CALIFORNIA 
 AGRICULTURAL EXTENSION SERVICE 
 
 CIRCULAR 126 
 October, 1942 
 
 Farm Finance : Dangers and 
 Opportunities in Wartime 
 
 MURRAY R. BENEDICT 
 
 CONTRIBUTION FROM THE 
 GIANNINI FOUNDATION OF AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS 
 
 Cooperative Extension work in Agriculture and Home Economics, College of Agriculture, 
 
 University of California, and United States Department of Agriculture cooperating. 
 
 Distributed in furtherance of the Acts of Congress of May 8, and June 30, 1914. 
 
 B. H. Crocheron, Director, California Agricultural Extension Service. 
 
 THE COLLEGE OF AGRICULTURE 
 
 UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA 
 
 BERKELEY, CALIFORNIA 
 
A 1916 Prediction: 
 
 '1 do not know of any class in America who are 
 likely to be more powerfully affected in their business 
 relations by the economic situation of the United States 
 at the close of the European War than the farmers. 
 
 ''The prices of agricultural products are soaring sky- 
 ward. A period of rising prices almost invariably cre- 
 ates a speculative spirit. This speculative spirit grows 
 by what it feeds on, and sometimes goes beyond the 
 bounds of reason. In that case disaster is certain to come 
 to somebody. The lucky ones who get out from under 
 in time will make money; the others will become 
 
 bankrupt. 
 
 * * * 
 
 ''The best and soundest advice which I could give 
 American farmers, therefore, is to be cautious. If you 
 know exactly how long the war will last you can safely 
 speculate. If you do not, you had better go slow. At all 
 events, whatever you do, don't be in debt when the war 
 closes, for if you are heavily in debt at that time I can 
 predict your bankruptcy with about as much feeling of 
 certainty as I can predict that the sun will continue to 
 shine or the moon to wax and wane." 
 
 (Source: Thomas Nixon Carver. Professor of Political Economy, 
 Harvard University. In: the University of California Journal of Agri- 
 culture. December, 1916.) 
 
FARM FINANCE: DANGERS AND 
 OPPORTUNITIES IN WARTIME 
 
 MUEEAY E. BENEDICT^ 
 EXPERIENCE AFTER WORLD WAR I 
 
 Twenty years ago (1922) the farm people of America entered a trying 
 period of readjustment. Prices had fallen almost 50 per cent in two 
 years. Their farms were burdened with far heavier mortgage debts than 
 ever in their history, and there were large amounts of personal and col- 
 lateral loans that could not be met from the reduced incomes then pre- 
 vailing. Because of an unwieldy debt and cost situation, the security of 
 thousands of farm families was gravely threatened. Surprisingly enough, 
 these conditions followed close on the heels of a time when farm incomes 
 had been more than double those of any year before 1916. 
 
 The problems confronting agriculture at that time were the result of 
 inflationary price increases, followed by deflation ; of unwise speculation 
 in land; and of a lost opportunity in the way of reducing outstanding 
 debts. We are now in the midst of another war. Incomes are again reach- 
 ing high levels. It will be helpful, therefore, to review briefly the main 
 features of farm finance during that period and to appraise the wisdom 
 of farmers' financial policies then. The similarities of current price and 
 income conditions to those of World War I are sufficient to warrant an 
 effort to draw such lessons as we can from this earlier experience. 
 
 For the four years, 1917 through 1920, cash income from farm pro- 
 duction exceeded by some 27.0 billion dollars what it would have been 
 had annual values been the same as those of 1914.^ Expenditures for 
 farm production rose also but not so much. Data are not available for 
 all farm costs. Estimates have been made, however, for the more iPxipor- 
 tant items, namely, hired labor, feed, fertilizer, farm implements, ma- 
 chine operation, cotton ginning, taxes, and interest on farm mortgages. 
 For the four years mentioned, the increase in these items amounted to 
 about 8.6 billions over what they would have totaled had the 1914 levels 
 of expenditures continued.^ Thus if we ignore certain minor items of 
 cost, there flowed into the hands of farmers during these four years 
 somewhat more than 18 billion dollars in excess of what would have 
 come to them had prices, quantities, and costs remained at 1914 levels. 
 
 ^ Professor of Agricultural Economics, Agricultural Economist in the Experiment 
 Station, and Agricultural Economist on the Giannini Foundation. 
 
 2 See: United States Department of Agriculture. Agricultural Statistics 1941: 
 .554. 1941. 
 
 ^ Data from : United States Department of Agriculture. Agricultural Statistics 
 1937:386. 1937. 
 
 L 3 J 
 
4 California Agricultural Extension Service [Cir. 126 
 
 What became of this 18 billions? Part of it, of course, went in higher 
 expenses for living, such items as clothing and purchased foods. These 
 increases, however, were much smaller for farm families than for city 
 dwellers since, in general, the farms continued to furnish food and shel- 
 ter as in earlier periods. Costs for home-grown foods did not change sig- 
 nificantly, and housing costs did not increase to any such extent as did 
 those of city dwellers. 
 
 Considerable amounts of the increased income of farmers went, of 
 course, into Liberty Bonds. Unfortunately, much of this investment 
 found its way eventually into speculative ventures of one kind or an- 
 other which yielded little permanent benefit to farm people. Other sub- 
 stantial amounts went into the purchase of farms at seriously inflated 
 values. Most of this amount, as will be shown later, was wiped out in the 
 deflation that followed. 
 
 The Course of Farm-Mortgage Debt and Land Prices in the United 
 States. — Leaving aside for the present a fuller discussion of the income 
 situation, let us consider what happened to farm debts during these 
 years, for it was this aftermath of heavy indebtedness that caused much 
 of the acute distress in farm areas, and constituted the gravest threat 
 to the security and well-being of farm families. 
 
 Farm-mortgage debt in the United States in 1914 amounted to ap- 
 proximately 4.7 billion dollars. By 1921 this had more than doubled and 
 stood at over 10.2 billions.* In addition, there had been a marked increase 
 in short-term debt, much of which was destined later to be merged with 
 the mortgage debt shown above. Thus, total mortgage debt did not reach 
 its peak of nearly 10.8 billions until 1923, more than two years after the 
 abrupt decline in farm prices which occurred in 1920. 
 
 It will be seen that during a four-year period in which the increased 
 value of United States farm production had exceeded cost increases for 
 major items by some 18 billion dollars, farmers were actually in a worse 
 position than when this period started. They did not get out of debt nor 
 even reduce their indebtedness. Instead, the load of mortgage debt bur- 
 dening American farms had been increased by nearly 5 billions (1917 
 through 1920). While debts had thus been increased markedly, the in- 
 comes out of which they were to be paid had declined sharply. Total cash 
 income for 1919 was estimated at 14.4 billions. By 1921 this had fallen 
 to 8.1 billions. Through most of the twenties, it showed a gradual in- 
 crease, moving up to 11.2 billions in 1929. Costs declined much more 
 slowly than did incomes, and some actually continued to increase. 
 
 Not only had American farmers burdened themselves with a large ad- 
 
 * United States Department of Agriculture. Agricultural Statistics 1941:594. 
 1941. 
 
Farm Finance in Wartime 5 
 
 ditional private debt ; they also carried a share in the burden of increased 
 public debts, particularly those of states, counties, and school districts. 
 Debts of this kind grew enormously during these years. This is illus- 
 trated in part by the growth of farm taxes, which stood at 393 million 
 dollars in 1919 but did not reach their peak of 567 millions until 1929. 
 They did not again fall below the 1919 level until 1933. (Such tax in- 
 creases were not, of course, due solely to increased public debts. Both 
 the amounts of public service provided and their costs had been in- 
 creased, and did not decline correspondingly when farm incomes fell off.) 
 
 The full effect of this heavy load of farm debt did not appear until a 
 few years later, as may be seen from the record of farm bankruptcies. 
 Although the number of bankruptcies is not an accurate measure of 
 financial distress among farmers, since bankruptcy is not the usual form 
 of adjustment adopted by farmers,^ changes in numbers of bankruptcies 
 give some indication of the increase in finanical distress. From 1910 to 
 1914, inclusive, the average annual number of farm bankruptcies was 
 870. For the next five years (1915 to 1919), the average number was 
 1,530. By 1924 the number had reached serious proportions : 7,772 cases 
 were reported for that year. The two succeeding years showed similar 
 high levels : 7,872 and 7,769. The number of bankruptcies fell off slow^ly 
 in the succeeding years and has not since reached numbers as high as 
 those of the years just mentioned. 
 
 In 1926 the number of farms changing hands by involuntary sale, 
 that is, by forced sale, tax delinquency, mortgage foreclosure, and bank- 
 ruptcy, amounted to 21.6 farms per 1,000. This number, except for a 
 slight decline in 1928 and 1929, crept steadily upward until 1933, in 
 which year there were 54.1 such involuntary transfers per 1,000 farms : 
 during that year alone, one farmer out of every twenty throughout 
 the United States suffered the loss of his farm. During the five-j^ear 
 period, 1932 through 1936, nearly one fifth of all farms in the United 
 States changed hands by forced sale of one kind or another.* It was thus 
 that some of the excessive debt assumed in 1919 and 1920 was liquidated. 
 
 But this tells only part of the story of what became of the 24 billion 
 
 •■' It is more usual for farmers to surrender the farm or to let it go through fore- 
 closure than to apply for the formal court process of bankruptcy. Thus the financial 
 distress was far more widespread than would be indicated by the record of bank- 
 ruptcies. 
 
 « This is on the assumption that the same farm did not go through such sale more 
 than once during this period. 
 
 Data on which these statements are based are taken from : 
 
 [United States Bureau of Agricultural Economics.] The farm debt problem. 
 IT. S. 73d Cong. House Doc. 9 :27. 1933. 
 
 Stauber, B. K., and M. M. Eegan. The farm real-estate situation, 1935-36. U. S. 
 Dept. Agr. Cir. 417:26. 1936. 
 
 Eegan, M. M. The farm real estate situation, 1936-37, 1937-38, and 1938-39. 
 U. S. Dept. Agr. Cir. 548:1-41. 1939. 
 
6 California Agricultural Extension Service [Cir. 126 
 
 dollars^ of agricultural assets which disappeared in the past twenty-five 
 years. Not all farms were bought with borrowed money. Some of the 
 additional income went into competitive bidding for lands, often on a 
 speculative basis. In 1914 the value of farm real estate in the United 
 States was estimated at 39.6 billion dollars. By 1917 this stood at 45.5 
 billions. In the succeeding three years, United States farm lands were 
 
 TABLE 1 
 
 Farm Real Estate: Index Numbers of Estimated Value per. Acre 
 (1912-1914=100) 
 
 Year 
 
 United 
 states 
 
 California 
 
 Year 
 
 United 
 
 States 
 
 California 
 
 1912 
 
 1913 
 
 1914 
 
 97 
 100 
 103 
 103 
 108 
 117 
 129 
 140 
 170 
 157 
 139 
 135 
 130 
 127 
 124 
 119 
 
 93 
 99 
 108 
 111 
 116 
 130 
 136 
 142 
 167 
 168 
 166 
 165 
 164 
 164 
 163 
 162 
 
 1928 
 
 1929 
 
 1930 
 
 117 
 116 
 115 
 106 
 
 89 
 73 
 
 76 
 79 
 
 82 
 85 
 85 
 84 
 84 
 S5 
 91 
 
 161 
 160 
 160 
 
 1915. 
 
 1931 
 
 158 
 
 1916 
 
 1932 
 
 1933 
 
 1934 
 
 1935 
 
 1936 
 
 1937 
 
 133 
 
 1917 
 
 109 
 
 1918 
 
 1919 
 
 1920 
 
 110 
 115 
 119 
 
 1921 
 
 124 
 
 1922 
 
 1938 
 
 123 
 
 1923 
 
 1939 
 
 1940 
 
 1941 
 
 1942 
 
 121 
 
 1924 
 
 1925 
 
 1926 
 
 1927 
 
 121 
 122 
 128 
 
 Sources of data: 
 
 Data for United States to 1939, inclusive, from: United States Departmeiit of Agriculture. Agri- 
 cultural Statistics 1941:583. 1941. 
 
 Data for California to 1939, inclusive, from: The farm real estate situation, 1936-37, 1937-38, and 
 1938-39. U. S. Dept. Agr. Cir. 548:5. 1939. 
 
 All data for 1940, 1941, and 1942 from: United States Bureau of Agricultural Economics. Farm 
 real estate values show general rise during the past year. 3 p. April 13, 1942. (Mimeo.) 
 
 bid up to 66.3 billions, an increase of 20.8 billions. This is, of course, not 
 all represented in land sales : it is the amount by which the valuations 
 placed on the nation's farm lands were increased, whether they had been 
 sold or had remained in the hands of former owners. This increase in the 
 capitalization of farm lands did not in itself increase the earning power 
 of the lands in any way. It was simply a heavier capitalization carried by 
 farmers on essentially the same lands and in this respect represented an 
 additional financial burden for operating farmers to carry. By 1933 this 
 value had shrunk again, not only to 1914 levels but far below them. The 
 1933 valuation of 30.7 billions was well below even the 34.8 billions esti- 
 mated value of farm lands in 1910. 
 
 It is apparent, then, that in this quarter century the farmers of the 
 United States had gained little from their temporary period of pros- 
 
 ^ That is, 18 billion dollars in additional income plus 6 billions of increased in- 
 debtedness. 
 
Farm Finance in Wartime 7 
 
 perity, had invested heavily in expected future high incomes from lands, 
 and had suffered capital losses similar to those w^hich befell the holders 
 of common stocks in 1929. 
 
 100 
 
 
 
 
 
 , 
 
 ^^^^ 
 
 \ United 
 
 *| California 
 
 \ 
 % 
 
 I 
 
 
 f 1 
 1 / 
 / / 
 
 V^ States 
 
 \ 
 \ 
 
 y 
 
 f 
 
 
 \ 
 
 y 
 
 W^^ 
 
 
 - 
 
 
 
 
 - 
 
 
 
 1 1 1 
 
 m ■V rf 
 
 Fig. 1. — Farm real estate : index numbers of estimated values per 
 acre (1912-1914 = 100) ; United States and California, 1912-1942. 
 (Source of data: table 1.) 
 
 The Course of Land Prices and Mortgage Debt in California. — Thus 
 far we have been considering- the debt situation for the United States. It 
 is appropriate to point out here, however, that the course of events dif- 
 fered in California from that of the nation as a whole, though the gen- 
 eral implications are much the same. 
 
 Between 1914 and 1919, California land values rose earlier and faster 
 than those for the United States but did not quite reach the peak at- 
 tained for the country as a whole in 1920. After 1920, California valua- 
 tions fell off much more slowly than did those for the United States and 
 have remained higher up to the present time, in terms of relation to 
 1912-1914 values. This comparison is shown in table 1 and in figure 1. 
 
8 California Agricultural Extension Service [Cir. 126 
 
 The reasons for this difference are to be found both in the character 
 of the crops grown and in the stage of development through which Cali- 
 fornia agriculture was passing at that time. Through most of the twen- 
 ties, industrial activity in the United States was at a relatively high level 
 and much of the urban population was prosperous. The nation's food 
 habits were changing in the direction of more use of fruits and vegetables 
 and less use of wheat and other starchy foods. Both factors were favor- 
 able to many of the specialty crops grown in California. Furthermore, 
 California's own population was growing at an unprecedented rate.^ 
 Large amounts of capital were flowing into the state from other parts of 
 the United States. It was a period of relative optimism as far as new 
 investments in agriculture were concerned. Between 1919 and 1929 the 
 grape acreage of the state increased by 94 per cent. Lemons and oranges, 
 which had experienced a large acreage increase in the previous decade, 
 showed a substantial further increase of 25 to 30 per cent. Subtropical 
 fruits and nuts gained 82 per cent. Vegetables and temperate-zone fruits 
 likewise were expanded greatly, the former increasing by 91 per cent, 
 the latter by 63 per cent. 
 
 The optimism which would lead to these large plantings would natur- 
 ally have a stimulating effect upon land prices. Most of these investments 
 were not expected to yield returns until several years later. Hence, in 
 most lines the effects of these heavy increases in production were not yet 
 apparent in the market. Troublesome surpluses were to appear in the 
 thirties, however. 
 
 As a result of the influences mentioned above, California land values 
 did not, during the twenties, follow closely the downward trend of those 
 of the United States. As late as 1930 they were only 8 points below the 
 peak figure of 168 (1912-1914=100), which was reached in 1921. There 
 was a sharp drop in the early thirties, though the level still remained 
 significantly higher than that for the nation as a whole. 
 
 Great care is needed in making any assumption that California land 
 prices will continue to show this distinctive behavior. They will no doubt 
 continue to reflect price conditions for the products characteristic of 
 the state rather than those for crops more common in other parts of the 
 country. These may, however, be either lower or higher relatively than 
 the general average for the United States. The period of most rapid 
 intensive development of California farm lands is probably past. The 
 change in food habits will probably continue, possibly at a faster, pos- 
 sibly at a slower rate. The local population is continuing to increase at 
 a rapid rate, and this should lend strength to the local markets for 
 specialty crops. On the other hand, the plantings of the twenties have 
 
 *• In terms of total numbers. 
 
Farm Finance in Wartime 9 
 
 now come into much fuller production, export markets for some products 
 have been seriously curtailed, and in some cases, important competitive 
 areas are increasing their production. 
 
 Taking all factors into account, it seems likely that Land prices in Cali- 
 fornia will follow a somewhat different pattern from those of the United 
 States and one which will vary considerably from area to area within the 
 
 2oe 
 
 »00 
 
 United 
 
 Statas 
 
 
 
 
 /^ ' 
 
 ^^•t»^ 
 
 
 90 
 
 / 
 
 
 "'^^^ 
 
 
 
 / 
 
 
 ^ W^l 
 
 
 
 y 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 ^^^^""^ 
 
 
 
 
 
 y 
 
 
 
 
 o "^ 
 
 
 
 
 
 I 
 
 1 r 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 6 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 California ^♦••••' 
 
 '■•>«, , 
 
 
 
 
 ,^"0^--' 
 
 
 
 
 .^' 
 
 
 
 
 
 y 
 
 
 
 
 1 
 
 
 
 / 
 
 ^111111 1 .1 1 
 
 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 
 
 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 
 
 1 
 
 Fig. 2. — Relative changes in farm-mortgage debt by years, California 
 and the United States, 1910-1940. (Source of data: table 2.) 
 
 state according to the price conditions for the various crops. It seems 
 unlikely, however, that they will have the support of such a prolonged 
 period of optimism and rapid development as that which marked the 
 period from 1910 to 1930. 
 
 From 1910, the earliest date for which estimates are available, the 
 California farm-mortgage debt grew, for the most part in modest incre- 
 ments, until 1920. In that year it increased by 60 million dollars and in 
 the following year by 85 millions. After a brief and slight recession, the 
 upward trend was resumed in 1924, and did not reach its maximum until 
 1932. Thus the expansion of mortgage debt in California continued for 
 
10 
 
 California Agricultural Extension Service [Cir. 126 
 
 nearly ten years after the peak had been reached for the United States 
 as a whole. These changes and relations are shown in table 2 and figure 2. 
 As of January 1, 1935, it is estimated that 67,444 California farms 
 were mortgaged.^ This number included 55,234 owner-operated farms 
 and 12,210 operated by tenants and hired managers. Individual mort- 
 gages were much larger on the manager and tenant farms : here they 
 averaged $16,388, while on owner-operated farms the average size of 
 
 TABLE 2 
 
 Estimated Farm-Mortgage Debt by Years, California and the United States, 
 
 1910-1940 
 
 Year 
 
 California 
 
 United 
 
 states 
 
 Year 
 
 California 
 
 United 
 States 
 
 1910 
 
 1911 
 
 million 
 dollars 
 
 107 
 
 122 
 
 152 
 
 191 
 
 220 
 
 239 
 
 256 
 
 300 
 
 338 
 
 345 
 
 404 
 
 489 
 
 489 
 
 441 
 
 462 
 
 493 
 
 million 
 dollars 
 3,208 
 3,522 
 3,930 
 4,348 
 4,707 
 4,991 
 5,256 
 5,826 
 6,537 
 7,137 
 8,449 
 10,221 
 10,702 
 10.786 
 10,665 
 9,913 
 
 1926 
 
 1927 
 
 1928 
 
 million 
 dollars 
 
 520 
 
 551 
 
 546 
 
 557 
 
 615 
 
 637 
 
 638 
 
 623 
 
 580 
 
 533 
 
 525 
 
 533 
 
 539 
 
 543 
 
 542 
 
 million 
 dollars 
 9,713 
 9,658 
 
 1912 
 
 9,757 
 
 1913. 
 
 1929 
 
 9 757 
 
 1914 
 
 1930 
 
 1931 
 
 9,631 
 
 1915 
 
 9,458 
 
 1916 
 
 1932 
 
 9,214 
 
 1917 
 
 1918 
 
 1933 
 
 1934 
 
 8,638 
 7,887 
 
 1919 . 
 
 1935 
 
 7,786 
 
 1920 
 
 1921 
 
 1936 
 
 1937 
 
 7,639 
 7.390 
 
 1922 
 
 1938 
 
 7,214 
 
 1923 
 
 1939 
 
 7,071 
 
 1924 
 
 1940 
 
 6,910 
 
 1925 
 
 
 
 
 
 Source of data: 
 
 Horton, Donald C, Harald C. Larsen, and Norman J. Wall. Farm-mortgage credit facilities in 
 the United States. U. S. Dept. Agr. Misc. Pub. 478:219, 220, 221. 1942. 
 
 mortgage was $5,378. Approximately half (49.8 per cent) of all owner- 
 operated farms in the state were mortgaged and nearly 31 per cent of 
 the manager- and tenant-operated farms. 
 
 In addition to the mortgage debt shown above, the farmers of Cali- 
 fornia owe substantial but fluctuating amounts on personal and col- 
 lateral loans. As of January 1, 1941, these amounted to 95.2 million 
 dollars. Of this, 79.3 millions was in the form of commercial bank loans. 
 The production-credit associations held 9.7 millions, Farm Security 5.7 
 millions, and the Emergency Crop and Feed Loans Office 0.5 million."^" 
 
 ^ Data from : United States Bureau of the Census and United States Bureau of 
 Agricultural Economics. Farm mortgage indebtedness in the United States (detailed 
 summary). 12 p. Cooperative Survey. August 26, 1937. (Lithoprinted.) (Some of the 
 data secured in the 1940 Census have been published but as yet these have not been 
 fully analyzed.) 
 
 ^° United States Bureau of Agricultural Economics. Agricultural loans in Califor- 
 nia, p. 12, 17. Washington, D. C. April, 1942. (Mimeo.) 
 
Farm Finance in Wartime 
 
 11 
 
 TABLE 3 
 
 Cash Income from Farm Marketings 
 
 Year 
 
 United States 
 
 Cash income 
 from sales of 
 crops, live- 
 stock, and 
 livestock 
 products 
 
 Government 
 payments 
 
 California 
 
 Cash income 
 from sales of 
 crops, live- 
 stock, and 
 livestock 
 products 
 
 Government 
 payments 
 
 1910 
 1911 
 1912 
 1913 
 1914 
 1915 
 1916 
 1917 
 1918 
 1919 
 1920 
 1921 
 1922 
 1923 
 1924 
 1925 
 1926 
 1927 
 1928 
 1929 
 1930 
 1931 
 1932 
 1933 
 1934 
 1935 
 1936 
 1937 
 1938 
 1939 
 1940 
 1941 
 
 million 
 
 dollars 
 
 5,785 
 
 5,581 
 
 5,966 
 
 6,251 
 
 6,015 
 
 6,391 
 
 7,755 
 
 10,648 
 
 13,464 
 
 14,436 
 
 12,553 
 
 8,107 
 
 8,518 
 
 9,524 
 
 10,150 
 
 10,927 
 
 10,529 
 
 10,699 
 
 11,024 
 
 11,221 
 
 8,883 
 
 6,283 
 
 4,682 
 
 5,278 
 
 6,273 
 
 6,969 
 
 8,212 
 
 8,788 
 
 7,649 
 
 7,852 
 
 8,331* 
 
 11,185* 
 
 million 
 dollars 
 
 131 
 447 
 573 
 287 
 367 
 482 
 807 
 766^ 
 
 million 
 dollars 
 
 508 
 560 
 577 
 606 
 633 
 690 
 568 
 447 
 360 
 407 
 466 
 515 
 613 
 692 
 563 
 592 
 641 
 849 
 
 million 
 dollars 
 
 * Preliminary. 
 Sources of data: 
 
 United States figures, 1910-1937, from: United States Department of 
 Agriculture. Agricultural Statistics 1941:554. 1941. 
 
 Other figures from: United States Bureau of Agricultural Economics. Farm 
 value, gross income, and cash income from farm production. [Title varies.] 
 Annual issues, August, 1930-February 26, 1942. (Mimeo.) 
 
 FARM INCOMES, CALIFORNIA AND THE UNITED STATES 
 
 Brief reference has been made to the fluctuations in United States 
 farm income during and after World War I. For the convenience of the 
 reader, these data are presented more fully in table 3 and figure 3. While 
 estimates are available back to 1910 for the United States as a whole, 
 
12 
 
 California Agricultural Extension Service [Cir. 126 
 
 those for California go back only to 1924. Hence it is not possible to show 
 the course of California farm income during and immediately after the 
 last war. 
 
 United States farm incomes for 1942 will undoubtedly be much higher 
 than those of recent years. Prices of farm products for the first quarter 
 of 1942 averaged more than a third higher than for the first quarter of 
 1941, and the volume of marketings for a number of the livestock prod- 
 
 14 
 12 
 10 
 8 
 6 
 4 
 2 
 
 
 
 c 
 
 c 
 
 - 
 
 
 
 
 A 
 
 1 
 
 
 
 / 
 
 A^ 
 
 
 / 
 
 - / 
 
 1/ ^ 
 
 \ A - 
 
 / 
 
 - / 
 
 
 \/ 
 
 
 ^/^"^"^^ 
 
 
 V 
 
 
 - 
 
 
 
 
 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 
 
 t 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 
 
 1 1 f 1 1 1 1 1 1 
 
 1 
 
 
 Fig. 3. — United States cash income from farm marketings, 
 1910-1941. (Source of data: table 3, col. 1.) 
 
 nets was larger than a year ago. The latest estimate of 1941 cash farm 
 income is 11.8 billion dollars as compared to 9.1 billions in 1940. Current 
 and prospective economic conditions suggest that 1942 income will be 
 close to 14 billions. The largest income on record was that of 14.6 billions 
 in 1919. Income per farm and per capita will probably set a new high 
 record this year.'' The income of California farms may well pass the 
 billion-dollar mark. 
 
 The index of prices received by farmers stood at 93 in 1939 (1909- 
 1914=100). In April, 1942, it stood at 150. This is an increase of more 
 than 60 per cent in less than three years and far exceeds the rate of 
 increase in prices of all commodities or in the costs of things farmers 
 
 " George, Frank. Income: increase. Agricultural Situation 26(3) :6. 1942. 
 
Farm Finance in Wartime 13 
 
 buy. The index for wholesale prices of all commodities rose in the same 
 period from 113 to 144 (approximately 27 per cent) . Prices for products 
 used by farmers for living rose from 120 to 150 (to March, 1942) ; those 
 for commodities used in production from 122 to 149 (to March, 1942). 
 Farm wage rates increased from 123 to 167 in the same period. They 
 have, of course, risen more than this in some areas and for some tasks. 
 
 During World War I, prices of farm products rose between 1914 and 
 1917, a comparable period, from an index of 101 to 175. Thus it will be 
 seen that the rise was more rapid in that period. Yet the rate of increase 
 over the past two years is certainly enough to cause grave concern. In 
 considering inflationary effects, the most important problem is the rate 
 of increase rather than the justice or injustice of the level from which the 
 advance started, or that of the level it has reached. It is evident that a 
 price increase for a major group of products so rapid as to gain more 
 than 50 per cent in less than two and a half years is bound to be seriously 
 disturbing to the whole economy if not checked. 
 
 A continued rise in food costs and other living expenses is certain to 
 set in motion far-reaching changes which will eventually react to the 
 disadvantage of farm people. Powerful demands for wage increases will 
 result; salaries of public employees will have to be adjusted; costs of 
 supplies will increase. These are the very items that do not fall so rap- 
 idly as do the prices of farm products when the spree is over. Thus farm- 
 ers may find themselves saddled not only with larger debts (if the higher 
 prices lead to land speculation) but with higher taxes, increased wage 
 rates, and many other items which will make for slow and painful re- 
 adjustment a few years hence. Farm taxes, for example, rose during and 
 following World War I from an index of 118 in 1914 to 281, but this 
 peak figure did not come until 1929, almost ten years after the drop in 
 farm prices. In California the increase was still more marked (from 124 
 in 1914 to 332 in 1928) . Wages in the United States stood at 105 in 1914, 
 but by 1920 they had reached 240. In 1932, twelve years after the fall 
 in farm prices, they still stood at 189." 
 
 It seems evident that regardless of views about parity and other goals, 
 farmers are likely to find their longer-term interests damaged by price 
 increases that are so large and so rapid as to set up an inflationary spirit. 
 There can be little doubt that in World War II, as in World War I, 
 farm prices led off the procession. This is not, of course, to say that other 
 advances would not have occurred had farm prices remained stable. It 
 does emphasize, however, the stake farmers have in policies which will 
 keep all prices relatively stable. 
 
 ^Warren, G. F., and F. A. Pearson. Prices, p. 206. John Wiley and Sons, Inc., New 
 York, N. Y. 1933. 
 
14 California Agricultural Extension Service [Cir. 126 
 
 FARM COSTS IN RELATION TO INCOME 
 
 The farmer's financial situation is reflected only in part by the record 
 of income changes. Costs also have an important bearing on amounts 
 available for debt repayment or capital increase. They react more slovv^ly 
 tlian do prices of things the farmer sells. Prices of farm products are 
 more flexible than those for most commodities and services. With sharply 
 increased demand or curtailed supply, they tend to rise quickly, and 
 under opposite circumstances to decline with equal or greater abrupt- 
 ness. 
 
 As previously indicated, both in "World War I and World War II, 
 agricultural prices have been near the head of the procession in the up- 
 swing, and the changes have been both rapid and large. In the earlier 
 period, farm prices jumped from 98 in 1915 to 175 in 1917. Two years 
 later they had reached 213. In this war they have moved up from 98 in 
 1940 to 150 in April, 1942. Tliey had reached 143 as early as December, 
 1941. The all-commodities index moved up nearly as much between 1915 
 and 1917 (from 102 to 172). This, however, included a number of com- 
 modities which had spectacular rises because of wartime conditions but 
 did not bulk large in the farmer's purchases. Chemicals, for example, 
 had already risen to 138 by 1915 and stood at 203 in 1917. Textiles like- 
 wise had risen from 96 to 175. On the other hand, household furnishings 
 and "miscellaneous items" had moved up only from 103 to 136 and from 
 79 to 111, respectively."" 
 
 On the down side we have seen that farm prices are likely to show 
 much quicker adjustments than those of many other types of commodi- 
 ties. They dropped from 213 in 1919 to 125 in 1921, and again in the 
 early thirties they fell from 126 in 1930 to 65 in 1932. Even with the far- 
 flung and costly efforts at price support applied during the late thirties, 
 farm prices fell from 121 in 1937 to 93 in 1939. In contrast, commodities 
 used in farm production declined only from 192 in 1919 to 141 in 1921. 
 Commodities used in family living did not reach their peak until 1920, 
 when they stood at 222. Their downward adjustment from 1919 to 1921 
 was from 210 to 161." Farm taxes continued their upward trend until 
 1929, when they stood at 281 as compared to 200 in 1919 and 259 in 1921. 
 
 Even if the index of the prices of things bought by farmers moved up 
 at the same rate as that of products sold by farmers, the higher incomes 
 now being received by farmers would still leave larger balances avail- 
 able for debt retirement, for savings, or for consumption. Only part of 
 
 "United States Department of Agriculture. Agricultural Statistics 1941:559. 
 1941. 
 
 "United States Department of Agriculture. Agricultural Statistics 1941:555. 
 1941. 
 
Farm Finance in Wartime 15 
 
 the cost of farm operation is in the form of cash outlays. If most of the 
 labor is hired, this is a cash cost and offsets a considerable part of the in- 
 crease in farm income. If the labor is largely or wholly supplied by the 
 farm family, a rising level of wages is reflected in more money for the 
 farm family to spend. Supplies, taxes, and costs for groceries and cloth- 
 ing are cash costs, but the several other items such as food and shelter 
 furnished by the farm, interest on owned investment, and depreciation, 
 unless equipment is actually replaced, are not cash items and may be 
 costing little if any more than in periods of lower prices. Interest charges 
 also, unless debt is increased, will remain relatively constant. Thus 
 despite increases in many of the cost items, net farm income is likely to 
 increase during a period of rapidly rising prices, unless practically 
 everything, including labor, is bought for cash. 
 
 In these circumstances an atmosphere of false prosperity is created. 
 Eventually, however, costs catch up and after farm incomes decline tend 
 to remain higher than before the rise and fall in farm incomes. Hence, if 
 obligations have been taken on on the basis of this temporary enlarge- 
 ment of spendable income, hardship is bound to result. 
 
 LONG-TERM TRENDS IN LAND VALUES 
 
 Until around 1900, land prices were established in relation to an 
 undeveloped frontier on which lands were still available for homestead- 
 ing. Farmers and prospective farmers had the alternative of buying 
 lands in the older farming areas or of undertaking the hardships, un- 
 certainties, and delay of developing a farm from the raw lands still 
 available in the West. Such lands were by no means "free" as compared 
 to those in the East and Middle West, but the form of payment was dif- 
 ferent. In these new areas, roads, schools, buildings, towns, and other 
 items of capital had still to be provided. Kainfall was more uncertain 
 and markets were distant. The savings which created the private and 
 public structures on these lands had to be provided through the priva- 
 tions of the settlers, except for such amounts as were borrowed. Records 
 of land prices during this time are meager and scattered. We may con- 
 clude, however, that an important if not a major factor in their deter- 
 mination was the cost in terms of hardship, time, and money, of develop- 
 ing available homestead lands in the West. The relation of land value to 
 farm incomes and to the business situation was apparently less direct 
 than in later years. 
 
 By 1900, or before, good lands available for homesteading had become 
 very scarce and the tide of pioneer settlement, which had lasted for 
 nearly three centuries, had about run its course. 
 
 From the late nineties until 1914, there was a significant and fairly 
 
16 California Agricultural Extension Service [Cir. 126 
 
 rapid rise in farm prices. This, coupled with the growing scarcity of land 
 for homesteading, brought about a continuing increase in the prices of 
 farm lands such that farmers came to look upon these increases as nor- 
 mal and a significant noncash item in their incomes. They were generally 
 willing to bid up the price of land beyond the level of a direct capitaliza- 
 tion of its current cash earning power. That is, if land was earning $6 
 per acre per year net and the customary rate of interest was 6 per cent, 
 it would yield a customary rate of interest on $100. Actually such land 
 was likely to sell at $150 per acre or even more, which put it on a basis 
 of 4 per cent or less in current earnings. The farmer, however, expected 
 it to rise 1 or 2 per cent a year in value so that he would get his normal 
 return on investment, even though it remained a noncash item retriev- 
 able only at some later period in life when the farm was sold, or in the 
 form of higher rents expected to be attainable after a few years of in- 
 creasing land values. 
 
 These increasing valuations on farm lands also enlarged the borrow- 
 ing power of farmers and contributed to a rising volume of mortgage 
 debt. Mortgages could be allowed to run indefinitely or even could be 
 added to without much pressure for repayment on the part of lenders, 
 since the security back of the mortgage was increasing in value. 
 
 After 1913 this tendency was accelerated. By 1917, when we entered 
 the war, the index number for farm-land prices in the United States had 
 advanced from 100 in 1913 to 108 in 1916, an increase of 2% per cent 
 a year. It was in the next four years, however, that the large and, as it 
 later proved, disastrous increases occurred. Land prices went to 117 in 
 1917, to 129 in 1918, to 140 in 1919, and to 170 in 1920.'" The greatest 
 increase of all occurred after the close of the war. It resulted from the 
 speculative impulses already set in motion and from the continuation 
 through 1919 of high prices for farm products. Many farmers had come 
 to believe that prices were on a permanently higher level. The fact that 
 prices did not decline significantly immediately after the Armistice 
 tended to clinch this belief. 
 
 After 1920 began the long and painful readjustment which resulted 
 from a reversal of this upward trend that had lasted for more than 
 twenty years. By 1933 the index of United States farm-land values had 
 dropped to 73, 27 points below what it had been in 1913. During these 
 thirteen years (1921-1933) the prices of farm lands showed an average 
 decline of more than 7.4 per cent a year. The large decreases, which make 
 up a good part of this average, occurred in 1921 and 1922 and in 1932 
 and 1933. It is evident that no farm owner who was not in a strong finan- 
 
 ^ United States Department of Agriculture. Agricultural Statistics 1941:583, 
 1941. 
 
Farm Finance in Wartime 17 
 
 cial position could stand declines of such magnitude without finding" 
 himself in difficulty. 
 
 The extremely low prices of 1933 were in part a result of the great 
 number of distress sales occurring at that time and did not represent 
 farmers' real estimates of future earning power of the lands. Great num- 
 bers of mortgages were falling due. Many creditor agencies, under neces- 
 sity of making their assets more liquid, were unable or unwilling to re- 
 new mortgages. New sources of funds were in the main unavailable until 
 1933, when the United States Government reorganized the federal-farm- 
 credit agencies and broadened their capacity to make loans. Since these 
 agencies afforded almost the only significant source of new loans at that 
 time, transfers to them reached unprecedented volumes. In 1933 the fed- 
 eral land banks had outstanding loans of 1.1 billion dollars. By 1937 
 these had reached 2.1 billions, and land bank commissioner loans which 
 had been initiated in 1934 stood at 836 millions.'^ During 1934 the vol- 
 ume of land bank and land bank commissioner loans made reached the 
 staggering figure of 107 millions a month." 
 
 This mammoth program of refinancing, together with the washing 
 up of a good part of the most desperate cases, brought a check to the 
 downward trend of land prices. With gradually improving conditions, 
 prices began to improve and by 1941 had reached an index of 86, which 
 was still 14 points below the 1913 level. 
 
 A release by the United States Department of Agriculture under date 
 of April 13, 1942, states that farm-real-estate prices have risen about 7 
 per cent in the 12 months March 1, 1941, to March 1, 1942. This is much 
 the most spectacular rise of recent years and comes within 3 points of 
 the increase of 1916 to 1917. It has led to some fears that the unfortunate 
 episode of 1917 to 1920 is about to be repeated. 
 
 LIKELIHOOD OF A SLUMP AFTER THE PRESENT WAR 
 
 Predicting for the future in a world so torn by struggles and forces of 
 unprecedented magnitude is indeed a hazardous undertaking. Many 
 new types of economic and monetary control have come into use since 
 1920. Most of them are too recent for safe appraisal of their effectiveness 
 and long-term results. In the United States we have tried easy-credit and 
 low-interest policies, gold buying, dollar devaluation, deficit spending, 
 crop control, and farm subsidies; in fact, nearly the whole gamut of 
 plans for raising the prices of farm products and industrial goods. Some 
 
 ^^ United States Department of Agriculture. Agricultural Statistics 1941:594. 
 1941. 
 
 " United States Bureau of Agricultural Economics. Federal land bank and land 
 bank commissioner loan activity decreases. Agricultural Finance Eeview 1(2) :60. 
 1938. (Lithoprinted.) 
 
J 
 
 I SR. 
 
 <t> 
 
 i? 
 
 
 
 t^ 
 
 s 
 
 bl) 
 
 
 
 <5 
 
 
 c3 
 
 
 O 
 
 13 
 
 
 03 
 
 
 rn 
 
 
 '^ 
 
 fl 
 
 a> 
 
 
 •4-1 
 
 p 
 
 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 
 Th 
 
 r| 
 
 +-> 
 
 
 13 
 
 o 
 
 CO 
 0) 
 
 -1-3 
 
 
 
 o 
 
 f^ 
 
 
 , 
 
 
 i^ 
 
 
 ,,— s 
 
 PH 
 
 
 
 O 
 
 
 a 
 
 
 o 
 I— 1 
 
 CT^ 
 
 P 
 
 
 II 
 
 tn 
 
 .. 
 
 
 a; 
 
 a 
 
 
 I— 1 
 
 o 
 
 o 
 
 
 Oi 
 
 r^ 
 
 ^H 
 
 
 I— 1 
 
 1 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 
 o 
 
 M 
 
 
 
 Ci 
 
 -M 
 
 T— 1 
 
 
 
 u 
 
 
 
 V— ^ 
 
 «S 
 
 c^i 
 
 
 rH 
 
 Ph 
 
 CO 
 
 
 "^ 
 
 
 Oi 
 
 
 Oi 
 
 (M 
 
 i-H 
 
 
 1— 1 
 
 CO 
 
 , 
 
 
 1 
 
 CTi 
 
 CvJ 
 
 
 CO 
 
 iH 
 
 CO 
 
 
 
 
 05 
 
 
 t- 
 
 •4^ 
 
 iH 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 oo 
 
 
 CO 03 
 
 T-H 
 
 
 Oi 
 
 t^ 
 
 1 
 
 
 4-i 
 
 rH CO 
 
 
 Tl 
 
 r/T 
 
 (N 
 
 
 n 
 
 ^ 
 
 Ttf 
 
 
 
 CtirH 
 
 
 i; 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 o 
 
 CO 
 l—i 
 
 o 
 
 a 
 
 
 r— 1 
 
 (M 
 
 <D 
 
 
 c3 
 
 o 
 
 % 
 
 
 O 
 
 •m 
 
 oi 
 
 
 
 OJ 
 
 -M 
 
 
 OJ 
 
 
 02 
 
 
 a 
 
 •S 
 
 Ph 
 
 ^-N 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 f! 
 
 
 I— 1 
 
 03 
 
 
 
 
 M 
 O 
 
 
 <I1 
 
 
 O 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 • • 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 '3 
 
 o 
 
 1 
 
 g 
 
 t% 
 
 
 % 
 
 o 
 
 .2 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 ?3 
 
 '3 
 
 <^ 
 
 m 
 
 ^^' .^ 
 
 r^ 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 2 
 
 -)-3 
 
 u 
 
 
 cvi 
 
 ;3 
 
 0) 
 
 ^ 
 
 6 
 
 
 be 
 
 <1 
 
 fl 
 
 t^ 
 
 
 >< 
 
 
 rri 
 
 <y 
 
 
 
 T— 1 
 
 
 t— 1 
 I 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 o 
 o 
 
 1 
 
 •" 
 
 03 
 
 o 
 
 ■«tl 
 
 a 
 
 o 
 
 
 w 
 
 bl 
 
 ^ 
 
 CO 
 
 1 
 
 \=^ 
 
 on 
 
 I— 1 
 
 ?3 
 
 
 CO 
 
 ;-i 
 
 
 
 Oi 
 
 O 
 
 13 
 
 aUSO J9,I 
 
Farm Finance in Wartime 19 
 
 degree of recovery was achieved during the thirties, but the results were 
 not all that was expected by the sponsors of these programs, and the 
 prices of most products did not approach those of 1919. Not until the 
 appearance of the huge demands occasioned by the outbreak of World 
 War II did prices of farm products show rapid and important increases. 
 Thus there is good reason to believe that war demand is the most impor- 
 tant factor in maintaining the current levels of prices. It is, of course, a 
 factor that will cease to operate after peace comes. 
 
 It is unsafe to judge the future too exclusively by the past. This is a 
 mistake some of the military leaders seem to have made in the present 
 war. Yet despite the differences in method, the results of the struggle 
 seem now to be taking on again many of the broad outlines of the 1918 
 picture, with Russia and France exchanging roles. Likewise in the realm 
 of economic affairs, the various war periods seem to show important simi- 
 larities despite widely differing conditions of economic development 
 and monetary and banking structure. 
 
 If we ignore the Mexican and Spanish wars, which had only minor 
 economic effect, the United States has passed through four major w^ar 
 periods : the American Revolution, the War of 1812, the American Civil 
 War, and World War I. Two of these, the War of 1812 and World War I, 
 were associated with world-wide dislocations of trade. The other two, 
 while not so definitely connected with major wars abroad, came in 
 periods of unsettled and precarious conditions in Europe. 
 
 The pattern of price behavior is surprisingly similar in all four 
 periods. Prices rose rapidly during the wars and fell sharply after 
 them. 
 
 Thus in the Revolutionary period the index of wholesale prices (1910- 
 1914 = 100) rose from 86 in 1776 to 226 in 1779. 
 
 In the Napoleonic period it rose from 115 in 1808 to 182 in 1814. 
 
 In the Civil War period it rose from 89 in 1861 to 193 in 1864. 
 
 In the period of World War I it rose from 99 in 1914 to 226 in 1920.'' 
 These changes are shown graphically in figure 4. 
 
 All of these increases were followed by rapid postwar recessions. In 
 the first period the nation was undeveloped, was, in fact, almost wholly 
 agricultural. It had no developed monetary system and little in the way 
 of banking and government organization. By 1918 it had a huge and 
 complicated industrial organization and a far more developed monetary 
 system and banking organization. Yet prices followed much the same 
 course in both cases. 
 
 Can we, then, safely conclude that because of new devices and policies 
 
 ^8 Warren, G. F., and F. A. Pearson. Wholesale prices for 213 years, 1720 to 1932. 
 Part I. Wholesale prices in the United States for 135 years, 1797 to 1932. New York 
 (Cornell) Agr. Exp. Sta. Memoir 142:6-10. 1932. 
 
20 California Agricultural Extension Service [Cir. 126 
 
 we have come into a new era where things will not happen that way 
 again? In 1919 many farmers were convinced that the higher price level 
 was permanent and there would not be a return to the prewar levels. 
 Yet in only a few years thereafter the prices of many farm products 
 were well below those of 1910 to 1914. Again, one must caution that pre- 
 dictions are dangerous. Yet when a farmer buys land at inflated prices 
 during a war period, he is predicting that war prices will continue. 
 We cannot say that they will not, but thus far the experience is 4 to 
 that they will return to substantially lower levels than those now existing. 
 The extent of such a drop is, of course, dependent in large measure 
 upon the magnitude of the rise during the war period. At the present 
 time, much more drastic attempts are being made to control the upswing 
 than were undertaken in any previous war period. If these efforts are 
 successful, the urge to speculate in land may be substantially lessened, 
 the costs of the war will be far lower, and the prospects of a disastrous 
 postwar slump or chaotic inflation will be markedly decreased. 
 
 REASONS FOR USE OF CREDIT 
 
 The purpose of credit is to put buying power in the hands of those who 
 can make the most effective use of it. The justification for borrowing, on 
 the part of the borrower, is the belief that he can make the borrowed 
 funds earn more than he has to pay for them, in the way of interest and 
 risk. The justification on the part of the lender is the belief that the net 
 interest (contract rate minus risk cost) will yield him more than he 
 could make by using the funds himself. Often, of course, the lender is in 
 no position to make any use of the funds and wants only safety plus 
 whatever earnings he can obtain. 
 
 The borrower is thus compelled to make an estimate of the returns out 
 of which the interest payments and principal can be paid. For short-term 
 loans such estimates can be made with a fair degree of assurance, esti- 
 mates being subject only to the characteristic production hazards and 
 year-to-year price variations. For longer-term loans the unpredictable 
 and sometimes ruinous hazards of a fall in the general price level are 
 involved. Thus, on the basis of 5 per cent interest, if a farmer buys 100 
 acres of land currently yielding a net return of $10 per acre, he will pay 
 $20,000 for it. Possibly half of this, or $10,000, is his own investment and 
 half is borrowed. If he plans to pay this off at the end of twenty years, 
 he would normally expect to pay over the twenty years $10,000 in 
 interest and to forego whatever return he might have had on his own 
 $10,000. If that could have earned, say, 3 per cent, the total cost for the 
 twenty years, assuming no change in land earnings or land values, will 
 have been $16,000. To cover this, he will expect to obtain a net return 
 
Farm Finance in Wartime 21 
 
 averaging $10 per acre per year, or $20,000. This would be the situation 
 if no speculative gains or losses were involved and if annual payments on 
 principal were not made. If, however, net earnings of the land should 
 fall by only as much as $5 per acre per year during this period, the true 
 value of the farm at the end of this time would be only $10,000. The total 
 cost to the farm purchaser will then have been $10,000 interest on the 
 mortgage plus the $6,000 interest on his own investment, which he might 
 have secured had he not invested it in land, plus also the $10,000 of 
 capital value lost. This is a total of $26,000 or an annual cost of $1,300, 
 whereas his original expectation was only for an earning of $1,000 a 
 year from the land. In the meantime, this earning will have fallen to 
 $500 a year. 
 
 The usual practice now, of course, is to make some payment on the 
 principal year by year, which would reduce the total cost for interest. 
 The general principle, however, is that illustrated. 
 
 It is also true that the earnings of the land, and in consequence its 
 price, may rise rather than fall and thus a profit will be shown. But if 
 we can judge by the experience of the past twenty years, land purchased 
 in a period of high prices is more likely to decline in value than to in- 
 crease. While the illustration may seem extreme as to the amount of 
 decrease, the figures show that for the nation as a whole an even greater 
 decline in land values did occur in less than twenty years. The index of 
 estimated value per acre fell from 170 in 1920 to 73 in 1933. 
 
 No one can say whether this situation is likely to be repeated. Factors 
 which appear to make improbable a sustained advance in the valuation 
 of farm real estate in the United States are the following. We have a 
 large, developed capacity for farm production. Population is not increas- 
 ing at rates that previously prevailed. Thus consumption of farm prod- 
 ucts cannot be expected to increase so rapidly as in some earlier periods. 
 Several competing agricultural areas have been undergoing rapid de- 
 velopment and mechanization in recent years, notably Canada, Aus- 
 tralia, Argentina, Brazil, South Africa, and Russia. Interest rates are 
 the lowest in our history. (An annual income capitalized at a low rate 
 of interest makes for a high valuation in land. ) Markedly higher interest 
 rates do not seem in prospect, but on the other hand, there seems little 
 likelihood of significant lowering of the rates now prevailing. Thus the 
 majority of the factors involved do not point in the direction of markedly 
 higher values in land in the longer-term postwar period. 
 
 On the other side of the picture is the possibility of monetary inflation, 
 which might increase land values markedly if it occurs. This would 
 appear in the form of higher prices and incomes, which presumably 
 would make the retirement of debts easier. Predictions about this are 
 
22 California Agricultural Extension Service [Cir. 126 
 
 of little value at the present time. It is evident that the government will 
 use very drastic methods to prevent inflation. The experience of other 
 warring countries indicates that a considerable measure of control can 
 be achieved if the action taken is sufficiently comprehensive and force- 
 ful. Even though inflation should take hold, however, past experience 
 indicates that prices would again recede long before most farm mort- 
 gages incurred in the inflationary period had been paid off. Speculative 
 undertakings looking to purcliase and resale at an advance in price 
 during an inflationary period are, of course, on a par with speculation 
 in common stocks or in commodities and present the same opportunities 
 and dangers. In general, speculation of this kind is dangerous for those 
 whose financial condition makes them unable to afford losses if prices 
 take an unexpected turn. 
 
 Why, then, do farm families undertake the risks of land purcliase? 
 There are a number of reasons, aside from the purely financial. One is 
 the desire for an assured place of residence and work opportunity. 
 Another is the satisfaction and pride in ownership of land. Still others 
 are the desire to round out an operating unit to a more efficient and 
 satisfactory size or makeup and the desire to put savings into a form 
 which seems substantial and one in which the farmer feels he knows 
 values. 
 
 These are desirable aims and should be encouraged provided they do 
 not result in excessive bidding up of values and the assumption of dan- 
 gerous and unwieldy loads of debt. As in the purchase of stocks or other 
 investments, many of the dangers are avoided if purchases can be made 
 outright with little or no borrowing. Then losses of money values may 
 occur, but the real property remains and continues to be an asset rather 
 than a liability, even though a smaller one than had been anticipated. 
 Certainly such investment of surplus funds in a type of property whose 
 value is known is a safer outlet for surplus funds of most farm people 
 than is the purchase of stocks and bonds of enterprises they know little 
 about. There is, however, an alternative and safe outlet for surplus 
 funds, as is discussed in' a later section, namely, government bonds, 
 federal-land-bank bonds, and similar securities. 
 
 We have discussed at length the purposes and dangers in borrowing 
 for land purchase. These considerations may have little bearing on the 
 advisability of borrowing for short periods for purposes of production. 
 Here the likelihood of large and unpredictable changes in the general 
 price level is much less. The major concern is with the probability of 
 being able to make a profit on the funds so used and with timing the 
 loan in such a way as to minimize interest charges and make repayment 
 possible at the time agreed upon. There is, to be sure, considerable risk 
 
Farm Finance in Wartime 23 
 
 of failure in production and of sudden price changes. Fluctuations in 
 production and prices, however, are likely to average out over a period of 
 two or three years. Also the amounts involved for such production loans 
 are seldom as large in proportion to prospective earnings over the years 
 as are those resulting from purchases of land. Some dangers do exist, 
 however, in the purchase of heavy equipment in periods of high prices 
 with plans for making payment over a period of years. The purchase of 
 tractors, automobiles, and similar equipment contributed in no small 
 measure to the financial difficulties of farmers in 1920 and 1921. The 
 precipitous drop in farm prices in August, 1920, found many with un- 
 desirably heavy short- and medium-term commitments. Many of these 
 had later to be converted into mortgage debt and thus contributed to 
 the continued rise in mortgage debt after farm prices and land prices 
 had begun their downward trend. 
 
 INTEREST ON FARM LOANS 
 
 Average rates of interest charged on farm-mortgage loans in California 
 stood at 6.9 per cent in 1910, the earliest year for which estimates are 
 available. There was little change until 1934, when they first dropped 
 below 6.5 per cent. They reached a low of 5.6 per cent in 1938, but 
 increased slightly in 1940 to 5.7 per cent.^^ 
 
 During recent years the rates charged by the federal land banks 
 throughout the country have been reduced below the market rate by 
 special act of Congress. Land-bank rates reached their peak in 1921, 
 when they stood at 6 per cent (their legal maximum). Thereafter they 
 declined gradually with the improving salability of land-bank bonds, 
 the larger availability of low-cost funds, and certain special guarantees 
 and aids provided by the federal government. By 1935 the average rate 
 in California stood at 4.9 per cent, probably the lowest figure for these 
 farm-mortgage loans in the history of the state (table 4). Thereafter, 
 under the general easy-money policy of the government, together with 
 interest guarantees on land-bank bonds, interest rates fell to levels far 
 below those of any previous period. For land-bank borrowers, the con- 
 tract rate of interest is now 4 per cent on loans made through most 
 national farm loan associations, 4I/4 per cent on loans made under special 
 authority through associations having stock of impaired value, 4^/2 V^^ 
 cent on loans made directly to the borrower by the bank and not through 
 an association, and 5 per cent on commissioner loans. By act of Congress, 
 however, the following reduced rates on both federal-land-bank and 
 land-bank-commissioner loans (regardless of the rate written on the 
 
 ^^Horton, Donald C, Harald C. Larsen, and Norman J. Wall. Farm-mortgage 
 credit facilities in the United States. U. S. Dept. Agr. Misc. Pub. 478:227-28. 1942. 
 
24 
 
 California Agricultural Extension Service [Cir. 126 
 
 mortgage) are in effect until July 1, 1944: federal-land-bank loans 
 through national farm loan associations, S^/o per cent; loans under 
 special authority through associations with impaired stock, 3%^ per 
 cent ; direct loans, 4 per cent; commissioner loans, 3% per cent/° 
 
 TABLE 4 
 
 Average Rates of Interest Charged on Farm-Mortgage Loans Recorded 
 Annually in California, 1917-1935 
 
 Year 
 
 Individ- 
 uals 
 
 National 
 
 and 
 
 state 
 
 banks 
 
 Insurance 
 companies 
 
 Federal 
 land bank 
 and land 
 bank com- 
 missioner 
 
 Joint- 
 stock 
 land 
 banks 
 
 Others 
 
 All 
 
 1917 
 
 1918 
 
 1919 
 
 1920 
 
 1921 
 
 1922 
 
 1923. , 
 
 per cent 
 6 3 
 6,4 
 6,3 
 
 6,4 
 6.6 
 6.7 
 6.6 
 6,7 
 6.6 
 6 6 
 6 6 
 6.6 
 6 5 
 
 6.6 
 6.6 
 6,5 
 6,4 
 6,1 
 6,0 
 
 per cent 
 6,4 
 6,8 
 6,9 
 
 6,9 
 7.1 
 6.9 
 6.9 
 
 6 9 
 
 7 
 6.9 
 6 9 
 6.7 
 6 7 
 
 6.8 
 7.0 
 6.7 
 6.5 
 6.3 
 6.4 
 
 per cent 
 7,5 
 6,9 
 7,0 
 
 7,4 
 
 7.5 
 7.1 
 6.8 
 7,1 
 6.9 
 6,5 
 7,4 
 6,6 
 6 4 
 
 6,4 
 6,4 
 6 7 
 6,9 
 5,5 
 6,6 
 
 per cent 
 5 
 5,4 
 5,5 
 
 5 6 
 6,0 
 5,7 
 5,5 
 5 4 
 5,4 
 5 5 
 5 3 
 5 
 5,3 
 
 5,5 
 5,5 
 5,5 
 5,1 
 5,0 
 4,9 
 
 per cent 
 
 6 
 6 
 6,0 
 6,0 
 6 
 6,0 
 6 
 6 
 6 
 6,0 
 
 6,0 
 6,0 
 
 5,8 
 6,0 
 6 
 6,0 
 
 per cent 
 6,5 
 7.4 
 7.2 
 
 6 7 
 6 9 
 6,7 
 6.4 
 6.9 
 6.5 
 6.7 
 6.5 
 6.5 
 6.5 
 
 6.6 
 6.7 
 6.6 
 6.5 
 
 5.8 
 6,1 
 
 per cent 
 6,4 
 6 5 
 6.6 
 
 6,6 
 6,9 
 6,7 
 6 7 
 
 1924 
 
 1925 
 
 1926 
 
 1927 
 
 6,8 
 6.7 
 6.7 
 6.6 
 
 1928 
 
 1929 
 
 1930 
 
 1931 
 
 1932 
 
 1933 . 
 
 6.6 
 6.6 
 
 6.7 
 6.7 
 6.6 
 
 6 2 
 
 1934 
 
 5 5 
 
 1935 
 
 5.9 
 
 Source of data: 
 
 United States Bureau of Agricultural Economics. Farm-mortgage recordings in California, p. 6, 
 Washington, D. C. March, 1939. (Mimeo.) 
 
 The special rates last mentioned are made possible only by subsidies 
 from the federal government, and unless other action is taken in the 
 meantime the contract rates written into the mortgages will again come 
 into effect on July 1, 1944. 
 
 Specific tabulations of the interest rates in California charged by the 
 various lending agencies from 1917 to 1935 (the only period for which 
 these data are available) are shown in table 4. 
 
 Interest rates on farm mortgages are about as favorable as those to 
 any group of borrowers. For the nation as a whole and as an average for 
 all classes of lenders, rates had dropped from approximately 6 per cent 
 in 1929 to around 5 per cent in 1938. The contract rate of 4 per cent on 
 
 ^"Farm Credit Administration, 11th District. Summary of activities, p. 3. Berke- 
 ley, California. April 15, 1941. 
 
Farm Finance in Wartime 25 
 
 federal-land-bank loans was reported in 1939 as the lowest mortgage rate 
 available to any class of individual borrowers in the country. The average 
 rate of 5.25 per cent paid on mortgages in 1937 was lower than the 
 average of 5.90 per cent paid on mortgages on urban properties and 5.28 
 per cent for all industrial enterprises. The average farm-mortgage rate 
 was lower than for any important enterprise except the 4.55 per cent 
 paid on long-term indebtedness of railroads and 4.71 per cent on public 
 utilities.^' 
 
 The exceedingly favorable situation with respect to terms and interest 
 rates on farm-mortgage loans may well be stressed at this time since they 
 make unlikely a degree of federal relief in any succeeding period com- 
 parable to that afforded in the depression of the thirties. Not only was 
 the interest rate lowered, often by as much as one third, but long-term 
 amortized loans were introduced on a scale previously unknown in this 
 country in the field of farm loans. Such relief was made possible through 
 the existence of abnormally low rates for money generally and the fact 
 that important and overdue improvements in the provision of farm- 
 mortgage credit were put into effect; there was also a substantial amount 
 of federal subsidy. 
 
 A policy of subsidizing interest rates in normal times is not to be 
 recommended since it tends to stimulate borrowing and may lead to the 
 placing of excessive valuations on land. Such higher valuations are of 
 benefit only to those who own land at the time the increase occurs since 
 later purchasers have discounted the advantage through the higher price 
 paid and may actually suffer serious loss if the subsidy is later with- 
 drawn. If such a subsidy is continued indefinitely, it may operate merely 
 to maintain an artificial level of land prices which will benefit no one 
 once the land has changed hands and the interest-rate subsidy has been 
 translated into higher land prices. 
 
 It would seem the part of wisdom, therefore, for farmers and the 
 government to foster in normal times an efficient lending procedure op- 
 erating on a self-supporting basis and providing to farmers the lowest 
 rates of interest and the most favorable terms compatible with conditions 
 in the money market. Under such a policy, special aid may be warranted 
 in periods of serious distress. Credit institutions which require con- 
 tinuous subsidization have been found in the past to be in danger of 
 adverse legislative action withdrawing the subsidy and in some cases 
 wrecking the institution. This has, in fact, been the fate of most of the 
 state farm loan agencies set up in this country. 
 
 The debt situation of American farmers is now the most favorable that 
 
 2^ Farm Credit Administration. Farmers' interest bill lowered. Press Service 9-54. 
 March 20, 1939. (Mimeo.) 
 
26 California Agricultural Extension Service [Cir. 126 
 
 it has been in a quarter of a century. If the proceeds of currently better 
 incomes can be used wisely for the reduction of existing mortgage debt 
 and the accumulation of reserves, American agriculture may well come 
 out of this period in the strongest financial position it has ever held. 
 But if the present favorable terms and interest rates lead it into exten- 
 sive speculation and borrowing, the burden in any succeeding serious 
 depression may be even more onerous than that of the thirties. 
 
 THE PROBLEM OF RESIDENTIAL AND SPECULATIVE 
 VALUES IN LANDS 
 
 There are two fairly distinct bases for value in farm lands. One is the 
 present and prospective net income from farm production. The other 
 is a value resting upon its desirability as a place of residence or its poten- 
 tialities as a producer of wealth of some other kind. Thus lands located 
 in an area of possible or probable oil development are likely to be valued 
 at more than the present or prospective farm-production incomes would 
 warrant. Lands near enough to cities to be likely areas for home or indus- 
 trial sites are likewise apt to be overvalued on the basis of current 
 earnings from farm products. 
 
 The values which are not based upon returns from farm production 
 may be, and often are, substantial and justifiable. They are apt to be 
 somewhat more speculative, however. Those based upon farm production 
 are speculative in that prices or production or both may fluctuate from 
 period to period. Nevertheless, there will normally be some production 
 and some continuing income which can be realized without selling the 
 property itself. To realize the other values and income in cash, however, 
 the property must usually be sold. Residential values may, of course, 
 be in the form of satisfactions to the farm operator and his family. They 
 are based upon an income which actually exists, but which is not in cash 
 and which is consumed continuously by the farm family as a part of its 
 real income. While such real income is a warrantable basis for value in 
 land, it is not a suitable basis for credit unless the farm operator has from 
 other sources than the farm a reasonably sure source of income with 
 which to carry it. It is in a sense a luxury which is entirely commendable 
 provided the farm family has sufficient capital to pay outright for the 
 value attributable to this kind of income and, in addition, enough to 
 provide a reasonable margin of safety on that part of the land value 
 attributable to net income from farm production. 
 
 Thus a farm may be capable of earning a return on $10,000. It is, 
 however, in an attractive location where schools, roads, churches, and 
 other facilities are good or where there are prospects of speculative gains 
 from further development. Enough people want these added advantages 
 
Farm Finance in Wartime 27 
 
 so that prices of this and comparable farms are bid up to $15,000. This 
 added $5,000 may be a wise investment in better family living provided 
 the buyer owns it outright or has outside income to take care of it. It is 
 not a suitable basis for credit which is to be serviced by income from the 
 products of the farm. Such a farm might warrant, on a 50 per cent basis, 
 a loan of $5,000. It would not warrant a loan of $7,500 unless outside 
 sources of income are clearly in prospect. To make the larger loan is to 
 endanger the borrower and very possibly to involve the lender in pro- 
 ceedings to force the sale of the property. 
 
 In a similar manner, lands which have prospects of higher values 
 through residential development, oil discoveries, or prospective new 
 irrigation enterprises may be entirely warrantable speculative invest- 
 ments, but these prospects cannot be regarded as a good basis for the 
 ordinary types of farm loan. These are made for production of agri- 
 cultural crops, and the service charges on them are intended to be met 
 by the income from such production. They do not contemplate sale of 
 the property for satisfaction of the loan. 
 
 This distinction is especially important in times like the present when 
 attention is apt to be focused upon the selling prices of land or its merits 
 as an offset to possible depreciation in the value of money rather than 
 upon its current and prospective earning power. In land as in stocks, 
 investments based upon these considerations may well be warranted 
 provided the purchaser is able to pay cash in full or at least to make a 
 very large down payment and does not have to bid too high for the thing 
 purchased. If either lands or stocks are owned outright, they may slirink 
 in value but the shrinkage will not result in disaster or unbearable 
 burdens of debt. 
 
 Estimates of probable net earnings from farm production must also, 
 of course, be considered with special care in times like the present if 
 long-term loans are involved. Such loans call for a long series of pay- 
 ments which may have to come out of earnings much smaller than those 
 of the present time. Where mortgage loans are already in existence, or 
 are made at the present time, this danger can be lessened by accumulat- 
 ing reserves to meet possible later deficits in income. The federal land 
 banks have special provisions for this. For loans from other agencies, 
 reserves can be built up in government bonds or similar forms of saving. 
 
 The basic principle involved is that speculative values not based upon 
 continuous income from production and values based upon noncash 
 income, such as attractiveness for residential purposes, should not be 
 used as a means of securing debts unless the borrower is prepared to face 
 the prospect of enforced sale and the creditor to force such sale if 
 necessary. 
 
28 California Agricultural Extension Service [C^r. 126 
 
 SAVINGS AND THE USE OF CREDIT 
 
 As was shown in an earlier section, net farm incomes are running 
 larger than in any period since 1919. Cash expenses have not yet caught 
 up with them. As a consequence, farm families have a greater oppor- 
 tunity for debt retirement and the accumulation of savings than they 
 have had in more than twenty years. 
 
 The responsibility for large-scale buying of war bonds and stamps 
 rests alike on farm and nonfarm families. There is every reason to 
 expect, as in the last war, generous and patriotic response on the part 
 of farm people. 
 
 Although it may be safely assumed that large amounts will be put into 
 this wholehearted support of the war effort, the present period offers 
 one of the best opportunities this generation has seen for reducing farm 
 indebtedness and getting into a strong position to meet the difficult times 
 that may be ahead. That farmers are taking advantage of this possibility 
 is evident in the record of advance payments and pay-offs on mortgage 
 loans due the federal land banks. Especially favorable arrangements 
 have been made whereby borrowers from that agency may make advance 
 payments which can in case of need be drawn upon to meet future install- 
 ments and which otherwise will operate to advance the retirement of 
 the mortgage. Such accumulations draw interest at the prevailing rate 
 of the land bank and thus serve to reduce the interest load borne by the 
 borrower. Furthermore, mortgages are being retired at a rate of more 
 than 500 per month (for the Eleventh Farm Loan District as a whole) . 
 
 In general, the farm-mortgage situation, both in California and in 
 the United States, is getting into a more wholesome condition than for 
 many years. Much of the mortgage debt has been converted to amortized 
 long-term form. In 1940, federal-land-bank^ and land-bank-commissioner 
 loans in California amounted to 135 million dollars as compared to 5-8 
 millions for land-bank and joint-stock-land-bank loans in 1930 and 11 
 millions in 1920.^^ All of these are amortized long-term loans. In addition, 
 significant amounts of insurance-company and "other-lender" loans 
 have been converted to an amortization basis. On January 1, 1940, total 
 mortgage loans for the state amounted to 542 million dollars, of which 
 393 millions was held by individuals, banks, and others, and 13 millions 
 by life-insurance companies. 
 
 For the United States, farm-mortgage loans had been reduced by 
 January 1, 1940, to 7 billion dollars, the lowest figure since 1918, and 
 nearly 4 billions less than the peak amount of nearly 11 billions in 1923. 
 
 ^ United States Bureau of Agricultural Eeonomics. Agricultural loans in Califor- 
 nia (1942). p. 2. 1942. (Mimeo.) 
 
Farm Finance in Wartime 29 
 
 Not all farms are mortgaged. In California about half of the owner- 
 operated farms are thus encumbered. For farm families whose farms are 
 not mortgaged, the current situation offers better than usual opportun- 
 ities to accumulate a reserve. This can be done with benefit both to them- 
 selves and to the war effort. A major problem of national management 
 at the present time is that of absorbing excess purchasing power in the 
 hands of consumers. National income has risen from around 60 or 70 
 billions to well over 100 billions. At the same time, goods available for 
 purchase are substantially fewer than they were a few years ago. If much 
 of this increased purchasing power finds its way into the consumer-goods 
 market, there will be excessive competition for a sharply limited supply 
 of goods. Prices will surge upward despite controls, and quality will 
 deteriorate. 
 
 If, instead, nearly all of the free purchasing power except that re- 
 quired for buying necessities can be absorbed in debt retirement, tax 
 payments, and savings, income receivers will buy their necessities at 
 lower prices and will acquire important volumes of savings, which not 
 only will buy more and better goods later, but will aid substantially in 
 meeting the postwar readjustment. 
 
 There would be an enlarged potential demand for many commodities 
 even if the national income had not grown so enormously. Many of the 
 most expensive items of family equipment, such as automobiles, radios, 
 refrigerators, and washing machines, are not now being manufactured. 
 Hence, some of the income formerly used in ordinary living is now being 
 freed for purchase of other goods or for taxes and saving. The absorption 
 of such funds will have to be very drastic and comprehensive if serious 
 price inflation is to be avoided. 
 
 As a whole, farmers have been for many decades interest payers in- 
 stead of interest receivers. The annual payments of interest have been a 
 heavy drain on farm incomes. The accumulation of substantial savings 
 in the form of war bonds could simplify very greatly the financing of 
 farm production and at the same time provide an interest income that 
 would offset much of that paid out on short-term loans. For the present 
 there are limitations on the pledging of some types of federal securities 
 as collateral since they are nonnegotiable, and borrowing on collateral 
 of that kind would be inflationary. It is likely, however, that once the 
 period of war financing; is over, assets of that kind can be used in place 
 of usual types of security in obtaining loans for agricultural production. 
 Thus the ordinary financing of farm operations for farmers owning such 
 securities could be much simplified wdiile interest charges on similar 
 amounts would be largely offset. For example, a loan of $1,000 for 4 
 months at 6 per cent would require less interest payment than would be 
 
30 California Agricultural Extension Service [Cir. 126 
 
 brought in by $1,000 in bonds at 2% or 3 per cent. If held to maturity, 
 there would be no loss on the face amount of the bond even if the bond 
 market should decline in the meantime. 
 
 After the close of World War I, many farmers held substantial 
 amounts of Liberty Bonds. Unfortunately, great numbers were per- 
 suaded to part with these for stock purchase and other dubious financial 
 ventures. Promoters and stock salesmen found farmer owners of Liberty 
 Bonds a particularly fruitful market for the things they had to sell. In 
 the light of longer experience, it seems evident that most former holders 
 of such securities would have done better to hold them, except where 
 they had debts to pay, even though the rates of interest were less attrac- 
 tive than those prevailing or expected in some other forms of investment. 
 
 APPENDIX 
 
 WHAT CALIFORNIA FARMERS THINK ABOUT THE USE OF 
 CREDIT IN WARTIME 
 
 During the winter of 1941-42, representative farm men and women 
 in forty-two of California's fifty-eight counties assembled for one-day 
 conferences on credit use and related problems. These conferences were 
 arranged by the Agricultural Extension Service of the University of 
 California and were attended by 2,553 farm men and women, invited for 
 the specific purpose of discussing these problems and making recom- 
 mendations suited to conditions in their respective counties. Lectures 
 and other formal arrangements were limited to the minimum needed for 
 bringing out the more pertinent facts of the situation. There was no 
 attempt to influence their thinking or conclusions, except for such im- 
 plications as might arise from the facts presented. 
 
 After a brief presentation of charts and data by University repre- 
 sentatives and others, each conference broke up into several committees, 
 one of which discussed farm finance and credit. 
 
 The committees drew up resolutions and recommendations which were 
 then passed upon by the conference as a whole. The following summary 
 gives the gist of the conclusions arrived at in the forty-two conferences. 
 This summary covers for the most part only the results of the finance 
 committees, since the other subjects dealt with lie outside the scope of 
 this circular. 
 
 There is a surprising uniformity in points considered most important 
 by these various groups of farm people. All were impressed by the long 
 history of wartime inflation and deflation and the dangers of unwise 
 
Farm Finance in Wartime 31 
 
 borrowing in periods of high prices. "While it is difficult to classify accu- 
 rately the numerous recommendations with their wide variations in 
 wording, the following points are the ones appearing most frequently 
 in the summaries of the conferences — the ones that seemed to stand out 
 in the minds of the farm people : 
 
 1. Recommendation that farm families use the increased incomes of 
 the war period to reduce their long-term debts, if they have any, 
 and to put themselves in strong financial condition. (Presented and 
 adopted at thirty-six of the forty-two conferences. ) 
 
 2. Recommendation that loans be based on long-term, or "normal," 
 valuations of land rather than on any inflated valuations that may 
 arise as a result of war conditions. (Presented and adopted at 
 twenty-nine conferences.) 
 
 3. Recommendation that financial reserves be built up during the 
 present period of higher incomes., (Presented and adopted at twen- 
 ty-one conferences. ) 
 
 4. Recommendation that farmers buy war bonds. (Covered in prin- 
 ciple in practically all of the conferences, but mentioned specifically 
 in only eighteen.) 
 
 5. Recommendation that special efforts be made both by lending agen- 
 cies and by farmers to discourage speculative purchase of land. 
 (Presented and adopted at fifteen conferences.) 
 
 Many other points were discussed and acted upon by one or more of 
 the county meetings. Nine conferences mentioned specifically a feeling 
 that existing credit agencies are adequate and that credit should be 
 secured through them rather than by tapping new sources or drawing 
 significant amounts of outside private funds into the industry. A few 
 stressed the importance of preventing inflation. In general, however, the 
 technical nature of this problem kept it out of active discussion. There 
 was considerable stress on limiting short-term credit to farmers com- 
 petent to use it effectively but, with that limitation, a feeling that short- 
 term loans for production should be both granted and taken freely with 
 a view to enlarging production on existing units. There appeared to be 
 little feeling that any shortage of such funds is in prospect. Several con- 
 ferences recommended against the advance of credit and use of materials 
 for operations by inexperienced people or on lands of dubious produc- 
 tivity. 
 
 Some groups recommended more conservative loaning on one-crop 
 farms than on those which are diversified. The need for enlarging or 
 rounding out some farm units was recognized, and in several conferences 
 
32 California Agricultural Extension Service [Cir. 126 
 
 was regarded as a legitimate basis for borrowing for land purchase if 
 the obligations assumed are not so large as to endanger the operator's 
 solvency. 
 
 Interest rates came in for relatively little discussion, and the various 
 resolutions reflect some differences of opinion. A few conferences 
 recommended continuance of the subsidized interest rates now in effect, 
 while others urged either early or gradual return to a nonsubsidy basis. 
 
 In six counties specific recommendation was made that farmers now 
 holding short-term mortgages arrange to refinance these on a long-term 
 amortized basis. One county group suggested repeal of the Frazier- 
 Lempke amendment to the federal bankruptcy act on the ground that 
 it tends to inhibit normal new financing. 
 
 In general, the tone of the conferences and of the resolutions passed 
 looked strongly in the direction of conservative financing in the present 
 period. Major stress was on repayment of debts, accumulation of re- 
 serves, purchase of bonds, confining loans to qualified borrow^ers, and 
 putting the house in order for whatever adverse conditions may arise in 
 the postwar period. For the short run, nearh^ all of the conferences 
 favored the use of production credit where it can be made to contribute 
 to the war program, but urged caution in regard to becoming over- 
 extended, especially in speculative lines. 
 
 In the sections dealing wi th family living, emphasis was placed upon 
 accumulation of reserves in the form of war bonds and stamps, life in- 
 surance, savings accounts, tax-savings certificates, and the creation of 
 family cash reserves. It was pointed out that money saved in these ways 
 will not only help to prevent inflation but can be used to better advantage 
 in improving family living when new and better equipment, furnishings, 
 and building materials become available after the close of the war. It 
 was felt that long-term indebtedness for household or family living pur- 
 poses should be discouraged, that credit should not be used to raise the 
 standard of living, and, in general, that installment credit or easy- 
 payment plans should not be used. Since little new household equipment 
 will be made, present equipment should be put in good repair. Strerss was 
 also placed on the production for home use of milk, meat, poultry, eggs, 
 fruits, berries, and vearetables. 
 
 15W-11, '42(3102)