gg^ HOME UNIVERSITY LIBRARY OF MODERN KNOWLEDGE No. 5 Editors : HERBERT FISHER, M.A., F.B.A. PROF. GILBERT MURRAY, LiTT.D., LL.D., F.B.A. PROF. J. ARTHUR THOMSON, M.A. P*OF. WILLIAM T. BREWSTER, M.A. A complete classified list of the volumes of THE HOME UNIVERSITY LIBRARY already published will be found at the back of this book. THE STOCK EXCHANGE A SHORT STUDY OF INVESTMENT AND SPECULATION FRANCIS W. HIRST EDITOR OF THE ECONOMIST NEW YORK HENRY HOLT AND COMPANY LONDON WILLIAMS AND NORGATF IQII, . V : f. ; HENR.Y JHO^T ANOf -COMPANY THE UNIVERSITY P'RESS, CAMBRIDGE, U.S.A. CONTENTS CHAP. PAGE INTRODUCTION ......... 7 I THE EARLY HISTORY OF BANKING AND STOCK-JOBBING ....... 13 II THE LONDON STOCK EXCHANGE. 180C- 1910 ........... 40 III LONDON'S FOREIGN MARKET AND THE FOREIGN BOURSES ...... 76 IV WALL STREET V GOOD SECURITIES AND THE ART OF IN- VESTMENT ......... 137 VI SPECULATIVE SECURITIES AND MODES OF SPECULATION ........ iCi 1 VII WHY THE PRICES OF SECURITIES RISE AND FALL ......... 187 VIII THE CREATION OF NEW DEBT AND CAP- ITAL .... ...... 212 IX CAUTIONS AND PRECAUTIONS .... 242 GLOSSARY .......... 53 BIBLIOGRAPHY .... 255 THE STOCK EXCHANGE INTRODUCTION IN an old Pennsylvanian almanac of the eighteenth century two qualities were postu- lated for success in business: first, appli- cation or industry, and second, thrift or frugality. The first without the second often leads to nothing. "A man if he knows not how to save as he gets, may keep his nose all his life to the grindstone, and die not worth a groat at last." The old proverb, A fat kitchen makes a lean mil, should remind us moderns that not only excess in eating and drinking, but luxurious and expensive follies of all kinds may drive the hardest worker into debt and difficulty, until after long enjoyment of a good income he ends his career in poverty and dependence. This book is not concerned, however, with the moral value of thrift, or even with the advantages which savings bestow upon the individual. Without sav- ings indeed, or without an inherited fortune, 7 f 8 THE STOCK EXCHANGE no one can feel quite independent. This is a strong and sufficient moral ground for not spending all that one earns. But our particular business is neither with the first process of earning, nor with the second of saving, but with a third. We have to con- sider neither the making nor the saving of money, but its investment after it has been earned and saved. "Investment" is a com- paratively new word; it was not known to Dr. Johnson as a financial term, and many of the investor's facilities are essentially modern. Nor does our subject allow us to treat of all investments, it confines us to that most usual form of investment in Stock Exchange Securities. But it is important to bear in mind through- out that the accumulation of wealth, and the reduction of poverty, and all tjie means by which material comforts and conveniences are multiplied, by w^hich the arts flourish, by which letters and learning are spread through all ranks of society, depend ulti- mately upon the thrift and savings of indi- viduals, assisted by the honesty, the efficiency and the peaceful proclivities of their Govern- ments. That the virtue of saving is easy for the rich and difficult for the poor must be INTRODUCTION 9 confessed; that it is sometimes morally and economically right to spend all one's income and even to borrow may be admitted. But, ! nevertheless, progress depends upon saving, i Banks and Stock Exchanges, which facilitate and encourage saving, are themselves the fruits of saving; without saving they could not have been called into existence. When capital shrinks, when the community they serve sinks into decay, these institutions like- wise must come to grief. Thanks, however/ to the onward march of invention and science, ' as well as to the growing reluctance of nations to engage in war, progress is now the rule and decay the exception. The art of making money is a mystery which cannot be taught; and though many books have been written with prescriptions, for acquiring a fortune, few men have ever! made themselves a penny the richer by! reading them. But the art of keeping money j after you have made it, and of increasing: your surplus capital by judicious invest- ments, can be learnt. Any person with pru- dence and self-restraint can in ordinary times and circumstances secure himself against serious capital depreciation, and obtain a steady dividend on the moneys he has been 10 THE STOCK EXCHANGE able to put by from time to time. This was not always so. In fact, until the last century property and trade were so insecure, even in the most settled and civilised coun- tries, that a man who had saved money was often at a loss what to do. He might have to choose between spending it and hiding it away. The miser, who hoarded his gold, because he could not trust it out of his sight, was to be found side by side with the Jew, who lent it out at exorbitant rates of interest, calculating that he would gain in usury from those who paid more than he lost in bad debts. Pirates by sea, brigands on land, sovereigns and nobles who extorted loans only to repudiate them, Governments which supplied their needs by debasing the coinage, or by issuing worthless paper money these are but samples from a big bunch of circumstances that made the accumulation and investment of wealth in olden times so difficult and hazardous. But now, apart from the wonderful im- provements in administration, justice, and police, the most skilful and successful burglar can no longer rob a rich man of his fortune. And why? Not because the police are more efficient, not because safes have been per- INTRODUCTION 11 fected, not because the art of thieving has decayed. No, simply and solely because the rich man no longer buries his gold. Hoarding is obsolete or obsolescent. It has been super- seded by two special inventions, two marvel- lously ingenious contrivances, which have made the safe disposal of savings incom- parably simpler and easier. These inventions are the Bank and the Stock Exchange, or, shall we say, the cheque and the Stock Exchange security? In Great Britain and the United States, in Canada, Australia, New Zealand and the Cape, almost every one who is in the posses- sion of a moderate income, say 300 a year, or more, has a bank account, into which he deposits his earnings and from which he draws his expenses. If he is of a thrifty and saving disposition, he lives well within his income; and when his balance at the bank grows larger than is necessary he will pick out a security and instruct his banker or broker to buy it for him. This security may be a bond with coupons attached. The purchaser may keep the bond at home and cut off the coupons as they become due, sending them to his banker, who will exchange them for money, and add them to his balance 12 THE STOCK EXCHANGE at the bank. More usually he will deposit his security at a bank, leaving the banker to look after his coupons and add them to his balance as they become due. Or he may have bought the registered stock of some public corporation or private company, in which case the dividend will be sent him regularly by post. The security, of course, is paid for by a cheque upon his bank, and the bank takes that sum from his balance and hands it over to the broker, who buys the security and takes a small commission for his trouble. A hundred years ago the use of the cheque was hardly understood even in London, and an English country gentleman would have had infinitely more trouble in making a small investment than would nowa- days a remote Australian squatter, or a wheat- grower in the wildest West of Canada. A letter posted to London from a distant village of Saskatchewan in 1910 would arrive with far more certainty, and perhaps not less speed, than a letter posted in 1810 from a village in Sutherland or Argyllshire. A penny stamp with a cheque enclosed in a brief letter of in- structions to the banker, and the thing is done. But the thrifty Scot of 1810 would have had the utmost difficulty, and great ex- INTRODUCTION 13 pense as well as risk, in converting a similar amount of cash savings into an interest- bearing security. In 1710 the thing would have been practically impossible. The Bank of England had only just been called into ex- istence, and, in fact, there were no bankers, no brokers, and no Stock Exchange in the modern sense of the word. A man who wished to invest, without personally employing his capital, had practically no choice but to buy property and let it out at a rent, or lend his money on mortgage. Bank of England Stock or National Debt had just begun to be a po- litical speculation for the moneyed Whigs in London. Merchant venturers might risk a large sum in a joint-stock voyage. Otherwise the average Englishman at the beginning of the eighteenth century A.D. was hardly better off for investment than the average Athenian in the age of Pericles, or the average Roman in the days of Cicero. But modern inventions have brought dan- gers as well as securities. There are many traps and pitfalls for the would-be investor. If by very hard work a thrifty person saves 100 or 1,000 one would expect him to take very good care of it. He need not be in any hurry. It will be perfectly safe, yielding him 14 THE STOCK EXCHANGE a modest interest, if he deposits it in a respect- able bank or in the savings department of a post-office. Unfortunately a natural passion for high interest, or the promise of an in- crease in his capital too often makes him an easy prey to some plausible rogue. In a moment of weakness he draws a cheque, buys some unmarketable security, and the greater part if not the whole of his hard-earned sav- ings is irrevocably lost. The wild-cat prospec- tuses, concealed advertisements and inspired tips in which so many newspapers abound are so many traps and pitfalls for the unwary. I have written this little book in the hope that at any rate a few thousands of readers may avoid such losses, and that some hundreds of thousands, perhaps millions, of pounds, which might have been sunk in fraud- ulent companies, may flow through honest hands into sound securities and profitable concerns. Wasteful expenditure and riotous living are often truly described as an ill feature of our age and country. But the reckless waste of savings through mere care- lessness, stupidity, or credulity, may be more deplorable than the wasteful expenditure of income; for it often involves helpless widows and orphans in a wretched and unforeseen INTRODUCTION 15 yet easily avoidable poverty. With a little attention and common sense these miseries can be guarded against. We shall be concerned mainly, as I have said, and as the title of the book implies, with investments in Stock Exchange securities, and more especially in the securities which are bought and sold on the London Stock Exchange. Every Stock Exchange has its own list of securities, and only a small number of stocks are international in the sense of being quoted at the same time on the Ex- changes of London, Paris, Berlin, and New York. But London is the banking and financial centre of the world; nor can any territorial limit be set to British investments. Our merchants and shippers seek profit in every corner of the globe; our investors large and small have interests in every con- tinent, and the London Stock Exchange List is in itself a sort of key to the distribution) of British trade and capital. Moreover, an English book of this description should ap-; peal directly to our American kinsmen in the I United States, to Canadians, Australians, ^ and New Zealanders as well as to the people! now happily drawn together in a United South Africa. It will, therefore, be proper 16 THE STOCK EXCHANGE within a small compass to take a wide view; for, as Burke says, "Great empires and little minds go ill together." But while this is the main purpose, I have aimed incidentally at bringing to bear upon this subject the teachings of history. The stock markets of to-day are not only more interesting but far more intelligible if we can approach them with the lantern of experience in our hand. Those who understand a busi- ness or an institution best are those who have made it or grown up with it. The next best thing is to learn how it has grown up, and then watch or take part in its actual working. With some of the opinions expressed in later chapters the readers will often disagree. Many of them are drawn less from books than from conversation and observation. Every genuine attempt to portray the com- plex conditions of modern business life must fail in a greater or less degree. The colouring will be too bright here, and there too sombre. Something material will be left out. Some expressions may be too strong, and some fac- tors may be over-emphasised. Perhaps I may be accused of a certain bias in favour of the investor and of the general public. And this may well be. At the same time I INTRODUCTION 17 would beg to assure the reader that he and I have no better friends than the numberless bankers, brokers, dealers, and promoters of new undertakings who practise callings so useful and so indispensable with the highest sense of honour, the most scrupulous in- tegrity, and the most consummate ability in the great financial and commercial centres of the world. CHAPTER I THE EARLY HISTORY OF BANKING AND STOCK-JOBBING STOCK EXCHANGE is an honest word. It means exactly what you would expect. Just as a Corn Exchange is a place where corn is bought and sold, so a Stock Exchange is a place where stocks are exchanged, or, if you like, where stocks and shares are bought and sold. It is as familiar to the modern business world as a bank, and in the great commercial capitals, where credit and speculation are focussed, the two are invariably found to- gether. In London the Stock Exchange lies alongside the Bank of England, and round them within a quarter of a mile are clustered hundreds of British, foreign, and colonial banks, exchange houses, discount houses, and financial institutions of every sort and kind. So in New York. There the great banks and financial houses congregate about Wall Street in a fashion that might point 18 EARLY HISTORY 19 rather to their dependence upon the Stock Exchange than to the dependence of the Stock Exchange upon them. Wall Street, in fact, suggests a blend of banking and speculation. But two centuries ago there were few banks and no Stock Exchanges. If we go back only a century our London Stock Exchange was but a struggling institution, a weakling in its cradle, despised and disliked by turns, often threatened with extinction by an irate legis- lature. Even banks were only just beginning to prove their utility, and the true principles of banking were understood by few. Nor had any country in the world at that time a really sound system of currency. The Bank of England itself would not and could not give five pounds for a five-pound Bank of England note. Yet after 1790, when the Bank of Amsterdam fell into disrepute it admitted its insolvency in 1795 London had outdis- tanced all competitors as a disposer of capital, a dealer in credit and a manager of money transactions. In a single century the revolu- tion has been accomplished. In this year of grace (1911) there is hardly an important country except China and even China is planning reform which would not be SO THE STOCK EXCHANGE ashamed to own such a law and system of currency and banking as England boasted a century ago, hardly a great city in the whole world whose merchants and investors are not better provided with facilities than were the wealthy citizens of London in 1811. A con- trast so remarkable may well set us thinking and lead us towards an explanation of the problem we have to solve. For the Stock Ex- change does not stand alone; it is not an iso- lated phenomenon: it is an item in the cata- logue of progress, like the post and the rail way, the telegraph and the telephone. Material progress and advancement are made up of many parts all hanging together. Banks and Stock Exchanges are the outward and visible signs of a wonderful improvement in money and credit. But they could not possibly be what they are without one another, or without a hundred other inventions. For example, what would a bank or a Stock Exchange be without a post-office? And what would a post-office be without railways, steamers, and telegraphs? And how could we have had rail- ways and telegraphs if steam power and elec- tricity had not been discovered and applied? But, though the wonderful inventions that have made the modern system of rapid travel EARLY HISTORY 21 and instantaneous communication are re- sponsible for an equally wonderful system of international commerce and finance, I do not pretend that a Stock Exchange would be im- possible without the railway and the tele- graph. In fact, the London Stock Exchange was founded before either was known. All that is really necessary to make a Stock Ex- change is a sufficient quantity of stocks and shares and a sufficient number of investors or speculators desirous of buying and selling this sort of commodity. Indeed the philosopher, looking back to the civilisation of ancient Greece and Rome, may well wonder why, with their baths, their theatres, their courts of law, their shops and markets and banks, Athens and Rome never invented or possessed a Stock Exchange. But this is only another way of expressing surprise that the convenient device of translating capital and debts into terms of interest-bearing paper was not in- vented until comparatively recent times. If the scheme proposed by Xenophon for a sort of joint-stock bank at Athens had been adopted, it might easily have led to the foundation of a Stock Exchange. Interest-bearing paper, in the sense of Stock Exchange securities, was part of a contrivance 22 THE STOCK EXCHANGE of the moneyed interest to finance the Con- (/ tinental wars of William of Orange. But William's was not the first needy Government that would have welcomed any plan for relieving its necessities at the expense of posterity. Money, of course, and money-lending can be traced back far beyond the Christian era. Athenian lawyers in the days of Demosthenes argued about mortgages on land and ships. But an investor could not buy a share in a company or lend money to the State by put- ting a talent into Greek bonds. There were no Italian rentes for a Roman citizen to buy with a bag of coins bearing Csesar's image and inscription. It may well be asked why the world made no steady progress in wealth until the eight- eenth century, and why since then, in spite of wars and armaments, plagues and famines, earthquakes and conflagrations, capital has accumulated at an ever-increasing rate. I am inclined to think that among the various con- tributory causes an improvement of money, ^ a development of credit, and a multiplication of investments (three closely connected facts) have played a decisive part. The establish- ment of sound and honest money comes first; EARLY HISTORY 23 for without this there can be no confidence, and without confidence trade cannot flourish and wealth cannot accumulate. When Europe began to wake from the dark centuries that followed the fall of the Roman Empire, Italy took the lead not only in the renaissance of art and learning, but also in commerce. The Bank of Venice is supposed to have been founded in 1157. In the four- teenth century the Florentines forged ahead, and the Bank of the Medici became the financial centre of what little financial inter- course and commerce then existed between the principal nations. In 1401 a bank was founded at Barcelona, and in 1407 the Republic of Genoa, being embarrassed by a multitude of loans, consolidated them into a "mountain" (monte) and made this heap of debt the capital of a bank which was placed under the management of eight directors elected by the holders of the debt or stock. Various cities and territories belonging to Genoa were made over to the bank as secur- ity for the debt. The fame and success of the Italian banks led to the foundation of small lending houses in other countries by Lombard merchants. Quite a number settled in Lon- don, and gave their name to Lombard Street. 4 THE STOCK EXCHANGE As the Italian cities declined those of Ger- many and Northern Europe rose, and the Hanseatic League flourished during the fif- teenth and sixteenth centuries. Then Holland shook off the Spanish yoke and forged a new link between freedom and wealth. The fa- mous Bank of Amsterdam was founded in 1609. Its prime purpose was to provide a good mercantile currency to remedy the evils of worn and clipped coins, which harassed merchants everywhere and embarrassed spe- cially the trade between Holland and other countries. Already the Dutch were becom- ing the principal carriers and merchants of Northern Europe. The bank established this predominance. It received bad coins at very nearly their intrinsic value, issuing coin of standard weight and fineness in return. At the same time it was enacted that all foreign bills of exchange drawn upon, or negotiated at, Amsterdam of the value of more than 600 guilders should be paid in bank money. Thus the value of bills on Holland was raised abroad, and foreign merchants found it con- venient to keep an account at the Bank of Amsterdam, so that they might have legal money to buy foreign bills. The bank was the property of the city and was under the EARLY HISTORY 25 control of four burgomasters. It was founded on the principle of providing good money for the finance of foreign trade in the freest and most prosperous commercial port. It was also a bank of deposit, and as such carried to con- siderable perfection the principle of written transfer. Any person who chose to lodge money in the bank might transfer it from his own name to that of another; and the law, as we have seen, required foreign bills of exchange to be paid by such transfers. The device is really the same as that by which a business transaction between two persons who have accounts at the same bank is now settled. One draws a cheque in favour of the other. The amount of money at the bank remains the same, but some of it is transferred in the bank's book from the name of the customer who drew the cheque to that of the other who endorsed it. Thus there is a transfer of money without any actual movement of cash. The Bank of Amsterdam flourished for a hundred and fifty years. Its fall was brought about by the misconduct of its directors, preceded and followed by a relative decline in the commerce of Holland, which yielded to the growing strength and wealth of Eng- land. In one of the most instructive digres- 26 THE STOCK EXCHANGE sions of his great masterpiece, The Wealth of Nations, Adam Smith explains how the money current in small commercial city states like Amsterdam, Hamburg, and Nuremburg con- sisted largely of foreign coins, many of them worn and debased, and how, in order to rem- edy the inconveniences of these exchanges, banks were originally established in these and other cities, which came in time to serve wider purposes. But larger and more self- contained countries, like England and France, which then depended but little upon foreign commerce, were more troubled by the de- fects of their own currencies than by the bad coin of their neighbours. And so the Bank of England originated not so much from external necessities or the requirements of foreign trade as from the needs of Govern- ment and reasons of State. England, indeed, had at first made but slow progress in the arts of economising money and manufacturing credit. The profitable busi- ness of money-changing was monopolised by Henry the First, John, Edward the Third, and some of their successors, who established the office of Royal Exchanger in London at Old Change near St. Paul's and in other towns. This official had the exclusive privi- EARLY HISTORY 27 lege of exchanging gold coins for silver, and foreign for English money. The king farmed out the office, or shared in the profits, and the office in each town was called the Exchange, a name still attached to many of the covered markets where merchants meet to buy and sell and speculate in particular commodities such as w r ool, cotton, corn, as well as in stocks and shares. The office, which had fallen into disuse, was revived by a proclamation of Charles the First, much to the dissatisfaction of the goldsmiths, who had been making good profits by culling out heavy coins for melting or for sale to the Dutch mint. The Gold- smiths' Company and the Common Council appealed in vain against this ordinance; but after the Commonwealth was established the business of money-changing fell again into the hands of the goldsmiths. Another trade, that of money-lending, was monopolised by the Jews from the Conquest until their expul- sion in 1290, when the Lombards succeeded to the craft and proved equally usurious, their rates being proportioned to their risks. There was also a legal rate of interest 10 per cent, from 1571 to 1624, then 8 till 1651, and 6 till 1714, after which it was fixed at 5 for England, and 6 for Ireland. The term 28 THE STOCK EXCHANGE "usury" denoted any rate of interest above that which the law sanctioned and enforced. After Charles the First's time the goldsmiths became the principal lenders and dealers in money, though reinforced by the Jews whom Cromwell readmitted to England. Then, as Gilbart, our leading authority on English banking, explains, a new era began in the history of banking. "The goldsmiths, who were previously only money-changers, now became also money-borrowers, and allowed interest on the sums they borrowed. They were agents for receiving rents. They lent money to the king on the security of the taxes. The receipts they issued for the money lodged at their houses circulated from hand to hand, and were known by the name of Goldsmiths' Notes. These may be considered as the first kind of bank-notes issued in England." The banking goldsmiths made way rapidly, and attracted large quantities of cash, which enabled them to advance money to Cromwell and Charles the Second at high rates in ad- vance of the revenues . These ' ' new-fashioned bankers " were sharply criticised by the pam- phleteers, and even by Sir Josiah Child, for draining away money from the country to London and preventing its investment in EARLY HISTORY 29 land. Here, in fact, we have a small begin- ning of the modern system of investment by deposit in banks. After the Restoration, it is written, "King Charles the Second being in want of money, these goldsmith bankers took 10 per cent, of him barefacedly and by private contracts. On many bills, orders, tallies and debts of that king they got 20, sometimes 30 per cent, to the great dis- honour of the Government." In 1667, when the Dutch fleet sailed up the Thames, set fire to Chatham, and burnt four ships of the line, there occurred the first recorded "run" on our banks. The alarm was allayed by a royal proclamation promising that the payments to the bankers should be made as usual from the Exchequer. But in 1672 the Exchequer was closed and the king repudiated a debt of 1,328,526 which he had borrowed of the goldsmiths at 8 per cent. This shameless act caused wide distress. "Not merchants only, but widows, orphans and others became sud- denly deprived of the whole of their property. They came in crowds to the bankers, but could obtain neither the principal nor the interest of the money they had deposited." Ultimately the king compounded after the manner of Central American Republics. He SO THE STOCK EXCHANGE refused to repay the principal, but granted a patent to pay 6 per cent, interest out of his hereditary excise. Then after six years he again suspended payment. This Goldsmiths' Debt, or Bankers' Debt, was reconsidered in the years following the Revolution. After some litigation the claims of the creditors were partially recognised. A settlement was reached in 1705, the Government agreeing to pay 3 per cent, (about half the market rate) on the capital with the right to discharge the whole at any time by payment of one half the amount originally lent. We are now brought to the foundation of the Bank of England, which coincides with the first chapter in the English History of Stocks and Stock Jobbing a development much hated by the old Jacobites and Tories. They called it "Dutch finance," and their prejudice was justified partly by political, partly by economic, and partly by moral considerations. Politically they hated the Bank and the Stock which it issued, because it supplied the Government with money; for the Government was the Whig Government, standing between the country and the return of the Stuarts. Economically they disliked both Bank and Debt, because easy borrowing EARLY HISTORY SI meant heavy expenditure on war, and an increase of taxes, principally on land, to pay the growing interest on the debt. Morally and socially they hated the new "Dutch" -finance, because it stimulated speculation, * and increased the power of London and of the moneyed interest at the expense of the coun- try gentlemen. But the new system with all its evils had come to stay, and was destined not only to make many fortunes and bank- ruptcies, but also to give a marvellous im- petus to the growth of credit, trade and capital. What happened has been often told, and for our purpose it is enough to retell the story very briefly. During the seventeenth century our kings generally borrowed by means of Exchequer tallies, which were acknowledgments of sums paid by private lenders to the Exchequer. The tally was a willow stick four or five feet long and about one inch square. There were notches on one side to express the amount of the debt, and identical descriptions of the payment were written on two of the three vacant sides. The stick was split in half through the notches. One half was given to the person making payment into the Ex- chequer; the other half of the counter tally, 32 THE STOCK EXCHANGE or counter foil, was kept at the Exchequer as a check. Here, it will be seen, we have at once the origin of the modern cheque system of our banks; and in the United States the early spelling of "check" is still adhered to. There were two kinds of tallies Tallies of Pro and Tallies of Sol. The Tallies of Pro were like a modern cheque on a banker, and served as a voucher to the holder at the Ex- chequer of account. This Tally was so called because it was struck "Pro," i. e. for the bene- fit of the person named. Tallies of Sol were acknowledgments of sums paid (solutum) into the Exchequer, and were issued when loans were raised from the public; while Tallies of Sol (as Mr. Joseph Burn points out in his excellent lectures on "Stock Exchange Investments") came into play when public subscriptions were not forthcoming, being issued in lieu of cash for the payment of ordi- nary disbursements by the Government. The Tally system was not abolished till 1783, and served the purpose of modern Treasury bills enabling the Government to borrow small sums for short periods. But the action of Charles the Second in repudiating the Goldsmiths' Debt naturally made tallies sus- pect, and increased the difficulty of borrow- EARLY HISTORY 33 ing. Hence after the Revolution the Parlia- ment of William had to find money for foreign wars by other methods, and in 1692 a million was raised by life annuities. In 1694 the Bank of England was founded. It was the project of William Paterson, a clever but speculative Scot, who afterwards came to grief in the Darien enterprise. It was the first of our Joint-Stock Banks, and though not the first of our Joint-Stock Companies it gave the first opportunity for general dealings in Stocks and Shares. The scheme com- mended itself to Montagu a Whig statesman of great financial ability as a means of raising money; and the Government granted a charter to the Bank on condition that the Bank should lend the whole of its original capital (1,200,000) to the Government, re- ceiving in return (1) 96,000 annually, i. e. 8 per cent, interest plus 4,000 for manage- ment, (2) the right to issue notes to the extent of 1,200,000 and (3) the right to do banking business. In plan, therefore, and original pur- pose the Bank of England resembles the Bank of Genoa rather than the Bank of Amsterdam. At first all went well. The tallies, which had been at a heavy discount, soon rose to par. But in 1696 the Bank failed in an attempt 34 THE STOCK EXCHANGE to carry out a recoinage, the currency then being in a very bad state. A suspension of payments followed with a depreciation of bank notes and Exchequer tallies; but the Bank's credit was restored with the aid of the Government. In the following year the Gov- ernment had to borrow another million, which was added to the Bank's capital with a cor- responding increase of the note issue. In spite of the enmity of private banks the Bank of England was well supported by the moneyed interest. Its early issues were fully subscribed, and in 1709, when the capital was doubled, the whole of the new stock over two millions, was issued at a premium of 15 per cent, and subscribed in four hours. The National Debt meanwhile was grow- ing in various ways. In 1698 the New East India Company received a charter on the con- dition that its capital was lent to the Govern- ment. By 1711 the funded Debt had grown to 11,750,000, all of which was held by public investors as annuities, bank stock, East India Stock, etc., at various rates of in- terest. But there was also a huge unfunded debt which had grown to 9 millions in 1710. A new Joint-Stock Company called the South Sea Company was promoted with the aid of EARLY HISTORY 35 Harley and St. John to take over this Debt. In return for this it was granted trading privileges, and to provide interest on its 9 millions of capital stock the Government assigned various duties on wine, and beer and tobacco, etc. For ten years the company engaged in the African Ocean trade and other commercial ventures with little success. Then Sir John Blunt one of the directors, a cun- ning and plausible scrivener, hatched another scheme, and by corrupt means won over Aislabie the Chancellor of the Exchequer, and various other ministers and members of Parliament. The idea was taken from the famous Mississippi Company scheme of Law, which had burst over France with such disastrous ruin a year before. Undeterred by this example, Blunt boldly offered to take over the whole National Debt, amounting to 31 millions, if the Government would guarantee 5 per cent, interest for seven years and 4 per cent, thereafter in perpetuity. For some time the Bank of England and the South Sea Company bid against each other for the favour of the Government, but eventually the company's offer was accepted. The company then opened its first subscription of a million in 100 stock at 300. Blunt opportunely 36 THE STOCK EXCHANGE circulated a report that Gibraltar and Port Mahon would be exchanged with Spain for some places in Peru, whereby the South Sea trade would be protected and enlarged. Persons of all ranks crowded to South Sea House, and the stock went off like hot cakes. This was in April. By midsummer there was a second, and then a third subscription, accompanied by promises of more and more prodigious dividends. The city went mad; stock-jobbers ran from coffee-house to coffee- house inviting subscriptions to the great bubble and to little bubble companies of all descriptions. It was the first joint-stock mania. "All distinction of party, religion, sex, character, and circumstances," writes Smollett, the historian of the time, "were swallowed up in this universal concern. Ex- change Alley was filled with a strange con- course of statesmen and clergymen, church- men and dissenters, Whigs and Tories, physi- cians, lawyers, tradesmen, and even with mul- titudes of females. All other possessions and employments were utterly neglected; and the people's attention wholly engrossed by this and other chimerical schemes, which were known by the denomination of bubbles. New companies started up every day, under EARLY HISTORY 37 the countenance of the prime nobility. The Prince of Wales was constituted Governor of the Welsh copper company: the Duke of Chandos appeared at the head of the York buildings company: the Duke of Bridgewater formed a third, for building houses in London and Westminster. About a hundred such schemes were projected and put in execution, to the ruin of many thousands. The sums proposed to be raised by these expedients amounted to three hundred millions sterling, which exceeded the value of all the lands in England. The nation was so intoxicated with the spirit of adventure, that people became a prey to the grossest delusion. An obscure projector, pretending to have formed a very advantageous scheme, which, however, he did not explain, published proposals for a sub- scription in which he promised that in one month the particulars of his project should be disclosed. In the meantime he declared that every person paying two guineas should be entitled to a subscription for one hundred pounds, which would produce that sum yearly. In one forenoon this adventurer re- ceived a thousand of these subscriptions; and in the evening set out for another kingdom." The third South Sea subscription was 38 THE STOCK EXCHANGE 1,000 for 100 stock, and 2,000 was touched before September, when the stock began to fall. By September 29 it had sunk to 150. Several eminent bankers and gold- smiths, who had lent great sums on it, were forced to stop payment and abscond. "The dbb of this portentous tide was so violent that it bore down everything in its way; and an immense number of families were over- whelmed with ruin." Walpole called in the aid of the Bank, but its resources were un- equal to the emergency. The king was sum- moned back from Hanover; Parliament was assembled, and Walpole laid before it a wise scheme for restoring the public credit. So the curtain closed on this strange scene of national infatuation. But it must be said, for the credit of Parlia- ment, that a thorough inquiry was instituted and some severe punishments meted out. In the salutary reaction that followed, the Brit- ish public began to appreciate the value of gilt-edged securities, and the British Govern- ment, under the prudent guidance of Walpole, practised peace and economy. The public credit responded marvellously. In Queen Anne's reign 6 per cent, had been the usual rate of interest on public loans. Within six years of the bubble in 1726 a 3 per cent. EARLY HISTORY 39 Government stock in 10 lottery tickets was issued at par, and actually sold up to 107 in 1739. In the wars with Spain and France (1740-1747) 30 millions more in new loans at various rates were added to the National Debt; but in the ensuing peace credit speed- ily revived, and in 1749 a successful scheme of conversion was effected by which the interest on the greater part of the debt was reduced to 3 per cent. Two funds were established, one being called the 3 per cent, consolidated annuities. Thus were created the world-famed British "Consols" (i. e. consolidateds) which, through many fluctuations of credit, retained "the sweet simplicity of 3 per cent." for more than a century. After a short interval of peace London's stock and share markets were again flooded with Government paper by the Seven Years' War (1756-1763) which added 54 millions to the National Debt in lottery loans, bearing interest at 3, 3|, and 4 per cent, apart from the prizes. During the succeeding peace some debt was paid off, and some was converted from 4 per cent, to 3 per cent. But in 1776 the long war of Ameri- can Independence broke out, and ten years later, when its financial consequences became 40 THE STOCK EXCHANGE clear, the National Debt was found to have been nearly doubled, having increased from 128 to 244 millions, while the charge for in- terest had more than doubled, having risen from 4,471,000 to 9,302,000. At the Peace of Versailles, in 1783, the funded debt consisted of 107,000,000, 3 per cent, consols, 37,000,000 3 per cent, reduced, 32,000,000 Four per cents., and 17,000,000 Fives, while a further 42 millions was owing to the Bank, to the East India and South Sea Companies, and to the Civil List. After another breathing space the country was launched upon the most disastrous and ter- rible of all our wars, the war of the French Revolution. Just before its commencement in 1793 the Funded Debt amounted to about 228 millions with an interest charge of about 7f millions, and the unfunded or floating debt was 16 millions, with an interest charge of just under half a million. At the conclusion of peace in 1815, according to the computation of Robert Hamilton, the National Debt had run up to the appalling total of 758 millions and the charge for interest and annuities was 27,652,000. No wonder that in this last period the London Stock Exchange had be- come an important institution, or that great EARLY HISTORY 41 ' fortunes had been made by contractors and loan-mongers of all descriptions. No wonder either that the country was submerged in pauperism and its Government fast approach- ing a state of bankruptcy. From this brief account of the National Debt, which must have absorbed a very great part of the National Savings from 1700 up to the year 1815, we may return to Stock Jobbing, with which, as has been seen, the | origin and expansion of our national war loans are so intimately and even inseparably associated. It has been shown how during the South Sea Bubble speculation ran through ! all ranks of London Society. But the boom ' in South Sea Stock had, as it were, a gilt- edged basis in the favour and support of the Government. Harley, as Chancellor of the Exchequer, had been Governor, and one of the original directors was St. John (Viscount Bolingbroke). In the huge swindle of 1720 |Aislabie, the Chancellor of the Exchequer, and Lord Sunderland, who represented the Ministry in the House of Lords, were deeply implicated. No wonder, then, that rank and fashion led that wild rush of speculators to Change Alley. A ballad-monger of the time , tells how the stars and garters vied with the j meaner rabble 4* THE STOCK EXCHANGE "To buy and sell, to see and hear The Jews and Gentiles squabble," and how "the greatest ladies" "Plied in chariots daily, Or pawned their jewels for a sum To venture in the Alley." In the reaction that followed stock-job- bing suffered discredit; but it was a genuine profession, meeting a new and genuine need. The public debt proved to be unextinguish- able : the public funds grew so fast and fluctu- ated so rapidly under the influence of wars and rumours of wars that the quick-witted gentry of Change Alley and the coffee-houses found plenty of occupation. Private banks and joint-stock companies were also multiply- ing. Even during the mushrooii growths of the South Sea Boom two sound insurance companies which still exist the London As- surance Corporation and the Royal Exchange Assurance found recognition and capital. It may be asked where all the money came from. The answer is to be found in the fact, upon which we have been insisting, that these new interest-bearing securities gave employ- ment to wealth that had previously lain idle. The practice of hoarding is not easily extir- EARLY HISTORY 43 pated, and only yields to the gradual growth of confidence in the credit of Government, of banks, of brokers, and of established com- panies. It says much for the statesmen, the merchants, the bankers, and even the Stock- jobbers of eighteenth century London that money came out so freely in this very first epoch of investment. At the Revolution one fugitive is said to have carried his fortune of 20,000 away with him in a strong box. A generation later he would have taken it in bank-notes or negotiable stock. The jobbers were long in housing them- selves. At first they frequented the Royal Exchange and the Rotunda of the Bank, then the coffee-houses and the streets Cornhill, Lombard Street and especially Change Alley and Sweetings Alley. Old Jonathan's Coffee- house was a favourite resort for those who pre- ferred indoor comfort to the rough and tumble and exposure of Change Alley. It was burnt down in 1748. But New Jonathan's took its place, and, in July 1773, "the brokers and others at New Jonathan's came to a resolution that, instead of its being called New Jona- than's it should be called The Stock Exchange, which is to be wrote over the door." From this time London may be said to have pos- 44 THE STOCK EXCHANGE sessed a Stock Exchange in the modern sense, though much business in the public funds was still transacted at the Bank, and dealings in foreign securities still centred in the Royal Exchange. The members of Jonathan's paid a small subscription and eventually drew up rules, and appointed a committee of manage- ment. But daily admission could be gained by a payment of sixpence. At length the membership of brokers and jobbers outgrew the accommodation, and at the end of the eighteenth century it was determined to pro- vide new quarters. A building was erected close to the Bank of England, in Capel Court, and opened in March 1802 with a membership of about five hundred. But this belongs to our next chapter. Here it only remains to add that the first Stock Exchange book was published in 1761. Its title ran: Every man his own broker, or a Guide to Exchange Alley. The author, J. Mortimer, was an economist of some merit. He had been British Consul in Holland and had seen the workings of the Amsterdam Bourse and the arbitrage business between London and Amsterdam, which was already considerable in the middle of the eighteenth century; for the Dutchmen were fond of speculating in the London market. EARLY HISTORY 45 Mortimer seems to have lost money in stocks, and the main purpose of his book is to warn the investing public and the Government against the jobbers. He therefore gives minute instructions to would-be investors in Government funds, showing them how to deal directly with the officials at the Bank of Eng- land. We shall have occasion in another chapter to refer to this interesting book, which ran to many editions. It shows that much of the slang and many of the arts and tricks of speculation were already in vogue before the formation of the London Stock Exchange. 1 1 Before proceeding with the next chapter, readers un- familiar with the subject should read the glossary at the end of the book (p. 253). CHAPTER II THE LONDON STOCK EXCHANGE, 1800-1910 AT the desire of the Royal Commission of 1877 the officials of the London Stock Ex- change supplied a short summary of the origin and objects of the institution. The secretary stated that the earliest minutes on the subject were dated December 1798, and that these records referred to the existence of a Stock Exchange in 1773 apparently the Stock Exchange Coffee-house in Thread- needle Street, to which any person was ad- mitted on payment of sixpence. Already these rooms were known as "the Stock Ex- change," or "the House"; and although transactions in the public funds were also carried on in the Rotunda of the Bank of England "there is little doubt that the Stock Exchange Rooms afforded a ready market for the operations of the bankers, merchants, and capitalists connected with the floating of the numerous loans raised at that period for the service of the State." It is 46 LONDON STOCK EXCHANGE 47 on record, continues this official authority, that the rooms were under the control of a "committee for general purposes," though the expenses of management were defrayed by the voluntary subscription of frequenters. The functions of the committee were from the first, as they have since remained, "judicial as regards the settlement of disputed bar- gains, and administrative as regards rules for the general conduct of business, and for the liquidation of defaulters' accounts." Early in 1801 the rooms were felt to be inadequate for the increased business arising out of the war loans, and, moreover, "it be- came apparent that the indiscriminate admis- sion of the public was calculated to expose the dealers to the loss of valuable property." This led to the establishment of a strict and privileged monopoly, resembling in some respects that of the law brokers correspond- ing to solicitors and jobbers to barristers. A group of Stock Exchange men, having acquired "a centrical situation," or site, in Capel Court, raised a capital of 20,000 in 400 shares of 50 each and founded a new institution, to which the affairs of the old rooms were ultimately transferred. The first stone of the new building was laid in May 48 THE STOCK EXCHANGE 1801. A committee for general purposes, con- sisting of thirty proprietors, was formed, who elected members of the new Stock Exchange by ballot, at a subscription of ten guineas each. The deed of settlement (March 27, 1802) recites that, whereas the Stock Ex- change in Threadneedle Street, where the stock-jobbers and stock-brokers met, had been found inconvenient, W. Hammond and others had secured a site, and had "caused to be erected a spacious building for the trans- acting of buying and selling the public stocks or funds of this kingdom." By the same deed the management, regulations, and direc- tion of the new Stock Exchange were vested in a committee consisting of thirty members, or subscribers, to be chosen annually by ballot on March 25, while the treasury ship and man- agement of the building were placed under the sole direction of nine trustees and man- agers (separate from the committee) as repre- sentatives of the proprietors. By this deed of settlement the London Stock Exchange was governed till 1876, when a new deed (sub- stantially reproducing the original deed) was executed. The new Stock Exchange was opened in March 1802, with a list of about 500 subscribers. The regulations of the LONDON STOCK EXCHANGE 49 committee, whose main purpose was to ensure the prompt and regular adjustment of all transactions, were first codified and printed in 1812. They have, of course, been amended and enlarged from time to time to meet the new conditions and expansion of business. The constitution of the Stock Exchange remains substantially unaltered, being still vested in two bodies the managers and the committee, the former representing the share- holders or proprietors, and the latter the members or subscribers. The nine managers (who are elected in threes for five years by the shareholders) fix the charges for admis- sion of new members and appoint most of the officials, excepting, of course, the secretary to the committee. They also look after the building. 1 The committee, on the other hand, control all Stock Exchange business, and administer the rules and regulations; they adjudicate all questions between, and com- plaints against, members, They inquire, and decide, whether their rules have been com- plied with by governments and companies which ask for settlements or for official quota- tion of their stocks in the Stock Exchange 1 There are 20,000 shares (12 paid) in the Stock Exchange and 416,700 debentures outstanding. 50 THE STOCK EXCHANGE List. Their number is thirty, and they are elected every year by the members. At the beginning of their term the committee elect a Chairman and Vice-Chairman. They also elect every March, before they go out of office, all the old Stock Exchange members who wish to be re-elected, membership being granted for one year only. Any member can object to any other member being re-elected, but this is a very unusual incident. The great principle upon which the committee' acts, and to which most of its regulations are directed, is the inviolability of contracts. It has power to suspend- or expel any member for breaking its rules, or for non-compliance with its decisions, or for dishonourable con- duct. A member of the London Stock Ex- change is prohibited from advertising or from sending circulars to any but his own clients. He is also forbidden to belong to any other Stock Exchange, or "bucket shop," or other competing institution. New members are now compelled to become proprietors by acquiring at least one Stock Exchange share, paying a heavy entrance fee and an annual subscription of forty guineas. Yet the pre- cautions against impecuniosity are inade- quate. Defaults are far too common. The LONDON STOCK EXCHANGE 51 membership of the Stock Exchange had risen to about 800 in 1845. In 1877 the members exceeded 2,000, and there were over 500 share- holders or proprietors. In 1910 the member- ship was 5,019. The average dividend on the shares of the Stock Exchange had been over 20 per cent, during the first seventy-five years of its existence; the dividend in 1909 was 10 a share. At first, as appears from the deed of settlement, the new Stock Ex- change was confined to transactions in the funds. The jobbers in foreign stocks were excluded, and resorted mainly to the walks of the Royal Exchange. A certain amount of business in the funds continued for some time in the Rotunda of the Bank of England. Nor did the Alley men cease to ply their trade hi the streets and coffee-houses. But after the close of the Napoleonic wars foreign loans and mining and canal shares were in- troduced into the new Stock Exchange; and as all these offered higher rates of interest at a time when the yield on Government loans was falling, the Stock Exchange obtained a large accession of business from the specula- tive public. This led, it is stated, "to a proper apportionment of apartments for the dealing in English and foreign stocks." One 52 THE STOCK EXCHANGE' room was appropriated to British and an- other to foreign government stocks, and one corner of the foreign room was assigned to dealings in "the shares and scrip certificates of the numberless companies which from time to time have been introduced." The years 1824 and 1825 and 1826 saw a great outburst of speculation, which found vent in the flotation of many joint-stock projects as well as in an output of loans to the new re- publics of South America. This epoch will repay closer study. It marks the beginning of cosmopolitan finance, and even in a very rapid survey we can afford to pause and re- flect upon occurrences which have been repeated or substantially reproduced at in- tervals in all parts of the world. In "a complete view of joint-stock com- panies" formed in 1824 and 1825, the author, Henry English, enumerated 626 joint-stock projects which would have required for their fulfilment a capital of 372 millions sterling! Their objects were various and for the most part useful. Some companies were to be formed for insurance and investment; others for the construction of canals and railways. Many were to be local gas companies, and there were mining flotations of all sorts. LONDON STOCK EXCHANGE 53 Between 1818 and 1832 and especially in 1824 and 1825 there were also issued in London quite a number of foreign loans in all perhaps some 40 millions sterling were sub- scribed in this way. According to a parlia- mentary paper, foreign government loans to a nominal value of 34 millions were con- tracted for by London houses at 23 millions, while foreign mining companies and similar liabilities, with a deposit of 10 per cent, paid, amounted to 24 millions. A table before me gives twenty-six foreign government loans in all for the period 1818 to 1832, and shows that of these only ten continued to pay interest in 1837. Of the ten survivors several defaulted a little later. All the good loans (and some of the bad ones) were issued either by N. W. Rothschild or by T. Wilson & Co. Among the curiosities of the list one notices that Neapolitan credit was much better than Prussian; for while Rothschild floated a Prussian 5 per cent, loan in 1818 at 72, the Neapolitan Fives six years later fetched 92^. In 1825 Ricardo sold Greek Fives to the public at 56|. In 1821 Haldimand issued a Spanish 5 per cent, loan at 56, and two years later J. Campbell & Co. issued another at 30 J! London was badly 54 THE STOCK EXCHANGE hit by the Spanish American Republics. In 1824 Baring Brothers contrived to issue 1,000,000 Buenos Ayres Sixes at 85. Colum- bia actually raised, at 6 per cent., nearly 7 mil- lions sterling of nominal debt, and at prices ranging from 84 to 88J. Questioned after- wards as to the causes of the boom and of the crisis which succeeded, a Governor of the Bank of England said he thought the specula- tive movement was started by the conversion and reduction of Government 5 per cents, in 1823. These reductions "prompted almost everybody to entertain any proposition for investment, however absurd." The excite- ment, he thought, "was further promoted by the acknowledgment of South American Republics by this country, and the induce- ments held to those governments, in which all classes of the community in England seem to have engaged simultaneously." One foreign mining company was described later at its winding-up as "one of the projects ventured in a period when it was thought the golden age had been realised, and when, without a proper consideration for the consequences, the public too eagerly encouraged the schemes of the day." Commercial credit and the ex- changes were at the same time disturbed by LONDON STOCK EXCHANGE 55 speculation in iron and other raw materials; and finally a crisis was precipitated by the failure of Messrs. Pole & Co., an important London house with large country connec- tions. The strain must have been enormous; for according to James Wilson, the first editor and proprietor of the Economist, the total subscribed, (i. e. promised) for foreign loans, mines, etcl in 1824-5 was 48 millions, and for home railways, banks, and other projects 126 millions, on which altogether only 35 millions were paid up ! No wonder that a crash came. After a decade of depression and quiescence, when stock and share speculation took a new start in connection with railways, the "little go" for the sale of letters of allotment was held in the Royal Exchange before the mer- chants assembled, until at last the swarms of the "little go" or "Alley men" became such a nuisance that the beadles had to drive them out. In the height of this speculation, it is recorded such was the distrust of steam locomotion some of the "dabblers" made a price of one farthing per share for 50 shares of what afterwards turned out to be one of the most important of English railways. In the boom years of 1834-6, joint-stock companies with a total capital of 135 millions were 56 THE STOCK EXCHANGE formed, divided into more than 2j million shares. New railway companies accounted for over 69 millions of capital with 590 thou- sand shares, banks for 23 millions capital and 670 thousand shares. Allowing an aver- age of 3 for deposit on each share, the total sums raised were only just over 1\ millions. The market recovered slowly from this out- put of liabilities. But in the course of time the importance and profit-making capacity of the new iron roads began more and more to fill the public mind. The first railway boom was fairly launched in 1834-5. Within twelve months over 600 distinct projects for railway lines in the United Kingdom were placed be- fore the public, demanding upwards of six hundred millions of money. But as five or six competing companies often asked parlia- mentary powers for practically the same line, the real capital required was very much smaller. The actual capital of the British lines, which were incorporated by statute in 1844-5 and were in course of construction, was only 55 millions. Foreign railroad schemes also poured in from all quarters eager for British capital, and these again would have absorbed from seventy to a hundred millions sterling. As might have been sup- LONDON STOCK EXCHANGE 57 posed these projects, actual and anticipatory, led to a great demand for, and a still greater speculation in, iron, which more than doubled in price and so magnified the difficulties oc- casioned by the inadequacy of available capital and credit. Ten years later, in a warning article as to the probability of an- other crisis on the analogy of the previous one, which appeared in the Economist in October 1845, the promotions and flotations of the three periods of speculation were thus compared and summarised in millions sterling: Home Schemes. Foreign. Total. Paid up and Deposits. 1824-5 156 43 204 35 1834-7 129 21 150 22 1844-5 612 79 691 78 At the time when this account was made up the premiums on railways, which had not yet secured an Act of Parliament, could not be estimated at less than 40 millions, which represented "increased wealth hanging on opinion." Mr. Wilson's warning forecasts proved correct, and the Stock Exchange panics and liquidations, which took place in the late autumn and winter of 1845-6, cul- minated in the money panic and banking crisis of October 1847. An anonymous but well-informed writer 58 THE STOCK EXCHANGE affords us a glimpse of the Stock Exchange in 1845, at the height of the railway boom: "The share market, which, till within the last two years, was occupied with four or' five distinct brokers and a number of jobbers, whose means of business were very small, has now become the grand focus of specula- tion and legitimate business. English and foreign government securities are quite de- serted for the superior attractions of English and foreign Railway scrip, which, of all shades and character, has been freely distributed throughout the United Kingdom. "The broker and jobbers who had the first 'pick' of the market, must have made con- siderable sums by their commissions; since the other brokers and jobbers, who paid more attention to the other public securities, were almost discarded by their former customers, who, in many cases, were led to believe that the * English and Foreign Stock' broker and jobber could not transact share business. Indeed, it appears to have been some time before the veil of mystery was removed, or that the public arrived at a clear under- standing of the subject. In the meanwhile the old and respectable members of the House had the mortification to see persons, who LONDON STOCK EXCHANGE 59 formerly had been of little reputation on the Exchange, and in many instances even their own clerks, carrying on an extensive and profitable business in shares; and as long as this lasted there was no end to the success of those who had the sway of the market. Gradually dealings were dispersed and spread among the whole of the fraternity, and then followed the height of speculation, engen- dered by the general operations of the chief part of the community. The shares of every new company coming out at a premium, induced rich and poor to thrust themselves into the market; and the schemes that are every day resorted to in order to gain posses- sion of letters of allotment which may bring a price, if the shares be. paid on, are of the most multifarious, and, in many instances, fraudulent description. "Such has been the increase of business in consequence of the speculation in shares that the accounts which used formerly to occupy not more than one or two days at the outside, nearly exhaust the week, before differences can be paid, transfers made, and the books of the brokers regularly adjusted. The extent of the transactions has increased beyond measure; night and day clerks are 60 THE STOCK EXCHANGE engaged in arranging sales and purchases, and conducting the correspondence which is re- quired between their masters and principals. "Innumerable instances are stated of persons, who a few months ago were not worth anything, having made their thousands of pounds, and several of these are junior members of the House, who were fortunate enough to deal in those shares which have attained high premiums. Considering the time and attention required in share business, the brokers do not get too well paid; although there may be every reason to suppose that many are obtaining immense incomes from it by the inordinate influx of commissions. This will, we think, be seen when we state that the principal [part] of the business be- ing transacted in the new scrip, upon which not more than l to 3 has been paid, they only realise the small commission of Is. 3d. per share. If they buy or sell largely of Brighton, Birmingham and Grand Junction, they get the larger commission; but these descriptions have not been dealt in to any comparable extent with the issues of the new companies. Brighton and South Eastern have undergone considerable fluctuation dur- ing the mania; but then, as the business was LONDON STOCK EXCHANGE 61 in a few hands, it cannot be supposed to have extended its beneficial influence over the whole market." S6me fortunate brokers were said to have made 3,000 and 4,000 a day by their busi- ness, but not, of course, by commissions. By lucky speculations they might easily have made much larger amounts. One fortunate individual outside the House, who held largely of Churnett Valley scrip before the announcement of the sanction of the Board of Trade to the project, "sold at the best price of the market when the announce- ment was made, and netted by his one coup 27,000." Very large sums were made and lost in London and York, and Direct Northern two of the leading "fancies" which were dealt in more for speculation than investment. The number of American and foreign lines introduced on the London Stock Exchange added to the excitement prevailing. But, compared with the madness of 1825 and 1826, there was this much to be said for the rail- way mania of 1844-5 viz. that the new lines were undertakings of vast utility and national importance, and though viewed at first with much jealousy and distrust, were already producing results which the most sanguine 6* THE STOCK EXCHANGE liad never counted on. Consequently, writes one sober critic, speculation in railway shares was encouraged not only as an investment likely to yield high rates of interest, but also for the benefit it confers on mankind at large. "The feasibility of the numerous schemes, and the elements of success they present, have, under these circumstances, raised an unanimous feeling in their favour, which, sanctioned as they have been by Government superintendence and Govern- ment interference, could not but contribute to feed the growing desire of the public to embark in them. The warnings that have been given have, therefore, not been re- garded, and the mania has gone on to an extent almost unprecedented even by the great South Sea bubble itself." The following criticism made by the same writer in 1845 was fully justified by events: "The feasibility of the greater number of the schemes brought before the public has encouraged the example of starting com- peting lines; while, in addition, foreign pro- jects of the most questionable description have come out, the shares of which have maintained high premiums for a few days, and have then sunk into utter worthlessness. LONDON STOCK EXCHANGE 03 Among all this incongruous mass there must be part that will ripen to decay; and hence, while the stability of the system itself is acknowledged, it is that stability which has fostered many of the sham companies of the present day. When the crash does come it will be terrible. The best of the securities will feel it for a time, though restoration to a proper value will, no doubt, follow when the market shall have settled down and the web of ephemeral speculation be cleared away." It is interesting to learn from the same source that the swindling and blundering which marked the flotation and management of British railways in those early days were gradually corrected by the criticisms of a few honest and competent journals. Morier Evans, the historian of the crisis of 1847-8, compared the prices of certain rail- way securities in the height of the boom (August 1845) and the depth of the depres- sion (October 1848). Thus in August 1845, Great Western rose to 236, and fell in October 1848 to 65J-, London and North-Western rose to 254 and fell to 99; Midland rose to 183 and fell to 64. Northern of France rose to 7f and fell to 5f . Scandals of all kinds surrounded the promotion of our railways. 64 THE STOCK EXCHANGE Extortionate sums were paid for worthless land. The financiers, the lawyers and all concerned had such pickings and perquisites that we can hardly understand (even after allowing for the good work of the critics) how the main English lines emerged with their finances on a basis so much sounder than similar undertakings in many other countries* Capital was collected from all parts of the country, and the transactions in railway shares were so voluminous and universal that the ordinary channels were quite inadequate. Clerks at small salaries in banks and mer-' chants' counting-houses openly proclaimed themselves buyers and sellers of the various ' favourite shares, just as if they represented. 1 their employers. Not only in London, but 1 in Manchester, Leeds, Liverpool, Glasgow,' Dublin, Hull, Edinburgh and Bristol, rail- way share markets were established, and the business of the City was for a time equalled if not surpassed by the provinces. As an anxious contemporary put it on the eve of the crisis: "The farmer is now as deep in railway shares as the merchant, the merchant as the banker; and the whole circle of society is entangled in the mania." The long list of failures that occurred in LONDON STOCK EXCHANGE 65 1847 and 1848 attests the correctness of this analysis. But with every succeeding decade the stability of our banks and merchant houses and of all our financial institutions has steadily grown with the increasing wealth and intelligence of the nation. In the pages of Bagehot and other writers we may read of a strain on credit which caused extraordinary measures to be taken by the Bank of England in 1857 as a result of the American panic, and again (for the last time) hi 1866, after the failure of Overend Gurney. The Baring Crisis of 1890 was brought about by over- confidence in the pace at which Argentina's potential wealth would be developed and ex- ploited by British capital. In the two pre- vious years over 60 millions of British capital had been lent to Argentina, but in midsummer 1890 a loan of 5 millions for the Argentine Government missed fire. A revolution and a run on the banks followed. Mr. Burn says: "The fall in South American securities was very heavy, and the situation from August to October was very delicate. There was a de- cided undercurrent of opinion that several houses, notably Baring's, had dangerously increased their acceptances." At the weekly meeting, on Thursday, Nov. 6, of the Di- 66 THE STOCK EXCHANGE rectors of the Bank of England the Bank rate was unaltered, though the reserves stood at only 11 millions; but on the following day it was unexpectedly raised to 6 per cent., and the Stock Exchange began to be alarmed. However, the settlement on the following Tuesday passed off without trouble. But on the Wednesday three banks were reported to be in difficulties. On Thursday it was learned that the Bank of France had lent 3 millions of gold to the Bank of England; on Friday a meeting was held at the Bank to consider the affairs of Messrs. Barings, and on Satur- day (Nov. 15) it was definitely announced that a scheme had been carried through to enable them to meet their liabilities. The firm's liabilities, which amounted to 21 mil- lions sterling, were liquidated in the course of four years; and the effects of this sup- pressed crisis remained for a long time. A speculative recovery was powerfully stimulated by the wonderful discoveries and skilful exploitation of the Rand mines in the Transvaal by cosmopolitan groups of finan- ciers, among whom Cecil Rhodes was the most popular figure. This Napoleon of Cape Town and Kimberley became the hero of our Stock Exchange. Skilfully blending finance and politics, he for a long time worked in LONDON STOCK EXCHANGE 67 alliance with the Dutch party at the Cape, keeping on good terms with the Boers, and simultaneously by a handsome contribution to Parnell's funds he contrived to secure Irish Nationalist assistance for the Chartered Company. Nevertheless his reputation in London was that of an empire-builder. The Press fell under his sway, and the London Stock Exchange responded enthusiastically to all the financial schemes, good, bad and indifferent, of the new South African leader and his fellow magnates. But the enormous fortunes made in the nineties under the Kruger regime did not satisfy. Those who had received much wanted more. Those who had shorn one flock of investing lambs wanted to shear another. Those who had become millionaires on a sudden objected to pay any toll whatever to the Government, and conceived the idea of turning out the Boers and of so producing another Kaffir boom which would raise their wealth beyond the utmost dreams of human avarice. In pursuance of this plan fictions of all sorts were circulated. Old President Kruger, ob- stinate and unenlightened, but a quite human mixture of shrewdness and stupidity, virtue and vice, was represented as a monster of tyranny and corruption. The strength and 88 THE STOCK EXCHANGE courage of the Boer farmers were made light of, and Rhodes even assured the British Government (then embarked on a policy of interference) that the Boers could not shoot. It may be doubtful how far the Cabinet really meant to go, and how far it drifted into an avoidable catastrophe through mere mishandling of the negotiations. But, whether deliberate or accidental, certain it is that the war proved more disastrous to the London Stock Exchange and the in- terests of the City than any event which had taken place since the failure of Overend Gurney. A military promenade, which was to have been over in a month or two, re- sulted in three years of stubborn and anxious warfare. The total cost, which was esti- mated by Sir Michael Hicks-Beach, the Chancellor of the Exchequer, in October 1899, at 10 millions, to be defrayed by a levy on the gold mines, eventually came to about 250 millions, every penny of which was con- tributed by British loans and British taxes. For a moment, at the outbreak of the war, Transvaal mining shares rose, but as soon as the idea of a promenade vanished, and a long prospect of difficult and costly operations opened out they began to droop, and fell to lower and lower depths as the war dragged LONDON STOCK EXCHANGE 69 on. Consols followed the same movement as Kaffirs. They had receded partly as a result of increasing expenditure and diminishing Sinking Fund, partly through fear of war, from a top price of 113 in 1898 to about 104 at the outbreak of hostilities. But the "Khaki" 2f per cent, loan in the spring of 1900 was raised with enthusiasm, showing that the public believed in a speedy ending of the war and a substantial indemnity from the mines. When the Milner policy of un- conditional surrender was at last abandoned, and the peace of Vereeniging signed, Consols and Kaffirs rallied. But it was only a short and feverish flicker of speculative purchases, which collapsed under heavy liquidation. The mining industry had been temporarily ruined, the cost of living had risen, the native labour had dispersed, a strange mixture of luxury, waste, misery, disease, plunder and demoralisation had dislocated the social organism and the mechanism of business. Many of the promoters and speculators who had been most eaget for the war were ruined. All the mining houses connected with the Rand suffered severely, nor did they recoup their losses by the costly experiment of importing Chinese coolies. ^ A declension of Consols by 20 per cent, was 70 THE STOCK EXCHANGE proportionate to the increase of supply; for the National Debt was enlarged by 160 mil- lions sterling in order to meet the extraordi- nary expenditure on the war. For four or five years the Sinking Fund was practically or actually suspended, and when, under the firm financial guidance of Mr. Asquith, the reduc- tion of Debt was vigorously renewed at an unparalleled rate, the decline of national credit was checked rather than arrested; for the enormous cost of the Russo-Japanese War had drained many millions of British and French capital into the new 5 and 6 per cent, bonds of these two combatants. In fact the public debts of the world, along with wars, armaments and taxation, have expanded in the first ten years of the twentieth century more rapidly than the effective demand for them. Possibly and if some limitation of armaments can be arranged, probably the decline of gilt-edged securities may now cease and a substantial recovery commence. For British Consols to yield more than 3 per cent, in time of peace and prosperous trade is cer- tainly abnormal. But then the scope of trustee securities was extended by some 300 millions in 1900 for the benefit of our colonies, and the growth of armaments in a dozen years by 30 millions sterling represents each year LONDON STOCK EXCHANGE 71 an economic waste equivalent to what our grandfathers would have considered a very formidable and costly war. The effect of the Kaffir boom in England was to create a new and very popular field for speculative investment. The House rapidly expanded, and the mining section suddenly bulged out into the Kaffir Circus, which after hours filled Throgmorton Street with wild and noisy confusion. The slump was disastrous and protracted. The losses in Chartered shares and in many of the inferior mines of the Transvaal and of Rhodesia have never been recovered, but in the last three or four years the intrinsic merits of the Rand mines, the reconciliation and union of South Africa, and a great improvement in the labour supply have contributed to restore values to the Kaffir market and animation to the Kaffir Circus. But Consols, gilt-edged securities of all kinds, home, colonial and foreign, British railways, bank and insurance shares, breweries, and many other industrial securities have all exhibited, as the direct or indirect consequence of the Boer War, falls of from 10 to 50 per cent. The loss of capital and credit caused by such a shrinkage cannot be computed; but every banker and cambist in London knows how much London's prestige 73 THE STOCK EXCHANGE and influence as the headquarters of inter-^ national money and exchange were shaken. If those who made the war had been allowed to make a tariff, the greatest emporium, the greatest shipping, broking and banking centre of the world would have been not only shaken but shattered. Grass would have grown in the port of London and in the streets of the City. Gradually the London ware- houses would have emptied, the shipping of its port would have shrunk, the value of a bill on London would have disappeared, the London money market and the London stock markets would by degrees have yielded their proud supremacy a supremacy founded upon a wise policy of political, economic, commercial and financial freedom. Instead of these disasters, thanks almost entirely to its freedom from tariffs and consequent mono- poly of wholesale markets, London has now again strengthened its position as the importer and re-exporter of metals and raw materials of all kinds. And, thanks partly to this, partly to its vast supply of free and loanable capital, it has recently acquired complete command of the expanding market in rubber. With this control of the raw product, which is now governed by the sales in Mincing Lane, the acquisition and financial management LONDON STOCK EXCHANGE 73 j of the new plantations for the growth of " tame " rubber has naturally come to Great Britain. The rubber boom in the spring of 1910 may fairly be represented as the harvest which English and Scottish financiers and brokers have reaped as a result of free markets and unimpeded trade. Another episode in the history of the Lon- don Stock Exchange the American crisis and panic of 1907 may conveniently be deferred to later chapters. It remains to say a few words as to the rules of the London Stock Exchange, and its methods of doing business. The feature which distinguishes it from provincial, colonial and foreign Exchanges is the division of functions between brokers and jobbers, a division which seems to go back to its foundation. The job- j ber works on the floor of the House, and deals only with the broker. The broker takes orders from the outside public and buys from or sells to the jobber. Thus the broker feeds the jobber much as the solicitor feeds the barrister. The broker takes his commission and the jobber his turn. The working of the system is very simple, and may be illustrated by a simple example. Jones, an investor, sees that Consols stand at about 79. He determines to buy 1,000 nominal, i. e. to 74 THE STOCK EXCHANGE spend 790. So he tells his broker Smith to buy him that amount at the best price obtain- able. Smith goes from his broker's office into the House and makes his way to the group of jobbers who deal in the Consol mar- ket. He finds Robinson and asks him the price of Consols. Robinson replies 7Sf-79, meaning that he will buy at 78| and sell at 79. Smith buys from him at 79, and the bargain is complete. Smith sends a contract note to Jones which runs as follows: 1000 Consols at 79 .... 790 Contract Stamp 2s. Commission J l 5 Jones sends a cheque for 791 7s., which 1 expressly includes the broker's commission, and also in reality includes the jobber's remuneration. This system, with its division of functions, is very good for active securities in which there are numerous transactions. In such cases the separate existence of jobbers makes for a free market and close prices. There is no place in the world where good j stocks are more easily and quickly realisable ; at a minimum of loss, or purchasable so near the market price, as on the London Stock Exchange. For this and other reasons it re- ceives a vast amount of American and foreign LONDON STOCK EXCHANGE 75 orders, and its official list is the largest and the most international in the world. But the investor should note that a quotation in the official list does not mean, in the case of securities seldom dealt in, that your broker can at any time get a jobber to deal in the stock at the nominal or quoted price. And when there is a slump in a market and a rush of selling orders with no support, as happened in rubber shares in the months of June and July 1910, the jobbers are apt to be away at lunch all day, and the brokers have to report to their clients that they simply cannot find a purchaser. It should be added that London Stock Ex- change brokers are not allowed to advertise. They- may only send circulars to their own clients. The first business, therefore, of an English investor is to find a good broker. He will then be protected in all his transac- tions by the rules and regulations of the London Stock Exchange. Or if he lives in | a large provincial town with a Stock Exchange j of its own, he may prefer to do business with one of its members a local broker. In that case he will probably be just as well served. I What he must avoid like the plague is the outsider who offers to sell him rubbish shares charging no commission. CHAPTER III LONDON'S FOREIGN MARKET AND THE FOREIGN BOURSES A SPECIAL chapter will be dedicated to "Wall Street and the American market; for they stand in magnificent isolation from the rest of the world, always excepting Canada and Mexico. No doubt, as the population grows and the pioneering or buccaneering instinct finds itself cramped by the want of new territories at home to explore or exploit, the interest of American finance in foreign affairs tends to expand. At present this ex- pansion is felt mainly in two directions east- wards towards China and Japan, southwards through Mexico to Panama and the Spanish republics. But such is the banking and economic supremacy of England that a citizen of the United States finds it most convenient to visit Argentina or Brazil via London, and many of the products of South America are shipped to London before they reach their 76 LONDON'S FOREIGN MARKET 77 ultimate destination in New York or Boston or Philadelphia. It is the same with Ex- change transactions. The bill on London still reigns supreme. Besides, the United States is still a borrower rather than a lender, which, in itself, explains why there is practically no foreign market on the New York Stock Exchange. British consols, German and Russian bonds, French rentes are unquoted because they are not wanted. Even the New York railway market is purely American with the exception of lines like the Canadian Pacific or the Mexican Group, which connect with the American system. Thus London's financial relations with the world in general are distinguished from its relations with America, and this distinction is accurately reflected by the London Stock Exchange. The groups of jobbers who deal in foreign bonds and foreign railways stand quite apart from the American crowd. The causes that have attracted foreign merchants and speculators to London from the time of the Romans, well deserve detailed examination. The economic historian might show how admirably the estuary of the Thames was adapted for commerce with all the northern ports of Europe, and how, after 78 THE STOCK EXCHANGE the discovery of America, the capital of Eng- land was almost bound to be the centre of the commercial world. Our insular security and our rich resources of coal and iron enabled us to take full advantage of the inventions which revolutionised manufactures, trans- port, and exchange between 1750 and 1850. British shipping and British manufactures, though small in comparison with modern ideas, were large in comparison with their rivals. In capital, credit, currency, and the art of banking, London got the start and kept it. Necessitous foreign Governments and corporations began to look to London houses, like those of Rothschild and Baring, to supply their small, but growing, demands for capital. Sixty years ago, indeed, Paris was still a formidable rival in finance, and the United States in shipping. But just at this critical moment England adopted the policy of a free market for gold and all commodities. A sound currency and an almost perfect bank- ing system were firmly established at the same time that perfect freedom of import- ing and exporting was given to the whole nation. In the course of ' a few years all protective duties, and all duties upon exports such as coal and machinery were entirely LONDON'S FOREIGN MARKET 79 removed. Our trade advanced by leaps and bounds. British shipping expanded at such a rate that before the end of the century it actually represented, and still represents, roughly, half the world's mercantile marine. The United States, after the Civil War, adopted an exactly opposite policy of re- striction. Prices were artificially raised. The high tariff wall, which was erected to ex- clude foreign competition, raised the cost of production. American manufacturers were unable to compete in neutral markets, and the American mercantile marine, which had threatened to rival and outdistance ours, dwindled into insignificance. Meanwhile, on the Continent, Germany forged ahead under' the stimulus of the Zollverein, which swept away all the petty tariffs that had isolated and impoverished its kingdoms and duchies. A fairly liberal policy, aided by the adoption of a gold standard, allowed German com- merce to grow rapidly, and London benefited enormously by the increasing wealth of Hamburg and Berlin. France clung to the bimetallic system, which prevented her great stores of gold and capital from playing their full part in international operations. In Bagehot's Lombard Street the retro- 80 THE STOCK EXCHANGE spective eye may see how London had be- come, in the seventies, the great centre for the investment of capital and for the diffusion of credit. With the suspension of specie pay- ments by the Bank of France during the Franco-German War, its use as a reservoir of specie came to an end. "No one can draw a cheque on it and be sure of getting gold or silver for that cheque. Accordingly, the whole liability for such international payments in cash is thrown on the Bank of England." Eight years after Bagehot wrote these words in 1878 the Bank of France resumed specie payments. But it could not recover its position as a European settling house. And, as every banker and cambist knows, the stock of gold at Paris and Berlin is not acces- sible, because the Bank of France can exercise an option to pay in silver at the old conven- tional ratio, and the Bank of Germany can practically prevent gold payments when they appear inconvenient. Thus, by a concur- rence of natural and fortuitous circumstances with the restrictive and artificial regulations imposed by potential rivals, the number of international bills drawn on London incal- culably surpasses those drawn upon other centres. It is the greatest shop, the greatest LONDON'S FOREIGN MAEKET 81 store, the freest market for commodities, gold and securities, the greatest disposer of capital, the greatest dispenser of credit, but above and beyond, as well as by reason of all these marks of financial and commercial supremacy, it is the world's clearing house. The wealth which it thus acquires and dis- poses is vaster far than in the days of Bagehot, when the London Money Market was usually dependent on the Bank of England. Now, in normal times, it can finance itself. In Bage- hot's time the output of capital issues or loans to British, foreign, and colonial borrowers would vary from twenty to thirty millions a year. In 1910 the figure went far above 200 millions. A single illustration may be given of London's banking power. In 1908, after the great American panic, the United States Government appointed a Commission to suggest monetary and bank- ing reforms. The Commissioners came over to Europe and made close inquiries. Their interviews with leading bankers in London, Paris and Berlin, which have lately been published, constitute an invaluable accumu- lation of ascertained facts and authoritative opinions. At the Bank of England they learned how, in times of stress, its rate 82 THE STOCK EXCHANGE dominates and controls all the money markets and gold-movements of the world. The crisis which broke out in New York, in October 1907, was the most formidable of its kind ever known. There had never been such an enormous demand for gold; yet the drain was successfully met, and practically all that the American banks required was supplied in a few weeks from London without any dangerous depletion of the Bank's reserve. On October 31st the total bullion held by the Bank was 31 millions, and the Bank rate was raised to 5| per cent. On November 4th it was raised to 6 per cent., and on November 7th to 7 per cent., the total bullion held being 28 millions. This rate proved effective and from that time the inflow of gold from abroad exceeded the outflow to New York, so that on December llth the total bullion was 34 millions. Gold came to London from twenty-four countries, including British colonies; and by the end of January, when the rate had been gradually reduced to 4 per cent., the Bank of England's stock of gold had risen to 38 millions sterling. With this supremacy as bullion broker and arbiter of credit, as disposer of cash for short periods and lender of capital to foreign LONDON'S FOREIGN MARKET 83 I and colonial borrowers, it is no wonder that London through its Stock Exchange should provide the world's principal market in foreign securities. Paris, of course, has its specialities. It is financier-in-chief to Russia, Spain, and Turkey. But the London Stock Exchange list of foreign securities has no rival. Hardly a country, from the gilt-edged rentes of France to the comparatively worthless paper of Honduras, whose stocks are not dealt in freely from day to day by the lead- ing jobbers of our foreign market. Their observation, "with extensive view, surveys mankind from China to Peru.'' The taste of the British public for invest- ment abroad has grown rapidly with the increasing overflow of our surplus capital. Perhaps we are a little too much inclined to trust the foreigner. Certainly there is often a want of discrimination. A bond yielding 4| or 5 per cent., with a fairly strong power like Japan or a prosperous country like Argentina, or a promising railway behind it, may be pretty safe; but for the sake of an extra 1 per cent, a certain type of investor is willing to run a serious risk of losing his capital in some dishonest municipality, or discredited government, or in a company 84 THE STOCK EXCHANGE formed abroad for the very purpose of de- frauding him. Many persons who read these pages may probably have received ingenious circulars suggesting that risks can be avoided by a geographical distribution of capital, and that in this way a high yield can be secured without danger. It is at first sight a taking fallacy. But a single question will discover and expose it. How can four rotten com- panies, located, let us say, in Brazil, Costa Rica, Portugal and Russia be made less rotten by the fact that they are widely separated? Our markets for foreign bonds and foreign railway securities stand, of necessity, in close connection with the foreign bourses on which the same or allied securities are quoted. In some cases, where the credit of a country rests almost entirely on its credit in London, the tone of the London market will dominate the tone of the domestic bourses. The dis- tribution of British capital is a subject which more properly belongs to a later chapter. But it should here be plainly stated that our foreign trade and the supremacy of the Lon- don Stock Exchange in international stocks depend mainly upon our exports of capital. Thus London holds a great part of the ex- ternal debt of Japan, and the price of Japa- LONDON'S FOREIGN MARKET 85 nese bonds depends, therefore, mainly upon London's judgment of Japan's financial strength at any given time. The internal bonds are mainly held in Japan, yield a higher rate of interest, and stand on a more independent footing. Again, the great Ar- gentine railways are British companies, with their head offices in London, so that London is the principal, if not the sole market, for their bonds and shares. The external debt of the Argentine Government is also held mainly in London, where, in fact, the greater part of it has been issued at various times by Barings and other London houses. British investments in Argentina Govern- ment debt, railways, land companies, ranches, etc. run to several hundred millions sterling. Smaller, but still important, are our holdings in Brazil, Chili, Peru, and Mexico. The London house of Rothschild is the agent and guardian of Brazilian finance, a delicate and difficult task. The instability of the Latin republics of South America is pro- verbial. Upon the whole, the Governments of Argentina and Chili enjoy the best credit, but the security of a good Argentine or Bra- zilian railroad is often preferred to that of the Government, and is certainly superior 86 THE STOCK EXCHANGE to the credit of municipal or provincial securities, among which there have been many defaulters. It is hardly possible to speak of "investment" in Central America. At present, any one who buys the paper of those States is a mere speculator. Bank- ruptcy and repudiation are the rule, payment of interest the exception. Even in South America, a public authority which has not within the last thirty years repudiated its debt or compounded with its creditors is a rare exception. No doubt, as civilisation advances and trade expands, South America gradually becomes a safer and safer field for the investment of savings. But the utmost care should be exercised, especially when seductive offers of (unmarketable) bonds are received through the post. It is essential that the security should be quoted on the London Stock Exchange, but even then the price quoted may be an old one at which it is easy to buy, but impossible to sell. The amateur investor should make a selection, and then consult a good broker on the London Stock Exchange as to present prices and prospects. After the Stock Exchange of London, that of Paris stands next as an international LONDON'S FOREIGN MARKET 87 ! factor, because, after London, Paris has the greatest amount of disposable capital both in the short and the long loan market. The annual overflow of British savings into foreign and colonial investments may now perhaps reach 200 millions sterling; the average overflow of French savings is perhaps a quarter of that sum. For their size, Hol- land and Belgium contribute freely, but Ger- many requires most of her savings for home investment, and the United States still con- sumes more new capital than it produces. The French divide their bourses into two kinds commercial exchanges (bourses de com- merce) and stock exchanges (bourses des valeurs) . Their history goes back to mediaeval times, but the clearly marked division be- tween the two is comparatively modern. The merchandise brokers, who operate on the com- mercial exchanges, are called courtiers en marchandises. The operators on stock ex- changes are called agents de change. Under the old regime both professions were mono- polised, and both were thrown open after the Revolution. The merchandise brokers are still free, but after various changes the French stock-broker is now again a privileged person with exclusive rights, not only to trade in government and other officially 88 THE STOCK EXCHANGE quoted securities, but also to negotiate bills of exchange and similar instruments of credit. The stock-brokers of Paris number only seventy, and form a close corporation under Government control. The provincial bourses, of which Lyons, Bourdeaux, Marseilles, Lille, and Nantes are the most important, are very similarly organised. According to M. Vidal, the author of a brilliant study on this subject, the mono- poly of stock-brokers and the privileges of the Paris Bourse rest upon legislation of 1807 and 1816. A stock-broker really owns an office under Government, which holds from him a bond for 125,000 francs, on which be receives 4 per cent. When he withdraws from business he has a right to sell his office ard transfer the bond to a successor whom he introduces to the Government. Year by year this monopoly of the stock-broker increases in value as business and commissions multiply. But the Government occasionally modifies conditions, as in 1898, when it increased the number of Paris stock-brokers from 60 to 70. At first, the Paris Bourse was forbidden to quote foreign securities, but this prohibition was removed in 1823. But many securi- ties are not quoted in the official list of the Paris Bourse, either because the stock-brokers LONDON'S FOREIGN MARKET 89 (possibly under Government inspiration) have not chosen to admit them, or because they do not fulfil statutory conditions. Such securi- ties, however, may be, and often are, dealt hi on the coulisse, which may be described as the curb market, so called because in former times the bankers and coulissiers thronged a narrow passage called La Coulisse. Anybody may become a coulissier, or outside broker, who likes to pay the licence duty. And while dealings in French rentes are by law restricted to the stock-brokers who deal on the parquet, a market in these exists and is tolerated on the coulisse, though the trans- actions of coulissiers in these securities are not recognised by courts of law. Among foreign bourses, from this interna- tional standpoint of the foreign market, Paris stands easily first in power and resources. The capital exports of France have long been on a substantial scale, and consequently its holdings of foreign securities are very large. It is, of course, the great market for Russian bonds; it holds most of the Spanish, Portu- guese, and Turkish debt, and has considerable amounts of capital invested in Egypt, Tunis, Roumania, Greece, and South America. Ac- cording to a skilful but perhaps exaggerated 90 THE STOCK EXCHANGE valuation of M. Alfred Neymarck, the foreign securities now held by French capitalists (Government bonds included) exceed 32 bil- lion francs, say 1,300,000,000, distributed in round figures as follows: Foreign French Investments Francs, by Countries. 1 Russia .... 9,500,000,000 2 Spain and Portugal . . 3,500,000,000 3 Egypt and Suez Canal . 3,500,000,000 4 Roumania and Greece . 3,500,000,000 5 Argentine, Brazil and Mexico . . . 2,750,000,000 6 Tunis and French Colonies 2,500,000,000 7 Austria and Hungary . 2,000,000,000 8 Italy .... 1,150,000,000 9 China and Japan . . 1,000,000,000 10 United States and Canada 750,000,000 11 Great Britain . . . 500,000,000 12 Belgium and Holland . 500,000,000 13 Germany . . . 500,000,000 14 Turkey, Servia and Bulgaria . . . 500,000,000 15 Switzerland 500,000,000 Total . . . 32,650,000,000 At the end of 1910 M. Neymarck raised his aggregate to 35 billion francs. If, then, we LONDON'S FOREIGN MARKET 91 take Mr. Paish's not ungenerous estimate of 3,500,000,000 as the round figure total of British investments abroad the French aggre- gate is considerably more than one-third of the British. It is roughly equal to the French national and municipal debt; for there are 26 billion francs of 3 per cent, rentes, and 6 or 7 millions of municipal and other lottery bonds, nearly all held by French investors. M. Neymarck further estimates that in normal years the French people put aside in savings about 70,000,000, of which a variable fraction goes abroad. This seems small compared with British capital invest- ments (amounting this year to 250 millions sterling), which, of course, only represent a portion of our national savings; but it is a very large sum compared with other countries. Germany's wealth is probably in- creasing more rapidly than that of France, but its annual surplus is usually absorbed by the requirements of the Imperial and State Governments and of the municipalities, whose debts have been increasing at a prodigious rate, as well as by the demands of a trade which is largely carried on on credit. Hence it is that the great Stock Exchanges of Ger- many Berlin, Hamburg and Frankfurt are 92 THE STOCK EXCHANGE almost entirely concerned with imperial, state and municipal loans, with German bank- shares and German "industrials." But as the banks and industrial companies have branches in many foreign countries the whole world swarms with German commercial travellers a very large amount of German capital must be employed abroad, more especially in Russia, Scandinavia, Italy, the Low Coun- tries and South America. The total German capital employed abroad has been variously estimated at from 500 to 1,000 millions ster- ling. But there are no accurate figures. Ber- lin operators often speculate heavily in London. The Berlin Bourse consists of two departments, the Stock Exchange and the Produce Exchange, and both are supervised by the Chamber of Commerce. The Stock Exchange had 1,329 members in 1909; but over 3,000 other persons held cards of admis- sion entitling them to go on the floor of the Stock and Produce Exchanges. In 1899 the Berlin Stock Exchange had 1,625 members. The figures for 1909 were the lowest since 1898. The Berlin Stock Exchange List is a four-page sheet, and it includes in its official quotations a large number of continental state loans, foreign railways, banks, etc. The LONDON'S FOREIGN MARKET 93 Stock Exchanges of Frankfurt and Hamburg are also of more than national importance. Big German loans are usually issued simul- taneously by a "consortium" of banking houses in all the chief cities of the federated empire. The Dutch people are very active specu- lators, particularly in oil companies and in inferior sorts of American railroad securities. The Amsterdam Bourse is in close communi- cation with the London Stock Exchange. The Brussels Bourse looks to both Paris and London. Its speciality lies in tramway com- panies, of which it was the pioneer. It has established tramway systems with valuable concessions, or "street franchises," in all parts of the world. At Antwerp a great and growing port and emporium speculation is busy with raw products such as wool, rubber, and coffee. The free port of Hamburg is another huge emporium, and its trade breeds lively speculation in sugar, coffee, etc. But its Stock Exchange and money market play an important part, and a crisis in Hamburg is speedily visited upon Copenhagen, Stock- holm, Helsingfors, and the old Hanseatic towns; for Hamburg is the chief employer of trading capital in the North Sea and the 94 THE STOCK EXCHANGE Baltic. Thus when Hamburg found it neces- sary to contract credit and draw in loans after the American collapse of 1907, there followed a crop of banking failures in Copen- hagen, as well as troubles in Stockholm. Russian trade is largely in the hands of Germany, and German is as much spoken as Russian in the bourse of St. Petersburg. Thanks to its high tariff, the manufactures, commerce, and navigation of Russia are con- trolled by monopolies and combinations, which have capitalised the tariff in much the same way as the more celebrated "Trusts" of the United States. The largest of these, "Prodameta" (from "prodet," to sell, and metal), has with its subsidiaries a capital of 18,000,000. There are similar combinations in coal, petroleum, and navigation. But the Russian public has too little cash and too* little enterprise to drive a great business in stocks and shares. Here, as else- where, the Russian Government's repressive policy makes itself felt. The "Birsha" of St. Petersburg is prohibited from dealing in non-Russian securities, and even the Russian banks are debarred from advancing money on foreign securities. Jews and foreigners are also prohibited from lending money on mort- LONDON'S FOREIGN MARKET 95 gage, with the result that first mortgages in Russia have to be placed at 8 or 9 per cent, interest. The St. Petersburg Bourse is much smaller than the Stock Exchanges of Glasgow, Man- chester, or Liverpool, in so far as it has only 56 authorised brokers, who must be Russian subjects, and have a monopoly of dealings in Russian Government bonds. But any person introduced by a broker or banker may do business in the Birsha on payment of a half-yearly subscription, and a stranger may even be introduced for the day for a fee of one rouble. There is, therefore, a strange mixture of free trade and monopoly. The official list of the St. Petersburg Bourse con- tains about 500 securities, all Russian, the chief activity being in the shares of railways and banks. There is no business for the account, and there are no regular settlements. All stock sold must be paid for within one or, at most, two days. The two principal bourses of Spain are in Madrid and Barcelona, and of late years Madrid has become the more important. But Spanish banking and finance are very largely French; for Paris still controls the principal railroads and banks of Spain. But Spanish capital is growing, and the people 96 THE STOCK EXCHANGE are beginning to own a large and ever larger share of the public debt. British capital is mainly interested in mining and commercial enterprise, especially at Bilbao, Barcelona, Seville, and Juarez. Spain presents a close parallel with Italy. Few things are more remarkable in the last dozen years of Euro- pean finance than the great upward move- ment of Spanish and Italian credit. In both cases the improvement may be traced to the abandonment of colonial aspirations. The costly wars of Italy in Somaliland and Abys- sinia, and of Spain in Cuba and the Philip- pines, drained both exchequers. The currency depreciated and the national credit fell very low. In fact, in 1898 the mean price of Italian Fives was 9 If , and of Spanish Fours 46J. Taking the years 1898 and 1907, and comparing the movements of European credit, we find a fall of 19 in British consols, of 6 in French Threes, and of 11 in German Threes, while Italian Fives rose 8, and Span- ish Fours no less than 42 points. Unfortunately, ten years of progress have been checked, in the case of Spain, by the Morocco War and the growth of internal troubles, in the case of Italy by an expensive military and naval rivalry with Austria. LONDON'S FOREIGN MARKET 97 Nevertheless the finances of Spain and Italy have made an extraordinary advance all the more extraordinary by contrast with the general downward movement in gilt-edged stocks as well as in the best railway deben- tures during the last ten or twelve years. The Italians have bought up their debt (chiefly held in France) with amazing rapid- ity, and are hi a fan- way to revive their mediaeval prowess in international finance. The chief bourses of Italy are in Rome, Turin, Genoa, and Milan. An economic and Stock Exchange crisis occurred in 1899-1900, and again in 1907-8. Between those dates Stock Exchange values expanded, and the period of prosperity terminated in a great outburst of speculation. The boom began in January 1905, and culminated for a time in September. Then came a set back, but another rapid ex- pansion followed, which terminated in March 1906. The most popular mania was for motor car company shares. The 25 lire shares of one company (the Fiat) were actually bought up to 2,300 lire 92 times the nominal price of issue. The company then subdivided its shares. In November 1906 the new 10 lire shares stood at 750. By October 1907 they had fallen to 80 lire, and by May 1908 to 34 98 THE STOCK EXCHANGE lire. Turin was the principal market, and the speculative mania produced even more ridiculous excesses than the rubber share mania in England. What remained of the bubble was pricked in the autumn of 1907, by a sudden cessation of purchasing from the United States, when luxurious expenditure of all kinds was curtailed after the fall of the Knickerbocker Trust. The Stock Exchange securities of Italy consist, first, of the na- tional debt, including the nationalised rail- ways, second banks, third mines, fourth lighting companies, and, lastly, industrial companies of all kinds, representing a more or less watery capitalisation of the protec- tive tariff. More interesting to British investors than either Spain or Italy are the two great rival powers of the Far East, Japan and China. The rise of Japan, by a rapid adoption of Western methods, to the position of a strong military and naval power (culminating in its defeat first of China, and then of Russia) has, of course, been coincident with the crea- tion of a very heavy debt and a deplorably heavy system of taxation. As Russia leaned upon Paris, so for their war with Russia the Japanese turned to London, where they con- LONDON'S FOREIGN MARKET 99 traded very large loans mostly at 5 per cent. Since the conclusion of peace they have suc- ceeded in keeping their expenditure within their income, and by very skilful finance have converted most of their debt to a 4J per cent, basis. The same speculative fever and spirit of commercial expansion, which pervaded Europe and America in 1906 and 1907, invaded Japan. The Stock Exchanges of Tokio and other large towns were scenes of great excitement, and when the American crash came, no country was more utterly prostrated than Japan, dependent as it is upon the United States market for its silk and other exports. A great many failures ensued. Banks closed their doors, and some German houses, which had introduced a sys- tem of long credits, came to grief. Attempts to introduce British capital into Japanese industrials have not been very successful, though some of the best Japanese bank shares have found favour. But a very large amount of Japanese debt is held in London, and the Japanese Government keeps ample floating balances on this side, knowing well how to support the market. In quite recent years, with the suspension of borrowing by the Japanese Government, 100 THE STOCK EXCHANGE the attention of English investors in the Far East has been directed mainly towards China, India, and the Malay States. The awakening of China has been very slow, but the pace has been marvellously quickened in the last decade. The sagacity and trustworthiness of the Chinese merchant, and the marvellous industry of a vast population, are the best securities of those who invest in the new railways. Against the honesty of the nation have to be placed the incapacity and corrup- tion of the Government. There is grave danger that funds subscribed to the Govern- ment for railway loans may be misused or devoted to other purposes. But, after all, few countries can boast that they have been free from railway scandals, and there are grounds for thinking that great political reforms may ere long renovate the whole machinery of Chinese administration. The railways already built appear to be profitable, and now that a start has been made, it seems certain that this extraordinarily promising field will absorb and find profitable employ- ment for a vast amount of British capital. There is no reason why, eventually, Chinese engineers should not become as competent as Chinese bankers and merchants; but LONDON'S FOREIGN MARKET 101 until the mysterious rlddb of China lias been a little further unravelled, the investor in Chinese loans must regard himself as some- thing of a speculator who deserves a rather high interest in return for his risk. The Chinaman is not only a shrewd and com- petent business man: he is also a confirmed and incurable gambler. From time to time the Shanghai Stock Exchange becomes a scene of the wildest speculation, and it is safe to predict that, when a new China is evolved, Stock Exchanges will spring up in all the large towns, and China will become subject to vicissitudes and crises as violent as those which convulse the United States. Of this, a foretaste was afforded in the spring and summer of 1910, when Shanghai caught the rubber infection from London. All classes and races took part, but the native Chinaman plunged deepest. When the break in prices came, one Chinese operator was so heavily involved that, on his failure, many of the native banks had to suspend payment, with the result that for months the trade and credit of this great shipping and business centre were disorganised. CHAPTER IV WALL STREET A FAR-SIGHTED and experienced operator, who lately retired from the New York Stock Exchange, has encouraged me to attempt a brief sketch of the American system (centred in New York) from the standpoint both of an investor and of a speculator. On the other side of the Atlantic, indeed, an adventurous element enters almost invariably into almost every investment, and Wall Street is the synonym for speculation. The Marble Stock Exchange of New York stands in Broad Street* But the great banks are in Wall Street. Wall Street is the nerve-centre of the richest and most speculative country in the world. It stands in the popular mind for all that is sinister in American politics, all that is reprehensible in American business, all that is vast and hazardous, all that is covetous and unscrupulous in high or low finance. It is a term that covers a multitude of things and 102 WALL STREET 103 provokes a multitude of thoughts in every true American. For Wall Street is the ac- cepted mirror and barometer of all American business. There, as in a magnified Monte Carlo, fortunes are won and lost, if not by the hour or the day, at least by the week or the month. There, too, the great trusts are organised; there receiverships and profitable reconstructions are arranged; there sensa- tional dividends and other surprises are hatched, by the insiders for the outsiders; there melons are cut; there all things and most persons are "done" in a strictly financial sense. (But the secret of Wall Street's su- premacy lies in the power of its banks as manufactories and curtailers of credit?) Hence it is not merely a market of bonds and shares, not merely a recorder but a manipulator and controller of prices. One thing about Wall Street that strikes the most casual visitor is its purely American character. It takes no interest whatever in European securities. It only cares for Europe because Europe cares for America by taking an interest in American securities. Just as our Wall Brook marks the line of the old Roman wall of Londinium, so Wall Street marks the old Dutch wall of the little 104 THE STOCK EXCHANGE Dutch Colony of New Amsterdam; but its financial story goes back hardly more than a century. In 1790, the year after the adoption of the Constitution, Hamilton reported to Congress the plan of a national bank. In 1791, despite opposition from Madison, Jef- ferson and other powerful men (who held a central bank to be unconstitutional, because the individual States had not delegated bank- ing authority to Congress), the bill was passed and signed by Washington. The Bank, which was located in Wall Street, was mod- elled on the Bank of England. Its charter, limited to twenty years, expired in 1811, and was not renewed. The dissolution of the iBank not only deprived the country of a large foreign capital, which could ill be spared, but was one of the causes that led in 1814 to the suspension of specie payments in most of the States of New England. The second Bank of the United States, which lasted from 1816 to 1832, was established in Philadelphia. But the financial prerogative of New York may fairly be dated from the year 1791, when it became for a time the depository of the funds of the United States Government and the seat of its financial operations. Faint echoes of Wall Street's early days WALL STREET 105 were still heard in 1880. In a gossipy chronicle of that year we read: "The names of the old merchants who went down to the sea in ships, and of the money-changers and high treasurers who, in those days, were wont to come into the Street to draw from or deposit in the United States Bank, the Man- hattan Company, or the Bank of New York, to inquire for the quotations, or to exchange views on the state of the market, are almost forgotten. But, moving about among these phantom groups, we recognise the stateliest figure of all, that of Alexander Hamilton. Then we see new banks set up and operations slowly widening through the terms of five Presidents. But it is only within the past forty-five years that Wall Street has got a special significance as the centre, not only of money but of speculation. From 1835 to 1880 a series of great inflations and corre- spondent depressions occurring there furnish a most protracted, singular and striking chapter in the annals of finance." We may now add that the thirty years which have passed since 1880 have been at least as strik- ing and remarkable. The early history of public finance in the United States was sadly marred by dis- 106 THE STOCK EXCHANGE honesty, and this dishonesty may probably be traced to the bad traditions of currency that came from the colonial days. The de- basement of a paper currency was a favourite device for reducing foreign debts, and new issues of paper were often made when a colony was in need of money. These ruinous expedients not only debased public credit and public money, they also undermined confi- dence and lowered the character of banking and mercantile transactions. The establish- ment of the Federal Union and of the United States Bank led to an improvement; but from time to time suspension of payments oc- curred, individual states repudiated their debts, and vicious currency legislation caused widespread loss, distrust and confusion, by which insiders with knowledge grew rich at the expense of the community. Possibly, indeed probably, the speculative temper of the American people is derived from the ups and downs of its currency; certainly many of the worst financial crises may be traced di- rectly or indirectly to unsound money and the insecure basis of credit. But, besides this, the rarefied air of New York acts like champagne upon a nervous and excitable population. The association known as the New York WALL STREET 107 Stock Exchange was formed at the beginning of the nineteenth century by a baker's dozen of stock-dealers, who met under a sycamore tree in Wall Street, opposite to the present banking house of Brown Brothers & Co., and would job off small lots of "governments," or stock in the Manhattan Company and Bank of New York. In 1816 there was a permanent organisation of 28 members, and in 1837 when Rothschild's agents in New York, the big firm of Josephs, fell with a crash the New York Stock Exchange had become a power and a danger to a community which was rapidly developing a thirst for stock and share speculation. But in the year 1862 there sprang up a formidable competitor called at first the Public Board and later the Open Board of Brokers. This was the time of the Civil War. The printing presses of the North were issuing greenbacks by the million. Ruined merchants turned in despair to speculation, and flocked to the "coal hole," as the subterranean department in William Street was called, where the first sessions of this Public Board were held. According to a contemporary who witnessed these scenes, "lawyers whose tastes were speculative rather than litigious, more than one clergyman 108 THE STOCK EXCHANGE whose pastoral labours were unremunera- tive, broken-down operators, merchants out of business, clerks out of situations, Jews 'native and to the manner born/ as well as the greenest and most unsophisticated parties from the rural districts, swelled the motley throng." The ups and downs of the war, dis- torted by telegraphic manipulations, helped the brokers and commission agents and money-changers; for rapid fluctuations in greenbacks and stocks of all kinds held together an active crowd of speculators. A sharp competition arose between the Old Board and the New. The New offered to do business at ^ brokerage, i. e. 3 dollars and 12 cents on a hundred shares. The Old Board thereupon lowered its commission rates from J per cent, to | per cent., and resolved to expel any member who dealt with the rival body. Meanwhile the Wall Street soil produced of a sudden a wondrous mushroom growth of bankers and brokers. "The basements of William, Wall and Broad Streets and of Ex- change Place seemed to have been suddenly penetrated with innumerable burrows in- habited by new and singular animals mostly rodents gnawing at the vast cheese of spec- ulation." Promoters offered the usual wild- WALL STREET 109 cat schemes that appear and are subscribed for in such times gold claims in Colorado, copper franchises in Wisconsin, and so on. In such cases distance often lent enchantment to the view. Fluctuations of the currency during the war made all transactions hazard- ous. When greenbacks were issued it was hoped that they would circulate at par with the gold dollar. But early in 1862 a premium on gold appeared, and in July 1864 the pre- mium touched 285, and the cash value of the paper dollar fell to its lowest point 36 cents. A gold exchange was opened in New York called the Gold Room, which at one time had between four and five hundred members. There was often wild speculation made in gold futures, and on one celebrated Black Friday (September 24, 1869) Jay Gould and others made a corner in gold which caused heavy losses to many unfor- tunate merchants. Meanwhile the Open Board of Brokers flourished exceedingly, and in 1864 moved to a hall in 16 Broad Street. But after the war, when amalgamations came into favour, the two Boards and another Board for the buying and selling of Government bonds were united under the title of the New York Stock and 110 THE STOCK EXCHANGE Exchange Board, the same whose marble palace now fronts on Broad Street. In this splendid hall business is conducted in strict accordance with an elaborate constitution and by-laws. Membership is restricted, a seat can be bought only at a very high price. Infringements of rules are severely punished by fine, suspension, or expulsion. It differs from the London Stock Exchange in various ways. First, there is no distinction between jobbers and brokers. All members are both or either. Hence there is only one transac- tion no middleman stands between the public and the market. This first distinction the New York Stock Exchange has in common with all the Stock Exchanges of the Old and the New World, so far as we are aware. The jobber is a Lon- don creation, and he has not been imitated. Whether it is due to him or to some other cause, such as the banking supremacy of London, that the stock and share market of London is the freest market of its kind in the world is a question in dispute, and one that cannot easily be answered. The New York Exchange also differs from ours in the rigidity of its commission law. A New York broker charges one-eighth commission per cent, on WALL STREET 111 the par value, each way, neither more nor less. This is very profitable work. In Lon- don of course by arrangement, especially when the business is on a large scale, lower rates can be obtained without offending against the laws and rules of the Stock Ex- change. As a centre of speculative activity New York has no rival. The publicity of its quotations is only matched by the rapidity with which they are circulated to the most distant towns of the American continent. This is all due to the tape machine, called "the Ticker," an American invention which has been developed in an extraordinary way during the last thirty years. The reliability of tape prices is remarkable, and any mistake is speedily corrected. The tape machine is not officially recognised. Nevertheless its mechanical efficiency has been proved, and it contributes an invaluable check upon dis- honest brokers. Tape machines are to be found all over the States; you see them in secluded health resorts, where an enterpris- ing New York broker may have taken a room in order to cater for the adventurous instincts of the tired millionaire. The same contri- vance enables far away newspapers to give their readers a complete list of New York THE STOCK EXCHANGE prices on the following morning. But for these machines and their extension the volume of speculation would without doubt be reduced enormously. It is difficult to see, now that the tape machine and the telephone have been perfected, how the invention of aids and facilities to speculation can go much further. By these means the actual prices of securities and the alluring bait of incessantly , fluctuating favourites are kept before a naturally speculative public all the time* With a tape machine by his side the banker, the merchant, the manufacturer can sip the sweet excitements of the Stock Exchange in his arm-chair. To watch the tape machine is the main business of some and the main pleasure of others. Certainly this invention is the grand cause of the expansion of specu- lative business. If it could be extinguished the Stock Exchange would probably be de- nuded of half its members and the Other half would find their profits heavily reduced. The whole American public has been edu- cated to the "ticker." Its services to the in- vestor must be set against the stimulus it has given to gambling on the Stock Exchange. But when all deductions have been made and of course an active market means a free WALL STREET US market and closer quotations it can hardly be admitted among the inventions that have made the world more civilised. The fortnightly settlements of London would be impossible in New York, though it is almost incredible to an English broker that the day's transactions can be settled, as New York settles them, by the day. On one record occasion the Clearing-house settled and balanced transactions in about 3,200,000 shares, of an approximate value of 50 millions sterling. This test proved con- clusively the perfection of New York's finan- cial machinery for settling Stock Exchange transactions. Brokers obtain their funds through two species of loans, called respec- tively "Time" loans and "Call" loans. Tune loans are made for a specified date. Call loans are a speciality of the New York market. Brokerage houses in ordinary times carry 60 per cent, of their borrowings in Tune loans and 40 per cent, in Call loans. Negotiations for time money are carried on directly with the lenders or with street brokers they select to represent them. Call loans are negotiated on the Stock Exchange much after the manner in which stocks are bought and sold. These "Call" loans are 114 THE STOCK EXCHANGE all made upon collateral which must have an aggregate market value of at least 20 per cent, above the face value of the loan. A call loan can be terminated by either party the next day, or any day thereafter, by giv- ing notice before 1 o'clock, and must be paid at once when the lender calls it. Similarly in London bankers lend out funds "at call or short notice." Before noon the banks and Trust compa- nies notify their brokers in what is called the "money crowd" on the Stock Exchange to lend a stated amount of money. At about 2.30 in the afternoon this crowd is thickest and noisiest. By then the Stock Exchange knows pretty accurately how much it will need, and its brokers go into the "crowd " to bid for what they want, buying money from the bankers' agents at the lowest rate obtainable. This Stock Exchange money market of New York rests upon the solid economic basis of supply and demand. Occasional attempts are made to manipulate it, but generally without result. A few of the banks and Trust companies never ask more than 6 per cent, per annum for their money, even in times of panic; but at such times their brokers, instead of offering their money publicly, go WALL STREET 115 about privately, selecting the most reputable houses, and generally ask for gilt-edged dividend-paying securities as collateral, and for larger margins than are demanded in quieter times. The extreme rates that are published represent loans of small sums to the needy and poorer class of borrowers. If there were no adequate supply of call money available New York Stock Exchange methods would have to be changed. The daily settle- ment is universal in the Stock Exchanges of the United States, and is doubtless one of the causes why failures or defaults are so commendably rare. The profession of broker on the New York Stock Exchange is indeed a very remunerative one. Most of the members are well off and many of them are rich. Until they have saved a sufficient capital out of their com- missions they often have the good sense to avoid speculation. But when they once have money free they begin to invest and operate for their own account, or, as they say, "take an interest in the market." A clever man in this position, who is really in the swim and the know, can usually do well for himself; and it is surprising how many of these pro- fessionals have the self-restraint to avoid 116 THE STOCK EXCHANGE great risks. They know from the experience of unfortunate clients the danger of "over- trading," and as over-trading is the character- istic vice of the amateur speculator a word here may be in season. "The rapid expan- sion of an investor into a speculator," said a successful Wall Street broker to the writer, "is one of our most familiar sights." A man comes down to a broker's office with five thousand dollars, and says he wants to invest it to the best advantage. The broker asks him whether he wishes to make a pure invest- ment or whether he would like his holding to have "a speculative tail" to it. In nine cases out of ten the investor admits that he had the idea of increasing his capital in mind when he came there. The broker then ex- plains to him that he can safely buy $10,000 worth of securities, on which he can pay 50 per cent., and the broker will lend him the balance of the purchase money at current rates of interest. The broker says, in effect: "I will buy you ten thousand dollars' worth of stock with your five thousand dollars, and with five thousand additional dollars, which I will borrow for you from month to month at 5 per cent, or whatever is the market rate, as long as you like to hold the stock." Our WALL STREET 117 investor is captivated by the plan. He neglects the possibility of a fall, in which case his losses are doubled, because his mind is taken up with the probability and practical certainty of a rise. He has opened his ac- count in Wall Street en the basis of what is known as a 50 per cent, margin. He is half investor, half speculator. The fluctuations of the market begin to excite him. If he loses, he wants to make good the loss. If he gains, his appetite for more is whetted. He hovers about Wall Street listening eagerly for points. Presently he meets a tipster, who suggests something better and hints to the novice that he may quadruple his gains if he contents himself with a 25 per cent, margin, owning only a quarter of the stock which is to make his fortune. His own spec- ulative investment begins to look very small and slow to him, as he listens to the feverish and exaggerated talk all around him, and reads the inspired utterances of the secular and financial press. The temptation to in- crease his risks without increasing his capital is nearly irresistible, and in a comparatively short time he has 50,000 dollars' worth of stocks with only the same original capital of 5,000 dollars, owing his broker 45,000 dollars 118 THE STOCK EXCHANGE instead of 5,000. He is then, of course, in a position in which a small decline in prices will swamp all his capital. The investor has become a speculator, in reality a plunger. He is over-trading; the nerve strain is making him miserable, but he can't stop. A 10 per cent, decline wipes him out. No matter how good a security may be, there are many unforeseen events which may cause a fall of 10 per cent, in its market price without affecting in the least its real value. But such temporary fluctuations seldom cause, even in panics, a 50 per cent, depre- ciation in the value of investment securities, so that our investor would have been com- paratively safe if he had not yielded to the temptation to "over-trade." But whether his capital is risked or not, the more he bor- rows and the more he shifts his securities the greater, in fact, the cost of his holdings in interest and commissions the more prob- abilities weigh against his emerging from Wall Street with a profit. In his Twenty Years of Inside Life in Wall Street, Mr. Fowler relates an incident of this kind which may be condensed to serve as an illustration. One day, in January 1865, a rough farmer, entering the office of a Wall Street broker, produced from his portly wallet WALL STREET two documents, the first a certificate of good character from the local school-master, the other a certificate of $ ? 300 deposit in the bank of his native village. Next he spread out on the table a cutting from a newspaper headed "Petroleum," setting forth that the books of the Sixtieth National Petroleum Company were still open to subscription; capital $1,000,000 in $10 shares, and the Company was generously allowing the public to buy them at $3 a share. The property consisted of 30 acres in the very midst of the oil region, quite near to the celebrated Buchanan farm; three wells already sunk, and room for more; every indication of oil; a dividend of 2 per cent, a month guaranteed; books to be closed positively and irrevocably on the 21st instant. "Them air Petrollum shares is what I've come for. Two per cent, a month dividend is enough for me," said the rustic. This was at the height of the oil boom. The brokers tried hard to dissuade their client; but only by quoting the agricultural maxim, "Don't put all your eggs in one basket," could they prevail on him to invest no more than $1,300 in this company, keeping the balance of a thousand for other tempting opportunities. They went to the office of the Petroleum 120 THE STOCK EXCHANGE Company, paid in the money, and received certificates for 433 shares. The investor was charmed with the certificates. In the foreground was engraved a flowing well, sending up a jet 100 feet into the air and fall- ing in a graceful parabolic curve into a huge tank inscribed with the company's name. Near by was a pyramid of barrels, and in the background several vessels and railroad trains were being laden with petroleum. The petro- leum fever had raged eight months and cul- minated in February, after bubble companies with a nominal capital of 300 million dollars had been organised. A special Petroleum Stock Exchange had been created, which, dying soon afterwards, had its remains incor- porated with the Mining Stock Board, another product of another contemporary bubble. Five months afterwards the rustic lost faith in petroleum, and sold his stock at 10 cents a share; but he was more fortunate with his balance. First he "sold short" in gold and made $5,000. Then he became a bull of Erie and made another $5,000; then, in spite of his brokers, he fell into the claws of the Lobster. They lost sight of him for three months until one day in November, when he rushed into the office, crying: "The Lobster has busted, and I'm busted." WALL STREET 121 He had just $200 left. It was a damp, chill day; every one looked blue, but the rustic's face was the bluest of all. They took him and cheered him with a certain beverage, and then found that the poor man had borrowed money from friends in his village to meet the demands of the rapacious Lobster for more margin. The debt weighed on his mind; but at this point an operator joined them in high spirits. He had just made a little pile out of a heavy fall in Prairie du Chien. It had already fallen to 91, and he predicted it would fall to 50 inside of the week, and volunteered to sell calls in it at 110 which should be deliverable at any time in the next thirty days. The rustic's face brightened and he gave this new friend his last $200 for a call of 200 (hundred dollar) shares. The operator filled out a form, signed it and sent it to his broker, who guaranteed it. The document would run as follows : New York, November , 1865. For Value received the Bearer may CALL ON ME for Two Hundred Shares of the Ordinary Stock of the Prairie du Chien Company at 110 per cent, at any time in thirty days from date. The bearer is entitled THE STOCK EXCHANGE to all dividends or extra dividends declared during the time. Signed : The stock called Prairie du Chien, or Prairie Dog, was not inconveniently large for the pool made by Stimpson and Marston in the au- tumn of this year (1865). There were only about 29,000 shares to be handled. In August the stock had broken to 33. The pool pro- ceeded with the utmost secrecy to buy nearly all the stock. On the Saturday when the rustic bought his call it had risen to par. " On the following Monday it sold from 125 to 250 in twenty minutes, amid the fiercest excite- ment ever known before in the Brokers* Board." On that "black bear Monday," when our hero reached the lobby of the Brokers' Board Prairie du Chien had just struck 200. Trem- bling with joy he fumbled forth his lucky "call," sent it in to his broker, and in three minutes had sold his 200 shares at 210. Ten minutes later he "called" upon his operating bear friend, who bought the stock at 225 and delivered it to the party who had just bought the 200 shares at 210. In 48 hours the two hundred dollars had swollen to $20,000, for each of his two hundred 100-dollar shares had WALL STREET 123 doubled in value between the time when he bought the call and the time when he sold it. After this happy event the rustic might have retired to his village as an agricultural capitalist. Unfortunately, but naturally enough, history relates that he became en- amoured of "calls and puts." He never thought of returning in glory and comfort to his village, but hunted for new opportunities in the street, "until one fine day in February he heard that Henry Keep was selling calls in Old Southern at a price slightly above the market, and promptly secured calls for 500 shares duly signed by Henry Keep. Hearing of Keep's sales, and reasoning that Keep was not such a fool as to sell calls on Old Southern if it were going to rise, the bears bought his calls freely and used them as a margin to sell short. A little later, when the price had risen considerably, Keep began selling "puts," also on favourable terms. Then the bulls bought these "puts" and used them as mar- gins to buy Old Southern. Thus the wily operator stiffened the price doubly, first by inducing short sales at a low price, next by inducing purchases at a high price. A "put," be it remembered, is in form exactly like a call; only for the key words 124 THE STOCK EXCHANGE "CALL ON ME" you substitute "DE- 1 LIVER ME," so that while the person who buys a call does so in hope of the price rising within the time prescribed, the person who buys a "put" does so in hope of it falling. Our hero held his call for 500 shares until Old Southern touched 98, when he "called," re- ceived the stock, sold it for cash at 100, and netted a profit of $12,000. Successful and elated, the farmer now blossomed out as a City man, sought the aid of a fashionable tailor and cultivated Wall Street society. A new acquaintance dazzled him with the story of the Pacific Mail. Its fluctuations from 1850 to 1864 had scattered fortune and ruin through the crowd of speculators. In Decem- ber 1861, when the Trent affair threatened war with England, it had fallen to 69. The capital stock was 4 million dollars in 40,000 shares. But in 1862 a powerful ring acquired 26,000 shares, which were transferred to a banking firm to hold as trustees for five years for the joint benefit of members of the ring. After 1864, with the end of the war the price of the stock began to rise by leaps and bounds. The public demand was met with generous supplies. In 1865 the capital was increased from 4 to 10 million dollars, and the price WALL STREET 125 was 240. Next year, when the capital was doubled and the price 180, the trustees of the pool held 130,000 shares. Soon afterwards L. W. Jerome, then a giant of the Stock Exchange, bought 100,000 shares from the trustees of the pool at 20 per cent, below the market price, and began to unload artfully but slowly. Unfortunately for him the winter brought currency troubles and a severe de- pression. The market was deluged with stock, and in a few days Pacific Mail fell from 163 to 115. In later years the watered stock of this steamship company sank to 10; but the fall to 115 pretty nearly ruined Jerome, who was only saved from extinction by the charity of the pool, which released him from part of his contract. "The same blow," we are told, "which felled this financial giant also struck hard upon our bucolic pigmy." Dazzled by the fortunes won in Pacific Mail, he had bought 400 shares at 175, putting up a margin of no less than 60 per cent., "a dead open and shut thing" as he expressed it, certainly a judicious and ample margin in ordinary cases. But in thirty days this margin was wiped out. He sold his four hundred shares at the lowest panic price, losing $24,000. For a month the agriculturist 1S6 THE STOCK EXCHANGE retired to the backwoods with a poor remain- der of $5,000. But he returned, and by a series of lucky turns, raised it in eight months to $13,000. Then he ran across his Pacific Mail adviser, who gave him another inside tip about Atlantic Mail. Unwarned by his experience with its Pacific sister, he listened to the story of its wonderful promise. It had fallen 20 per cent, and must recover. So he bought 100 shares at 93, depositing a 10 per cent, margin. That very day Atlantic Mail began to drop. It hung for a while at 87, and then broke 64 per cent, in an hour. Again our poor friend sold at the lowest point, 23. It usually happens so. After this calamity he retired finally from Wall Street with $2,500 in his wallet, just $200 more than he had brought with him originally. His first, best broker asks why he did not retire with his $30,000 safely invested, and replies "Operators come into the street with the intention of making 5 or 10 or 20,000 dollars, which having been done, they say they will draw out their profits and retire. But they don't. Their broker blandly hovers over and guards their precious little piles for himself. He inquires in an insinuating voice, just as he is going to the Board, whether his cus- WALL STREET 127 tomer 'has anything to say.' The customer generally has something to say in the shape of an order to buy or sell, and then in five minutes, or thereabouts, he finds his pile is locked fast as a margin in the fond embrace of his broker, who sits over it and feeds upon it till what with interest, commissions, turns, losses, etc., the precious little pile dwindles, and finally disappears." It hardly ne*eds argument to prove that the odds are heavily against the amateur specu- lator. If he is not actually fleeced and swindled he is far more likely than not to lose. It is like betting against the bank. The wear and tear of commissions and stamps and interest eats away his capital, even if the luck is evenly balanced. As an example of the means by which the small fry find their way into the mouth of the great pike operators a very old story may be revived. Jay Gould or some such person on one occasion being asked for advice by the pastor of a rich and fashionable New York Taber- nacle, whispered a recommendation of Pacific Mail and promised to reimburse the pious man if his purchases of that stock should result in loss. When the pastor came to him later, deeply distressed by a heavy personal 128 THE STOCK EXCHANGE loss, Gould was as good as his word, and promptly handed him a cheque for the amount. " But how about my parishioners? " inquired the reverend gentleman. "You placed no ban of secrecy upon me, and their losses are enormous." To which Gould re- plied calmly, "They were the people I was after." Thus was verified a Japanese prov- erb: "The darkest place is just below the candlestick." Mr. Thomas Gibson, in a recent analysis of the art of speculation, has described the results of a careful examination of 4,000 speculative accounts spread over a period of ten years. Four points were established. 1. Most of the operations were pure gam- bling. 2. Success almost invariably led to excess and disaster. 3. There was a marked tendency to buy at the top and sell at the bottom. 4. About 80 per cent, of the accounts showed a final loss. Thus, apart from all the worry, work, and anxiety, four-fifths of these eager fortune hunters actually lost money as well as time. In another case 500 speculative accounts in Steel Common taken from the books of differ- WALL STREET 129 ent firms between July 1901 and March 1903 (in both of which months the stock sold at 37) gave the following results: In 343 cases the accounts terminated in loss; 88 showed a profit; 52 fairly balanced; and in 17 cases the Steel Stocks were taken up by the purchasers to be held "in all cases at a considerable paper loss." So wide of the mark is the popular fancy that stock market speculation on borrowed money is a hopeful enterprise. It is a curious fact that comparatively few, even among professional operators, are to be found often on the bear side. I have met hardened speculators who boasted that they never had done, and never would do anything so immoral as to try to make money in this way "out of other men's losses" by the fall of ; a' stock. But a very little reflection will show that no code of ethics can make a valid dis- tinction between betting that a horse will win and betting that it will lose. It may be wrong to buy beyond your purse when things look cheap, or to sell more than you possess when they look dear. But there is exactly the same moral objection to either course, and of course there is nothing like a bear contingent to steady and check a falling market. The speculator for a rise who is trying to sell in a 130 THE STOCK EXCHANGE falling market has every reason to be grateful to the speculator for a fall who has sold "short," and is therefore forced to buy stock in order to meet his obligations. Theoreti- cally a successful operator should be capable of bearish and bullish moods, for, on the whole, over a period of years stocks and shares tend to maintain their level, though great changes in price may result from great wars, which destroy vast quantities of capital and create vast quantities of Government debt, or from long periods of peace when capi- tal accumulates and interest falls. But bear operations, especially on a large scale, are very dangerous, because there may be a shortage of available stock, and in that case holders may squeeze the bear to any extent and force kim to buy back at ruinous prices. This may ac- count for some of the almost superstitious objections entertained against bear opera- tions. A shrewd old New York broker, just before retiring, told a young disciple, "If I had to live my life over again I would always be a bull, but I would not always have an interest." In other words, he would only speculate in a rising market. At other times he would be content with his commissions. To return to Wall Street. Since the end WALL STREET 131 of the Civil War it has seen three crises, each of which may be said to have marked the end of a distinctive epoch in finance. The panic of 1873 when Jay Cooke came to grief and the New York Stock Exchange closed for ten days stopped the construction of railways between the Great Lakes and the Pacific coast a productive work which found peaceful occupation for the million disbanded soldiers of the Civil War, and had so solved what seemed the almost insoluble problem of that vast accession of idle men to the labour market. After five years' rest and recupera- tion another era of speculative expansion commenced in 1878, anticipating the resump- tion of specie payments, and lasted with many ups and downs for about six years, during which time many thousands of miles of railway were built parallel to, and in com- petition with, some of the most prosperous existing lines. The capital embarked in these new adventures proved, for the most part, unfortunate for the original investors; hence, after the panic of 1884 brought this second era of prosperity to an end, there followed a period of transition during which these new and at first unprofitable lines were being absorbed by the older and stronger corpora- THE STOCK EXCHANGE tions. Then came another outburst of specu- lation, which was marked by the entry of large foreign operators into the New York market, and by a great development of Lon- don's dealings in Americans, or "Yankees," as they were called. A check to this was administered by the Baring crisis. But the collapse in New York was not quite due, and was postponed till 1893; its proximate cause being the vicious silver legislation of the United States Government. A heavy cloud of depression hung over Wall Street until 1896, when Mr. McKinley was elected President on a straight gold platform. This restored the confidence of the moneyed interest, and laid the train for a new era of speculative activity. By the Dingley tariff the profits of favoured manufacturers were enormously increased at the expense of the general public, and upon the passing of the Tariff there followed in logical sequence the organisation of trusts to stifle competition and raise prices to the utmost limit of the protective and prohibitive duties. From the Wall Street point of view this chapter may be called the capitalising of the tariff. It lasted till the Stock Exchange and banking crisis of 1907. That disastrous collapse of credit started with the run on the WALL STREET 133 Knickerbocker Trust in October, and ended in a suspension of cash payments which was continued for many weeks by nearly all the banks in practically all parts of the United States. This crisis and its consequences, political, social and economic, are still vivid in the memory. But though the crisis stands out clear and the consequences are undeniable, a lively controversy still rages about its causes. Perhaps it may here be affirmed that the unhealthy conditions caused by tariff and trusts on the one hand, and by the cur- rency and banking laws on the other, were largely responsible for the severity of the cataclysm; for the storm, after blowing down the whole fabric of credit, left behind it not only a long and deep depression in almost every branch of industry but a wide- spread and apparently irresistible popular resentment against the Tariff. Each of the crises named was marked by one common feature a suspension of pay- ment by the New York banks; and in the case of all except the last the funds of the Wall Street banks were mainly employed in loans on Stock Exchange collateral for the purpose of speculative operations. Indeed, 134 THE STOCK EXCHANGE Wall Street and the Stock Exchange were till the late nineties practically synonymous terms, so that a banking crisis would naturally attend any really severe crisis upon the Stock Exchange. But the reason why the Wall Street banks could not withstand the "runs" of October. 1907 was rather different; for in the era of great trust and corporate flotations after 1906 immense sums of bank money had been loaned to the managers under "syndi- cate agreements." This money had been available for Stock Exchange operations; but now there were Stock Exchange loans and syndicate loans in Wall Street, and the latter proved not to be liquid like the former. When the liquidation of Stock Exchange loans was finished, and creditors of the banks were still clamorous, there was nothing for the banks to do but suspend payment; for the syndicate loans were found to be quite unwieldy and uncollectable in such an emergency. The fact that one institution in New York was financing 81 syndicates at one time, will give some idea of the extent to which the re- sources of Wall Street were used outside of the Stock Exchange when the collapse came in 1907. Since that time the current has changed back again to Stock Exchange WALL STREET 135 operations, and now there is direct manipula- tion of prices of securities on the Stock Ex- change by groups of capitalists who had for some years devoted their operations almost entirely to the creation and management of syndicates. The New York Stock Exchange business differs radically in one respect from all others : its dealings are practically confined to home corporations. Canadian Pacific Railway shares are dealt in sparingly, and there is a nominal market for some issues of Japanese bonds. There used to be a market for some Mexican rails, but now a recorded sale rarely appears. American investments have always been sufficiently attractive to hold the bulk of American capital. This will change some day, but not soon. Some day American colonial securities will probably be quoted and actively dealt in. There is a steady ab- sorption of good shares by small investors. Every year the registry of stock holders shows an increase in numbers in most of the old-established dividend-paying corpora- tions. Hence comes the demand for more public control of corporations and more protection for investors. The business of the New York Stock Exchange will be- 13(5 THE STOCK EXCHANGE come more of an investment character, as American securities develop into sure revenue producers. Railway shares that used to be of doubtful value have become sound invest- ments, and there are comparatively few low- priced shares now available for the shrewd investor who likes to buy shares that may ultimately become revenue producing. Such buyers, if they still fancy American securi- ties, must eventually turn to the ordinary shares of industrial corporations, of which there will be a large assortment from which to choose; but the market for them will not be so broad and speculatively attractive as it has been for the ordinary shares of railway corporations. It may always be possible to buy but not always possible to sell. The tendency of public opinion is to force the New York Stock Exchange to protect the in- terests of dealers in its securities with the utmost possible care. CHAPTER V GOOD SECURITIES AND THE ART OP INVESTMENT AFTER our survey of Stock Exchanges in the past and the present my readers will be prepared for some critical examination of the area and modes of investment. The difference between investment and specula- tion cannot be defined accurately; but every one has a rough idea of a line which divides safety, with the certainty of a reasonable interest, from risk, with all its possibilities of loss or profit. The theme of speculation! will be developed in our next chapter. Our present object is to direct the attention of the genuine investor, who wants his interest \ to be as high as is compatible with the safety of his principal, to some of the general rules and considerations that should limit and guide his choice. The largest and most varied list of securi- ties in the world is the "Daily Official List" 137 138 THE STOCK EXCHANGE of the London Stock Exchange. It now con- sists of sixteen large pages. The price of a single copy is sixpence. It is published by the Trustees and Managers of the Stock Exchange, under the authority of the Com- mittee, at 4, Copthall Buildings, London, E.G. Largely as the result of the ever- increasing tendency both at home and abroad ^o give commercial and industrial under- takings the form of joint-stock companies, the London list has expanded very rapidly in the last half -century. Up to the, year 1867 one page sufficed, then four till 1889, then eight till 1900, and twelve from 1900 to 1902, when it reached its present limit of sixteen. In the last twenty -five years the total nominal value of all the securities quoted has nearly doubled from 5,480,000,000 in 1885 to 10,200,000,000 in 1909, about twice the nominal capital value of the securities quoted on the Paris Bourse according to the latest statement that I have seen. In 1902 the total par value of the listed and unlisted securities dealt in on the New York Stock Exchange was only about 3,000,000,000. The London Stock Exchange List is sub- divided into thirty-eight different classes of ,very varying importance. The Foreign GOOD SECURITIES 139 market, including the loans of foreign gov- ernments and foreign provincial and muni- cipal issues, deals with a nominal capital of over three thousand million pounds sterling. Other great groups are The Consol market, includ- ing colonial and municipal issues 1737 millions- The Home railway market . 1220 American railroads, includ- ing U. S. steel 1803 Foreign railway market . . 571 Colonial " . . 229 " Indian . . 145 Then there are the immense markets of home banking, insurance, shipping, gas, waterworks, canals, mining, industrial, finan- cial and miscellaneous, comprising about 1,500,000,000 of nominal values. The mis- cellaneous market includes a great number of British companies working abroad or in the colonies, or partially at home and par- tially abroad, such as land, mining, rubber, nitrate, telegraphs, etc. In the foreign bond market only a fraction of the capital invested is British. In American railways, British capital comes easily next after American. In all the other markets of the London 140 THE STOCK EXCHANGE Stock Exchange home investors own the whole, or a greatly preponderating share. Before leaving the list we shall do well to insist again, at the risk of repetition, that it is not always possible to buy or sell at the prices quoted. A jobber cannot be forced to deal. The real test of saleability is the column showing "business done," which indicates clearly enough what are the active securities. Among inactive securities there are many (such as small but sound State and municipal loans) which are saleable enough. On the other hand, small specula- tive securities such as rubber and oil com- panies, and many other commercial and in- dustrial ventures, are easily got rid of when for some reason or other speculation flourishes, but are at other times almost un- marketable. The best markets for local industrials are often found on provincial Stock Exchanges, such as Glasgow, Man- chester, or Liverpool. For investment purposes securities may be divided into public and private, the former being based on public credit backed by taxes (or rates), and the latter on private credit backed by profits, good will, and tangible assets. GOOD SECURITIES 141 The best Government loans, starting with British Consols and French Rentes, and end- ing with the Imperial and State loans of Germany, yielded at the close of 1910 from 3 to 4 per cent, interest. Twelve years ago they yielded from 2f to 3j per cent. The change has come about mainly through enormous borrowings for wars and increased armaments. If, as seems now happily not im- probable, we may look forward to a period of abstention from war, with limitations of mili- tary and naval expenditure by arrangement among the Powers, a substantial appreciation in the credit of these gilt-edged securities (especially British and German) can confi- dently be predicted, though it may be long before we return to the levels of 1897 and 1898. With the increasing demands for public improvements of all kinds, the output of municipal loans throughout the world is a formidable competitor with the borrowing propensities of national governments. For- tunately, the good municipal loans are gener- ally well spent for purposes which are directly or indirectly profitable. The investor is also protected, as a rule, either by a sinking fund, or by a provision for repayment at par on a given date, or by a statutory limitation 142 THE STOCK EXCHANGE of the total indebtedness in accordance with the assessable value of the town, or by more than one of these methods in combination. No British municipality has ever, since the Municipal Corporations Act of 1835, failed to pay its interest punctually. Among the States of the American Union there were some scandalous repudiations in the days of Sidney Smith, which have been immortal- ised by the stinging pen of that wittiest of economic and political writers. However, with a mere handful of exceptions the record of North American and colonial towns has been clean for a generation, and their credit is deservedly high. But as the coupons upon the city bonds of the United States are not payable in London, they are of little interest to English investors. Some care should be exercised in regard to the size of towns; for small colonial villages, which might almost be wheeled out of the municipal area in a single night, sometimes call themselves "cities," and get their bonds hawked about in London. The investor should wait for a good pro- spectus or take the issue of a decent-sized colonial town which is duly quoted in the London Stock Exchange list. But he may well be satisfied with a slightly lower rate of GOOD SECURITIES 143 interest in home municipal stocks, from which, if he is an "inscribed" holder, he will receive his interest regularly without trouble. All the larger issues are readily marketable at any moment, though of course the jobber's turn is rather bigger than in the case of consols. To judge the value of second-class public securities requires a rather wide knowledge of political and financial conditions. A rough criterion is the market's own appreciation. But the market seldom discriminates ade- quately between loans for war or armaments and loans for capital and reproductive pur- poses. The value of its judgment is rather technical as between different securities of the same class. But a nation groaning under a dead-weight debt contracted for war is in a very much inferior position to that of a country like Canada which has borrowed mainly for reproductive purposes. And in the same country there may be many public issues of very varying merit. Thus a close study of the various Greek bonds will show why the railway loan is considered the best, and so yields the lowest rate of interest. Similar distinctions may be made in the case of Turkish, Argentine, Chinese, and Bra- 144 THE STOCK EXCHANGE zilian loans. As a rule, in the case of coun- tries which are financially weak and over- burdened with debt, the market prefers loans specially mortgaged on some branch of the customs or inland revenue. In coun- tries with rising credit the lower interest loans standing well below par are the most attractive. A railway bond guaranteed by the Government has a double security, and may in some cases be preferred to a direct Government issue. Indeed, the unguaranteed bonds of the best British railway companies in South America often yield a lower rate of interest than those of the Government whose territory they serve. Generally speaking, investors, who do not wish to lose their capital, should avoid the municipal, and provincial issues of South America, and all Central American loans, and all the loans of Venezuela, Colombia and other minor re- publics of South America. To judge by ex- perience and present conditions, Argentina, Chile, and Brazil are the most secure of South American States. But even in these, as well as in Mexico, there are elements of political danger and social disorder which cannot be overlooked. Turning from public to private securities, GOOD SECURITIES 145 we are faced by an entirely new set of con- siderations, and the task of the investor is far more difficult and complicated. By a skilful and cautious use of local knowledge a careful buyer may often secure for himself a high rate of interest with comparatively little risk. But even so he will be well advised not to entrust all his eggs to a local basket. In case of the accidents and misfortunes due to unforeseen frauds, or unsuspected mismanagement, or fashion, or competition, any local concern may come to grief. A town or part of a town may decay, an industry may decline, the values and rents of lands, houses, factories, and shops, may shrink and dwindle to the most alarming extent. Cer- tainly those who have capital should take care that a good part of it is distributed among unassailable securities of a national or international character. Let us now pass to the technicalities of joint-stock companies their bonds, their pre ference stocks, and their ordinary shares, and to the general merits of the security which various species of undertakings offer. During the last seventy or eighty years railway enterprise has probably proved the most productive and profitable of all invest- 146 THE STOCK EXCHANGE ments. The early promotions of course con- tained a large sprinkling of swindles. The early railroad pioneers were often of the buccaneering type a type not yet extinct in new countries. But in the average case where the promoters have attained an average standard of honesty, and the engineers an average standard of skill, the faith of the investor has been justified. So far no in- vention for land transport has appeared which seems at all likely to vie with the steel car, drawn by steam or electricity along steel rails, in cheapness and celerity. It might seem that steamships should provide equally attractive openings to the investor. But here a vital difference emerges. Almost every railway enjoys at least a partial mono- poly. It has a route fixed and permanent, which no competitor can use without its consent. The people along the route must use it for travelling or freight, and it is only in densely populated countries that an alter- native line is often available without great loss of time and convenience. But the sea is a public highway open to all. No shipping company can exclude a competitor from its route. And as soon as a lucrative monopoly begins to be enjoyed, another company, or a GOOD SECURITIES 147 swarm of tramps, is almost certain to appear. Tramways and improved roads, with bicycles and motor cars, have no doubt reduced short distance passenger traffic in some places, but they also act as feeders to a trunk line. There may be a future danger to railroad investors in aeroplanes and flying machines; but at present the peril seems to attach to the persons rather than to the competitors of aeronauts. Telegraph companies are threat- ened by telephones and marconigrams, but so far they seem likely to survive. The tele- phone is a quick substitute for the personal interview. The telegram is a quick sub- stitute for the letter. Each has its special use, and therefore the capital invested in each may continue to yield interest. So, again, many substitutes have been invented for rubber; but none of them has yet proved at all formidable. It would be possible to fill many pages in this way discussing the probable future of the different branches of commerce and industry into which capital is being and has been poured by investors. But our special purpose here is to define broadly what is a satisfactory security, leaving the investor to speculate upon and allow for the possi- 148 THE STOCK EXCHANGE bility of any particular business being super- seded by the invention of a superior process or a cheaper substitute. And here it may be well to begin by accepting, with limitations, the received opinion that, in the sphere of private or commercial as distinguished from government and public stocks, the best security is a first mortgage upon any flourish- ing enterprise which can offer ample assets. It is not every undertaking that can provide satisfactory security for the issue of bonds. In fact, it may almost be said that a real freehold estate, with a market value consid- erably above the total issue of first mortgage bonds, is the only case in which a first mort- gage in itself offers anything like an impreg- nable security even in a stable and civilised country. For this purpose, pastoral or agri- cultural land is superior to urban values, as it is generally subject to less violent fluctua- tions. But even here there is the possibility of a confiscatory land tax and that passed by the Labour Government in Australia in 1910 almost deserves the epithet which will make a heavy reduction in the selling value of the lands of a pastoral company, and so endanger the capital even of those who hold first mortgage bonds on the property. The GOOD SECURITIES 149 value of a first mortgage rests on the fact that if the interest is not paid the mortgagees can immediately seize and sell the property. Where the property consists of real estate, timber, or other valuable and marketable goods in ample amount, and the courts of justice can be relied on, the security may be called perfect. But in nine cases out of ten the property of the corporation or com- pany owes most of its value to the under- taking as a whole. As Mr. E. S. Meade puts it, in his excellent treatise on Corpora- tion Finance, "When the property of the company is specialised to the use of a particu- lar business, such as a railroad or manufactur- ing plant, where the business must be carried on in a certain place and by people who are skilled in its management, and where the property, once devoted to a particular use, can be turned to no other use, the real security of the creditor is not the property but the earnings of the property." On this view the much-vaunted first mortgage on a railroad owes its value to the fact not that it enables you to sell the property, but that it is a first charge on the earnings. In other words, the American first mortgage bond is no better than the floating charge 150 THE STOCK EXCHANGE of an ordinary English debenture, ^nd if the surplus earnings in bad times are less it is really less valuable. Other things being equal, a well-covered first preference is almost as good as an equally well-covered bond or debenture. Let us put the American first mortgage bond to the practical test of bankruptcy. If we look at the actual wording of the 1897 mortgage securing "the first lien con- vertible four per cent, gold bonds" of the Union Pacific Railroad Company (a typically gilt-edged investment though the line was in a receiver's hands twenty years ago) we find that it assigns to the trustee all the several lines of railroad; property, terminals, prem- ises, etc., belonging to the railroad company. Under this and other mortgage deeds the trustee for the bondholders has large and sweeping powers over the property of the corporation in the event of bankruptcy. He can, in theory, sell the property, or enter upon it and operate it, applying the proceeds or revenues to the liquidation of its debts. In theory, I say, and according to the letter of the law, the property of a corporation which fails to pay interest on its bonds, or to meet them when due, is to be seized by GOOD SECURITIES 151 the trustee and sold. It is for this that the mortgage deed was drawn, for this that the trustee exists. A similar procedure is actually carried out in small bankruptcies. But in large affairs the American law does not work. Just as, in a panic, American banks are allowed to suspend cash payments with- out closing their doors, so (to quote our previous authority) "the theory of the cor- poration mortgage cannot in many cases be carried out." How, then, is the mortgage made null and void, and "the property protected against its creditors"? It is done "by invoking the aid of a court of equity." A receivership is the easy and comfortable haven into which in troublous times an American corporation steers. I am not exaggerating. Mr. Meade, who has studied the law and the facts ex- haustively, declares that "at the first threat of disaster" the directors, "who see long before any creditor the impending insolvency of the company, fly to the shelter of a court of equity." Equity shields them from the law, and bars the best secured creditors from their legal remedy. The judge usually appoints the chief lawyer of the bankrupt corporation, or possibly even its president, THE STOCK EXCHANGE as receiver. Or he may, and often does in smaller cases, appoint some unsuccessful lawyer connected with the court; for a receivership is a paid office, and receiver- ships, especially in bad times, are large fountains of patronage. The plea, we are told, which usually prevails with the judge on these occasions, is that, unless the court intervenes and appoints a receiver, the creditors of the company will seize upon its property. But exactly the same plea could be urged in respect of a house-owner who failed to pay interest on his mortgage. The only difference is that in the case of a cor- poration the stockholders, who own it, are a numerous body. . To get the money or substitute for money that he needs to carry on the business, the receiver usually resorts to what are called "receiver's certificates." A receiver's certifi- cate is "a short term note secured by a first mortgage upon all the property in the re- ceiver's hands." The plight of the first mortgage bondholder may now be imagined. He has not only lost his legal remedy for recovering his principal, but an equitable first mortgage has been put in front of his legal first mortgage. When, therefore, the first mortgage bond of American law is put GOOD SECURITIES 153 to the sole test for which it was intended, it only too frequently proves to be not worth the paper it was written upon. In course of time, no doubt, the interest on the bond may be resumed, and its value may be restored. But it is not in practice the security which it professes to be in theory. Equity has taken away what the law gave. Looking back over thirty years, the ordinary stockholder in a sound and well-conducted company like the Pennsylvania has been better off for dividends, and better secured as to principal, than the owner of the highly-valued first mortgage gold bonds of many American railroad corporations. The prestige of the American first mortgage bond is so great and so undeserved, and its superiority to the ordinary English debenture so frequently asserted, that I shall borrow from Mr. Meade a concrete illustration of the risks a receiver is allowed to run. First of all, however, it may be asked whether the bondholders take the receivership and the receiver's certificates lying down? Appar- ently not, but they spend their money vainly in equitable suits. "Existing creditors of the company are violently opposed to the issue of receiver's certificates of large amount, and often appeal 154 THE STOCK EXCHANGE to the court not to allow the receiver to place this new incumbrance ahead of the lien on their security. Their pleas are, however, usually disregarded. The court usually stands by its own appointee, the receiver, and is usually guided as to the necessity of the issue of certificates by the receiver's recom- mendations. The amount of money which the receiver will spend upon the property depends on his conception of his duties." So much for the practice as stated by a friendly writer. Now for the illustration. In 1896 the Baltimore and Ohio went into a receivership. Two receivers were appointed. The road was in a bad way. What was to be done? The proper thing, I submit, would have been for the receivers, acting as trustees for the bondholders, to endeavour first of all to sell the line on favourable terms to some stronger neighbour and competitor like the Pennsylvania or the Chesapeake. But the receivers were ambitious and clever. They saw a chance of making a reputation and took it. They issued receiver's certificates and car-trust certificates as freely as if they were in charge of the purse of Fortunatus. They spent enormous sums on reconstruc- tion and equipment. Mr. Meade writes: "Earnings were heavily drawn upon, and GOOD SECURITIES 155 in many instances bondholders were forced to wait until the property on which they had a lien was put into condition to earn the interest. . . . This work was not carried through without severe opposition. Suit after suit was brought by security-holders to restrain the receivers from increasing the burdens of the property. It was urged that they were destroying the value of the first mortgage bonds by their reckless issue of certificates. . . . Their policy was denounced as a gross usurpation of power." The policy, we are told, was abundantly justified by success. The efficiency and earn- ing power of the road was improved. But mark the writer's summing up. "The Balti- more and Ohio receivers took great risks. They applied a desperate remedy to a des- perate situation. Their success on this ac- count was all the more conspicuous and bril- liant." Running great risks! That is all very well for ordinary shareholders, who put their money into speculative securities know- ing that they stand to win or lose much. But bondholders do not lend their money on those terms. They accept a small rate of interest in return for a guarantee that their principal is safe, and that if the interest fails, the principal can be promptly regained 156 THE STOCK EXCHANGE by process of law. They stood to gain noth- ing except their principal by the desperate and brilliant risks run at their expense by the receivers. They naturally and rightly objected. Many of them probably sold their bonds at a heavy depreciation. It is no answer to say that it all turned out well in the end and that it was good business for the stockholders. The affair reflects credit, no doubt, on the managing skill and enterprise of the receivers; but it proves the emptiness of the theoretical superiority of first mort- gage bonds in America over other prior charges, and should serve as a tremendous warning to investors not to put any faith in these documents beyond what may prop- erly attach to an ordinary debenture. The bonds of a weak company, as I have said, may be less secure and reliable than the or- dinary stock of a strong one. In America, of course, these warnings are largely unnecessary; but bonds, even of in- dustrial corporations in the United States and Canada, as well as in Mexico and South America, have been so widely and skilfully advertised in London, that the guileless in- vestor, unaware of precedent and practice, fancies that he has got hold of a gilt-edged security with a fairly high rate of interest, GOOD SECURITIES 157 and that even in the event of bankruptcy his capital must be returned to him intact. This is a complete delusion. In most cases he is an unintentional speculator in loss, with very little to gain in case the company, after default, becomes a prosperous concern. From this point of view he would do far better to buy preference stock with a cumulative dividend. The bond buyer in a rickety railroad or industrial corporation surrenders the chance of participation in increased earnings in exchange for the doubtful guar- antee of a fixed rate of interest and a legal document (which will probably be dis- honoured) entitling him to prompt posses- sion of the property in case of default. American bonds are either for long or short terms. Of the long term bonds, which alone are suitable to the ordinary investor, there are three main varieties, namely, first and second mortgage bonds, collateral trust bonds, and car trust (or equipment) certifi- cates. Owing to the established doctrine of receiverships, none of these are what they pretend to be perfect securities. In every case the security depends upon the prosper- ity of the company or corporation and the amount of surplus revenue which remains after the interest on the bond has been paid. 158 THE STOCK EXCHANGE Provided a property is otherwise free and there is a guarantee that it shall remain un- encumbered, I can see little to choose be- tween a first mortgage bond, an equipment bond, and an ordinary debenture. But if there is any conceivable risk of bankruptcy the would-be investor, who is really in search of safety, should turn aside from the glittering bond and buy a public security issued by some respectable government or municipality. A debenture may be defined as a certificate of debt issued by a corporation or company, without mortgage or collateral security. In the United States the debenture holder is legally an unsecured creditor; the bond- holder is legally secured but equitably un- secured. What the debenture holder pos- sesses is (1) a prior claim to earnings, and (2) a right of action against the company if they fail to pay him his interest or to repay him his principal when due. Of course, if there is a first mortgage upon the property of an undertaking which has issued debentures a first mortgage bond is better than a deben- ture. The purchaser of a debenture should take care that this is not and cannot be the case. The so-called income bond is a bond on which the interest or income is only payable according to the discretion of the directors, GOOD SECURITIES 159 though in the event of a receivership the principal must ultimately be repaid if the money will go round. In this respect it is superior to preference stock, but as the in- terest of an income bond is not cumulative, it is in another respect inferior to a cumulative preference. The objection to bonds of all kinds in countries whose courts do not allow the legal security to become effective has now been clearly stated. The capital may be lost or locked up for an indefinite time in a receivership. Otherwise the value of a specific security is, as we have seen, greatest where the assets of the company are really saleable apart from its good-will as a going concern. A land or pastoral company, or a well-situated shop with a valuable site, are cases in point. Machinery often proves almost worthless when an industrial company goes bankrupt. In England a right of fore- closure is a real and effective right, and a debenture with a trust deed containing this right and attaching sufficiently valuable free- hold property to the debentures for the pur- pose, safeguards the security of the principal, apart from the earning power of the concern. Provision for a sinking fund is another valu- able item that may appear in a debenture trust deed ; and if the deed is properly drawn 160 THE STOCK EXCHANGE and the assets attached are not undervalued, it will be found that the price of the deben- tures will shrink comparatively little when the profits of the company dwindle. This is naturally the reverse of an American bond- holder's experience when his corporation be- gins to go downhill towards a receivership. To sum up the matter. An investor who really wishes to sleep over his debentures, and is not disposed to haggle about a quarter or half per cent., should first and foremost look to see what margin there has been of earnings over and above fixed charges in years of depression. Next he will read the trust deed, if any, to see the nature of the debenture or mortgage issue. Then he will find out what sort of consideration the courts of justice of the country or State in which the corporation is formed are accustomed to give (a) to bondholders in case the concern goes bankrupt, and (b) to foreigners. Eng- lish investors often find that litigation in foreign courts is merely throwing good money after bad. A British company, whether working abroad or at home, is certainly to be preferred to a foreign company, other things being equal. American company law varies from State to State, and is often most un- satisfactory to shareholders. Lastly, let the GOOD SECURITIES 161 investor keep always in mind that an ill- covered bond, so far from being a gilt-edged security, may be of all speculations the one least likely to prove profitable. When we leave debentures or bonds to buy company stock we put aside all thought of trying to secure our principal in the event of failure and bankruptcy. As a rule, the purchaser, even of a preference stock, can only claim that it ranks before ordinary stock in the distribution of earnings. True it is sometimes provided that in the event of a company being dissolved or wound up, either compulsorily or voluntarily, the holders of preferred stock shall rank before the holders of ordinary or common stock in the distribution of assets. But in such cases there are not likely to be any assets left after the creditors have been satisfied. There are various other legal devices by which the technical position of a preference holder may be strengthened in the articles of association or incorporation, and of these, perhaps the most valuable is a limitation on the power of the directors to mortgage the property; for of course mortgages and debentures take pre- cedence of preferred stock, and every addi- tion to indebtedness impairs the position of preference shareholders. The main division 162 THE STOCK EXCHANGE of preference stocks is, however, into cumu- lative and non-cumulative. "Cumulative" means, in the case of companies whose profits fluctuate heavily, that in good times the preference shareholder may hope to recover in a lump the dividends which he has lost in whole or in part during periods of depression. But as the control of a company is usually possessed by the common stock it often hap- pens that this right has to be compromised during a reconstruction. That is to say, in order to avoid a winding up, in which every- thing might be lost, the preference share- holder has to consent to forego his past claims for the sake of keeping the company and his future hopes alive. But, of course, the cumulative type is far the better. The ordinary stock of good railways is often an excellent investment in times of depression and bad trade. Concerning the common stock in American industrial companies, a critical student observes: "It is usually ,?old at a low figure, liberal representations concerning anticipated earnings being made to influence its purchase. These representa- tions are not often realised." One or two general observations upon investments in both ordinary and preference shares may fitly close this chapter. In the GOOD SECURITIES 163 first place, a natural monopoly or a franchise conferred by public charter is the most stable basis for investment. The most dangerous imaginable prop for a company to rest upon is a bounty or a protective tariff which may at any time be withdrawn or swept away. An industry which flourishes without tariff aid in a protected country is presumably in a very strong condition. The most impor- tant consideration of all is the management, and here the advantage of investment in a local concern with which the investor is well acquainted can readily be perceived. If some change in the management occurs of which he disapproves, he can probably get out without much loss (if there is any sort of a market) before the concern begins to go downhill. Last, but not least, the time to invest in industrial and commercial en- terprises of all kinds is in periods of trade depression, when dividends and prices are low. A prospectus of a new company usually appears in moments of buoyancy and pros- perity, and on such occasions a subscription is of course likely to prove unfortunate. But this consideration does not, of course, apply to new issues of well-established companies, which may at any time require more capital for the profitable extension of business. CHAPTER VI SPECULATIVE SECURITIES AND MODES OF SPECULATION PROBABLY even in an old and conservative country like England the average investor is a speculator in the sense that he not only wishes his investment to yield him interest but also hopes and expects that he will some day be able to sell out at a profit. Such an aspiration is perfectly natural and legitimate. Anybody who has large sums to invest will very properly ask: "Is this a good time for investment?" meaning, of course: "Are stocks just now cheap and below their normal level?" Thus, towards the close of a war the credit of the belligerents is apt to be ab- normally low, and so long as there is enough revenue left to pay interest on the debt there is a good opportunity for investment. Many investors in England and France made very handsome profits by buying Spanish bonds during Spain's war with the United States, 164 SPECULATIVE SECURITIES 165 or the bonds of Russia and Japan when those two Powers were at war in Manchuria. In this respect speculative panics and banking crises resemble wars. Immense profits were reaped by purchasers of American railroad stocks in the autumn and winter of 1907, when the American market, owing to the complete collapse of credit, was in a state of prostration, and dozens of sound securities had fallen 50 per cent, below their normal value. But when stocks or commodities are really cheap the public is usually timid; when they rise to absurd heights it rushes in and buys madly. A man really seems to require a great and unusual amount of courage to buy freely when securities are cheap, and none at all to buy when they are dear. People think and act in mobs; and the speculative fever always rages in an atmosphere of high prices. But a very sharp distinction must be drawn between the speculator who buys speculative securities, or "rubbish," and the speculator who buys sound investment stocks. Thus in the American market there are well-known gambling counters such as Erie or Wabash or Southern Common non-dividend payers which have no intrinsic value and therefore 166 THE STOCK EXCHANGE move very rapidly in times of excitement. There is all the difference in the world be- tween these and the Union Pacific, which has paid a dividend of 10 per cent, for several years past. And yet in the last six years the Union Pacific has fluctuated between a maximum of 211 and a minimum of 74. Most remarkable certainly almost romantic is the history of this line. A friend of mine of middle age well remembers buying Union Pacifies at 8 and selling out at 13. In periods of excitement these marvels are dilated upon, and new Harrimans are conjured up who might perform similar wonders with the Erie or the Southern Railway. But > nearly all markets have rubbishy shares which serve as gambling counters. Thus the foreign market has the bonds of Honduras, and of other defaulting states, or provinces, or municipali- ties, of Central and South America. Every industrial market has ordinary shares in well- watered companies which may have been successful in their day, but are now practically hopeless. Even our staid Home Railways have weaker brethren, who seldom show their heads above the dividend line. But there is one whole class of securities which are essentially speculative from causes SPECULATIVE SECURITIES 167 peculiar to themselves. The mining markets and the new market for shares in rubber securities are speculative, not because they yield no dividends but because it is so difficult to form a correct estimate of their value from month to month or f rcm year to year. There are, for example, the South African gold mines, known as "Kaffirs," which date from the sensational discoveries on the Rand in the eighties of last century. There is the great De Beers monopoly of diamonds at Kim- berley a monopoly created by Mr. Rhodes and Mr. Beit, but now threatened by the dis- coveries in German South- West Africa. There are the silver mines of the United States, Mexico and Canada. There are copper mines innumerable in all parts of the world from Rio Tinto, most ancient and renowned of all, in Spain, to the latest American discoveries. There are the old tin mines of Cornwall, the modern tin mines of Malay and the modernest of Nigeria. Nor have we mentioned the gold, silver, and copper mines of Australia, among which Coolgardie and Broken Hill are pre- eminent, or the gold mines of West Africa, familiarly called the Jungle in Throgmorton Street. In the year 1907 the leading pro- ducers of gold were 168 THE STOCK EXCHANGE Ounces. Africa .... 7,536,000 U. S. A. . . . 4,335,000 Australia . . . 3,619,000 Mexico . . . 925,000 Russia . . . 900,000 The Mining List of the London Stock Exchange contains a vast selection of good, bad, and indifferent companies. But even the best are rather speculative. And why? First of all, they are dwindling securities. A mine which has yielded an average of 10 per cent, in dividends for the last five years looks very cheap, but may be very dear; for it may not have more than ten years of profit- able life. Buying shares in a successful mine is a little like buying the unexpired lease of a house without knowing the date at which it will expire. In the second place, however honestly however scientifically conducted a mine may be, it is practically impossible in nearly all cases (even assuming the market value of the ore to remain stable) to estimate its value for investment. When will the mine be worked out? When will it cease to pay? Nobody knows; even the experts can only guess, and SPECULATIVE SECURITIES 169 their public guesses are not always believed. The truth is that, in the flotation and finance of mines, engineers and geologists play very much the same part that valuers do as wit- nesses in arbitrations and rating appeals. It is their business to make out the best valuation they can for their clients, and every mining failure in the world has been intro- duced to the credulous public by highly coloured pseudo-scientific "reports" from "eminent geologists." Gold exercises a mysterious attraction over the uneducated mind, especially in the City and on the Stock Exchange. A tiny parcel of gold is watched with far more interest than a large cargo of mutton. The very elect are sometimes strangely excited over the import or export of a few thousand sovereigns or a small quantity of bullion. Hence it has been found easy to float a gold mine on less evi- dence of the existence of gold than would be needed in any other case though perhaps "Baron" Albert Grant's "Emma" silver mine might be cited by partisans of the white rival. The unfortunate purchasers of Emma shares found out afterwards that there was neither silver nor title, and eventually for every 20 subscribed they received back only 170 THE STOCK EXCHANGE a paltry shilling. Most people have heard the punning epigram , "Titles a king can give, honours he can't; Titles without honour are but a Baron Grant." But it is less commonly known that after the Emma Silver Mine fiasco some wit added " Yes, but you 're in an even worse dilemma If you cannot get a title to your Emma." Nevertheless, while the ordinary mining prospectus should be put into the waste- paper basket by any one who is not a mining expert with special knowledge, well-established mines of all kinds, from coal to gold, are legitimate, useful, and often profitable ven- tures. If the risk is well understood and well distributed, and if the wasting character of the securities is generously allowed for by the recipient of dividends, there is no reason why people of fortune should not include a proportion of mining shares in their holdings. The degree of risk that attaches depends largely upon the nature of the product. Gold, fortunately for gold-standard countries, has proved itself to be during the last hundred years one of the stablest of all commodities. Of course the nominal price of gold in a SPECULATIVE SECURITIES 171 country with a gold currency does not vary at all. By the regulation of the London Mint, an ounce of standard gold bullion is coined into 3 17s. 10|cL But people seldom take gold bullion to the Mint, as they would have to wait some time before receiving the coin. The Bank of England acts as an intermediary. It takes gold at 3 17s. 9d. and pays cash, the difference of three halfpence per ounce be- tween the Bank price and the Mint price representing the Bank's discount and its charge for the work involved. Since the closing of the Indian Mints in 1893 to the free coinage of silver, the Indian rupee has been fixed at Is. 4dL and is therefore now a silver representative of a gold standard. Australia coins sovereigns of the same weight and fine- ness as England, while in Canada the British sovereign and the United States eagle are both legal tender to any amount. The currency of the United States is much complicated and sadly in need of reform. But the standard is really gold, the units being the gold dollar weighing 25.8 grains and the gold eagle (or ten-dollar piece) weighing 258 grains. An English sovereign exchanges for about 4 dol- lars 87 cents. But though the price of gold is necessarily invariable in countries where there 173 THE STOCK EXCHANGE is a real gold standard, and where the Gov- ernment undertakes to coin gold at a fixed rate by weight, it does not follow that the real price of gold is immutable. As a matter of fact it varies constantly. For the real price of gold is its purchasing power. In a silver- standard country the price of silver is fixed, while the price of gold is the amount you can purchase at any tune in the standard silver coin. Hence in Great Britain, or the colonies, or the United States, when we talk of rising or falling prices we are talking of gold prices. When we say that prices are rising we mean that the value or purchasing power of gold is diminishing, and when we say that prices are falling we mean that its value or purchasing power is rising. It is, therefore, wrong to think of a gold mine as producing a metal whose value is fixed or permanent. Its price in a gold standard country is fixed, but its value varies. Nevertheless, the comparative stability of gold (proved by index numbers which measure it in terms of commodities) does certainly reduce one of the speculative elements that play an important part in mining shares. After gold probably silver and iron and SPECULATIVE SECURITIES 173 coal come next in order of stability; though silver has fallen enormously in the last forty years. From 1868 to 1872 the aver- age price of silver was 60 pence per ounce. In 1902-3 it fetched only 24 pence. Iron mines are now very largely owned by iron and steel companies, of which the hugest example is the Steel Trust of the United States a vast concern built up by Mr. Carnegie and sold on his retirement to Messrs. J. P. Morgan & Co., who formed thereout the Billion Dollar Trust. It is said to own something like half the iron ore of the United States, and it man- ufactures all kinds of iron and steel goods. It has also the distinction of being almost the only United States industrial corporation whose securities are dealt in freely on the London Stock Exchange and quoted on the London Stock Exchange List. As the value of iron is more likely to increase than dimin- ish, its debentures are probably at least as good a security as those of a first-class railway company. A good deal of water has been squeezed out of the ordinary shares by the application of profits to capital; and the profits ought to be increased rather than diminished, if a sweeping reduction of the American Tariff now a possible if not a 174 THE STOCK EXCHANGE probable event should be effected, bringing with it a diminution in the cost of production. That the American iron and steel industry needs no protection is generally admitted. No doubt the most speculative ores are copper and tin, and in these cases the investor must expect his shares to fluctuate as wildly as the metals. A boom in trade usually raises the prices of tin and copper far above their normal level, and a slump like that of October 1907 causes a corresponding dip or depression. Thus between 1904 and the spring of 1907 the price of copper nearly doubled, and that of tin rose about 40 per cent. Tin, however, is more easily cornered than copper, as the output is much smaller. Speculation in the metal soon brings about an inflation of the shares, and when the bubble is pricked many of those who fancied they were successful investors, awake to discover that they have been unsuccessful gamblers. The shadow thrown by commod- ity prices on share prices is often a long one, simply because a small fall may wipe out profits and dividends. Thus the movements of copper company shares are apt to be far more violent than those of copper. The shares of Amalgamated Copper fluctuated SPECULATIVE SECURITIES 175 in 1904 between a lowest of 44 and a highest of 85, in 1907 between a lowest of 43 and a highest of 124. The great Rio Tinto mines of Spain, on the other hand, produce other metals also, and so have been more steady. A comparatively new commodity, rubber, promises to outdo even copper in rapidity of movement; for its price has moved in the last few years from Ss. per Ib. to l&s., and back in the summer and autumn of 1910 from 12s. to 6s. Until recent years practically all the rubber marketed was "wild" rubber; that is to say, it was obtained by tapping wild rubber trees, mainly in Brazil and the Congo. Fortunately for humanity seeing that the collection of wild rubber, especially in the Congo, has been accompanied by the most atrocious barbarities it has been discovered that the "Hevea Brasiliensis," the best variety of rubber tree, can be cultivated successfully in the Malay Peninsula, Ceylon, and some other tropical countries. A few of the first experimental plantations produced remarkable results, and already hi 1908 and 1909 a good many Englishmen and Scots, who had special knowledge of their own, began to invest in rubber plantations. To- wards the end of 1909, as rubber rose in price, 176 THE STOCK EXCHANGE owing to a greatly increased demand from the United States for motor tyres, etc., it began to dawn on the public that rubber investments offered phenomenal profits. Just because a few skilfully managed plantations, with rubber at an exceptionally high price, did really seem to be worth many times the ori- ginal capital, it was assumed that rubber trees could be planted by anybody almost anywhere so as to yield similarly marvellous results. The London company promoters saw their opportunity. The public was evi- dently "on the feed." It wanted rubber shares, and it got them to the tune of many millions in the spring of 1910. There were plenty of unsuccessful planters of tea, coffee, etc., in Ceylon and Malaya, who were de- lighted to sell "suitable" land at some high multiple of its true value. So boards of di- rectors were assembled, printing presses were set to work, and hundreds of rubber planta- tion companies were floated upon a credulous and voracious public. Clerks and office boys, footmen and nursemaids, subscribed with eagerness, and followed the tips of the Daily Menace with the unsuspecting simplicity of their masters and mistresses. It was a sad example of plundering and blundering. SPECULATIVE SECURITIES 177 Never, perhaps, since the Kaffir boom had so many small savings been transferred into less meritorious pockets. But the distinctions between speculation and investment are by no means exhausted by merely regarding the quality of the pur- chase. It is true that a man who buys Erie Common, or Nicaragua bonds, or puts his money into a new rubber company, is a speculator, while a man who buys Pennsyl- vania Stock or German Threes, or puts his money into a new issue of an English munici- pality, is an investor. But there is plenty of speculation in gilt-edged securities; and in ordinary times the typical speculator is the fool who gambles with borrowed money. A man with 100 who buys a Central American "security" and puts it away in the hope that (though it yields him no interest) it will rise before long and enable him to clear out at a handsome profit is far less likely to suffer than the man who buys, say, 5,000 of some good security for the account, and uses his hundred pounds to pay contangoes and differences. How heavy are the odds against this sort of speculator we have shown by statistics in our chapter on Wall Street. But as long as civilisation lasts people will 178 THE STOCK EXCHANGE go on playing this foolish game in the face of all experience. Just as in the case of a lottery the chance of a gain outweighs the probability of a loss. A correspondent of mine once inquired: "Is 5 per cent, necessarily speculative? Is 6 per cent, only to be had from speculations? Is it gambling to buy mining shares which yield anything between 5 and 10 per cent.? Where can the line be drawn?" A stock- broker, being asked wherein consisted the difference between investment and specula- tion, answered that speculation means dealing for carry-over purposes, while investment ap- plies to any case where the purchase is paid for. Another, with a Balfourian turn of mind, held that the real distinction depends on the intention of the purchaser. If a man buys a security and takes it up to hold he is an inves- tor, no matter what the security may be, no matter how rash or prudent the choice. On this view there are different kinds of investors. Thus one buys gilt-edged securities if the chief object is to make absolutely sure of regular dividends; or, again, if the main desire is to have a large income another will buy ordinary and preference stocks with a high yield regardless of risk. Lastly, those SPECULATIVE SECURITIES 179 aim at a future appreciation of capital rather than at immediate or regular dividends, may buy a speculative stock like Grand Trunk, or Steel Common, or some unlucky industrial, which appears to be struggling out of its difficulties, intending of course to watch it carefully and look ahead (which is what the word "speculation" implies), whereas the gilt-edged man prefers something he can sleep over. Upon this view speculation comes in where the buyer's intention is not to pay but to get out with a profit if possible before the end of the account, or after a series of con- tinuations at some future account. Such a man may fairly be said to be playing or gambling with his money, and not dealing with it seriously or permanently as it is the intention of an investor to do. I am not quite satisfied to allow the distinction between speculation and investment to rest upon in- tention. The foundation is rather too slip- pery. It reminds me of the eminent sophist who, at an early stage of our fiscal contro- versy, argued that the question whether a duty is protective or not depends upon whether the Government imposing it in- tended it to be protective. If, as a matter of fact, a man is running risks and is speculating he cannot be called 180 THE STOCK EXCHANGE an investor on the ground that he is unaware of the fact that he is running speculative risks. Perhaps a distinction may be drawn, however, between a member of the outside public and a person who is actually in the market. The moment an outsider begins to borrow, and gets out of his depths, he is certainly gambling or speculating, even if the stocks he is interested in are Consols. On the other hand, a member of the Stock Exchange, who makes a regular business of buying and selling shares, can hardly be called a speculator in any vicious sense if he works with borrowed money. A member of the Stock Exchange almost always has an interest in the market, and probably uses his credit freely; but it is difficult to see much difference between him and a wholesale dealer or mer- chant in wheat, cotton, wool, etc., who often has to rely on his banker for 75 per cent, of the value of his purchases. So much for the difference between specula- tion and investment. But we have still to touch upon the technical side of the subject, which calls for a brief statement of the mode or modes of conducting speculation on the London Stock Exchange; and for this pur- pose we may accept as a practical definition SPECULATIVE SECURITIES 181 of the speculator a person who interests him- self in the temporary fluctuations of shares, who bets or wagers (though not within the meaning of the Gaming Acts) that certain securities will rise or fall. If the contract were a gaming contract within the meaning of the Gaming Acts it would be null and void in the eyes of the law, and neither party would be able to enforce it. The reason why a specula- tive contract with a Stock Exchange broker is legal and enforceable is that the motive of the buyer or seller has nothing to do with the contract. The broker may not, and often does not, know whether his client will take up the purchase, or whether he will actually part with the stock which he instructs the broker to sell. One plain difference between a Stock Exchange speculation and a bet upon a horse is that in the case of the bet one party loses and the other gains, whereas if A commissions B to buy him 100 of shares and they rise to 110, B loses nothing by paying 10 to A on the conclusion of the account. But, generally speaking, when speculation in stocks is carried on with an outside broker or "bucket shop" (i. e. between two principals) the law holds it to be a gaming contract. This is in itself a sufficient reason against speculative persons 182 THE STOCK EXCHANGE dealing with these establishments. If they win heavily they will very likely not be paid. . The reader will probably have a pretty clear idea from previous chapters of the two kinds of speculation for the rise and for the fall. The Bull, who speculates for the rise, buys stock, and the Bear, who speculates for the fall, sells it. The one buys in the hope of selling at a profit; the other sells in the hope of buying back after the stock has cheapened, and so pocketing the difference. A bear operator is said to sell "short," because he sells what he has not got, and when the time comes to fulfil the contract he has to borrow stock. As the fluctuations of stock their ups and downs must on the average over a long period be more or less equivalent, it would follow that the operator least likely to lose would be the person with a "flair" for the market who was just as ready to be a bear as to be a bull. But as a matter of fact the great majority of speculators are always bulls. Optimism seems to be of the essence of speculation. A boom like the Kaffir boom, or the rubber boom, requires the enthusiastic co-operation of a credulous public. The public understands how it may make money SPECULATIVE SECURITIES 183 out of a rise, but it cannot understand how to make money out of a fall. So it will borrow for the rise but not for the fall. On the London Stock Exchange there are monthly accounts or settlements for the Consol market, and "fortnightly" accounts, varying from 11 to 14 days, for other stocks. The actual account or settlement covers four days: (1) the Mining Contango Day; (2) the general Contango Day; (3) the Ticket or Name Day; (4) the Account Day, formerly known as the Settlement, or Pay Day. Ac- count therefore means either the whole "fort- night" or month over which an account runs, or the actual days of settlement, or the Fourth Day of the Settlement. For "Contango" another name is "Continuation" or "Carry over." The two Contango days are of com- paratively modern growth, necessitated by the increasing volume of speculative accounts which require extra days for the settling of bargains. Stocks and shares bought or sold for the current account must be either paid for on Pay Day, or carried over (continued) on Contango Day. The speculator for the rise, who does not wish to cut a loss or realise a profit, instructs his broker to carry over or continue his shares. In that case the trans- 184 THE STOCK EXCHANGE action is postponed for a consideration, and interest is charged for holding over the stock to the next settlement. This interest is called the contango rate. Thus, as a rule, the bull pays a contango rate, and the bear who is speculating for a fall is said to "take in" the securities and to receive the rate or contango. But sometimes in a depressed and bearish market, the bear has to pay a "backwarda- tion" instead of receiving a contango. It is all a question of demand and supply. If there is a demand for money and a plentiful supply of stock there is a contango; if there is a scarcity of stock for delivery against sales there is a "backwardation" to be paid by sellers who are short of stock. If on balance there are securities which cannot be adjusted, the bulls have to pay for an excess, or the bears for a deficiency. In the case of the bears this means either delivering the stock they have sold, or borrowing it from a holder, undertaking to replace it on the next account day. All this is very difficult and technical. But it is worth even the investor's while to master the rudiments of the subject; for temporary causes of market fluctuations have to be allowed for. Enough has at least been said to show that the bull is a fictitious buyer, who borrows money in order to keep his pur- SPECULATIVE SECURITIES 185 chase going, while the bear is a fictitious seller, who borrows stock in order to keep his sale going. Both have to pay commissions, either at each account or at the end of the transac- tion, and both either pay or receive "differ- ences" according as they gain or lose during each account. The student of market fluctua- tions is interested in the contango rate. If it is high it shows that there are a great number of bulls, if it is low or disappears into a "back- wardation" it shows that the bears are pre- dominant. In either event there is likely to be a change in the market as a result of profit- taking along with real sales in the one case and real purchases in the other. But of late years another kind of speculation has become fashionable, which tends to rob stock ex- change operators of this index to the condition and immediate future of a market. Instead of paying contango rates and commissions, a speculator will pledge securities with his bank, and with the loan so obtained will buy other securities and hold for a rise. The advantage of this method is that there is no commission or contango rate. The disadvantage to the mere gambler is that his speculation is limited by the amount of securities he can pledge. Moreover, the scientific operator, who wishes to benefit by foreseeing a fall as well as a rise, 186 THE STOCK EXCHANGE is helpless. If he leans on a banker's loan he can only be a bull; if he wants to sell stock short he must go to a broker and follow the method above described. It remains to describe "options," a favour- ite method with members of the Stock Ex- change and one much in vogue with foreigners. There are three kinds of options. (1) The Put. Smith contracts to pay Jones money for the right to sell him a certain se- curity on a given date, at a named price. (2) The Call. Smith contracts to pay Jones money for the right to buy from him a certain security on a given date, at a named price. (3) The Put and Call, or Double Option, known in Wall Street as a "straddle." Under this the person who buys the option buys the right either to sell or buy the se- curity named on a given date, at a named price. The double option usually costs double as much as the Put or the Call. If the line between common speculative accounts and a bet or wager appears rather fine, it is almost invisible in the case of options to the naked eye of an ordinary ob- server, and hardly visible in the case of a double option, even to the sharp eyes of judges whose lives have been given up to the mak- ing and refining of distinctions. CHAPTER VII WHY THE PRICES OF SECURITIES RISE AND FALL To the economist few inquiries are more difficult or more fascinating than that which is directed to the causes of price movements. It leads him into the remotest abstractions of monetary theory, into subtle disquisitions on the delicate fabric of credit, and some- times carries him through a maze of statistics into imaginary parallels between the recur- rence of sun spots and of commercial crises. To the business man who must always be something of a speculator for he wants to buy for the future when things are cheap and be short of stock when they are dear a scent for prices is of overwhelming practical im- portance. But he can seldom afford to take long views. He proceeds mainly by rule of thumb. The gold problem, and the silver problem, and the credit problem are to him unsolved and insoluble puzzles. Perhaps, 187 188 THE STOCK EXCHANGE even if he could understand the professors, he would not get along very much better. Still there are principles and rules drawn partly from experience, partly from the operations of reason and common sense, which deserve to be plainly stated even though our space is altogether too limited for any exhaustive discussion. In the first place, the prices both of commodities, and securities depend upon the law of supply and demand. If the world's demands for woollen and worsted cloth remain unchanged while the supply of sheep's wool increases, then the price of wool is bound to fall; if they decrease then the price rises. Again, if the supply of wool remains constant, and the demand for cloth rises or falls, the price of wool will rise or fall until an equilibrium is attained. Other things being equal, an increase of supply or a diminution of the demand lowers the price, while a decrease of the supply or an augmentation of the demand raises it. Thus when to meet the expenses of the Boer War our Government issued more than 150 millions of Consols and Exchequer bonds, and Treasury bills, the price of Con- sols fell heavily; and when the war was over, it was found that the proportion by which PRICES OF SECURITIES 189 the National Debt had increased corre- sponded almost exactly with the proportion by which the price of Consols had fallen, showing that the public demand for gilt- edged securities had remained fairly constant. There is therefore at least one fundamental cause of price variations which applies equally to commodities and securities. Again, as was indicated in the preceding chapter, a close parallelism is to be found when you have a security whose rate of inter- est depends on the profit derived from a raw material. The shares in copper mines, or tin mines, or rubber plantations, are obvious cases in point. The market for the shares fluctuates freely with the selling price of the product. It was the enormous rise in the price of rubber from 3s. to 12,?. per Ib. that caused the rubber share boom; and as soon as the prices of rubber at the auctions in Mincing Lane began to fall the downward movement in rubber shares commenced. While rubber prices were at the top, rubber plantation com- panies were floated successfully by the hour. When the slump came the fish ceased to bite, and the company promoter turned his atten- tion from rubber to other things. Another supposed connection between com- modity prices and security prices may be 190 THE STOCK EXCHANGE noted. Except in countries with a silver standard, or in those unhappy communities which are at the mercy of an inconvertible paper currency, prices mean gold prices. Hence a great increase in the production of gold tends to reduce its purchasing power and so to raise prices, while a great diminution in the output tends to increase the purchasing power and so to lower the general level of prices. But in the case of interest-bearing securities this factor is almost negligible; for the value of the security depends primarily upon the rate of interest which it bears, and the rate of interest has no real connection with the relation between the quantity of gold in the world and the quantity of securities. Roughly speaking, the yield of Consols was much the same (about 3 per cent.) in 1750, in 1850, and in 1910; but of course the out- put of gold and the relation between gold and securities, or gold and silver, or gold and credit were so entirely different at the three dates that no scientific mind would dream of attempting to bring these things into com- parison. The fluctuations of the Bank of England's gold reserve are a barometer of the London money market, and gilt-edged securi- ties naturally tend to fall when the short loan PRICES OF SECURITIES 191 and discount rates rise. But the price, or pur- chasing power, of gold has no connection with the price of money or credit. Money may become dearer while the output of gold diminishes, or cheaper while it increases. And here for the sake of clearness, in order to make quite plain what money is and what it does and why its purchasing power varies at different times in the' same country, and at the same time in different countries where different standards or different tariffs are in force, we shall permit ourselves to digress a little upon the meaning of money. Modern monetary systems may be divided into three main varieties gold standard, sil- ver standard, and inconvertible paper. Gold standard countries usually have a token cur- rency of silver and copper or nickel for the convenience of retail purchases, and also bank-notes issued by the authority of the State for the transference of large sums. If the gold standard is absolute, as in England, then bank-notes are absolutely and at all times con- vertible into gold. In France, which retains a system aptly described as limping bimetallism, the notes of the bank of France may be met by that institution in either gold or silver, and as the silver is not worth its face value 192 THE STOCK EXCHANGE a bill on Paris cannot compete with a bill on London for international purposes. But in France and in all the countries of the Latin Union, however large the stock of silver and however much silver predominates in the actual currency, the prices current are gold prices, the purchasing power of the silver coin being not its intrinsic value but its conven- tional value as a fraction of the napoleon or other gold coin having a certain fineness and weight. Thus so many sovereigns ex- change for so many napoleons simply because both are gold coins of a known weight; and so many shillings exchange for so many francs because 20 shillings go to a pound and 20 francs to a napoleon. In China, on the other hand, which (in so far as it has any standard at all) has a silver standard, the prices are silver prices, and their movements are quite independent of movements in gold-standard countries. Thus in a given month the price of wheat or rice may fall in Pekin while it rises in Paris or London. This means that all the world over an ounce of silver will buy more wheat at the end of the month than at the beginning, and, conversely, that an ounce of gold will buy less wheat all the world over, at the end than at the beginning of the month. PRICES OF SECURITIES 193 It also means that the price of silver in gold currency has risen while the price of gold in silver currency has fallen. The worst kind of currency is an incon- vertible paper currency, and some important countries, such as Russia and Brazil, are still on a paper basis. They endeavour however, by keeping a large gold reserve in a central bank, to maintain a fixed relation between gold and paper. Where no such relation is maintained, as in Chile, the most deplorable and fraudulent confusions result. There is, indeed, nothing so demoralising to business as an inconvertible paper currency which fluctuates in accordance with the "dis- cretion" of a corrupt Government. It will be seen, then, that commercial relations be- tween gold-using countries are comparatively simple, but that exchanges between gold and silver standard countries, or gold and paper countries, may be extremely changeful and hazardous. In such cases a speculative ele- ment enters into international transactions. It was this consideration among others that prompted the British Government to regulate the Indian currency and to fix the value of the rupee so that the external trade of India with its chief customers might be simplified, 194 THE STOCK EXCHANGE and its internal prices might not suffer from the fluctuations of a metal so variable as silver had then become. The slight variations of exchange between gold-standard countries depend upon the balance of trade and indebtedness at any given time. If in order to balance indebted- ness it is necessary to send gold from London to Paris or New York the exchange is said to be unfavourable to England and vice versa. This uncertainty, it will readily be under- stood, introduces a slight element of specula- tion into the arbitrage dealings between the leading bourses. But whether it be of gold, or silver, or paper, money in every country of the world is the measure of value and the medium of exchange. The price of a thing is its value as measured in the country's money. When the farmer exchanges his wheat for clothing and machinery, he does not barter. He first sells his wheat for money, and then uses the money to buy what he needs. The proper- ties of good money as the professors rightly declare are that it should be portable, coinable, divisible, indestructible, and stable in value. "Portable" really means "pre- ' eious" as gold or diamonds are precious, i. e. PRICES OF SECURITIES 195 small and costly. "Coinable" means that it can easily be melted, cast into equal sizes, and stamped with a recognisable mark. Thus gold, silver, copper, are ductile and coinable. "Divisible" means that it must not lose value when divided. Thus two half- ounces of gold or copper are worth as much as one ounce. But if a large gem is cut into small ones it may lose most of its value. "Indestructibility" is a most important quality. The wear and tear of a. gold coin is so incredibly small that hardly any saving is effected by keeping the gold in banks and issuing gold certificates like the one-pound notes in Scotland. The possession in so remarkable degree of all these qualities has led to the establishment of gold as the stan- dard of value and measure of exchange in most countries, with silver as the subsidiary coin and copper or nickel as token for petty payments. The last-named property of good money "stability in value" requires a few words of explanation. By what can only be described as a piece of great good fortune the value (that is to say the purchasing power) of gold has been during the last century ex- traordinarily steady. If you look at any par- ticular commodity such as wheat, or wool, 196 THE STOCK EXCHANGE or cotton, or iron, or silver, or rubber, you will find that its prices in gold fluctuate enor- mously from year to year, and sometimes even from month to month. But if you take twenty commodities you find that their prices hardly ever rise and fall together. Thus in the old days, when harvests were all-impor- tant, it used to be said that if wheat were cheap wool would be dear, and vice versa. For when the poor had cheap bread they could buy clothes, and so there was a greatly in- creased demand for wool, and wool necessarily rose in price. Of course a great diminution in the output of gold will ultimately increase its purchasing power and lower the general level of prices, whereas a great increase of the output, such as that which followed the gold discoveries in Australia in the middle, or the gold discoveries on the Rand at the end of last century, must tend to decrease the value and lower the purchasing power of gold, that is to raise the gold prices of commodities. But just because of its indestructibility the mass of gold in the world is so enormous in comparison with what the mines can add to it in a year that the effect of an increase or diminution in output is at first very slight; and whenever the supply is enlarged the effect PRICES OF SECURITIES 197 is apt to be balanced or nearly balanced either by an increase in the production of other com- modities or by an enlarged demand for gold from Governments which have established a gold currency, or from banks which wish to strengthen their reserves of the precious metal. The relation between gold and credit is subtle and difficult. Many able writers main- tain stoutly that gold is the basis of credit, and city men are very fond of attributing changes in the price of money, movements of securities and upheavals of credit to gold production or gold movements. But gold is by no means essential to credit. Credit exists in all civilised countries, where there is a demand for it by substantial persons, without regard to the question whether there is a gold standard or not. The real basis of credit is credibility. Gold cannot make credit or cure credit. Bankers may come to grief at a time when the reserves of gold are un- usually large. A bank with a 25 per cent, reserve of gold against its liabilities may collapse through misuse of credit when a bank with a 5 per cent, reserve, conservatively managed, may be perfectly safe and unassail- able. On the other hand, great gold dis- coveries and a greatly increased output of 198 THE STOCK EXCHANGE gold may cause a general rise of prices, which again may produce a fever of speculation. And as a speculative boom causes a strain upon credit, the money markets of the world become tight and a general crisis and depres- sion will result. Thus there may be, and at times there is, a close causal connection between gold and credit or gold and specula- tion. The best known example is perhaps to be found in the events following the gold discoveries in Australia. But this inquiry would take us too far from our path. But whatever be the relationship of gold to the money market, the money market cer- tainly has a far greater effect upon the prices of securities than upon the prices of commo- dities. For speculative buying and selling affect nearly all classes of stocks and shares; and gilt-edged securities, which can be sold at a moment's notice, are always in demand when money is unlendable in the short loan market. At such a time capitalists who lend in this market are apt to buy consols and kin- dred securities, keeping them until money and discount rates rise. Thus consols tend to rise owing to professional buying, when money is cheap, and to fall, owing to professional selling, when money becomes dearer. There PRICES OF SECURITIES 199 is therefore a real connection between the price of consols and the bank rate; and when the consol market hears of a probable or act- ual rise in the bank rate it usually anticipates this sequence and makes consols a fraction lower. And as a general rule a rise in the bank rate (by enhancing the charges for bor- rowed money) acts in restraint of specula- tion, not only in stocks and shares, but also in grain, cotton, copper, rubber, iron, tin and other commodities which lend themselves to speculation in futures. But by this time a reader may be getting impatient. He may be saying, and probably is saying, to himself: "Why cannot he come to business, and tell me why Stock Exchange prices jump up and down in such extraordi- nary ways without the least regard to gold, or bank rate, or any of these abstruse pheno- mena?" Perhaps the writer has a secret sympathy with this critic. At any rate he will bow to the wish, and give as plain answer as he can to a plain question. In the first place, apart altogether from the causes which affect the prices of com- modities as well as the prices of securities, the value of a security depends mainly upon a quality or attribute which a bale of 800 THE STOCK EXCHANGE cotton, or a ton of coal, or a suit of clothes, does not possess. It is either actually or potentially interest-bearing. This quality is visible in a bond with coupons attached. A bond like that for example which is bought by subscribers to a Prussian State loan will have attached to it quarterly or half-yearly cou- pons, which can be cashed on the date when they become due anywhere in Germany, or in almost any great centre of finance. If the interest is 4 per cent, and the coupons are half-yearly, each coupon attached to a bond for a thousand marks will be exchangeable for 20 marks cash. If the Prussian Government promises to redeem the bond at the end of a period, say of twenty years, at par, it is obvious that at its maturity the bond will be worth par, neither more nor less. So if the purchaser got it at a subscription price of 990 marks he will get the principal back with 10 marks additional. In the mean time it will rise and fall according to the conditions, first of German credit, secondly of the interna- tional rate of interest. If the German Gov- ernment has a long series of deficits, its credit will tend to fall; if it has a long series of sur- pluses and is so able to reduce debt, its credit will tend to rise. But these tendencies may be PRICES OF SECURITIES 201 wholly or in part counteracted by antagonist tic movements of an international character. A great war like that between Japan and Russia destroys a vast amount of capilal and absorbs vast quantities of savings. Money which might have bought German bonds was diverted by high and attractive rates of 5, 6 or 7 per cent, into the new bonds issued by Russia and Japan for the purpose of defraying war expenses. But the Prussian State bond, to which we have referred, is not likely to fluctuate much, and the limits of its fluctuation will be more and more restricted the more nearly it approaches its maturity, when the holder of it is entitled to be paid off in cash. Thus, while the intrinsic value of a coat or a pair of boots depends upon its warmth, durability, fit, etc., the value of a security depends mainly upon (1) the rate of interest, (2) the safety of the principal, (3) the likelihood of the principal or the rate of inter- est either rising or falling. The quality of a good bond is security of a fixed rate of interest and security of principal. The quality of a good share is the probability that it will rise in. value, and that the rate of interest or dividend will improve. Here, then, we have the main causes of a rise or fall in securities. 202 THE STOCK EXCHANGE But the business of Stock Exchange opera- tors is to endeavour to forecast and discount in advance the natural fluctuations of intrinsic value. In the old days, before the telegraph, when postal communications were slow and untrustworthy, fortunes were made by getting early information, or spreading false informa- tion, of victories and defeats, which would enchance or depress the price of Government stocks. Thus the London stock-jobbers in the days of the French wars had private messengers and carrier pigeons to bring them news. In accordance with these reports, the insiders would first buy or sell the funds and then publish the report, and sell what they had bought to the public or buy from it what they had sold. The first Rothschild, or rather the founder of the house, laid the foundations of his immense fortune by getting early news of important events. Nowadays the principle is still the same, but the art of anticipation has been made much more doubtful and complicated. Tele- graphs and telephones are open to all. Every one can watch from day to day, and almost from hour to hour, the progress of wars and revolutions abroad. What everybody reads at the same time in his morning paper is of PRICES OF SECURITIES 203 no particular use to anybody in a speculative sense. Besides, many foreign governments especially the sturdy borrowers keep large funds in London and Paris for the express purpose of supporting the market. Hence in the market for Government bonds, except when insiders know in advance about some pending reorganisation of the finances of some discredited Government, big movements are rare, and the losses or profits they cause are widely distributed. Consequently suc- cessful jobbers in the foreign market of the London Stock Exchange, and in the con- sol market, live and flourish on their daily turnover rather than upon occasional specu- lative scoops, though no doubt their success largely depends upon their skill in acquiring a good store of stocks when they are cheap and upon being short of them when they are dear. When we come to the prices of railroad and industrial stocks the causes of movement are much more difficult to detect, and the possi- bility of making large profits by inside know- ledge is much greater. The newspapers may be the conscious or unconscious tools of the manipulators. In new countries the banks are apt to be a working part of the speculative 204 THE STOCK EXCHANGE machinery. Thus in the United States those who use great fortunes in finance frequently have a controlling interest in a bank, or even in a chain of banks. What is called "a com- munity of interests" may be established which will control perhaps important rail- roads and huge industrial corporations, as well as a number of banks and trust com- panies. The various ways in which such a "community" may manipulate a susceptible market like Wall Street might be made the subject of a long and fascinating volume. Suppose that a powerful group wishes to create the appearance, and even temporarily the reality, of a general trade depression in the United States, or at least to exaggerate a depression which actually exists. This is not at all impossible. The controlled railways may announce and partially carry out a policy of reduced orders for rails, equipment and repairs. They may ostentatiously pro- claim an addition to the number of idle cars. Well-disciplined combinations of steel and textile mills may declare a curtailment of production the closing of some mills, short time in others, etc. Banks may suddenly become ultra conservative; the open accounts and credits of small speculative customers PRICES OF SECURITIES 205 may be closed. In this way a general feeling of despondency can be created. Stocks will fall, partly in consequence of the action of the banks causing a compulsory liquidation of speculative accounts, partly through the voluntary action of speculators and specula- tive investors who think that trade, earnings, profits and dividends are likely to decline. Thus a bear market is created. The syndi- cate or pool or community of interests can now employ huge funds to advantage in pro- fitable purchases of those stocks and shares which fall most and are most responsive to ups and downs of trade. Such a policy of course represents great difficulties and dan- gers. It must be carried out very cautiously, and very secretly, and very honourably as be- tween the members. Leakages are disastrous. And if it is too successful it may create a slump, or a panic, leading to widespread ruin in which the community of interests may itself be seriously involved. For these and other technical reasons, touched upon in our chapter on Wall Street, the great American operators and manipulators do not very frequently enter upon a concerted plan for colossal bear operations. Such a course is unpopular. It offends public sentiment. Rapid ups and 206 THE STOCK EXCHANGE downs of stocks and shares give a general and pleasurable excitement, appealing to the speculative nature and traditions of the people. But a long bearish movement, accom- panied by unemployment, short time, reduced earnings and profits and general economies in the style of living and expenditure, pro- duces or may produce all manner of unpleas- ant consequences economic, social, and political. In fact, there is a sort of moral sentiment against bearish operations on a grand scale, which makes Wall Street (the greatest financial manipulator in the world) the home of the bull who tosses securities up rather than of the bear who tears them down. Big men the so-called giants often boast that they never operate on the short side, never play for a fall. The sketch "bear" operation of a great community of interests, which has been out- lined above, is therefore comparatively rare, cautious and temporary. Wall Street has of course to wait upon circumstances. Some- times it is caught by circumstances. But whether circumstances hurt or hinder, it must always try to adjust itself to economic and political conditions. A political assas- sination, a war, a movement against the PRICES OF SECURITIES 207 trusts, unfavourable decisions in the courts, an unexpected downfall of the favourite party, a catastrophe like the San Francisco earth- quake such events as these may produce an irresistible and unforeseen flood of liquidation against which the strongest combination of bankers and corporation men will struggle in vain. In a general scramble produced by some unexpected event insiders and outsiders are for once on a par. But in such cases there is more likely to be a general loss than a general profit. For in the history of specu- lation the unsuspected and unexpected event is usually a calamity. Real prosperity is built up gradually. The Stock Exchange anticipates and exaggerates it, until the speculative fabric has been reared so high above the real foundation that a decline, which may become a crash, is seen to be inevitable. Generally speaking, with their superior knowledge of banking and trade conditions, the insiders are able to unload at high levels just as they have been able to load at low levels. We may draw from American experience this general conclusion, that by speculating in stocks of a national size and significance the outside public loses far more than it gains. It begins to buy 308 THE STOCK EXCHANGE when they are dear, and it begins to sell when they are cheap. It knows nothing of "rigs," "corners," "pools," and "commu- nities of interest," until long after they are dissolved. But the same person who loses in the general market may gain in the local market. Take, say, the inhabitant of a rising provincial town in one of the Western States. He may lose heavily in Southern, or Erie, or Steels, or Union Pacific. But he may make a modest fortune by judicious investments in local light railways (often called in America "interurban") or industrial corporations, or trading companies, of which Wall Street knows nothing. For the purposes of scientific analysis we may rest our theory of Stock Exchange quotations upon a distinction between prices and values. Prices are temporary; they shift rapidly; values are intrinsic; they move slowly. The price represents the momentary market view of a stock or bond what you can get for it on the exchange if you instruct your broker to sell. The value is the real worth a thing undefinable and impossible to ascertain. If the real value were ascer- tainable and available to the public then price and value would be identical, and in PRICES OF SECURITIES 209 the case of gilt-edged securities we may say that price and value are as nearly as possible identical. For intrinsic values do change, like everything else in this world. They may be said, in the case of bonds and preference stocks, to depend mainly upon 1. The rate of interest. 2. The margin of surplus earning power, or revenue. In the case of a bond there is also, first, the quality of the security pledged as guarantee of the principal, and, second, the date of maturity or redemption. The first may change, as land, buildings, machinery, etc., change hi value. The second is always changing, getting nearer day by day. Both stocks and bonds are, of course, also affected in their intrinsic value by the money market and by the relationship of the supply of capital seeking investment to the demand for capital by new flotations. When the new demand exceeds the supply of new money capital is withdrawn from old issues, and values tend to fall. The intrinsic value of com- mon stock depends also in a supreme degree upon the actual efficiency of the corporation or company, the condition of its plant, the 310 THE STOCK EXCHANGE skill of its management, and the contentment, intelligence and industry of its whole staff. Of course, all these changeful elements of intrinsic value enter into prices. But as prices sometimes fluctuate violently from day to day, and even from hour to hour, it is obvious that they must also be affected by other causes. What these are, or may be, the reader will now be able to supply for him- self. But they may be summed up under one or two heads: 1. False rumours, which have got about either by design or through the careless- ness and mistakes of newsmongers. Very often a depressing rumour is merely a gross exaggeration of some tiny bit of comparatively trifling truth. 2. Rigs, pools, combinations and other technical devices by which the market is either flooded with, or made bare of, a particular stock or groups of stock. A competent, and by no means unfriendly, observer of Wall Street, where manipulation is a fine art, thus describes the class of pro- fessional speculators "who make the stock market their life study and business." "These men base their operations, or try to, on values as measured by income; but PRICES OF SECURITIES they study value so as to be able to buy at less than value, and then they work to sell at as much more than value as they can get. They employ every means in their power to make stocks attractive to investors and other possible buyers when they are 'long' and want to sell, or to make the market appear doubtful or dangerous when they are 'short' and want to buy." This may help the outsider to realise why "for days, weeks, and sometimes for months," prices may represent manipulation rather than intrinsic value. This may also help him to see why a clever man, who really wants to speculate with any probability of success, must become the member of a great Stock Exchange or enter a community of financial interests. It is safe to invest, but it is utterly unsafe to speculate, on intrinsic values. The insider who spends his life in watching and manipulating prices is often a very poor investor, a very poor judge of intrinsic values. The outsider surveying the world's politics and finance and commerce with a calm and unimpassioned judgment may be, and probably is, an excellent investor; but if he attempts to guess at prices by the day and the week without inside knowledge he is sure to come to grief. CHAPTER VHI THE CREATION OF NEW DEBT AND CAPITAL FOB many reasons a good citizen, as well as a good investor, should take some trouble to understand the methods by which govern- ments and municipalities and companies borrow, or obtain new capital. Anybody who can criticise public finance is a useful and influential person. The investor who can criticise prospectuses and balance-sheets for himself is in a strong position; for both are protected by an atmosphere of advertisement from the great majority of newspaper critics. The city journalist is seldom allowed a free hand. It is a bad policy for both parties. The reader of a city page wants neither puff nor blackmail, but honest, discriminating, responsible criticism; and if he does not get it he may either drop the newspaper or drop the idea of subscribing for the issue. What he usually finds in his newspaper, when a 212 CREATION OF NEW DEBT 213 prospectus is advertised, is a colourless sum- mary; and sometimes the prospectus is pre- ceded a few days before by some article, apparently spontaneous, but really paid for, descanting upon the wonderful resources of the region which the new company is going to exploit, or the extraordinary profits likely to be derived by the lucky person who in- , vests, from the very thing on which the prospectus is going to found its appeal. Im- pecunious foreign governments and munici- palities often condescend to bait the ground beforehand with carefully prepared statistics of their prosperity. The beggar's rags excite charity, but the investor's purse is not opened by pity. When a country is on the verge of a new loan it is apt to appear before its credi- tors in very fine raiment. Boasting precedes borrowing. This, of course, does not apply to first-class countries, whose debts are gilt- edged securities. They merely issue state- ments of what money they want, and leave the public to apply to the issuing house or banking syndicate which has undertaken the floating of the loan. This is often the most favourable opportunity of securing an abso- lutely good security. You get your inscribed stock or bond-to-bearer for yourself without 214 THE STOCK EXCHANGE brokerage fees, and it may very likely go to a premium, as a government or local author- ity generally issues at something well below the market price for fear that the loan should prove unsuccessful and injure the prestige of the administration. The same reasoning applies to colonial government securities, and also, perhaps, to the loans of countries of the second rank, so long as the investor is reasonably well informed about their debts and prospects as well as about the technical features of the new loan. Hence there is a very large class of new issues to which, in my judgment, the following sweeping statement by a very able financial critic is not at all applicable: "We arrive inevitably at the conclusion that any investor, who has no special know- ledge to work on, commits a very serious indiscretion by subscribing for any new issue on his own judgment, based on a perusal of the prospectus, and without the counsel and advice of his stockbroker. It cannot be too early grasped by any one who is in a position to invest money that the judicious investor is the investor who rejoices in a good broker, trusts him, and takes his advice." Agreed that the beginning of wisdom in CREATION OF NEW DEBT 215 investment is to contract a business friend- ship with a good broker, who must of course be a member of the London Stock Exchange, or of some good provincial Exchange, it does not follow that the end of wisdom is to trust him blindly, unless, indeed, the broker is abnormally wise and the client abnormally foolish. A person of reasonable aptitude and shrewdness, who can give, say, one per cent, of his business time to looking after his savings, ought to be able to form an opinion of his own; and so long as he contents him- self with good securities yielding from 3j to 4| per cent, he will probably do best by sub- scribing from time to time for suitable issues of government and other stocks. But when securities are cheap, and nothing new offers, you may simply instruct the branch manager of your bank, who instructs his London broker, to buy any security you want. There is no loss in so doing, as it is the practice of the London Stock Exchange brokers to divide their commission with the bank from which they receive instructions. But the advice of Mr. Hartley Withers, which I have quoted and criticised, is sound enough if we limit it to the ordinary company prospectus. These, as he says, "should be scanned in a 216 THE STOCK EXCHANGE spirit of jaundiced criticism, and with the most pessimistic readiness to believe that they are speciously alluring traps laid by some designing financier to relieve the reader of some of his money." In such cases the ad- vice of an expert, or better still, of two, will probably save you from loss; for even the shrewdest and most enlightened persons are sometimes caught by the glittering bait of a prospectus which would never have been issued to the public had it really been the profitable certainty it professes to be. And here we come to a very important con- sideration too often left out of account in discussions of capital issues. I mean that in Great Britain, at all events, there is never any difficulty in raising capital locally or privately for the creation or extension of any business which offers a reasonable probability of large profits. A really good thing from Glasgow, or Yorkshire, or Lancashire, or the Midlands, seldom comes to London to be floated on the public. The insiders naturally keep it to themselves and their friends. Sometimes, no doubt, a brilliantly successful manufacturer or merchant, who has built up his business and wishes to retire, may think that he will get the biggest price for the good-will by turning CREATION OF NEW DEBT 217 the concern into a limited liability company. But what is good for him may be very bad for the public. They are invited, perhaps, to over-capitalise the concern. The vendor, after selling his business to the company, may remain as managing director, but his interest is no longer so keen. He is as rich as any one could need to be whatever the fate of the company. He sold at the zenith of his fortunes, and the investing public, buying, as usual, at the top, this time by subscription, sees the profits declining year by year from "the average profits of the last two years" upon which the prospectus was based. In many of these cases the debentures are a fairly good security, especially if they are well protected by real assets. They are also protected by English law; for companies of this description are usually incorporated under the Companies' Consolidation Act of 1908. Foreign and colonial companies, which raise capital in England and register abroad, are not under our Companies Acts. The laws under which they register may give poor protection to shareholders, and in any case the situation of English shareholders who seek justice from a foreign or colonial court is not often enviable. Besides, such a 218 THE STOCK EXCHANGE company may be seriously injured by un- fair if not confiscatory legislation, of which there have been recent instances in the pro- vince of Ontario and the commonwealth of Australia, to say nothing of South American republics. But a very large part of our capital ex- ports goes into companies like Argentine railways, Ceylon tea, Malay rubber planta- tions and the like, which are duly registered in London; and in view of the fact that the most profitable enterprises at home are never open to public subscription it would be ab- surd to advise investors who have a taste for industrials and commercial ventures to avoid all foreign and colonial prospectuses. For obviously in new countries like Ar- gentina, or old but unexploited countries like China, where capital is very scarce, capital has to be attracted by the offer of favourable terms. Too often, no doubt, the difference between what the lender gives and what the creditor gets is monstrously large. One has heard of a corrupt South American Gov- ernment which sought for money in London and got it apparently at 6 per cent.; for the loan was a 6 per cent, loan issued to the public at par, or thereabouts. But the CREATION OF NEW DEBT 219 issuing house bought the loan at 75 per cent., and after the various representatives, negotia- tors, and officials had handled it, the purposes for which the loan was nominally floated probably did not receive more than 50 per cent, of the sums so greedily supplied by our simple and gullible public. Is it surprising that a loan like this, nominally at 6, really at 12, per cent., proves unreproductive, that the impecunious province or municipality after a year or two fails to pay the interest, that there is a grave scandal, and eventually a composition by which the investors lose perhaps half their subscriptions? Much might be said if we had room for such a digression on the economic signifi- cance of our capital exports. But that the vast importance of this subject may be appreciated we shall here set out in detail the Economist's table of London's public issues of capital for the full twelve months of 1910, when as a result partly of great prosperity, partly of general buoyancy and speculative activity, partly of the very special and extraordinary boom in rubber plantations an amazing record was established over the previous figures for 1909 or any similar period. The British Government in 1910 raised 220 THE STOCK EXCHANGE 21,000,000 by Exchequer bonds for the purpose of repaying the outstanding portion of the War Loan. This sum was not really ANALYSIS OF NEW CAPITAL APPLICATIONS. Description. Total 1909. Total 1910. i British. Government loans 3,840,000 29,152,600 22,072,100 4,899,700 6,590,800 10,624,700 400,000 11,244,500 30,766,700 160,000 4,340,500 3,621,600 3,044,500 nil nil 4,335,900 1,578,200 3,589,400 5,924,200 1,918,200 2,560,100 7,194,500 10,510,400 1,511,300 976,800 825,500 1,025,100 1,709,500 1,938,100 6,001,900 24,595,000 35,631,600 18,431,000 1,627,900 4,308,500 7,119,400 3,715,000 10,096,000 49,974,700 562,400 2,595,700 4,234,500 18,343,100 675,000 250,000 6,086,300 320,400 5,169,900 19,143,800 9,466,400 5,409,300 6,160,000 4,701,000 368,500 131,700 1,503,700 1,313,200 4,600,000 10,789,000 11,116,100 Colonial " .... British Municipal and County loans Colonial Corporations Foreign British railways Indian and Colonial railways . . . Foreign railways Mining Companies South African Other mines Exploration and financial Breweries and distilleries Merchants, importers and exporters Rubber Oil Iron, coal, steel, and engineering . . Electric lighting, power, telegraphs, etc Motor traction and manufacturing . Gas and water Hotels, theatres, and entertainments Patents and proprietary articles . . Docks, harbours, and shipping . . . 182,356,800 267,439,100 CREATION OF NEW DEBT new capital, but a continuation of an old public debt. The Colonial and Indian Gov- ernments were as usual large borrowers. Foreign Governments made less heavy de- mands, thanks to the abstinence of Russia and Japan. The foreign railway figure of close upon fifty millions is practically all for North and South America. The United States lines issued large amounts of bonds, while all the Argentine railways were floating debentures or increasing their preference capital in order to meet the expenditure entailed by their policy of rapid extension. The rubber and oil totals were inflated by the rush of prospectuses at the time of the boom, and the "exploration and financial" figure was also swollen by the many finance companies formed in connection with the same outburst of speculation. The increase in the banks and insurance total is due to the Banco Espanol del Rio de la Plata which doubled its capital. The foregoing table shows the destination of the new capital according to its purposes; the table on our next page shows its destina- tion according to countries. The United Kingdom total includes the Government borrowing, and the capitals of 222 THE STOCK EXCHANGE DESTINATION OF NEW CAPITAL. Whole year 1909. Whole year 1910. United Kingdom total . . . . 18,681,400 60,296,500 British Possessions India and Ceylon 15,336,100 17 991 600 South Africa 11 291 500 3 379 100 Canada 26 814 200 36 882 500 Australasia Other British Possessions . . 11,380,300 9,936,100 13,385,200 20,739,700 Total British Possessions . . . Foreign Countries Russia 74,758,200 9 472 500 92,378,100 3 918 800 Finland 2 328 400 143 000 Denmark 487 500 1 089 000 Sweden 881 000 Norway 381 100 50 000 United States 15 905 400 39 590 100 Brazil 9 218 600 11 813 900 Argentine 21 738 100 22 865 000 Chili 4,098,000 4 684 600 Mexico 9,109,600 5 087 100 Central America 1,591,700 35 000 Other South American Republics China 2,615,800 740 000 3,141,500 1 610 100 Japan 4 723 600 Austria-Hungary f 4 098 000 Bulgaria 3 603 600 Greece 1 572 100 France . 900 000 Turkey 1 431 000 Germany and Possessions . . Dutch East Indies > 5,625,900* ] 794,000 4 382 900 Cuba 1 916 200 Philippine Islands 403 900 Other foreign countries . . . . 1,634,700 Total foreign countries .... 88,917,200 114,764,500 Total for whole year 182,356,800 267,439,100 * Not separately distinguished until 1910. CREATION OF NEW DEBT most of the investment companies formed to conduct or finance operations on the Stock Exchange. The British Possessions figure is nearly 18,000,000 above 1909, owing to the demands of Canada, and the rush of money to the Straits Settlements for rubber cultivation. The only other point requiring mention is the increased flow of capital from England to Europe, which has mostly been applied to developing the oilfields of Austria and Bulgaria. The promotion of a new company in Lon- don has been described with vivacity and veracity by Mr. Hartley Withers, in his recent book on Stocks and Shares; the problems and operations of American promoters in the flotation of new undertakings and the com- bining of old ones into new trusts and cor- porations have been expounded critically and exhaustively by Mr. Edward S. Meade, in his clever study of Corporation Finance. In new countries like Canada, Argentina or Aus- tralia, and in countries like the United States which are still filling up and present ever fresh openings for the profitable employment of new capital, the promoter plays an all-important part in economic developments. The function has been so much abused that the name is 224 THE STOCK EXCHANGE in evil odour. But an honest promoter, with a good eye for a good opening and the skill and credit to utilise his opportunity, is really a public benefactor and deserves to be well rewarded. If he is unscrupulous, floats bad propositions, and takes more than his share, he is a public nuisance, and probably in the long run will suffer the rogue's fate. For, happily, honesty is the best policy; and it pays particularly well in walks where dis- honesty is particularly prevalent. From the standpoint of general utility there is all the difference between the pro- moter of a real new enterprise and the pro- moter of a trust or combination. The former is calculated to increase wealth; the latter is rather likely to diminish it. The former is good for employment, the latter is likely to reduce it. The former increases the good things of the world and multiplies the conveniences of life. The latter aims at restricting them and so increasing their cost. One is addition, the other subtraction. One enlarges the world's resources and enriches the consumer by giving him something new; the other exploits him by establishing a monopoly and so forcing him to pay higher prices or to pay the old prices for inferior CREATION OF NEW DEBT 225 articles. The idea that union means strength and that great size means great profits in industrial combinations has been circulated and believed for a generation. But there are signs that the cult is dying down. A strict combination of all the manufacturing concerns in a protective country may enable them to extract every possible penny of the protective duty out of the consumers. That they should unite for this purpose is the most natural and certain thing hi the world, and to attain the end a promoter is often needed. The reason why they so often have to go to Wall Street, or to some similar financial centre, is that they cannot all agree how the capital shall be watered and how the shares shall be subdivided. Very often, indeed, the scheme or proposition is made by a promoter, and the individual manufacturers are in- duced to come in by tempting offers, or threats of ruin if they stay out. From the investor's point of view, the history of these unions, associations, trusts, or combinations has been generally disappointing. Many of them are waterlogged from the outset. In a free trade country they cannot raise prices on account of foreign competition. In a protected country prices have already been 226 THE STOCK EXCHANGE raised, and what they gain by raising them higher they may lose by diminished con- sumption. The keenness and energy of the individual employer is lost by centra- lisation. Much is often wasted at the outset by buying worthless mills with antiquated plant, merely to close them down. Then other independents crop up who have also to be bought up if there are funds for the purpose. The absolute or relative failure of nearly all the English combines which have been floated on the market is too well known to be insisted upon. In the United States the idea of converting every branch of indus- try into a single trust a consolidation of all competing plants with a view to extract- ing monopoly profits has been carried further than anywhere else. Under the shelter of the tariff huge concerns have grown up; by the zeal of the promoter they have been enlarged into million and billion dollar trusts. In a sense, all the competitors are promoters, and in this sense the transaction has usually been very profitable; for the watering of capital merely means that the promoters have received from the public far more money than the consolidated concerns are worth. CREATION OF NEW DEBT 227 In some celebrated cases, after a series of years in which the common stock has received no dividends and the preferential sharehold- ers have been only irregularly paid, a good deal of water has been squeezed out and fortunes have been made by large operators who bought stock in years of depression. But I am inclined to think that if all the industrial combinations promoted and marketed in the United States and listed in New York or other American Stock Exchanges could be examined historically from the standpoint of the original investors and subscribers (leaving out those who received some part of the pro- motion profits in stock) the record would prove disappointing. The promoter who is consolidating com- petitive interests into a trust or association may appeal for support on various grounds: 1. Competition will be eliminated and so prices can be raised and controlled. In times of depression prices can be maintained by curtailing output and closing factories. 2. A centralised management can effect the economies that belong to large operations. Superfluous persons can 28 THE STOCK EXCHANGE be dismissed regardless of local claims. 3. The size of the concern should enable it to get very favourable terms from railways and from producers. A large buyer can afford also to deal sternly with small customers who seek to cancel orders or "readjust contracts" when trade becomes bad. 4. A large combination is in a better position to resist the demands of organised labour. All these propositions are plausible, but all contain a mixture of truth and error. To the last one, for instance, it may be urged that just as it is easier to deal with organised labour than with undisciplined labour, so labour leaders can extract terms more easily from the executive of a federation than from individual employers. Moreover, if a com- bination in restraint of trade deals harshly with labour it becomes unpopular and may become the object of legislative or adminis- trative attack. The economy of large opera- tions is often more than off-set by central mismanagement. The directors of a big trust may be directors of banks and many other CREATION OF NEW DEBT 229 concerns. Their income may be derived mainly from financial operations. Their interest in, and the time they can spare to, the trust may be, and probably is, very small. In any case, half-a-dozen men sitting in a central office and issuing orders to local factories of which they have no practical ex- perience are usually a poor substitute for the individual manager who has made the busi- ness by his own exertions and is now enjoying the capital sum for which he has exchanged his concern. The ingenuity of the corporation lawyer who frames the trust will overcome all the technical difficulties, but it is generally found that a great concern cannot be fairly capitalised. The proper basis for determining the value of all the plants together would be the earning power of each individual plant averaged over a series of years. But a little reflection will show that when it comes to capitalisation all will expect to get more than their concerns are really worth, and all will succeed in various degrees. Very often the trust promoter is forced to "fight for his own hand," as one of them expressed it, through- out a long and complicated course of dip- lomacy, associating with the stronger mem- bers of the trade and squeezing others. He 230 THE STOCK EXCHANGE has to keep his eye, of course, on the public, and in most cases, as Mr. Meade puts it, his business is "to buy plants from their owners at one price and sell them to the investor at a higher price." When, by alliance, persuasion, and coercion, the promoter has "assembled his proposition," he will approach bankers. In important cases a syndicate will be formed and a financial plan devised, consisting usu- ally of bonds, preference and common stock. In the case of a consolidation, bonds are usu- ally issued in part payment to the individual concerns. Thus, when the Steel Trust was floated by Messrs. J. P. Morgan, Mr. Carne- gie and his associates were in such a command- ing position that they were able to demand successfully no less than three hundred million dollars of first mortgage bonds. Preference stocks also play a very important part. Thus large industrial companies in the United States (mostly consolidations) supply at the present time over one hundred issues of pre- ferred stocks. When a company is floated to develop some new traffic or industry, the promoter is often an engineer with banking connections. The promoting engineer is defined by Mr. Meade as "a firm or corporation engaged in the busi- ness of building trolley roads, power plants, CREATION OF NEW DEBT 231 railroads; doing all kinds of engineering and construction work within a certain field." Such firms, especially in London and other great money centres, will often have a large capital as well as a big credit. They will possess a skilled organisation of engineers, chemists, lawyers, and accountants. British, German, and French engineering and promot- ing firms of this type are prepared to under- take contracts and promote enterprises in all parts of the world. There are great advan- tages in an engineering contractor being as- sociated with and interested in the success of a great engineering enterprise. But it is not de- sirable that after the company has been formed it should be controlled by its contrac- tor, because the contractor is always inter- ested in construction. If, for example, the dominating interest in a railroad company is the contractor, he is apt to be always extending the line, regardless of shareholders' interests, in order to provide his own firm with work. Small flotations usually originate with local men, especially landowners who desire to sell their land on favourable terms for coal, oil, or similar propositions. Among the preparations made for the float- ing of a new company, or for an issue of new 232 THE STOCK EXCHANGE capital by an old one, none is more important than the underwriting of shares. In few cases can a promoter afford to appeal to the public until the sale of his wares has been thus guaranteed. By acting as underwriters for new issues, City capitalists often make very large profits, though from time to time, when the public fails to bite, they stand to lose. Thus when a new issue is unsuccessful, or partially unsuccessful, it is announced that the underwriters have been left with, say, 75 per cent, on their hands. A few years ago the underwriters in ordinary cases merely engaged to take any shares which might not be subscribed by the public, so that such a result would have been thought very disap- pointing. But now it is becoming more and more common for the issuers to stipulate that the underwriters shall actually purchase at the price named whatever quantity of shares they may have underwritten; so that, whereas the old form of an underwriting con- tract merely obliged the underwriters to take a fixed amount or a fixed proportion condition- ally, the new form obliges them to take it absolutely. In other words, there is a "firm," as distinct from a hypothetical undertaking. The underwriters are allotted then- shares CREATION OF NEW DEBT 233 and actually receive them. But whether they underwrite "firm" or no, the vast majority of Stock Exchange men who engage in this business buy the new issue for the purpose of selling it at a profit to their clients. .And this they can usually do, if it is at all promising; for even if, after the stock is issued, it stands at a discount of 2 per cent., yet, if it has been underwritten at a discount of 5 per cent., an underwriting broker or banker can still dispose of it gradually to his clients on very satisfactory terms. But be- sides the underwriters who underwrite in order to sell as quickly as possible the specu- lative underwriters there is also now a very large and important class of underwriters, who underwrite good securities with a view to holding them as investments. Conspicuous among these are the insurance companies, which have grown to be very great and im- portant factors in the capital and investment market. For short dated issues such as the short term notes, with which London is often flooded by American railroads and industrial corporations, and even by American cities, the banks compete with the insurance com- panies. These short term notes " mature "- i. e. are repaid at various dates, and an in- 234 THE STOCK EXCHANGE surance company often likes to have a security of this sort, which will pay good interest and mature, or fall due, in a year when an extra amount of revenue will be required for bo- nuses. Banks, again, when money is cheap and plentiful, find that by purchasing such notes they can get a run of comparatively high interest for a few months. But an in- surance company does not need to keep its capital liquid in the same way as a bank. It is a great investor. In fact, in the case of the biggest companies the investment department is becoming as important as the insurance de- partment. By underwriting good issues an insurance manager does better, as a rule, than by buying securities in the open market; for in this way he gets them well below the market price. That part of a new issue, therefore, which is bought by an insurance company is taken permanently off the market and stowed away. And it will be held firmly for the sake of the interest, without much regard to its price fluctuations, for an indefinite period, un- less (as sometimes happens) some great con- flagration like the San Francisco disaster forces a company to realise part of its holdings. Hence it often happens that, when a new issue has to be taken very largely by the underwrit- CREATION OF NEW DEBT 235 ers, it is better placed and more firmly held than when it is over-subscribed by the public; for the outsiders who subscribe for new issues are often "stags," who apply for far more than they could really buy in the hope of be- ing able to sell shortly afterwards at a pre- mium. In that case the premium rapidly runs off under a fire of sales, and the stock may stand for a long time at a discount. There is, of course, a vast difference be- tween good underwriters and bad ones. Dur- ing the rubber and oil boom, in the early months of 1910, there was a great rush of pop- ular issues many of which afterwards proved to be bubble companies. In that case, as Mr. Withers recently pointed out in a valuable article (Investor's Monthly Manual, Oct. 1910) underwriting is "a simple and easy method of putting a nice cheque into one's pocket by merely undertaking to do something which one is most unlikely to be asked to do." Most interesting stories, he adds, are told of profits so made and of resultant banquets by more or less impecunious gentlemen in the West End, who, having a sort of semi-con- nection with the City, acquired the privilege of underwriting, on generous terms, blocks of shares in rubber or oil companies for which 236 THE STOCK EXCHANGE they could not possibly have paid had they been called upon to do so. "This sort of un- derwriter is merely an impudent fraud, like anybody else who takes money in return for a promise that he could not keep. Luckily, he can only make his appearance when the public is demented by one of its periodical speculative manias." Of course the weak underwriters of this class are often caught, especially towards the end of a boom when the public is glutted. Many poor City clerks, as well as smart West Enders, were left at the end of the rubber boom with quantities of unsaleable scrip, liable to heavy calls which they could not meet. A respectable new ven- ture will never make underwriting arrange- ments of this sort. It may perhaps be legiti- mate, where the risk is high, for the under- writers' commission to run up to 10 per cent.; but where it runs up to 25 per cent, the sub- scribing public which knows nothing of all this is obviously being swindled. In any case, whenever the underwriting arrange- ments, made behind the scenes, do not ensure that the shares underwritten can be taken up and paid for in short, whenever the under- writers are not men of substance and credit the subscribing public is shamefully wronged. CREATION OF NEW DEBT 237 It would be greatly to the advantage of the City if these scandals could be made im- possible by legislation. There are, therefore, two distinct types of underwriters shading off into one another: (1) The speculative underwriter, who under- writes to sell; and (2) the investing under- writer, who underwrites as a real purchaser, to obtain and hold securities. Both kinds do the work for a commission by means of which they obtain the shares at anything from 1 to 25 per cent, (or even more) below the nominal price. The solid underwriter is of course mainly concerned with good public loans, home, foreign, and colonial, or bond issues of railways and industrial companies, whereon the commission or discount is not very large. But it is one of the weakest points of a prospectus that it does not dis- close either the price at which the issue has been taken by the issuing houses, or the com- mission which has been paid to underwriters. Information of this sort, however, generally leaks out in the City, and is conveyed by the best informed City editors to the public. It is generally provided in the prospectus of a new issue, whether by a public authority or by a private company, that a subscriber 238 THE STOCK EXCHANGE shall pay by instalments spread over several months. This method, which is now practi- cally universal, was introduced by the British Government during the eighteenth century, and in some cases a system of underwriting was adopted in those early days of public borrowing either in order to enrich favoured individuals or for the more legitimate purpose of ensuring success. In the tenth edition of Mortimer's Every Man his own Broker, issued in 1775, the system then in vogue is described as follows: "When the Parliament has voted these supplies, and resolved on the ways and means of raising them, a subscription is set on foot, and is either open to the public, in which case every responsible person is at liberty to apply, by a proper letter to the right honourable the Lords Commissioners of the Treasury, for leave to be admitted to be a contributor, naming in his letter the sum he desires to contribute; or else it is private, that is to say, a certain number of persons of fortune have agreed to be answerable for the whole sum to be subscribed; and have made the required deposit. In this case, the only step to be taken, by those who are not of the num- ber just mentioned, is to apply to them for CREATION OF NEW DEBT 239 such part of the subscription as you want, which if you are a particular friend, they will, perhaps, spare you without any premium, or for a very small one; for it is not to be presumed, that any inconsiderable number of men, who have subscribed for the whole sum to be raised, intend, or can keep it, but that they propose to include in their subscrip- tion, all their friends and acquaintances. Sometimes the subscription lies open to the public at the bank or at the Exchequer, and then every person is allowed to subscribe what he thinks proper; and if, upon casting up the whole, there is a surplus subscribed, as has generally been the case, the sum each subscriber has subscribed, is reduced in a just proportion, so as to make in the whole, the sum granted by Parliament. "As soon as conveniently may be, after the subscription is closed, receipts are made out, and delivered to the subscribers, for the several sums by them subscribed. . . . The first deposit is generally of fifteen per cent., and is made on or about the time of sub- scribing; the second is about a month after, and so on till the whole is paid in, which is generally in October; each monthly payment being either ten or fifteen per cent. Those, 240 THE STOCK EXCHANGE who chuse to pay the whole sum before the appointed day of payment, are allowed three per cent, from the time of such payment to October. The subscription receipts thus paid in full, are called in the Alley, Heavy-Horse, because the gentlemen of the Alley can make greater advantage than three per cent, by the Light-Horse, and therefore they will not give so good a price for the Heavy; nay, some of them will have absolutely nothing to do with it, for this reason, that they can buy a thou- sand pound, Light-Horse (with one payment made) for the same money as one hundred pounds heavy, and by buying for the Light, they have an opportunity of sporting with, and gaining a profit on, a nominal thousand, for the same money that it would cost to buy an hundred Heavy. Light-Horse, therefore, is the commodity to jobb with." The advantage of "Light-Horse" to specu- lators, of course, was that a small amount of cash would buy a large amount of paper value. After the first payment, for example, a person could buy for 75 a receipt for 500 scrip, and for much less if, according to custom, the value of the lottery ticket were deducted. No doubt, many purchasers of Light-Horse were persons of small capital who bought for CREATION OF NEW DEBT 241 the rise and were anxious to sell or get out as soon as possible. When a cheap and tempt- ing prospectus appears nowadays it is always over-subscribed in the same way by small operators who sell out the moment a good premium is established. But sometimes they are disappointed. The issue does not go to a premium. In that case, writes Mortimer, the disappointed gambler in Light-Horse scrip "may put it out to nurse, that is, deposit it in the hands of some moneyed man, who for a proper consideration will pay upon it and keep it as his security till the proprietor has an opportunity of selling it to advantage." Those acquainted with the problems of modern banking, and the competition be- tween commerce and the Stock Exchange for accommodation, will be interested to know that 150 years ago "a branch of business perhaps as considerable as any amongst the bankers near the Alley" was the taking in of various kinds of paper, such as scrip, long annuities, etc., in pawn. At one time, in- deed, the pawning of scrip became so large and profitable a business that the bankers and bill brokers of Lombard Street "openly refused to discount bills, to the great detri- ment of the commercial interest." CHAPTER IX CAUTIONS AND PRECAUTIONS IN the preceding chapters Stock Exchange securities have been discussed principally from the standpoints of London and New York. In some respects Paris and Berlin are equally interesting, especially in their banking ramifications and in the alliance dangerous to both which public diplomacy has con- tracted with high finance. But if the financial panorama of the old world and the new had to be studied from two centres only, there is no doubt that Lombard Street and Wall Street should be chosen. The city of London, with all its vast and delicate financial organi- sation clustering round the Bank and the Stock Exchange and Lloyds, directing, con- trolling, guiding or influencing rates of in- terest and discount, rates of exchange and rates of insurance in all parts of the world, is unique as a market for commodities, a market for stocks, and a market for capital. Here all these things are bought and sold on 242 CAUTIONS AND PRECAUTIONS 243 an international scale. It would be a mis- take to say that London is not speculative. For one thing the City entertains too many canny but venturesome Scots to allow such a charge to be brought. But there is so much old wealth, such long traditions of caution and stability, so keen a sense of re- sponsibility among those in command of the leading banks and houses, that London, with its unequalled annual surplus or overflow of capital for export, should be reckoned rather as the capital city of banking and invest- ment than as the chosen home of speculation. That second title belongs of right to New York. It borrows money from across the Atlantic in order to lend it to the West. Its Stock Exchange list is reprinted hourly by the tape machine from New Orleans to San Francisco, and from San Francisco to Mon- treal. Over ninety millions of people are animated by the palpitations of Wall Street. This ferment of speculation over so vast a continent has its good and its evil sides. At times it becomes an international danger, and ends in a panic which sweeps away thousands of apparently flourishing concerns, scattering gloom over the trade and securi- ties of the whole world. But the rapid de- 244 THE STOCK EXCHANGE velopment of material resources, mining, agri- culture, manufactures, transportation, is of necessity associated with speculation. For speculation in the best sense is the investment of capital and the use of credit to finance enterprises which promise to yield handsome profits. But for a verdant and evergreen faith, salted with the love of risk and adven- ture for their own sakes, how could mountains be bored and waters bridged? If there were not superstition there could be no religion, if there were no bad speculations there would be no good investments, if there were no wild ventures there would be no brilliantly success- ful enterprises; the same sort of sentiment which gave Dr. Cook a temporary notoriety invested Nansen with permanent fame. New York, then, must be valued fairly, not as a sort of gambling hell, but as a nerve centre of North American enterprise. It is the ultimate temple and court of high finance before which nearly all important local propositions for large enterprises through- out the States of the Union, and often far beyond its northern and southern bounda- ries, ultimately bow the knee. Nevertheless, those cautions and precau- tions which it has been our purpose to throw CAUTIONS AND PRECAUTIONS 245 in the path of rash investment, are by no means to be slighted merely because material enterprise, enriching the world and spreading the comforts of civilisation through hitherto inhospitable and barren regions, is necessarily based upon the credit provided by the banker and the money provided by the speculator. Those who have saved money by their own enterprise and thrift are fools if they lend it gladly on promises of romantic profits in distant regions. It is a good principle to remember that if an enterprise is really very promising, money will be found somehow locally, by those who have seen it with their own eyes. When doubtful propositions have to be floated the promoters always calculate that distance will lend enchantment to the view. They try to raise their money among people who can only read their prospectus. Of course there are not many hard and fast rules in business life; but there are some in connection with investment with which the reader of these pages will have become acquainted. In recapitulating some of them we may be able to add a few further hints. First of all, an investor may of course be well advised to insure himself against death, 246 THE STOCK EXCHANGE sickness, fire, burglary, etc., so reducing that annual surplus which would otherwise be available for investment proper. Then, sec- ondly, he may use another part of his surplus to buy his own house by instalments. Often, though not always, he may thus make a very high rate of interest on his money; and if in the neighbourhood in which he lives rents are tending to rise year by year, he may look not only for a high rate of interest but for an ap- preciation of his principal. But when he comes to the purchase of a Stock Exchange se- curity he should be careful, in the first place, that he buys it from a respectable quarter, i. e. from an official broker of a good Stock Exchange, or from a respectable banker, who acts as an intermediary. Any one who is in the happy position of being able to invest frequently should certainly be in touch with a good broker, or better still, with two, if eti- quette does not stand in the way. He may very well ask his broker to send a short list of securities of various types and yields to com- pare with his own list. The advertisements and circulars which come by post from unau- thorised brokers and bucket shops (often with some grand title to suggest that they are "investment" companies or "bankers") CAUTIONS AND PRECAUTIONS 247 should be treated with the same respect as a German invitation to a lottery. Some- times these companies have the impudence to ask you for a list of your investments, and to promise you that if you will take their advice they will be able to exchange them for equally good securities which will yield you one or two per cent. more. And they will charge you no commission! This is very kind indeed, and many simple folk respond to their appeal. Probably the so-called "bank" or "investment" company has bought a lot of rubbish, usually called "bonds," from shaky industrial concerns, or from half bankrupt states and municipalities of South America. They have bought, let us say, the 6 per cent, bonds of the Yoko Silk Company in Japan at 60, which they sell you at 90, the 5 per cent, bonds of the Brazilian Province of at 55, which they sell you at 75, and a few other similar bargains. They tell you that if you then spread your risks scientifically over different countries you will be perfectly safe. You perhaps do not realise that none of these securities which you are ad- vised to buy are quoted in the London Stock Exchange. If they were, the game would be impossible. As it is, you cannot know what 248 THE STOCK EXCHANGE your philanthropic company actually gave for them, and if asked they explain that officially quoted stocks never go so cheap as those they are able to offer you. Some time after you have been gulled you may be forced to sell one of these bargains, and then, if your company is still in existence, it will tell you that all the stocks you bought from them have fallen heavily in price, or at least that they are not immediately saleable. They will perhaps promise to make inquiries and try to find a purchaser. Your best hope then is, by threatening them with exposure, to force them to pass on the rubbish they have sold you to some equally foolish and inexperienced person. That is not a pleasant thought. But if you can persuade a bucket shop to buy its wares back at any sort of price, you may be sure it will not keep them in its larder. The theory of geographical distribution is perfectly harmless so long as you keep to good marketable securities for which there are official quotations. But there is very little in it. It is a mistake, of course, to keep all your money in one security or in one trade, or in securities connected with one trade. But it would be silly to interpret the proverb about eggs so literally that one should make CAUTIONS AND PRECAUTIONS 249 a special effort to scatter one's money in tinjr parcels over the face of the globe. Another important caution is to beware of shares not fully paid up. Many bank and insurance shares are of this description. The majority are safe; but the possible risk is too serious for any one of moderate means to undertake. On the other hand, good shares of this kind, with a liability of perhaps from 75 to 50 per cent., which might be called up in an emergency, yield a rather high rate of interest, and you can insure against a call at a very trifling expense. If you have insured yourself at Lloyds you can hold shares of this description and sleep on them comfortably. Apart from circulars, the investor may easily be trapped by what he reads in news- papers, especially the concealed advertise- ments which often appear as articles in organs not known to be disreputable. Every one who has had any experience of the press knows the difficulties and dangers, the temptations and embarrassments, by which its proprietors, managers, and editors are surrounded. In Paris, if not elsewhere, there are newspapers (which may be politically square) whose financial columns are let to an advertising company! I do not know of any sovereign. 250 THE STOCK EXCHANGE remedy. It is only by degrees that a reader can discover which papers are independent and which are not, which are flabbily opti- mistic, which are hopelessly and slavishly corrupt. Newspapers are apt to shift from one class to another as they change their pro- prietors, management, and staff. Sometimes a respectable journal, finding its advertising revenue dwindle, will abandon criticism of prospectuses, in order not to give offence. I am glad to think and to feel sure that this policy is bad in the long run. The loss of reputation and interest will prove far worse for revenue than the slight temporary disad- vantages which it is sought to obviate. The three qualities an investor should demand and look for in his newspaper are 1. Honesty, i. e. unpurchasable candour. . Sound information about conditions at home and abroad. 3. Criticism directed not merely to the dark side of the picture, but to all the con- siderations, good, bad and indifferent, which affect security values. It is right that newspaper criticisms of City finance should err, if at all, on the side of pessimism. For the average reader errs on the other side. It is the crude and greedy CAUTIONS AND PRECAUTIONS 251 optimism of a speculative public that allows so many transparently false ventures to be successfully launched. But if the number of honest newspapers and of journalists finan- cially competent could be multiplied in all parts of the world, vast sums now wasted could be saved, and many a rogue's avenue to affluence would be closed. To found and maintain a good newspaper is one of the most useful, public spirited, and patriotic services that a man can perform. But it is a task not to be lightly undertaken. For the rest, the investor, having found his Stock Exchange, his broker, and his news- papers, and bearing in mind such precepts touching bonds, preference stocks, etc., as we have been able to provide, will, if he be wise, above all remember not on any account to allow his investment to exceed his capital. The so-called investor who buys ten times more than he owns is a miserable, nervous, and timid creature; for every movement in his "investments" causes him ten times the amount of perturbation which it ought to cause him. He is always cutting losses, or jumping at small profits, instead of letting his original judgment stand. Besides, na investor, unless he be an absolute insider. 252 THE STOCK EXCHANGE could hope to make money after borrowing at 4 or 5 per cent, and paying commissions. It is like playing against the bank at Monte Carlo. The essence of investment is that it should be for long periods, with the reser- vation that the investor should keep a suf- ficiently close watch on his holding to be ready to take advantage of any substantial rise which, in his judgment, is not likely to last. People should take care to keep abreast of political and economic events in foreign countries in which they are financially in- terested. You may have holdings in Spain, Greece, Turkey, Egypt, Japan, China or South America. In such cases you should keep an eye on communications in respectable newspapers dealing with affairs in these countries, more especially if they are critical. | Rose-coloured accounts, accompanied by open r or concealed advertising, are more than worthless. They rather provoke suspicion; for they suggest that a show of prosperity and strength is being made in London for the purpose of some impending credit operation. GLOSSARY Account Day. The last of the three days on which London Stock Exchange bargains are settled. Allotment. When a new loan is issued to the public sub- scriptions are invited. If the loan has not been oversub- scribed the applicants receive allotment in full. If it has been oversubscribed the amount has to be allotted, or divided up, among the applicants. Arbitrage. Stock Exchange transactions between two coun- tries. If the same stock is cheaper in New York than in London it may pay a London operator to execute an order in New York, and vice versa. Similar transactions be- tween the London and the Provincial Stock Exchanges are called shunting. Bear. An operator who sells "short," with a view to re- purchasing at a profit. Bonds. Securities representing the debts of a public authority or of a company, and in the latter case often secured by a mortgage. They are usually to "bearer," with interest coupons attached, and are transferable by delivery. Broker. This term is used in a special sense for a member of the London Stock Exchange who buys or sells securities for the public, from or to the jobber. Bucket Shop. A term of reproach sometimes applied gener- ally to all outside brokers not connected with a Stock Exchange. Some are unloading shops which advertise to catch investors; others are gambling shops which offer facilities to speculators. Butt. An operator who buys stock for which he does not mean to pay, with a view to reselling at a profit. Bullion. Gold or silver in bars. Carry Over. The continuation of speculative bargains from one account to another on the London Stock Exchange. Coupons. Interest tickets attached to bonds, which the owner cuts off from time to time as they become due for payment. Dealer. See Jobber. 253 254 THE STOCK EXCHANGE Debentures. A general term for bonds, but not necessarily or usually including a mortgage. It usually means a floating charge on the assets of a company. The leading English debentures are the debenture stock of English railways. In case of default on interest the debenture holders (though there is no mortgage on the line) can put the property in the hands of a receiver. Deferred Stocks. Stocks which can only receive interest after a dividend has been paid on preference and preferred ordinary. Dividend. Divisible profit; the interest declared from time to time by a company on its shares, and paid to its share- holders. GiU-edged Securities. A term applied to Consols and other first-class securities which are regarded as quite safe. Jobber. Jobbers, or dealers, are members of the London Stock Exchange who stand in the house and "make prices," buying from, or selling to, the brokers. Kaffirs. The Stock Exchange name for South African mining shares. Liability. For shares not fully paid up the holder is liable in case the company fails or requires more capital. Thus, on a ten pound share, with one pound paid, the liability is nine pounds. Liquidation. The winding up of a company in bankruptcy. To liquidate is to realise or sell out securities. A liquid asset is a security which can easily and quickly be turned into cash. Margin. The excess percentage over and above the market price of a security deposited with a banker in return for a loan. Thus a banker may require a five per cent, margin of protection on Consols, and ten per cent on railway stocks. Margin is sometimes called "cover." When a security depreciates and the margin runs off, more cover is required, otherwise the security will be sold. Options. (See p. 186). Ordinary or Common Stock. The lowest class of security except where deferred stock has been issued. Ordinary ranks after preference, as preference ranks after debenture for interest. Par Value. The face value of a stock. The par value of a ten pound share is 10, that of a hundred pound share 100. Preference or Preferred Stock. Securities which rank before ordinary or common stock for dividend. Prospectus. A published invitation to the public to invest in a new loan or company. GLOSSARY 255 1 Put an& Call. (See p. 186.) Rente. A French term for debt or public funds. French rentes are the equivalent of British Consols. Script. The paper receipt for a new security, on which only one or two instalments have been paid. Short. Selling "short," i. e. selling what one has not got. tr (See Bear.) Sinking Fund. A fund set apart for the redemption of debt. Trustee Stocks. Securities in which Trustees are authorised by law to invest. Turn. The jobber's turn is the difference between the prices at which he will buy and sell a security. Underwriting. An agreement to take a new capital issue at a price below that at which it is offered to the public. Th discount is the underwriter's commission. Watered Stock. A company which increases its nominal cap- ital without improving its assets is said to water its stock. BIBLIOGRAPHY 1. Stocks and Shares, by Hartley Withers (London: Smith Elder & Co., 1910). This, like the author's previous treatise, "The Meaning of Mone immediately became a standard book. Mr. Withers, as City Editor of Morning Post, has of course an intimate acquaintance with London finance, which appears in every page of this scholarly and brilliant volume. 2. Stock Exchange Law and Practise, by W. A. Bewes (Lon- don: Sweet & Maxwell, 1910). An excellent book addressed to lawyers and professional men, which large Investors should place on their shelves for reference. It deals with the rules and regulations of the London Stock Exchange, Its relations to provincial exchanges, and to English law as Interpreted by the courts. 3. The History, Law and Practise of the Stock Exchange, by A. P. Poley and F. H. Carruthers Gould (London: Pitman & Sons, 1907). This Is an alternative to the preceding work In our list, and has consid- erable merits of its own. 4. Stock Exchange Securities, by [Sir] Robert Giffen (London: George Bell & Sons, 1877). Essays by the celebrated economist and statistician on the causes of fluc- tuations in Stock Exchange Securities. 5. Stock Exchange Investments in Theory and Practise, by Joseph Burn, 1909 (London: C. & E. Layton, 1909). An admirable course of lectures delivered to students at the Institute of Actuaries, full of historical Information and practical guidance. 256 THE STOCK EXCHANGE 6. A Plain Guide to Investment and Finance, by T. E. Young (London: Macdonald & Evans, 1908). The first part of this useful book contains a good deal of practical guidance to investors. 7. Every Man His Own Broker, by J. Mortimer. The first book on London Stock Jobbing. The first edition was published In 1761. 8. The Work of Wall Street, by Sereno S. Pratt (New York: D. Appleton & Co., 1910). The book was written in 1903, and though not brought up to date in this edition, is by far the best description I have read of the Wall Street system. 9. Forty Years of American Finance, by A. D. Noyes (New York: G. P. Putnam's Sons, 1909). A trustworthy history of American finance from 1865 to 1907. 10. Corporation Finance, by Edward S. Meade (New York: D. Appleton & Co., 1910). A most illuminating work to which the present writer is very much in- debted. It is chiefly concerned with the promotion and marketing of Ameri- can railroad and industrial securities. 11. The History and Methods of the Paris Bourse, by E. Vidal. A learned and acute study published at Washington in 1910 by the National Monetary Commission of the United States (61st Congress, 2nd Session, Document No. 573). 12. London Stock Exchange Commission. Minutes of Evi- dence. London, 1878 [C. 2157. 1]. This contains the evidence of many official and leading members of the London Stock Exchange, with important descriptions and criticisms of its organisation and methods thirty-three years ago. HENRY HOLT AND COMPANY THE HOME UNIVERSITY LIBRARY of Modern Knowledge The editors are Professors Gilbert Murray, H. A. L. Fisher, W. T. Brewster and J. Arthur Thomson. Jackets in variegated colours . Cloth bound , good paper, clear type, 256 pages per volume, bibliographies, indices, also maps or illustrations, where needed. Each complete and sold separately. Per volume, LITERATURE AND ART. [Order Number] 73. EURIPIDES AND HIS AGE. By Gilbert Murray, Regius Pro- fessor of Greek, Oxford. 101. DANTE. By Jefferson B. Fletcher. Columbia University. An inter- pretation of Dante and his teaching from his writings. 2. SHAKESPEARE. By John Masefield. "One of the very few in- dispensable adjuncts to a Shakespearean Library." Boston Transcript. 81. CHAUCER AND HIS TIMES. By Grace E. Hadow, Lecturer Lady Margaret Hall, Oxford; Late Reader, Bryn Mawr. 97. MILTON. By John Bailey. 59. DR. JOHNSON AND HIS CIRCLE. By John Bailey. Johnson's life, character, works, and friendships are surveyed; and there is a notable vindication of the "Genius of Boswell." 83. WILLIAM MORRIS: HIS WORK AND INFLUENCE. By A. Clut- ton Brock, author of "Shelley: The Man and the Poet." William Morris believed that the artist should toil for love of his work rather than the gain of his employer, and so he turned from making works of art to remaking society. 73. SHELLEY, GODWIN AND THEIR CIRCLE. By H. N. Braihford. The influence of the French Revolution on England. 70. ANCIENT ART AND RITUAL. By Jane E. Harrison, LL. D., D. Litt. "One of the 100 most important books of 1913." New York Times Review. 45. MEDIEVAL ENGLISH LITERATURE. By W. P. Ker, Professor of English Literature, University College, London. "One of the soundest scholars. His style is effective, simple, yet never dry." The Athenaeum. 87. THE RENAISSANCE. By Edith Sichel, author of "Catherine de Medici," "Men and Women of the French Renaissance." 89. ELIZABETHAN LITERATURE. By J. M. Robertson, M. P., author of "Montaigne and Shakespeare," "Modern Humanists." 27. MODERN ENGLISH LITERATURE. ByG.H.Mair. From Wyatt and Surrey to Synge and Yeats. "One of the best of this great series." Chicago Evening Post. 61. THE VICTORIAN AGE IN LITERATURE. By G. K. Chesterton. 40. THE ENGLISH LANGUAGE. By L. P. Smith. A concise history of its origin and development. 66. WRITING ENGLISH PROSE. By William T. Brewster, Professor of English, Columbia University. "Should be put into the hands of every man who is beginning to write and of every teacher of English who has brains enough to understand sense." New York ^ ur ^. 58. THE NEWSPAPER. By G. Binney Dibblee. The first full account from the inside of newspaper organization as it exists to-day. 48. GREAT WRITERS OF AMERICA. By W. P. Trent and John Erskine, Columbia University. 93. AN OUTLINE OF RUSSIAN LITERATURE. By Maurice Baring, author of "The Russian People," etc. Tolstoi, Tourgenieff, Dos- toieffsky, Pushkin (the father of Russian Literature,) Saltykov (the satirist,) Leskov, and many other authors. 31. LANDMARKS IN FRENCH LITERATURE, By G. L. Strachey, Scholar of Trinity College, Cambridge. "It is difficult to imagine how a better account of French Literature could be given in 250 pages." London Times. 64. THE LITERATURE OF GERMANY. By J. G. Robertson. 62. PAINTERS AND PAINTING. By Sir Frederick Wedmore. With 16 half-tone illustrations. 38. ARCHITECTURE. By Prof. W. R. Lethaby. An introduction to the history and theory of the art of building. 108. PATRIOTISM IN LITERATURE. By John Drinkwater. 109. MUSIC. By Sir W. H. Hadow. NATURAL SCIENCE. DISEASE AND ITS CAUSES. By W. T. Councilman, M. D., LL. D., Professor of Pathology, Harvard University. SEX. By J. Arthur Thompson and Patrick Geddes, joint authors of "The Evolution of Sex." PLANT LIFE. By J. B. Farmer, D. Sc., F. R. S., Professor of Bot- tany in the Imperial College of Science, London. This very fully illustrated volume contains an account of the salient features of plant form and function. THE ORIGIN AND NATURE OF LIFE. By Benjamin M. Moore, Professor of Bio-Chemistry, Liverpool. CHEMISTRY. By Raphael Meldola, F. R. S., Professor of Chem- istry, Finsbury Technical College. Presents the way in which the science has developed and the stage it has reached. ELECTRICITY. By Gisbert Kapp, Professor of Electrical En- gineering, University of Birmingham. THE MAKING OF THE EARTH. By J. W. Gregory, Professor of Geology, Glasgow University. 38 maps and figures. Describes the origin of the earth, the formation and changes of its surface and structure, its geological history, the first appearance of life, and its influence upon the globe. MAN: A HISTORY OF THE HUMAN BODY. By A. Keith, M. D., Hunter ian Professor, Royal College of Surgeons, London. Shows how the human body developed. NERVES. By David Fraser Harris, M. D., Professor of Physi- ology, Dalhousie University, Halifax. Explains in non-technical language the place and powers of the nervous system. AN INTRODUCTION TO SCIENCE. By Prof. J. Arthur Thomson, Science Editor of the Home University Library. For those unac- quainted with the scientific volumes in the series, this should prove an excellent introduction. EVOLUTION. By Prof. J. Arthur Thomson and Prof. Patrick Geddes. Explains to the layman what the tide means to the scien- tific world. ASTRONOMY. By A. R. Hinks, Chief Assistant at the Cambridge Observatory. "Decidedly original in substance, and the most readable and informative little book on modern astronomy we have seen for a long time." Nature. PSYCHICAL RESEARCH. By Prof. W. F. Barrett, formerly Presi- dent of the Society for Psychical Research. THE EVOLUTION OF PLANTS. By Dr. D. H. Scott, President of the Linnean Society of London. The story of the development of flowering plants, from the earliest zoological times, unlocked from technical language. BIOLOGY. By J. Arthur Thomson and Patrick Geddes. 43. MATTER AND ENERGY. By F. Soddy, Lecturer in Physical Chemistry and Radioactivity, University of Glasgow. "Brilliant. Can hardly be surpassed. Sure to attract attention." New York Sun. 41. PSYCHOLOGY, THE STUDY OF BEHAVIOUR. By William Me- Dougall, of Oxford. A well digested summary of the essentials of the science put in excellent literary form by a leading authority. 42. THE PRINCIPLES OF PHYSIOLOGY. By Prof. J. G. McKendrick, A compact statement by the Emeritus "Professor at Glasgow, for uninstructed readers. 37. ANTHROPOLOGY. By R. R. Marett, Reader in Social Anthro- pology, Oxford. Seeks to plot out and sum up the general series of changes, bodily and mental, undergone by man in the course of history. "Excellent. So enthusiastic, so clear and witty, and so well adapted to the general reader." American Library Association Booklist. 17. CRIME AND INSANITY. By Dr. C. Mercier, author of "Crime and Criminals," etc. 12. THE ANIMAL WORLD. By Prof . F. W. Gamble. 15. INTRODUCTION TO MATHEMATICS. By A. N. Whitchead, author of "Universal Algebra." PHILOSOPHY AND RELIGION. 69. A HISTORY OF FREEDOM OF THOUGHT. By John B. Bury, M. A., LL. D., Regius Professor of Modern History in Cambridge University. Summarizes the history of the long struggle between authority and reason and of the emergence of the principle that co- ercion of opinion is a mistake. 96. A HISTORY OF PHILOSOPHY. By Clement C. J. Webb, Oxford. 35. THE PROBLEMS OF PHILOSOPHY. By Bertrand Russell, Lee- turer and Late Fellow, Trinity College, Cambridge. 60. COMPARATIVE RELIGION. By Prof. J. Estlin Carpenter. "One of the few authorities on this subject compares all the religions to see what they have to offer on the great themes of religion." Chris- Han Work and Evangelist. 44. BUDDHISM. By Mrs. Rhys Davids, Lecturer on Indian Philoso- phy, Manchester. 46. ENGLISH SECTS: A HISTORY OF NONCONFORMITY. ByW.B. Selbie. Principal of Manchester College, Oxford. 55. MISSIONS: THEIR RISE AND DEVELOPMENT. By Mrs. MM- dell Creighton, author of "History of England." The author seeks to prove that missions have done more to civilize the world than any other human agency. 52. ETHICS. By G. E. Moore, Lecturer in Moral Science, Cambridge. Discusses what is right and what is wrong, and the whys and where- fores. C5. THE LITERATURE OF THE OLD TESTAMENT. By George F. Moore. Professor of the History of Religion, Harvard University "A popular work of the highest order. Will be profitable to anybody who cares enough about Bible study to read a serious book on the subject." American Journal of Theology. 88. RELIGIOUS DEVELOPMENT BETWEEN OLD AND NEW TESTA- MENTS. By R. H. Charles, Canon of Westminster. Shows how religious and ethical thought between 180 P. C. and 100 A. D. grew naturally into that of the New Testament. 50. THE MAKING OF THE NEW TESTAMENT. By B. W. Bacon, Professor of New Testament Criticism, Yale. An authoritative summary of the results of modern critical research with regard to the origins of the New Testament. SOCIAL SCIENCE. 91. THE NEGRO. By W. E. Burghardt DuBois, author of "Souls of Black Folks," etc. A history of the black man in Africa, America and elsewhere. 77. CO-PARTNERSHIP AND PROFIT SHARING. By Aneurin WU- liaras, Chairman, Executive Committee, International Co-opera- tive Alliance, etc. Explains the various types of co-partnership and profit-sharing, and gives details of the arrangements, now in force in many of the creat industries. 99. POLITICAL THOUGHT: THE UTILITARIANS. FROM BENT- HAM TO J. S. MILL. By William L. P. Davidson. 103. ENGLISH POLITICAL THOUGHT. From Locke to Bentham. By Harold J. Laski, Professor of Political Science in the London School of Economics. 98. POLITICAL THOUGHT: FROM HERBERT SPENCER TO THE PRESENT DAY. By Ernest Barker, M. A. 79. UNEMPLOYMENT. By A. C. Pigou, M. A., Professor of Political Economy at Cambridge. The meaning, measurement, distribution, and effects of unemployment, its relation to wages, trade fluctuations, and disputes, and some proposals of remedy or relief. 80. COMMON-SENSE IN LAW. By Prof. Paul Vinogradoff, D. C. L., LL. D. Social and Legal Rules Legal Rights and Duties Facts and Acts in Law Legislation Custom Judicial Precedents Equity The Law of Nature. 49. ELEMENTS OF POLITICAL ECONOMY. By S. J. Chapman, Professor of Political Economy and Dean of Faculty of Commerce and Administration, University of Manchester. 11. THE SCIENCE OF WEALTH. By J. A. Hobson, author of "Prob- lems of Poverty." A study of the structure and working of the modern business world. 1. PARLIAMENT. ITS HISTORY, CONSTITUTION, AND PRAC- TICE. By Sir Courtenay P. Ilbert, Clerk of the House of Commons. 16. LIBERALISM. By Prof. L. T. Hobhouse, author of "Democracy and Reaction." A masterly philosophical and historical review of the subject. 5. THE STOCK EXCHANGE. By F. W. Hirst, Editor of the London Economist. Reveals to the non-financial mind the facts about invest- ment, speculation, and the other terms which the title suggests. 10. THE SOCIALIST MOVEMENT. By J. Ramsay Macdonald, Chair- man of the British Labor Party. 28. THE EVOLUTION OF INDUSTRY. By D. H. MacGregor, Professor of Political Economy, University of Leeds. An outline of the recent changes that have given us the present conditions of the working classes and the principles involved. 29. ELEMENTS OF ENGLISH LAW. By W. M. Geldart, Vinerian Professor of English Law, Oxford. A simple statement of the basic principles of the English legal system on which that of the United States is based. 32. THE SCHOOL: AN INTRODUCTION TO THE STUDY OF EDU- CATION. By J. J. Findlay, Professor of Education, Manchester. Presents the history, the psychological basis, and the theory of the school with a rare power of summary and suggestion. 6. IRISH NATIONALITY. By Mrs. J. R. Green. A brilliant account of the genius and mission of the Irish people. "An entrancing work, and I would advise every one with a drop of Irish blood in his veins or a vein of Irish sympathy in his heart to read it." New Yor\ Time* Review. 107. STUDY OF HEREDITY. By Ernest William MacBride. GENERAL HISTORY AND GEOGRAPHY. 102. SERBIA. By L. F. Waring, with preface by J. M. Jovanovitch, Serbian Minister to Great Britain. The main outlines of Serbian history, with special emphasis on the immediate causes of the war. and the questions in the after-the-war settlement. 33. THE HISTORY OF ENGLAND. By A. F. Pollard, Professor of English History, University of London. 95. BELGIUM. By R.C.K. Ensor, Sometime Scholar of Balliol College. The geographical, linguistic, historical, artistic and literary associa- tions. 100. POLAND. By J. Alison Phillips, University of Dublin. The history of Poland with special emphasis upon the Polish qustion of the pre- sent day. 34. CANADA. By A. G. Bradley. 72. GERMANY OF TO-DAY. By Charles Tower. 78. LATIN AMERICA. By William R. Shepherd, Professor of His- tory, Columbia. With maps. The historical, artistic, and commercial development of the Central South American republics. 18. THE OPENING UP OF AFRICA. By Sir H. H. Johnston. 19. THE CIVILIZATION OF CHINA. By H. A. Gtfes, Professor of Chinese, Cambridge. 36. PEOPLES AND PROBLEMS OF INDIA. By Sir T. W. Holderness, "The best small treatise dealing with the range of subjects fairly in- dicated by the title." The Dial. 26. THE DAWN OF HISTORY. By J. L. Myers, Professor of Ancient History, Oxford. 92. THE ANCIENT EAST. By D.G. Hogarth, M. A.,F. B. A.,F.S. A., Connects with Prof. Myers's "Dawn of History" (No. 26) at about 1000 B. C. and reviews the history of Assyria, Babylon, Cilicia, Persia and Macedon. 30. ROME. By W. Warde Fowler, author of "Social Life at Rome," etc. 13. MEDIEVAL EUROPE. By H. W. C. Davis, Fellow at Balliol Col- lege, Oxford, author of "Charlemagne," etc. 3. THE FRENCH REVOLUTION. By Hilaire Belloc. 57. NAPOLEON, By H. A. L. Fisher, Vice-Chancellor of Sheffield Uni- versity. Author of "The Republican Tradition in Europe." 20. HISTORY OF OUR TIME. (1885-1911). By C. P. Gooch. 22. THE PAPACY AND MODERN TIMES. By Rev. William Barry, D. D., author of "The Papal Monarchy," etc. The story of the rise and fall of the Temporal Power. 108. WALES. By W. Watkin Davies, M.A.. F.R. Hist.S., Barrister-at- Law, author of "How to Read History," etc. 110. EGYPT, By E. A. Wallis Budge. 104. OUR FORERUNNERS. By M. C. Burkitt, M.A., F.S.A. A com- prehensive study of the beginnings of mankind and the culture of th e prehistoric era. 4. A SHORT HISTORY OF WAR AND PEACE. By G. H. Pern., author of "Russia in Revolution," etc. 94. THE NAVY AND SEA POWER. By David Hannay, author of "Short History of the Royal Navy," etc. A brief history of the navies, sea Power, and ship growth of all nations, including the rise and decline of America on the sea, and explaining the present British supremacy. 8. POLAR EXPLORATION. By Dr. W. S. Bruce, Leader of the "Scotia" expedition. Emphasizes the results of the expeditions. 51. MASTER MARINERS. By John R. Spears, author of "The His- tory of Our Navy," etc. A history of sea craft adventure from the earliest times. 86. EXPLORATION OF THE ALPS. By Arnold Lunn, M. A. 7. MODERN GEOGRAPHY. By Dr. Marion Newbigin. Shows the re- lation of physical features to living things and to some of the chief in- stitutions of civilization. 76. THE OCEAN. A GENERAL ACCOUNT OF THE SCIENCE OF THE SEA. By Sir John Murray/K. C. B., Naturalist H. M. S. "Chal- lenger," 1872-1876, joint author of "The Depths of the Ocean," etc. 84. THE GROWTH OF EUROPE. By Granville Cole, Professor of Geology, Royal College of Science, Ireland. A study of the geology and physical geography in connection with the political geography. 105. COMMERCIAL GEOGRAPHY. By Marion I. Newbigin. Funda- mental conceptions of commodities, transport and market. AMERICAN HISTORY. 47. THE COLONIAL PERIOD (1607-1766). By Charles McLean An- drews, Professor of American History, Yale. 82. THE WARS BETWEEN ENGLAND AND AMERICA (1763-1815). By Theodore C. Smith, Professor of American History, Williams College. A history of the period, with especial emphasis on The Re- volution and The War of 1812. 67. FROM JEFFERSON TO LINCOLN (1815-1860). By William Mac- Donald. Professor of History, Brown University. The author makes the history of this period circulate about constitutional ideas and slavery sentiment. 25. THE CIVIL WAR (1854-1865). By Frederick L. Paxson, Professor of American History, University of Wisconsin. 39. RECONSTRUCTION AND UNION (1865-1912). By Paul Leland Haworth. A History of the United States in our own times. Published by HENRY HOLT AND COMPANY, 19 West 44th St., New York I 14 DAY USE RETURN TO DESK FROM WHICH BORROWED LOAN DEPT. This book is due on the last date stamped below, or on the date to which renewed. immediate recall. 251 JUN: inu-si 'R4-12M I ; uH II II -. , ** - 1 b J369 5 o ; AUG151969 REC'D LD fl JG 16 '69 -4PM 3 i ^ ^ L D21A-40-4 6 63 Univ^f^CaHSrnia Berkeley YB 18252 592959 UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA LIBRARY