HD
UC-NRLF
U
*- c
S vi
*S M H
111
U
bflO)
$
IQI
6
10
$7 86
21 S 72
$8 2^
III
2 \
T T Q A
216 ! 5
fO*4
5-75
192
\ I
J
II.O4
217..., Q i
TO 64
101
II
12 75
218 8 *
9AO
1 04
1
a
i^./i
6 04
2IQ A 1
4v
4 80
IQ5...
I
i
O Q7
220 ' 7
4-y
8 o?
196 . .. .
7
7
y-y/
8 72
!22I Q I
IO 45
197
A
7
4 60
i 222 7 O
1M*K>
8 91
198
2
SO4
22 ? 8 I
O 7O
199
g
8
9O7
224 7
y-o u
8 oc
200
6
u
i
7 oO
"** /
225 7
8O5
201
g
g
II 12
226 7
8 O e
202
10
9OI
.Ul
227 6 6
7 48
201...
'
6
6 11
228 : 4 ii
5 65
204 ..
2
7
oo
8 72
22O A 8
5 >U 3
c 77
205...
II 12
*?y
230 ' 8 5
9*68
206
I
IO 45
271 1 II
4 en
207
II
iu.^3
e 6?
212 . 4 II
4O U
c 65
208
7
II
910
, *?*
27^ ..88
9O7
209
7
8 o^
274... I 1
TTC
210
10
ii 08
*W"
27C T -I
I 44
211
S 1
8 ai
276 A 1
A 80
212
10 ^^
*o' J 4 J
277... ?
4-y
57C
213
IO
11.88
278... ^
1 07
214...
IO
ii 88
Total wages for each week, $382.94. Average for week, $7.94.
Total number of makers, 48.
Total number gloves made, 332 dozen, 10 pairs. Average, 7 dozen.
These averages are slightly below those given in state reports quoted
on pages 27-28.
1 A representative week for workers in regular shops on grade of
men's gloves that compete with imported gloves. (Week ending
August 3, 1911.)
3 2 THE LEATHER GLOVE INDUSTRY
On page 27 we quoted the amount of women's pay
from the State report. In table B we give the actual
pay for makers working under factory conditions.
From these tables it may be seen that wages for full-
time workers are from $10 to $12 per week. It is not at
all uncommon to hear of an individual maker who for a
short period may maintain an average of three dollars
per day. These periods of high production, however,
are usually followed by corresponding times of low pro-
duction or even by an entire cessation of work. Hence
it is not the object of the manager to encourage these
sporadic efforts at speed, since a steady average will
produce better results in the long run.
A large marginal labor element is found in the making
branch of the industry, for many women make gloves for
" pin money." There is scarcely a family of the middle
or lower class of which some woman member does not
make gloves. In a large number of cases, particularly
where the head of the family is a cutter, this is made
necessary by the smallness or uncertainty of the bread-
winner's wages. Thus an increase in the cutter s pay
would automatically cut down the supply of makers, and
this artificial influence added to the natural economic
influence has much to do with the disparity between the
pay of men and women in the glove industry and the
corresponding ratio in other industries*
In making at home mothers are often assisted by a
small child, who can do some of the simpler tasks, such
as matching the smaller pieces with their corresponding
1 The condition of the laboring class is further complicated by the fact
that 80 per cent, of the heads of families in Gloversville have equities in
the houses they occupy, thus greatly affecting their freedom of move-
ment. So long as the whole family can earn a living total they will
remain.
INDUSTRIAL ASPECTS 33
backs and palms from which they have been separated
during the process of silking. The matching is done by
means of the numbers put on by the cutters. Children
could not thus assist in factories under the Labor Law.
The extent to which the wage-earners of Gloversville
and Johnstown depend upon glove-making for employ-
ment makes the welfare of the community depend to an
unusual degree upon the prosperity of this one industry.
If we leave out of account made-to-order cities like
Gary, the industrial situation in Fulton County may well
be said to be unique. The New York Slate Department
of Labor Report for 1902 shows that in 1900 67.2 per
cent, of the value of manufactured products in Glovers-
ville was gloves ; 47 per cent, of the manufactured
products of Johnstown was gloves ; 82 per cent, of
wage earners of Fulton County were employed in gloves
and allied trades ; 87.6 per cent, of wage earners in
Gloversville were thus employed. In 1900 also the
value of the gloves produced in Fulton County was
$9,458,603 or 57.1 per cent, of the total for the United
States. 1
From the foregoing facts it appears that the labor
problems of Fulton County are almost entirely those
of the glove industry. In the summer of 1910 one
manufacturer was reported to have on hand 420,000
dozen of gloves cut and not made. Another large
manufacturer discharged half of his cutting force and
limited the remaining half to twelve dozen per week.
The supply of makers, on the other hand, is never equal
to the demand. For this reason many efforts have been
made by individual manufacturers and the Manufacturers'
l The value of gloves produced in New York City was $586,061;
Buffalo, $106,000; Syracuse, $56,434; Binghamton, $36,263.
34
THE LEATHER GLOVE INDUSTRY
Association to increase the supply of makers. The
Gloversville Board of Trade, controlled by glove manu-
facturers, constantly seeks to increase the number of
families in the city, but by a strange contrast they are
said to oppose the existence of any other industry than
glove making and skin dressing. It is alleged that
efforts are made to keep out other lines of employment
to avoid the possible competition for men's labor.
Gloversville is situated upon a branch railroad. The
unfavorable freight facilities have much to do with this
situation. The materials for glove making are so light
as not to be seriously affected by high carriage charges.
One of the interesting efforts to increase the making
force was the establishment in November, 1909, of an
industrial department in the Gloversville High School to
teach glove making. No official report has yet been
issued. In the absence of such a report the writer made
a personal inspection of the plant. A well-lighted base-
ment room was fitted with a power table and sixteen
machines of standard type.
The class that was working was composed of thirteen
boys and two girls in all stages of progress. The
director is a woman who had had practical experience
as a teacher of beginners in the shops. It was interest-
ing to watch the development of the pupils in various
stages.
Practically all classes of the population were repre-
sented. German, Italian, American and among the rest
the son of a leading politician. One of the most notable
facts in connection with this school-shop is the fact that
boys are engaged in making. They are being trained
with a view to developing more careful businessmen for
the industry. Many attempts have been made in the
past to train boys at a later age and also to train men
INDUSTRIAL ASPECTS 35
to take up making, but the nimbleness of fingers seems
to be lacking and there is a general feeling on the part
of boys that making is "women's work." Some of the
far-sighted men in the industry realize that to maintain
a normal and balanced community the superiority of
men's earning power must be established or, at least,
ways must be found to enable a man in the industry to
earn wages sufficient to maintain a family without the
necessity for the assistance of his wife or children of
school age. These men look forward with hope to the
educating influence of the industrial department of the
public school.
Changes are going on slowly in the methods of manu-
facture and factory organization. The complaint was
constantly made in the older days that the manufacture
was all guesswork. A fine scorn was shown for accu-
rate cost accounting. The manufacturer then was his
own foreman, and if the shop were not in his own back-
yard he sat down on the block with his dinner-pail and
visited with the men as they all ate together.
A study of the census figures shows that in 1905 the
number of factories was less than in 1900. This is largely
due to the introduction of machinery in some of the less
skilled branches. For example, a machine has been in-
vented for shaving or grinding the skins. This machine
reduces the cost of the process from $i per dozen skins
to $0.083^. Again, the cutting of linings for some of
the cheaper grades of children's gloves cost the smaller
manufacturer in earlier times about $0.06 per dozen pairs
of gloves. The modern manufacturer uses a machine
which reduces the cost to $o.oi^i per dozen pairs. Each
of the large manufacturers employs a statistical expert to
check cost accounting. The closeness of the computa-
tion is shown by the bids for some of the army contracts,
36 THE LEATHER GLOVE INDUSTRY
where the prices of the various competitors sometimes
differ as little as two cents per pair. There yet remain
factories that produce at a disadvantage. Their presence
is on the whole detrimental to the industry because they
must cover inefficient methods largely by reducing wages
below the rate established by the Manufacturers' Associ-
ation. Efficiency and organization throughout the whole
industry is not so high as we have a right to expect it to
be in a protected industry.
LABOR ORGANIZATION
Records of union organization in Fulton County, New
York, are very hard to obtain. In the Manufacturers 1
Brief submitted to the Ways and Means Committee (p.
12) the statement is made that there exists no union in
the industry or any combination of manufacturers to
control the price of the product. The New York State
Department of Labor Reports, however, contain returns
from the Table Cutters' Union. ' This fact will be ex-
plained later in the present chapter.
It is true that the Manufacturers Association does
not approve of the existence of a labor union. It is
their fiat that there shall not be one, and as a conse-
quence the men will not admit membership in the union
or talk about labor conditions. Hence most of the in-
formation must be got from outside sources. But in a
city as small as Gloversville, where the welfare of all
business is so intimately connected with a single indus-
try, information as to the conditions of that industry is
pretty generally distributed. And by comparison it is
found that the various reports agree in substance.
The earliest record is that as a part of the Knights of
1 M Y. State Department of Labor Report, 1908, p. 116.
INDUSTRIAL ASPECTS 37
Labor movement a strike was declared in 1881 for cash
payments. The strike was won by the men and no
further activity was, shown until 1893 when, in anticipa-
tion of the Wilson Tariff, the manufacturers announced
a cut in wages from $0.90 per dozen pairs to $0.80 per
dozen pairs for cutting standard grades of gloves. In
the face of the explanation that the reduced Tariff made
the cut necessary, the men accepted the new rate, but
began to organize their union on a fighting basis.
No further change occurred until September, 1897,
when after the passage of the Dingley Tariff, a demand
was made by the cutters for the restoration of the rate
of $0.90 per dozen, in existence before the cut of 1893.
At this time the rate for cutting was agreed upon by an
annual conference between the representatives of the
Manufacturers and the International Glove Table Cutters'
Union. The Manufacturers refused to make the advance
and a strike was declared, which lasted eleven weeks.
A compromise was finally reached at an advance of 10
per cent, or $0.88. Here we see a saving of two cents
per dozen resulting to the manufacturers as the net
result of the two changes extending over a period of
four years.
The annual conference agreement remained in force
whereby the manufacturers continued to treat with the
cutters as a unit until the fall of 1903. Then a demand
was made that the men individually sign an agreement
to work with any one who might be put into the shops.
Of course this meant the ultimate overthrow of the
union and the establishment of the open shop. The
practical success of the strike of 1897 and the final effect
of the terms of the proposed agreement, persuaded the
cutters to resist. Moreover, it was generally thought
that the real purpose of the manufacturers was to abro-
38 THE LEATHER GLOVE INDUSTRY
gate the existing agreement so far as to enable them to
employ Russian cutters who were being driven out of
Warsaw about that time.
The importance of this demand further illustrated by
the fact that in 1901 an action had been brought at the
instigation of the International Glove Cutters, to recover
a penalty from a firm of glove manufacturers in Grinnell,
Iowa, 1 under the contract labor law. So important is
this case in its effect upon the relation of laborers and
manufacturers in the industry that an extract from the
opinion in the case is worthy of attention.
United States v. Morrison, 109 Fed. Reporter 891,
(Dist. Court, S. D., Iowa C. D. May 14, 1901.)
On demurrer to Information.
The information filed is in two counts. The first count in
substance charges that defendant a resident of Grinnell, Iowa,
did in June 1900 aid in bringing- from Prague, Austria one
Adolph Zuza, a cutter of ladies kid gloves, who was then a
native, resident and citizen of Prague, Austria, and then a
subject to the Emperor of Austria.
The information further charges that while Zuza was to
perform labor in this country, and under which agreement
Zuza came to the U. S. with money furnished him by the
defendant for his transportation, that the agreement preceded
furnishing the aid and preceeded Zuza's coming to America
pursuant to the agreement, and after having received the aid
in transportation from the defendant to perform in the U. S.
the services and labor of cutting ladies' kid gloves and the
information then changes.
" And the said Adolph Zuza was not . . . then and there a
skilled workman under any contract and agreement to per-
form labor and services in the United States in or upon any
'U. S. v. D. S. Morrison, U. S. Dist. Court, Des Moines, unre-
ported case.
INDUSTRIAL ASPECTS
39
industry not then established in the United States, and not
established in the U. S., February 26, A. D., 1885."
The grounds for the demurrer are that a ladies' kid glove
cutter is an expert mechanic ; that he is not a person engaged
in common or ordinary labor ; that the business requires
skill, that Feb. 26, 1885, the business of making ladies' kid
gloves was not an established industry in the U. S.; that the
trade of a ladies' kid glove cutter requires skill and intelli-
gence and is an art or profession known to but very few
persons in the world. The count then recites the history of
the Contract Labor Law and continues. But the truth is that
the protective Tariff laws and the laws against importing an
alien laborer are upon the same subject and have the same
purpose in view, which is that of protecting the laboring man
of our country from the competition of the laboring man of
foreign lands. And the subject of " kid gloves " as it is found
in the schedules of the last formed tariff laws of the United
States, will show the ever-increasing concern of congress to
not simply raise a revenue, but to bring about the manu-
facture of such gloves in this country.
The practical effect of all this and especially the result of
the tariff act of 1897 is of great interest. But so far as this
case is concerned the difficulty is not to get the information
but to get information of which a court will take judicial
notice, ... I have made the most diligent and tireless search
in the reports of the departments for data and facts germane
to the imports of ladies' gloves, and the manufacturer thereof
in this country and received practically no information. It
is plain to me that the tariff laws, and especially the one now
in force had for one of its objects either the creation of the
industry, if not already established, or its maintenance if
already established. And this perhaps is the one question in
this case ; Is the manufacture of ladies' kid gloves an estab-
lished business in the U. S.? If established, when was it
established?
But the U. S. Attorney charges in the information and
charges it most specifically that February 26, 1885, as well as
4 THE LEATHER GLOVE INDUSTRY
in the year 1890, the manufacture of ladies' kid gloves was
an established industry in the United States. This allegation
calls for proof and the government must furnish it. And it
follows that the demurrer must be overruled because of the
allegations in the information. I have a belief touching them,
but it may be that the government will furnish evidence, of
which I know nothing ; at all events I cannot judicially
notice the facts, and the material facts are practically all in
dispute. What are the duties of a ladies' glove cutter ? Is it
skilled labor ? Can it readily be procured in this country ?
Is it an occupation or profession? Is it an established busi-
ness in this country? If so, when was it established? Some
of these questions, probably all, are involved. So I will sub-
mit the facts to the jury to find the facts. We will then know
the services of a ladies' glove cutter ; ... we will learn how
extensively ladies' kid gloves were manufactured in the United
States, February 26, 1885, and how extensively they were
manufactured in 1890 ; we will ascertain whether it is true
that there are but few such cutters in the United States, and
possible but the one, or but few at most, of such west of the
Mississippi river, and but few in the country; ... we will
learn the truth of this and the statute will be construed so as
to give aid to the American laborers and not such construction
as to throw them out of employment.
In the hearing upon the case for the determination of
the facts referred to, part of the evidence submitted con-
sisted of the files of the Gloversville newspapers, contain-
ing advertisements for cutters. The decision held that
these advertisements were sufficient to show a need for
more men in the industry in the United States, and that
the testimony tended to show that the International
Glove Cutters' Union was a closed corporation, since by
its rules the trade could only go from father to son.
Therefore recovery could not be made, and importation
of cutters under contract could not be stopped. The
INDUSTRIAL ASPECTS 4 I
cutters maintained that there never were any places open,
that the advertisements had been run for the purpose of
making ^prima facie case under just such circumstances.
However this may be, the decision referred to, together
with the coming of the Russian cutters, no doubt had
much to do with the demand of the manufacturers at this
time.
On December 21, 1903, the men decided to strike.
The struggle lasted until June 28, 1904. A few shops
ran all through the strike, but the industry was prac-
tically crippled. The Union was beaten and broken.
Since that time all but a few small shops have been run
on the open-shop basis.
About 1907 the union referred to at the beginning of
this chapter, and reported in the New York State Re-
ports, was formed. It may more properly be called a
philosophical union than anything else, so the statement
of the manufacturers to the Ways and Means Committee
may be said to be true in substance.
The contrast between the apparent intent of the deci-
sion quoted and its effect upon the industry is clearly
evident from the consequences which have followed the
decision. Curiously enough the majority of the men in
the Cutters' Union in 1907 were those admitted to the
United States as a result of this decision. They were
used as instruments to break the earlier union and are
now the nucleus of the existing union.
Reference is here made only to the Glove Cutters'
Union. There has never been a union among makers in
Fulton County. This is undoubtedly due to the fact
which we have already noted, that the supply of makers
is far below the demand at all times. The natural result
is a correspondingly favorable treatment of makers and
relatively high pay. The rates are assumed to be uni-
4 2 THE LEATHER GLOVE INDUSTRY
form, but undoubtedly even in the face of disapproval on
the part of the Manufacturers' Association special rates
may secretly be extended to specially skilled sewers.
THE MANUFACTURERS' ASSOCIATION
The existence of a strong organization in the labor
field of any industry implies that sooner or later there
must be an equally strong association of manufacturers,
otherwise the labor force by piecemeal attack will event-
ually drive out profits.
This is the case in the glove industry. The early
associations, both of cutters and manufacturers, were not
strong, but following the strikes of 1897 the Interna-
tional Glove Cutters' Union grew to such power that an
association of manufacturers was formed to resist the
demands of the cutters. This organization is in exist-
ence to-day, and to it may be traced many of the real
advances that have come to the industry. The present
association was organized in 1902 under the voluntary
associations law of New York State. 1 It is an unincor-
porated body.
The membership in the association while not restricted
to, is in fact confined to, manufacturers in Gloversville
and Johnstown who make chiefly fine dress gloves. Al-
though its membership in point of volume of production
of fine gloves represents about 50 per cent, in numbers
of manufacturers it includes not more than 20 per cent,
or about thirty members. Membership is by firms, not
by individuals.
The first real problem of the association was the strike
of 1903, and it proved a severe test to the organization.
We have pointed out that the Cutters' Union having
'Mr. James Warbasse, Secretary Glove Manufacturers' Association.
INDUSTRIAL ASPECTS 43
won the strike of 1897 had grown in strength. The first
point of attack by the union had been the suit previously
mentioned, to prevent the importation or employment of
any cutters not members of the union. Encouraged by
the decision, in this case favorably to the manufacturers,
the Association decided to force matters, with the result
that they broke the union and have maintained an open-
shop basis since that time. There is only one small
union shop in Fulton County.
The general trend of the efforts of the association has
been for the improvement of the industry and the estab-
lishment of a higher plane of efficiency. The uniform
rate of pay has had a tendency to prevent constant shift-
ing about of the cutters. It has not been quite so suc-
cessful in the case of makers. Another point that must
not be overlooked is that the association makes for
standardization of output and reliability of goods. In
this it reminds us of the strict regulations as to quality
which were in force in the Scotish guilds of glove
makers.
So far as the association has assisted in keeping down
the wages of men, and in this the open shop probably is
the only definite step, the effect has been on the whole
bad for the trade because the low average wages paid to
cutters is already having its effect upon the supply of
cutters which hitherto has equaled or exceeded the
demand. Boys will not take up a trade with so little
certainty and promise. During the summer of 1912
reports began to be current of an actual shortage of
cutters. In time this must act to force up wages but
only if some degree of certainty can be established in
the industry.
In matters outside of the manufacture proper the
association has been active. In the legislative steps
44 THE LEATHER GLOVE INDUSTRY
leading up to the Payne-Aldrich Tariff act the association
played a prominent part as shown by the hearings of the
Ways and Means Committee. 1 The real future of the
industry is along the line of permanent settling of the
Tariff and strengthening of the Manufacturers Associa-
tion which will then be able to devote its attention to
building up the industry from within.
FACTORY DISTRIBUTION
There is practically no such thing in the glove industry
as a factory district in the usual sense of the term, and
no necessity for the development of a sweat-shop district
or plan of manufacture. Factories are located in widely-
scattered parts of the cities and in the majority of cases
have plenty of air and light. This scattered distribution
has its influence upon the health and the whole life of
the community. Little stores are situated at intervals
along all the residence streets, and bakers' wagons go
about announcing their coming by the ringing of a bell.
So busy are most of the housekeepers that they will not
take time to go to a common shopping or marketing
center. The doorbell is often answered by a woman with
an unfinished glove in her hand. A great amount of
work is sent into the homes of the workers. This is
easy because of the lightness of the goods and their small
bulk. Occasionally one sees a small boy carrying a
bundle of unfinished or finished gloves to or from the
factory, but by far the greater part of the distributing is
done by the agents of the manufacturer, who go about
in a wagon or automobile. The distribution is really
done at the expense of the makers, for a lower price is
paid for some work done out of the factory than is paid
1 Tariff Hearings, Nov. 28, 1908.
INDUSTRIAL ASPECTS 45
for the same grade of work done in the factory. 1 We
must keep in mind also that in most cases factory makers
are compelled to furnish their own machines and to pay
for repairs upon them.
Through the courtesy of one of the manufacturers the
writer was permitted to accompany his agent in his
rounds and covered in the course of a forenoon most of
the streets of Gloversville. The driver, who has had six-
teen years' experience in that particular business, states
that practically every street in the city has some houses
where glove making in some of its branches is done.
The power wires running from poles in the street to the
houses also corroborate this statement.
The Fulton County Gas and Electric Company re-
ported in 1910 that they had 1000 motors in private
houses or small privately-owned buildings, for use in
driving sewing machines. The number given includes
both Gloversville and Johnstown. In 1911 the same
company reported that the number had risen to 1300.
Upon a rough estimate this number would represent an
average of one motor in every four or five houses. Some
families have more than one, so the actual number of
dwellings wired for power would be a little below the
average of one in five. A standing charge of fifty cents
per month is made for installing the motors and the total
cost is about $1.20 to $1.50 per month. The extended
use of motors in this way is one of the most significant
facts of the industry. Some home operators report that
the use of the motor- driven machine increases their out-
put by one dozen pairs per day. Judged by factory
standards of production this estimate seems rather high,
it may be explained by the fact that in home work
'See Appendix I.
46 THE LEATHER GLOVE INDUSTRY
hours are not limited as in the factory. This industry,
through the peculiar system of putting out gloves, forms
an interesting link between industry and agriculture,
enabling workers to live at great distances from the fac-
tory, where they can have gardens and plenty of room.
The increased use of electric power, although holding
possibilities of increased nervous strain, yet offers great
physical relief and makes possible the use of the many
small water powers in which the foot-hills of the Adiron-
dacks abound. The limits of the industry may also be
greatly extended by the use of the automobile for col-
lecting and distributing gloves, and the establishment of
the parcel post may do much in this direction.
CHAPTER VI
TARIFFS.
IN the preceding chapters we have made a brief study
of the history, organization, wages and labor conditions,
of the glove industry. It is the purpose of this chapter
to ascertain the exact bearing of the tariff rate upon the
industry.
The vital questions are : First, who are the persons or
classes effected by the tariff? Second, can the industry
exist without the tariff? And third, what facts should
determine the rate of tariff?
In answer to the second question we may quote from
the Argument of the Manufacturers' Association before
the Ways and Means Committee. " Before the McKinley
Act of 1890 there was no glove industry in the United
States competing in our markets with foreign made
gloves." 1
Previous to 1890 the rate of duty on men's fine gloves
was 50 per cent, ad valorem. Much litigation resulted
upon charges of undervaluation and from the adminis-
trative point of view the ad valorem rate was not satis-
factory. Hence in framing the McKinley law the rate
was made 50 per cent, plus $1.00 per dozen pairs. This
rate also proved unsatisfactory and in 1894 the rate was
made entirely specific and fixed at $4 per dozen pairs.
The Dingley law in 1897 left the rate on men's gloves
unchanged. The rate as fixed on men's gloves in 1909
'See Appendix III.
47
4 8 THE LEATHER GLOVE INDUSTRY
is also $4 per dozen pairs. Certain cumulative items
may bring the total up to $4.80 per dozen pairs. 1
This means that for every pair of men's gloves made
in the United States or imported to the United States
the wearer may be forced to pay thirty to forty cents
extra because of the tariff. In fact the testimony of the
Manufacturers' representative before the Ways and Means
Committee shows this to be true. 2
On women's gloves the duty under the present law is
from $1.25 to $2.50 per dozen pairs.
The explanation of this difference between the rates
on men's and women's gloves brings out a curious state
of affairs. According to Mr. Frederick Brooks, who
appeared before the Ways and Means Committee, as
counsel for the importers, the question of the tariff rate
on gloves had been considered ever since 1890 as settled
upon a basis of division of the field. By this actual or
tacit agreement, the importers were given control of the
market in ladies' gloves, while the men's glove business
was left to the domestic producers. 3
The effect of the difference in rate is shown by a study
of the percentage of production of the two kinds of
gloves in the United States. About 95 per cent, of the
men's fine gloves used in the United States are made
here while only about 5 per cent, or 6 per cent, of the
women's gloves used in the United States are made
here. 4 Two factors are found here, however, one the
larger profit on men's gloves and the other the smallness
of the trained labor force. The latter fact was brought
out in the preceding chapter.
*See Tariff Law, Appendix IX.
1 Tariff Hearings, Nov. 28, 1908.
8 This statement does not appear in the Hearings, but was made to
the writer by Mr. Brooks in an intervie^w. ^
4 Tariff Hearings, Nov. 28, 1908, pp/-S5i3 seq.
TARIFFS 49
Clearly, then, the admitted increase of selling price of
men's gloves entitles the public to know the facts upon
which are based the tariff rate making the increase
possible.
The manufacturer argues that he does not get the in-
crease, that it is just sufficient to cover the difference in
cost of production in American and European glove-pro-
ducing centers. Our problem now is to trace this tax
to its point of incidence.
To answer our first question we must first lay down
some principles by which to test the tax. Three groups
must be considered: the laborers, the manufacturers,
and the consuming public. The first two classes are to
a degree identical with the third class, but the degree is
so slight that we may say they are mutually exclusive.
To the laborer the question of importance in a tariff
rate is the question as to whether the rate is sufficient
to enable him to collect wages to cover the cost of liv-
ing according to the standard of his own country.
To the manufacturer it is important to have tariff
high enough to enable him to pay a rate of wages suffi-
iently high to attract laborers from the competing trades
of his own country and leave a margin for a reasonable
profit. In considering the rate upon a single product
the question of the equivalence between the wages of the
workers in the foreign and domestic fields is of less
immediate importance than the relative rates of pay in
the given industry and in other domestic industries
demanding labor of the same grade.
The consumer appears to be the person upon whom
the benefits are last conferred but upon whom the
burden falls immediately in the form of an increased
price. The weight of the burden in the glove industry
has been indicated in paragraph 5 of this chapter.
5 THE LEATHER GLOVE INDUSTRY
So long as the manufacturer conducts his business
upon a purely individual basis and does not ask for help
from the public in the form of tariff restriction, we may
fairly say he is entitled to secrecy in his business and the
profits which he may make from it; but as soon as he
asks for a protective rate, the burden of which falls upon
the consumer, the public is entitled to such information
concerning his business as will enable its agents to place
the rate at the lowest possible point.
This investigation should always keep in mind the
bearing of the determination upon the laborers in the
industry as well as upon the general public.
As stated in the introduction, the glove industry
presents a striking example of the relation between
economic theory and practical politics. Before the Ways
and Means Committee on November 28, 1908,' there
appeared representatives of the importers of gloves and
also a representative of the Glove Manufacturers' As-
sociation of the United States. Though the consuming
public is frequently mentioned in the discussion, it is
rather as an argument for one side or the other side
than out of consideration for the consumer himself.
To settle the third and most important question of
this chapter we must examine the available data as to
wages paid in the glove industry in the United States
and Europe. For the purpose of determining the basis
of a tariff rate the glove industry offers some advantages
not found in many other industries. In the first place
nearly all of the processes of manufacture are paid for at
piece rates. Hence the labor cost per unit of product'
can be found directly from the wages paid. In the sec-
/^^J
1 Tariff Hearings, Ways and Means Com., Nov. 28, 1908. p.' ,2516,
seq.
'The unit in the glove industry is one dozen pairs.
TARIFFS -!
ond place very little machinery is employed, nearly all the
processes being carried on by hand. In the third place
most of the machinery and tools used in the American
system of manufacture, at least, is owned by the laborers,
who at the time of the passage of the Payne-Aldrich law
even paid charges for power used in driving such of them
as are power-driven, thus relieving the manufacturer of
part of his overhead charges. Hence we see that wages
represent practically the whole manufacturing cost.
The Bulletin of Information for the Committee, 1908,
shows that the principal sources of supply for imported
gloves are England, Germany and France. The fixing
of labor cost of gloves made in these countries is a diffi-
cult process as compared with the determination of sim-
ilar costs in the United States. The wages paid in the
United States are uniform, and are fixed by the Glove
Manufacturers' Association. 1 Previous to 1903, while
the Glove Cutters' Association was strong, the rates
were fixed by conferences of representatives of the man-
ufacturers and cutters, but at present there is, as we
have shown, no effective organization of cutters with
which the manufacturers can confer, and there never has
been an organization of makers in Fulton County.
Hence the rates cannot represent a united agreement.
In foreign countries there is no organization similar
to the Glove Manufacturers' Association of the United
States. No general figures are obtainable for English
costs nor for the earnings of English glove workers.
Two affidavits of individual makers were submitted to
the Ways and Means Committee, but no attempt is made
to show that these rates are representative of costs all
over England, and furthermore they cover only a single
'See Schedule, Appendix I.
cj2 THE LEATHER GLOVE INDUSTRY
part of fabrication cost. Many of the leading English
firms maintain factories in the United States and conse-
quently are in a position to furnish the complete facts if
they chose to do so. While our tariff schedules are
made upon the present bases they will simply shift the
manufacture for their trade in the United States from
one country to the other as the rate varies.
In the case of German manufacturing costs we are
somewhat better off from the fact that figures represent-
ing cost of fabrication were submitted to the Ways and
Means Committee l by representatives of the importers
and also by representatives of the Glove Manufacturers'
Association of the United States. The German Govern-
ment also submitted certain statements which are, how-
ever, merely assertions of isolated costs and are not shown
to be representative. 2 Hence we are thrown back upon
a comparison of costs as estimated by the importers and
manufacturers.
It is readily seen that the tendency of each advocate in
a controversy of this sort will be to represent the facts
in the light most favorable to his side. This does not
imply bad faith, but comes from the fact that it is gen-
erally understood that the final determination will in all
probability be a compromise. The tendency of the do-
mestic manufacturer will be to underestimate the foreign
cost and overestimate his own, and thus secure the ben-
efits of an overestimated difference in cost. In the same
way the foreigner will overestimate his own cost to get
the benefit of a rate fixed upon too low an estimated dif-
ference. Consequently when we find an estimate of the
1 Tariff Hfarings, Nov. 28, 1908, p.'-2523> Sen. Doc. 68, 6ist Cong.,
p. 42; Sen. Doc. 74, 6ist Cong.
2 Senate Document 68, part 2, 6ist Cong., ist Session.
TARIFFS 53
two sides in agreement we may fairly say that it repre-
sents the actual cost.
For a given sample of gloves the manufacturers' repre-
sentative estimated the German fabrication cost at $2.14
per dozen pairs. 1 The cost of manufacturing a similar
kind in Germany, as stated by the importers, varies from
$1.51 to $1.91 per dozen pairs.
The cost of manufacturing the same sample of gloves
in the United States, as stated by the manufacturers'
representative, is $5.49 per dozen pairs, and as stated by
the importers it is $3.72.
We note that there is substantial agreement in Ger-
man cost of fabrication and a wide divergence in the
estimated cost of fabrication in the United States.
Hence we have made an attempt to reach the actual cost
in the United States by adding together the cost of the
various parts of the work as found in the Manufacturers'
Schedule and adding an allowance for the parts of the
work not covered by piece rates (general expenses).
This allowance is determined by adding to higher general
expenses, as stated in the importers' schedule, for Ger-
man cost 30 per cent. This computation gives us $3.50,
a sum even higher than the importers' estimate. It
must be noted in connection with this estimate that we
are using net labor costs, and that an added number of
inspections would change the total. We are, however,
including all costs as found in the average or ordinary
factory.
The following tables, I and III, present the facts sub-
mitted to the committe as a basis for action. Table II
(as indicated in the introductory notes) is our own com-
bination of the various costs. We note in Table I the
Tariff Hearings, p.
54
THE LEATHER GLOVE INDUSTRY
tendency to which we have referred, namely, the attempt
to overestimate costs to obtain a favorable difference.
The item " Dyeing," included in Table I, is not a proper
making charge, but is part of the process of finishing
leather. To make the comparison a fair one, this item
must be subtracted, as indicated in the table.
TABLE I
COST OF MANUFACTURING GLOVES IN GERMANY 1
Lamb and schmaschen, 3 inch, men's and ladies'
Marks per Marks per
dozen. dozen.
Dyeing (not proper making charge) 1.50 2.00
Cutting 2.30 2.80
Trimming 10 .20
Sewing (including material) 2.30 2.80
Laying or dressing 30 .40
General expenses 1.50 2.00
8.00 10.20
Less item I (not proper making charge) 6.50 8.20
Equivalent in United States money 2 .................. $1.51 $1.91
General expenses include foremen, tacking, polishing, making press
cutting, stamping, ridelling, and blacking.
From these figures we must attempt to ascertain the
real difference in labor cost in the United States and
Germany. Combining these various estimates we get
widely varying results, as may be seen from the tables
following.
If we accept the estimate of the American manufac-
turers as to costs in both countries, we obtain a differ-
ence of $3.25 per dozen. If we accept the figures of the
importers as to costs in both countries, we have, re-
spectively, $2.21 and $1.81, as we take the low or high
estimate for German costs.
1 Tariff Hearings , 1908, p. 523. Statement submitted to Ways and
Means Committee by Importers of Gloves.
1 Mark taken as equal to 24 cents.
TARIFFS 55
TABLE II
COST OF MANUFACTURING MEN'S GLOVES 1 IN THE UNITED STATES
Column I, prices as found in Manufacturers' Schedule for 1910.
(Same as for 1908). See Appendix I.
Column 2, prices as found in Importers' Statement, Tariff Hearings,
P- 2523.
Price per Price per
dozen. dozen.
Shaving $0.30
Cutting 90 $1.20
Slitting 10
Trimming (included) 10
Needle sewing 18
Silking (included) 18 .35
Pulling 06
Making ^ i.io i.oo
Hemming t,'- 12 .15
Laying off .15
Fastening
Tacking .12
Examining .20
Sciling .55
Banding
Boxing
$3-04 $3.72
Add allowance for processes not paid for by piece .
rates 467
$3.507
Now using our own estimates (Table II) of the
United States' cost and the importers' estimate of
German cost we have as the difference in labor cost
$1.99 or $1.59 according to whether we take the low or
high estimate for German cost. Using our estimate for
United States' cost and the American manufacturers'
estimate of German cost we have $1.36.
1 General expenses are computed as being slightly more than 307 per
cent, higher in United States than in Germany. The total ad valorem
equivalent of present tariff is 41 per cent. (Information for Committee,
1908). Cost of fabrication of women's gloves is the same as for men's
gloves.
5 6 THE LEATHER GLOVE INDUSTRY
TABLE III
COST OF FABRICATION IN GRENOBLE, MEN'S AND LADIES ' ; 3-INCH OVER-
SEAM. NO FASTENINGS
Column i, low cost; column 2, high cost.
Francs per dozen.
Cutting (riddling) 3.150 3.25
Choosing 1.50
Stamping , 025
Press cutting OQO .09
Cutting glove to length 015 .05
Cutting thumbs and fourchettes 355
i row embroidery or point .300 .75
End pulling .150
Closing 1. 100 1.90
Matching fourchettes .090 .09
Thumbs i.ioo
Tacking tapes (Col. 2 Rabbatur) 300 .25
Sewing welts and bandalettes 400 .40
Tacking welts and bandalettes 250 .30
Blacking no .10
Tacking together 035 .05
Dressing 300 .30
Polishing 100
Salaries 1.560
Dyeing 1.470 1.50
Silk .314 .15
Thread 077
T>Pe 155
General 1.335 3.50
12.481 14.18
Less dyeing, not a proper making charge 1-470 1.50
ii.oii 12.68
Equivalent in United States money $2.20 $ 2 53
To summarize these facts, the American manufacturer
says the difference of labor cost in the manufacture of a
dozen pairs of gloves in Germany and the United States
is $3.25 ; the importer says it varies from $1.81 to $2. 21.
Our computation puts the difference between $1.36 and
$1.99. The tariff rate (which includes 20 per cent, duty
on the raw material) is $4.80.
In the following tables we present the computations
from which these conclusions are drawn.
Jc ?S
1 Tariff Hearings > Nov. 28, 1908, p.**5-23. Statement submitted to
Ways and Means Committee by Importers of Gloves.
TARIFFS 57
It must be observed that in Table I the first item has
not been included in the total since it is not a proper
charge upon making cost. If then we compare the
results found with the statement of German cost as
found in the estimate of the American Manufacturers,
we have a fair working basis as follows :
CASE A l
Cost of fabrication (for sample shown) in Gloversville $5-49
Cost of fabrication (for sample shown) in Germany 2.14
Difference in labor cost $3-35
Add tariff on raw material (20 per cent, adval.} 1.25
Labor cost difference in Gloversville and Germany $4.60
Rate of present tariff $4.80
CASE B
Cost of fabrication in United States $3-72
Cost of fabrication in Germany 1.51
Difference in cost in United States and Germany $2.21
Add tariff on raw material 1.25
$3^46
In Case B we have taken the American cost as stated
by the importers a and deducted from it the low cost as
found in Table I. Now let us take cost of manufacture
in United States as determined in column i of Table II
and we have the following :
CASE C
Cost of fabrication in United States $3-50
Cost of fabrication in Germany 1.51
Difference in labor cost in Germany and United States $i-99
Add tariff on raw material 1.25
Rate of tariff just equal to difference $3.24
If now we substitute in these computations a rate of
cost in Germany equal to the higher set of corrected
figures in Table I, we have :
1 Tariff Hearings, p.sj^3. f See Table II.
58 THE LEATHER GLOVE INDUSTRY
CASE B'
Cost of fabrication in United States $3.72
Cost of fabrication in Germany i.gi
Difference in labor cost $1.81
Add tariff on raw material ... 1.25
Rate of tariff just equal to difference $3.06
CASE C
Cost of fabrication in United States $3.50
Cost of fabrication in Germany 1.91
Difference in labor cost $1.50
Add tariff on raw material 1.25
Rate of tariff just equals difference $2.84
For further comparison let us turn to Table III for
the costs of fabrication in France as reported in the im-
porters' statements. There is no such method of check-
ing these figure* as we found in the case of the German
manufacture, because the manufacturers of the United
States did not include in their evidence any statements
as to cost in France. The rates of wages as given in
Dr. Cote's 1 study of the French industry are so varied
that it is impossible to reach a basis of comparison even
for the part of the work covered. He gives only the fig-
ures for cutting costs, which represent not more than
one-quarter of the total fabrication cost. It must be
noted that we have eliminated from the table certain
items which are not properly included in the costs of
fabrication, but are a part of the cost of raw material,
which is assumed to be the same in all these compari-
sons. Comparing costs from Tables II and III by the
same methods which are used in comparing German and
United States cost of fabrication, we see that using the
American manufacturers' estimates of cost of fabrication
in the United States and the importers' statement of
'Cote, U Industrie gantiere , etc.
TARIFFS 59
cost of fabrication in France we get a difference in labor
cost of $3.29, or $2.96, according to whether we are
using the low or high estimate of cost in France.
Using our own estimate of cost as found in the United
States and the importers' estimates of cost in France, the
only ones obtainable, we have $1.30, or $0.97 as the dif-
ference.
Or, in other words, the manufacturers' figures would
show that it costs from $2.96 to $3.29 more to make a
dozen pairs of gloves in the United States than it costs
in France.
The importers say that it costs from $1.19 to $1.52
more to make a dozen pairs of gloves in the United
States than it costs in France.
Our estimate shows that it costs from $0.97 to $1.30
more to make a dozen pairs of gloves in the United
States than it costs in France.
The computations upon which these facts are derived
are placed here for convenience :
Case D. Case E. Case F.
Cost of fabrication in United States $3-72 $3-50 $S-4Q
Cost of fabrication in France 2.20 2.20 2.20
Difference in labor cost $1.52 $1.30 $3.20
Add tariff on raw material 1.25 1.25 1.25
Tariff just equal to difference $2.77 $2.55
Present rate of tariff $4.80 $4,80
Case D'. Case E'. Case F'.
Cost of fabrication in United States $3.72 $3-50 $5-40
Cost of fabrication in France 2.53 2.53 2.53
Difference in labor cost $1.19 $0.97 $2.96
Add tariff on raw material 1.25 1.25 1.25
Tariff just equal to difference $2.55 $2.22 $4.21
Present rate of tariff $4.80 $4.80 $4.80
These computations assume the accuracy of the costs
as shown in the Tables I, II and III and make no allow-
60 THE LEATHER GLOVE INDUSTRY
ance for a margin to cover "reasonable profit." We
believe that what is wanted first of all is an exact deter-
mination of the absolute difference in the fabrication
cost of the product in question. When we have secured
this net difference it will be a simple matter to add to it
a percentage or general allowance which will be the
same for all industries. All the computations further
assume the use of a grade of leather suitable for making
gloves to sell at $12.50 per dozen, wholesale. It is in
this way that we derive the amount to be added for
tariff on raw material. The testimony at the Tariff
Hearings shows that 20 per cent, on raw material is
equal to about 10 per cent, of the value of the finished
goods.
While leather suitable for making fine gloves is manu-
factured in the United States, yet the percentage in
proportion to the total consumption is small and if we
eliminate "Mocha" in the production of which the
Americans have a practical monopoly, we see that the
benefit of the tariff on raw material is very little dis-
tributed. On the other hand, the burden of this part of
the tariff falls on all consumers. In the Hearings of
1908, the manufacturers asked to have this part of the
tariff continued, on the ground that while asking for
protection for themselves they could not consistently
withhold their support from the allied branch of the
industry. While we cannot overlook the generosity of
the argument as between the manufacturers of gloves
and leather, we must also remember that the contribu-
tion to the leather manufacturer comes from the con-
suming public and not from the makers of gloves.
The feeling among the producers of leather is that if
compelled to submit to a reduction of the tariff, the
manufacturers of gloves will consent to the removal of
the duty on the raw material first of all.
TARIFFS 61
The only effect of the removal of the tariff on raw
material upon the manufacturer of gloves will be to re-
duce slightly the amount of capital required to carry on
his business. The effect upon the maker of glove-
leather may be more serious, but with that we cannot
deal here. As we have shown in Chapters I and II, the
raw material for the glove manufacturer is tanned leather,
and we are necessarily concerned here with getting the
cheapest possible supply of raw material.
The saving to the consumer from the removal of the
twenty-per-cent duty on glove-leather could not exceed
ten per cent of the present price of the glove, and would
be from ten to fifteen cents per pair.
The question cannot be left here. We must consider
whether the facts justify a further saving to the con-
sumer. From the computations and tables in the earlier
part of this chapter we see that while the tariff rate on
men's gloves varies from $4 to $4.80 per dozen pairs
(including the tariff on raw material), the actual differ-
ence in labor cost varies according to the particular set
of facts upon which it is based, from $3.25 to $0.97.
Hence removing the tariff on raw material and taking
the lowest estimate of difference in labor cost, viz., that
in Case E', we see that the tariff on this basis may be
brought from $4.80, the present total, to $0.97, thus re-
sulting in a saving to the consuming public of $3.83 per
dozen pairs of gloves, or, in terms of individual use,
nearly $0.32 per pair.
We must notice that the case taken here uses as a basis
the lowest difference in labor cost between France and
the United States. The lowest difference between Ger-
many and the United States as shown in our tables is
$1.36. If this be made the basis of the tariff, the saving
to the consumer will be $3.44 per dozen pairs, or
approximately $0.29 per pair.
62 THE LEATHER GLOVE INDUSTRY
We have one further means of testing the rate. We
pointed out that in 1890 an attempt was made to so fix
the rate as to give the market in women's gloves to the
importers. This principle remained in force until 1908,
and the testimony of the domestic manufacturers showed
at that time that they were making about five or six per
cent of the total amount of women's gloves used in the
United States, in competition with gloves imported under
the rates lower than on men's gloves. 1
The rates then in force varied from $1.75 to $2.50 per
dozen pairs. Let us assume that all the women's gloves
made here are similar in material to those covered by our
tables; then the part of the rate attributable to duty on
raw material will be $1.25, and the remainder of the rate
will represent the difference in labor cost. This remain-
der will be $1.25, a sum so near $0.97 and $1.36 as to
indicate the probability of accuracy in our estimate.
There is a peculiar psychological consideration affect-
ing the saving which we have indicated.
In the argument of the American manufacturers, stress
is laid upon the fact that prices in gloves usually run in
even quarters of a dollar, and the inference is that no
savings between these figures will be passed on to the
consumer unless his psychology changes or keener
competition arises among the retailers. But this ten-
dency is already felt. It is not at all uncommon to see
gloves displayed in furnishing stores at $1.10 and $1.15,
and the department stores are acquainting their cus-
tomers with such prices as $0.79 and $0.89.
Further importance is given to the present discussion
by the fact that at the time of the passage of the latest
tariff law the House Bill carried a rate that was the same
1 Tariff Hearings.
TARIFFS 63
both upon men's and women's gloves. Thus it may be
seen that if the present rate is prohibitive with respect
to men's gloves it would become so at once in the case
of women's. This would have added at once to the pro-
tected business of this country an amount of five million
dollars annually.
It is conceded that the cost of making men's and
women's gloves of the shorter lengths is approximately
the same. The decrease in the cost of the smaller amount
of leather in a woman's glove is nearly equaled by the
extra cost of the somewhat finer ornamentation. Thus
the two kinds are about equally expensive, so far as ma-
terial is concerned. Exactly the same rates are paid for
cutting and sewing the two kinds. There is only one
real point of difference, and that is a trade difficulty
rather than one of manufacture. The element of style
plays an important part in the market for women's
gloves. 1 The change in the length of the sleeves of
women's clothing may effect an entire change in the de-
mand for gloves : calling now for one length in gloves
and now for another. Since one of the great difficulties
of the present situation is the occurrence of a succession
of alternate rush and slack seasons, it is reasonable to
suppose that the addition of a new element of uncer-
tainty might prove to be so disadvantageous as to offset
the gain coming from the enlargement of the field. This
objection seems to be a minor one, and if we leave it out
of consideration it is difficult to see why the logic of the
situation does not demand the same tariff upon both
men's and women's gloves.
This very fact led to the bitter controversy that arose
over the determination of the tariff rate for the Payne-
1 Cote, Chapter II, Sur la Mode.
64 THE LEATHER GLOVE INDUSTRY
Aldrich bill. The Manufacturers' Association asked for
a uniform rate ' upon men's and women's gloves, ignoring
it is charged, the alleged agreement of 1890; which pro-
vided for a division of the field. The house Bill carried
the rate asked for by the manufacturers, while the Senate
bill carried the rate of the present law.
The report of these facts called forth a storm of pro-
test from consumers of gloves all over the United States.
Many newspapers took up the discussion, not uninflu-
enced, it is charged, by the fact that the majority of the
importers were closely allied with the large department
stores which are extensive advertisers. The greater
part of the product of the domestic maker is handled by
small haberdashers, who do not make extensive use of
the great city dailies.
The final decision was made in the conference com-
mittee on July 29, 1909. All other items of the schedule
except lumber and gloves had been settled and it was
expected that in the case of gloves the rate of the house
bill would be approved. This rate would have made the
duty on men's and women's gloves alike $4.00 with
certain cumulative additions for grades receiving more
work than the ordinary kinds.
As the matter was being pressed to its conclusion a
letter from the President was handed to the Chairman.
Immediately an adjournment was taken, and in the re-con-
vened session the rate upon gloves was fixed as found in
the Senate bill. This was slightly lower than the rate
of the Dingley law upon Ladies " Schmaschen " gloves
and the same as the Dingley law on all other grades. 8
The natural inference would be that the change of
1 See Appendix for proposed rate.
'See Appendix IX.
TARIFFS 65
attitude in the Conference was traceable to the Presi-
dent's letter. That such is the fact is borne out by the
interview published in the Outlook of Dec. 2, 1911.
" But I could not get free lumber either. The only way
I procured the substantial reduction from $1.50 was by
sending the Conference Committee an intimation that I
should veto the bill if it carried a lumber duty higher
than $1.25. / took a similar and equally successful stand
regarding gloves, on some classes of which an increase
had been proposed for the benefit of an " infant industry."
Some of my critics will ask " If you could do so much
in these instances by swinging your veto club* why did
you not use the same weapon all along the line?"
Here at once we have both the difficulty of the tariff
situation and the remedy. We have shown that the
Committee did not have in its possession facts sufficiently
authenticated to permit of a scientific determination of
the rate of duty. But that such facts are obtainable we
believe this study has shown. In fact some of them
have been established to the satisfaction of a court of
law. 2
That a proper use of the facts can be made, once they
are known, seems clear from the effect of the President's
action in the case of the Payne-Aldrich law. True, he
was no doubt influenced by the newspaper campaign fos-
tered by the importers. But if the facts were ascertained
by a properly authorized government agent, canvassing
the foreign fields as we have covered the domestic field,
the publication of the facts themselves would be a suffi-
cient answer to all misrepresentation. No room would
remain for half statement or misstatement of costs, and
1 Italics are the writer's.
*U. S. v. D. S. Morrison, 109 Fed. Reporter, 891. See p. 387.
66 THE LEATHER GLOVE INDUSTRY
consequently the preliminary political skirmishing would
be entirely removed.
Only in the final enactment of the rate would political
action be called for, and this would become largely a
matter of form. The people would always have in the
reports of the committee or commission a ready check
for any attempt to give undue advantage to any interest.
The action of the President could then be as definite as
it was in 1909, and would rest beyond any question upon
a fair basis of fact.
In answering the questions outlined at the beginning
of this chapter we have shown, first, that the burden of
the tariff falls upon the consumer of gloves ; second, that
some tariff is necessary to maintain the industry in the
United States because of the labor cost here, which is
higher than in European glove centers; third, that the
present rate of tariff on men's gloves is higher than is
necessary to meet the difference in labor cost. In assert-
ing this we must remember that no manufacturer can be
expected to invest capital in the building of a plant the
utility of which may be destroyed by a legislative act.
Hence before attempting to fix the fair rate of tariff we
must find a better method of fixing it, one depending
upon economic fact and not on political change.
CHAPTER VII
SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION
IN our summary of the leather-glove industry of the
United States we have shown that it furnishes one of the
best examples obtainable of the working of the tariff sys-
tem of the United States. We have shown that it pre-
sents a favorable opportunity for the application of the
principles of scientific tariff-making.
To do this we have traced the development of the in-
dustry through all the stages of industrial evolution from
the simplest kind of domestic production to the stage in
which factory organization and methods have been
brought to a fairly good state of perfection. We have
pointed out the fact that in the earlier stages of the in-
dustry, when the conditions of supply for raw materials
were much more favorable than they have been since
1890, growth was slow. On the other hand, it appears
that with the adoption of the tariff of 1890, which was
the first tariff to be fixed upon the basis of protection in
the modern sense, there began a new period of remark-
ably rapid growth. During this period, from 1890 to
1912, the glove industry has reached its maturity. The
importance of this growth can only be appreciated after
examining, as we have done, the nature of the industry.
Glove making presents so curious a combination of art
and industry that marked advances in Europe have been
very slow. European glove-workers, particularly cutters,
consider themselves artists rather than artisans.
67
68 THE LEATHER GLOVE INDUSTRY
This attitude was shown by workers in the American
glove industry up to 1901. The effect of the decision
of the courts handed down in that year, permitting the
importation of foreign cutters, was to change this attitude.
The resulting increase in the number of cutters made
them more dependent upon the demands of the manufac-
turers and hastened the organization of the factories upon
a more modern industrial basis. We may say that in the
United States the industry has been put upon a strictly
modern basis for the first time in its history. This
advance has been made with almost none of the disad-
vantages usually accompanying factory growth. As we
have shown in our discussion the absence of the usual
factory district in the glove centers has prevented crowd-
ing and congestion which generally occur in a highly
centralized industry. The scattered location of the fac-
tories in the cities of Gloversville and Johnstown gives
plenty of opportunity for the erection of well-lighted,
well-ventilated factories.
In addition to the factory side of the industry there is
a large amount of work done in the homes of the
workers under conditions which seem strikingly free
from the evils of home work as they exist in large cities.
The housing conditions of the two glove cities are very
favorable. By far the larger part of the population live
in detached houses, rarely are there more than two
families in one house. We have shown the great extent
of this kind of production and its growth as indicated by
the increased use of small motors installed in the homes
of workers for the operation of sewing machines. There
were in 1911, 1300 of these motors in private houses, an
increase of nearly thirty per cent over the previous year.
This increase is one of the most significant tendencies of
the industry. It promises a much wider extension of
SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION 69
the home working system than has existed up to the
present time and a utilization of a greater number of the
small power sites that abound in the foothills of the
Adirondacks. The most serious limitation upon the ex-
tension of home working has been the problem of trans-
portation among the scattered houses of the outlying
hamlets and farming sections. In the summer months
the use of automobiles has done much to remedy this
difficulty. But the summer months include the slack
season, and in the winter months of the rush season the
roads of Fulton county and the surrounding counties are
not easily traveled by any vehicle. With the beginning
of the year 1913 a very effective method of handling this
problem will come into use in the form of the parcel
post. Gloves made and unmade are light in weight and
small in bulk, so they can easily be sent through the
mails. This method will be particularly effective in
reaching workers living upon rural free-delivery routes.
From all these facts we see that the glove industry is
in a promising condition from a manufacturing point of
view. In the earlier chapters we showed the relation be-
tween the tariff and the condition of the industry in the
United States. We showed that there is an actual dif-
ference in the labor cost of making a dozen pairs of
gloves in the United States and either Germany or
France, the countries from which most importations of
gloves come. Without some tariff to offset this differ-
ence in labor cost, the industry could not have advanced
to its present state of development. The period of pro-
tection in the glove industry needs to be somewhat
longer than in other industries, because the training of a
force of workers in a glove industry is a relatively slow
process. Once trained, the force becomes more perma-
nent than in many other lines of manufacture, because
70 THE LEATHER GLOVE INDUSTRY
women who as girls learned the trade of sewing gloves
are able to carry it on in their homes after marriage.
We considered both the advantages and disadvantages of
this form of work in the proper place.
Our final consideration was the question as to the per-
manency and amount of the tariff upon gloves. If we
concede the principle of protection it must undoubtedly
be at the minimum rate; but again the minimum rate
implies permanency in the rate, for capital will not flow
into an industry protected at the minimum rate for a
short or indefinite period. That the rate of the Payne-
Aldrich law was not at the minimum we believe we have
shown. The reason for the high rate we have shown to
lie in the method of determining the rate. This study
shows that the facts for the scientific determination are
obtainable and the proper method of handling these facts
calls for the establishment of a permanent non-partisan
body with power to obtain the facts in this as in every
other industry, and power to fix the rate of tariff upon
those facts when found. This power implies the right
of the body to make changes in the rate for proved cause
when necessary.
From our study of the glove industry we conclude, first,
that during the twenty-two years of its protected exist-
ence since 1890 it has developed a trained labor force, so
fortunately situated in living and working conditions and
with such prospects of immediate growth as to entitle
the industry to at least a temporary continuation of
protection.
Second, that the present method of fixing the rate of
protection upon the industry is responsible for the exces-
sive rate and the improper distribution of the benefit of
the rate between manufacturer and laborer, the liability
to change in rate enabling the manufacturer to resist the
demand of the laborer for his share in the protection.
SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION 7 !
And, finally, if the tariff be adjusted by a permanent
nonpartisan body able to make adjustments for proved
cause when needed, and empowered to demand the high
efficiency necessitated by a close adjustment of the rate
to actual difference in labor cost of production in the
factories of the more efficient class, the future of the
industry is assured and it will form a strong part in our
diversified system of production.
APPENDIX I
SCHEDULE OF PRICES
Of the Glove Manufacturers Association of the United States
as adopted for the year 1910, for Table Cutting:, American
Table Cutting:, Sewing: Fine Gloves. (Second column, table
as agreed upon for year ending: December i, 1900, by repre-
sentatives of the Glove Manufacturers Association and of the
Fulton County International Glove Table Cutters Union.)
Price per doz. pr.
Kind of Work. 1910. 1900.
Imported or domestic kid or suede $0.90 $0.88
Mocha castor or Mocha reindeer i.oo .93*4
Mocha castor for fur-lined gloves pr where two inches
or more of extra leather is required i.io 1.05
Craven tan, napa or dipped lamb or sheep 95 .95
Same if for lamb or fur-lined gloves 1.05 1.05
Real kid or goat i.oo i.oo
Oil or alum-dressed deerskins i.io
Indian-tanned deerskins 95 .95
Little jacks 1.20 1.20
Cambretta and Mocha kid 99 .99
Coltskin i.io
Calfskin 1.05
Chamois or fleshers, all colors 86 .84
Women's wide cuff gauntlets, flare included but not
bound 1.20
Women's wide cuff gauntlets, flare included with bind-
ing . 1.25
Women's gauntlets, with cuff up to 2# inches wide.
including flare 1.05 1.05
Automobile gauntlets, not combination 1.50
For dowling the cuffs of women's gauntlets extra 10 .10
All mittens 18 cents per doz. less than corresponding
gloves
Boys' gloves not to exceed 8% inches of leather for
lined or 8 inches for unlined and 2^ inches in top
length, not cur on cadet patterns 80 .80
Cutting lamb linings 70
Cutting fur linings i.oo
Tilburys with fourchettes and part thumbs 50
Backs.. 40 -40
Palms Kid palms incl. fourchettes and thumbs 70
Mocha palm incl. fourchettes and thumbs 75
Buck or cambretta incl. fourchettes and thumbs... .80
APPENDIX I
73
Extras.
Spring pieces ........................................................ 03 .03
Laps ..................................................................... 05 .05
Ridelle ................................................................... n .11
Gores ..................................................................... 05 .05
Blue mark running length of glovr .......................... 05
Extra wrist binding ............................................. 05
Flat slit welt ......................... ................................. 03 ......
Band tops ........ .................................................... 15 .15
Quirks if not in pattern ............................................. 10 .10
Mocha or reindeer rags to be cut by day at ............... 3.00 ......
Deerskin rags, per dozen ......................................... 10 ......
Men's goods or women's lined gloves, cut with more
than % inch flare on each side ............................... 10
Women's barritz and mousquetaire gloves, where
flare is used, with more than % inch on each side... .10
Punching and trimming gloves ................................. 10 ......
Punching and trimming mittens ................................ 10 .....
Slitting gloves by hand .......................................... 40
Slitting mittens by hand .......................................... 15 ......
Slitting one-finger mittens by hand .......................... 20
Cutting single pairs ............................................... 15
Cutting single pairs and slitting by hand .................... 25
7^ cents per inch for every inch or part of an inch in
length in excess of 3# inches on men's and 4#
inches on women's gloves excepting on all chamois,
which shall be 5 cents per inch.
French chalk applied if wanted.
Only two kinds of gloves and one throw-out (boys) shall
be required from one batch of leather.
Fourchettes shall be replaced only before the glove is made.
Cutters will be allowed to draw up to $20 if they have
earned same, on the second Saturday after regular pay-day.
Any special extra work, not provided for in this schedule,
may be adjusted between the manufacturer and the cutter.
Dowling. *
Dowling per dozen gloves up to 4/^ inch top ............. $0.30 $0.30
Dowling per dozen gloves 4^ to 8 inch top ............. 43# -43/4
Dowling per dozen gloves 8 to 12 inch top ............. 57>
Dowling per dozen gloves 12 to 16 inch top ............ .75
Dowling per dozen gloves 16 to 20 inch top .......... 90
Imported or domestic suede ...................................... 5
Cambretta or Mocha ....................... ......................... 32^
Where the cutter dowls the skins and then cuts the gloves
therefrom, he shall be credited for both the dowling and cut-
ting per dozen gloves in accordance with the table-cutting
schedule and not in any other way.
Prices for cutting men's gloves up to 3/^ inch top and
74 APPENDIX I
women's gloves up to 4/^ inch top with slit binding:, number-
ing:, sizing, punching thumbs and fourchettes, including Eng-
lish thumbs, when cut from the following stock:
AMERICAN TABLE CUTTING SCHEDULE
As adopted by the Glove Manufacturers Association of the
United States tor the year 1910.
CLASS A
The following is required of "A" cutting: " Lined, un-
lined and silk-lined/'
Tranks accurately measured crossways, or lengthways if
faults should make it necessary, and spudded.
Thumb tranks accurately measured, and spudded, numbered,
sized, and punched or not, as required.
CLASS B
Class " B " consists of lined gloves or mittens.
Tranks measured and spudded.
Thumbs not measured but so worked out that they will be
in due proportion to the size of the glove, sized, and punched
or not, as required.
CLASS C
Class "C" calls for same trank measurements, but not as
careful workmanship as class " B," numbered, sized, or not,
as required.
Tranks not spudded. Thumbs not measured, but num-
bered, sized, and punched or not, as required.
Prices for cutting men's and women's gloves and mittens
with slit binding, numbering, sizing, punching thumbs and
fourchettes, including English thumbs, when cut from the
following stock:
Class
Kind of Work. A. B. C.
Imported or domestic kid or suede, or flesher $0.40 $0.65 $0.55
Mocha castor or Mocha reindeer 80
Friezed lamb 80 .75
Mocha castor, or Mocha reindeer, or friezed lamb
or sheep if for lamb or fur-lined gloves, or where
two inches or more of extra leather is required... .85
Cravan tan, napa, or dipped lamb or sheep 75 .65 .55
Oil-dressed deerskin gloves, colored or smoked,
punched or not, as required i.oo
APPENDIX I
75
Deerskin mittens, all kinds, punched or not, as re-
Suired 78
ian-tanned deerskin gloves, punched or not. as
required 95
Little jacks, gloves, punched or not, as required.... 1.05 .95
Cambretta and Mocha kid gloves 80
Coltskin gloves i.oo
Calfskin gloves 95
Chamois 70 .65
Women's wide-cuff gauntlets, flare included but not
bound .95 .85 .75
Women's wide-cuff gauntlets, flare included, in-
cluding binding i.oo .90 .80
Women's gauntlets, with cuff up to 2)4 inches
wide, including flare 80 .76 .60
Automobile gauntlets i.oo
Automobile gauntlets, combination .90
Automobile gauntlets, cuff and gores cut by hand.. 1.25
Boys' gloves, lined or unlined, not to exceed nine
inc hes of leather, not cut on cadet patterns 60 .52^ .40
Boys' deerskin gloves 80
Boys' Mocha gloves 75 .65
Gloves and mittens of German deer, 15 cents per
dozen above price paid for cutting Mocha.
Childrens mitts, kid or suede 42^ -35 -20
Childrens mitts, Mocha or buck 55 .40 .30
Cutting lamb linings from skins, long wool 70
Cutting lamb linings from skins, short wool 60
Cutting lamb linings from plates 60
Cutting fur linings from skins 90
Cutting fur linings from plates 80
Tilburys with fourchettes and part thumbs 50
Backs, kid or suede 30
Backs, buckskin 35
Palms, kid or suede, including fourchettes and
thumbs 50 .45 .30
Palms, Mocha, including fourchettes and thumbs... .60
Palms, buck, including fourchettes and thumbs 75
Men's or women's mittens, when not otherwise
provided for, 15 cents less than corresponding
gloves.
Extras.
Button stays $0.05
Laps, 24 to the dozen 05
Gores, where split bindings are also required 05
Extra wrist binding 05
Quirks, if not in pattern 10
Mocha or reindeer rags, per dozen 15
Men's and women's gloves cut with more than % inch flare on
each side 10
Deerskin rags, per dozen extra 15
Punching and trimming gloves 10
Punching and trimming mittens 05
Cutting single pairs, per pair 10
76 APPENDIX I
Cutting single pairs and slitting by hand 25
Punching silk-lined thumbs 05
Gloves or mitts, for fur or lamb-lined, where two cr more inches
of leather is required 05
No more than three kinds of gloves shall be required from one batch
of leather.
The expense of mistakes is to be borne by those who make them.
This applies to working over of tranks and all other mistakes.
(Last two notes same as last two in Table Cutting Schedule.)
SCHEDULE OF MAXIMUM PRICES FOR SEWING FINE GLOVES
AS ADOPTED BY THE GLOVE MANUFACTURERS* ASSOCIATION OF THE
UNITED STATES FOR THE YEAR IQIO
In Out of
Kind of work. factory, factory.
Silking (two, three or four-needle machines).
Two-needle completely around center row $0.18 $0.18
Single, double or triple drawn or plain four-needle .... 8 to 10 8 to 10
Two-needle around center row, one end open i2> .12%
Two-needle around center row, one end open, ends
picked
Two-needle reverse around center row, one end open. .15 .15
Three or four-needle around center row, one end open .18 .18
Single needle machine.
Making draw on single needle machine n .11
Brosser machine.
One row brosser 10 .10
Baker or Union Special Machine.
One row embroidery 10 .10
Two rows embroidery 14 .14
Three rows embroidery 18 .18
Hand Work.
Making full spear points 30 .30
Making drops for spear points 20 .20
Sewing on ordinary slit stay pieces 05 .05
Making button holes 12 .12
Buttons sewn on plain 07 .07
Buttons sewn on with tape 10
Sewing tape stays for one fastener up to 2% inches long .08 .08
Sewing tape stays for two fasteners, up to 4 inches long .10 .10
Sewing leather stays for one fastener, up to 2# inches
long - 10 .10
Sewing leather stays for two fasteners, up to 4 inches
long 12 .12
End pulling according to work required 2 to 6 2 to 6
APPENDIX I 77
Hemming, etc.
Putting on white hem on overseam, sewing down on
both sides 12 .12
Self hem on overseam 06 .06
Sewing slit binding on lockstitck 05 .05
Reinforcing slits on lockstitch 10 .10
Sewing continuous binding around slit and top on
overstitch machine 09 .09
Sewing continuous binding around hem and slit, once
around on lockstitch machine 10 .10
Sewing down and trimming slit binding 08 .08
Sewing on slit binding and stitching once around the
slit and twice across the top 18 .18
Sewing on slit binding and stitching twice around the
slit and twice across the top known as the " Horse-
shoe'' hem 20 .20
Sewing on slit binding and stitching once around slit
and twice across the top, where slit binding is
trimmed by hemmer to leave part of slit binding to
serve as button piece 20 .20
Sewing in slit binding, stitching once around slit and
twice across top and fastening by a single row of
stitching, the button piece part of the binding thus
forming the ordinary box hem 22 .22
Same as next preceding item when operator is required
to mark pattern for box 25 .25
Rubbering with six rows and in center gore 20 .20
Rubbering with six rows with side gore 15 .15
Rubbering with six rows if side gore is already in 10 .10
Double rubbering on extra long top and setting in gore .22 .22
Furring straight around 15 .15
Furring spring top 40 .40
Making fleece or plush glove lining .10 .10
Making fleece or plush mitten lining 08 .08
Sewing.
Inseam.
Making lined or silk-lined gloves, with or without
quirks, without quirks, slit bindings tacked but not
sewn on, fourchettes trimmed 70 .60
If made mock pique, side seam stitching on palm .85 .75
If made mock pique, side seam stitching on back 90 .80
Closing glove where fitting up has been done by an
operator other than the closer 20 .20
Making hem-top mittens complete 45 .45
Making fur-top mittens complete 35 .35
Making fleece-lined gloves complete i.oo i.oo
If made without laps or quirks 5 cents less for each.
Overseam.
Men's or women's gloves with quirks, not hemmed,
but with binding sewn on 85 .75
Men's or women's gloves, without quirks, but with
bindings sewn on 75 .65
7 8 APPENDIX I
Men's or women's overseam mittens 30 .30
Misses' or children's overseam mittens 25 .25
Gloves made without bindings or welts, deduct 5 cents
from schedule price for making such gloves.
Pique.
Fitting up for pique or inseam, slit welts sewn on,
fourchettes trimmed and ends tied 55 .50
Same without slit welts 50 .45
Closing gloves on pique 85 .78
Making pique mittens.. 38 .36
Fitting up pique mittens ro .10
Closing pique thumbs 10 .10
Triple Stitch.
Making gloves on triple-stitch machine, with quirks
but not hemmed, all ends tied i .40
Prixseam.
Making prixseam with quirks, but not hemmed, all
ends tied 1.30 1.20
Gauge Outseam.
When gauge is used.
Making men's or women's all outseam, with or with-
out quirks, all ends tied 1. 10 i. oo
Making men's or women's half outseam, with or with-
out quirks, all ends tied.. ....' 85 .80
Making men's or women's outseam mittens.. 30 .30
Above with thumbs sewn in flat 10 cents extra.
Trimmer Outseam.
Making full outseam with quirks, slit binding tacked. .90 .80
Making half outseam with quirks, slit binding tacked. .75 .65
Making outseam mittens, round thumb 30 .30
Making outseam mittens, English thumb . 30 .30
Above with thumbs sewn in flat in cents extra.
The clause in the schedule " all ends tied " refers to all ends
except quirk ends, and quirk ends should be fastened by back-
stitching at least four stitches.
Mousquetaires and Barritz.
Musoquetaircs made overstitch, slit sewed on :
6-8 inches .80
10 inches 85
12 inches i.oo
16 inches i.io
20 inches 1.20
Barritz made overseam, no slit bindings :
6-8 inches 75
10 inches 80
12 inches 95
16 inches 1.05
20 inches 1.15
APPENDIX I
Mousquetaire made gauge (when gauge is used) with-
out slit bindings :
79
6 inches.
8 inches.
10 inches.
12 inches.
16 inches.
,10
IS
.20
25
.40
Mousquetaires made pique Fitting :
Fitting up
6 inches 55
8-12 inches 60
Above 12 inches 65
Closing
6 inches 85
8 inches 90
10 inches.. 95
12 inches.
14 inches.
16 inches.
18 inches.
20 inches.
,00
05
,10
.20
Silking monsquetaires, drawn back :
Above 8 inches 12
Two draw 12
Stitching around 15
FACTORY HOURS
Making Department
Factories shall be open from 7 to 12 o'clock in the forenoon
and from I to 6 o'clock in the afternoon, Saturdays excepted,
when the closing 1 hour shall be 5 o'clock, excepting: during the
months of June, July and August, when the closing hour shall
be 12 o'clock noon.
Piece workers in the making department shall work not less
than seven hours each working day, from 8 a. m. to n a. m.;
i p. m. to 3 p. m., except on Saturdays during June, July and
August, when they shall work four hours, from 8 a. m. to
12 m.
APPENDIX II
PROPOSED SCHEDULE*
Submitted to the Ways and Means Committee by the Glove
Manufacturers' Association of the United States.
Paragraph 439.
Act of 1897.
Gloves :
Gloves, made wholly or in
part of leather whether wholly
or partly manufactured, shall
pay duty at the following-
rates :
The lengths stated in each
case being the extreme length
when stretched to their full
extent, namely :
Paragraph as amended or
reconstructed.
Gloves :
Gloves, made wholly or in
part of leather whether wholly
or partly manufactured, shall
pay duty at the following
rates, namely :
On gloves not exceeding
eleven inches in length, four
dollars per dozen pairs ;
On gloves exceeding eleven
inches in length, an additional
duty of fifty cents per dozen
pairs for each inch or major
portion of an inch in excess
of said eleven inches, the
length in each case being the
extreme length when stretched
to its full extent.
80
Tariff Hearings, Nov. 28, 1908.
APPENDIX II 8l
Paragraph 440.
Act of 1897. Paragraph as amended or
reconstructed.
Women's or children's
"glace" finish, Schmaschen
(of sheep origin), not over
fourteen inches in length, one
dollar and seventy-five cents
per dozen pairs ;
Over fourteen inches and
not over seventeen inches in
length, two dollars and
twenty-five cents per dozen
pairs ;
Over seventeen inches in
length, two dollars and
seventy-five cents per dozen
pairs ;
Men's " glace " finish,
Schmaschen (sheep), three
dollars per dozen pairs.
Paragraph 441.
Act of 1897. Paragraph as amended or
reconstructed.
Women's or children's
" glace " finish, lamb or sheep,
not over fourteen inches in
length, two dollars and fifty
cents per dozen pairs ;
Over fourteen and not over
seventeen inches in length,
three dollars and fifty cents
per dozen pairs ;
Over seventeen inches in
length, four dollars and fifty
cents per dozen pairs ;
Men's "glace" finish, lamb
or sheep, four dollars per
dozen pairs.
82 APPENDIX II
Paragraph 442.
Act of 1897. Paragraph as amended or
reconstructed.
Women's or children's
"glace" finish, goat, kid or
other leather than of sheep
origin, not over fourteen
inches in length, three dollars
per dozen pairs ;
Over fourteen and not over
seventeen inches in length,
three dollars and seventy-five
cents per dozen pairs ;
Over seventeen inches in
length, four dollars and
seventy-five cents per dozen
pairs ;
Men's "glace" finish, kid,
goat, or other leather than of
sheep origin, four dollars per
dozen pairs.
Paragraph 443.
Act of 1897. Paragraph as amended or
reconstructed.
Women's or children's, of
sheep origin, with exterior
grain surface removed, by
whatever name known, not
over seventeen inches in
length, two dollars and fifty
cents per dozen pairs ;
Over seventeen inches in
length, three dollars and fifty
cents per dozen pairs ;
Men's, of sheep origin,
with exterior surface removed,
by whatever name known,
four dollars per dozen pairs.
APPENDIX II 83
Paragraph 444.
Act of 1897. Paragraph as amended or
reconstructed.
Women's or children's, kid,
goat, or other leather than of
sheep origin, with exterior
grain surface removed, by
whatever name known, not
over fourteen inches in length,
three dollars per dozen pairs ;
Over fourteen inches and
not over seventeen inches in
length, three dollars and
seventy-five cents per dozen
pairs ;
Over seventeen inches in
length, four dollars and
seventy-five cents per dozen
pairs ;
Men's goat, kid, or other
leather than of sheep origin,
with exterior grain surface
removed, by whatever name
known, four dollars per dozen
pairs.
Paragraph 445.
Act of 1897. Paragraph as amended or
reconstructed.
In addition to the foregoing In addition to the foregoing
rates there shall be paid the rates there shall be paid the
following cumulative duties : following cumulative duties :
On all leather gloves, when On all gloves, wholly or
lined, one dollar per dozen in part of leather, when lined
pairs ; with cotton, woolen or silk
fabrics, one dollar per dozen
pairs ;
When lined with skin or
fur, five dollars per dozen
pairs ;
On all pique or prixseam On all pique or prixseam
gloves, forty cents per dozen gloves, forty cents per dozen
pairs ; pairs ;
On all hand-sewn gloves,
one dollar per dozen pairs ;
8 4
APPENDIX II
On all gloves, stitched or
embroidered, with more than
three single strands or cords,
forty cents per dozen pairs.
On all gloves having crows'
feet stitched, sewn or silked
on the backs thereof, or hav-
ing stitched, sewn, embroid-
ered or silked on the backs
thereof points, each point con-
sisting of more than a single
row of stitching, sewing, em-
broidery, or silking, whether
the same be continuous or
otherwise, forty cents per
dozen pairs ;
On all gloves having more
than a single line of stitching,
sewing, embroidery or silk-
ing, on the cuffs or wrists
thereof, twenty-five cents per
dozen pairs.
Paragraph 446.
Act of 1897.
Glove tranks, with or with-
out the usual accompanying
pieces, shall pay seventy-five
per centum of the duty pro-
vided for the gloves in the
fabrication of which they are
suitable.
Paragraph as amended or
reconstructed.
Glove tranks, with or with-
out the usual accompanying
pieces, shall pay seventy-five
per centum of the duty pro-
vided for the gloves in the
fabrication of which they are
suitable.
APPENDIX III
ARGUMENT FOR PROPOSED SCHEDULE'
"The Glove Manufacturers' Association of the United
States desires to call your attention to the trade developments
in connection with the tariff schedule on gloves contained in
paragraphs 439 to 446, both inclusive, of the Dingley Act.
We are confident that your Committee will discern that no in-
dustry in the United States has made, or can make, a more
satisfactory showing under protection than the glove industry,
to demonstrate which we review the history of this industry.
" Before the McKinley Act of 1890 there was no glove in-
dustry in the United States competing in our markets with the
foreign-made gloves. There has been, during 1 the previous
fifty years, developed the manufacture of gloves for working-
men, but such gloves were made in this country only, as we
are the only people in the world paying a sufficiently high
rate of wages to enable the working man to indulge in the
luxury of protecting 1 his hands while at work. The working-
men's gloves we manufacture are considered curiosities in
other parts of the world, where no such articles are made or
used, and to-day the manufacture of such workingmen's gloves
still remains the largest part of the glove industry, the census
of 1905 showing that 65.3 per cent, of American production
was of the workingmen's gloves.
" Prior to 1890 the tariff on gloves was 50 per cent, ad val-
orem. It was clearly demonstrated that under an ad valorem
tariff no legitimate trade could be developed or continued here
because of undervaluations, the business going into the hands
of agents of foreign manufacturers, against whom the Ameri-
can importer could not successfully compete. The American
dealer confined his purchases practically to the agents of im-
porters, and the American manufacturers found no opportunity
to compete with the enormous importation of men's and
women's gloves. The ad valorem rate of 50 per cent, gave no
'Tariff Hearings before Ways and Means Committee, November 28,
1008.
85
86 APPENDIX HI
consideration to the theory of protection, but simply repre-
sented a tariff for revenue, and there was no glove industry in
the United States making: fine gloves under that rate.
" In the consideration of the McKinley bill the question of
giving" protection, so as to build up an American industry, was
thoroughly investigated, with the conclusion that such oppor-
tunity was given on men's gloves, while leaving the women's
gloves on a purely revenue basis. It was believed that the
highly skilled labor necessary for the manufacture of women's
gloves could not be found in the United States.
In the fiscal year 1890 there were imported 127,000 dozen
pairs of men's gloves, paying a revenue of $229,222.50. The
McKinley bill imposed, in addition to the previous 50 per
cent, ad valorem rate, one dollar per dozen extra on men's
gloves. From the date of its enactment, the American fine-
glove industry had its start, until to-day it has developed into
an industry giving employment to twenty thousand working
mem scattered over the United States in twenty-seven states,
but mainly centered in Fulton County, in the State of New
York.
When, in the course of events, the consideration of a revised
tariff, with the avowed purpose of enacting a tariff for revenue
only, took place in 1893 under the chairmanship, in this com-
mittee, of Mr. Wilson, the business of manufacturing men's
gloves had already made its start. The importation of
men's gloves during the fiscal year 1893 amounted to 103,808
dozen pairs, paying in duties $448,943.64, which was a reduc-
tion of 24,000 dozens under the importations of 1890. The
Democratic revision of the tariff showed clearly that proper
appreciation had been given to the need and justice of a pro-
tective tariff on men's gloves, and further, that a schedule to
be just, and fairly complied with under the law, could not be
based on ad valorem rates.
The Wilson bill of 1893, for the first time, placed exclusively
specific duties on gloves, and moreover, after the fullest and
most careful study of the problem, gave increased rates of duty
on men's gloves, while lowering the duty on women's gloves,
in specific form to about one-half the rates which maintained
under the McKinley bill. At this point attention should be
directed to the fact that the Wilson bill duties on women's
gloves, which were only about one-half of the rates of duty im-
posed under the McKinley Act, did not increase the importa-
tion of women's gloves, nor augment the government's reve-
nues, but had quite the contrary effect.
APPENDIX III 87
In 1893, under the McKinley Act, there were imported
1,314,862 dozen pairs, paying- a revenue of $3,252,653, while
in 1896, under the Wilson Act, with its reduction of duties on
women's and children's gloves, only 1,176,776 dozens of these
gloves were imported, paying duties of $2,075,548. These fig-
ures show that the lower Wilson bill rates did not increase the
importation of this article of semi-luxury, but on the contrary
fewer women's gloves were imported under these lower rates
and the government revenue decreased nearly a million and a
quarter of dollars.
When the Dingley Act of 1897 was under consideration,
these facts were clearly presented and a demand was made for
the continuance of the duties on men's gloves, which was agreed
to. So the rates of the Dingley bill, on men's gloves, were
exactly those of the Wilson bill, with the addition of the extra
cumulative provisions on the more elaborately and expen-
sively sewn and embroidered gloves. We were not able, at
that time, to persuade Congress to place a compensatory pro-
tective duty on women's gloves such as had been given on
men's gloves ; and, although the duties on women's gloves
were increased to some extent under the Dingley bill, they still
remained purely revenue duties, and inadequate to provide
protection to our manufacturers."
APPENDIX IV
State.
tn
V
O
M oo oo Number of
2? $ establishments.
i
'2.
C3
$10,705,599
9,004,427
6,348,407
6,219.647
Salaried offi-
cials, clerks, Total,
etc.
1
8
640
637
296
328
1
rt
"rt
ft
$584,573
544,17
262,873
294*574
||
^
1
United States -j
New York .... -I
1905
1900
1905
1900
10,645
14,180
#3,840,253
4,151,126
2,131.053
2,723,702
Census of Manufactures, 1905, Bulletin 72.
APPENDIX V
VALUE OF GLOVES, OF KID OR OTHER LEATHER, IMPORTED : 1900 TO 1905 l
Year.
Value.
1
Year.
l
Value.
f QOC
&d 727 dSo
Sc,^66,'?8i
i 90 i .........
. . c t;^d 2^0
IOO3
5 W V3OJ/
C O2O 278
IOOO
6 IO7.76C
Census of Manufactures, 1905, Bulletin 72.
1 Bureau of Statistics, Department of Commerce and Labor, Commerce and
Navigation of the United States.
APPENDIX VI
89
5-S.S
-^lo-
85:
in
to oo
?, s
N N
2 J
&
I-
\o vo H 9 v o *T- * "P^ *J o o<
t^.d rf * w o o ^. rf ovo i-" vd
M in m t-x vn - moo oo t^ t^ moo
* *I o
I -s
111?
; I S "I
I | 4
i J -a Si
I .2 = -o
1 < 1
! S
I
* "o
I 5 !":-=: 8 I
^ 1 1
__w-
M _?%
ro vO O 10
10 t^ 00 ON
**" ^*^-^^-^>-v^-*. "^ ^T
IO *" fO
*- "g
, to t;
; - rt s
! l I 1
* s
2
^"rt.SJ g.JJ i_5fe^^5^"5* *
i.S g g S ofll < f > ' f ' { *J**' 3 S
_^5 r, ** 1/5 (/; -^ r:
llflJ
illli
Ti *^ *
Hnftllll
= S^S C -rt^,P
Zuc/5 w>H
APPENDIX VII
PRODUCTS, BY KIND, QUANTITY AND VALUE: 1905 AND 1900
1905.
1900.
It. I 7 fAQ 78 C
t T A 72I 27A
Gloves, mittens, and gauntlets:
Total dozen pairs*
f* 1 />/4 w ij;)
7 770 1.4.6
2 89 ^ 66 1
Si 7 I 22 772
& 1 6 o "?o 1 68
Men's
Lined
1 317 083
OC2 82O
Value
56. 3 3 3.081
*4.,QCQ.QO2
Unlined
i CQ8 112
I ^14 5O7
58 182.680
7 /i c8 7c6
Women's
Lined
Dozen pairs ............
70688
78 781
Value
&1Q&32C
C78 762
Unlined
I 74, IO2
221 O?Q
Value
Si, 420, 807
5l. 772, 74.6
Gauntlets
Dozen pairs ..... ......
(1)
24 OO4.
Value
('
Si ?o.6ij2
Children's
Lined
161 673
1 88 366
Value
1U1,U/ J
te-12 Cl8
$7OQ CCA
Unlined
fjj*t5 ltj
50.268
1 16,14.2
Value
*I CC.-JC2
J44Q.CQ6
All other products, including custom work and
C6t 7611
5682 066
' Not reported separately.
APPENDIX VIII
DRESS AND WORKING GLOVES, MITTENS AND GAUNTLETS, BY QUANTITY, WITH
PER CENT. EACH KIND is or TOTAL: 1905
Aggregate.
Men's.
Women's.
Children's.
C i-
It
Z^
ii
r
g.S
&*
-"3
r
It
Q
il
u **
r
S2
gl
Q
i ?
3.370,146
977, { 594
43 ',897
545 6 97
2,392,552
1,126,547
1,266,005
1 00.0
29.0
71.0
,..
2,915.415
7 > 5, 949
3M,i5
401,799
2,199,466
1,002,933
1,196,533
100.0
24.6
75-4
253,790
183,333
49,364
133,969
70,457
30,324
40,133
1 00.0
72.2
27.8
200,941
78,312
68,383
9,929
122,629
93,290
29,339
1 00.0
39.0
Dress :
Xotal
Lined ....
Unlined .
Working :
61.0
Lined ....
Unlined ..
Census of Mtnufactures, 1905, Bulletin 72.
Qi
APPENDIX IX
RATES OF DUTY
Schedules 1890, 1894, 1897 and 1909
Men's.
1890.
McKinley.
1894.
Wilson.
1897.
Dingley.
1909.
Payne-
Aldrich.
co/fc and $i oo
&1 OO
*-? oo
*-? oo
50 % and i.oo
4. OO
4..OO
4.OO
Kid
50% and i.oo
d OO
4..OO
4..OO
co %> and I oo
4 OO
4 oo
A no
Suede kid
co % and i .00
****
A OO
A OO
A OO
Women's.
Schmaschen :
SI.7C
I OO
I.7C
I.2C l
Under 17
v '&
CQ%
I CO
2 2C
2 2C
j v / c
CO%
l 'J^
2 OO
*^*3
2.7C
**3
2.7 c
Lamb:
$2.2C
I 7C
**/D
2. CO
2.CO
**:>
CO%
2.7C
2. CO
0. en
Over
CO%
7.7C
A. CO
4. co
Kid:
13-25
2.2C
7.OO
^.OO
Under 17... ...........
J 2
CO%
7 CO
5.7C
3.7C
* IS
CQ%
4 OO
4..7C
4..7C
Suede, etc., sheep :
J v /
s%
I.7C
2. CO
2.CO
Under 17 ..
CO tfn
2 7C
? CQ
2 CO
Over
5 2?
co%
*"IJ
3-5
*o v
Suede, etc., kid :
ri*
CQ%
2.2C
I
roo
^.oo
Under 17*
y* /o
co%
7.OO
J.7C,
1.7 c
* 2
CQ%
4..OO
4.7C
4.7 c
Extra Cumulative Men's
and Women's.
$1 OO
I.OO
I.OO
I.OO
Pique or prixseam
.50
CO
1
40
dO
.40
.40
!> w
\
1 Reduction.
APPENDIX X
IMPORTATIONS OF GLOVES (MEN'S AND WOMEN'S AND CHILDREN'S)
Total Gloves.
Year ending June 30, 1907 ,
Year ending June 30, 1908.
Year ending June 30, 1909
Year ending June 30, 1910,
Year ending June 30, 1911 .
Quantities,
dozen pairs.
Values.
Duties.
1,186,569.68
902,541.20
1,159,221,78
1,309.107.79
1,196,871.12
$10,261,945.65
7,760,645.26
7,210,554.81
7.755.239.26
7.775.436.61
^4,243,363.57
3,184,937.83
3,617,425.67
3,840,492.94
3.554.754.83
Department of Commerce and Labor, Bureau of Statistics.
93
APPENDIX XI
LEATHER GLOVES'
The Chamber of Commerce of Altenburg reports as follows
regarding- pamphlet 20, page 2515 :
Mr. Littauer has made statements regarding the conditions
of production in Germany, which are to a great extent based
on erroneous suppositions. It would take too long to ex-
amine into all of the details of Littauer's statements, and only
a few specially important points will be taken up here.
Littauer alleges that the production of a dozen pairs of
leather gloves, exclusive of the leather, costs $2.14 (8.98
marks) in Germany. This, however, is not in accordance
with facts, for even though this price may be paid in certain
regions, it cannot be taken as the average rate. Moreover,
the prices for cutting out, as cited by him, are also incorrect.
The minimum wages for cutting out gloves were cited at 2.30
to 2.80 marks, whereas, for instance, at Munich the minimum
wages are 3.36 marks per dozen and at Altenburg 3.10 marks.
Littauer further states that the leather for a dozen pairs of
gloves costs $7 in America, including duty, a price which is
by no means correct, as the cost is considerably lower.
On page 2526 of the report, Littauer speaks of the wages
for sewing, mentioning 24 to 30 cents a dozen (i to 1.30
marks) as the wages for ordinary sewing in Germany, as
against 75 cents a dozen in America, and 50 to 60 cents a dozen
(2.30 to 2. 55 marks) for whipped seam in Germany, as against
$1.40 per dozen in America. The lowest wages for ordinary
sewing in Germany amount, however, to 1.55 to 2.70 marks,
and for whipped seem to 3. 30 to 4.20 marks. Littauer further
states that a large number of German manufacturers send
their gloves to Belgium to be sewed, because, as he supposes,
the sewing wages are cheaper there. This statement is also
wrong, for seam sewing is 25 pfennigs dearer in Belgium than
in Germany. The real reason why the German manufacturers
have their sewing done in Belgium is because a finer and
Senate Document 68, Pt. 2, 6ist Congress ist Session.
94
APPENDIX XI 95
better seam is made in that country than in Germany. Lit-
tauer's statement regarding: the dyers' wages in Germany are
as incorrect as those regarding- the wages paid for cutting out
and sewing seams.
The hearings before the Committee on Ways and Means,
which also related to the duties on leather gloves, show that
erroneous ideas are entertained by American manufacturers
regarding the cost of manufacture of gloves. Thus the expert,
Mr. Littauer, who was examined on this matter, stated that
the production of a dozen leather gloves in Germany cost
$2.14, or 9 marks. However, even if ihis price (as we doubt)
should be paid in individual districts, it cannot be taken as
the average rate, but must be regarded as an exception, for
in reality the cost of production of fine gloves in Germany
comes to 13 or 16 marks. In view of this price, the present
tariff seems amply sufficient to offset the difference in the cost
of production in America and Germany. The prices for cut-
ting are likewise quite wrongly given by the incorrectly
informed importers. Thus, 2.30 to 2.80 marks are given as
as the minimum wages for cutting, whereas, for instance, in
Munich, the minimum wages per dozen are 3.36 marks.
Equally incorrect are the statements with regard to dyeing.
The assertion of Mr. Littauer that the leather for a dozen
gloves costs $7 is also erroneous, the price being much less on
an average. Furthermore, the statements concerning the
wages paid for sewing seams (p. 2526 of the report) are also
incorrect. Mr. Littauer mentions 24 to 30 cents (i to 1.30
marks) as the wages for ordinary seams, and 54 to 60 cents
(2.30 to 2.55 marks) as the rate paid for whipped seams. It
is unlikely that such wages are paid anywhere in Germany, as
the lowest wages in Germany for ordinary seams are 1.55 to
2.70 marks, and the rate paid for whipped seams 3.30 to 4.20
marks. The reason why the German manufacturers send
their gloves to Belgium to be sewed is by no means because
the prices for sewing seams are cheaper there than in Germany,
for as a matter of fact Belgium seams cost 20 to 25 pfennigs
per dozen more than in Germany. Mr. Littauer therefore
errs in this regard also.
BIBLIOGRAPHY
In the preparation of this monograph the following works have been
read or consulted. Quotations from each are credited in the proper
place.
Hull, William. The History of the Glove Trade with the Customs
Connected with the Gloves. London, 1834.
Beck, S. W. Gloves , their Annals and Associations. London,
1883.
Cote, Leon. L'industrie gantiere et Vouvrier gantier a Grenoble.
Preface de Jean Jaures. Paris, 1903.
Pfliiger, Rudolph. Die lederhandschuhindustrie Deutschlands , ihre
Entwicklung und ihre Lage. Heidelberg, 1908.
Belgium Section de la Statistique. Les salaire dans V Industrie gan-
toise. Brussels, 1901.
U. S. Department of Commerce and Labor. Census of 1905, Bulle-
tin 72.
Census of 1900, Part IIT, Manufactures.
Glover 1 s Review. A Monthly Trade Journal published at Glovers-
ville.
New York State Department of Labor. Report of Bureau of Labor
Statistics, 1900, Part I, Industrial Training.
96
VITA
THE writer of this monograph, Daniel Walter Red-
mond, was born at Oxford, N. Y., in 1876. He received
his elementary training in the public schools of New
York state and at the High School at Greene, N. Y.
His college work was done at Hamilton College from
which he received the degree of Ph. B. in 1901.
In 1901-1904 he taught in the High School at Clinton,
N. Y. In 1904-5 he taught in Jenner's Preparatory
School at Syracuse, N. Y. From 1905-12 he has been
a Special Instructor in the department of Public Speak-
ing at the College of the City of New York.
In economics and allied subjects the author has studied
under Professor Delos DeWolf Smyth at Hamilton
College and under Professors E. R. A. Seligman, H. R.
Seager, J. B. Clark, H. L. Moore, F. H. Giddings, A.
A. Tenney, Frank J. Goodnow and T. R. Powell at
Columbia University.
97
FOURTEEN DAY USE
RETURN TO DESK FROM WHICH BORROWED
This book is due on the last date stamped below, or
on the date to which renewed.
Renewed books are subject to immediate recall.
5Jan'56MCZ
* *Jfcu
General Library
LD 21-100m-2, 55 University of California
(B139s22)476 Berkeley