I ! ?p fifl Jill 1 I 111 I! MODERN TARIFF HISTORY GERMANY UNITED STATES FRANCE MODEEN TAEIFF HISTOEY GERMANY-UNITED STATES-FRANCE BY PERCY ASHLEY, M.A. WITH A PREFACE BY THE RT. HON. R. B. HALDANE, LL.D., K.C., M.P. AUTHOR OF "THE PATH WAV TO REALITY," ETC. LONDON JOHN MURRAY, ALBEMARLE STREET 1904 LIBRARY UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA SAiNTA BARBARA CONTENTS PART I GERMANY CHAPTER PAGE I. THE FORMATION OF THE ZOLLVEREIN . . 3 II. THE BEGINNINGS OF PROTECTION AND THE FIRST CRISIS . . ... 20 III. THE SECOND CRISIS AND THE COMMERCIAL TREATIES . . . 35 IV. THE ZOLLVEREIN AFTER THE TREATIES THE COMPLETION OF FREE TRADE AND THE RE- ACTION . . . 48 V. THE ATTITUDE OF THE ECONOMISTS . . 63 VI. GERMAN COMMERCIAL POLICY TO 1894 . . 78 VII. THE REVIVAL OF THE PROTECTIONIST MOVE- MENT, AND THE NEW TARIFF . . .100 VIII. RECENT ECONOMIC DISCUSSION IN GERMANY . 113 A BRIEF BIBLIOGRAPHY . . . 137 PART II THE UNITED STATES I. THE ORIGINS OF AMERICAN COMMERCIAL POLICY 141 II. THE GROWTH OF PROTECTION AND THE COMPRO- MISE OF 1833 . . . i 60 III. COMPROMISE, PROTECTION, AND REACTION ECO- NOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES TO 1860 . . ... 175 IV. WAR TAXATION AND ITS RETENTION FOR PRO- TECTIVE PURPOSES . . . 193 vi CONTENTS CHAPTER PAGE V. POLITICAL PARTIES AND THE TARIFF ECONOMIC PROGRESS OF THE UNITED STATES TO 1890 . 212 VI. THE NEW THEORY OF PROTECTION AND THE McKiNLEY TARIFF . . . .225 VII. THE WILSON AND DINGLEY TARIFFS . . 239 VIII. RECIPROCITY UNDER THE AMERICAN TARIFF CONCLUSION . . . . . 252 A BRIEF BIBLIOGRAPHY . . . 263 PART III FRANCE I. FRENCH COMMERCIAL POLICY FROM 1789 TO 1830 267 II. THE MONARCHY OF JULY . ... 284 III. THE SECOND REPUBLIC AND THE SECOND EMPIRE THE COMMERCIAL TREATIES . . . 296 IV. COMMERCIAL POLICY, 1870-81 . . . 313 V. THE MOVEMENT TOWARDS PROTECTION FOR AGRI- CULTURE THE FRANCO-ITALIAN TARIFF WAR. 327 VI. THE TARIFF OF 1892 AND SUBSEQUENT DEVELOP- MENTS THE FRANCO-SWISS TARIFF WAR CONCLUSION . . ... A BRIEF BIBLIOGRAPHY . ... INDEX . . . ... 361 PREFACE THE year 1903 will be a memorable one in the history of British politics. After a period notable mainly for its lack of interest a stirring controversy arose. Sides were taken violently, and families were divided. The line of party cleavage was destroyed. There was as much bitterness within the ranks of the Conservative party as there had been, seventeen years before, within the ranks of Liberalism about Home Rule. And yet, as in the latter case, the split was over no novel topic. In both its economic and its Imperial aspects the proposition which convulsed politicians and dis- tracted statesmen had been made many times before. What was fresh was only this, that a protagonist of the first order had come on the scene, a minister of commanding personality and great energy. He declared himself converted to the necessity of the new policy, and it was not long before he found at least half the Unionist party at his back. It is not Mr. Chamberlain's way to do things by halves, and in an incredibly short time he had founded a powerful organisation to support and develop his idea. There were viii PREFACE meetings everywhere, and people could talk of nothing but the fiscal question and its bear- ing on colonial policy. The British public took its usual course. It delights in the spectacle of a strong man fighting, and it showed its pleasure in rounds of applause. But this could not con- tinue. In its heart the public hates everything sudden, especially when it takes the shape of an abstract proposition. What was put before the country, the eloquence and energy of the pro- tagonist notwithstanding, was propounded both suddenly and in an abstract form. People began to ask about the cost, and then to grow suspicious and sulky. The by-elections became ominous, and even London club enthusiasm flattened. At first the prejudice had been unduly for the policy. Later on it became markedly against it. The final opinion of the nation still remains for delivery ; the time for judgment has not yet come. Speculation as to what that judgment will be when the British mind has mastered the argument on both sides lies beyond the purpose and scope of these pages. One thing is, however, certain. Much good has arisen from the fact that men and women have been forced to bend their minds on a topic of momentous importance, and to think as closely as they are capable of doing. We are inclined by our national character to avoid sharply defined issues, and to evade them by middle courses. Here, protestations to the contrary not- withstanding, it quickly appeared that no middle PREFACE ix course could be anything but a hollow makeshift. Then there came about another good thing. The public began to feel that platitudes were of little weight on either side of the argument. In the early stage of the controversy they were as abundant as is usual in such discussions. Presently the necessity of precision in reasoning and of accuracy in figures and in materials became ap- parent. The expert rose in the popular estimation, and even the political economist assumed an heroic aspect. The works of Adam Smith, of Friedrich List, and of other great students, began to be displayed in the booksellers' windows. Then there were signs of something further. The public grew discontented with arguments and conclu- sions, however eminent their authors, which be- longed to days that were past. There arose an almost feverish desire for a more modern presenta- tion of the case on both sides, a presentation that should bring it up to date. People began to realise that the conditions of commercial and indus- trial competition had become vastly developed. They grew dimly aware that the controversy was of dimensions even further reaching than they had surmised. They learned that the problem had for a century past been occupying the attention of acute minds abroad, with the most varying and far-reaching results to national policy. They began to see that political as well as economic aspects had been and must be taken into account. In other words, the problem for Great Britain x PREFACE began to display itself as highly complex and full of ramifications, a problem on which the analogy of other countries with different political and geo- graphical conditions could at best throw a very dim light. It became apparent that the most careful scrutiny and weighing were at every point essential. The difficulty of counting the cost of a sweeping change in economic policy became every day more obvious. And yet it was equally ap- parent that the problem of how to bring the machinery of the Empire up to date was a real problem. How to make up his mind grew for the man in the street a question of much greater diffi- culty than he had at first thought. Yet there remained, and remains, the irony of the situation. He has got to make up his mind, and to say " aye " or " no " to those who have presented to him the question for decision. Such seems to be the nature of the present situation. Fortunately there is no hurry. It would be disastrous were it otherwise. The public is showing that it means to have full materials before it finally pronounces. It is be- ginning to give a preliminary indication that it regards the question as a twofold one : first, is change necessary? second, ought it, if necessary, to assume the form of renunciation of the freedom which we have to-day of buying where we please at the cheapest rate, and selling where we can in ever - increasing markets? For the necessity of bartering goods for goods in growing quan- PREFACE xi titles is, on balance, ever causing the markets to grow, Protective duties notwithstanding. More- over, logically at least, an alternative is possible. The needed reform of the machinery of the Empire may be capable of being effected in an altogether different fashion. Such seem to be the alter- natives in the end of the year 1904. To discuss them fully would be outside the purpose of this book. I have referred to them only in order to show in what relation the book itself stands to them. As I have already reminded the reader, our problem in this country is original neither on its economic nor on its political side. Germany, the United States, and France have all considered it. The analogy of their cases can help, regard being had to their differing geographical and other conditions, but to a limited amount our judgment about the British case. But there is much that is in the highest degree instructive in the other cases, if they are examined by an adequate method. That method can be one only the historical method. By the historical method I mean the plan of examining the state of things that has to be inquired into in connection with its past, and in the light of all materials which can show why and by what steps it has come about. Such a method has become familiar in this country ; for example, in the study of the constitution, which we all agree can be understood and esti- mated adequately only by the aid of its history, Sir Henry Maine and other writers have applied xii PREFACE the method with conspicuous success to institu- tions of a different kind, mainly juridical. In Germany the method has, however, been applied to the study of economics with a thoroughness that has not been attained here. The result has been great reluctance on the part of German thinkers to treat the question between Free Trade and Protection as an abstract one a reluctance which has its parallel in that which makes English- men refuse to regard such questions as those that have been raised over the monarchy, or the theo- retical perfection of our unwritten constitution as practical questions. These are before us as insti- tutions which have grown up, and are likely to be altered only by a process of growth. Can the economic tradition of the last half -century be regarded as open to reconsideration by Great Britain more readily than modern German econo- mists, such as those of the school of Schmoller, allow the corresponding fiscal condition of Germany to be open to reconsideration ? Must we not regard it as incumbent on us to take a very wide survey of the past as well as the present before we jump at conclusions as regards the future ? Is the problem, or is it not, conditioned by considerations of policy and of geographical position, as much as the problem has been thought to be by foreign statesmen who have had to deal with a past and a present differing from ours in material respects, and with people whose genius is different from ours? PREFACE xiii These questions and others of a kindred nature arose in my mind a year ago, when I had to try to make as unprejudiced a reconsideration of the fiscal question as a politician is capable of. I wanted to examine the new political issue in this spirit, and I was so fortunate as to have the co-operation of the author of this book. Mr. Percy Ashley had been working as an economist at kindred problems ; he was in a more detached position than myself. After twelve months of discussion and joint reading we found we had collected a mass of material a fragment, no doubt, of the whole, but enough to make us feel that we knew better than at the outset where we stood. I sug- gested to Mr. Ashley, who had already con- templated lecturing on these subjects in the London School of Economics, that he should write an introduction to the study of this problem, as it had arisen in Germany, in America, and in France, based on a strict application of the his- torical method. He made the suggestion that I should write something by way of introduction to his introduction. As we had been working continuously together, I agreed, not because I felt I could add much, but because the outcome of our joint studies had made me feel that we were of one mind, and had got materials together which were worthy of a little attention. Such essays as this abound in Germany. Here there are distin- guished economists who have done similar work, but there has been little encouragement given to xiv PREFACE them to throw the results of their labours into a popular form. I have stated the origin of the investigation which is recorded in the pages which follow, and have described the spirit in which the endeavour was made to conduct it. The book is, of course, no more than an elementary one. It should, how- ever, serve to show people that there are three large fields of historical study which cannot be safely neglected by anyone who wishes to arrive at conclusions of any value about the wider aspects of the new policy. The essay should also serve to remind the public how vain it is to jump at conclusions based on current opinion in foreign countries. As well might we draw the inference that we should substitute for our own constitution that of the United States or Germany because they are prosperous under their political arrange- ments. Their histories and their needs and the conditions of their development are not as ours. If we look at the economic past of these coun- tries in detail, the danger of rash inference becomes obvious. The German Empire has been developed out of a mass of small states, each possessing its own tariff arrangements. Unity had to be bought at a price. That unity was largely based on internal free trade given in exchange for external protection. An immense army had to be provided for the defence of a land with extensive frontiers, a land which had France on one side and Russia on the other. Internal sources had to be maintained PREFACE xv from which could be drawn a race of strong soldiers, and an adequate home food-supply in case of war. This meant that agriculture had to be artificially fostered and protected. The alterna- tive of command of the sea could be no alternative for Germany. The spirit of militarism, if it was necessary that it should continue to be dominant, must largely affect both the form of the constitu- tion of the German Empire and the fiscal and industrial policy of her rulers. Yet the course has not been a plain one. The ominous growth of the Social Democratic party, and the division of opinion among German statesmen and economists in recent years as to which of two kinds of evil it was better to accept in the interests of national safety, has caused much uneasiness. To-day a majority of their economists remind us, at times impatiently, that they too have studied Adam Smith, and know the argument for Free Trade in England. But they add that England is not Ger- many, and that for Germany other considerations have to be taken into account besides those of how wealth may be best produced and distributed. Readers of the essays by prominent writers which are published from year to year in Professor Schmoller's Jahrbuch know how often irritation is shown over the advice which we are so fond of giving to our foreign neighbours. But not less striking is the recognition that protective duties are dangerous instruments, and the opinion, very generally expressed, that we have been lucky in xvi PREFACE being able, by our position as a sea power, to be rid of them. Even List declared such duties to be of a merely temporary value, and looked forward to a time when Germany might be as able as England to be free of them. It was to the self- confidence of Cobden, rather than to his principles, that List took exception. When writers like Professor Wagner point out that British commerce shows signs of stagnation, they are careful to insist that this has little or nothing to do with Free Trade, and that the same symptoms will inevitably develop themselves in German commerce when it reaches a similar state of development. The world is producing for itself now, and no nation can hope to keep a monopolist position. That is one of the lessons which the historical method teaches, and a Protectionist writer like Wagner frankly tells us that it is not on the ground of commercial advantage, but despite commercial disadvantage, that he wishes to put restrictions on trade liberty in order to keep agriculture in Germany pros- perous in the interest of the safety of the empire. In one conclusion, however, the majority of German writers seem to concur. They declare that the system of duties in Germany is in danger of being abused through the undue influence of the manu- facturers. Protection may be, they think, a useful servant, but it is a very bad master. It leads to officials being subjected to pressure from the capitalists. Much as we may have to learn from Germany PREFACE xvii in other spheres, we seem to have nothing to envy here. At best she bears her burden cheerfully in the interest of what she considers her own safety, with the aim of being, as far as she can be, self- sufficing. But she is under no illusion about the fact that she has had a price to pay, and that a growing political party is grumbling about that price. What we have to admire is the wonderful faculty of organisation which has enabled the nation, by the application of science to its indus- tries and by such steps as the taking control of its railway system, to reduce its difficulties to a mini- mum. The story of the protective movement in Germany is summarised in the eighth chapter of the first part of this book. Anyone who wishes to find the strongest statement of the case for Pro- tection from its German champions cannot do better, after going through the first part, than to read through the short treatise lately published by Professor Wagner under the title, Agrar- und Industriestaat. But how far the conclusions of that treatise are from receiving general acceptance he will speedily discover if he turns to the writings even of those German economists who favour a tariff for " big revolver " purposes. And if he goes still further and looks into the arguments of yet another group, he will find that they look on the " big revolver " as not only a dubious posses- sion in point of utility, but as a drawback to its possessors in matters that are of vital importance. The story of the tariff movement in the United xviii PREFACE States is a wholly different one. Considerations of national defence have, of course, had no place in it, at all events for a long time past. But the protec- tionist traditions which arose in the end of the eighteenth century under the influence of Hamil- ton have retained a deep hold. The reasons are not difficult to discern. The United States possess an enormous and still growing home market, which diminishes the importance for the Republic of foreign commerce. The country produces its own food in abundance. The tariff question in Ameri- can politics has not, like the tariff question with us, been dwarfed in importance by other topics. On the contrary, it has been throughout one of the most important issues with which Congress has been called on to deal. The result of this has been that the manufacturers have brought influ- ence to bear in a fashion which has no parallel in this country. To the manufacturers Protection has undoubtedly afforded facilities which they could not have had without it. By means of the tariffs they have been enabled to develop the trust system to an extent which would have been impossible in the face of free competition. Of the effect of this on the public mind in the United States it is not easy for a foreigner to judge. But there are indications that the very independent and practical mind of the nation is becoming disposed to inquire into the utility of these huge monopolist organisations more closely than before. It would probably be very difficult to bring the mind of the PREFACE xix American people strongly on the side of Free Trade. They have not had occasion to feel the want of it. Yet it would probably be still more difficult to get that people to agree in stating the principle on which the defence of their protec- tionist system rests. The impression one gathers from the study of such books as Taussig's Tariff History is that the United States have gained, at all events in recent times, nothing at all by Pro- tection, and that they would be just as well off to-day had their system been a Free Trade one. Apart from the disturbing effect on the individual manufacturer of the trust, the cost of production has been greatly raised under the American tariff system, to the serious detriment of certain great industries, such as shipbuilding. What is clear is that in the case of America also no analogy presents itself which could be usefully followed by Great Britain from an economic standpoint. France presents to the eye of the student of finance a spectacle which is by no means satisfac- tory. The inference which a study of her economic history suggests is that she has suffered so severely from want of liberty to buy when her people best could, that but for an exceptionally fertile soil she would have been to-day in a very serious position. The story is told by Mr. Ashley in the last part of this volume, and I shall not try to summarise it. Unlike Germany, and like our own country, she has a great seaboard, and might have had a great foreign trade, with a consequent 32 xx PREFACE development of her home industries. She has not been hampered by the geographical conditions which have played their part in determining the rulers of Germany to subordinate considerations of economic development to those of national defence. She has throughout been able to look to sea power, in large measure, at all events, for the protection of her avenues of food-supply on north, on west, and on south. So far as a foreigner may presume to form an opinion, she would have been better off throughout under a Free Trade system. Her people possess great intelligence, industry, and adaptability, and she has large supplies of raw materials. But the class influence of the manu- facturers on her politics has been immense, and she has had to pay for this. Her history is a striking illustration of the tendency of a protective system to get the upper hand, and, having got it, to keep it. I come back to the case of Great Britain. Are we, then, it will be asked, satisfied that we live and compete under the best of all possible conditions ? Do you say that there is nothing which remains to be done ? My answer is in the negative. To me it seems that what has emerged from the discussion which has been raging for more than a year is that there is much room for reform. But in the case of a small island with a great seaboard, and with a great national capacity for command of the sea, protective remedies seem to me to be no remedies. I do not lose sight of the considerations that weigh on the PREFACE xxi minds of many thoughtful people. The burden of the Empire and of its defence is growing, and must in time outstrip our resources. We cannot hope, unless aided by the over-sea dominions of the Crown, to be able permanently and adequately to watch over their safety. We have no longer the monopoly of days gone by. Foreign countries have developed not only their manufactures, but their fleets and armies. Great as has been the growth of our national wealth, our comparatively small home population has, so far as capacity for manufacture is concerned, probably got near to saturation point. But can we infer that it is possible to bring the subjects of the Empire within an economic ring-fence, such as the geographical conditions of Germany and the United States have made possible ? Our loose-jointed Empire, loose-jointed in area and in constitution alike, does not seem to admit of this. Its history reminds us that its cohesion has rested on just this looseness of jointing ; never on mechanical devices, but always upon the simple co-existence of common purpose and sentiment with the most complete local liberty. What is has not been put together from without. It is the result of a pro- cess of growth. When I consider two things the first, the extreme difficulty of avoiding the friction arising from the want of local liberty which every tariff system tends to bring with it ; the second, the impossibility of counting, for a country so peculiarly conditioned as is ours, the economic xxii PREFACE price which must be paid if we part with the exist- ing liberty of buying and selling I feel misgiving about the new policy. Its risk is tremendous, and what is risked is nothing short of the cohesion of the Empire. Surely the burden of proof rests heavily on those who invite us to leap with them. Vestigia nulla retrorsum ! There seems to be another way along which one can see further. For the sake of the Empire, as well as for our own sakes, we must seek to develop the wealth of the islands which form the centre of the Empire, and to expand their commerce. In days gone by it was the production of the best quality of goods that gave us a monopolist posi- tion. We cannot again hope for a monopolist position. But with the development of the im- port trade of the world larger markets than ever are open to our people for competition. That this must be so the theory of exchange on which foreign trade rests shows. That it is so the statistics demonstrate. If we would remain ahead of our rivals, we must continue to be ahead of them in quality of what we make. No tariff can keep out that quality which is the key to quantity. On this side I hope and believe that the recent con- troversy has wakened up the nation, and made it see that alike on the side of economic as of social and imperial questions the key to progress is method and the education in the widest sense of our people. In the distant parts of the King's dominions PREFACE xxiii there is reproducing itself rapidly among those of our own race the unwritten and developing con- stitution under which we ourselves live. Its basis is liberty government of the people by the people for the people. But such liberty, as experience has shown, makes for and does not exclude the common ends and ties of feeling which are the real basis on which rests the unity of the subjects of the Crown. Is it beyond the capacity of a suffi- ciently broad-minded statesmanship to turn its attention to these vital matters, steadily keeping in view that bargains and written rules and what- ever restricts complete freedom are perilous to them ? Such a statesmanship might find real work to do in bringing the machinery of the Empire into the shape which would allow of the greatest liberty of development alike at home and across the seas. The way may be difficult, but the histories of foreign nations can hardly be relied on to point us to any other. R. B. HALDANE. CLOANDEN, AUCHTERARDER, 1st September, 1904. NOTE THE present volume is based chiefly on lectures delivered at the London School of Economics in the Lent and Summer Terms of 1904. They were an attempt to provide students with a brief and, so far as possible, unpartisan sketch of the development of tariff policy in those states which are most frequently compared with the United Kingdom ; and of the forces, political and eco- nomic, which have determined that development. The writer does not profess to offer the results of much original research ; the bibliographies and footnotes will, it is hoped, sufficiently indicate the extent of his indebtedness to others. P. A. August, 1904. PART I GERMANY MODEKN TAEIFF HISTOKY CHAPTER I THE FORMATION OF THE ZOLLVEREIN AT the close of the Napoleonic wars Germany was in a state of the utmost political and economic confusion, and the Congress of Vienna did little to remedy the evil. It gave the new Germanic Confederation a constitution vague and impractic- able, and it offered no effective means of dealing with the most pressing problem, that of economic reorganisation. One of the worst results of Ger- man particularism was the existence of a separate customs system in each of the thirty-nine states, many of them very small, which composed the Confederation ; and, moreover, commerce was ham- pered in every conceivable way, not merely within Germany, but also within the larger states, such as Prussia. In that kingdom there were nearly sixty different local tariffs with a total of nearly two 4 THE FORMATION OF THE ZOLLVEREIN thousand eight hundred classes of goods ; l in some of its provinces, particularly in the western part of the monarchy, the importation of foreign manufactures and products was allowed free or on payment of only moderate duties, in others it was either absolutely prohibited or subject to extremely heavy duties. The first reforms came in Prussia by the Tariff Act of 1818. Its authors Biilow, the Minister of Finances, and Maassen, who was responsible for the details of the tariff were greatly influenced by the economic ideas of Adam Smith, which were at that time making their way in Germany ; the internal customs were abolished, and the whole tariff policy reformed in the direction of the estab- lishment of greater liberty of trade and commerce. Under the new system the importation of raw materials was to be free ; an average duty of 10 per cent, was imposed on manufactured goods ; " colonial produce " was to pay up to 20 per cent. ; and there were to be moderate duties on the transit of goods passing through Prussia to other states. There was also to be an excise levied on the consumption of certain goods in Prussia itself. The tariff so adopted was more liberal than any continental tariff of the time, and in some ways the new policy was more advanced than that even of Great Britain. Germany par- ticularly the northern part was predominantly agrarian, and exported considerable quantities of 1 Zimmermann, i. 1. THE PRUSSIAN TARIFF OF 1818 5 agricultural produce to foreign markets. The landowners in Prussia were interested in Free Trade, and so were the coast towns on the Baltic with their extensive carrying trade. Manufac- tures were developing slowly ; they had received some stimulus from the "continental system" of Napoleon, but the new tariff gave only a moderate protection to the home manufacturers, who were by no means satisfied with it ; and it contained no prohibitions of import except in regard to salt and playing cards, which were Government monopolies. It had one peculiarity the new duties were not levied on the value of the imported goods, but consisted of a fixed charge on a given weight or measure of each commodity. These " specific " duties were on the average at first about 10 per cent, on the estimated value of the goods, and remained not at the same percentage, but at the same actual amount, whatever changes came over the value. This procedure had the advantage of simplicity ; it was not necessary to provide a staff of expert valuers at all the customs stations. On the other hand, there was the distinct disadvantage, which later was severely felt, that there came to be no particular relation between the value of the commodity and the duty ; if the value of the given quantity of a particular article declined for any reason, the old duty might become ex- tremely heavy ; whilst on the other hand, if the quality improved, and with it the value, the duty became proportionately so much smaller. So that 6 THE FORMATION OF THE ZOLLVEREIN the duties tended to become much more protective for goods of inferior quality than for the better class of commodities. 1 The new tariff came into force on January 1st, 1819, and in the same year a policy was inaugurated which was destined to have the most far-reaching results. In the kingdom of Prussia there were no less than thirteen " enclaves," petty states or parts of states completely surrounded by Prussian terri- tory. All of these attempted to maintain customs systems of their own, and as a result came into sharp conflict with Prussia, whose new tariff and its vigorous enforcement against them roused con- siderable indignation in Germany. It was, how- ever, impossible for them permanently to resist the pressure, and in 1819 the little principality of Schwarzburg-Sondershausen accepted Prussia's offer to take over the administration of its customs, and in return to give it the right of trading with 1 la the report of Dr. (afterwards Sir John) Bowring, who visited Germany to report on the Zollverein to the British Government in 1840, it is stated that the effect of the fall in prices since 1818 and of some increases of duty had been to make the duties on some kinds of manufactured goods anything from 20 to 80 per cent., so that in some cases they became absolutely prohibitive. These duties had come to be higher on goods of coarse quality than on fine qualities ; the actual duty on woollen goods varied from 3 to 120 per cent. Friedrich List welcomed this effect of the Tariff, because it gave pro- tection to ' ' articles of common use, which every land can best manu- facture for itself, and of which the home manufacture, on account of its great amount, is most important for the country" (Schippel, p. 86). This system has been commonly adhered to throughout German tariff legislation, as in Great Britain since the middle of last century, mainly because of its superior administrative advantages. For an account and criticism of the alternative method of ad valorem duties, see pp. 168 n., and 236-8. PROPOSALS OF NEBENIUS 7 Prussia free from all restrictions, and a proportion of the total joint customs revenue. But there was much indignation in particularist circles, and it was only very slowly that the other enclaves followed the example ; in fact, the next instance was not till 1822. The policy of Prussia, as exemplified in the agreement with Schwarzburg-Sondershausen, was to take the absolute control of any union which might be formed ; but it was quite evident that whatever the small states might do, the larger states would not agree to any such system. All clung to their independence ; the small states would not subordinate themselves to the larger, save under compulsion, and scarcely any state was willing to consider the economic interests of the whole Confederation as superior to its own private aims ; there was, in fact, an incessant commercial and industrial war. But already there were signs that the people were becoming weary of these con- ditions. Early in 1819, Nebenius, an official of Baden, issued on behalf of his Government a memorandum on the economic condition of Germany. He pointed out that, though that country suffered from the tariff system of its neighbours, it suffered still more from the com- mercial policy of its own component states. The only real remedy was the formation of a league of the German states, the abandonment of their protective policy against each other, and the adop- tion of a common tariff against foreign countries. 8 THE FORMATION OF THE ZOLLVEREIN At the same time, it would be necessary for the German states to bring their system of internal taxation into something approaching uniformity. It is this memorandum which has given Nebenius the credit of being the father of the idea of the later Zollverein, but the idea was not confined to him. In April, 1819, a deputation of manufacturers and others, chiefly from the South German states, appeared at the Federal Diet to urge the adoption of a similar policy : that deputation represented a commercial and trade union, which had been formed two or three years before, largely under the leadership of Friedrich List, and, unlike Nebenius, it was avowedly protectionist in the interests of German industry. Unfortunately the Federal Diet was hopelessly weak, and exercised practically no influence on the policy of the various states ; it could do nothing in the direction pro- posed, and reform had to come in another way. The southern states set to work to attain the desired end by treaties among themselves ; it was absolutely necessary for them to do something, since they were harassed in the north by the growing Prussian Union and in the south by Austria both with their transit duties. So there began a series of conferences between the southern states at Darmstadt between 1820 and 1823 on schemes to resist Prussia, and to combine on a common tariff policy conferences which had no practical result, but at their close " offered foreign countries a new and pitiable picture of German UNION OF BAVARIA AND WURTTEMBURG 9 confusion, and of the triumph of petty particular- ist interests over the common good." 1 The failure of the conferences was followed by a new tariff war in Southern Germany, and such a condition of affairs could not long continue. Wiirttemberg in particular was untiring in its efforts to improve the situation ; it called a fresh conference at Stuttgart (1823 to 1825), which was again unsatis- factory and produced no immediate result. Re- course was then had to separate treaties. Already in 1824 an agreement had been made between Baden and Hesse-Darmstadt, and also one between Wiirttemberg and the Hohenzollern principalities in its midst. Early in 1825 Wurttemberg and Bavaria had agreed on a scheme of Customs Union under joint administration, and they now tried to get Baden, Hesse, Electoral Hesse and Nassau to join them. These negotiations failed, but in April, 1827, a provisional agreement, confirmed and completed in January of the following year, established a Union of Bavaria and Wurttemberg on the basis of a common tariff, abolition of duties on commodities passing between the two contract- ing countries, joint administration of the customs, and division of the net proceeds of the duties according to population. Prussia had not failed to follow the course of these negotiations, or to learn the lesson which they taught. Until this time, it seems that the Prussian statesmen had not thought of a larger 1 Weber, p. 34. 10 THE FORMATION OF THE ZOLLVEREIN union, except in the form of a customs system under the direction of themselves alone. They had treated the other enclaves, which had united with them - - Schwarzburg - Rudolstadt, Saxe - Weimar, Lippe, Mecklenburg -Schwerin just as Schwarzburg-Sondershausen ; the small states were given no share in the management of the Union. " In the south, on the other hand, Bavaria and Wurttemberg had fully realised the idea of a union with equal rights to all its members, with independent administration and complete reserva- tion of all individual rights, without prejudice to the necessary unity of the whole and to the common end in view. Clearly this system must commend itself to the Governments of the minor states rather than the Prussian plan, which in- volved some loss of independence." 1 The Prussian rulers saw the danger, and changed their policy. In February, 1825, less than a month after the completion of the treaty between Bavaria and Wurttemberg, and largely because of that treaty, 2 an agreement was made between Prussia and Hesse-Darmstadt, which laid the foundation of the later Zollverein. No changes were to be made without mutual consent, and Hesse kept control of the customs administration within its own area. Events now moved rapidly. In August, 1828, 1 Weber, p. 61. 2 "The political purpose had triumphed over the fears of the Prussian financiers, for, shortly before, on the 18th of January, Bavaria and Wurttemberg had finally completed their Customs Union" (Zimmermaun, i. p. 53). THE FINAL NEGOTIATIONS 11 some of the minor states, including Hanover, Brunswick, and the two Hanse towns, Hamburg and Bremen, formed a Middle German Commercial Union, under the leadership of Saxony, chiefly to resist the pressure of the two existing unions. But the new organisation was inchoate and short- lived ; it had no definite policy or purpose beyond that of resistance, and found no means of recon- ciling the interests of its constituent members. In fact, the small states were in an impossible posi- tion, and their difficulties were intensified when in May, 1829, an agreement was made between the Prussian Union and Bavaria and Wiirttemberg, on the basis of reciprocal reduction of duties to the extent of 20 to 50 per cent, on many com- modities, the approximation of the two customs systems to a common form, and yearly conferences. The Middle German Union was breaking down ; its members were showing an inclination to draw near to the Prussian Union or the Southern Union, as suited them best, and in 1830 Saxony intimated to Prussia its desire to enter into negotiations for its entry into the Prussian Union. The collapse was completed when Electoral Hesse joined Prussia in 1831 an event of considerable importance, since the geographical position of that state between the western provinces of Prussia and Hesse-Darm- stadt could establish or prevent the real effective- ness of the commercial alliance of these two. The Northern and Southern Unions now drew together, and the final negotiations commenced. They were 12 THE FORMATION OF THE ZOLLVEREIN most delicate and difficult, for there were many diverse interests to be reconciled. In Prussia itself, the sea-towns and the agricultural provinces were favourable to freedom of trade, and the manufacturers desired protection ; the former, how- ever, had the upper hand. The northern states of Germany, and especially the Hanse towns, supported the liberal policy ; and so did the great commercial centre of Frankfurt - on - Main. In Saxony, the traders of Leipzig inclined towards union with Prussia since they sympathised with the ideas which underlay her tariff; the manu- facturers who wanted protection were hostile. The southern states were divided in the same way. Moreover, the manufacturers of Prussia felt that they would be seriously menaced by the free com- petition, from the industries of Saxony for example, which must follow a complete union. The divisions to be made of the proceeds of the tariff were also a difficult matter, for the consumption of " colonial produce" per head was much greater in Prussia than in the south ; and further, some of the smaller states were strongly averse to the surrender of any sovereign rights. 1 The Prussian ministers were by 1 It is curious to observe how indifferent Austria was to these negotiations ; Metternich and his colleagues did not regard them as dangerous, and did not believe that they could be successful. They might possibly have drawn the southern states towards Austria by commercial treaties, but the efforts which they made in this direction were scarcely serious, and altogether ineffective. Great Britain, on the other hand, was fully alive to the danger which threatened her position in the German market, and attempted to check the formation of a great German customs area by treaties with various small German ORGANISATION AND POLICY 13 no means optimistic, but the negotiations were carried to a successful issue, partly because of economic considerations, and partly because of political motives on the part of Prussia these latter were in fact the determining consideration. 1 The work was done by Maassen, now Minister of Finance in Prussia, and Von Mieg, who represented Bavaria and Wiirttemberg. On the 22nd of March, 1833, Bavaria and Wiirttemberg joined the Prussian Union, and the example was immediately followed by Saxony. Negotiations had meanwhile been going on with Hesse- Cassel and the Thuringian states, and in May of the same year they also gave their adhesion. The Zollverein, so formed by a series of treaties, and including seventeen states with a population of some twenty-three millions, came into force on January 1st, 1834. Policy was to be determined from time to time by an annual meet- ing of representatives of the constituent states, but any change required unanimous approval ; this (though probably unavoidable in view of the tenacity with which the several states clung to their independence) was one of the weak points of the organisation a proposal, approved by all the states. The treaty completed with the free city of Frankfurt did for some time prevent that city from joining the Zollverein. France made a number of attempts to detach the smaller states, especially those along the Rhine, by the offer of special tariff treatment, but without success (Weber, p. 105). 1 " The anxiety of the economist had been forced to yield to the hopes of the statesman " (Von Treitschke). 14 THE FORMATION OF THE ZOLLVEREIN states chiefly concerned, might be vetoed by one of the least important members of the Union. A common tariff (based in the main on the rates in force in Prussia) against all states outside the Union, and the abolition of all duties on goods passing between the various members, were the fundamental principles ; but each state kept its own commercial code, its own patent laws (with the right to tax commodities, coming from other members, which would infringe patents) and its own Government monopolies. The proceeds of the customs duties were to be divided amongst the states in proportion to population. The tariff rates imposed moderate duties on manufactured articles, duties for revenue on colonial produce, and gave freedom of import for raw materials and some manufactured articles required for industry. Much still remained to be done before the Zollverein became a unified commercial and industrial organi- sation, but the foundations were firmly laid. Many important states still stood aloof, particu- larly the northern states Hanover, Brunswick, Oldenburg, Holstein, the two Mecklenburgs, the three Hanse towns and Luxemburg with Baden and the important commercial city of Frankfurt. Some of these did not long remain outside the Union ; the accession of the isolated Grand -Duchy of Baden, realised by its Government to be inevit- able after the breakdown of the Middle German Union, was delayed only till May, 1835, by the hostility to Prussia of some of its political parties. FOREIGN RELATIONS 15 In the same year Nassau joined the Zollverein, and the example was followed by Frankfurt after long and difficult negotiations at the beginning of 1836. In the next five years a number of small and not very important territories such as Wai- deck, Pyrmont, and Lippe-Detmold were in- cluded in the Zollverein without receiving the rights of independent members. Most of the larger states which persisted in their independence continued to act separately, but in May, 1834, Hanover, Oldenburg, and Brunswick, whose in- terests were nearly identical, formed a union of their own, called the Steuerverein. Almost immediately after the completion of the work of organisation, attempts were made to place the relations of the Zollverein with the neighbour- ing states on a more satisfactory footing. The diplomatic representation was entrusted to Prussia, but the first efforts were by no means successful. The negotiations with Russia, which pursued an almost prohibitive policy, failed completely, as did those with Austria ; * whilst the Zollverein was distinctly worsted in a conflict with the Govern- ment of Louis Philippe in France. 2 The chief treaties actually completed were with Holland and Great Britain. In the former case there was some- thing like a short customs war ; the Dutch Government desired a commercial treaty, and to enforce its desire, and partly also to protect Dutch 1 The details of these negotiations can be read in Zimmermann, i. pp. 138-52. 2 Ibid., p. 162. 16 THE FORMATION OF THE ZOLLVEREIN agriculture against German competition, it im- posed higher duties on grain in October, 1835. The Zollverein replied by the imposition of higher duties on Dutch sugar, and by the abolition of privileges enjoyed by Dutch vessels on the Rhine. Negotiations for a treaty then began, but broke down over the sugar question, since the growing sugar industry in Germany was strongly hostile to any concessions to Holland in this matter. So at first it was only possible to make an agreement in 1837 in regard to shipping, which put the vessels of the two nations on an equality. Negotiations continued, however, and in the beginning of 1839 a further treaty was completed, which reduced a number of duties on Dutch produce. But it was speedily felt in the Zollverein that the concessions made to Holland were too great, and certainly there is in this case no sign of the skill which sub- sequently characterised the conduct of German commercial negotiations. Consequently the treaty was denounced by the Zollverein less than two years later. The treaty with Great Britain, com- pleted in March, 1841, was also limited to the matter of shipping ; it exempted Prussia from many of the restrictions contained in the English Navigation Acts, and on the whole was of some benefit to Germany, whilst Great Britain, in return, got the same reduction in the duties on sugar and rice as had been granted to Holland. The treaty was not popular, in the southern states particularly, and came to an end in 1848. FIRST RENEWAL OF THE ZOLLVEREIN 17 In 1841 the formal renewal of the Zollverein took place. It was perfectly clear that its institution had been of the utmost benefit to the constituent states ; industrial and commercial development had been greatly stimulated ; many of the causes of inter-state disputes had been removed, and Govern- ments and people were on the whole alike well satisfied. The only difficulty at the renewal was caused by Prussia, for the financial arrangements of the Union had benefited the smaller states, but had reduced the revenues of Prussia, and her statesmen were somewhat dissatisfied, though they recognised fully the advantages which they had gained. 1 But the difficulty was not insuperable, for no one was anxious to break up the Union ; certain additional financial arrangements were made, not quite satis- factory to Prussia, but accepted by her, and the Zollverein was renewed on May 8th, 1841, for twelve years. Immediately afterwards there came fresh additions of territory. Brunswick was dis- contented with the action of Hanover in the Steuer- verein, and quitted that organisation in 1842 ; in the same year it entered the Zollverein. So did Lippe-Detmold and Schaumburg, and, much more important still, Luxemburg, which, though in personal union with the kingdom of Holland, was 1 " Although Prussia does not fail to recognise that its subjects have shared in the general advantageous results of the Union, yet the position is altogether different when viewed from the financial stand- point" (Circular of the Prussian Government, 1839 ; quoted in Weber, p. 185). It would have been inadvisable to refer to the political advantages accruing to Prussia, Q 18 THE FORMATION OF THE ZOLLVEREIN itself a member of the Germanic Confederation. In the last case special arrangements had to be made to prevent the Dutch Government making use of the position of Luxemburg to influence the policy of the Zollverein, and so the representation of the Duchy in the Councils of the Union was entrusted to Prussia. One other important event of this period, which it will be convenient to notice here, was the treaty with Belgium. It was desirable that the relations between that country and the Zollverein should be as amicable as possible, since a great part of the German import and export trade passed over the Belgian railways and through Belgian ports. For the purposes of negotiations, then, the Belgian Government was in a strong position owing to this fact, and also because its geographical situation enabled it to play off France against Germany. The result was the treaty of 1844, by which the Zollverein gave a reduction of duties on com- modities coming from Belgium, and on some articles of Belgian origin (particularly iron) ; whilst Belgium, on its side, guaranteed the existing freedom of transit for goods coming from or going to the Zollverein, and established certain preferences for German products. The shipping of the two nations was put on an equal footing. Weber holds that the treaty chiefly benefited Belgium, since she gained easier access to German markets with her iron, whilst the Zollverein got no new concession of importance ; and he adds that Prussia would NEGOTIATIONS WITH BELGIUM 19 never have yielded so much but for the fear of Belgian alliance with France 1 ; but the Zollverein had secured freedom of transit for its goods through Belgium, and the establishment of an entrepot at Antwerp, and these were matters of no small im- portance. 2 1 Weber, pp. 213, 214. 2 Zimmermann, i. p. 278. CHAPTER II THE BEGINNINGS OF PROTECTION AND THE FIRST CRISIS DURING the early years of the Zollverein there had been only a few increases in the customs duties, 1 but after 1840 there was a marked upward tendency in the tariff rates, due to a distinct movement towards Protection, which found its scientific ex- pression in the writings of Friedrich List, and particularly in his System of National Economy, published in 1841. His doctrine, that protection is necessary to enable a nation to pass from the purely agricultural condition of society to a higher stage of combined industry and agriculture, 2 that the en- couragement of " production " was less immediately important than the development of "productive powers," and that if Germany was to make economic 1 On cotton and woollen yarn from six to eight thaler per centner, and on the finer qualities of bar iron from one thaler to three thaler. 2 " In short, history and statistics alike prove the correctness of the dictum expressed by the ministers of George I. : that nations are richer and more powerful the more they export manufactured goods and import the means of subsistence and raw materials. In fact, it may be proved that entire nations have been ruined merely because they have exported only means of subsistence and raw materials, and have imported only manufactured goods " (List, System of Political Economy, trans. Lloyd, p. 218). 20 A MOVEMENT TOWARDS PROTECTION 21 progress in the face of the overwhelming industrial supremacy of Great Britain, a reasoned policy of Protection was essential rthis doctrine found ready acceptance in the industrial circles of the Zollverein. List pointed always to the example of Great Britain, whose long-continued policy, he held, had been to secure the home market for its manufacturers, to encourage the increase of " productive powers " by the free admission, not of foreign goods, but of foreign workmen, and to bear a temporary loss for the sake of an ultimate gain. This policy had laid the foundation of Great Britain's industrial power, and he called on Germany to follow the example. 1 The practical demand for the application of List's doctrine came from the manufacturers of iron and the cotton-spinners, and over this proposal there arose, between 1841 and 1850, the first real struggle between the rival policies of Free Trade and Protection. In the case of the iron producers, the call for increased duties was due largely to the over-production in England and the consequent reduction of the prices of English iron in the 1 " If any nation whatever is qualified for the establishment of a national manufacturing power, it is Germany. ... If any nation what- ever has a right to anticipate rich results from a protective system adapted to her circumstances, for the progress of her home manu- factures, for the increase of her foreign trade and her navigation, for the perfecting of her internal means of transport, for the prosperity of her agriculture, as also for the maintenance of her independence and the increase of her power abroad, it is Germany. Yes, we venture to assert, that on the development of the German protective system depend the existence, the independence, and the future of the German nationality " (List, System of Political Economy, trans. Lloyd, p. 425). For a general statement of List's view see below, pp. 65 aeq., and 72. 22 THE BEGINNINGS OF PROTECTION foreign market to a point at which continental manufacturers could not compete with them. There was a great increase in the importation of iron into Germany, from 0*9 million centner in 1839 to 2-6 million in 1842, and 4'2 million in 1843. In 1839 the German iron works produced 78 per cent, of the total amount consumed in Germany, whilst by 1843 their share had fallen to 45 per cent. 1 The cotton-spinning industry had been growing rapidly in Prussia, Saxony, and the south-western states since the establishment of the Zollverein, but it was not yet firmly established, and in 1842 the import of cotton was more than double the home production. The request for protection for these two industries naturally led to a sharp conflict of interests between the producers and the consumers of the two commodities. There was a growing demand for industrial machinery, and the manufacturers were opposed to any policy likely to increase its cost ; and to the producers of cotton goods (an industry which had made rapid progress of recent years, and supplied one of the chief exports of the Zollverein) an ample supply of British cotton was an absolute necessity. The division over the question was also territorial. On the whole the north was in favour of Free Trade. The attitude of the Prussian Government was de- termined in the main by the agricultural and com- mercial interests. Large quantities of agricultural 1 Seriug, Geschichte der preussischdeutschen Eisenzolle von 1818 bis zur Gegenwart (1882). THE FREE TRADE FORCES 23 produce, chiefly grain and timber, were exported, especially to Great Britain after the repeal of the Corn Laws : and on the other hand, the landowners needed agricultural machinery and feared an in- crease in its price as a result of the proposed higher duties ; so that the Prussian Conservatives, whose strength lay in the agricultural districts, were, unlike their English contemporaries, strong advo- cates of freer trade. The Baltic ports Dantzig, Stettin, Elbing, Konigsberg, and others were engaged in the export of grain and timber, and were opposed to anything which might tend to restrict trade. 1 These influences were strong enough to overcome any inclination on the part of the Prussian Government to accede to the demands of the iron producers of the Rhine province. The two great Hanse towns (Hamburg and Bremen) took the same line ; both had a large trade with Great Britain and America, exporting linen, timber, minerals, woollens, glassware, and wines, and im- porting manufactured goods, tobacco, and colonial produce generally. Frankfurt, which was the great entrepot for British trade, also stood firmly on the Free Trade side. Saxony was carried the same way by the influence of the traders of Leipzig and the weavers, whose industry far exceeded in importance that of the spinners. The Thuringian states followed the lead of Prussia and Saxony. 1 Schippel points out that in the absence of a well-organised railway system the sea made foreign markets nearer to the lands along the Baltic than the inland territories of the Zollverein. 24 THE BEGINNINGS OF PROTECTION Brunswick and Nassau supported Prussia largely because the financial results of the Zollverein had been for them so favourable that they were un- willing to break with her. The southern states, on the other hand, were distinctly inclined to Protection. Bavaria wavered ; it was difficult for its Government to decide between the rival spinning and weaving industries, but it was carried into the protectionist movement by the personal authority of King Ludwig I., who seems to have been influenced chiefly by political con- siderations. Wiirttemberg and Baden, on the other hand, were anxious for the protection of the cotton- spinning industry, which had been most successful in those territories ; and they were supported by Hesse. The conflict continued for several years and was particularly keen at the annual conferences. After the Karlsruhe Conference in 1845 feeling was so strong that Prussia was accused of being unduly under the influence of Great Britain. On the other hand, the Prussian Government had declared, as early as 1842, that the southern Governments took too narrow a view of the eco- nomic interests of Germany, and were swayed by the cotton-spinners, who were suffering from bad organisation and the over-hasty development of their industry. 1 Both sides gave way somewhat, and by 1850 the duties had been considerably increased. In 1843 the duty on certain kinds 1 Zimniermanu, pp. 190 and 200. INCREASE OF DUTIES 25 of cotton yarn was increased by 50 per cent. ; in 1844 a small duty was imposed on pig-iron, hitherto admitted free, and there were slight in- creases on iron bars and rails. In the same year the duties on various kinds of woollen goods were increased 33 per cent., and those on gold and silver articles and leather gloves were doubled. In 1846 there were still further increases on all kinds of cotton yarn, linen yarn and twist, and various other commodities. On the other hand, however, there were reductions on a number of raw materials, and in the transit dues in 1850. It must be remembered also that the changes in the price of commodities (and there had been a very marked fall during this period) had not been followed by any corresponding change in the amount of the duties which, as already pointed out, had been fixed according to the value thirty years before of a particular quantity of each com- modity. The result was that duties, which had been quite moderate originally, had now come to be in some cases almost prohibitive. 1 It is impossible to say how much further the movement towards Protection would have gone had it not been for political considerations, and particularly the problem of the relation of Austria to the Zollverein. The Austrian Government, under Prince Met- ternich, had paid little attention to the negotiations 1 Michaelis, Kommissionsbericht fiber den premsischfranzosinchen Handelsvertrugentwurf, quoted in tichippel, pp. 135-7 ; cf. note oil p. 6. 26 THE BEGINNINGS OF PROTECTION for the formation of the Zollverein ; its attempts to interfere had been unimportant, and its whole action in the matter had been marked by that complete indifference to economic questions which was its peculiar characteristic amongst the Govern- ments of Europe. Its own tariff policy was pro- tectionist, or rather in many cases prohibitive. But after 1833 even Metternich awoke to the danger which threatened Austrian authority in the Germanic Confederation from the growing influence of Prussia, and, as time went on, he realised that the economic leadership of that state in the Zollverein might easily be extended to political action also. In 1841 the Austrian minis- ters began to consider the possibility of the ad- hesion of the Austrian Empire to the Zollverein, but came to the conclusion that for the time being, at any rate, it was impracticable, partly owing to the supposed impossibility of abandoning the policy of high Protection, and partly because of the peculiar position of Hungary, which was not in economic union with the rest of the empire. 1 But from that time onward the problem was always under consideration, and the discussion became vigorous after the renewal of the Zollverein. In Austria itself the manufacturers clung to the pro- tective policy, but in the community as a whole there was considerable dissatisfaction with it ; and, further, the Austrian statesmen were more and more impressed by the political necessity of check- 1 Weber, p. 244. AUSTRIA AND THE ZOLLVEREIN 27 ing the Prussian advance. Consequently, the Austrian efforts were now directed towards forcing an entrance into the Zollverein, or, as a less prefer- able alternative, towards destroying it. These efforts became much more vigorous after the events of the revolutionary years 1848 and 1849. For one thing, the action of the National Assembly at Frankfurt, in offering to Frederick William IV. of Prussia the Imperial Crown of a Germany from which Austria was excluded, had brought home to the Austrian statesmen the extreme weakness of their position ; and further, Metternich had been succeeded by one of the ablest and strongest min- isters Austria has ever had, Prince Schwarzenberg. 1 Moreover, the conditions in the Zollverein were not unfavourable. It has already been pointed out that difficulties had arisen between Prussia and her colleagues in 1841 over the division of the customs revenue, and the dissatisfaction then created in the southern states had been increased by the growing preponderance of Prussia. They were, therefore, not unwilling to admit Austria, partly to keep Prussia in check thus adopting in the Zollverein that policy of " balance " which had reduced the Confederation to impotence and partly because they desired support for their pro- tectionist schemes. They were, however, ham- pered by the knowledge that with the compara- 1 Prussian diplomacy had received its severest blow in the Treaty of Olmutz in November, 1850, on the questions of the Elbe Duchies and Hesse-Cassel. 28 THE BEGINNINGS OF PROTECTION lively small consumption of imported goods in Austria any division of the customs revenues on the old lines would seriously reduce their revenues. 1 In 1849 the Austrian Government began to put forward proposals for the complete economic union of Germany and the non-German territories of the Austrian monarchy. It proposed, that is to say, the establishment of a complete industrial state, including a large part of Middle Europe and a population of over seventy millions ; in this state neither the commercial, nor the industrial, nor the agricultural class would be predominant, but a tariff policy was to be adopted which would equally guard all three. The Prussian Government from the first realised the political effect of an acceptance of the Austrian proposals, and set itself resolutely to oppose her admission. The most striking manifestation of this was its action in regard to Hanover. It has already been mentioned that in 1834 Hanover had formed, particularly with Oldenburg and Brunswick, a Steuerverein in the north. Since then there had been constant disputes with Prussia, which con- tinued even after the adhesion of Brunswick to the Zollverein, an event destructive of the effective- ness of the Northern Union, and seriously crippling Hanover by cutting her territory in two. Negotia- tions had been going on for years between Prussia 1 Thus in October, 1851, Beust declared that, for financial and economic reasons, Saxony could not leave the Zollverein ; and Bavaria and Wiirttemberg requested Austria to guarantee the maintenance of their existing revenues (Ziminermauu, p. 358). AGREEMENT BETWEEN PRUSSIA AND HANOVER 29 and Hanover, but without success, owing to the excessive demands made by the latter ; but now suddenly Prussia gave way, and concluded in September, 1851, a treaty in which she accepted most of the conditions which she had hitherto decisively rejected. Hanover received permission to import iron rails free of duty, and a guarantee of a larger share of the customs revenue than she would have received on the basis of population. The treaty was advantageous to Hanover in many ways, since it was clearly impossible for her much longer to maintain her economic isolation ; and for Prussia also the results were of great importance. For, in the first place, the alliance with Hanover secured the connection of her territories, even if the Zollverein should break up; and secondly, it strengthened the Free Trade party, as did the treaty between Prussia and Oldenburg early in the following year. 1 But the treaty was with Prussia not with the Zollverein ; it was therefore necessary for Prussia either to force the other states to accept the treaty, or to break up the Zollverein and throw herself into union with the northern states. 2 Negotiations for the renewal of the Zollverein had already begun under the terms of the treaty of 1841, and they were complicated by the simul- taneous discussions with Austria. In form, the controversy arose over the procedure to be 1 Neither Hanover nor Oldenburg had any industries to protect. 2 Weber, pp. 294, 297. 30 THE BEGINNINGS OF PROTECTION ' adopted. Prussia insisted that the renewal of the Zollverein, with the acceptance of the treaty with Hanover and the various modifications of the tariff required by that, or considered necessary after the experiences of recent years, must precede any treaty with Austria. The southern states, on the other hand, wished the negotiations with Austria to be completed before the settlement of the future constitution of the Zollverein, since those negotiations might mean the admission of Austria. It is not necessary to follow in detail the course of the extremely involved proceedings of the various conferences which agitated Germany from September, 1851, to April, 1853. Whilst endeavouring to secure the treaty with the Zollverein as a whole, Austria was secretly pre- paring the way for the formation of a union to include herself and the South German states, in the event of Prussia refusing to give way and breaking up the Zollverein. 1 The Prussian states- men, on the other hand, as we have seen, were preparing for this and planning a new union in the north. Neither side was anxious to take the decisive step ; but the current ran strongly against Prussia, partly because of the distrust inspired by her unyielding attitude, and partly owing to the 1 The conferences between Austria and the Zollverein states began in January, 1852, at Vienna. Prussia and the Thuringian states were not represented ; the public negotiations were in regard to the Zollverein treaty with Austria, but at the same time there were private conferences for the formation of a union without Prussia (Zimmermann, i. p. 371). THE AUSTRIAN PROBLEM 31 superior statesmanship of Schwarzenberg, until the death of that statesman in April, 1852 ; after that date the action of Prussia became more decided. At the first conference of all the states of the Union at Berlin in the same month, Manteuffel, the Prussian Minister President, declared uncom- promisingly the determination of his state to settle the question of the new constitution of the Zollverein before making any treaty with Austria. In May the Prussian Ministry published a note, in which it asserted that Prussia had not sought in the Zollverein any financial or political advan- tage, but simply the promotion of the economic progress of Germany, and expressed its willingness to negotiate with Austria for an extension of that system, but repeated that it was absolutely necessary to determine the area and policy of the Zollverein before any useful action could be taken in that direction. It condemned strongly the methods of the southern states in entering into secret rela- tions with Austria, and lamented the bad impression which the sight of the internal discord of Germany must make on foreign nations. But neither the southern states nor Austria were convinced of the sincerity of the Prussian declarations, and as they persisted in their policy, the Prussian Government thought itself compelled to play its last card by its announcement of September, 1852, that it con- sidered the general negotiations for the renewal of the Zollverein at an end, and henceforward would only discuss treaties with separate states. But by 32 THE BEGINNINGS OF PROTECTION this time both parties were prepared to give way. On the one side, Prussia was not anxious to carry out its threat, and was beginning to realise that its obstinacy had been carried too far ; whatever her statesmen might say, they could not fail to recognise the political advantages which the Zollverein had given them, and they could not afford to run the risk of a union between Austria and the southern states. Further, it was doubtful whether Hanover was prepared to go the whole way with Prussia, who was more dependent than she cared to admit on the action of that state. On the other hand, Von Beust and Von den Pfordten, the Ministers of Saxony and Bavaria and the leaders of the policy of the south, had become aware that the commercial and industrial classes of their states were doubtful as to the advantages to be gained by union with Austria alone, and were not prepared to sacrifice the economic benefits of the Zollverein for the sake of the political aims of the Governments. The conferences with Austria had been by no means satisfactory ; the attempts to find a basis of agreement for the rival interests had so far failed. A more conciliatory attitude was adopted on all sides, and Prussia entered into direct relations with Austria without waiting for the settlement of the problem of the Zollverein. Progress then became rapid, and in February, 1853, a treaty between Prussia and Austria was signed for twelve years. The entrance of Austria to the Zollverein was postponed, but it was agreed that THE AUSTRO-PRUSSIAN TREATY 33 in 1860 a joint commission should be appointed to consider plans for her complete admission. Meanwhile, the two contracting parties undertook reciprocal favoured treatment of each other. Many commodities, chiefly raw and semi-manufactured goods and manufactures of small value, were to pass between the two contracting states free from any duty ; and the duties on such articles as cotton yarn and goods, chemicals, iron and metal goods of all kinds except machinery, glass, agricultural produce, linen yarn, woollen and silk goods, and many other manufactured commodities were re- duced 25 per cent. The terms of the treaty were to extend to all states in customs union with Prussia, and the Italian possessions of Austria. 1 The treaty was a compromise favourable to Austria, for it was the kind of arrangement usually made to prepare the way for a complete union. But Prussia had gained time, and she had secured the renewal of the Zollverein ; therefore the treaty on the whole gave general satisfaction in Germany. 2 In the following April the Zollverein was renewed by a series of treaties which made various modifi- cations and rearrangements, but in the main continued the old conditions, and Hanover was 1 In the treaty there was a clause which hampered Germany for some time. By Art. iv., if one of the two contracting parties reduced the duty on a commodity coming from a third state, not in receipt of favoured treatment at the date of the treaty, then the other party could impose a duty equivalent to the reduction on all goods of that kind coming from the state which had made that reduction. 2 Weber, p. 335. D 34 THE BEGINNINGS OF PROTECTION included. The years from 1853 to 1860 have been described as the period of the stagnation of the Zollverein. The protectionist movement was satis- fied for a time ; l the treaty with Austria did not greatly develop trade between the two countries, 2 but there was a considerable growth of German industry ; and the temporary defeat of Prussia seemed to put an end to any danger of the adop- tion of the policy of Free Trade which that state was supposed to represent. The mutual distrust inspired by the conflict left its effects, and in spite of numerous attempts at the annual conferences from various sides, no serious changes were made in the policy or administration of the Zollverein. But by 1860 the political and economic conditions had alike changed ; it was necessary for Prussia to take decisive action if Austria was to be kept out of the Zollverein. The new commercial policy of the western states rendered a reconsideration of Germany's own policy inevitable, and furnished Prussia with her most effective weapon against her rival. 1 Schippel, p. 138. 2 The export of raw materials from Austria to the territories of the Zollverein increased somewhat ; the export of manufactured goods remained almost stationary. The increased exports from the Zollverein to Austria were chiefly cotton and woollen yarn, iron and metal goods. CHAPTER III THE SECOND CRISIS AND THE COMMERCIAL TREATIES THE years 1861 to 1864 are filled by the second great crisis in the history of the Zollverein, and in many respects the phenomena of the former crisis were repeated. Economic and political considera- tions were again involved, and political aims to a large extent again determined commercial policy. The treaty with Austria had provided for the commencement, about the year 1860, of negotiations for the admission of that state to the Zollverein. But in order that there might be any real prospect of those negotiations being brought to a successful issue, it was necessary on the one side that the finances of the Austrian Empire should be brought into order, so that when the time for negotiations came she might have a free hand, and that her protective policy should be to some extent modified ; and on the other side, that the Zollverein should not follow a policy so liberal as to frighten Austria away. 1 None of these conditions were realised ; for the war of 1859 and the loss of Lombardy had 1 Lotz, i. p. 10. 35 36 THE COMMERCIAL TREATIES again brought Austrian finances into disorder, and, moreover, between 1853 and 1862, the protectionist party had regained strength, and practically none of the reforms contemplated in the treaty of 1853 with the Zollverein had been carried out. 1 From a purely economic point of view the Zoll- verein, in its endeavour to secure a large market for its agricultural and industrial products, might adopt either one of two policies. It might adopt the plan put forward long before by Brack, of forming a large area with Austria with Free Trade within and a strong policy of Protection against all outside. In this way a large home market would be secured and a self-sufficing economic state created. Or alternatively, the Zollverein might adopt a more liberal tariff policy, and estab- lish closer commercial relations with the western states of Europe. The first of these alternatives was supported by the high Protectionists in the Zollverein that is, by a considerable number of the manufacturers, especially in the iron industries, and by some of the South German states, particularly Bavaria and Wiirttemberg, which had always advocated union with Austria, and represented to some extent in politics that " Greater Germany " party whose ideal was the establishment of a German Empire which should include all the possessions of Austria, even though many of them were inhabited by peoples not of German stock. There were great difficulties 1 Weber, p. 399. THE FREE TRADE MOVEMENT 37 in the way of the realisation of this ideal, and the Austrian Government seems about 1860 to have lost much of its earlier interest in the matter ; in 1861 it admitted that for the time the obstacles were almost insuperable. 1 The second alternative was supported by the Free Traders, or rather by those classes who desired the lessened restriction of foreign trade, and by the anti- Austrian poli- ticians of Prussia. In the late fifties there was something approach- ing to a real agitation for Free Trade in Northern Germany. It found its theoretical expression in the writings of Prince-Smith, to whose energy and influence was due the foundation of the German Economic Congress, which gathered together after 1858 all the reforming forces. There was an admitted need for the amendment of the tariff; no readjustment of the specific duties had been made to bring them into a more satisfactory rela- tion to values. But the reformers desired to go further than this ; they wished the amendments to be made deliberately in the direction of greater freedom of trade. Much of their political strength continued to depend on the support given to their ideas by the landowners, who wanted cheaper machinery, and also the extension of the English market for their grain. Germany was still an overwhelmingly agricultural country at the be- ginning of the second half of the century two- thirds of her population were engaged in agricul- 1 Ibid., p. 383. 38 THE COMMERCIAL TREATIES ture, 1 and the proportion declined only slowly up to 1870 ; much grain was exported from the north, especially to Great Britain. 2 The Free Trade movement took its rise therefore in the agricul- tural eastern provinces of Prussia, but it was sup- ported also by the weavers, who wanted cheap English yarn, by the middle class and small officials, to whom the cheapness of many commodities was a matter of very great importance, and by the commercial classes and the seaports. On the other side, many of the manufacturers were beginning to feel that they were strong enough to do without much of the protection they had hitherto enjoyed ; some of them were already largely exporting (for example, one-quarter of the produce of the woollen industry was sent abroad), and they were anxious to get rid of anything which in any way hampered their relations with foreign markets. 3 Political circumstances in Prussia itself were changing ; the moderate Liberals were becoming predominant in the Parliament, and though vigorously opposing them on the question of the reorganisation of the army, the Government was quite ready to use their support for its anti- Austrian programme, and was therefore favourably inclined towards a com- mercial policy which commended itself to them, and would repel Austria. 4 It found its opportunity 1 Voigt, in Handels- und Machtpolitik, vol. i, p. 141. 2 The average value of the surplus of grain exported over that im- ported was estimated for 1860-4 at 35 mill. mks. (Lotz, i. p. 11). 3 Weber, 389. In 1859 manufactured goods amounted, so far as values were concerned, to 4 of the total export (Lotz, i. p. 52). 4 Cf. Lotz, i. pp. 28-30. THE FRENCH TREATY SYSTEM 39 i in the necessity of dealing with the situation ^ created by the change which had come over the economic policy of the states of western Europe, and by the altered attitude of France. It has already been remarked that the trade relations between the Zollverein and France under the Monarchy of July had been greatly strained. A long commercial struggle had now been going on for nearly twenty years. 1 After the failure of negotiations in 1839, the July Monarchy had imposed very high duties on German goods ; the Zollverein had replied in 1843 with retaliatory duties increases on gloves, brandy, etc. and most of these were still in force. Negotiations up to 1851 had failed, and fresh attempts after 1853 had been equally unsuccessful. In 1860 Napoleon III., by his own personal will and in spite of strong and general opposition in France, had broken with French traditional policy and made a commercial treaty with Great Britain, which " ranks with the treaty which founded the Zollverein, as perhaps the most important international event of the century in the sphere of economics."' By the treaty France undertook to impose on an agreed number of British products no duties higher than 30 per cent., and after October, 1864, 24 per cent., 1 Zimmermann, i. pp. 161-2., 263-5, 393-5. 2 Weber, 368. It is interesting to notice the failure of this his- torian's prophecy in the following sentence, written in 1871. "The impetus which this treaty gave to the customs policy of all European countries is still far from ended, is rather becoming stronger, and in all probability will end only by a complete change of the whole customs legislation." 40 THE COMMERCIAL TREATIES ad valorem ; and Great Britain, on her side, under- took to abandon some duties and to reduce those on French wines. And further, both sides bound themselves to reciprocal "most favoured nation" treatment, that is to say, any tariff advantage granted by one of the contracting parties to any other state was, ipso facto, to extend to the other contracting party also. 1 The British treaty in- augurated a series which covered Western Europe like a net. Treaties were made by France with Belgium, Italy, Holland, Switzerland, Sweden, Norway, and other countries, and of these, the Belgian treaty, with its reciprocal reductions and provision for mutual " most favoured nation " treat- ment, became the model for all the others. The net result was that France had one general or "autonomous" tariff, which applied to all countries with which special arrangements had not been made ; and a treaty or " conventional " tariff, with rates of duty settled by treaty with any one country and then extended to all other treaty countries by the action of the " most favoured nation " clause. Most of the nations which entered into the system were influenced partly by the desire not to let 1 "English industry had long reached a point where it had no further need of protection against foreign competition ; in fact, the existing protection was rather a burden. Already it was necessary for it to fight in the great world markets with similar products of the great industrial states, and it could therefore easily face their com- petition in its own country, where all the conditions were favourable to it. It was to be anticipated that this impulse would drive other states to a reform of their strict customs systems, and in this the English industry would assuredly find its benefit. The justice of this calculation has since then been completely established " (Weber, p. 370). FRANCO-GERMAN RELATIONS 41 Great Britain secure greater advantages in France than they themselves enjoyed, and partly by the anxiety to do something to compensate for the loss of part of the American market, owing to the United States' high protective tariff of 1861. It became absolutely necessary for the Zollverein to take action. Great Britain generalised all the reductions which she had made in the French treaty, she extended them to the products of all countries ; but France only gave reductions to the treaty states. Consequently the British and Belgian manufacturers enjoyed an immense advantage over the Germans, 1 and the trade of Germany with France was at the best only small, for, whilst it imported from that country goods to the value of 154,000,000 francs, it sent her goods worth only 82,000,000 francs. 2 The German manufacturers hoped that by a treaty they would secure a greatly developed market in France for their iron and steel, textiles, leather goods, etc., many of which were prohibited by the French " autonomous " as distinct from the "conventional" or treaty tariff. France, on the other hand, communicated early in 1861 her willingness to negotiate with Prussia, which was entrusted with the diplomatic representa- tion of the Zollverein, and Prussia readily accepted the invitation. 1 e.g. " Edged tools from treaty states paid a duty into France of 18 francs per 100 kilo., but from the Zollverein 160 francs ; the duties on paper were respectively 10 and 160 francs, on iron tools 12 and 60 francs " (Schippel, p. 171). 2 Lotz, i. p. 37. 42 THE COMMERCIAL TREATIES It was clear, however, that the treaty proposed must have much wider effects than the mere de- velopment of the trade with France. It must involve a readjustment of the whole Zollverein tariff, and to that there was no particular opposi- tion ; in fact, the work of reform had commenced already in March, 1861, the transit duties were abolished, and also a considerable number of the export duties. But of far greater importance was the probable influence of the contemplated treaty on the relations to Austria. The Prussian states- men realised at once that the grant of reduction of duties to France, and the establishment of " most favoured nation " terms with that country would render impossible the continuance of the special relations, under the treaty of 1853, with Austria, and would put an end to the idea of a union between Austria and the Zollverein. 1 Free Trade was to be the most potent weapon employed by Prussia in her effort to exclude Austria from the future German Empire. 2 The other states of the Zollverein realised this, and at once a struggle began. It was, in fact, a repetition of the events of ten years before. The time for the renewal of the Zollverein was drawing near, and, just as on the previous occasion, Prussia had made a treaty with Hanover and insisted on its acceptance as a condition of the renewal of the union, whilst the southern states had striven to make the admission of Austria 1 Weber, p. 373. 2 Schippel, p. 172. CONFLICT OVER THE FRENCH TREATY 43 the basis of negotiation, so now Prussia pushed on the completion of the treaty with France in order to repel Austria. And again she insisted that the new treaty should be accepted by the other states if the Zollverein were to be continued. The treaty between Prussia and France was hastened ad- mittedly for political reasons, 1 and was completed on 29th March, 1862, though the actual signing did not take place till the following August, after approval had been given by the Prussian Parliament. It was communicated immediately to the other Governments for their acceptance, and was speedily rejected by Wiirttemberg, Hanover, Nassau, and Hesse-Darmstadt ; Saxony alone, abandoning her old policy, now threw herself on the Prussian side. The attitude of the opposition was undoubtedly influenced by the proposal put forward in July by Austria for a complete union with the Zollverein, the preliminary condition, of course, being the postponement of any arrangement with France till after that event. To this Prussia would not accede, declaring herself bound, for her own part, to carry out the treaty. The southern states attempted, at the end of 1862, to open direct negotiations with France, but were rejected. 2 Meanwhile conferences on the renewal of the Zollverein were going on, but the difficulties were great. In November, 1862, the Prussian Government had declared definitely that it took the rejection of the French 1 Weber, p. 386. 3 Schippel, p. 175, quoting Bismarck's speech on 26th December, 1862. 44 THE COMMERCIAL TREATIES treaty by the southern states to mean their intention not to continue the Zollverein. After the confer- ences of the first half of 1863 on the Austrian question and the renewal of the Zollverein had produced no satisfactory result, the Bavarian Government suggested the formation of a separate union from which Prussia and her allies should be excluded, and which should come to terms with Austria on the basis of the treaty of 1853. But it soon became apparent that only Bavaria and Wurttemberg were prepared to go so far, and even in those states the Governments were not sure of the support of the whole of their population. After further complicated discussions, in which both sides attempted to justify themselves before public opinion, but the Prussian Government was handi- capped by the impossibility of stating its real aims, Prussia, on the 17th December, 1863, gave formal notice of the termination of the Zollverein. The other states now yielded, particularly as Austria was now less inclined to push her proposals. The conferences were renewed in February, 1864, and at the same time Prussia began negotiations for a simple treaty with Austria. After some delay, on the llth April, 1865, a treaty, containing not much more than the guarantee of simple " most favoured nation " treatment, was made with Austria, and in May, after the acceptance in the previous year by the southern states of the French treaty, the Zoll- verein was formally renewed. 1 In the same year 1 Its practical renewal dates from October in the previous year. CHANGES IN THE TARIFF 45 treaties similiar to the one with Austria were made with Belgium, Great Britain (including her colonial possessions), and Italy, and the treaty with France, so long under discussion, at last came into force. The Zollverein had followed the example of the last-named country in its adoption of the system of " autonomous " and " conventional " tariffs. The series of treaties thus completed brought of necessity sweeping changes in the customs tariff of the Zollverein. Already, whilst the negotiations with France were in progress, but without particular reference to them, the transit duties had been abol- ished, and all the parties to the treaties now bound themselves to maintain this policy for the future. Further, there had been a growing inclination to abandon the idea of helping those industries for which the raw materials were produced at home by prohibiting or limiting the export of the latter. In no case was the method very effective, and in some instances, such as the leather and woollen industries, it could be shown to be harmful. 1 Most export duties were now abolished ; some remained, but were reduced, as, for example, those on materials requisite for paper-making. All the contracting parties reserved to themselves the right to prohibit exports, but under strong French pressure the Zollverein agreed not to make use of this power in regard to coal. Much more important was the reduction of duties on imports, and this [presented the greatest 1 Lotz, i.^p. 43. 46 THE COMMERCIAL TREATIES difficulties. For the insertion in most of the treaties of the " most favoured nation " clause meant that any reduction granted by the Zollverein to one power would have to be extended to all the others. So the Zollverein in granting reductions to France had to consider, not simply their effect on the imports from that country, but how far the neces- sary extension to other lands, for instance, Great Britain and Belgium, would encourage the attack by their manufacturers on the German home market. The reductions made under these con- ditions represented a deliberate policy of Free Trade, in that they were inspired by the desire not only to promote trade relations with the contract- ing states, but also to improve the tariff by the removal of anomalies, and by abolishing protection wherever it seemed no longer required. So the tariff was disencumbered of duties which had no protective or financial results (as that on zinc, of which the Zollverein exported none and imported much) ; the duties introduced for retaliatory pur- poses (usually without effect) and no longer im- portant as the surtaxes on French goods imposed in 1842 and the duty on Russian tallow were abolished ; and all the raw and semi-manufactured materials of industry were admitted free. 1 On none of these things was there much differ- ence of opinion, but the case was different in regard to manufactured commodities ; some of the in- dustries, such as the iron trades and the cotton 1 Lotz, i. pp. 42-4. REDUCED DUTIES ON MANUFACTURES 47 spinners, still clung to Protection, and had strongly opposed the treaties for that reason. But their resistance was overcome, and a great number of reductions were made the treaty with France alone had provided for 161 changes in the tariff, mostly in regard to manufactured goods. Thus the duty on cotton goods was reduced 40-80 per cent., on silk 50 per cent., on silk goods 45 per cent., on pig-iron 25 per cent., on leather 60 per cent., on leather goods 50 per cent., on sewing needles 80 per cent., on woollen cloth 60-80 per cent., on fine iron goods 80 per cent., on pressed glass 33 per cent. 1 These changes, however, were not made on any definite plan the tariff had never yet undergone a complete and systematic revision ; that might have followed, but the rapidity of the subsequent movement towards Free Trade rendered any rearrangement of the tariff unnecessary, by almost destroying it. 1 Weber, pp. 441-3. CHAPTER IV THE ZOLLVEREIN AFTER THE TREATIES THE COMPLETION OF FREE TRADE AND THE REACTION IT is a striking testimony to the strength of the Zollverein and its hold upon Germany that during the war of 1866, when the constituent states were fighting each other, the joint customs administra- tion went on without interruption. 1 After the speedy termination of the struggle and the destruc- tion of all prospect of Austrian predominance in Germany, there came a reform of the constitution of the Zollverein by the treaty of 1867 between the North German Confederation on the one side, and Bavaria, Wiirttemberg, Baden, and Hesse on the other. 2 The system of a union of independent states, each possessing the right to veto any pro- posal, was replaced by an organisation in which matters were decided by a majority of votes a change generally felt to be necessary on account of 1 Weber, pp. 462-3. 2 It should be noted that Hanover, Electoral Hesse, Nassau, and Frankfurt, hitherto independent states of the Zollverein, had become part of the Prussian Kingdom ; and the Zollverein area was extended by the inclusion of Schleswig-Holstein. also added to Prussia. 48 ' FORMATION OF THE EMPIRE 49 the innumerable difficulties and delays which the old method had called forth. The Zollverein, thus reconstituted, now included all the German states except Hamburg and Bremen. The Cus- toms Union Council (Zollbundesrath) consisted of fifty-eight members, of whom Prussia had seven- teen, and represented the old general conference ; but to it was added a Customs Parliament (Zoll- parlement) composed of members of the North German Parliament and representatives of the South German states. 1 The position was some- what peculiar, for many of the states were largely dependent on the customs revenue, and this was controlled by the Customs Parliament. Con- sequently, while each separate state could fix its expenditure at whatever it pleased, it could not control the chief part of its revenue a fact which gave great impetus to the movement for complete union. In 1871 the Franco-German War, and the pat- riotic enthusiasm it evoked, brought the establish- ment of the Empire, and at last political as well as economic union was attained. 2 In the Empire, legislation concerning customs and trade was to be a matter for the Imperial Parliament ; the proceeds of the customs duties were to go to the imperial exchequer, and not to be divided between the state exchequers as before ; the duties were to be 1 Weber, p. 467. s There were some slight modifications to this Hamburg and Bremen were in the empire, but not in the Customs Union ; Luxemburg is still in the Union, but not in the Empire. 50 THE ZOLLVEREIN AFTER THE TREATIES collected by officials of the separate states, but under the control of the Emperor as executive official of the Empire. The new machinery speedily showed itself to be effective, and the old wearisome negotiations between the states on every proposal for a change of economic policy were at an end. 1 The wars of 1866 and 1871 necessarily made considerable changes in the commercial relations of Germany to Austria and France. Austria was inclined to a less strongly protectionist policy, partly because her statesmen, in the reorganisation of the empire, were compelled to pay more atten- tion to the interests of Hungary, which was mainly agrarian, exported grain and other agricultural produce, and was distinctly sympathetic to freer trade. In the treaty of 1868 between Austria and the Zollverein there were reductions made on both sides ; by Austria on manufactured goods, by Ger- many on wine and iron. 2 In the case of France, there were fears that she might refuse to renew the treaty with Germany whilst continuing her arrangements with other powers ; and it was also likely that, should Thiers remain in power, she would adopt a strongly protective policy. All that could be obtained was secured in the Treaty of Frankfurt in May, 1871, but it was little more than the guarantee of perpetual " most favoured nation " treatment ; it did not secure a permanent set of low duties as the previous treaty had done. Other treaties of the same kind as this were made 1 Zimmermann, ii. pp. 71, 72, 2 Lotz, i. 86-8, THE ADMISSION OF ALSACE-LORRAINE 51 in March, 1868, with Spain and her possessions in Cuba, Porto Rico, and the Philippines ; and in the following year with the moderately protective Switzerland, with Mexico and Japan. The Franco-German War had one other most important economic effect. The acquisition of Alsace-Lorraine greatly increased the competition which German spinners and textile manufacturers had to meet, without bringing any corresponding development of the home market. In Germany in 1868 there were 3,000,000 cotton spindles and 37,000 weaving looms, whilst in the same year there were in Alsace-Lorraine 2,131,000 cotton spindles and 48,536 looms. 1 There was great dis- cussion and uncertainty in Germany as to the policy to be adopted in regard to the new imperial lands ; but finally it was found necessary to admit them completely into the Union, and the prosperity which followed immediately after the war made the new competition less felt than it would other- wise have been. 2 The policy pursued by the Zollverein after 1866 was in the direction of Free Trade, and under the guidance of Delbruck the movement progressed with great rapidity. In 1868 the reductions made in the treaty with Austria were generalised ; some duties were abolished, and there were reductions on certain kinds of cotton goods, linen yarn, pig- iron, unwrought steel, drugs, fine leather goods, and other commodities. 3 Then came the further 1 Zimmermann, ii. p. 81. 2 Ibid., pp. 81-5. 3 Schippel, p. 185. 52 THE ZOLLVEREIN AFTER THE TREATIES reform in 1870, which simplified the tariff, reduced still further the duties on iron and steel, and freed altogether a number of articles, particularly chemi- cals. Finally, in 1873 there were still more changes, and the completion of the general policy of the reduction or entire abandonment of protective tariffs, and the adoption of tariffs for revenue purposes only. 1 The changes thus made were not to come entirely into force before the 1st January, 1877, but by that time the duties on iron, except on fine goods, were completely gone, as on most other things. Only a small group of highly finished commodities remained liable to duties ; the German Empire had become very nearly a free-trading state. As the duties on iron form about the best illus- tration of the line of movement, it may be useful to set them out here. COMMODITY Pig-iron .... Bar-Iron .... 1839 l8 4S l8 ^5 iS68 1870 1873 1877 2 1-50 1 0-50 6-18 9-18 5-7 5-7 3-50-5 2 Iron Plates . 9-24 18-24 7-15 7-15 5-7 2 Coarse Cast-Iron Goods .... 6 6 2-40 2-40 2'40 2 Coarse Iron Goods . 36 36 8-16 8-16 8 5 Fine Iron Goods . . 60-300 60-300 24-60 24-60 24-60 24-60 ! 24-6 (Marks per 100 kilog.) The establishment of this policy was the result of mingled economic and political forces. The landowners of the eastern provinces were still 1 Schippel, p. 186, remarks that the tariff legislation of these five years was altogether in the spirit of the financial reforms of Gladstone and Peel. PRACTICAL COMPLETION OF FREE TRADE 53 free traders, and so in a more moderate way were the commercial class and many of the manufac- turers. 1 The opposition came, as always, from the heavy iron and spinning industries, championed chiefly by the southern states. The Free Trade movement, which was so strong that Government proposals to protect petroleum and raise the duty on tobacco for financial reasons were rejected, 2 found its political advantage in the fact that there was at the time no compact Conservative party, and that Bismarck was relying for support in his schemes for the organisation of the empire on the moderate Liberals. Unwilling to accept many items in their political programme, he disarmed their hostility by the adoption of their economic policy ; but he left commercial matters largely to Delbriick and Camphausen. 3 The practical completion of the Free Trade policy by the cessation of the iron duties was followed by an immediate and sharp reaction. The representatives of the iron and cotton industries had never ceased their agitation against the reduc- tion of the tariff, and in conjunction with the manu- facturers of chemicals, sugar, linen, and leather, they had formed the Central Union, which com- menced to work for a return to Protection. They were aided by the conditions of German industry after 1872, but still more by the changes which 1 Lotz, i. pp. 91, 92. 2 Zimmermann, ii. pp. 219, 220. 3 Zimmermann (ii. p. 230) complains that the whole policy at this time was a slavish imitation of the action of Great Britain, without any regard to the difference in geographical and economic conditions. 54 THE ZOLLVEREIN AFTER THE TREATIES were coming over German agriculture and by the financial needs of the Empire. In the history of German trade after 1871 the dominant fact is the payment of the war indemnity of nearly six milliard francs (including interest) by France ; much of it was paid in bills of exchange, but a great amount in gold. The results were a great increase of imports, whilst exports remained almost stationary ; a very rapid rise in prices, as a result of the great influx of gold ; and consider- able impetus to industry from the high prices and also from the expenditure by the Government on railways and public works. There followed the usual results excessive development of works, over-capitalisation, and over-production. In June, 1870, there were in Prussia 410 joint-stock com- panies with a total capital of three milliard marks ; by the end of 1874 the number had increased to 2,267, with a capital of seven and one-third milliards. 1 But already in 1873 the crash had com- menced ; it was widespread and general, not merely in Germany, but outside. There followed a rapid fall in prices and general depression ; and for a time the low level of prices in Germany kept serious foreign competition away. Then, however, the situation gradually improved ; markets became steadier, and prices began to rise. But just then Great Britain entered upon a period of depression; agricultural difficulties, due to bad harvests, affected the whole country; there was a drop in the home 1 Blum, p. 158, quoting Max Wirth's Geschichte der Handelskrisen. THE REACTION 55 demand for iron and textile goods, and the British manufacturers, who were over-producing as a result of the impetus given by the unusually high prices of 1872 and 1873, now sent large quantities of goods abroad at extremely low prices, that is to say, they "dumped." This counteracted the tendency of the German market towards a rise in prices, and seriously hindered the recovery of the German manufactures ; hence came the renewed demand for Protection, strongest in the case of the textile and iron industries. 1 Moreover, a very important change had come over the opinions of the landowners. With the development of means of transport and the growth of the American railways, the Russian and even American competition in the supply of grain to the European markets was beginning to be severely felt; the German landowners were not only ceasing to be exporters, but were severely threatened even in the home market. Further, the movement of population to the towns had com- menced in Germany, and the more attractive conditions offered by industrial employment were beginning to deprive the landowners of their labourers. They had ceased to have any further interest in the promotion of Free Trade ; in fact, they were themselves beginning to desire some measure of protection. And even some of those observers who believed that it would be a mistake 1 Dietzel, in Quarterly Journal of Economics, May, 1903. Cf. Lotz, i. pp. 122-37. 56 THE ZOLLVEREIN AFTER THE TREATIES to attempt to shut out the foreign and cheaper supplies of foodstufts, were yet, like Conrad, willing to establish a moderate amount of protection for grain, by a scale of duties limited in duration and gradually diminishing, to enable the agriculturists to transfer their attention to other branches of production. 1 How far this joint protectionist movement of agriculture and industry would have been success- ful, if left to itself, is doubtful ; the determining factor in the situation was the condition of the imperial finances. The expenditure of the empire was increasing rapidly, and to Bismarck it seemed impossible to continue to raise the revenue required by direct taxation, which was becoming extremely burdensome. It was felt that a rearrangement of the imperial finances was absolutely necessary, both on economic and political grounds, and Bismarck resolved that his best policy was to have recourse to indirect taxation in the form of customs duties, and to substitute the proceeds of these for the contributions to the imperial exchequer from the separate states contributions which they raised by direct taxes. The demands on the states were steadily rising ; in 1874 they were 51,400,000 marks, whilst by 1878-9 they had risen to over 70,000,000 marks. The Chancellor was much in- fluenced by these considerations, and as a member of the landowning class he was not insensible to its demands ; the position of affairs in home 1 Dietzel, pp. 386, 387. BISMARCK'S NEW POLICY 57 politics had changed, and he could afford to break with the Liberals. In October, 1878, 204 members (i.e. a majority) of the Reichstag signed a declara- tion in favour of the reconsideration of fiscal policy. 1 And another fact which had considerable weight with the Chancellor was the growth of Protection in the neighbouring countries, particularly in France in the tariff' of 1878. 2 The policy which Bismarck now adopted had three objects in view. First, he desired to establish (to use his own words) "a customs system which secures to the entire home production a preference before foreign pro- duction in the home market, whilst keeping within the limits imposed by financial interests." Secondly, there was to be a reform of the railway system and railway rates, to promote the transport of German goods, and to put an end to the preference given on many of the railways to foreign products ; he wished to obtain an imperial railway system, and when that proved impracticable, he resolved that the Prussian railways, at least, should become the property of the 1 Blum (p. 310) quotes from the Circular : " In view of the com- mercial policy of most of the countries bordering on Germany, with the knowledge of the absence of a German customs tariff and the evil effect of this on national well-being, and on account of the continuance of the crisis in German industry and agriculture (the signatories) believe a reform of the tariff, based on the result of careful investiga- tions and expert balancing of interests, to be absolutely necessary. . . . Although holding diverse views as to commercial policy, the signatories are agreed on this fundamental point that the difficult problems of German commercial policy cannot simply be solved by phrases about Free Trade and Protection, but that it is much more necessary to reconcile the real and supposed conflicts of interests by the exercise of a scientific, patriotic, and reasonable spirit." 2 Lotz, i. pp. 146-9. .58 THE ZOLLVEREIN AFTER THE TREATIES state. And thirdly, he was anxious for the re- arrangement of the imperial finances. 1 The argument for the new policy was set out in a letter addressed by the Chancellor on 15th December, 1878, to a committee appointed by the Bundesrath to consider the revision of the tariff. The financial object of tariff reform, according to this memorandum, was to be the reduction of direct and the increase of indirect taxation ; and the Chancellor calculated that if the future import duties were to average 5 per cent, ad valorem, the increased revenue would amount to about seventy million marks, or almost exactly the amount which in the year 1878-9 was contributed by the separate states to the imperial exchequer. To secure this result it was necessary to return to the principle of the liability to taxation of all foreign products crossing the frontier, with the exception of those materials for industry which Germany either did not produce at all, or produced only to an inade- quate amount. This proposal the Chancellor pro- ceeded to justify on the ground of the economic interests of the nation. " I leave undecided the question whether complete mutual freedom of international commerce, such as is contemplated by the theory of Free Trade, would not serve the interests of Germany. But as long as most of the countries with which our trade is carried on surround themselves with customs barriers, which there is still a growing tendency to multiply, it 1 Blum, pp. 305, 306 ; cf. Dawson, pp. 47-54. BISMARCK'S ARGUMENT FOR PROTECTION 59 does not seem to me justifiable, or to the economic interest of the nation, that we should allow our- selves to be restricted in the satisfaction of our financial wants by the apprehension that German products will thereby be but slightly preferred to foreign ones." Protective duties for particular industries he thought likely to cause difficulty and arouse hostility, but a customs system protecting the whole home production would "in no way appear partial, because its effects would be more equally spread over all the productive circles of the land than is the case with a system of protective duties for isolated branches of industry. The minority of the population, which does not produce at all, but exclusively consumes, will apparently be injured by a customs system favouring the entire national production. Yet if by means of such a system the aggregate sum of the values produced in the country increase, and thus the national wealth be on the whole enhanced, the non-produc- ing parts of the population and especially the state and communal officials who are dependent upon a fixed money income will eventually be benefited." He therefore proposed the maintenance of the existing duties and their possible increase, and the introduction of new duties ; and he held that, except in cases where the foreign commodity was not produced in Germany and was indispens- able, the greater part, if not the whole, of the import duty would be borne by the foreigner. And in any case a small duty of from 5 to 10 per 60 THE ZOLLVEREIN AFTER THE TREATIES cent, would only be one of the forces affecting prices ; it would probably not do the consumer any harm, and would do the home producer some good. In regard to agriculture, the Ministry, in the memorandum which accompanied its definite proposals, declared that the duties were so small that they could not be regarded as protective to any considerable extent, and would not diminish, and still less exclude, the import of foreign grain ; but they would check the swamping of the German market by the surplus products of other lands, and make German agriculture better able to hold its own, even if the general price of grain should fall. Even granted that the result of the new duties be an increase in the price of the necessaries of life, the Government asserted that this would be corrected ultimately by the increase of home pro- duction and by the greater demand for labour and consequent rise of wages. 1 The Chancellor was supported by the iron and textile industries and their allies, and by the land- owners and the agrarian party generally. He was opposed by the exporters, who feared retaliation (though this opposition was somewhat weakened by the growing tariffs of foreign powers), by the two great seaports, which dreaded the dislocation of their trade, and by the municipalities, which, on the great Municipal Day at Berlin, where seventy- two town councils were represented, protested strongly against any policy likely to cause an in- 1 See passages quoted in Schippel, pp. 230-2. THE NEW TARIFF 6l crease in the price of food. 1 The National Liberals led the opposition, but they were a declining party, and they had no hold on the workmen ; the Socialist movement was growing rapidly, but its leaders seem to have been disinclined to take any vigorous action. Thus in 1876, the Socialist Congress at Gotha declared that "the Socialists of Germany are indifferent to the controversy raging in the proprietary classes as to Protection and Free Trade ; the problem is a practical one, and must be so considered in each particular case." And some of the Socialist leaders were apparently inclined to take the line that a protective tariff might increase the demand for labour in the home market, and consequently bring some benefit to the workmen, though, on the other hand, they disapproved of proposals which tended to raise the price of food. 2 In spite of a considerable amount of opposition, the tariff proposals were carried, 3 not, however, before the agrarian party, which held the political balance, had forced the Government to increase considerably the duties originally proposed on agricultural produce. The tariff ultimately adopted dealt with forty-three groups of commodities, and retained the system of specific duties, that is to say, duties levied on a given quantity of each commodity, and not changing with the changes in 1 Blum,, p. 330. 2 For a sketch of the Socialist attitude towards the problems of tariff policy, see Schippel, pp. 323-52. 3 The details of the controversy may be read in Zimmermann, ii. pp. 271-300 ; and Lotz, i. pp. 163-74. 62 THE ZOLLVEREIN AFTER THE TREATIES value of that quantity. In fact, the whole tariff system was inelastic, defective, and unscientific ; in particular it did not take sufficient account of the complications of industry, and lacked adaptability. 1 The new policy was based on the principle of moderate protection for agriculture and industry alike. The British protective system, up to 1846, had been maintained chiefly for the sake of agriculture ; the German protective system from 1848 to 1860 had been dictated by the interests of manufacturers ; now an effort was to be made to harmonise the two, and to give a fair measure of protection to all. And at this point it will be convenient to examine the attitude of the German economists towards national fiscal policy up to the establishment of the new tariff. 1 Schumacher, Verhandlungen, pp, 157, 158. CHAPTER V THE ATTITUDE OF THE ECONOMISTS AT the outset of a survey of the movement of economic thought in Germany in the last century, it is necessary to remind ourselves of two very important influences which have dominated the whole of German political thought during that period. The first of these is the idea of the paternal state an idea based on the historical fact that the Prussian State is the creation of a series of strong rulers, such as the Great Elector, Frederick William L, and Frederick II., working by means of a powerful and highly centralised bureaucracy. For centuries the nation looked for impetus and initiative in all departments of national life to the monarchs, and on the whole it rarely looked in vain. The second great influence is that of the desire for national unity a desire dis- appointed at the War of Liberation, but ever growing in strength, attempting to realise itself in the abortive movements of 1848-9, and at last triumphant in 1870. The effect of these two ideas has been a general sympathy on the part of all German writers on economics and politics towards 63 64 THE ATTITUDE OF THE ECONOMISTS State action, and an inability amongst economists to keep their discussions free from political con- siderations. Most of the German economists of the early years of the nineteenth century were followers and interpreters of Adam Smith, and the most im- portant representatives of this school were Rau, whose Lehrbuch was published between 1826 and 1832, and Nebenius, the official of Baden, who, it will be remembered, played a considerable part in the foundation of the German Zollverein. l But as early as 1809 a note of revolt against the doctrines of Adam Smith was sounded by Adam Muller, whose Elemente der Staatskunst was pub- lished in that year. His criticism of Adam Smith is based chiefly on his own conception of the State as representing the " totality of national life." Too much regard, he held, is paid by Adam Smith to the individual and to the immediate production of exchange values ; and he complains that the collective interests of the community, the main- tenance of collective production in the future, and the social well-being of the workers are almost entirely ignored, and that Adam Smith neglects to point out " the necessary counterpoise and com- pletion of the division of labour," namely, the prin- ciple of the "national combination of labour." For Great Britain Adam Smith's individualistic economics might be adequate, and probably were ; for Germany and the continental states generally 1 See p. 7, FRIEDRICH LIST 65 a different theory of economic action and of the relation of the State to commerce and industry was absolutely necessary. Much more important and much more influen- tial was the work of Friedrich List (1789-1846), who published his Rationale System der Politischen Oekonomie in 1841 a book which owed its wide- reaching success partly to its power of argument and abundance of historical illustration, and partly to its fervid patriotism and its appeal to that growing desire for national unity which animated the vast majority of the German people. It is less an economic argument than a great political appeal, and its title gives the key to its contents. Like Muller, List lays great emphasis on the distinc- tion between "private economy" and "national economy." * National unity is the first essential of individual well-being, and "private economic in- terests, like all others, must be subordinated to the maintenance, completion, and strengthening of a nationality." Like Muller again, he emphasises the fact that it is not to the production of wealth alone that the economic policy of the nation should be directed, but to the creation of many- sided productive powers, and the harmony and balance of the three branches of national economic 1 List, National System of Political Economy (translated by Lloyd), chap. xiv. e ' The foreign trade of a nation must not be estimated in the way in which individual merchants judge it, solely and only according to the theory of values (i.e. by regarding merely the gain at any particular moment of some material advantage) ; the nation is bound to keep steadily in view all those conditions on which its present and future existence, prosperity, and power depend" (chap. xii.). F 66 THE ATTITUDE OF THE ECONOMISTS action agriculture, manufacture, commerce. In this latter idea of the balance of the three depart- ments of economic activity we may detect traces of the influence of one of the most remarkable works of Fichte, whose Geschlossene Handelsstaat, published in 1800, sets forth a scheme of a self- contained socialistic state, in which perhaps the most important task of the Government is to maintain the balance between the producers of food and raw material, the producers of manu- factured goods and the merchants, and to prevent the predominance of any one group over the others ; from this ideal state foreign trade must be excluded, because it is certain to tend to destroy such a balance. But whilst he desired to maintain agriculture, List also held most strongly that in- dustrial development is essential to any community which desires to attain to the highest possible level of civilisation. 1 To enable industries to grow up, protection by tariffs and all possible forms of governmental action is necessary until such time as the manufactures are strong enough to stand 1 c ' Manufactories and manufactures are the mothers and children of municipal liberty, of intelligence, of the arts and sciences, of internal and external commerce, of navigation and improvements in transport, of civilisation and political power. They are the chief means of liberating agriculture from its chains, and of elevating it to a com- mercial character and to a degree of art and science, by which the rents, farming profits, and wages are increased, and greater value is given to landed property. The popular school has attributed this civilising power to foreign trade. ... If, however, trade in the manufactures of far distant lands exercises admittedly so beneficial an influence on our agricultural industry, how much more beneficial must the influence be of those manufactures which are bound up with us locally, commercially, and politically" (List, chap. xii.). THE HISTORICAL SCHOOL 67 alone and to contend effectually with foreign com- petition. This is the " infant industries " argument for Protection ; but it will be noticed that even List did not contemplate the maintenance of Pro- tection as a permanent policy the ultimate ideal for each state is (in his doctrine) that by these " educational tariffs " it should at last become strong enough to cast off trade restrictions. 1 But in spite of the increase of prosperity and growth of industrial activity in Germany since the estab- lishment of the Customs Union, Protection could reasonably, at the date of List's book, be thought necessary to enable the rising industries to develop in face of the overwhelming industrial power of Great Britain. Two years after the publication of List's great book, there appeared the first work of the school which was to exert the most potent influence on German economic thought for the remainder of the nineteenth century the historical school. In 1843 Roscher published his Grundriss, and this was followed in 1848 by Hildebrand's Die Nationaloekonomie der Gregenwart und Zukunft, and in 1853 by the book of Karl Knies entitled Die Politische Oekonomie von Standpunkte der geschichtlicJien Methode. These various works formulated the general principles on which the new school has worked, and the principles have been applied since that time by an ever-increasing army of students and investigators, who have 1 See below, p. 72. 68 THE ATTITUDE OF THE ECONOMISTS devoted themselves chiefly to historical inquiry and the collection of the facts of economic history, and to the deduction from the results so obtained of principles which may serve as a guide for the economic action of communities, and particularly of their own country. The historical school has on the whole always thrown its weight on the side of Protection, at least for Germany. It does not regard either Free Trade or Protection as an ideal, except in so far as universal Free Trade is a far-off goal, desirable, but only to be reached when the whole political character of the world is changed. Both Free Trade and Protection have their uses in the different stages of national development. " The fundamental propositions," set forth by Knies and adopted by all the historical school, " are that the economic constitution of society at any epoch on the one hand, and on the other the contemporary theoretic conception of economic science, are results of a definite historical development ; that they are both in vital connection with the whole social organism of the period, having grown up along with it and under the same conditions of time, place, and nationality ; that the economic system must there- fore be regarded as passing through a series of phases correlative with the successive stages of civilisation, and can at no point of this movement be considered to have attained an entirely definite form ; that no more the present than any previous economic organisation of society is to be regarded SCHMOLLER'S " MERCANTILE SYSTEM" 69 as absolutely good and right, but only as a phase in a continual historical evolution ; and that in like manner the now prevalent economic doctrine is not to be viewed as complete and final, but only as representing a certain stage in the unfolding or progressive manifestation of the truth." 1 Given the particular conditions of Germany, most of the writers of the historical school have held that their country was at the time of the Bismarckian tariff legislation of the late seventies in the stage where protection and vigorous State action in regard to commerce and industry were necessary, and their general views are best represented by the greatest of living economic historians, Professor Gustav Schmoller. In his Mercantile System, published in 1884, Professor Schmoller has given a clear exposition of this theory, though in an elaborate historical setting. He traces the development (with special reference to Germany) of the economic unit from the village through the town and the territory to the state ; " political organisms and economic organisms are by no means necessarily conterminous ; and yet the great and brilliant achievements of history, both political and economic, are wont to be accomplished at times when economic organisation has rested on the same foundation as political power and order." 5 Like Miiller and List, and like all the members of the historical school, he emphasises the moral element, and the 1 Ingram, History of Political Economy, p. 203. 2 Schmoller, The Mercantile System (translated by VV. J. Ashley). 70 THE ATTITUDE OF THE ECONOMISTS need for the consideration of the general interest of society. " All economic and political life rests upon psychical mass movements, mass sentiments, and mass conceptions, gravitating around certain centres." 3 "The idea that economic life has ever been a process mainly dependent on individual action an idea based on the impression that it is concerned merely with methods of satisfying in- dividual needs is mistaken with regard to all stages of human civilisation, and in some respects it is more mistaken the further we go back." 2 So the municipal economic policy of the Middle Ages, in spite of its local partiality and prejudices, was fully justified so long as the towns were the most important forces on the side of civilisation and economic progress. Later the place of the towns was taken by the territories, striving to make them- selves into self-contained and self-conscious eco- nomic unites. " What to each in its time gave riches and superiority, first to Milan, Venice, Florence, and Genoa, then later to Spain and Portugal, and now to Holland, France, and England, and to some extent to Denmark and Sweden, was a state policy in economic matters, as superior to the territorial as that had been to the municipal. ... It was not only a question of state armies, fleets, and civil services ; it was a question rather of unifying systems of finance and economy which should encompass the forces of millions and whole countries and give unity to their social life." 3 And this is 1 Loc. cit.y p. 61. 2 Loc. cit., pp. 3-4. 3 Loc. cit., pp. 48-9. THE TRUE VIEW OF PROTECTION 71 the true conception of mercantilism ; it is, in fact, a great policy of national construction, " state making and national economy making at the same time. . . . The essence of the system lies not in some doctrine of money or of a balance of trade ; not in tariff barriers, protective duties, or navigation laws, but in something far greater : namely, in the total transformation of society and its organisation, as well as of the state and its institutions, in the replacing of a local and territorial economic policy by that of the national state." 1 And so to Pro- fessor Schmoller the practice and theory of the European states in the first half of the nineteenth century, as expounded by List, had a truer relation to their actual economic conditions than had the theories of Adam Smith. 2 But this doctrine of Protection is a very relative one ; it all depends on the particular condition of a country at a given time. The policy of Bis- marck in his tariff legislation may, on this reason- ing, have been a sound one for Germany twenty- five years ago, when it was necessary to take all possible steps to consolidate the Empire and pro- mote its economic development. It is defensible on precisely the same principles as those which led Adam Smith to defend the old Navigation Acts ; but this very fact would condemn merely pro- tective tariffs as a permanent policy. There is a higher stage of development, when the infant industries have become adult and are able to fight 1 LOG. cit., pp. 50-1. 2 Loc. cit., p. 60. 72 THE ATTITUDE OF THE ECONOMISTS their own way in the world. To give them per- manent protection is to keep them in perpetual tutelage. List himself wrote that " a nation which has already attained manufacturing supremacy can only protect its own manufacturers against retro- gression and indolence by the free importation of the means of subsistence and raw materials and by the competition of foreign manufactured goods." 1 England, he argued, had by 1841 reached the highest stage of development, and for her Free Trade was the right economic policy. 2 So also 1 List, loc. cit., chap. xv. The previous passage is interesting : " Eng- land will then give up the idea that she is designed to monopolise the manufacturing power of the whole world. She will no longer require that France, Germany, and North America should sacrifice their own manufactures in consideration of the concession by England of permitting the import, duty free, of agricultural products and raw material. She will recognise the legitimacy of protective systems in those nations, although she will herself more and more favour Free Trade," for^the reason given above. He adds that England will cease to urge foreign nations to become Free Traders ; " she will herself permit competition without regard to the foreign systems of pro- tection." * "Finally, history teaches us how nations which have been endowed by nature with all resources which are requisite for the attainment of the highest grade of wealth and power, may and must without on that account forfeiting the end in view modify their systems according to the measure of their own progress : in the first stage, adopting Free Trade with more advanced nations as a means of raising themselves from a state of barbarism, and of making advances in agriculture ; in the second stage, promoting the growth of manufac- tures, fisheries, navigation, and foreign trade by means of commercial restrictions ; and in the last stage, after reaching the highest degree of wealth and power, by gradually reverting to the principle of Free Trade and of unrestricted competition in the home as well as in foreign markets, that so their agriculturists, manufacturers, and merchants may be preserved from indolence and stimulated to retain the supre- macy which they have acquired " (chap. x.). He adds that Great Britain alone appeared (in his time) to have reached this final stage. GERMAN ECONOMISTS AND STATE ACTION 73 Professor Schmoller writes : " That age could begin to think and act in the spirit of Free Trade which had left so far behind it the toilsome work of national development that it regarded its best results as matters of course " ; l and most of the other members of the German historical school of the present day seem to regard German industries as having reached the stage in which they no longer have need of what List called " educational tariffs " (Erziehungszolle). 2 Where they do defend the maintenance of the tariffs against the importa- tion of manufactured commodities, they do so, as we shall see later, on entirely different grounds. The German historical school has taken up also an altogether different attitude towards State action from that adopted by the older English economists. They allow a very large sphere of action to the State, and the term applied to so many of them " Socialists of the Chair " means that they go a considerable way towards that form of socialism which in its origin is associated with the name of Ferdinand Lassalle. As a philosophic doctrine, however, it is much older than that writer. Fichte had opposed to the " security " theory of the State the proposition that " it is the duty of the State to give each man that which is his due, then to estab- lish him in the actual possession of his property, 1 Schmoller, loc. cit., pp. 61-2. 2 Cf. Schacht, " Inhalt und Kritik des Zolltarifentwurfs " in Schmoller's Jahrbuch, 1902 ; and Wagner, Agrar- und Industriestaat, 2nd ed., p. 223. 74 THE ATTITUDE OF THE ECONOMISTS and then to safeguard him therein." 1 Many of the followers of Hegel, whose philosophic teaching tended "to glorify existing institutions, to see in Church and State the objective embodiment of the Absolute Idea," 2 had regarded the Prussian State as the instrument appointed to bring about the social reformation. The term " state social- ism " was adopted in Germany to indicate the antithesis to revolutionary socialism, and to mark a policy of reform, not by the destruction, but by the utilisation of the existing state organisation. So in Professor Wagner's articles on " Finanz- politik und Staatsozialismus," published in 1887, it is asserted that "the chief aim of the State at present in taxation and every other form of its activity ought to be to alter the national distribu- tion of wealth to the advantage of the working class. All politics must become social politics ; the State must turn workman's friend." 3 This does not mean merely the protection of the worker by factory legislation and his relief in time of poverty by the Poor Law system ; it includes the ownership of railways and other industrial enterprises by the State, the undertaking by the State of whatever enterprises are desirable, but cannot be, or are not likely to be, undertaken by private individuals or companies, and the establish- ment of State-aided compulsory insurances against 1 Fichte, Der Geschlossene Handeltsatuat , bk. i. chap. i. 8 Russell, German Social Democracy, p. 2. 3 Rae, Contemporary Socialism, p. 387. GERMAN RAILWAY POLICY 75 sickness and accident, and State systems of old-age pensions. This state socialism found its expression in the social legislation of Prince Bismarck, which was inspired partly by a genuine interest in social reform, and partly by a desire (not in the least successful) to outbid the Social Democrats for popular favour. 1 A most important and beneficial influence was exercised on the industrial development of Germany by the new railway policy. The older State action in this matter had taken the form of subventions to private companies, and the purchase or direct construction of railways to only a limited extent. In 1875 eight lines were owned, and eight others were managed by the Government, and thirty were privately owned and managed. The con- stitution of the Empire provided for the imperial control and supervision of railways, the building by the Government of railways " considered neces- sary for the defence of Germany or for the purpose of general commerce," and the settlement of railway rates. An Imperial Railway Board was set up in 1873, and Bismarck secured the passage through the Prussian Parliament of a law enabling the Government to transfer the railways of that state to the empire. This was intended to show an example, but the smaller states would not take the same line ; and consequently, with the exception of those in Alsace and Lorraine, the railways re- 1 For a detailed description of this policy, see Dawson, Bismarck and State Socialism. 76 THE ATTITUDE OF THE ECONOMISTS mained the property of the several states. The Prussian Government then set to work to buy up the lines in its own territory ; between 1879 and 1882 about six thousand miles were bought, and the process was continued, until, in 1902, the Prussian State railways were over nineteen thou- sand miles in extent. In the Empire, as a whole, the state Governments between them owned in 1900 railways over twenty-eight thousand miles in length. 1 Not only has this policy of State owner- ship been financially extremely beneficial, but it has enabled the Governments to establish a scien- tific and coherent system of railway rates, which promotes, instead of hampering, trade. The Chancellor's policy of social reform was exemplified by the Sickness Insurance Law of 1883, with its complement the Accident Insurance Laws of 1884 and 1885, and the Old Age and Infirmity Insurance Law of 1889 (now replaced by the enactment of 1899) ; these applied to the working-class population of the whole Empire, and there could be no contracting-out. Under the Sickness and Accident Laws, every manual worker and every person whose salary is below a certain amount must insure in some fund ; usually he pays two-thirds and his employer one-third of the weekly contribution, and in return he receives free medical treatment and sick -pay during illness. The Old Age Insurance system, which includes provision for permanent incapacity arising from 1 The Statesman's Year-book, 1903, p. 674. COMPULSORY INSURANCE 77 ill-health, follows the same general lines ; it is compulsory on all persons in receipt of incomes of less than 100 a year, with certain small excep- tions, and is optional for a large number of other persons. l The obligation to insure begins at sixteen years of age ; employer and employed pay an equal share of the premium ; the pension, to which the State gives a subsidy of 2 10s. per annum, can first be claimed at the age of seventy, or in the case of permanent disablement by ill-health, after five years' insurance. 2 The schemes have hardly yet passed out of the experimental stage it is not yet twenty years since they came into force, but there can be no question that they have con- stituted the most serious and most successful attempt yet made to deal with the problem. 1 It was estimated at the occupation census of 1895 that over 12,000,000 persons were liable to insurance under this law (Board of Trade Report, p. 15 n.). 2 For full details on the whole subject, see the Board of Trade Report, 1899, and especially Brooks' Compulsory Insurance Report of the United States Commissioner of Labour. CHAPTER VI GERMAN COMMERCIAL POLICY TO 1894 FOR some years after the adoption of the new tariff in 1880, German foreign trade remained almost stationary in value, and even declined a little. The following table shows the movement of imports and exports (exclusive of the precious metals) of Germany for the period 1880-91 in million marks : l Year. Import. Export. 1880 .... 2,819 ... 2,893 1881 .... 2,962 ... 2,975 1882 .... 3,128 ... 3,188 1883 . . . . 3,263 ... 3,270 1884 . . . . 3,260 ... 3,203 1885 . . . . 2,937 ... 2,859 1886 . . . . 2,877 ... 2,984 1887 .... 3,111 ... 3,134 1888 . . . . 3,271 ... 3,204 1889 .... 3,990 ... 3,165 1890 .... 4,146 ... 3,327 1891 .... 4,151 ... 3,176 It will be observed that for the five years 1880 to 1884, the average value of imports was 3,086 1 Statistisches Jahrbuchfur das Deutsche Reich, 1892, p. 38. 78 FOREIGN TRADE AND CUSTOMS REVENUE 79 million marks, whilst the average for the next four years was 3,049 million marks, or about two million pounds a year less ; the average of exports was for 1880 to 1884, 3,106 millions, and for 1885 to 1888, 3,045 millions, or about three million pounds less. After 1888 the figures are not alto- gether comparable, because of the inclusion of Hamburg and Bremen, which, though long under negotiation, had been delayed by the return to Protection. 1 It will be noticed further that after 1888 there was a sharp rise in imports, whilst exports remained at about the same level, and the excess of imports over exports became very large. For the imperial exchequer the effects of the new customs system seem to have been altogether satisfactory. In 1877-8 the net revenue from the customs was 103 '7 million marks, or 2 '4 marks per head of population ; by 1883-4 the amount had risen to 189*7 million, or 4*2 marks per head ; and in 1889-90 a total was reached of 357*7 million, or 7*3 marks per head. The contribution to the imperial exchequer from the separate states, which had reached 70 million marks in 1878-9, sank rapidly until in the year 1882-3 the customs revenue not only supplied an amount equal to the old contributions, but provided a surplus which could be distributed amongst the states ; and in 1884-5 nearly 41 million marks were available for this purpose. 8 After 1880 the most noticeable feature in the 1 Zimmermann, ii. p. 98. 2 Blum, p. 306. 80 GERMAN COMMERCIAL POLICY TO 1894 history of the German tariff is the increase of the duties on agricultural products, coincident with the growth of the political power of the agrarian party. It is true that there were some slight increases in the duties on manufactured commodi- ties, but these were not very important, and against them must be set some small reductions. 1 The agrarians complained of growing competition, and urged the necessity of protecting the food supply of the empire against the dangers of war ; and they secured increases, of which the more important are shown in the following table : DUTY PER 100 KILO. Commodity. 1879. 1881. 1885. 1888. Wheat . . 1 mk. ... ... 3 mk. ... 5 mk. Rye . 1 ... ... 3 ... 5 Barley . . -5 ... ... l ... 2j Flour . . 2 ... 3mk. ... 7 ... 10| Meat of all kinds 12 ... ... 20 ... As regards Germany's foreign trade, the ex- porters had feared at the time of the establishment of the new protective tariff that they might be hampered by retaliation on the part of foreign nations. Fortunately their fears in this direction were not realised, since the Government of Prince Bismarck was able, in most cases, either to make new treaties, or to secure the maintenance of the existing treaty relations. Political influence enabled Germany between 1880 and 1888 to establish, with such Eastern Powers as China, Japan, Corea, Siam, and also with Servia and Roumania, treaties which 1 Lotz, i. 177. FOREIGN COMMERCIAL RELATIONS 81 bound those Powers to reduce some of their exist- ing duties, or, at least, not to increase those duties on German products, without imposing any corre- sponding obligation on Germany herself. Of another kind were the treaties with Italy, Spain, Greece, Switzerland, in which the reductions of duties were mutual, although on the German side they were not, except in the case of Switzerland, very important. With the great states, such as Austria - Hungary, Belgium, the Netherlands, France, Sweden, and Norway, all that could be obtained was a continuance of " most favoured nation " treatment, whose importance for Germany was enhanced by the fact that France had made treaties with the other countries, which gave her certain reductions of duties, and that under the " most favoured nation " clause Germany enjoyed the same advantages. In Great Britain, under the treaty of 1865, Germany continued to re- ceive the same favourable treatment a privilege which was extended to her also in the British Colonies. 1 With Russia and the United States the condition of affairs was by no means so satis- factory, for both those nations were particularly interested in the export of agricultural produce, and therefore came into sharp conflict with Germany over the new tariff, which they not unnaturally regarded as directed specially against themselves. Russia had always refused to bind herself by treaties, even of the simplest kind, 1 Ibid.., ii. pp. 60-3, 82 GERMAN COMMERCIAL POLICY TO 1894 and from 1877 onwards her tariff wall was steadily rising a fact which was not without influence on the movement of the German tariff between 1880 and 1890. Germany's relations with the United States had long been based on reciprocal "most favoured nation " treatment, but this had been of little value ; the situation was now very strained, and the German policy in regard to agricultural products must be counted as one of the strong motives for the high protective policy adopted in America by the McKinley Tariff. On the whole Prince Bismarck was disinclined to the old policy of conventional tariffs ; he seems to have been opposed to anything which would bind the hands of the Government in its defence of the commercial interests of the country. He adhered, with certain slight exceptions, to the simple system of the autonomous tariff; but by 1890 a considerable change had come over the political conditions of Germany, marked by the dismissal of Prince Bismarck and the appointment of General Caprivi as his successor. In home affairs the chief features of the new system were the abandonment of anti-socialist legislation and the attempt towards a " labour policy," illustrated by the international conference at Berlin ; in par- liamentary politics the important development was the rise of the Centre or Catholic party. 1 In 1 In 1887 the National Liberals were the largest party in the Reich- stag with 99 members, the Centre came next with 98, and the Conserva- tives next with 80; at the election of 1890 106 members of the Centre were returned and 73 Conservatives, while the National Liberals fell to 42. MOVEMENT OF FOOD PRICES 83 foreign policy, the independent attitude was abandoned, and the most striking example was furnished by the Anglo-German arrangement with regard to East Africa, under which Great Britain was given a free hand there and in Zanzibar, in exchange for the surrender of Heligoland to Germany. Commercial policy was now to be modified in the same way as the result of a number of converging influences. The question of the food supply had suddenly become serious. The following table shows the movement of wholesale prices for wheat and rye per 100 kilog. at Berlin, for the period 1880 to 1891 i 1 Year. Wheat. Rye. 1880 . . .218 mks. ... 188 mks. 1881 . . .219 ... 195 1882 . . . 204 ... 152 1883 . . . 186 ... 145 1884 . . .162 ... 143 1885 . . . 161 ... 141 1886 . . .151 ... 131 1887 . . .164 ... 121 1888 . . .172 ... 134 1889 188 ... 156 1890 . . .195 ... 170 1891 . . .224 ... 211 It will be observed that, as a result of a number of causes, the agricultural duties did not prevent a continued fall in prices until 1886, but after that year there was an upward movement which became extremely sharp with the failure of harvests in 1890 and 1891. This was particularly the case in regard 1 Bade, pp. 27-8. 84 GERMAN COMMERCIAL POLICY TO 189* to rye, which is the chief bread-stuff for a very large part of the German population. In 1891 the Russian Government found itself compelled, in view of the acute economic distress in Russia, to prohibit the export of wheat and rye and other agricultural produce. At the same time, the diffi- culties of the German exporters were increased by the adoption of the McKinley Tariff in the United States and by the marked movement towards higher protection all over Europe. Most of the nations with which Germany had treaties either gave notice of their termination, or were inclined to do so, and France was also about to renounce the treaties which she had made with various countries, and by which Germany had profited. It had become necessary for Germany to re- adjust her policy. It was believed to be clearly impossible for her to continue in the old way and to make no effort to influence the tariffs of her neighbours. It was therefore decided to endeavour to continue the existing reciprocity arrangements, but to elaborate them into a new series of treaties, which should return to the old principle of re- ciprocal reductions of duties. The agrarian party clung to the protection of the autonomous tariff, and were opposed to any modifications ; but under the prevailing circumstances they were not unwilling to see a temporary reduction of the duties. What they did object to was anything which would establish those reductions for any considerable number of years. On the other hand, the growth RETURN TO THE TREATY SYSTEM 85 of industry not only rendered a large and cheap food supply desirable, but made it necessary that everything possible should be done to secure a large and assured foreign market for German manu- factured articles. The latter was the dominant consideration, but if German manufacturers were to export freely, foreigners must be allowed to have easier access to the German market. "The conclusion of new international treaties with simple ' most favoured nation ' treatment, without the settlement of tariffs, would indeed give Germany the possibility of securing an in- ternal market for its own manufactures by means of an arbitrary protective tariff, but would provide not the slightest guarantee for the maintenance of that foreign market which is so essential for our export trade. In face of the world competition of the economically developed states, becoming ever fiercer with the rapid increase of production and its aids, permanent intercourse between them is conceivable only in the form of a reasonable exchange of commodities, and this presupposes again a deliberate reciprocal limitation of free action in regard to tariffs. Under the present commercial conditions, Germany cannot count on the maintenance of its export, unless by such limita- tions on its own side it secures to other nations the possibility of paying for its goods, wholly or in part, by their own products." l The home producers, both agricultural and 1 Government Memorandum, quoted in Lotz, i. p. 87. 86 GERMAN COMMERCIAL POLICY TO 1894 industrial, must consent to some sacrifices, for "con- cessions at the hands of agricultural nations, such as Austria-Hungary, Italy, and Russia, were to be obtained only by the reduction of certain duties on agricultural commodities ; concessions at the hands of manufacturing nations, like Belgium and Switzerland, by the reduction of certain German duties on manufactured products." 1 The manu- facturers as a whole supported the new policy, since they were anxious for the growth of the export trade, and did not fear foreign competition in the home markets so much as formerly ; the working classes also gave their support to it, and the opposition was in the main confined to the agrarians, who were called on to make the chief sacrifices, and were unwilling to do so for any length of time. The new policy was inaugurated in December, 1891, by the commercial treaty with the Austro- Hungarian Empire, which for some time had been desirous of entering into closer relations with Germany, since the latter country was its most important market, taking on an average over one- half of the total Austro-Hungarian exports. 2 But at the same time, only about 10 per cent, of the German exports went to Austria-Hungary, and her imports from that country were only about 14 per cent, of the whole, so that for the purposes of negotiations Germany was in much the stronger position. Hungary was particularly interested in 1 DietzeL, pp 367-8. 2 Wuttke, p. 415. TARIFF CHANGES 87 the reduction of the German agrarian duties, and in Austria itself there was a reaction against the protective policy of recent years. Following the treaty with Austria came others with Italy, Belgium, and at the beginning of 1892 with Switzerland. They were all to remain in force till the 31st of December, 1903, and unless then re- nounced were to continue indefinitely, but were to be terminable at one year's notice from either side. The bases of all these treaties were the same reciprocal "most favoured nation" treatment and reduction of duties. The most important changes on the German side were in the case of the agri- cultural duties, which were reduced below the level of 1888, but in no case to the rate of 1885 ; thus the duties on wheat and rye were lowered from 5 to 3^ marks per 100 kilog., on barley from 2J to 2, on flour from 10^ to 7J, and on meat from 20 to 15. In manufactured articles moderate reduc- tions were made in the import duties on joinery, glass, and earthenware, some iron goods, textiles, paper, leather manufactures, and others. In all, it was estimated that the articles affected by these reductions and by some abolitions of unimportant duties had been imported from the four countries concerned to the amount of 260 million marks on an average for the years 1888 to 1890. 1 On the other side there were general reductions of duties on German manufactured goods ; and in a number of cases where reductions were not made, the con- 1 Lotz, ii. p. 83. 88 GERMAN COMMERCIAL POLICY TO 1894 trading states bound themselves not to make an increase. The German exporters were by no means satisfied, for they had hoped to obtain greater reductions of hostile tariffs, and they overlooked the fact that they had, at any rate, prevented any further advances for a considerable period. They were, however, willing to accept the treaties, and though the agrarians made a strong opposition on certain points, they were not powerful enough to secure the rejection of the Government policy. Then, however, agricultural conditions changed, and there was a fall in prices, due partly to im- proved harvests at home, and partly to the increase of imports to Germany from the United States and Roumania. The following table shows the movements of prices from 1891 to 1894 : l QUOTATIONS PER 100 KILOG. 1891. 1892. 1893. 1894. Wheat (at Cologne) 23-2 mks. 19'2 mks. 16-4 mks. 14-1 mks. Flour 31-0 26-2 22-1 19'2 %e 22-2 19-1 15-2 12'7 Barley (at Mannheim) 18-7 l6'8 17'7 15-3 The result was that the Government had much more difficulty in carrying the second series of commercial treaties in the latter part of 1893 with Servia, Spain, and especially Roumania. The last- named country was coming to be one of the most important sources of Germany's food supply, par- ticularly during the conflict with Russia. In 1889 5 per cent, of the German supply of wheat came 1 Dietzel, p. 369. RUSSO-GERMAN COMMERCIAL RELATIONS 89 from Roumania, but in 1893 the amount had risen to 20 '4 per cent., and to an even higher point in the case of rye. 1 The agrarian party were therefore strongly hostile to anything which would encourage the increase of the quantities imported from Rou- mania, whilst, on the other hand, the manufacturers, who sent, it was estimated, 100 million marks worth of goods per annum to that country, wanted a treaty which would still further develop their market. The new treaties, although supported by the whole force of the manufacturers, were confirmed by the Reichstag only after a most strenuous opposition from the agrarians. The conflict reached its height over the treaty with Russia, which was in some ways the most important of all. It has already been remarked that the commercial relations be- tween that country and Germany had for some time been distinctly strained, but the trade between the two was, nevertheless, very considerable. In 1 890 Russia imported from Germany goods to the value of 10,300,000 30 per cent, being for manufactured goods and exported to her goods to the value of 27,000,000 95 per cent, of these latter being foodstuffs, raw materials, and unfinished goods. 2 In 1891 Russia sent into Germany more than one- half (53 per cent.) of the latter 's total import of cereals, and this quantity taken by Germany amounted to about one-sixth of the total Russian export of cereals. Germany sent to Russia iron 1 Lotz, ii. p. 110. 2 Wuttke, p. 419, and British Foreign Office Report, p. 41. 90 GERMAN COMMERCIAL POLICY TO 1894 and steel goods, chemicals used in manufactures, coal and coke, porcelain and cement, and a very large quantity of flour. Moreover, she had a large transit trade, for a considerable proportion of the Russian supplies of raw cotton and wool came to her through Germany. Germany had two grounds of complaint against Russia. The highly prohibitive tariff, which, after eight increases of duties between 1881 and 1891, culminated in the last year in a new general scheme of duties and reached the highest point in Russian protective policy since 1850, affected all nations equally ; but the discrimination against land-borne in favour of sea-borne goods hindered the com- petition of Germany with Great Britain in the supply of coal and iron, and in the carrying trade. Russia had hitherto stood apart from the treaty system, in her unwillingness to bind her customs tariff for any definite time, but now she was not disinclined to modify her policy, particularly as the treaties already made by Germany put her in an extremely difficult position. Those treaties had given reductions of duties on agricultural produce to other nations, and thereby they enjoyed a distinct advantage over Russia. After the con- clusion of the first series of treaties, Russian corn paid a duty 43 per cent, higher than that imposed on the products of the favoured nations Austria- Hungary, Italy, Switzerland, Belgium, in the treaties, 1 and the United States, Argentina, Servia, 1 British Foreign Office Report, p. 42. RUSSO-GERMAN NEGOTIATIONS 91 Bulgaria, and Turkey, under the "most favoured nation " clause. Roumania was also about to be included. Negotiations between the two Powers had com- menced towards the end of 1891, by Russia pro- posing that Germany should grant her the terms of the conventional tariff in regard to most agri- cultural products, together with free entry for a number of raw materials, and offering in return to make some concessions, but not on metals, textiles, chemicals, or sugar. The German Government replied that the proposals were inacceptable, since they secured to Russia reductions on 80 per cent, of her exports, and gave practically nothing in return ; it suggested, therefore, that Russia should remove the obstacles to commercial intercourse on the frontier by simplifying the customs regulations, equalise the duties on sea- and land-borne goods, and reduce the duties on about four-fifths of the tariff groups of commodities. Negotiations were continued after the control of Russian commercial policy had passed into the hands of M. Witte, who proposed to establish a minimum and maxi- mum tariff the minimum to be a slightly modified version of the tariff of 1891, for the benefit of those states which gave Russia "most favoured nation" treatment, and the maximum to be the same tariff increased in various cases and against various countries. In October, 1892, Russia offered to admit German goods under the minimum tariff, and to abolish the preferential treatment of sea- 92 GERMAN COMMERCIAL POLICY TO 1894 borne trade ; and in March of the following year the German Government replied with its final proposals. It offered the conventional tariff terms in return for considerable reductions on the Russian minimum tariff, and the promotion of trade by the rearrangement of the customs regulations. On the refusal of the Russian Government to consider these proposals and the failure of an attempt at a conference of experts, the actual tariff war began. From August 1st, 1893, German goods imported into Russia became subject to the maximum tariff, which imposed on them surtaxes amounting to at least 30 per cent, on manufactured goods and 20 per cent, on semi-manufactured articles. In the same month Germany replied by imposing sur- taxes of 50 per cent, on all Russian goods liable to customs duties one result being that the duty was about 115 per cent, higher on Russian bread stuffs than on those imported from America, Hungary, Roumania, and Argentina. In return, the Russian Government again increased the tariff against German produce by 50 per cent., and raised the shipping dues against German vessels. It extended these measures to Finland ; and the German Government consequently applied the 50 per cent, surtaxes to goods imported from that Duchy also. All these various increases had been made by the 16th of August, but the strain on both sides was very much too severe ; early in September fresh negotiations were opened, and on October 16th the first conference was held at Berlin. THE TARIFF WAR 93 "The statistics published by the German Govern- ment show that after the outbreak of the tariff war, the German export trade to Russia had been partially paralysed. The export of locomo- tives ceased ; the export of wrought iron was one- third of the average in the preceding year, and of cement less than one -half. And in addition to the losses of the German exporters and manufac- turers, it became apparent that a large number of Germans lived by the import and handling of Russian products, and they were, of course, severely affected. The railways, which are State property, were run, on certain branches, at a loss. German ships were practically excluded from Russian ports, and the German coast towns, interested in the carrying trade, were heavy sufferers. . . . With the approach of winter the situation became worse, as the Baltic ports were closed by the ice. The large trade in extra-European goods, which had been carried on through Germany, was crippled. The transit of raw cotton through Germany for the Russian market was, in 1893, only one-half what it had been in the preceding year. And in addition to the economical losses, a grave danger was im- minent. There is ample proof that the tariff war, as it proceeded, was regarded by both re- sponsible parties as likely to lead to a state of things dangerous for the peace of Europe." 1 On the other side, Russia was suffering from the injury inflicted on her agricultural exports, particularly 1 Report, p. 46. 94 GERMAN COMMERCIAL POLICY TO 1894 after the good harvest of 1893. The following table shows the movement of imports and exports between the two countries for the years 1890 to 1894 inclusive. It will be remembered that the acute struggle was in the latter half of 1893, and in the first two months of 1894. RUSSIAN EXPORTS TO GERMANY. Mill. Roubles. 1890 . . .178 1891 . . .193 1892 . . .138 1893 . . .133 1894 . . 148 GERMAN EXPORTS TO RUSSIA. Mill. Marks. 54 58 38 35 54 Both sides were now anxious to come to terms, and political motives combined with economic interests to bring about this result. Russia desired a treaty with Germany as a first step in a series of such treaties, and Germany was anxious to do something to counterbalance the growing Russo- French alliance. The outcome of this less hostile disposition on both sides was the treaty signed on February 10th, 1894. The German Govern- ment declared that German trade, commerce, and shipping were profoundly interested in the reduc- tion of the Russian duties, and that, on the other hand, the freer importation of Russian grain would not seriously affect the German agricultural in- terests, since the really dangerous menace was from the United States, Roumania, and other countries which already enjoyed treaty privileges. The agrarian party fiercely resisted the treaty, but it was carried after a hard struggle. THE TREATY OF 1894 95 It was a compromise. Russia received "most favoured nation " treatment, which gave her the benefit of the lower grain duties ; she also secured the abolition of duties on some of her products, such as flax, oil-seed, and wool, and an advantage over the United States in the duty on oil. Ger- many, for her part, obtained a reduction of duties on 120 articles as, for instance, 20 per cent, on leather goods, 17 to 20 per cent, on un wrought iron, 18 per cent, on iron machinery, 17 to 20 per cent, on pottery, 17 per cent, on paper, 12 to 30 per cent, on woollen tissues. Both parties bound themselves for ten years not to increase the duties on certain specified goods. The treaty also pro- vided that Russia should abandon the distinction between sea-borne and land-borne goods, whilst Germany undertook that Russian goods should not be subject to higher rates than domestic goods for carriage on the Prussian State railways. The following table show the movement of trade between the two countries since 1893. 1 1 These are the figures given in the Statistisches Jahrbuchfiir das Deutsche Reich, 1902, pp. 174-6, but the Russian returns give an alto- gether different set of figures. They are quoted in the Foreign Office Report, p. 50, and may be set out here as showing the difficulty of obtaining accurate trade statistics. (The value of the rouble has fluctuated between 2*. 0|rf. and 2*. 2d.) RUSSIAN EXPORTS TO GERMANY. RUSSIAN IMPORTS FROM GERMANY. Mill. Roubles. Mill. Roubles. 1893 132 101 1894 148 143 1895 1T9 176 1896 185 190 1897 175 180 1898 179 202 1899 164 231 1900 188 215 96 GERMAN COMMERCIAL POLICY TO 1894 GERMAN IMPORTS FROM RUSSIA. Mill. Marks. 353-4 1893 1894 1895 1896 1897 1898 1899 1900 1901 1902 543-9 568-8 634-7 708-3 736-6 715-9 729-5 729-5 773-6 GERMAN EXPORTS TO RUSSIA. Mill. Marks. 184-6 194-8 220-9 364-1 372-0 440-5 437-3 359-1 345-9 372-1 Thus Germany had returned to the system of the "autonomous" and "conventional" tariffs ; the former applied against all those countries which had not made with her a commercial treaty pro- viding for reciprocal reductions of duties, and the latter containing all the lower rates of duty estab- blished by treaties and generalised to treaty powers by the force of the " most favoured nation " clause. But it is important to note that the system adopted differed from that now employed by France ; there the Government can increase the minimum (" con- ventional") as well as the maximum ("autono- mous") rates at any time, whilst the German Government, in its treaties, bound itself not to increase the tariff rates for a term of years. The Russian treaty seems to have been satis- factory in its effect, but this was by no means the case with all the others, and in particular the settle- ment of Germany's commercial relations with the Austro-Hungarian Empire was not followed by results equal to the expectations of the German EFFECT OF THE TREATIES 97 exporters. They had hoped for a great expansion of the Austrian market, but their export of textile manufactures actually declined for some time. 1 There was an increase in respect of metals, but exports as a whole were almost stationary ; they were valued at 420 million marks in 1893, 436 million in 1895, 477 million in 1896, 435 million in 1897, 466 million in 1899, 511 million in 1900. Imports, on the other hand, from Austria rose rapidly ; they were 580 million marks in 1893, after a decline in 1895 they rose to 600 million in 1897, and to 730 million in 1899. The Austrian Empire sent chiefly agricultural produce to Germany, and the general effect of the treaty seems to have been to increase the competition which the German agrarians had to meet, without securing any considerable increase of market for the manufacturers. 2 The negotiations with Spain brought Germany into yet another tariff war. In 1893 a treaty had been signed between the two countries, which was accepted by the German Parliament, but rejected by the Spanish. There- upon the German Government withdrew the " most favoured nation " treatment of Spanish goods, and subjected them to the autonomous tariff; the Spanish Government did the same for German goods. Germany, in her turn, imposed a surtax of 100 per cent, on all commodities 1 The average import of textiles into Austria-Hungary from Germany from 1892-4 was 33 '8 million kronen; 1897-9, 30 '8 million kronen (Wuttke, p. 439). 2 Wuttke, p. 458. H 98 GERMAN COMMERCIAL POLICY TO 1894 coming from Spain. Spain then proposed in 1896 that both sides should make use simply of the lowest rates of the autonomous tariff terms which Ger- many accepted. But inasmuch as France, England, Switzerland, and other countries enjoyed in Spanish markets preferences over Germany, the Govern- ment of the last-named country soon became anxious to obtain more satisfactory terms, and at the time of the purchase of the Caroline Islands, in the beginning of 1899, a fresh treaty was signed, securing reciprocal " most favoured nation " treat- ment. 1 A word must be said as to the commercial rela- tions of Germany to two other countries, Great Britain and the United States. Ever since the treaty of 1865, Germany had enjoyed the advan- tages of the " most favoured nation " clause in Great Britain and in all its colonial possessions. In 1897 the Canadian Government granted a reduction of duties on British goods alone, and Germany immediately protested against this on the ground that it violated the terms of the treaty of 1865. The British Government, therefore, gave a year's notice of the renunciation of the treaty, but suggested that it would be willing to undertake negotiations for a fresh arrangement. Germany then decided to continue the treaty so far as con- cerned Great Britain and those of her colonies which did not discriminate between British and German goods ; but against Canada she applied 1 Zimmennann, ii. pp. 308, 309. RELATIONS WITH THE UNITED STATES 99 her autonomous tariff. This arrangement has been renewed from time to time, but so far no new treaty has been made. With the United States German relations had almost always been far from satisfactory. By the Saratoga Convention, signed in 1891, Germany abandoned many of the restric- tions on the import of American meat, and gave the United States a right to participate in certain reductions of duties, whilst she received in return " most favoured nation " treatment for her sugar products. But this was not of much use to her, since the United States subsequently imposed surtaxes upon all bounty-fed sugar, and in spite of all its efforts the German Government could not secure preferential treatment. 1 1 A few other treaties were made towards the end of the century, the chief being the agreement with Japan in 1896. CHAPTER VII THE REVIVAL OF THE PROTECTIONIST MOVEMENT, AND THE NEW TARIFF COUNT CAPRIVI had succeeded in carrying the commercial treaties, but he had incurred the fierce hostility of the agrarians, and soon after the con- clusion of the Russian treaty they were strong enough to secure his overthrow and his replace- ment by Prince Hohenlohe. The period from the latter 's succession to office until the close of the century was characterised chiefly by the revival of the protectionist agitation, particularly amongst the agrarians. But before noticing the causes of this agitation and its results, it will be well to review some of the features of the industrial development of Germany since the foundation of the Empire. 1 The population of the Empire increased from 41 millions in 1871 to 56 millions in 1900, and is continuing to increase to the extent of some 850,000 persons a year. 2 The imports in 1872 for 1 For a brief and fairly reliable sketch, see Veritas, The German Empire of To-day. 2 Cf. Troeltsch, pp. 10-11. 100 GERMAN INDUSTRIAL DEVELOPMENT 101 home consumption were estimated at 163,000,000, and in 1902 at about 290,000,000. The exports of domestic produce were valued in 1872 at 116,000,000, and in 1902 at 240,000,000. The production of coal averaged 32 million tons a year for the period 1870-4, and 97 million tons for the period 1896-1900. In the former period the average quantity of pig-iron produced was 1'8 million tons, and in the latter period 7'4 million tons ; in 1902 it was 8*3 million tons. The pro- duction of steel averaged 1*1 million tons for the period 1881-5, and 5 '5 million tons for the period 1896-1900 ; in 1902 it was 7*6 million tons. The German merchant navy (vessels of 17^ tons and upwards) increased from 982,000 tons in 1870 to 2,093,000 tons in 1901. The annual tonnage of vessels built rose from 32,600 in 1878 (the first year for which figures are available) to 101,900 in 1901. In all the scientific industries, particu- larly in the production of chemicals, dyes, and colours, there has been a very marked advance aided by an educational system which is un- doubtedly superior on the technical and scientific sides to anything to be found elsewhere, and by an enlightened policy on the part of the manu- facturers, such as that described in the case of the chemical trades by Professor Dewar in his presidential address to the British Associa- tion at Belfast in 1902. Much aid has been given to the industrial development of the coun- try by a well-conceived railway transport policy, 102 REVIVAL OF THE PROTECTIONIST MOVEMENT rendered easy by the State ownership of rail- ways. It is important to observe also that the indus- trialisation of Germany is marked by the same general features as the economic history of England after the industrial revolution. There is the same rapid growth of the towns (an increase as astonishing as that of the American cities), 1 and the same decline in the agricultural population, which in 1870 was about one-half, and in 1900 about one-third of the whole, having fallen both relatively and actually. But agriculture still re- mains the chief occupation ; according to the census of 1895, llf million persons were employed in agriculture and kindred occupations, about 9 millions in industry, and about 3 millions in com- merce and transport. 2 At the same time, and as a natural consequence, there has been a constant increase of dependence on the foreign food supplies. 3 The following table shows the increase in the surplus of the amount of grain, meal, and flour imported into Germany over the amount exported : 1881-1885 .... 39-1 million cwt. 1886-1890 .... 42-8 1891-1895 .... 70-1 1896-1900 . . . . 103-1 1 Cf. Shaw, Municipal Government in Continental Europe, chap. v. 2 Troeltsch,, p. 25. 3 Cf. Voigt, " Deutschland und die Weltmarkt' (in Handels- und Machtpolltik), pp. 154-79. IMPORTS AND EXPORTS 103 The prices of agricultural produce have, on the whole, steadily fallen ; but there still remains a con- siderable difference between the various parts of the Empire, largely because of the distance in many cases of the markets from the place of production, and the difficulties of transport, in spite of the growth of German railways. 1 The following table shows some of these differences in 1902 : Wheat per 1,000 kg. Rye per 1,000 kg. Berlin . . 163-1 mks. ... 144-2 mks. Danzig. . 162-4 ... 139'4 Mannheim . 174-0 ... 150-3 Munich . 183-3 ... 151'9 Thirdly, imports greatly exceed exports. In the Free Trade period, from 1872 to 1879, the average annual imports were valued at 190,000,000, and the exports at 130,000,000; and although the latter were admittedly under-estimated, there yet remained a considerable excess of imports over exports. After 1879 the statistics were improved, and at first the new protectionist system acted as a drag. The import trade declined for a time, and in 1880 exports were slightly in excess of imports. From then till 1888 the two were in practical equilibrium, but after 1888 and the inclusion of the Hanse towns, the turn came, and the following table shows the " special trade " of Germany since 1893, in million marks : 1 Troeltsch, pp. 29 and 30. 2 Statitstischeti Jahrbuch, 1902, pp. 164-6. 104 REVIVAL OF THE PROTECTIONIST MOVEMENT Year. Imports for Home Consumption. Exports for German Home Produce. Excess of Imports over Exports. 1893 . . 4,134 3,245 889 1894 . . 4,285 3,051 1,234 1895 . . 4,246 3,424 822 1896 . . 4,558 3,754 ... 804 1897 . . 4,865 3,786 1,079 1898 . . 5,440 4,010 1,430 1899 - . 5,784 4,368 1,416 1900 . . 6,043 4,753 1,290 1901 . . 5,710 4,513 1,197 1902 . . 5,806 4,813 993 During the same period there has been a marked increase in the import of manufactured articles. The following table gives the figures for the ten years from 1893 to 1902 in million marks : Year. 1893 1894 1895 1896 1897 1898 1899 1900 1901 1902 Million Marks. 901 835 925 939 966 1,015 1,148 1,200 1,064 1,103 Average 1893-1897 = 913-2 Average 1898-1902=1,106-0 It should be added that German industry has been characterised more than that of any other country, with the exception of the United States, by the rise of trusts, or by their practical equivalent in economic effect, the Kartels, which now number over four hundred, and, though strongest in the coal 1 Statistisches Jahrbuch, 1902, p. 96. THE KARTELS 105 and iron industries, are gradually extending them- selves over the whole range of German industry. " They are combinations for maintaining prices (and more or less for the joint marketing of the produce) by a number of concerns which retain their own independence as producers. 1 And these Kartels have notoriously sought to relieve the German market in times of depression by sending abroad below the domestic price. . . . The Kartels have, however, advanced considerably beyond the point of lower foreign prices ; they have devised a plan whereby export is assisted and encouraged by the grant of bonuses by the several syndicates to their members and customers. This plan appears to have been first introduced in 1891, and it would seem to have been more systematically established in 1897. In the period of expanding trade which soon followed it was quite unnecessary, but in 1901 the reaction again came." 2 Finally, it must be pointed out that neither the tariff nor the Kartels (though it is one of the commonest claims of the latter and of the American trusts that they can regulate industry and give it a more equable course) have been able to guard Germany against recurring periods of acute depression, such as that through which the country passed between 1901 and 1903. 1 It is in this respect that the Kartels chiefly differ from the American trusts. 2 W. J. Ashley, The Tariff Problem, pp. 120-1. For a detailed description of the organisation and working of the Kartels, see Raffalo- vich, Trusts, Cartels et Syndicats, and the Consular Report for the Frankfurt District, 1903. 106 REVIVAL OF THE PROTECTIONIST MOVEMENT It has already been remarked that the closing years of the nineteenth century witnessed the revival of protectionist movements, arising chiefly amongst the agrarians. We have observed that after 1891 there was a somewhat rapid decline in the price of agricultural produce, particularly grain. This was due hi part to the effects of the treaties, which opened the German market more than before to foreign grain, and partly to the good harvests. The agricultural party ascribed the fall solely to the tariffs, and until 1896-7 their great cry was the fall of prices ; x but then a turn came, and the following table shows the movement of prices from 1894 to 1897 : 2 QUOTATIONS PER 100 KG. 1894. 1895. 1896. 1897. Wheat (at Cologne) 14-1 mks. 14-7 inks. 16.2 mks. 18-4 inks. Flour 19-2 20-2 21-4 23'9 Rye 12-7 12-6 13-0 13-8 Barley (at Mannheim) 15-3 15-7 16-1 16-7 After 1896 they raised the new cry of " Leute- not," declaring that the rapid development of industry was denuding the land of labourers, and that the agricultural interest was suffering from low prices because of the reciprocity treaties made for the sake of the industrial exporters, and at the same time was hampered by the withdrawal of labourers from the rural districts, which increased the agricultural cost of production. The agrarian party therefore denounced the " export orgy," and 1 Lotz, ii. p. 134. 2 Dietzel, p. 369. RECONSIDERATION OF POLICY 107 the policy which furthered the exportation of manufactured articles by the importation of agri- cultural produce. They put forward a demand for duties protecting all branches of agriculture grain, cattle, garden products, etc. * Moreover, the time for the renewal of the treaties was approaching, and it became necessary for the Government to prepare for negotiations. It pro- posed to do so by the adoption of a new tariff which should contain higher rates of duty, and should also be much more specialised and detailed than the tariff of 1879. It believed that the higher the rates of the tariff, the better the terms which could be' forced from foreign nations, and also that it was desirable to specialise the tariff rates in order to enable reductions to be made on any one article, without this involving reductions on a number of others. 2 The basis of the scheme was to be the simultaneous protection both of agri- culture and manufactures ; but the strong agrarian 1 Dietzel, pp. 370-3 ; cf. Lotz, ii. p. 137. 2 "It frequently happens that another nation lays stress on securing a reduction of rates on certain specialties, and is disposed to pay for this concession with one equally advantageous to us. But if now the Customs Act be made up too summarily, and these specialties are bunched together with many other articles under one head, we must lower the rate on the whole group for the sake of one article. The result of that would be that third nations, having the advantage of ' most favoured nation ' clauses, would profit by the reduction of the duties on the other commodities included in the same group, without having to pay an equivalent of their own therefor. The more specialised the Customs Act, the more compensation material there would be for treaties ; and the more general, the less there would be " (Dietzel, p. 376, summarising the argument of the Imperial Minister of the Interior). 108 REVIVAL OF THE PROTECTIONIST MOVEMENT movement, which had been going on since 1893 and found its representation in the Bund der Landwirte, directed the new policy mainly in the interests of the large landowners. The result was the Bill of 1901, which dealt with 946 groups of commodities. There was a long and fierce parlia- mentary battle, and the new tariff was not carried till December, 1902 ; it is, however, not to come into force until such a time as the Government shall appoint. The principle of the new tariff is the increased protection of agriculture and industry alike, but the primary object is the improvement of agri- culture ; and for that purpose minimum duties, very considerably higher than the old tariff rates, are established for the chief kinds of grain. The differences are shown in the following table : OLD DUTIES. NEW DUTIES. (per ton). (per ton). Autonomous Tariff. Treaty Tariff. Maximum. Minimum. s. d. s. d. s. d. s. d. Wheat 2 10 I 15 3 5 2 15 Rye . 2 10 1 15 3 2 10 Barley 1 2 6 1 2 1 10 Oats . 2 1 8 3 2 10 The minimum duties represent the point below which the duty may not be lowered in any com- mercial treaties which the Government may make. " These four duties form 7 per cent, of our total import. If, however, we consider these four duties in relation only to imports liable to duties as THE NEW TARIFF 109 must be done, since we can consider only these articles which can be used for concessions they form one-seventh of the import ; and if we exclude further all colonial produce liable to duty and some other articles which are of no use in negotia- tions with the treaty states . . . we perceive how much is lost to us, so far as negotiations are con- cerned, by the fixing of the minimum tariff for grain." 1 There are increases on other agricultural produce, but no minimum is fixed for these. As regards the duties on manufactured goods, the principles of the new tariff are (1) "the main- tenance of the existing exemption of raw materials so far as these are not produced at all in Germany, or are only produced in insufficient quantity or inferior quality " ; (2) taxation on semi-manufac- tured goods intended to be worked up for export, only to such an extent as not to interfere with the export trade ; (3) increase of taxation on manu- factured goods. 2 Thus raw materials, or materials only in the first stage of manufacture, are to be admitted free ; for example, raw silk and once- twisted silk are exempt from duty, the duty on silk yarn is reduced by nearly two-thirds, the duties on woollen and cotton yarn and cotton thread either remain at the old level or are reduced ; but rates on twice-twisted silk, which represents the employment of more labour, are increased 42 per cent. On woollen and half- woollen goods there is 1 Schacht, in Schmoller's Jahrbuch, 1902,, part ii. p. 342. * Schacht, p. 309. 110 REVIVAL OF THE PROTECTIONIST MOVEMENT an increase of from 15 to 30 per cent., on cotton manufactures from 57 to 80 per cent., on leather goods 50 to 100 per cent. The rates on all kinds of iron are advanced considerably, as also on tools and all manner of machinery, with an elaborate reclassification. Of the tariff as a whole Dr. Schacht points out that its main tendencies are towards the increase of taxation on agricultural produce generally, and also towards the raising of the cost of half-finished goods. There is also a higher taxation of many manufactured goods, on the assumption that the greater the labour expended on a particular commodity, the higher should it be taxed. These principles, he adds, are due to a complete misunderstanding of the productive power of Germany ; the tariff proposals will promote the production of grain and of half-finished goods, but will harm the small farming and manufactures. Yet these latter are the most important factor in the economic life of Germany to-day. The main economic problem is the question of popula- tion, and work can be provided for the rapidly increasing numbers not by the "extensive" in- dustries of grain-growing and the manufacture of half-finished goods, but by the "intensive" indus- tries of small farming and the manufacture of finished goods. It is essential, then, that nothing should be done to hamper German industry in any way ; " we dare not adopt a policy which makes competition more difficult for us by increasing the cost of raw and semi-manufactured materials, and CRITICISM OF THE TARIFF 111 reduces our labourers' strength by raising the price of the necessaries of life. But that is the policy of the tariff, and thereby it not only misunderstands the real foundations of German economic life, but lays a direct burden upon the lower classes." 1 And Professor Schmoller, whilst not agreeing in all points with his contributor, adds that he shares the opinion of Dr. Schacht that the officials entrusted with the preparation of the tariff are much too protectionist, and far too much inclined to consider every new duty as a sign of progress ; and he agrees also that those interests which are well organised and best represented have exercised far too great an influence in the shaping of the tariff. 2 He thinks, however, that a moderate protection for agriculture, and even a slight increase of some of the agricultural duties, is desirable, and he hopes that the tariff, in spite of defects, may, in the hands of a skilful diplomacy, offer adequate oppor- tunities for negotiations with foreign Powers. The tariff so established is to be the autonomous scale of duties, but the treaties are still unsettled, and the German Government finds itself sur- rounded with difficulties both at home and abroad. It is clear that after its surrender to the great land- owners by the grant of minimum duties, the min- istry will have to seek most of its " compensation material " in the unfixed agricultural duties and in the duties on manufactured goods. Reductions on merely industrial products would naturally not 1 Schacht, p. 351. 2 Footnote to Schacht, p. 353. 112 REVIVAL OF THE PROTECTIONIST MOVEMENT be acceptable to any country except Belgium, and high all-round protection to agriculture would ren- der it impossible to make many treaties, since Switzerland, Hungary, Russia, and France are all interested in reductions on the various kinds of agricultural produce. But the smaller agricultur- ists, the " Nebenagrarien," are certain to resent reductions in duty only on those agricultural pro- ducts, chiefly connected with cattle-rearing and dairy-farming, in which they are interested, and already their alliance with the " Hauptagrarien," the grain producers, is breaking up. On the other hand, the manufacturers are opposed to the main- tenance of high agrarian duties, since that will interfere with the negotiations for the reduction of foreign tariffs on their productions, and at the same time they will resist any decrease of German duties on manufactured goods. The working classes, under the lead of the Socialists, though apparently still indifferent to the general question of Protection and Free Trade, are strongly opposed to the increased agricultural duties, as tending to raise the price of food. Moreover, foreign nations, particularly Austria, Russia, and Switzerland, have prepared for the negotiations by devising new tariffs with increased rates of duty. The German Government may, and probably will, succeed in some measure in overcoming these difficulties as it did in 1892-4, but its task is one of the utmost difficulty, and after prolonged diplo- matic discussions the issue is still uncertain. CHAPTER VIII RECENT ECONOMIC DISCUSSION IN GERMANY IN the long controversy which raged during the preparation of the tariff and the passage of the law through the Reichstag, it was natural that the economists should play a very conspicuous part, and they may be divided into three main groups. The thoroughgoing Protectionists are chiefly so in the interest of agriculture ; they approach the subject from different standpoints, but they are represented chiefly by Professor Adoph Wagner. Then there is what may be called the Middle School, led by Professor Schmoller ; and finally there is the small Free Trade group, whose most conspicuous member is Professor Brentano of Munich. The agrarian group are all in favour of increased duties on agricultural produce in order to help the landowners and farmers, whose lamentations, as we have seen, are similar to those with which we are familiar in Great Britain. But it is important to observe that scarcely any amongst them care to base their arguments solely on the economic 114 RECENT ECONOMIC DISCUSSION IX GERMANY distress of the agrarian interests. They all advance other considerations, and their general position is summed up in a sentence of their chief economic representative, Professor Wagner: "An adequate protection for agriculture, higher than the present, would be in the general interest of the whole com- munity, even if by its means the industrial develop- ment of the state and possibly also the growth of population should be not entirely stopped, but certainly slackened, in the all-round interests of the workers and of the economic organisation of Germany. The maintenance of a capable German agriculture means the maintenance of the German people now and for the future." l The argument on which this conclusion is based is elabo- rated in Professor Wagner's book entitled Agrar- und Industriestaat, and an attempt must be made here to indicate its chief propositions. There is a group of extreme agricultural Protectionists, but apparently they find it convenient to accept Wagner's arguments, at least for the present. Professor Wagner views with the greatest anxiety what he regards as the excessive industrialisa- tion of Germany, and his views on this matter are shared by many others, such as Professor Oldenburg and Professor Pohle (Frankfort). 2 The maintenance of the industrial state requires three things : (1) that other countries are willing and 1 Wagner, Agrar- und Industriestaat, 2nd ed., pp. 1, 2. 2 See the Report of Professor Pohle, and the speech of Professor Oldenburg in the Verhandlungen des Vereins fur Socialpolitik, vol. xcviii. pp. 183 aeq. and 230 seq. "AGRAR- UNO INDUSTRIESTAAT" 115 able to supply agricultural products, both as food and raw materials, cheaply ; (2) that these supplies can be safely conveyed to the industrial state ; and (3) that the manufactured goods of that state can be assured of an adequate market in the countries which supply the food and raw material. 1 And in regard to all three of these necessary conditions there are considerable dangers now threatening. In the first place, several countries, hitherto content to remain in the agricultural stage of development, are turning their attention to industry; thus not merely is the United States (on which Great Britain has so long depended for the greater part of its food supply) becoming preponderatingly industrial, but Russia, Canada, Australia, Italy, and Roumania are all striving to make themselves into industrial communities. And this means not only that they will sooner or later consume most of their own supplies of raw material (it is, for example, inevitable that the United States should itself ultimately make use of the greater part of its production of raw cotton), but that further, as these states become more industrial their population will greatly increase, and they will make greater demands on their own food supplies. They will thus tend to use for their own purposes most of their production of food and raw material ; they will have less to export, and the older industrial states, which have based their organisation entirely on the assumption that these supplies are per- 1 Wagner, loc. cit., pp. 143 seq. 116 RECENT ECONOMIC DISCUSSION IN GERMANY manent, will find themselves hopelessly crippled. Secondly, even if the supply continue, it will always be liable to be cut in time of war. To guard against this as much as possible, the in- dustrial nations find themselves bound to incur ever-increasing expenditures on naval armaments, and a growing burden of taxation. 1 Thus between 1898-9 and 1903-4, the expenditure on the German navy advanced from six million pounds to ten and a half million pounds, and the British expenditure from twenty-four million to thirty-five million. And thirdly, even though the supplies of food and raw material continue quite unchecked, the growth of industrial competition on the one hand, and the attempt of various nations to supply their own industrial wants on the other hand, must make it ever more difficult for a manufacturing nation to dispose of its manufactured goods abroad, except by constantly cutting down its prices. These general propositions Professor Wagner supports by an elaborate examination of the sources of the German supply of food and raw material, illustrating its growing dependence on foreign countries ; and by a most detailed investigation of the movement during the last forty years of the British export industry, which, he holds, is tending to become almost stationary, or at any rate to expand only at the cost of very great efforts. 1 Cf. the strong advocacy of a powerful German navy by a group of economists in Handel- und Machtpolitik (ed. Schmoller, Sering, and Wagner). THE DANGERS AND THE REMEDY 117 He regards the whole foundation of the industrial state in the form which it has taken in Great Britain, and which it seems likely to assume in Germany, as altogether unsound. So also Professor Pohle writes : " The rule of the system of industry for export cannot long endure. That system, as Roscher already recognised, contained an element truly of temporary brilliancy, but of permanent outward and inward peril. It is an idle dream to believe that the economic future of Germany can be permanently based on the production of industrial commodities for foreign nations." 1 The remedy is to make Germany as independent as possible of foreign nations. Not that foreign trade is to be cut off, but attention is to be paid more to the balance between the manufacturing and agricultural interests of Germany. 2 Produc- tion for the home market must be the primary consideration ; the condition of agriculture must be improved before the decline has gone so far as to be irremediable, the agricultural population recruited, and the rush to the towns checked. This may mean a slackening in the rate of the increase of the population, but that would not be un- welcome. The best way to attain these ends is to give agriculture the stimulus of greater protection. " It is not to be denied that, like all the great things which a nation needs armaments, civil administration, justice, a system of education, 1 Pohle, p. 10. a Wagner, loc. cit., pp. 42 and 43. 118 RECENT ECONOMIC DISCUSSION IN GERMANY arrangements for the care of the economic interests of the community, etc. so also the maintenance of the permanent economic and numerical strength of the nation in an adequate and sturdy agrarian population requires sacrifices. But we believe these sacrifices, in this case as in the others we have named, are necessary for that higher object which we have in view." 1 And Professor Wagner, whilst recognising that the increased duties which he advocates on the import of agricultural produce might, and very possibly would, mean an increase in the cost of living to the lower classes of the community, yet thinks that compensation could be given for this by employing the proceeds of the new duties in further State grants to the various pension funds. Other economists, sharing the same general opinions, take the same line in regard to the union of tariff legislation and social reform ; "it appears to be beyond dispute that increased duties on grain would result in higher prices for bread, and therefore the working-class population, amongst whom the expenditure on foodstuffs may amount to 75 per cent, of their income (whilst in the case of the most prosperous class the amount may fall to 20 per cent.) must in every case, as Sering claims, receive an equivalent compensation by the extension of social legislation and the reform of the imperial taxes with more attention to social needs (im sozialen Sinne}"' 1 Wagner, loc. cit., p. 36. 2 Von Halle, Volks- und Seewirtschaft, p. 11. THE CRITICISM OF WAGNER 119 We may take the criticism of these last points first. As Professor Lotz has pointed out, 1 Wagner has failed to demonstrate that higher protective duties are the sole means of improving agri- culture and stopping the decline of the agricul- tural population. The fact that in spite of their present protection the German landowners are in a bad way, is partly at least to be ascribed to their own defects, to their lack of enterprise, their want of money, and consequent disinclination and in- ability to make improvements. The value of agriculture to the national life is, no doubt, con- siderable ; but it would be extremely hard to demonstrate that a reduction in the number of industrial workers and an increase in the number of the peasantry and rural labourers would tend to raise the general level of civilisation in the com- munity. So Conrad writes : " There can be no doubt that an increase of the well-being at home and the remunerative employment of the growing population with which we have to deal, can only be expected from industry and commerce. And, consequently, it is beyond dispute that our tariff policy must have in view chiefly their interests." 2 And, as Lotz has again pointed out, while it is desirable to lessen the pressure upon the towns and to remove large masses of the people from conditions which do not make for physical efficiency, there are ways of doing this without taking them 1 Verhandlungen des Vereins fur Socialpolitifc, vol. xcviii. p. 121 seq. 2 Conrad, Jahrbucher, February, 1902, p. 189. 120 RECENT ECONOMIC DISCUSSION IN GERMANY back to agriculture. It is certain that the develop- ment of means of transport and transit will, before very long, enable Great Britain and Germany to carry out, if they choose to do so, great schemes of industrial redistribution which will spread the workers over larger districts, and put an end to much of that density of population in limited areas, which is at present one of the most painful characteristics of our industrial societies. 1 As to the growth of population, it is argued by Wagner's opponents that for Germany, situated as she is, and compelled to be a great military power, it is essen j tial to have as large a population as possible, and that such a population can be maintained only by persisting in the policy which she has so success- fully followed, the policy of industrialism ; and Wagner's reply, that the strength of a population does not depend so much on its numbers as on its efficiency, hardly meets the case. In regard to the corn duties, Wagner does not carry even all the protectionist economists with him ; Schmoller is not particularly favourable to any increase (unless it does not unduly raise the cost of living to the workers), whilst Conrad is decidedly hostile. The latter is in favour only of the raising of the duties on cattle and cattle products (which is practically prevented by the new tariff proposals) ; apparently he thinks that the grain duties have even harmed the landowners, by rendering them less alive to ] On this point cf. Wells, Anticipations, chap, i., and Mr. W. L. Magdens's pamphlet on Industrial Redistribution. FOOD PRICES AND THE TARIFF 121 the need of improvement in their methods. 1 More- over, there is not wanting evidence that the agrarian protective duties have affected the cost of living in Germany disadvantageously. The following table shows the comparative prices in England and Prussia of wheat 2 per 1,000 kg. : 1871- 1875- 1881- 1886- 1891- 1896- 1875 1880 1885 1890 1895 1900 England . . 246-4 206-8 180-4 142-8 128-2 134-3 Prussia . . 235-2 211-2 189'0 173-9 165-5 l60'9 Prussia more or less than England . -11-2 +4-4 +8-6+31-1 +37'3 +26'6 In Westphalia, which is mainly industrial, the prices were in comparison with England, in 1871-5 the same, 1876-80 15'6 marks more, 1881-5 17'2 marks more, 1886-90 40'8 marks more, 1891-5 45-2 marks more, 1896-1900 30'1 marks more. 3 It will be seen that since the introduction of the tariff policy established by Bismarck, the Prussian prices have become much higher than the English. And on the question of food prices in general a recent writer remarks that "there is in Germany no longer anything said about the great cheapness of food " (as compared with other countries). 1 Conrad, "Die Stellung der Landwirtschaftlichen Zolle" (Verein filr Socialpolitik, vol. xc.). Cf. Von Halle, Volks- und Seewirthschaft , pp. 10-13 : " If they regard a higher duty on grain as a panacea . . . the result for the agricultural classes of East Germany will be as fatal as the clinging to an out-of-date economic system was, fifty years earlier, to the planters of the southern states of the American Union ; for the whole state, it would, in view of the geographical position of Germany and international relations, be even more fatal." 2 Conrad, loc. cit., p. 125. 3 Conrad, Jahrbiicher, February, 1902, p. 161. 122 RECENT ECONOMIC DISCUSSION IN GERMANY " Whilst Germany had up to the seventies cheaper food than France and England, to-day in the south-west of Germany it is not only dearer than in Free Trade England, but sometimes even dearer than in France, though that country has a higher tariff on wheat than Germany, and much dearer than in America." 1 The arguments as to the bases of the industrial state are more serious, but on the whole not more convincing. After all, it is possible to take too long a view, and to carry speculation too far. It may be perfectly true that a time will come when the whole food supply of the world will be con- sumed by the countries that produce it, that is to say, that unless some of the now chiefly industrial states return in some degree to agriculture the supply of bread-stuffs will not keep pace with the world's demand. But this prospect will scarcely seem very near to those who have been told so much of the unlimited resources of Canada, who remember the almost untouched possibilities of Argentina and Uruguay and other South American states, of Egypt and Northern Africa, of Russia and Siberia (under an intelligent economic policy), and of Asia Minor. Similarly, in regard to the exhaustion of raw material, it is, of course, probable that ultimately the United States will consume all its own cotton (though it is worth noting that Cobden had the same fear seventy years ago). But there 1 Weile, Der Einfluss der Deutschen Schutzzollpolitik aufdie Entwicke- lung der Industrie und Handwerkschaft, p. 22. MARKETS FOR MANUFACTURED GOODS 123 are great possibilities of the production of cotton in other lands, as yet almost undeveloped, as, for example, in British West Africa. It must be a very long time before the alarming condition of things which Professor Wagner foresees is realised, and, in any case, that condition can only come about very gradually, and as it conies there will be a gradual transference back to agriculture of the labour for which industry cannot provide employ- ment. 1 As to the question of markets for manu- factured products, there is no evidence that they are declining. As a matter of fact, they are in- creasing even in protected countries. If we take Germany itself, the growth of her export trade means a corresponding growth in her import trade, and this increase is not merely of imports of food and raw materials, but it is in manufactured goods also. As civilisation advances with the develop- ment of the industrial state, the standard of life rises, the wants of the community increase, com- modities which were once luxuries come to be regarded as necessaries, and, in spite of tariffs, they are imported from abroad. Wagner recognises that this will always be the case to a con- siderable extent, but seems hardly to realise how considerable that extent is. The following table sets out the recent movement of the im- 1 Cf., for the above criticism of Wagner and for further discussion of the problem, Dietzel, "The German Tariif Controversy," in the Q. J. Economics, May, 1903, especially pp. 405 seq. ; and Brentano, Dei Schrecken des uberwiegenden Industriestaats. 124 RECENT ECONOMIC DISCUSSION IN GERMANY port of manufactured goods into some protected countries : l Country. Average 1892-1896. Average 1897-1901. Germany . . 891 '4 mill. mks. ... 1,078-6 mill. mks. France . . 585-8 frs. ... 714-0 frs. Switzerland . 273-6 ... 347'7 Italy . . . 255-0 lire ... 312-7 lire Austria-Hungary 398-2 kr. ... 456-0 kr. Holland . . 287'8 gulden ... 362-4 gulden 1891-1895. 1896-1900. Russia . . 105-7 mill, roubles ... 1 66 -4 mill, roubles " Why should the result in the future be any different ? Why should the decline of our export industries, taken as a whole, set in, in case Russia, Canada, Central and South America, Eastern Asia, Cape Colony, and Australia should develop manu- factures at some future time ? If to-day a more extensive division of labour is taking place within the industrial realm, and a comprehensive inter- change of products between countries like England, France, and Germany (that is, lands, all of which lie in the temperate zone, all on about the same plane of social and economic development), is it not probable that such a division of labour and such intercourse will not only continue, but extend even further, when it includes not only the industrial states of to-day on the one side, but Russia and others on the other side ? For between the former and the latter there is a much greater diversity of natural as well as social conditions than exists 1 Statistical Abstract for the Principal and Other Foreign Countries, 1903, pp. 65-71. THE THEORY OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE 125 between England, France, and Germany." 1 And the number of countries which can ever become largely industrial is comparatively limited (few have resources of the right kind), and in the others the market for manufactured goods will always be very large. It is true that competition in those markets will become more and more keen, but this simply means that no one country is likely to have in the future such a complete industrial predomin- ance as Great Britain used to enjoy. There is one other point in Professor Wagner's argument which should be noted. The English theory of international trade as expounded by Torrens, Ricardo, and Mill has never had much influence amongst continental economists, and Wagner attacks it on the ground that the greatest relative advantage, which it presupposes as the reason why a country should devote itself to the production of a particular commodity or group of commodities, may work extremely badly for the community as a whole. It may mean that a coun- try will find itself limited to the production of one thing alone, and hence will lose all the advan- tages which come from the possession of diverse industries and a variety of technical skill ; or it may mean that a country will be compelled to devote itself more and more to the production of commodities in which its advantage over its competitors is of the worse kind, namely, cheapness arising not from efficiency of method or abundance 1 Dietzel, loc. cit. } p. 403, 126 RECENT ECONOMIC DISCUSSION IN GERMANY of materials, but from ill-paid and sweated labour. 1 As to the first of these alternatives, it can only be said that there is no evidence in any industrial coun- try of any such process taking place ; but on the contrary, new industries requiring great technical skill are rising in all industrial communities. The second point will be familiar to English readers in Mr. and Mrs. Webb's work on Industrial Democracy. They will remember that in appen- dix ii. of that work this argument against Free Trade that it may, according to that pure theory of international trade which has been adopted by British economists, lead to the dependence of this country on sweated and ill-paid industries is elab- orately stated ; but they will remember also the authors' strong argument that no system of pro- tection would remedy this, but that safeguards against it must be sought elsewhere. 2 The admitted 1 Wagner, loc. cit., pp. 32 seq. ; cf. Pohle, p. 218. " In regard to a great part of this industry (the manufacture of clothing) we are entitled to say that Germany's ruling position in the world-market can be maintained only at the expense of the workers' standard of living. Of the conditions of work which prevail in that industry we may fairly use the English expression that wages are only enough to keep 1 body and soul together,' and that the hours of labour are as many as the hours of the day. In a great part of these branches of industry home employment is still predominant. The miserable condition of the home workers of the Erzgebirge, the Fichtelgebirge, the Thurin- gian Forest, and other German hill districts, is well known ; and all these work largely, if not chiefly, for export. There are still worse conditions ruling among the home industries of the towns, and particu- larly in the different branches of the clothing trade " (Pohle, p. 218). 2 " But though the existence of parasitic trades knocks the bottom out of the argument for laisser faire, it adds no weight to the case for a protective tariff. . . . The advocate of a protective tariff aims at excluding imports ; the opponent of ' sweating/ on the other hand THE MIDDLE SCHOOL 127 truth of the facts alleged only implies the necessity of State action to put an end to the conditions which render " parasitic industries " possible ; it is difficult to see how any policy, which aims simply at restraining the growth of industry and at stimulating the development of agriculture, would be likely to remedy the evil. We pass now to the Middle School, which, in the main, follows the lead of Professor Schmoller. With the general attitude of that group towards Free Trade and Protection we are already fami- liar ; l to them " the tariff problem admits of only relative solution " all depends on the particular conditions of time and place. They are not hostile to Free Trade, but they believe it to be only one of various policies to be applied according to cir- cumstances. Neither are they Protectionists ; in sees with regret the rapid growth of particular exports, which imply the extension within the country of its most highly subsidised or most parasitic industries. Hence, whatever ingenious arguments may be found in favour of a protective tariff, such a remedy fails altogether to cope with this particular evil. If the expansion of the industries which England pursues to the greatest economic advantage say, for instance, coal mining and shipbuilding, textile manufacture and machine-making is being checked, this is not because coal and ships, textiles and machinery are being imported into England from abroad, but because other less advantageous industries within England itself, by reason of being favoured with some kind of bounty, have secured the use of some of the nation's brains and capital, and some of its export trade. ... In short, the absolute exclusion by each country of the imports competing with its own products would not, any more than Free Trade itself, prevent the expansion within the country of those industries which afforded to its wage-earners the worst con- ditions of employment" (Webb, Industrial Democracy, ed. 1897, ii. pp. 865-6). 1 See above, Chapter V. 128 RECENT ECONOMIC DISCUSSION IN GERMANY fact, their advocacy of the use of tariffs for the purposes of promoting international exchange is in- compatible with protectionist ideals. Professor Schmoller holds that for the purposes of negotia- tion agrarian and industrial duties are alike neces- sary, and believing that agriculture is suffering, he would encourage cattle-rearing by duties on foreign cattle and meat, but would support duties on bread-stuffs only when they do not raise the price of bread unduly whatever that may mean. But to him the tariff is important chiefly as a weapon. " I believe that we may draw this lesson from history, that all protective movements are closely connected with national sentiment, strivings after international authority, efforts towards the balance of power, and therefore will continue to exist so long as amongst the fully developed states there are others striving after economic develop- ment, and so long as the peoples for economic purposes have need of every weapon which stands ready for their use." 1 He points out that the increases of the tariff in the eighties were used by Bismarck in this way, and that the Bismarckian idea has now been taken up again. But the nego- tiation tariff is not to be a high protective tariff; it is supported by him only in order to give Ger- many a better position in commercial negotiations. Schmoller holds that the " neo-mercantilism " of the present day has arisen out of the nationalist 1 Verhandlungen des Vereins fur Socialpolitik , 1902, p. 265. The following quotations are from Schmoller's speech, pp. 264-71. THE TARIFF AS A WEAPON 129 movements, and is based not on List's theory of " educational tariffs " (i.e. the infant industries doctrine), but on the desire to possess an "inter- national weapon " (Machtmittel). " The new period of Protection, this neo-mercantilism, has come, not because the theorists and statesmen were incapable of understanding the lofty arguments of Free Trade, not because everywhere some monopolists and large manufacturers control the Government, but out of natural nationalist tendencies, particu- larly in those countries with the most liberal and democratic constitutions. It is based not alone or even chiefly on the doctrine of ' educational tariffs,' but arises out of an instinctive, rather than reasoned, motive that the tariffs are an inter- national weapon which, skilfully employed, can be of the utmost use." A strong tariff is particularly needed to enable Germany to fight the extreme protectionist policy of Russia and the United States. These views are shared by a very considerable number of the younger German economists, the most distinguished, perhaps, being Dr. Schuhmac- her, head of the great Commercial High School at Cologne. 1 But this policy of tariffs to be employed as a means of fighting other nations which pursue a policy of exclusion has certain serious dangers. We have seen that the application of the policy against France under the Monarchy of July, 1 See his long report in the Verhandlungen des Vereins fur Social- politik, 1902. K 130 RECENT ECONOMIC DISCUSSION IN GERMANY against Spain and other powers, has not always produced satisfactory results. The increase of the agricultural duties by Bismarck in the eighties did nothing to promote exchange with Russia for a number of years in fact, by the admission of the German Government itself, German trade with Russia declined steadily between 1880 and 1890 ; the conflict with Russia in the nineties was short and sharp, and, on the whole, in that case the policy was justified, but the risks run were very great. Moreover, these tariffs for negotiation are like armaments ; when one country increases them, others do the same. As soon as the proposals for the new German tariff were published, Austria and Switzerland proceeded to revise and increase their tariffs, in order to be ready to fight Germany. And further, when protective duties are once granted, whatever the original purpose may have been, a vested interest in their maintenance is created, and the producers so protected are sure to oppose any proposal to reduce the duties in the effort to bribe foreign powers. So, as we have seen, the agrarian interest in Germany has fiercely opposed any treaty reductions of the grain duties. Schmoller himself recognises that " admittedly this neo-mercantilism frequently overlooks the fact that these weapons may as often be used unskilfully and mistakenly, as rightly. The agitation of the interested classes commonly fails to see that ex- cessive protection as a whole does more harm than good. So Russia, the United States, and France THE TARIFF AND ECONOMIC REFORM 131 have fallen into a high protective system, and sometimes into a commercial policy which, though it aims at international power, is of a worse kind, and hinders the economic development of these countries instead of promoting it." And elsewhere (as has been pointed out), Schmoller writes in regard to the new tariff that the officials who planned it were much too favourable to Protection pure and simple, and that those interested groups, which were well organised and skilfully led, exer- cised far too great an influence upon it. 1 Another moderate view is that of Professor Conrad, of Halle. He thinks that industrial pro- tection has gone far enough, but he would protect agriculture so far as that policy does not involve the depression of the standard of living for the working classes. He would retain the existing duties on foodstuffs for the present, because of the critical condition of German agriculture, but the only duties he would increase are those which would encourage the development of special branches, such as cattle-rearing and dairy-farming. Professor Sering, of Berlin, favours the increase of the agricultural duties only because he thinks that they will help agriculture over a transition period in which radical changes must be made, if the con- dition of the eastern provinces is not to be a serious social menace to Germany. He will support the heightened grain duties only if they are to be regarded as part of a social programme which shall 1 Schmoller's Jahrbuch, 1902, part ii. p. 353. 132 RECENT ECONOMIC DISCUSSION IN GERMANY include the reduction of duties on such com- modities as coffee, petroleum, etc., the gradual prohibition of the invasion of the eastern provinces by the cheaper Slav labour, and the transformation (by a national system of land purchase) of the large estates of the eastern provinces of Prussia into peasant holdings. Unless these steps are taken to maintain the peasantry, in whom he believes the strength of Germany to lie, he will oppose the new duties. 1 It will have been noticed that none of the economists quoted are inclined to defend increased duties on manufactured goods ; the Free Trade school naturally demands their abolition, not at once, but gradually. It recognises fully that educational tariffs may be of use to a country in some periods of its economic development it is prepared to defend their application in the past ; but it is opposed to " maintenance tariffs " (Erhaltungszolle). 2 Such tariffs not only hinder the territorial division of labour, which has the same effect on production as labour-saving machinery ; they not only prevent or delay a reduction in the national cost of production and the attainment of "a greater total product from a given expenditure of labour, and a higher national dividend than before," 3 but they also strengthen the industrial combinations, and enable them to 1 Verhandlungen des Vereinsfiir Socialpolitik, 1902, pp. 244-7. 2 Brentano, Das Freihandelsargument , p. 15. 3 Dietzel. THE FREE TRADE ARGUMENT 133 maintain artificial prices in the home market by eliminating competition from outside. This party accepts entirely the industrialisation of Germany, and believes that in the present stage of that country's development "the real protection of national labour is Free Trade." 1 The material progress of Germany depends on the extension of her manufactures and the completion of the division of labour between the industrial com- munities of the world. The agricultural duties are to be condemned, since they not only increase the cost of food by limiting the supply from countries where it is produced more cheaply than in Germany, but also by limiting imports reduce the market for German exports, which are chiefly manufactured goods, and so in two ways hamper the growth of industry. 2 They also point to the experience of Germany as an illustration of the fact that duties once imposed are much more likely to increase than to decrease. Some of their criticisms of Wagner and his allies have already been indicated ; and it is unnecessary to state their more general argument, since it follows the lines of ordinary English economic thought. On the whole, then, so far as German economists in the past have been advocates of Protection, their arguments have been based largely on the political need of securing the development of German economic strength as a basis for political power. To-day that condition has been realised, and the 1 Brentauo. 2 Ibid.., pp. 16, 17. 134 RECENT ECONOMIC DISCUSSION IN GERMANY argument for Protection is shifted on to another ground ; it is alleged that the development has been too one-sided, and that the comparative neglect of agriculture has become a source of weakness to the Empire. Yet for more than twenty years agriculture has received a large measure of protection, and one is forced to believe that if, in spite of that, it has not held its ground, the reasons are to be sought in causes over which tariffs have little control. As to the other argu- ment for Protection the need for negotiation tariffs no economist has shown that the result could not be obtained in another way ; if they are to be used at all, a system of occasional duties- such as that established by the recent Sugar Con- vention and employed in the United States under the McKinley Tariff 1 would be preferable to the imposition of a general tariff on manufactured goods, which might, or might not, be reduced. Tariffs for negotiation are at best, as even their defenders in Germany readily admit, a dangerous weapon ; the policy can only be successful where the country making use of them is not dependent on supplies drawn from the country against which they are employed, whilst the latter is so dependent upon the former. And, finally, it must be borne in mind that tariffs are, after all, only the crudest form of Protection, and are not necessarily the only or most efficient means of promoting the economic well-being of a nation ; and the safest 1 See pp. 255-6. CONCLUSION 135 lesson to draw from the experience of Germany is the simple fact that changes in tariff policy have been only one, and commonly not the most important, amongst the many causes of her eco- nomic progress. A BRIEF BIBLIOGRAPHY WEBER, W. Der Deutsche Zollverein. 1871. ZIMMERMANN, A. Gesckichte der Preussisch-Deutschen Handels- politik. 1891. (I.) ZIMMERMANN, A. Die Handelspolitik des Deutschen Reiches, 1871- 1900. 1901. (II.) SCHIPPEL, MAX. Grundziige der Handelspolitik. 1902. LOTZ, W. Die Ideen der Deutschen Handelspolitik, 1860-91. 1892. (I.) LOTZ, W. "Die Handelspolitik des Deutschen Reiches, 1890- 1900 " (in Beitr'dge zur Neuesten Handelspolitik Deutchslands, voi. iii. 1901). (II.) Foreign Office Report on Tariff Wars. (Cd. 1938. 1904.) POSCHINGER, H. Bismarck als Volkswirth. 1889-90. WUTTKE, R. " Der deutsch-oesterreich-ungarische Handels- vertrag vom 6 Dezember, 1891." (In Verhandlungen des Vereins fur Socialpolitik, 1902). BLUM, H. Das Deutsche Reich zur Zeit Bismarcks. 1893. VON HALLE, E. Folks- und See-Wirthschaft. 1903. DAWSON, W. H. Bismarck and State Socialism. 1891. "VERITAS." German Empire of To-day. 1902. POGSON, G. A. Germany and its Trade. 1903. Statistisches Jahrbuchfiir das Deutsche Reich. LIST, F. System of National Economy (trans, by Lloyd. 1885). SCHMOLLER, G. The Mercantile System (trans, by W. J. Ashley. 1896). SCHMOLLER, WAGNER, and SEEING (Editors). Handels- und Macht- politik. 2 vols. 1900. 137 138 A BRIEF BIBLIOGRAPHY WAGNER, A. Agrar- und Industriestaat. 2nd edition. 1902. POHLE, L. Deutschland am Scheidewege. 1902. TROELTSCH, W. Ueber die Neuesten Ver'dnderungen im Deutschen Wirtschaftsleben. 1899. BRENT ANO, L. Das Freihandelsargument. 1901. BRENTANO, L. Die Schrecken des iiberrviegenden Industriestaats. 1901. DIETZEL, H. "The German Tariff Controversy" (Quart. J. Econ., May, 1903). GOTHEIN, G. Die Wirkung der Handelsvertr'dge (in publications of the Berlin Volkswirthschaftliche Gesellschaft, 1895). CONRAD, J. " Die Stellung der Laadwirthschaftlichen Zolle " (Vereinfiir Socialpolitik, vol. xc.). CONRAD, J. "Die Agrarzolle in der Zolltarifvorlage " (in Jahr- bucher fur National'okonomie und Statistik, February, 1902). DADE, H. "Die Agrarzolle " (in Beitr'dge zur Neuesten Handels- Politik Deutschlands, vol. ii., 1901). SCHACHT, H. "Inhalt und Kritik des Zolltarifentwurfs " (in Schmoller's Jahrbuch, 1902). Verhandlungen des Vereins fur Socialpolitik. Vol. xcviii. PART II THE UNITED STATES CHAPTER I THE ORIGINS OF AMERICAN COMMERCIAL POLICY THE economic relations between the states of the American Union at the end of the War of Independence resemble closely the condition of affairs in the Germanic Confederation after the Congress of Vienna. The separate colonies had been allowed by Great Britain to impose customs duties for revenue purposes, and had also been influenced somewhat by protectionist ideas ; l and although after 1776 this latter motive seems to have lost its force, the customs duties continued to be levied by each state against all others, in- cluding even its fellow-members of the Union. Yet the feeling in favour of freedom of trade was sufficiently strong partly as the result of reaction against the restrictive policy of Great Britain to restrain the new Confederation from imposing any tariff laws between 1776 and 178 1. 2 There were practically no manufactures to protect ; the colonies were almost entirely engaged in agri- 1 Stanwood, i. p. 25, quotes from the preambles to the Revenue Acts of various colonies. Cf. Hill, pp. 14-15. * Hill, pp. 39-40. 141 142 ORIGINS OF AMERICAN COMMERCIAL POLICY cultural pursuits or in the carrying trade ; and although there was a certain amount of iron pro- duced, yet "in the main, the colonies made only such manufactures as could not be imported." 1 When from 1782 onwards a change came over American policy, and tariff legislation began, the determining forces seem to have been chiefly political the necessity of raising money for the purposes of government, and the desire to be able to meet and resist the commercial legislation of the European Powers, and particularly the high tariff and Navigation Acts of Great Britain. 2 These considerations drove the states rapidly in the direction of commercial as well as political union, 3 and after some years of uncertainty, owing to the unwillingness of some members of the Union to surrender their liberty of economic action, the Constitution of 1787 settled that " Congress shall have power to lay and collect taxes, duties, imposts, and excises, to pay the debts and provide for the common defence and 1 Taussig, p. 10. 2 "At first the rates were low and the articles taxed few, being generally luxuries or commodities the importation of which was thought harmful. In this category slaves, rum, spirits and wine, tea, coffee, and sugar held important places. The southern states did not go beyond these purely revenue measures. In all the northern states rates were advanced and other articles were added to the list, until in 1785 and 1786 the tariff schedules were generally extensive and taxes were imposed for both revenue and protective purposes, or, to use a phrase of more recent times, for revenue with incidental protection. In some of the states, indeed, protection was the principal end sought." Hill, p. 43. J The German states followed the opposite direction between 1833 and 1871. THE FIRST TARIFF ACT 143 general welfare of the United States ; but all duties, imposts, and excises shall be uniform throughout the United States ; ... to regulate commerce with foreign nations, and among the several States, and with the Indian tribes ; . . . to make all laws which shall be necessary and proper for carrying into execution the foregoing powers." 1 The first use made by Congress of the authority so conferred appeared in the Tariff Act of 1789. It was a combination of specific and ad valorem duties, and was to continue in force for seven years. Specific duties a fixed tax on a given amount of each commodity were imposed on thirty-six articles, the chief being spirits (8-10 cents per gallon), tea (6-20 cents per lb.), sugar, salt, molasses, cordage, steel (56 cents per cwt.), and nails ; and there were ad valorem duties of 15 per cent, on carriages, 10 per cent, on glass, china, earthenware, lace, and some others, 7J per cent, on paper, gloves, leather, buttons, clothing, hats, and metal wares, and 5 per cent, on all other imports except seventeen raw materials (such as saltpetre, wool, cotton, hides, fur, dye-stuffs), which were admitted free. 2 Drawbacks of the full duty less 1 per cent, were granted for all commodities re-exported within twelve months ; and finally, to stimulate the American carrying trade, a discount of 10 per cent, was given on all goods imported 1 Art. i. sec. 8. See text in Bryce, Amer. Commonwealth, i. p. 700. 2 Stanwood, i. pp. 58-60. 144 ORIGINS OF AMERICAN COMMERCIAL POLICY in vessels owned entirely by American citizens. Though the duties thus imposed were, on the whole, quite moderate, it is by no means certain that the legislation was inspired solely by financial needs. 1 It is true that these were considerable, and in face of the widespread dislike to direct taxation and to excises could only be satisfied by recourse to customs duties ; but it is also clear that in the minds of many of its supporters the Act had a protective purpose, and for that very reason it called forth a good deal of opposi- tion, particularly from the Southern States. It was a policy of Protection, chiefly for manufactures, modified partly by the inexperience of the legis- lators 2 and partly by regard to considerations of revenue. 3 In the very next year, after Hamilton, the Secretary of the Treasury, had failed to secure 1 ' ' It has often been said that the first Tariff Act, that of 1789, was a protective measure, and that in the debate on it the protective policy appeared full grown. But such considerations had little to do with the Act ; and the discussions on Protection by no means indicate what was the real centre of interest. ... Its main object was to secure revenue. " Taussig, pp. 14-15. 2 Channing, United States, p. 139. 3 For the evidence that protective considerations did weigh with the promoters of the measure, see Hill, pp. 108 seq., and the account of the debates given by Stanwood, i. pp. 39 seq. Mayo-Smith and Seligman, p. 6, agree with Taussig, and remark that " it is erroneous to speak of any protectionist movement at this period " ; but this seems to be based on the idea that the authors of the tariff did not regard average duties of 8 per cent, ad valorem as protective a supposition which is not proved, and is in direct conflict with the preamble to the Act, which asserts that " it is necessary for the support of the Government, . . . and the encouragement and pro- tection of manufactures, that duties be laid,' 5 etc. Dewey (p. 84) holds that the evidence as to the consciously protective character of the tariff is conclusive. HAMILTON'S REPORT 145 an Excise Act, the tariff was increased all round to meet the growing financial needs of the Union ; the specific duty on steel was advanced from 56 to 75 cents per cwt., and many articles previously in the 5 per cent, ad valorem list were now made subject to 7J per cent, and 10 per cent. In the following year an excise on spirits (somewhat lower than the customs duty) was established ; but it was always unpopular and difficult to collect, and in 1802 was finally abandoned. In 1790 Congress had directed the Secretary to the Treasury to prepare and report plans " for the encouragement and promotion of such manufac- tories as will tend to render the United States independent of other nations for essential, particu- larly for military, supplies." Hamilton replied in December, 1791, with a " Report on Manufactures," which remains still one of the most elaborate general arguments for Protection, and contains most of the ideas which multitudes of writers have since elaborated. 1 There is the argument from the desirability of national self-sufficiency. "Every nation . . . ought to endeavour to possess within itself all the essentials of national supply. These comprise the means of subsistence, habitation, clothing, and defence. The possession of these is necessary to the perfection of the body politic, to the safety as well as to the welfare of society. The want of either is the want of an important organ of political life and motion ; and in the 1 Full text in Taussig, State Papers and Speeches on the Tariff. L 146 ORIGINS OF AMERICAN COMMERCIAL POLICY various crises which await a state it must severely feel the effects of any such deficiency." There is the advocacy of the home market, though primarily in the interests of the agricultural producers ; the restrictive policy of European Powers, and the fluctuations of their crops, make the foreign market too unreliable for the American farmer ; it is there- fore desirable to create for his produce the largest possible demand at home, and this can best be done by promoting "manufacturing establishments." " This idea of an extensive domestic market for the surplus produce of the soil is of the first conse- quence. It is of all things that which most effec- tually conduces to a flourishing state of agriculture." But the firm establishment of the necessary manu- factures in the face of foreign competition is a task of great difficulty, and so we naturally come to the famous " infant industries " argument. " Whatever room there may be for an expectation that the in- dustry of a people, under the direction of private interest, will, upon equal terms, find out the most beneficial employment for itself, there is none for a reliance that it will struggle against the force of unequal terms, or will of itself surmount all the adventitious barriers to a successful competition which may have been erected either by the advan- tages naturally acquired from practice and previous possession of the ground, or by those which may have sprung from positive regulation and an arti- ficial policy " this last phrase doubtless a reference to Great Britain. Finally, Hamilton argues that FURTHER TARIFF LEGISLATION 147 any increase of prices arising from Protection will soon be more than counterbalanced by the increase of production, and resulting cheapness, which it will call forth ; and he urges the essential harmony of the industrial and agricultural interests, since the farmers may have to pay more for a time for manufactured goods, but will find the value of their farms enhanced by the growth of the demand for agricultural produce, both food and raw material. As definite proposals he recommends the grant of bounties, the free admission of raw materials (or the payment of drawbacks), and general protection against all manufactured articles which can be pro- duced in the country. From 1790 onwards there were constant altera- tions in the tariff between 1792 and 1816 there were some twenty-five Tariff Acts passed, all modifying the customs duties in one way or another. But Hamilton's Report, and the ideas it embodied, do not seem to have exercised any special influence on the legislation of this period ; the motives were always financial. 1 Up to 1808 there were increases of duties on various commodi- ties ; some specific duties were replaced by duties ad valorem ; and some articles (chiefly those useful for military purposes) were added to the free list. Alone in the duty imposed in 1804 on window glass " was any concession made to the protective 1 " With two or three exceptions, they had no other motive than to adjust the revenue to the needs of the Treasury " (Stanwood, i. p. 111). Cf. Taussig, p. 16, 148 ORIGINS OF AMERICAN COMMERCIAL POLICY policy." 1 But whilst this was the policy of Con- gress, it is evident that the feeling in favour of Protection was growing in the country at large. It was held back by the general prosperity of American trade during the Napoleonic wars until the United States became involved in the European complica- tions after the year 1807 ; until that time the American export and carrying trade had reaped great benefit from British difficulties. The follow- ing table shows the movement of the foreign trade of the United States from 1791 to 1807 (in million dollars) : 2 Gross Exports. 19-0 20-7 26-1 33-0 48-0 67-0 56-8 61-5 78-6 71-0 94-0 72-0 55-8 77-7 95-5 101-5 108-3 The most striking column here is that of re- exports, which represents the growth of the carry- 1 Stanwood, i. p. 115. 2 Taussig, p. 12. Financial years ending Sept. 30. Gross Imports. Re-exports. 1791 . 29-2 5 1792 31-5 1-7 1793 31-1 2-1 1794 . 34-6 6-5 1795 . 69-7 8-5 1796 81-4 26-3 1797 . 75-4 27-0 1798 . 68-5 33-0 1799 . 79-0 45-5 1800 . 91-2 39-1 1801 . 111-3 46-6 1802 . 76-3 35-7 1803 . 64-7 13-6 1804 85-0 36-2 1805 . 120-6 53-2 1806 . 129-4 60-3 1807 . 138-5 59-6 EFFECTS OF THE NAPOLEONIC WARS 149 ing trade of the United States, and the commercial importance of the war to that country is most markedly illustrated by a comparison of the figures for 1802 and 1803, the years of the Treaty of Amiens, with those which immediately precede and follow them. But with 1808 a change came. In November, 1806, Napoleon had replied to the British blockade of the French coast by the Berlin Decree, which declared the British Islands blockaded, and forbade all trade in British goods. Great Britain answered by proclaiming the continental coasting trade at least for ports under French control closed to neutrals, and at the end of 1807 ordered "the condemnation of any American vessel seized while on a voyage to any European port closed to British vessels, unless such vessel had first touched at a British port. Napoleon, on his part, in the Milan Decree (December 17th, 1807) declared that any ship which had obeyed the above order was good prize if seized in any port under his control. At this time, Napoleon was the virtual master of all the continental ports except those of Sweden, Norway, and Turkey, and the British were supreme on the ocean. These orders and decrees, therefore, provided for the speedy annihilation of American shipping, and this seems to have been the object of the last British Order in Council, if one may judge from a perusal of Mr. Perceval's correspondence on the subject. The official reason as stated was a desire to compel the United States to retaliate 150 ORIGINS OF AMERICAN COMMERCIAL POLICY upon the French Government." 1 But it was not to be expected that the United States would quietly submit to this treatment. On December 23rd, 1807, Congress passed the Embargo Act, which pro- hibited American vessels from leaving for foreign ports, and foreign vessels from taking any cargo except that already on board. The vigorous enforcement of these orders on both sides for although in March, 1809, the Embargo Act was repealed, it was replaced by the establishment of Non-Intercourse with France, Great Britain, their allies and colonies was one of the chief causes of the Anglo-American War of 1812. With the political effects of these various regula- tions we are not concerned ; but they were of great importance for the economic development of the United States. The following table shows the movement of American foreign trade (in million dollars) from the issue of the Embargo at the beginning of 1808 to the end of the war. 2 It should be noted that at the commencement of the war of 1812 the United States import duties were doubled. Year. (1807 Gross Imports. . 138-5 Re-exports. 59-6 Gross Exports. 108-3) 1808 57-0 13-0 20-4 1809 . 59-4 20-8 52-2 1810 85-4 24-4 66-7 1811 53-4 16-0 61-3 1812 . 77-0 8-5 38-5 1813 22-0 2-8 27-9 1814 13-0 1 6-9 Charming, United States, pp. 177-8. 2 Taussig, p. 12. GROWTH OF AMERICAN INDUSTRY 151 So by 1814 American foreign trade had practi- cally ceased to exist. The war was equivalent in its effects to a policy of Protection amounting to prohibition, and American manufactures, left in secure possession of the home market, entered upon a course of rapid expansion. Especially was that the case with the production of woollen goods, which increased in value from four million dollars in 1810 to nineteen million in 1815; 1 and with cotton spinning, which it is estimated employed 4,500 spindles in 1805, 87,000 in 1810, and 130,000 in 1815. 2 There were the beginnings of cotton weaving, and the growth of the manufacture of iron, glass, and pottery. 3 It was during these years that the factory system began (but only began) to replace domestic industry in the United States : "the manufacture of cotton and wool passed rapidly from the household to the mill ; but the methods of domestic and neighbourhood industry continued to predominate, even in those industries, down to and including the decade between 1820 and 1830." 4 Just at the close of 1814 a treaty of peace was signed by Great Britain and the United States, and this was followed in 1815 by a commercial agreement, intended at first for four years, but 1 "A loose, though significant guess" (Taussig, p. 40 n.). 2 Taussig, p. 28, from Woodbury's Report of 1836. 3 " See what has been, only by the short operation of the Embargo and Non-intercourse Act, done in America ! . . . We have here before us the seeds of a great event nothing less than the complete and absolute independence of America upon English manufactures " (William Cobbett, quoted in Bolles, ii. p. 289). 4 Twelfth Census of the United States, vii. p. liii. 152 ORIGINS OF AMERICAN COMMERCIAL POLICY prolonged in 1818 for another ten years ; by it the contracting parties bound themselves not to impose discriminating duties on each other's pro- ducts. 1 The first result of the cessation of hostilities was a swift rise of imports ; from $13,000,000 in 1814 they rose to $113,000,000 in 1815 (with only six months of peace), and $147,000,000 in 1816. This last was the highest figure yet recorded, and moreover, as re-exports were comparatively small, "the value of net im- ports was almost double that of any year pre- ceding the war." 2 The phenomena of Continental Europe at this time were repeated in the United States ; the barriers erected during the long war were removed, and both found themselves exposed to a sweeping invasion of British manufactured goods, which severely threatened the very exist- ence of some at least of the industries which had grown up under the shelter of the system of prohibition. In the United States the manu- facturers of cottons, woollens, and chemicals thought themselves particularly imperilled, and in 1815 President Madison called Congress to their help. " Under circumstances giving a power- ful impulse to manufacturing industry," he wrote, 3 "it has made among us a progress and exhibited an efficiency which justify a belief that with a protection not more than is due to the enter- prising citizens whose interests are now at stake, 1 Charming, United States, p. 198. 2 Stanwood, i. p. 131. 3 Seventh Annual Message, 1815. THE COMMENCEMENT OF PROTECTION 153 it will become at an early day not only safe against occasional competitions from abroad, but a source of domestic wealth and even of external commerce. In selecting the branches more especially entitled to the public patronage, a preference is obviously claimed by such as will relieve the United States from a dependence on foreign supplies, ever subject to casual failures, for articles necessary for the public defence or connected with the primary wants of individuals. It will be an additional recommendation of particular manufactures where the materials for them are extensively drawn from our agriculture, and consequently impart and insure to that great fund of national prosperity and independence an encouragement which cannot fail to be rewarded." The result was the tariff of 1816, which com- menced a series of enactments which for about twenty years became more and more protectionist. But the first steps were quite moderate. The original scheme was to reduce the war duties 29 per cent. that is, to leave the permanent duties 42 per cent, higher than before the war of 1812 ; but the proposals were considerably modified in their passage through Congress owing to the opposition of the shipping interest and the rivalry of the various groups of states which sought protection for their industries. 1 So the proposed 1 "The difficulty is illustrated most clearly by the objections of Northern members to a protecting duty on sugar and of Southern members to giving protection to cotton manufactures. On the question of protection to iron the North and the South united against the Middle States" (Stanwood,, i. p. 157). 154 ORIGINS OF AMERICAN COMMERCIAL POLICY duty of $1.25 per cwt. on bar-iron was reduced by the House of Representatives to 45 cents ; the proposed duty on sugar was cut down consider- ably ; instead of the desired rate of 33^ per cent, the cotton manufactures obtained only 25 per cent, for three years and 20 per cent, after the expiration of that term. 1 That protectionist motives exercised a strong influence over the tariff discussions there can be no doubt, but they had not yet obtained a complete control over the minds of the legislators. 2 The new tariff was a combination of specific and ad valorem duties. The new customs laws seem to have had little effect, so far at least as the iron and cotton indus- tries were concerned. The imports of bar -iron rose from 12,293 tons in 1816 to 21,160 tons in 1817, and, after a temporary decline, to 22,459 tons in 1820, whilst the home production fell rapidly 1 In connection with cottons the system of the "minimum valuation" was adopted; i.e. it was directed that all cotton, cloths, etc., "the original cost of which at the place imported shall be less than 25 cents per sq. yard, shall be taken and deemed to have cost 25 cents per sq. yard, and shall be charged with duty accordingly. " Taussig writes (p. 30) : " After 1818 the use of the power-loom, and the fall in the price of raw cotton, combined greatly to reduce the prices of cotton goods. The price of coarse cottons fell to 19 cents in 1819, 13 cents in 1826, and 8^ cents in 1829. The minimum duty became propor- tionately heavier as the price decreased, and in a few years after its enactment, had become prohibitive of the importation of the coarser kinds of cotton cloths." 2 Taussig (pp. 18-19) seems to think that the new duties (averaging 20 per cent.) were the outcome chiefly of financial needs. Dewey (p. 162) holds that " Protection was adopted as a fundamental basis of the fiscal system and revenue was subordinated to industrial needs." He adds, however, that there was little opposition, because the country was confronted by a real crisis. ECONOMIC CRISIS 155 in part doubtless because of the technical defects of the manufactures. Similarly in the cotton manufacture " the tariff of 1816 was not protective so far as those establishments were concerned which had not the most efficient machinery. This is almost equivalent to saying that it was protective in relation to but one factory in the country." 1 The help given to the makers of woollens by the duties was also only slight ; and the three industries soon began to invoke again the aid of Congress. In 1818 they secured an increase in the duty on bar- iron, and a prolongation of the 25 per cent, on cottons until 1826 ; but apart from these increases, the protectionist movement for some time made little progress. This was due in part to the atti- tude of the Southern States, where agriculture was prosperous owing to the world-wide demand for their cotton and tobacco ; they believed that protection for manufactures, which were practically impossible under the climatic conditions of the South and with slave labour, would be inimical to their interests. Moreover, in politics it was the "era of good feeling" there were no organised political parties to seek in the advocacy of Protec- tion an election cry. But in 1818-19 there came an economic crisis ; the prices of the agricultural staples of the United States, hitherto high, fell rapidly, thus imitating the prices of manufactured goods, which had declined sharply when the con- 1 Stanwood, i. p. 173. Cf. for the effect of the various duties, Taussig, pp. 34-5, 40-1, 50-1. 156 ORIGINS OF AMERICAN COMMERCIAL POLICY elusion of the war had removed the restrictions on imports. This fall in agricultural prices to some extent benefited the manufacturers, but did not moderate their demand for Protection ; and the agriculturists, especially in the North, became more favourable to it in their desire in view of European legislation to develop the home market. 1 Thus one important effect of the crisis was to revive and strengthen the agitation in favour of more protection, just as the crisis of 1873 and the following years in Germany prepared the way for Bismarck's tariff legislation. In 1819 the Con- gressional Committee on Manufactures, under the stimulus of the commercial trouble of that year, 2 brought forward proposals for a complete revision of all the tariff rates, with large increases all round, partly to provide revenue to meet a growing deficit in the national accounts, and partly to extend the protection already given to manufactured goods. There was a prolonged conflict, and in April it was carried through the House of Representatives only to be summarily rejected by a majority of one vote in the Senate. From 1820 to 1824 there was some agitation throughout the Union in favour of tariff changes, but practically no attempt was made to give ex- 1 Taussig, pp. 19-24. 2 " Its causes were complex : in part the inability of the manufac- turing industries to recover a stable footing after the abnormal growth occasioned by the embargo and the war, and in part a spirit of specula- tion developed by several years of rapid commercial expansion and bad banking" (Dewey, p. 166). THE ACT OF 1824 157 pression to it in the legislature until the new Con- gress, to meet at the end of 1823, had been elected. The effect of the census of 1820, which determined the apportionment of seats in the House of Repre- sentatives, 1 had been to increase the representation of the Middle States New York, Pennsylvania, Ohio, Kentucky, Tennessee which were strongly protectionist. President Monroe invited the new Congress to " a review of the tariff for the purpose of affording such additional protection to those articles which we are prepared to manufacture, or which are more immediately connected with the defence and independence of the country." The response to this appeal was the Tariff Act of 1824, of which "it may be said without reservation that the sole object was the protection of manufactures " ; 2 the financial position of the Government made it unnecessary to consider revenue. It increased the duties on iron, lead, wool, hemp though not so much as those interested had desired ; on cotton and woollen goods the ad valorem duties were raised from 25 to 33^ per cent., but the additional protection to woollens was discounted by the doubling of the duty on raw wool. Strong oppo- 1 ' ( Representatives and direct taxes shall be apportioned among the several States which may be included within this Union, according to their respective numbers. . . . The actual enumeration shall be made within three years after the first meeting of the Congress of the United States, and within every subsequent term of ten years. . . . The number of Representatives shall not exceed one for every thirty thousand " (Original form of art. i. sec. 2 of the Constitution, given in Bryce, Amer. Comm., i. p. 697). 2 Stanwood, i. p. 202. sition came from the commercial classes of New England to the tariff as a whole ; from the ship- builders to the increases on hemp (for cordage), flax, and iron ; from the manufacturers there to the increases on molasses (for rum) and raw wool. But New England was not solid in its resistance to the new tariff, for it had itself growing manufactures of cotton and woollen goods ; and hence its vote was divided. 1 The South was united ; it exported cotton largely, and feared retaliation, particularly from Great Britain. The Middle and Western States, whose interests were chiefly agricultural, threw their whole weight on the side of the new proposals, partly in their desire for the development of the home market, and partly to obtain protec- tion for their hemp, wool, and flax. 2 The combina- tion of these states and the manufacturers of New England carried the Act of 1824, but only by a small majority. Two other points about the proposals of that year are noticeable. A clause providing for the imposition of a surtax equivalent in amount to the bounty paid by a foreign country on any goods imported into the United States was rejected, on the ground that it would be a breach of the Com- 1 In the division on the Bill of 1819, 19 New England representatives voted for it, 18 against ; New York, New Jersey, Pennsylvania, and Delaware gave 55 votes for, 1 against ; the South, 8 for, 63 against ; Ohio, Illinois, and Indiana, 8 for, none against (Stanwood, i. pp. 192-3). In 1824 the South voted against the proposed tariff, the Middle and Western States for ; of the New England States, Rhode Island and Connecticut for, the rest against (Taussig, pp. 74-5). 2 Taussig, pp. 70-5. THE CONSTITUTIONAL QUESTION 159 mercial Treaty of 1815 with Great Britain, which guaranteed that no unfavourably discriminating duties should be imposed by the United States on commodities coming from that country. And much more important than this was the question whether the levying of import duties for protective purposes was constitutionally within the power of Congress or not ; the matter was raised only tenta- tively, and was not much discussed, but it was subsequently to form the subject of very consider- able controversy. 1 1 Stanwood, pp. 220-5. CHAPTER II THE GROWTH OF PROTECTION, AND THE COMPROMISE OF 1833 FOR a short time after the passing of the Tariff Act of 1824 the manufacturers seem to have been satisfied ; but in the latter part of 1826 a demand for a greater amount of protection made its appear- ance amongst the producers of woollen goods. Their complaint was to the effect that the British duties on raw wool had been reduced, that wages in Great Britain were lower, and therefore the Americans could not effectively compete with the British manufacturers, and were in a very de- pressed state. 1 They did not ask for a reduction of the duty on raw wool probably believing that the agricultural states would not listen to such a proposal but for an increase in the duties on woollen goods. The Woollens Bill of 1827, which was introduced to meet their demands, passed the House of Representatives, only to be immediately wrecked in the Senate ; but the woollen manu- facturers had revived the whole protectionist move- ment. A widespread campaign had commenced, 1 Stanwood, i. pp. 253-4, 277- 160 THE TARIFF AND PARTY POLITICS l6l and the advocates of Protection found skilful and influential exponents of their views in Matthew Carey, and Niles, whose Weekly Register became their storehouse of facts and arguments. After the Woollens Bill had been introduced, the Free Trade party realised the necessity of vigorous action, and began a counter-campaign. But unlike previous controversies on the tariff question, the economic discussion was now to become inex- tricably involved with party politics ; and American tariff legislation entered upon a new stage. The " era of good feeling " was at an end ; political parties were at last taking shape again, and round Andrew Jackson there was being formed a party which represented a break with all the traditions of the past. 1 The outcome of the protectionist agitation was the Tariff Act of 1828, under which " the experi- ment of protecting was now to be carried to the highest point it ever reached." 2 That Act, destined to be known as the "Act of Abominations," was passed at a time when men's thoughts were con- centrated on the approaching presidential campaign, and the determination of the Jackson party to secure the election of their chief. The supporters of the retiring President, Adams, whose leader was Henry Clay, were definitely in favour of Protec- tion ; the Jackson party was divided the Southern members, who were united in their support of Jackson, being in favour of a considerable re- 1 Wilson, pp. 12-21. Bolles, ii. p. 407. M 162 THE GROWTH OF PROTECTION duction of duties, whilst the Middle States, whose votes would turn the election, were almost as strongly protectionist. The outcome of this peculiar position was an extraordinary series of party complications and political manoeuvres, in which Jackson's supporters were led with astonish- ing skill by Martin van Buren. A Tariff Bill was framed, greatly increasing duties on manufactured goods and raw materials alike ; and ultimately it was passed by a curious combination. The South voted solidly against it, so did two-thirds of the New England members ; the vote of the Western and Middle States, combined with the protectionist vote from New England, carried it. 1 But the votes of the members were determined in the main by party considerations ; many excessively high duties had been inserted in the Bill by the votes of Southern members desirous of making it so unpopular that it could not pass ; yet though they voted against it at the last it was carried largely by the votes of people with whom they were politically allied, who were not anxious for Protection, but meant to capture the vote of the Middle States for their presidential candidate. 2 In this they were successful ; at the election of November, 1828, Jackson was returned by an overwhelming majority. The increases made by the new tariff in the 1 Taussig, p. 98. 2 The complicated story of these mauoeuvres can be read in Stan- wood, i. chap. viii. THE "ACT OF ABOMINATIONS" 163 customs duties were very considerable. The duties on hemp were raised from $35 to $45 a ton, though good hemp could scarcely be grown in the country ; on molasses from 5 to 7j cents a gallon, whilst drawbacks to the manufacturers of rum were refused ; on pig-iron from 56 to 62J cents per cwt. ; on hammered bar-iron from 90 to 112 cents per cwt, and on rolled bar-iron from $30 to $37 a ton. 1 But the chief developments had regard to woollens. It is admitted that the difficulties of the American manufacturers of woollen goods in meeting British competition were due in large measure to their technical deficiencies and the preference of the American consumers for the better quality goods from Great Britain ; 2 but they secured in 1828 increased specific duties on woollen goods, though to nothing like the extent which they had desired. On the other hand, the old ad valorem duty on raw wool was replaced by a specific duty of 4 cents a pound, with the addition of an ad valorem rate which ultimately was to reach the height of 50 per cent. This particular clause seems to have been designed to secure the support of the agricultural states, and at the same time to damage the Tariff Act by making it unpopular with the manufacturers. The passage of the Tariff Act of 1828 led immediately to one of the most fateful political conflicts in the history of the United States. We have seen that the Southern States were strongly 1 Taussig, pp. 88-9, 93, 2 Stanwood, i. p. 280. 164 THE GROWTH OF PROTECTION opposed to Protection, and they were offended also by the appropriation of federal surplus revenues to the construction of public works, particularly roads and canals, almost entirely in the North, which with its growing manufactures was in urgent need of the development of its means of communication. 1 At the time when the new tariff proposals were being discussed in 1827, the inhabitants of South Carolina (always the leader of the South in action) had protested against the protective duties on the ground that "the duties laid by Congress, of whatever description, are levied in great part on articles purchased by Southern industry and consumed by the South ; but these duties are expended almost exclusively for the benefit of other sections of the Union. . . . All that is taken from us is disposed of elsewhere. We are benefited in the South by those expendi- tures in no way that we can perceive and feel. All that we pay is accumulated in defending and improving distant sections of the Union, and the prosperity of the North is built upon the im- poverishment of the South." 2 The Southern States had every claim for special consideration ; in 1829 out of a total export valued at about $56,000,000, $34,000,000 represented the cotton, rice, and tobacco exported from the South. 3 The exports 1 Jackson was opposed to this policy, but was overruled by Congress (Wilson, p. 39). 2 Quoted in Stanwood, i. p. 261. 3 Wilson, p. 50. "The contribution of the South appears still more striking if it be compared with the total value of agricultural exports, which was a little under $44,000,000." THE FREE TRADERS AND REVENUE DUTIES 165 of raw cotton were $26,575,000, as against $1,258,000 worth of cotton goods. South Carolina was fourth amongst the exporting states of the Union. In the tariff of 1828 protection for manufactures had reached its highest point ; but the scheme then adopted was so thoroughly bad that all were agreed on the necessity of some changes ; and for some time therefore, though its leaders were preparing their plans, the South did not think it necessary to take decisive action. The first changes were made in 1830. The duties were reduced on tea by 50 per cent., on coffee by 60 per cent, (and after 1831 by 80 per cent.), and on cocoa by 50 per cent., whilst the duty on molasses was put back to the old level, and the system of drawbacks renewed. But these were not all the changes required ; the agitation of the Free Trade party continued, though it is important to notice that they did not ask for a complete abolition of duties in fact, they were will- ing on financial grounds to retain somewhat heavy rates. In the Petition to the Senate, from the Free Trade Convention at Philadelphia in 1831, it is stated that " the people prefer, in time of peace, duties raised on the importation of foreign merchandise to any internal tax, direct or indirect. Whether for good or for evil, that system affords an encouragement to domestic manufactures not less efficient for being incidental. Duties on im- ports, amounting on an average to about 20 per cent, of the value, appear necessary to the support 166 THE GROWTH OF PROTECTION of Government" 1 The petitioners condemn the high duties of 1828, even after the changes of 1830, because without giving real help to the protected trades they hamper all the others. They point out that in the existing conditions of American industry manufacturers must have recourse to foreign supplies they give as an instance iron goods, with growing imports in spite of increased duties 2 and they complain that the duties greatly increase the cost of materials to manufacturers, especially the shipbuilders. The same petition also presents what is probably the best short statement of the Southern objections to the protective legislation: "The Southern States have always confined themselves almost exclusively to the cultivation of the rich products of their climate. This is the only advantage they enjoy, and they owe it to nature. As they make but few, they consume a much greater proportion of manufactured articles imported from other states or other countries. That system, therefore, that enhances beyond measure the price of those objects of necessary consumption operates most unequally and unjustly upon them. They are forbidden to 1 Text in Taussig, State Papers. The Petition, which is an elaborate statement of the practical argument for Free Trade, was written by Albert Gallatin. 2 The Petition gives the following figures of imports : Rolled Iron. Hammered Iron. Manufactures of Iron. 1817-1820 . . 2,237 tons ... 16,887 tons ... Not ascertained. 1821-1824 . . 4,212 ... 23,162 ... $2,600,000 1825-1827 . . 5,400 ... 22,650 ... $3,630,000 1828-1830 . . 6,450 ... 31,000 ... $3,660,000 THE SOUTHERN PROTEST 16? supply themselves on the cheapest terms consistent with the revenue necessary for the exigencies of Government. As the greatest consumers, they must not only pay a greater share of the duties requisite to defray the necessary national expen- diture, but they are compelled to pay the enhanced price occasioned by the protecting system. That system cannot be extended to them. They find in it no indemnity, no compensation for the injury which it inflicts upon them. They have not, they cannot, in self-defence erect manufacturing estab- lishments. The nature of their population for- bids it." 1 Moderate men in the Northern States were anxious to make some concession to the South, and the feeling in favour of a reduction of duties was strengthened by the condition of the public 1 Readers of De Tocqueville's La Democratic en Amerique will remember his description (17th ed., vol. ii. chap. x. pp. 320-5) of the contrast presented to the traveller down the Ohio River by the two banks, and his prophecy of a great conflict as the inevitable outcome of the difference between the economic and social organisation of North and South. With the opinion of the petitioners, quoted above, may be contrasted the belief of Hamilton, in his Report on Manu- factures (Taussig, State Papers, p. 59), that "ideas of a contrariety of interests between the northern and southern regions of the Union are in the main as unfounded as they are mischievous. The diversity of circumstances on which such contrariety is usually predicated authorises a directly contrary conclusion." Forty years later De Tocqueville agreed with this : " Je vois bien dans les differentes parties de 1' Union des interets differents, mais je n'en decouvre pas qui soient contraires les uns aux autres" (loc. cit., p. 369). But he anticipated conflict owing to the dissatisfaction of the South at seeing itself outpaced in prosperity and political power by the North, and the difference of temperament arising from the difference of economic conditions. 168 THE GROWTH OF PROTECTION finances. The customs receipts had been suffi- ciently large to allow of the paying off of the National Debt with great rapidity. Between Jan- uary 1st, 1828, and January 1st, 1832, the amount was reduced from $67,475,000 to $24,322,000, and the interest payable had fallen by one-half. Mean- while the receipts from customs were rising ; conse- quently, with the Congress which met in December, 1831, there began a revision of the tariff, and the new Act was adopted in June, 1832. 1 The duties on flax and hemp were reduced slightly, as were also those on pig and bar iron. But the chief changes were in the case of wool and woollens ; the cheaper kinds of raw wool were admitted free, on the others the duties were considerably reduced ; on cheap woollen goods the ad valorem duty was reduced to 5 per cent., on worsted goods from 25 to 10 per cent. ; on other qualities they were nominally increased but practically reduced, owing to the abolition of the system of minimums. 2 The number of absolutely free articles was increased from 49 to 180 ; tea and coffee imported in Ameri- can vessels were to be free. " In fact, the protec- 1 A Report of the Congressional Committee which prepared the scheme contains an elaborate discussion of the relative merits of specific and ad valorem duties, and declares in favour of the latter on the grounds that they affect all quab'ties of a commodity equally^ as specific duties do not unless very elaborately detailed ; and that they enable the proportion of taxation intended by the legislature to be maintained in spite of fluctuations of values. These advantages outweigh the dis- advantage of the encouragement given to false declarations of value (Bolles, ii. pp. 415-16). For a fuller discussion of this question, see pp. 236-8. 2 Stanwood, i. p. 384. THE SOUTHERN LINE OF RESISTANCE 169 live system was put back, in the main, to where it had been in 1824. The result was to clear the tariff of the excrescences which had grown on it in 1828, and to put it in a form in which the protectionists could advocate its permanent reten- tion." 1 But this very fact drove the Southern States into open revolt ; so long as there was a chance, by ordinary legislative means, of over- throwing Protection, they were disinclined to have recourse to other weapons, but they interpreted the action of Congress in 1832 as meaning the permanent incorporation of Protection in the fiscal policy of the Union. The line which the leaders of the South, es- pecially Calhoun and Hayne, would take had already been revealed ; it was the adoption of a particular view as to the manner in which the Con- stitution should be interpreted. There were two possibilities ; the Federal Government might be comparatively weak, and confined to the exercise of powers based on a strict and narrow interpreta- tion of the actual terms of the Constitution, whilst the separate states enjoyed extensive rights and powers that is to say, there could be a league of states, not a Union ; or the Federal Government might continually increase in authority, and the terms of the Constitution might be liberally inter- preted at the cost of a constant diminution of the powers of the various members of the Union. Economic and political considerations alike deter- 1 Taussig, p. 105. 170 THE GROWTH OF PROTECTION mined the Southern States to adopt the former view. Under their climatic conditions, and with slave-labour, there could be no considerable growth of manufactures, and it was quite certain that the South would be outpaced in population and wealth by the North, and still more by the Middle States. That would mean the political predominance of the North, and it seemed that the result would be the maintenance of the protective policy to which the South was so strenuously opposed it might also mean the overthrow of slavery. The leaders of the South argued in the tariff controversies from 1827 to 1832, as we have seen, that the policy of Protection benefited one portion of the Union at the expense of another ; and as they could not prevent the passage of the Tariff Acts, they main- tained that the Acts themselves were unconstitu- tional, whatever the courts might say. They argued that customs duties for protective purposes were not within the terms of that clause of the Consti- tution which authorised Congress "to lay and collect taxes, duties, imposts, and excises, to pay the debts and provide for the general defence and welfare of the United States " ; or that even if they were so included, or could be, by an applica- tion of the doctrine of "implied powers," the duties actually levied violated the rule that "all duties, imposts, and excises shall be uniform throughout the United States," since they bore more heavily upon the South than upon the North. But if the obnoxious tariff laws were THE DOCTRINE OF NULLIFICATION " 171 passed, and maintained by the courts, what was to be done ? In a famous debate in regard to public land, in 1830, Hayne, of South Carolina, had argued that "the Constitution of the Union was a compact between the states ; that to make the Federal Government the sole judge, through its judiciary, of the extent of its own powers, was to leave the states utterly without guarantee of the rights reserved to them, and might result in destroying the federal character of the Government altogether ; and that if the states could not defend themselves in cases where the unconstitutionally of acts of the Federal Government seemed to them deliberate and palpable, the government might be consolidated to a point of intolerable tyranny." 1 Authority for the action now taken in 1833 was found in the resolutions passed by Virginia and Kentucky at the time of their entry into the Union, to the effect that "in case of a de- liberate, palpable, and dangerous exercise of other powers, not granted by the said compact, the states, who are members thereof, have the right, and are in duty bound, to interpose, for arresting the progress of the evil, and for maintaining within their respective limits the authorities, rights, and liberties appertaining to them." 1 The practical application of this doctrine was the method of "nullification." On November 24th, 1832, a State Convention in South Carolina declared the Tariff 1 Wilson, pp. 43-4. 2 Ibid., p. 45. 172 THE GROWTH OF PROTECTION Acts of 1828 and 1832 null and void within that state, and announced that, in the event of the Federal Government attempting to enforce the law, South Carolina would deem it necessary to withdraw from the Union. Jackson, originally elected with Southern support, had now been re- elected by an overwhelming majority, and whatever his personal views on the tariff question itself may have been, he would have nothing to do with nullification, which he declared to be " incompati- ble with the existence of the Union, contradicted expressly by the letter of the Constitution, unauthor- ised by its spirit, inconsistent with every principle on which it was founded, and destructive of the great object for which it was formed." l In January, 1833, a Bill was introduced into Congress, known as the Force Bill, authorising the President to use the Federal military and naval forces to enforce the tariff, wherever the collectors might encounter obstacles. But neither side was anxious to push the matter to extremes. Not all the Southern States were prepared to follow South Carolina, and the Free Traders of the North cared more for the maintenance of the Constitution than for the over- throw of the tariff. On the other hand, the politi- cal leaders of the Protectionists recognised the necessity of yielding to some extent. In February Clay introduced his Compromise Bill. By it all duties in excess of 20 per cent, ad valorem were to be reduced by one-tenth of the excess in each 1 Wilson, p. 61. THE COMPROMISE OF 1833 173 alternate year up to 1839, and after that by a greater amount, so that the whole excess should be abolished by 1842 ; a number of duties were to be entirely abolished in 1833, and many more in 1842. 1 The result would be that by 1842 the free list would be much enlarged, and duties brought to a uniform level of 20 per cent, ad valorem. This amounted to " giving manufacturers ten years' notice to prepare for the final abandonment of the principle of Protection " ; 2 but it is more than probable that Clay and his friends did not antici- pate any such event they hoped that something would happen to enable the notice to be cancelled. The compromise was readily accepted by Calhoun on behalf of the South, and became law on March 2nd, 1833. On March llth, South Caro- lina repealed the nullification ordinance, but also declared the Force Bill void. As a temporary political expedient, Clay's com- promise was successful in that it put an end to the crisis, but it did not settle the real question at issue. The Federal Government had asserted its right to enforce the Federal law even against the will of the individual states ; but South Carolina still adhered to its doctrine of nullification. Practi- cally, the South was victorious ; it had compelled the North to repeal the obnoxious tariff, though the Force Bill remained on the statute book as a statement of the powers of the Federal Govern- 1 Stanwood, i. pp. 307-8. 2 Bolles, ii. p. 425. 174 THE GROWTH OF PROTECTION ment. The problem was put aside for a time, but it was to return a generation later to be solved only by war. 1 1 For the details of the conflict and the constitutional argument, see Wilson, pp. 23-65 ; Stanwood, i. chaps, ix. and x. ; Johnston, History of American Politics, chaps, xi. to xiv. ; and cf. Bryce, American Commonwealth, chaps, xxxi. to xxxv. CHAPTER III COMPROMISE, PROTECTION, AND RE- ACTIONECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES TO 1860 FOR eight years the Tariff Act established by the Compromise Act of 1833 remained untouched ; and consequently during all that period the United States were moving steadily in the direction of the removal of restrictions upon foreign trade. The first four years, from the passage of the Act till towards the end of 1836, were a time of general prosperity, but unfortunately they were also coin- cident with the beginnings of financial disorder, resulting not from economic causes, but from the extraordinary policy of the Government. 1 The chief example of the reckless financial methods of the administration of President Jackson (1829-37) was the attack upon the United States Bank. That institution had been originally established in 1791 with a charter for twenty years, but from the first there had been considerable doubts as to the 1 The year 1833 " marks the change, for some time impending, from rational and conservative, to reckless and destructive, finance, and from comparative prudence on the part of the business community to wild speculation " (Stan wood, ii. p. 1). 175 176 DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES constitutionality of the proceeding. The result was that the charter was allowed to lapse in 1811 ; but the bank had proved so useful that it was renewed in 1816. The Treasury had subscribed one-fifth of the bank's capital, and the President nominated one-fifth of its directors ; it was the depository of the Federal revenues, its notes were legal tender for all payments to the United States Government, and it was bound to redeem its notes in specie on demand. From the first, the new Democratic party were hostile to the bank, partly because, with their theory as to the interpretation of the Constitution, they held the bank charter to be unconstitutional, in spite of a decision of the Supreme Court to the contrary effect in 1819 ; partly because they thought that its privileges con- stituted an " un-American monopoly " ; and partly because they supposed it to exercise great political influence in the interest of their opponents. There seems to have been little basis for their charges in regard to this last matter, or for the further charges of mismanagement, but Jackson resolved to over- throw the bank, and when Congress passed an Act renewing the charter it encountered a Presidential veto, which the majority was not strong enough to override. Clay endeavoured to make the bank question the principal issue at the Presidential election in November, 1832, with disastrous results ; the triumphant return of Jackson only strengthened his determination to destroy the bank. In Septem- ber, 1833, having at last secured a Secretary of the DANGEROUS FINANCIAL LEGISLATION 177 Treasury who was ready to help him, Jackson pro- ceeded to withdraw the Government deposits from the bank, and not to replace them. The Federal revenues were henceforth to be deposited in certain selected state banks (i.e. banks under state charters), which were not chosen always for their financial soundness, but in some cases at least for their use- fulness for party purposes. 1 In the years 1833 to 1836 there was a great rise of imports, but in spite of this the reduction of duties had brought a diminished customs revenue. However, the sales of public land in these years were so great as to give the Treasury a huge sur- plus, and in 1836 the National Debt was extin- guished. 2 If the sales of public land were to go on, a continued surplus might be expected. The obvious course would have been to reduce taxa- tion, but no one was willing to touch the Com- promise of 1833, which had already come to possess an almost sacred character. Consequently it was decided, on the proposal of Calhoun, that on and after January 31st, 1837, all the surplus funds remaining in the Treasury above $5,000,000 should be distributed between the various states, with the proviso, however, that money so distri- buted could be recalled by the Federal Govern- ment if necessary a course never adopted, and in fact impossible. Three such distributions were 1 Wilson, p. 88. Dewey (p. 209) apparently thinks that the charges against Jackson for favouritism in this matter are exaggerated ; "the interests of the Government were well safeguarded." 2 Stanwood, i. p. 284. N 178 DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES made in 1837, amounting to $37,000,000; after that there was no longer a surplus, but a deficit. In the same period there was an extraordinary increase in the number of banks of issue (from 329 in 1829 to 788 in 1837), 1 stimulated by the new deposit system of the Federal Government, the growth of speculation, particularly in land, and the development of industry. The states exercised no control over the new banks, and allowed them, even when they possessed scarcely any capital, to issue notes freely. The country was flooded with paper money in all stages of depreciation, and prices rose rapidly. To protect itself as much as possible, the Treasury in July, 1836, issued a circular requiring all payments for public lands to be made in cash. This increased the difficulties of the money market, already very great and complicated by the calling in of loans by English creditors ; 2 and by the beginning of 1837 commercial credit was badly shaken. Food prices rose rapidly, 3 and then a sudden fall in the price of cotton, following on the over-production resulting from the rapid rise in prices between 1833 and 1835, brought a general crash. All the banks in the country ceased payments in specie. 4 With all this the tariff had nothing to do, for the reductions of duties under the Act of 1833 1 Dewey, p. 225. 2 Ibid., p. 230. 3 Between 1834 and 1837 flour rose from $5 to $11 a barrel, and corn from 53 cents to $1.16 a bushel ; early in 1837 there were bread riots in New York (Wilson, p. 93). 4 Stanwood, ii. p. 8. COMMERCIAL CRISIS 179 were not to be considerable until about 1840. 1 The financial distress was due simply to the confusion into which the policy of the Jackson Administration and the growth of speculation, stimulated by the great sales of public lands and excessive credit to purchasers, had thrown the credit system of the country ; consequently there seems to have been no proposal made in any quarter for an alteration of the tariff or a return to a greater measure of protection. After the crisis there was the inevitable period of stagnation commercial recovery was very slow ; and the general depression may have been, and probably was, increased by the knowledge of the manu- facturers that under the Act of 1833 the pace of the reduction of duties was now to quicken. But, nevertheless, the efforts towards a change in the Tariff Act were very slight, and met with little support. Two financial reforms only were made. In 1838 the State of New York began the policy of permitting the establishment of any bank without need of a special charter, on con- dition of its promoters depositing with the State Treasury securities to the amount represented by 1 Even Stanwood, who is strongly protectionist in sympathy, writes : ' ' No candid student of history will hold that the Tariff Act of 1833 had even a slight direct influence, by an injurious effect upon domestic manufacture, in bringing on the crisis. The evidence is necessarily of a negative character, but it is conclusive. The fact that manufacturers were flourishing up to the time when the financial storm burst, as all authorities deemed that they were, is all-sufficing" (Stanwood, ii. p. 8). The connection of this and the following crisis with the tariff appears to have been a later invention of Henry Carey. 180 DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES its issue of notes. And in 1840 the Independent Treasury Act was passed, under which the Treasury was itself to keep all the proceeds of the public revenue in its own hands (not making use of the banks) and to make and receive payments only in specie. 1 By the election of November, 1840, the Demo- crats were utterly discredited, in spite of some diplo- matic successes of Van Buren, who had succeeded Jackson as President in 1837. The main defect of his administration had been his steadfast ad- herence to the financial policy of his predecessor, and his failure to devise any satisfactory measures for dealing with the commercial situation. The new political parties had now been definitely formed ; on the one side were the Democrats, led by the President himself and Benton, with their advocacy of a conservative interpretation of the Constitution and their consequent opposition to the expenditure of Federal moneys on internal improvements, to Protection, and to the National Bank ; and on the other side were the Whigs, as the Republican party of Clay and ex-President Adams was called since 1834, representing many diverse elements, but agreed upon a wide interpre- tation of the Constitution and protective legisla- tion. Already there were signs of the difficulties to be caused later by the anti-slavery party a more serious menace to the Democrats than to the Whigs, since the former were dependent for 1 Dewey, pp. 235-7. FAILURE OF THE WHIG PROGRAMME 181 much of their political strength on the South. 1 The Whigs, not so much because of their new policy as because of the discredit into which the Democrats had fallen, were able to carry the election of Harrison, a successful soldier, as President in November, 1840, and immediately upon his taking office they prepared to commence financial legislation. They proposed to repeal the Independent Treasury Act, to re-establish the National Bank, to amend the tariff in order to meet the large Treasury deficit, and also to dis- tribute amongst the states the proceeds of the sales of public lands, so that these would not henceforth be reckoned as a source of Federal revenue. But scarcely had these proposals been put forward when the President died, and was succeeded by Vice-President Tyler. The new President was not a Whig at all, but a discon- tented Democrat, who had been adopted by the Whigs as one of their candidates only in order to detach a certain number of votes from their opponents and to attempt to secure doubtful states. He was by no means in sympathy with their proposals, and immediately vetoed a Bill establishing a new National Bank. The Distribu- tion Bill was carried only after some difficulties with the President and subject to the proviso (which in fact reduced it to impotence) that the distribution should be suspended if at any time 1 Wilson, pp. 112-14. Cf. Johnston, American Politics, chaps, xiii. and xiv. 182 DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES it became necessary for revenue purposes to levy customs duties of more than 20 per cent. As a hasty expedient to provide money, a temporary Tariff Act was passed in September, 1841, laying a duty of 20 per cent, on all merchandise previously paying less, or free ; there were, however, certain exceptions to this general rule, and the proposal to tax tea and coffee was rejected. 1 By the end of 1841, the financial situation was worse than ever. In spite of large issues of Treasury notes, there was a heavy deficit, and there seemed every likelihood that the final re- missions of duty, now about to take place under the Act of 1833, would still further increase the difficulties of the Treasury. This fact, coupled with the general uncertainty, probably seriously hindered the manufacturers ; and the commercial troubles had again become acute. In 1841 fifty- five banks had stopped payment; in January, 1842, six states, including Pennsylvania and Maryland, were unable to meet their obligations ; and by the end of April twenty -six more banks were sus- pended. 2 It was absolutely necessary for some action to be taken, and after another temporary measure had been passed to prolong certain duties, Congress adopted in August, 1842, the new Tariff Act, which was carried only after much diffi- 1 One of the earliest acts of the new Whig administration was the repeal of the Independent Treasury Act in 1841. The Act was restored in 1846, and has remained in force since (Dewey, pp. 239, 252-5). 2 Stauwood, ii. p. 18. TARIFF ACT OF 1842 183 culty, and by means of complicated parliamentary manoeuvres. It was passed by the Whigs and was therefore decidedly protectionist, 1 and was much more elaborately detailed than any of its pre- decessors. It was based on the Tariff Act of 1832, and in comparison with that it increased the duties on cotton manufactures, on glass, and on the cheapest wools, whilst it reduced the duties on woollens, wool, leather, and some other com- modities. But in contrast to the position of the duties in 1841, which under the Compromise Act were drawing close to an all-round rate of 20 per cent., the Act of 1842 marks a distinct return towards Protection. The average duty was to be about 30 per cent., though on manu- factured goods it was a good deal higher. There can, on the whole, be little doubt that the new Act had a distinctly beneficent effect, 2 mainly because it gave the manufacturers certainty as 1 " It marks the last triumph of the protectionist policy before the Civil War " (Mayo-Smith and Seligman, p. 9). 2 Stanwood becomes enthusiastic oil the point. " The final plunge to the 20 per cent. max. rate of the compromise tariff was bringing the industries dependent upon protection to a standstill ; and all business suffered in the stagnation of employment, in the cessation of the movement of money and goods, which are as the circulation of the blood in the body of commerce. The adoption of any improved tariff would have removed one cause of the existing evil the un- certainty as to the future. The enactment of a tariff which promised prosperity and health to the starved manufacturers removed all causes, and actually restored the prosperity which it promised. There is no other enactment affecting the duties on imports, the effect of which is so clear, so indisputable as there was never another which worked so indisputably " (pp. 36-7). Taussig is more moderate, but agrees that, in the manner indicated above, the tariff did have a decidedly good effect on the commercial and industrial situation. 184 DEVELOPMENT OF THE -UNITED STATES to the conditions under which their industries were to be carried on, and helped to improve matters in the iron and cotton industries, which contributed an impetus to all the rest. It is at any rate certain that in 1842 there began a revival of trade and commerce, and although such a revival must assuredly have taken place in any case, it is probable that it was quickened by the increased protection afforded by the new tariff. And from the point of view of revenue the new customs duties were quite satisfactory ; in the year ending June 30th, 1844, and onwards, the Treasury found itself again in possession of a surplus. But the tariff was not destined to remain long untouched. The Presidential election of November, 1844, resulted in the triumph of the Democrats, represented by Polk. 1 The new President was opposed to the whole protectionist system, though his colleague in the campaign, the Democratic candidate for the Vice-Presidency, was a Protec- tionist, and so was able to secure Pennsylvania for his party. In his first message to Congress, President Polk recognised the right of that body to levy customs duties, but advocated the limitation of the exercise of this power to revenue duties only. In December, 1845, his Secretary of the Treasury, Walker, presented to Congress a lengthy report on the tariff, which was simply an elaborate 1 The defeat of the Whigs was due in part at least to the abstension of the an ti-slavery party, who threw away their votes on an independent candidate of their own. WALKER'S REPORT 185 argument for Free Trade. 1 After expressing doubts as to the constitutional validity of protective duties, the Secretary proceeds to argue against them on economic grounds ; and some passages from the Report may be quoted as illustrating his general line of argument. He wrote : "At least two-thirds of the taxes imposed by the present tariff are paid not into the Treasury, but to the protected classes. The revenue from imports last year exceeded twenty-seven millions of dollars. This in itself is a heavy tax ; but the whole tax imposed upon the people by the present tariff is not less than eighty-one millions of dollars of which twenty-seven millions are paid to the Government upon the imports and fifty -four millions to the protected classes in enhanced prices of similar domestic articles. " The occasional fall in prices of some articles after a tariff is no proof that this was the effect of the tariff; because from improved machinery, diminished prices of the raw material, or other causes, prices may fall even after a tariff, but they would hi such cases have fallen even more but for the tariff. The truest comparison is between the present price of the same article at home and abroad ; and to the extent that the price is lower in the foreign market than in our own, the duty, if equal to the difference, must to that extent enhance the price, and in the same ratio with the lower duty. 1 Full text ill Taussig, State Papers. 186 DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES "An appeal has been made to the poor by the friends of protection, on the ground that it augments the wages of labour. In reply it is contended that the wages of labour have not augmented since the tariff of 1842, and that in some cases they have diminished. 1 ... A pro- tective tariff is a question regarding the enhance- ment of the profits of capital. That is its object, and not to augment the wages of labour, which would reduce those profits. It is a question of percentage, and is to decide whether money vested in our manufactures shall by special legislation yield a profit of 10, 20, or 30 per cent., or whether it shall remain satisfied with a dividend equal to that accruing from the same capital invested in agriculture, commerce, or navigation. "The tariff is thus a double benefit to the manufacturer and a double loss to the farmer and planter a benefit to the former in nearly a monopoly of the home market and in enhanced prices of his fabrics ; and a loss to the latter in the payment of those high prices and a total or partial exclusion from the foreign market. The true question is whether the farmer and planter shall to a great extent supply our people with cheap manufactures purchased abroad with their agricul- tural products, or whether this exchange shall be forbidden by high duties on such manufactures, and their supply thrown as a monopoly, at large 1 There seems to be no adequate evidence for this statement of the Secretary. TARIFF ACT OF 1846 187 prices, by high tariffs, into the hands of our own manufacturers. " Let our commerce be as free as our political institutions. Let us, with revenue duties only, open our ports to all the world ; and nation after nation will soon follow our example. If we reduce our tariff the party opposed to the corn laws of England would soon prevail and admit all our agricultural products at all times freely into her ports in exchange for her exports. And if England would now repeal her duties upon our wheat, flour, Indian corn, and other agricultural products, our own restrictive system would certainly be doomed to overthrow." * Proceeding from these principles, the Secretary advocated duties for revenue purposes only, with the imposition of maximum rates on luxuries, the abolition of all minimums and all specific duties, and the substitution of ad valorem rates. The result of this policy of the President and his advisers was the Tariff Act of 1846, adopted after only a short, though at times exciting, parlia- mentary struggle. All minimums and specific duties were abolished, and commodities were divided into a number of classes with duties rang- ing from 5 per cent, to 40 per cent., and in the 1 Bolles (ii. pp. 449-50) speaks of the British manufacturers "having zealously laboured for Folk's election, and contributed munificently to that end." He alleges that large sums of money were subscribed in England and expended on behalf of Folk's candidature in the United States. Elsewhere (p. 452) he speaks of the tariff of 1846 as "sponsored by the English nation." No satisfactory evidence for these statements is offered. 188 DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES one case of brandy and spirits to 100 per cent. ; there was also a class of free articles, the chief being tea, coffee, and iron and copper ore. Manu- factures of iron and other metals, wool, and woollens paid 30 per cent., as did manufactures of leather and glass ; cotton goods paid 25 per cent. On the whole, the duties were considerably lower than under the Act of 1842. The new tariff remained in force for eleven years with practically no alterations, and during that period the United States experienced a very rapid economic development. Population increased from 17,069,000 to 31,433,321 between 1840 and I860. 1 By 1850 the factory system was firmly developed, 2 but the population was still over- whelmingly agricultural ; in 1850, when the first reliable census of the United States was taken, only 12*5 per cent, of the population were living in urban areas of more than eight thousand inhabi- tants. 3 The quantity of corn grown rose from 592 million bushels in 1850 to 839 million bushels 1 Allowance must be made for increases of territory (e.g. in Texas and Mexico) between these dates. Between 1846 and 1857 the United States received more than three million immigrants (Stanwood, ii. p. 87). In each of the five years after 1849 the annual number was over 350,000. 2 " It was not until about 1840 that the factory method of manu- facture extended itself widely to miscellaneous industries, and began rapidly to force from the markets the handmade products with which every community had hitherto chiefly supplied itself. It seems probable that until about the year 1850, the bulk of general manufacturing done in the United States was carried on in the shop and the household, by the labour of the family or individual proprietors, with apprentice assistance" (Twelfth Census, vii. p. liii.). 3 As against 33 '1 in 1900. INDUSTRIAL DEVELOPMENT 189 in 1860, but so far the production was almost entirely for the home market. The total value of the manufactured products of the United States was estimated in 1850 at 1,019 million dollars, and in 1860 at 1,886 million. 1 A great stimulus had been given by the discovery of a number of new processes which came into general use from about 1845 onward. The year 1838 had witnessed the invention of Nasmyth's steam-hammer, and about 1840 anthracite coal began to be used for the pro- duction of iron ; in 1841 the power-loom for carpet- weaving was invented, and some years earlier the knitting-frame had been first worked by machinery. The amount of pig-iron manufactured by the an- thracite process was estimated in 1844 at 65,000 gross tons, and in 1856 at 394,000 nett tons. 2 The quantity of steel rails manufactured rose from 24,000 tons in 1849 to 184,000 in 1856. 3 The value of the American production of iron was esti- mated in 1850 at 60 million dollars, whilst imports amounted to only 16 million. 4 The number of cotton spindles employed in the United States was reckoned at 2,112,000 in 1840 and rose to 3,634,000 in 1850, and to 5,236,000 in 1860 ; whilst the value of the cotton goods exported averaged 4 million dollars between 1844 and 1849, and had doubled by 1859. 5 The woollen manufacturers 1 Twelfth Census, vol. vii. p. xlvii. 2 Taussig, p. 132. 3 Taussig, p. 134. 4 Bolles, ii. p. 457. 5 Taussig, pp. 141-2. Stanwood admits (ii. p. 90) that "the new tariff caused little injury to the cotton manufactures . . . the importation of cotton goods in 1846 was valued at $13,000,000 ; in 1855 it was only $15,500,000," 190 DEVELOPMENT OF THE UNITED STATES were hampered by the duty of 30 per cent, on raw wool, and there was little advance in the production of woollens of the best quality ; but in the coarser goods there was distinct progress, and the census figures give the value of the products of the woollen manufacture as 20 million dollars in 1840. 43-5 million in 1850, and 61 -9 million in I860. 1 The foreign trade of the United States increased enormously. The following table gives the figures for imports and exports of merchandise from 1847 to 1857, when another alteration in the tariff was made : Year. Imports. Exports. $ 63(E1188s4)476D A 000 "734 539