'- ^ jv_& ,U I y tfria&jfecg&fe5iate8^ moerstttt of d^ 4 4 California * POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS DURING THE PELOPONNESIAN WAR. HonDcm : C. J. CLAY and SONS, CAMBRIDGE UNIVEESITY PRESS WAREHOUSE, AVE MARIA LANE. (JTambritige: DEIGHTON, BELL AND CO. 3Uijifl: F. A. BROCKHAUS. Cambtitijje $tetorfraI aEssaps. $.0. I POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS DURING THE PELOPONNESIAN WAR BY L. WHIBLEY, M.A., FELLOW OF. PEMBROKE COLLEGE, CAMBRIDGE. PRINCE CONSORT DISSERTATION, 1888. SECOND EDITION eambntfge: N ^i22^ AT THE UNIVERSITY PRESS, ii [All Rights reserved.] ^ &* ^v Deckels PRINTED BY C. J. CLAY, M.A. AND SONS, AT THE UNIVERSITY PRESS. PKEFACE TO THE SECOND EDITION. npHE following dissertation was published at the beginning of this year in accordance with the terms under which the Prince Consort Prize is awarded. In preparing the second edition I have made few changes of importance. The subject was originally chosen by myself and approved by the Adjudicators. The purpose I have kept in view is to describe the state of politics and political parties in Athens, without discussing the separate and successive events of political history. Certain questions, which do not directly bear on the history of politics, are treated at some length, either on account of the intrinsic interest of those questions or on account of the obscurity in which they are involved. A list of the chief modern historians whose works I have consulted is prefixed ; I have also quoted in the notes the source from which im- 109423 VI PREFACE. portant suggestions or conclusions have been derived. In particular I wish to acknowledge how much I am indebted to Dr Beloch, whose work "Die attische Politik seit Perikles " contains a most able discussion of the political life of Athens. In preparing my dissertation for publication I had the advantage of many criticisms and sugges- tions from Mr R. A. Neil of Pembroke College, to whom I offer my heartiest thanks. L. WHIBLEY. Pembroke College, Cambbidge, November, 1889. CONTENTS. PAGE Introduction 1 CHAPTER I. The Athenian Constitution and Empire . . . 14 CHAPTER II. Division and Composition of Parties .... 35 CHAPTER III. Parties in detail. Their Organization and Policy . 47 CHAPTER IV. Parties in relation to the War. Party Government in Athens 104 Index 135 LIST OF THE CHIEF MODERN WORKS QUOTED AND CONSULTED. Beloch (J.), Die attische Politik seit Perikles. Die Bevolkerung der griechisch-romischen Welt. Zur Finanzgeschichte Athens (in the Rheinisches Museum, xxxix. 1884). Bockh (A.), Die Staatshaushaltung der Athener (Dritte Auflage herausgegebeu von Max Frankel). Buchsenschiitz (B.), Besitz und Erwerb im griechischen Alterthume. Curtius (E.), The History of Greece (translated by A. W. Ward). Droysen (J. G.), Bemerkungen iiber die attischen Strategen (in Hermes, ix). Frankel (M.), Die attischen Geschworenengerichte. Freese (W. L.), Der Parteikampf der Reichen und der Armen in Athen. Gilbert (G.), Beitrage zur innern Geschichte Athens im Zeit- alter des peloponnesischen Krieges. Handbuch der griechischen Staats-alterthiiiner. Erster Band. Grote (G.), A History of Greece (the edition of 1870 in 12 volumes). Hertzberg (G. F), Alkibiades. KirchhofF(A.), De Republica Atheniensi (in the Abhandlungen der k. Pr. Akademie, Berlin 1878). Kohler (U.), Urkunden und Untersuchungen zur Geschichte des delisch-attischen Bundes (ib. 1869). Muller-Strubing (H.), Aristophanes und die historische Kritik. Der Staat der Athener (in Philologus, Supplement- band iv.). Oncken (W.), Athen und Hellas. Zweiter Band. Scheibe (K. F.), Die oligarchische Umwalzung zu Athen am Ende des peloponnesischen Krieges. Vischer (W.), Kleine Schriften. Erster Band. Wilamowitz-Mollendorff* (U. von), Philologische Untersu- chungen i., Aus Kydathen. UNiVtkotTY OF INTRODUCTION. In the history of Athens the period of the Pelo- The period ponnesian war deserves and admits of special atten- ^^ tion. Not only have we fuller materials, scanty as nesian these are, for this epoch than for any other part war ' of Athenian history, but the period has a unity and an interest of its own. The years before are differentiated by the ascendency of Pericles, which overshadowed the ordinary forces of politics; the years succeeding 404 show us Athens completely transformed by the struggles and sufferings she had gone through; and finally the war itself was of critical and decisive importance, for all states of Greece were involved in it 1 , and the history of Athens is for the time not the history of a single commonwealth but broadens into the history of all Greece. Herein lies the historical importance of the period, and on this account the political movements, the composition and organization of parties, the subjects on which they were divided, and the policy they pursued possess an interest greater than usually attaches to political history. 1 Thuc. i. 1, emphasizes its importance in this respect. W. 1 2 INTRODUCTION. Inade- But if the study of Athenian politics in this bUuofthe P er id has special importance, it has also special original difficulties. The original authorities for political ties. events are very inadequate, and this deficiency of original materials has led to the multiplication of modern works, since the absence of certain informa- tion leaves a wide field to be filled up according to the views of individual writers. Hence the most widely divergent and even contradictory theories find supporters, and between these theories it is some- times impossible to decide. Our investigations often fail to attain to any positive result, and many ques- tions remain in the realm of complete uncertainty or at best of mere probability. Besides the deficiency of available materials there is another general characteristic of the original authorities which must not be left out of view. The bias, which must have influenced them in writing on political events, is variously estimated, and this is largely responsible for the differences of modern writers. Oldviewof The old school of historians represented by Bockh fomcs an and K - F - Hermann, and caricatured by Mitford, accepting without question the blame cast on the democracy by ancient writers, and in some cases intensifying it, passed on it a verdict almost wholly unfavourable. While Pericles obtained from most of this school almost more than his due meed of praise, the people he had led and those leaders who followed in his footsteps were visited with condemnation. The people as well as the demagogues lacked every political virtue and committed every political fault. INTRODUCTION. 3 Grote employed a new method, which led to new Grote and conclusions. No contemporary authority must be writers. implicitly trusted without allowing for the political sympathies and antipathies he entertained. This critical treatment threw a new light on political questions, and led to a revision of the former verdict. Conclusions favourable to democracy were deduced, conclusions which were coloured by Grote's own enthusiasm. The effect of his work has been per- manent, no later historian has been able to dis- regard it: many have accepted his views and ex- tended their application 1 ; others have disagreed with many of his conclusions, but have had to justify their dissent by sounder arguments than had been hitherto accepted. The present tendency leans to a more moderate estimate of Athenian democracy, less unfavourable than that of the early school, but not so enthusiastic as that of Grote 2 . The uncertainty of our conclusions on political Bias of subjects, which is due to the inadequacy and bias of \^ 01 ?Hi es the original authorities, requires us to review those against de- authorities, with especial reference to these two points. At the outset it must be admitted that they are ^ in the main unfavourable to the democracy 3 . Our histories all come from one side, and scarcely give us more than half the truth ; at best the leading democrats have to be whitewashed 4 , and it is im- 1 e.g. Oncken, and in the main Miiller-Striibing. 2 Beloch and Gilbert are representatives of this tendency. 3 This is true not only of the historians but of the poets and philosophers, such as Aristophanes, Euripides, Plato and Socrates. 4 As Cleon has been by Grote. Oncken, Athen und Hellas, ii. 12 dides. 4 INTRODUCTION. possible to realize how far we should have to revise our conclusions, if any work written from the demo- cratic standpoint had come down to us. Thucy- Of all authorities Thucydides is by far the most important, but this is because the other authorities are so lamentably meagre. Thucydides was not writing the history of a period, but of an event, the Peloponnesian war. He carefully avoids home politics 1 , and leaves out of view all subjects which were not more or less closely connected with the causes and progress of the war. Hence, except in the eighth book, we get but little light on politics from Thucydides, and Muller-Strubing 2 is justified in asking "Is there another representation of the history of a period, written by an able, well in- structed contemporary, from which we get so little definite information on constitutional development, political party struggles, the motives of the events described, intellectual movements or the inner life of the people?" p. 205, says that the only reference to him in ancient writers which is not unfavourable is in Plut. Praec. reip. ger. 13. To this we may perhaps add Dem. 40, 25, where he is referred to without depreciation or apology as an eminent general. 1 Among important events not mentioned by Thucydides are the raising of the tribute in 425, the raising of the dicast's fee, the ostracism of Hyperbolus (only incidentally referred to at a later date). His account of affairs after the mutilation of the Hermae is very confused, and his description of the measures taken after the Sicilian expedition is exceedingly indefinite. 2 Aristophanes, p. 386. It is true that the speeches in Thu- cydides, whatever view be taken of their authenticity, throw great light on the political ideas Of his time; but even when he does describe some important debate, he does not usually distinguish the political parties by name. INTRODUCTION. 5 We are on more dangerous ground in discussing the bias of Thucydides: with some writers it has been the fashion to accept everything that Thucy- dides wrote, almost as if he were verbally inspired ; but even in his case personal prejudice must have had an unconscious effect 1 . His known aristocratic sympathies and his condemnation by the democracy are sufficient to account for his bias, which appears in his favourable judgment of Antiphon 2 , compared with his description of Hyperbolus 3 , as well as in the severe condemnation of Cleon 4 , which is not justified by his own account of that demagogue. As Oncken 5 says, we may implicitly trust Thucydides for statements of fact, but must exercise our own judgment in criticizing his comments on events. Xenophon takes up the history where Thucydides Xenophon. leaves off. He gives a full account of the trial of the generals in 406 and of the break-up of the rule of the Thirty, but both accounts are coloured by the most extreme prejudice ; and his contributions to the history of politics (and there are scarcely more than these) are as far below those of Thucydides, as he himself is inferior as an historian. Aristophanes is of far greater importance, but we Aristo- get little more from him than isolated references to p nes ' 1 A. Schmidt quoted by Muller-Striibing, ib. p. 482, says, "The man who thinks Thucydides impartial is in error. Theopompus' partiality was gross and evident, but Thucydides' is so carefully concealed, that we can only discover it with immense trouble and luck." 2 viii. 68. 3 viii. 73. 4 He sums up his career in v. 16, but he never mentions him without some unfavourable description, iii. 36, iv. 28, 39. 5 Athen und Hellas, ii. p. 231. 6 INTRODUCTION. single characters or events. Even these must be received with great caution. His political views made him an opponent of the extreme democrats, and the antagonism was embittered by personal feel- ing, for we are told of at least three occasions, on which Cleon attacked the poet or his representative 1 . But apart from his political prejudices, he was, as a comic poet, not bound by any canons of historical truth*. In his representation of public men Aristo- phanes employs paradox as frequently as exaggera- tion. Hence there are many passages in which we must interpret him by contraries; in particular I think that this interpretation serves to explain many details of Cleon's character in " the Knights." His treat- It has been pointed out 3 that Cleon, as he appears ment of j n Aristophanes, differs essentially from the picture that we have of him in Thucydides. For the passionate orator, overawing the people, who appears in the pages of the historian, the poet has substituted a cringing flatterer and servant of the Demos. This opposition can be traced in detail throughout the play. Thus Cleon is charged with neglect of military duty (dcTTparelaY, a reproach appropriate enough in Cleon's mouth against Nicias, but absurd as applied to the victor of Pylus : he is charged with plotting with the Spartans 5 , another paradox, when we re- member that in the year before he had objected to 1 The first three plays of Aristophanes were brought out in the name of Callistratus, against whom, therefore, Cleon's first attack must have been directed. Muller-Strubing, ib. p. 72. 2 See Muller-Strubing, ib. pp. 3 and 5. 3 By Oncken, ib. p. 226. 4 443. 5 465. INTRODUCTION. 7 treating with them at all : again he is charged with receiving bribes from Mytilene 1 , an impossibility when we remember the sentiments Thucydides puts into his mouth in the debate on the treatment of Lesbos, but a charge actually made by Cleon against his opponents 2 : lastly with advocating peace 3 . When we consider that many of these charges have been laboriously explained by scholiasts, both ancient and modern, as referring to actual incidents in Cleon's career, it is worth while pointing out that the poet is simply turning against Cleon charges which the demagogue constantly brought against his opponents/^ These gained their piquancy from their very in- appropriateness to him, and we may conclude that we have here to deal not with exaggeration but with paradox. Aristophanes' treatment of public men may be His treat- tested in cases where we have other evidence. He p^.^ condemns Pericles 4 , though not so severely as he does Cleon ; but every one now rejects his authority in the case of Pericles, because that statesman is redeemed by the testimony of Thucydides 5 . It is 1 834. 2 Thuc. iii. 38. 3 669. 4 See passages quoted in the next note. In Vesp. 715, which apparently refers to Pericles, no distinction is drawn between him and the other demagogues; but in Eq. 191, 283 he is favourably contrasted with Cleon. 6 Hermann, Staatsalterthumer, 164, is strikingly illogical. After quoting Aristophanes (Ach. 525, Pax 605) on Pericles, he admits " it would be partial to ascribe such views to Pericles," but immediately afterwards he gives an unfavourable description of the later demagogues, the details of which are unsupported except by isolated references to Aristophanes. tion. 8 INTRODUCTION. obvious that Aristophanes' treatment of Cleon is of no more value, as a piece of impartial evidence. From these reasons it will be seen that it is necessary to use Aristophanes for historical purposes with the utmost care. We may accept the rule laid down by Yischer 1 " For the judgment of individual character, for the discovery of single facts, we must regard the old comedy as an entirely unreliable authority, which can only be justified in connection with other sources, and not always then." The work A valuable contribution to our knowledge of the Athenian Athenian democracy and empire, as well as a most Constitu- trenchant criticism of it, is contained in the work on the Athenian Constitution, which was for a long time ascribed to Xenophon. The view that it came from his pen is now generally given up, and although the authorship cannot be determined, there is good reason for fixing the date at which it was produced between 424 and 41 4 2 . It has, therefore, exceptional value from the fact that it was written at a time before the Athenian power had suffered any grave diminution, and lacks the morbid sense of its defects, which were subsequently regarded as the causes of disaster. 1 Kleine Schriften, i. p. 184. 2 Kirchhoff (Abhand. der Akad. Ber. 1878, pp. 124), ascribes it to the former date, as he thinks it must have been written before Brasidas' march to Thrace. Miiller-Strubing (Philologus, Supplementband iv. p. 74), dismissing this consideration, thinks 415 the most likely date. He sees in the work the attempt of an extreme oligarch to combine the different sections of the oligar- chical party in a common policy against the constitution. He thinks the tone of the work is consistent with what we know of Phrynichus, whom he concludes to be the author. INTRODUCTION. V Throughout the work there is a contrast between The what the author regards as the ideally best con-^^ nt stitution 1 oligarchy, and the constitution which of the . writer. Athens had adopted democracy. To him oligarchs are ^prjo-Toi 2 , democrats Trovrjpol, and the Athenian constitution favours the base at the expense of the good. His fondness for oligarchy is carried so far that in his eyes the possession of oligarchic sym- pathies is equivalent to virtue and wisdom 3 , men of his party are ol /3e\Tio~TOL, in all states to jBekTLo-rov is ivavrlov rfj SrjfjLOfcpaTLq 4 ', and evvofxia 5 according to his standard would involve the over- throw of democracy and the enslavement of the people. These quotations will suffice to show the extreme and undisguised prejudice, which he en- tertains for oligarchy, and which deprives his work of all claim to judicial criticism ; but he also shows clearly enough that granting the imperfections of democracy, the Athenians pursue the end most desirable for 6 themselves, i.e. to be free and rule 7 , and take the best means to preserve the con- stitution 8 . I have discussed the standpoint of the writer at some length, because I shall have occasion to refer to his opinions again, and it will be useful to remember then that he is no friend to the democracy. 1 i. 8. 2 i. 1. These terms jSArtorot, xPVvtoI, rrownpoi are all used in their quasi-political sense. 3 i. 7. 4 i. 5. 5 i. 9. 6 i. 6. b...irov7)pbs O-evplfficet rb ayadbv curry re koI roh bfiolois avr$. 7 i. 8. 8 i. 1. 10 INTRODUCTION. Lysias and Andocides. Aristotle, Plutarch and Diodorus. Inscrip- tions. The other authorities may be briefly dismissed. Lysias and Andocides give us a certain amount of information on political events, the latter being especially useful for the years 415, 410, 404-3. Coming to authors who were not contemporary, we find Aristotle's contributions of no very definite value. Most of his statements are general, and even when he evidently has Athens in view, his criticism is often more appropriate to his own age than to the earlier period 1 . Plutarch and Diodorus add little to our knowledge ; we are indebted to them for some information, which they derived from authors, whose works are now no longer extant. Of these the most important were Ephorus and Theopompus. The difficulty of criticism is increased, when we get the authorities only at second hand. I have now discussed the materials of direct historical importance, with the exception of inscrip- tions. On constitutional points these often give us valuable information, but they are far from filling up the deficiencies of our authors. I have endea- voured to show that our only extant historians, Thucydides and Xenophon, give us absolutely no information on many political events, so that we often have to rely on non-historical writers, orators, philosophers and poets ; and that even from the sum of all these materials we cannot get a continu- ous history of politics. 1 Aristotle was not favourable to extreme democracy (Pol. 1312 b, 5). His ideal was a [xtari iroKireia and according to Plutarch (Nic. 2) his favourite statesmen were Thucydides, Nicias and Theramenes, men of moderate views. INTRODUCTION. 11 The consequence is that politics in Athens ap- No cow- pear to us in a series of dissolving views : some few t l nuous r o history of events can be clearly understood, but we are generally politics. left to our own resources for the causes and con- sequences of them. It is the same with the actors ^ on the political stage. Some few men stand out vividly before us ; Thucydides and Aristophanes together enable us to realize Pericles, Cleon and Nicias : but other characters must have played a part of hardly less importance, and they appear to us only once or in one scene. To take an example, what part did Diodotus take in Athenian politics ? We may conclude from his one appearance in Thucydides, that he was not only a statesman of ability but in all probability the leader of the moderate party at this juncture 1 , but we never hear of him again. Who was Thudippus who proposed the most important financial measure in this period, the increase of the tribute in 425 2 ? We only know of his existence from the inscription containing his proposal, and yet he must have been a prominent member of his party to be entrusted with so important a duty. The case is the same with Demostratus 3 who proposed the enrolment of forces for the Sicilian expedition, with Thessalus 4 who prosecuted Alcibiades, and with many others. Nor is our knowledge of institutions and events Uncer- more satisfactory. The absence of any account of^^ tional 1 Thuc. iii. 41 ff. The words ocnrep Kal iv rrj irpoTtpq. tKKK-qaiq. points. avrtXeye k.t.X. point to his having taken the lead on this occasion. 2 C. I. A. i. 37. 3 Ar. Lysist. 391. 4 Plut. Ale. 22. 12 INTRODUCTION. the constitution at this period admits of the widest difference of opinion on constitutional points. To take a few instances: some historians have developed a theory of the constitution in which the premier- ship is held by a state treasurer 1 , whom other autho- rities will not allow to exist ; another historian 2 has argued with great ability that there was absolutely no change in the laws between 460 and 411, and this theory, while it lacks sufficient confirmation to be accepted, cannot be satisfactorily disproved. These are typical cases, and it would be easy to cite many others, in which directly contradictory opinions are maintained between which it is impossible to decide 3 . Uncer- This uncertainty and difference of opinion are IhTmb'ect e( l ua % manifest on the subject of political parties. of political Original authorities give us little definite informa- par ies. ^^ Qn ^ e division of parties, on their policy, or on the political standing of prominent men. Hence there results a great confusion of ideas ; some modern historians talk of two parties, others of three ; and the same men are variously described as aristocrats, oligarchs and democrats. It is only possible to ob- 1 Miiller-Strubing's great theory of the ra/nlas tt}s koivtjs Trpoad- dov. Bockh, i. p. 200, regarded this officer as the head of Athenian finance. Most historians believe that this office was not instituted before Euclides. 2 Wilamowitz, Aus Kydathen, p. 52, thinks that there was no process of legislation in this period. 3 Some are discussed below, see pp. 20, 64 n. 2, 69 n. 1, 122 n. 1. In particular we have no evidence to determine whether institutions, known to exist in the fourth century, were part of the constitution before the archonship of Euclides, e.g. the po/ho- dtrai and iinxeipoTovla. INTRODUCTION. 13 tain more definite conceptions by realizing as far as possible the conditions of political life at Athens, and the motives of political action ; on this account it is necessary to discuss the Athenian constitution and the Athenian empire in so far as they directly concern the study of politics, while we may neglect details indifferent to this purpose. CHAPTER I. The Athenian Constitution and Empire. Necessity The Athenian constitution was an extreme de- %acyin mocra cy, and it was impossible that it should be Athens. otherwise. The internal history of Athens, the policy of her statesmen, the influence of events in Greece, contributed to make this the only form of government possible, while it was certainly the only form which corresponded to her highest interests. Aristotle 1 admits that in a large city any other ^ibrm of constitution than democracy is an anomaly. The history of Athens in the fifth century is the history of her rise as a commercial and maritime power, and it is unnecessary to argue that in Greece there was a close connection between democracy and sea power and trade 2 . This tendency, which was at first natural, was fostered by her statesmen ; Pericles and Themistocles directed their efforts to make Athens exclusively a sea power, and the attention paid to her fleet and 1 Pol. 1286 b, 20, e7re 5 /cat /xel^ovs elvai avfx^^rjKe ras 7r6Xeis icrcos ovd pfydiov ti yiveadai irokiTeiav ertpav irapb, drj/jLOKpariav. 2 See Muller-Striibing, Aristophanes, p. 82. Cf. Aristot. ib. 1304 a, 22, 6 vclvtikos 6'xXos ac.t.X. Kesp. Ath. i. 2. THE ATHENIAN CONSTITUTION AND EMPIRE. 15 fortifications rendered the city almost an island 1 . While internal circumstances demanded this con- stitution, the position of Athens in Greece had an equally strong influence in this direction. I shall endeavour to prove below that the confederacy of which Athens was the head was held together by community of democratic feeling and interest, and \^~ that on this account democracy was necessary to maintain the alliance. We see in the history of this period that democracy was for Athens a state of stable equilibrium ; any disturbance of this could be only temporary and was always followed by a return to the former state. It was impossible even to introduce a less extreme form of democracy ; a moderate democracy is only possible as a step in development, but cannot be artificially created from an extreme democracy 2 . The Athenian constitution rested on the two Principles principles of freedom and equality 3 . Speech and {-fc^ % opinion were free, and all citizens were equal before mocracy. the law. From this equality of the citizens it resulted 1 Eesp. Ath. ii. 14. Thuc. i. 143, Attica falls short of being an island in only one particular the liability to ravages. 2 Eesp. Ath. iii. 8, 9. The lines of Aristophanes referring to Alcibiades (Ranae 1431) may be referred appropriately enough to such a constitution, ov XPV Xtovros (TKTjfivov kv iroXei rptyeiv, rjv 5' eKTpa ^ is n0 l ess often applied to the presidents of the Helle- notamiae, who constantly change." The change of presidents within this latter board is established by C. I. A. i. 188, in which five different names occur followed by the words koL ^vvdpxovres. The reason however for the* change of presidents on a board entrusted with the control of the revenue of the state is obvious ; and the fact that we do not find a change of presidents similarly attested in the case of the generals, is negative evidence that one man held that position for a year. 1 Thus Pericles seems to have been entrusted with full powers on more than one occasion (Thuc. ii. 22, 55). Similarly the conduct of Nicias in connection with the command at Pylos can only be explained on the theory that he was in supreme control of military affairs (Thuc. iv. 27, 42). See Droysen and Beloch, 1. c. 2 In Thuc. ii. 31 the Athenians go out vavdrjfiei nepiKXtovs arpaTryyovvTos ; the other generals must have gone too. In v. 52 Alcibiades leads a large force to the Peloponnesus, but he was probably not the only general. The posi- tion of Athens as a power in Greece. 24 POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS. evidence will be enough perhaps to prove that he was also so de jure 1 , import- , If, then, we may assume the existence of such a position \ president, he must have been the most important man in the state. In dignity he was formally raised above all other citizens, he was practically "President of the Republic." In power he was the head of the most important board of magistrates, and if we may compare this board to a modern cabinet, we may look upon him as a prime minister. The preemi- nence of this position made it the highest prize in the state, and it had great influence on politics. There is one other subject which cannot be passed over, the position of Athens as a power in Greece. To discuss the division of parties we must know the subjects on which they were divided, and as during the period of the Peloponnesian war very few ques- tions of home policy arose, and foreign affairs were all- important, it is necessary to understand the relation in which Athens stood to the other powers of Greece, in order to realize the attitude of parties to the dif- ferent questions of foreign policy. Athens and Sparta divided between them the Empire of Greece. Athens was preeminently a sea power. She was the mistress and leader of the sea states, as Sparta was of the land powers. Any pretensions she had to land empire she renounced in 445, and by this concession she obtained the recog- 1 Gilbert (Beitrage, pp. 38, ff.) rejects the theory of a irp^ravis: he believes that in all cases where generals have superior authority they had been appointed avTotcparopes. It is unreasonable to sup- pose that this extraordinary power was conferred so often. See Beloch, Att. Pol. pp. 2856. THE ATHENIAN CONSTITUTION AND EMPIRE. 25 nition of her dominion of the sea. Here she was absolute : the sea was regarded as part of her terri- tory, and as late as 419 it was regarded as a violation of her right for ships of war to cross it without her consent 1 . At the beginning of the war all the sea states with few exceptions were her subjects or allies 2 . This alliance was the source of her power. The Athens and relation of Athens to the confederacy of Delos had L^racv passed from that of leadership to that of dominion 3 ; of Delos. the original allies had with few exceptions become subjects 4 . This process was the inevitable result of circum- stances. If the league was to continue at all, the strongest power was bound to come to the front and the weaker states to renounce their independence 5 . To maintain the efficiency of the league for its original purposes it was necessary to retain unwilling members, forbid retirement and punish revolt 6 . For the same 1 Thuc. v. 56, the Argives complain to the Athenians, 6'n, yey pa /j. fjiivov ev reus o-rrovdcus 5ia rrjs eavrQv ckcuttovs fx-q idv TToXe/jdovs dutvcu, idaeiav Kara OdXacraav TrapairKevaai.. The , Athenians regarded this action of the Lacedaemonians as a violation of their alliance. The toll levied by the Athenians in the Bosporus is another instance of the same claim on the part of Athens to the exclusive control of the sea. 2 All the eastern colonies of Greece, either on the islands or on the coast at a distance from Central Greece (e.g. Macedonia, Thrace, and Asia Minor) were members of the alliance. 3 The rjyefjLovia had without design on her part become an apxh- See Grote, v. pp. 146152, cf. Thuc. i. 9799. 4 The members of the confederacy originally tyfi/xaxoi, were now vttt)kooi; Thucydides calls them 5ov\oi. See Gilbert, Hand- buch, i. pp. 392 and 405, and Thuc. i. 98, iii. 10, vi. 76. 5 See Muller-Striibing, Aristophanes, pp. 81 2. 6 Grote, v. 154. "The confederacy was perpetual and peremp- tory, not allowing retirement or evasion." 26 POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS. reason it was a matter of military expediency to strengthen the weak spots in the frontier of the league, to fill up the gaps, and to constrain indepen- dent and neutral states to join against their will, that they might not offer a place of vantage to the foe. The want of one link might weaken or destroy the 7 whole chain. It was a question of self-preservation 1 ; and the Athenians were only carrying this theory to a logical conclusion in seeking to win Thera and Melos. This is the argument underlying the Melian debate, although the selfishness of the policy is there presented with an exaggeration of brutality, that probably surpassed the truth 2 . The relation of Athens to her subjects was based on the power of the stronger, and perhaps justified the title of rvpavvk, which was employed by both friends and enemies to describe it 8 . Control of Athens alone controlled the policy and adminis- Athens tered the affairs of the league. The members were over the m , affairs of subject to a direct tax, assessed by Athens, paid into her treasury, and administered by her officers. Athens also interfered to a considerable extent with the constitution of some of the states 4 , watched over 1 Thuc. vi. 83, irapovpapxoi 2 , and required all lawsuits of importance to be settled in the Athenian courts. The subjection of the allies put Athenian power on an artificial basis, for it was opposed to the Gre- cian ideal of autonomy for each single state 3 . This violation of Greek national feeling, combined with the practical hardships of tribute and compulsory jurisdiction, naturally created enemies for Athens in the subject states ; but it will appear from a con- sideration of the circumstances that the discontented \y were a comparatively small body, and that the bulk of the allies were sincerely attached to the Athenian alliance. The tribute was chiefly irksome from the method Tribute, in which it was raised and administered ; a common fund was a necessity, and the allies purchased by their contributions immunity from service which was undertaken by Athens. The amount of these * contributions was never excessive, but the burden of it bore most heavily on the rich men 4 and they , alone were offended. possibly in some of the subject states (Samos, according to Grote's theory, vii. p. 218, n. 2). 1 These were extraordinary officers, see Wilamowitz, Aus Kydathen, p. 16 and p. 75. Wilamowitz, ib. p. 73. 3 It was with a view to this feeling that Sparta professed to undertake ttjv iXevdtpwaiv rrjs 'EXXaSos. The enslavement of the Athenian allies and the possible subjection of the rest of Greece are prominently brought forward by the enemies of Athens. Cf. Thuc. i. 68, 122. 4 It is probable that in most states it was assessed on a graduated scale like the Athenian elj 5' ivavrlovs diroXXOovaiv tv rots 8iicav vtt7)k6u)i>). Chios forms an exception to this, as it remained faith- ful till 412, even under an oligarchy; but the revolt then proceeded from the oligarchs. 2 Thuc. i. 143, ra twv ^vmaolxuv 86ev lax^ojxev. iii. 13, 8l r\v i) 'Atti/o7 o>0eXeirai. iii. 46, iffx^ofiev 5 irpos roi>s rroXe/xlovs r<5e. 3 Bockh, i. p. 69. THE ATHENIAN CONSTITUTION AND EMPIRE. 33 to maintain the alliance. The war was forced on Athens by Sparta with a view to break up the alliance, and the main cause of it was the jealousy felt by Sparta for the growing power of Athens 1 . Other causes naturally contributed to it, and chief among these the antithesis between democracy and oligarchy, which had divided the states of Greece from the time that Athens first formed a counter alliance to Sparta 2 . Hence the war became in course of time a conflict of political principles ; com- munity of feeling and interest joined democrats on the one side against oligarchs on the other ; advan- tage was taken of internal differences 3 , and the area of the war became extended as states hitherto neutral entered on it in support of those with whom they were politically in sympathy. Consequently, as in the case of the Athenian confederacy, a change of constitution carried with it a change of side, and a change of side was usually accompanied by the over- throw of the existing constitution. This is well illustrated by the conduct of Argos, who joined the Athenian alliance, as a democratic state 4 , but with the rise of oligarchic feeling went over to Sparta, and soon established an oligarchy 5 . This government 1 Thucydides is careful to insist on every possible occasion that the real (as opposed to the pretended) cause of the war was Sparta's fear of the growth of the Athenian empire. See Thuc. i. 23, 33, 86, 88, 118, 140. 2 Cf. Isocr. Paneg. 16. Thuc. iii. 82. 3 Cf. the attack on Plataea, Thuc. ii. 2 ; on Boeotia, Thuc. iv. 76. See Vischer, Kleine Schriften, i. p. 78. 4 They regarded Athens as tt6\lv re ofylai CkoTip.La twv avdpwv ^aOvrdr-qv toix7]v refjLovaa TTJs 7r6\ews r6 ixkv dfjfiov rb 5' dXLyovs iroli] Plut. Per. 14. 38 POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS. time Pericles was supreme and above all parties, and during his life the opposition was hopelessly dis- organized. After his death, when political struggles were renewed, and party divisions again became pro- minent, we find the opposition to the democratic policy organized under the leadership of Nicias. The history of the succeeding years shows us a large body of men, combined under recognized leaders and following a consistent policy. This body may on these grounds be fairly re- garded as a political party in opposition to the demo- crats. Its members were, however, quite distinct from the oligarchs; they were not hostile to the constitution, / and though they may have criticized its defects, they I were not eager to change it ; they were men of moderate views opposed to the democratic policy. Three poli- We can therefore distinguish three political par- wrties ^ es > ^e two extremes of oligarchy and democracy and the intermediate section, corresponding to the modern divisions of right, left and centre. These political sections were not sharply divided; parties were more or less in solution and had a tendency to merge in one another. The oligarchs, especially, as they could not declare their aims, but pursued them secretly, attached themselves to whatever policy they thought would best advance them, and only on rare occasions organized themselves for a decisive effort. With these qualifications we may distinguish the / three parties 1 as (1) The democrats proper, or the democrats from conviction, shading off into (2) the 1 I am indebted to Dr Beloch (Att. Pol. p. 13) for the titles " democrats from conviction," and " opportunist democrats." \ DIVISION AND COMPOSITION OF PARTIES. 39 middle party, mainly composed of moderate or oppor- tunist democrats, but including also some moderate oligarchs, who serve as a link to (3) the oligarchs proper, opposed by conviction to democracy and eager to overthrow it, but not as . a party taking a prominent part in ordinary political life. Having settled the main lines of party division, Composi the subject, which naturally suggests itself for discus- par ties. sion, is the composition of the different parties, or the relation in which they stand to the different sections of the population considered from the point \ of view of wealth and occupation. I have argued that as a cause of division ques- \ tions of the day were of more importance than the permanent principles men entertained on the subject of the constitution. On this account we must de- termine w 7 hat policy was in accordance with the inte- rests of the different classes, before we can understand how the parties were composed. Generally speaking a man's political position is mainly determined by his class interests, and, in the case of Athens the importance of economic considerations has been gene- rally recognized. Thus Bockh 1 says, "the great war between aristocracy and democracy always going on in Greece was largely a war of possessors and non- possessors," while other writers 2 regard the conflict of \/ parties as nothing else than a war of rich against poor. 1 Bockh, i. p. 182. This too is Plato's description, (Hep. iv. 422 e). " Each city is composed of at least two cities, hostile to each other rich and poor." 2 This is the main argument of W. L. Freese in his book "Der Parteikampf der Reichen und der Armen in Athen " ; cf. Beloch, Att. Pol., pp. 1, 2. 40 POLITICAL PAKTIES IN ATHENS. Popula- In order to understand and apply this conclusion Attica. ** * s necessary to have a clear view of the population of Attica in its economic aspect. The total population at the beginning of the war may be regarded, at the most probable estimate, as about 250,000 1 , made up as follows: 35,000 citizens of full age, representing a total citizen population of about 105,000; 10,000 metoecs, who with their families amounted to about 30,000, and about 100,000 slaves. Agricuitu- Of the Athenian citizens at the beginning of the majority" war * ne g rea ter number lived in the country culti- vating their own farms. This fact we have on the explicit statement of Thucydides 2 , and there seems no reason to reject his statement, as we know that the land of Attica was very much divided. Not- withstanding the war, which must have had a disastrous effect on population and property, we are told that even in 403 out of a probable total of 20,000 citizens there were only 5000 who owned no land 3 . Of these landowners all did not live on their 1 This is the estimate of Beloch, Bevolkerung, p. 73, and is in sharp conflict with that of Bockh, which is double this number (i. p. 51). For a discussion of the grounds on which the former is based I would refer to Dr Beloch's work. To me his arguments appear conclusive. 2 ii. 14 and 16. 3 Dionysius in the argument to Lysias 23. It is somewhat difficult to believe that three-fourths of the population were even then possessed of landed property. Muller^Striibing (Philologus, Supplementband, iv. p. 62) thinks that the 5000 represented more than half the citizens, but the total of 20,000 has been accepted by Bockh, Biichsenschutz and Freese, as well as by Beloch in his examination of the population of Attica, ib. p. 99. DIVISION AND COMPOSITION OF PARTIES. 41 estates ; many of the richer men especially resided in the town, either leasing their property or having it worked by slaves 1 . From these considerations we may conclude that in spite of the commercial changes fostered by Themistocles and Pericles the class interested in agriculture must have formed a majority of the population. Of the rest of the citizens many of the richer men either were engaged personally in industry and com- merce or at least profited by them, in lending their capital at a high rate of interest ; but the bulk of the inhabitants of the town and the Piraeus must have been poor men, as much reduced to the necessity of manual labour 2 as the poor aliens and slaves, who with them formed the industrial class. Such was the division of classes according to\Distribu- occupation ; on the distribution of wealth we have'jj^^ not such definite information. At the beginning of the war there were about 15 to 16,000 Athenians of at least hoplite census, as opposed to 19 to / 20,000 Thetes 3 . The classes owning a substantial property formed therefore almost half the citizens ; but the Thetes must not all be considered as I poor men. Many owned small plots of land, which raised them above our standard of poverty 4 , and 1 Bockh, i. p. 53. 2 lb., i. p. 58 ; cf. Plato, Rep. viii. 565 a. 3 Beloch, ib. p. 70. In the use of the term Thetes, I have assumed that all property was taken into account in arranging the classes for the da V v P&mp fioipa. In Aristotle the ixiaoi. are both the middle class and the middle party. Pol. 1295 b. CHAPTER III. Parties in detail. Their Organization and Policy. 1. The Democratic Party. The first party to be considered is that of the Titles of democrats proper, the ' democrats from conviction,' &iff erent who are so called in contrast to the middle party, parties. the members of which, though for the most part democrats, formed a separate party. Some infor- mation of the way in which the democrats were regarded by their contemporaries may be obtained from the titles applied to them. As these titles were usually invented and employed by writers in oppo- sition to the democracy, the complimentary title was naturally chosen by the oligarchs, and the term of abuse applied to their opponents. The first and most common title of the democrats is neutral ; they are called 6 Brjfios 1 , i.e. the popular party, to ttXyjOos or ol iroXKoi, the numbers of the democrats appearing great in proportion to those of the 6\tyoL 1 These titles are so well known and occur so often that it is unnecessary to quote the evidence for their use. Freese, Partei- kampf der Reichen und der Armen, pp. 24 5, gives most of them. 48 POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS. Secondly, the oligarchs are frequently called tt\ov- crioiy Bvvarol, and though the term is not used as a party phrase Xenophon talks of 6 Brjfios as ol Trevrjres tcov itoXltouv 1 . A third class of names points to the contrast with respect to birth and culture. The oligarchs assumed the titles of tcaXol /cdyaOol, /3e\rcaToo, yvcopcfjbot, and above all of ^pijo-rol, while the demo- crats were styled irovrjpol, jio^Orjpol and the like 2 . 1 Xen. Mem. iv. 2, 37. Cf. Resp. Ath. i. 2, and Plut. Per. 7, where iroWol ko.1 TrivrjTes is opposed to 6\iyoi /cat ttXovo'iol. 2 The application of uncomplimentary terms to denote political opponents has always been frequent. Such terms, at first em- ployed in mere abuse, gradually obtain literary recognition and come into use as ordinary party titles. There is some significance in the words chosen to describe the Athenian democracy. The opposition of XPW 1 - an( ^ Trovypol occurs throughout the Respub- lica Atheniensium ; the author uses other words to describe parties (e.g. drjfxos, irtvrjTes, and Stj/jlotlkol are contrasted with yevvcuot and TrXotiaioi, i. 2), but none so frequently as irovr)pbs and its opposite. The use of irourjpbt in connection with the Athenian democracy is very general: see especially Thuc. viii. 47 (where Alcibiades uses TTovrjpia as synonymous with drj/xoKparia), Ar. Eccl. 176 (where the antithesis between xpvvrbs and wovrjpbs is brought out), and Eur. Supp. 243 (in which the poet refers to irovrjpol irpocrTaTai, a phrase which ocurs also in Ar. I.e.). In Aristot. Pol. 1294 a, 2 irovrjpo- Kpareiadcu is contrasted with apurroKpaTeiadcu. The word p.oxdrjpbs is not so frequent in a political sense, but it is found in several passages as a substitute for irovypos with exactly the same mean- ing. Thus in Ar. Eq. 1303, Thuc. viii. 73, Plut. Arist. 7, Nic. 11, it is employed to describe Hyperbolus, while in the same passages in Thuc. and Plut. Nic, in Plut. Ale. 13, and Ar. Pax 681 irov-ripbs is used of the same man. Similarly Xen. (Hell. i. 4. 13) in describing the prosecution of Alcibiades in 415 talks of ol /ao%- B-qporepa Xiyovres as having driven him out, an expression which recalls Thuc. vi. 89 (where Alcibiades speaks of those ol iirl rb\ irovypdrepa i^rjyov rbv 6'xXoj/). Cf. also Ar. Lys. 576, and Ran. 421, Aristot. Pol. 1320 a, 34 (/iox^pd drj^oKpaTia). The choice of these PARTIES IN DETAIL. 49 Separating from these titles the abusive associa- Democra- tions connected with them, they point to the fact ^K? y that the Brjfjuos was largely composed of the poorer composed classes, who were reduced to the necessity of manual classes. labour in agriculture or trade, and who could not afford the education and leisure considered essential by the rich. This inference is supported by the con- clusion arrived at in the last chapter that the demo- cratic party found its chief support in the poorer classes, although there were many of the middle and richer classes, especially among the merchants and manufacturers, who gave an enthusiastic alle- n giance to the democracy and its policy 1 ; in fact both the leading politicians and the leading gene- rals were usually men of some degree of wealth and often of birth, whose attachment to the demo- cracy, though it depended in part on the power and distinction conferred upon them 2 , was mainly a matter of conviction. The peasant farmers of small property, whose income ranked them with the poorer classes, must have been sincerely devoted to the democratic con- particular terms may possibly have had some connection with their original meaning of laborious (cf. Ar. Vesp. 466 irducjp irovrjpi), and the application of them may have arisen from the idea, common to the philosophy of the age, that manual labour was degrading in itself and fatal to a life of culture or political activity. Cf. Socra- tes in Aelian, Var. Hist. x. 14 (tj apyia ade\v Kal rrjv 6\r}v -rryopLovlav (cx^v. The passage of Teleclides, quoted by Plut. Per. 16, probably refers to this position of his. 3 Thuc. ii. 65, eyiyvero \6ycp [xtv brjpLOK parta, Zpyip d viro rov irpsjJTOV dvdpos a-pxh- 4 Cf. the panic in 415, Thuc. vi. 53, 60. 5 See Vischer, Kleine Schriften, p. 106 ; Thuc. vi. 15 talks of his rrapapofita. PARTIES IN DETAIL. 57 a virtue in Pericles, while he substituted for the pure and highminded patriotism of the latter a selfish ambition for his personal advancement 1 . The democratic party could alone enable him to His career. reach the goal before him, and on this account he attached himself to it. Of his early life we know little, but we may conclude that, in spite of his temporary attempt to outbid Nicias for the Spartan 7rpoj;evla 2 , he began public life as a democrat 3 . His anti-Spartan policy was based on democratic tradi- tions, and was urged in his own interests, as war would give him a chance of military distinction. He found himself thwarted by the influence of Nicias and by the even balance of parties in the state, and on this account he challenged ostracism. Fearing the result of this he combined with his chief political rival to get rid of Hyperbolus, who stood in his way as a competitor for the leadership of the demos. For a time his influence was diminished, and to recover his former position he advocated the Sicilian expedition, which would, if carried to a successful issue, have assured him not only overwhelming popularity, but the military position and prestige necessary for his purpose. In fear of such an issue, the extreme democrats under Androcles, and the oligarchs under Thessalus, combined to overthrow him. From 415 to 411 his plans were interrupted by his compulsory exile. After trying without success to establish his influence in Sparta and Persia by 1 Plut. Ale. 2, to (frikoveiKov nal to (pikoirpuTov. 2 Thuc. v. 43. 3 The evidence is collected in Beloch, Att. Pol. p. 50. Cf. especially Thuc. vi. 89. 58 POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS. services rendered against Athens, he made his recall the immediate object of his life. To secure this end he was not scrupulous about the means employed, and had no hesitation in working against the de- mocracy. For his fall had been mainly due to the democrats, and his return, while Androcles was chief demagogue, was impossible. On these grounds he initiated the oligarchic movement of 411, foreseeing that his opportunity would come, as it did, in the confusion caused by the revolution. He took this step however from no love for the oligarchs, from whom he broke as soon as possible, while they for their part saw clearly enough that he was a man " unfitted for oligarchy 1 ." Apparently the sincerity of his democratic pro- fessions was not doubted when he was recalled by the army at Samos 2 , and entrusted with supreme power 3 . His advocacy of the rule of the 5000 was entirely due to motives of expediency 4 , as it started a division in the ranks of the Four Hundred, which was the cause of their overthrow; and the restoration of full democracy in 410 was probably 1 Thuc. viii. 63. Cf. also 68, and 70 (the oligarchs do not recall the exiles because of Alcibiades). 2 Thuc. viii. 81. 3 Thuc. viii. 82, arpaT^ov e'i\ovTO...Kai rd irpdyfidra iravra dverldecrav. He had got the coveted position at Samos, and had now only to have it confirmed at Athens. 4 Thuc. viii. 86, diroKpivdjAevos 6'ti...toi>s fj.kv irevTaKtax 1 '^ ^ ov kwXijol dpxew. Some have thought on the strength of this pas- sage that his ideal was a moderate democracy. This evidence in itself is insufficient. Alcibiades found his chief support in the fleet ; and the fleet would have nothing to say to a limitation of the franchise. PARTIES IN DETAIL. 59 due to the fleet, in which Alcibiades' influence was paramount. After this he proceeded cautiously ; he wished to strengthen his claim on Athens by military services, before taking advantage of his recall from banish- ment. When he did return, he came as the deliverer of Athens and the hope of the future, and at last it seemed as if the long desired reward was to be his. He had apparently been elected Trpvravis rdov arparTjyoov 1 before his return, he now had full powers conferred on him (dvapprjOeU dirdvTwv yye- fjLwv avroKpdroop 2 ). With some classes he enjoyed an unbounded popularity 3 , and it only needed a continuance of popular favour and the successful conduct of the war on his part to give him a position in the state as strong as that of Pericles. But, before his power was firmly established, his enemies raised the charge that he was aiming at the tyranny, and this suspicion combined with his mismanagement of the war caused his final over- throw, and deprived Athens of the only man who of all her citizens might have effected her salvation. I have summarized Alcibiades' career, because I Aims of At cilyiciclss think the most satisfactory explanation of it is afforded by the supposition that he was striving to follow in Pericles' footsteps and establish a personal govern- ment on a constitutional basis. It is usually assumed that his aim throughout life was to overthrow the democracy and establish 1 See Beloch, Att. Pol. pp. 2867, for a discussion of this. 2 Xen. Hell. i. 4. 20, cf. Diod. xiii. 67, Plut. Ale. 3*3. 3 Plut. Ale. 34 and 35. magogues. 60 POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS. himself as tyrant, that he was in the main equally indifferent to oligarchy and democracy 1 , while some claim him as an adherent of the moderate democrats 2 . If the explanation I have suggested is right, the object he pursued was perfectly legal and within the constitution 3 , and his consistency of purpose is evi- dent through the apparent vacillation of his conduct. He attached himself to democracy, not for its own sake, but because his interests were bound up with it, as the only form of government which could grant his wishes ; and for the democratic constitution and party he worked, except for the interval of his banish- ment, throughout his life * v Lesser de- I have discussed the position of the leading de- magogue, and the opportunity it offered him of at- 1 As Phrynichus (Thuc. viii. 48) said. Thucydides endorses the remark, and it may be true of Alcibiades' philosophic stand- point, but prudential motives attached him to democracy. 2 Chiefly on the strength of Thuc. viii. 86, which I have dis- cussed above, p. 58, n. 4. 3 The suspicion was certainly entertained in 415 and 407 that he was aiming at tyranny. (Thuc. vi. 15, Plut. Ale. 34 35.) The very fact however that both in 415 when he might have appealed to the army with a good hope of success, and in 407 when he had so excellent an opportunity, he did not take the decisive step seems to argue that he purposely avoided any illegal or revolutionary method. 4 This would explain the constant hatred of the oligarchs to- wards him, which is abundantly proved. On the other hand, the other demagogues had no love for him. He was a man out of sympathy with them, a rival claimant for the people's favour, whose success would throw them completely into the shade. This explains his conduct to Hyperbolus, the action of Androcles and others. Thuc. ii. 65 refers to the rivalry of demagogues, in con- nection especially with the Sicilian expedition ; vi. 15 he traces his fall to the fear and envy of his greatness. PARTIES IN DETAIL. 61 taining almost monarchic power ; there were how- ever many demagogues contented with a much humbler position. These are usually cast into the shade by the greater men, and so do not receive the attention they deserve. Our authorities seldom mention more than the leading demagogue; we can- not fill up the gaps, but we must not forget that they only exist owing to the deficiency of our in- formation, and were this complete we should see the political stage crowded with figures. The mention of a few names from Aristophanes and other sources will give us some idea of these lesser politicians. Pisander 1 (if he may be ranked as a true democrat) is the constant object of Aristo- phanes' abuse. Hyperbolus 2 appears in Aristophanes long before the historians mention him. We hear of Theorus, Aeschines and Phanus 3 as three com- panions of Cleon, who were probably humble poli- ticians, of Thudippus who proposed the raising of the tribute 4 , of Demostratus who took a prominent part in advocating the Sicilian expedition 5 . From Andocides we hear of Demophantus proposing a democratic oath, probably on the restoration of full democracy in 410 6 ; from Lysias of Cleisthenes, Epigenes, Demophanes as active democrats in 410 7 , and from Xenophon of Archedemus, Timocrates 1 Babyl. fr. 81 (Kock), Pax 395, Lys. 490. 2 Ach. 846, Eq. 1303, Nub. 623. 3 Ar. Vesp. 1220, cf. Ach. 134, Eq. 1256. 4 C. I. A. i. 37. 6 Ar. Lys. 391. 6 Andoc. 1. 96. 7 Lys. 25. 25. 62 POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS. and Callixenus as prosecutors of the generals in 406 1 . This list, incomplete as it is, will suffice to show at once how many active politicians there must have been, and how little we know of them. Sphere of Demagogy was a profession, with a method and magogues. sphere of its own. The object of it was to protect the interests and to gain the favour of the people by zealous devotion to their service. There were three places in which the demagogue could do this, the public assembly, the council, and the law courts. Of these the assembly was the most important. All business of state was under its control, by it the policy of the commonwealth was decided, the ad- ministration was carried on and the magistrates were criticized and directed. In proportion to the import- ance of the assembly the power of the orator rose, and oratory was an essential part of the demagogic art' 2 . The business side of the demagogue's duty in the assembly was to propose and support the decrees, in which all state business was embodied, and hence the ifrr/cpicr/jLa was regarded as his special weapon 3 . Any business introduced in the assembly required 1 Xen. Hell. i. 7. For Archedemus cf. also Ar. Ran. 420. 2 The importance of oratory appears in the prominence given by Thucydides to the speeches of public men, and in the complaints of Pericles and Cleon that the people allow themselves to be carried away by oratory. Cf. Thuc. ii. 43, iii. 38. In Ar. Eq. 860 Cleon says to Demos firj tov Xiyovros iadi. Possibly this was a constant reproach of Cleon's, but it may be a reminiscence of the actual speech reported by Thucydides 1. c. 3 Cf. Ar. Eq. 1383, Nub. 1428, Aves, 1035, and see Gilbert, Reitrage, p. 79. PARTIES IN DETAIL. 63 the previous sanction of the council, and on this account it was necessary for the democrats to be well represented there. The lesser men of the party and the rising demagogues tried to get a place on it. Possibly the competition for a seat there was not very keen, and in spite of the uncertainty of the lot many of the demagogues, including Cleon 1 , Hyperbolus 2 and Androcles 3 , were members of the council at some period of their career. Coming to the actual part taken by the dema-Vma/ice. gogues in political affairs, there are some subjects in which they took a special interest and displayed par- ticular activity. These were the administration of finance, the criticism and prosecution of magistrates, and the prosecution of suspected oligarchs. Legisla- ' tion on financial matters belonged to the assembly, administration to the council 4 , while we have seen that the generals, also, had some financial duties. Failing a post on the board of generals or on the council, the demagogues' influence must have been unofficial ; but in some way nearly all demagogues concerned themselves with finance. As Bockh 5 say : " Some statesmen occupied themselves with it exclusively ; and all the great demagogues en- deavoured to obtain either direct or indirect in- fluence over it." Pericles is known to have con- 1 Ar. Eq. 774 (Cleon says t)vLk epotiXevov) refers probably to a fact. Cf. Gilbert, Beitrage, p. 82, Beloch, Att. Pol. p. 335. 2 According to Gilbert, Beitrage, p. 81. 3 Andoc. 1. 27 (Androcles appears as acting on behalf of the J30V\7)). 4 Bockh, i. 183. ib. 64 POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS. trolled the financial as well as the general policy of Athens. Cleon 1 followed his example. Cleophon, who in many ways was Cleon's political heir, devoted his attention to finance, and for years took a leading part in financial administration, apparently with great success 2 . Criticism The demagogue also undertook the censure and tutionof' if necessary the prosecution of inefficient or corrupt magis- magistrates. The assembly must have been the fre- trates. . quent scene of complaints against official mismanage- ment, and here Cleon criticized Nicias' conduct in the command at Pylos 3 f The demagogues did not always confine themselves to criticism, and the prosecution of generals was constant. The idea that power involved responsibility was 1 Ar. Eq. 774 (on the povMj). Gilbert, Beitrage, pp. 13342, thinks Ach. 5 refers to an endeavour of Cleon's to reduce the Kara- Tia was limited to one party. The oligarchs may have endeavoured to use it against their opponents. Lys. 12. 4 calls the Thirty Trovrjpoi /cat avKo^avrai, and the Zvvco/jLoatcu eirl Skats may not have been entirely defensive. On the other hand the Athenian courts were at this date apparently singularly free from corruption. So also in all probability were the orators. No definite evidence can be brought against them, and we have positive testimony in the case of Cleophon of his innocence, Lys. 19. 48. 2 Vol. iii. pp. 813 (English Trans.). 52 68 POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS. istence. Pericles' successors were the people's ser- vants and flatterers." There is in the above description this amount of truth that there was no one like Pericles to succeed him. The talents which Pericles possessed were not found united in any other man. As a consequence political life was not kept at the high level at which it had been before ; and men of less refinement took the lead 1 , partly no doubt because the development of democracy had opened up a career to all and ex- tended political education, partly because there were no great statesmen in the ranks of birth and wealth. But though this imported a certain amount of coarse- ness and passion into political life, we must be careful to distinguish between the character of the politicians and their aims. While we may admit a change in the method pursued, there was, except in one particular, no great change of policy. Objects The democrats throughout the war always kept democrats. ^ wo g rea ^ objects in view, to defend the democracy and to maintain the empire. This purpose is referred to by the author of the work on " the Athenian Consti- tution," when he says that, " the demos do not wish to live as subjects in a well ordered city but to be free and rule 2 ;" and the watchwords of democracy and empire appear no less prominently in the funeral oration of Pericles 3 . To the maintenance of the democracy and the alliance, as I have argued above, the continuance of the war was regarded as indis- 1 Cf. Ar. Eq. 191 (an implied comparison between Pericles and Cleon). 2 i. 8. 3 Thuc. ii. 36 and 37. PARTIES IN DETAIL. 69 pensable. We thus arrive at three principles of de- mocratic policy which were inseparably connected. The democrats were determined to defend the demo- cracy, to maintain the alliance, and on this account I to prosecute the war with all possible vigour to a decisive end. These principles Cleon and his suc- cessors held in common with Pericles, and it was only in the application of them that they neglected his advice. The objects of the democrats fall naturally into Defence the two divisions of home and foreign policy. On the i e U cracyt first head little need be said. It is a statement which requires no proof, that the democrats were attached to the democracy, and the history of the period shows how ready they were to defend it against every attack. There was only one interval during which the constitution was modified and the change was abnormal and temporary. The reforms of 413 were the inevitable result of a reaction against extreme democracy, which was regarded as respon- sible for the Sicilian disaster. The reforms then introduced prepared the way for the revolution of 411. This was only effected in the absence of a large number of the citizens keenly attached to the democracy, and by a system of terrorism and assassi- nation which stifled all opposition* The oligarchy of the Four Hundred was an unnatural product, and was soon superseded by a mixed constitution, which only served as an intermediate step to the restora- tion of full democracy- 1 . 1 There is no direct testimony for this restoration, except perhaps the psephism of Demophantus. The point, though long 70 POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS. The di- There is one point in particular in which we can cast's fee. trace the consistent effort of the democrats to defend the constitution in all its principles. It is in the resolve to maintain the system of paid jury courts. The jury fee was in itself neither a heavy charge on the revenue 1 , nor sufficient to compete with the remuneration of ordinary labour. It was a partial compensation to the dicast for his sacrifice of time. As such it was absolutely necessary to the system of large jury courts, which were regarded as an essen- tial part of the democratic constitution. Without some compensation it would have been impossible to induce a sufficient number of citizens to under- take judicial duties. The abuse lavished on this fee was doubtless meant for the institution which re- quired it, and it is obvious that without it the system of popular jurisdiction must have broken down. About 425 this fee was raised from two to three obols, and the increase, which in all probability was proposed by Cleon 2 , was occasioned by the general rise of prices consequent on the war 3 . In 411 all disputed, has been established in detail by Vischer, Kleine Schrif- ten, pp. 205 38, and is scarcely any longer a matter of doubt. 1 At its highest when the fee was three obols (425 411) it was not more than 150 talents. This amount is derived from Ar. Vesp. 660, which Frankel regards as absurdly exaggerated (see above, p. 44, n. 1). Beloch (Rhein. Mus. xxxix. p. 244) thinks the total amount required for the three obol fee was about 100 talents, of which about a third came from the court fees, while from 410 onwards, after the revolt of the allies, for a two obol fee scarcely more than 33 talents were required. 2 This appears from Ar. Eq. 255. 3 Miiller-Stnibing, Aristophanes, pp. 149157. It was rendered possible by the increase of the 6pos, which took place about the same time. See below, p. 72. [ PARTIES IN DETAIL. 71 state payments were abolished by the oligarchs, and the powers of the jury courts passed to the council. We do not know what arrangements were made for the next year or two 1 ; but after the overthrow of oligarchy, perhaps simultaneously with the return to full democracy, as soon as the measure was finan- cially possible, the pay was restored ; apparently at the lower fee of two obols*. This is sufficient to show the importance attached by the democrats to popular jury courts and to the system of pay which alone rendered them possible. The foreign policy of the democrats includes two Foreign subjects, closely connected with one another, the ^2^ alliance and the war 3 . With reference to these democrats. Pericles had carefully marked out the policy he con- sidered essential to success in three principles 4 . The first was to make no co ncession tO -Sparta. to conclude no peace that did not leave Athens mistress of the situation 5 . The second was to keep a strictjiand over the allies, for herein was the source of Athenian power (and, ns a corollary to this, to pay attention to the fleet and avoid lan d pngRgmrmnts) 6 . The third was to at tempt no fre sh conquests 7 . It was in the last 1 During the moderate democracy of 411 10 powers of govern- ment including probably judicial administration were entrusted to men of hoplite census, who of course did not need the dicast's fee. 2 Ar. Ran. 1466, quoted by Beloch, ib. p. 239, and discussed by him. 3 The relation of the democrats (and the other political parties) to the war is discussed at length in the next chapter. 4 See Oncken, Athen und Hellas, i. pp. 3027. 5 /XT] diceip JleXoTrovvrjaioLs, Thuc. i. 140 141. 6 tol tCov Zv/jLfjL&xui' Sia x L P s ^X 6 "'* Thuc. ii. 13 ; cf. i. 143. 7 o>yV ri brucratBeu, Thuc. i. 144 ; cf. Plut. Per. 20. 72 POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS. L point only that his advice was disregarded; the other two principles were upheld without compro- mise by Cleon and his successors against Nicias and his party. Treatment In their conduct to the allies the democrats were allies certainly following the rules laid down by Pericles ; but they carried out those rules with unnecessary harshness and brutality. This appears in their pro- posed treatment of My til en e, their actual treatment of Chios and Scione, as well as in their action towards Thera and Melos. The general attitude of the democrats to the allies has been already discussed 1 ; they maintained that the relation was one of tyrant and subject, and to a certain extent they realized their theory. For the present, however, there is one important measure, affecting the allies, which requires attention. Baising The tribute of the allies, which at the beginning tritot of the period did not exceed 600 talents 2 , was at some later period doubled. For this fact there has always been satisfactory authority 3 , but the date 1 See above, chapter I. p. 26. 2 Thuc. ii. 13. Diod. xii. 40 (from another source) and [Andoc] 4. 11 give the tribute as 460 talents at this time. Inscriptions support them, and Beloch (Ehein. Mus. xxxix. pp. 35 ff.) thinks that Diodorus is right, and that, while he gives the 6pos only, Thucy- dides is reckoning the total receipts from the allies, including indirect taxation and the toll from the Bosporus. 3 Andoc. 3. 9, Aesch. F. L. 337, both say that more than 1200 talents came in yearly during the peace of Nicias. Plut. Arist. 24 wrongly says that the tribute was gradually raised to 1300 talents by the demagogues. Cf. also Ar. Vesp. 655 ff., where the total revenue of Athens is put at 2000 talents, pointing to a large increase. Grote, v. p. 269, n. 2, argued that these passages were PARTIES IN DETAIL. 73 was not known until the examination of inscriptions proved conclusively that it took place in the year 425 \ The many passages in the Equites 2 , in which Aristophanes dwells on the oppression of the allies, point to some such measure, and evidently bring it into connection with Cleon and his party. The actual proposer, Thudippus, is an unknown man and can only have acted as the agent of the democrats ; one statement 3 , in itself of very doubtful authority, makes Alcibiades the moving spirit ; but though he doubtless supported the proposal, and may have been on the commission of assessment, it is probable that he did not take a leading part. Cleon was fresh from his triumph at Pylus, and was then at the height of his power. There can scarcely be a doubt that he was responsible for it 4 . Whatever view we may take of the justice of this The in- step, it was absolutely necessary. The expenses of nece ssity. war 5 , which may usually be regarded as extraor- dinary, had become permanent; the reserves had been exhausted, and Athens had herself to submit to a property tax (elopa). In addition to this it had been determined to take the offensive against Sparta, and it may have seemed that the need for the increase would be only temporary. not sufficient to outweigh the silence of Thucydides ; but their substantial accuracy is established by Kohler's investigations. 1 Kohler, Abhand. der Akad. Berl., 1869, pp. 14253. 2 313, 802, 1034; cf. Vesp. 671. 3 [Andoc] 4. 11. 4 Kohler, ib. p. 151. 5 See below (chap. IV.) on the financial history of the war. 74 POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS. The The amount in itself does not seem excessive. excessive. If Athens alone raised a tax of 200 talents, a sum of 1100 or 1200 talents was not out of proportion for the whole of the allies. If we may assume that the allies felt the confederation to be for their interest, it was just that they should make pecuniary sacrifices in return for the active service undertaken by Athens. It is also possible that the increase did not involve any violation of the original terms of the alliance arranged by Aristides. We know that the league was gradually extended, that the number of members in the alliance in 476 was far smaller than it was after the Persians had been driven from the Aegean, and that many states which originally sup- plied ships subsequently contributed money 1 . More- over we have the explicit testimony of Thucydides 2 that the original contribution amounted to 460 talents. To produce this amount the states then in the alliance must have paid at a higher rate, than they did later; and as time went on and fresh states joined the confederation, we find that the total 1 The original extent of the league is a matter in dispute. Kirchhoff (Hermes, xi. pp. 1 ff.) argues that the league owed its great extension to the battle of Eurymedon. In this he is followed by Frankel (n. 626 to Bockh). Beloch (Rhein. Mus. xliii. pp. 104 ff .) attacks this theory, but it cannot be disputed that the league gained many new members in the fifth century. 2 i. 96. Kirchhoff (ib. p. 30) regards this amount as impossible. In this opinion he is followed by many historians (Busolt, Griech. Gesch. ii. p. 352, Gilbert, Handbuch, i. p. 396). Kirchhoff 's explanation of the passage in Thucydides is not satisfactory, nor is it safe to regard it as an interpolation, as Diod. xi. 47, Plut. Arist. 24, and Nep. Arist. 3 are in agreement with Thucydides. PARTIES IN DETAIL. 75 revenue was not increased, and individual contribu- tions were lowered 1 . Thus the tribute of those states which had contributed from the first must in time have been considerably reduced, and the increase of 425 may only have restored the average rate of the original assessment 2 . It is hard to apportion fairly the burden of taxa- tion between different classes or different parts of an empire ; it is probable that, considering the military exertions of Athens, she had more to bear than the allies, and did not get a fair return for the sacrifices she made 3 . In their war policy the democrats were at one War with Pericles in insisting on an active prosecution of ^^ the war and refusing all concession to Sparta. They democrats. regarded the feud as irreconcileable, and hence when Athens was in a position to impose terms they would only have such as would place Sparta at a permanent disadvantage 4 , and when the course of the war was 1 Frankel, n. 629. The quota lists show that the rate of tribute was lowered in 450 and 446. 2 I have omitted to consider the change in the method of levying the tribute, effected by the introduction of the efoocrr^ in 413. We know neither the motives for nor the effects of this change, and have not much ground for regarding it as a part of the democratic policy. 3 Cf. Wilamowitz, Aus Kydathen, pp. 27, 28. "The value of money was overestimated (i. e. in allowing the allies to purchase immunity from service). Athenians of means contributed at a higher rate than the allies, and the charge that Athens exacted more than she needed is untrue." Cf. Plut. Per. 12 (Pericles argued that the Athenians owed nothing to the allies, whom they protected from Persia without calling upon them for service). 4 They were not content to return to the status quo; Athens wa3 to be in a position of definite superiority to Sparta. Hence 76 POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS. unfavourable to Athens they would consent to no peace which involved the slightest diminution of Athenian power. But in their desire to crush Sparta, they neg- lected Pericles' advice as to the plan of war to be followed ; they carried the war into the enemy's camp by vigorous land campaigns, and endeavoured by alliance and by distant conquest to strengthen themselves against the foe. Plan of In the first place they were not satisfied with the war ' purely defensive system of Pericles. They would not wait for Sparta to be weary of war, they wanted to inflict injury on her and reduce her to submission. Hence they effected the blockade of the Peloponnesus, and attempted the investment of Boeotia, which ended so disastrously at Delium. Alliance From the same motive they sought alliance with jj-qos. the enemies of Sparta, in order to strengthen them- selves against her. Argos had been Sparta's great rival in the Peloponnesus; she had formerly been allied with Athens against Sparta, and was the most powerful democracy in Greece next to Athens. There was therefore every motive for an alliance between these two powers. The truce between Argos and Sparta prevented any immediate action; but in all probability Athens anticipated its expiry, and the democrats made overtures to Argos 1 . These over- after Pylos irXelovos, fieifaw wptyovro (Thuc. iv. 21, 41). The terms Cleon demanded in 425 would have made Athens as a land power almost a match for Sparta. 1 Ar. Eq. 464 5, speaking of Cleon, otitcovv fi kv 'Apyelots a irpaTrei Xavddvei \ irpotpaaiv /jlv 'Apydovs rjpuv iroiei k.t.X. This probably had some foundation in fact ; see Gilbert, Beitrage, PARTIES IN DETAIL. 77 tures were not however carried to any conclusion, and the accession of the peace party to power in 421 and the alliance with Sparta defeated this project. As soon as Athens and Sparta began to draw apart, Alcibiades pressed on the alliance with Argos, and from that time (with the interval of the oligarchic revolution at Argos) Athens found in her a true ally. The desire of the Athenians for the extension of The the empire, connected with their wish to strengthen Slcll n expedi- t hem selves against Sparta, led not only to the at- tion. tacks on Thera and Melos, but to the fatal Sicilian expedition. This project, which arose from the arro- gant assumption that Athens, as mistress of the sea, should include within her dominion all islands in- habited by Greeks, had been mooted in the time of Pericles 1 . Athens had real interests in Sicily 2 , to protect which she sent forces thither as early as 427, and her interference had been constant down to the year 424. The expedition of 415 was the resump- tion of a previous plan on a larger scale, and owing to the fact that Athens was not actually engaged in war 3 elsewhere its prospects seemed favourable. The proposal was probably due to the ambition of Alci- biades ; but when once started, it met with enthusi- 188 90. The approaching expiry of the truce was a great motive with Sparta for the conclusion of the war. 1 Plut. Per. 20. 2 If the Ionians succumbed to the Dorians, the latter might send aid to Sparta (as they did after 413), Thuc. iii. 86. Cf. ii. 7. It is important to remember that commercial interests were involved in the expedition. Many merchants sailed with it in the hopes of making a profit (Thuc. vi. 31), and the conquest of Sicily would have caused a vast extension of Athenian trade. 3 Except in Thrace. 78 POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS. astic support. The only opposition, which must have been of a very half-hearted character, came from Nicias and his following; and though all sec- tions of the population were eager for it, the demo- cratic party must bear the responsibility. The conquest of Sicily was no impossible feat. The failure of the attempt was due to incompetence and mismanagement on the Athenian side, combined with the greatest skill and courage on the part of their opponents 1 . But admitting that the prospect was good, the expedition was a great blunder from the democratic stand-point. The struggle with Sparta had not been fought out, a renewal of the contest was inevitable, and Athens was doing what she could to hasten it. Had her force not been wasted in Sicily she would have been a match for Sparta when the struggle was renewed. But for this misguided piece of aggression, the democratic policy was as sane as it was consistent. Their constant effort was to maintain the constitution and the alliance, and on this account to offer an uncompromising resistance to Sparta, whose hostility threatened both. 1 Time. ii. 65 says the Sicilian expedition was not an error of judgment, but failed because those at home did not, owing to political dissensions, take proper measures to support it. It is hard to see to what he refers, as the Athenians sent overwhelming forces to Sicily. The loss of Alcibiades, and the action he took in obtain- ing help for Syracuse, were of great effect, but Nicias was really to blame. Thucydides' narrative makes it painfully evident that he missed every possible occasion, that Syracuse (and with it Sicily) might have been speedily reduced, and that his early mistakes might have been repaired by a slight display of energy. PARTIES IN DETAIL. 79 2. The Oligarchical Party. In the general obscurity and uncertainty of the political history of Athens the democratic party and its policy appear to us in comparative distinctness owing to the prominence given to them by the con- temporary authorities. Of the other political sections we have not such definite information, and we are therefore reduced to inference and conjecture, so that our knowledge is both less complete and less reliable. A feeling of opposition to an extreme democracy Opposition must have been excited in the minds of many Athe- ^^ nians, and to this feeling the education of the day couraged contributed not a little. Aristotle insists on the philosophy importance of the adaptation of general education J the da y- to the constitution 1 ; but at Athens the teaching of the philosophers was directly antagonistic to the ex- isting government. The Athenian constitution depended on the sov- ereignty of law 2 , and there was a tendency to over- estimate the value of institutions, which were regarded as sacred and almost perfect : the philosophy of the period, on the contrary, was sceptical, took nothing for granted, and put every institution on its trial. The caricature of Aristophanes 3 is equally appli- cable to the Sophists or to Socrates : 1 Ar. Pol. 1310 a, 12 fiiyiaTov d ttclvtuv irpos to diafi^eiv rcis 7ro\iTelas . . .to 7rcu5euecr0cu irpos rds 7ro\tre/as. 2 Wilamowitz, Aus Kydathen, pp. 47 ff. 3 Nub. 13991400. 80 POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS. The oli- garchs a disloyal faction. W9 r)hv /catvoL*; TTpccyfjuaaiv zeal Sef^ot? 6/jnXeiv teal twv KaOearourcov vojxcov virepfypovelv Bv- vaaOcu. While Socrates 1 contrasted the existing constitu- tion with the ideal state of his philosophy, and found it wanting, the Sophists 2 , so far as we can attribute to them any unity of thought, decried the acceptance of anything on tradition and exalted the individual above the state. Both brought the blemishes of the constitution into prominence without proposing any positive or practical reform. The consequence was that while many regarded the constitution with critical eyes ? but were content to put up with it, others found in this teaching a justification of their own feelings against the democracy, and made it their one poli- tical object to attack or undermine it. From this class came most of the oligarchic leaders. The oligarchs as a whole were a disloyal faction 3 , 1 Cf. Vischer, Kleine Schriften, i. p. 102. " Socrates' influence was not of a nature to form practical statesmen. His just discon- tent with the existing democracy, and his method of criticizing everything, had the effect of teaching his pupils the defects of the state and making them estimate it lightly, without positive results. No good Athenian statesman of importance came from his ac- quaintance, but many a mischievous one." See also Hertzberg, Alkibiades, pp. 33 36, and Grote, viii. p. 198, on Plato. 2 Cf. Vischer, ib. p. 155. " The principle that the individual exists only in the state is reversed, the state is now the tool to give power and weight to the individual will." Cf. Muller-Stnibing, Aristophanes, p. 244. This exaltation of the individual was the result of the general philosophic movement of which the Sophists were the representatives. 3 They come under Bolingbroke's definition, "National inter- ests would be sometimes sacrificed and always made subordinate PARTIES IN DETAIL. 81 for neither their methods nor their objects entitle them to be regarded as a party. They not only rejected the obligation to obey the laws, but they were traitors to their country, for they intrigued with the national enemy against it ; their ends were always selfish and treasonable, and were pursued by means of conspiracy and terrorism. They formed, as their name 1 implies, a small mi- nority of the state, and were for the most part men of wealth 2 , or political adventurers who saw possi- bilities of their own advancement in the chance of revolution. In particular many of the young aristo- crats 3 , who looked with contempt on the rule of the lower classes, and were anxious to overthrow it, joined their ranks. The motives which put the rich men in oppo- Natural sition to the constitution are obvious. Political fti ie rich struggles in most states are between the privi- leged few and the excluded many, who suffer from to personal interests ; and that, I think, is the true characteristic of faction." 1 6\iyot, the most general title. 2 For the natural opposition of the rich to the democracy and its policy, which I have discussed above, there is direct evidence. Thuc. viii. 47, 48 (the trierarchs and rich men wish to get power into their own hands) ; ib. 63 (they resolve to go on with the revo- lution ws ovk^tc d'XXoiS rj (yts, iV%(5os Kal tXoijtov Kai vo~i tQp Urw ovk tuoL 6vTes. 2 Plut. Arist. 13; cf. Muller-Striibing, Aristophanes, pp. 244 ff. PARTIES IN DETAIL. 83 tells us, men of noble families and great property, becoming impoverished by the war, and seeing their political power and reputation in the state vanishing, while others got the honours and controlled the government, conspired against the democracy. This attitude they maintained throughout the fifth century, opposing the progress of democracy both by legitimate methods and by conspiracy ; but after the ostracism of Thucydides open opposition was abandoned for intrigue 1 . Henceforth their objects were treasonable, and this circumstance shaped both their action and their organization. They could not openly advocate their proposals, Organiza- but had either to withdraw altogether from political ^. life, as many of them did, or dissemble their convic- tions 2 , and under the guise of democrats work against democracy. For the same reason their po- litical associations were in the first place secret, and in the second place separate, for combination would have brought suspicion on them. For this purpose they combined in political clubs Oligarchic called eraipelaL*. Politicians of all parties seem to have adopted organizations of this nature to ^\ strengthen their position, but they were especially favoured by the oligarchs. Their original purpose \ seems to have been mainly defensive : the men who * 1 See above, p. 37. 2 Beloch, Att. Pol. p. 13. 3 For these see Vischer, Kleine Schriften, i. pp. 153 204, who collects all the available information on this subject, and endeavours to trace their influence on history. See. also Scheibe, Die oligarchische Umwalzung, p. 5. They are called ^ww^ocrtat in Thuc. viii. 54. 62 84 POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS. gathered this band of helpers round them used their assistance in law-suits and elections 1 ; and as oligarchs were especially liable to prosecution, and as they needed close organization to compensate for their deficiency of numbers, these clubs came to be regarded in time as oligarchic institutions, although they were not confined to one party 2 . Of their constitution we know little: they were naturally secret 3 ; many of the clubs were centred round a single individual 4 , to whose interests they were devoted; and though usually independent of each other 5 , they might be united, whenever there seemed a good opportunity of taking steps to carry their wishes into effect. Thus the oligarchic clubs, if not essentially treason- able, were adapted to treasonable ends 6 . Con- It is probable that these associations were kept nection of these i Thuc. 1. c. Zvvufxoaiai iirl diKais Kal d/)%a?s. Cf. Plato Theaet. 173 D, eraipelai iir dpxds. 2 Thus Pericles, Nicias and Alcibiades each had his hetaery, see Vischer, ib. pp. 163, 169, 174. 3 Plato Eep. ii. 365 d, iirl yap rb \avddveiv ^vvcj/noaias re Kal iraipelas ^vvd^o/jiev. 4 Thus we hear of the hetaeries of Phaeax, Euphiletus, Alcibia- des, &c. 6 Thuc. viii. 54 (Pisander induced the clubs to combine 8wws %vp Keifitvoip vofiuv (bo5oi, aXXa irapa roi>s KadearCoTas ir\eove%lq. The combina- tion of hetaeries at Samos (to iraipiKov) is called a %vi>wfAo X PARTIES IN DETAIL. 95 party shaded off on the one hand to the democrats, on the other to the oligarchs. It included men of keen democratic feeling, who, however, must be ranked with this party as being in opposition to the democratic policy, as well as men who would have preferred a moderate form of oligarchy. But these, and indeed the bulk of the party, usually accepted the con- stitution as it was and worked loyally under it. They were opportunists 1 on this point, and so long as the constitution in existence was not guilty of flagrant excess, and ensured a general security, they were content. Hence they went with the stream, and acquiesced, in democracy, till the current of events set in the direction of oligarchy, when they made no attempt to resist the movement. Many men, indeed, who usually acted with this \ party, desired to see a moderate oligarchy established, and the revolutions of 411 and 404 were both carried / out with their help. They did not, however, take sufficient precautions to prevent oppression and secure moderation, and on both occasions they broke from the oligarchs, when they saw the character of their government. As I have said, the party was not homogeneous, Reforms and so did not pursue one ideal of government: we ^ s } red ^V can see, however, by their action, when placed in 1 See Beloch, Att. Pol. p. 13. Cf. Eur. Suppl. 2445 (speak- ing of this party), rpiuiv 5 fioipQv 7) V fieacp aivfei 7r6Xets, k6 f r & tne franchise were limited to men the people, of a certain amount of property, they would be able to serve the state without requiring pay, while it was only the system of pay which enabled the demos to take part in some functions of government. In 412 there was a reaction against extreme democracy and in consequence the government passed to the moderates ; it was probably owing to their influence that the powers of the assembly and council were limited by the institution of the 7rp6fiov\oi, who were themselves men of the middle party 2 . In 411 those of the middle party who supported the oligarchic movement did so in the hope that a government based on a limited franchise would be introduced 3 , and it 1 I have omitted to discuss the objection that some individuals who may be ranked with this party (e.g. Socrates) had to the lot, but the question was more one for philosophers than for practical politicians; and the system does not seem to have caused any general dissatisfaction. 2 So far as we can judge from the little we know of them; Hagnon and Sophocles (identified by many historians with the poet) were members. 3 The proposal to entrust power to the Five Thousand in 411 was probably put in as a blind to attract the moderates, cf. Thuc. viii. 65, 67, 72. They laid great stress on making this ele- ment a reality, and their disappointment was the cause of the split, ib. 89, 92, 93. PARTIES IN DETAIL. 97 was their disappointment in this respect that caused them to break with the extreme oligarchs. They v were then able to overthrow the oligarchy and esta- blish a government after their own heart, based on the two essential conditions of a limited franchise and the abolition of pay 1 . The same thing happened in 404 ; those of the middle party who supported the institution of the Thirty did so in the hope that they would establish a constitution on a sufficiently broad basis 2 while avoiding the blemishes of democracy. They were again disappointed, and Theramenes for a second time led the malcontents, but he was no match for the extreme oligarchs. On questions of general policy this party formed, The middle at least for the first half of the war, the regular Qfr^%^ position. They were during all this time the peace cratic party 3 , and though they were not ready like the oli- garchs to accept peace at any price, and so to betray Athenian interests to Sparta, they were anxious to bring the war to a conclusion, so long as peace in- e,\jtL volved no loss of honour or empire. On this as on I other subjects they took up a position intermediate between the two parties, set themselves against ex- treme tendencies in either direction, and became the 1 Thuc. viii. 97. 2 Thus Theramenes (who probably desired a more restricted franchise than most of the middle party), objected to the limit of 3000 being fixed, Xen. Hell. ii. 3, 19. His own ideal is expressed ib. ii. 3, 48 ; he was opposed to ol 5ov\oi /cai oi 6l diroplav SpaxM* dv dirodofxevot. rrjv ttoKlv, being admitted to citizenship: on the other hand he objected to the tyranny of an absolute council. 3 See chapter iv. p. 119. w. 7 'policy. /\ ^yt 98 POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS. advocates of compromise. On this account their / policy always seems negative, and Nicias' attitude was one of monotonous opposition to the democratic proposals. In fact it would be possible to deny to this party any positive merits in statesmanship, were it not that it is redeemed by a few men, for whose \ proposals the party may claim credit. Aristoplm-^ Above all others Aristophanes may be regarded Tentative 6 ' as ^ e representative man of this party, and I think of the we can trace in his works a definite and consistent par y ' policy, which he constantly advocates 1 . He stood midway between the extreme democrats and the oligarchs; while severe on the faults of democracy and castigating the evil side of the assembly and of the law courts, and the system of state pay 2 , he had no sympathy with the oligarchs 3 , and was 1 Aristophanes was a partisan, and, as I have argued above, his delineation of character did not always keep on truthful lines ; but this did not hinder him from having genuine political ideas, and seriously advocating them. Th. Kock (Rhein. Mus. xxxix. pp. 118 ff .) insists on the serious purpose of Aristophanes. " The Aristophanic dramas," he says (p. 125), " are closely connected with the movements of popular feeling in politics and education, religion or art, with the practical aim of affecting the movements by conviction ; they are distinctly didactic." 2 The evils of the KK\r)Tas devpo ^vvayeLv kclI crvvadpoi^eiu els $v, K&irevra Trotrjcai ToXvirrjv /xeyd\r)v, Kar K ravrvs ry A-^/xy xKalvav v k.t.X. When the danger had been realized in 411, he blames the Greeks. Lys. 433, fyOpuv TTCLpovruv j3ap(3apopa) of 200 talents was raised for six years from 428/7, which brought in 1200 talents. The other revenues would more than suffice for the ordinary expenses of administra- tion. This therefore gives us a total of more than 13,000 talents, or an average expenditure of 1500 talents a year on the war. This expenditure had exhausted the treasury, and the war for the next two years had to be supported out of the ordinary revenues. This may account for the remissness of the Athenians in Thrace, and must 1 i. p. 320. 2 Beloch, Rhein. Mus. xxxix. pp. 244 9. 3 About 4150 talents from 431 to 427/6, and about 800 from then to 423/2. PARTIES IN RELATION TO THE WAR. Ill have been a most urgent motive for concluding peace, though Thucydides does not mention it 1 . During the years of peace the finances naturally recovered, and we have it on fair authority 2 that 7000 talents were stored in the Acropolis. The loans from the temple began again in 415, and in consequence of the Sicilian expedition the treasury was emptied (with the exception of the reserve of 1000 talents) 3 . For the ten years from 422/1 to 413/2 we may reckon that more than 12,000 talents were spent on war purposes 4 . After this we have no accurate data of either revenue or expenditure, as the tribute was superseded by indirect taxation and the extent of the Athenian dominion varied. The reserve of 1000 talents was spent, a property tax was twice imposed, and extraordinary contributions were levied. We are reduced to speculation, and the average of 1100 talents 5 for the last seven years may not be far from the truth. This makes the total public ex- penditure on the war about 35,000 talents 6 , without 1 In v. 14 where he gives the Athenian motives. 2 Andoc. 3. 8, which Beloch I.e. thinks exaggerated, as Athens had still to meet the cost of operations in Thrace, Melos and the Peloponnesus. 3 Thuc. viii. 15. 4 The tribute of the allies alone during that period would have produced this amount. 5 This Beloch (ib. p. 249) thinks the minimum, as certain sums omitted from consideration above must be added (e.g. expenditure of 405/4). 6 In the present value of money, according to Beloch, about 30,000,000. I have throughout accepted his figures without discussion, as for the purpose of the argument strict accuracy is not essential. It is probable, that he has, if anything, under- stated the expenditure, as he assumes that the v\ds. See note on next page. 122 POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS. the support of the people at the time of the election, and retained it until events brought their opponents into favour. Even then the generals had a certain degree of power, until their year of office expired, for they had the control of military operations, and their rivals could not take the initiative. As therefore the generalship was the most important office, election to it was keenly contested, and when a choice had to be made between alternative policies, the result of this election must have been for the time decisive 1 . 1 There are some minor points in connection with the election of the generals which I have left out of consideration. 1. The time of election has been much disputed. There is now a strong balance of opinion that the generals were chosen towards the end of Munychion (April) and entered on office in Hecatombaeon (July); see Beloch, Att. Pol. pp. 265 ff.; he dis- cusses the question at length and quotes other authorities. If this date is correct there was an interval of about three months between election and entry on office, so that generals might hold office for three months after their policy had been condemned by the election of their opponents. 2. The method of election is quite unknown and there is the widest diversity of opinion. See Beloch, Att. Pol. pp. 276 ff. Gilbert, Beitrage, pp. 16 24, Droysen, Hermes ix. pp. 1 ff. The two latter writers think that the generals were elected by the whole people, but that in the election regard was had to the tribes as far as possible, in order that each tribe might usually but not without exception be represented on the board. Beloch thinks that the -jrpvTavis was elected by the whole people from any tribe, but his nine colleagues by the separate tribes, one tribe losing by lot or rotation its right of election. This would answer to the facts well enough, as we occasionally find two generals elected from the same tribe, but the other eight are always, so far as we know, from eight other tribes. The subject is too obscure for a certain decision. There is one consideration pertinent to the political aspect of the strategia. If each general was elected e air&vTwv (Poll. viii. 87) and by all, it would naturally result that one party having a majority of votes, would carry all the ten candidates. This is PARTY GOVERNMENT IN ATHENS. 123 If then we know the generals of any year, and Lists of the policy advocated by the majority, we have a clue 9 enerals - to the state of parties at the time, and can discover which of them was in control of the government. We are seldom able to obtain a full list for any year. We have usually to depend on the chance mention of three or four names in Thucydides and Xenophon, occasionally supplemented by information derived from inscriptions relating to the financial business and military operations of the year. These sources, however, usually contain enough to enable us to trace the transfer of power in successive years. The lists, so far as we know them, have been drawn up 1 , and justify us in concluding that on most occasions the V' election of the generals was a political conflict of great importance, in which the parties put forth their utmost efforts. The constant changes of policy and magistrates False which we see represented in this way throw a clear Athenian light on the politics of the period, and enable us to politics. dispose of some fallacious theories which have hitherto been accepted. Of these the most important is, that, whatever may have been the strength of the different parties, the democracy alone took any im- portant part in politics. Some trace this to the clearly disproved by the lists of generals, for in years when political feeling ran high, we find men of opposite parties elected, e.g. Nicias and Lysicles, rival party leaders, in 428/7, so Nicias and Cleon in 424/3. The minority must have had some means of obtaining representation. 1 By Beloch, Att. Pol., Anhang i. pp. 289 ff., where he gives a list of generals with a commentary quoting the authorities on which the list for each year is based. See also Gilbert, Beitrage, who discusses the generals elected each year. 124 POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS. terrorism established by the demagogues 1 , others to the want of a representative system 2 . The first ex- planation scarcely requires consideration, the second is worth discussing. Every decision of the assembly is regarded as the voice of the mob ; when a change of policy occurs, it is traced to the fickleness of the popular will, because, it is argued, the respectable citizens did not as a rule attend the assembly, and their voice was not heard owing to the lack of repre- sentation. We are told 8 that "the size of Attica rendered the difficulty of attending the assembly so great that those who lived at a distance did not usually attend, and political power was in the hands of the proletariate. It was really the inhabitants of the town and Piraeus who filled the assemblies, passed decrees, made laws, elected and deposed magistrates." This may be true of the ordinary work of administra- tion, at which no one was very anxious to attend 4 ; but we cannot suppose that the middle class let every- thing go by default. It is reasonable to conclude that the country people nocked in 5 to vote on any great question (such as proposals for war or peace), as 1 e.g. Curtius, vol. iii. p. 115 (English Trans.). His argument is discussed and disproved by Miiller-Striibing, Aristophanes, pp. 4967, and Oncken, Athen und Hellas, ii. pp. 212 ff. 2 The complaint is frequent. See Beloch, Att. Pol. p. 7, (although his statement there is general, and does not refer to the fifth century in particular). 3 Beloch, I.e. 4 Cf. Ar. Ach. 19, which shows the reluctance of citizens to attend the iia<\r} 3 CD 5 CD i l CO fQ CO CD o p a l; 8 3 s O cc CD _, ci 5 CD O ?3 "^Pw 1 -s ^ CD *4 > B Ohl. to a ,2 s- 2 s 5 O O CO . CD ll O CD 173 CD < nfe CD 5 a M " . o. CD CO C3 5 1* 2 g 43 .2 3 2 g.9 o ^.2 SSI'S fll ** m "-* co s-i a 83.1 Pw Ph M ' m CD H CO c3 1 * .2 J O I ft.S S 2 2' g 0.2 ft'Ss ~S ^^3 P - 2 I O P^ fe rt 11.1 8J CD _!_?>? . 1*3*81 ^ P co M CD .1 .5 "-3 gsz; l-S &"^ fe-S * A CQ O 4B as, co CsD 11 a GQ 81 M Ph 3 < i 1 P B * rdlS Ii 1 *! * r2 CC s o 3 J a a a I ft"S^S ?!>!* & E 8 C3T3 B w o .y -^ -a t5 ^ CO o d rfl CO Q 12 d ft|1 b 3 o c3m o la ^ P-: P^^ ^ CD O cPh do S ,2 O PM CO Sh 9 J is 03 Ph. 2 ' CC Ph O 3 if 3 o Ci 00 <9 ^ CN CD o CD ^3 d ^rd 2 s 2 ft-d t-.S i i CD to & &S 2 B H o3^ S.& J J ."S a ^ * 550 O I|l S 2 5=1 d^ t3 h ,d g '^ 2 .5 a * -S o.S 5 a, g .2 o go CD 2 ** B ^ * oq 4* ew "9 M a 9 03 I 2 ^a a -l l^H "S o S - kJ ft rd -^ o3 +2 ^ CO CD CD P< ^ 550 9 o3 ^ ft 550 03 ?* H O R 03 .2 S CD E 9 9 ^ >>US d S 550 03 CQ ---i If If J d ^3 r] S r& +-( CD 3 s d^3 S2^|o a pci o .5 -i 3 Ph. q "- rjj i^i 55C 3 *h fl'^O "S'S 03 rP CD 03 ^5 -S CD ^'+3 Pw CO 5h ^.S & -^ 'fl CD $ <<^ +3 CD d O O 03 CO ^, J9 CD d co d^ I ffi a ^^rd.2 S ^^ol| M -^ 03 - - ei_i O CS rg O O "^ CD || d.SoQ2 Eh B3 o Ph S 0Q o3 O CO CD o3 to O CQ Ph CO O c3 f-i ,0 ft a CD ft d^ ft OQ ft I a: I H >-, o3 13 CD CO 2 q.'s! -S 03^ & .- a a S 2-^-2 1 g 43 ft^ -g o o co O '^3 8-3 bail < ft^a O Q, . ^ *h S 2 2 d' O O SH QJ Pm ft J 2 2 2 p ^^ * * T3 * rd 03 o ^O T -1 'O T* H -? OS 4SO3 CO CM S o "3 rH O 00 t^ D 128 POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS. Conclusion Such a map of political events enables us to rived from rea ^ ze vividly the energy and persistency with which these facts, the struggle of parties was kept up in Athens. The constant changes of government and of policy are sufficient proof that parties were sharply divided and equally resolute in the pursuit of their political ends. We may, therefore, reject the theory that the mob of the town had any monopoly of political activity. A brief review of the different periods of the war will show this more clearly. Different The war falls naturally into three parts, the first 1 'periods of p er i 0( j going down to the peace of Nicias, the second 2 covering the years of peace, and the third 3 lasting from the renewal of the war to the surrender of Athens. Each of these periods has distinct charac- teristics; the struggle of the rival parties varied greatly in the first and last years of the war, and in the second period, which was one of nominal peace, the situation was complicated by the prominence of political questions other than those of war and peace. Party In the first years of the war parties were fairly \ f^the es matched and had an equal share of office. The ad- first part vocates of peace and war controlled the government ' in turn, and each party endeavoured to use their influence in the assembly to carry their policy into effect. The changes of government were largely due to the course of events and the temporary success or failure of the rival parties. Thus the sufferings caused by the second invasion in 430 and the losses of Athens in 428-7 led to peace negotiations being 1 431421. 2 421413. 3 413404. PARTY GOVERNMENT IN ATHENS. 129 opened in those years 1 . Similarly the success of Brasidas in 424 induced the Athenians to consent to an armistice, and the peace of Mcias was rendered possible by the defeat of Cleon. There were, there- fore, at least four occasions on which the peace party took definite steps to realize their policy, while the war party, profiting by their own good fortune or the blunders of their opponents, procured the rejection of Spartan proposals in several instances 2 . Generally speaking a change of government was followed by a change of policy ; but on other occasions the peace party were entrusted with office owing to the failure of their opponents to conduct the war successfully, and they were expected to continue military opera- tions until the state had a favourable opportunity for concluding peace 3 . During the years succeeding the peace of Nicias Party the political situation was changed. The peace was !owf 421 nominally preserved until 413, and in this interval, to 413. as compared with the previous period, the position of parties was inverted; the peace party endeavoured to maintain the existing situation, and the war party to disturb it. The government was again shared between the two parties, and for the first few years neither party had a decisive superiority, so that the policy of the state was marked by vacillation and 1 For the peace negotiations of 430 see Thuc. ii. 59. The peace proposals mentioned in Thuc. iv. 21 and Ar. Ach. 653 4 are generally referred to the year 427 ; see Beloch, Att. Pol. p. 34. 2 After Pylus the Spartans sent embassies on several occasions in vain ; Ar. Pax 665 7 evidently refers to these. 3 Apparently in 428 and 425, although the peace party were in power, they were not allowed to initiate peace negotiations. w. 9 130 POLITICAL PAKTIES IN ATHENS. compromise. The history of the period is so involved that it is worth while to review it briefly in detail. The advocates of peace did not retain their po- sition for long ; a reaction of popular feeling brought Alcibiades into power, and he was able to bring about the alliance with Argos, which led Athens into in- direct hostilities with Sparta 1 . This unsatisfactory state of affairs, in which Athens was attacking a power with whom she was nominally allied, reached a climax in the battle of Mantinea. Nicias, who was in office, was able to prevent any effective force being sent against Sparta, while Alcibiades, who accom- panied the expedition, managed to involve the Athenian arms. This intolerable balance of power caused the resort to ostracism in 41 7 2 . The rival leaders agreed to submit their claims to the decision of the whole state with some hope that for the future the policy of one or the other might be carried out vigorously and consistently. The intervention of Hyperbolus led to a change of plan and to the com- bination of the former rivals. For the time Nicias seems to have gained ground and Alcibiades took a less prominent position 3 . In order to recover the influence he had lost he advocated the Sicilian ex- 1 Alcibiades could not get either the peace or alliance with Sparta renounced by Athens; but he procured a formal declar- ation that Sparta had broken the truce, Thuc. v. 56. 2 The ostracism of Hyperbolus took place in some year be- tween 418 and 415; on the whole there is more authority for the date 417, and I have adopted Beloch's explanation of the events connected with the ostracism (Att. Pol. pp. 54 5). 3 Although both were generals, the policy of Nicias was carried out; see Beloch, ib. p. 57. PARTY GOVERNMENT IN ATHENS. 131 pedition, and during his exile and the absence of Nicias Androcles and the extreme democrats brought about a renewal of the war. After the disaster in Sicily there was no longer Party an even division of parties, and, except for the in- till the terval of the oligarchic revolution, the war was e J} d f & the war. always vigorously supported by the government 1 . The preponderance of the war party was due to two causes, which I have discussed above. On the one hand the social changes brought about by a long-continued war had altered the composition and relative strength of the different parties 2 , and on the other the Athenians realized the importance of the war to Athens and to Greece, and were obsti- nately determined not to give way 3 . During the oligarchy of 411 three embassies were sent to Sparta, but with this exception the policy of resistance to the last was invariably maintained. The Spartan proposals were rejected whenever they were offered 4 , and even after the crushing and hopeless defeat of Aegospotami the spirit of the Athenians was not broken, they refused every suggestion of concession and only yielded to the inevitable necessities of famine. 1 The peace party, although in a minority, was not extinct. Its existence may be traced in Diod. xiii. 53, where he says that some Athenians advocated the acceptance of the Spartan propo- sals after Cyzicus. 2 See above, p. 94. 3 See above, p. 118. 4 In 413 (Thuc. vii. 18), 410 (Diod. xiii. 53), 408 (See Gilbert, Beitrage, pp. 3612), 406 (Schol. to Ar. Ran. 1533), 405. The proposals of 408 and 406 do not rest on good authority and are open to doubt ; see Grote viii. p. 1 for the latter. 92 132 POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS. Final con- Finally this survey of political events strengthens three important conclusions which I have already accepted on somewhat insufficient evidence. In the first place we may conclude that the conditions of political life at Athens were normal, that there was \- a balance of political forces which practically re- sulted in party government. There were regular principles of party division; parties were distinctly and not unequally divided, and they sought to obtain official power in order to carry their principles into ' effect. In the second place the great cause of party division was not the preference which men had for particular constitutional forms, but the one great political question which overshadowed all others. During the whole war, except for an interval of four months, the democratic constitution was maintained, , almost without modification 1 ; but the contest about war and peace was never suspended, the advocates of the rival policies were always confronting each other, and enjoyed in turn success or failure. Lastly the resolution of the Athenians to make no terms with Sparta rose, as their prospects of victory became more distant 2 and as their losses and sufferings were 1 Reforms limiting the powers of the democracy were intro- duced in 413 (see above p. 96), and after the overthrow of the oligarchy full democracy was not immediately restored (see p. 97) ; but these modifications were due to exceptional circumstances and were merely temporary. 2 The two critical disasters in the latter part of the war were- the defeats in Sicily and at Aegospotami. After the first edoicei XPV VCU M v8i6vcu (Thuc. viii. 1); and after the second the Athenians immediately prepared for a siege, and as time went on in spite of famine ov dieXtyovro irepi didWayrjs (Xen. Hell. ii. 2. 4 and ii. 2. 11). CONCLUSION. 133 every day aggravated. We may therefore conclude that the general determination of a majority of the citizens to carry the struggle to a decisive end was founded not on a calculation of personal interest but on political convictions. It was recognized that the power of Athens and her dominion over other states, even her independent existence, depended on a suc- cessful issue of the war. It is the merit of the de- mocratic party that from the first they realized the tremendous interests involved in the war and never swerved in their resolve to defend those interests without concession. And they must not be con- demned for the result ; the duel for the supremacy between Athens and Sparta was a life and death struggle, and it was impossible for Athens, at least, to draw back. "The Peloponnesian war was begun by Sparta under vain pretexts and with guilty conscience ; but the Athenians themselves do not deny that for years before they had gathered all their forces together and braced themselves for a decisive contest. And the moral responsibility for the war, in which this glori- ous nation consumed itself, Athens must bear. She can bear the burden, for national unity is a treasure on which a nation may stake its existence, and for the sake of the Hellenes it Avas the duty of Athens to fight the Dorians to the death. It was, therefore, no vulgar ambition, no purposeless beating of the air, when Athens undertook and carried on this war with all her forces and with unexampled self-sacrifice ; and he who understands this will admire the Athenians more in misfortune than prosperity. 134 POLITICAL PARTIES IN ATHENS. " We do not quarrel with history. The doom of Athens was inevitable and not undeserved. But yet it was the conquered cause that pleased the gods; and we, mortals of a later day, cannot reflect without regret on the fall of this wondrous nation, which nature meant for the political ideal but nature missed the mark 1 ." 1 This passage is adapted from the concluding words of Wilamowitz's Festrede "Von des attischen Eeiches Herrlichkeit " (Aus Kydathen, pp. 44 5). He lays more stress on the claim of Athens to dominion over the other Greeks than I have done ; but the passage seems on the whole so true that it may fairly be quoted in support of my argument. INDEX. Eeferences in all cases are to Athenian politics and institutions. Agriculture, majority of population engaged in, 40 ; ruined by the war, 94, 112 Alcibiades, prosecuted by Thessa- lus, 11; eager for military com- mand, 53; compared with Peri- cles, 56; career of, 57; aims of, 59; attached to the demo- cracy, 60; connection of, with doubling of the tribute, 73; ad- vocates Argive alliance, 76, 130; proposes Sicilian expedition, 78, 131 ; banishment of, 90 ; and the mutilation of the Hermae, 90, n. 3 ; at the battle of Mantinea, 130 Allies, see Confederacy; subjection of, to Athens, 26 ff. ; treatment of, by democrats, 72, 93 ; by the middle party, 100 ; proposals of Aristophanes with regard to, 100 Andocides and Athenian history, 10 Androcles, demagogue and general, 53; helps to overthrow Alcibi- ades, 57, 90; on the council, 63 Argos, relations of, to Athens and Sparta, 33; alliance of, with Athens, 76, 130 Aristocratic party at Athens breaks up, 37 Aristophanes and political history, 5 ; political prejudice of, 6 ; attacked by Cleon, 6; paradox and exaggeration in works of, 6 ; his character of Cleon, 6, 8 ; his treatment of Pericles, 7; advo- cates a definite and consistent policy, 98 ff. ; proposals of, for confederation, 100; feeling of, for Hellenic unity, 101 ; recog- nises the danger from Persia, 102 Aristotle, as an authority on Athe- nian politics, 10 ; political views of, 10 n. 1 ; on necessity of demo- cracy in a large city, 14 n. 1; definition of extreme democracy by, 18 n. 2 Army, The, numbers of hoplites in, 41, 108 ; pay of, 43 Assembly, The, all power vested in, 16, 17, 121; control of magis- trates by, 16; control of all 136 INDEX. branches of government by, 18; direct power of, 18 ; demagogues in, 62; importance of oratory in, 62; not dominated by the mob, 124 ; struggle of parties in, 125 Athens, as a commercial and mari- time power, 14, 24; almost an island, 15 n. 1 ; as a power in Greece, 24; absolute dominion of sea held by, 25 n. 1 : and the confederacy, 25; relation of, to her subjects, 26; contributed more than the allies, 75 n. 3 ; and Ar- gos, 33, 76 ; existence of, at stake in the war, 117 ; responsible for the war, 133 Chios, faithful to Athens even under an oligarchy, 32 n. 1; harshly treated by the democrats, 72 Cimon, 37 n. 3 ; policy of, 101 Classes, relation of, to political par- ties, 39, 45 ; effects of war on, 115 Cleon, whitewashed by Grote, 3 n. 4 ; description of, by Thucydides, 5 ; attacks of, on Aristophanes, 6; as represented by Aristophanes, 6 ; made known to us by Thucy- dides and Aristophanes, 11; mem- ber of the trading class, 49 n. 1 ; as general, 53; on the council, 63; and finance, 64; raises di- cast's fee, 70; follows Pericles in foreign policy, 72 ; responsible for raising the tribute, 73; attacked by oligarchs, 89 ; in the Equites, 98 n. 2; defeat of, made peace possible, 129 Cleophon, demagogue and general, 53; interest of, in finance, re- moved by the oligarchs, 88 Confederacy, The, held together by democratic feeling, 15; most sea powers included in, 25 n. 2; source of Athenian power, 25, 30, 71; change in the relations of Athens to, 25 nn. 3 6; affairs of, controlled by Athens, 26 ; tri- bute of, 27 (see Tribute); com- pulsory jurisdiction within, 27; attachment of democrats to, 30 ; practically a voluntary league, 30 ; hostility of oligarchs to, 31 ; ne- cessity of, to Athenian democracy, 32; policy of Pericles with re- gard to, 71 ; treatment of, by de- mocrats, 72 Constitution, The Athenian, author- ship of work on, 8 n. 2 ; uncer- tainty of our knowledge of, 12 ; extreme democracy, 14; princi- ples of, 15 n. 3; laws of, re- garded as sacred, 18 n. 1; threat- ened by the war, 34, 118; defence of, by the democrats, 69; de- pended on the sovereignty of law, 79 ; hostility of oligarchs to, 85 ; attitude of middle party to, 95; maintained throughout the war, 132 Com Supply, 112; how affected by the war, 113 n. 4 Council, The, powers of, 17; pay of, 44 ; demagogues on, 63 Demagogues, party agents of the de- mocracy, 51; the chief, 51 (see Trpoararns) ; the lesser, 60 ; ob- jects of, 62 ; in the assembly, 62 ; on the council, 63 : concerned with finance, 63; prosecution of magistrates by, 64; prosecution INDEX. 137 of suspected oligarchs by 65 ; prosecution of allies by, 66 ; sup- posed interests of, in the war, 105; supposed terrorism exer- cised by, 124 Democracy, original authorities un- favourable to the Athenian, 3 n. 3 ; a necessity at Athens, 14 ; bond of union between Athens and the allies, 32; a cause of war, 33; a cause of party divi- sion, 35 ; and tyranny, 54, 55 ; restored at Athens by Alcibiades, 58, 69 n. 1 Democrats, The, principles of policy of, 34, 68 ; policy of, opposed by the middle party, 36 ; triumph of, during the fifth century, 37 ; as a political party, 38 ; and the poorer classes, 45 ; titles applied to, 47, 48 n. 2 ; largely composed of poorer classes, 49 ; leaders of, usually men of wealth, 49; strength of, 50 ; organization of, 50 ; supposed degeneracy of, 67 ; objects of, 68 ; defence of demo- cracy by, 69; and the dicast's fee, 70 ; foreign policy of, 71 ; treatment of the allies by, 72; war policy of, 75 ; plan of war recommended by, 76; their po- licy consistent, 78; and the allies, 99 ; resolve of, to carry on the war, 105, 118, 133 ; sup- posed interest of, in the war, 105 Demophantus, as a demagogue, 61 Demosthenes, supporter of the war policy, 118 Demostratus, and the Sicilian expe- dition, 11, 61 Diodorus, and Athenian history, 10 Diodotus, leader of the moderate party, 11 ; on the revolt of the allies, 32 n. 1 ; treatment of the allies advocated by, 100 Dicasts, irresponsible, 16 ; in theory all Athenians, 16 ; pay of, 44 ; pay of, necessary to system of popular jurisdiction, 70 ; increase of pay of, 70 ; total expenditure on, 70 n. 1 ; pay of, abolished in 411, 70 ; pay of, restored, 71 Elff<; 27 140 INDEX. Phrynichus, work on the Athenian Constitution ascribed to, 8 n. 2 Pisander, as a demagogue, 61; pos- sibly a disguised oligarch, 90, n. 3 Plutarch and Athenian history, 10 Political Parties, uncertainty and difference of opinion on, 12 ; di- vided by political principles, 35 ; divided by questions of the day, 36 ; three in number, 38 ; com- position of, 39, 45; struggle of, throughout the war, 121, 125, 128 ; fairly matched in first part of war, 128 ; government shared between, during peace of Nicias, 129 ; division of, based on regular principles, 132 Politics, Athenian, importance and difficulty of study of, 2 ; inade- quacy and bias of original au- thorities on, 2, 3 ; old view of, 2 ; Grote's view of, 3 ; present esti- mate, 3; no continuous history of, 10 ; foreign politics more im- portant than home, 24; false theory of, 123 ff. Population of Attica, at the begin- ning of the war, 40 ; numbers of different classes of, 41 ; decline of, owing to the war, 107 HopiaTal, 64 n. 2 Hp6j3oiAoi, appointed in 413, 16 n. 1, 96 ; not directly mentioned by Thucydides, 64 n. 2 Hpoo-TaTrjs tov dr/fiov, chief dema- gogue, 51 ; position of not offi- cial, 51; Grote's theory of, 52; not "leader of the opposition," 52 ; often held military command, 53 ; did not often take the field, 54 ; position open to, if also gene- ral, 54 ILpvTavis r<2v (rrpaTrrycou, theory of, 20 ; evidence for existence of, 21 n. 1, 22 nn., 23 nn. ; importance of office of, 24 ; combination of powers of, with political influ- ence, 55 tyrjcpKr/jia, special weapon of the demagogue, 62 ; 98 n. 2 Sicilian Expedition, The, advocated by Alcibiades, 57; part of the democratic policy, 77 ; motives of Athenians in undertaking, 77 ; cause of failure of, 78 n. 1 ; ex- haustion of treasury consequent on, 111 ; regarded as a commer- cial investment, 114; altered the situation of Athens, 117; advo- cated by Alcibiades, 131 Socrates, and the Athenian Consti- tution, 80 n. 1 ; objection of, to the lot, 96 n. 1 Sophists, The, and the Athenian Constitution, 80 n. 1 Sparta, professions of, in under- taking the war, 27 n. 3 ; supports oligarchs against Athens, 31 nn. 1, 2; objects of, in forcing on the war, 33, 117 ; and Argos, 33, 76 ; allied with Persia and Syracuse, 118 ; to blame for beginning the war, 133 State Pay, importance of, exagge- rated, 42, 45; condemned by Aristophanes, 98 Themistocles, efforts of, to make Athens a sea power, 14 Thera, Athens seeks to gain, 26, 72 Theramenes, probable treachery of, INDEX. 141 in 404, 87 ; breaks with the oli- garchs, 97 ; ideal of government of, 97 n. 2 Thessalus, prosecutor of Alcibiades, 11, 57, 90 Thirty, The, violent rule of, 87 n. 2; and the middle party, 97 Thucydides, son of Olorus, as an historian, 4 ; avoids home poli- tics, 4 ; bias of, 5 ; treatment of Antiphon, Hyperbolus and Cleon by, 5 ; does not distinguish poli- tical parties by name, 92 n. 1 Thucydides, son of Melesias, orga- nizes the opposition, 37 ; is os- tracized, 37 Thudippus and the increase of tri- bute, 11, 51, 73 Trade, Athenian, depended on em- pire of sea, 32; conditions of, 113 ; how affected by the war, 114 Tribute of Confederacy , a necessity, 27 ; raised and administered by Athenian officers, 27 ; amount of, at beginning of the war, 72 n. 2 ; doubled in 425, 73; amount of, not excessive, 74 ; original assess- ment of, 74 n. 1 ; reduction of, at different times, 75 n. 1 ; change in method of levying, 75 n. 2 ; as a source of Athenian revenue, 110 Trierarchy, a burden on the rich, 82 ; duty of, divided, 116 Xenophon, contributions of, to his- tory of Athenian politics, 5 ; work on Athenian constitution ascribed to, 8 CAMBRIDGE: PRINTED BY C J. CLAY, M.A. AND SONS, AT THE UNIVERSITY PRESS. APR Lo LOAN DEPT i^-b&i W5,t*S - date due. _l___j^JOjimmed iare reca]1 f ~?Ennsrnbn*-nT-mit ^ oSSSfejsaa, General library A, y u ' 1 1 0942;