of this to be the unusuall}' long series of good crops.^ An equally unusually long series of bad harvests, during the second half of the centur}', accounts satisfactorily for the sim- ultaneous rise of the medium prices of corn. The great war which lasted from 1793 to 1815, too, according to a very prevalent opinion, must have caused the value of money to decline; a fact which is generally accredited to the increase of paper money in so many states. Every great w^ar may very easily have for effect to slacken the speed of the circulation of mone}", to promote the hoard- ing and even the burial of treasure for a rainy day, and to par- alyze credit and its power to supply the place of money. Hence, it seems preferable to seek for the cause of the vari- ations in price, during the great war, in the commodities them- selves whose price was afiected; since their production must cious metals was interrupted about the middle of the eighteenth century by another decline, and that the latter yielded to a subsequent rise in 1S15 and afterwards. Thus David Hume^ History of England, ch. 44, App. 31, ch. 49, App. A. Toung^ Political Arithmetics, ch. 6. More recently, Rau^ Lehr- buch, I, § 176. M. Chevalier, Cours, III, 320 ff. One of the principal advo- cates of the opinion that &\^rj increase made in the medium of circulation produces a corresponding depreciation is Nebenius, Deutsche Vierteljahrs- schrift (1841). In England a quarter of Avheat was worth, on an average, 38s. -|d., from 1595 to 1685. On a similar stability of corn prices in Belgium, see ScJnverz, Belgische Landwirthschaft, III, 37. According to Suckburg (1. c), the value in exchange of money from 1640 to 1700 declined 32-I per cent.; from 1700 to 1760, 43 per cent; from 1760 to 1806, 84 per cent. ^Frorn 1637 to 1700 the price of corn in England averaged 51 shillings; from 1701 to 1764 only 40^ shillings. ' Thus, the dearness of wheat in Germany, during the first thirty years after the Thirty Years' War was caused, in large part, by the depopulation produced by the War. ilG CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Cii. IV have been enormously disturbed. It rendered the brawniest men and the most powerful horses unproductive, and even employed them as agents of destruction. It interrupted trade in a thousand ways, or drove it into unnatural channels, and turned the intellectual interests of nations into every direction save that of economic industry. To this must be added the absence of security everywhere.^'' The cessation of these restrictions upon production, in con- sequence of the restoration of peace throughout the world and the great progress afterwards made in almost all branches of industry, explain why, from 1818 to 1848, the precious metals have apparently stood higher than during the period immedi- ately preceding.^^ ^^ SECTION CXXXVIII. REVOLUTION IN PRICES. — INFLUENCE OF THE NON-MON- ETARY USE OF GOLD AND SILVER. To understand why so great an increase in the production of the precious metals produced so small a decline of their value in exchange, we must turn our attention to the other and further uses of gold and silver. The amount devoted to these uses can never be very accurately determined, since '" In Germany, also, the cause of the enhanced dearness of so many goods during the Thirty Years' War is to be sought for in the goods themselves. " Since 1815, most Birmingham and Sheffield wares have fallen from 50 to 70 or 80 per cent, in price — at least from 20 to 30. (McCulloc/t, Statist. Account, I, 705.) The Quarterly Review, May, 1830, speaks even of an average de- cline of prices of English commodities in general, of 50 per cent. '2 Excellently carried out in Tooke, History of Prices, III, 1838. That the world's market is not so very readily affected by an increase of the medium of circulation, is established by this fact, among others, that the immense ex- portation of French metallic money in consequence of the issue of paper money between 1716 and 1720, and again in 1790 and the following years, is coincident with very low prices of wheat in the neighboring countries. (Hel- ferich, loc. cit., 139, 190 ff.) And yet, in the former case, the amount was 400,000,000 francs, and in the latter, at least 1,000,000. Sec. CXXXVIII.] REVOLUTION IN PRICES. 417 governmental stamping of every new gold or silver article would atlbrd no evidence as to the number of such articles manufactured out of old articles etc. ^ Certain it is, however, that the aggregate amount of gold and silver thus employed, increases with the increase of luxury and wealth among mod- em nations, and that a quantity of the precious metals thus used, especiall}^ when used for purposes of gilding for instance, is irrestorably lost. '~ In addition to this, there is the wear and ' yacob estimates this part at only 2^ per cent., McCulloch^ at 20, Lowe at 25, Necker and Hdferich at 50, Humboldt at 66^ of the whole quantity worked. It certainly is, in our day, on account of the ever growing aggre- gate supply, greater than hitherto ; but it is very different in different coun- tries. Nebenius^ Deutsche Vierteljahrsschrift, 1851, 56 seq., estimates the aggi'egate consumption of new gold and silver for industrial purposes at 14^2 piasters yearly, and in addition to this seven millions of old gold and silver (Bruchgold nnd Bruchsilber). The annual wear and tear of previously ex- isting articles of gold and silver, it is estimated, amounts to 4,420,000 piasters (^Itt)' ^^^ annual increase of their aggregate amounts in Europe to 6,000,000 piasters (i_J^ per cent., corresponding to the increase of population), and 4,- 200,000 (one-fith of the entire consumption), is employed, as he claims, in gilding, plating etc. The last item is probably much increased by galvanic silver-plating, the invention of photography etc. 2 Jacob embraces in the amount of metal employed in industrial purposes, in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, \ of the amount which, after de- ducting the loss in Asiastic trade, was added to the gold and silver stores of Eui-ope; i. e., in the seventeenth century, about 2,500,000 piasters yearly; in the eighteenth century, % (l); that is, annually, 15,000,000 piasters; in 1S30, in England, £2,457,221; in France, 120,000; Switzerland, 350,000; in the rest of Europe, 1,605,490; in North America, about 300,000; altogether, £5,900,000. Humboldt's estimate is 2 1,000,000 piasters; McCtdlock^s, £6,0^0,000. Accord- ing to the records of the Paris Monnate, the amount of silver ware in France increased seven fold between 1709 and 1759. (Humboldt.) In England, be- tween 1807 and 1S14, 8,290,000 ounces of silver were stamped for manufac- turing purposes: from 1S30 to 1837, only 7,387,000; in 1851, 924,000. AIc- Cullocli estimates the annual consumption of silver, in Birmingham alone, lor plating purposes, at 150,000 ounces; in Sheffield, at 500,000; and the gold consumption in the pottery districts at £650 per week. Birmingham con- sumed (1831) for gilding purposes, £1,000 gold yearly. (Whatcly.) It now employs weekly 3,000 ounces of gold and 6,000 ounces of silver in the man- ufacture of gold and silver ware, besides the quantity intended for gilding and silver-washing purposes. (Quart. Rev., April, 1S66, 3S1.) The jewelers of New York manufacture yearly 3,000,000 of dollars worth of gold and Vol. I. — 27 418 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. IV. tear of coin in circulation, which is naturally greater in the case of large pieces than of small, and, therefore, in the case of silver than of gold. There is, further, the damage caused by the loss of coin in conflagrations and shipwrecks, and that occasioned by buried and forgotten treasure. ^ But, lastly, the principal cause consists in the powerful in- crease of the demand for money, which, during the last two centuries, the great impulse given to the rapidity of circula- tion, and the great increase in the substitutes for money, have scarcely been able to outweigh. Besides the great growth silver ware, mostly new material. (Economist, April i6, 1853.) There were in Vienna, in 1781, only 167 workers in gold and silver; in 1840, 229; in 1847, 539. (Baumga7-tner^ in the Wiener Akademie, May 3, 1S57.) yacob esti- mates the aggregate mass of gold and silver ware, in plate, instruments etc., in Europe and America, to be ij^ as great as that of the ready money; and in England alone to be twice as great (ch. 28) ; while Tengoborski thinks that at the beginning of the nineteenth century, the coin constituted 2^ of the entire amount of the precious metals. Sometimes a movement in the opposite direction takes place, as, for instance, in those revolutions in which the silver of the church was confiscated; in the imfortunate wars of Louis XIV., etc. Nebmius, loc. cit., 17, mentions a South German silversmith who melted down in the years succeeding 1802, monastery silver to the amount of 11,000,000 guldens. ^ On the wear and tear of coin, see § 120, and Hermann^ in the Archiv. der politischen Oek., I, 1841. Compare also, Faust, Concilia pro Aerario, 1641, 263 fF, This wear and tear is so great that AI. Chevalier supposes that it alone would suffice to reduce an amount of money under Constantine the Great of 5,000 millions to 300 millions, in the time of Philip IV. (ob. 1314.) Cours, II, 322. How great a number of coins, especially of the snxaller de- nominations, are entirely lost is evident from the fact, that at the time of the demonetization of the 15-sous and 30-sous pieces of 1791-92, amounting to 25,000,000, only 16,000,000 were presented for redemption. Of the lo-centime pieces stamped with an N, amounting to 3,286,932 francs, there were only 2,000,000 left when they were withdrawn from circulation, and this although individuals had added to the coinage. (M. Chevalier, III, 321.) The total loss caused on this score, McCulloch estimates at i per cent, per annum, and Helferich, at ^ per cent. The greater the aggregate stock of gold and silver, the greater the absolute amount of wear and tear. If, therefore, there were annually an equal influx of mineral products to the markets, the pressure of this increase of supply from that cause alone would take the shape of a con- verging series of prices. (Toohe, History of Prices, II, 151 ft") Sec. CXXXVIIL] REVOLUTION IN PRICES. 419 of population and of wealth, at least in Europe and the new world, I need call attention only to the immense advance made in the division of labor, and to the transition from trade by barter to trade through the instrumentality of money. The entire war and merchant marine of England, about 1602, had, according to Anderson, a capacity of only 45,000 tons, — that is, not one-fifth of what the small city of Bremen has now ; a capacity which at the close of the year 1873 amounted to 237,206 tons — while in 1872 its merchant marine alone had a capacity of 7,213,000 tons. The aggregate foreign trade of England, France, Russia and the United States, in 1750, amounted to about 260,000,000 thalers; in 1864, it was over 5,400,000,000, and between 1871 and 1872, in one year, over 9,000,000,000 thalers. Nor should it be forgotten that Europe's trade with the East, since the beginning of the six- teenth century, increased immensely. This, at present, pro- duces uniformly a very " unfavorable balance" for Europe, which can be made up for only by very large shipments of silver to foreign parts.* If China and India were suddenly to * The British East India Company exported gold and silver on an average per annum from : 171 1 — 1720, ...... £434,000 1 72 1— 1730, 532,000 1731— 1740> ...... 487,000 1741— 1750, ...... 631,000 1751—1760, ...... 571,000 1761 — 1770, ...... 152,000 1771 — 1780, ...... 43,000 1781— 1790, 393.000 1791 — iSoo, ...... 352,000 1801 — 1807, ....... 852,000 Milhurn^ Oriental Commerce, 1S13, 419. According to M. Chevalier^ In- troduction aux Rapports de 1' Exposition de 1867, the trade of Europe and North America, with India, China, Japan and the Australian islands, amounted in 1800, to only 410 million francs, in 1S66, to 4,024 million. Yet, for a time, the largely increased exportation of English manufactures to East India and of East Indian opium to China, had changed the relation so that the exportation of the precious metals from South Asia, by a great deal, more than counterbalanced the imports. On the other hand, between 1853 and 1856, 420 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. IV. draw on us for other commodities instead of gold and silver, the result would be a great revolution in prices in Europe. SECTION CXXXIX. HISTORY OF PRICES. — CALIFORNI AN AND AUSTRALIAN DISCOVERIES. Tengoborski is of opinion, that the flow of gold from Sibe- ria alone would have been absorbed by the ever-increasing want of civilized nations of money; but that the coincident dis- coveries in California and Australia, in September 1847, and February 185 1, must sooner or later produce a revolution in prices. And, indeed, the fecundity of these countries is un- paralleled. North America, which in 1846 produced only 3,600 pounds of gold, according to Soetbeer, produced in the years from 1849 to 1863, respectively, 118,000, 148,000, 178,000, 195,000, 180,000, 165,000, 165,000, 165,000, 160,000, 145,000, 125,000, 120,000, 115,000 and 110,000. Austria produced in the years from 1851 to 1863 respectively, 27,000, 196,000, 250,000, 160,000, 170,000, 195,000, 180,000, 175,000, 160,000, 150,000, 160,000, 160,000, 170,000, pounds of gold. Prom 1864 to 1867, the aggregate production of gold in the world was, according to the last mentioned authority, a yearly average of 188.4 minions of thalers, and of silver, 94,8 millions. In Europe, Russia not included, the production was, in 1863, 240,ooo,cxx) thalers were shipped to India and China from England and the Mediterranean harbors ; in 1863 and 1S64, even as much as 300 millions, to be, for the most part, buried there. Moreover, the immense quantity of cash money — often as much as from 12 to 15 million in pounds sterling — in the state ti-easury, and silver ornaments (§§ 44, 123) customary in India, demand a considerable yearly supply to make up for wear. Nexvmarch speaks of 400 million pounds sterling which can be maintained in its condition hitherto by a yearly increase of i per cent. (History of Prices, VI, 723.) From 1865 to 1869, English steamships carried gold and silver to the East in the following quantities, yearly : 93.9, 66.3, 24.6, 70.2 and 60.4 million thalers, in addition to which almost as much came directly from California. Statist. Journ., 1871, 122 seq. Sec. CXXXIX.] HISTORY OF PRICES. 421 3,960 pounds of gold and 405,000 pounds of silver; in the Russian Empire, 46,500 pounds of gold and 40,000 of silver; in Mexico 12,000 pounds of gold and 1,250,000 pounds of silver; in South and Central America, 12,500 pounds of gold and 520,000 pounds of silver; in Africa, India and Lesser Asia, 30,000 pounds of gold and 40,000 pounds of silver — a total of 384,000 pounds of gold, and 2,905,000 pounds of silver. F. X. Neu- mann ^ "^ estimates that the whole world produced, in the years ' Tooke-Nezvinaixh, History of Prices, VI, 147 If., estimates the aggregate stock of gold at the end of 1S48 at £5,600,000; in 1856, at £172,000,000 more. According to Lavasseur^ the amount of silver in the East increased, between 1848 and 1S57, from 22 to 24 milliards of francs; andthe amount of gold from 9^ to 15^ milliards. (Annuarie d'Economie politique, 1858, 632.) The total amount of gold and silver in the civilized world, Wolovjski estimated at from 55 to 60 milliards of francs, in 1S70. (L'Or et I'Argent, Enqugte, 19.) Compare Mason^ The Gold Regions of California from the Official Reports, 1848. Teiigoborski^p-wx les Gites auriferes de la Californie et de I'Australie, 1S53. Goldfield's Statistics issued from the Mining Department in Victoria, 1S62. W. R. Blake, The Production of the precious Metals, or statist No- tice of the principal Gold and Silver producing Regions of the World (New York, 1869). 2 Soetbeer's Denkschrift betr. die deutsche Munzeinigung Mai, 1869, aud earlier yet, in FaucJier''s Vierteljahrsschrift, 1865, II, According to M. Che- valier, all the mines of the world, a short time previous to 1S65, produced 284,000 kilogrammes of gold, and 190,000 kilogrammes of silver in a year; a total of 373,000 thalers (Journal des Economistes, Jime, 1866), while, in 1848, the total amount of gold coinage in the world was estimated at 560,- 000,000; Great Britain, France, North America and Sidney had, since that time and up to 1871, added to this £597,780,000. The additions have been made in decreasing quantities: thus, 1857-59, 37-2 millions annually; 1869-71, 16.99 millions annually. (Statist. Journ., 1872, 376 ff.) The estimates as to how much a gold-digger might make in a day have been variously estimated. Thus, Larkin estimates it from $25 to $50; Mason, at $10; Folson, at $25 to $40; Butler King, at $16, reckoning one ounce at $16. All these estimates seem to give an altogether too high average. In Australia, according to Khull, Colonial Review, June, 1853, a digger can produce only one ounce daily, or less than 4 thalers. According to W. Stamer^ Recollections of a Life of Adventure, II, 1866, a gold-washer in Victoria earned in 1S58, on an average, £250 per year; in 1865, only £70; while day labor was worth 15 shillings. Hence, great hopes have to be built on the lottery-nature of gold- washing. On the Rhine, a gold-washer is satisfied with 7^ of a gramme of gold, that is worth from 13 to 18 silver groschens. (Dauhrie, Comptes rendus de 1' Academic des Sciences, XXII, 639.) It should be borne in mind, how- 422 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. IV. 1868-1870, annually, 192.8 million thalers of gold, and 94 mil- lion thalers of silver; and in 1873, ^f both metals, 291 million thalers. The question, whether in this second half of the nineteenth century, we are to have a revolution in prices similar to that which took place in the sixteenth century can be ansv^^ered only hypotheticaUy. The gold diggings now most productive will, probably, as we may judge from analogous cases in the past, be soon exhausted. ^ But it is entirely possible that, for ever, that the Rhine-lander devotes to gold-washing only the leisure time which his avocation as a-fisherman leaves him, while the gold-washer in the new world, as a rule, devotes his whole time to it; and that his labors are in- terrupted by tlie long rainy season, attacks of fever etc. To this must be added the great difference of the average prices of the means of subsistence and the difference of all social conditions. 3 Compare, for instance, on the early productiveness of the Brazilian gold districts which soon ceased : Sj>ix iind Martins^ Reise nach Brasilien, I, 262 f., 350. Gardner^ Travels in the Interior of Brazil, 1S46. On Hispaniola, see Benzoin, N. Mundo, I, 6i, and Peschel, Gesch. der Entdeckungen, 304, 556. Hitherto, gold had been obtained by the usual mining process, only in very few places. As a rule, it has been found in alluvial land not far from the surface. Compare Ansted, The Gold-Seekers' Manual, 1849. These cir- cumstances have made the production of gold important from the first; and they still make it comparatively easy, while it causes little demand for capital but for great skill. As soon, therefore, as the greater part of the country washed for gold has been worked, which does not require a long time, the whole is abandoned, while in the production of silver the great amount of capital fixed in pits, shafts, kilns etc. ties the parties engaged in the enterprise to the spot, and necessitates the continuation of the enterprise. In recent times, however,. Australia and California have developed the mining and machine production of gold to a surprising extent. According to Laur, La Production des Metaux precieux en Californie, 1862, 33, and the Journal des Economistes, Nov. 1862, Californian gold-quartz produced, in 1851, on an average, 635 francs per ton; in i860, only from 80 to 85 francs; but the gold- washing methods have become cheaper in the ratio of 2,500: i. How- ever, the production of the precious metals seems even now to be decreasing According to the Statist. Journal, 1866, 99, it amounted on an average to Gold. Silver. 1849 — 51, - - £23.9 million. £15.5 million. 18^2—56, ... - 38.7 " 16.1 1S57— 59, - - - 36-5 " I7-I 186(^63, .... 33.5 " 18.2 1864—68, - - - 30.0 " 19.5 " Sec. CXXXIX.] HISTORY OF PRICES. 423 a long series of years, other diggings will be found equally rich. It is almost certain that the restless activity of the Eng- lish and of North Americans will not cease until they have exhausted the favors of nature. ^ Every improvement in agri- culture, in the means of communication, and in the public se- curity of the gold lands, makes the cost of production smaller. There are doubtless in other countries a great many placers which need only to be touched with, the linger of European civilization to produce gold in abundance. ^ It would, indeed, be necessary that this same civilization should make these same countries better markets for the precious metals by in- creasing their demand. The number of gold-diggers in Victoria steadily decreased from 125,764 in 1S57, to 63,053 in 1S67. * One of the chief difficulties in the way of the production of gold is the loss by embezzlement, which is estimated at an average of 20 per cent. Small companies of men working on their own account would be less ex- posed to temptation, and the Anglo-Saxon races and the North Americans are very well adapted thereto. (M. Chevalier^ III, 261.) 5 Gold is in a certain sense one of the most widespread of metals, although it is found anywhere only in small quantities; so that on the Rhine, for in- stance, it takes from 17 to 22 millions of gold grains to make a kilogramme. An extraordinarily large number of places owe their civilization to gold- seekers. Compare Tacitus^ Agi'., 12. I select the following " finds " from Ritter's Erdkunde. The Shangallas (I, 249); still more the terrace of Faz- oglu itself (I, 253, compare Bruce^ Travels, V, 316, VI, 255, 342), in Monomo- tapa (I, 140); in Manica, west from Sofala (I, 145), especially since the sup- pression of the slave trade (I, 305, 471); in Mandigo land (I, 360, 372); on the road from Gambia to Timbuctoo (I, 457); on Lake Mangara (I, 493) ; between Timbuctoo and Finnin (I, 445); in Nubia (I, 667, seq.); unused silver and quicksilver mines on the lower Bagradas (I, 493) ; gold wealth at Malacca, aurea chersonesus (V, 6 f, 27); Tonkin, Lao and Ava (III, 926, 1,2 16, IV, I, 213); Assam (IV, 294); smaller Thibet (III, 657); Kashmere (III, 1,155); on i:pper Setledsch (III, 654 ff., 668); in the mountainous sources of the Indus (III, 508, 529, 593, 60S); on the Cabool (VII, 23); in Peshaver (VII, 223); Badakschan (VTI, 795); rich silver mines abandoned for want of wood near Herat (VIII, 243); in Armenia (X, 273). It is said that in southern China there are great treasures of the precious metals, the removal of which has been opposed thus far. (IV, 756.) Arabia's richness in gold mines, spoken of by Diodor.^ II, 50, III, 45, and Agatharch, De Mare rubro, 60, is of doubtful existence, as no traces of them are to be found in the country to-day. 4:24: CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. IV. So far as silver is concerned, there can be no question that America possesses mines unlimited in extent, and, as yet, almost untouched. " The time will come," says Duport,^ " a century sooner or later, when the production of silver will have no other limits than those put to it by the continual decline in the price of silver." There seems, also, to be no lack of quicksilver, especially in California; and the cost of its production hitherto may be lessened very much by the labor of better workmen, machines and means of transporta- tion.''' All this supposes great progress of the mining countries in civilization in general ; and yet, thus far, Mexico's republi- can independence etc., as compared with the later years of the Spanish colonial system there, is a great retrogression. The conquest of Spanish America by the United States would give a vast impetus to economic improvement; and here, On the other hand, on both shores of the Pacific Ocean, the portions of the earth richest in volcanoes seem to possess almost everywhere quantities of gold equal to those of California and Victoria. (Edinburgh Revievv^, Jan., 1863, 82 ff.) What an amount of treasure can be obtained at times from old and long since forgotten "iinds " is proved by the Altai (that is gold mountain), which even the old Tschudi had rummaged (K. Rittc}\ II); and where Herodotus' (III, 16) love of truth, so frequently called in question, has re- cently been so brilliantly vindicated. Compare v. Ungern-Sternberg^ Gesch. des Goldes, 1835. A. Erman, Ueber die geographische Verbreitung des Goldes, 1835. According to MurcJiison, Siberia, ch. 17, gold is to be found only " in crystalline and paleozoic rocks, or in the drift from these rocks, which is a tertiary accumulation of the pliocene age ;" and that it is found most abundantly " in quartz-ore, vein-stones and traverse altered Silurian slates, chiefly lower Silurian, frequently near their junction with eruptive rocks." ^ Compare Humboldt, N. Espagne, IV, 147 ff. ; St. Clair Duport, Essai sur la Production des Metaux precieux en Mexique, 1843; M. Chevalier, Cours., Ill, 483 ff ' The cost of a kilogramme of silver, expressed in terms of silver itself, up to the moment that it is shipped, is estimated by Diiport as follows: salt and magistral, 61 grainmes; quicksilver, 112 grammes; stamping it, 171 grammes ; transformation of the ore, 72 grammes ; rent and superintendence, 38; duties etc., 145 ; smelting, transportation and shipping, 35. There remains as profit for mining it, 336 grammes. As to how the production of Ameri- can silver increases and runs parallel with the cheapness of quicksilver, see Humboldt, N. Espagne, IV, 91 ff. Sec. CXXXIX.] HISTORY OF PRICES. 425 again, the increase of production would be attended by an in- creased demand. But especially must the demand for the precious metals, which naturally increases with the wealth, commerce and lux- ury of nations, constitute a decisive element in answering our question. Nothing, for instance, were a reduction in prices impending, would promote it so much as a series of devastat- ing wars or revolutions in Em-ope. Moreover, it should not be forgotten, that the money market is now almost commen- surable with the world, and will soon embrace it within its limits ; and that market embraces not only the precious metals but the numberless representatives of money and media of credit. The basin, therefore, to which the gold and silver streams of the world are tributary is immeasurably greater than it was in the sixteenth century ; its level cannot be changed as readily, and an equal addition made every year to its pre- vious contents can increase it only by a small amount.^ Nor could a considerable decline of the value of the precious met- als be readily produced without making the circulation of money slower, and the employment of means of credit rela- tively less frequent, in consequence of which, the further de- cline would, to a certain, extent, be arrested.* In the case of other commodities a decline of prices leads only probably to an absolutely greater demand ; in the case of money, it leads to a demand necessarily greater. That the money market in our days can stand pretty rude shocks is evident from the fact, among others, that the price of gold is so high as com- pared with that of silver.^° ^^ 8 Wolotvski calculates that the absolutely much smaller yearly increment to the amount of the precious metals in the sixteenth century, frequently j'^, now constitutes only -^^ of the greater existing amount. (L'Or et I'Argent Enqu6te, 50.) 8 In the United States the stock of cash money in 1S20 was estimated at 5.1 thalers per capita; in 1849, at 8.6 thalers; in 1S54, °'^ ^'^^ other hand, at 13 thalers. ">The weight of the mass of gold introduced into Europe annually stood to that of silver in the ratio of i : 60-65, i" the seventeenth century ; in the 426 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. IV. SECTION CXL. REVOLUTION IN PRICES. — ITS INFLUENCE ON THE NA- TIONAL RESOURCES. The ulterior consequences of such a revolution in prices would contribute to the real wealth of a people only in the sense that they would place such a people in a way, with less sacrifice, to employ the precious metals on a large scale in min- first hall of the eighteenth century, in that of 1:30; in the second half, in that of 1 : 40; and yet the variations in price were not in the least parallel. According to Scetbeer (Beitrage und Materialien zur Beurtheilung von Geld und Bankfragen, 1855, 102 seq.), the average silver-course (stlbercurs) of gold had, 1852-54, sunk only 2.05 per cent., as compared with that of iSoo-40. And yet the value of the annual production of gold stood to the annual pro- duction of silver, in the beginning of the nineteenth century, as 29 to 71 ; in 1846, as 47 to 53; in 1848-56, as 3 to i. " While the public, even since 1850, think they have noticed a depreciation in the value of money, there are a great many learned political economists who are by no means prepared to grant it. The principal advocates of this opinion are Tooke, and Nexvinarch,ir\ vol. VI. of the History of Prices (1857). Also Lavergne, in the Journal des Economistes. And really the enhanced dearness of many kinds of goods up to 1S57, might have been accounted for by causes affecting the goods themselves: diminished supply by reason of bad harvests, commercial gluts etc.; increased demand by capitalization on a gigantic scale, speculation, but especially by the elevation of the lower classes etc. The London Avholesale prices were on the 1st day of January, 1869, near- ly all lower by 10 per cent, than on the ist day of July, 1S57. Only in- digo, cotton and meat had risen. (Hildeb rand's Jahrb., 1S70, I, 328.) In many instances the enhanced dearness is entirely local, by reason of the greater facilities for transportation in places where prices were already high- er. But as new truths are very easily exaggerated by their discoverers, much of Tooke's view concerning these events depends upon a polemic car- ried too far against the theory of the balance of trade which was customary in the so-called currency school. Compare, in opposition to Tooke, Lavas- sciir, in the Journal des Economistes, March, 1S38, and M. Chevalier, La Baisse probable de I'Or, 1858. Lavassetir, from the difference between the official and real custom-house prices in France, calculates that raw materials in 1856 were on the average 63 per cent., and in 1858, 20 per cent, higher than in 1826; and that manufactured articles were in 1856, just as high, and in 1858, 6 per cent, lower than in 1856. An average made of all commodities Sec. CXL.] REVOLUTION IN PRICES. 427 istering to the luxuries of life. This small ach'anlage itself would be counterbalanced by the depreciation of the metallic stock, and especially by the necessity of henceforth devoting a larger quantity of gold and silver to the purposes of circula- tion.^ But such a revolution would produce a sudden reverse in the distribution of a nation's wealth amon In the sixteenth century, this class was of small importance in most coun- tries ; in our times, their ruin would cause general disturbance. The wiser class of capitalists would, indeed, find means to exchange their credits for more certain values, or make it a condition that they should receive in the end a large sum. ^Thus, for instance, the son of a deceased land owner who retains the lands as his own acquits himself towards his brothers who have entered the Sec. CXL.] REVOLUTION IN PRICES. 420 Other hand, owners of large estates who have alienated their tithe-rights, or right to vassal-service etc. for capital, or for fixed sums to be paid at regular intervals, that is, in a great many places the great mass of the nobilit}'', undergo a not insignificant social fall. The condition of those who earned a living by manual labor no doubt deteriorated in the sixteenth centur}', as ma}'^ be in- ferred from the extraordinary activity of public charity in that period. Between 1500 and 1550, silver purchased, in Orleans, from 4.1 to 4.5 times as much common labor as it does now, while silver, as compared with the average price of twenty-seven commodities, has grown cheaper in the ratio of only from 2.6 to 2.7:1. (Mantellier.) It was impossible for this class to raise the price of their wares as rapidly as that of the medium of circulation declined, because they could not wait, nor hold back their commodity even for a moment. (§ 164.) ^ This would, indeed, be very difTerent in our day. Wages, because of the facilities, both physical and moral, which have every- where been placed in the wa}- of emigration, were necessarily one of these articles which rose soonest in price, as compared with money.^° Lastly, the state itself profits by the diminished military or civil service of their country by paying them a certain sum peri- odically. If a revolntion were really impending, the owners of land would soon emulate one another to improve their estates by borrowing capital, if for no other reason, to turn the depreciation of the medium of circulation to their own advantge. In the sixteenth century, the indebtedness of land owners was relatively unimportant. 9 It appears from Roger's Tables, Statist. Journal, 1861, 551 ft", that, between 15S3 and 1620, a time during which the population of England increased neither in wealth nor in numbers, there was a considerable increase in the price of nearly all English commodities. Thus, for instance, wheat was, from 1591 to 1600, 468 per cent., and from 1611 to 1620, even 495 per cent, higher than from 1530 to 1533. The Saxon laborer earned, in 1599, in corn, only half as much as in 1455. (Tiibinger Ztschr., 1871, 354.) "> When labor is indispensable to employers, it may happen that a small decline in the supply may largely raise the price. Wages, in almost all branches of labor, rose between 1851 and 1856, by about from 15 to 20 per cent. 430 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. IV. thing-value, that is, real value of its public debt ; ^^ but it loses, at the same time, on all taxes, duties etc., which are not esti- mated at a certain percentage of the value of the articles taxed.'^^ As a rule, therefore, it would need to impose new taxes. Now, the parliamentary right to impose taxes, how- ever extensive it may juridically be, is, ordinarily, of great importance in practice only when there is question of increas- ing the existing burthen. Hence, this right, wherever it ex- ists, is brought into the utmost activity by a revolution in prices.-*^ ^* However, the new additions of gold and silver to the already existing supply may not immediately produce a correspond- ing depreciation of the value of the precious metals. If the first receivers of the additional supply of money exchange it rapidly for other goods, it will probably bring them the former value in exchange of the metal. Not until it has passed into a third or fourth person's hands is the depreciation apt to be perceptible. It is, therefore, in this case, a great advantage to be the first hand. The world-threatening power of Spain, in the seventeenth century, was very essentially promoted by the American gold and silver mines ; ^^ nor is it a matter of less " This, also, was of little significance in the sixteenth century, but how important now ! J^ Income taxes, ad valorem duties and tithes rise and fall in their nominal amount as the price of the medium of circulation falls and rises. 13 Thus, for instance, the victory of the English Parliament over the un- limited power of the crown, in the first half of the seventeenth century, was very much promoted by the fact that the crown, in spite of all its economy, was always in financial straits in consequence of the depreciation of money. (Power of the purse, power of the sword!) However, any force kept stead- ily in action is a two-edged sword. While under favorable circumstances, it may be thereby developed, under unfavorable circumstances it may be thereby exhausted. How great a number of representative assemblies, during the revolutions in prices in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, allowed their energies to grow dormant! '^ Most of the above points are very well discussed in the work W. S., cited above, § 137. '* As no one then doubted : Compare TV. Raleigh^ The Discovery of Guiana, Pref. I refer to Philip of Macedon, Sec. CXLI.J EFP^ECT OF ENHANCEMENT. 431 significance to-da}-, lliat the great mineral wealth of the world belongs to Siberia, California and Australia ; that is, especially to Russia and to countries colonized by Great Britain. Fur- ther, as to the classes into which a nation is divided, it was only the crown, the Church and a compartively small number of officials, soldiers and officers who controlled Spanish Amer- ica ;^^ and who can tell how the absolute monarchy of Spain was strengthened by this fact? In the seventeenth century, on the other hand, it is principally manufacturers and mer- chants, and more especially yet, workmen, w^ho reap the im- mediate advantages of new discoveries of gold. SECTION CXLI. EFFECT OF AN ENHANCEMENT OF THE PRICE OF THE PRECIOUS METALS. A great enhancement of the precious metals would naturally and necessarily produce a revolution in prices in a direction ^ opposite to the one just described, and one which would be much more injurious to a nation's economy. Such a revolu- tion would weigh most heavily on the most sensitive, and the momentarily most productive classes of the people, inasmuch as the price of the ready product as compared with advances made for the purposes of production would be a declining one ; and it would benefit those classes who live in leisure on the fruits of previous labor. There would, at the same time, be a perceptible growth of consumption in certain departments, useful, no doubt, in themselves, but apt to degenerate into ex- cess, and which are, therefore, most easily cared for. (§212, seq.) '* Compare liosc/icy, Kolonien, Kolonialpolitik unci Auswanderung, 1S56, 145 ff. ' Something similar inight have been observed in England in 1S19 etc., at the restoration of a depreciated paper currency. Among nations in a com- paratively low stage of civilization, a variation in the medium of circulation is of less importance than among more highly civilized nations, because trade in money, and still more, credit, are relatively speaking undeveloped. 433 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Cii. IV. To this extent, the gold discoveries of the nineteenth century, without which an enhancement of the price of money would undoubtedly have taken place, have warded off a great eco- nomic malady from the nations. Moreover, this inverted rev- olution in prices may be moderated by governmental measures, such as a diminution of taxes, emissions of paper money etc.^ SECTION CXLII. THE PRICE OF GOLD AS COMPARED WITH THAT OF SIL- VER. The price of gold as compared with that of silver does not, by any means, depend entirely on the ratio of the quantities of the two to each other. Rather is it, in the long run, deter- mined by the average cost of production necessary at those gold and silver mines which exist under the most disadvanta- geous conditions, but which it is still necessary to work in order to satisfy the aggregate requirement of these metals. On the whole, with an advance of economic civilization, the dearness of gold as compared with that of silver has been en- hanced. The former, in the middle ages, was worth from ten to twelve times as much as the latter,^ while now it is ' Fatvcett greatly exaggerates when he says that with an increase of popu- lation and wealth, an increase of money is as much a want as hunger. (Man- ual, 370.) ^ Galiatn, Delia Moneta, III, i. At the time of the Lex Salica, 10: i. After the Edictum Pistense of Charles II., ch. 24 (Pertz, Mon. Germ., Ill, 488), 12: 1. At the time of the Sachsenspiegel (III, 45), again, 10: i. Under Saint Louis, king of France, 12.5: i. (Leblanc, Traite historique des Mon- naies de la France, ch. i, 2.) In Poland, 1356, 12: i. (Muraion, Dissertt. Medii Aevi, II, 28.) In England, 1262, 9.6; 1272 = 12.5; 1345 = 13.7:1. (Rogers, i, 593 fF.) Under Henry VI., and in 1494=12:1. (A7iderson, Origin of Commerce, a. 1422, 1494.) In Denmark, under the former Kings of the Union = 8: I. ('Z)rt///;«««72, Danische Geschischte, III, 52.) And so throughout almost the whole of Scandinavia's medieval period, as for instance in the Graugans. (Wilda, Gesch. des deutschen Strafrechts, I, 329.) In Italy, 1579= 12: 1. (Scan/ffi, Sopra le Moneta, 1582.) In Holland, 1589 = 11.6:1. Bodinus, De Republ., 1584, II, 3, maintains 12:1 as the general Sec. CXLII.] RATIO OF GOLD TO SILVER. 433 worth from fifteen to almost sixteen times as much.^ In the same period of time, also, gold in highly civilized countries is wont to be comparatively dearer.^ These facts are explained as well by the demand as by the supply. As the production of gold requires so little skill or c;apital, and that of silver so much of both, the former may be considered a natural product to a greater extent than the latter, and therefore, the rule laid down in §130 is applicable to it. {Senior.) Besides, in the higher stages of civilization, espe- cially when the precious metals are cheap, larger payments are usual, to the making of which, gold is certainly best adapted; just as in every day trade merchants are wont to accept a gold piece in payment, even at something of a premi- um, while the peasantry hesitate to do so.'* ratio; but the Apostolic Chamber adopted the ratio of 12.8: i. In Germany, according to the instances cited \iy A. Riesc^ 1522 r= 10:1. The monetary laws of Germany give it in 1524:^=11^:1, in 1551 =:ii : i, i559=ii|:i; Biidelius, De Monetis, 1591 = 11^: i. At the beginning of the seventeenth century the relation in Spain was = 13.3; in Germany = 12.16; in Flanders =: 13.22; in England = 13.5: I. (Forboniiats, Finances de la France, I, 52.) About 1641, in Flanders, it was 12.5; in France, 13.5; in Spain, 14.1. Imme- diately after Colbert's death it -was, in Genoa, 15.03; in Milan = 14.75: i. (Montaiiari, Delia Moneta, 80.) While in the seventeenth century gold rose, it sank in the eighteenth, on account of the Brazilian gold washings and the many bank notes in circulation, which were for the most part of a large de- nomination. (Stcuari, Principles, III, ch. 13.) Still it was in Amsterdam in 1751=14.5: I. - In Hamburg, the relation of the price of gold to that of silver bars, var- ied, between 1816 and 1852, from between 15.11-16.2 to i (Soetbeer) ; in London, from i8i6 to 1837, between 15.80 and 14.97 to i. ^In Asia, it is generally lower than in Europe — for centuries mostly = 10: I. But in Birmah it is = 17: i, mostly on account of the extent to which indulgence in luxury is carried there. (Cravjfurd, Embassy, 433. Hitter, Erdkunde, V, 244, 266.) Concerning China, see M. Chevalier, Cours, III, 359. In Africa, gold is low as compared with silver, in proportion to the distance from the civilized world. Thus, an ounce of gold in Shenaar cost 12 piastres; in Suakim, 20; in Djidda, 22. (Ritter, Erdkunde, I, 538.) In Timbuctoo, Mungo Park found the relation of gold to silver to be as 1%: i. Compare Marco Polo, II, 39 seq. * In antiquity, a similar course is to be observed. According to Menu's Indian laws, VIII, 134 seq., —lYz'- 1; in the East, for a long time, =10: i; Vol. I.— 28 43J: CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch. IV It is very much of a question whether gold or silver is, on the whole, subject to greater variations in price. The fact that gold is more strictly a natural product would of itself constitute a powerful element of variation. (§ 112). But, on the other hand, its greater durability and the greater care be- stowed on its preservation, have for eflect to make the exist- ing quantity preponderate in importance over its annual in- crease. The demand for gold varies more suddenly than the demand for silver. In case of war or sedition, the former is more easily carried away or hidden. It is also more desir- able for the state for its military fund. On the other hand, on account of its greater capacity for transportation, it may fol- low such claims when made on it, more easily, from country to country. On the whole, I am inclined to think that, for short periods of time, silver maintains its value better, and gold for longer ones.^ under Darius Hystaspis, =13: i. (Herodot., Ill, 95.) In Greece, in the time of Lysias, =10: i (Lystas, pro bonis Arist., Conon); according to Plato, = 12: I (Hipparcli.^ 231): according to Demosthenes^ adv. Phorm., 214, =14: i (Bockh, Staatst., I, 43); Menander's estimate, =10: i, probably because Alex- ander's victory had made gold cheaper. (Pollux^ IX, 76.) Among the Ro- mans, about 189 B. C, =10:1 (Livy, XXXVIII, 11); somewhat later, r=ii.t;: I (Mommsen, in the histor. phil. Berichten der K. Sachs. Gesellschaft, 1S51, 184 ff.); in the fourth century after Christ, =14: i. (Tkeod., Cod. VIII, 4, 27.) We sometimes find sudden variations. Thus, according to Polyb., XXXIV, 10, gold, in Italy, sank about ^ in consequence of the opening of the mines at Aquilea. It sank to the proportion of 9: i when Ctesar spent the contents of the Roman treasure, which consisted of gold. (Sueron., Cses., 54.) The ratio of 17 : i, during Hannibal's wars, was a species of Na- tional bankruptcy. See Plitt., H. N., XXXIII, B. ^ After the February revolution, the gold-agio, as compared with silver, rose from 10-17 to 70 per 1,000. (M. Chevalier Cours, III, 346.) On the other hand, since the discovery of America, gold, as compared with com- modities, has declined much less than silver. Compare Hermann, Ueber den gegenwartigen Zustand des Miinzwesens, in Rail's Archiv., I, 151 ff. Ac- cording to Lord Liverpool, Treatise on the Coins of the Realm, the value of gold coin in the London market, as compared Avith bank notes, varied in 40 years, almost 5^ per cent. Sec. CXLIIL] RATIO OF GOLD TO SILVER. 435 SECTION CXLIIL THE PRICE OF GOLD AS COMPARED WITH THAT OF SILVER. [CONTINUED.] If the gold-production of California should be attended^ by a notable depression of the value of that metal, it becomes a question whether or not silver would be necessarily depreci- ated with it. Senior claims that it would not, for the reason that the two precious metals do not, for most purposes, act as substitutes each of the other. If a country needed 1,000 pounds of gold and 15,000 pounds of silver as money ,^ and these two sums of metal were equal in value, an increase of gold by one-half, which would depreciate its price in relation to silver to 10: 1, would not overflow the channels of circulation. The 1,500 pounds of gold are now also equal to only 15,000 pounds of silver, and vice versa. I would put very important limitations to this assertion. Even a moderate depreciation of gold would drive out the silver from all those countries which had a mixed coinage made up of the two metals; and hence the supply of silver w'ould be increased in the other countries. And so it is quite possible, up to a certain point, that the larger silver coin should be replaced by small gold ones, ten and five franc pieces etc. Rau is certainly right in his surmise that a general rise in the price of commodities as compared with coin, the result of a great increase of gold, would go farthest in countries in which the gold is the medium of circulation, begin later in those 1 In recent times, it has become possible to exti-act from ancient silver coins a small quantity of gold, and with some advantage. European indus- try produced in this way about 1,600 kilogrammes of gold per annum. One half of this amount is obtained in France and the rest in Hamburg, Amster- dam, Brussels and St. Petersburg. (Michel Chevalier^ Cours, III, 302.) ^Senior, On the Value of Money, 77 ff. It is certain that a simple varia- tion in prices would not induce people to have gold table services, or archi- tectural ornaments of silver. 436 CIRCULATION OF GOODS. [B. II, Ch IV, which had a mixed circulation, and continue for the the short- est time in those countries which, by force of law, had a silver circulation only.^ * * Rau, Lehrbuch, 6th ed., I, § 277 c. In Rau's opinion (loc. cit.) we maj, in the course of the next decades, expect a decline of the price of gold of about 76 per cent., and of only 10 per cent, of the price of silver (because of the low prices of quicksilver.) But here he seems to overlook entirely what influence a change of standard in important commercial districts would have. •* Compare the works already mentioned. Flectvjood, Chronicon precio- sum, or an Account of English Gold and Silver Money, the Price of Corn and other Commodities etc., for Six Hundred Years last past, 1707; Diiprd de Saint Maur, Essai sur les Monnaies ou Reflexions sur les Rapports entre les Denrees et I'Argent, 1746; linger^ Ordnung der Fruchtpreise, 1752; Paucton^ Metrologie ou Traite des Mesures etc., des anciens Peuples et les modernes, 17S0; the appendix to Macfherson''s Annals of Commerce, 1805; the tables in Gamier' s translation of Adam Smith, vol. II, 1822; A. Toung, Inquiry into the progressive Value of Money in England, as marked by the Price of Agricultural Products, 1812; W. F. Lloyd, Prices of Corn in Ox- ford, in the Beginning of the fourteenth Century, and also from 1583 to the present Time, 1830; Hclferick, in the TiJb. Zeitschrift, 1858,471 ff. There are some very interesting notes on the history of prices during the Merovingian and Carolingian periods in GiUrard, Polyptiques, I, 141 ff. APPENDIX T. PAPER MONEY. PAPER mmj: SECTION I. PAPER MONEY AND MONEY-PAPER. Paper money must be distinguished from other value-paper or money-paper,^ which may also run to the possessor or holder, and not unfrequently serve as a medium of payment. In the case of these bonds or obligations,^ their circulating capacity is a secondary matter, and the principal thing the authentication of an economic legal relation; whereas paper money is intended principally, if not exclusively, to act as m.oney. ^ Money-paper appears in a great many different forms, but it nearly always bears interest. Its value depends in great part on the rate and certainty of its interest. On the * Furnished by the author expressly for this edition. ' Thus, for instance, the bonds (and their coupons) of states, cities, great corporations, certificates of stock, mortgages, bills of exchange, checks. -A Prussian regulation of 1765 (Goldschmidt, Handbuch des Handels- rechts, I, 550), calls money-paper (Effeden)^ instruments of trade in which a value or a valuta is designated. 3 Garnier, French translation of Adam Smith, II, 143 ft'., distinguishes be- tween coin-paper and promise-paper: the latter is never found in circulation at the same time with the capital which it represents. Say says that, for in- stance, evidences of state indebtedness, state bonds, call for money if they would circulate, but they seldom act as money in circulation. (Traitd, III, ch. 2.) Sismondi very well determines the difterence in his Richesse Com- merciale, I, 160. Rnu, Lehrbuch, I, § 293, requires of all good paper money : a., that its mere transfer, even without any proof of its rightful acquisition, should suffice to vest the property in it in the receiver; b., that the power emitting it should enjoy universal confidence or be able to compel universal recognition; c, that its redemption should not be fixed for any definite point of time. 4j(.0 paper money. [App. I, Other hand, the endeavor to insure a more favorable reception for paper money by the promise of interest has been exceed- ingly seldom successful.^ And in reality, good prospects as to interest (Zinsaussichten) and ease of transfer from one hand to another are two qualities which lie in very different direc- tions.^ The many recent writers who claim for paper money the marks of irredeemableness and forced circulation, confound the unfortunately too frequent degeneration of an institution with its real nature. They contradict, too, usage of speech, which, in countries where silver is the standard, unhesitatingly ■* That it is not possible to keep paper money from declining in value, by the payment of interest, the people of North America learned from more than one experiment during the eighteenth century. (Benjamin Franhlin^ Remarks and Facts relative to the Paper Money of America, 1765.) The same phenomenon was observed in the case of the Spanish valcs^ which Avere created during the North American war in consequence of the absence of the silver fleet. (Boiir-going^ Tableau de 1' Espagne, II, 38 ff. Hum- boldt., N. Espagne, II, SoS.) When the Portuguese ^/cj/zrw (since 1797) still bore six per cent, they depreciated in value; and when the payment of the interest was suddenly stopped, the rate of exchange did not become any lower. (Balbt, Esai statist, sur le Portugal, I, 323.) In Austria, in Septem- ber, 1820, the bank notes which bore no interest were at a premium as com- pared with the imperial treasury notes, which did bear interest of i per cent., although the credit of both kinds of paper had ultimately the same founda- tion, namely, Austrian state-credit. ' The attenipt to make paper money pay interest suggests (as the Saint Si- monists recommend it should, with much ado; Etifantin, Ser les Banques, d' Escompte in the Producteur, 1826), that awkward sword, invented by Count Wilhelm von Biickeburg, to the blade of which a pistol is affixed ! Shortly before each term for the payment of interest, the circulation of such paper money would be arrested. If the rate of discount should sink below the rate of interest such notes bore, they would be sought after eagerly and disappear in quantities, and, not be ever seen again until the rate of discount had risen to a high figure, Avhen they would be suddenly presented for re- demption. Such interest-bearing paper money, therefore, would be a seri- ous element to aggravate the fluctuations of the money-market between good and bad times. When interest-bearing paper money pays interest at the rate usual in the country, it is hoarded by misers, (v. Struensee. Abhandlungen, III, 387.) Compare Forbotmais, Principes dconomiques, p. 234, ed. Guill., whereas f. Pr/V^WiVz, Kunst reich zu werden (1S40), 359, takes delight in elab- orating the idea of an interest-bearing paper money. Sec. I.] PAPER MONEY AND MONEY-PAPER. 441 calls gold coins money, although they cannot be forced on any one." The paper monc}'' issued by the state deserves, indeed, the appellation in the fullest measure; but starting from this point we hnd a number of grades in a downward direction, whicli may still be called mone}^;'' and we shall see especially that the differences between state paper money and bank notes so widely asserted are, in great measure, differences not of kind but of deefree. The idea of replacing the precious metals as a medium of circulation by a less costly material, even the ancients were acquainted with ; but with the exception of the Carthaginians, they scarcely ever made any use of it except in cases of need and transitorily.^ ^ Of jurists, see Thol, Handelsrecht, I, § 51, and the authorities for and against in Goldschmidt^ Handelsrecht, II, Kap. 4, i, 2. The compulsory circulation of paper money is an essential element only in reference to the person that issues it. Of political economists, especially A. Wagner in BluntschWs Staatsworterbuch, Art. Papiergeld, Band, VII, who, however, is very soon compelled to oppose to paper money " proper," another kind not "proper." Adam Smith unhesitatingly accounts bank notes also paper- money. (W. of N., IT, ch. 2, p. 2S, Bas.) Huskisson understands by "paper- money " only the irredeemable paper-mon«y of the state, while bank notes should be considered as " paper currency." (The Question concerning the Depreciation of our Currency, 18 10.) "> Seyd, Miinz, Wahrungs-und Bankfragen in Deutschland, 50 fF., distin- guishes four classes of paper-money: ist class, paper-money covered by cash ; 2d class, bank notes covered after the manner of banks ; 3d class, state paper-money; 4th class, svich paper money as the notes of the Southern Confederacy after its defeat. ^Even Plato, De Legg., V, 742, was acquainted with money after the Spar- tan type, intended only for internal trade : VOfXCfffxa Irtijcopcov^ WJTdtz, fxev ivTCfxov roT?" dk dXXoc^ dv&f>io~occ; ddoxc/jov. Besides the state kept for foreign trade a supply of the universal Hellenic money, of which in case of need, private individuals could acquire what portion they needed by exchange. When Dionysius I. issued tin instead of silver money, all the Syracusans, although they noticed the forgery, acted in their intercourse with one another as if they considered the coins genuine. (Aristot., CEcon., 11,21, Pollux, IX, 79. Timotheos behaved more honorably when, pressed by the dearth of money, he gave his troops copper coin tokens, which passed for the time being for their full value in the camp; but which Avere later to be redeemed at their full value in silver. (Aristot., CEc. II, 22.) Compare 4:4:2 PAPER MONEY. [App. I. Similarly, the middle ages in Europe; as in general all greater development of the credit-system — and all paper money is credit-money — has a natural growth only in the higher stages of civilization.^ ^^ PolycEii, Strateg., IV, lo, 2. The iron money which the Klazomenians ex- clianged with the rich for silver, which bore interest, but wliich the rich were forced to take, had a longer duration; the silver was used to pay for- eign state creditors, the iron money circulated for the time being in the city, and was gradually redeemed. (Aristot.^ loc. cit., II, 17.) We are still more forcibly reminded of paper money by the Carthagenian leather money, where any object whatever of the size of a coin was shut up in a leather envelope with the state seal, and then circulated as if it were the coin it purported to be. Mien's, Beschryving der Munstn, 1726, explains the saga of Dido's ox-skin by means of this leather money. Certain it is, how- ever, that the surprise with which the sophistical dialogue, Eryxias, mentions the matter, is a proof how foreign it was to the Greeks. Concerning the Roman plated denarii which were stamped with the silver coins, but which were also accepted by the state treasury, see Mommsen, R. G., I, 405. ^ In ihe middle ages, leather money was issued as a promise of future pay- ment: by the doge of Venice in the wars of 1122 and 1126 (Montanari, Delia Moneta, 34); by King John, of England, during the struggle of the barons (Camden); Emp. Frederick II. at the siege of Faventia ("il/^fc^/z^/, Hist. Fior., 130, Villani, Hist. Fior., VI, 21) ; by Louis IX. during his captivity (v. Raumer Hohenstaufen, V, 461), John of France, 1360 (Anderson, Origin of Com- merce). On the Frankfurt lead marks which w-ere afterwards redeemed by the Rechnerei: Kirchner, I, 541. Lavallette's copper tokens during the siege of Malta had the inscription: non cbs sed fides. The paper money which was is- sued during the siege of Leyden, the inhabitants afterwards would rather preserve than have redeemed, ad ferpetuain liberationis div'mce menioriatii. (Bornitii, De Nummis, 1605, I, 15. Distress coins, melacs, during the siege of Landau and of the Hungarian Ragoczy, Marfurgcr, Beschreibung der Banquen, 213. Krones, Zur Geschichte Ungarns im Zeitalter R's, 1870.) '" The Chinese have had various kinds of paper-money in their country since the 7th century after Christ. Sometimes they called them " flying coins, convenient coins," and sometimes coupons, bans, conventions (Klaproth, Memoires relatives a I'Asie, I, 375 if.), against which the caravans, as soon as they had passed the limits were obliged to exchange their silver (Pegolotti, Pratica dclla Mercatura in Delia decima etc.. Ill, 3). These had compulsory circulation in China. The great Mongolian khans here became acquainted with paper-money. (M. Polo, II, 21.) Thus, especially in Persia, where re- fusal to accept such money and the imitation of it was punished with death (1340). Compare Ferishta, ed. Briggs, I, 414 IT. d^Ohsson, Hist, des Mon- gols, IV, loi ft".; II, 4S7. Even here there occured cases of state bankruptcy Sec. II.] ADVANTAGES AND DISADVANTAGES. 44,3 SECTION II. ADVANTAGES AND DISADVANTAGES OF PAPER MONEY. Where it is at all possible to give paper money the same purchasing power as metallic money possesses, it is unquestion- able that the former must have many advantages over the lat- ter. True, paper money is very inconvenient for small amounts ; ^ but all the more convenient for large amounts, as well for purposes of counting as for purposes of the storing up of values and for transmission from place to place; a matter of greater importance in proportion to the badness of a coun- try's means of transportation, and to the cheapness of the metal of its currency hitherto.^ It seems a still more important matter to most people that paper money dispenses with the use of a great quantity of the precious metals for purposes of circula- tion, which can now either be turned into utensils, etc. in the country itself or used in foreign countries to make investments of capital there, or in the purchase of commodities.^ In na- and finally withdrawals of the depreciated paper. Klaprotli^ loc. cit.) In Japan, according to Oliphant^ Narrative of L. Elgin's Mission to China and Sapan (1859), all foreign coins were required to be exchanged against paper- money at the offices of the state bankers. ' Adam Smith mentions North American paper money of the amount of I shilling, and Yorkshire bank notes of the amount of i^ shillings. Sweden had, until 1S28, notes of 2'$> pfennigs. 2 Hence in Sweden, with its copper standard of long duration, the sj'stem of banks of issue was developed very early. The transport-notes (Trans- fortzcttcl) (to be found in that country as far back as 1661) of the Stockholm bank are considered the oldest bank notes. Compare, however, Palgrave, in the Statist. Journal, 1873. When, in 1768, Catherine II. introduced paper money into Russia, the people gladly paid }( per cent, exchange to the state treasury for it. (BrUckner, in Hildebrand's ]ii\\YhuchQr, 1863, 49.) Accoi-din"- to CcDicrin, Oconomie der menschl. Gesellschaft, 116, private individuals in from four to five months exchanged 40 millions of silver roubles for paper. And thus, in 17S0, Berlin bank notes stood a few per cent, above par, and the notes of the S. Carlos-Bank, in 1788, from i to i^ per cent. (Rau, Ar- chiv., II, 161.) 3 When at times in which paper money is looked upon with diffidence 4,4:4: PAPER MONEY. [App. I. tional economies whose commerce is a growing one, the same advantage finds a negative expression in this, that they are not compelled to satisfy the increasing demand for money by pro- curing costly metals.* Of the individual members of the na- tion, all these advantages of convenience will be experienced by those who employ the paper money. The economical or saving advantages of paper money are appropriated by the issuers to themselves, in the form of a non-interest bearing loan, which they make to those owners of money or to those who are entitled to a money-claim and to whom the paper money is acceptable instead of cash mone}^^ A diminution for instance of the number of bank notes or of state paper peasants and others bury their metallic money, this advantage of course is lost. On the other hand, the exportation of precious metal money, caused by the emission of paper money, must not be considered a necessary evil, but rather as the condition precedent which in most cases makes the above advantages of the paper money possible for the first time. Compare Ad. War- ner, Die russische Papierwahrung (iS6S), 22, 24, 33. Ht'cardo, Proposals for an economical and sure Currency, 1S16, estimated that England, after the abolition of the bank restriction, needed twenty million pounds sterling. The interest on this amount of capital inclusive of wear and tear etc., should be estimated at at least ten percent. ; that is for the whole kingdom at at least ft-om two and one-half to three millions a year. On this Ricardo founded his proposal to base the bank notes on gold bars. In its time, the essay : Guineas an unnecessary and expensive Incumbrance on Commerce, or the Impolitj' of repealing the Bank-Restriction Bill considered (London, 1802), met ^vith great approval. *Adam S?nith calls attention to the analogous case in which a manufac- turer replaces a costly machine by a cheap one, sells the former and em- ploys the diiference between the old one and the new in enlarging his business. (W. of N., II, ch. 2.) When, indeed, all nations have introduced the use of paper money, the greater portion of the advantages which the one nation was able to obtain by its means cease, and the only ultimate result is a depreciation of the value of money and of the precious metals. Formerly the advantage reaped by the single nation that emitted paper money was greater than its share in the depreciation. (Wolozush', Enqu^tede 1S65, loS.) * When E. Seyd calls bank notes more costly than metallic money, because the former in England require an outlay for administration of i^ per cent, per annum, while the wear and tear of metallic money amounts to i per cent, only in 20 years (Statist. Journal, 1872, 511), he overlooks the loss in interest and the costs of coinage in the latter case. >^ Sec. II.] ADVANTAGES AND DISADVANTAGES. 445 money does not diminish the available capital of the people. Its only effect is that a smaller portion of it is at the disposal of the bank or of the government. But in contrast with these advantages are the great disad- vantages, since paper mone}^ is wanting in most of those properties which originally made the precious metals the best instruments of exchange and the best measures of value. In addition to this, paper money may be increased at pleasure, and at almost no cost; and an occasional surplus of it cannot flow either into other branches of employment (as a surplus of metallic money may into utensils, ornamentation, etc.) nor in- to other countries. And thus the constancy of value of paper money, that is, one of the chief requisites of all good money,is imperiled in the highest degree. True, the paym ent-power, or " legal tender " character given such money by the state may certainly supplement in some way its matter and form- value. But this supplement or addition constitutes,in the case of large amounts,^ a small quota; or else the quantity of money as compared with the amount of money needed for commerce would have to be fixed very accurately; a thing of peculiar difficulty in the case of paper money, which is almost costless.'^ ^ Related to this is the fact that in France, during the assignat-crisis, the large bills of 10,000 francs were harder to get rid of than the small ones. (A. ScJimtdt's Parisier Zustande, III, 22.) ' The numbering of paper money. A state which should neglect this would not only reserve to itself the possibility of an unlimited increase, but would surrender all control of its officials charged with the emission of the paper money. Latv, Trade and Money, 162, advises that a large money re- ward should be paid to any one who should show the existence of a higher number than allowed by law, or of a duplicate number. And indeed, as comptroller-in-chief, he caused the frdvot des tnarckands to be removed, be- cause charged with the duty of burning the paper withdrawn from circula- tion, he (the^rdvoi) noticed that the same number reappeared several times. 446 PAPER MONEY. [App. I. SECTION III. KINDS OF REDEMPTION. While precious metal money carries, so to speak, by far the greater portion of its value in itself, and this to such an extent that it appears on the inscription found on its face, the inscrip- tion found on paper money is almost the only reason of its value.^ (Credit-value.) The issuer promises in one form or an- other, expressly or tacitly, that he intends to redeem the note, almost valueless in itself, in real* goods ; and the value of this promise depends on the probability of its fulfillment.'-^ The only fully satisfactory kind of redemption consists in this, that every holder of the paper money may, immediately on demand, obtain its nominal value in good current metallic money. This only can, in the long run, keep paper money up to its full nominal value. But experience teaches that even with less per- fect modes of redemption, paper money may maintain a part of its nominal value, and a part greater in proportion as the fol- lowing conditions are approximated to : freedom from personal considerations, the immediateness of the redemption, and cur- rency of the goods by means of which redemption is effected. Thus, for instance, the acceptance of paper money for all debts due the state, in countries where taxation is heavy, where there are large state industries etc. ; where the lauds of the state are farmed out etc., has a great influence on its course of exchange.^ Redemption in parcels of land is a very imperfect ' If a traveler wished to pay his inn-keeper in the note of a bank entirely un- known in the place, the latter would certainly refuse it. If, on the other hand, the traveler were to offer him a silver coin, the stamp and inscription of which were not familiar, still it would be taken at the value of the metal it contained, after deduction made of the costs of testing it, re-coining it, and compensation for the trouble caused. Ignored by Berkeley^ who, indeed, considered metallic money nothing but " counters " or tickets (Querist, No. 23, 26, 441, 475), and who ascribes important advantages to paper money, — which by "stamp" and "signature" is made as costly as gold (440) — over me- tallic money (226). 2 Any person who has witnessed a tax-execution, or sale of property for the Sec. III.] ADVANTAGES AND DISADVANTAGES. 447 one, not only on account of the great differences in the value of pieces of land according to quality, situation, the times etc., but also because only a very small number of men, especially where money is the usual medium of exchange, are in a con- dition to accept parcels of land.^ It is a question whether the non-pajment of taxes (Stuerexecution) will admit that a tax receipt is at least as real goods as an umbrella or a glass window that protects one from the storm. Alichazlis considers the amount of running payments to the state for duties, taxes etc., as the only right basis for full-value paper money. (Ber liner Vierteljahrsschrift, 1S63, III.) Better yet when Hofkcn advises that only as much paper money should be issued as amounted to the average bal- ance {Bestand) in the national ti'easury. The tax-basis is defended with great warmth by L. Stein. Louis XIV., in 1704 issued paper money bearing 7 per cent, interest, the acceptance of which by all the royal officers of the treasury was prohibited! ('iPwi't^/, Reflexions, 863, Daire.) Xaw, Trade and Money (1705) ascribes to parcels of land the greatest constancy of value, be- cause they cannot be replaced, because they can be neither increased nor de- creased, and because they help to produce all other goods (p. 170). While silver cannot but depreciate, they have a prospect but to rise (188). Hence Lavj recommended notes based on parcels of land as the best money. (163, 191, 195.) Similarly, Benjamin Franklin, Modest Inquiry into the Nature and Necessity of a Paper Currency: and the Paper Money of Pennsylvania, New York and New Jersey was actually based on parcels of land, and was to be extinguished by the enfeoffed owners, and the interest paid by them. (Ebe- ling^ Gesch. und Erdbeschreib, von N. Amerika, III, 621, IV, 649.) ^ F. Renonard de Ste Croix, Voyage aux Indes orientales (1810), I, 32, de- scribes a species of paper money based on parcels of land which had lost 40 per cent, of its nominal value, although the holders of them were invested with the fief at only one-half their value. The French mandats territoriaux of 1796, declined in five months to 5 per cent, of their nominal value, although they contained the provision that the holders might, without public sale (Auction), have a certain amount of the national estates allotted to them in exchange for the mandats. The assignats were still more defective after their redemption (at the Caisse de Vcxtraordittaire), which was at first in- tended, and their drawing of interest were not fulfilled. Leaving the tax- basis out of consideration, the notes might, at the sale of the national estates, be brought in as means of payment: a thing which would not have been in- operative, provided the amount of the paper money had been strictly limited to the price of the pieces of land estimated in money. On the ist of April, 1790, 400,000,000 francs in assignats were issued, and in September, 800,000,000 more, both together about equal to the secularized property of the church. (Ad. Schmidt, Pariscr Zustande, II, 97.) But as afterwards all proportion between these two magnitudes ceased, or rather as up to January i, 1793, 448 PAPER MONEY. [App. I. threat of punishing the refusal to accept paper money, or to accept it at its full nominal value, can be called a negative mode of redemption. Certain it is, however, that it is the most barbarous and in the long run the least efficient mode, one in which the issuer calculates only on the fear of those who accept it; and, w^hat is most demoralizing, on the hope they entertain that they in turn shall be able to dispose of it to others as timid.^^ 3,626,000,000 assignats were issued ; up to September, 1794, over 8,800,000,000 ; up to September, 1795, 19,700,000,000; and finally up to September, 1796, 45,578,000,000 francs, of which perhaps 6,500,000 were either burned or de- monetized, the price of the national estates on lands must naturally have risen as vastly as the assignats declined. *The paper money issued by Colbert's successor, Chamillard, soon lost on account of its too great amount, 25 per cent, of its value, spite of the fact that it bore interest, and that ]^ of all payments to private persons had to be made in it. (Forbonnais^ Recherches et Considerations, II, 182.) When the people of the United States, in 1775, issued paper money, it did not de- cline in value up to the end of 1776, so long as the amount did not exceed $20,000,000, as it was considered a matter of honor to take it at par. After- wards, when the amount issued continued to increase, not even the law that a refusal to accept it, or insisting on taking it below par, should be punished with the loss of the commodity, and that the guilty party should be declared a national enemy, could keep it from declining in value; so that in May, 1871, a dollar in specie was worth $200.5 in paper. Compare Franklin^ Works, ed. Sparks, II, 421, VIII, 328, 505. France, during the Reign of Terror, on the 2d day of April 1793, threat- ened the claiming of a discount in the taking of assignats with six years' confinement in chains, and on the ist day of August, on Couthon's motion, with twenty years' confinement. In addition to this, maximum prices for the principal necessities of life were fixed and the exceeding of them was pun- ished by severe penalties ; and in France, and still more in the neighboring conquered countries, there were many persons who preferred to take assignats instead of payment rather than permit themselves to be robbed by requisi- tions. And yet on the 4th of June, 1796, one franc in specie exchanged for 800 francs assignats. Compare Biisch, Geldumlauf, III (§ 58 ft'., d'lvernois^ Etat. des Finances Fran^aise, 1796). 5 The Prussian treasury notes of 1806, by virtue of a decree published in 1807, were to be taken by all at a rate of exchange to be ofiicially published from time to time. Between December i, 1807, and February 28, 1809, the highest " normal course of exchange " was 71, and the lowest 27 per cent. In January, 1815, a refusal to take them at par, except in certain cases, was Sec. IV.] COMPULSORY CIRCULATION. 449 SECTION IV. COMPULSORY CIRCULATION. When paper money which is not completely redeemable — and it is scarcely possible that in the long run it should be thus redeemable — has sunk below its nominal value, the re- sult in the case of all private paper money is the bankruptcy (Vcrmogensbruch) of the individual issuing it; in the case of state paper money, the legal provision that it shall have a com- puJaory circulation (Ztvangcoursc; cours force)} To what ex- threatened with from 500 to 1,000 thalers of a money-fine or from 6 to 12 months' imprisonment. But indeed, in December, 1812, of 8,000,000 thalers, there were only 731,625 still circulating. Compare § 7 of the decree of the 19th of Januar}-, 1S13. In April, 1815, it was ordered that the half of all taxes should be paid in such notes, or that if not, Sj^ per cent, should be added as a penalty. This penalty, reduced in 1827 to i silver groschen, was not formally abolished even in 1S70, although it had long fallen into disu- etude. There was a run of the owners of the notes in 1830, for redemp- tion, and again in 1841 and 1848; in 1848 to the extent of at most 40,000 thalers in one day, and altogether not over 100,000 thalers. (Bergius, in the Tiibinger Zeitschr., 1870, 226 if.) About 1846, it was estimated that scarcely i\o '"■ JS'ir °f Prussian paper money was presented for redemption, while ^ of the state receipts came in in the shape of paper money. (Rati, Archiv., V, 125, 207.) The Saxon ti-easury notes never lost over 2 per cent., although the state treasury redeemed them up to 1804 only at an agio of 9 pfennigs per thaler, and afterwards of i ffennig. ' Those entitled to make money claims are either compelled to accept the paper money at its nominal value or only at its current value for the time being. In the latter instance, the unjust compulsion is much smaller, but at the same time the whole expedient is much less productive to the state ; and hence the former is the more usual. It was provided in Austria on the 22d of May and the 2d of June, 1848, that the former should be the rule, and that the latter should govern in cases in which gold or foreign silver had been stipulated ibr. (Hofken, Oesterreichs Finanzprobleme, p. 53.) On the 7th of February, 1S56, it was permitted to contract by express promise for loans in the metallic currency of the country, both for the interest and the repay- ment of the principal. Hence a species of parallel-currcnc3\ ^^ ^^ be made entirely impossible for private individuals to protect themselves against the compulsory circulation of paper money, the more prudent are forced to send their capital into foreign countries, which operates very disadvantageously to poor countries especially. (Wagfier, Tubing. Zeitschr., 1S63, 441.) Vol. L — 29 450 PAPER MONEY. [App. I. tent the real rate of exchange of paper money shall fall in any case depends not only on the amount issued as compared with the wants of trade, but also and still more on the degree of con- fidence which the state of public affairs inspires.^ The first consequence attending a depreciated currency is, that the good precious metal money is withdrawn from circulation and even from the country; for the reason that it cannot maintain its true value side by side with the paper money ; the usual effect in all untenable mixed standards or currencies.^ A second, and * Thus, for instance, the Frederick coins, and for a time the French assignats were helped by the popular enthusiasm, while Gustavus III., of Sweden, could give little value to his paper, (v. Strue?tsee, Abh., Ill, 577.) In France, in 1796, 2,400,000,000 maiidats were issued instead of all the out- standing assignats; that is, as many as there were assignats at the close of the year 1792. And yet the latter were then only 25 per cent, below par ; the former, before one month had elapsed. So, and in nine months, almost 98 per cent, below par. (St Cliamaus, Nouvelle Essai sur la Richesse des Na- tions, p. 150. (A. ScJimidf, Parisier Zustiinde, III, 121 if.) In Austria, in 181 1, the volume of paper money was contracted, but in a manner so violent and destructive of credit that its rate of exchange did not rise in conse- quence. (Tub. Zeitschr., 1763, 1874.) After 184S, also, the rate of exchange of Austrian paper money was much more perceptibly influenced by the variations in the political state of affairs than by the changes in its volume. (Tub. Zeitschr., 1856, 129.) In the summer and winter of 1866, about 650,000,000 paper rubles circulated, with scarcely any increase or decrease ; and yet the ratio of exchange was, during a part of the summer, 66, and in winter, 84 per cent, of the silver value of the ruble. (Wagner, Russ. Pa- pierwahrung, 74.) Instances in which the increase in the price of commod- ities began to be more general only after the volume of paper money had decreased; in Austria, in 1851 and 1866; in Russia, in 1857 (loc. cit). ' Then precious metal money becomes a commodity of .which great stores may be collected in the country itself, at the banks, but chiefly for foreign trade. It is said that Austrian business men in 1S60 and the following years invested "hoards" to the amount of several hundred million florins in ex- change on metallic-currency counti'ies. (Tiib. Zeitschr., 422.) Good paper money will never drive out the whole supply of cash money out of a coun- try, because a good portion must always be kept for purposes of redemption ; depreciated paper money operates much farther in this direction. Even the exportation of small change may become a profitable speculation as soon as the amount of depreciation of paper money exceeds the seigniorage. Then usually small change of a worse kind is stamped, as, for instance, in Aus- tria, copper instead of silver; and in i860, 12 millions florins of paper small Sec. IV.] COMPULSORY CIRCULATION. 45 1 worse consequence is the unrightful revolution produced in so many income and property relations, based on old contracts, to the advantage of the debtor, to the disadvantage of the cred- itor, and of those who receive nominally fixed salaries.* These consequences are in kind similar to those produced by the clipping of the coin; but in degree the}" are much more dan- gerous. ^ Besides, the depreciation of paper produces, by no means, an equal rise in the prices of all commodities. The prices of those commodities, the sellers of which are most favorably situated in the struggle for prices, rise earliest and highest. This is true especially of foreign commodities, also of those inland commodities which can be easily exported, and most particularly of those commodities which have the change. Here the exportation of the better money is not a consequence, but the motive to the manufacturing of the worse. * During the assignat-period it could happen that a land owner, after the term for which he had farmed out his land, might be compelled to surrender it to the farmers, for the reason that the taxes, requisitions, etc., paid by the farmers, amounted to more than the farm rent. In the case of the former, the calculation was based on the recent depreciated value of the assignats ; in the case of the latter, on the higher value the assignats had at the moment tha-t the contract was concluded. (BiiscJi, Geldumlauf, III, 62.) A writer in the Revue des deux Mondes, April 15, 1865, thinks that one reason why the American civil war was so popular in the northwest was because the paper money issued during the rebellion made it easy for that part of the country to pay off the mortgage-debts which had burthencd it since 1848. Even of the two law catastrophes, Duclos. in his memoirs, remarks that they produced a great admixture of those who had been formerly separated hy differences of class and wiped out thepreviousideasof decorum, fitness, etc. * During the time that the clipping of the coin was practiced, it is scarcely possible to show that money was debased below 11 per cent, of what its value should have been. See, on the other hand, § 3. In Austria, in iSio, a per- son had to give 1,200 florins in paper money for 100 florins in silver. (Tiib. Zeitschr., 1861, 593.) In North America, in 1781, it took $280 in paper to purchase $1 in silver. (Ebeling^ Gesch. und Erdbeschreib., von N. A., 1856, III, 580; IV, 440; V, 437.) During the American civil war, the paper money of the Southern States declined to ^ (December, 1863) and even to -^-^ (Oc- tober, 1864) of its nominal value. Compare Hoch^ Finanzen der V. Staaten, 514 ff. Observed even by StorcJi, Handbuch, 7?a?^V translation. III, 141 if. (See, on the other hand, C. King, Thoughts, p. 113.) In Paris in Julv, 1795, the greater number of commodities estimated in assignats were worth as 452 PAPER MONEY. [App. I, greatest capacity for circulation, for instance, gold and silver.^ Hence, it would be a great mistake in countries where there is an irredeemable paper currency with compulsory circula- tion, to measure its purchasing power at a special discount as compared with the precious metals. Therefore, a depreciated paper currency has transitorily an effect on industry similar to that of a protective tariff, and even as the payment of export premiums; inasmuch as it enables manufacturers to permit a part of their cost of production, viz. : that which they have to pay their workmen, their older creditors, and in part, also, their furnishers of raw material, to rise in a less degree than the paper money has declined in value.''^ This is indeed a very inequitable advantage accorded to private individuals in the much as if the rate of exchange of the latter was 6-14 per cent, of their nominal value, while it actually amounted to only 3^ per cent. " Where an agio of exchange of metallic money as compared with paper is prohibited, the decline of the latter will manifest itself not only in foreign rates of exchange, but also in the price of bars of the precious metals. ' The changes of the agio or premium depend mainly on the supply and demand of the precious metals, that is, on the extent and intensity of the busi- ness transactions which have to be made in these metals themselves. (Wag- ner^ Russ. Papierw., 87.) Hence, for short periods of time, it may be said in a paper currency country, that business transactions based on cash money have a great element of variation in them. ( Wagner in BluntschW s Staats- wSrterbuch, III, 971.) The purchase and lease-hold prices of fixed capital, of houses, for instance, rise much less because most people look upon the dis- tress as transitory, and of short duration. (A. Walker, Sc. of W., 133.) In Austria- in 1859, the rise of the agio of exchange of silver from par to 40 per cent., and its subsequent fall within 7 months to 20 per cent., left the price of coin almost entirely unaffected. (A. Wagner, Gdtt. Anz., 1S60, 114.) That country people in general suffer more from a bad paper currency than the towns people and inhabitants of cities, see Bonaniy Price, Currency and Banking, 175, seq. In the northern states of the American union, in 1864, 12 home kinds of commodities had risen 148 per cent, 7 foreign kinds of commodities, 164 per cent., and 7 which could be obtained only from the southern states, 353 per cent. (v. Hock, 186 seq.) As too great issues of pa- per money are so frequently made on account of war, it is comparatively easy to understand why it is that articles for which war creates a demand should rise in price very soon and very high; while the very opposite hap- pens in times of taxation-distress, in the case of a great many articles of lux- ury, which can readily be dispensed with. BUsch remarks (Werke, VII, 91), Sec. IV.] COMPULSORY CIRCULATION. 453 face of the universal distress of the country.^ ^ And these bad consequences are aggravated by the downward-path princi- ple which a depreciated paper money always involves. The state whose financial distress introduced the evil, sees a great portion of its revenues melt away before its eyes;^° while in what concerns its outlay, nothing is more calculated to mis- lead it than such an imagined creation out ot nothing. And a thing which greatly contributes to this is the frightful sensi- tiveness of a depreciated paper currency in the presence of complications of foreign politics, a quality which may cause the government as many inconveniences from without as the issue of its paper money produced conveniences to it at home.''^ that retail dealers frequently raise their prices in order not to be obliged to pay out so many small coins as change for the paper dollar. 8 Compare Hufeland^ N. Grundlegung, II, 241. Self-seeking undertakers ( Unternehmer =^ men of enterprise) have, on this account, both in Austria and Russia (Wagner, Russ. P. W., 105), but more so in North America (v. Hock, 556 ft"), opposed measures intended to restore values ( Valuta), on the ground that they were anti-national. Even Sperausky experienced this in 1809, when he published very correct ideas on paper money, while in the "fairy" times of Catherine II., no one even thought that state paper money is a state debt. (Bernhardi, Russ. Geschichte, II, 2, 636.) One of the prin- cipal representatives of this course is H. C. Carey, Our Resources (1866), and in the New York Herald, 1865. On the other hand, Faucher rightly calls the more active exportation of countries, with a bad paper currency, an ex- portation of barbarous nations, the commerce of misery, to which any price paid in metal or in any higher-standing product of civilization is acceptable. (Vierteljahrsschrift, 1868, IV, 167.) The nation in the aggregate loses in in- ternational trade for the simple reason that its foreign creditors will accept its paper money at most at its current rate of exchange against specie, while foreign debtors force it upon the nation at its nominal value. ^ The different provinces also of a large empire may have very different degress of depreciation of the same paper money. Thus, in the interior of Russia its rate of exchange against specie had for a long time not declined beyond 50 per cent, of its nominal value; while the foreign rate of exchange supposed a decline to 33^/^ per cent. (Cancrin^ Weltreichthum, 68.) '0 An enhancement of duties, taxes (Abgaben) etc., will seldom be able to progress in the same measure as the paper money sinks ; in any case, a law would be necessary to effect this, which, however, comes always later than the decline. (Stsmoudi, Du Papier Monnaie, 27.) " Wagner, Russische Papierwtihrung, 142, estimates that the Crimean war 454 PAPER MONEY. [App. I. Hence recourse is had to additional issues of paper, which are easily increased in the same measure as the rate of exchange (Conrs) has declined. ^^ Great private interests operate in the same direction. Between the increase of the volume of the paper currency in circulation and its consequent depreciation, some time always elapses; and in the mean time, either the purchasing power of the money-owner or his loaning capital is really greater than before. The former increases the de- mand for commodities, the latter facihtates their coming into existence. However, the flight of speculation with which the increase of paper money is wont to be accompanied ^^ in the beginning depends on an error shared by many men as to its true value. Hence it does not last long, and the critical shriv- eling up of the inflated bubbles is greater in proportion to what the previous dimensions of these bubbles were. And now many believe that the nation's business or economy might be kept on its course by new emissions of paper money; and the wise ones hope, at least, to be able thereby to post- pone the catastrophe long enough to enable themselves to get their property into a safe condition. And in fact, the restora- tion of a depreciated currency is accompanied by crises en- tirely similar to those which followed its first decline; only they are in an opposite direction.^^ And hence conscientious depreciated the average current rate of exchange of Russian paper monej by I I.I percent, the Italian war of 1S59 by 14.5 per cent., the German war of 1866 by 19.4 per cent., spite of tlie fact that Russia did not participate di- rectly in the last two wars. "'The more than forty-five milliards French a ssignats, estimated at their rates current, really produced to the state only about six milliards. (Ge?itz, Histor. Journ., i8oo, II, 317, after Lecoidicux.) 13 Very well explained by H. Thornton^ Paper Credit of Great Britain, ch. 10. As to how, in Austria, the paper-money crisis contributed to bring the rigid national resources into a molten state, and to shake off the national in- ertia by the feeling of insecurity, see Buquoy, Theorie d. Wirthschaft, 1816, 347 fl". Schdffle, System, 3 aufl., 254 seq., thinks that if Austria should first adjust its values, and then, in case of another war, have recourse to a second depreciation, the disastrous disturbances of its national economy consequent herein would be produced twice instead of once, and not without reason. I'' The Prussian treasury-bills stood, in June, 1809, at 36 per cent, of their Sec. IV.] COMPULSORY CIRCULATION. 455 Statesmen are frequently deterred from seeking to eflect such a restoration. Yet the darkest side of a paper currency sev- ered of due connection with precious metal-money consists in the frequent and violent fluctuations of value to which it is subject.^^ The consequence of these fluctuations is, that every commercial transaction, every credit-transaction, and even every act of saving, in which money plays any part, is made to bear the impress of a game of chance ;^^ a conse- quence of far and deep reaching influence, especially in the higher stages of civilization, where the importance of com- merce, of the credit-system, and of money-economy as contra- distinguished from barter-economy is so great; producing there a state of uncertainty which is otherwise peculiar only nominal value; June, iSio, 84^ per cent; January, 1812, I3J^; December, 1812, 44;^; June, 1813, 26j^; July, 1813, 24^^; December 31, 1813, 49K ; January', 181 5, 88; January 5, 1816, 99 per cent. Austrian paper money ex- pressed in terms of metallic money, amounted, on an average, between 1849 and 1855, to 292,000,000, florins: but at certain moments, it fluctuated from 231,000,000 to 337,000,000. (Tubing. Zeitschr., 1856, 124.) The agio of silver fluctuated during the Bancozettel (bank-billets, a species of Austrian paper money) period from one day to another on 'Change 40 and even 100 per cent.: thus, on the news of Napoleon's entry into Paris, between the 25th of March and the 4th of April, from 330 to 440; on the receipt of the news of the result of the battle of Waterloo, in three days, from 458 to 412; after Napoleon's abdication, from 412 to 320. (Gentz, Werke, V, 62.) Hnskisson rightly calls a depreciated paper currency a much worse thing than clipped coin : the clipping of the coin is, so to speak, one great blow after which people can again calculate with certainty; but bad paper money is one con- tinual fluctuation. ""The only diflprence here is that it is not left to individuals to say whether they will join in the game or not." (Hidfcrich.) '* During the later assignat-period every house was full of commodities, every pocket of samples; every "exquisite " and every lady was a merchant, because no one had any further confidence in the money. People had retro- graded to the barbarous condition of trade by barter. (Goncourf, Histoire de la Socidt^ frangaise pendant le Directoire, 1854.) The French constitution of 1795 fixed the salaries of members of the Directory at the value of 50,000 myriogramnies of wheat (art. 173, 68). In Delaware, while the depreciation of paper money lasted, farm rent was usually required to be paid in produce. (Ebeling, V, 37.) 456 PAPER MONEY. [App. I. to barbarous medieval times,''''^ All this discourages the best business men and the best husbandmen more than it does any other class of people, and demorahzes the whole economy of a nation; and demoralizes it the more in proportion as it is easier for the state to influence the value of paper money as compared with specie, and as its influence is more irresistible.^^ The compulsory circulation of paper money is a much more powerful and yet a much more simple screw by means of which to practice extortion than is the most burdensome tax- ation or forced loan, and at the same time the most compre- hensive power which a government can possess to carry out both these measures. (Ad. Wagner.) All the horrors of the later Roman republic, the draining of the provinces by robber-governors with their publicans and sinners, the building up of monstrous fortunes without any production proper, but through usury and rapine alone : all this is made to revive again through the instrumentalit}^ of the national-economic disease called a paper crisis, in a less violent form, indeed, but in one which is much more insidious and scarcely less pernicious. '' " Of all contrivances for cheating mankind, none has been more effectual than that which deludes them with paper money." (D. Webster.) The American Secretary of the Treasury, McCttUocJi, says, in the report of De- cember 7, iS6S, of the legal tender notes : " there can be no doubt that these acts have tended to blunt and deaden the public conscience, and they are chargeable in no small degree with the demoralization which so generally prevails." Niebulir attributes the decline of old Spanish honesty which was formerly so much relied on in all gi-eat money centers, principally to the vales. ('Nichtphilol. Nachlass, 4S9.) 18 This calls to our mind the impersonal mass-crimes to which our own times so frightfully incline, when many a man who would recoil in horror from an ordinary act of pocket-picking or from manslaughter with intent to commit larceny, robs thousands in cold blood by means of a swindling en- terprise, or, for the sake of a fraudulent insurance, destroys the lives of a whole ship's crew. Sec. V.J RESUMPTION OF SPECIE PAYMENT. 457 SECTION V. RESUMPTION OF SPECIE PAYMENTS. The healing of such a paper-money disease as we have de- scribed, it has been endeavored to effect in three ways more particularly. A. By the reduction or bringing back of the depreciated paper money to its full nominal value. And this is best done by gradually drawing paper money into the state treasury by means of taxation or by loans, and refusing to allow such pa- per money to be again issued. The consequent rise in the rate at which the outstanding paper money notes exchange against specie is produced not only by the diminution of the quantity of paper in circulation, but also by the increasing confidence in the future which such a governmental measure inspires.^ While this mode of procedure has in the abstract most in its favor, 3^ et it is not to be recommended in practice except where the depreciation of paper money has either not gone very far or where it has existed only a short time.^ ' Saxon loans of two million thalers treasury notes (Kassetibilleis), August, 1S13, which were then to bear interest in silver and to be paid in silver. The purchase of the precious metals, or loans made by the state in foreigrr coun- tries, with the intention of redeeming paper money, eftect the same end at a much greater cost. (Peschel, D. Vierteljahrsschrift, 185S, III, 254.) If the currency consists of bank notes endowed by the state with compulsory cir- culation and an irredeemable character, such a metallic loan made in order to reimburse the bank for a loan to the state in depreciated notes is a gift made to the bank without reason; and the metallic money brought into the country flows back into foreign parts when the bank restriction is removed, because it, together with the appreciated notes, creates a too abundant circu- lation. - Although in England the suspension of the redemption of notes had lasted from 1797 to 1S19, depreciation of notes during the greater part of fhis time either did not occur at all (Summer of 1797 to 1799, 1S02 If.) or was very small ; and even during the last five war years, it did not amount to much over 30 per cent. About 1817, the notes of themselves again rose to par, and had lost but little during the following years, in consequence of the "reat loans of the continental powers in the English market. Under suchcircum- 458 PAPER MONEY. [App. I. Otherwise the revolution in all property-relations and the dis- turbance of all rightful speculation — always dangerous and easily abused ^- produced by the depreciation would be re- peated by the restoration of values, with this difference only that the disturbance would be produced the second time in an opposite direction. And that those who were previously in- jured should now be compensated for the damage sustained in the first instance is impossible in proportion as the depreciation has been of longer duration. Many of the sufferers from the effects of depreciation are now compelled, even as tax-payers, to contribute to the enrichment of the speculators who have accumulated the depreciated paper into their own hands. B. The extreme opposite of such a course would consist in this, that the depreciated paper should be allowed to go on sinking lower and lower until it was practically worthless, whereupon a new currency, whether of metal or paper, would have to appear like a new world after the waters of a deluge had been abated. Hence, therefore, one of two things: universal bankruptcy entered into with the clearest purpose, or the resignation of despair!^ stances, the repeated promise of the state to make the notes redeemable at their full nominal value was certainly a cogent reason for the Peel's Act of 1819. 'In favor hereof are especially Tooke, Hist, of Prices, II, p. 60 ff., and y. S. Mill, Principles, III, ch. 13. Opposed to it, the so-called Birmingham- Atw^ood school and also Lord Ashburton, in his statement before the Agri- cultural Committee, 1836. But according to Rob. MuscJiet, Tables, exhibit- ing the Gain and Loss to the Bondholders arising from the Fluctuations in the Value of the Currency (1826), the state creditors, on the whole, lost more by the depreciation of the notes than they gained by their subsequent rise. Ad. Wag-ner also is decidedly in favor of the course A. 2 This has occurred not unfrequently in the case of the paper money of subdued revolt: thus, for instance, the Hungarian of 1849; in the case of the Southern Confederacy. But the assignats, too, came to this end, although, according to BiiscJi (Werke IX, 526), the intentions of the country at first were good; and in Austria, in 1810, many prophecies looking in this direc- tion were made. (Per contra Rehberg, Sammtl. Schriften. IV, 334.) Not very differently did it fare with the Swedish coin-tokens (Munzzcichen) of Charles XII, which were altered 7 times between 1715 and 1718; and where besides, the tokens called in in a much too short space of time were transformed Sec. v.] resumption OF SPECIE PAYMENT. 459 C. The middle course between these two has, therefore, been most frequently pursued, viz. : the legal rediictlen of the value of the coin (gesctzliche Devalvirung)^ which consists in reducing the nominal value of paper money to its current value at the moment the law goes into force, and by redeeming it either in specie or in other paper to be issued in smaller quantities/ x\l- though this has been not seldom based on the false principle that the value of every separate amount of money is inversely as the aggregate amount of all the money in circulation ; yet it cannot be questioned that it is only the open declaration of the state bankruptcy which the whole measure involves, and which in most instances has already happened beyond repair. Here there is no new and dangerous disturbance of the na- tion's economy whatever; and the fluctuations of value in the into small change coins -j'j their value hitherto. (Bruckner in HildchramVs Jahrb. 1864, I, 161, ff.) ■^Thu^ it was, for instance, in Austria, in iSii and 1820, at \ and | of the rtominal value, in 1799 in the United States, in 1813 in Denmark with the currency notes (Courantzettel)^ in 1816 in Norway with the royal bank dol- lar notes, in Sweden in 1S14 with the bank notes (Bancozeticlu) at llYz per cent., in 1839 in Russia Avith the bankassignationetiy at f of their nominal value. Of th-eoretical writers this course is recommended among others by Jacob, Staatsfinanzwissenschaft, § 980 fF.; Nebetiius, CEff. Credit, 2 Aufl., ff. ; Deutsche Vierteljahrsschrift, 1841, I, 65; Ran, Lehrbuch, III, § 528; HelferkJi, Tiib. Ztschr., 1856, 435 ff. According to v. Rotteck, Lehrbuch, IV, 402, it may be assumed that paper money is spread among the people of a country in proportion to their resources : which is also the hypothesis on which all direct taxation is based. Hence the gradual depreciation of paper money operates like the imposition of a tax and the reduction of value (Dc- ralvirung) is, so to speak, only the release of the same. Besides Getitz (Werke by Schlezier, IV, 58) shows from the example of Austria in 181 1, that in the case of the taking up of a depreciated paper currency it makes a better impression to give 100 florins in specie for 1,000 florins in paper, than 200 florins in a new kind of paper. The holders of the old paper money have now lost confidence in all paper currency. Of similar import is the imme- diate abolition of the compulsary circulation of paper money at its nominal value (Piince Smith in Faucher^s Vierteljahrsschrift, VII, 126 ff.), and the in- troduction of compulsory circulation in accordance with the day's quotations of the actual value of the paper as compared with specie. (Strachc, Die Valuta in CEsterreich, 1861; fer contra, Ad. Wagner, Tiib. Zeitschr., 1S61, 606 ff.) 460 PAPER MONEY. [App. I. future which are inseparable from the gradual contraction of the volume of paper, continued until it has reached its nomi- nal value, are avoided: this last, of course, only on the sup- position that either the pure metallic or the redeemable paper currency is rigidly adhered to.^ But the problem, how to pro- tect both parties" to contracts entered into at a rate of the cur- rency different from that under which they are to be performed, from all damage, is one which will never be perfectly solved. Hence, of the different measures to economically preserve a state in cases of extraordinary need, the emission of paper money with compulsory circulation is much more universally disastrous to the people than the effecting of loans at the very highest rate of interest, and even than being in arrears in the matter of paying the officials and creditors of the state.* 5 Such measures as were adopted in Austria, in iSii, where a "redemption and extinction deputation," independent of the government was established and sworn to prevent a furtlier increase of paper money, are not sufficient of themselves alone. * The Code Civil (art. 1S95) makes the nominal value entirely conclusive; so, also, the Prussian Landrecht (I, § 790): which is to proclaim the omnipo- tence and infallibility of the state power in the most ingenuous or else in the most brutal manner. The power given by PucJita to metallic value (Pan- decten, VII, aufl., § 38) is applicable neither to paper money nor to small coin; and it ignores entirely that stamped coins and currency money are something different from mere metallic commodities and even from metallic bars. The Austrian civil law (biirgerliche Gesetzbuck) decides in favor of the current value (986 seq.): a view which most inodern jurists since Savigny (Obligationenrecht, I, 404; earlier yet, Hiifeland^ Ueber die rechtliche Natur des Geldschulden, 180) entertain. But they even fail to recognize that the depreciation, for instance, of paper money as compared with specie and gen- eral decrease of purchasing power are identical only in the case of such paper money or reduced coins which have no compulsory circulation. (A. Wagner, Tub. Ztschr., 1863, 47S ff.) ' Let us suppose that at the moment the state could perform its duty to its servants only to the extent of one half If it should frankly admit this, pay one-half in good money and remain in debt for the other half, it might subsequently, in better times, make good to them or to their heirs what it had now refused ; and thus private credit, from the disturbance of which the state can only suifer, suffer no diminution. Both are quite different when the state disguises its insolvency under the mask of apparent full payment in paper inoney which has lost 50 per cent, of its nominal value. In oppo- Sec. VI.] A CURSE OR A BLESSING. 4G1 SECTION VI. PAPER MONEY — A CURSE OR A BLESSING .!> Considering the double-edged-sword character of this mighty instrument,^ and the frightful consequences which its sition to the myth that the absignats saved France, see Levasseiir, in the Acad, des Sc. m. et. p. ' It not unfrequently happens that a nation's paper money has been directly or indirectly affected by an unfriendly state. Tlius for instance, England, in 1794, tolerated an assignat manufactory at Lambeth, •while Frenchmen imi- tated English bank notes. (Archenkolz, Aenalen XI, 429.) Napoleon in iSi3 issued forged Russian bank notes. (Cancrin, CEconomie der menschl. Ge- sellschaft, 136. Niebuhr, Gesch. der Revolution, II, 314.) When Maria Theresa first Avished to introduce paper money, Bolza, her minister of fi- nance, in his urgent appeal to her to desist from adopting such a measure, foretold the subsequent bankruptcy etc. (Mailath, Oesterr. Gesch., V., 83.) Adam Smith compares gold and silver circulation to a highway which, in- deed, produces nothing directly. Paper money is an advance similar to that which Avould be produced by the consti'uction of a machine adapted to the carriage of persons and goods through the air, and which permit the high- ways hitherto used to be turned into meadows, arable land etc. Ad. Smith very strongly emphasizes the insecurity of these " Daidalian wings " as com- pared with the " solid ground of gold and silver," especially in the transitory misfortune produced by war. (W. of N., II, p. 78, Bas.) David Hume says of ail paper media of exchange, that thev share all the harmfulness of an in- crease of specie money, enhancement of the price of commodities, aggrava- tion of the obstacles to exportation; but that they do not share in the useful properties of specie money. (Discourses, On Money and on the Balance of Trade.) The younger Mirabeau kept Necker from pursuing his plan to issue paper money with the words : die ;papier monnaie c'est la feste circidante! In- consistent as Napoleon was in his bank policy (compare Horn, Bankfreiheit, 304), he always rejected paper money. As in 1S05 he wrote to the minister of justice: je ne veut ^as de papier monnaie : so, in opposition to the minister of the interior, he in 1810 compared it to the plague: le plus grandjliau des nations. (Acad, des Sciences m. et p., 1864, II, 212.) Sismondi, too, compares paper money to the paper cannons of the Chinese, which render a cheap service until the hour of danger comes. (N. Principles, II, 107.) Of the banks he says: les avantages aussi-legers les dangers aussi graves. (Eludes, II, 421). Cancrin, CEkonomie der menschl. Gesellschaft, 1845, 152 ff., says he thinks that possibly it might have been well never to have established banks, but that yet the craving for the new is preponderately {^pod, it brings 462 PAPER MONEY. [App. I. abuse produces, it is easy to conceive why so many political economists have expressed such serious doubts as to whether, on the whole, the invention of paper money has been more of a curse or of a blessing to mankind. The controversy is an idle one to a certain extent, since no mature nation (or in- dividual), and no nation which considers itself mature will re- nounce the possibility of a brilliant growth simply because it fears that it may not be able to withstand the temptations to dan- gerous abuse connected therewith. Politically, the best safe- guard against such temptation is a so-called moderate consti- tution, which compels the supreme power in the state by wise and appropriate counterweights, to allow all rightful in- terests to assert themselves, or at least to find expression; and itself to make use not only of the most skillful but also of the most highly esteemed instruments and measures. Such a constitution, indeed, cannot be made; it must be the ripe fruit of a long continued and well conducted national life.^ Of the extremes of forms of government, unlimited monarchy and democrac}^ are about equally exposed to the paper-money disease.^ Aristocracies are less exposed to it, for the reason that from their very nature they eschew centralization ; and the inventions and improvements with it. Even Toohe considers the insecurity of paper money a disadvantage which more than counterbalances its cheap- ness. (Considerations on the State of the Currency, 1S29, 85.) On the doubts of Jefferson and Gallatin^ see IVolozvski, Enqu^te, 170, seq. Webster called paper money " the most effectual of inventions to fertilize the rich man's field by the sweat of the poor man's brow." Tout papier monnaie par lilt meine est tin r7iensonage. (M. Chevalier, Cours, III, 428.) M. Niebuhr calls banks a poison which should be used with moderation. (Bankrevolution und Bankreform, 1846, 37.) Compare the writers named in § 2. ^ Avec la liberie un peuple rCa jamais de mauvaiscs monnaies (F. Lenormajit) : entirely so, provided libertd be translated " true and insured freedom." 2 Law's giddy projects under the regents of Orleans and the assignats of the first republic ; Austria, Russia and the United States; the Danish abso- lute monarchy, and Sweden, both under Charles XII., and its oligarchical times. The history of Rhode Island paper money is peculiarly scandalous. All debts had to be paid within two years, or to be held invalid, and juries were dispensed with in such cases. (Ebeling, Gesch. und Erdbeschreib. von N. America, II, 173 ff.) Sec. VI.] A CURSE OR A BLESSING. 4G3 paper-money system is intimately connected with tlie latter. Nothing so strengthens the central authority as the paper- prerogative with an unlimited power over the prices of all com- modities; and, on the other hand, whenever paper money is to have a wide field for action, there is supposed * a far-reach- ing and intimate interwearing of the ditlerent members of the nation's economy with one another. And in w^iat concerns the various economic stages, paper money is far removed from all medieval times; and for the same reasons that make external commerce here preponderant and condense all commerce into caravans, staple-towns, fairs, and recommend the collection of treasure etc.^ Later, on the other hand, we find two stages especially adapted to paper money. We have first, as yet un- developed but intellectually active (and therefore desirous of progress) colonial countries, possessed in abundance of natural means of production without however being able to concen- trate them into the hands of an undertaker ( Unternehmer) for ^ Ad. Mailer compares "cosmopolitan" metallic money to a universal lan- guage : paper money ties one to the country, as people do not like to travel in foreign parts when they understand only their native language. As paper money compels subjects to take an interest in the state, a state like Austria would act very foolishly if it should begin its reorganization by enhancing its depreciated values (Valuta). (Elemente der Staatskunst, i8o, III, 171; II, 339 ff.) Even in 1S30, he found fault with the Austrian loan for the pay- ment of the paper money. (Briefwechsel mit Gentz, 321 seq.) He lauded paper money because he claimed it led a country back to the barter and service-economy of the middle ages. (Verm. Schriften, I, 59 ff.) Similarly, Gentz., in his later writings. Compare Rosclier, Gesch., der N. CEk., in Deutschland, II, 762. 6 Who, for instance, would lay by a paper dollar in the savings bank for his godchild.' In this respect, too, oriental countries have preserved much of the medieval. Concerning the aversion of the Egyptians of our day for all paper money, see Stephan., ^gypten, 250 seq. This is all the more sur- prising since during several months after the harvest, there are from 4,000,000 to 8,000,000 piasters in specie sent every day from Alexandria by post to private individuals in the provinces. In addition to this there is the immense dilYerence in the French, English and Austrian coins circulating in the coun- try, and which have very different rates in the different provinces. It is still worse in Arabia, (v. Maltzan, Reise, I, 27.) 464 PAPER MONEY, [Arp. I. want of. money.® Here both the saving of the precious metals and the facilitation of transportation effected by means of paper money are of greatest utility. And then we have very highly developed and rich countries; not only because their economic popular education may protect them against the dangers of paper money, but because the rich man has relat- ively least need of money and may dispense with stores of specie most readily, because of his influence over the supply of others.'^ ^ Compare v. ScMozer, Anfangsgriinde, I, 140 ff. M. Niebuhr (Rau's Ar- chiv. N. F., II, 125) finds paper money best adapted to countries without any exchange-trade, but which at the same time require a species of money easily computed and easy of transportation (Russia); countries whose na- tional economy has an extraordinarily rapid growth (the United States) ; and in unusually solid countries (Scotland). "^List, Nat. System der politischen ffik., I, 394. A private individual of small means who should go on his travels without money would be subject to all sorts of annoyances; a king or a Rothschild, just as soon as he was recognized as such, would find credit everywhere. Thus, English business- men have outstanding claims in all parts of the world, which might with- out any great difficulty be called in in the precious metals. The more the division of labor is developed, the better may the condition of a nation's whole economy be seen reflected in the course of its banking system and its exportation and importation. ,.^ ^^ s ■''iv't ^J V^v^' jsi ^^-Ji-^t=^ CM