fl.-i;; 
 
 THE LIBRARY 
 
 OF 
 
 THE UNIVERSITY 
 
 OF CALIFORNIA 
 
 RIVERSIDE 
 
 GIFT OF 
 
 Dr. Gordon Watkins

 
 Industrial Freedom: 
 
 ^ ^tutrg in IpoUtira. 
 
 > ^ 
 B. R. WISE, 
 
 III 
 Sovietinie Attorney-General of New South Wales, and Honorary 
 
 Member of the Cobden Club. 
 
 "War and Tariffs these are the two great enemies of mankind 
 
 John Br ght. 
 
 " Becau';e right is right, to follow the right is wisdom, in the 
 scorn of consequence." Tennyson. 
 
 CASSELL & COMPANY, Limited 
 
 LONDON, PARIS <S- MELBOURNE. 
 1892.
 
 HFZO^S 
 
 L05
 
 0.0 
 
 SIR HENRY PARKES, G.C.M.G., etc. etc. 
 
 AN HONOURED CHIEF AND FRIEND.
 
 PREFACE. 
 
 During the years 1880-82, a few Oxford graduates and under- 
 graduates, who had been brought together by the influence of 
 the late Arnold Toynbee, used to meet once a month during 
 term time, alternately in Oxford and London, for the purpose 
 of discussing in detail, and with complete frankness, some 
 specified political or social question.* 
 
 One of the subjects frequently referred to at these meetings 
 was the attitude of the working classes towards Free Trade ; 
 and it was agreed that some member of the Society should 
 prepare a paper, under Toynbee's supervision, on the best 
 means of fixing popular attention on the relation of political 
 economy to fiscal questions. 
 
 The execution of this idea was allotted to the present 
 writer, and an outline of a pamphlet was prepared and sub- 
 mitted to Toynbee for criticism in 1882. Toynbee in that 
 year was engaged upon the London lectures which led to his 
 last illness, and was, consequently, unable to carry out his plan 
 of a conjoint work. He did, however, discuss very fully with 
 the writer, in several conversations, the scheme of the intended 
 work, and suggested many modifications of that which had 
 
 * The nicinbers of this Society, wliich liad no name, vere Arnold Toynbee ; 
 Alfred Milner, New College, Editor of Toynbee's posthumous work, "The 
 Industrial Revolution "' ; P. L. (jell, Balliol College ; F. C. Montague, Balliol 
 College; E. T. Cook, Xew College; D. G. Ritchie, Jesus College; J. A. 
 Hamilton, Balliol College; J. D. Rogers, Balliol College; Hon. W. Bruce, 
 Balliol College ; and B. R. Wise, Queen's College. Mr. Ritchie's essay on 
 "Darwinism and Politics," in Swan Sonnenschein & Co.'s "Social Science 
 Series," and Mr. Montague's book on "The Limits of Individual Liberty" 
 (Kegan Paul >S: Co., 1884), both originated in these meetings.
 
 vi Preface. 
 
 been originally proposed. The result was that, in 1883, the 
 manuscript of a pamphlet of about fifty pages, of which the 
 spirit was Toynbee's, although the words were not, was sub- 
 mitted to the Cobden Club for publication. By a series of 
 mischances, this manuscript, of which no copy had been kept, 
 was lost, and the loss was not made known to the writer until 
 after the lapse of twelve months, A\hen it was too late to recall 
 even the form of the argument which Toynbee had suggested. 
 The original idea was not, however, left unexecuted. In 1885, 
 the writer embodied something of Toynbee's opinions in a 
 pamphlet published in Sydney under the title of " Free Trade 
 and Wages," which is now out of print. 
 
 The present work was first intended as a new edition of 
 this pamphlet ; but as it proceeded, and the stress of controversy 
 with Protectionists compelled attention to other aspects of the 
 fiscal question, it gradually assumed a new and distinct form, 
 until there is now left in it nothing of Toynbee, save some 
 traces of his influence, and the pious feeling which acknow- 
 ledges that, as the inception of the work was due to him, so its 
 execution should be taken as a tribute to his memory. The 
 writer's best hope is that those who knew Toynbee, and those 
 who trace no small portion of their better selves to the influence 
 of his luminous enthusiasm, may not think the tribute alto- 
 gether unworthy. 
 
 One word more upon tlie scope and method of the work. 
 Written, as it has been, at intervals during the rare and busy 
 leisure of an active ijrofessional and public life, it cannot lay 
 claim to either literary or scientific completeness. Its merit, if 
 any, lies in the directly practical character of its arguments and 
 illustrations. For seven years the writer has been engaged by 
 the side of Sir Henry Parkes in the forefront of an active 
 political controversy with the Protectionists of his native
 
 Preface. vii 
 
 country, until he has gained an exceptional familiarity with the 
 modes of thought and expression that win favour for Protection 
 among voters. The aim of the work is to make use of this special 
 knowledge of Protectionist arguments to put together a complete 
 and scientific statement of the Free Trade case, from the point 
 of view of one who is addressing himself to the voters of a 
 Democratic country. There is thus no intention to rival or 
 supplant other well-known text-books of Free Trade, but rather 
 to write a work which shall be complementary both to Professor 
 Fawcett's carefully tabulated index of arguments, and to the 
 elaborate rhetorical presentment of the case by Mr. Henry 
 George. If the writer has in places gone beyond this aim, or 
 departed from his proper method, his excuse is offered in the 
 language of a fellow-student who, defending himself by antici- 
 pation from the same charge, urges as follows : " I cannot," 
 he says, "think that any man with open and attentive eyes, 
 and with confidence in his own impartiality, as based upon a 
 rational view of life, does wrong in uttering the best reflections 
 he can make on the way in which things are going, or the way 
 in which he thinks they should go." * 
 
 * "Essays and Addresses," by Eerr.ard Eosar.quet, M.A. (London : Swan 
 Sonnenschein & Co., 1889), p. vi. 
 
 Sydney, Fehniarv loth, i8qi.
 
 CONTENTS. 
 
 PREFACE 
 
 fart X. 
 
 THE REVIVAL OF FROTECTION. 
 
 CHAPTER I. Its Nature i 
 
 II. Its Causes 7 
 
 ,, III. Its Sigmkicance 19 
 
 ,, IV. Illustrations 23 
 
 {a) Great Britain ... 23 
 
 (6) The Continent of Euroie . 42 
 
 {c) The United States . . .48 
 
 (d) The British Colonies. . . ;6 
 
 part XX. 
 
 PREPARING THE ARENA. 
 
 CHAPTER I. Definition of Free Trade 
 
 ,, II. Division of the Arguments 
 
 ,, III. Economics and Politics .... 
 
 ,, IV. Economics and the Tariff 
 
 ,, V. Nationalist Economics .... 
 
 ,, VI. Nationalist Economics and the Tariff 
 
 ,, VII. Free Trade and Laissez-faire 
 
 ,, VIII. Protection and Socialism 
 
 73 
 77 
 87 
 97 
 I OS 
 129 
 
 138 
 159 
 
 llart XXX. 
 
 THE ECONOMIC ARGUMENT. 
 
 CHAPTER I. Free Trade and Production . 
 
 ,, II. Protection and Production 
 
 ,, III. Free Trade and Prices 
 
 IV. Protection and Prices 
 
 165 
 
 167 
 
 173 
 181
 
 X Contents. 
 
 I'AGE 
 
 CHAPTER V. Free Trade and Wages 187 
 
 ,, VI. Protection and Wages 204 
 
 ,, VII. Do High Prices make High Wages? . . 207 
 VIII. Does more Work mean more Money ? . . 221 
 
 fart lY. 
 
 THE POLITICAL ARGUMENT. 
 
 CHAPTER I. The Arguments Classified .... 237 
 ,, II. The Infant Industry Argument . . . 241 
 
 ,, III. The "Diversification OF Industry"Argument 259 
 
 (rt) The Argument Stated . . 259 
 
 (b) The Argument Tested bv Facts . 265 
 
 (c) The Argument Tested bv Theory . 273 
 
 (d) Thb Other Side of the Shield . 278 
 
 ,, IV. The Home Market Argument. . . . 286 
 V. The Paui'er Labour Argument . . . 302 
 VI. The Cost of Protection 323 
 
 ^ppcntiicc!: 
 
 APPENDIX I. Tables of Wages in the English Cotton, 
 
 Woollen, Worsted, and Iron Trades . 337 
 
 ,, II. An Examination of J. S. Mill's supposed 
 approval of Protective Tariffs in a 
 Young Country 343 
 
 ,, III. Comparison of the Progress of New South 
 
 Wales under Free Trade with that of 
 Victoria under Protection .... 347
 
 INDUSTRIAL FREEDOM: 
 
 A STUDY IN POLITICS. 
 
 SUMMARY. 
 
 flart Im 
 THE PROTECTIONIST REVIVAL. 
 
 CHAPTER I. 
 
 ITS NATURE. 
 THE CHARACTERISTICS OF THE MODERN PROTECTIVE 
 
 SPIRIT Page I 
 
 Modern Protection differs from the old form of that poHcy 
 {a) In the composition of the party who support it. 
 {b) In its objects. 
 In consequence of this difference, EngHsh Free Trade argu- 
 ments are not necessarily applicable to the present dispute. 
 
 CHAPTER II. 
 
 ITS CAUSES. 
 CAUSES WHICH HAVE AIDED THE REVIVAL OF 
 
 PROTECTION Page 7 
 
 The revival of Protection has been assisted by a misconception 
 of the nature of Free Trade, arising from several circumstances, 
 viz. : 
 
 {a) The mistake of Free Traders in directing their 
 arguments principally to the effect of Free Trade 
 upon the production of wealth, instead of to the 
 question of its effect on wages.
 
 xii " Summary. 
 
 {b) The supposition that Free Trade is hostile to the 
 working classes. 
 
 {c) The supposition that Free Trade requires a general 
 adoption of the principle oi laissez faire. 
 
 {d) The supposition that Free Traders are indifterent 
 to the evils of the competitive system. 
 
 ie) The growing discontent with existing social con- 
 ditions. 
 Summary. 
 
 CHAPTER III. 
 
 ITS SIGNIFICANCE .... Page 19 
 
 1. The Protectionist revival is often exaggerated, both 
 
 {a) In its extent. 
 
 {b) In its significance. 
 
 2. The mere fact of Protection creates no inference against 
 the wisdom of Free Trade. The truth is that Protection has 
 been adopted for varying reasons of a special, local, and tem- 
 porary character. There has been no general revolt against 
 Free Trade, and no deliberate rejection of the policy. 
 
 THE REVIVAL OF RESTRICTION. 
 CHAPTER IV. 
 
 ILLUSTKAl IONS. 
 SECTION I. GREAT BRITAIN. . . Page!}, 
 
 I. Protectionists treat the example of Great Britain in two 
 ways : either, they admit that Free Trade is proved to be a 
 success for her ; or, they say it is a " one-sided Free Trade," 
 and not the Free Trade that was desired.
 
 Summary. xiii 
 
 2. The success of Free Trade in Great Britain is an incon- 
 testable historical fact. 
 
 3. Summary of investigation of the subject : Mr. Giffen's 
 researches on the magnitude of the general advance in pro- 
 sperity since Free Trade. 
 
 4. The Protectionist assertion that this increase has been 
 caused entirely by railways and other mechanical improvements 
 is improbable, because 
 
 {a) A sudden or (except on the hypothesis that it is 
 due to Free Trade) an inexplicable advance in 
 trade has taken place after every dose of Free 
 Trade legislation. 
 
 {/i) The mechanical factor, when working without 
 Free Trade, has produced a less result. 
 
 5. Examination of the statement, that England adopted 
 Free Trade under the mistaken belief that other nations would 
 follow her example. 
 
 6. The statement is not historically true. Conclusion : 
 The significance of the Anti-Corn Law agitation, and the 
 arguments by which it was supported, are in no way weakened, 
 either by the experience of forty-five years, or by inquiries into 
 the motives and anticipations of the Free Trade leaders. 
 
 Notes on the condition of England under Protection : 
 
 XoTi-: A, Extract from Mattineau"s History of the Peace. 
 N'oTK B. I'xtract from I'apor by George \V. Medley. 
 
 SECriOX II. THE CONTIXKNT OF EUROPE . . . f age 0^2 
 
 1. A\'hen England adopted Free Trade, the general belief 
 in the peaceful tendencies of the age caused an over-sanguine 
 anticipation of the universal triumph of Free Trade. 
 
 2. This anticipation was to some extent shared by Cobden. 
 
 3. Owing cliiefly to the si)irit of Nationalism, the period of 
 peace came to an end. 
 
 4. Ford Sandon's Return of Tariff changes, since 1S50,
 
 xiv Summary. 
 
 shows, that until the effects of the Franco-German War were 
 fully felt, there was a steady movement throughout Europe in 
 the direction of Free Trade. 
 
 5. The modern revival of Protection in Europe is intimately 
 connected with the growth of militarism, which is the chief 
 reason why European nations have ceased to follow in the Free 
 Trade footsteps of Great Britain. 
 
 CHAPTER IV. 
 
 ILLUSTRATIONS. 
 SECTION III. THE UNITED STATES Page ^^ 
 
 1. Difficulty of Studying tariff movements in the United 
 States. 
 
 2. The revolt of the American Colonies was largely a revolt 
 against Protection. 
 
 3. The tariffs from 1789 to 1861. 
 
 4. Connection between tariffs and prosperity. 
 
 5. Conclusion : High tariffs have generally been the result 
 of some morbid industrial condition. The recent growth of 
 Protection is directly traceable to the Civil War. 
 
 CHAPTER IV. 
 
 ILLUSTRATIONS. 
 SECTION IV. THE HRITISH COLONIES .... /rt,7<' 56 
 
 1. The most deliberate repudiation of Free Trade has 
 occurred in the British Colonies. 
 
 2. This is largely owing to the influence of Victoria, 
 
 5. Which is now decreasing, owing to a decline in the com- 
 parative importance of the colony. Protection in the other
 
 Summary. xv 
 
 colonies is mainly traceable to a desire to retaliate upon 
 Victoria. 
 
 4. Protection in Canada originated partly in retaliation on 
 the United States, and partly 
 
 5. As a revenue measure, owing to the difficulty, with such 
 a scattered population, of devising any acceptable system of 
 direct taxation. 
 
 6. The Revenue Question in Australia. The tendency is 
 for the rich men to become Protectionists in order to escape 
 direct taxation. The struggle is becoming one between the 
 classes and the masses. 
 
 7. This was not the case in the Victorian struggle of 1866 
 and onward, which began as a Democratic struggle against the 
 large land-owners. Characteristics of the struggle. 
 
 8. Summary. 
 
 Note. Extract from " The Tariff on Trial," by Sir Richard 
 Cartwright, N. Am. Rev., May, 1890. 
 
 Part II. 
 PREPARING THE ARENA. 
 
 CHAPTER I. 
 
 DEFINITION- OF FREE TRADE . . ra;;e 73 
 
 1. The revival of Protection not being the result of a new 
 economic doctrine, but of indifference to the old, it is necessary 
 to re-state the Free Trade case. 
 
 2. Free Trade may be used in several senses ; but in this 
 controversy it bears the limited meaning of " the absence of 
 duties of a protective character." 
 
 3. Illustrations of this from Mr. Cobden's speeches. 
 
 4. Necessity for so limiting the meaning of the term.
 
 Xvi SUMMARV. 
 
 ' CHAPTER 11. 
 
 DIVISION OF THE ARGUMENT . . Page 77 
 
 1. The issue between Protectionists and Free Traders is 
 often obscured by neglect to observe the distinction between 
 the poHtical and the economic arguments, which may be 
 adduced on either side. 
 
 2. Nature of the distinction between poHtical and economic. 
 
 3. The political argument considered and illustrated. 
 
 4. Application to the tariff controversy. Economic argu- 
 ments deal solely with the effect of a policy on the production 
 of wealth ; while the political arguments suggest other tests of 
 its merits. 
 
 5. The economic argument ought to be considered before 
 the political, both because most of the political arguments in 
 favour of Protection tacitly assume an economic basis, and 
 because the economic result of a policy is always an important, 
 and often the only, test of its political soundness. 
 
 CHAPTER HI. 
 
 KCONOMICS AND POLITICS: OR, THE VALUE OF THE ECONOMIC 
 ARCLMENT Page ?>1 
 
 1. The validity of any economic argument in a political 
 discussion is sometimes denied. It is therefore necessary to 
 consider the relation between politics and economics. 
 
 2. The nature of economic assumptions. 
 
 3. The assumption of the universality and dominance of 
 self-interest is said to be unreal. 
 
 4. Consideration of this criticism. It is partly true ; but 
 it does not affect the validity of economic arguments when 
 these are applied to discussions upon the best means of in- 
 creasing natural produrtivencss.
 
 Summary. xvii 
 
 5. Secondly, it is said "the term wealth is incapable of 
 definition." 
 
 6. This criticism ignores the distinction between the pro- 
 vinces of politics and economics. Moreover, it is not quite 
 correct. Political economy does take some account of the 
 differences in the kinds of wealth. 
 
 7. Conclusion. Economic conclusions must be applied 
 cautiously, and have only a limited range ; but inasmuch as 
 they concern the production of material wealth, no politician 
 
 can discard them. Importance of wealth to a modern indus- 
 trial community. 
 
 CHAPTER IV. 
 
 ECONOMICS AND THE TARIFF . . Tage 97 
 
 1. Since a tariff is intended to directly affect national 
 productiveness, the economic conclusions as to the best methods 
 of production cannot be ignored, if the circumstances are such 
 as to allow of economic conclusions being applied at all. Do 
 the assumptions of political economy square with the facts of a 
 tariff controversy ? 
 
 2. The first postulate of economics as to the predominance 
 of self-interest is not unreal in tariff discussions. A tariff is 
 concerned directly with tlie production of wealth, and appeals 
 entirely to the motive of self interest. 
 
 3. The second postulate of economics, as to the equality of 
 the competing units, is also sufficiently true to facts, wlien the 
 matter of consideration is the ])rcduction of wealth. 
 
 4. Nor does it lie in the mouths of Protectionists to evade 
 economic conclusions by asserting that the acc^uisition of 
 wealth is of little importance as compared with its right use. 
 This may be true, but wlien tlie material advancement of a 
 country is the thing aimed at, the degree of national produc- 
 tiveness is of primary importance. Besides, the political 
 
 A
 
 Xvlii Si'.UMAKi'. 
 
 arguments in favour of Protection really postulate an economic 
 basis. 
 
 5. Summary. Full weight may be given to the objections 
 against political economy without weakening the economic 
 argument in fiivour of Free Trade. 
 
 CHAPTER V. 
 
 NATIONALIST ECONOIHICS . . . pa^e 105 
 
 1. The consensus of scientific opinion against Protection 
 has led to an attempt to frame a new syste:-a of economics. 
 
 2. It must, however, be remembered that the term 
 "economic," as used by nationalists, no longer connotes 
 exclusively material wealth, but includes everything which 
 has any relation to national well-being. This leads to the 
 result that 
 
 3. Economic investigation becomes historical and not 
 deductive, and the tests of economic conformity alter. 
 
 4. A science of this nature cannot answer the individualist 
 conclusions. It may justify the passing of them by, but it 
 does not meet them on the sanie plane, because it does 
 not propose to consider tlic effect of a tariff upon wealth 
 production. 
 
 5. The fundamental difference between the new and the 
 old system is that the former adopts the nation as the in- 
 dustrial unit instead of the individual. 
 
 6. The " science " tested by reference to its scope and 
 method. No sciciilifu results are possible from a "science" 
 whose subject is "the comfort and happiness of a nation." 
 
 7. The "science" further tested by its practical maxims. 
 
 {a) National self-dependence : Impossible in point of 
 fact and not theoretically desirable.
 
 Summary. xix 
 
 {b) The duty of developing the productive powers of a 
 nation, rather than increasing its wealth. 
 
 8. Conclusion. The study has no claim to be considered 
 a science, but is useful in its historical investigations and 
 political suggestions. 
 
 Note.- On the Characteristics of Nationalist Writers. 
 
 CHAPTER \T. 
 
 NATIONALIST ECONOMICS AND THE TARIIF . . . Pa^c 129 
 
 1. Further test of the so-called " science,'' by applying it to 
 the tariff dispute. Materials. 
 
 2. The argument stated. 
 
 3. It rests on two assumptions 
 
 {a) That manufacturing excellence is more productive 
 than rural skill of national intelligence and 
 character. 
 
 {b) That manufacturing excellence cannot be attained 
 without Protection. 
 
 But {a) is beside the mark at present, because (i.) 
 No country to-day is without a high degree of 
 manufacturing ski!!, and (ii.) Under jjresent con- 
 ditions, country pursuits are more favourable than 
 manufacturing to tlic culiivation of character and 
 intelligence. 
 
 4. {b) rests on the assumption that stlf-inlcicsl cannot be 
 relied upon to establish profitable manufactures, 'i he alleged 
 reasons for this stated and considered. 
 
 5. Conclusion: The so-called "economic"' case for Pro- 
 tection is really a iSeries of doubtful political propositions. 
 
 Note. On Nationalists and Protection. 
 
 A 2
 
 CHAPTER VII 
 
 FREE TRADE AND LAISSEZ FAIRE Ta^e I38 
 
 1. Protection and Free Trade are almost always discussed 
 with reference to their cognate political theories of socialism 
 and Laissez faire. 
 
 2. Historical reasons of this : The negative character of 
 Adam Smith's work was not at first perceived, and his doctrine 
 of " natural liberty " was perverted to their own purposes by 
 the opponents of all remedial legislation. 
 
 3. Laissez faire, however, is not a part of economic 
 teaching. 
 
 4. Free Traders, who believe in Laissez faire, have a logical 
 advantage in arguing about Protection ; but no arguments 
 which are based upon this maxim will ever convince. 
 
 5. The extension of a rule of practice justified by Free Trade 
 within its own province to another department of human 
 activity is neither sound in theory nor possible in practice. 
 The maxim of Laissez faire can never be applied within the 
 field of the distribution of wealth, both because 
 
 (a) The postulate of equality of the competing units is 
 
 unreal. 
 (i') The political considerations would overwhehn any 
 
 economic conclusions. 
 
 6. The recognition of these truths was very slow. But 
 practical necessities gradually broke down the opposition which 
 was founded upon " Laissez faire." 
 
 7. Conclusion : The Free Trade argument is independent of 
 any political theory.
 
 Summary. xxi 
 
 CHAPTER VIII. 
 
 PROTECTION AND SOCIALISM . . Page 159 
 
 1. The po'itical arguments in favour of Protection are 
 at bottom socialistic. 
 
 2. Some Free Traders {e.g., Professor Sumner) consider this 
 to be condemnatory of Protection. Many Protectionists are 
 inconsistent enough to denounce socialism. 
 
 3. On the other hand, many Free Traders are ready to 
 support socialistic measures under certain circumstances, viz., 
 provided that (i.) The end desired is on a balance of advan- 
 tages and disadvantages found to be good, (ii.) That State 
 action can achieve it. (iii.) That private enterprise cannot. 
 
 Protection fails to satisfy these three conditions of legiti- 
 mate State action. 
 
 Note. The limits of State interference. 
 
 fart IIX. 
 THE ECONOMIC ARGUMENT. 
 
 CHAPTER I. 
 
 i'RKE TRADE AND PRODUCTION . . Fagc 165 
 
 1. The material prosperity of a country must in the long 
 run depend upon its capacity to produce wealth. 
 
 2. Free Trade increases national productiveness by applying 
 the princii)le of division of employment on a large scale. 
 
 Under Free Trade, men choose their own occupations. 
 If, then, some industries are not followed, this is a sign that 
 they are believed to be less profitable than others.
 
 xxii Summary'. 
 
 CHAPTER 11. 
 
 PROTECTION AND PRODUCTION . . Page 167 
 
 Protection lessens the power to produce in three ways : 
 (i.) Under Protection men are attracted by the pro- 
 mise of State aid from the industries they would 
 naturally follow if left to themselves, into others 
 from which, if left to themselves, they would hold 
 aloof. 
 Protection, therefore, diminishes natural productiveness by 
 attracting capital and labour from the more to the less profit- 
 able occupations. 
 
 This source of loss, however, will be avoided if the new 
 industries are started with imported labour and capital. 
 
 (ii.) A second cause of diminution in the national 
 productiveness arising from Protection is the loss 
 of wealth which is occasioned by the necessity of 
 providing a fund, out of which the profits in the 
 protected industries may be made equal to those 
 of the national industries, 
 (iii.) A third loss arises from the decrease in the pur- 
 chasing power of the customer, arising from the 
 increase of prices occasioned by protective duties. 
 
 CHAPTER in. 
 
 FREE TRADE AND PRICES . . Page ly^ 
 
 1. The complaint against Free Trade of causing an exces- 
 sive cheapness is due to a misconception of the effect of low 
 prices on prothirtion. 
 
 2. A low level of prices may be due to one or more of 
 three causes, \\/.. -. 
 
 (i.) To a lessened cost of i)roduction.
 
 SuMMAKV. xxiii 
 
 (ii.) To a decreased power of consumption, 
 (iii.) To a scarcity of gold. 
 The cheapness which was the chief characteristic of the 
 recent industrial depression arose from all three causes. 
 
 3. Free Trade lowers prices by cheapening the processes 
 of production ; of this sort of cheapness there can never be 
 too much, because every fall in prices arising from this cause 
 only, must stimulate demand. 
 
 4. Free Trade, besides lowering prices, also steadies them : 
 
 ((-?) I')y widening the area of production. 
 (/>) By widening tlie area of consumption. 
 {c) By giving a more accurate knowledge of the state 
 of markets. 
 
 5. Free Trade cannot, however, prevent commercial crises, 
 or the disastrous falls in prices which accompany commercial 
 crises. 
 
 CHAPTER IV. 
 
 PROTECTION' AND TRICES . . Pa^e 181 
 
 1. The argument of the preceding chapters rested on the 
 unexpressed assumption that Protection raised prices. 
 
 2. Although this is sometimes denied. Protection must 
 raise prices or else it fails to protect. 
 
 3. Protection may have been supposed not to raise prices 
 owing to 
 
 (i.) The fact that prices generally have fallen all over 
 
 the world, 
 (i'.) That a later effect of Protection is often to reduce 
 particular prices by encouraging an excessive in- 
 ternal com|)ctition. 
 
 4. The tendency of Protection to lower prices when the 
 supply has exceeded the demand of the home market is 
 generally checked by trusts, podls. and other forms of com- 
 bination.
 
 Xxiv Sl'Af^JAKV. 
 
 CHAPTER V. 
 
 FREE TRADE AND WAGES . . fa^e 187 
 
 1. Wages arc the labourer's sliare of the product. 
 
 2. Free Trade acts on wages by improving the efficiency of 
 labour. 
 
 3. First objection to this view T/ia/ competition betiveen a 
 country of high 7uages and one of low wages, tends to depress the 
 rate of the former to that of the latter. 
 
 4. The fallacy of this lies in comparing the rate of wages 
 with the labour-cost of production. 
 
 5. Second objection 77/c7/ Free Trade depresses wages to 
 the prof t of rent. This can only be the case when Free Trade 
 acts as a di':couragcment of industrial variety. The case of 
 Ireland considered. 
 
 6. The objection is theoretically sound under some circum- 
 stances, but these circumstances are in practice non-existent. 
 Free Trade docs not, in fact, discourage industrial variety; 
 nor, if it did, is Protection the best remedy. 
 
 7. Free Trade also steadies wages. Importance of this. 
 
 CHAPTER \l. 
 
 PROTEC'JION AND WAGES . . , Pa^e 204 
 
 1. Protection affects wages by diminishing the efficiency of 
 labour. 
 
 2. The allegations to the contrary refer to the influence of 
 Protection in encouraging new industries. Consideration ot 
 
 this deferred. 
 
 CHAPTER \ll. 
 
 DO HIGH I'RICKS MAKl', HIGH V,-AGi;S? .... Pa ^e 2oy 
 
 1. Consideration of the i'rotcctionist argument that em- 
 ployment is better than rhcai^icss. 
 
 2. 'Phis really rests on the as'^umption that " high prices 
 make high wages."
 
 Sl/MMAKV. 3{XV 
 
 3. This assumption is unlikely to be true on a priori 
 grounds. 
 
 4. It is also unsupported by evidence, and is contradicted 
 by the records of six centuries of English industrial history, 
 and by a comparison between wages in New South Wales and 
 Victoria. 
 
 5. If Protection were limited to one trade, it might cause 
 a temporary rise of Vf ages in that trade. 
 
 6. Even if a rise occur in nominal wages, real wages may 
 remain unaltered. 
 
 7. Protectionist?, however, advocate " all-round " Pro- 
 tection. 
 
 8. This is impossible. 
 
 9. The argument that " high prices make high wage:; " is 
 inconsistent with the argument that Protection lowers prices. 
 
 CH.VrTER VIII. 
 
 DDKS MORK WORK Ml.AN MORE MONEY? . . . /'j.^ 221 
 
 1. Statement of the Protectionist argument, which is really 
 rather an allegation of fact. 
 
 AMiether employment is better than cheapness is a question 
 of evidence. Protectionists make the statement, but fail to 
 support it by facts. 
 
 2. Discussion of the Protectionist tlieory of the importance 
 "of employment." The question is not "Whether Protection 
 causes an increase of employment in this or that trade?" but 
 " A\"hether it causes an increase all round ? '' 
 
 Now, since the admitted object and effect of Protection is 
 to cause something to be made in one country which, in a state 
 of freedom, would be made in another. Protection must cause 
 a waste of labour. 
 
 3. Put labour which is wasted cannot be a source of 
 wealth.
 
 xxvi Summary. 
 
 The question to be considered is not whether Protection 
 gives employment, but whether the employment which it gives 
 is more productive than that which it destroys. 
 
 Illustration from the kerosene industry of New South Wales, 
 showing that Protection is a raost costly form of outdoor relief. 
 
 4. The fallacy of the Protectionist argument lies in the 
 assumption that the persons who are employed in protected 
 trades would be unemployed, if there were no Protection. 
 
 This assumption, however, cannot be true, generally ; since 
 in so far as Protection causes unnecessary labour, must it 
 diminish the labour available for productive employment. 
 
 Protection changes the nature of employment, but does not 
 increase the total. 
 
 Illustration from Canadian trade, 
 
 5. The foregoing conclusions are conceivably open to 
 qualifications in practice ; it is, however, most questionable 
 whether under any circumstances Protection is a good mea-ns 
 for giving State assistance to the labour market. 
 
 Whatever employment is given by Protection must be given 
 at the expense of others. 
 
 Protection is thus only a form of legalised plunder, and 
 those who benefit by it are, in reality, the recipients of public 
 charity. 
 
 fart lY. 
 
 THE POLITICAL ARGUMENT IN FAVOUR OP 
 PROTECTION. 
 
 CHAPTER I. 
 
 THK AROU.MIA'IS CLASSIFIED . . Page 2^7 
 
 I. All the political arguments arc reducible on analysis to 
 one of four, viz. : 
 
 {a) The Infant Industry Argument. 
 (/') The Variety of Industry Argument.
 
 SuAfMARv. xxvii 
 
 {c) The Home Market Argument, 
 {d) The Pauper Labour Argument. 
 
 2. These have had a distinct historic sequence and con- 
 nection, both in America and AustraHa. 
 
 CHAPTER n. 
 
 THE INFANT INDUSTRY ARGUMENT Page 2^1 
 
 I. The argument stated. 
 
 2. Its assumption is, that a time will come, when the young 
 industry can stand alone. 
 
 3. Test of this assumption by the tariff changes of the 
 United States, with special reference to the cotton and iron 
 industries. 
 
 4. And by the tariff changes of Victoria. 
 
 5. These tests lead to the conclusion of fact, that the 
 infants never grow up. 
 
 6. The assumption tested by theory : It ignores the weak- 
 ness of human nature, and overlooks both the natural and the 
 artificial inter-dependence of trades. 
 
 7. Conclusion : Protection can be established only for a 
 time j nor can it be limited to specific industries. 
 
 CHAPTER III. 
 
 THE DIVERSIFICATION OF INDUSTRY ARGU^ilENT . . rai;e 2$<j 
 
 I. THE ARGU.MICNT S'JAIED. 
 
 I. The origin of the argument is partly the sentiment of 
 national sufficiency, and partly the economic conditions of 
 a young country.
 
 XXviii Si'MMAKV. 
 
 2. The assumptions of the argument are (i.) That there is 
 in fact no sufficient diversity; (ii.) That sufficient diversity 
 cannot be obtained without Protection ; (iii.) That Protection 
 is a less evil than want of diversity. 
 
 3. Admission that diversity of industry is desirable. 
 
 4. Method of argument. What has to be proved. 
 
 11. THE ARGUMENT TESTED BY FACTS. 
 
 5. Has any country in fact suffered from want of diversity? 
 
 6. Instance of America under the Colonial system. 
 
 7. Instance of the industrial growth of the Western States. 
 
 8. Instance of the industrial growth of Victoria. 
 
 III. THE ARGUMENT TESTED BY THEORY. 
 
 9. It is theoretically most improbable that any country 
 should suffer from industrial uniformity, if capital accumulates 
 and population increases. 
 
 10. The conditions of manufacturing success are 
 
 (/?) A large and concentrated population, which Free 
 Trade is at least as likely to give as Protection. 
 
 {/>) Abundance of capital, which Free Trade is more 
 likely to give. 
 
 IV. -THE OTHER SIDE OF THE (QUESTION. 
 
 1 1. There arc certain natural limits to diversification, which 
 cannot be passed without great risk. 
 
 12. 'J'he cost of diversification may be excessive. 
 
 13. The argument can never be used as a general defence 
 of protective policy.
 
 SiT.UMAKV. XXIX 
 
 CHAPTER IV. 
 
 THE HOME MARKET ARGUMENT . . /"a^v 286 
 
 1. The economic basis of the argument is the fallacy that 
 home trade is more profitable than foreign. 
 
 2. Political supports to the argument are 
 
 (a) The dread of war, which is the only logical basis 
 of Protection. 
 
 {d) The idea that foreign trade is more precarious than 
 home. List's views stated and examined. 
 
 (c) The idea that the home market causes land to be 
 profitably put to new uses. 
 
 {d) The idea that a home market increases the number 
 of customers. This is really an appeal to the 
 farmer to subsidise persons to buy his products. 
 
 {e) The idea first propounded by Mr. Hoyt, that the 
 home market enables the requirements of a com- 
 munity for manufactured goods to be fully supplied. 
 This ignores the danger of an over-supply. 
 
 3. The theory of the argument is opposed at every point 
 by facts. 
 
 CHAPTER V. 
 
 THE PAUl'KR LAliOUR ARCUMKXT. . Aioe 202 
 
 1. Increasing importance of this argument. 
 
 2. What is " pauper " labour ? Difiiculty of getting accurate 
 information about wages : necessity of limiting comparison to 
 specific trades in specific places. 
 
 3. Neverthele3s, for the sake of argument, it may be 
 admitted that wages are higlier in a young than an old 
 community. 
 
 4. The argument can only apply to those industries which 
 are exposed to foreign competition. These are chiefiy handi- 
 crafts.
 
 XXX Summary. 
 
 5. The price of goods does not depend upon the rate of 
 wages, but upon the cost of labour. 
 
 6. Since the "cost of labour" depends upon the natural 
 and the acquired efficiency of the labourer, and since a 
 labourer is both more intelligent and more assisted by nature 
 and machinery in a young than in an old country, the cost of 
 labour is likely to be less in the former than the latter, except 
 in the lowest and most degrading forms of handicraft, which it 
 is undesirable to introduce into a young country. 
 
 7. The argument is also inconsistent with the theory that 
 Protection lowers prices. 
 
 8. It is incapable of any jast application, because a scale of 
 duties would be required varying according to the rate of wages 
 paid in every competing community. 
 
 9. Protection is generally demanded against high-waged 
 countries. 
 
 10. But a low labour cost makes a high rate of wages. 
 
 1 1. Free Trade is more favourable than Protection to a low 
 labour cost. 
 
 12. Protection hastens a fall in wages. 
 
 CHAPTER VI. 
 
 THE COST OF PROTECTION . . I\ioe 323 
 
 1. The only way to conii)letely meet Protectionist sirgu- 
 menls is to treat the question as one of expediency ; granted 
 that Protection will do all that is claimed for it, is not the price 
 too high ? 
 
 2. Protection is an economic evil, because it is always 
 a waste of productive power. 
 
 3. It is a political evil, because it causes inequality and 
 corruption, and destroys the value of self-reliance. 
 
 4. It is a social evil, because it is antagonistic to progress. 
 
 5. It is a moral evil in its operation both abroad and at home. 
 
 6. Conclusion.
 
 Summary. 
 
 APPENDICES 
 
 I. Rates of wages in the cotton, woollen, worsted, and iron 
 
 industries of Great Britain since 1830 . . Page ^37 
 
 II. Examination of Mill's Defence of Protection in young 
 
 countries Faq-e 343 
 
 III. Comparison between the progress of New South Wales 
 and of Victoria , rai^e 347
 
 INDUSTRIAL FREEDOM. 
 
 THE REVIVAL OF PROTECTION. 
 
 CHAPTER I. 
 
 CHARACTERISTICS OF MODERN PROTECTION. 
 
 ^ I. Anyone who writes a new book upon Free Trade 
 ought, if he is not wholly graceless, to begin his work with 
 an apology. The subject has been worn so threadbare, 
 both by economists and politicians, that any novelty of treat- 
 ment or illustration is almost impossible ; while the arguments 
 on either side of the fiscal controversy seem to possess the 
 theological characteristic of only carrying conviction to the 
 minds of those who are previously disposed to believe. 
 
 Nevertheless, while men continue to be exercised over 
 tariff disputes, and while so many interests are affected by 
 the taxation measures of Protectionists, there must always 
 be room for a well-considered monograph upon the leading 
 features of the controversy, especially if care be taken in 
 compiling it to avoid the extremes of arid abstraction and 
 partisan rhetoric. 
 
 Therefore, in this attempt to revive an old argument 
 an efifort will be made to present both sides impartially ; 
 and to present them in such a way and with so sparing a 
 use of illustration from passing phenomena or special trades, 
 that the application of the arguments may not be confined 
 to parlicular countries or industries, but may extend over 
 
 B
 
 2 IXDUSTRIAL FREEDOM. 
 
 as large an area and for as long a time as the nature of 
 the subject will permit. 
 
 First, then, let us enquire into the reasons which make 
 a restatement of the points in controversy necessary. 
 
 By a turn of the political wheel Free Trade has gone under 
 for a time, although its triumphant reappearance is already 
 heralded by many signs. Still it cannot be denied that 
 the doctrine which was thought to be dead forty years ago, 
 and was even then spoken of as "dead and disgusting," 
 is now full of life and vigour. That such a phenomenon, 
 startling and disappointing as it must be to those who, 
 only a generation past, successfully maintained the battle 
 of industrial freedom, cannot be entirely owing to the in- 
 capacity of mankind to understand economic abstractions, 
 nor to what Professor Sidgwick has termed " the selfish 
 activity of the protected classes," will be readily admitted by 
 all who recognise that e.yery widespread popular delusion must, 
 if it is honestly believed, contain at least a modicum of truth. 
 
 What, then, is the explanation of the survival of Protec- 
 tion, and how comes it that a doctrine so discredited by 
 reason and experience is able at the present time to command 
 the support of intelligent and honest men ? To answer these 
 questions as they should be answered, it will be necessary 
 to pass in review and compare with each other the character- 
 istics of Protection in its earlier and its later stage. 
 
 2. A glance beneath the surface of events will soon reveal 
 the fact, that the contest which is raging now about protective 
 tariffs resembles that about the Corn Laws in little more than 
 name. The old battle-cries, indeed, are still in use ; but the 
 composition of the contending forces has been changed, and 
 the battle is being fought upon a different ground. 
 
 Broadly speaking, the old Free Trade movement was 
 an assertion on the part of the middle classes of their rights as
 
 The Revival of Protection: 3 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. i., ? 3] 
 
 consumers ; while the Protectionist movement of to-day is an 
 effort on the part of the manufacturing classes to obtain 
 privileges as producers. 
 
 This difference is illustrated by a comparison of the compo- 
 sition of the Anti-Corn Law League in England, and that of the 
 Protectionist party in Australia and America. The League 
 was in its origin a movement of the manufacturers and middle 
 classes, which gradually attracted to itself the more intelligent 
 among the artisans. In Australia and America, however, the 
 purses of the manufacturers support Protection, and the work- 
 ing classes, who were at first inclined to follow their employers, 
 are gradually returning to Free Trade. Nor is this the only 
 point of contrast between the new and the old Protectionism. 
 
 In England, it was only the aristocracy of labour which 
 became Free Traders; while the "residuum," under the 
 leadership of Feargus O'Connor, furiously denounced the 
 Anti-Corn Law League. In Australasia and America, on the 
 contrary, the aristocracy of labour, as represented by the Trade 
 Unions, is inclined to be Protectionist, while disorganised 
 labour leans more towards Free Trade. Lastly strangest con- 
 trast of all the farmers and landlords, who in England were 
 the backbone of Protection, are in Australasia and America 
 its weakest adherents. ^ 
 
 3. The reason for this change in the composition of the 
 two parties is easily found. 
 
 1 During the last three years there has been a tendency in New South 
 Wales and Tasmania, on the part of land-owners of all classes, to support 
 Protectionist candidates. But this attitude is not owing to any dislike of Free 
 Trade, but to a belief on the part of the great land-owners that Free Trade involves 
 direct taxation with a view to agricultural settlement ; and, on the part of the 
 small farmers, that Protection will enable them to retaliate on the neighbouring 
 colony of Victoria. The Free Trade movement in Victoria is almost exclusively 
 confined to farmers. Out of thirty-five agricultural associations, thirty have, 
 up to the present date (June, 1890), declared in favour of a return to Free 
 Trade. A Free Trade Democratic Association has now been started in Mel- 
 bourne, and will soon make its influence felt in the politics of the colony. 
 B 2
 
 4 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 The manufacturers and artisans of Australasia and America 
 look upon a different side of the question of Free Trade from 
 that which was perceived in England. It is not with them 
 a question of obtaining cheap raw materials these they have 
 always to their hands but a question of establishing new 
 industries. They desire to create, while the Englishman 
 desired to develop what was already created. Consequently, 
 the classes which in England encouraged the competition of 
 foreigners, because only foreigners could offer them the neces- 
 sary raw material, wish now, in Australasia and America, to 
 exclude the same competition, for fear it may destroy their 
 infant industries. 
 
 4. The change in the composition of the two parties has 
 materially affected the arguments by which either policy is 
 supported, and rendered necessary an alteration in the manner 
 of their presentment. At the present time the feelings of un- 
 reasoning men are enlisted on the side of Protection. At the 
 time of the Corn Laws in England it was just the reverse. 
 Then the cry for cheap food aroused such general sympathy, 
 that feelings made clear what the intellect might fail to grasp. 
 But in Australasia and America similar feelings lead further 
 on the path of error. Labour is scarce, land is cheap, capital 
 abundant. The spectacle is consequently presented of the 
 simultaneous existence of high wages and large profits, so that 
 the foundation is laid for the misleading argument, that such a 
 country cannot successfully compete against another country of 
 low wages and small profits. This at once gives rise to the 
 cry, that Protection is required to prevent wages and profits 
 from sinking to the European level. Such a cry attracts the 
 working classes, and gains the ear of the philanthropist. The 
 Protectionist appears to be the patriot who is desirous of de- 
 veloping the resources of his native land, and trying to prevent 
 a national stagiiation. He is the man wlio would guard the well 
 paid "native"' against the competition of the ill-paid European,
 
 The Revival of Protection. 5 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. i., \ 5.] 
 
 and who, by legislative interference, would maintain that union 
 of high wages and large profits, which is the striking economic 
 feature of a young country. The activity of the state in a 
 young country is extended, so that the idea that legislation can 
 accomplish even this result, arouses no misgiving in the minds 
 of men who ardently desire it. Nor is it of any avail in a 
 young country, where wages are high, to urge that Protection 
 must increase the price of articles in daily use. An intelligent 
 Protectionist would reply at once that he admits this fact, but 
 that he is prepared to undergo a private inconvenience for the 
 public benefit. He would say, as the Ballarat digger said to 
 Sir Charles Uilke, that "he preferred to pay dearer for his 
 jacket and moleskins, because by so doing he aided in build- 
 ing up in the colony such trades as the making of clothes, in 
 which his brother and other men, physically too weak to be 
 diggers, could gain an honest living." 
 
 It is plain that men who act under feelings like these must 
 be approached with very different arguments from those which 
 would appeal to working men in Europe. 
 
 5. Nor are the English arguments always applicable to the 
 circumstances of a young country, where (as has been already 
 pointed out) labour is scarce, land is cheap, and capital 
 abundant. The requisites of production stand to each other, 
 in Australasia and America, in such an abnormal relation, that 
 the abstractions of the English economists have often to be 
 qualified before they can be taken as an explanation of facts. 
 This is of itself a fruitful source of economic error, and offers 
 some excuse for the popular impatience of scientific arguments. 
 At times, indeed, the language of Free Trade arguments even 
 gives a confirmation to the popular delusion. For example, as 
 Professor Sidgwick has pointed out, 1 much that was urged 
 upon the English people as an argument in favour of Free 
 
 Address delivered before the British Association in 1886, since published 
 under the title of " The Scope and Method of Economics."
 
 6 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 Trade, is capable of being turned against Free Trade by those 
 who regard the question from another standpoint. Such an 
 argument, for instance, as that which appeared in the July 
 number of the Edinburgh Review for 1841, and which has 
 been repeated by many writers in various forms, would appeal 
 in very different ways to a patriotic Australian and to a patriotic 
 Englishman. " The early progress of any nation," says the 
 Free Trade writer, " that attempts to rival England in manu- 
 factures must be slow, for it has to contend with our great 
 capital, our traditionary skill, our almost infinite division of 
 labour, our long-established perseverance, energy, and enter- 
 prise, our knowledge of markets, and with the habits of those 
 who have been brought up to be our customers. ... If these 
 difficulties were once surmounted, this superiority so far at 
 least as respects the commodity in which we find ourselves 
 undersold would be gone for ever, in consequence of the 
 well-known law of manufacturing industr}', that ccekris 
 paribus with every increase of the quantity produced, the 
 relative cost of production is diminished." This argument 
 might have come straight out of a Melbourne Protectionist 
 newspaper instead of from the Edinhirgh Revietv. For it 
 cannot be denied (to quote the words of Professor wSidgwick 
 again) that "a consideration of the above law, and of the vis 
 inertice here attributed to an established superiority in manu- 
 factures and commerce, supplies an important qualification of 
 the general argument for Free Trade. For along with the 
 tendency of industry to go where it could be most economically 
 carried on, we have also to recognise the tendency for it to 
 stay and develop where it has once been planted ; and the 
 advantage of leaving this latter tendency undisturbed would 
 naturally be less clear to the patriotic foreigner than to the 
 patriotic Englishman. The proclamation of a free race for all, 
 just when England had a start which she might keep up for 
 centuries, would not seem to him a manifest realisation of 
 eternal justice ; to delay the race for a generation or two, and
 
 The Revival of Protection. 7 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. ii., \ 2] 
 
 meanwhile apply judiciously disturbing causes, in the form of 
 protective duties, would seem likely to secure a fairer start for 
 other nations, and ultimately, therefore, a better organisation of 
 the world's industry even from a cosmopolitan point of view." 
 
 6. It is apparent from the considerations expressed in the 
 preceding pages, that modern Protection requires to be met by 
 a line of argument different from that which was in use at an 
 earlier period. This is a truth which Free Trade writers have 
 been slow to recognise. They have not always seen that the 
 two most striking features of the new form of Protection, 
 namely, the expressed intention of creating new industries, and 
 the readiness to submit to temporary sacrifices for the purpose 
 of securing this result, can both lay claim to be justified by the 
 reasoning of English economists ; and they have consequently 
 fallen into the error of repeating old truths to opponents who 
 do not deny them. The extent of this error and its results will 
 form the subject of the following chapter. 
 
 CHAPTER II. 
 
 CAUSES WHICH HAVE AIDED THE REVIVAL OF PROTECTION. 
 
 I. The difficulty of applying the economic arguments in 
 their old form to the circumstances of a young country has been 
 already incidentally referred to in discussing the characteristics 
 of the Protectionist revival. It remains to consider how other 
 causes have assisted the progress of Protection. Among these 
 the mistakes and omissions of the Free Trade party must take 
 a prominent place. 
 
 % 2. It is certain that an error has been made by many Free 
 Tr.ide writers in approaching the question of Protection from
 
 8 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 the wrong side, and contemplating it in a different aspect from 
 that which is regarded by Protectionists themselves. Most 
 of these writers deal almost exclusively with the influence of 
 Free Trade upon the production of wealth, while the Pro- 
 tectionists chiefly direct their attention to the influence of a 
 fiscal policy upon the distribution of wealth. The consequence 
 has been that the arguments and the illustrations of Free 
 Traders have failed to appeal, as effectively as they deserve, to 
 the mass of Protectionist voters. 
 
 Such a mistake was natural to men reared in the midst of 
 the old controversy, and living for the most part in Free Trade 
 England. But in young countries, and, of late years, even in 
 England, it is necessary to put forward the cause of Free Trade 
 in another and more attractive light, and to consider it in its 
 effect upon the distribution of wealth as distinguished from its 
 effect upon production. 
 
 The reason for thus changing the point of view is the altera- 
 tion which has been made during recent years in the centre of 
 political power. In the days of Cobden and the Anti-Corn Law 
 League, when the middle classes formed the bulk of English 
 voters, it was most politic to dwell upon the influence of Free 
 Trade in cheapening the price of goods ; but in young countries 
 and at the present time in England, where the electorates are 
 controlled by working men, the voters wish to understand the 
 influence of that policy in raising wages. Accordingly, although 
 the old arguments remain quite true, it is desirable now, if we 
 wish to arrest general attention, to lay them aside for a time, 
 and bring out others which are more attractive to working men. 
 
 Unfortunately Free Traders have been slow to recognise 
 that, under the altered circumstances of an extended suffrage, 
 they must change the popular presentment of their views. As a 
 rule they still deal only with the figures of production. They tell 
 us, for example, that tke trade of England has advanced by 
 leaps and bounds ; that since Free Trade was introduced, the 
 income-tax returns are ten times what they were ; that the
 
 The Revival of Protectiojst. 9 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. ii., \ 3.] 
 
 quantity of funded wealth is daily growing larger, and the popu- 
 lation is increasing with an unsurpassed rapidity. They point 
 to the table of exports, to the growing cities, to the decline of 
 pauperism and of crime, and to the many signs of English in- 
 dustry and enterprise in every quarter of the globe, and, rolling 
 out their columns of magnificent statistics, they expect the 
 world to be convinced ! But working men, particularly in 
 Australasia and America, know well that this is not the last 
 word upon the subject ! The matter of concern to them is not 
 so much that goods should be produced in plenty, as that they 
 should have an opportunity to use their skill ; and, even in 
 England, the working classes care more for a policy which 
 promises high wages than for one which promises cheap goods. 
 It is hardly reasonable to expect that a man, who has but six- 
 pence in his pocket, should be greatly moved by hearing that 
 the price of silk has been reduced to half-a-crown ! 
 
 Accordingly, Free Trade must be justified in young countries 
 and to working men in quite another way than by a catalogue 
 of its effects upon production. It must be shown that Free 
 Trade has also an effect in raising wages ; that, whilst suggesting 
 desires, it gives means to satisfy them by cheapening most 
 articles of common use, and by bringing about the conditions 
 which are most favourable to a fairer distribution of wealth, and 
 most conducive in any community to a lasting rise in the 
 average standard of comfort. In making this investigation, the 
 real effect on wages of any fiscal policy will have to be con- 
 sidered, and the futility of attempting to raise wages by merely 
 altering a customs tariff ought to be made plain. It is certain 
 that, until such an inquiry is attempted, the Free Trade argu- 
 ments will fly above the heads of those whom it is intended to 
 convince. 
 
 3. Partly in consequence of having directed so much 
 attention to the effect of Free Trade upon capital, and 
 partly for other reasons to be mentioned, Free Traders have
 
 lo Industrial Freedom. 
 
 incurred the charge of being hostile to the working-classes. No 
 one, who has lived in a country where the fiscal controversy is 
 active, can have failed to notice the strong and bitter feeling with 
 which Free Traders are denounced by those who aspire to a 
 political position by the aid of the working-classes. This feeling 
 is, no doubt, to a great extent fictitious. It is necessary at times 
 for the "friend of the working man" and "friendship for the 
 working man" is a recognised profession in most English- 
 speaking countries to use strong language if he would not 
 have his sincerity suspected. Free Trade and Free Traders 
 offer a convenient object of attack, the more so that Free Trade 
 has been identified with an unpopular party both in Australasia 
 and America. The Free Traders in Victoria, where the fiscal 
 battle was first fought, were land-monopolists and Tories. 
 The Free Traders in America were Southern slave-owners. 
 It has taken a whole generation in both countries to dissociate 
 Free Trade from these unpopular causes. 
 
 4. Independently, however, of these local causes of ill- 
 feeling, there is a more general ground for the popular idea that 
 Free Traders have no sympathy with the aspirations of the 
 working-classes. This arises from the attitude which has been 
 adopted by many Free Trade writers towards the measures of 
 reform demanded by the working-classes. 
 
 Most of those whom the public regard as the champions of 
 Free Trade, from Ricardo to Professor Fawcett (with the two 
 notable, but often unperceived, exceptions of Richard Cobden and 
 John Stuart Mill), have been pedantically attached to that declin- 
 ing school of political thought which would restrict the action 
 of the State within the narrowest bounds. In consequence of 
 this, Free Trade has come to be identified with the general 
 principle of " Laisser faire." Indeed, so deeply rooted is this 
 confusion of ideas, that it is not uncommon, even in Radical 
 journals, to find Trade Unions denounced as a violation of 
 Free Trade principles, and a system of unregulated competition
 
 The Revival of Proiection. ii 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. ii., \ 5.] 
 
 between masters and men justified by an appeal to the same 
 authority. 
 
 Rightly or wrongly, however, working-men have believed 
 that their condition could never be permanently bettered until 
 the Government should interfere actively and widely upon 
 their behalf; and they have accordingly demanded and ob- 
 tained a long series of Acts of Parliament, to regulate and 
 protect labour, of which the Factory Acts are the best- 
 known examples. 
 
 All these measures have been opposed in the name of Free 
 Trade, although (as will be shown later in these pages) Free 
 Trade is an influence which works in the field of Production, 
 and offers no argument either for or against the interference of 
 Government within the field of Distribution. What wonder, 
 then, that working-men, when they have found Free Traders 
 confronting them at every effort to alleviate their lot by law, 
 have ceased to take an interest in the promised benefits of 
 Free Trade, and have regarded it as a middle-class doctrine, 
 comforting enough to the well-to-do, but offering no help to 
 them in their especial needs. 
 
 If, therefore, we would justify Free Trade to working-men, 
 we must break away from the ancient argument and show the 
 true relation of Free Trade to a general scheme of government. 
 This will be attempted later in these pages. At present the 
 misconception which exists upon this point is only mentioned 
 as one reason for the prevalent mistrust of Free Trade doctrines, 
 and as a special reason for their discredit among working-men. 
 
 5. Not less dangerous to the influence of P'ree Trade than 
 its supposed hostility to the interests of the working-classes, has 
 been its supposed indifference to the evils of the competitive 
 system. 
 
 Philanthropists and writers of the type of Mr. Ruskin have 
 exhausted themselves in denunciation of the immorality and 
 narrowness of the Free Trade systemi
 
 12 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 It is needless to say that these denunciations have been for 
 the most part ignorant and misdirected. But they have had so 
 much influence on a large class of benevolent people, who do 
 not reason closely or at all on economic questions, that it is 
 necessary to give them a passing attention. 
 
 It is said that Free Trade is indifferent to everything except 
 material \vealth, and that its last word is " to buy in the 
 cheapest and sell in the dearest market." 
 
 This is a charge which, from the modicum of truth which 
 it contains, has been peculiarly destructive. 
 
 Free Traders have, no doubt, written with only one object 
 that of showing the effect of a Free Trade policy upon national 
 wealth ; and it may be, that in looking at this single point, they 
 have seemed to attach an excessive importance to material 
 wealth. But this limitation of view no more justifies the asser- 
 tion that Free Traders have no regard for the higher objects of 
 national life, than the omission to mention pictures in a work 
 on mathematics would justify a charge against its writer of 
 ignorance of art. Because a Free Trader advocates the aboli- 
 tion of taxes on imports, it does not, therefore, follow that he 
 regards this measure as a panacea for every industrial evil ; nor, 
 because he urges the advantages of free exchange, must he be 
 supposed to hold that the highest social ideal is reached by 
 merely buying in the cheapest and selling in the dearest market. 
 The very silliness of a contrary supposition ought to be its own 
 refutation. Yet, no one who has read Protectionist literature, or 
 Mr. Ruskin's writings upon economics, can deny that even 
 patent silliness is no impediment to the popularity of a ground- 
 less charge. 
 
 The only excuse for this wild vilification is a misapprehen- 
 sion of the attitude of Free Traders towards the doctrine of 
 free competition. 
 
 6. The Ricardian assumption of the existence within the 
 industrial field of an universal and ever-active competiton an
 
 The Revii^al of Protection. 13 
 
 Pt. 1., Ch. u., \ 6.] 
 
 assumption which was in accordance with facts at the time 
 Ricardo wrote has been taken by newspaper writers and 
 others to be an assertion of principle. This imaginary prin- 
 ciple has been erected into a "natural law," which is 
 supposed to have been discovered by political economists ! 
 Then, by a confusion in the use of the term " law," political 
 economy has been invoked by way of protest against every 
 attempt to regulate or interefere with competition ! 
 
 In fact, however, as every economist has pointed out, the 
 " laws " of political economy are mere expressions of the 
 regular sequence of certain events under certain assumed con- 
 ditions. The most important of these conditions is that of 
 free competition. It is assumed that there is a never-ceasing 
 competition between the units of every industrial system, 
 although it is admitted that this assumption only applies in 
 fact to the wholesale trade and the great articles of commerce. 
 Nor is this the whole of the assumption. The competition of 
 abstract political economy is not the competition of masters 
 and men as we see them in every-day life, but it is the com- 
 petition of certain imaginary industrial units. These units are 
 spoken of sometimes as individuals, and at other times as groups 
 of individuals; but they are always supposed to have this 
 characteristic the units are equal to one another. It cannot 
 be too often repeated that the competition of abstract political 
 economy that competition through which alone political 
 economy has any pretension to the character of a science is a 
 competition between equal units. This is no place to consider 
 whether this assumption still holds true in these days of " pools 
 and combinations," (i) or whether it was not always too far re- 
 moved from facts to be of great practical value. It is enough 
 to point out here how a misconception of its true nature has 
 prejudiced the progress of f'ree Trade. It has been imagined 
 that Free Trade being a doctrine founded upon political 
 
 Sec, for a discussion of this point, an article by Piof. Jolr.'i !'. ( ''..irl< in 
 tlie Political Science Quarterly for Marcli, 1887, vol. ii., p. 62.
 
 14 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 economy, justified the universal reign of lawless and unregulated 
 competition. Nothing could be further from the truth. 
 
 7. So far from justifying the universal reign of competition, 
 the doctrines of Free Trade have no application outside of 
 their own limited sphere. Free Trade is simply an expedient 
 for carrying the principles of division of employment into inter- 
 national commerce. It is merely a means of facilitating the 
 greatest possible production of wealth through facilitating 
 exchange. Having accomplished that, its work is ended, and 
 it leaves to other agencies the work of distribution. 
 
 Free Trade, in other words (using the term in its proper sense, 
 to mean " the absence of protective duties "), operates exclu- 
 sively within the field of production. Now, within the field of 
 production there happens to be a competition between equal 
 units. There is, as a general rule, an equality between those 
 who buy and those who sell commodities, since both goods 
 and capital can be removed from place to place, and the post- 
 ponement of a sale or purchase causes at the worst a loss of 
 money. 
 
 But once within the field of distribution, circumstances 
 alter. The wages of labour and the price of goods are not in 
 fact now, nor have they ever been, determined by the same 
 forces ; nor is that condition of free and equal competition, 
 which political economy assumes to exist when it determines 
 the laws of production and exchange, generally, or often, 
 present at the time of the division of the product between those 
 who have co-operated to produce it. That effective competi- 
 tiouj which is the fundamental assumption of abstract political 
 economy, does not as a rule exist between a labourer on the one 
 side, and an employer on the other ; and, therefore, to rigidly 
 apply the principles which determine the price of goods to a 
 determination of the rate of wages, would be in a high degree 
 misleading. Buyers and sellers may, for the purposes of an 
 abstract argument, be presumed to stand towards each other on
 
 The Revival of Protection. 15 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. ii., \ 8.] 
 
 a footing of equality ; but to assume that the competition 
 between the employer on the one hand, and the wage-earners 
 on the other, when the latter are unorganised and unprotected 
 by law, is a competition between equal units, is so fanciful and 
 contrary to fact, that any conclusions drawn from such an 
 assumption can have little value under present circumstances. 
 Unfortunately, however, many Free Traders have not recog- 
 nised this fact, but have attempted to apply maxims which are 
 true when applied to the production of wealth, where there is 
 an effective and equal competition between buyer and seller 
 to the case of labourers seeking to obtain for themselves a 
 higher rate of wages, although the determinant of the rate of 
 wages is composed of such incalculable elements as the habits, 
 desires, and customs of human beings. 
 
 It follows, from the fact that the laws of the distribution of 
 wealth are less absolute and more changeable than those of its 
 production, and from the fact that Free Trade operates chiefly 
 within the field of production, that, although it may be demon- 
 strable that government ought to leave men free to produce 
 and exchange commodities when and how they please, it does 
 not follow that the same policy should be applied to propor- 
 tioning the distribution of commodities among those who have 
 produced them. Unlimited competition may be good in the 
 one case and evil in the other, without Free Trade giving us 
 any guide for pronouncing a judgment. ^ The evils, therefore, 
 of unlimited competition within the field of distribution offer 
 no argument against the removal of protective tariffs. 
 
 8. The last cause which may be mentioned as having had 
 an influence in the revival of Protectionism, is the discontent 
 with existing industrial conditions, which is a prevalent sign of 
 the times. 
 
 It is not easy to trace this cause in actual operation, but no 
 reader of Protectionist literature can fail to recognise its 
 
 1 See further on tliis subject infra Part II., chap. 7.
 
 1 6 Industrial FrerdoM. 
 
 presence. The jealousy of wealth, the dislike of " laisser 
 faire," the pressure of the competitive system, all give rise to a 
 profound dissatisfaction with existing social conditions. The 
 evils of the day are felt to be intolerably irksome, until it seems 
 as if the wished-for blessing might be found in any change of 
 policy. There can be no question that, as the labour party in 
 America, under the leadership of Henry George, is turning 
 against Protectionism, so in England and Australia, discontent 
 creates antagonism towards Free Trade. 
 
 It ought to be needless to point out that the remedy for the 
 evils which create this discontent lies altogether outside the 
 influence of Protection or Free Trade. Neither Free Trade 
 nor Protection is a panacea for industrial evils, nor will either 
 policy satisfy the wants of working men. Irregular employ- 
 ment, crowded homes, an existence without pleasure, an 
 insecure old age these are causes of complaint which 
 cannot be removed by any changes in a fiscal policy. No 
 mere tariff reform will give the poorer workmen regular employ- 
 ment, nor build them healthy dwellings near their work, nor 
 find them openings for secure investment, nor relieve the 
 monotony of their dull existence. All that can be done by 
 the agency of taxation is to mitigate as far as possible the evils 
 which exist, and to guard against creating others. Free Traders 
 hold, that under their policy the remedial agencies will work 
 with the greatest force ; but they do not say that Free Trade 
 has of itself the power to remove industrial grievances. 
 
 9. To sum up the conclusions of this chapter, we have 
 noted that the revival of Protection is largely due to the follow- 
 ing causes, viz, : 
 
 I. To the fact that Free Trade writers have directed 
 their chief attention to the effect of the policy in 
 increisin^r wealth, instead of considering its effect 
 on wages.
 
 The Revival of Protection. 17 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. ii., \ 9.] 
 
 2. To the discredit which has attached to Free Trade 
 
 through being associated with unpopular or aristo- 
 cratic parties. 
 
 3. To the idea that Free Trade is identical with a 
 general policy of "laisser faire." 
 
 4. To the idea that Free Traders are indifferent to the 
 evils of the competitive system. 
 
 5. To the prevailing discontent with existing social and 
 
 industrial conditions. 
 
 The mere enumeration of these causes proves the necessity 
 for a restatement of the Free Trade case. We have to deal 
 with a new class of opponents, variously prejudiced against us, 
 and suffering from real grievances, to all of which they imagine 
 Free Traders are indifferent, and some of which they trace 
 directly to the policy. 
 
 We have, therefore, to be careful to show that we do not 
 gloss over any facts, nor disregard any interest. We have to 
 be careful, also, to look at many facts from the standpoint of 
 working-men and yet not to raise excessive hopes in the minds 
 of those whom we address. Above all, we have to dissociate 
 Free Trade from the policy of laisser fai7'e. Some Free 
 Traders may be advocates of laisser /aire ; but there are many, 
 and their numbers are growing, who look upon Free Trade 
 simply as an instrument which destroys one form of State 
 interference, in order to leave the ground clear for more 
 effective action by the State in new directions. 
 
 Nor are Free I'radcrs necessarily wedded to the present 
 social system. Free I'rade is merely voluntary trade : a Free 
 Trader only maintains that men should be allowed to buy and 
 sell where and what they will. But he does not say that men's 
 freedom should in no case be controlled by voluntary associa- 
 tion, nor by public opinion. There is nothing inconsistent 
 with Free Trade in a body of men agreeing to pay more 
 than necessary for any article, provided they do not force 
 c
 
 1 8 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 other people to follow their exaniple. Finally, there is 
 nothing in the doctrines of Free Trade which requires their 
 disciple to make a fetish of universal and unregulated competi- 
 tion. A Free Trader can admit as evils many things of which 
 Protectionists complain. He can join with a Protectionist in 
 his protest against labour being bought and sold like a bale of 
 goods. He, too, may refuse to believe that masters and men 
 can never be secured against the misery of fluctuating trade, 
 and can prefer that the evils of dependence should be lessened, 
 rather than that the number of millionaires should be increased 
 with an unparalleled rapidity. 
 
 In short, the final aim of an honest Free Trader differs but 
 little from that of an honest Protectionist, however much they 
 may dispute with one another as to means. The ideal of both 
 is, or ought to be, the same, namely : to prevent the labourer 
 sinking into the mere drudge of a machine, and to make him 
 once again a craftsman with an artistic love and knowledge of 
 his work. 
 
 But, while thus recognising the evils of our present indus- 
 trial system, a Free Trader would desire it to be understood 
 by those who suffer that, if Free Trade has proved an im- 
 perfect remedy, Protection is a poison. The grievances of 
 the Protectionists are real enough, but their hostility is mis- 
 directed. The remedy, as will be pointed out later in these 
 pages, is independent either of Protection or Free Trade. But, 
 while Protection aggravates existing evils, Free Trade not only 
 does much to mitigate them, but also brings about many con- 
 ditions under which these evils can be more easily removed.
 
 The Revival of Protection. 19 
 
 Ft. I., Ch, iii., ? I.] 
 
 CHAPTER III. 
 
 THE SIGNIFICAN'CE OF A PROTECTIONIST REVIVAL. 
 
 I. In the inquiry which has been conducted through the 
 last two chapters into the nature and the causes of the Protec- 
 tionist revival, no direct reference has been made to its extent 
 or its significance. Yet both of these are so often overstated or 
 misunderstood, that it is desirable to give them some attention 
 before entering upon a discussion of the merits of the rival 
 fiscal policies. 
 
 The impression of many Protectionists if we may judge 
 Protectionist voters by the speeches and writings of their 
 political leaders would appear to be that Great Ikitain stands 
 alone, among civilised nations, in her acceptance of the 
 doctrine of Free Trade, and that all other countries have 
 deliberately declined to follow her example. From this it is 
 argued that, if the pol'cy were good, its merits would have been 
 so decisively established by Great Britain's forty years' experi- 
 ment, that the fact of its universal rejection is conclusive 
 against it. 
 
 It is hardly necessary to point out that this is both an in- 
 correct statement of facts and an unsound argument. 
 
 i; 2. In the first place it is not true that England is the only 
 Free Trade country. Neither Holland, Norway, Belgium, 
 Switzerland, nor Denmark can be called protected countries ; 
 and some of them notably Holland have tariffs very little 
 higher than that of England. These countries are, of course, 
 not to be compared in extent of territory with their Pro- 
 tectionist neighbours; but they are not one whit behind them 
 in the other elements of national greatness. They are free, 
 wealthy, peaceful, and progressive 1 Can any of the European 
 countries which have adopted Protection be characterised in 
 the same terms? Without over-estimating the importaic; of 
 c 2
 
 20 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 a fiscal policy, it is at least noticeable that those European 
 countries, which are most free from clerical and military 
 domination, are precisely the countries which most incline 
 towards an unrestricted commerce ; while the military and 
 reactionary governments favour Protection. 
 
 3. Suppose, however, it were otherwise, and that England 
 stood absolutely alone in her adherence to Free Trade it 
 is surely plain that this fact would not justify a conclusion 
 that the policy was unsound, unless we first knew the 
 reasons which induced other countries to adopt or retain 
 Protection? It might be that these had no reference to the 
 fiscal controversy, but were local and special reasons of a 
 political and temporary character. If, for example, one country 
 imposed protective duties, for the purpose of retaliating upon a 
 hostile neighbour, or another imposed them because the 
 Custom House offered the easiest means of raising a large 
 revenue for wasteful expenditure it could hardly be contended 
 that the action of either of these countries raised even a pre- 
 sumption against the expediency of Free Trade in a country of 
 different industrial and political conditions. The fiscal problem 
 is emphatically one which cannot be decided by the method of 
 counting heads. Every country must work out a solution for 
 itself according to its own conditions and its own needs. The 
 experience of one country, although it may be valuable as a 
 test of theory, is seldom useful to other countries as a guide to 
 practice, since the necessary conditions of a just comparison 
 are seldom, if ever, present.^ 
 
 1 Mr. Giffen, in his paper on "The Use of Import and Export 
 .Statistics" (" Essays in Finance," Second Series, p. 200), makes the followin;^ 
 remarks in this connection : 
 
 " To make any statistical comparison at all possible between different 
 regimes, it would be necessary, either to find two coimtries practically alike in their 
 economic and industrial circumstances, and in the character of their people, 
 subject ihem to the opposite rJ^i.yus, and then ascertain and compare their 
 relative material progress : or, to find a particular country subjected at different
 
 The Revival of Protection. 21 
 
 Pt. '., Ch. iil., \ 4.] 
 
 4. Thus, although the results of either fiscal policy in 
 any particular case can never be ignored, yet the greatest 
 caution must be exercised in drawing inferences. Still more 
 is caution necessary, when it is proposed to draw an inference, 
 not from results, but from motives. There is no better instance 
 of want of caution in this respect than the familiar Protectionist 
 cry which we are now considering. 
 
 There is, indeed, no doubt but that the disinclination of 
 many countries, both new and old, to abandon their Protective 
 policies, and the inclination of others to adopt Protection, is a 
 phenomenon, which requires careful explanation in view of the 
 signal and incontestable success of the British experiment. But 
 while giving full weight to any inference that can be legitimately 
 drawn from the conduct of the citizens of one country for the 
 guidance of citizens of another, and recognising that Free 
 Trade has not spread so rapidly as might have been expected, 
 it would be a mistake to assume that the doctrine of Free Trade 
 has been impeached in any material point, cither by the ex- 
 perience of Great Britain after forty years of a Free Trade 
 policy, or by the Protectionist proclivities of other countries, 
 
 periods to the two opposite regimes without any other differences, and then 
 compare the different results, if any such are appreciable. Experience does not 
 supply us with such cases. No two communities are sufficiently alike to be 
 comparable in strict logic. The slightest differences in the race or moral con- 
 dition of the two communities, which are to outward appearance much the 
 same, might make a great deal of difference to their material progress. If the 
 two are subjected to different economic riSginies, how are we to tell whetlier the 
 inferior progress of the one materially even when we are sure about the 
 inferiority is due to the tei^iine, and not to other differences in the character 
 of the communities which we cannot so well appreciate ? The same with a 
 community at different periods of its own history. How can we tell that there 
 is no moral difference of a serious kind to affect the economic progress of the 
 community between one period and another? External economic circumstances 
 are, besides, incessantly changing, and may affect two communities apiiarently 
 of nmch the same character and position quite differently. If it were possible 
 to institute many points of comparison and exhibit an uniform result in all, it 
 might be safe to infer that it was the regime which did make the difference, no 
 other imiform cause of difference being assignable; but this condition, of 
 course, it is impossible to fulfil."
 
 22 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 The contrary is rather the case. Enghsh experience has indis- 
 putably shown the wisdom of a Free Trade poHcy, so that there 
 is hardly an intelligent American or Australian Protectionist, 
 who does not readily admit that Free Trade is a necessity for a 
 manufacturing or commercial country in the situation of Great 
 Britain. Nor are the Protectionist inclinations of other countries 
 really an impeachment of Free Trade, when the circumstances 
 attendant on their origin are understood. Moreover, so far 
 from English example having carried no weight, it will be 
 found, that after the adoption of Free Trade by Great Britain, 
 there was a marked and steady movement in the same direction 
 throughout the continent of Europe. It is true that this move- 
 ment has been interrupted during the last twenty years, but an 
 examination of the facts reveals that every country, with the ex- 
 ception of Canada and Victoria, that has adopted a Protectionist 
 policy during this period, has done this under the stress of war, 
 and that the influences which have bean at work in favour of 
 restriction have already begun to wane. 
 
 The truth, accordingly^ is that this so-called revival of Pro- 
 tection has very little significance in the fiscal controversy. It 
 hag proceeded from circumstances which have only a remote 
 connection with Protection and Free Trade, and has seldom 
 been due to any deliberate rejection of a Free Trade policy. In 
 every case, moreover, even when it has proceeded from 
 an avowed adherence to Protectionist doctrines, it has 
 originated under the stress of exceptional and peculiar 
 difiicultics, arising from a morbid and abnormal industrial con- 
 dition. Thirdly, in most cases, it has been an interruption of 
 an earlier and well defined movement in the direction of 
 Free Trade, which, accordmg to present indications, is likely 
 to be renewed. Under these circumstances the much vaunted 
 Protectionist revival is not likely to be of much use to logical 
 champions of commercial restrictions. As, however, the Pro- 
 tectionist voter attaches great importance to the argument from 
 numbers, it will be advisable to make a more detailed examina-
 
 The Revival of Protection. 23 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. iii., \ 4.] 
 
 tion of the causes which have led the principal countries to raise 
 their tariffs, because it must be admitted that, if these causes 
 vary, or if they are mutually inconsistent, or if they have no 
 application to the conditions of the country in which the 
 example is quoted, the strength of the Protectionist's assertion, 
 that all the wisdom of the world is upon his side, becomes con- 
 siderably diminished. 
 
 It will be convenient, in pursuing this inquiry, to deal 
 separately with the examples of Great Britain, the continent of 
 Europe, the United States of America, and the British 
 Colonies. 
 
 CHAPTER IV. 
 
 ILLUSTRATIONS. t 
 
 SECTION I. GREAT BRITAIN. 
 
 I. It is not easy to understand the fashion in which Pro- 
 tectionists treat Great Britain's forty-five years' experience of 
 a Free Trade policy. At one time they admit that it has been 
 such as to establish once for all the superiority of Free Trade 
 for a country situated like Great Britain. At another they assert, 
 that Free Trade was adopted under a mistaken view as to the 
 probable effect of English example upon foreign nations; and that, 
 if tlie leaders of the Anti-Corn Law League could have foreseen 
 that, after forty-five years, England would stand almost alone in 
 the practice of commercial freedom, they would never have 
 begun their famous agitation. Forgetful of the Free Trade 
 maxim that " the best way to fight hostile tariffs is by free 
 imports," these disputants assert that the Free Trade, which 
 the exertions of the Liberal party won for England, is not the 
 Free Trade for which the leaders strove, but a " one-sided " 
 Free Trade, which Bright and Cobden in their earlier days
 
 24 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 would have regarded as little less pernicious than a close 
 Protection. 
 
 Either of these methods of treatment allows the Pro- 
 tectionist orator to put English experience upon one side. 
 
 2. If all Protectionists agreed that Free Trade had proved 
 a great success in England, there would be no need to insist 
 upon this fact in any controversial work. Unfortunately, how- 
 ever, the native-born Australian, and, in a less degree, the 
 native-born American, often prides himself upon his indifference 
 to the history of other countries. Absorbed in the great work of 
 making a new nation, and rightly impatient of the vapid affecta- 
 tion of English ways and indiscriminate reliance upon English 
 taste, which seems inevitable in a subordinate community, he is 
 apt to confound the callow criticisms of the English traveller with 
 the sohd teachings of English experience, and dismiss each 
 with the same contempt. This tendency has, until quite 
 recently, been fostered in Australia by the omission from the 
 school and university curriculum of any teaching of history the 
 reason assigned for this being the remarkable fear that to teach 
 history might wound religious susceptibilities ! The conse- 
 quence is that, in spite of the disavowals of responsible Pro- 
 tectionist writers, voters are still found in Australasia and 
 America who believe that the condition of England has not 
 materially improved either subsequently to or in consequence 
 of the adoption of Free Trade. 
 
 3. It may be doubted whether any fact of industrial 
 history is capable of easier or more conclusive proof than that 
 Great Britain has enormously advanced in every direction of 
 national progress since the adoption of Free Trade. All the 
 evidence points to the same conclusion^ and is, as Mr. Giffcn 
 has insisted, cumulative ; so that it must be disproved in each 
 particular item, if any doubt is to be thrown upon the im- 
 pression created by a survey of the whole. " 'I'o justify the
 
 The Revival of Protection. 25 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. iv., 5 3-1 
 
 belief," says this eminent writer, " that there has been no great 
 general advance, every one of the propositions stated [by him] 
 would have to be disproved, and an opposite set of statements, 
 all hanging together and all supporting the view of retrogression, 
 or no advance, or very little advance, would have to be made 
 good. There are too many facts to permit the setting up of a 
 plea of ignorance, or impossibility of arriving at any con- 
 clusion." ^ 
 
 Nor, indeed, is the one fact of a stupendous growth in 
 material wealth denied by any but a few fanatics the signs of 
 it are too manifest to the eye to admit of question or to require 
 demonstration by figures ~ but those who desire to depreciate 
 the English example, content themselves with making the 
 assertion that the chief benefit of their improvement has gone to 
 the rich, while the poor have been growing poorer year by year. 
 Such a statement naturally appeals to many prejudices, and 
 often finds acceptance among men who do not know the 
 facts. 
 
 In reality the assertion is almost unsupported by evidence. 
 All the facts tell the other way. Official and private records of 
 rates of wages and hours of labour show, that the workman 
 receives to-day from 50 to 100 per cent, more money for 20 per 
 cent, less work than was the case under Protection ; and that, 
 owing to a large fall in the prices of the chief articles of con- 
 sumption, the purchasing power of his wages is considerably 
 increased. In addition to this improvement in his relations 
 with employers, the workman to-day gets the benefit of largely 
 increased Government expenditure. He not only pays less 
 taxes, but he gets more much more from the Government 
 than he ever received under the Protective system. He 
 is now better fed, better clothed, better housed, better 
 educated, better cared for in his health and amusements 
 
 ' " Essays in Finance " ; Second Series. 
 
 2 The paper by Mr. Medley, printed as a note to this cliaptcr, contains 
 some of the more striicing facts.
 
 26 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 than at any other period in Enghsh history. All the facts 
 agree to prove that the poor have not grown poorer. Pauperism 
 has diminished ; crime has diminished ; the deposits in the 
 Savings Bank have increased ; the funds of the Friendly and 
 Benefit Societies have increased ; the investments of small 
 savings are greater than they were ; life is in every direction 
 longer, easier, and more comfortable ; even the rate of mortality 
 has declined, so that on an average a man lives two years, and a 
 woman three and a half years longer than was the case before 
 Free Trade. Is, then, the other part of the assertion true, and 
 have the rich grown richer ? The facts again agree to support 
 a negative answer ! The returns to the Income Tax and to 
 the Probate Duties demonstrate conclusively that the number 
 of the moderately rich has been increasing, and that the 
 increase of capital per head of the capitalist classes is 
 by no means so great as the increase of working-class in- 
 comes. 
 
 It may be that Protectionists will take exception to the value 
 of the evidence by which these facts are sustained ; and, no 
 one would deny that the relations between evidence and con- 
 clusions in matters of this nature are always diificult to deter- 
 mine. But is any other kind of evidence forthcoming? Is it 
 possible to get any other accumulation of facts, whether of the 
 same or of a different character, to support the conclusion that 
 the condition of the working-classes in Great Britain has become 
 worse, instead of better, since the introduction of Free Trade ? 
 And if it is not possible to do this, it must surely be admitted 
 that the experience of Great Britain has a certain bearing on 
 the fiscal controversy . No doubt Protection may be sup- 
 ported by different arguments in different countries ; but 
 English experience is at least of so much value, that it justifies 
 Free Traders in putting Protectionists to proof of their assertions. 
 They tell us that Free Trade creates monopolies ; that it in- 
 creases profits at the expense of wages ; that it produces 
 paupers j that it destroys manufactures ! The contrary has
 
 The REVirAL of Protection. 27 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. iv., \ 3.] 
 
 been the case in England ; let them, therefore, prove their 
 statements. 1 
 
 1 It will be apparent to all who are familiar with the subject, that the 
 passages in the text about the condition of the working-classes are only a 
 summary of Mr. Giffen's two Essays oa the " Progress of the Working- 
 Classes," since re-published in the author's second series of "Essays on 
 Finance." This masterpiece of statistical investigation is supported in its 
 conclusions by the analysis, which the late Mr. Brassey has made public, 
 of the pay-sheets of his enormous business as contractor. This gives a 
 faithful record of the rise and fall of wages, during that period, in the two 
 great trades of the builders and the engineers {see "Work and Wages"). 
 In addition to this there is a collection of statistics made in 1866 by 
 Professor Leone Levi and Mr. Dudley Baxter under the title of " Wages and 
 Earnings of the Working-Classes." These are collected chiefly from private 
 sources, and most of the information appears to be drawn from the more 
 favoured trades, so that, without questioning the accuracy of the figures, it is 
 possible to believe that these gentlemen have made too high an estimate of the 
 average earnings of the working-classes. Another useful source of authentic 
 information is the annual return furnished by the Chamber of Commerce in 
 different centres to the English Board of Trade, which are published among 
 the miscellaneous statistics of the United Kingdom. The Board of Trade 
 Journal now contains regular returns of wages, compiled from the best official 
 and private sources. 
 
 In a note to this chapter the writer has put together the results of some 
 independent investigations which he made in 1883 on the variation in wages in 
 the four great English industries the cotton, woollen, worsted, and iron trades 
 which, together, employ about one-half of the artisan population, to which 
 the reader is refeired for further information. 
 
 There is especial reason at the present time for emphasising the fact of 
 the great and continuous advance in the well-being of the poorer classes, 
 because a most active section of Free Traders have been misled by Mr. Henry 
 George into an assertion to the contrary, and have thus considerably weakened 
 the force of their attack upon Protection. Mr. George's work on " Progress and 
 Poverty," which was his earliest important writing, begins, as is well known, 
 with the assertion that "the poor have grown poorer and the rich richer." 
 Although this is the fundamental proposition of the work, no tittle of evidence 
 is advanced in its support. Its truth is quietly assumed. Vet all the known 
 evidence as to the condition of old countries tells the other way. It may 
 indeed be the case although Mr. Giffen doubts this that the agricultural 
 labourers in Great Britain were better off in the middle of the last century than 
 they ever have been since ; but there is atnple evidence to show that the con- 
 dition of the great body of labourers was worse [e.i;., sec Eden's " State of the 
 Poor"). Mr. Giffen quotes from M. Yves Guyot ("Principles of Social 
 Economy" [linglish Translation], Swan Sonnenschein li Co.), to show that 
 there has been a similar improvement in France and (jermany. Perhaps Mr. 
 George in penning the phrase only had in mind the Western States of .America, 
 with regard to which it is probably true.
 
 28 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 It is, indeed, possible that the arguments of those who 
 insist upon the great improvement which has taken place in 
 the condition of the working-classes under Free Trade are 
 open to criticism upon one point, viz. that the increase in 
 money wages is sometimes exaggerated. Mr, Giffen estimates 
 that the average rate of wages in England has doubled since 
 1830. This may be the case and no one can differ from 
 Mr. Giffen on such a matter without hesitation but the 
 average advance in wages as disclosed by the Board of Trade 
 returns from 1830 to 1833, in the four principal English 
 industries the cotton, woollen, worsted, and iron trades 
 does not appear to have been so great. The question is 
 dealt with in detail in the note at the end of this chapter, 
 so that it will be sufficient here to summarise the con- 
 clusions. 
 
 Mr. Giffen's statement appears to be borne out by the 
 figures returned for those four trades as the wages paid to 
 skilled labour. I'he increase in these cases has often been 
 more than double. But among the body of unskilled lal)Ourers, 
 the increase, so far as can be gathered from the Board of 
 Trade Statistics, is not more -than from twenty-five to fifty 
 per cent. In fact, it is a remarkable illustration of the truth 
 that the stronger the labourer^ and the better he is able 
 to protect himself, the more likely is he to obtain good 
 wages, that these figures show, that not only is it the class 
 of skilled labourers who have benefited most, but in almost 
 every case they have been the first to get the advantage of 
 a rising market. Indeed, the figures of the cotton, woollen, 
 worsted, and iron trades lead to these two conclusions : first, that 
 the increase of wages has been largest among the best-paid 
 class of artisans, less among the class of medium ability, and 
 least among the common labourers ; and, secondly, that a rise 
 in wages comes earliest to the best-paid class, later to the 
 middle class, and latest to the unskilled workman. These asser- 
 tions are not put forward as the invariable laws of rising wages,
 
 The Revival of Protection. 29 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. iv., ? 3.] 
 
 but they are certainly conclusions from a large number of 
 important observations. 
 
 But it may be said, the unskilled labourers form the mass 
 of the community, and since it is the poorest classes that suffer 
 most, it is in their prosperity that the country is most interested. 
 This leads to another branch of our inquiry, viz., whether wages 
 have increased beyond the greater cost of living ? There can 
 be no doubt that even the poorest workman receives more 
 money than he used ; but does a sovereign in England go as 
 far now as it did thirty years ago ? In the hands of a workman 
 it does. If anyone will make a table of the articles of a 
 labourer's consumption, and, by a reference to any book on 
 prices, estimate the cost of living, say thirty years ago, and at 
 the present time, he will find that in respect of most items of a 
 labourer's expenditure there has been a marked decrease of 
 price, and that in respect of only two items has there been any 
 increase. These two are meat and house-rent. The price of 
 meat has nearly doubled, and rent has increased one and a-half 
 times. But none the less, it is not true, as has been written, 
 that rent has swallowed up the whole of the increase in work- 
 men's wages. Theoretically, Mr. George's views are sound 
 enough. Imagine a country with entirely unrestrained com- 
 petition, with a limited quantity of land in private hands, shut 
 out from all foreign trade, and its people prohibited from 
 emigrating then undoubtedly rent would increase at tlie 
 expense of both wages and profits. But these theoretical con- 
 ditions do not prevail in any country in the world, not even in 
 Ireland, and in a Free Trade country least of all. 
 
 In fact, ncitlicr the rise in rent, ^ nor the greater cost of 
 meat has reduced the workman's real income below what it 
 was under Protection. By making a table of the average 
 iiccc-ssary expenses of a wor'rcman, with a wife and three 
 children, in 1840, and at the present day, it will l)e found 
 
 ' Part of the rise in rent is due to improved house accommodation.
 
 30 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 that, while in 1840 an unskilled workman seldom had meat 
 more than once a week, now, allowing for meat every day, and 
 also for the rise in rent, he has a larger balance than he used 
 to have.i That is to say, under Free Trade, even when the 
 rise in wages has been lowest, namely, among the class of un- 
 skilled labourers, it has at least outpaced the increase in the 
 cost of living. Other facts point to the same conclusion. The 
 consumption of tea and sugar, for example, per head of the 
 population, is four times what it used to be in the days of Pro- 
 tection. It is the same with the consumption of rice, tobacco, 
 spirits, and similar luxuries. What better evidence could be 
 given that the prosperity of the last forty years has been diffused 
 among the masses ? The articles named are emphatically poor 
 men's luxuries, and not such that an increased consumption of 
 them by the rich could make much difference to the (quantity 
 consumed. But, as has already been observed, all the facts 
 agree. There is no test by which improvement in material 
 prosperity can be measured, which does not bear out the 
 
 1 Weekly necessary expenses of a carpenter, with a wife and three children : 
 
 1840. 1890. 
 
 s. d. s. d. 
 
 8 quartern loaves ... S ^ 4 
 
 Bibs, meat ... ... ... ... ... 44 60 
 
 i^lbs. butter 16 19 
 
 lib. cheese ... ... ... ... ... 07 08 
 
 2lbs. sugar ... ... ... ... ... i 2 04 
 
 jlb. tea 16 o 45 
 
 lib. soap ... ... ... ... ...05 04 
 
 lib. candles ... ... ... ... ... 06 05 
 
 lib. rice... ... ... ... ... ...04 02 
 
 2 gals, milk ... ... ... .. ..04 08 
 
 Vegetables ... ... ... ... ... 06 10 
 
 Coals, firing ... ... ... ... ...10 16 
 
 Rent ... ... ... . , ...40 6 6 
 
 Clothes and sundries ... ... ... ...30 30 
 
 24 10 26 8^ 
 
 The increase on a wage of 24s. lod. since 1846 has been to at least 28s., and 
 in most cases to ^os.
 
 The Revival of Fkotection: 31 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. iv.,54.] 
 
 assertion that there has been a great and general advance in well- 
 being among the masses of Great Britain since the abolition of 
 a protective tariff. No one would say that the advance has 
 been sufficient. The condition of the poor in England is 
 terrible, and their improvement has been little enough, even 
 when measured by a low ideal, so that it is hard to see things 
 as they are without desiring something like a revolution for the 
 better. Still, the fact of an enormous progress must be kept in 
 view, progress which may not be recognised until comparison 
 is made with the former state of things. As Mr, Giffen warns 
 us, " discontent with the present must not make us forget that 
 things have been so much worse." 
 
 4. The prosperity of Great Britain under Free Trade is 
 logically fatal to the protective dogma, that the only way to 
 secure prosperity is by means of protective duties against 
 foreign imports. The prosperity of a protected country is not, 
 by a parity of reasoning, fatal to Free Trade, because Free 
 Trade is not a dogma, but a mere negative assertion of the 
 errors of Protection. Protection, on the other hand, not only 
 asserts the wisdom of protective duties, but justifies its action by 
 the tacit and expressed assumption that national wealth cannot 
 be produced or diffused without them. Hence, as Professor 
 Sumner has pointed out, " either prosperity in a Free Trade 
 country, or distress in a Protectionist country, is fatal to Pro- 
 tectionism ; while distress in a Free Trade country, or pro- 
 sperity in a Protectionist country, proves nothing against Free 
 Trade." 1 
 
 Nevertheless, it is frequently asserted that the prosperity of 
 Great Britain proves nothing in the fiscal controversy, because 
 the credit of it cannot be claimed entirely for Free Trade, but 
 must be shared by the mechanical and scientific improvements 
 which have characterised the period since Protection was 
 
 ' " Protectionism the -ism which teaches that Waste makes Wealth.'' 
 New York : Holt & Co., 1885 ; p. 26.
 
 32 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 abolished. It is plain that this argument effectually prevents 
 Protectionists from taking credit to their system for the progress 
 of the United States, since not only has the invention of 
 machinery played a most important part in their industrial 
 development, hut it has been aided by unparalleled natural 
 resources. In the United States are millions of acres of fertile 
 land, with soil thirty feet deep ; there are minerals of every 
 kind in useful proximity to each other; there are coal-fields, 
 oil-wells, and every sort of natural product in astonishing abun- 
 dance ; and all these resources are not locked up in inacces- 
 sible regions, but are brought near to the markets of the world 
 by a most extensive system of railway and river communication. 
 Add to all this, that on an average half a million immigrants are 
 being poured into the country every year, representing each of 
 them a capital expenditure of ;j^2oo, or, in a body, a total incre- 
 ment of one hundred million pounds per annum to the national 
 capital ; that there is little or no expenditure for military pur- 
 poses, and that there is an unrestricted system of Free Trade 
 from one end of the vast continent to the other, and we have a 
 combination of every circumstance which is most favourable to 
 the increase of wealth. Under such conditions, it would be 
 miraculous if America had not become a great manufacturing 
 country. Her present inferiority in this respect to Great 
 I'ritain is probably solely due to her protective tariff. 
 
 Disregarding, however, the logical irrelevance of the inquiry, 
 and admitting that an assent to its necessity cuts both ways, it 
 is expedient, for controversial purposes, to ascertain, if possible, 
 v.-hat portion of Great Britain's prosperity has l)ccn due to Free 
 Trade, and what portion to other causes. 
 
 No one can deny that railways, telegraphs, and every other 
 improvement in the means of intercourse and production, have 
 had a great influence in every part of the world in extending 
 commerce and increasing wealth ; but, nevertheless, it can be 
 shown, with as much certainty as such an investigalion admit:-, 
 that a chief part of the increase in the wealth of Great Britain,
 
 The Revival of Protection. 33 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. !v., \ 4.] 
 
 during the last forty years has been due to the abolition of the 
 protective system. It can also be shown h-^ a priori reasoning, 
 that a nation cannot reap the full advantages of improvements 
 in locomotion and mechanical processes under any systen which 
 restricts the intercourse between its citizens and foreigners. 
 
 There are two methods of conducting this inquiry. The 
 first is by comparing the condition of trade in the year imme- 
 diately preceding the remission of a tax on imports, with its 
 condition in the year immediately following. If, then, it is 
 found, that in every case a dose of Free Trade has been followed 
 by an otherwise inexplicable increase in the volume of com- 
 merce, it may be fairly concluded that there is a connection 
 between this increase and the legislation which preceded it. 
 The second method is to estimate the influence of the mechan- 
 ical or locomotive agencies, when they are at work without 
 Free Trade, in order to deduct what ought to be assigned to 
 them from the total increase of wealth. This method is ex- 
 tremely complicated, and not, perhaps, altogether satisfactory, 
 owing to the difficulty of making an accurate estimate of the 
 value of the mechanical and locomotive factor. 
 
 Both methods, however, have been used by Mr. Gladstone, 
 in an article which is now lost in the kaleidoscopic pages of a 
 monthly magazine. 1 It may accordingly be useful to indicate 
 the character of Mr. Ghdstoiii's conc'.usions, without attempt- 
 ing to summarise his article. 
 
 He first estimates the average annual increase in the volume 
 of British trade, from the date of the first use of railways up to 
 1842, which was the first year of any large instalment of Free 
 Trade, by the following method : He finds that, for the twenty 
 years from 1 810-1830, English trade was almost stationary ; but 
 that in 1830, with the use of raihvays, there came a suddea 
 increase, which continued year by year as new railways were 
 opened. Consequently, he sets down the growth of trade from 
 
 ' Nineteenth Century, February, 1880.
 
 34 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 1830 to 1842 to what, for the purposes of this calculation, 
 he terms the locomotive factor. 
 
 Assuming this method to be correct, and that the period is 
 not too short to form the basis of such an estimate, the difficult 
 question still remains, how to use the figures, which have 
 been thus obtained, for the purpose of comparison with other 
 periods. 
 
 Mr, Gladstone attempts to get over this difficulty in the 
 following way : ^He takes the number of miles of railway open 
 during the years 1830-42, together with the mileage receipts 
 during the same year, and, on the assumption that the increase 
 before referred to during that period was owing to the locomo- 
 tive agencies alone, he arrives at a rough estimate of the effect 
 of each new mile of railway upon the volume of English trade. 
 Then he calculates from this basis the deductions which have 
 to be made from the yearly increase in that volume subse- 
 quently to 1842, on account of railways, and making an equal 
 allowance on account of telegraphs and ocean steamships, and 
 recognising that the influence of these factors has been increas- 
 ing, and not constant, he reaches the conclusion that by far 
 the larger portion of the increase in Enghsh trade during the 
 last forty years must be assigned to other causes than improve- 
 ments in the means of locomotion. 
 
 This conclusion is, at best, imperfect ; but it is at least 
 as worthy of attention as the unsupported statements of Pro- 
 tectionist orators and letter-writers, that the whole of the 
 improved condition of English trade in recent years is owing 
 to mechanical improvements in the means of intercourse. 
 
 Mr. Gladstone also attempts the first of the two methods, 
 which have been already mentioned as suitable to an enquiry 
 into the causes of the growth of England's trade, and which, 
 although it is not so strictly scientific as the other, enables us, 
 to arrive at more accurate results, and estimate with a greater 
 degree of precision the effect upon trade by the removal of 
 Protectionist restrictions.
 
 The Revival of Protection. 35 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. iv., \ 4.] 
 
 Mr, Gladstone takes the fluctuations in the export trade as 
 an index of prosperity, because any increase in the export of 
 home-made articles is an unerring indication of general indus- 
 trial activity ; and because any increase in the export trade of a 
 country which lends, and does not borrow capital, is always 
 accompanied by all those other signs of progress for which an 
 explanation is being sought in this inquiry. He begins with 
 the period 1816-30, when railways were not invented, and Pro- 
 tection had the field to itself. It is instructive to find that during 
 those fifteen years of peace, down to 1830 inclusive, although 
 mechanical invention was in constant growth, the value of British 
 exports remained almost stationary at about ;^36, 000,000, 
 or, if account were taken of the growth of population during 
 that period, that there was an actual decline in the value per 
 head of the population. Well may Mr. Gladstone say that 
 during those years Protection proved itself to be, in the United 
 Kingdom at least, but another name for paralysis ! 
 
 The first instalment of Free Trade legislation was granted 
 in 1842, by which time, thanks to the growth of railways, 
 English exports had increased to ^^5 1,400,000, but the remis- 
 sions of duty did not take effect until 1843. That year is con- 
 sequently the first in which the influence of Free Trade can be 
 perceived. The concession to freedom was very slight, con- 
 sisting almost entirely of a permission to import certain articles, 
 which had previously been prohibited, at reasonable duties ; 
 yet, slight as the concession was, the three years, 1843-45, 
 showed an average export of ^57,000,000, an aggregate growth, 
 that is, of ^6,000,000, and an annual growth, one year with 
 another, of two millions. 
 
 The second instalment of Free Trade was given by Sir Robert 
 Peel in the year 1845. By the tariff of that year all export 
 duties were abolished, and 430 out of the 813 articles of raw 
 material were admitted free of duty ; but the Corn Laws, the 
 Navigation Laws, and the Sugar Duties remained untouched. 
 The three years during which this tariff was in force were 
 D 2
 
 36 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 marked by three great calamities. The first, scarcity in Eng- 
 land and famine in Ireland ; the second, commercial panic 
 with the suspension of the Bank Charter Act in 1847 ; and the 
 third, in 1848, wars and revolutions on the continent, which in 
 one year drove British exports down by ;^6,ooo,ooo. In the 
 days of more stringent Protection, any one of similar occur- 
 rences had caused a disastrous decline ; under Free Trade, 
 however, the result of all of them combined was little more than 
 a stoppage of growth. The average of the exports for the 
 three years, 1845-8, was ;^'56, 500,000, as compared with 
 ^57,000,000, which had been the average of the period from 
 1842 to 1845. 
 
 The third dose of Free Trade was given in 1849, ^y ^^^ ^o'^^ 
 cessation of the Corn Duties at the beginning of that year, and 
 the abolition of more tlian 100 other taxes upon imports, together 
 with the repeal of the Navigation Acts later in the Parliament- 
 ary session. For that year the exports rose suddenly frcm 
 ;j"5 2,800,000 to ;^63, 500,000. The rise steadily continued, 
 so that the average annual value of exports for the three years, 
 1849 to 1852, was ;^7 2,000,000, representing an increase of 
 ;^i 5,000,000 per annum over the preceding triennium. 
 
 The fourth instalment of Free Trade legislation began with 
 the new tariff of 1853. The three years from 1853-55, not- 
 withstanding the Crimean War, show an average export of 
 ;^97, 000,000. From 1853, a very flourishing year, with an 
 export of ^78,000,000, we pass to 1854, with the enormous 
 increment of ;2{^2o,ooo,coo, and a total export value of 
 ;;/^98, 000,000. The effect of the war is seen during the next 
 two years by the exports remaining about stationary ; but, in 
 spite of this, the average for the three years, 1853-55, is 
 ^94,000,000, or an increase of _;;^2 2,000,000 on the previous 
 triennium. This increase continued steadily up to 1859. 
 
 The fifth and last Free Trade period is marked by Mr. 
 Cobden's French Treaty, and by the Customs Act of i860, 
 which finally established the principle that no protective duties
 
 The Revival of Protection. 37 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. iv., \ 5.] 
 
 should be charged, and by the repeal of the paper duties. 
 This was again followed by an increase in our exports ; but it 
 is not possible to estimate the quantity of this increase for any 
 purpose of comparison, since we have no limit provided by any 
 fresh epoch of Free Trade legislation. It is, however, very 
 noteworthy that, since the removal of the Free Trade stimulus 
 if we leave out of account the exceptional years 1870-75, when, 
 owing to the consequences of the Franco-German war, trade 
 advanced by leaps and bounds the increase in English exports 
 tends to become more regular and steady, as if it were hence- 
 forward to be attributed mainly to the growth of population. 
 
 It may be that these figures are not rigidly conclusive, 
 because social problems do not admit of being demonstrated 
 like a rule of mathematics. But let any candid man put this 
 question to himself " Supposing that in any other case but 
 one in which Protection was at issue with Free Trade, I found 
 that legislation of a certain character was always followed by 
 the same results, for which no other cause can be suggested, 
 must I not therefore conclude that there is a close connection 
 between this legislation and the subsequent events ? " This is 
 a test which would be recognised in every other matter of 
 political experience ; why, then, should Free Traders have to 
 ask that the same openness of mind, and readiness to look at 
 facts, should be displayed by everyone who enters upon the 
 fiscal controversy ? 
 
 >5 5. Protectionists, who cannot deny the fact of English 
 progress under Free Trade, adopt, as has been observed 
 already, another method of disparaging the vali:e of her 
 example. They insist that the anticipations of the Free 
 Trade leaders have not been realised, and that, as the struggle 
 was conducted under the belief that other nations would be 
 compelled to follow England, if she adopted Free Trade, the 
 whole case is now re-opened, and the old arguments cease to 
 apply.
 
 38 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 The motives and anticipations of the leaders of the Anti- 
 Corn Law I^eague are, of course, wholly immaterial to the 
 question, " Whether Free Trade or Protection is the better 
 policy for Australasia or America ? " Nevertheless, the state- 
 ment that Gobden only fought for universal Free Trade, and 
 that, being disappointed of this, he would have ceased his 
 efforts, has obtained a vogue in both these countries, which 
 would be surprising in any other controversy. It is used in 
 two ways first, as an easy justification for abuse of the Free 
 Trade leaders ; and, secondly, as an excuse for disregarding 
 English experience. No one, therefore, who defends the Free 
 Trade cause in either Australasia or America, can afford to 
 treat this statement as it deserves ; he must show once more 
 that the Corn Laws fell by their own weight, and that the dis- 
 appointment of any expectations, that the restrictive laws of any 
 other countries would fall in the same way, has in no degree 
 weakened the significance of the British uprising against the 
 misery and injustice of a protective tariff. To assert the con- 
 trary, is one of those perversions of historical fact which are, 
 unhappily, only too frequent in the fiscal controversy. 
 
 The basis of the charge is a speech of Mr. Cobden's in the 
 House of Commons on January 15, 1846, in which he said, " I 
 believe that if you abolish the Corn Laws honestly, and adopt 
 Free Trade in its simplicity, there will not be a tariff in Europe 
 that will not be changed in less than five years to follow your 
 example." Speaking again at a public meeting in 1852, he 
 made a similar prophecy ; and on these two passages, Protec- 
 tionists have raised a structure of abuse and ridicule, every one 
 of them, from Mr. Serjeant Byles to Mr. James G. Blaine, con- 
 tributing his little stone ! 
 
 Yet, after all, what do the words amount to, even reading 
 them literally and without the explanation of surrounding 
 facts ? They are, at most, an impeachment of Mr. Cobden's 
 political judgment. To take them as expressive of the general 
 opinion of his party, and then to say that it was this opinion
 
 The Revival of Protection: 39 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. iv., } 5.] 
 
 which stimulated the party to its exertions, is to disregard the 
 whole weight of evidence upon the other side. Quotations 
 might be multiplied to fill a volume, to show from the pages 
 of Hansard, and from the speeches of the Free Trade 
 leaders as reported in The League, which was their organ in 
 the Press, that the English people were under no misapprehen- 
 sion as to what would be the conduct of other nations, when 
 they adopted Free Trade ; but that they deliberately aban- 
 doned Protection, because, after a fair trial, it had proved, 
 in the words of Lord John Russell's resolution, "the blight 
 of commerce, the bane of agriculture, the source of bitter 
 divisions between classes, the cause of poverty, fever, mort- 
 ality, and crime among the people." ^ No fact in history is 
 more certain, and iQ.\v are more easily demonstrated, than 
 that the Corn Laws were abolished because they injured 
 England, and that the advocates of industrial freedom were 
 indifferent to the course which other nations might pursue 
 so long as Englishmen obtained bread. 
 
 Thus Sir R. Peel, in a speech on the Corn Laws, in the 
 House of Commons, Jan. 27th, 1846, said : 
 
 " I fairly avow to you that, in making this great reduction 
 upon the import of articles the produce and manufacture of 
 foreign countries I have no guarantee to give you that other 
 countries will immediately follow our example. I give you that 
 advantage in the argument. Wearied with our long and un- 
 availing efforts to enter into satisfactory commercial treaties 
 with other nations, we have resolved at length to consult our 
 own interests, and not to punish those other countries for 
 the wrong they do us in continuing their high duties upon 
 the importation of our products and manufactures by con- 
 tinuing high duties ourselves, encouraging unlawful trade. We 
 have had no communication with any foreign government upon 
 
 1 See nolo at end of this chapter (p. 65) on the condition of llngland 
 "Under Protection,
 
 40 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 the subject of these reductions. We cannot promise that France 
 will immediately make a corresponding reduction in her tariff. 
 I cannot promise that Russia will prove her gratitude to us for 
 our reduction of duty on her tallow by any diminution of her 
 duties. You may, therefore, say, in opposition to the present 
 plan, what is this superfluous liberality, that you are going to 
 do away with all these duties, and yet you expect nothing in 
 return ? I may, perhaps, be told that many foreign countries, 
 since the former relaxation of duties on our part and that 
 would be perfectly consistent with the fact foreign countries 
 which have benefited by our relaxation, have not followed our 
 example, nay, have not only not followed our example, but 
 have actually applied to the importation of British goods higher 
 rates of duties than formerly. I quite admit it. I give you all 
 the benefit of that argument. I rely upon the fact as conclu- 
 sive proof of the policy of the course we are pursuing. It is 
 a fact that other countries have not followed our example, 
 and have levied higher duties in some cases upon our 
 goods. But what has been the result upon the amount of 
 your exports? You have defied the regulations of those 
 countries. Your export trade is greatly increased." 
 
 On July 6th, 1849, wiih reference to Mr. Disraeli's assump- 
 tion, " that you cannot fight hostile tariffs with free imports," 
 Sir R. Peel said : 
 
 " I so totally dissent from that assumption that I maintain 
 that the best way to compete with hostile tariffs is to encourage 
 free imports. So far from thinking the principle of Protection 
 a salutary principle, I maintain that the more widely you extend 
 it, the greater the injury you will inflict on the national wealth, 
 and the more you will cripple the national industry. 
 ****** 
 
 " To re establish duties upon the import of foreign produce 
 to be regulated by the principle of reciprocity, would be 
 accompanied with insuperable difficulties. You have, in my
 
 The Revival of Protection, 41 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. iv., \ 5.) 
 
 opinion, no alternative but to maintain that degree of Free 
 Trade you have established, and gradually to extend it so far 
 as considerations of revenue will permit" 
 
 Finally, if further evidence be wanted, there is this state- 
 ment from a letter from Mr. John Bright to the writer, dated 
 shortly before his death : - 
 
 " I never," he says, "held the opinion that the reform of 
 the tariff would be at once followed by a like change of policy 
 in other countries. If Mr. Cobden expressed such an opinion, 
 of which I have no recollection, I can only say that he had 
 more faith in the common sense of other nations than I had." ^ 
 
 1 The whole of the letter is worth publishing 
 
 One Ash, Rochdale, 
 
 December loth, 1887. 
 
 My Dear Sir, I never held the opinion that the reform of the tariff 
 would be at once followed by a like change of policy in other countries. If Mr. 
 Cobden expressed such an opinion, of which I have no recollection, I can 
 only say that he had more faith in the common sense of other nations than 
 I had. As to the changes of circumstances since the year 1846, it is every 
 way in our favour, for we have had forty years of Free Trade, and all the 
 facts are wonderfully on our side. Further, I would assert without fear of 
 error, that our adherence to our Free Trade policy is the more necessary and 
 advantageous to us seeing that other countries have not yet followed our 
 example. Surely, if other nations injure us by their high duties, it would be 
 no compensation to us to put difficulties in the way of our buying what we 
 want. It would be better if we were free to buy and to sell, but to make it 
 difficult to buy by high duties in our tariff, because foreign tariff makes it 
 difficult to sell, seciTis to me an idea that can only be entertained by men who 
 are totally unable to reason. 
 
 The high tariffs of European countries are in great part the result of the 
 great armaments of those countries. The tariff of the United States Ts breaking 
 down, and must break down. If the Protectionists of America could persuade 
 or permit the Government to spend annually twenty millions sterling on a great 
 army, and a great navy, their tariff might be sustained, but that being impossible, 
 the tariff must be reformed, and some approach will be made in the direction 
 of Free Trade. As to your Colonies, their true interest is in the adoption of t! e 
 Free Trade policy. In our individual life every man is a Free Trader. He buys 
 as cheaply as he can, and sells at the best price he can get. Why should not 
 multitudes of men do the same ? 
 
 In .\merica there are some forty States, and there is no tariff between these 
 Slaves there is a perfect Free Trade between them why should not the same
 
 42 Industrial Freedom, 
 
 The matter might fairly rest here.i But the disappointment 
 of Mr. Cobden's hopes is such a constant source of satisfaction 
 of Protectionists, and has so disturbed the minds of many of 
 the faithful, that it will not be waste of time to pursue the in- 
 vestigation further, and, if possible, discover the sources of Mr. 
 Cobden's error. Those who regard the reputation of its great 
 men as the most precious heritage of the English-speaking race 
 will be the less averse to this inquiry because it will be 
 incidentally the means of vindicating the sagacity of Mr. 
 Cobden from many undeserved reproaches. 
 
 Let us proceed, therefore, to discuss the causes of that Pro- 
 tectionist revival upon the Continent of Europe which is 
 supposed by some to be a proof of the foolishness of Free Trade 
 anticipations. 
 
 SECTION II. THE CONTINENT OF EUROPE. 
 
 I. The full significance of the Protectionist revival on the 
 Continent of Europe cannot be understood without some 
 reference to the circumstances under which Great Britain 
 entered on her Free Trade policy. How came Mr. Cobden, 
 who was the most sagacious of men, to indulge in his sanguine 
 hopes, and why were they not fulfilled? Few subjects of 
 historical inquiry better repay investigation. 
 
 freedom prevail between the States and Canada, and between both and the 
 United Kingdom ? And why not between your Austrahan Colonies and between 
 them and this, their Mother Country? 
 
 Free Trade is the policy of wisdom and peace between nations. 
 
 I am, Sir, yours faithfully, 
 
 John Bright. 
 To the Hon. B. R. Wise, Sydney. 
 
 1 Sir T. Farrer in his " Free Trade v. Fair Trade," refers to the following 
 further passages from the speeches of Free Trade leaders ; 
 
 Hansard, vol. 68 of 1843. 
 ,, vol. 'J J, of 1844. 
 ,, vol. 106 of 1849.
 
 The Revival of Protectiox. 43 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. iv., Sec. II., { 2.] 
 
 During the years of the Free Trade agitation and triumph 
 in Great Britain the European world was in a dream of 
 universal peace. There had been no great war since the con- 
 clusion of the second Treaty of Paris in 1815; while the 
 revolutionary explosion of 1848 only seemed to most onlookers 
 to have ended those dynastic struggles which had been the 
 principal cause of war for many centuries. It was not then 
 perceived that the growing force of nationalism would prove 
 even more fruitful than the jealousies and intrigues of rival 
 potentates in creating international hostilities. The peaceful 
 enthusiasm culminated in the International Exhibition of 1851, 
 when people for the first time realised the enormous strides 
 which Europe had made in its industrial progress since the 
 Napoleonic wars. The praises of industry and commerce 
 were in everybody's mouth : and it was thought incredible 
 that, after so plain a proof of the paramount interest which 
 the toiling masses have in the preservation of peace, their 
 rulers would ever again be able to induce men to record their 
 votes in favour of aggressive war. Commerce was thus 
 naturally regarded as the handmaid of peace, teaching nations 
 to know each other better, and breaking down the prejudice? 
 which the interests of selfish rulers had sedulously fostered. 
 The interests of the people were to overcome the ambition of 
 princes, and all the nations of the world were to be joined 
 together by the golden tie of peaceful trade. 
 
 2. Nor were these only the idle dreams of a few 
 enthusiasts. Men most competent to judge saw no reason for 
 believing that the frequent and rapid intercourse between 
 people of foreign countries, which railways and steamships were 
 rendering possible, could have any other result than that of 
 destroying international enmities, and creating a common 
 commercial interest in the continuance of peace. Even Mr. 
 Cobden, as we have seen, yielded to the influences of his 
 time, and ventured on that prophecy which, in a'l his copious
 
 44 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 forecasts of the commercial future, is the only one that can be 
 quoted to his discredit, and which is always quoted by Pro- 
 tectionists who know nothing else of all that Mr. Cobden wrote 
 or spoke. Everything else which he anticipated as a result 
 of Free Trade has been realised in the manner and by the means 
 which he foretold. Surely, if he had been a mere quack, this 
 could never have happened ? Correct judgments upon politics 
 and accurate forecasts of the course of commerce during many 
 years must be something more than lucky guesses.^ If the 
 matter in controversy were anything else except Protection 
 and Free Trade, we should not hesitate to say that Cobden's 
 accurate prognostications of the future arose from his firm 
 grasp of a principle which rested upon sound knowledge, and 
 was in accord with the deepest sentiments of human nature. 
 The controversy being as it is, we will merely note the fact 
 of his general accuracy, and, admitting that he was wrong in 
 one instance, proceed to examine into the causes of his error. 
 Perhaps at the end of such an inquiry it may be seen that it is 
 sometimes better to be wrong with Cobden than to be right 
 with his critics. 
 
 3. The face of the scene suddenly changed. The thirty- 
 eight years of peace came to an end, and the Crimean War and 
 the growth of the new spirit of nationalism destroyed for 
 a time all hopes of its return. 
 
 The Crimean War was followed by the American War, the 
 Danish War, the Austrian War, the French War, the Turkish 
 War, and no one can say at what time another war may not be 
 added to this gloomy list. Profoundly peaceful Europe was 
 thus suddenly changed into an armed camp ; and con- 
 temporaneously with this, the Europe which was advancing 
 
 1 If Uie famous saying, that a copy of the Times was of more value than 
 the whole of Thucydides, is to be taken literally, it is an error of literary and 
 nc t of poli ical judgment.
 
 The Revival of Protection. 45 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. iv., \ 4.] 
 
 towards Free Trade has gone back towards Protection. The 
 weapons of commercial warfare have been called to the 
 assistance of national armies. 
 
 4. In the year 1879 a return was moved for in the 
 English House of Commons, by Lord Sandon, of the changes 
 which had been made by foreign nations in their tariffs since 
 the year 1850. It was perhaps expected that this return would 
 prove to demonstration the absurdity of Mr. Cobden's expecta- 
 tion and the rapid progress of Protection. 
 
 In fact, it proved the opposite. 
 
 The information collected showed beyond a doubt that, 
 until the results of the Franco-Prussian War began to be felt in 
 their full stress, there had been a steady progress towards Free 
 Trnde on the part of almost all civilised nations. 
 
 From 1850 to 1874 the alterations in the tariffs of Russia, 
 Germany, France, Italy, Holland, Belgium, Sweden and 
 Norway, Austria, Spain, and Portugal, had been steadily in the 
 direction of Free Trade. 
 
 It was about the year 1874 that Europe entered into the 
 full enjoyment of the legacy of evil left behind by the war of 
 1870. In that year the prodigious armaments of European 
 countries seemed to have reached a limit; yet still they increased, 
 and still it was necessary to raise taxes for their support. 
 Direct taxation was resorted to in many forms ; and when the 
 wealthy classes came to the conclusion that this means of 
 raising revenue was exhausted, resort was had to tlie Customs 
 House. 
 
 In this way the progress towards Free Trade has been 
 checked, and been perhaps delayed for two generations. 
 Military rulers cannot be exi)ected to have sympathy with free- 
 dom in any form ; while the vested interests which have grown 
 up under the Protection thus incidentally conferred form 
 ano.her force to bar the path of commercial liberty. Yet even 
 now the peaceful, liberal, and progressive nations such as
 
 46 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 Holland, Switzerland, Belgium, Norway, Italy, and Denmark 
 are also nations which incline towards Free Trade. ^ 
 
 5. It is no part of this treatise to inquire how far the 
 rulers of these different countries were justified, from their own 
 points of view, in fighting their neighbours by means of re- 
 taliatory duties, or in selecting the Customs House as an easy 
 means of raising revenue for a wasteful expenditure. It is only 
 intended to draw attention to the reasons which falsified the san- 
 guine expectations of some of the early Free Traders. It would 
 no doubt have been a gain to Mr. Cobden's reputation if he had 
 foreseen the tremendous change which was about to take 
 place in international relations. But that he failed to do so, 
 and that, in consequence, some of his hopes were disappointed, 
 is no reflection on the soundness of his views, nor any reason 
 for depreciating the wisdom of his policy. 
 
 1 The Protective reaction on the Continent has also been assisted by the 
 changed conditions of agricultural production. The development of the 
 American, Australian, and Indian wheat fields not only shut the farmers of 
 Eastern and Central Europe out of the English market, of which they had had 
 possession since the Peace of 1815, but also exposed all European agriculturists 
 to a new and fierce competition, to which they have been slow to adapt them- 
 selves. Simultaneously with the development of these new sources of produc- 
 tion, came the cheapening in the cost of transportation both by sea and land, 
 which is perhaps the most notable industrial phenomenon of the present century. 
 The Protective duties imposed since 1873 in France, Germany, Austria, and 
 Italy, are in part due to an attempt to stave off or mitigate the effects of these 
 great changes. The process is thus described by M. Alexandre Peer in an 
 article on the fiscal situation in the February number of ' ' La Revue d'Economie 
 Politique " of the year 1891 : " Alors commen^a la stagnation sur le Continent. 
 A Test, les produits russes et roumains exer^aient une pression ; a I'ouest, les 
 marches etaient en partie fermes et en partie occup^s par les produits meilleur 
 marche d'outre-mer. L'Europe Centrale commen(;a a se sentir mal a I'aise : 
 I'Empire d'Allemagne, repousse par I'Angleterre, interdit les transports de 
 I'Autriche-Hongrie, et rAutricbe-Hongrie, de son cote, ferma ses frontieres a 
 la Russie et a la Roumanie ; il s'ensuivit uii mouvement pareil a celui que 
 provoque I'arret subit d'un train, quand les wagons sont successivement un i 
 un refoules en arriere. " Professor Taussig, on p. 326 of the first volume of 
 the Economic Journal, has some suggestive remarks upon these occurrenceF, 
 which need not, however, be referred to at greater length in the present 
 connection.
 
 The Revival of Protection. 47 
 
 Pt. I., Ch iv., \ 5.] 
 
 The tariff changes of the Continental States since 1850 have 
 also another bearing on the fiscal controversy. They show that 
 the example of these States is of little or no value to Australasia 
 or America. The inclination of mankind towards war must, 
 no doubt, be taken into account by politicians ; but the fact 
 that nations when disposed towards war adopt Protective tariffs 
 is no reason why peaceful nations such as the Australian 
 Colonies should do the same. When a Protectionist orator in 
 Sydney or Melbourne proclaims, in his large and disdainful 
 way, that nine-tenths of the civilised world agree with him,^ we 
 may fairly remind him that nine-tenths of the civilised world is 
 also in favour of the conscription. And if he should reply that 
 that coincidence has nothing to do with his argument, we may 
 call in the aid of Lord Sandon's return,- and point out the 
 close connection which exists in Europe between the growth of 
 Protection and the advance of militarism. 
 
 Protection is, in fact, the natural weapon of military rulers. 
 It is a system which flourishes in proportion to the strength of 
 militarism, and everywhere decreases in favour as a people 
 becomes freer and more peaceful. Such is the system which, 
 in the name of " Liberalism," certain politicians introduced into 
 Victoria.^ But the growth of Protection in that Colony is 
 a subject for another chapter. Let us first, however, treat of 
 the United States. 
 
 ' The Free Trade minority is always overlooked in these ingenious 
 calculations. 
 
 2 This is dealt with in detail by Sir T. Farrer in his " Free Trade v. Fair 
 Trade." 
 
 3 The Protectionists in Victoria call themselves. "Liberals." In New 
 South Wales, as in Canada, the nomenclature of parties is more appropriate 
 and the Liberals are the advocates of industrial freedom. It would be strange 
 indeed if the party which fought for civil and religious freedom should try to 
 put fetters upon freedom of industry.
 
 48 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 section iii. the united states.' 
 
 I. One of the most instructive economic works which 
 yet remain to be Avritten is an adequate history of the 
 Protective movement in the United States. The difficulties 
 of such a work are enormous. The tariffs, as enacted from 
 time to time, have always been extraordinarily complex ; 
 while the large powers of construing Acts of Congress 
 conferred upon the Customs Boards have still further in- 
 creased the complexity of legislation. The consequence is, 
 that an adequate treatment of the subject would not only 
 require a knowledge of the processes of manufacture in all 
 branches which can hardly be possessed by any individual, 
 since no one is acquainted with the secrets of every trade but 
 would also involve an accurate consideration of the fluctuations 
 in prices, the conditions of trade, and the course of industrial 
 development during the last hundred years ; and even if the 
 initial difficulty were overcome of understanding the precise 
 nature of tariff legislation, the obscure problem of tracing its 
 effects would still present itself for a solution. The tariff in the 
 United States has seldom, if ever, worked alone, but other 
 influences have almost always obscured its operation. Currency 
 delusions, war, the development of the interior, immigration, 
 improvement in the means of locomotion, have all, at one 
 time or another, rendered the precise effect of a tariff difficult 
 to trace, eitlaer by prejudicing its working when it has been low, 
 or hiding its injurious influence when it has been high. The 
 one fact which stands out plainly from this intricate confusion 
 is, that in all periods of American history high tariffs have 
 resulted from a morbid condition of national affairs. 
 
 v^ 2. Noone, for instince, could contend that the circumstances 
 
 1 For the contents of this section the wri'.er is largely indebted to Professor 
 Sumner's " Lectures on the History of Protection in the United States," and to 
 Professor Taussig's "Tariff History of the United States," two admirable 
 works which are too little known in England and Australia.
 
 The Revival of Protection. 49 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. iv., Sec. III., 2.] 
 
 which led to the passing of the first Tariff Act of 1789 
 have any application to the present time. That measure had 
 two objects the first was to raise a Federal revenue from the 
 only source then open to the Federal Government ; the second 
 was to re-establish the natural industries of the United States, 
 and to restore them to the same position which they would 
 have held if they had not been crushed for many years by the 
 protective legislation of Great Britain. The revolt of the 
 American Colonies was very largely a revolt against Protection. 
 It was an effort on the part of the Americans to secure the 
 benefits of a larger commerce. The policy of the British 
 Government had been to cramp American trade, and thwart 
 the development of American industry. Bancroft, the great 
 American historian, says : " American independence, like the 
 great rivers of the country, had many sources, but the head- 
 spring that coloured all the stream was the British Navigation 
 Act. . . . This odious measure provided that no com- 
 modities whatever, being the growth, product, or manufacture 
 of Asia, Africa, or America, should be imported into Eng- 
 land or her Colonies except in ships belonging to English 
 subjects, and of which the master and the greater part of the 
 crew were also English. Subsequently, the ordinance was re- 
 enacted with additional clauses, virtually excluding foreign 
 ships from American harbours, and sacrificing to English 
 monopoly the natural rights of the Colonies." 
 
 Nor were the efforts of the English Protectionists directed 
 only against external commerce. Their despotic regulations 
 were equally directed towards the suppression of manufactures 
 and the destruction of internal trade. 
 
 " In 1699 the British Parliament prohibited the Colonies 
 from exporting wool, jam, or woollen fabrics, and from carry- 
 ing them coastwise from one Colony and place to another. In 
 1719 Parliament declared that the erection of manufactories in 
 the Colonies tended to lessen their dependence on the 
 Mother Country ; and the EngUsh manufacturers memorialised 
 
 E
 
 50 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 Parliament that the Colonies were carrying on trade and erecting 
 manufactories, with a view to obtainmg legislation to arrest it. 
 In 1 73 1 the Board of Trade were instructed to inquire as to the 
 Colonial laws made to encourage manufactures, as to manu- 
 factories set up, and as to trade carried on in the Colonies, and 
 to report thereon. In 1732 they reported that Massachusetts 
 had passed a law to encourage manufactures ; that the people 
 of New York, Connecticut, Rhode Island, and Maryland had 
 fallen into the manufacture of woollen and linen for the use of 
 their own families, and of flax and hemp into coarse bags and 
 halters, all of which interfered with the profits of the British 
 merchants. The Board recommended that the minds of the 
 people of those Colonies should be immediately diverted, and a 
 stop be put to it, or the practice would be extended. The same 
 year Parliament prohibited the exportation of hats from the 
 Colonies, and trading in them from one Colony to another by 
 ships, carts, or horses. No hatter should set up in business 
 who had not served seven years, nor have more than two 
 apprentices ; and no black person should work at the trade. 
 Iron mills for slitting and rolling, and plating-forges, were pro- 
 hibited under a penalty of ;^5oo. This system of prohibition 
 and restriction continued to increase till the Colonies rebelled, 
 and declared independence in 1776." 
 
 As might have been expected after such a history, the first 
 effort of the independent States was to retaliate upon Great 
 Britain by cutting off the trade which she had ende<ivoured to 
 preserve by such injurious measures. 
 
 3. The first Tariff Act was passed in 1789. The preamble 
 of this Act limited the duration of the Protective duties to 
 seven years, that being the time after which, according to the 
 Protectionists of that day, the infant industries would be able 
 to stand alone. Before the seven years expired, the Act had 
 been altered many times, and every alteration was in the 
 direction of higher duties ; while, it is almost needless to say.
 
 The Revival of Protection. 51 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. iv., \ 3.] 
 
 the infants or that day continue to be infants still. After one 
 hundred years of Protection, not one of them can walk alone. 
 In spite, however, of the alterations in the original Act, the tariff 
 remained for twenty years a revenue measure. The duties were 
 in all cases moderate, ranging from five per cent, ad valorem 
 to fifteen per cent, on articles of luxury, and the ostensible 
 ground for such increases as were made was the necessity for 
 raising a larger revenue. 
 
 The first great change occurred in 1808, when, as Professor 
 Taussig says, " the complications with England and France led 
 to a series of measures which mark a turning-point in the 
 industrial history of the country." The Berlin and Milan 
 Decrees, the English Orders-in-Council, the Embargo, the 
 Non-Intercourse Act (1809), practically destroyed all foreign 
 commerce. War with England followed in 18 12. Then, as 
 always, tariffs provoked war, and war in its turn provoked still 
 higher tarifTs. The first serious agitation in favour of Pro- 
 tection dates, in the opinion of Professor Taussig who has 
 made a more careful study of the question than any other 
 writer from the period of 180815, when measures of overt 
 hostilities terminating in open war, fanned that flame of discord 
 and suspicion in which the fetters of a tariff are always forged. 
 The conclusion of peace led to a slight reduction in duties ; 
 but in 18 16 the manufacturers' agitation was successful, and 
 duties of twenty-five per cent, were imposed upon iron, wool, 
 cotton, and other articles of domestic manufacture. 
 
 The next alteration of the tariff occurred in 1824, and was 
 due, as has often been the case, to the pressure of a financial 
 crisis. The termination of the Continental wars caused com- 
 mercial unsettlement throughout the civilised world, so that it 
 was many years before trade flowed again in its natural channels. 
 The period of transition from war to peace was necessarily 
 attended with much distress. This was aggravated in America 
 by an excessive issue of paper money, until a crash occurred in 
 1819, from which the country did not recover for four years. 
 E 2
 
 52 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 During that period the Protectionists were active. Periods of 
 national distress are always the opportunity of financial quacks. 
 Defeated only by the vote of one State in 1820, they obtained 
 a high tariff in 1824, which they again increased in 1828, being 
 aided in the latter undertaking by the English crisis of 1825-26.1 
 In the tariff of 1828 the Protective movement reached its 
 highest point before the Civil War. The measures which 
 followed in 1832 and 1833 the year of Clay's compromise 
 tariff moderated the peculiarly offensive provisions of the Act 
 of 1828, and provided for the gradual reduction of duties to a 
 uniform rate of twenty per cent, by the year 1842. In that 
 year, however, the tariff, instead of being reduced, was again 
 raised. Again we can trace in this fresh instalment of Pro- 
 tection the influence of currency delusions. The crisis of 
 1837 is described by the Hon. Hugh McCulloch, who was 
 Secretary to the Treasury in three Administrations, as the most 
 severe ever experienced in the United States, both in its 
 immediate and its after-consequences. Every bank in America, 
 except the Chemical Bank of New York, suspended specie 
 payments, and the country did not recover from the disaster 
 until 1843. The collapse was due, said Mr. McCulloch, in 
 his first report to Congress, as was the great expansion of 1835 
 and 1836, which immediately preceded it, to "excessive bank 
 circulation and discounts, and an abuse of the credit system, 
 stimulated in the first place by Government deposits with the 
 State Banks, and swelled by currency and credits until, under 
 the wild spirit of speculation which invaded the country, labour 
 and production decreased to such an extent that the country 
 which should have been the great food-producing country of 
 the world became an importer of bread-stuffs." ^ The Act of 
 
 1 .\ graphic description of this crisis, wliich was largely due to wild specula- 
 tion in South America, and was one of the fiercest ever experienced, is contained 
 in Martineau's " History of the Peace," book ii. , chapter viii. 
 
 2 Sec " Men and Measures of Haifa Century," by Hugh McCulloch (Samp- 
 son Low & Co., London, 1888), a work of extreme interest, which throws 
 many side-lights upon economic questions.
 
 The Revival of Protection. 53 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. iv., 54.] 
 
 1842 continued in force for ten years, when it was superseded 
 by the Act of 1846, which greatly lowered the range of duties. 
 In 1857 duties were again reduced, and remained low until 
 the Morrill Tariff of 186 r. This was passed in 1859-60, when 
 Congress was once more under the influence of the feelings 
 inspired by a commercial crisis. This had occurred in 1857 
 as a consequence of similar causes to that which had produced 
 the crisis of 1837 namely, the unhealthy extension of various 
 forms of credit. The Morrill Tariff, however, made only slight 
 increases in existing duties, and professed to make the increases 
 even less than they were. Its chief effect, according to Pro- 
 fessor Taussig, was to alter the mode of collection. Hardly 
 had this tariff come into operation when the Civil War began. 
 From that moment dates the orgie of Protectionists. The 
 exigencies of the war were everywhere seized upon as an excuse 
 for the foundation of tariff monopolies ; and the history of 
 tariff legislation since that date is one of the most disgraceful 
 examples ever offered to the world of the methods by which 
 organised wealth is able to corrupt a legislative body. The 
 framing of a tariff has been aptly described as a game of grab, 
 in which every interest tries to steal some public money, and 
 in which one robber assists another in return for the permission 
 to do more plundering on his own account. The world, per- 
 haps, has never afforded a more striking instance of the 
 inherent evils of a Protective system than is offered by the 
 debasement of American politics, and the unhappy condition 
 of the industrial classes during the last five-and-twenty years. 
 Fortunately, the writing on the wall is plain. The system of 
 Protection cannot last for many years, now that the adoption 
 of the Australian ballot system has restored freedom of voting 
 to the mass of American citizens. 
 
 4. It would unduly protract this inquiry if any attempt 
 were made to investigate the connection between the fluctu- 
 ating tariff legislation of the United States and the general
 
 54 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 prosperity of the country. Both Free Traders and Protec- 
 tionists have asserted that such a connection exists ; and each 
 has claimed, with much parade of facts, that the tariff which 
 they favour has produced prosperity, and that depressions have 
 been due to changes in an opposite direction. Professor 
 Taussig, in his chapter on "The Tariff, 1830 1860," has 
 summarised all that can be said upon this point by either 
 side with an impartiality which is as rare in tariff contro- 
 versies as it is commendable. He concludes his remarks as 
 follows : 
 
 "In truth, there has been a great deal of loose talk about 
 tariffs and crises. Whenever there has been a crisis, the 
 Free Traders or Protectionists, as the case may be, have been 
 tempted to use it as a means for overthrowing the system they 
 opposed. . . . But the effect of tariffs cannot be traced by 
 any such rough-and-ready method. The tariff system of a 
 country is but one of many factors entering into its general 
 prosperity. Its influence, good or bad, may be strengthened 
 or may be counteracted by other causes ; while it is exceedingly 
 difficult, generally impossible, to trace its separate effect. 
 Least of all can its influence be traced in those variations of 
 outward prosperity and depression which are marked by ' good 
 times ' and crises. A Protective tariff may sometimes strengthen 
 other causes which are bringing on a commercial crisis. Some 
 such effect is very likely traceable to the tariff in the years 
 before the crisis of 1873. It may sometimes be the occasion 
 of a revival of activity, when the other conditions are already 
 favourable to such a revival. This may have been the case in 
 1843. But these are only incidental effects, and lie quite out- 
 side the real problem as to the results of Protection. As a 
 rule, the tariff system of a country operates neither to cause nor 
 to prevent crises. They are the results of conditions of ex- 
 change and production on which it can exercise no great or 
 permanent influence. . . . There is no way of eliminating
 
 The Revival of Protection. 55 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. iv., } 5.] 
 
 the other factors and determining how much can be ascribed 
 to the tariff alone." 1 
 
 5. These conditions prevent the example of America 
 from being of much value to other countries. The conditions 
 of the United States, both physical and political, are unique. 
 In no other country in the world is there an extent of territory 
 so great or of such varied resources ; and over no other portion 
 of the globe of equal extent is trade so perfectly untrammeled. 
 When Protectionists point to American prosperity as a con- 
 sequence of Protection, they forget that no other country offers 
 such an example of the wisdom of Free Trade. Over an area 
 of 3,547,390 square miles there is no Customs House, and 
 goods can pass as freely from New York to San Francisco, 
 as they can from Birmingham to London. The rapid 
 development of new countries, the growth of arts, the 
 enormous influx of immigrants, have all combined to obscure 
 the influences of the American tariff. No other country 
 is so well adapted both by nature and art to endure the 
 burdens of high taxation. But such a fact gives little 
 warrant for the assertion that high taxation is a universal 
 good. America is a country by itself, whose conditions 
 are so peculiar, and whose growth has been so rapid, 
 that it affords but little instruction to tariff disputants in 
 other lands. All that this chapter has endeavoured to make 
 plain is, that in America, as in Europe, high tariffs have 
 originated in an unhealthy condition of the body politic. 
 Sometimes this condition is the result of war, sometimes 
 of speculation, sometimes of delusions about currency ; but 
 whenever it exists, from any cause, Protection flourishes. 
 Quack doctors have no chance when the patient is in health. 2 
 
 1 " T.iriff History of the United States," Taussig, pp. 121, 122. (G. P. 
 Putnam's Sons, New York and London, 1888.) 
 
 ^ Colonel Grosvenor's "Does Protection Protect?" contains a mass of 
 information on this subject. The tracts of the Tariff Reform League and
 
 56 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 SECTION IV. THE BRITISH COLONIES. 
 
 I. While the causes which have contributed to the revival 
 of Protection in Europe and the United States have not been 
 such as to give rise to permanent anxiety for the ultimate 
 success of Free Trade, no candid supporter of that policy can 
 view without disquietude the fiscal legislation of the British 
 Colonies. 
 
 Colonial tariffs have had two distinguishing characteristics 
 in having been adopted more deliberately for the sake of 
 Protection than has been the case elsewhere, and in being 
 the direct result of those misapprehensions and mistakes 
 which have been noticed in an earlier chapter as inducing a 
 mistrust of Free Trade among the working classes. 
 
 This has been especially the case in the Colony of Vic- 
 toria. The first restrictive tariff in Victoria was passed in 
 1865. Since that date it has been altered four times 
 without counting unimportant modifications namely, in 1870, 
 1872, 1880, and 1889. On each occasion the scale of duties 
 has been raised and their scope widened, until duties averaging 
 30 per cent, ad valorem are now levied on nearly a thousand 
 
 the " Economic Monographs," issued by G. P. Putnam's Sons, are also well 
 worthy of attention. 
 
 Of the authors who have tried to deal with this great subject, Professor 
 Taussig, and Professor Sumner of Yale, appear to have been the most 
 successful. Professor Taussig, in his " Tarift History,'' gives an admir- 
 able survey of the course of fiscal legislation ; while Professor Sumner, in his 
 " Lectures on the History of Protection," aims rather at illustrating the effects 
 of the various tariffs upon the condition of the country. In addition to these 
 principal works, much information is contained in the tracts of the Tariff Reform 
 League. The reports presented by Mr. Secretary McCulloch during his terms 
 of office at the Treasury are also very valuable in showing the intimate 
 connection which exists between Protection and currency delusions. 
 
 It would lie outside the scope of the preseat work to enter upon any 
 detailed inquiry into the causes or effects of Protection in the United States. 
 All that is desirable in the present connection is to indicate the special nature of 
 the crises which in America, as in Europe, have led to an apparent and (as 
 events will prove) a temporary abandonment o'" the principle of industrial 
 freedom.
 
 The Revival of Protection. 57 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. jv., \ 2] 
 
 articles of commerce. The tariff occupies twenty-five pages ot 
 close print ; and no visitor can pass from Sydney to Melbourne 
 although these cities are as closely related by ties of business 
 and friendship as Liverpool is to Manchester, or Boston to New 
 York without being subjected to a tiresome delay of thirty 
 minutes while his person is inspected by detectives and his 
 luggage searched as if he were a suspected thief. Such is 
 commerce as it is understood in Victoria, and this is the way 
 in which Protectionists testify to their belief in the unity of 
 Australasia. 
 
 2. Unfortunately for the interests of Free Trade, Victoria 
 was the foremost Colony in the Australasian group at the time 
 when she entered upon her reactionary policy. She then held 
 the lead in population, wealth, trade, commerce, shipping, 
 manufactures, agriculture ; and although she has for several 
 years lost her position of supremacy in all these signs of 
 material progress, except agriculture, to the Free Trade Colony 
 of New South Wales^ she exercised in 1865 a dominating 
 influence throughout Australia. The effect of this extended 
 even into New South Wales, so that shrewd observers like Sir 
 Charles Dilke, visiting the Mother Colony in 1866, could 
 publish the opinion that " the pastoral tenants of the Crown 
 stood alone in their support of Free Trade." - It is a 
 striking instance of the difficulty which must beset even ex- 
 perienced publicists in attempting to catch the drift of foreign 
 opinion that, within twelve months of this sentence being 
 penned, one of the strongest Colonial Ministries that ever 
 existed that under the leadership of Sir James Martin was 
 so hopelessly beaten at the polls upon the straight issue of 
 Protection that the Protectionists did not exist again as a 
 party in New South Wales until 1886. In spite of this 
 reversal of his expectations, Sir Charles Dilkc has had the 
 
 1 See Appendix N'o. III. 
 
 2 "Greater Britain," First Edition, vol. ii., p. 59 (London, 1S6S).
 
 58 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 courage, in the last edition of his work, published in 1890, to 
 repeat his gloomy forecast of the prospects of Free Trade in 
 New South Wales in almost the same language which he used 
 in 1866.1 A stopped clock must point to the right hour at 
 least once in a day ; but it has yet to be seen whether, in 
 spite of an accidental victory, the permanent triumph of Pro- 
 tection in New South Wales is not even farther off from 1890 
 than 1890 was from 1866. 
 
 The younger Colonies of South Australia and New Zealand 
 were necessarily more exposed than New South Wales to the 
 influence of Victorian opinion. Not only were they largely 
 developed by Victorian capital, but many of their press-men 
 and politicians received their earliest training in the Protec- 
 tionist struggles of the Southern Colony. The consequence 
 was that both in South Australia, Queensland, and New 
 Zealand, there was a steady drift of opinion in favour of Vic- 
 torian views. At the same time the movement towards Pro- 
 tection was assisted by the totally different feeling of an- 
 tagonism to Victoria. The policy of extreme provincialism 
 which that Colony has pursued, not only in her Customs 
 tariff, but in other departments of administration, naturally 
 aroused a bitterness of feeling in the neighbouring Colonies, 
 which gave rise in South Australia and Queensland to an 
 
 1 The portion of Sir Charles Dilke's book which deals with New South 
 Wales is full of strange errors, both in the estimate of persons and of policies. 
 He appears to have written the Australian portion of his work entirely under 
 Victorian influences, and to have looked at everything through Protectionist 
 spectacles. It is a great pity that a work which contains so much valuable 
 niatter, and gives so admirable a survey of the institutions and development of 
 the English dominions, should be so unreliable when it treats of the progress 
 and opinijns of the Free Trade Colony of New South Wales. It is natural 
 that Protectionists should strive, by all means in their power, to decry the pro- 
 gress of a Frei Trade country, and to conceal the fact of its supremacy ; but 
 it is surprising that an English statesman should not have informed himself 
 more accurately of the reasons which have induced New South Wales, alone of 
 the Australian Colonies, to adhere to a policy of commercial freedom. Sir 
 Charles Dilke, however, appears in all pans of his work to hold a brief for 
 Protection,
 
 The Reviva^ of Protection. 59 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. iv., 5 3.] 
 
 irresistible demand for retaliation. New South Wales up to the 
 present time has been sufficiently powerful to treat the 
 jealousies of her southern neighbour with a good-humoured in- 
 difference; but even in New South Wales the desire to 
 retaliate upon Victoria is the strongest element in the Pro- 
 tectionist cause.i This is especially the case among the 
 farmers. 
 
 3. The friends of Victoria were naturally unable to resist 
 this legitimate appHcation of their favourite doctrines ; and 
 thus, by a strange irony of fate, Victoria has been confined on 
 every side, except that bordering upon New South Wales, by 
 fetters of her own forging. The limits thus placed upon her 
 trade have reduced her to a condition of grave financial 
 difficulty. Her exports have failed for many years past to keep 
 pace with the increase of population. In the meantime her 
 debts have been increasing by leaps and bounds. She 
 has borrowed twenty millions of pounds upon her public 
 credit during the last ten years ; while the increase of her 
 private indebtedness during the same period has been 
 enormous.^ Naturally the expenditure of so much capital 
 in a compact community of less than a million souls, 
 produced that boom of which Sir Charles Dilke has written 
 in such glowing terms. The boom, however, has ended 
 as booms will; and at the time of writing (1890) the 
 Colony of Victoria, which, according to Protectionists, is the 
 paradise of working men, is suffering from a protracted agony 
 of hard times. The Protectionist Ministry proposes the familiar 
 remedy of more borrowing. Railways are to be made with 
 English money at a cost of fourteen millions ! Should this 
 proposal be adopted, and should England be inclined to lend 
 the money, the crash may be postponed. But in the mean- 
 
 1 Thus all the constituencies along the border return Protectionist 
 members. 
 
 ' Sft Appendi.x,
 
 6o Industrial Freedom. 
 
 time, unless the experiment of irrigation succeeds beyond the 
 most sanguine expectations in giving the Colony new articles 
 of export, or unless her hot-house manufactures can expand 
 into new commercial channels, the necessary payments of 
 interest to her foreign creditors will form every year an in- 
 creasing proportion of the total value of her exports. It is no 
 wonder that Victorian Protectionists have so suddenly become 
 converted to the merits of Federation ! 
 
 4. The desire to retaliate upon a Protectionist neighbour 
 which has stimulated the Protective movement in Australia, 
 has operated in the same direction in the case of Canada. 
 Although the Canadian tariff was adopted mainly as a revenue 
 measure, the commercial tactics of the manufacturers of the 
 United States undoubtedly affected the result. Secure within 
 their own market, it was a common practice of the New 
 England and Pennsylvania manufacturers to treat Canada as a 
 useful outlet for surplus stock. This was sold at any price 
 that would secure a buyer, until Canadian manufacturers com- 
 plained that they could find no market for their goods in the 
 face of competition of this nature. The Canadian people 
 were appealed to by their pride not to allow their country 
 to be the dumping-ground of American rubbish, but to 
 establish for themselves a firm and national system of trade 
 and manufacture. How far the attempt to do this by means 
 of Protection has proved to be successful is an inquiry that 
 would lie outside the province of this work. It is enough to 
 state that while Canadian trade has developed since the tariff 
 of 1879 i"^ some directions, the signs of progress in others are 
 by no means satisfactory.^ A full examination, however, into 
 Canadian progress under Protection would require a detailed 
 investigation of many complicated figures, the value of which 
 would diminish as each year a'Med new facts and fresh 
 
 1 See extract in note at end of this section fr5ni " 'Y\\i Tariff on Trial, " by 
 Sir Richard Cartwright {The Xorih Amciican A'eviav, May, ifgo).
 
 Th Revival of Protection. 6i 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. iv., \ 5.] 
 
 statistics to Canadian history. All that is desired in the 
 present connection is to indicate the causes which have led to 
 the adoption of Protection, and not to estimate the results of 
 the system. 
 
 5. But, although retaliation was a powerful motive in 
 inducing the acceptance of the Canadian tariff, it is doubtful 
 wliether the measure was not finally accepted rather for revenue 
 than for fiscal reasons. It is certain that the leaders of both politi- 
 cal parties evaded a contest upon the strictly fiscal issue. Thus 
 the Hon. Edward Blake, leader of the Liberal or low-tariff party, 
 used the following words in his electoral manifesto in 1882: 
 " Our adversaries wish to present to you an issue as between 
 the present tariff and absolute Free Trade. That is not the 
 true issue. Free Trade is, as I have repeatedly explained, for 
 us impossible ; and the issue is, whether the present tariff is 
 perfect, or defective and unjust." 
 
 Similar views were expressed in 1877 by Mr. Mackenzie, 
 then the leader of the sa called Free Trade party: "My 
 honourable friend (Sir J. Macdonald) has stated very correctly 
 the position I have taken up that is, that we have not 
 really the questions of Protection and Free Trade as 
 political principles of action to define or expose in this 
 country." 
 
 Similar extracts might be made from the speeches and 
 writings of other Canadian politicians ; but enough has been 
 quoted to show that the Canadian tariff was regarded by many 
 of its friends and opponents as an exceptional piece of legisla- 
 tion, demanded by the circumstances of the country, and was 
 not a deliberate rejection of the principles of Free Trade. 
 \\'ithout entering into details, which would lie outside the 
 scope of this work, it is enough to say that the supposed excep- 
 tional circumstances which justified the tariff were those 
 physical and national characteristics which were thought to 
 render impossible any form of direct taxation.
 
 62 INDUSTRIAL FREEDOM. 
 
 6. The same difificulty of obtaining revenue without 
 resorting to the Customs House has been felt very strongly 
 in Australia, Direct taxation must always be a matter of 
 difficulty in young and sparsely settled countries. If land is 
 taxed, the cry is raised that the development of the country is 
 being retarded ; if realised wealth is taxed, the Government is 
 denounced for discouraging the investment of foreign capital. 
 And whether the taxes are levied on land or personalty, it must 
 always be difficult in a young country, where local and personal 
 feeling runs so high, either in friendship or enmity, to obtain 
 satisfactory assessments without incurring the charge of 
 favouritism or needlessly exposing private affairs. The con- 
 sequence is that every Government, whatever may be its fiscal 
 creed, is tempted to raise taxes by the easy method of the 
 Customs House. Directly this is attempted the " interests " 
 combine ; and, sometimes before the country has had time to 
 realise what is being done, and contrary to the intention of the 
 Ministry, a Protective tax is sneaked into the tariff. One tax 
 of this kind soon leads to another, until the country finds 
 itself committed to a Protective policy. 
 
 This explains why the Free Trade party in the Australian 
 Colonies is everywhere the party of economy. The aim of Pro- 
 tectionists is to increase public expenditure beyond the annual 
 revenue, in the assurance that the difficulty of raising fresh 
 taxation by any other means, except through the Customs 
 House, will be so great as to necessitate a revision of the tariff. 
 They then anticipate a general scramble, in which the highly 
 organised manufacturers' rings will be able to obtain an ample 
 share of public money. The Protectionists have hitherto been 
 assisted in this object by the Colonial Upper Houses, which 
 give the wealthy land-owning class a degree of influence far 
 greater than that which is possessed by the same classes in 
 communities whose form of government is outwardly less 
 democratic. Thus, the Upper House in New South Wales, 
 although it contains a large majority of Free Traders, has
 
 TtiE Revival of Protection. 63 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. iv., \ 7.] 
 
 consistently thrown out every measure to impose direct taxation. 
 The fiscal struggle in New South Wales has thus entered on a 
 new phase ; it has become a struggle of the masses against 
 the classes, and the men of wealth are being driven slowly but 
 surely into the camp of the Protectionists. 
 
 7. This has not always been the case in the course of this 
 controversy. In Victoria, indeed, the position of parties in the 
 early days of the struggle was quite the opposite. The land- 
 owners and men of wealth were the Free Traders, the masses 
 were Protectionists. 
 
 This was not owing to any special characteristics of either of 
 the rival doctrines, but to the political accidents of the time. The 
 real struggle in Victoria in 1865-6 was not between Free Traders 
 and Protectionists, but between the landowners and the people. 
 
 It happened that the landowners were closely connected, 
 both socially and by their financial relations, with the banking 
 corporations and the mercantile classes, and thus the merchants 
 and the banks were drawn into the struggle in self-defence. But 
 primarily the movement was against landowners and not against 
 merchants. As the contest continued, the issue of Protection 
 was put more plainly forward, both in order to attract the 
 manufacturing classes to the popular side, and because the anti- 
 popular party happened to hold Free Trade views. The feel- 
 ings generated in this bitter struggle have spread from Victoria 
 to the rest of Australia, and the Protectionist party in that 
 continent endeavours by every means in its power to associate 
 Free Traders with Conservatism. 
 
 In truth, however, except in New South Wales, where 
 parties are divided by their fiscal opinions, and where Free 
 Traders are the democratic and popular party, there has been no 
 straight fight upon the simple issue of Protection and Free 
 Trade. Protection has been adopted for a variety of differing 
 and sometimes inconsistent reasons, among which positive 
 hostility towards Free Trade has had but little influence.
 
 64 iNbVSTklAL pR p. EDO St. 
 
 In practice it matters, of course, very little with what 
 object Protective duties are imposed whether it is to maintain 
 costly armies or to save property owners from bearing their 
 share of the national taxes. But when the conduct of a nation 
 in adopting Protection is quoted as an example, then the motives 
 which induced it to take that step become of the utmost im- 
 portance ; because if the motives are such as might reasonably 
 affect our minds, then the case of that country is in point for us ; 
 but if the motives are altogether exceptional and far removed 
 from those which either do or ought to operate upon us, then 
 the example is of no value, except in so far as it illustrates the 
 working and effect of the policy in question. The issue, 
 whether Protection or Free Trade should be adopted in any 
 particular country, is not one that ought to be decided by 
 counting heads. But when an appeal is made to the conduct 
 of other nations, it is necessary to bear in mind the facts and 
 circumstances by which they have been controlled. 
 
 As a result of our inquiry we see that there has been 
 no deliberate rejection of Free Trade as a sound principle, but 
 only an abandonment of its practice under the stress of great 
 and exceptional difficulties. It has still to be proved whether 
 the rulers of many of the now Protected countries would not 
 have acted more wisely by adhering under all difficulties 
 to the natural policy of allowing men to buy and sell wherever 
 they please ; and it has yet to be seen whether, in the crash of 
 the first great civil commotion, these childish impediments 
 to human intercourse will not tumble to the ground. 
 
 There are already many signs that the evils which arise 
 from a disorganisation of industrial relations are the greatest in 
 those countries which have strayed the farthest from the path 
 of freedom. 1 
 
 It is not, however, intended to investigate tlie working of 
 
 ' Thus the report of the Enghsh Royal Commission on the Depression of 
 Trade [ci)-c. 1883-7) shows that the depression was greater in the Protected 
 than in the Free Trade countries.
 
 The Revival of Protection. 65 
 
 Pt. 1., Ch. iv., \ 7.] 
 
 Protective tariffs in this treatise. The materials for such an 
 investigation are very voluminous and of uncertain value; while 
 the circumstances which have to be taken into account in draw- 
 ing a comparison between the industrial conditions of several 
 countries are so numerous and impalpable that no sound 
 practical conclusion can be based on such an inquiry. There 
 are indeed a few points in which comparisons can be drawn 
 between Great Britain and the United States, and between the 
 Colonies of New South Wales and Victoria ; while if the com- 
 parison is limited to particular industries, other countries may 
 be added to the list. But, for the most part, each country 
 must stand by itself; and the question between the rival 
 policies must be decided upon facts drawn from its own history, 
 and conclusions based on its own conditions. It is generally 
 waste of power and a cause of confusion to draw arguments 
 from the circumstances of other countries for any other pur- 
 pose than that of estimating with correctness the actual opera- 
 tion of a fiscal policy. A knowledge of the industrial 
 conditions of other countries is more generally useful as a 
 check upon rash inferences than as a guide for our own 
 conduct.^ 
 
 1 See Appendix III. : Comparison between the Progress of Victoria and 
 New South Wales since 1866. 
 
 Note i. 
 
 The condition of England under protection. 
 
 (Extract from Martineau's " Plistory of the Peace.") 
 
 In Carlisle the Committee of Inquiry reported that a fourth of the popular 
 tion wrs in a state bordering on starvation actually cet-tain to die of famine, 
 unless relieved by extraordinary exertions. In the woollen districts of Wilt- 
 shire the allowance to the independent labourer was not two- thirds of the 
 viinimum in the workhouse ; and the large existing population consumed only 
 a fourth of the bread and meat required by the much smaller population of 
 1S20. In Stockport more than half the master-spinners had failed before the 
 clo'e of 1842 ; dwelling-liouses to the number of 3,000 were shut up ; and the 
 occupiers of many hundreds more were unable to pay rates at all. I'ivc 
 thousand persons were walking the streets in compulsory idleness ; and the 
 Burnley (Guardians wrote to the Secretary of State that the distress was far
 
 66 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 beyond their managc;Tient ; so that a Government Commissioner and Govern- 
 ment funds were sent down without delay. At a meeting at Manchester, where 
 humble shopkeepers were the speakers, anecdotes were related which told 
 more than declamation. Rent-collectors were afraid to meet their principals, 
 as no money could be collected. Provision dealers were subject to incursions 
 from a wolfish man prowling for food for his children, or from a half-frantic 
 woman with her dying baby at her breast, or from parties of ten or a dozen 
 desperate wretches who were levying contributions along the street. The linen- 
 draper told how new clothes had become out of the question among his 
 customers, and they bought only remnants and patches to mend the old ones. 
 The baker was more and more surprised at the number of people who bought 
 halfpennyworths of bread. A provision dealer used to throw away outside 
 scraps of bacon ; but now respectable customers of twenty years' standing 
 bought them in pennyworths to moisten their potatoes. These shopkeepers 
 contemplated nothing but ruin from the impoverished condition of their 
 customers. While rates were increasing beyond all precedent, their trade was 
 only one-half or one-third, or even one-tenth what it had been three years 
 
 before. 
 
 ** 
 
 At Leeds the pauper stone-heap amounted to 150,000 tons ; and the 
 Guardians offered the paupers 6s. per week for doing nothing, rather than 
 7s. 6d. per week for stone-breaking. The millwrights and other trades were 
 offering a premium on emigration, to induce their "hands" to go away. At 
 Hinckley one-third of the inhabitants were paupers ; more than a fifth of the 
 houses stood empty ; and there was not work enough in the place to employ 
 properly one-third of the weavers. In Dorsetshire a man and his wife had for 
 wages 2S. 6d. per week and three loaves ; and the ablest labourers had 
 63. or 7s. 
 
 There were riots of nailers and miners at Dudley and .Stourbridge, and 
 tumult over the whole district, requiring the active services of the military. The 
 rioters resisted a reduction of wages, and hustled some of the masters, as did 
 other rioters in Wales, where a gentleman of property had a narrow escape 
 with his life. In the Potteries a force of 6,000 malcontents, spread over an 
 extent of seven miles, and occasionally comrnitting violence on recusant masters 
 or men, kept Staffordshire in alarm. Troops were encamped- on the Pottery 
 racecourse, and magistrates tried to conciliate and mediate, but with little effect. 
 In Manchester the influx of malcontents became alarming in August, 1842. 
 Mills were stopped, and in some the windows broken and machinery injured. 
 The Riot Act was read four times in one day, and prisoners were taken by 
 scores at once. A large attendance of military was necessary, as there were 
 threats of tearing up the railings and cutting the gas-pipes. At one time all 
 the chief towns in the manufacturing district seemed to be in the hands of 
 the mob. 
 
 Further and detailed information on the subject is to be 
 found in Karl Marx's " Essay on Capital '' and in Engel's " Con-
 
 The Revival of PkotectioiV. 67 
 
 Pt I., Ch. iv., Note i.] 
 
 dition of the Working Classes in 1844." The novels of " Sybil" 
 and " Yeast " also give an insight into the true nature of the 
 time. 
 
 Mr. Medley has collected some of the more striking facts 
 in a leaflet which is published by the Cobden Club, and is 
 here in part reprinted : 
 
 "During these thirty years (1815-45) the state of the country was simply 
 awful. 
 
 "At one time, one out of every eleven of the population was a pauper. 
 
 "Some idea of the state of things may be gained from Xhe facts which 
 follow : 
 
 "In 1816, at Hinckley, Leicestershire, the Poor Rate was 52s. in the 
 pound. 
 
 " In 1817, at Langdon, Dorsetshire, 409 out of 575 inhabitants were receiv- 
 ing relief ; while in Ely three-fourths of the population were in the same 
 plight. 
 
 " In 1819, 1820, and 1822, agriculture was in a state of universal distress, 
 and petitions for relief were presented to Parliament. 
 
 " During the time these laws were in force, there were no fewer than five 
 Parliamentary Committees to inquire into the cause of the distress. 
 
 " Farmers were ruined by thousands. One newspaper in Norwich adver- 
 tised 120 sales of stock in one day. 
 
 "In 1 89 the workhouses in some parts of the country were so crowded 
 that at times four, five, or si.x people had to sleep in one bed. 
 
 "Sheffield had 20,000 and Leeds 30,000 people dependent on the 
 rates. 
 
 " Whole families were reduced to live on bran. In Huddersfield 13,000 
 people were reduced to semi-starvation. 
 
 " In 1839-42, in Stockport, one-half the factories were closed ; 3,000 dwell- 
 ings unoccupied ; artisans were breaking stones on the road ; the Poor Rate 
 was 10s. in the pound ; and outside scraps of bacon were bought in penny- 
 worths by respectable people to moisten their potatoes. 
 
 " At Leeds the pauper stone-heap amounted to 150,000 to'nS. 
 
 " In Dorsetshire a man and his wife had for wages 2S. 6d. a week and 
 their house, and the ablest labourers had but 6s. or 7s. 
 
 " In 1839, in Devonshire, the whole of a poor man's wages would scarcely 
 produce dry bread for a family of four or five children. 
 
 " As to meat, in those times it was scarcely ever touched. 
 
 " In 1840 Lord John Russell told the House of Commons that the people 
 were in a worse condition than the negroes in the West Indies. 
 
 " In 1842, in Bolton, there were 6,995 applicants for relief to the Poor Pro- 
 tection Society, whose weekly earnings averaged only 13d. per head; 5,305 
 persons were visited, and they had only 4^6 blankets amongst them, or about 
 one blanket to every eleven perstns, 
 
 F 2
 
 68 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 "In one district in Manchester there were 2,000 families without a 
 bed. 
 
 " In Glasgow 12,000 people were on the relief funds, 
 
 "In Accrington, out of a population of 9,000, only 100 were fully 
 employed. 
 
 "The reports of the factory inspectors showed that 10 per cent, of the 
 cotton mills, and 12 per cent, of the woollen mills of Lancashire and Yorkshire 
 were standing idle, and that of the rest, only one-fourth were working full time. 
 As Cobden showed, in answer to Sir Robert Peel, the stocking-frames of 
 Nottingham were as idle as the looms of Stockport ; the glass-cutters of Stour- 
 bridge, and the glovers of Yeovil, were undergoing the same privations as the 
 potters of Stoke and the miners of Staffordshire, where 25,000 men were 
 destitute of employment. He knew of a place where 100 wedding-rings were 
 pawned in a single week to provide bread, and of another place where men and 
 women subsisted on boiled nettles, and dug up the decayed carcase of a cow 
 rather than perish of hunger. 
 
 "Such was the state of things which existed under a system which was 
 called Protection. 
 
 "In those days the population of Great Britain was about fifteen millions ; 
 it is now over thirty millions. 
 
 "In 1884, under Free Trade, there is not a man, woman, or child who i3 
 not better off than he or she would have been under the old starvation 
 lasvs. 
 
 " Labourers get higher wages than they did under these laws, and with the 
 same money they command more of the necessaries and conveniences of life 
 than they could then. 
 
 " With these facts before them, they will not listen to those who, under 
 pretence of protecting their interests, would induce them to vote for putting a 
 duty on Foreign Wheat that is, levying a Bread Tax." 
 
 Note 2. 
 
 FACTS SHOWING THE PROGRESS OF ENGLAND UNDfiR 
 FREE TRADE. 
 
 British Produce and Manuf.\ctures Exported. 
 
 
 UNDER PROTECTION'. 
 
 
 UNDER FREE TRADE. 
 
 Year. 
 1815 
 
 Total Value. 
 
 51,603,000 
 
 Per Head of 
 
 Population. 
 
 . s. d. 
 
 Year. 
 1846 
 
 Tot.-il Value. 
 
 
 52,786,000 
 
 Per Head o( 
 
 Population. 
 
 s. d. 
 ... 2 I 5 
 
 1821 
 
 ... 36,659,000 
 
 I 14 7 
 
 1856 
 
 ... 115,826,000 
 
 4 2 10 
 
 1831 
 
 37,164,000 
 
 I 10 7 
 
 1866 
 
 ... 188,917,000 
 
 ..657 
 
 1835 
 
 47,372,000* 
 
 
 
 1876 
 
 ... 200,639,000 
 
 ... 6 I 3 
 
 1842 
 
 47,284,000 
 
 ... I 15 
 
 1884 
 
 232,927,000 
 
 696 
 
 ' This increase was caused by fiscal reforms, duties upon more than 700 articles 
 being reduced and modified between 1F31 and i?3.).
 
 Pt, 
 
 The Revival of Protection. 
 
 I,, Ch. iv., Note 2. 
 
 Analysis of Imports and Exports for i 
 
 69 
 
 Living Animals, Food, Spirits, Wine, Tobacco, " 
 
 Seeds, and Oil Cake 172,104,684 
 
 Raw Materials, and other Materials of Manufactuie, 
 including Cotton, Wool, Ores, Hides, Skins, 
 Coal, &c 
 
 Leather ... 
 
 Cotton, Linen, Jute, Silk, Woollen, and other Tex- 
 tile Manufactures, including Yarns 
 
 Metals in Various Stages of Manufacture ... 
 
 Steam Engines, Machinery, Tools, Hardware, and 
 
 Cutlery ... ... (Import trifling, not stated separately 
 
 Exports of British 
 Produce and 
 Imports. Manufactures, 
 
 11,076 558 
 
 146,489,696 
 5. 41 1. 253 
 
 21,813,819 
 14,773,281 
 
 Alkali Chemicals and Drugs ... 
 
 Other Manufactured Articles ... 
 
 Miscellaneous Articles ... 
 
 Total Exports, British Produce and Manufactures 
 
 E.xports of Foreign and Colonial Produce ... 
 
 Total real value of Imports and Exports 
 
 Gold and Silver Bullion and Specie 
 
 13.469.551 
 2.016,136 
 
 109,844,281 
 37,162,152 
 
 13,051,028 
 
 7,839.516 
 
 38,468,353 
 
 232,927.575 
 62,443,715 
 
 389.774.589 295,371,290 
 20,321,853 21,999,222 
 
 2,362,093 
 23.337,202 
 3,482,521 
 
 ;^4io,096,402 ^^317,370.512 
 
 British Shipping under Protection and under Free Trade. 
 
 total tonnage belonging to 
 
 THE united KINGDO.M. 
 
 under 
 protection. 
 
 Tons. 
 1816 . 2,504,000 
 
 1845 3.123,000 
 
 Increase 619,000 
 
 under 
 free trade. 
 
 Tons. 
 1845 . 3,123,000 
 1880 . 6,574,000 
 
 Increase 3, 45 1, 000 
 
 total tonnage entered and 
 cleared with cargoes. 
 
 UNDER 
 
 protection. 
 
 r845. Tons. 
 
 British 6,617,000 
 Foreign 2,715,000 
 
 Total 9,332,000 
 
 UNDER 
 
 FREE TRADE. 
 
 1884. Tons. 
 
 British 40,156,000 
 
 Foreigni3,8f4,coo 
 
 Total 53,970,000 
 
 It was prophesied that the repeal of the Navigation Laws would ruin British 
 shipping, but it still maintains its supremacy. 
 
 Consumption of Articles of I.mpoktkd Food per Head of the 
 Population. 
 
 Under Protection, 1840. 
 Bacon and Hams, asmall fraction of ilb. 
 
 P.utter 
 
 lib. 
 
 Cheese 
 
 nearly lib. 
 
 Wheat and Flour 
 
 42Mbs. 
 
 Eggs 
 
 ... 3^ in number 
 
 Rice 
 
 nearly lib. 
 
 Sugar, raw 
 
 i5lbs. 
 
 Tea 
 
 ... nearly i.]lb. 
 
 Under Free Trade, 1883. 
 Bacon and Hams ... nearly nibs. 
 
 Butter above 7lbs. 
 
 Cheese above 5^ lbs. 
 
 Wheat and Flour ... nearly 251 lbs. 
 
 Eggs above 26 in number 
 
 Rice nearly i2{lbs. 
 
 Sugar, raw nearly 62lbs. 
 
 Tea above 4^1bs.
 
 70 
 
 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 Protection Prices, 1841. 
 
 Tea Ss. per lb. 
 
 Coffee 2S. per lb. 
 
 Sugar 9d. per lb. 
 
 Free Trade Prices, 1? 
 
 Tea 
 
 Coffee 
 
 Sugar 
 
 2S. per lb. 
 IS. per lb. 
 2d. per lb. 
 
 Social and Economic Results of Free Trade. 
 
 The number of paupers relieved in England and Wales on the istof January, 
 1849, the first year of the present statistics, was 934,419, the population being 
 17,564,000 ; on the ist of January, 1884, the number of paupers was 774,310, 
 and the population 26,951,000. In 1849 the proportion relieved to population 
 was I in 18 ; in 1884 it was i in 34. 
 
 The amount expended in poor relief per head of the population was the same 
 in 1883 as in 1845 viz., 6s. a fact largely attributable to increased humanity in 
 the treatment of the poor ; but the rateable value of the property assessed to 
 the Poor Rate increased from ^^62, 540,000 in 1841, to _^i4t,407,686 in 1883. 
 
 The total capital of the savings banks was ^^24, 474,000 in 1841 ; it was 
 ^^86,756,000 in 1884. 
 
 The total traffic receipts of railways were ^4,535,000 in 1843, and _^7i, 062,000 
 in 1883. 
 
 The total assessment of Income Tax in Great Britain in 1842 was 
 ^^251, 000,000 ; in 1882 it was ,^565, 25 1,000, 
 
 Note 3. 
 
 NORTH AMERICAN REVIEW {s'o\.(iX\., "^o. '^y May, 1890. 
 
 Extracts from "The Tariff on Trial," by Sir Richard J. Cartwright, K.C.M.G., 
 and Thomas G. Shearman. 
 
 One of the most remarkable, and in many ways one of the most important, 
 results of the Protectionist propaganda which was preached very successfully in 
 Canada in 1877 and 1878, and which was actually reduced to practice in 1879, 
 was that the good old wholesome dislike to taxation (and consequently to undue 
 and extravagant expenditure) was for the time being completely rooted up from 
 the minds of the majority. As very often happens, the indirect and secondary 
 result of a false theory is not the least mischievous. In this case it has 
 practically removed all check on expenditure by the Government. 
 
 Once imbue the minds of a large section of the people with the idea that 
 wealth can be created by imposing taxes, and it is obvious that they have no 
 longer any reason for opposing the imposition of new taxation, and that when 
 the Government wants money it need only profess that it desires to encourage 
 new industries to find a ready excuse for refilling its coffers. The present 
 Government of Canada have not been slow to learn and profit by this lesson. 
 
 Under a system of taxation for purposes of revenue only, the total expendi- 
 ture of Canada for the year 1874 was i?23, 316,316. In 1878, under the same 
 svstem, it had increased to .$23,519,301, being an increase of barely .?203,coo 
 in four years, in spite of the fact that a very large sum of money had been
 
 The Revival of Protection. 71 
 
 Pt. I., Ch. iv., Note 3.] 
 
 expended in the interval upon public works. Under a system of taxation for 
 Protection the total expenditure of Canada for the year 1889 was $36,917,834, 
 having increased by an amount of 13,398,531 in eleven years. So in 1878 the 
 actual taxation of Canada was .$17,841,938, though, as there was a deficit in 
 that year, the necessary taxation might Le placed at 19,000,000. In 1889 
 the actual taxation was 30,613,522, being an increase of 11,613,522, taking 
 the necessary taxation (so-called) of 1878 as a basis, 
 
 ** 
 
 Unfortunately there is a yet darker shade to the picture. What the result 
 may have been in other countries I cannot say, but in Canada (over and above 
 the extravagant expenditure above referred to) one most important consequence 
 of the introduction of the Protective system has been at the same time to make 
 provision for a large and permanent corruption fund, to be applied with the 
 effect and regularity of a machine to debauching the Press and Electorate as 
 occasion serves. 
 
 It is probable that this result is inherent in the system. Speaking with 
 knowledge, I say deliberately that I can conceive no more effectual method of 
 installing and intrenching corruption in the politics of any country than to give 
 a large number of active, energetic business men frequently persons possessed 
 of great wealth, and almost always having a large control of money a direct 
 pecuniary interest in controlling legislation and in supporting any particular 
 political party. Of course they will do it, and there is but one way in which 
 they can do it. Being subsidised, they must subsidise in return. It is quite 
 impossible to pause to point out the innumerable ways in which this corrupt 
 system works for evil at all times and periods ; but I will give one notable ex- 
 ample. Shortly before one of our General Elections the present Premier of the 
 Dominion (Sir John Macdonald), being pressed for funds, deliberately sum- 
 moned some eighty or ninety of the principal Protected manufacturers in Canada 
 to meet him at the Queen's Hotel in Toronto ; and then and there, in good set 
 phrase, told them that as the Government had helped them to enrich them- 
 selves at the public expense, they in return must help the Government to keep 
 in place ; nor did he dismiss them till they had assessed themselves in a large 
 amount for the purpose of providing a fund wherewith to corrupt the electors 
 of the Dominion. 
 
 * * * * * 
 
 To put the matter briefly, the results of the introduction of the Protective 
 system in Canada have been : 
 
 1. To remove all check on the expenditure of the Government, and to 
 encourage a reckless extravagance on their part which has resulted in an annual 
 expenditure for Federal purposes of nearly 50 per cent, more (after making all 
 deductions), for a population of less thanyf zr millions, than the sum required by 
 the United States for the like objects when their population was over tzccnty 
 millions. 
 
 2. To Fvstematise and intensify the tendency (always so perilous to the 
 welfare of representative Governments) to use corrupt means for the purpose of 
 influencing the Press and the Electorate, and to make it the direct pecuniary 
 interest of a very active and influential class to provide a regular and large fund 
 for such purposes.
 
 72 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 3. To aggravate and accelerate the tendency to accumulate large fortunes 
 in few hands, and at the same time to increase the indebtedness and depreciate 
 the value of the property owned by the mass of the community, more especially 
 in the case of the agricultural class. 
 
 4. To favour the growth of a few large towns at the expense of the smaller 
 ones and of the rural population, which latter has been reduced to an absolutely 
 stationary condition over very large portions of the Dominion, in spite of a 
 large (alleged) immigration and of the fact that much new territory has been 
 thrown open.
 
 fart XI. 
 
 PREPARING THE ARENA. 
 
 CHAPTER I. 
 
 DEFINITION OF FREE TRADE. 
 
 I. The discussion which has been carried through the first 
 four chapters upon the nature and the causes and the sig- 
 nificance of modern Protectionism ought, at least, to have 
 suggested the reflection that there is nothing new in the Pro- 
 tectionist doctrine as it is preached in America and the British 
 Colonies. These countries have not been perverted through 
 the discovery of any new economic doctrine, but simply from 
 indifference to the old, under the stress of new political 
 conditions. Men who have no knowledge either by personal 
 experience or through books of the appalling misery of 
 England under its Protective policy have accepted in an un- 
 thinking way the general tenets of Free Trade ; but they have 
 not reasoned for themselves upon the application of these 
 tenets, nor traced them to the facts on which they rest. Con- 
 sequently many inhabitants of a young country have come to 
 think that Free Trade is something peculiarly British and be- 
 longing to the Old World, with which they themselves need have 
 nothing to do. They sec that all the conditions of production 
 are different from what they arc in Europe; that instead cf 
 labour being abundant and land scarce, labour is scarce and 
 land abundant ; that capital is cfear and wages are liigh, where 
 in older countries capital is cheap and wages are low. Under 
 such circumstances they are inclined to take a merely academic 
 interest in discussions on Free Trade and to lend a rcadv car
 
 74 Industrial Freedom, 
 
 to those who tell them that the old truths have no application 
 to their new conditions. 
 
 It is therefore desirable, even at the risk of going over 
 often-trodden ground, to re-state the economic argument 
 in favour of Free Trade, in order to show that in all its 
 bearings it has the same application to the circumstances 
 of all countries. 
 
 2. But first let us be sure in what sense we are using the 
 term Free Trade. 
 
 In its political and controversial sense Free Trade simply- 
 mean s the absence of duties of a Protective character. 
 
 It is sometimes used, in a wider sense, to denote the absence 
 of all Customs duties ; but this is not the meaning which it 
 bears when it is used in opposition to the term "Protection." 
 In that sense it is simply the absence of duties of a Protective 
 character. 
 
 It is no mere pedantry to insist upon this simple definition, 
 because much of the confusion and heat of the controversy 
 between Free Traders and Protectionists arises from neglecting 
 to remember it. 
 
 How often, for example, in New South Wales, have we not 
 heard Protectionists maintain their arguments against the 
 differential railway rates ! And in England trades unions have 
 been frequently declared, even by those who ought to have 
 known better, to be a violation of the principles of Free 
 Trade. Now diff'erential railway rates and trades unions may 
 be in themselves good things or bad things ; but neither the 
 one nor the other has anything to do with the imposition of 
 Customs duties. It would be just as logical to denounce them 
 in the name of Gothic architecture as in the name of Protection 
 or Free Trade ! Of course, if the term Free Trade is used in 
 an altogether different sense, and extended to mean "a general 
 principle of non-interference in industrial matters either by the 
 Government or by organised public opinion," the complaints to
 
 Preparing the Arena. 75 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. i., \ 3.] 
 
 which reference has been made are logical enough. But not 
 only is the term not generally used in this wide sense, but it 
 would be impossible to carry on an argument upon the fiscal 
 controversy if the meaning of the words " Free Trade " were so 
 indefinite and large. 
 
 3. Cobden, with his usual sagacity, perceived this long ago, 
 when replying to the argument (which is one that seems to 
 exercise a strange fascination over a certain class of minds) 
 that because the commerce of no country is absolutely free, it 
 is justifiable to make the commerce of any particular country 
 less free than it is, he used the following words : " We do not 
 want to touch duties simply for revenue, but we want to prevent 
 certain parties from having a revenue which is of benefit to 
 themselves, but advantage to none else. On the contrary, what 
 we seek for is the improvement of Her Majesty's revenue ; 
 what we wish to gain is that improvement. We say that your 
 monopoly gives you a temporary advantage a temporary, not 
 a permanent advantage, and that you thereby cripple the 
 resources of the revenue." ^ 
 
 And again: "One of your candidates actually says that 
 Free Trade means the abolition of all Customs House 
 duties. We have said, thousands of times, that our object 
 is not to take away the Queen's officers from the Customs 
 House, but to take away those officers who sit at the 
 receipt of custom to take tithe and toll for the benefit of 
 peculiar classes."- 
 
 4. The practical importance of recognising that Free 
 Trade is not inconsistent with a tariff for revenue purposes has 
 become greater by reason of the growing political power of 
 those who earnestly advocate the abolition of all indirect taxes. 
 Cobden himself belonged to this party, and his last political 
 
 1 Mouse of Commons, May 15th, 1843. 
 - I-ondon, Oct. 13th, 1843.
 
 76 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 utterance was in favour of its views ; but Cobden was pre- 
 eminently a man of practical sagacity, who recognised, as the 
 more far-seeing members of the single-tax party ought also to 
 recognise, that in politics only one thing can be done at a time. 
 It is idle to rail against revenue duties when an active agitation 
 is on foot to replace them by Protective duties ; and it can 
 only encumber the supporters of Free Trade to have to fight in 
 a double controversy. 
 
 It cannot be too clearly recognised that the present struggle 
 between Free Traders and Protectionists is being fought upon 
 a single issue. We are not now discussing the respective 
 merits of direct and indirect taxation, but we are endeavouring 
 to clear the ground for such a discussion by beating out of the 
 field those who maintain as the cardinal maxim of their creed 
 that duties of a Protective character must exist. Until this 
 belief is destroyed, it is idle to argue the larger question 
 whether there should be any Customs duties at all. Protection 
 is wholly inconsistent with direct taxation ; Free Trade is not 
 inconsistent with it, but it stands apart as an independent fiscal 
 principle. 
 
 But if it is important to bear in mind that the question at 
 issue is not between direct and indirect taxation, it is even more 
 important to remember that we are not disputing about rival 
 principles of government. Free Trade, as opposed to Pro- 
 tection, in the sense in which it has been defined, is not 
 a principle of government, but a principle of sound finance. 
 It is a commercial expedient for securing the easiest inter- 
 change of commodities. A discussion of Free Trade need 
 not, therefore, raise the question whether individualism ought 
 to prevail in all industrial matters to the exclusion of any 
 direction or control either by Government or by organised 
 opinion, but only the small question whether Customs duties 
 ought to be of a revenue or a protective character. If poli- 
 ticians and newspaj)er writers would once perceive within 
 what narrow limits this controversy should be waged, there
 
 Preparing the Arena. 77 
 
 Pt. n., Ch. i!.,5 I.] 
 
 would be less exaggeration in the language upon either 
 side, and the working of either policy would be better 
 understood.^ 
 
 CHAPTER 11. 
 
 DIVISION OF THE ARGUMENTS INTO CLASSES ECONOMIC AND 
 POLITICAL. 
 
 I. It is of the highest importance in the fiscal controversy 
 to keep in mind a division of the arguments into two classes 
 the political, and the economic. The omission to observe this 
 fundamental distinction has been the source of much confusion 
 and ill-feeling. 
 
 No one can read discussions about a tariff without being 
 struck by the tendency, which exists on both sides, to under- 
 estimate either the intelligence or honesty of opponents. There 
 would seem at first sight to be no reason in the nature of things 
 why Customs duties should not be discussed with as much 
 calmness as any other form of taxation. Yet no one will deny 
 that this is not the case. Probate duties, stamp duties, house 
 duties, taxes upon income, taxes upon land, are gloomy subjects 
 of discussion in the most exciting times ; but let a word be 
 dropped about an increase or reduction in the tariff, and sober 
 men on either side are smitten with an almost fanatical frenzy. 
 
 1 The necessity for keeping strictly to tliis definition of Free Trade is 
 illustrated by a common Protectionist argument, which seems to be used partly 
 by way of exhortation to Protectionists and partly by way of depreciating Free 
 Traders. 
 
 The argument is this : " No country," it is said, "is a Free Trade 
 country. Even England levies Customs duties." 
 
 It is dificult to sec how the violation of a principle in one point is an 
 nrgument in favour of further violations, nor how the imperfection of a Free 
 Trade system justifies its total ovcrthrowal. Yet such is the enthusiasm of some 
 advocates of free exchange (who, it may be remarked, generally vote with Pro- 
 tectionists), that because our commerce is not absolutely free, they arc prepared 
 out of pure regard for consistency to make it less free than it is !
 
 7 8 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 Free Traders consider the unwillingness to accept what appears 
 to them to be elementary and axiomatic truths, demonstrable 
 as any proposition in Euclid, to be a sign of perverseness or 
 stupidity ; while Protectionists do not hesitate to attribute the 
 most sinister motives to all the advocates of free exchange. 
 
 This curious state of affairs is no doubt partly owing to the 
 fact that fiscal arguments are still enveloped in the atmosphere 
 of party controversy, in which the doctrines of Free Trade 
 were first carried into practice ; but it is also, in no small 
 degree, the result of a failure to perceive that fiscal contro- 
 versies involve several distinct issues, which require to be dealt 
 with by different classes of arguments. Thus, whatever the 
 cause may be, it is quite certain that, after years of controversy, 
 the issue is no clearer than it was, nor the end nearer. Each 
 party is still fighting in the air, and neither meets the other's 
 arguments. 
 
 2. One way to make an end of this confusion is to state 
 the point which is at issue. 
 
 Neither Protection nor Free Trade can be discussed as 
 a purely economic question. Each policy involves political as 
 well as economic considerations. Each may therefore be 
 supported by political as well as economic arguments. 
 
 Free Traders, as a rule, confine their attention to the 
 economic arguments that is to say, they demonstrate that 
 Protection causes a diminution of material wealth, and are 
 then content ; Protectionists, on the other hand, without openly 
 ignoring economic conclusions, rest their advocacy almost en- 
 tirely upon considerations of politics. 
 
 Now, it is true that economic and political considerations 
 are in practical life inextricably interblended ; and that no one 
 can form a sound opinion whether Protection or Free Trade is 
 good for a particular country without taking both into account. 
 Nevertheless, it does not require much reflection to see that the 
 two considerations must be kept apart in argument ; and that one
 
 Preparing the Arena. 79 
 
 Pt. IL.Ch. ii., 5 3.] 
 
 of two disputants can never convince the other if each is 
 looking at a different side of the shield. 
 
 What, then, is the broad distinction between the economic 
 and the political aspects of the fiscal controversy ? 
 
 It is this : Viewed as a question to be settled by economic 
 arguments, the test of either policy is its result upon the pro- 
 duction of wealth using the term " production " in its largest 
 sense to include exchange and every other form of wealth- 
 creation. If it increases the aggregate of wealth possessed by 
 a country, a fiscal policy is economically good ; if it lessens the 
 aggregate, it is economically bad. 
 
 Viewed, however, as a question of politics, the test of 
 a fiscal policy is not so simple, because it depends upon the 
 determination of the question, " What is best for the well-being 
 of the nation as a whole?" Some politicians, for instance, 
 may desire to divide the aggregate of wealth among a greater 
 variety of industries, even at the risk of lessening the total 
 amount to be divided ; others, again, may have such a dread 
 of the interruption of commerce by war as to wish their 
 country to be independent of all foreign supplies, and with this 
 end in view may be indifferent to the quantity of wealth pro- 
 duced or the cost of its production. And in many other ways 
 political considerations may be brought forward to override 
 conclusions of economic reasoning. " .' . " 
 
 3. It will accordingly be conceded at the outset of this 
 argument that no mere economic demonstration is able to solve 
 the fiscal problem. 
 
 The welfare of a nation is composed of many elements, 
 and the paths towards it are extremely numerous, so that many 
 aspects of a political question must of necessity lie beyond the 
 range of any purely economic argument. 
 
 Everyone who has had to come to a reasoned conclusion 
 upon political questions must have felt himself pressed by these 
 considerations. Even the most extreme Free Trader using
 
 So Industrial Frredom, 
 
 the term in its wide Spencerian sense, to mean an advocate of 
 universal and unrestricted competition would hesitate before 
 he allowed a foreign line of steamers to have the exclusive 
 carriage of 'the ocean mails between Great Britain and her 
 Colonies. Yet it might be that the foreign company wou'd 
 carry the mails for nothing, while an English company would 
 charge a high price for the same work. It is obvious that mere 
 economic considerations hardly enter into a case of this kind. 
 
 Another familiar instance of the overriding of economic by 
 political considerations is offered by the salutary practice of 
 subsidising ocean-going merchant steamers of a high class on 
 condition that they comply with certain requisites which will 
 enable them in time of war to take their place as cruisers in 
 protecting commerce. An incidental result of these subsidies 
 may be to keep up freights by excluding competition, and to 
 that extent they will be harmful to commerce. But neverthe- 
 less the nation may gain from them more than it loses, because 
 every such subsidised vessel is in reality part of the naval reserve. 
 Consequently, if the net result be that a larger sum is saved on 
 the naval estimates than the total cost of the subsidies in- 
 cluding in their cost the indirect losses which they cause to 
 merchants and producers the transaction is on balance 
 profitable. 
 
 Occasions must also arise in the history of a nation when 
 motives of humanity, regard for safety, or other urgent reasons, 
 compel wise rulers to subordinate considerations of economic?. 
 The Irish famine was such an occasion. Cobden thought 
 that another had arisen in his lifetime owing to the congested 
 state of population in tlie English towns. He proposed to 
 correct this consequence of bad land laws by employing the 
 Queen's ships in the free transport of emigrants from Great 
 Britain to the Colonies. Whether this temporary measure 
 of alleviation would have been successful is open to argument, 
 but there is no inconsistency between such a proposal and a 
 most vehement oppo :it!on to Protective taxes.
 
 Preparing the Arena, 8i 
 
 Pt. ir., Ch. ii., \\.\ 
 
 4. Let us now apply these distinctions to arguments about 
 the tariff. 
 
 The economic argument which will be developed at length 
 in later chapters of this work is exclusively directed to a con- 
 sideration of the effect of Free Trade upon the production and 
 accumulation of material wealth. It starts with the assumptions 
 of the Individualist school of political economy as to the 
 strength and universality of the desire for wealth, and as to the 
 existence of an ever-active competition between equal units. 
 It then proceeds to show that under natural conditions trade 
 will develop according to the requirements of a country, with- 
 out any encourngement from Protective tariffs ; that every in- 
 dustry which rests upon Protection must divert labour and 
 capital from the more to the less profitable employments, and 
 that, consequently. Protection must be less favourable than 
 Free Trade to the accumulation of material wealth. 
 
 The political argument passes by these economic con- 
 clusions, and, ignoring the effect of tariffs upon the production 
 of wealth, considers them as means of securing a more equal 
 distribution of advantages and comforts among the labouring 
 classes, and of encouraging the developement of latent national 
 resources. 
 
 If the Protectionist argument were stated with reference to 
 economic conclusions which is seldom or never the case it 
 would read something as follows : "We admit your demonstra- 
 tion to be correct. We allow that under Free Trade wealth is 
 produced most rapidly and accumulates in the largest quanti- 
 ties ; but we say that Protection gives other advantages which 
 Free Trade does not give, and which more than compensate a 
 country for its lessened wealth." 
 
 This is a fair and logical position if it can be held. Un- 
 fortunately Free Traders are not always willing to attack it with 
 any but economic weapons. Yet it is idle to expect to make 
 much impression wiih the weapons of economics upon the 
 mind of a man who is impervious to all considerations except 
 
 G
 
 82 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 those which are poUtical. Free Traders, therefore, if they are to 
 make converts, must go beyond their economic demonstrations 
 and fight the battle on the ground which the Protectionists 
 themselves have chosen. 
 
 The question then will be " Whether there is any good 
 reason for the opinion that Protection, though it reduces wealth 
 and lessens national productiveness, adds to a nation elements 
 of strength and happiness which greater riches could not give." 
 
 In order to answer this it will be necessary to consider 
 separately each of the advantages which Protection is sup- 
 posed to confer. 
 
 If as a result of the inquiry it shall be found that these ad- 
 vantages are either non-existent or illusory cadit qucestio ; but, 
 on the other hand, it will by no means follow that the question 
 must be answered in favour of Protection, even although it be 
 found that some substantial advantages are given by that 
 policy. The only consequence of such a discovery will be to 
 necessitate a further inquiry, " Whether Protection does not 
 bring with it certain political or social disadvantages which far 
 outweigh the benefits which it may be supposed to confer." 
 
 Whenever political considerations enter into the inquiry, the 
 question in every case whether it relates to a whole tariff or 
 to a single duty will always be one of a balance of advan- 
 tages. The absolutely best is never possible in politics. Every 
 political measure, whether it relates to industry or not, must 
 steer a middle course between the evils which it remedies and 
 those which it creates. The utmost certainty a statesman can 
 obtain will rest upon a reasonable hope that he is not making 
 a mistake. He will assure himself of this in the first instance 
 by evidence ; and where evidence fails, by reference to 
 principles and experience. But even with all precautions, 
 the wise application of scientific conclusions to the facts of 
 daily life must be to a large extent the result of empirical 
 knowledge. When it is otherwise and when it is possible to 
 frame exact rules for the constitution and working of political
 
 Preparing the Arena. 83 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. ii. t 5.] 
 
 societies human nature will have become less variable or more 
 accurately known. 
 
 5. Free Traders have, accordingly, to prove two points : 
 They must show first, that Free Trade is more efficient than 
 Protection as a means of increasing national productiveness ; 
 and, secondly, that it is more conducive to the general well- 
 being of the nation as a whole. They must prove the economic 
 issue by economic reasoning, and defeat the political objections 
 which Protectionists may urge to the economic conclusions 
 by political reasoning. 
 
 It is sometimes, however, contended that the political con- 
 siderations should be dealt with in the first instance, and that 
 economic reasoning ought only to be brought into play when 
 political arguments have failed. The ground of this contention 
 is the paramount importance of the political considerations 
 which are involved in the tariff controversy. 
 
 There is no doubt that these considerations are paramount 
 to anything which can be urged on purely economic grounds, 
 since the right distribution of wealth and the due development 
 of national powers are of far greater importar.ce to a State than 
 the mere possession of riches. It does not, however, follow 
 that the economic argument upon the tariff can be subordinated 
 to the political. The contrary is the case. 
 
 In the first place, it happens that most of the political argu- 
 ments in favour of Protection tacitly assume an economic 
 basis that is to say, they really depend upon the assumption 
 that Protection is more favourable than Free Trade to national 
 productiveness. 
 
 A Free Trader says that a high tariff must lessen wealth. 
 The Protectionist replies that the effect of a tariff on the pro- 
 duction and accumulation of wealth must not be considered by 
 itself ; that the real object of inquiry is as to its effect upon 
 the national welfare. Free Traders will accede to this state- 
 ment of the case ; but having done so they are entitled to call 
 
 G 2
 
 84 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 for some evidence, even if proof be not forthcoming, that 
 a policy which increases the aggregate of wealth can in any way 
 diminish the general happiness. When once it is proved or 
 admitted that Free Trade is more favourable than Protection 
 to the production of material wealth, a strong presumption 
 arises that it is also more conducive to national welfare. This 
 presumption may be overcome ; but while it stands, it puts a 
 heavy burden of proof upon Protectionist shoulders. If the 
 sum to be divided among all citizens is increased by Free 
 Trade, the share of each is not likely to be diminished by an in- 
 crease in the dividend. No doubt it may be shown that an 
 increase in the aggregate of wealth gives rise to inequalities of 
 distribution, but no one is entitled to assume this result. 
 Therefore, although for purposes of controversy it is necessary 
 to consider all Protectionist arguments even when they are 
 mutually destructive such a concession ought not to be in- 
 terpreted as a waiver of the demand that Protectionists should 
 first show " Ho\v and why a policy which increases wealth 
 injures the national welfare." 
 
 There is also another reason why the economic argument 
 should take priority. 
 
 Suppose that each party agree that the final test of any 
 measure is its effect upon the national welfare, still its effect 
 upon the production and accumulation of material wealth must 
 be considered first, because there is no available test of national 
 well-being except material prosperity. The only known 
 measure of national progress or retrogression is increase or 
 decrease of material wealth. No one suggests that this is a 
 perfect measure, or that it supplies a final test, but it is the 
 first test, and none otiier can be used without it. 
 
 Suppose, for instance, that Free Traders accept the standard 
 proposed by Protectionists, that the comfort and happiness of 
 a nation is greatest when its wealth is most equally divided 
 among all its citizens, so that the standard of comfort among 
 the producing classes is highest, still the question will be,
 
 PkEPARlKG THE AreNA. 85 
 
 Pi. n., Ch. ;i., if.] 
 
 " What have the producing classes got to spend ? " It is true 
 that their standard of Hving can be tested by statistics of crime, 
 education, and disease, and is not always indicated by the rate 
 of wages. But all these tests are, in their final analysis, in <o 
 far as an analysis of such things is possible, dependent on the 
 material prosperity of the classes with reference to which they 
 are used. A poor man may be virtuous and well educated ; 
 but a virtuous and well-educated class of wage-earners is always 
 a symptom of a high relative standard of material comfort. 
 Consequently after all political arguments on the tariff question 
 have spent their force, and even before one of them can be 
 applied, the economic argument must be considered ; because 
 the production of material wealth is both a necessary founda- 
 tion and the only available test of progress in national well- 
 being. Accordingly, whenever the political considerations 
 which are urged against the economic conclusions, either ex- 
 pressly or impliedly assume that Protection increases national 
 wealth, then the economic argument in favour of Free Trade 
 has first to be disposed of. 
 
 6. It may be thought that these concessions to the Pro- 
 tectionist side of the controversy materially weaken the force 
 of the economic argument in favour of Free Trade. 
 
 This belief, as will be seen later in these pages, rests upon 
 a misai)prehension of the true nature of the fiscal controversy, 
 which, although it must be affected to a large extent by con- 
 siderations of politics, is yet determined in its final issue by the 
 effect of either policy upon the material wealth-producing power 
 of the community in question. A correct perception of this 
 is of so much importance to a right handling of the arguments 
 on either side that it will be desirable to clear the ground still 
 further before making use of them. 
 
 A\'e shall see, as the lines of the controversy become 
 clearer, that the distinction which has been insisted upon in 
 the preceding pages between the ecoroniic and political argu-
 
 86: Industrial Freedom. 
 
 ments is very seldom regarded. We shall find also that when 
 it is regarded in name it is ignored in practice, and that the 
 attempts which have been made to evade the sledge-hammer 
 blows of economic reasoning by the construction of a new 
 theory of economics have really ended in throwing a few 
 political catchwords such as " national welfare," " the comfort 
 and happiness of the people," " national development," and 
 the like into a large phrase, and pretending thus to have 
 obtained a new basis for a scientific system. But this is to 
 anticipate the remaining chapters of this part, which will be 
 devoted to an inquiry into the relation of economics to 
 politics as a whole, and to a tariff in particular, in order to 
 understand better how an economic argument upon the tariff 
 is likely to be modified by that class of political considerations 
 which peculiarly affect fiscal problems. Next an attempt will 
 be made to ascertain whether it is possible to frame an 
 economic defence of a Protective tariff upon any other basis 
 than that upon which the Free Trade argument is usually 
 erected. Finally, this being done, the economic and the 
 political aspect of the controversy will each be separately con- 
 sidered. 
 
 At present it is sufficient to bear in mind that if the com- 
 batants would really grapple with each other which they 
 seldom, if ever, do at present they must meet economic 
 arguments with economic arguments, and political with political. 
 And if Protectionists should say that they have all along been 
 willing to adopt this course, and that none of their recognised 
 leaders attempt to defend Protection upon economic grounds 
 as the term " economic " is understood by the followers of 
 Adam Smith the answer is, that they are right in their state- 
 ment, but that the leaders cannot control the rank and file of 
 Protectionist voters. No doubt most Protectionist writers 
 admit that Free Trade is unassailable if the postulates and 
 definitions of Individualist political economy are once admitted 
 this is whnt the unlearned voter means when he savs, "Free
 
 Preparing the Arena. 87 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. iii., \ I.] 
 
 Trade is good in theory, but of no use in practice " but even 
 learned writers, after making this admission, often drop into 
 vulgar errors, and talk about " the excess of imports," or " the 
 drain of gold," or the need for " keeping the money in the 
 country," or some other catch-phrase, which has no mean- 
 ing apart from the arguments and conclusions of that form of 
 economic science which they have openly disavowed. Thus, 
 then, is the necessity great for clear distinctions, if we would 
 avoid confusion in this very dusty fight. 
 
 CHAPTER III. 
 
 ECONOMICS AND TOLITICS, OR THE VALUE OF THE ECONOMIC 
 ARGUMENT. 
 
 I. The last two chapters ought to have disclosed the object 
 of the controversy, and the lines upon which it has to be 
 conducted. The time, however, is not yet arrived for entering 
 upon the argument. The ground must first be cleared of 
 those objectors who insist that economic argument is, from its 
 nature, of no value in a practical discussion. The next four 
 chapters will, accordingly, be devoted to considering the 
 limitations which attach to any economic argument, and to an 
 inquiry into the application of the economic argument in 
 favour of Free Trade to a tariff controversy. In other words, 
 we must see whether those Protectionists are right who object 
 to the use of any economic conclusions in a discussion about 
 Protection. 
 
 This objection takes a double form. 
 
 First, it is said that economic assumptions are of such an 
 abstract character, and so far removed from the facts of life, 
 that they can never have much importance for practical men ;
 
 88 Industrial Freedom 
 
 and, secondly, it is denied that the tariff is in any aspect an 
 economic question. 
 
 The latter of these objections plainly depends upon the 
 question whether the political arguments in favour of Protection 
 not only override the economic argument in favour of Free 
 Trade, but are wholly independent of economic considera- 
 tions. This can only be determined after each of the 
 political arguments have been considered, which will be done 
 in the later chapters of this work.^ 
 
 The first objection, however, plainly strikes at the root of 
 all economic discussions, by denying the utility of political 
 economy in affording any aid to the comprehension of 
 practical problems. It will accordingly be necessary, even 
 at the risk of covering familiar ground, to examine briefly 
 into the relation between politics and economics, as it is 
 understood by those who claim to defend Free Trade by 
 economic conclusions. 
 
 2. Political economy, as the term is understood in 
 England, rests upon two fundamental assumptions viz.. 
 First, that the universal and dominant instinct of human 
 nature, in its relation to non-human and material objects, is to 
 endeavour to satisfy desires by the least possible expenditure 
 of time and labour; and, secondly, that the struggle for 
 existence in the industrial world, as it is at present organised, 
 necessitates competition, and that the competing units 
 whether the unit be an individual or a group of individuals 
 are equal. 
 
 Starting from these assumptions, political economy attempts 
 a scientific investigation into the influences which affect the 
 production and the distribution of wealth. Sometimes the 
 inquiry into the influences which affect the exchange of wealth 
 is made a third division of the science; but, properly speaking, 
 
 ' Sec infra, Part III., Chapters 6 and 7.
 
 Preparing the Arena 89 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. Hi., \ 3.] 
 
 exchange is a method of production, similar in its action, with 
 regard to completed articles of commerce, to the method of 
 division of employment with regard to articles in process of 
 completion. Exchange is, in fact, only a manifestation on a 
 large scale of a well-known method of facilitating production 
 by the co-operation of different sorts of labour. 
 
 Political economy is thus a formal science, which occupies 
 towards the art of politics much the same relation as the 
 formal science of jurisprudence occupies towards the art of 
 legislation. Its principal function is analysis. It analyses, first 
 distinguishing the action of each the three factors (land, 
 labour, and capital) which co-operate in the production of 
 wealth ; and secondly, it analyses the causes which affect 
 the distribution of wealth after it has been produced. In 
 every process, however, its method rests upon the assumptions 
 already mentioned ; and its conclusions derive their practical 
 value from the nearness or remoteness of the assumed con- 
 ditions to actual facts. 
 
 This is the point of attack. 
 
 Political economy in the sense of the English or In- 
 dividualist school, which owes its paternity to Adam Smith 
 is declared to be an idle study, for two reasons : Eirst, it is 
 said, " Its fundamental assumption is untrue, since men are 
 not, in fact, dominated by the desire for gain." 
 
 Secondly, it is said, " Even if the desire for wealth is 
 universal and supreme, the term ' wealth ' is incapable of 
 definition."' 
 
 There is, unquestionably, much truth in both these 
 criticisms. The question, however, is whether they destroy 
 the value of economic conclusions. Let us examine them in 
 detail. 
 
 3. The first of these objections is expressed with great 
 force and lucidity by Mr. Henry Sidgwick in a passage of his 
 " Political Economy," which is mucli relied upon by an able
 
 90 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 opponent of economics whose work will have to be considered 
 later in some detail, Mr. H. M. Hoyt.^ The passage is in 
 these terms : 
 
 "The first and most fundamental [assumption] is that all 
 persons engaged in industry will, in selling or lending goods, or 
 contracting to render services, endeavour, cater is paribus, to get as 
 much wealth as they can in return for the commodity they offer. 
 This is often more briefly expressed by saying that political 
 economy assumes the universality and unlimitedness of the desire 
 for wealth. Against this assumption it has been argued that men 
 do not, for the most part, desire wealth in general, but this or that 
 particular kind of wealth ; in fact, that ' the desire of wealth ' is 
 an abstraction] compounding a great variety of different and 
 heterogeneous motives, which have been mistaken for a single 
 
 homogeneous force There are other things obtainable by 
 
 labour, besides wealth, which mankind generally, if not universally, 
 desire, such as power and reputation ; and it is further undeniable 
 that men are largely induced to render services of various kinds 
 by family affection, friendship, compassion, national and local 
 patriotism, and other kinds of esprit de corps, and other motives. 
 The amount of unpaid work which is done from such motives in 
 modern civilised society, forms a substantial part of the whole, 
 and political economists are, perhaps, fairly chargeable with an 
 omission in making no express reference to such work with the 
 exception of the mutual services rendered by husbands and wives, 
 by parents and children." 
 
 4. The soundness of this criticism may be at once ad- 
 mitted. But what does it amount to ? Simply to this : That 
 many matters lie beyond the ken of economic science, and 
 that of those that come within it, none can be completely 
 dealt with in every aspect. But to admit that great caution 
 must be exercised in applying economic conclusions to the 
 facts of industrial life is very different from denying that they 
 
 ' " Protection versus Free Trade. The Scientific Validity and I'"conomic 
 Operation of Defensive Duties in the United St ites." By Henry M. Iloyt. 
 3rd Edit. New York : D. Appleton & Co. 1886. 
 
 It must be remembered that the term "political economy" in this and 
 the following chapter always means English or Individualist political 
 economy,
 
 Preparing the Arena. 91 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. iii., \ 4.] 
 
 can have a practical value under any circumstances. As a 
 rule, those writers who, like Mr. Sidgwick, are most keenly 
 alive to the imperfections which are charged against political 
 economy, are the very men who insist most strongly on its 
 practical advantages. Granted that men desire other things 
 than wealth, and that this desire is in some instances stronger 
 than the desire of wealth, this does not invalidate the assump- 
 tion that when men are engaged in acquiring wealth, their desire 
 for it is universal and unlimited. 
 
 The economic man, whose structure has been the butt of 
 much cheap derision, is admittedly an abstraction moved by one 
 idea ; and in real life men do, no doubt, move and have their 
 being in a multitude of other motives and desires. Love of 
 country, family or reputation, pride,'comradeship, artistic im- 
 pulses, charily, politeness, loyalty to class or tradition all 
 these are influences which are unquestionably more potent in 
 many cases than the desire of gain. But have any of them the 
 same effect upon the production of material wealth ? Pro- 
 tectionist critics of political economy appear to forget that 
 economics only profess to deal with material wealth. Of wliat 
 use is it, then, to point out that certain motives impel men to 
 neglect wealth, if there is one powerful and universal motive 
 which urges men to its production and acquisition ? So far as 
 motives of the former class prevail, by so much will the scope 
 of economic science be diminished ; but wherever wealtli 
 is not neglected, but pursued, there an example is presented 
 of the operation of the economic motive. It would be absurd 
 to apply economic tests to the decision of questions of con- 
 science or duty ; but it does not therefore follow that it 
 is absurd to eliminate all motives but the desire for profit, when 
 we are treating of men's conduct in trading with each other. 
 Suppose, for the sake of argument, that an individual here and 
 there starts a business from philanthropic motives, so that he is 
 pecuniarily indifferent to its success or failure, can such a rare 
 instance justify the statement that men are not as a rule
 
 92 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 dominated by the desire for gain when they enter upon corr- 
 mercial enterprises ? When men are brought into a direct 
 relation with the tangible material objects which we call 
 " wealth," either by way of producing them for others or of 
 acquiring them for themselves, what motive has a wider range 
 or a more powerful influence than self-interest? Certainly, 
 there can be no valid objection in such a case to eliminating 
 all other motives for the purposes of scientific study, provided 
 that due caution is exercised in applying any conclusions 
 arrived at by this process. And the test of applicability will 
 be the nearness or remoteness of the assumption to the facts of 
 the particular case. Where self-interest dominates, economic 
 conclusions apply; where it is overridden by other motives, 
 they must be corrected. AVhat, then, is the applicability of 
 economic conclusions to a discussion about tariffs ? This is a 
 subject which it will be convenient to defer until the next 
 chapter, in order that we may continue our examination into 
 the objections which are urged against the applicability of 
 economics to any practical case. 
 
 5. The second objection to the use of political economy 
 in practical discussions is that the term "wealth" is incapable 
 either of analysis or definition. Here, again, the criticism is 
 best expressed in the words of a Free Trade economist of high 
 repute, the late Mr. Walter Bagehot : 
 
 "Just as this science [polilical economy] takes an abstract and 
 one-sided view of man, who is one of its subjects, so it also takes an 
 abstract and one-sided view of wcaUh, which is its other subject. 
 Wealth is infinitely various ; as the wants of human nature are 
 almost innumerable, so the kinds of wealth are various. \Yhy 
 man wants so many things is a great subject, fit for inquiry ; 
 which of them it would be wise for men to want more of, and which 
 of them it would be wise to want less of, are also great subjects, equally 
 fit. But with these subjects political economy does not deal at all. 
 It leaves the first to the metaphysician, who has to explain, if he 
 can, the origin and order of human wants ; and the second to the 
 moralist, who is to decide to the best of his ability which of these
 
 Preparia-g the Arena. 93 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. ili., J 6.] 
 
 tastes are to be encouraged and when, which to be discouraged 
 and when. The only peculiarity of wealth with which the economist 
 is concerned is its differentia specijiea ihai which makes it wealth. 
 . . . . He regards a pot of beer and a picture, a book of 
 religion and a pack of cards, as all equally wealth, and therefore, 
 for his purpose, equally worthy of regard." 
 
 6. Thus the defect in the scope of political economy 
 which Mr. Ruskin believes himself to have discovered was 
 not after all unknown or disregarded by the professors of 
 the science ! It is not, however, quite correct to say, as Mr. 
 Bagehot does, that an economist does not concern himself with 
 the sort of wealth which is produced, or the uses to which 
 wealth is put. It is true that wealth is defined simply by 
 reference to its possession of an exchange value, and that 
 whatever possesses an exchange value is, economically speaking, 
 " wealth ; " but the nature and uses of wealth are important 
 considerations in dealing with the methods of production. It 
 certainly falls within the purview of the economist to discuss 
 how the accumulated wealth of a society can be most effectively 
 employed in the creation of more wealth. 
 
 Nevertheless, the criticism is, in the main, sound. It is a 
 limitation to the practical value of economics that it is unable 
 to differentiate the various forms of wealth. But this is just 
 one of the limitations, already referred to, which necessitate 
 the correction of economic conclusions by reference to political 
 considerations. It is clear that " wealth," which means one thing 
 to the economist, may mean another to the politician. The 
 love of gin, for example, is the desire for one kind of wealth, 
 which, as Mr. Cliffe Leslie has observed, " often competes in 
 the mind of a poor man with the love of a decent dwelling." 
 Yet the moralist and the politician will obviously regard it as 
 a matter of very unequal importance, both to the individual and 
 the State, which of these desires be satisfied. In short, while 
 tlie economist fixes his attention on the production and ex- 
 change of material wealth, and deals with distribution only as
 
 94 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 a part of the process of its production, the politician has 
 further to consider what kinds of wealth should be produced, 
 and to what uses it should be put. On these questions a 
 purely economic argument, although it is not quite silent, offers 
 very little guidance. It deals with the uses to which wealth 
 should be put, only in so far as it attempts to prove that un- 
 productive expenditure checks the further production of wealt'n, 
 while a different mode of expenditure would encourage it ; and 
 it deals with the manner in which wealth is distributed, only 
 as a question which arises in the course of production, when 
 the rules have to be determined under which the portions of 
 wealth in process of production will be divided between those 
 who are actually engaged in producing it. It does not, how- 
 ever, decide the ends of civil society ; nor does it say anything 
 as to the uses to which wealth may be put in any other 
 direction than that of wealth-production. It is probable that 
 this defect in the range of economic science ought to be 
 remedied. Such, at least, is the opinion of Professor Walker, 
 the eminent American economist and Free Trader, who thus 
 emphasises the Protectionist criticisms of the point now under 
 discussion : ^ 
 
 " It is," he says, " in the use made of the existing body of wealth 
 that the wealth of the next generation isdetermined. It matters far less 
 for the future greatness of a nation what is the sum of its wealth to- 
 day, whether large or small, than what are the habits of its people 
 in the daily consumption of that wealth ; to what use those means 
 are devoted, whether to ends which inspire social ambition, which 
 restrict population within limits consistent with a high per capita 
 production, which increase the efficiency of the labourer and supply 
 instrumentalities for rendering his labour still more productive ; or 
 to ends which allow the increase of population in the degree that of 
 itself involves poverty, squalor, and disease, which debauch the 
 labourer morally and physically, striking at both his power and 
 
 1 Lest any reader might think it unfair to express Protectionist criticisms 
 in the words of Free Trade economists, it may be stated that all the quotations 
 in this chapter have been adopted by Mr. Hoyt as correct expressions of, to 
 his mind, fatal defects in the value of Individualist economics.
 
 Preparing the Arena, 95 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. iii., \ 7.] 
 
 disposition to work hard and continuously, and which waste in idle or 
 vicious indulgences the wealth which should go to increase capital. 
 
 " To trace to their effects upon production the forces which are 
 set in motion by the uses made of wealth, to show how certain 
 forms of consumption clear the mind, strengthen the hand, and 
 elevate the aims of the individual economic agent while promoting 
 that social order and mutual confidence which are favourable con- 
 ditions for the complete development and harmonious action of the 
 industrial system ; how other forms of consumption debase and 
 debauch man as an economic agent, and introduce disorder and 
 waste here is the opportunity for some great moral philosopher to 
 write the most important chapter in political economy, now, alas ! 
 almost a blank." 
 
 7. Professor Walker's words will dose the subject for 
 most Free Traders. ^ Individualist economics are admittedly 
 defective upon that side which deals with the consumption of 
 wealth. But is this a proof that the science is inapplicable 
 to political discussions? Or to carry the matter a step 
 further has it any bearing at all upon the applicability of 
 economic conclusions to a tariff controversy? Has a tariff 
 more to do with the manner in which wealth is used, or with 
 the manner and the quantity in which it is produced ? 
 
 1 In the following passage from a little volume by R. R. Bowker, entitled 
 " Of Work and We.ilth," which is published at New York in the " Questions 
 of the Day " series, the distinctions in the text are thus referred to: "The 
 wealth of nations with which, as a state-craft, economics deals, is of two 
 orders wealth potential, and wealth produ:ed. Potential wealth is, in truth, 
 ' abundance of life : ' to a nation, the amount of living vigour, present and pro- 
 spective, applicable, within the limits of over-populat'on, to produce work; as to 
 each man, health, length of years, natural capacity for production increased by 
 skill. Every ' able-bodied' immigrant is thus said to be worth to the United 
 States, whose land still invites labour, a thousand dollars. It is this wealt'i 
 which Ruskin regaids, fulminating against economists for their narrow defini- 
 tions ; and Adam Smith himself included it in reckoning the capital of a 
 country. It is this with whicli a statesman largely concerns himself in his 
 economic direction of tlie State. But this wealth cannot be exchanged ; like 
 all higher things, it is beyond value and 'without price.' Produced wealth 
 alone has value, in the economic sense of power in exchange ; and it is this with 
 which economists, as such, primarily deal. When, then, we speak of weahh, 
 we mean usually the fruits of work, not the possibilities of it ; wealth is labour 
 stored by combination with materials.
 
 96 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 To neglect the conclusions of a science which deals with 
 the production and distribution of wealth, because it does not 
 also deal adequately with its consumption, is to ignore the im- 
 portance which the possession of material wealth has always 
 played in the political development of an industrial people. 
 The mere possession of wealth in large quantities does not, it is 
 true, make a nation great ; nor does extent of territory ; but 
 just as extent of territory is often a powerful influence in 
 liberating the forces which contribute to national greatness, so 
 is the possession of wealth. And wealth is even more import- 
 ant to the national welfare of an industrial State than is 
 extent of territory. " Man," it is true, " does not live by bread 
 a^-one " ; but without bread the existence of an industrial 
 community would at least be cramped ! Riches alone cannot 
 give a nation happiness or greatness ; but without riches a 
 nation will have difficulty in obtaining either ! In fact, as 
 political societies are now constituted, the possession of 
 material wealth is the basis of all national development. The 
 days of the hardy barbarian are gone by ; and though abuse of 
 wealth may still create effete societies, the want of it will cer- 
 tainly prevent the full realisation of all the capacities whether 
 moral, intellectual, or material which are latent in an industrial 
 community. 
 
 To refuse, therefore, to consider the economic effect of any 
 political measure, on the ground that economics only concerns 
 itself with the production and accumulation of wealth, and not 
 with its uses, is equivalent to a refusal to regard the operation 
 of the measure upon that which underlies and stimulates the 
 beneficial influence of every quickening force of national life. 
 It is true that a nation is the resultant of many forces ; but it 
 is not true that the economic is the least important. 
 
 It is beside the mark for Protectionists to take up time by 
 ridiculing the imperfections and limi'ations of political economy. 
 No one is more alive to these than the economists themselves. 
 It is admittedly impossible to obtain precision in the postulates
 
 Preparing the Arena. 97 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. iv.,? I.] 
 
 and definitions of the science except at some sacrifice of reality. 
 But in that department of its investigations which deals with 
 the production and exchange of wealth, the postulates and 
 definitions of political economy do square fairly with facts. 
 While men are engaged in buying and selling, they are domin- 
 ated by the desire to make good bargains. Such persons, too, 
 while they are so engaged, do compete with one another upon 
 terms of practical equality; and the object of their desire is 
 capable of being defined by its " sj^ecijica differentia'' the 
 possession of exchange value. Consequently, an analysis of 
 the influences which affect the production of wealth may 
 suggest practical tests of the value of any political measure 
 which is designed to make a nation richer. It remains to 
 consider how far a Protective tariff is a measure within this 
 category, and with what degree of correctness its pretensions 
 may be tested by the conclusions of economic reasoning. 
 
 CHAPTER IV. 
 
 ECONOMICS AND THE TARIFF. 
 
 I. It has already been observed that the economic test of 
 any political measure is its effect upon the production and 
 accumulation of material wealth. Can this test be usefully 
 applied to a tariff? If it can be, then economic analysis will 
 help to a decision in the tariff controversy ; if it cannot be, 
 then Protectionists are right in saying that, so far as the tariff 
 is concerned, political economy is an " idle study.'' 
 
 Now a tariff is essentially a measure which is designed to 
 affect in some way the production of material wealth ; and 
 therefore, since economics is the science which deals with the 
 I)roduction of material wealth, economic conclusions must 
 influence a right decision on tarjT questions, if they can have 
 
 H
 
 98 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 any weight in politics at all. If this were not so, the framer or 
 supporter of a tariff might logically refuse to consider its effect 
 upon the production of wealth. Let any Protectionist, then, 
 who questions the applicability of economics to tariff issues 
 truthfully answer the questions, " Whether he would dare to 
 disregard the possible effect of any tariff upon national pro- 
 ductiveness." Whether he supports Protection because it 
 " diversifies industries," or because it gives a "home market," 
 or because it encourages " infant industries," or for any other 
 reason the basis of his argument must always be that it 
 affects, by increase or decrease, or alteration in kind, the actual 
 or potential wealth of the community. 
 
 The direct object of a Protective tariff is to induce some 
 citizens to follow a certain calling. Why have they held aloof 
 from that calling previously? Because it would not have 
 returned them a sufficient profit. The tariff is to remedy this. 
 By the imposition of a Protective duty it is to give a profit 
 where there was none before. Bearing in mind, then, the 
 argument of the last chapter, it is clear that, since a Protective 
 tariff is primarily intended to operate upon the production of 
 wealth by appealing to the motive of self-interest, all tariff argu- 
 ments will have an economic basis. Whatever may be the 
 political or social benefits which are supposed to accrue from 
 tariff legislation, these must all depend upon a previous acquisi- 
 tion of material wealth. Consequently, the extent to which a 
 Protective tariff affects the aggregate of national wealth can 
 never be disregarded by those who advocate a tariff with the 
 immediate object of encouraging new forms of productiveness. 
 The supposed advantages of a tariff all spring from the fact that 
 wealth is produced. It is the qualities which arise from labour 
 in wealth-producing, and the power of enjoyment which arises 
 from the profits of wealth-producing, that the Protectionist 
 legislator seeks to conserve. The kind of wealth which he 
 seeks to produce is also, no doubt, important in his eyes ; and 
 to this extent he is entitled to modify an economic conclusion-
 
 Preparing the Arena. 99 
 
 Pt. IT., Ch. iv., ? 2.] 
 
 by reference to the political considerations which may determine 
 his selection of desirable occupations for his fellow-citizens. 
 But he cannot ignore the science which deals with every form 
 of wealth-production, by saying that he desires to encourage 
 only certain forms of it. The larger must include the less. 
 
 Admitting, then, that it is a question of the first importance 
 whether Free Trade or Protection gives more effective help in 
 producing and accumulating wealth, the next matter for con- 
 sideration is the applicability of economic methods in discover- 
 ing the answer. 
 
 2. Now the practical utility of economic analysis depends, 
 as has been seen, upon the reality of the two assumptions of 
 an active and dominating self-interest, and an active and equal 
 competition. Are these mere assumptions true in the case of 
 tariff problems ? If they are, the economic analysis can be 
 used in their solution ; if they are not, it must be discarded. 
 
 Let us examine first the suggestion that the postulate of 
 economics is unreal, when the subject of consideration is the 
 motives which induce men to support a Protective tariff. 
 
 The denial that men as a rule are moved by the desire of 
 gain is, as has been already mentioned, probably open to ques- 
 tion, since it is difficult to see what other motive has a wider 
 range or a more powerful influence. But when we are dealing 
 only with tariff discussions it is many times harder to under- 
 stand what possible objection there can be to eliminating other 
 motives than self-interest, for the purposes of scientific study. 
 It is unquestionable that in the pursuit of material wealthy the 
 desire for gain, or (what is the same thing in other words) the 
 impulse to gratify desires with the least possible expenditure of 
 effort, is so largely predominant over all others that it may 
 fairly be considered by itself. As has been said by an Ameri- 
 can writer^ : " Between one dollar and two dollars a man has 
 
 ' Mr. John Bascom, quoted by Professor Perry.
 
 loo Industrial Freedom. 
 
 no choice he must take the greater ; between one day and two 
 days of labour he must take the less ; between the present and 
 the future he must take the present. This is not a sphere of 
 caprice, or scarcely even of liberty the actions themselves 
 present no alternative." But the effect of a tariff upon the 
 production and accumulation of rraterial wealth is admittedly 
 of great importance. There cannot, therefore, be much un- 
 reality in assuming that the citizens of the community whose tariff 
 is in question desire to produce and retain wealth witli as little 
 sacrifice as possible ; nor is it unpractical, in considering the 
 effect of a tariff upon wealth, to eliminate from the discussion 
 all the motives which may influence those who pursue wealth, 
 except that which is everywhere supreme in prompting to the 
 pursuit. To quote again from Mr. John Bascom : " Which- 
 ever one of a thousand motives engages man in the pursuit of 
 wealth, once in that pursuit these all conform to one method, 
 and acknowledge one law." If the elimination of all motives 
 save one is ever permissible and it is only by such means 
 that abstractions can be formed it must be so where the 
 motive which remains is that which predominates so largely in 
 the majority of concrete specimens that all others are reduced 
 to insignificance. This is the case with the motive of self- 
 interest when the citizens of a State desire a Protective tariff. 
 
 3. Assuming, then, that the first postulate of economic 
 science as to the predominance of self-interest is sufficiently 
 close to the truth to justify it being taken as the basis of a 
 scientific abstraction for purposes of tariff disputes, let us see 
 whether the second postulate as to the equality of the com- 
 peting units is also applicable. 
 
 The competition which political economy assumes to be 
 ever active a competition the existence of which alone gives 
 political economy a claim to be regarded as a science is a 
 competition of equal units. These may be individuals or 
 groups of individuals, but they are always assumed to be equal
 
 Preparing the Arena. ioi 
 
 pt. ir.,ch. iv.,$3.) 
 
 to one another. In practice, no doubt, an exact equality docs 
 not exist. In many cases such as the competition between 
 landlords and tenants in Ireland, or usurers and peasants in 
 Eastern Europe the superiority of one side or the other is 
 so marked that the parties can never discuss a bargain upon 
 equal terms. This was the chronic condition of whole classes 
 in earlier periods of European history a fact which explains 
 the inapplicability of modern economic ideas to the indus- 
 trialism of the Middle Ages. It is the condition now of all 
 classes in the East, where economic ideas are equally inapplic- 
 able. It is the condition still of many individuals even in the 
 most advanced communities. The progress of society from 
 status to contract, which Sir Henry Maine has lucidly illus- 
 trated, is not yet complete. The environment of an individual 
 citizen has not yet become the result of his own choice, 
 although the tendency in every democratic country is to 
 enlarge the sphere of individual freedom. Even now, however, 
 class traditions, oppressive customs, bad land laws, lack of 
 education, difficulties of locomotion, mere localism, and many 
 other causes, tend in a greater or less degree to impede the 
 exercise of a free volition by classes or by individuals. Never- 
 theless, political economy takes no account of these fetters 
 upon individual freedom. It assumes that every man is or 
 may become equally equipped for the struggle of existence, and 
 that as a fact the active combatants do engage upon equal 
 terms. This assumption is true, for all practical purposes, as 
 regards the competition of wholesale traders. 
 
 Men who buy and sell on a large scale, whether as merchants 
 or producers, do practically stand upon a footing of equality. 
 Unlike the artisan, who (unless he belong to a trade union) 
 must accept work when it is offered or starve, the capitalist 
 merchant or manufacturer can afford to let his prices be 
 determined by the higgling of the market. Such compulsion 
 as may exist in certain cases to buy or sell is the consequence 
 of abnormal causes, and does not permanently or materially 
 
 UB'^ARY 
 UNIVERSITY C: CALiFORNlA
 
 102 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 affect the general range of prices. The only modification 
 which is required in the assumption of an equality of the 
 competing units, before it is made the basis of an economical 
 analysis of tariff questions, is owing to the effect produced on 
 competition by the existence of trusts and combines. But even 
 in this case the modification is more apparent than real at 
 least, so far as it affects the dispute between Protection and Free 
 Trade ; because, although trusts and combines, when favoured 
 by Protection, may destroy competition in a particular trade 
 within the Protected country, they do not invalidate the 
 assumption upon which the economic analysis is based 
 namely, that free competition would exist if it were not for the 
 Protective tariff. Moreover, even if trusts could be formed 
 in a Free Trade country and no trust has been permanently 
 successful when it is exposed to foreign competition they 
 could, ex hypothesis be formed in all trades ; so that their only 
 effect, so far as the economic assumption is concerned, would 
 be to alter the nature of the competing units. 
 
 4. It remains to be seen whether the refusal to submit a 
 tariff to economic tests can be justified by the objection to 
 political economy that it treats the acquisition of wealth, which 
 is really a matter of minor importance, as if it were a matter of 
 the first importance. 
 
 This may be a perfectly valid objection in certain cases 
 as, for instance, where the question was the desirability of 
 forming a State collection of pictures, or of subsidising a 
 National Theatre but it can have little or no applicability 
 where the material advancement of a country is the special 
 object aimed at. But every one of the advantages which a 
 Protective tariff is supposed to give is, in its ultimate analysis, 
 material. 
 
 " Men are to develop their various faculties." How, but 
 by being encouraged to follow profitable trades? "Men are 
 to have a home market." How, but by producing something
 
 Preparing the Arena. 103 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. iv., \ s.] 
 
 to sell ? " All the capacities and faculties of a nation are to 
 be developed." Upon what other foundation than material 
 prosperity is this development to rest ? 
 
 It is true that, after economic arguments have been con- 
 sidered, a wise politician should direct his mind to the best 
 uses to which wealth can be put ; but it would surely be the 
 height of absurdity so to fix attention on the mode of spending 
 as to render a community neglectful of the best means of 
 acquisition. Protectionists who attack economic arguments on 
 account of imperfections and limitations which nobody denies, 
 omit to notice that their own political arguments assume an 
 economic basis. They begin by declaring that the narrow field 
 of political economy renders it an "idle study;" and yet the 
 moment they test their own conclusions, they take their stand 
 within the much-derided limits of economic science, and cannot 
 move a step outside without falling into an unfathomable bog. 
 It is not sufficient in a tariff controversy to attack economic 
 arguments in general terms ; Protectionists should go further, 
 and prove that the particular economic argument in favour 
 of Free Trade is overridden by political considerations. In 
 other words, although circumstances may render economic 
 reasoning inapplicable to all the facts of life, it does not 
 follow that the existence of these circumstances can be 
 assumed, in order to invalidate the economic argument against 
 Protection. 
 
 S 5. To sum up, then, the results of this inquiry into the 
 relation of economics to the tariff, we may say that those wlio 
 condemn the use of economic analysis in the solution of tariff 
 problems are, as might have been expected, partly right and 
 partly wrong. They are right in insisting that economic 
 methods should be used with extreme caution ; Ijut they are 
 wrong in saying that they cannot be used at all. The argu- 
 ments for or against any tariff are in part economic and in part 
 political ; and while the economist cannot safely refuse to
 
 104 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 qualify his abstract conclusions by considerations of politics, 
 the politician cannot find a basis for any of his arguments 
 against Free Trade unless he openly or tacitly adopt the 
 methods and conclusions of an economic science. Economic 
 conclusions therefore, so far from being valueless, possess a 
 high importance as a test of fiscal legislation. 
 
 But when it is once conceded and few disputants would 
 refuse the concession were it openly demanded of them that 
 no sound political judgment can be formed about a tariff if 
 its effect upon the increase of wealth is disregarded, a very 
 significant factor has entered into the fiscal controversy 
 namely, the contrast between the attitudes of Protectionists and 
 Free Traders towards economic arguments. 
 
 The Free Traders have never been afraid to frame a scientific 
 statement of their case. They have, indeed, erred in the other 
 extreme of making their arguments too scientific. They have 
 proved, with a wearisome iteration, that Protective tariffs cannot 
 increase wealth, and have insisted, until the world is tired, that 
 it is mathematically demonstrable that their efi"ect is to diminish 
 wealth. The unanimity of condemnation has, indeed, been 
 remarkable. Mr. Mongredien, in his admirable essay " Free 
 Trade and English Commerce," mentions (p. 32) that in 1883 
 the British Museum Library, under the catalogue title " Political 
 Economy," contained the names of seventy-seven authors of 
 various nationalities and languages; of these, only tivo advo- 
 cated Protection ! 
 
 Such a consensus of expert opinion can only be set aside in 
 one of two ways namely, either by denying the applicability of 
 economic reasoning, or by impeaching its validity. Some Pro- 
 tectionists adopt the former course, by insisting that although 
 Free Trade may be economically sound, the political advantages 
 of Protection more than countervail its economic inferiority. 
 Others take a more courageous stand, and, denying the scien- 
 tific value of Individualist economics, proceed to determine the 
 laws of national well-being by a new economic system of their
 
 Preparing the Arena. 105 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. V.,? I.] 
 
 own construction. A consideration of the views of the former 
 class may be deferred until the political aspect of the fiscal 
 argument comes under review. For the present we may con- 
 fine our attention to an inquiry into the nature of this new 
 system and its application to tariff disputes. This will form 
 the subject of the next chapter. 
 
 CHAPTER V. 
 
 NATIONALIST ECONOMICS. 
 
 I. It has been implied in the argument of the preceding 
 chapter that no systematic defence of Protection upon economic 
 grounds has been attempted. As this statement might be 
 denied by the more ardent partisans of a restrictive policy, 
 some further explanation of its meaning is desirable. 
 
 The term "economic" has already been defined as "that 
 which relates to the production and accumulation of material 
 wealth." An economic argument is, thus, an argument which 
 is directed exclusively to the consideration of the effect of a 
 fiscal policy upon wealth in its production and accumulation. 
 The necessity for considering this has been already pointed 
 out, and it has also been observed that Protectionists have 
 usually directed their attention to other matters. 
 
 In taking this course, Protectionists often claim to be 
 making use of the conclusions of political economy. They 
 have founded, they say, a political economy of their own, the 
 conclusions and methods of which are free from all the objec- 
 tions that are urged against the school of Ricardo and Mill. 
 From this study they deduce general rules of policy which, 
 as tliey maintain, are a sufficient economic justification for 
 Protective tariffs. 
 
 As it would be idle to dispute about terms, and make
 
 ic6 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 differences where none exist, there can be no objection to 
 assenting to a new use of the term " potitical economy," if the 
 methods and conclusions of Protectionists can justify the change. 
 This, however, is a fitting subject for inquiry " Are there any 
 other modes of economic reasoning ? Is it possible to frame 
 any general argument in favour of Protection, which shall be 
 independent of empiricism and expediency, by applying the 
 conclusions of a new science of economics with different defini- 
 tions, different methods, and different scope?" Should Pro- 
 tectionists succeed in doing this, they will, undoubtedly, have 
 turned the flank of their opponents. 
 
 2. The first point to be observed about the new science is 
 that the meaning of the word " economic " has been changed. 
 Economic, with writers of the Individualist school, always con- 
 noted material wealth. With writers of the new school its 
 meaning is enlarged to include everything which has any rela- 
 tion to national well-being. 
 
 " Political economy," says the Hon. Thomas Reed, Speaker of 
 the House of Representatives, in one of tlie tersest and most com- 
 plete defences of Protective tariffs which have ever been penned, " is 
 an idle study except when it concerns itself with everything that 
 adds to the comfort and happiness of the people." 
 
 "The political economy of a nation," says List,- "is a com- 
 pound of the economy of the people and the financial economy of 
 the State, when the State embraces a whole nation fitted for inde- 
 pendence by the number of its population, the extent of its territory ; 
 by its political institutions, civilisation, wealth, and power and 
 thus fitted for stability and political influence." The economy of 
 the people is thus defined : "Those institutions, regulations, laws 
 and conditions on which the economy of the individual subjects of a 
 State is dependent, and by which it is regulated." The financial 
 
 ^Delford's Magazine, Oct., 1889. The article was intended as a Protec- 
 tionist manifesto, addressed to the educated classes of the Western States. 
 
 2 "The National System of P0litic.1l Economy." By Friedrich List. English 
 translation, p. 195. (Longmans & Co., London, 1885.) The first German 
 edition of this work appeared in 1841. It has had a vogue in .America which is 
 quite out of proportion to its merits.
 
 Preparing the Arena. 107 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. v., \ 3.] 
 
 economy of a people is thus defined : " That which has reference to 
 the raising, the expending, and the administration of the material 
 means of government of a community."^ 
 
 The same author expresses this idea in another passage in 
 the following terms : 
 
 "National economy is that science which, correctly appreciating 
 the existing interests and the individual circumstances of nations, 
 teaches how every separate nation can be raised to that stage of in- 
 dustrial development in which union with other nations equally 
 well developed, and consequently freedom of trade, can become 
 possible or useful to it" (p. 127). 
 
 It will be apparent from these extracts that an economic 
 argument, in the language of writers of this school, no longer 
 means an argument which is exclusively devoted to the con- 
 sideration of changes in the degree of national productiveness of 
 material wealth, but one which takes within its purview every 
 fact whether it be an intellectual concept, or a tangible phe- 
 nomenon, or a condition of the senses which may, either 
 directly or indirectly, promote the well-being of the citizens of 
 a State. 
 
 3. It follows from this use of terras that economic in- 
 vestigation ceases to be conducted by abstract processes, and 
 becomes an historical inquiry into the social, political, moral, 
 and religious conditions of a nation. The opposing methods 
 are thus contrasted by Professor Sumner and Mr. H. M. 
 Hoyt : 
 
 "We have," says Professor Sumner, "to understand that an 
 economic investigation may be carried on just as independently as 
 
 1 Mr. H. M. Hoyt ("Protection lersiis fVee Trade. The Scientific Validity 
 and I'^conomic Operation of Defensive Duties in the United States." By Henry 
 M. floyt. New York: D. Appleton c^ Co. Third Edition, Revised. 1886) 
 adopts a similar view of the meaning of the term. (5^e pp. 74, 79, 391, 396 ) 
 This is the most elaborate defence of Protection yet published. 
 
 Professor Thomson, a disciple of List, without rejecting Individualist 
 economics, treats its conclusions as valueless. ("Political Economy, with Especial 
 Reference to the Industrial History of Nations." By R. E. Thompson, MA. 
 Philadelphia; Porter- Coates. 1882.)
 
 io8 Industrial Freedom, 
 
 a chemical or physical or biological investigation. The economist 
 does not need to be on the look-out all the time to correct his 
 results by reference to some outside considerations, or to the dogmas 
 of jejune and rickety systems of metaphysical speculation. On the 
 contrary, he should regard the introduction of extraneous e'ements 
 no matter under what high-sounding names of moral, politica', 
 and social as sure signs of impending confusion and fallacy 
 {Princeton Review, March, 1882). 
 
 To this Mr. Hoyt replies (p. 74 [n.]) : 
 
 " Professor Sumner's form of economic investigation might be 
 adequate to effect the immediate exchange of commodities existing 
 on a given day. It would not account for the existing stock, nor 
 would it furnish a clue to the nature or amount of to-morrow's 
 supply, or where tomorrow's supply was to come from. A given 
 kind of moral, political, and social man n ust, at last, be a definite 
 kind of economic man in correspondence with himself. His wants 
 are peculiar to his traits, and the preparations to meet them must 
 grow out of his environment. You cannot expect a human being 
 with one sort of aptitudes, to go off and live in a part of the world 
 and in pursuits which do not engage those aptitudes. lie will 
 make the arena of his struggle such that it will engage his best 
 efforts physical, mental, and moral. Then the economic results 
 will take care of themselves." 
 
 It will follow, also, from this change in the scope of 
 "economic" science, that if the new subjects introduced into 
 it are capable of scientific treatment, fresh tests must be 
 devised of the value of any fiscal policy. It will not be 
 enough to demonstrate that Protection lessens national pro- 
 ductiveness, because Protectionists will apply some other 
 formula by which to estimate the influence of tariffs upon the 
 political, moral, social, and religious environment of a whole 
 nation. It will be matter for inquiry later whether it is 
 possible to frame a satisfactory formula for this purpose. 
 
 4. It is, as has already been admitted, quite legitimate 
 for Protectionists to adopt any basis for their science that they 
 please. Nevertheless, it must not be forgotten, in following 
 their attempt to establish a new economic science, with
 
 PRErARlNG THE ArEJVA. IO9 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. v., \ 4.] 
 
 different definitions, methods, and scope, that its conclusions, 
 whatever they may be, will not answer the conclusions of the 
 Individualist political economy. They may justify a busy man 
 in passing these by as verbal conceits, but they cannot meet 
 them, because they stand on a different plane. If it be once 
 admitted that the effect of a tariff upon the production of 
 wealth is an important element in its success, then a scientific 
 demonstration that a tariff lessens the wealth-producing power 
 of a community is not disproved by showing that the same tariff 
 advances national welfare in the direction of morals, politics, 
 or religion. It may have such an effect, and the Individualist 
 arguments may, in consequence, be overridden ; but, for what 
 it may be worth, the economic demonstration, as such, remains 
 unassailed. But we have seen in a previous chapter that a 
 Protectionist cannot ignore the influence of a Protective tariff 
 upon national productiveness. U, therefore, he wants to 
 disprove the proposition that Protection lessens the aggregate 
 of national wealth, he must do more than show that his 
 policy carries with it other advantages which compensate for 
 its impoverishing influence ; he must himself demonstrate 
 that Protection increases national wealth. But where is the 
 man courageous enough to maintain the simple proposition 
 that the best way to increase the aggregate of material wealth 
 in any community is by preventing or restricting international 
 exchange ? 
 
 Professor Sumner has pointed out, in the article in the 
 Princeton Fevieiv which has been already quoted from,^ what 
 the work is which lies before any ambitious man who is 
 desirous of becoming a Protectionist Ricardo. Such an one 
 " must boldly declare that there is a science of wealth based 
 on restrictions; that he can discover the principles of it, and 
 reduce them to a theory ; that trade between countries is a 
 mischievors thing at least, if it runs on parallels of latitude; 
 
 1 See above, p. 108.
 
 no Industrial Freedom. 
 
 that isolation and antagonism of nations is the law of Nature 
 upon which wealth and civilisation depend ; and that there is 
 therefore no universal science of wealth, but only a national 
 science of wealth, and that this science is, in its final ana- 
 lysis, only a generalisation from certain empirical maxims of 
 economic policy." And when our aspiring theorist has reached 
 this point, he must then frame his tests of the effect of a tariff 
 upon national productiveness. To use again the words of 
 Professor Sumner, he must answer these questions : *' Does a 
 tariff enable the population of a country to command greater 
 material good for a given effort?" and "Does it lessen the 
 ratio of effort and sacrifice to comfort and enjoyment ?"i It 
 is only by this means that any direct answer can be given to 
 the economic solution of the fiscal problem as it is arrived at 
 by the Individualist.^ 
 
 It will be necessary to keep these considerations in mind, in 
 order to understand the logical significance of the Protectionist 
 theory of economics and its proper use in a tariff dispute. 
 After these preliminary explanations we are in a position to 
 begin a critical examination of the theory and precepts of 
 " Nationalist economics." 
 
 5. The essential divergence between the Nationalists and 
 
 1 Professor Sumner also suggests two other test questions : ' ' Does the 
 statute enacted by the Legislature alter the distribution of property so that 
 one man enjoys another man s earnings ? Has the State a law in operation 
 which enables one citizen to collect taxes of another?" and " Does the tariff 
 prevent me from supporting myself and my family by my labour as well as I 
 could do if there were no Protecting taxes? " 
 
 - " If Protection be good, it is good in and of itself; if it is bad, it has 
 no business to be begging to lean on something so respectable as revenue. 
 The burden of proof, at any rate, lies upon the man who brings in a theory 
 interrupting the play of natural laws. Let him bring forward and prove his 
 theory of res'riction. Let us hear the arguments and see the grounds that 
 justify the prohibition of an advantageous trade." (Professor Perry, quoted 
 by Mr. Hoyt, p. 196,) So Professor Walker. [The Protectionist must give] 
 "an analysis of the conditions of production, which shall disclose the law 
 which makes trade within the lines of sovereignty beneficial, and trade across 
 the boundaries of separate States deleterious to one or both parties."
 
 Preparing the Arena. in 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. iv., 55.] 
 
 Individualists is, as the terms import, that the one adopts the 
 nation as the industrial unit, the other the individual. This 
 leads to a radical difference of scope and method. 
 
 The "Nationalists" (as the members of thi^s school like to 
 designate themselves) view every nation as a whole, and treat 
 of its national development. In their eyes a political com- 
 munity is not a congeries of individual atoms, but a sentient 
 living organism, with roots in the past and branches reaching 
 to the future. The scope of economics, as these writers 
 understand the term, is to discover the laws of national 
 growth, and to define the rules by which each nation may 
 achieve its complete development. This body of laws and 
 rules may differ for different peoples, since they are determined 
 by the history, temperament, and capacities of each political 
 community. The "economist" will, however, deal primarily 
 with the economics of his own country, and will endeavour to 
 indicate the measures by which the acquired and latent 
 capacities of the whole body of citizens may be most fully and 
 harmoniously developed. 
 
 As a consequence of this widened scope, the method of the 
 science alters. It no longer deduces the industrial movement 
 of a nation from a consideration of the industrial movements 
 of its individual citizens ; but starting with the nation as the 
 unit, and explaining its existing industrial condition by refer- 
 ence to historical, political, moral, and religious considerations, 
 it proceeds to discuss the power of free industrial movement 
 which the individual has from time to time possessed, and the 
 power which, in the present interest of the State, it is desirable 
 to give him. The following extracts will make the contentions 
 clearer : 
 
 "Every distinct community," says Mr. Hoyt, "society, state, 
 nation, every political entity, is to be discussed as an industrial 
 entity y It is impossible to conceive of the terms of an industrial 
 economic problem except under the condition of nationality 
 
 ^ The italics are in the original.
 
 112 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 The difference between civilisation and barbarism lies in the desires 
 to be satisfiei, the things to be exchanged, and their mode of pro- 
 duction. These depend on moral, intellectual, and political con- 
 sideration-, as well as economic" (pp. 79, 80). 
 
 And again he says : 
 
 "No real scientific results can be obtained by the atomistic view 
 of the co-workers in a given society or nation. . . . The attempt 
 to deal with the individuals as units involves us in the vicious error 
 to which Mr. Herbert Spencer has called our attention that of 
 ' mistaking a part for a whole,' and thus * its relations to existence 
 in general will be misapprehended.' By this discrete treatment the 
 whole is completely lost sight of, and the aggregates which the 
 whole involve disappear from our investigations " (p. 234). 
 
 The problem which is to be solved by this repudiation of 
 Individualist econoniics is thus stated : 
 
 "The real problem is, then, to ascertain how the industry of a 
 nation may be made to yield the greatest annual product " (p. 89). 
 
 List expresses the same ideas in more sonorous language : 
 
 "The system of the school [of Adam Smith] suffers," he says, 
 "from three main defects : firstly, from boundless cosmopolitanism, 
 which neither recognises the principle of nationality, nor takes into 
 consideration the satisfaction of its interests ; secondly, from a dead 
 viateriaHsm, which everywhere regards the mere exchangeable value 
 of things without taking into consideration the mental and polit'cal, 
 the present and the future interests, and the productive powers of 
 the nation ; thirdly, from a disorganising particularism and indi- 
 vidualism, which, ignoring the nature and character of social labour, 
 and the operation of the union of powers in their higher conse- 
 quences, considers private industry only as it would develop itself 
 under a state of free interchange with society [i.e., with the whole 
 human race) were that race not divided into separate national 
 societies. 
 
 "Between each individual and entire humanity, however, stands 
 the nation, with its special language and literature, with Hs peculiar 
 origin and history, with its special manners and customs, laws and 
 institutions, with the claims of all these for existence, independence, 
 perfection, and continuance for the future, and with its separate 
 territory ; a society which, united by a thousand ties of mind and of 
 interests, combines itself into one independent whole, which recog- 
 nises the law of right for and within itself, and in its united
 
 Pruparing the ARL^*A. 113 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. v., \ 6.] 
 
 character is still opposed to other societies of a similar kind in thtir 
 national liberty, and consequently can only under the existing con- 
 ditions of the world maintain self-existence and independence by its 
 own power and resources. As the individual chiefly obtains by 
 means of the nation, and in the nation, mental culture, power of pro- 
 duction, security and prosperity, so is the civilisation of the human 
 race only conceivable and possible by means of the civilisation and 
 development of the individual nations. 
 
 " Meanwhile, however, an infinite difference exists in the condi- 
 tion and circumstances of the various nations : we observe among 
 them giants and dwarfs, well-formed bodies and cripples, civilised, 
 half-civilised, and barbarous nations ; but in all of them, as in the 
 individual human being, exists the impulse of self-preservation, the 
 striving for improvement which is implanted by Nature. It is the 
 task of politics to civilise the barbarous nationalities, to make the 
 small and weak ones great and strong, but, above all, to secure to 
 them existence and continuance. It is the task of national economy 
 to accomplish the economical development of the nation, and to pre- 
 pare it for admission into the universal society of the future." 
 
 6. Let us pause a moment to estimate the value of this 
 new " science " by reference to its avowed range. We recall 
 that the main objection to Individualist economics was the diffi- 
 culty of making any useful abstraction of a being so infinitely 
 mixed and various as " the individual citizen." Yet an abstrac- 
 tion of some sort must be made if the " science " of political 
 economy is to be anything more than the study of history. If 
 generalised conclusions are to be reached as to the laws of 
 national progress, or if a scientific analysis is to be attempted 
 of the elements of national greatness and it is only by per- 
 forming both these tasks that Nationalist economics can justify 
 its claim to being scientific the variant and accidental elements 
 must be eliminated from the object of study. But let any one 
 attempt to eliminate the variant and accidental elements from 
 " a nation." How is he even to make a beginning in such a 
 task ? Merely to enumerate the forces which compose the 
 stream of a nation's life would be hardly possible without a 
 wider range of knowledge than mankind as yet possesses ; 
 while even if the difficulties of enumeration could be success- 
 I
 
 114 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 fully overcome, the work of separating the permanent from the 
 transitory elements would prove insuperable. Who is to 
 decide upon the precise degree of influence to be given to any 
 of the constituent elements of national greatness ? Take only 
 one example. Religion has been at all times a powerful factor 
 in national development; but could any one estimate its 
 influence in any but the vaguest terms? If Individualist 
 economics were objectionable because its scope was too 
 narrow, Nationalist economics manifestly errs upon the other 
 side by covering an illimitable field. The " welfare of a 
 nation " is a conception of so vague a character that it cannot 
 be submitted to any scientific analysis. Its elements are not 
 only doubtful, but illusory ; because, even were it possible to 
 come to an agreement upon the nature of national well-being, 
 still the things which admittedly go to make a nation great and 
 prosperous such as morality, high spirit, orderliness, capacity 
 to govern, love of beauty, obedience, spirituality, intellectual 
 force, and many other qualities and conditions are of a 
 character which cannot be measured by any known standard, 
 or reduced to any common denomination. Were it not that 
 large phrases possess an irresistible attraction for a certain 
 class of minds, it might be thought unnecessary to pursue this 
 subject further. But this so-called science wraps itself in such 
 high-sounding jargon and, as Professor Sumner says, " mas- 
 querades under such an affectation of learning and philosophy " 
 that it has met with more than the ordinary success of economic 
 quackery. Take away, however, all verbiage, drop such talk 
 as " the operation of the union of powers in their higher con- 
 sequences," and present the theory for consideration in the 
 simple language of Mr. Reed ! It becomes at once apparent 
 that a science which deals with everything that adds to the 
 *' comfort and happiness of the people " is defining its objects 
 in terms of the unknown. Who shall say in what " the comfort 
 and happiness " of a nation consist ? Or are there to be as many 
 sciences of political economy as there are professors ? Certainly,
 
 Preparing the Arena. T15 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. v., {6.] 
 
 it would seem that if practical conclusions of precision cannot 
 be obtained from the science the scope of which is limited to a 
 consideration of the individual, none can be looked for from 
 that the range of which is boundless. The unscientific 
 character of the inquiry is further illustrated by also putting into 
 plain language the problem which is proposed for investiga- 
 tion " Analyse the causes and expound the nature of 
 national well-being." Such a problem may be studied historic- 
 ally, and history may often suggest an empirical solution, just 
 as the historical studies of the Nationalist school have been par- 
 ticularly fruitful in throwing light upon the complexities of 
 modern industrialism. But an attempt in our present state 
 of knowledge to treat this problem scientifically can only result 
 in the creation of utterly useless abstractions, or the pronounce- 
 ment of a series of inconsequent dogmas. 
 
 Let it, however, be assumed, for purposes of argument^ that 
 the subject-matter of Nationalist economics is capable of scien- 
 tific treatment still Individualists, whose studies are so con- 
 temptuously cast upon one side, will want to know what 
 measure of national happiness and comfort these new philo- 
 sophers desire them to adopt ; because if no such measure can 
 be found, students have no means of testing the conformity of 
 a legislative act to the scientific rule. But we have only to run 
 over in our minds a few of the constituent elements of happi- 
 ness or comfort to see that they consist of things which are 
 quite immeasurable. What means exist by which we can esti- 
 mate the value of different qualities, conditions, or ideas ? 
 And yet these things enter very largely into the concept of 
 national well-being. Or, again, suppose that any of these things 
 could be measured separately from the others, to what common 
 denominator can they all be reduced in order that their values 
 may be compared? Yet it is upon a "science" such as this 
 that Protection rests as if the framing of a large and general 
 statement were the same thing as the construction of a scientific 
 theory. No wonder that Professor Sumner, after many years 
 I 2
 
 11 6 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 of active battle with " scientists " of tliis school, denounces 
 their pretensions as " an arrant piece of economic quackery." 
 Our business, however, is to investigate this science further, 
 without resort to terms of contumely. Let us test it again by 
 reference to its practical conclusions. 
 
 9. Nationalist economists profess to have discovered two 
 fundamental rules for the guidance of their political disciples. 
 The first of these is, " That every nation must be entirely self- 
 supporting ; " and the second, " That the development of 
 productive powers, and not the increase of national wealth, is 
 the object of wise statesmanship." Let us treat of each of these 
 rules in turn. 
 
 The notion that every nation must be self-supporting is 
 worked out by List in the following series of propositions : 
 
 "The idea of independence and pcwer originates in the very 
 idea of ' the nation '"' (p. 181). 
 
 " Nations have to pass through the following stages of economical 
 development : original barbarism, pastoral condition, agricultural 
 condition, agricultural-manufactuiing condition, and agricultu'-al- 
 manufacturing-commercial condition " (p. 177). 
 
 " In a country devoted to mere raw agriculture, dulness of mind, 
 awkwardness of body, obstinate adherence to old notions, custom", 
 methods and processes, want of culture, of prosperity, and of liberty, 
 prevail" (p. 197). 
 
 ' Manufacturing occupations [on the other hand] develop and 
 bring into action an incomparably greater variety and higher type 
 of mental qualities and abilities" (p. 199). " They are at once the 
 offspring, and at the same time the supporters and nurses, of science 
 and the arts " (p. 200). 
 
 [Statesmen must accordingly encourage manufactures by pre- 
 venting the competition of any nation in a higher manufacturing 
 stage than has been reached in their own country (Chaps. XVII. 
 XX.).] 
 
 Mr. H. M. Hoyt expresses the same idea thus : 
 
 " It is indispensable, if a given nation is to live on a given area, 
 that opportunity should be afforded them to render mutual services 
 to each other, or to somebody else somewhere else. If there were 
 no such opportunity, the nation would be non-existent. There is no
 
 Preparing the Arena. 117 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. v., 5 9] 
 
 existing or historical nation in which the vast mass of services by 
 which men satisfy each other's desires have not been rendered 
 within the lines of the political entity. To that extent the political 
 entity and the industrial entity, as a matter of fact, do correspond" 
 (p. 361). 
 
 And again : 
 
 "The external relations of nations have not grown out of 
 economic movements " (p. 362). " [If they had] no economic 
 reason could be given why the industrial entity should correspond to 
 the political entity" (p. 367). "[But in fact] the people of a 
 nation are bound together by sentiments different in degree, not in 
 kind, from those which bind together the members of a household. 
 In the nation, as in the family, there is a vast multitude of services 
 exchanged between its members which are not economic. The 
 economic and non-economic services are grounded in the same sub- 
 stratum of humanity ; and the effort to separate them, and render 
 one here, and the other with people in another family, simply means 
 disintegration. It is the union and mutual exchange of these two 
 kinds of services which result in our welfare and create the senti- 
 ment known as patriotism. It is a genuine emotion, and is a true 
 economic force. It reconciles us, also, to accept the averaged 
 results of our efficiency expended on our own physical conditions. 
 It engenders that sense of community which operates with such force 
 in family and nation. Thanks to this feeling for the commonweal, 
 the eternal and destructive war the belluvi omttiuin contra omnes 
 which an unscrupulous self-interest would not fail to generate among 
 men engaged in the isolated prosecution of their own economic 
 interests, ceases in the higher well-ordered organisation of society. 
 On it are based the various forms of economy in common family 
 economy, corporation or association economy, municipal economy, 
 and national economy. And these forces of economy in common 
 are so essentially the condition and complement of industrial 
 economy, that the latter without them could either not be main- 
 tained at all, or at least only in the very lowest stage of civilisation." 
 
 From these considerations it follows that 
 
 " The problem is simply to provide the opportunity of economic 
 labour for a population born or thrown together on a given geo- 
 graphical area, on which area there are overruling political motives 
 for maintaining a political entity. The industrial entity must then 
 be made to conform to the political entity, or both perish. Drop 
 all considerations of patriotism, social ties, kindred, politics, and sub- 
 mit to the economic forces alone, and I grant there would be no
 
 ii8 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 economic reason for any correspondence of the industrial and 
 political entities. But then there might be no economic reason for 
 the existence of Germany or France " (p. 369). 
 
 Again there is reason to complain of the unnecessary use 
 of pompous language. All this talk about the necessity for a 
 correspondence between the political and the industrial entity 
 only itieans that it is desirable, for political reasons, to develop 
 every national resource, and that this object is best achieved 
 by a policy of Protection. We may agree with the object, and 
 dispute the efficacy of the means ; but we cannot now project 
 this political discussion into the middle of an economic 
 argument. That must be reserved until a later chapter.^ 
 But an admission that it is desirable, in the interests of a nation, 
 that all the capacities of all its citizens should have an oppor- 
 tunity of coming into play, does not require us to prohibit 
 trade with any nation more developed than ourselves. Nor is 
 it by any means clear that a nation advances most rapidly by 
 concerning itself exclusively with its own affairs, at the cost of 
 an industrial warfare with all the rest of the world. Yet, 
 according to List, " Each nation, like each individual, has its 
 own interests nearest at heart. Russia is not called upon to 
 care for the welfare of Germany ; Germany must care for 
 Germany, and Russia for Russia " (p. 93). Nor must your 
 Nationalist statesman stand upon the fear of war. " War," says 
 List again, " acts on a State like a prohibitive tariff system. 
 It thereby becomes acquainted with the great advantages of a 
 manufacturing power of its own. ... A war which leads 
 to the change of the purely agricultural State into an agricul- 
 tural-manufacturing State is therefore a blessing to the nation." 
 Notable conclusions these for a philosopher who repudiated 
 the economics of Adam Smith because they took no notice of 
 religion or morality ! 
 
 The mischievous idea that every nation must be independ- 
 ent of all others like the Stoic idea that every individual 
 
 1 ScehdQw, Part III.
 
 Preparing the Arena. 119 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. v., \ 8.] 
 
 must be self-sufficing is best refuted by history and experi- 
 ence. Such an achievement, even if it be desirable, has never 
 yet been possible. Nations, Hke men, grow stagnant by non- 
 intercourse ; their latent capacities wither, and the impulse of 
 ambition dies.i 
 
 Mr. Hoyt may be right in his assertion that " considerations 
 of patriotism, social ties, kindred and politics," require a nation 
 in its best interest to trade as little as possible with the inhabit- 
 ants of other countries. No one can dispute an ex cathedra 
 statement ; but in that case the Chinese reached the perfection 
 of economic wisdom when, in the true spirit of Nationalist 
 philosophy, they built a wall around their territory in order to 
 maintain, by the most efficient means possible, the " corre- 
 spondence of their political and industrial entities." And how 
 distressing is the lack of correspondence between these 
 " entities " in the case of Great Britain ! 
 
 The Nationalist champions have, at any rate, this advan- 
 tage their rule is unassailable by logic. Let who will declare, 
 with numerous rhetoric and sonorous phrase, that the interests 
 of the State require an independence of the foreigner 
 no one can say him nay. He has Providence behind him, 
 and natural rights, and knowledge of the future, and, failing 
 these, he is at least entitled to his own opinion. Those 
 who are not of the faithful can only wonder and look 
 at a map. 
 
 8, We pass now from the Nationalist rules for inter- 
 national dealings to those for internal statesmanship. These 
 are summed in the maxim " That it is the duty of statesmen 
 
 ' The commercial, rather than the manufacturing, nations have been in the 
 forefront of civilisation: e.g., Carthaginians, Ilanseatic Towns, Venice and 
 Holland, in older times; while European nations might fairly be ranked 
 according to their civilisation by looking at the magnitude per head of the 
 population of their foreign trade. 
 
 "If trade pinches tlie mind," says Lowell, in his "Essay on Josiah 
 Quincv," " the influence of commerce is liberating and cnlarsjing.''
 
 I20 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 to develop a nation's productive powers." This is thus ex- 
 pounded by its author, List : 
 
 " The prosperity of a nation is not greater in the proportion in 
 which it has amassed more wealth [ie., vaUies of exchange), but in 
 the proportion in which it has more developed its powers of produce 
 tion.^ Although laws and public institutions do not produce im- 
 mediate values, they nevertheless produce productive powers ; and 
 Say is mistaken if he maintains that nations have been enabled to 
 become wealthy under all forms of government, and that by means 
 of laws no wealth can be created " (p. 144). 
 
 Mr. Hoyt says, in effect, the same thing in answer to the 
 well-known Free Trade inquiry, " How can taxes create 
 wealth?": 
 
 " The Protectionist proposes to create nothing. He can create 
 neither matter nor material forces. The energy he proposes to set 
 free is already in the men and things he deals with. . . . The 
 Protective statute renders possible the formation of the structural 
 organisation peculiar to a given country through which the pro- 
 ductive forces take effect" (pp. 380, 383). 
 
 The theoretical basis of this maxim is a denial of Adam 
 Smith's proposition that " Industry can only be increased by 
 the increase of capital."- This is thus expressed by a Pro- 
 tectionist writer, Mr. George Basil Dixwell, in a passage quoted 
 by Mr. Hoyt (p. 388) : 
 
 "To make the proposition [that laws and government cannot 
 increase industry] a vast gap has to be filled. It requires to be 
 proved that in a normal condition of things there is no unemployed 
 capital and no funds wliich, although intended for unproductive 
 consumption, are capable of being instantly turned to the support 
 of production the moment that a new industry introduced by a Pro- 
 tective law presents a profitable field of employment." 
 
 This is simply the old economic exposure of the fallacy of 
 Mill's statement that "a demand for commodities is not a 
 
 1 The italics are in the Knglisli translation. 
 
 2 "Wealth of Xation=," l^ook IV., Chapter 11. " Th*? industry of the 
 community can only be augmented in proportion as its capital increases, and 
 the capital of the conitnunity can only incrensc in accordance with the savings 
 which it gradually makes from its income." [Sec List, pp. 225 and 597.)
 
 Preparing the Arena. 121 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. v., } 8.] 
 
 demand for labour;" and it is perfectly sound. The Nationalists 
 are right in asserting that the development of productive 
 powers is a most important element in national greatness^ 
 which, under certain circumstances, may be of greater importance 
 than the accumulation of exchange values. Their error consists 
 in failing to observe that, on the Individualist theory, there is 
 a necessary connection between the accumulation of exchange 
 values, or "capital," and the development of new industries; 
 and that as capital accumulates, the self-interest which prompts 
 to its profitable use will direct it into new channels of pro- 
 ductiveness. Nationalists admit that self-interest will endeavour 
 to use capital in this way, but they deny its power to do so 
 without Government assistance. They assert that the competi- 
 tion of more highly developed nations will prevent the establish- 
 ment of the desired industry ; and that, therefore, this competi- 
 tion must be prevented by restrictive duties. The difference 
 between the two parties is, therefore, largely one of fact, not 
 theory : " Does foreign competition in fact prevent the 
 development of a nation's productive powers ? " And, secondly, 
 " If so, are restrictive laws the best means of encouraging this 
 development ? " But these are plainly questions of politics, 
 which are out of place in a discussion about the value of a 
 scientific theory. They will be examined fully in a later portion 
 of this work, when the time comes for dealing with the political 
 arguments in favour of Protection. 
 
 The maxim which, for the sake of brevity, may be termed 
 " the productive powers maxim " is also supported on another 
 ground. It is said that the self-interest of individuals cannot be 
 relied upon to develop natural resources without aid from the 
 Government. The reason given for this assertion is so 
 curious and difficult to understand that it will be better to 
 express it in the words of List : 
 
 " It is a further sophism," he says, "arrived at by confounding 
 the llieory of mere values with that of the powers of production, 
 when the popular school infers from the doctrine that ' The wealth
 
 122 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 of the nation is merely the aggregate oj the -wealth of all individuals 
 in it, and that the private interest of every individual is better able 
 than all State regulations to incite to production and accumulation 
 ^w^a//A,' the conclusion that the national industry would prosper 
 best if only every individual were left undisturbed in the occupation 
 of accumulating wealth. That doctrine can be conceded without 
 the conclusion resulting from it at which the school desires thus to 
 arrive ; for the point in question is not that of immediately increasing 
 by commercial restrictions the amount of the values in exchange in 
 the nation, but of increasing the amount of its productive powers. But 
 that the aggregate of the productive powers of the nation is not 
 synonymous with the aggregate of the productive powers of all in- 
 dividuals, each considered separately that the total amount of these 
 powers depends chiefly on social and political conditions, but 
 especially on the degree in which the nation has rendered effectual 
 the division of labour and the confederation of the powers of pro- 
 duction within itself we believe we have sufficiently demonstrated 
 in the preceding chapters" (pp. 169, 170). 
 
 Nothing could illustrate more clearly than this passage the 
 danger of confusing an empiric statement of facts with a 
 scientific argument. But it will be well to defer criticism until 
 the maxims of the school are fully stated. It remains to point 
 out how the object of the Nationalists is to be achieved. This 
 is also explained by List. 
 
 The care of a statesman, as has been said, ought to be not 
 
 so much the increase of wealth as the development of a nation's 
 
 productive powers. This is to be achieved by the temporary 
 
 sacrifice of wealth. 
 
 "The nation must sacrifice and give up a measure of material 
 property in order to gain culture, skill, and power of united pro- 
 duction ; it must sacrifice some present advantages in order to 
 secure to itself some future ones" (p. 144). 
 
 To this end it must restrict its trade with foreign countries, 
 and prevent individuals from following their own interests. If a 
 statesman should permit citizens merely to concern themselves 
 with getting rich, he is like an improvident landowner who 
 
 " puts out his savings at interest, and keeps his sons at common hard 
 work, instead of foregoing his interest and submitting to a present 
 loss ill order to give his sons the benefit of education " (p. 13S).
 
 Preparing the Arena. 123 
 
 Pt. II Ch. v., } 9.] 
 
 The above extracts will have given a brief but sufficient 
 summary of the practical conclusions of Nationalist economists. 
 Do these confirm its pretensions to be regarded as a science ? 
 Certainly they do not commend themselves to unassisted 
 reason. 
 
 In the first place, they utterly repudiate the notion that the 
 maxims of morality have any place in international transac- 
 tions. Every nation is to be for itself, at whatever cost of 
 injury to others. Secondly, they display the utmost mistrust of 
 the individual citizen. They treat him in all industrial matters 
 as a person who cannot be allowed a free choice. He is to be 
 driven into this trade or that, as the changing wisdom of law- 
 givers may determine ; and in no case is it to be conceded 
 that he is the man of all others who is most likely to know and 
 pursue his own interest. Legislative restrictions trammel him 
 on every side, and Parliament, and not himself, determines what 
 pursuits he is to follow and what avoid. In all this Nationalists 
 are, of course, determined by the highest considerations for the 
 well-being of the person whom they so insult ; just as slavery 
 was never supported for any other reason than because it 
 increased the happiness of the slaves ! 
 
 Time can be the only judge of such expedients; but while 
 waiting for the verdict of posterity, it is not out of place 
 to remind these doctors of human character that a narrow 
 and vulgar provinciality is not patriotism, and that human 
 nature reaches its highest development when it consciously, 
 a fid of its oivfi free will, enjoys at all times that which is best. 
 
 The question, however, which we are now discussing is not 
 about expediency, but about principles. 
 
 9, We are now in a position to pass judgment on the 
 scientific character of Nationalist economy. We have traced 
 this system through its definitions, scope, methods, and con- 
 clusions; but are wc any nearer the perception of a single 
 general principle ? The scope of the science is ludicrously
 
 124 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 vague; its method is empiric; its conclusions are immoral 
 according to the prevalent ideas of morality. At best, it has 
 furnished a few political arguments by which to test the 
 conclusions of Individualistic economics ; but it has never 
 really grappled with economic problems, while its criticisms 
 generally fall short because it misconceives the character of 
 the individualistic science. 
 
 Take, for instance, its cardinal maxim : that the increase of 
 the wealth of all individual citizens is not the same thing as 
 the development of productive powers ! This is valueless as a 
 scientific statement, although it may lead to useful political 
 results, while as a piece of criticism it is beside the mark, 
 because it ignores the limitations of the scientific school. It is 
 idle to impeach the validity of the individualist methods by 
 mentioning the social and political conditions under which the 
 work of a nation can be most effectively performed, and then 
 complaining that the Individualistic science does not take all' 
 of these into account. No Individualist would deny that the 
 efficacy of a labourer depends in a great degree upon his social 
 and political environment. In fact, this is the reason why 
 economic conclusions about the products of labour have 
 constantly to be corrected by reference to the conditions of 
 the workman. But this admission is not inconsistent with a 
 belief in Individualist methods. 
 
 The "individual" of Adam Smith's political economy is 
 not, as Mr. Hoyt imagines, " a niasterless, clanless man," but 
 a citizen. His citizenship is assumed, so that there is no 
 necessity to devote chapters to discussing its component 
 elements. And not only is citizenship assumed, but that 
 kind of citizenship which is only possible in highly civilised 
 communities of the modern type, and which is described as 
 citizenship in an industrial community. It is true that these 
 assumptions are not made in so many words in every economic 
 writing, but they are implied in the postulates. The free play 
 of self-interest and the equality of competing units are only
 
 Preparing the Arena. 125 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. v., 5 9.] 
 
 possible in a highly organised industrial State. Consequently, 
 the tests of economics which Nationalists afifect to make by 
 applying its conclusions to conditions of savagery and isolation 
 have no reference to the case. 
 
 Nor do Nationalists fare any better when they accuse the 
 Individualist of ignoring the productive force of civil and social 
 organisation. The theory of man's economic perfectibility 
 runs through the whole scheme of economic study. It may 
 be that, in fact, the individual's efforts are hampered, either 
 because he cannot, for some reason, use his full productive 
 powers, or because capital cannot find a safe investment in 
 developing a latent national resource ; but the only scientific 
 consequence of this is a necessity in such a case of correcting 
 an economic conclusion. The inability of the "economic" 
 individual in certain cases to do all that he desires does not 
 invalidate the scientific investigation of what the results would 
 be if he were able to have his way. Indeed, the practical 
 utility of economics often consists in indications of legislative 
 hindrances to the free and most effective exercise of human 
 industry. 
 
 So, on the other hand, the mere enumeration of the social 
 and political conditions under which the work of a nation 
 can be most effectively performed is in no sense the con- 
 struction of a science. It is, at most, a useful study in history 
 or politics. 
 
 The conclusion is inevitable to anyone who reads Nationalist 
 writings, that every attempt to found an economic science on 
 any other basis than that of Individualism inevitably becomes 
 empiric, both in its scope and method. Whatever may be the 
 value of the arguments and the conclusions of the Nationalists, 
 they are at best historical ; they establish no general principle, 
 but depend upon varying conditions of local circumstances. 
 This is not necessarily an impeachment of their bearing on the 
 fiscal controversy. It may yet turn out that Protection and 
 Free Trade are only, after all, matters of expediency, and not
 
 126 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 of principle : in which case the pohtical investigations of the 
 Nationalists may possibly correct our economic conclusions 
 almost beyond recognition. At present, however, we are only 
 considering the claim of Nationalist economics to be regarded 
 as a science, and we have come to the conclusion that it 
 cannot be substantiated. 
 
 Note to Chapter V. 
 
 THE CHARACTERISTICS OF NATIONALIST WRITERS. 
 
 No attempt has been made in the present chapter to estimate the 
 importance of the Nationalistic school of writers, or to exhibit all their 
 characteristics. The references to their writings have been strictly limited 
 to the requirements of the present argument that is to say, only those 
 passages have been referred to which seemed to affect the validity of the 
 methods and conclusions of individualist economics as applied to tariff 
 controversies. This leaves a large part of their work untouched. 
 
 It would be absurd to deny that many writers of this school of whom 
 Roscher may be considered the head exhibit in a notable degree many of 
 the best attributes of scientific investigators. Their historical investigations 
 have been particularly fruitful in showing the modem character of economic 
 ideas and their inapplicability to undeveloped communities, such as those 
 of Europe in the Middle Ages or of Asia at the present time ; while their 
 analysis of existing social conditions has thrown a clearer light upon many 
 of the complexities of modern industrialism. It is now, for instance, 
 generally recognised that the growth of trusts and combines has materially 
 qualified the old assumptions about competition, and that within the field 
 of distribution these assumptions were always so wide of the mark as to 
 possess very little scientific value. But it is in the change of temper in 
 which economics are studied that the influence of the school is most 
 perceived. There is no longer any inclination to include all phenomena in 
 a few neat theories, and judge of facts by them ; but in its place is a readi- 
 ness to test, theories by fact and observation, and a growing caution in 
 applying them. 
 
 But this recognition of the services rendered by some Nationalist writers 
 to the study of economic questions must not blind us to the serious evils of 
 their influence. They have caused the pendulum to swing so far upon the 
 other side, that it is hardly possible to obtain a respectful hearing for 
 deductive reasoning. The recent publication of Mr. Marshall's " Principles 
 of Economics" will, it is hoped, have a corrective influence ; but no lapse 
 of time can impair the merits of John Stuart Mill's epoch-making work. 
 Sober wisdom, whether in economics or politics, is at a discount in this 
 a^e of fanatics and cranks, but every succeeding generation, for many years
 
 Preparing the Arena. 127 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. v., ? 9 ] 
 
 to come, will testify to the sound judgment, foresight, and sagacity of that 
 great thinker. 
 
 Nor must we forget that a wide distinction exists between the greater 
 and the lesser writers of this new school. Just as in time past every 
 newspaper writer had " The Laws of Political Economy " always on his 
 pen, and was ready to say, with Mr. Lowe, " Political economy belongs to 
 no nation : it is of no country. ... It will assert itself, whether you 
 wish it or not. It is founded on the attributes of the human mind, and no 
 power can change it " so theMr. Lowes of to-day exhaust their stock of vitu- 
 perative epithets in condemnation of the idea that any scientific analysis of 
 economic facts is ever possible. Chief among offenders of this sort are 
 List and H. B. Carey ; while as for Mr. Ruskin, it were only charitable to 
 assume that his writings upon economics ought not to be taken seriously. i 
 One characteristic of these writers, and the swarm of pamphleteers they 
 have created, is the infinite variety of their topics. They write voluminously 
 on every subject, human and divine, except economics ; they indulge freely 
 in misty speculations on the nature and the destiny of man ; they discourse 
 upon distinctions of race and climate, and know exactly what the world 
 was intended to be and what it is going to become ; and in every case their 
 authority is unimpeachable by human reason, because all of them are 
 believers in "natural rights," and some of them are theologians ! This is 
 not pleasantry, but a literalstatement of facts. Theintrusionof theology and 
 transcendentalism into reasonings upon economic subjects is a distinguish- 
 ing feature of the Nationalist school. Sometimes the result is most grotesque. 
 Mr. Carey, for instance, who has been regarded as a prophet in America for 
 many years, has attested that "Trade between nations is illegitimate if it 
 runs along parallels of latitude, but legitimate along meridians of longi- 
 tude." No one can dispute this astonishing discovery, because Mr. Carey 
 makes it under the express authority of " Providence" and "Nature" ! 
 
 Fortunately, the best work in economics is now being done in America 
 under theinfluence of ihepolitical science schools in more than oneuniversity,- 
 
 ' Mr. E. T. Cook, in "Studies on Ruskin," p. 29 (n.), has ingeniously 
 suggested as an excuse for Mr. Ruskin's worst extravagances of vilification 
 that he was criticising not the teachings of political economy, but " luhat is 
 the same thing what it loas believed to teach." A plain man, who was not if 
 the brotherhood, might be disposed to think that a special duty was cast upon 
 a teacher of tlie gospel of " truth, sincerity, and nobleness" to ascertain wha', 
 for instance, J. S. Mill did really teach, before terming him "a one-eyed flat- 
 fish " on account of what " he was supposed to teach " which in this case w, s 
 not by any means " the same thing." 
 
 - The Political Science Quarterly, The Economic Science Quarterly, 
 and the studies of the Johns Hopkins University, are the current sources of 
 information as to what is being done in the United States in the prosecution c f 
 economic studies.
 
 128 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 so that it may be hoped that before many years have gone by the 
 class of literature of which Mr. Carey's writings are a sample will only 
 possess an antiquarian interest ; at present it is a melancholy fact that they 
 are regarded by many voters as scientific revelations. 
 
 The elucidation of those matters of universal interest which occupy the 
 province of economics requires the exercise in an exceptional degree of the 
 rare, but humble, qualities of patience and sagacity. In no intellectual pur- 
 suit is it more dangerous than in political economy to give rein to the imagi- 
 nation. In tracing the working of society through all its manifold connections, 
 brilliance, enthusiasm, sympathy, and even genius, must always be subor- 
 dinated to an accurate regard for detail and a more than judicial hesitancy 
 in the adoption of conclusions. This is especially necessary in dealing 
 with questions of international commerce, because, owing to the minute 
 and ever-changing inter-dependence of trades, no one can be sure that he 
 sees any commercial transaction in all its bearings. There is a tendency 
 to give undue weight to the facts which first meet the eye, although these 
 are often of less importance than those which are concealed from the 
 general public, and known only to the experts of the particular trade. Nor 
 must the student of commerce ignore the danger of mistaking local and 
 passing for permanent phenomena. Even ten years is but a short time in 
 the industrial history of a nation ; yet, let any country pass through only a 
 three years' depression of trade, and how many quack remedies and revo- 
 lutionary schemes will be put forward by its inhabitants, and gravely 
 considered by so-called economic writers ! 
 
 These dangers to the scientific character of economic studies are 
 increasing as civilisation becomes more complex and a survey of the whole 
 more difficult. Added to this is a temporary cause of danger from the 
 wave of mere expansive benevolence, which is based on no reflection and 
 holds before itself no definite aim, that threatens now to submerge all 
 serious and detailed treatment of social problems. On the one side, the 
 intellect of the country is being repelled from the study of politics and 
 driven into the pursuit of physical science ; on the other, the sentimentalists, 
 without knowledge, are encouraging disturbance and aggravating diffi- 
 culties. The risk of such a state of affairs is only dimly perceived at 
 present ; but it may yet be that Liberal institutions will go under before the 
 indifference of one class of their supporters and the ignorance of another. 
 The forc-'s of reaction are always organised and watchful, and every social 
 trouble or disorder make; in their favour. The greater, then, is the reason 
 for showi.ig that political economy is capable of scientific treatment, and 
 that, while not ignoring the just claims of sentiment to find legitimate 
 expression in an organised national existence, its conclusions are capable of 
 being expressed in general terms, which are something more than abstiact 
 generalities.
 
 Preparing the Arena. 129 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. vi., \ I.] 
 
 CHAPTER VI. 
 
 NATIONALIST ECONOMICS AND THE TARIFF. 
 
 I. It will be remembered that, before entering upon the 
 economic argument in favour of Free Trade, it became neces- 
 sary to clear the ground for a fair fight by getting rid of a con- 
 tention that economic arguments could not lead to any results 
 in the present case. This contention was supported by the 
 statement that there was a new science of economics, witli 
 a different definition, scope, and method, the results of which 
 completely invalidated all the investigations of Individualists. 
 Inquiry has proved that this claim cannot be justified ; but it 
 will be well to probe the pretensions of the science still 
 further by showing how its so-called principles are applied to 
 the issues in the tariff dispute. 
 
 This task is fortunately rendered easier by the admirable 
 monograph of Mr. H. M. Hoyt, to which such frequent 
 reference has already been made.^ Most Nationalist writers 
 touch incidentally upon the question of the tariff; and it is 
 believed that all of them, except Roscher, advocate Protection.- 
 But, so far as the writer is aware, no one, except Mr. Hoyt, has 
 devoted a separate treatise to a justification of Protection by 
 reference to Nationalist principles. But whether Mr. Hoyt 
 stands alone or not, his work is certainly an elaborate, careful, 
 and ingenious statement of the Protectionist case, expressed 
 with a temperateness of language that is unhappily rare. 
 
 He begins with a criticism and repudiation of the In- 
 dividualist doctrines, tlien states the doctrines of the Nationalist 
 school, and then finally a])plies these to the tariff controvcrs;;. 
 
 1 " rrotoction versus Five Trntle. The Scientific Validity and Economic 
 Operation of IJifensive Duties in the I'nited States." By I.'cnry M. l]u\t. 
 Third Ivlition, Revised. New Yoff., i835 
 
 - Sec note at end of cliaptcr. 
 
 J
 
 130 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 His illustrations and arguments are, naturally, directed prin- 
 cipally to American voters ; but they are, nevertheless, of a 
 sufficient general application to interest a foreign reader. In 
 fact, the treatise is regarded as a text-book in Australia ; and 
 that it has largely influenced American thought would be 
 apparent to any reader of the Forum, Belford's Magazi?ie, the 
 North American Review, and the Ailantic Monthly, during 
 the Presidential campaign of 1888. A less connected view of 
 the Protectionist argument is afforded by the Congressional 
 speeches on the tariff question. The six best of these on 
 either side have been collected and published in a cheap form, 
 under the title of "An Appeal to the American People as 
 a Jury," which forms an invaluable handbook of the fiscal 
 policy from an American standpoint. It naturally, however, 
 lacks the consecutive character of Mr. Hoyt's treatise, and is 
 more useful for its graphic illustrations of the actual working 
 of the tariff in the United States. 
 
 The argument has three steps : (ist) That a high degree 
 of manufacturing skill is necessary to the best national develop- 
 ment ; and (2nd) That this cannot be obtained without Pro- 
 tection ; (3rd) That the loss in money values which Protection 
 causes is more than recouped by the advantages which it 
 confers. 
 
 List expresses the whole argument in the folloNving 
 passage : 
 
 " Tlie nation must sacrifice and give up a measure of material 
 property in order to gain culture, skill, and powers of united pro- 
 duction ; it must sacrifice some present advantages in order to 
 ensure to itself future ones. If, therefore, a manufacturing power, 
 developed in all its branches, forms a fundamental condition of all 
 higher advances in civilisation, material prosperity, and political 
 power in e\-ery nation (a fact which, we think, we have proved from 
 history) : if it be true (as we believe we can prove) that in the 
 present condition of the world a mere unprotected manufacturing 
 power cannot possibly be raised up under free competition with a 
 power which has long since grown in strength, and is protected on 
 its own territory ; how can anyone possibly undertake to prove by
 
 Preparing the Arena. 131 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. vL, \ 3.] 
 
 arguments only based on the mere theory of values that a nation 
 ought to buy its goods, like individual merchants, at places where 
 they are to be had the cheapest : that we act foolishly if we manu- 
 facture anything at all which can be got cheaper from abroad : that 
 we ought to place the industry of the nation at the mercy of the 
 self-interest of individuals? that Protective duties constitute 
 monopolies, which are granted to the individual home manufac- 
 turers at the expense of the nation? It is true that Protective duties 
 at first increase the price of manufactured good>, but it is just as 
 true, and, moreover, acknowledged by the prevailing economical 
 school, that in the course of time, by the nation being enabled to 
 build up a completely developed manufacturing power of its own, 
 those goods are produced more cheaply at home than the price at 
 which they can be imported from foreign parts. If, therefore, a 
 sacrifice of value is caused by Protective duties, it is made good by 
 the gain of a prnver of production, which not only secures to the 
 nation an infinitely greater amount of material goods, but also 
 industrial independence in case of war. Through industrial inde- 
 pendence, and the internal prosperity derived from it, the nation 
 obtains the means for successfully carrying on a foreign trade and 
 for extending its mercantile marine ; it increases its civilisation, 
 perfects its institutions internally, and strengthens its external 
 power. A nation capable of developing a manufacturing power, if 
 it makes use of the system of Protection, thus acts quite in the same 
 spirit as that landed proprietor did who, by the sacrifice of some 
 material wealth, allowed some of his children to learn a productive 
 trade." 
 
 3. Each step in this argument is open to dispute. It 
 is beside the mark to " prove from history that a manufac- 
 turing power, developed in all its branches, forms a funda- 
 mental condition of all higher advances in civilisation," 
 because there is no civilised country at the present time 
 which is not far superior in its manufacturing power to the 
 most completely developed rnanufacturing countries of the 
 days before steam-power. History furnishes no guide under 
 these altered circumstances. 'J'he question now is, not 
 " Wliether manufactures are necessary to national greatness?" 
 but "^Vhetl1er the best interests of tlie particular country 
 whose tariff is in question would be advanced by the establish- 
 ment, through the agency of Protection, of this or that manu- 
 J 2
 
 132 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 facture ? " List's arguments give us very little aid to a correct 
 answer. He dwells at great length on the superiority of an 
 artisan in character and intelligence to an agricultural labourer, 
 and argues from this that it is to the advantage of a country to 
 over-balance its "dull-witted" agriculturists by a greater 
 number of manufacturing hands. But those who live in younger 
 countries, where the rural labourer's intelligence is not depressed 
 by traditions of caste or exclusive land laws, will be very slow 
 to believe that the monotonous drudgery of tending a machine 
 inside the walls of an unwholesome factory is more conducive 
 to the cultivation of intelligence and character than the 
 healthy open-air and self-dependent Hfe of the Australian bush 
 or the Western' prairies. The increasing number of '' larrikins " 
 and " hoodlums " seems rather to suggest the opposite remedy 
 of distributing the city populations. Yet the argument that 
 Protection will increase the number of factory hands at the 
 expense of the agricultural part of the community lies at the 
 very foundation of the Nationalist defence of Protection. Are 
 Protectionists prepared to take this step ? Does any number 
 of them in a young country seriously believe that the urban 
 population is not already excessive in number and inferior in 
 character ? 
 
 4. Let us, however, grant that the first step in the argu- 
 ment can be established, and that it is desirable to establish 
 certain manufactures, does it follow that this cannot be done 
 without Protection? The Individualist answer is an emphatic 
 negative. The establishment of manufactures (he says) may 
 safely be left to private enterprise, because so soon as capital 
 accumulates it will be eager to find investment. INIr. Hoyt, 
 however, and his scliool, entertain a profound mistrust of un- 
 directed individual clTort. Tlicy will not believe that any hoiie 
 of profit can be relied upon to attract capital into an industry 
 that is exposed to the competition of a foreign country. It 
 may face the competition of a countryman, but it would be
 
 Preparing the Arena. 133 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. vi., ? 4.] 
 
 dangerous to the community to let it run the ribk of the 
 competition of a foreigner ! Here are his words : 
 
 " While considered as individuals, men may be trusted to pursue 
 the industry which seems to offer the best returns ; when we come 
 to international exchanges, we must abandon this atomistic view of 
 the co-workers in an organised nation. Our scientific standpoint 
 must be at an elevation which places the given nation in proper per- 
 spective with all the other political and industrial units which com- 
 pose the commercial nations of the world, who also have 'desires' 
 which they wish to gratify. The wants of a nation as a whole, and 
 its powers of supplying them as a whole whether by domestic 
 production or foreign exchange, or by their joint operation are 
 aggregates. The nature of our surplus production and the relation 
 of that surplus to the markets of the world, involve aggregate esti- 
 mates. The amount of foreign products needed, and the nature of 
 the purchase money which we carry in our hands, are to be treated 
 as aggregates, and the means of buying their gratification is an 
 aggregate. ... So some one, statesman or layman, must take 
 the trouble to sum up the details of a nation's industrial resources 
 and liabilities into the correct aggregate " (pp. 234, 235). 
 
 Again words ! Words ! 
 
 " Men may be trusted as individuals to follow their 
 private interest in internal commerce, but in international 
 commerce they must be guided by legislation." But are 
 the legislators any more to be trusted than the individuals ? 
 and if so, why ? Is it not notorious that legislators are 
 not chosen for their business knowledge, or their delicate 
 appreciation of the higher spiritual and social necessities of 
 the "individual citizen"? 
 
 Again, in what sense are the ''' wants of a nation " an aggre- 
 gate, except that they are resultant of the wants of individuals ? 
 To supply the wants of a nation, "as a whole/' is, surely, the 
 same thing as supj^lying the wants of each individual citizen. 
 Else could the parts be full and the whole empty ? But let 
 Mr. Hoyt speak in his own defence : 
 
 " If men could be born where they pleased, or if men could and 
 would go freely from one country to another when the demand for 
 the products of their industry in their native land failed, or when the
 
 134 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 pursuit of an occupation in which they had special aptitude is in- 
 capable of being carried on if men did not care where they lived 
 and where they died we might assent to speculations as to what 
 would be. If, on the other hand, all the motives of life except 
 economic ones keep him in his political home, the capacity and 
 opportunity of a man to work at all may depend on governmental 
 restraints on the products of foreign labour, and the industrial entity 
 must be conterminous with the political entity. It is not a question 
 of protecting the weak against the strong, or the high-priced labourer 
 against the low-priced labourer. It is giving to the labourer of a 
 given country the market for the products of his labour. It is to 
 prevent the labourer himself from being removed from the country, 
 and substituting therefor a trade in the product of his lal:)our. The 
 argument does go equally well with either end first. Germany success- 
 fully keeps its lower-priced labour in German industries on German 
 soil by protecting her home market ; and so does France, Otherwise, 
 it might conceivably happen that there would be no occasion for a 
 German to live in Germany." 
 
 And in another place : 
 
 "The problem, therefore, is not ' How far for a given exeilion 
 and sacrifice to get the maximum of material good,' but rather, ' How 
 we may so occupy our field of employment that we can expend upon 
 it all the exertions and all the sacrifices which we, as a people, are 
 willing and able to make. How we may get the maximum for all 
 which is possible when all our abilities and all our energies are called 
 into play' " (p. 201). 
 
 But again we ask, why cannot this problem be solved by the 
 free play of enlightened self-interest ? Why cannot individuals 
 be trusted to use their industrial organisation to the best ad- 
 vantage of the whole ? And if they cannot be trusted, who are 
 the persons to direct them ? Why should men lose their sense 
 of what is best for their own interests when they engage in 
 foreign trade ? If every man knows his own interest best, and 
 may be trusted to follow it, as, Mr. Hoyt admits, he may in in- 
 ternal trade, does not the presumption arise that national 
 industry will be most wisely organised by leaving the producing 
 class alone ? But to Mr. Hoyt, the idea of organisation and 
 the idea of individual action seem incompatible. He regards 
 the " individual " as " a masterless, clanless man," fighting
 
 Preparing the Arena. 135 
 
 Pt. IL, Ch. vi., \ s.] 
 
 against every one else, and indifferent to everything but the 
 momentary gratification of his desires. Yet there is no incon- 
 sistency between individuaUsm and organisation ; rather the 
 organisation that is firmest and directed to the highest ends 
 can only be created by freemen. Spontaneous recognition of 
 the necessity for union is an essential condition of strength. 
 But it will be just to hear Mr. Hoyt further. He thus works 
 out the application of his conception to fiscal policies ^ : 
 
 " Under Free Trade, men would follow certain natural industries. 
 The only natural industries are those connected with the land and 
 the product of raw material." (This fundamental position is assumed 
 without proof.) " The surplus of these is to be exchanged for 
 foreign manufactures. A time, however, will come when the surplus 
 of these industries will be more than foreigners can take, and, at the 
 same time, the demand for manufactures may be greater than 
 foreigners can satisfy. Under these circumstances, the theory of 
 Exchange breaks down, and the surplus of the natural industries is 
 unsaleable. To remedy this state of things, it is proposed to en- 
 courage the direct production in America of the goods which would, 
 in a state of freedom, be purchased from abroad. By such a direct 
 production, the market for the surplus of the natural industries is 
 enlarged, and the supply of the qualifications which are desired by 
 the producers of this surplus is rendered longer and more constant. 
 
 "The effect of this direct production is beneficial in another 
 way. It provides employment for the rapidly increasing stream of 
 immigrants, and enables the State to utilise the various capacities 
 which may be possessed both by the original inhabitants of the 
 country and by the new arrivals. It calls into play all our abilities 
 and all our energies." 
 
 5. The time for criticising this argument will come later, 
 when each of its parts is separately considered. It is sufficient, 
 for the present, to point out that it rests on several unexpressed 
 and unproved assumptions, of which the chief are, that without 
 Protection, direct production would not have taken place ; and 
 that under Free Trade there would have been no manufacturing 
 industries. A Free Trader, replying to the argument, would first 
 require some proof of the assumption that manufacturing 
 
 1 In this summary Mr. Hoyt's language has been adhered to very closely.
 
 136 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 industries were not " natural " to a country of such unequalled 
 wealth in raw materials as the United States ; and he would ask 
 next whether, if it should happen that, under Free Trade, 
 foreigners could not supply the American demand, anything 
 would stand in the way of the Americans supplying themselves ? 
 The " natural " course of events would be that, as population 
 increased, and the demand for manufactured goods became 
 sufficient to justify the erection of costly works, labour and 
 capital would be employed in a great variety of manufacturing 
 industries. 
 
 Mr. Hoyt's argument, however, whether good or bad, is 
 clearly not " economic " in the sense in which we have used 
 the term. It is, in fact, only the expression in larger terms 
 of the two stock phrases of Protectionist manufacturers : 
 " Keep the home market for the home labourer " and " Secure 
 diversity of industry." 
 
 Mr. Hoyt himself seems to recognise the political nature of 
 his argument at a later period of his work, when he admits that 
 he is driven to his conclusions by considerations of " patriotism, 
 social ties, kindred, and poliiics, and that, submitting to the 
 economic forces aloae, there would be no economic reason 
 for any correspondence of the industrial and political entities " 
 
 (P- 3(^9)- 
 
 It would be impossible to have a plainer avowal that the 
 so-called " economic " argument in favour of Protection is, in 
 all its attributes, political and moral. The admission is plain 
 that if it can be proved that the acquisition of material wealth 
 is the principal element of national productiveness, and the 
 most potent stimulus of latent energies, there is then no 
 reason why nations should not trade with one another. 
 
 But that is the very proposition which is demonstrated by 
 the Individualist economist, which Mr. Hoyt believes himself 
 to be refudng. 
 
 The truth is that Mr. Hoyt and the economists are not 
 arguing about the same point.
 
 Preparing the Arena. 137 
 
 Pt. IL, Ch. vi., \ 5.] 
 
 It is obvious that a purely economic argument cannot be 
 refuted by a process of reasoning which starts with an assump- 
 tion that the acquisition and production of wealth are matters of 
 trifling importance. The utmost which Mr. Hoyt's method 
 can achieve is to suggest reasoning for disregarding the eco- 
 nomic conclusions. The questions which he raises are of great 
 importance ; but it is a cause of confusion to term them 
 " economic." They are really the stock political arguments of 
 the Protectionist armoury, " Keep the money in the country," 
 " Diversify employment," " Encourage infant industries," and 
 " Preserve the home market for the home labourer." Any or all 
 of these phrases may contain reasons for modifying the eco- 
 nomic conclusions about the tariff; but we are not considering 
 them at present in that aspect, but only inquiring into their 
 effect in impugning, by economic methods, the validity of an 
 economic argument. The conclusion is inevitable that they 
 have failed to do this. The " economic " argument stands 
 firm against all " economic assaults." 
 
 Note to Chatter VI. 
 
 "nationalism and rROTECTION." 
 
 No reference has been made in the course of this chapter to the 
 particular Protectionist conclusions expressed by the various writers of 
 the Nationalist school ; but those of List are particularly noticeable, 
 in view of the importance attached to his pretentious work. He 
 is a strong opponent to any protection of agriculture (p. 214), and 
 advocates the free admission of all the raw materials of manufactur- 
 ing,' industry (pp. 217, 316, and 324). He was also of opinion that 
 " where any technical industry cannot be established by means of an 
 orijrjnal protection of forty to sixty per cent., and continue to maintain 
 itself under a continued protection of twenty to thirty per cent., the funda- 
 mental conditions of manufacturing power are lacking " (p. 313). The 
 length of time for \\ hich Protection was required for European nations wa'^, 
 he thought, "ten or fifteen years" from the date of writing (1841): 
 (p. 1S4;. 
 
 List, like most Protectionists, has the prospect of war ever before his 
 eyes. The bugltear of a general blockade scares him from one extreme to 
 another, and is the chief reason for his anxiety to make every nation self-
 
 138 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 supporting. His morbid and diseased mind he suffered from chronic 
 ill-health, and died by his own hand is also haunted by the spectre of 
 " perfidious Albion " ; he sees wickedness in every action of Great Britain, 
 and seriously warns his countrymen that the Secret Service money is spent 
 in bribing Continental countries to adopt Free Trade, just as the 
 average American voter is instructed to beware of " British gold " and the 
 "Cobden Club." Such are the writers to whose judgment we are asked 
 to entrust the delicate duty of adjusting the rival interests of the individual 
 and the vState ! 
 
 Mr. Hoyt seems to have taken warning by the failure of List's 
 prophecies,! and is more cautious of committing himself to any definite 
 statement as to the amount of Protection that is needed, or the length of 
 time for which it must be maintained. He also, however, objects to 
 Protection upon raw materials ; and in a noticeable passage admits the 
 injury which the American tariff has inflicted on the welfare of the 
 Southern States (p. 373). 
 
 CHAPTER VII. 
 
 FREE TRADE AND LAISSEZ FAIRE. 
 
 I. The lists are not even yet clear for the entry of the con- 
 testing arguments. The obstacles have been removed, but 
 the boundaries have still to be defined, lest the disputants 
 might never meet each other in a field which stretches from 
 the quicksands of Socialism to the arid waste of " LaissezfaireT 
 Yet the real battle-ground on which the contest must take 
 place is equally removed from each extreme. Unhappily, the 
 champions on either side are so unwilling to observe the proper 
 limits of their controversy, that it is necessary, if we would avoid 
 confusion, to define, with as much exactitude as the subject 
 will permit, the true relations of either fiscal policy to its cog- 
 nate political system. 
 
 It has already been observed, in the chapter which defined 
 the meaning of the term that Free Trade is not a principle of 
 
 1 An instructive test of the soundness of List's principles is furnished by 
 comparing his anticipations of the future with the actual course of events {see 
 especially pp. 104, 158, 184, 191).
 
 Preparing the Arena, 139 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. vii., \ 2.] 
 
 government, but an expedient of commerce. Commerce has 
 many other aids to its enlargement and extension of which 
 bank-notes and a system of credit are two familiar examples. 
 Each of these works within a special sphere by its own method, 
 and under its own rules. The sphere of Free Trade is the 
 production of exchange values, and its method is the extension 
 of the principle of division of employment into international 
 transactions. Not much room here, it would seem, for any 
 wide excursion into the philosophy of politics ! 
 
 It happens, however, that while exercising within its own 
 province its especial functions of cheapening products, steady- 
 ing prices, and equalising markets, Free Trade has established 
 an important rule of political conduct, which is capable of 
 being applied to many other departments of civil activity. This 
 is the well-known rule of Laissez faire. The principles by 
 which the practice of Free Trade is justified, and the practice 
 of the policy itself, have both shown that, in the case of inter- 
 national exchanges, it is wiser for a Government to allow its 
 traders to have a free choice in the selection of their articles of 
 barter than to attempt to control their sales and purchases 
 by the means of Customs duties. But that is a rule which is 
 strictly limited by its terms to international exchanges. How 
 has its extension been brought about ? 
 
 The theory and practice of banking have established 
 certain rules as to the right proportion which should be main- 
 tained between the value of a note issue and a gold reserve ; 
 yet no banker has thought of applying these rules without 
 modification to the issue of Exchequer bonds. Why should 
 not Free Traders and Protectionists be equally ready to confine 
 their fiscal rules to fiscal matters ? The answer to this question 
 is to be found in the historical circumstances under which 
 this rule was first pronounced and carried into practice. 
 
 2. When Adam Smith wrote the first systematic explana- 
 tion of the phenomena of an industrial and commercial society,
 
 140 - Industrial Freedom. 
 
 labour and capital were hampered at every turn by regulations 
 and restrictions. It requires a vigorous effort of the imagi- 
 nation to picture the conditions of industry prior to the great 
 industrial revolution which marked the close of the last century. 
 Wages, prices, processes of manufacture, migrations of labourers 
 in search of work, meetings of workmen, the transport of 
 goods, the wholesale trade, and all international commerce, 
 were either forbidden or regulated by law or custom down to 
 the minutest detail. Some industries were forbidden to be 
 carried on except by certain persons or at certain places. 
 Over-sea goods were only allowed to be carried in English 
 ships, or in ships of the nation whose product they were ; while 
 a high, and often prohibitive, tariff closed our ports still further. 
 The trade guilds, although their influence was on the wane, 
 still exercised a legal and customary right of hindering the 
 processes of manufacture, by applying their old rules to the 
 altered conditions of production by machinery and steam- 
 power.i But if the position of employers was rendered 
 irksome by their wide-reaching system of restraint and regula- 
 tion, the position of the workman was hardly that of a free 
 man. Whatever may have been his happiness in the possession 
 of regular employment and sufficient food and there is a 
 tendency now to over-estimate his condition of prosperity and 
 contentment he had little or no hope of ever altering his 
 mode of life. He worked, it is true, in a cottage instead of a 
 factory, and breathed pure air, and he fed at his master's table, 
 and served no other all his life ; but behind this idyllic picture 
 is another of a gross animal, unable to leave his parish because 
 he lacked the means of gaining a "settlement" in another 
 by forty days' continuous residence, subject to the brutality of 
 a master hardly more refined than himself, his wages fixed for 
 him by Justices in Quarter Sessions, prohibited by the laws of 
 apprenticeship from trying his hand at a new trade, without 
 
 1 See Brentano's " Essay on Trades Unionism."
 
 Preparing the Arena. 141 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. vii.,?3.] 
 
 interest, without hope, sunk in ignorance, bestiality, and vice.i 
 In the meantime, the conditions of industry were everywhere 
 changing. Even before the period of great mechanical discoveries 
 (1770 90) the old system of domestic industry was breaking 
 down before the growth of foreign trade and the accumulation 
 of capital. At the conclusion of the Seven Years' War (1763) 
 industry required new outlets in all directions. The old order 
 was passing away, but the old rules remained. It was the aim 
 of Adam Smith's great work to show how the industrial organisa- 
 tion should be made to correspond to the existing needs. ^ 
 
 3. It is a mistake to regard Adam Smith as a deductive 
 economist, theorising from abstract postulates. On the con- 
 trary, he was essentially an observer of the things about him, 
 and his method of study is chiefly, although not exclusively, 
 historical. He did so far yield to the influences of his time as 
 to take the doctrine of "natural liberty" as tlie philosophical 
 justification of his attacks upon the existing restrictions; but 
 he nowhere developes this into the extreme theory " that every 
 man in pursuance of his own advantage at the same time 
 furthers the good of all !" This later growth was due almost 
 entirely to the success of Adam Smith's proposals. The 
 doctrine of "natural liberty" gained a reflected glory from the 
 
 ' The pictures of the condition of the poor given in the'novels of Smollett 
 and Fielding are very instructive, and should be read as a corrective of the often 
 quoted passages from Defoe's "Tour through Great Britain." 
 
 - Toynbee's "Industrial Revolution ' gives the best, although frag- 
 mentary, account of the industrial changes during this period. 
 
 Professor Thorold Rogers' "Six Centuries of Work and Wages," and his 
 "Lectures on the Economic Interpretation of History,'' contain, perhaps, the 
 greatest quantity of systematised information upon the sul)ject ; while Professor 
 Ashley's " Introduction to English Economic History and Theory," and a 
 nst'ful Compendium, pre|)and by Mr. Gibljins for the University Extension 
 Se: i'-s, undir the title of ' ' 'ri.e liidr.'trinl History of Fnglan;!," are two notable 
 additions by Oxford nir-n to a sti'.dy v.hich the University of Oxford is making 
 peculiarly her own. 
 
 Eden's " State of the Poor," Xicliol's " History of the Poor Law," Baines' 
 " History of the Cotton Trade," and Scrivener's " History of the Iron Trade," 
 arc indispensable as works of rcfcrcr.ce.
 
 142 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 immediate and striking results which followed its practice. As 
 restriction after restriction fell before the force of law or 
 custom, the belief gained ground that some new principle of 
 policy had been discovered or revealed. 
 
 The same work was proceeding in France as in England, 
 only that the need for it was greater. From the time that the 
 merchant Legendre returned his famous answer to Colbert's 
 question, " How he might best protect French commerce ? " 
 '' Laissezfaire, laissez passer''^ until the Revolution, the aim 
 of every wise ruler was to lessen the restrictions upon the 
 passage, manufacture, and exchange of goods. The odious 
 ingenuity of these impediments, and the vigour with which 
 they were supported in the name of religion and order, caused 
 Turgot to adopt Legendre's saying as the cardinal maxim of 
 sound administration. From France it passed to England, 
 where it was received for a time as a new gospel by all those 
 and at that time they were many who suffered in their 
 fortunes or their ease in consequence of the corrupt and 
 injudicious interferences of Government with the private affairs 
 of citizens. It has not, however, been accepted as a scientific 
 principle by any economist or writer of repute, except Mr. 
 Herbert Spencer. This will probably be a hard saying to 
 many Nationalists ; yet, in truth, the reputation of the older 
 economists has suffered by the indiscretions of their thoughdess 
 followers. They never did, in fact, teach, as a scientific triith, 
 that "the road to national prosperity lies in the unchecked 
 and competitive pursuit of material wealth," i in spite of the 
 belief of many estimable persons to the contrary. Their 
 conclusions were strictly limited by their premisses, and were 
 only applicable to the facts of daily life, when the conditions, 
 which were assumed to exist universally, were present. Their 
 so called " natural laws " were mere statements of the regular 
 
 ' "Studies in Ruskin," by E. T. Cook (p. 30). It is only fair to mention 
 th.1t this is Mr. Cook's summary of Mr. Ruskin's opinion of economic teaching, 
 not a statement of his own.
 
 Preparing the Arena, 143 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. vii., \ 3.] 
 
 sequence in which certain results would follow from certain 
 combinations of ascertained facts. 
 
 Journalists and politicians, however, who were anxious to 
 clinch an argument, and busy men who wished to avoid one, 
 used the economic conclusions as statements of a natural law. 
 Ignoring the limitations under which their masters wrote, and 
 forgetful of the nature of their assumptions, these incautious dis- 
 ciples treated a scientific deduction as if it were a formula for daily 
 use ; and, not perceiving that the reforms which had been carried 
 by the influence of Adam Smith were purely negative, and 
 that the abolition of the antiquated legislation of restriction 
 would become useless if the labourer was prevented by the 
 changed conditions of his life from exercising his newly won 
 freedom of movement, they applied the arguments of Adam 
 Smith to every species of Protective legislation. Yet, in fact, 
 the position had entirely altered. The watchword, which had 
 been "Remove the shackles!" had become "Prevent the 
 forging of new shackles I" 
 
 It happened that Ricardo and many other economists 
 although John Stuart Mill was not of the number honestly 
 believed that many of the efforts to preserve the working- 
 classes against the dangers of their new condition would be 
 ineffective and mischievous ; and Ricardo gave evidence to 
 this effect before a Committee of the House of Commons. 
 The general public, not unnaturally, failed to discriminate 
 between these political opinions and the conclusions to which 
 the same men had arrived as scientific economists. It 
 happened also that most of the Free Trade manufacturers, 
 who were the backbone of the Anti-Corn-Law League, took 
 the same view of the new legislation, under the impression 
 that legal equality and freedom of contract were the only 
 conditions that were needed to secure the working-classes in 
 their just rights. Here, again, the greatest of the Free 
 Traders, Richard Cobden, held aloof. But the public have 
 been in no mood to discriminate, and Free Traders have
 
 144 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 been joined with the economists in a general condemna- 
 tion. 
 
 The same display of feeling is observable in the United 
 States, and is to some extent justified by the writings of Free 
 Traders. Not only have most American Free Traders been 
 unswerving devotees of Laissez /aire as a political maxim 
 moved thereto, no doubt, by the wonderful achievements of 
 Individualism in the United States and the frequent corrupt- 
 ness of Government action but they have assumed the 
 universality of the maxim as the basis of their justification of 
 Free Trade. Professor Sumner of whom all lovers of clear 
 thought and precise expressions must speak with unfeigned 
 respect has been the leader of this school,^ of which Professor 
 Fawcett, whose work upon Free Trade has been largely 
 circulated in the United States, is an English disciple. On 
 the other hand. Professor Walker and the younger school of 
 economists among whom may be named Professor Clark, 
 Professor Ely, Professor Richmond Mayo Smith, and Professor 
 Taussig have never supported Laissez /aire, either as a 
 political or scientific doctrine. It is to be feared, however, 
 that some time must elapse before the new school of writers 
 can clear the reputation of Free Trade from the effects of its 
 unfortunate association with an unpopular doctrine. 
 
 We are now in a position to understand the combination 
 of influences under which the notion has grown up to wliich 
 reference was made in the second chapter of this work that 
 Free Traders were fanatical adherents of Laissez /aire, and 
 that " Administrative Nihilism " (to use Professor Huxley's 
 expressive synonym) was the last word of economic teaching. 
 
 ' la tlie present state of tl;e law as to inienia'ional copyright, American 
 writings on political and economic subjec's are almost unknown in Great 
 Britain or Australia. Yet no one has ever penned a more kicid statement in 
 a shorter space, of the economic argument against Protection, from the stand- 
 point of a believer in Laissez faire, than is contained in Professor Sumner's 
 httle book entitled " Protectionism the ism which teaches that waste makes 
 wealth."
 
 Prep AH im the Aren-a. 145 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. vii.,54.] 
 
 No reader of Protectionist literature can entertain a doubt of 
 the wide influence of this misapprehension, to which the 
 rejection of the individual as the industrial unit, and the 
 adoption of Nationalism, is almost entirely due.^ The dislike 
 of Laissez /aire, which is the governing inspiration of 
 Nationalists, is so intense that it prevents a fair appreciation 
 of the meaning of the maxim. The same blindness of rage 
 obscures the vision of the fighting Protectionist. Remembering 
 that many prominent Free Traders are ardent believers in 
 this maxim, he has come to regard it as an essential part of 
 Free Trade, and as the logical outcome of Individualist 
 political economy, and has consequently sought for a new 
 basis for economics which will not lead to such an unworkable 
 conclusion. Popular impressions die hard ; and it will probably 
 be as difficult to persuade Protectionists and Socialists that 
 Laissez /aire is not a necessary part of economic teaching as 
 it is to persuade Individualists that Socialism does not mean 
 either a re-distribution of private property or the abolition of 
 capital. Nevertheless, the attempt must be made. 
 
 4. Whatever may be the merits of Laissez /aire and, 
 according to Mr. Herbert Spencer, they are great the maxim 
 is certainly not an expression of a scientific principle. It is 
 at best only the correct application of a principle being a 
 term of political art which does not belong to science. 
 
 An attempt has been made earlier in these pages- to define 
 the limits within which the maxim may be safely applied; and 
 it was suggested that within the field of the production of 
 wealth, where the economic postulate of an ever-active com- 
 petition between equal units is practically in accord with facts, 
 the best results were obtained under a policy of strict non- 
 interference ; but it was pointed out that, within the field of 
 the distribution of wealth, the conditions of competition were 
 so altered that no such general rule could be safely adopted. 
 
 ' 5(?6' List : Thookll. passim, Iloyt : Cliaps. II., IV., V. , and /,r^j/;//. 
 Sec above, p. 11-13. 
 
 K
 
 146 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 It is not to be expected that so fragmentary a discussion 
 of a large question should carry conviction to the minds of 
 those who are already believers in the universal applicability 
 of Laissez faire; nor is it desired in this treatise to enter 
 upon any long discussion of the subject. We are not now 
 concerned with principles of government, but with the smaller 
 question of a fiscal policy. There is no need to do more 
 than show the independence of the Free Trade argument of 
 this or any other political theory. 
 
 The Free Traders who have pressed into their service the 
 doctrine oi Laissez faire have certainly adopted a most con- 
 venient course ; because, if it can once be proved that 
 Governmental interference is always wrong, any argument 
 against the particular kind of interference known as Protection 
 becomes a work of supererogation. But although most Free 
 Traders who give up Laissez faire such as Mill, Cobden, 
 Jevons, and Toynbee in England, and Professors Walker, 
 Clark, Mayo Smith, Ely, and Taussig in the United States 
 undoubtedly yield a great advantage to their opponents, it 
 would be idle to expect to convince Protectionists of the 
 futility of Protection by any demonstration that the individual 
 always knows his interests best in the sense in which they are 
 identical with the interests of society. The mistrust of the 
 doctrine of Administrative Nihilism is so widespread and 
 deep-rooted that it may be doubted whether any Protectionist 
 writer could be induced to read a refutation of Protection 
 which rested on a proof of this kind. Accordingly, from 
 motives of controversial expediency, if for no other reason, it 
 will be well to meet Protectionists upon their own ground, 
 and discuss the interference of a Government in matters of 
 trade and tariffs as if there were no presumption either against 
 or in favour of interference in that or any other case. A few 
 words more in explanation of the reasons for taking this 
 course are, however, due to a deserved respect for the eminent 
 names of those who have conducted the dispute on other lines.
 
 Preparing the Arena. 147 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. vii., \ 5.1 
 
 5. The political maxim of Laissez faire is arrived at 
 partly by a process of induction, and partly by deduction from 
 economic principles. But since economic principles rest upon 
 an assumption of an ever-active competition between equal 
 units, no rule of practice can be founded upon economic 
 reasoning where there is either no competition at all or a com- 
 petition between unequal units. Now, it has already been ob- 
 served that the peculiar province of economic reasoning is the 
 production and accumulation of material wealth. Accord- 
 ingly, if the merits of a fiscal policy depend to an appreciable 
 extent upon its effect upon the production and accumulation of 
 material wealth, they can be tested to that extent by economic 
 rules. This is the justification of applying the " let alone " 
 maxim to all commercial dealings between foreign countries. 
 
 When, however, we enter the province of the distribution ot 
 wealth, and have to deal not with goods and prices, but with 
 human beings and wages, we are confronted by a totally 
 different set of facts. Our postulate becomes at once of 
 questionable accuracy. The competing units are not, in fact, 
 upon a footing of equality. 
 
 There is some approach to an equality between those who 
 buy and sell commodities, because goods and capital can both 
 be moved from place to place, and the postponement of a sale 
 or purchase only leads to a loss of money. But between the 
 labourer who is unaided by a union and unprotected by law, 
 and his employer, equality rarely exists. He is seldom, if ever, 
 in a position to make terms as to the price at which he shall 
 sell his labour. Being seldom capable of more than one occu- 
 pation, he must find work at that or starve. This disadvantage 
 is to some extent removed by the institution of Trade Unionism, 
 which is to the labourer what capital is to his employer, in that 
 it enables him to delay the sale of his services until the market 
 for them rises. But even trade unions do not bring about a 
 sufficiently real equality between labourers and employers to 
 justify the use of economic rules in regulating their mutual 
 K 2
 
 148 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 relations. The value of human labour cannot under any circum- 
 stances be determined, like that of a commodity, simply by the 
 higgling of the market, because labour cannot be stored, 
 moved, or sampled, like a bale of goods. Mr. Frederic 
 Harrison! has very happily expressed this difference. "For 
 those," he says, " who have commodities to sell there is a true 
 market. Here competition acts rapidly, fully, simply, fairly. 
 It is totally otherwise with a day-labourer, who has no com- 
 modity to sell. He must be himself present at every market 
 which means costlypersonal locomotion. He cannot correspond 
 with his employer : he cannot send a sample of his strength : 
 nor do employers knock at his cottage door. Moreover, when 
 buyer and seller meet, the bargain is made; his price is paid, 
 the goods change hands, they part ; the contract is complete 
 the transaction ends. But the relation of employer and em- 
 ployed is permanent, or at least continuous. It involves the 
 entire existence of one at least ; it implies sustained co-opera- 
 tion. This is no contract to sell something ; it is the contract 
 to do something : it is a contract of partnership or joint 
 activity : it is an association involving every side of life." 
 
 These words contain the kernel of the labour question, 
 which Free Traders who believe in Laissez faire are apt to over- 
 look. And yet, if we would persuade the working-classes to 
 support Free Trade, it cannot be too often repeated that such 
 sentiments are not at variance with the practice of that policy.^ 
 
 1 Fortnightly Review, 1878. 
 
 2 Professor R. T. Ely, whose work on " The Labour Movement in 
 America " was not known to the writer when he penned the text, expresses the 
 same idea with admirable perspicuity (pp. 101-3). "The labourer,'' he says, 
 "must offer labour in the labour market in which he resides, and cannot seek 
 the best market, or even a better market, like others who sell commodities. 
 He is often too uneducated to know the conditions of the labour market in other 
 localities, and too ignorant to be able to pass judgment on such data as are at 
 Lis command. When he does know, his poverty frequently prevents his re- 
 moval ; for he cannot sell his commodity in a remote place unless he removes 
 his own person thither, nor can he ship, as others do, a sample of his 
 commodity. 
 
 " If the demand fall^, labour cannot be withdrawn from the market, like other
 
 Preparing the Arena. 149 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. vii.,?s.] 
 
 There is also another reason why economic conclusions can 
 seldom be applied with any confidence to a d'scussion abouc 
 wages, besides the unreality, in such cases, of the economic 
 postulate : namely, the paramount importance of the political 
 considerations by which they must be modified. These arise 
 from the very nature of the subject. Human beings cannot be 
 
 wares. On the contrary, as the demand decreases the supply nmst increase, by 
 reason of competition of a- greater number of labourers. There are several 
 causes for this. Members of the family who before did not work outside the 
 home chiefly children and women will seek labour to eke out the father's in- 
 come. A decreased demand usually occurs at time of a general depression, 
 and the ranks of the working-men are enlarged by accessions from other social 
 classes. Competition may thus increase in severity almost to an unliinited ex- 
 tent between labourers to secure what little work there is. Thus it happens 
 that when demand for labour diminishes, the fall in wages is apt to be more 
 than in proportion to this diminution in demand. 
 
 ' ' The cost of production is the limit below which the price of other commodi- 
 ties cannot permanently fall, for the production is diminished as the price falls, 
 and at times ceases almost altogether. But the individual labourer cannot 
 diminish his supply of labour so long as he lives, and misery and death ' are the 
 factors which must bring about a decrease in the supply of his commodity, and 
 raise its price to the cost of production : in other words, to what it costs the 
 labourer and his family to live and to maintain the customary standard of life 
 among the members of bis class. 
 
 " Closely connected with the foregoing is the fact that the price of labour does 
 not at once rise when the demand increases, as is usually the case with other 
 commodities, for the first effect is that the unemployed receive wovk ; and after 
 the ' reserve army ' finds employment competition among purchasers of labour 
 raises its price. 
 
 " Finally, the on'y way to diminish the supply of the commodity labour in the 
 market in the future is, by prudence in marriage, to diminish the birth-rate. 
 But to accomplish this, will and intelligence are necessary, and some prob- 
 ability that the labourer would reap the fruits of his self-denial. No such 
 guarantee exists, because the folly of his fellows will render h's prudence of no 
 avail. In addition to this, the labotiier in America can hope to influence the 
 supply of labour offered in the market of the future only when he gains some 
 control over immigration." 
 
 ' "The way these operate is so simple th.it it 0'.if;ht to be better understooH. Fe.v now 
 st.iive oulrljjht ; but a large numljci', especially of the youne;, starve gr.-'t'i-rJ'y. as has 
 been abuncjantly shown by iece.it inveslijaiions ; but many more depths are occasioned 
 in other ways. A carpenter is i I, aad previous hard times have exhausted his resources. 
 He dies ; wliereas a more generous supply of de'icacies, better iiuising, and more skdful 
 medical attendance, would Iiave saved his hfe. A seco.id mechanic is so poo. that he feels 
 that he cannot afford an umbrella. In a severe rain storm to which he is cxpo'-ed the 
 seeds of consumption are laid. A third is unable to afford new shoes, and wet feet at a
 
 150 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 argued about as if they were inanimate objects, but account 
 must be taken of their variations in desires, capacities^ and 
 action. It is impossible to argue about labouv as if it were a 
 commodity, both because the labourer himself is a conscious 
 beiii^, who may at any tin-e refi^se to ^ct r.'.cording to our con- 
 clusions, and bee. use the State has an overwhelming interest in 
 the character of his actions. The purchase; of wealth fulfils 
 his purpose when he buys his goods ; and the final end of the 
 goods themselves is to be used. But the purchaser of labour 
 buys that with which he desires to enter into relations of 
 a more or less permanent character. His object is to keep the 
 labour for future use. The object of the labourer, on the con- 
 trary, is to sell his labour upon such terms that he may be able 
 to use it afterwards in furtherance of his own purposes. And 
 by the side of both employer and labourer stands the State, 
 whose interest is that neither party should be injuriously affected 
 in his power to perform the duties of citizenship. But if the 
 bargain is unrestricted, the employer might gain such a control 
 over the other's labour that he would be able to defeat the 
 object of the seller by dictating all or most of the uses to which 
 it might afterwards be put. This is a necessary consequence 
 of the relationship of employer and employed, so that it is the 
 duty of the State to watch, lest the terms of the bargain should 
 be such as to destroy or stunt the moral or political existence 
 of its actual or unborn citizens. 
 
 Professor R. T. Ely suggests a third distinction between 
 labour and other commodities in " the uncertainty of existence, 
 which, more than actual difference in possessions, distinguishes 
 
 time of feebleness, and insutTicient nourishment, cause his death. The most distinguished 
 statistician of our day. Dr. Engel, calls the causes of most deaths ' social.' The difficulty 
 is not to prescribe a remedy, but to apply it. A physician cannot tell a man earning a 
 dollar a day to take a trip to Egypt for weak lungs. No current fiction is more widely 
 removed from the truth than the common assertion that working-men and their families 
 enjoy exceptionally good health. The exact opposite is the truth ; and statistics have 
 established the fact beyond controversy that labourers are shorter-lived by many years 
 than those who belong to the wealthier social classes. Dr. Lyman Abbott quotes some 
 interesting statistics on this subject in a recent article in the Century Magazine."
 
 Preparing the Arena. 151 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. vii., \ 5.] 
 
 the well-to-do from the poor." The whole passage in which 
 Mr. Ely criticises the "natural liberty views" of Adam Smith 
 is worth quoting. {" The Labour Movement in America," 
 pp. 97-100.) 
 
 " The economic philosophers of the time believed that legal 
 equality and freedom of contract were the sole conditions 
 needed to enable the working-classes to secure a share of the 
 product of national industry sufficient to serve as a basis for 
 their physical, ethical, and spiritual development. This theory 
 was based on two fallacies : the first was the assumption of the 
 natural equality of men. The differences found among men, in 
 their opinion, were not due to original native qualities, but were 
 
 the result of education, legislation, and government 
 
 The second fallacy was the assumption that labour was a com- 
 modity just like other commodities, and the labourer a man 
 with a commodity for sale just like other men who offer their 
 wares to the public. It is true that labour is a commodity, for 
 it is bought and sold, but there are peculiarities about it which 
 distinguish it from other commodities, and that most radically. 
 
 " While labour is a commodity, it is an expenditure of human 
 force which involves the welfare of a personality. It is a com- 
 modity which is inseparably bound up with the labourer; and 
 in this it differs from other commodities. The one who offers 
 other commodities for sale reserves his own person. The 
 farmer who parts with a thousand bushels of wheat for money 
 reserves control of his own actions ; they are not brought in 
 question at all. Again, the man of property who sells other 
 commodities has an option. He may part with his wares and 
 maintain his life from other goods received in exchange, or he 
 can have recourse to his labour-power. The labourer, however, 
 has, as a rule, only the service residing in his own person with 
 wliich to sustain himself and his family. Again, a machine a 
 locomotive, for example and a working-man resemble each 
 other in this : they both render services, and the fate of both 
 depends upon the manner in which these services are extracted.
 
 152 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 But there is this radical difference : the machine which yields 
 its service to man is itself a commodity, and is only a means to 
 an end, while the labourer who parts with labour is no longer 
 a commodity in civilised lands, but is an end in himself, for 
 man is the beginning and termination of all economic life. The 
 consequence for the great mass of labourers possessed of only 
 average qualities are as follows, provided there is no interven- 
 tion of legislation, and provided the working-classes are not or- 
 ganised : While those who sell other commodities are able to 
 influence the price by a suitable regulation of production, so as 
 to bring about a satisfactory relation between supply and de- 
 mand, the purchaser of labour has it in his own power to 
 determine the price of this commodity and the other conditions 
 of sale. There may be exceptions for a time in a new country, 
 but these are temporary, and often more apparent than real. 
 Even now in the United States the right of capital to rule is 
 generally assumed as a matter of course, and when labour 
 would determine price and conditions of service, it is 
 called dictation. The reason is that man comes to this world 
 without reference to supply and demand,^ and the poverty of 
 the labourer compels him to offer the use of his labour-power 
 unreservedly and continuously. The purchase of labour gives 
 control over the labourer, and a far-reaching influence over his 
 physical, intellectual, social, and ethical existence. The con- 
 ditions of the labour contract determine the amount of this 
 rulership. Again, while illness, inability to labour by reason 
 of accident, or old age and death, do not destroy other com- 
 modities, or their power to support life, when these misfortunes 
 overtake the person of the labourer, he loses his power to sell 
 his only property, the commodity labour, and he can no longer 
 support himself and those dependent upon him." 
 
 1 " There are certain qualifications to what is here said which the limits of 
 this book will not allow me to ^numerate. It would he far too large a work 
 for present purposes were every to])ic to be treated exliausiively. I aUays 
 take it for granted that my reader is possessed of common sense, and will not 
 raise trivial objections ; also that he is to do some thinking himself.
 
 PflEPARlNG THE ArENA. 153 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. vii., 16.) 
 
 For these reasons, and for others which will readily suggest 
 themselves to a reader's mind, it follows that there is a radical 
 distinction between the ideas which may be applied in the pro- 
 duction of wealth and those which may be applied in its distri- 
 bution. Working-men have always insisted by their actions, if 
 not by words, that this distinction existed, although it 
 must be confessed that many Free Traders have been slow to 
 perceive that this contention was no less sound in theory than 
 it is true in fact. The wages of labour and the price of goods 
 are not in fact now, nor have they ever been, determined by the 
 same forces ; nor is it possible to use the processes of economic 
 reasoning in a discussion of this topic without adopting the 
 most fanciful assumptions. 
 
 6. The ideas which are expressed in the foregoing obser- 
 vations were only slowly recognised by politicians and eco- 
 nomists ; but in this respect the politicians led the way. 
 
 What is termed the great industrial revolution, consequent 
 upon the invention of machinery and the use of steam as a 
 motive power, came upon England with appalling suddenness. 
 The centres of industry shifted when its methods changed, and 
 great towns grew up upon the sides of what only ten years pre- 
 viously had been silent valleys. Population naturally followed 
 to the new workshops, and, once there, changed every habit of 
 its ancient life. The system of domestic industry under which 
 men worked in their own homes, employing a few apprentices 
 or journeymen, whom they treated as members of the family, 
 vanished utterly, and almost in a moment, before the institution 
 of the factory. The consequence was that all the old relation- 
 ships of industrial life were wrenched asunder, and for the first 
 time in English history the labourer was left entirely unpro- 
 tected in making terms with his employer. I'efore this date 
 he had always been strengthened by some support, whether of 
 legislation or custom. Even the laws which he was beginning 
 to find oppressive, sucli as those against apprenticeship or those
 
 154 Industrial Freedom, 
 
 which fixed wages, operated not infrequently to his advantage ; 
 while when laws failed custom intervened. " Custom," as 
 Mill observed, ** has always been the great protector of the 
 weak against the strong," In England it had turned the 
 villeins into copyholders, and to this day it forms the basis of 
 that benevolent despotism which the best of squires and 
 parsons exercise in many English parishes. Among the 
 artisans it had worked principally through the Trade Guilds, 
 whose customary regulations, harassing as they were beginning 
 to become, were originally designed to help the labourer to a 
 better footing, and to prevent unscrupulous employers from 
 taking an advantage of his weakness. All these safeguards 
 disappeared at the inauguration of the new industrial era. A 
 new set of employers grew up, having no high traditions of their 
 class, and subject to the restraints of no public opinion in their 
 dealings with workmen. The consequence was that for some 
 sixty years from 1770 to 1830 the relations between em- 
 ployers and employed were largely determined by an unre- 
 stricted competition, with a result so frightful in its cruelty and 
 horror that the experiment will never be repeated.^ Whatever 
 
 1 The story is well known, and w-ould in any case be out of place in the 
 present treatise. It may be read in the works of Karl Marx, or in the pages of 
 " Yeast," " Sybil," or "Alton Locke." One phase of it will illustrate the whole, 
 and may be told in the words used by Mr. Gibbins in his " Industrial History 
 of England " (pp. 178-9) : "When factories were first built there was a strong 
 repugnance on the part of parents, who had been accustomed to the old family 
 life under the domestic system, to send their children into these places. It was, 
 in fact, considered a disgrace so to do : the epithet of ' factory girl ' was the most 
 insulting that could be applied to a young woman, and girls who had once been 
 in a factory could never find employment elsewhere. It was not until the wages 
 of the workmen had been reduced to a starvation level that they consented to 
 their children and wives being employed in the mills. But the manufacturers 
 wanted labour by some means or other, and they got it. They got it from the 
 workhouses. They sent for parish apprentices from all parts of England, and 
 pretended to apj^rentice them to the new employments just introduced. The 
 mill-owners systematically conmiunicated with the overseers of the poor, who 
 arranged a day for the inspection of pauper children. Those chosen by the 
 manufacturer were then conveyed by waggons or canal-boats to their destina- 
 tion, and from that moment were doomed to slavery. Sometimes regular 
 traffickers would take the place of the manufacturer, and transfer a number of
 
 Preparing the Arena, 155 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. vii., 5 6.] 
 
 may be the evils of State interference, freedom of contract in 
 the determination of wages inevitably leads to industrial 
 anarchy. The working-classes instinctively felt that their only 
 
 children to a factory district, and there keep them, generally in some dark 
 cellar, till they could hand them over to a mill-owner in want of hands, who 
 would come and examine their height, strength, and bodily capacities, exactly 
 as did the slave-dealers in the American markets. After that the children were 
 simply at the mercy of their owners, nominally as apprentices, but in reality as 
 mere slaves, who got no wages, and whom it was not worth while even to feed 
 and clothe properly, because they were so cheap, and their places could be so 
 easily supplied. It was often arranged by the parish authorities, in order to 
 get rid of imbeciles, that one idiot should be taken by the mill-owner with every 
 twenty sane children. The fate of these unhappy idiots was even worse than 
 that of the others. The secret of their final end has never been disclosed, but 
 we can form some idea of their awful sufferings from the hardships of the other 
 victims to capitalist greed and cruelty. Their treatment was most inhuman. 
 The hours of their labour were only limited by exhaustion, after many modes 
 of torture had been unavailingly applied to force continued work. Children 
 were often worked sixteen hours a day, by day or by night. Even Sunday was 
 used as a convenient time to clean the machinery." The author of the 
 " History of the Factory Movement " writes : "In stench, in heated rooms, 
 amid the constant whirling of a thousand wheels, little fingers and little feet 
 were kept in ceaseless action, forced into unnatural activity by blows from the 
 heavy hands and feet of the merciless over-looker, and the infliction of bodily 
 pain by instruments of punishment invented by the sharpened ingenuity of in- 
 satiable selfishness. They were fed upon the coarsest and cheapest food, often 
 with the same as that served cut to the pigs of their master. They slept by 
 turns and in relays in filthy beds which were never cool, for one set of children 
 were sent to sleep in them as soon as the others had gone off to their daily or 
 nightly toil. There was often no discrimination of sexes, and disease, misery, 
 and vice grew as in a hotbed of contagion. Some of these miserable beings 
 tried to run away. To prevent their doing so, those suspected of this tendency 
 had irons riveted on their ankles with long links reaching up to the hips, and 
 were compelled to work and sleep in these chains, young women and girls, as 
 well as boys, suffering this brutal treatment. Many died, and were buried 
 secretly at night in some desolate spot, lest people should notice the number of 
 the graves ; and many committed suicide. 'I'he catalogue of cruelty and misery 
 is too long to recite here ; it may be read in the ' Memoirs of Robert Blincoe," 
 himself an apprentice, or in the pages of the Blue-books of the beginning of this 
 century, in which even the methodical, dry, official language is startled into life 
 by the misery it has to relate. It is, perhaps, not well for me to say more about 
 the subject, for one dares not trust oneself to try and set down calmly all that 
 might be told about this awful page in the history of industrial England. I 
 need only remark that during this period of unheeded and ghastly suffering in 
 the mills of our native land the British philanthropist was occupying himself 
 with agitating for the relief of the very largely imaginary woes of negro slaves
 
 156 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 safeguard was Protective legislation. Being forbidden by law 
 to combine in their own defence, or even to meet for the pur- 
 pose of discussing grievances,! they were of necessity compelled 
 to rely upon an outside power. Their demands were supported 
 by the Tory party, in part from genuine sympathy, and in part 
 from a feeling of hostility towards the class of manufacturers. 
 The first ameliorative measure was passed in 1803, for the better 
 regulation of the labour of children ; and then began that long 
 series of enactments designed to place the workman in a posi- 
 tion of equality with his employer, which has been more 
 characteristic of the legislation of Great Britain than of any 
 other country, and which, even in Great Britain, is not yet 
 completed. The Factory Acts, the Mining Acts, the Friendly 
 Societies and Trades Union Acts, the Education Acts, the 
 Employers' Liability Act, the Pawnbrokers' Act, the Ground 
 Game Act, the Agricultural Holdings Act, the Truck Acts, 
 the Irish Land Act of 1881, and many others, are illustrations 
 of this movement. All of these were, in the strict sense of the 
 word, Socialistic measures. They all invoked the intervention 
 of the State to remedy artificial inequalities, and place the 
 competitors in the industrial strife more nearly on a footing of 
 equality. All of these, as has been said, were opposed in the 
 name of Free Trade, and as an interference with freedom of 
 
 in other countries. He, of course, succeeded in raising the usual amount of 
 sentiment, and perhaps more than the usual amount of money, on behalf of an 
 inferior and barbaric race, who have repaid him by relapsing into a contented 
 indolence and a scarcely concealed savagery which have gone far to ruin our 
 possessions in the West Indies. The spectacle of England buying the freedom 
 of black slaves by riches drawn from the labour of her white ones affords an 
 interesting study for the cynical philosopher." 
 
 And yet proposals to remedy this state of things by means of legislation 
 were opposed in the name of Free Trade. No wonder that the policy has a 
 hard struggle to obtain a favourable consideration at the hands of working 
 men ! 
 
 1 This state of the law was first modified in 1824, but workmen were not 
 finally put upon an equality with employers in this respect until 1876. The first 
 volume of the new series of "State Trials, "now in course of publication, throws 
 a most lurid light upon the oppressive character of this class of legislation.
 
 Preparing the Arena. i^i 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. vii.,5 6.] 
 
 contract ; yet in reality they were an attempt to establish a real 
 state of freedom, in which the stronger party to the bargain 
 could not take advantage of the other's weakness. England 
 has, in consequence, had her reward in being the country of all 
 others which is most free from the fanatical spirit of revolu- 
 tionary anarchism.i But this remedial legislation is not ended 
 
 I Any one who examines English social legislation will see that it is very far 
 in advance of Australia in all respects except that of education. As illustrating 
 the immense distance which England has advanced beyond the United States 
 in her industrial legislation, it may be mentioned that of the sixteen demands 
 contained in the platform of the Socialist Labour Party, which is one of the 
 most radical organisations in the United States, no less than twelve (marked * 
 in the subjoined list) have been wholly or in part granted by the English Par- 
 liament. Some of these have been enjoyed by English workmen for many 
 years. The platform is published in full by Professor Ely, in his " Labour 
 Movement in America " (pp. 366-70), and is as follows : 
 
 * I. The United States shall take possession of the railroads, canals, tele- 
 
 graphs, telephones, and all other means of public transportation. 
 
 * 2. The municipalities to take possession of the local railroads, of ferries, 
 
 and of the supply of Hght to streets and public places. 
 3. Public lands to be declared inalienable. They shall be leased accord- 
 ing to fixed principles. Revocation of all grants of lands by the 
 United States to corporations or individuals the conditions of which 
 have not been complied with, or which are otherwise illegal, 
 
 * 4. The United States to have the exclusive right to issue money. 
 
 * 5. Congressional legislation, providing for the scientific management of 
 
 forests and waterways, and prohibiting the waste of the natural re- 
 sources of the country. 
 
 6. The United States to have the right of expropriation of running 
 
 patents ; new inventions to be free to all, but inventors to be re- 
 munerated by national rewards. 
 
 7. Legal provision that the rent of dwellings shall not exceed a per- 
 
 centage of the value of the building, as taxed by the municipality. 
 
 8. Inauguration of public works in times of economical depression. 
 
 * 9. Progressive income tax and lax on inheritances ; but smaller incomes 
 
 to be exempt. 
 
 * 10. Compulsory school education of all children under fourteen years of 
 
 age ; instruction in all educational institutions to be gratuitous, and 
 to be made accessible to all by public assistance (furnishing meals, 
 clothes, books, &c.). All instruction to be under the direction of 
 the United States, and to be organised on a uniform plan. 
 II. Repeal of all pauper, tramp, conspiracy, and temperance laws. Un- 
 abridged right of combination. 
 
 * 12 Oftlcial statistics concerning the condition of labour. Prohibition of
 
 158 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 yet. So long as there are any who are forced by external cir- 
 cumstances, in whose ordering they have had no voice, to start 
 in the struggle for existence handicapped by want of education : 
 so long as there are others who are weakened in the power of 
 self-improvement by any alterable condition of society : so long 
 as the State or public opinion maintains any institution which 
 directly or indirectly causes to others physical misery or 
 mental darkness so long it will be the duty of Free Traders 
 and Protectionists alike to agitate for a policy of action 
 which may bring us nearer to the day when inaction can be 
 justified. 
 
 7. It would be easy to amplify these observations 
 on the policy of " Let alone " into a treatise of many 
 pages,^ but enough has been said to illustrate the ne- 
 cessity of using the maxim with extreme caution in in- 
 dustrial matters. For the purposes of the Free Trade 
 argument, it cannot be too often repeated, if we would 
 persuade the wage-receiver to support Free Trade, that the 
 most Socialistic sentiments in favour of an alteration in their 
 industrial condition are not at variance with the teachings 
 of P'ree Trade. The experience derived from the practice of 
 Free Trade is no justification for the denunciation of State 
 interference in other directions. The unrestricted competition 
 
 the employment of children in tlie school age, and the employment 
 of female labour in occupations detrimental to health or morality. 
 Prohibition of the convict labour contract system. 
 
 * 13. All wages to be paid in cash money. Equalisation by law of women's 
 
 wages with those of men where equal service is performed. 
 
 * 14. Laws for the protection of life and limbs of working people, and an 
 
 efficient employers' liability law. 
 
 * 15. Legal incorporation of trades unions. 
 
 * 16. Reduction of the hours of labour in proportion to the progress of pro- 
 
 duction ; establishment by Act of Congress of a legal work-day of 
 not more than eight hours for all industrial workers, and correspond- 
 ing provisions for all agricultural labourers. 
 1 Montagu's "Limits of Individual Liberty" and Sir James Stephen's 
 " Liberty, Equahty, and Fraternity," may be referred to in this connection.
 
 Preparing the Arena. 159 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. vi!i.,? I.] 
 
 of private persons may be an expedient of great value in 
 furthering the production and exchange of goods, without 
 thereby becoming a general maxim of public policy. Free 
 Trade acts within its own province, and within that province, 
 but no further, it justifies an unrestricted competition. It may 
 be that Professor Sumner and Mr. Herbert Spencer are correct 
 in applying the principle to other departments of human 
 activity. On this question Free Trade offers no guidance in 
 the formation of a right judgment. Certainly, many Free 
 Traders, who to all appearance form a majority of the party, 
 vehemently repudiate the doctrines of Administrative Nihilism ; 
 while of those who are inclined to adopt it in a more or less 
 modified form, none need be induced by any Free Trade 
 leanings to deify the principle of competition and close their 
 eyes to every instance of its ravages. Nothing in the theory 
 or practice of Free Trade declares that competition ought to 
 be the governing influence of social life. A Free Trader would 
 rather be inclined to the opinion that competition is a force of 
 nature, like a flood or a gale, which, in Bacon's phrase, " man 
 must obey, so as to command." But the path of commercial 
 freedom lies altogether apart from these large questions. 
 
 CHAPTER Vni. 
 
 PROTECTION AND SOCIALISM. 
 
 I. In the discussion of all political arguments, one of two 
 theories of State action must be either expressed or assumed. 
 Beh'evers in Laisscz faire will adopt the view that the State is 
 a mere organisation for police purposes, with no constructive 
 powers or moral duties. Others, on the contrary among 
 whom all Protectionists ought to be numbered regard the
 
 i6o Industrial Freedom. 
 
 State as an organised expression of the popular will, which is 
 capable of directing individual citizens to the achievement of 
 many high aims. They believe that the power of combination 
 can reach to many things which are not attainable by individual 
 effort, and that the State is the greatest of all combinations for 
 the realisation of a complete and harmonious development 
 both of the individual and the nation. This view of State 
 action, which admits of many varieties, is in its essence 
 Socialism. 
 
 As we proceed to examine the political arguments by 
 which Protection is supported, we shall tind that all of them 
 are really contained in the single contention that under Free 
 Trade the rich may grow richer, but the poor nmst grow 
 poorer ! To prevent this, the State must interfere by regu- 
 lating the nature and restricting the quantity of foreign 
 exchanges. 
 
 What ought to be the attitude of Free Traders towards this 
 line of argument ? 
 
 We have seen in the last chapter that the argument for 
 Free Trade is independent of either a belief or disbelief in 
 the general wisdom of a policy of Laissez-faire. The same 
 arguments can be used to prove its independence of a belief 
 or disbelief in Socialism. But is it the part of a prudent 
 controversialist to use them ? 
 
 2. If we want to strike at the opinions which really sway 
 the judgment of Protectionists, we must attack them with 
 considerations of unquestionable strength. Now, seeing that 
 no Protectionist can admit that the "police theory" of State 
 action has any validity, it will be necessary to conduct the 
 argument against him from another standpoint. Accordingly, 
 we must meet him once more upon his own ground, and, admit- 
 ting the correctness of his Socialistic theory, demonstrate by his 
 own tests that tariff taxes, although they are Socialistic in their 
 method, do not accomplish the results which Socialists desire. 
 
 Many Free Traders of whom the writer is one would
 
 Preparing the Arena. i6i 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. viii., \ 2.] 
 
 readily and from conviction take this stand ; and, adopting 
 the view that the State must energetically use its power to 
 widen the sphere within which each man's will may work with 
 complete freedom, would be prepared to prove that the influ- 
 ence of Protection is no less pernicious in its moral than in its 
 material effects upon the development of a free people. Pro- 
 fessor Sumner, on the contrary, and a large class of Free Trade 
 writers, denounce Socialism in any form, and make the Social- 
 ism of Protection to be the head and front of its offending. 
 
 It is a curious instance of the hap-hazard inconsistencies of 
 most political opinions that many Protectionists indignantly 
 repudiate any connection between their views and those of the 
 Socialists. In fact, Socialism generally finds its strongest 
 enemies among Protected manufacturers. The men who 
 most detest and fear the spread of Socialist opinions are those 
 who owe their fortunes to Socialistic voters. Yet sincere 
 Protectionists who are also sincere opponents of Socialism 
 must either close their ears to all reasoning about principles or 
 have very uneasy consciences. 
 
 Professor Sumner has pointed out the connection between 
 these two policies with his usual terse lucidity : 
 
 "When I say that Protectionism is Socialism, I mean to classify it, 
 and bring it not only under the proper heading, but into relation 
 with its true affinities. Socialism is any device or doctritie i:<hose aim 
 is to save individuals from any of the difficulties or hardships of the 
 strugi:;le for existence and the competition of life by the intervention 
 of ' the State.'' Inasmuch as ' the State ' never is, or can be, 
 anything but some other people, Socialism is a device for making 
 some people fight the struggle for existence for others. The 
 devices always have a doctrine behind them which aims to prove 
 why this ought to be done. 
 
 " The Protected interests demand that they be saved from the 
 trouble and annoyance of business competition, and that they be 
 assured profits in their undertakings by ' the State ' : that is, at 
 the expense of their fellow-citizens. If this is not Socialism, then 
 there is no such thing. If employers may demand that ' the State ' 
 shall guarantee them profits, why may not the employes deni.ind 
 that 'the State' shall guarantee them wages? If we are taxed to 
 
 L
 
 1 62 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 provide profits, M'hy should we not be taxed for public workshops, 
 for insurance to labourers, or for any other devices which will give 
 wages, and save the labourer from the annoyances of life and the 
 risks and hardships of the struggle for existence? the ' we ' who 
 are to pay changes all the time, and the turn of the Protected 
 employer to pay will surely come before long. The plan of all 
 living on each other is capable of great expansion. It is, as yet, far 
 from being perfected, or carried out completely. The Protectionists 
 are only educating those who are as yet on the ' paying ' side of it, 
 but who will certainly use political power to put themselves also on 
 the ' receiving ' side of it. The argument that ' the State ' must do 
 something for me because my business does not pay is a very far- 
 reaching argument. If it is good for pig-iron and woollens, it is 
 good for all the things to which the Socialists apply it." 
 
 3. It would be interesting to hear a Protected manufac- 
 turer in answer to Professor Sumner's convincing words. His 
 reasoning, however, does not appeal with the same force to a 
 large class of Free Traders. 
 
 It would unnecessarily interrupt the present argument to 
 introduce a discussion on the attitude of Free Traders to the 
 large questions of policy involved in the theory of Socialism. 
 It will, however, not be out of place to remind those Protec- 
 tionists who are also Socialists that the Free Traders who re- 
 fuse to accept the maxim of ^'Laissezfaire'' as a scientific dogma 
 are pledged to no rejection of a measure because it happens 
 to be Socialistic. They are not to be scared by a nickname. 
 
 Recognising that the Factory Acts, the Poor Law, the 
 Irish Land Act, and many of the most beneficial measures of 
 this century, are Socialistic in their essence, they do not shrink 
 from other applications of the same principle. They do, how- 
 ever, require to be satisfied on three points before they will 
 support State action : viz., First that the State is the best 
 agency for the accomplishment of that which is desired ; 
 secondly That this object cannot be obtained by private 
 enterprise ; and thirdly that the result, when obtained, and 
 when all its effects are taken into account, is worth having on 
 a balance of advantages and disadvantages. 
 
 i
 
 Preparing the Arena. 163 
 
 Pt. II., Ch. vlli., ? 3.] 
 
 They say, further, that no satisfactory assurance can be 
 given by Protectionists as to any of these three demands. 
 
 It is the subject of the following chapters to inquire whether 
 this be true. 
 
 Note to Chapter VIII. 
 
 THE LIMITS OF STATE INTERFERENCE. 
 
 This is not the place to elaborate a theory of State interference, but 
 since Free Traders are accused of being fanatical adherents of that theory, 
 which would confine the action of the State to keeping order and adminis- 
 tering affairs, it is well, before mentioning particular cases, to state 
 summarily, and without reference to other matters, the general principles 
 on which Free Traders might justify a more active interference by the 
 State. 
 
 The State exists in order to secure liberty : that is to say, to bring about 
 conditions under which every citizen can, by a conscious exercise of will, at 
 all times do that which is best. Having provided these conditions, the 
 function of the State is at an end. Other influences must determine what 
 is good or bad, and must supply the motive which would make men choose 
 the former. Philosophy and religion begin their operations upon the 
 ground which the State has cleared ; but the action of the State should not 
 interfere with the work of either. It consequently becomes one part of the 
 business of political science to define the limits within which the State can 
 act without trenching on the province of moral agencies. It is not 
 necessary now to show in detail where those limits reach. It is enough for 
 our present purpose to mark them in rough outline. 
 
 Laws exist to prevent men unduly interfering with the individual free- 
 dom of their fellow-citizens ; or, looked at in another way, a law defines a 
 sphere within which each man's will may work with complete freedom. 
 What, then, determines the exact amount of interference with individual 
 freedom which is necessary for the advantage of Society? To that we 
 answer "Experience," and a clear sense of what is needed by the 
 individual, in order that he may attain to a full and harmonious develop- 
 ment. Whether this clearer sense of what is needed is evolved by 
 inherited instinct, or whether it is due to the inspired direction of sacred 
 writers, matters not to the State. All that the State has to do is to see 
 that such social conditions exist, that Society may satisfy its wants so soon 
 as it becomes aware of them, and so soon as it is certain that their satis- 
 faction is necessary to human development. Tliis is the utmost which the 
 State can do. It must not attempt to decide for Society what moral 
 influence should guide its judgments ; still less must it interfere witli the 
 
 I. 2
 
 164 Industrial Preedom. 
 
 free determination by every individual of the guiding principles of his own 
 life. Consequently, every act of the State is bad which weakens the 
 motives to self-improvement, either by unnecessarily taking away a duty 
 which is owed to others (as, for instance, the care of children), or by 
 preventing the full play of the human instinct towards self-development. 
 A law which forbids men to think as they like, and to express their 
 thoughts with a due regard to the public order, is bad, on the same ground 
 that a law would be bad which weakened individual self-reliance, or which 
 removed the motives towards thrift and industry. 
 
 It would seem, then, that the principles by which any act of State 
 interference should be tested may be summarised as follows : 
 
 1. The State ought in no case to weaken the motives for morality. 
 
 2. The State should not do that which might be done as well by private 
 
 persons. 
 
 3. The State should never act in such a way as to weaken individual 
 
 self-reliance. 
 But where the object to be gained is one of national importance, which 
 the efforts of individuals cannot accomplish, and when it can be gained 
 without discouraging any from making efforts on their own behalf, or from 
 entering into union for a common purpose, then all the conditions are 
 present which are required to justify State action.
 
 ^ai-t III. 
 
 THE ECONOMIC ARGUMENT. 
 
 CHAPTER I. 
 
 FREE TRADE IN ITS EFFECT UPON PRODUCTION. 
 
 I. In estimating the economic value of any fiscal policy, 
 the test to be applied is (as has already been mentioned^) the 
 effect of the policy in increasing the national productiveness. 
 The actual application of this test to the circumstances of a 
 particular country is, no doubt, extremely difficult ; but 
 its. theoretic value as a test of the economic efiicacy of 
 rival fiscal policies is, as we have seen, not on that account 
 impaired. 
 
 The material prosperity of a country must, in the long run, 
 depend upon the capacity of its citizens to produce wealth, so 
 that whatever enlarges that capacity must, per se, be an 
 advantage. Some men may take more interest in schemes for 
 distributing wealth than in schemes for facilitating its produc- 
 tion;, but no one can say that an increase in the national 
 productiveness can, of itself, and without the aid of any other 
 influence, cause any diminution in the material welfare of the 
 general body of citizens. The increase of wealth may be 
 accompanied by a displacement of labour and capital from one 
 industry to another, and such a displacement would probably 
 cause much undeserved suffering to individuals ; but if the 
 result of the displacement were that more wealth was produced 
 than had been produced before, no one could say that tlie 
 nition as a 7v/iole had become poorer. Possibly, iVc incrensc 
 
 ' Sec p. 79.
 
 1 66 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 of wealth might be accompanied by such grave evils of a 
 poUtical character that many men might reasonably wish to 
 keep their country poor. But this is a consideration of politics, 
 and not of economics, which will be dealt with in its proper 
 place. 
 
 When we come to deal with the political arguments upon 
 the tariff, arguments will be advanced to show that Free Trade 
 does not, and cannot, prejudicially affect the distribution of 
 national wealth ; but that, on the contrary, it assists the 
 labouring and poorer classes to obtain a fairer share of the 
 products of their toil by its efficacy in extending the area of 
 employment, in steadying wages, and in reducing the cost of 
 living. 
 
 At present, however, let us consider Free Trade solely as 
 an influence upon the production of wealth, and, waiving every 
 other consideration, follow the single inquiry, " How Free 
 Trade affects the aggregate of wealth within a country." 
 
 2. This is a matter which has already been so over- 
 laboured by writers on Free Trade, that it is not necessary 
 in this treatise to do more than indicate the heads of the 
 argument. 
 
 Regarded in its influence on production, Free Trade is 
 simply an expedient for carrying the piinciple of the division of 
 employment into international commerce. As it is found in 
 domestic industries that the largest quantity is produced when 
 each man confines himself to a particular department, so it can 
 be shown conclusively that wealth will accumulate most rapidly 
 in a country which produces those articles in the production of 
 which it has especial natural advantages, and exchanges these 
 for the other things it needs. Just as a baker would waste his 
 time by making his own clothes, so will a nation spend its 
 labour uselessly liy producing articles at greater cost than it can 
 buy them from another country. Nature gives gratuitously 
 to every country advantages peculiar to itself to one it is
 
 The Economic Argument. 167 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. ii., \ I.] 
 
 coal, to another iron, to another wheat, to another wool ; but, 
 thanks to Free Exchange, men in every quarter of the globe 
 can serve themselves of these free gifts. 
 
 Free Trade, as has often been remarked, is only another 
 name for voluntary trade. If, therefore, every man follows 
 his own interest, he will prefer to trade in whatever calling 
 returns him the largest profits. Accordingly, if we find 
 the citizens of any country in which capital and labour are 
 abundant choosing certain occupations in preference to others, 
 the reason must be that the occupations which they adopt are 
 considered likely to return them a larger profit than those 
 which they avoid. Following out these ideas, we reach the 
 familiar Free Trade conception of industrial progress, which 
 is, that as capital accumulates and labourers increase, the 
 desire for gain is a sufficient motive to secure the devclopmen 
 of every suitable industry. 
 
 CHAPTER II. 
 
 PROTECTION AND PRODUCTION. 
 
 I. We have next to consider the operation of Protection 
 upon the production of wealth. If any quantity of labour is 
 attracted from old and more profitable to new and less profit- 
 able occupations, it is plain that, unless there should haj^pen to 
 be a compensating increase in the productiveness of the labourer 
 which is left in the old pursuits, tlicre must be a decrease in the 
 national productiveness. 
 
 Now, altliough an increase in the productiveness of an 
 industry may, through an improvement in the process of manu- 
 flicturc, or through some other agency, occur simultaneously 
 with the withdrawal of a portion of the labour and capital 
 previously employed in it, the increase is seldom, if ever.
 
 1 68 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 occasioned by such a withdrawal. On the contrary, in most 
 industries the greater the expenditure of labour and cai)ital, 
 the greater the result. 
 
 The conclusion is thus reached that a withdrawal of capital 
 and labour from more to less profitable occupations must 
 occasion a loss of national wealth equivalent to the difference 
 between the profitableness of the natural and the artificial 
 industries. Suppose, for example, that the average rate of 
 profit under the natural conditions of a Free Trade country 
 where no special inducement is offered to follow one trade 
 rather than another, be ten per cent., and that an industry which 
 is not yet established in the country would only return three 
 per cent. : it is plain that unless these two rates of profit more 
 nearly approach each other, the industry which returns the 
 lower rate will be neglected ; and that to attract labour from 
 an industry which returns ten per cent, into one which only 
 returns three would be a net loss of seven per cent. 
 
 So far, the argument has proceeded upon the assumption 
 that the capital and labour which are required to establish a 
 Protected industry must be withdrawn from some other 
 employment. It remains to consider the supposition that 
 these may be imported from a foreign country. If this should 
 happen to any large extent, there will, undoubtedly, be an 
 increase to the national wealth. Consequently, if Protection is 
 to be carried out to the greatest advantage, each new industry 
 that is established must be created and sustained by imported 
 labour and imported capital. This has been the case in many 
 industries in the United States, where the huge burden of the 
 Protective tariff is only borne with such apparent ease on 
 account of the enormous influx of labour and capital from other 
 countries. In the cases of Canada and Victoria the influx has 
 not been so marked; while in all the Australian Colonies those 
 who most strongly advocate Protection most strongly oppose 
 assisted immigration. It may, therefore, be taken as a fact that 
 in most young countries, where tlie annual increase of population
 
 The Economic Argument. 169 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. ii., \ I. 
 
 is not larger than can be employed in the natural develop- 
 ment of the country, and where able-bodied persons willing to 
 work are always in demand, the labour and capital required to 
 start new industries must be supplied within the community, 
 and must therefore be withdrawn from those industries which 
 have grown up naturally and without State aid. 
 
 The cases, therefore, in which Protection induces an im- 
 portation of labour and capital need not materially qualify the 
 conclusion previously arrived at, that a transference of capital 
 and labour from an industry which returns a satisfactory profit 
 to one which would return a less profit, if it were not for the 
 subsidy given indirectly by a Proteciive tax, must cause an 
 immediate loss of wealth to the community. 
 
 In the most favourable view of the transaction the tax can 
 only cause a transference of money from the pockets of one 
 set of citizens into those of another j while what happens in 
 actual practice is a transference of money from those who 
 were using it reproductively to those who must use it un- 
 productively unless they are assisted by a subsidy, together 
 with a loss of many of the coins during the process of transfer, 
 owing to the cost of maintaining Custom House officers to 
 effect the operation. During the process of transfer many of 
 the coins fall upon the ground, and become visible to every 
 bystander. In such a case, if the bystander is a Protectionist, 
 he at once exclaims that the wealth of his country is in- 
 creasing ; and the more often a display is made of the same 
 coins the louder become his exclamations ! 
 
 The experience of Canada offers an instance, which is 
 cited by Sir T. Farrer, of the effect of a Protective tariff in 
 developing some industries at the expense of others. In 
 187S, under Free Trade, Canada exported of Iicr own manu- 
 factures to the value of ^825,000. In 1S84 she only exported 
 them to the value of ^700,000 : in spite of the fact that lier 
 population had increased and the development of her natural 
 resources had been improved during those six years.
 
 1 7 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 2. But the diminution of the productive power of a 
 country which is occasioned by the transference of capital 
 and labour from a more to a less profitable occupation is not 
 the only prejudicial effect which Protection has upon the 
 aggregate of national wealth. 
 
 The essential object of Protection is to draw people into 
 industries which they have hitherto declined to enter. The 
 inducement offered is, of course, pecuniary. The patriotic 
 founder of a new industry is to be protected against the 
 competition of anyone who lives inside the borders of another 
 country ; and this protection is to be afforded by means of a 
 tax upon all imported articles of the same nature with those 
 which he produces. 
 
 The first question which presents itself under these circum- 
 stances is as to the amount of the duty which it will be 
 necessary to impose to effect this object. The duty must 
 clearly be sufficient to enable the manufacturer to sell his 
 goods at a remunerative price. Now, a remunerative price 
 must be a price which will give the manufacturer the same 
 return for his monej', skill, and time as he could obtain by a 
 similar expenditure in any other occupation which is carried 
 on within the country. In other words, he must obtain the 
 average rate of profit {whatever that may be) which rules in 
 the community, taking into account the usual considerations, 
 such as risk, agreeableness of occupation, &c., which deter- 
 mine the rate of profit with which a man will be satisfied. 
 Suppose, for instance, the ruling rate of profit be ten per cent., 
 and that the manufacture of iron would only return one per 
 cent., no duty on iron would encourage the home manu- 
 facturers of that article unless it were sufficiently high to give 
 a reasonable expectation to the manufacturer that he would 
 obtain a return of ten per cent, upon his outlay. 
 
 There must, therefore, be such an expenditure of labour 
 ^vithin the community as will prodixc a fund from which 
 those who enter the new industries ma)- be recompensed lor
 
 TtiE Economic Argument. 171 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. ii., \ 3.] 
 
 the loss which they make in quitting the old. This labour is, 
 economically speaking, as much wasted as if it were employed 
 in digging holes in the sea-shore and filling them with sand. 
 Had Protective taxes not attracted capital and labour into 
 industries which did not pay without State aid, there would 
 have been no necessity for any expenditure for the purposes of 
 recompense. The operation of a Protective tax produces, 
 therefore, a double loss : It not only attracts men from the 
 industries in which they can produce more, to those in which 
 they produce less, but it compels those who continue in the 
 old industries to pay for the support of those who enter the new. 
 This, however, is not a full catalogue of the economic evils 
 of Protective taxes. 
 
 3. Such taxes cause yet a third loss to the productive 
 powers of a community, by reason of their effect in decreasing 
 the fund which is available for the employment of labour. 
 
 Any increase in the prices of articles of general consump- 
 tion soon tells its tale upon the purses of the bulk of a 
 community. Their power of purchasing becomes restricted, 
 and the employment which they can give to others is less than 
 it was. Nothing re-acts more quickly upon the labour market 
 than the impoverishment of the poorer classes, since this not 
 only directly reduces the demand for labour, but very speedily 
 increases the supply. When persons of small means find that 
 a sovereign only goes as far as fifteen shillings used to go, 
 they not only very sensibly contract their expenditure, but they 
 are forced to look about more actively for opportunities to 
 increase their income. The labourer is thus oppressed by 
 Protection on all sides. The cost of his living is increased, 
 and his opportunities of finding employment are diminished. 
 If he belongs to a Protected trade, he employs a portion of 
 his time in doing for himself what some one else in anotlier 
 co'jntry would do for him at a less price. If he is a member 
 of that larger class wlio cannot b; Protected, lie pays away a
 
 172 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 portion of his earnings in support of his Protected brethren ; 
 while, whatever his position in the community, he has to pay 
 more for what he wants than if he bought it in the open 
 market, and has, therefore, less to live upon than he had 
 before, and less to spend in giving employment to his fellow- 
 workmen. Yet we are asked to believe that when the citizens 
 of a State are exposed to these necessitous conditions, and 
 when all these sources of loss are added together, the country 
 as a whole will increase in wealth ! Surely a more extravagant 
 proposition was never submitted for the acceptance of intelli- 
 gent men. Wealth is the product of labour, which may be 
 directed by a tax from one channel into another, but which no 
 tax, however cunningly devised, can call into existence. 
 
 If labour seeks one channel in preference to another, the 
 reason for its choice is, plainly, the desire for greater profit. If 
 the encouragement of a tariff is required to attract men from 
 one occupation into another, that is an admission that the 
 occupation into which it is desired to lead them is not, by 
 itself, so lucrative as those which are of natural growth. As 
 Mr. George has expressed it : " If the time has come for the 
 establishment of an mdustry for which proper natural con- 
 ditions exist, restrictions upon importations in order to promote 
 its establishment are needless. If the time has not come, 
 such restrictions can only divert labour and capital from in- 
 dustries in which the return is greater to others in which it must 
 be less, and thus reduce the aggregate production of wealth." 
 
 We have thus reached the first step in the economic 
 argument in favour of Free Trade, and shown that Protection 
 lessens a nation's power to produce wealth by attracting capital 
 and labour from the more profitable to the less profitable 
 occupations, and by taxing the majority of a community in 
 order to provide a fund for keeping profits and wages in ccriain 
 industries up to the average rate. 
 
 The precise extent of the loss which is thus inflicted will 
 be a subject for a separate chapter.
 
 The Economic Argument. 173 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. iii., \ I.] 
 
 CHAPTER III. 
 
 FREE TRADE AND PRICES. 
 
 I. The hardiest advocate of a restricted commerce has 
 never had the courage to assert that Free Trade raised prices ; 
 the charge against a poUcy which permits free exchange has 
 always been the opposite. This abhorrence of cheapness 
 appears to be due, in a large degree, to the false idea that a 
 low level of prices must be associated with a low rate of 
 wages a misconception of facts, which is among the earliest, 
 as it is the longest-lived, of economic errors. The true 
 relation between prices and wages will be the subject of 
 inquiry when the effect of Free Trade upon the distribution 
 of wealth comes under review, but such an inquiry is foreign 
 to the scope of an argument directed only to the working of 
 a fiscal policy within the field of production. 
 
 The exact relation between prices and production is both 
 intricate and obscure. The economist says, and says un- 
 answerably, that there can be no such thing as excessive 
 cheapness, because the cheaper things become, the greater the 
 number of people who will buy them. The practical man of 
 business, on the other hand, asserts and brings forward facts 
 in support of his assertion that falling prices always check 
 production. 
 
 What is the explanation of this difference of opinion, and 
 what is the truth? 
 
 A low level of prices may be due to one or more of three 
 causes, viz. : 
 
 1. To a lessened cost of production. 
 
 2. To a decreased power of consumption. 
 
 3. To a scarcity of gold. 
 
 Each of these causes acting upon prices may affect the 
 production of wealth in a different way. Low prices, due to a
 
 174 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 scarcity of gold, may at first limit trade, and then abnormally 
 extend it by encouraging inflated credit ; low prices, due to a 
 decreased power of consumption, give rise to that unhealthy 
 over-production from which the industrial body is only relieved 
 by the drastic remedy of a commercial crisis. Low prices, 
 however, which are due to the lessening of the cost of pro- 
 duction are a healthy stimulus to the productive power of 
 the human race. 
 
 These differences in the causes of low prices are generally 
 overlooked by those who raise an outcry against cheapness. 
 This has been notably the case during the extraordinary 
 industrial depression which prevailed over all parts of the 
 civilised world during the six years 1883 to 1888. This 
 depression was unparalleled in history, both in its extent and 
 its duration, and it was, moreover, accompanied by a large and 
 rapid fall in prices. The consequence has been a revival of 
 the old fallacy that "Low prices inake low wages," and an 
 onslaught on the Free Trade doctrine that a cheapening of 
 prices is for the general advantage. The circumstances, how- 
 ever, of this unprecedented and disastrous period afford no 
 test for the guidance of voters in choosing between fiscal 
 policies, and certainly throw no discredit on the teachings of 
 Free Trade. On the whole, Free Trade countries came best 
 out of the ordeal, but all suffered terribly.^ The causes were 
 complicated, and perhaps impossible to trace. One fact, 
 however, is certain : that all the three causes which have been 
 mentioned as affecting prices were at work sim.ultaneously, 
 with the result that in 1886 prices had fallen thirty-six per 
 cent, below the average rate of 1873,- and that this fall 
 continued until the middle of 1888, when it received a check. 
 
 1 See Reports of Evidence taken before Royal Commission on Depression 
 of Trade, 1883-6. According to the Washington Labour Bureau, one million 
 men were out of work in the United States in 1886. 
 
 - Sec Journal of Statistical Society, passim, especially the papers read 
 by Mr. Giffen and Mr. Sauerbeck.
 
 The Economic Argument. 175 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. ili., \ 3.] 
 
 It would fall outside the scope of this argument to examine 
 in detail the many causes which have been believed to have 
 originated or prolonged this great depression. It may, how- 
 ever, be mentioned that the report of the Washington Labour 
 Bureau for 1886 classifies the causes assigned for industrial 
 depressions by witnesses before Congressional Committees of 
 Inquiry under 180 heads.^ Free Traders will learn with 
 pleasure that Free Trade was not considered to be the only 
 cause of industrial evils. Some witnesses attributed them also 
 to the use of tobacco, others to the neglect of female educa- 
 tion ; each of which explanations may serve to illustrate the 
 danger of indulging in generalisations upon the effect of low 
 prices ! 
 
 Low prices may be both the cause and the effect of in- 
 creased production. When the low prices are caused by an 
 extension of the market, or by a cheapening of the cost of pro- 
 duction, they give an immediate stimulus to the productive 
 powers of a community ; but when they are caused by a falling- 
 off in the demand without a corresponding diminution in the 
 supply, then they may mark a period both of low wages and 
 small profits. 
 
 3. Free Trade, however, is, as has been pointed out, an 
 instrument of production, in that it cheapens and steadies the 
 supply of raw materials, and permits the application of the 
 principle of division of employment to the transactions of 
 international commerce. It is, in other words, in itself a form 
 of a cheapened process of production ; and as it is applicable 
 to every kind of article, it must, therefore, affect prices in that 
 particular way which stimulates production. If the distinctions 
 between the various causes of low prices have been correctly 
 followed, and if the fact is once admitted that all these causes 
 have been at work during the last six years, the futility ot 
 
 ' .S'tv paper by Professor R. M, Smitli, Political Science Quarterly, I., 
 p. 444.
 
 176 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 the Protectionist alarm lest commodities should be too cheap 
 in consequence of Free Trade will be at once apparent. 
 Looking at cheapness simply as an influence upon production, 
 we can say with certainty that a cheapness of the sort induced 
 by Free Trade viz., a cheapness which arises from the use 
 of a wider area of production and a freer interchange of 
 goods can never be excessive. Whether it ever happens 
 that a cheapness arising from this cause can (as Protectionists 
 assert) so diminish employment that higher prices would be 
 an advantage to the labouring classes, because they would be 
 accompanied with more work, will be matter of inquiry when we 
 come to deal with the influence of Protection in reducing wages. 
 For the present, treating the question merely as one of 
 production, it must be apparent that a low level of prices, 
 arising from a cheapening of the processes of manufacture, 
 stimulates the productive power. The majority of mankind 
 is still so far beneath the level of its aspirations in its enjoy- 
 ment of material comforts, and the desires of all men are so 
 constantly enlarging, that no definable limit can be placed to 
 the extension of the present demand for the necessaries and 
 luxuries of life. All that can be said is, that in respect of any 
 particular article, the actual limit of demand is the price at 
 which it can be profitably produced ; and that, while every- 
 thing which tends to lower the price of remunerative pro- 
 duction increases demand, everything which increases demand 
 reacts in turn upon prices by causing production upon a 
 larger scale, and thus economising cost. Or, if tliis is thought 
 by those who believe in the theory of Protection to be too 
 abstract and vague, let them arrive at the same conclusion by 
 asking themselves two simple questions : " Would they think 
 it an advantage if other countries were to give us everything 
 we wanted, and took nothing in exchange?" If the reply is 
 in the affirmative, then let them ask "Whether, if a gift of 
 everything we want is advantageous, a gii"t of a part is not also 
 advantageous ?"
 
 The Economic Argument. 177 
 
 Pt III., Ch. iii , ? 4] 
 
 The difference between a free gift and a reduced price is 
 only one of degree. 
 
 4. Free Trade, besides lowering prices through cheapening 
 the process of production, also steadies them, and in this 
 performs a most important function. 
 
 The complexity of our present industrial system, and the 
 universal practice of producing on a large scale for an unknown 
 market,^ has made it a matter of supreme importance to check 
 as far as possible wide or sudden fluctuations in prices. 
 Industrial depressions, whatever be the variety of their causes, 
 resemble each other in this respect : that during their con- 
 tinuance the supply of commodities is greater than the effective 
 demand for them. This may arise from over-production or 
 under-consumption : that is to say, the supply may be unduly 
 increased, or the demand may be unduly lessened. Possibly, 
 as was the case during the last depression, these two things 
 may happen at the same time. But, whatever the immediate 
 cause, the result is always the same that enterprise is stopped, 
 labour is unemployed, stocks accumulate, and goods cannot be 
 sold at a price which is remunerative. Production, however, 
 cannot at once cease ; mills cannot be closed, nor skilled 
 workmen suffered to disperse. The adjustment of the supply 
 of a commodity to the effective demand for it is always a slow 
 process. It is therefore a matter of supreme concern to every 
 producer that he should be able to anticipate with some 
 
 1 " How does it happen that when enough of a commodity is produced, 
 men should still go on producing? . . . The explanation is that in our 
 present industrial organisation we produce on a large scale for an unknown 
 market. In old times the shoemaker made a pair of shoes for the man who 
 ordered them ; now our manufacturers make thousands of dozens in advance 
 of the demand. If tliey can do this so as to undersell others, they have an 
 imlimited market ; but if another undersells them, they lose the entire market. 
 It is the same way in agriculture. The .American farmer ruined the English, 
 and now the Indian wli-at tlireatens to displace the .Vmerican in the Euro- 
 pean market." (Professor Richmond Smith, in Political Science Qtiartcrly, 
 Vol. I., p. 447.) 
 M
 
 lyS Industrial Freedom. 
 
 degree of certainty the probable demand for his particular 
 class of goods. ^ 
 
 Now, if prices fluctuate, the equation between supply and 
 demand becomes more difficult to calculate, because both the 
 supply of and demand for any commodity are greatly affected 
 by the steadiness of its price. Men are always more ready to 
 enter upon new undertakings or to increase their purchases 
 when they can calculate the cost beforehand with some degree 
 of confidence and exactitude. Whatever, therefore, steadies 
 prices must tend to avert commercial depressions, and to 
 lessen their severity, by enabling a more accurate adjustment 
 to be made between supply and demand. 
 
 Free Trade operates in steadying prices by widening both 
 the area of production and the area of consumption. It not 
 only gives a larger supply of raw materials, but a wider market 
 for the sale of the finished goods.- 
 
 1 Of late years the power of production has enormously increased through 
 the invention of new machinery ; at the same time, the power of consumption 
 has diminished in consequence of the displacement of labour caused by the 
 adoption of mechanical processes. Professor Richmond .Smith quotes from 
 the Report of the National Bureau of Labour for i836 (already referred to) 
 many striking instances of this. 
 
 2 In the days before Free Trade, the price of a quartern loaf in England 
 was seldom steady for a month together. Every frost and every fall of raiii 
 might be, and often was, the presage of starvation. The price of a quarter of 
 wheat often doubled within a year ; while since the adoption of Free Trade 
 tlie annual variation is between twelve and fifteen shillings. Or, to express the 
 same fact in another way, the price of the quartern loaf, which in one year 
 I cached eighteenpence and in another sold for fourpence, has, since Free 
 Trade, remained almost stationary between fourpence and sevenpence. And 
 this is not all. While, under Protection, high prices were the rule, under Free 
 Trade they are exxepiional ; so that in thirty years the average price of wheat 
 has been reduced twelve shi'lings the quarter. It is difficult for those who have 
 nt'ver lived in a country wheic pox'crty and want abound to realise the ines imable 
 boon of cheap food. Rut those who have read the literature of the Chartist 
 period--such tales, for instance, as Kings!ey's " Yeast" or Disraeli's "Sybil" 
 know well that in those days the var)ing price of corn continually drove the 
 working-classes to starvation. Periodic starvation was, in fact, the normal 
 condition of masses of working-men in England previous to the introduction of 
 Free Trade ; and if this statement seem exaggerated, the cruellest and most
 
 The Economic Argument. 179 
 
 rt. iii.jCh. iii., ?4-] 
 
 A wide area of production must tend to steady, as well as 
 to reduce, the prices of raw material, because it not only- 
 increases the sources of their supply, but tends to make the 
 market independent of local disturbances. Suppose, for in- 
 stance, that New South Wales were dependent for her supply 
 of iron upon the furnaces of Lithgow : the price of iron might 
 be doubled in a single day by a strike, a breakage of ma- 
 chinery, disease among the workmen, or any other accident. 
 But when iron can be bought from England, Belgium, and 
 America, the failure of one market would only have a slight 
 effect upon prices in the others. The wider, therefore, the 
 area of production, the less the risk to a producer, and the 
 more constant his supply of raw materials. 
 
 Almost every article is, however, the raw material of another 
 in some stage of its production. Consequently, whatever 
 steadies the prices of raw materials affects production in all 
 its forms, by enabling producers to calculate beforehand all 
 the items of their outlay. 
 
 But in order that the supply of a commodity may not be 
 disproportionate to the demand for it, something more is 
 needed besides a regulation of the output. The probable 
 purchasing power of tlie customers must also be capable of 
 calculation. A producer must not only have an assurance that 
 there will be no sudden rise in the price of his raw materials, 
 but he must also be able to estimate the amount he is likely to 
 sell. In making this estimate, a producer is again assisted by 
 Free Trade. It is true that under Free Trade his market is 
 larger, and therefore his calculations will be more complicated ; 
 but the same security against the ill effects of local disturbances 
 whicli assisted him in his production will also assist him in his 
 sales. ^Vars, pestilences, bad harvests, and all the other 
 torments of producers, cannot have the same effect over a wide 
 
 rigid proof of its accuracy is given by the tables of mortality. The returns of 
 the l^;^ gistrAr-CJciieral sliow an increase in the number of dcalhi, with every 
 rise i!i the price of bread. 
 
 M 2
 
 i8o Industrial Freedom. 
 
 area that they would have within the hmits of a single country. 
 But it has already been remarked, in considering the effect of 
 Free Trade upon production, that there is always a danger, 
 under a system of Protection, of over-supplying the local 
 market. This danger is to a great extent obviated by a policy 
 of Free Exchange ; because, whatever widens the area of 
 consumption gives a larger market for the sale of goods. This 
 consideration explains why Free Trade countries are generally 
 the last to feel, and the first to recover from, a trade depression. 
 Their foreign trade affords them a speedier outlet for surplus 
 stock, and helps the more rapid readjustment between supply 
 and demand. 
 
 But it is not only by widening the areas of production and 
 consumption that Free Trade is an agency in the prevention of 
 commercial crises. It also acts in this direction by giving 
 producers a more accurate knowledge of the wants and the 
 position of their customers. Trade depressions, as has been 
 said, are always marked by an accumulation of unsaleable 
 goods. Sometimes this is owing to a mistake on the part of 
 the producers, as was the case in 1825, when a cargo of skates 
 was shipped to the Brazils, and grand pianos and diamond 
 tiaras were consigned for sale to the South American Indians;^ 
 and in such a case it cannot be denied that the crisis might 
 have been prevented, or at least alleviated, by greater know- 
 ledge. Even in cases where tlie error is not quite so gross, 
 there must always be room for more accurate information. 
 Can anyone doubt under which policy producers are less likely 
 to mistake their markets ? whether it will be under a policy 
 which encourages intercourse with foreigners, or under one 
 which insists on isolation? It must be iihiin tliat the risk of 
 producing goods wliicli are not wanted at tlie time is lessened 
 by everything which brings the inhabitants of distant countries 
 nearer to one anotlicr. Free Trade, like telegraphs and 
 
 1 5tv Martineau's " IIL-tory of t]u- Peace '" for an entertaining- account of 
 this commercial crisis.
 
 The Economic Argument. i8i 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. iv., 5 I.] 
 
 railways, tends to keep both producers and consumers better 
 informed as to each others' needs. 
 
 5. But, although Free Trade tends to steady prices, and 
 therefore to prevent commercial crises, by equalising, dis- 
 closing, and enlarging markets, it cannot prevent these terrible 
 disturbances. Fluctuating trade, with all its misery of wasted 
 efforts, savings squandered, and homes destroyed, is an evil 
 which lies beyond the range of any tariff. The causes of 
 commercial crises cannot be removed either by Protection or 
 Free Trade. Wars, excessive speculation, dishonesty, gambling 
 in land values to mention only the chief of such causes are 
 manifestly outside the influence of Customs duties. All that can 
 be done by any fiscal policy is to lessen the frequency of trade 
 depressions, and strengthen a community to bear them better. 
 In this beneficial and remedial work, Free Trade has always 
 played a most important part.^ 
 
 CHAPTER IV. 
 
 PROTECTION AND PRICES. 
 
 I. It was shown in the second chapter of this Part that Pro- 
 tection diminished the aggregate production of national wealth 
 in three ways : 
 
 I. By causing an artificial and compulsory transfer of 
 
 money and labour from profitable to unprofitable 
 
 industries. 
 
 1 The Report of the Royal Coniniission on tlie Depression of Trade contains 
 tlie followinsf paragraph : " There is no feature in the situation whicli %ve have 
 ])eeii called upon to examine, so satisfactory as the immense improvement that 
 lias taken place in the condition of the working-classes during the last twenty- 
 si\- years. At the present moment (i886) there is a good deal of distress, owing 
 to till' want of regular work ; but there can be no question that the workman 
 in this country [(jreat Britain] is, when fully employed, in almost every respect 
 in a better condition than his competitor in foreign countries."
 
 1 82 Industrial Fkeedo^t. 
 
 2. By causing a wasteful expenditure for the purpose of 
 
 giving to those who were induced by Protection to 
 change their employment a rate of profit in their new 
 occupations equal to that which they might be 
 making in the old. 
 
 3. By increasing the cost of living to consumers, and thus 
 
 lessening the amount which, but for Protection, 
 would have been available for the employment of 
 labour. 
 
 Underlying the argument by which these conclusions were 
 supported was the unexpressed assumption that Protection 
 raised prices an assumption which is so obviously contained 
 within the terms of the propositions submitted about Protection, 
 that it was not thought necessary to interrupt the argument by 
 inquiring into its correctness. Those, however, who have lived 
 in a country where Protectionists arc active, will know that no 
 proposition about commerce or finance is so plain that there 
 will not be some persons who dispute it ; and will not be sur- 
 prised to learn that it is even denied on public platforms and 
 in the columns of party newspapers that Protection has the 
 effect of raising prices. A few words, therefore, as to the effect 
 of Protection on prices will not be out of place in a work 
 which is intended to be of direct practical assistance to those 
 who are engaged in the fiscal controversy. 
 
 2. Very slight reflection will show that if Protection does 
 not raise prices it does not effect what is reciuired of it. That 
 much-regarded personage, the home producer, has complained 
 that he cannot sell an article of his own make at the low price 
 at which it can be imported, and the advocate of restricted 
 commerce has given him, in consequence, a Protective duty. If, 
 as some Protectionists assert, this duty will not increase 
 prices, why, we may ask, was it imposed ? If the only object 
 of the manufacturer who asked for the duty was that he might 
 sell his goods at a lower rate, Avhy did he not proceed to do
 
 The Economic Argument. 183 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. iv., \ 3.] 
 
 this without waiting for the imposition of a duty? He might 
 have been sure that no one would have offered him a higher 
 price than he himself asked. 
 
 Or, to express the same idea in a more general way, the 
 competition against which Customs duties are designed to 
 assist the home producer is the competition of low-priced 
 articles. Now, there cannot for any length of time be two 
 prices ruling at the same time in the same market for the same 
 article. Therefore, if certain articles can be bought in the 
 open market at a price which will not repay the home producer, 
 no production of these is likely to take place within the country 
 until their price rises to a height which will repay him. If, 
 however, the importation of the low-priced articles is stopped, 
 or if something is added to their price before they are allowed 
 to be landed, their price may be sufficiently raised to make it 
 worth the while of somebody wiihin the country to attempt 
 their production. 
 
 But the hypothesis with which the Protectionists start is that 
 foreign competition keeps prices below the level which native 
 capitalists regard as satisfactory. If, then, native capitalists do 
 enter the lists of competition, and if they have been previously 
 prevented from doing so by the low price of imported goods, 
 they must sell the goods of their own make at a price which is 
 higher than the price of the same quality of goods in the open 
 market. In other words, since the Protectionist assumption is 
 that home production is checked by the low prices of imported 
 goods, native home production can only come into existence 
 (if this assumption be true) when prices rise. This conclusion 
 so nearly approaches to a truism tliat, did not experience teach 
 the contrary, one would have pronounced it impossible that 
 confusion should exist about it even in the minds of those wlio 
 wish to be confused. 
 
 3. In justice, however, to those persons who repeat in an 
 authoritative way the assurance of Protectionist orators tliat
 
 184 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 Protection will not raise prices, two facts should be mentioned 
 which have given the statement a semblance of truth. These 
 are the universal fall in prices which has taken place during the 
 last thirty years, and the fall which often takes place in the 
 price of a particular article, in consequence of the competition 
 of Protected manufacturers one with the other. 
 
 The fall in prices, which is the marked commercial feature 
 of the last thirty years, has been due to many causes which it is 
 not necessary to enumerate here the chief of these being the 
 wonderful improvement in every process of manufacture and 
 in the means of transport. This fall, however, has occurred 
 contemporaneously with the introduction into many countries 
 of Protective duties, consequent chiefly upon the revival of 
 militarism as a result of the Franco-Prussian War, and has, of 
 course, affected most of the Protected articles. Uneducated or 
 unthinking persons, noticing an article has fallen in price since 
 Protection was imposed, adopt the familiar fallacy of attributing 
 this to the Protective duty, whereas in truth the price would 
 have fallen still lower if the Protective duty had not existed. It 
 is, for example, constantly asserted in New South Wales that a 
 duty of sixpence per gallon on kerosene, which was imposed 
 many years ago for revenue purposes, but which has now 
 become Protective, has had the result of lowering the price of 
 kerosene. The price of kerosene has no doubt fallen very 
 much since the duty was imposed ; but that has been owing to 
 the immense discoveries of natural oil-wells in America and 
 Southern Russia, and not in any way to the duty. This is 
 made apparent at once by the fact that the price of kerosene 
 at London, New York, or Batoum, after deducting freight and 
 charge, is less than its price in Sydney by just the amount of 
 the duty. It is, indeed, impossible that it should be otherwise. 
 The price of an article of universal consumption, such as 
 kerosene, is not likely to be determined for the whole world b)- 
 its price in New South Wales. 
 
 The fall of prices in consequence of internal competition is
 
 The Economic Argument. 185 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. v., \ 3] 
 
 another cause which has tended to obscure the operation upon 
 prices of Protective duties. It cannot be denied that, although 
 the immediate effect of Protection must be an increase in 
 prices, it is possible that the competition of the home pro- 
 ducers, one with the other, may, after a time, become so fierce, 
 that prices will fall below their normal level. This, however, 
 although it is a probable consequence of Protection, is by no 
 means necessary ; since a ruinous internal competition is 
 generally checked by the facilities for combination which Protec- 
 tion offers. In the absence, however, of any combination among 
 the Protected manufacturers to keep up prices by restricting 
 their output, a Protective tax must, in the long run, cause 
 excessive production. The home market, even in a country of 
 the gigantic size of the United States, is necessarily more limited 
 than that which is open to a Free Trade country. Industries 
 which exist under Free Trade prove by the very fact of their 
 existence their ability to hold their own against the competition 
 of the world. Industries, on the other hand, which require for 
 their support the fostering aid of a Protective duty, signify by 
 this admission their inability to cope with foreign industries 
 even on their own soil. How, then, can they compete with 
 them in foreign countries ? If the home manufacturer re- 
 quires to be Protected against the foreigner when the 
 foreigner is handicapped by all the costs and charges of trans- 
 port, how can he hope to undersell the foreigner in a foreign 
 market when he has himself to bear the cost of freight and 
 other charges of exportation ? Nowhere is a manufacturer 
 situated so favourably as in his own market. If, then, under 
 the most favourable circumstances, he cannot hold his own 
 against the foreigner, he is not likely to be able to do so 
 in a foreign market, where the circumstances arc less favour- 
 able to him and more fiivourable to his rival. If a Protected 
 manufacturer can sell his goods at a profit in a foreign country, 
 it is proof jjositive that he wants no Protection in his own. If, 
 however, he does want Protection in his own market and it
 
 i86 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 is on that assumption that the argument is being conducted 
 then he cannot sell his goods abroad except at a loss; and if he 
 does sell them abroad, he must make up for his loss by charging 
 more to the persons who have to pay for his Protection. 
 
 4. Seeing, then, that Protection renders no service to an 
 exporting country, and that no country which requires Pro- 
 tection can profitably export Protected articles, it follows that 
 when the home market of a Protected country has been 
 supplied there is no outlet for the surplus products. The 
 consequence must be an immediate fall in prices, which pro- 
 ducers will naturally endeavour to prevent. If no arrange- 
 ment can be come to for the creation of a pool or trust, a cut- 
 throat competition ensues. In either case the result is 
 disastrous. The pool, by annihilating competition within the 
 country, and being Protected against competition from out- 
 side, has both the labourer and the consumer at its mercy. 
 The only limit to its power of raising prices or reducing wages 
 is the untrustworthiness of its component parts. If high prices 
 tempt some members to secede from the pool, prices may again 
 fall; but so long as all the members hold together, a tyrannous 
 monopoly exists against which resistance is impotent. If no 
 pool is formed and a war of prices ensues, the workman is the 
 first to suffer. Since each ^^roducer must undersell his rival, 
 and since every one has a surplus of goods for sale, no 
 expedient is spared for cutting down the cost of production ; 
 and the first item of this cost which is sure to attract attention 
 is the wages of labour. If the native-born labourer will not 
 accept a reduction, his place will be supplied by imported 
 labourers from the most poverty-stricken countries in the Old 
 World. 
 
 This has been the invariable course of Protection in new 
 countries. At first prices rise, and all goes well in the Pro- 
 tected trade. The rise of prices soon attracts other capitalists 
 to take their share of the plunder which the law allows them.
 
 The Economic Argument. 187 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. v., \ I.] 
 
 In time come over-production and a glutted market. There is 
 no outlet abroad, for Protection has destroyed the trade with 
 foreign countries ; yet the goods which are constantly increasin;^ 
 have to be disposed of. Prices are then reduced and wages 
 are cut down ; strikes occur, and mills are closed ; distress 
 and famine at last cause outbursts of violence, which attract 
 public notice and compel the manufacturers to combine 
 together. A new period of combination is then entered upon, 
 the end of which no one can foresee; but which in its inception 
 has riveted the fetters of poverty upon the poor more firmly 
 than ever, and given to the possessor of wealth wider oppor- 
 tunities for the tyrannous exercise of power than were ever 
 dreamt of by despotic rulers. 
 
 CHAPTER V. 
 
 FREE TRADE AND WAGES. 
 
 I. A STATEMENT of the thcory of wages is beset with many 
 verbal difficulties, but these may be avoided without distorting 
 facts, if wages are defined as "The labourer's share of that 
 which is produced." They are that portion of the product 
 which remains after rent, profits, and taxes have been satisfied. 
 Consequently, if these factors are constant, the amount of each 
 man's wage will depend upon the proportion between the 
 quantity of this remainder and the number of workmen engaged 
 in the trade. 
 
 The theory may be expressed algebraically. Let R be rent, 
 p the average rate of profit, having regard to all the circum- 
 stances, such as security, agreeableness of occupation, &c., 
 which lead to the choice of one occupation rather than another. 
 Let P also include cost of materials, interest or capital, wages 
 of superintendence, wear and tear everything, in fact, which is
 
 i88 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 usually provided and allowed for by the capitalist employer. 
 Let T be taxes ; x the product. The amount divisible in 
 wages will then be expressed thus : x - (r + p + t). And if Q is 
 the number of labourers employed in the given occupation, 
 the share of each labourer will be 
 
 x-(r + p + t ) 
 Q 
 
 Assuming, as before, that R, p, t remain constant and we 
 are entitled to make this assumption in an economic argument 
 the rate of wages depends upon the relative amounts of x 
 and Q. So that wages may be increased either by increasing 
 the total product or by diminishing the number of labourers. 
 Mr. Edward Atkinson, of Boston,^ who has made a special 
 study of the wages question, has demonstrated by an elaborate 
 l)rocess of induction from a great variety of authentic illustra- 
 tions, that the tendency under the existing industrial system is 
 to raise wages by both these methods: i.e., by increasing x 
 and lessening Q. This result is due to the marvellous im- 
 provements which have been effected during the last fifty 
 years in the means of transport and in mechanical invention. 
 Mr. David A. Wells, now happily again a senator of the United 
 States, has pursued this line of investigation to the same 
 conclusion in his lately published work on " Recent Economic 
 Changes." All inquiries into the earnings of the working- 
 class since the inauguration of the industrial era at the 
 beginning of the present century lead by a series of cumulative 
 proofs to the conclusion that the tendency of the competitive 
 system of industry is towards the production of a steadily 
 
 1 "The Distribution of Products." G. P. Putnam's Sons, New York, 
 1885. See also, by the same author, " The Industrial Progress of tlie Nation," 
 Putnam's Sons, 1890. Further information on this deeply interesting economic 
 phenomenon which is the real cause of our recent trade depression and social 
 movements is to be found in Sir Lyon Playfair's recent volume of collected 
 addresses, and in Mr. Mongrrdien's pamphlet, "A Neglected Chapter in 
 Economics,"
 
 The Economic Argument. 189 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. v., \ 2.] 
 
 increasing quantity of things by means of a steadily decreasing 
 number of labourers. 
 
 Accordingly, if we assume that there is no check to the in- 
 crease of population (and the possibility of raising wages by 
 this means need not be considered here), the conclusion is 
 inevitable that there can be no general rise in the rates of real 
 wages except by means of an increase in the quantity of things 
 produced, nor of money wages except by means of a similar 
 increase, coupled with the maintenance of the relative prices at 
 which such products can be sold. Does it equally follow that 
 an increase in the quantity of things produced is an essential 
 requisite to the opening of new channels of employment, so 
 that wages may be earned in fresh pursuits by those who have 
 been displaced from their former occupations ? Experience 
 and theory alike reply in the affirmative. The accumulation 
 of capital gives the best known stimulus to the establishment 
 of new industries ; while every increase in the efficiency of 
 labour by raising wages and lowering prices creates new ranges 
 of desire, which must be satisfied by the exertions of new 
 labourers. Poverty may, for a time, ensue as a consequence 
 of an invention ; but labour adjusts itself in time to new con- 
 ditions with a silence and rapidity which bear a striking 
 testimony to the apparently inexhaustible productivity of 
 human powers 
 
 ^ 2. The action of Free Trade on wages becomes now easy 
 to trace. Free Trade is, as we have seen, a device for in- 
 creasing the number of things which can be made by a given 
 quantity of labour through access to the natural advantages of 
 distant countries. It is plain, therefore, if this be correct, that 
 l'"rce Trade cannol of itself cause any diminution in wages, and 
 that it \<, prima facie likely to raise them. 
 
 It does not follow, as we have repeatedly conceded, that 
 the labourer will always get a proper share of every increase in 
 national productiveness ; but it is impossible to argue from the
 
 IQO INDUSTRIAL FREEDOM. 
 
 mere fact of an increase having taken place that wages are 
 likely to fall. If it should happen that some other factor of 
 the product gets an undue share of the increase at the expense 
 of labour, this must arise from causes which are independent 
 of the economic operation of Free Trade ; because (to put the 
 case in its simplest form) an increase in the sum to be divided 
 cannot, per se, lessen the quotient. 
 
 It thus becomes necessary to consider whether Free Trade 
 has any other effect which may influence wages besides that ot 
 causing an increase in the aggregate of material wealth. Does 
 it, for instance, unduly raise profits, or rent, or taxes ; or does 
 it by any means depress the labourer so that he cannot claim 
 a fair share of the increase ? This is really an inquiry into the 
 effect of Free Trade upon the distribution of wealth, which 
 raises political rather than economic considerations.^ There 
 are, however, two ways in which Free Trade is alleged by Pro- 
 tectionists to lower the rate of wages, which may properly be 
 considered in this connection. 
 
 It is said, in the first place, that the tendency of commerce 
 between two countries in which the rates of wages differ is to 
 depress the higher rate to the level of the lower ; and, secondly, 
 that wage-earners are less able under Free Trade than under 
 Protection to prevent the owners of natural monopolies, sucli 
 as land or mines, from appropriating an undue proportion of 
 any increase in productiveness. 
 
 These arguments are plainly expressions in another form of 
 arguments, which are well known on the political side of the 
 fiscal controversy under the titles of the " Pauper Labour " and 
 tlie " Diversification of Industry " arguments. At present, 
 however, we are not concerned with these arguments in their 
 practical applications, but need only consider whether ihcy 
 have any theoretic value. 
 
 1 " Prot'^ction now assumes a new form, and is advocated as a means of 
 securing to the labourers a larger share in the distribution of wealth." (Prof. 
 PiUtcn's '' Economic Basis o'" Protection," p. 20.)
 
 The Economic Argument. 191 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. v., \ 3.] 
 
 3. The notion that the rates of wages in two competing 
 countries tend to an equality, so that a country of high wages 
 ought to be protected against the competition of a country of 
 low wages, depends upon the fallacy that the rate of wages is 
 the true measure of the cost of production. This confusion of 
 money wages with labour cost has always been a deeply seated 
 and frequent cause of error in the economics both of external 
 and internal trade. In former days it prompted the opposition 
 to the use of new machines, just as to-day it prompts the oppo- 
 sition to the labour-saving institution of foreign commerce. 
 The difference between the competition of machines and that 
 of cheap foreign labour is only one of degree. That which the 
 craftsman fears upon the introduction of new machinery is lest 
 his services should be more costly to his old employer than those 
 of the machine. That which the home producer fears at the 
 first rumour of foreign competition is lest his employer should be 
 able to import the foreign article at a less price than that at 
 which it can be made by home labour. In each case the fear is 
 lest the new competitor should be able to do more work at a less 
 price : in other words, lest it should prove more efficient than 
 the man who fears its competition. This fear is sometimes 
 well founded. The hand-loom weavers disappeared as a class 
 before the competition of the power-loom, and the Coventry 
 watchmakers have been sorely injured by the competition of 
 America and Switzerland. But when it is said that the foreign 
 competition of a cheap-labour country tends to reduce the 
 wages of a high-waged country, the statement is intended to 
 have a general application, and not to be limited to the 
 particular trade which is exposed to competition. 
 
 It is a truism of economic experience that no displacement 
 of labour can take place without causing much unmerited 
 suffering among labourers during the period that they are seek- 
 ing new employment ; and it is indisputable that during the 
 last twenty years whole classes of skilled artisans have sunk into 
 the reserve army of unskilled labour for no other reason than
 
 192 Industrial pREEDO^r. 
 
 that the invention of a new machine has destroyed the market 
 value of their special skill. But it is equally incontestable that 
 the wages of workmen generally have risen during this period, 
 and that the rise has been greatest in those countries, such as 
 America and England, where the competition of machinery has 
 been the keenest. It is the same with the competition of cheap 
 foreign labour. If it is successful, and if it does, as in the 
 Coventry watch trade, supplant a home industry, the reason 
 must be that, either in consequence of the low wages of labour 
 or, more probably, in spite of it it can produce the article which 
 is the subject of competition at a less cost than this can be pro- 
 duced at home. To this extent, therefore, foreign competition 
 is a labour-saving device to all those in the country who may 
 desire to buy the finished article. The labourer which it 
 supplants must find another occupation, and is assisted in 
 doing so by the increased power of saving, which the reduction 
 in the price of the article in the production of which it was 
 formerly employed has given to his former customers. Thus, 
 when the watch trade left Coventry, the trade in bicycles grew 
 up ; and the rate of wages is higher, and the number of artisans 
 greater in that city than at any other period in her history. An 
 extreme instance will test the soundness of these views. 
 
 Chemists tell us that honey can be manufactured in a 
 laboratory which is indistinguishable from the work of bees. 
 Yet should we on that account, and in order to employ labour, 
 prohibit the keeping of apiaries in order to establish chemical 
 works and their attendant industries in every country ? The 
 suggestion, says a Protectionist, is absurd. Yet, how does he 
 act differently from this when he deals in the Legislature witli 
 another article of sweetness namel}', sugar ? Sugar can be 
 grown in New South Wales by white labour, and it is grown in 
 Fiji by Kanakas. The white man says and possibly he says 
 truly that labour enters so largely into the cost of producing 
 sugar that it is impossible for a New South Welshman to com- 
 pete against Fiji in its production without the aid of a Protective
 
 The Economic Argument. 193 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. v., \ 4.] 
 
 tariff. Protectionists accordingly insist that no one in New 
 South Wales should be allowed to buy a ton of sugar from Fiji 
 without paying ^5 to the Government for every purchase. 
 How, then, does this differ from the suggested action against the 
 competition of the bees ? The result of the competition is in 
 each case the same namely, that the product is sold at a less 
 cost. What does it signify to the man who is competed with 
 whether his competitor be a bee or a black-fellow ? 
 
 4. The fallacy of the argument against the competition of 
 cheap labour lies in confusing the rate of wages with the labour 
 cost of production. 
 
 Now, the rate of wages can only be a measure of the true 
 cost of labour in those few industries in which the product is 
 the result of almost unassisted hand-work. In such cases, as 
 Mr. Atkinson points out, " both the materials worked upon, and 
 also the product, may bear a very high price, but the work upon 
 them not being aided by effective machinery, the quantity of 
 labour will be very large, and the result of the sale may there- 
 fore leave but a very small sum to be divided among very many 
 
 labourers, after the cost of materials has been set aside 
 
 For instance, after the pattern is drawn it takes merely manual 
 dexterity to make Brussels lace. The material which is used 
 in this branch of industry is fine and costly cotton-thread, which 
 is converted into lace by hand, without the aid of any machinery 
 whatever, but merely by the use of two or three simple tools. 
 The lace-makers of Brussels are among the poorest of the poorer 
 classes of European operatives. They work at the very lowest 
 rates of wages, which will barely keep them in existence, but 
 their product is of very high cost in money. The very best 
 Lyons silks and German velvets are other examples. They 
 are made upon hand-looms of the most primitive kind. Beet- 
 root sugar is another example. Beets require constant hand- 
 work in weeding. We cannot afford the time or labour for such 
 work so long as we can exchange wheat raided by michinery 
 N
 
 194 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 for money, and with the money buy our sugar. In all handi- 
 crafts the quantity of labour is very great, but even at the high 
 prices which such products bring, the total sum of money re- 
 covered from the sale leaves but a very low rate of wages to be 
 divided among those who have performed the work." 
 
 Most industries, however, in a country of high industrial 
 development, are assisted either by natural advantages or 
 mechanical appliances. Accordingly, in all such cases high 
 money wages become a necessary consequence of the low 
 labour cost. In other words, since the labour of each wage- 
 earner is rendered more efficient, the proportion between the 
 value of the product and the number of workmen increases, 
 so that there is both a larger quantity to divide and fewer 
 labourers to receive. Reverting to the formula used on a 
 previous page, if the wage of each labourer in a given occupa- 
 tion be 
 
 X (r -f p -f t) 
 
 ~~ "q 
 
 X is increased and q diminished. Low wages thus become 
 an indication of dear production ; while a high rate of money 
 wages is a necessary result of a low labour cost. " Low wages 
 and cheap labour are not synonymous terms ; but," as Mr. 
 Atkinson further says, at the conclusion of his investigations, 
 " that labour has, in fact^ proved to be cheapest by which the 
 largest product for each dollar expended was assured, and that 
 has been the highest paid labour." ("Distribution of Pro- 
 ducts," p. 66.)^ Low wages are rarely, if ever, the accompani- 
 ment of a degree of industrial efficiency. 
 
 1 Mr. Atkinbou's concluiions are as follows : First : The rate of wages con- 
 stitutes no standard even of the money cost of production : which cost must be 
 made up by adding together the sum of all wages and dividing by the product, 
 in order to establish a unit of cost in money by way of a unit of measure, 
 whether by the yard, barrel, or pound. 
 
 Second : Low rates of wages are not essential to a low cost of production, 
 but, on the contrary, usually indicate a high cost of production that is to fay, 
 a large measure of human labour and a large sum of wages at low rates. Con-
 
 The Economic Argument. 195 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. v.,?4.] 
 
 It follows, then, from these considerations, that the pauper 
 labour argument needs to be re-stated. It is not the competi- 
 tion of a low-waged country that Protectionists need fear ; but 
 what may become dangerous to particular industries is the com- 
 petition of a country where production is carried on at high 
 wages, and consequently at a low labour cost. In the latter 
 case, individual industries may suffer, as individual industries 
 have suffered, by the introduction of machines, but the country, 
 as a whole, gains in wealth. The question thus becomes one 
 of politics : " Whether, in the interests of the State, this injury to 
 individuals ought to be prevented?" Later in these pages, when 
 the political aspect of this argument comes to be discussed, it will 
 be shown that the alarms at foreign competition are to a great 
 extent illusory. Individual industries do not, in fact, suffer 
 from the competition of other countries to such a considerable 
 extent as to justify a politician in imposing the burdens of 
 Protection upon other industries. Trade is mutually beneficial, 
 and nations are dependent one upon the other ; if in the rush 
 of competition one country should gain an unfair profit for a 
 
 versely, high rates of wages may, and commonly do, indicate a low cost of pro- 
 duction that is to say, a small proportion of human labour and a small 
 proportionate sum of wages at high rates in a given quantity of product. 
 
 Third : Cheap labour, in a true sense, and low rates of wages, are not 
 synonymous terms, but are usually quite the reverse. 
 
 Fourth : An employer is not under the necessity of securing labour at low 
 rates of wages in order to make cheap goods, but he may, and commonly does, 
 pay high rates of wages, for the very purpose of assuring the production of 
 goods at the lowest cost that is, in order to be able to sell them on the lowest 
 terms, or "cheap," in the popular sense. 
 
 The abuse of the word cheap leads to more mischievous fallacies than any 
 other abuse of language. The cheapest labour is the best-paid labour ; it 
 is the best-paid labour applied to ir.acliincry that assures the largest product in 
 ratio to the cajiital invested. 
 
 If these proportions can be sustained, it may be submitted that the more the 
 capitalist increases his wealth and applies it to reproduction, the more the wel- 
 fare of the labourer is assured. The competition of capital with capital tends 
 constantly to a decrease in the ratio of the profit of capital to the total produc- 
 tion, and of necessity tends also to a constant increase in the rate of wages of 
 tlic labourer, thereby more than coimteracting the tendency of the competition 
 of labourer with labourer to diminish wages.
 
 196 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 time at the expense of another, the evils of attempting to adjust 
 the balance by the aid of a Protective tax are greater than the 
 temporary loss. Experience shows that foreign competition, 
 in the few cases where it is effective, is better met by studying 
 the laws of nature, and laying to heart the reasons why rivalry 
 has succeeded, than by looking to the laws of Parliament, and 
 praying for relief at the expense of others. If Protectionists 
 were right, and if the tendency of trade between two countries 
 of unequal rates of wages were to depress the higher rate to the 
 level of the lower, the rate of wages should vary in all 
 European countries according to the magnitude of each one's 
 dealings with the Asiatic or other uncivilised races. That is to 
 say : wages should be lowest in England of all European 
 nations, and in New South Wales of the Australian colonies. 
 The contrary is notoriously the case. So is it equally notorious 
 that the competition which the American or colonial Protec- 
 tionists most fear is not the competition of the dark-skinned 
 races, but the competition of the skilled and high-paid labour of 
 Great Britain. No instance can be cited by Protectionists of 
 any country whose rate of wages has been perceptibly affected 
 by a foreign commerce with a low-waged race. Again, as often 
 in this controversy, we must ask Protectionists to give us facts 
 as well as theory. 
 
 5. The second argument against Free Trade, as an 
 influence in raising wages that high wages depend upon a 
 diversity of industry, which Free Trade discourages will be 
 best understood by reference to the economic condition of 
 Ireland. 
 
 In th:\t country there were no important manufacturing 
 industries until very recent times each one, as it came into ex- 
 istence, having been ruthlessly destroyed by the Protectionist 
 measures of the British Parliament during the eighteenth century. 
 Ireland thus became a country of practically one industry. An 
 Irishman who would live in his own country must make his living
 
 The Economic Argument. 197 
 
 Pt. Ill ,Ch. v., ?5.] 
 
 out of the land. The consequence has been that rents have 
 risen at the expense of wages. This process has been checked 
 of recent years, partly by legislation, and partly by trades unions 
 and emigration, but chiefly by the creation of new outlets for 
 industrial activity. 
 
 But even now a Protectionist might fairly argue that a 
 high rate of wages could be created and maintained in 
 Ireland by a tariff upon imports. The result of this, he would 
 say, being the creation of new industries, the labourer would 
 be able to exercise a choice in the selection of his mode of life, 
 so that the landowners would no longer be enabled to exact 
 monopoly terms for the use of land. 
 
 It is quite conceivable that under these circumstances the 
 decrease in rent and the increased demand for labour would 
 more than compensate the wage-receiver for an increased price 
 of manufactured articles, so that the burden of the tariff would 
 be entirely borne by the owners of natural monopolies. But 
 to concede this is not to concede the desirability of imposing 
 a Protective tariff. As we shall see, there are other ways 
 besides Protection of establishing a variety of industries. If 
 Government aid is required at all as would probably be the 
 case in Ireland in the establishment of a new industry, there 
 is no method by which it can be given more wastefully, and 
 with a less effective result, than by means of a tariff, and there 
 is none which carries greater evils in its train. 
 
 This argument, which has some applicability to a country 
 situated so unhappily as Ireland, requires to be used with great 
 caution. Some Protectionists, not perceiving its necessary 
 limitations, extend it to all countries without discrimination. 
 Their mode of reasoning is as follows : 
 
 " Free Trade," they say, " results in an interchange of 
 these commodities which are the products of relative natural 
 advantages, due to superiority of soil, climate, or location. 
 The })opulalion increases, the available quantity of these
 
 198 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 diminishes, and the competition to obtain them raises the 
 profits of their owners. Thus, when population is small, 
 relatively to the available quantity of natural advantages, the 
 price of the products of these is low in comparison to the price 
 of manufactured commodities, as is evidenced by the fact that 
 in a newly settled country food and raw materials are generally 
 cheap, and other commodities are dear. 
 
 " With every increase in the population of a nation not 
 increasing [by means of Protection] the variety of its consump- 
 tion and the uses of its land, less fertile lands and poorer 
 national resources are brought into use, and the price of food 
 and raw material is raised. The increase of population, how- 
 ever, creates a keener competition among the producers of 
 commodities, and as a result they bear a lower price. Every 
 further increase in population adds to this contrast between the 
 value of food and material and that of finished commodities. 
 
 " As all natural resources are limited in quantity, the 
 surplus population cannot find employment upon them, but 
 must seek work in competition with their fellows who arc 
 engaged in the manufacture of finished commodities. For 
 these reasons a change in prices, due to increasing competition 
 in a Static society, is not nominal. Any decrease of price of 
 commodities does not result in an advantage to consumers 
 the advantage is secured by those who profit by the increased 
 price of food and material. Competition lowers wages and 
 interest, thus taking from those not exempt from its crushing 
 power, and at the same time increasing the advantage ot 
 monopolies to a corresponding degree." ^ 
 
 These are the words of Professor Patten, the Wharton 
 Professor of Political Economy in the University of Pennsyl- 
 vania, and not of ^Mr. Henry George. Thus nearly do the 
 extremists on either side approach one another, 
 
 1 "The Economic Basis of Protection," by Professor Patten, Whartonian 
 Professor of Political Economy in tlie University of Pennsylvania. Philadol- 
 pliia : J. B. Lippincott & Co., 1890.
 
 The Economic Argument. 199 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. v., \ 5.] 
 
 Yet the argument is undoubtedly a sound deduction from 
 economic postulates. Given a country of limited area and a 
 rapidly increasing population; given, too, that the population 
 has no means of escape by emigration, and that the means of 
 subsistence do not keep pace with the requirements of the 
 people ; given, too, that there is an effective competition 
 between all classes the result is an inevitable increase of rent, 
 at the expense of wages and profits. Since all must have food, 
 all must be at the mercy of the landowner. But where does 
 such a country exist ? The economic postulates cannot be 
 applied literally even to Ireland, where the pressure of popu- 
 lation upon the land has always been greatest. 
 
 The theoretical conclusion has, in fact, always been modified 
 by practical conditions ; and landowners have never been able 
 for any lengthened period to extort monopoly prices for the 
 use of land. Their theoretical power to do so has always been 
 directly, or indirectly, limited in fact. Sometimes rents have 
 been fixed by custom or by legislation ; sometimes they have been 
 forcibly lowered by a combination of tenants or by emigration ; 
 while the steady improvement in agricultural processes which 
 has characterised the last three centuries has so largely 
 increased the efficiency of agricultural labour, that the margin 
 of profitable cultivation is continuously expanding. These 
 considerations, however, jjlainly cannot affect the economic 
 soundness of the argument. All that we have to consider now 
 is its applicability to the fiscal controversy. 
 
 Is it the case that Free Trade assists the owners of natural 
 monopolies, and aggravates the tendency of rent to absorb 
 wages and profits ? 
 
 Professor Patten boldly answers in the affirmative, relying 
 on the reasoning already quoted. " A I'rotective policy," he 
 says, " results not in general high values, but in the high value 
 of commodities produced entirely by labour and capital, and a 
 low value of the products of natural monopolies. Free Trade 
 has the opposite effect. It tends to give a high value to the
 
 20O Industrial Freedom. 
 
 products of natural monopolies,^ and increases the competition 
 of producers of commodities, so that what they produce has a 
 low value relative to the price of products of natural 
 monopolies " (p. 38). 
 But is this so ? 
 
 6. A landlord can, no doubt, exact higher rents in a 
 country of no manufacturing industries than he can where a 
 variety of occupations attracts his tenants from the land ; but, 
 on the other hand, he is still more strengthened in his monopoly 
 if his fellow-citizens are forbidden by law to purchase any of 
 their food from foreign countries. 
 
 Let us, however, assume that Protectionists who use Pro- 
 fessor Patten's argument are, like List and Hoyt, opposed to 
 Protective taxes upon food or raw materials. The argument 
 then depends on the assertion that Protection creates an indus- 
 trial variety, while Free Trade preserves industrial uniformity. 
 
 This is an assertion which will have to be tested both Ly 
 facts and theory when we come to consider its political 
 application under the title of the Diversification of Industry. 
 It is sufficient to point out at present that it rests upon two 
 unproved assumptions, namely : 
 
 I. That a sufficient variety of industry cannot si)ring up 
 without Protection ; and 
 
 1 It is not an unfair introduction of the personal element to ask Mr. Fatten 
 wliat was the efifect of Protection upon the natural monopoly of nickel, of uhicli 
 his pious founder, Mr. Wharton, was the owner in the United States. Was 
 the price of nickel reduced when a tax of fifteen per cent, was placed upon that 
 metal in 1864? or were not the American people, in fact, compelled, in conse- 
 tjuence of that duty, to purchase all their nickel from Mr. Wharton, who 
 owned the only nickel mine in the United States ? 
 
 Perhaps Mr. Patten cannot be exix;ctcd to answer these questions plainly, 
 because he holds liis chair upon the express condition, by the terms of Mr. 
 Wharton's grant, that he preaches the doctrine of Protection. A strange 
 notion this of U'niversity teaching that Professors shall not be allowed to 
 exercise an impartial judgment on the subject of their studies. .And what sort 
 of scientific investigation of facts or iirinciples can be expected from men wlio 
 are thus trammelled?
 
 The Economic Argument. 201 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. v., \ 7.] 
 
 2. That Protection is the best method of creating the 
 desired variety. 
 
 Both of these assumptions will be shown to be unfounded 
 at a later period in this discussion. It is enough to concede 
 at present that in pure theory it is conceivable that Free 
 Trade might depress wages by increasing rent. In practice, 
 however, this seldom occurs although it has most nearly 
 happened in the case of Ireland ; and even if it did occur, 
 Protection is not the true remedy. Rents have a tendency to 
 increase either under Protection or Free Trade. If, under 
 peculiar circumstances, they increase more rapidly under Free 
 Trade than under Protection, the real remedy is not the 
 temporary check of a high tariff, but the permanent use of a tax 
 upon land values, which, by means of regular assessments ct 
 fixed periods, should give to the general body of citizens a 
 due portion of the State-earned increment. 
 
 7. The inquiry which has been conducted in the previous 
 pages leads to the conclusion that the effect of Free Trade 
 in raising the rate of wages by improving the efficiency of 
 labour is not lessened by any other economic operation of 
 the policy ; except in the rare case where Free Trade acts as 
 a discouragement of industrial variety, when it may possibly 
 depress labourers to the profit of landowners. It remains 
 to consider the effect on wages of a policy of Protection. 
 
 Before, however, entering upon this inquiry, some notice 
 should be taken of the influence of Free Trade in the direction 
 of steadying wages. Working-men make two demands in 
 respect of wages that they should be high, and that they 
 should be steady. It is hard to say which of these require- 
 ments is of more importance ; but it seems to be admitted that 
 regular employment at a steady rate tends to greater security 
 and independence than larger, but uncertain, gains. 
 
 Now, Free Trade, as we have seen, exercises a direct 
 influence in steadying prices ; this necessarily reacts on wages, 
 because, since real wages consist not so much in money as in
 
 202 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 money's worth, whatever steadies the prices of articles in 
 common use makes it easier to estimate incomes and calculate 
 expenditure, and thus offers increased opportunities for saving. 
 
 Nor is the benefit of steady prices confined to working- 
 men. Employers also find it an advantage to know before- 
 hand all the items of their outlay. From being able to make 
 more certain estimates, they are encouraged to undertake more 
 business ; and they can undertake this at a lower cost, without 
 reducing wages, because the risk is lessened. This activity in 
 business soon reacts upon the wages of the labourer, until it is 
 shown by yet another instance that Free Trade means Great 
 Trade, and Great Trade means Prosperity. Moreover, through 
 this steadying effect on prices, Free Trade proves itself to be a 
 great security against commercial crises. Fluctuating trade, 
 with all its misery of wasted efforts, savings squandered, homes 
 destroyed, is an evil which lies far outside the range of any 
 fiscal policy. But, although the cause of fluctuating trade is 
 independent either of Protection or Free Trade, Free Trade 
 can at least mitigate its evil. Wars, excessive speculation, dis- 
 honesty, gambling in land these are among the causes of 
 commercial crises which cannot be affected by Free Trade, 
 and with regard to which Protection is most certainly as 
 impotent. But Free Trade does at least remove one source 
 of danger. It gives a larger area for the production of raw 
 materials, so that no industry is now dependent upon the 
 supply of a single country. 
 
 Closely connected with this virtue is the effect of Free 
 Trade in giving a more accurate knowledge of the state of 
 distant markets. A Free Trade country, which encourages 
 intercourse with foreigners, is less likely to mistake its markets 
 than one whose policy is isolation. The danger of producing 
 goods which are not wanted at the time is plainly lessened by 
 a closer intercourse with those who are your customers. Free 
 Trade, like telegraphs and railways, serves to keep producers 
 and consumers both informed as to each others' needs. Thus,
 
 :V 
 
 The Economic Argument. 203 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. v.,?7.] 
 
 although commercial crises will continue to occur in Free 
 Trade countries, there is perhaps no risk of their resembling 
 some of those in earlier times, when, for instance, a cargo of 
 skates was shipped to the Brazils, and grand pianos lay upon 
 the beach at Valparaiso for the want of storage -room, and 
 diamond tiaras were consigned for sale among the savages of 
 South America ! Moreover, when the crisis comes, the work- 
 man will be more prepared to meet it in a Free Trade country. 
 In the first place, owing to the greater accumulation of capital, 
 employers will be able to keep business going for a longer 
 time. Secondly, the larger foreign trade will afford a quicker 
 outlet for the surplus stock, and bring the market sooner to its 
 normal state ; while, whether the spasm be prolonged or 
 momentary, the workman's greater power of saving and the 
 lower price of his domestic necessaries will both relieve the 
 pressure of the harder times. 
 
 This is no imaginary picture. Between 1877 and 18S0, 
 England suffered from a trade depression as profound as any 
 in her history. That time is near in all our recollections. It 
 was the time of reaction from the artificial stimulus which 
 followed the conclusion of the Franco-German War. It was 
 also a time of war in Europe, Africa, and Asia. There was 
 such a famine in Ireland as had not been known since 1846, 
 and for seven consecutive years the English harvest had 
 been bad. P^vents like these in former days produced the 
 Luddite and the Chartist riots. Yet during those three years 
 in England there was not one single outbreak. There were 
 splutterings of disorder in France, Germany, and Spain, 
 while in America the workers in the iron trade the most 
 Protected industry of that Protected country suffered such 
 extremities that they broke into actual riot, and occupied the 
 town of Pittsburg. 
 
 But that is not all. Not only was England quiet when 
 other countries were disordered, but, in spite of her difficulties, 
 and in spite of the slackness of work during those three years.
 
 204 Industrial Fkeedom. 
 
 there was actually no perceptible increase in the number of 
 paupers. The working-class largely lived upon their savings. 
 It is hardly possible to offer a more pointed illustration of the 
 working of a Free Trade poUcy. 
 
 Yet all the recent facts of English industrial history point 
 to the same conclusion. Crime has diminished ; pauperism 
 has diminished ; the deposits in the savings banks have 
 increased ; the funds of the friendly societies have increased ; 
 the consumption of domestic articles in common use, per head 
 of the population, is nearly three times what it was in 1840; 
 the rate of mortality has declined, so that on an average a man 
 lives two years, and a woman three and a half years, longer 
 than they used. 
 
 Where, we may ask again, is it possible to get an accumu- 
 lation of facts like these to support the contrary conclusion of 
 Protectionists that Free Trade has injured the working-classes, 
 depressing wages ? 
 
 CHAPTER VI. 
 
 PROTECTION AND WAGES. 
 
 I. That Free Trade, unless some other and distinct influence 
 should supervene, cannot lower wages we have already proved. 
 That Protection must lower them, unless something supervene, 
 should now be made equally clear. 
 
 Protection, as we have seen, must raise prices for a 
 t'me, until the competition of the home producers has over- 
 supplied the local market, or else it will fail of its economic 
 purpose. At any rate, it must be admitted even by the most 
 i npatient partisan that Protection either will raise prices, or 
 else it will not. And on that admission we may fairly ask If 
 it will not raise them, to whom is the advantage? If it will 
 raise them, who will have to pay the piper ?
 
 The Economic Argument. 205 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. vi., \ I.] 
 
 The Protectionists' desire to tax the "foreigner" is well 
 known, and is a laudable weakness that has seduced into the 
 Restrictionist ranks many of the less clear-headed voters. But 
 whatever confusion may exist in the minds of those who are 
 willing to be confused, as to the incidence of Customs duties,^ 
 there can be no means even imagined of shifting on to strange 
 shoulders the sum which is added by Protective duties to the 
 price of home-made articles. Every penny of this must fall 
 upon the purchasers of those articles who are the citizens of 
 the "Protected country." But if Protection raises prices and 
 the increase has to be paid by the " Protected " purchasers, 
 where do these fortunate people get the money from to pay the 
 higher prices ? 
 
 This is the key of the economic attack upon Protection in 
 regard to its effect on wages. 
 
 Assuming, as we have already assumed for the purposes of 
 an economic argument, that rent, profits, and taxes remain 
 constant, and remembering that wages are the remainder of 
 the product after rent, profits, and taxes have been satisfied, so 
 that the rate of wages depends upon the proportion between 
 the quantity of the product and the number of labourers who 
 are employed in its production, the conclusion is irresistible 
 that if every one has to pay more for what he buys, and if the 
 num.ber of things produced is not increased, wliile the number 
 of labourers keeps the same, the rate of wages must fall. 
 
 Or the argument may be expressed in another way. 
 
 Protection diminishes the efificiency of labour by depriving 
 it of the assistance of the superior relative advantages which 
 
 It is rarely, if ever, the case that a Protective Customs duty can be borne 
 by the exporting country, because Protected countries are always pressed by an 
 anxiety to export. A good illustration of the fallacy of the vie a- that Customs 
 diUics arc paid by the foreign -r is givjn by the case of tlie salt duty in New 
 Sjath W.ilcj. This is at the rate of 90s. per ton. Now, the price of salt in 
 bond at Sydney is about 15s. a ton, and salt can be bought at the niine at from 
 about los. to i2s. a ton. Yet it is gravely asserted that the foreign merchant 
 who buys salt at los. a ton can afford to pay a duty on it of four times the 
 cost price !
 
 2d6 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 exist in other countries. It compels a man to do for liiniself 
 what another person is willing to do for him at a cheaper rate, 
 and so it compels the ex^ion of a greater effort to produce a 
 given result. In other words, it lessens the quantity of things 
 produced in the Protected industry by any given number of 
 workmen working for a given time. The test is price. If ten 
 workmen, working eight hours under Free Trade, can produce 
 something which can be exchanged for a ton of foreign com- 
 modities, and if they cannot produce those commodities by 
 working for themselves with less than ten hours' labour, any 
 Protective tax which raised the price of the foreign commodities 
 so that the workmen can no longer purchase them by eight 
 hours' work must diminish the efficiency of labour by the 
 amount of extra exertion which is required to overcome the 
 new obstacle to the enjoyment of the foreign commodities 
 which is created by the enhancement of their price. 
 
 " But," argue Protectionists, " even if Protection does 
 weaken the efficiency of labour in one direction, it strengthens 
 it in many others. Natural advantages are not all-in-all. It is 
 true that Protection confines the labourer to using those natural 
 advantages which exist in his own country, and shuts him out 
 from those which exist elsewhere ; but, by way of compensa- 
 tion, it makes him a brisker and more capable workman." For 
 the sake of argument, grant the assertion. The only evidence 
 of its truth must be a fall in prices. If the home labour has 
 been made so efficient by means of Protection that it can 
 dispense with the assistance which Nature has afforded to the 
 producers of a similar article in other countries, all occasion 
 for Protection vanishes. The Protection of the article at home 
 is no longer prevented by the competition of the foreigner. 
 
 ^ 2. The conclusion is thus reached, that so long as Pro- 
 tection is required and the evidence of this is the higher 
 price of the Protected article it cannot raise wages, but must 
 have a tendency to depress them. If, however, it be true that
 
 The Economic Argument, 207 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. vn., \ I.] 
 
 Protection develops new industries and so creates an increased 
 demand for labour, or if it be true that Protection stimulates 
 new qualities in the labourer which greatly increase his effi- 
 ciency, then it may be that the effect of Protection upon wages 
 is not wholly bad. Nothing can be predicated of this with 
 certainty, because the probability is that if Protection gives 
 these compensating advantages to labour, there will be an 
 influx of immigrants to share them, and the rate of wages will 
 be again depressed by the competition of labourers with each 
 other. At present, however, we are treating these advantages 
 as non-existent. It will be our business later in these pages 
 to inquire into the claim of Protection to be justified upon the 
 score of encouraging new industries and diversifying the op- 
 portunities of employment.! At present we are only concerned 
 with the operation of Protection upon wages, in consequence 
 of its effect upon the aggregate of material wealth. And here 
 we are met by two phrases which require a full consideration. 
 The first of these is, "That high prices make high wages ; " 
 the second, that "More money makes more work." Both of 
 these contentions are plainly independent of the Nationalistic 
 argument in favour of production. They assume the economic 
 postulates, but deny that the conclusions are unfavourable to 
 a policy of restriction. They will be considered separately in 
 the next two chapters. 
 
 CHAPTER vn. 
 
 DO HIGH PRICKS MAKIi HIGH WAGES? 
 
 jj r. We are now outside the citadel of the Restrictionists, and 
 in the very centre of the battle. The true relation between 
 prices and wages is the determining issue of the fiscal contro- 
 versy. Low prices are, to the eye of the Protectionist, the true 
 
 1 See, for a further discussion of the effect of Protection upon wages, 
 Part IV., Chapter V. : " The Pauper Labour Argument."
 
 2o8 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 cause of low wages. According to his theory, they prevent 
 the establishment of new industries, and restrict the develop- 
 ment of those which are already in existence by compelling 
 manufacturers to exercise such great economies in production 
 that the wages of the labourer are reduced to the lowest 
 possible rate. He proposes, therefore, to raise prices by the 
 operation of Customs duties. To the argument that this may 
 press hardly upon slender purses, he has the ready reply that 
 " it is much more important to the workman to have large wages 
 than cheap commodities ; that cheapness destroys employment, 
 because commodities cannot be cheapened without somebody 
 suffering ; that commodities may be too cheap when they are 
 below the price at which our people can make them profitably ; 
 that, in short, we must be careful lest, in our regard for the 
 interests of consumers, we sacrifice the interests of producers." 
 Such arguments really rest on the assumption that high prices 
 make high wages, and low prices make low wages. Is this 
 assumption true either in fact or theory ? 
 
 ^ 2. It has been already pointed out that prices may be 
 raised in two ways : either by increasing the demand for goods 
 or by diminishing their supply ; and it has been shown that a 
 rise in prices which results from an increased demand is often 
 accompanied by an increase in wages.^ 
 
 But this is not the way in which Protectionists propose to 
 raise prices. Their plan is to restrict supply. They want to 
 keep out the goods which are supplied from abroad in order to 
 compel their fellow-citizens to purchase those which are made 
 
 1 "What we want is abundance. We do not say that Free Trade necessarily 
 brings low prices. It is possible with increased quantities still to advance 
 prices ; for it is possible that the country may be so prosperous under Free 
 Trade that whilst you have a greater quantity of anything than you had before, 
 increased demand, in consequence of increased prosperity, may arise, so that 
 the demand will be more than the supply, and you may raise the prices on some 
 articles. In some articles it has been the case. It has been so on wool and on 
 meat ; and we may not know yet what effect it may have on wheat itself." 
 Cobden, House of Commons, December 13, 1852.
 
 The Economic Argument, 209 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. vii., 5 4.1 
 
 at home. What is this but to substitute an artificial scarcity for 
 a natural abundance ? And what is the whole argument 
 against the low prices which are caused by the competition of 
 foreign countries but a repetition of the arguments of those who 
 fought against the introduction of machinery ? 
 
 Free Trade is merely a device for cheapening the process 
 of production. In its operation it may interfere with certain 
 kinds of labour, and may possibly destroy some industries ; but 
 has not the invention of every new machine the same effect in 
 a greater or less degree ? The power-loom threw thousands of 
 hand-loom weavers out of work by reducing the price of woven 
 goods ; but did the wages of weavers fall in consequence, or 
 did the Luddites gain advantage by breaking their plan of the 
 machinery ? Yet the Luddites were true Protectionists. They, 
 too, argued that employment was better than cheapness, and 
 that the producer ought not to be sacrificed to the consumer ; 
 and they, too, like their modern representatives, ignored the 
 interest of any section of the public but their own. Have 
 times changed in this respect, and can it be that scarcity is now 
 a greater benefit to labourers than abundance ? Can the limi- 
 tation of supply raise wages through the agency of prices ? 
 
 3. Certainly, the man who makes the assertion that this 
 can be, starts, as Sir T. Farrer points out, with a strong pre- 
 sumption against him. He cannot, by " any of the laws which 
 he proposes add one iota to the productive powers of the 
 world. He cannot add an idea to the brain of the thinker, a 
 muscle to the arm of the worker, a fertilising ingredient to the 
 soil. All his implements are fetters on free action or weapons 
 of destruction. To suppose that by preventing men from using 
 their natural powers and satisfying their natural desires you can 
 increase their capacity for production, and for earning wages by 
 production, is in the highest degree improbable." 
 
 4. Such an assumption is not only improbable it is 
 o
 
 2IO Industrial Freedom. 
 
 contrary to fact. The theory that " high prices make high wages " 
 is in flat contradiction to all experience. Cobden showed it to 
 be palpably untrue by every modern instance that was open to 
 examination. The facts of to-day disprove it to any one who 
 chooses to investigate them ; and the records of six centuries 
 have recently borne witness to the same effect. Yet this vain 
 and baseless theory, evolved out of the selfish imaginings of 
 interested persons, still continues its delusive hold upon the 
 minds of many working-men. 
 
 Let us test it first by reference to facts. Professor Thorold 
 Rogers than whom no one can speak with greater authority 
 recently published an inquiry into the condition of the 
 English working-classes from the earliest times of which we 
 have authentic record, under the title of " Six Centuries of 
 Work and Wages." Nothing is recorded in this work which 
 has not been taken from contemporary documents, with the 
 result that all readers of the English language have before 
 them now a complete and exact account of the movements of 
 wages and prices during the last six hundred years. Surely, if 
 the Protectionist theory were true, such an examination as this 
 would furnish some facts in its support. It furnishes none. 
 Every piece of testimony is the other way. Wages have not 
 risen with prices, and they have not fallen when prices became 
 low, but quite the contrary. Mr. Rogers, summing up the re- 
 sults of his investigations into the fluctuations of prices and 
 wages during these six centuries, lays it down as an universal 
 law that "wages have always increased absolutely /.f.,in their 
 money amount -and relatively i.e., in their purchasing power 
 when prices were low."i 
 
 1 " Six Centuries of Work and Wages," p. 527. Compare also p. 428 and 
 the following passage from p. 429: "As, therefore, wages do not rise with 
 prices, no crime against labour is more injurious than any expedients adopted 
 on the part of Government which tend to raise prices. Unluckily for them, 
 many working people have been misled by interested sophistry into believing 
 that high prices for employers mean good wages for workmen. I do not deny 
 that if an artificial stimulus is given to some particular industry, the demand
 
 The Economic Argument. 211 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. vi;.,?4] 
 
 Modern experience tells the same story. " Do you think," 
 said Cobden in the House of Commons on February 24th, 
 1842, "that the fallacy of 1815, which I heard put forth so 
 boldly last week, that wages rose and fell with the price of 
 bread, can now prevail in the minds of working-men after the 
 experience of the last three years ? Has not the price of bread 
 been higher during that time than for any three consecutive 
 years for the last twenty years ? And yet trade has suffered a 
 greater decline in every branch of industry during this period 
 than in any preceding three years. Still there are hon. 
 gentlemen on the other side of the House, with the reports of 
 committees in existence and before them proving all this, pre- 
 pared to support a Bill which, in their ignorance for I cannot 
 call it anything else they believe will keep up the price of 
 labour." Later in the same speech, Mr. Cobden referred to 
 manufacturing wages : " Have low wages," he said, " ever 
 proved the prosperity of our manufactures ? In every period 
 when wages have dropped, it has been found that the manufac- 
 turing interest dropped also ; and I hope that the manufacturers 
 will have credit for taking a rather more enlightened view of 
 their own interests than to conclude that the impoverishment 
 of the multitude, who are the great consumers of all they pro- 
 duce, would even tend to promote the prosperity of our manu- 
 
 for the produce of which is limited, but continual, and the craftsmen in which 
 are also limited, such a calling may get enhanced wages for a short time. But 
 others soon crowd into the calling, and very speedily the thing is made dearer, 
 and the producer remains no better off, having lost in the interval the knowledge 
 which competition gives as to the best conditions under which industry can be 
 exercised. But it is idle to argue that such an artificial stinmlus can be given 
 to every kind of industry. Were it universal, the country would be debarred 
 from all intercourse with foreign commerce, and the legislature would raise a 
 blockade round the ports far more effective than anything which the most 
 successful belligerent could enforce. If it be partial, it will either affect all con- 
 sumers or some. If all, it induces a universal scarcity without benefiting any 
 one, for internal competition is sure to do its work on profits and wages ; if 
 son\e, it simply narrows the area of consumption, and with even more rapid re- 
 sults on profits and wages. These elementary principles, which one is almost 
 ashamed to alle^jc, could be illustrated by a thousand facts." 
 
 O 2
 
 212 Industrial Freedom, 
 
 facturers. I will tell the House that by deteriorating that 
 population, of which they ought to be so proud, they will run 
 the risk of spoiling not merely the animal, but the intellectual 
 creature ; and that it is not a potato-fed race that will ever lead 
 the way in arts, arms, or commerce. To have a useful and a 
 prosperous people, we must take care that they are well fed." 
 
 The figures of English agriculture tell the same story. 
 During the present century the price of corn has fallen from 
 9SS. to 30s. a quarter, yet the wages of the agricultural labourer, 
 reckoned in money, are almost a third more than they were ninety 
 years ago ; while his real wages have increased even more, 
 owing to the greater cheapness of everything he buys. It 
 would be wearisome to cite many other instances in contradic- 
 tion to the unproved assertion of Protectionists that wages 
 and prices rise and fall together.^ It is for them to bring 
 forward proofs and illustrations in support of so incredible a 
 proposition. One further example may, however, be pardoned 
 on account of its instructive character. The economic condi- 
 tions of Victoria and New South Wales are as nearly similar as 
 those of any two countries can be, except that Victoria is a 
 strictly Protected country, while New South Wales has almost 
 a Free Trade tariff. Prices of " Protected" articles are higher 
 in Victoria than those of the same articles in New South Wales. 
 According to the Protectionist theory, wages in Victoria should 
 be higher also. Yet, so far as there is a difference in the rates 
 
 1 During the first twenty years of the century wheat was, on an average, 98s. 
 a quarter. The average weekly wages of the agricultural labourer were los. 
 from 1799 to 1803 ; I2S. from 1804-10 ; 12s. gd. from 1811-14. They then 
 sank about 17 per cent, from 1814-18, and about 20 per cent, more in 1819-20 ; 
 bringing them down in the last year of the decade to about 8s., for which year 
 the mean price of wheat is given by Mr. Tooke at 76s. Sir J. Caird, in his 
 book on the " Landed Interest,'' states that in 1878, when wheat was 46s., the 
 agricultural labourer's wages were 15s. a week. In 1886, wheat fell to 30s. a 
 quarter, but the nominal wages of the labourer were only less by 10 per cent. , 
 while, owing tc the fall in prices, his real wages did not alter. The agricultural 
 labourer was better off during the recent period of low prices of agricultural 
 products than at any other time in the century. [Summarised from Sir T. 
 Farrer's address to the Cobden Club, July 30, 1887.]
 
 The Economic Argument. 213 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. vii., \ 5.] 
 
 of wages in the two colonies, it is in favour of New South 
 Wales. 1 In short, the Protectionist assertion that wages and 
 prices rise and fall together cannot bear the test of argument. 
 It is, indeed, disproved by so many facts, that were it not for 
 the extraordinary influence of this delusion, we might fairly 
 decline to discuss it until some instance was brought forward 
 in its favour. Unfortunately, such is the nature of the contro- 
 versy between Protection and Free Trade that facts are seldom 
 accorded their due weight on either side ; but it may be doubted 
 whether there is any feature in the Protectionist revival more 
 surprising than that any number of persons at the present day 
 should believe that wages vary with prices when that cannot be 
 shown to have happened in any single instance, and when the 
 records of industrial history point unanimously to the opposite 
 conclusion. It must remain one of the marvels of human 
 credulity that persons not deficient in intelligence should give 
 credence to the bare assertion of interested parties, that " high 
 prices make high wages," when an unbroken record of experi- 
 ence proves the contrary. 
 
 5. We have hitherto been using the term wages with 
 reference to the whole community, and not to any particular 
 trade. This is the sense in which the term is used when 
 
 1 I am aware of the controversy which rages on this point between the sup- 
 porters of the two policies. Comparisons between rates of wages are notoriously- 
 difficult. It is, liowever, generally admitted that the nominal rates of wages 
 e.^., those fixed by trades unions are higlier in New South Wales. Victorian"", 
 however, assert that in their colony work is more regular, and rents are low er. 
 The latter part of the assertion is undoubtedly true as regards Melbourne, 
 where the natural features of the country make building easy and cheap, while 
 in Sydney similar work is necessarily very costly. Moreover, in the older 
 colony more of the land round the large towns is in the hands of large proprie- 
 tors, having been acquired by them in early days. Xevertheless, the balance 
 is in favour of New South Wales, so far as there is any difference between 
 the two colonies. I have satisfied myself by personal investigation that from 
 1886 to 1888 the wages paid to bricklayers, miners, and railv\ay servants were 
 from sixpence to one shilling a day higher in New South Wales than in 
 Victoiia. (See .Appendix III,)
 
 214 Industrial Freedom, 
 
 appeals arc made to the patriotism of consumers to submit to 
 a rise in prices for the purpose of raising wages. Certainly, 
 such an appeal is never intended to be understood with refer- 
 ence only to wages in Protected trades. Even a Protectionist 
 might shrink from asking a community to tax itself for the 
 benefit of the workmen in a few industries. Yet it cannot be 
 denied that a rise in prices, such as Protection must cause, may 
 for a time raise wages in the particular trade which is Protected. 
 It does not follow that this will be the necessary result of the 
 Protective duty ; but if the result of the duty is to shut out 
 foreign competition, and if the home producers are unable to 
 meet the demands of the local market, and if the supply of the 
 particular kind of labour which is required cannot be imme- 
 diately satisfied, the artificial scarcity which is created by Pro- 
 tection may cause a temporary rise of wages in one or more of 
 the Protected trades. This would unquestionably be an 
 advantage to some classes of wage-earners, but from the very 
 nature of its origin it cannot be permanent. 
 
 The transference of labour from one industry to another is 
 much more rapid than it used to be ; and there are now few 
 manufacturing processes which cannot in their simpler stages 
 be conducted by any person of ordinary intelligence. This 
 important difference between manufacturing and other pursuits 
 is often overlooked by the zealous advocates of manufacturers. 
 An agricultural labourer, a seaman, a clerk, an artisan in any 
 of the building trades, or a handicraftsman of whatever nature, 
 has to learn his business by a long apprenticeship. The man 
 who attends to a machine can almost learn his business in a 
 week. It is true that the higher processes of manufacture re- 
 quire both skill and taste, but they only give employment to a 
 small number compared with the large number of unskilled 
 "hands " who perform the chief of the work. It follows from 
 these considerations that any sudden rise of wages in one trade 
 is likely to attract labourers very rapidly from others ; and that 
 this attraction will be strongest towards those branches of
 
 The Economic Argument, 215 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. vii., \ s.] 
 
 employment which require the least skill. The consequence of 
 men thus crowding from other occupations into the Protected 
 trades would be that the wages of the less skilled labourers 
 would soon fall to their former level. Nor are the more skilled 
 members of the trade likely to enjoy the benefits of their posi- 
 tion for any great length of time. The smallness of the com- 
 munities in which Protection is now being tried makes the 
 competition among skilled labourers even more severe than it 
 is among the unskilled. Unskilled workmen in young colonies 
 can always command good wages in any occupation requiring 
 physical strength. Skilled workmen, on the other hand, 
 whether under Protection or Free Trade, are seldom so well 
 off as they are in England. The smallness of the scale upon 
 which business must be carried on in a small community pre- 
 vents that sub-division of employment under which a man's 
 peculiar talents acquire a special value. Wages of 20s., 28s., 
 and 4CS. a day, such as Sir Lowthian Bell mentions as the rate 
 for certain classes of workmen in the ship-building and iron 
 trades in the north of England, are unknown in Australia ; and 
 it is no uncommon thing to find among the passengers of the 
 homeward-bound steamers skilled English artisans, who are re- 
 turning to England because they cannot make the high wages 
 that they used to earn, in any part of Australia not even in 
 Protectionist Victoria. ^ 
 
 In these colonies manufacturers can only give a limited 
 employment to any class of labourers, and of those whom they 
 do employ, only a small number require any special skill or 
 training. Now, the skilled artisan is just the person who 
 
 1 In a paper read before the Industrial Remuneration Conference in 1885 
 {sec Report, p. 140), Sir Lowtliian Bell, the President of the Iron and Steel 
 Association, mentions a ship-builder who in one year paid from 8s. gd. to 
 I2S. io.\d. a day to all his skilled hands. Among tliese were ten who made 25s. 
 a (lay, and thirty who were paid 20s. a day. They were at work for 313 days 
 in the year. At the rolling-mills, furnace-men were paid 12s. 8d., and the head 
 sliearcrs 28s. 3kl. per day. The least experienced of the chief rollers received 
 17s. 5d., and the best 40s. iid. per day. The average daily receipts of fourteen 
 men employed at the rolls were 27s. 8d.
 
 2i6 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 emigrates most readily, as he has both the means to take this 
 step and the intelhgence to appreciate its advantage. Conse- 
 quently, most young countries have a superfluity of skilled 
 manufacturing labour ; while if there should not be any trade 
 for which skilled labour was not available at a low price, nothing 
 would be easier than for the "Protected" manufacturer to im- 
 port as much as he required. Accordingly, whatever may be 
 the effect of Protection in raising prices in a particular trade, 
 the wages in that trade are not likely to rise for any appreciable 
 length of time. They will be kept down both by the competi- 
 tion of the home labour market and the facility with which the 
 manufacturers will be able to import labour from other 
 countries. 
 
 6. There is, however, another consideration which should 
 not be overlooked in considering the effect of prices upon 
 wages viz., the difference between "nominal" and "real" 
 wages. Very slight reflection will show that a rise in the 
 money value of wages is of small advantage if the purchas- 
 ing power of money is diminished. If a sovereign under 
 Protection only goes as far as 15s. under Free Trade, the 
 workman whose wages are raised from 15s. to i8s. is worse off 
 by 2S. a week than he used to be. This diminution in real 
 wages must not be forgotten by those who are attracted 
 by the prospect of an immediate increase in their money 
 wages. Prices will not be allowed to rise in one industry 
 only.i 
 
 7. Protection will never be submitted to unless its 
 anticipated benefits are believed to be shared by all citizens 
 
 iThe experience of Protected countries shows that this conclusion of 
 abstract PoUiical Economy accords with facts. Wages are not higher, either in 
 the United States or in Victoria, in the protected than in the unprotected 
 trades. Indeed, in many of the " Protected " trades in the United States 
 wages have fallen so low that the native Americans have been displaced by 
 labourers of a lower standard of living.
 
 The Economic Argument, 217 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. vii., 5 7.] 
 
 alike. Consequently the scheme of the Protectionist is to 
 protect everything ! 
 
 Buoyed up by their belief in the ability of Governments 
 to regulate the price of goods and labour, Protectionists 
 are ready to apply their nostrum to every form of industry, 
 and indignantly repudiate the charge of wishing to confer a 
 favour upon special trades. Have they protected the native 
 industry of iron-producing? They will admit that by doing 
 so they have inflicted hardship upon every one who has to 
 purchase iron, such as machinists, boiler-makers, engineers, 
 shipbuilders, <Scc., &c. Seeing, then, that they have made iron 
 scarce and dear, they are willing to go further, and lay a duty 
 on the importation of every substance made of iron. By this 
 means, they say, the makers of iron-ware of every sort will be 
 able to recoup themselves for the higher price of their raw 
 material by charging higher prices to their ov/n customers. 
 
 But here a new injustice would arise if our Protectionists 
 were not so careful and far-sighted ! The consumers of iron 
 goods of all sorts the manufacturers and householders who 
 need boilers, fenders, pots, pans, and iron-ware of every kind 
 are they to go without Protection ? They are hindered in 
 their laudable desire to foster native industry by the high 
 prices they have to pay for their requisites of production. 
 Let them, says the Protectionist, accordingly obtain a tax to 
 raise the price of all the articles which they produce ; and if, 
 directly this complicated business is concluded, there should 
 crop u[) another lot of patriotic natives eager to have their 
 industry fostered, let them, too, obtain a tax even as the iron- 
 ware makers ! So the process continues. Every man who can 
 produce, or thinks he can produce, an article which is im- 
 ported, is, under the Protectionist creed, entitled to a duty. 
 No wonder that the politician who may liave started on his 
 career with the intention of protecting iron and nothing else, 
 soon, in a despair of puzzle-headedncss, cries out with iron 
 producers, iron labourers, iron consumers, and all the deluding
 
 2i8 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 and deluded crowd, "Protect not only iron, but coal, cotton, 
 bread, meat, tobacco, clothing, china ! Protect everybody and 
 e/erything!" that every one may have the pleasure of robbing 
 his neighbour to distribute to the poor, that the laying goose 
 may be destroyed and one golden egg divided ! 
 
 " If you tax corn," says Sir T. Farrer, " you must tax flour 
 and everything made of corn ; if you tax sugar, you must tax 
 biscuits and jams ; if you tax salt, you must tax chemicals ; if 
 you tax chemicals, you must tax dyed goods ; if you tax 
 leather, you must tax boots, shoes, gloves, harness, and 
 gearing; if you tax wool, you must tax yarns and woollen 
 goods ; if you tax yarns, you must tax cloth and silk ; if you 
 tax iron or steel, you must tax everything made of iron and 
 steel -from a ship to an umbrella." Generous indeed as is 
 the impulse which leads the advocate of a restricted com- 
 merce in a young country to demand that Protection should 
 be given equally to every one, it is to be feared that this all- 
 round system differs only from that which they so boastfully 
 despise in being more unjust and more impolitic. Could 
 such a system be carried out in its entirety, it would result in a 
 rise of nominal prices, which would leave the real rewards of 
 labour exactly as they were. 
 
 8. But the fundamental objection to a system of 
 all-round Protection is its complete impracticability. The 
 large majority of persons in any community can never be 
 Protected, because, as consumers, they outnumber the 
 producers ; so that Protection weighs upon them with all 
 its disadvantages, without being able to confer even an 
 imaginary benefit. All those who are engaged in rendering 
 services to make life and property secure such as judges, 
 soldiers, police, and civil servants in all their infinite variety 
 cannot fail to suffer unless with every rise in prices their 
 fixed salaries are also raised. Another class which can 
 receive no benefit is that which is engaged in what Mill calls,
 
 The Economic Argument. 219 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. vii., \ 8.] 
 
 in the widest sense of the term, "unproductive" labour, 
 whose duties might be better defined by borrowing from 
 Bastiat ^^ services itnmatene/s." This class comprises domestic 
 servants, lawyers, clergy, schoolmasters, authors, artists, and 
 all kinds of "professional men." Neither does the class of 
 retail dealers receive from the system anything but injury. If 
 we use " retail dealers" in its widest sense, to mean all who 
 are concerned merely with the distribution of wealth, this 
 class will comprise bankers, brokers, merchants (both whole- 
 sale and retail), railway servants, seamen, wharf labourers, 
 carriers, and many others. There is yet a fourth class to 
 whom Protection brings more hardship than aid, composed of 
 all whose products are immediately consumed upon the spot, 
 such as caterers, masons, carpenters, blacksmiths, gardeners, 
 bakers, butchers, &:c. In short, one may say that all those 
 whose services or trades are such that they can never fear the 
 competition of the foreigner are directly injured by a system 
 of Protection. 
 
 Such persons form by far the larger number in every 
 community. Probably not more than one person out of ten 
 is engaged in an industry which it is possible to protect. 
 Thus even all-round Protection turns out to be a favouring of 
 special trades, although every fresh application of the principle 
 may make it more difficult to trace its working. 
 
 The comparatively narrow sphere within which any Pro- 
 tective duties can operate leads to an important economic 
 consequence, by increasing the rapidity with which Protection 
 affects the labouring classes. Every loss which is inflicted on 
 the non-Protected portion of a community by a rise in prices 
 soon recoils upon producers. Increased prices result either 
 in a less consumption or a diminished power of saving ; and 
 as a great part of the industrial enterprises of a country are 
 canied on by the use of small savings, the result follows that 
 as producers lose the assistance of that capital industry begins 
 to bnszuish.
 
 220 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 9. It is worthy of notice, in conclusion, that the argu- 
 ment that Protection ought to be supported because by raising 
 prices it will raise wages is entirely inconsistent with the 
 argument that Protection ought to be supported because it 
 will in the long run bring prijces down. No one who has been 
 actively engaged in a campaign against Protection would feel 
 surprise at noticing that any two Protectionist arguments were 
 mutually destructive; but for the benefit of those whose 
 happier fortune has led them into other paths, it may be 
 mentioned that the two arguments are never intended to be 
 addressed to the same audience. The argument that Pro- 
 tection will raise wa!ges by raising prices is for the exclusive 
 use of the working-classes ; while the argument that Pro- 
 tection will lower prices is reserved with equal carefulness for 
 the voter with a fixed income ! As, however, the working- 
 classes are the power behind all policies, it is with the 
 arguments intended for their ears that Free Traders have the 
 most to do. 
 
 In spite, therefore, of the fact that there never has 
 been, nor can be, a general rise in wages in consequence of 
 a rise in prices resulting from a diminution of supply, the 
 idea that the contrary is possible is so deeply rooted in the 
 minds of many working-men that no excuse is needed for 
 devoting further time to its consideration. Let us assume, 
 then, for the sake of argument, that the high prices caused 
 by Protection can cause an increase of wages : where does the 
 money come from to pay the increase ? If everybody has to 
 give more for what he buys, how comes there to be a larger 
 sum available for wages ? By whose labour is it created ? 
 These are questions which go to the root of the Protectionist 
 argument. How far Protectionists succeed in answering them 
 will be the next inrjuiry.
 
 The Economic Argument. 22 1 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. viii., \ I.] 
 
 CHAPTER VIII. 
 
 DOES MORE WORK MEAN MORE MONEY? 
 
 I. If the argument of the last two chapters has been 
 followed, it will be remembered that the inquiry at present is 
 into the truth of the assertion that the higher prices caused by 
 Protection may be beneficial to the working-classes. 
 
 At first sight, a man would not appear to be better off for 
 having to pay a higher price for everything he wished to 
 purchase ; but the Protectionist explains that the benefit which 
 is thus conferred is of a twofold nature. 
 
 First he says, " High prices mean high wages." With 
 that theory we have already dealt. 
 
 Next he says, " More work means more money." It is 
 with this portion of the explanation that the argument is now 
 concerned. 
 
 Developed at more length, the Protectionist reply to the 
 question by which Free Traders hoped to have posed their 
 adversary namely, " Where does the money come from to 
 pay the higher prices ? " is of this nature : 
 
 " True," it is said, " that Protection raises prices for a time ; 
 true that it draws labour and capital into industries which they 
 would not enter if they were left to themselves ; true that high 
 prices cannot cause an all-round rise in real wages. Never- 
 theless, the encouragement which a judicious tariff will give to 
 the starting of new industries, or the development of those which 
 are already established, must so greatly increase the demand 
 for labour, that the wage-earning class under Protection, even 
 in the unprotected industries, will be better able to pay high 
 l)rices than the same class under Free Trade was able to pay 
 low prices." 
 
 The first remark whicli suggests itself as a criticism upon 
 this presentation of the Protectionist case is that it is rather an
 
 222 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 assertion of fact than an argument. It is merely an expansion 
 of the stock controversial phrase that " employment is better 
 than cheapness," of which the underlying assumption is that 
 Protection gives a wider and more regular employment than is 
 given by Free Trade. 
 
 The first question, therefore, which arises is in reference to 
 the truth of this assumption: " Is it a fact that a comparison 
 between countries whose industrial conditions in other 
 respects are in the main similar, shows that the employment of 
 the working-classes is more constant in those which have 
 adopted Protection than in those which have adopted Free 
 Trade?" This is, plainly, a question of evidence. Yet, how. 
 many writers or speakers think it necessary to obtain or weigh 
 the evidence on either side before they hazard an assertion, 
 one way or the other ? 
 
 It is one of the many indications of the empirical character 
 of most economic opinions that persons of eminence in other 
 branches of science do not hesitate to generalise upon com- 
 mercial or industrial phenomena, without even an elementary 
 knowledge of the facts on which their reasonings rest. A man 
 who would talk on law or physics with the assurance with 
 which some lawyers and scientists talk of commercial phe- 
 nomena, would be at once asked to produce some proof of his 
 acquaintance with the facts of the subject upon which he was 
 speaking. Yet men of education and intelligence, who are 
 accustomed to weigh their words about other matters, will 
 readily adopt a fixed opinion for or against Free Trade, without 
 any apparent consciousness that opinions upon such a matter 
 ought to rest upon accurate acquaintance with the industrial 
 conditions of the particular country to which they relate, and 
 require, before they can possess any value, at least a superficial 
 acquaintance with the course and extent of its foreign 
 commerce. 
 
 Although industrial and commercial phenomena are gener- 
 ally complex, on account of the variety and changeable
 
 The Economic Argument. 223 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. vlii., \ I.] 
 
 character of the forces by which they are occasioned, and 
 although any fiscal policy must be judged by its effect on 
 industry and commerce, the number of persons who study the 
 development of industry or the course of commerce, even as 
 regards one country or during any period of years, is small 
 indeed, as compared with the number of those who are 
 prepared to pronounce authoritatively in favour of Protection 
 or Free Trade. 
 
 It is surprising, for instance, how readily people will repeat 
 the old fallacy that " Employment is better than cheapness," 
 without inquiring whether the countries in which a low level 
 of prices prevails are not precisely those in which after 
 making allowance for other diversities of industrial conditions, 
 such as would arise from differences in the amount and 
 distribution of capital, labour, and available land the employ- 
 ment of the working-classes is the most regular and the most 
 profitable. Such neglect in the observation of industrial 
 facts certainly cannot be due to the difficulty of obtaining 
 information. 
 
 The Reports of the Commission of Enquiry into the State 
 of Trade in the United States, which was appointed in 1885 
 by Mr. Secretary McCulloch, collected a mass of authentic 
 information as to employment and wages in other countries 
 besides America ; while the late Royal Commission on the 
 Depression of Trade, of which Lord Iddesleigh was the 
 Chairman, has compiled an almost complete body of testimony 
 upon the industrial condition of every part of the civilised 
 world between the years 1883-6. . The results of these 
 investigations are supplemented from time to time by Official 
 Reports published by the Board of Trade in England and by 
 the Labour Bureau at Washington. 
 
 Surely, if there existed anywhere any proof that the best 
 way to give employment to the working-classes was to cause 
 an artificial scarcity of the articles they wished to buy, tlicse 
 officials and commissioners would have discovered it. Yet
 
 224 Industrial Ph^edoM, 
 
 nothing is more remarkable than the omission on the part of 
 Protectionists to adduce even a soUtary instance in support of 
 their theory that employment is made more regular by the 
 adoption of Protective duties. 
 
 It would be out of place, in a work which is intended chiefly 
 as a guide to the understanding of principles and their applica- 
 tion, rather than as a handbook of polemical illustrations, to enter 
 upon any lengthy statistical investigations in order to compare the 
 progress or condition of one country with another. The figures 
 upon which such a comparison must rest change from year to 
 year, so that it would be impossible to give any demonstration 
 of the superior condition of the working-classes in a Free 
 Trade country which would carry conviction to a reader two 
 or three years hence. All that can be done is to indicate, so 
 far as an extended range of reading will permit, that from time 
 to time this demonstration has been made by Free Trade 
 writers for the dates at which they wrote ; but that, unless the 
 newspapers and controversialists of his own side have been 
 singularly oblivious of his work, no Protectionist writer has 
 even attempted to prove the opposite. 
 
 The characteristic, indeed, of Protectionist utterances in 
 Australia where the controversy rages keenly is a resolute 
 ignoring of official records as to the condition of Protected 
 countries. Free Traders are not so unwilling to look at facts. 
 Their inclination to go for their arguments to men and 
 markets is as marked as is that of their opponents to lean upon 
 books and maxims. Dull as statistics must always be, they 
 are the only evidence by which a fiscal theory can be put to 
 the test of practice. Who will say that Protectionist orators 
 and writers are willing students of the figures of trade, wages, 
 and prices ? 
 
 It may be that some believer in Protection is prepared to 
 bring forward definite evidence in support of his theory that 
 the best way of giving employment is to cause a scarcity of 
 commodities. All that Free Traders say, at present, is that
 
 The Economic Argument. 225 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. viil., 5 2,] 
 
 such evidence is wanting. When it is produced they will be 
 prepared to consider it. Until it comes it is only by the 
 courtesy of controversy that they give consideration to the 
 strjnge theory. They are justified, however, in pointing out, 
 before they discuss the theory as a theory, and without entering 
 into details, that the body of testimony is against it. All the 
 reports which have been already mentioned, together with the 
 investigations of Mr. Giffen in England and Mr. Atkinson in 
 the United States, and the evidence which is afforded by other 
 official documents, show that, other things being equal, there 
 is, in fact, at least as steady and as large a field of employment 
 under Free Trade as under Protection. Commercial crises 
 and interruptions of employment occur at least as frequently 
 under Protection as they do under Free Trade. 
 
 2. Let us, however, for the sake of argument, waive all 
 objections founded upon want of evidence, and discuss the 
 theory of the Protectionists that "More work means more 
 money," upon a priori grounds. The allegation is that "Pro- 
 tection will give more employment." 
 
 Now, that the removal of a Protective duty might, at any 
 rate for a time, deprive some persons of employment, cannot 
 seriously be denied ; and by a parity of reasoning it may be 
 admitted that the imposition of Protective duties may cause 
 some persons to be employed who were previously idle. But 
 when Protectionists talk about giving employment, they have 
 in their mind the general body of workmen. It is not employ- 
 ment in a particular trade which they profess to consider, 
 but an increase in the total number of workers, and a more 
 constant demand for labour in all its branches. The question 
 accordingly to be considered is, " Whether Protection gives 
 more regular employment to the body of wage-earners than is 
 given by Free Trade?" 
 
 Let us recall for a moment what has been already sliown 
 to be the operation of Protection. The admitted object of 
 p
 
 2 26 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 Protectionists, and the admitted effect of Protective duties, is to 
 cause something to be made in one country which, in a state of 
 freedom, would be made in anodier. The proposal is, by 
 means of a duty, to bribe men into making for themselves at a 
 greater cost, or what is the same thing by a greater expendi- 
 ture of labour, the things which they had been in the habit 
 of obtaining at a less cost by a process of exchange. In so far, 
 then, as Protection increases the price of any article, it is a 
 device for causing unnecessary labour ; because the price of 
 most articles of common use which are the articles usually 
 affected by Protective duties is, under ordinary circumstances, 
 a measure of their cost of production. 
 
 Now, it has been shown in previous chapters of this work 
 that Protection causes a rise in prices at all events for a time 
 and that an increase of prices from this cause is not accom- 
 panied by any general rise in the rate of wages. The effect, 
 therefore, of Protective duties upon employment is that men 
 have to work for a longer time before they can earn enough 
 money to buy what they want. If Protective duties raise the 
 price of boots by two shillings a pair, every one who wants a 
 pair of boots must earn two shillings more before he can buy 
 them. Now, as has been proved in the last chapter, the wages 
 of workmen in other trades are not raised by a duty upon boots. 
 He therefore will have to earn the additional two shillings which 
 the boots will cost him by doing more work than he used to 
 do previously. In this sense, and in this sense only, does Pro- 
 tection give more employment to the working-classes they 
 have to work a longer time before they can earn enough to 
 purchase what they want. It has remained for Protectionists 
 to assert that the short cut to general prosperity consists in 
 compelling men to do for themselves what Nature has done for 
 them gratuitously in other countries. 
 
 The idea that tlie employment which is given by the neces- 
 sity of supplying the scarcity which is artificially created by 
 Protective duties is advantageous and profitable to a com-
 
 The Economic Argument. 227 
 
 Pt. in., ch. viii., 5 3.] 
 
 munity is in the same category with the idea that any one 
 causing two labourers to be paid instead of one thereby 
 doubles the amount of remuneration received in wages. The 
 Protectionist ironmaster, who insists that it will give employ- 
 ment to the people if he is allowed to make iron at six pounds 
 a ton, which persons can at present buy for three pounds, is 
 (without always knowing it himself) in the same position as the 
 temperance lecturer in the story, who happening himself to be 
 a manufacturer of bottles always urged his audience to smash 
 the bottles after they had drunk their ginger-beer ! 
 
 3. The plain truth is, that the matter of importance to a 
 community is not the mere giving of employment, but that the 
 employment which is given shall be profitable. Any number 
 of men might be employed in digging holes in the seashore 
 and filling them again with sand, but even a Protectionist 
 might hesitate to say that this was a mode of employment 
 that was advantageous to the nation even though all the 
 money spent in wages should be "kept in the country." 
 
 Yet simple and plain as these considerations are so that it 
 almost seems an insult to good sense to state them they are 
 not so simple and plain as not to be ignored by those who 
 carry into practice the doctrines of Protection. Perhaps no 
 better instance of the fatuity of those who think to benefit 
 a country by putting unnecessary labour upon its inhabitants 
 has ever been afforded than that which is offered by the 
 kerosene industry of New South Wales. 
 
 Many years ago a duty of sixpence a gallon was imposed 
 for revenue purposes on kerosene oil. At that time no 
 kerosene was produced in New South Wales, but large deposits 
 of shale have subsequently been discovered. A process was 
 soon adopted of extracting oil from the shale, and the six- 
 penny duty has been for some time highly Protective. The 
 abolition of the duty is, consequently, pressed for by Free 
 Traders, but strenuously resisted by Protectionists upon the 
 p 2
 
 228 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 ground that its retention affords employment. No Free Trader 
 can deny that this is the case. The question is, " Whether the 
 employment is profitable ? " The case stands thus: Since the 
 duty was imposed, great natural wells of kerosene have been 
 discovered in America and Southern Russia, and the process of 
 extracting oil from shale is almost entirely superseded by the 
 gratuitous operations of Nature. When oil bubbles from the 
 ground almost as if it were spring-water, one would hardly 
 think, unless one were acquainted with Protectionists, that 
 people would be found to urge that it was better to refuse the 
 gift of Nature and make oil by the old process. Yet so it is in 
 New South Whales. The oil is flowing from wells in Russia 
 and America, so that if a man wants oil he has little more to 
 do than dip a pannikin into the flowing stream. " But," argue 
 the Protectionists, " what ' employment ' is there in dipping a 
 pannikin into a stream ? Can we not in New South Whales get 
 the same oil by the laborious process of squeezing it out of our 
 own clay ? And shall we not by these means be developing 
 our natural resources and giving employment to our own 
 people? Let us then shut out the oil which flows in natural 
 streams, because Nature gives us that for next to nothing, and 
 set our men to work at squeezing the oil which we require out 
 of our own clay." Who can deny that such a policy, which is 
 literally carried out in New South Wales, will give employment, 
 and that, if the duty is removed, the employment may cease ? 
 
 Let us, however, carry the investigation a little further, and 
 inquire into the cost to the nation of providing this employ- 
 ment. The amount of kerosene imported in 1888 realised, 
 in round numbers, about ^25,000 in duty, and was a little 
 more than half the amount consumed. The full cost of the 
 tax, however, can only be calculated by adding to the amount 
 collected at the Customs House another ^25,000, being six- 
 ])ence a gallon on the total quantity of home-made oil consumed 
 in the colony. Fifty thousand pounds ! That Avas the amount 
 which it cost the inhabitants of New South Wales to give
 
 The Economic Argument. 229 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. viii.,? 3.] 
 
 employment to the persons who were engaged in the year 
 1888 in extracting kerosene from deposits of shale. 
 
 It will hardly be credited by any one who has not had 
 practical experience of the characteristics of a Protective 
 system that the number of hands who were so employed in 
 that year was only 299 ! Fifty thousand pounds to give 
 employment to 299 persons ! It would manifestly pay the 
 Government, if the duty were removed from kerosene, to give 
 _;;^i 0,000 to some speculative individual to build an asylum, in 
 which every one of these 299 persons might be supplied 
 gratuitously with food, clothing, and lodging for the rest 
 of their natural lives. Or if it is essential to the well- 
 being of the State that these men should be employed, 
 why not put a sum in the estimates which would give each 
 of them eight shillings a day to sit still with folded arms, and 
 do nothing if only by that means they would consent 
 to the free admission of kerosene oil ? To refuse to accept oil 
 which is manufactured by Nature in the bowels of the earth, 
 because to do so would throw out of employment some 
 three hundred persons who are engaged in manufacturing it by 
 machinery, is no whit more absurd than it would be for a 
 settler to refuse to draw his water from a running creek in 
 order that he might have the employment of digging a well on 
 its bank. 
 
 Yet this kerosene example is by no means an exceptional 
 instance of the extravagant absurdity of a Protectionist tariff. 
 The Victorian and American tariffs offer many similar cases, in 
 which the amount raised by the tariff is altogether dispro- 
 portionate to the employment which is given ; and in which 
 a far larger sum is collected by the tax at the Customs House 
 without taking into account the amount collected from the 
 consumers by the local manufacturers in the shape of 
 increased prices than would be required to give the current 
 wage to each of the workmen whom the tax allows to be 
 employed, and leave a handsome surplus over.
 
 230 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 4. It must be remembered that we are not dealing now with 
 the argument that Protection is desirable in order to cause a 
 variety of industries or in order to collect revenue both these 
 arguments will be dealt with later but only with the argument 
 that Protection is econojnically sound because it gives employment. 
 
 The root fallacy of this argument lies in the assumption 
 that the persons who are employed in the industries which 
 the tariff calls into existence would be idle if the tariff were 
 removed, 
 
 A moment's consideration will show that this assumption is 
 baseless. 
 
 The labour which is caused by Protection is unnecessary 
 labour, because (since the assumption is that, without Protec- 
 tion, the particular class of work in question would not be done) 
 the only reason for that labour is that it may produce something 
 which might be produced by far less labour in another country. 
 To ask a nation to give more labour to produce for itself what 
 it might obtain with less labour by a process of exchange is 
 manifestly to cause an unnecessary expenditure of effort. It is 
 no doubt true that this must in some industries cause an in- 
 crease of employment, but the question to be determined is, 
 Whether this indicates any economic advantages to the com- 
 munity? It would hardly be contended (to recur to our 
 former illustration), except by a thoroughly logical Pro- 
 tectionist, that any one who by bungling workmanship or 
 by extravagance caused two labourers to be paid instead 
 of one, thereby doubled the amount of money which he 
 expended in, directly or indirectly, remunerating labour. It is 
 undoubtedly true that the necessity of employing two men to 
 do the work of one does, for the moment, cause an increase in 
 the amount paid to the labourers in one class of occupation ; 
 but inasmuch as, by the hypothesis, one-half of this expendi- 
 ture is wasteful, it lessens, by the extent of its cost, the amount 
 which the engager of the labour is able to direct to productive 
 employment.
 
 The Economic Argument. 231, 
 
 Pt. Ill ,Ch. viii., 5 4.] 
 
 No one, for example, could imagine that it would conduce 
 to the general prosperity gradually to poison all the wells and 
 streams in England. Yet such an act might be defended by 
 every argument advanced in favour of Protection. As thirst 
 must still be quenched, another means must be adopted of 
 procuring drink. A new industry that which Protectionists 
 so much desire will accordingly spring up. Capital will 
 be directed to the distilling of salt water a great natural re- 
 source which will now be utilised. All fear of uniformity of oc- 
 cupation will then have vanished before the constant demand 
 for builders of all kinds, carters, horse-dealers, railways, tank- 
 makers, coopers, and fishermen, not to mention the number of 
 retail water-sellers whose services will also be required. And 
 in this case the industry will never perish. With every increase 
 of population more fresh water will be needed, and so a 
 profitable and permanent employment will have been provided 
 for the poor ! 
 
 An extreme instance like this reveals at once the under- 
 l)ing fallacy of the Protectionist assumptions. Those who 
 claim that Protection gives more employment than Free Trade 
 ignore the fact that this employment must be paid for. "You 
 cannot," said Cobden, "go on for ever feeding a dog with his 
 own tail."' There must in time come a limit to the power of 
 one class in a community to live upon another. Since a tax 
 upon imported commodities cannot of itself create wealth, the 
 higlier prices which the tax allows must be paid for out of 
 wealth already in existence. But if everybody has to pay 
 more for the things he wants, the power of a community to 
 save is necessarily lessened. Now, money is not, as a rule, 
 hoarded. Men invest their savings either directly in pro- 
 ductive enterprises or by depositing them in banks and 
 kindred institutions. Every penny which is invested employs 
 labour. Accordingly, whatever diminishes savings must di- 
 minish ihc power of employing labour. This is precisely the 
 (jpcralion of Protection. IJy taking more from people in th.e
 
 232 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 form of increased prices, it leaves them less to spend in the 
 form of invested savings. Protectionists see the labour which 
 the tariff employs, but they omit to notice the labour which 
 the tariff causes to be idle. 
 
 The decline in the export of Canadian manufactured pro- 
 duce, from ^825,000 in 1878, which was the last year of Free 
 Trade, to ^^7 00, 000 in 1884, which has already been referred 
 to, offers a good illustration of the double influence of a Pro- 
 tective tariff. The Canadian Protectionists who exult over 
 the increase in the number of hands employed in a few 
 weakly manufactures never speak of those who used to be 
 employed in the produce of articles of export, and wlio 
 lost their occupation on the introduction of Protection. It 
 may be a good thing to be occupied in working for the home 
 market, but it does not follow, without any evidence, 
 that the home market will give more employment than 
 the export trade. Any increase in the total of employment 
 can only arise from an increase in the total of productiveness, 
 which Protectionists have yet to prove can ever be the conse- 
 quence of a restricted trade. 
 
 The argument thus comes round to the point from which 
 it started. Other things being equal, employment will be 
 greatest and most constant in the country where there is the 
 most wealth. To cause a waste of wealth and an unnecessary 
 expenditure of labour in particular directions cannot increase 
 the aggregate number of men who arc employed unless it at 
 the same time reduces their wages. Once let it be recognised 
 that Protection causes waste, and the al)surdity of thinking 
 that the working-classes are better off because wealth is wasted 
 and labour is employed uselessly will be at once perceived. 
 Protection can divert industry from one channel into another, 
 but it can do no more. Py tlic whole amount of labour which 
 it causes to be employed needlessly does it lessen the pro- 
 ductive employment of the rest of the working-classes. 
 
 The same argument mav be staled in another wav. Since
 
 The Economic Argument, 233 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. viii.,?5.] 
 
 the aggregate wealth of a community is not increased because 
 a change in the character of goods demanded alters the 
 direction of capital, any apparent gain to one class of labourer 
 must be a loss to others. The whole amount payable in wages 
 can only be increased when the increased demand for those 
 articles which are afifected by the tariff is greater than the 
 diminished demand for others. But to assent to this proposi- 
 tion is equivalent to an admission that employment can only 
 be increased by an increase in the aggregate of wealth and 
 that, as has been proved, is not a result of Protection. 
 
 5. It must, of course, be borne in mind that the argu- 
 ment of the preceding pages has been entirely economic : that 
 is to say, it has proceeded on the assumption of a free move- 
 ment of capital and labour, which is the postulate of all 
 economic reasoning. There may, however, be circumstances 
 in which this postulate cannot be conceded, and in such a case 
 the conclusions must be qualified. What the full extent of the 
 qualification must be, and what are the circumstances under 
 which it must be made, are the proper subjects of the concluding 
 portion of this work. All that is relevant to the present 
 inquiry is a reminder that every abstract argument in the field 
 of politics must be subject to practical limitations. No 
 attempt has been made, up to the present point in the argu- 
 ment, to indicate the nature of the special limitations which, 
 either rightly or wrongly, are sometimes thought to be required 
 upon the economic argument against Protection ; but an en- 
 deavour has been made by a variety of methods to enforce 
 the homely truth tliat waste cannot make wealth, and the 
 diflicully of the argument has been entirely caused by the 
 simplicity of the conclusion. Even, however, if we assume 
 that tliere may be (-ircumstances under which, in a country of 
 large but undeveloped natural resources which has at the same 
 time a considerable quantity both of its labour and its capital 
 unemployed, even a I'roteclive ta.\ may be one means of
 
 2 34 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 directing industry to a permanent and profitable channel, still 
 the inquiry must be made whether such a tax would be the best 
 means of effecting this result, or whether the temporary 
 difificulty might not be more effectively dealt with by other 
 means, such as the gift of a bonus or the placing of Govern- 
 ment contracts with local producers at non-competitive prices. 
 It is plain, also, that such a qualification of the conclusions of 
 abstract reasoning, even were it practically justified, would in 
 no way affect the validity of the previous reasoning which has 
 been directed against those who maintain two consecutive 
 propositions ist. That without Protection prices must be 
 unremunerative to the producer ; 2nd. That with Protection 
 the consumer will be better off, in spite of high prices, 
 because he will obtain more constant and profitable em- 
 ployment. In order to probe these assertions, the questions 
 have been put in a variety of forms. At what will the 
 employment be, and who will pay for it?" And the old 
 conclusion has been reached : that men cannot be employed 
 except by the proceeds of labour. From which it follows 
 that whatever diminishes the proceeds of labour either 
 by lessening its efficiency or imposing new and artificial 
 obstacles in its way must diminish employment. That this 
 is the result of Protection cannot be denied by any one who 
 believes that where labour is free and capital abundant, men 
 will naturally follow the most profitable occupations. If Pro- 
 tective taxes are required to establish industries which cannot 
 grow up naturally, that fact is conclusive evidence that the 
 return of the Protected industries is less than that of those 
 which are already in existence. Protection, by holding out the 
 bribe of high prices, may draw labour from one channel into 
 another ; but by every penny which it takes from the consumer 
 in the form of higher prices, by so much does it lessen the 
 employment of those workmen who are not protected. 
 
 ^Vhethcr or not it is a good thing that one class of 
 woikrr.cn sho i!d live upon tlie con'ributions of another may
 
 The Economic Argument. 235 
 
 Pt. III., Ch. viii., \ 5.] 
 
 be a fair subject for argument. All that Free Traders ask is 
 that the recipients of public charity should acknowledge their 
 obligation. Let it be fairly understood that when a Pro- 
 tectionist manufacturer asks for taxes in order to give employ- 
 ment, he is really asking the rest of the community to pay for 
 the support of himself and his workmen ; and we may be sure 
 that it will become a matter for most critical consideration as 
 to whether or not the case is a deserving one for public charity. 
 Our present cause of complaint is that Protectionists have not 
 the courage to plunder us openly. They take sixpence here 
 and a penny there from every citizen who buys their goods, 
 but instead of collecting it from him in a fair and open 
 manner every time he makes a purchase, they disguise their 
 operations by increasing prices. No one will deny that in 
 taking this course the restrictionists are wise in their genera- 
 tion. For what length of time would a law remain upon the 
 statute-book of a democratic country which should empower a 
 constable to detain every man or woman as one left a shop, 
 and then and there, for every pound's worth of goods which 
 he or she had bought, to claim five shillings for the support of 
 certain manufacturers? Yet a 25 per cent, duty takes more 
 than 5s. in the ^ from every purchaser of the Protected 
 article for all the time that a duty of that amount is required 
 in order to equalise the prices of home-made and imported 
 goods. The only difference between taking the five shillings 
 by means of a policeman as one leaves the shop and taking 
 it over the counter in the form of an increased price, is that 
 the former method is honest and open, while the latter is 
 fraudulent and secret. 
 
 Track the Protectionist argument from point to point, and 
 it must end in the admission that under Protection one class 
 will live upon another. Let it assume what disguise it ma\-, 
 I'rotection, if it is effective, can never be anything more than 
 spoliation under the forms of law. Every Protective tax, by 
 whatever extent it operates to the exclusion of imported goods.
 
 236 Industrial Freedom, 
 
 is a licence to one class of the community to plunder another 
 under the pretence of charity. Hard as these words are, there 
 are times when the use of plain words is necessary. 
 
 Such a time has always arrived when benevolent but 
 heedless men are moved by the sight of sufferings to coun- 
 tenance quack remedies. Such is the present situation of 
 the fiscal controversy. The ravages of competition have been 
 great, and the intelligence to hear the cry of distress is 
 growing keener. What more easy and more satisfying to lazy 
 emotionability than to denounce competition in all its forms, 
 and to urge that a beginning should be made with the com- 
 petition of foreign nations ? If only the cure were so easy ! 
 Knowledge, however, and experience teach the contrary ; and 
 in the meantime, to those who despise knowledge in political 
 affairs, and who have not the strength of character to possess 
 their souls in patience, we may fairly say, as plainly as we can, 
 " Not only will your policy of commercial restriction fail to 
 remedy the evils of which you complain, but it is in every 
 aspect a disgraceful policy, because it turns your workmen 
 into beggars for public charity, and your manufacturers into 
 thieves." Great indeed should be the advantages which are 
 to compensate for evils such as these !
 
 fart X. 
 
 THE POLITICAL ARGUMENT. 
 
 CHAPTER I. 
 
 THE ARGUMENTS CLASSIFIED. 
 
 I. All that can be said in favour of Protection on 
 political grounds may be reduced, on analysis, under one of 
 four heads, which may be conveniently designated by the 
 names which the arguments bear in popular controversy. 
 These are : 
 
 1. The Infant Industry Argument. 
 
 2. The Variety of Industry Argument. 
 
 3. The Home Market Argument. 
 
 4. The Pauper Labour Argument. 
 
 2. It is well pointed out by Professor Taussig, in his 
 "Tariff History of the United States," that these arguments 
 have a certain historical connection. The whole passage 
 referred to is so instructive, and the work from which it is 
 taken so little known to Australian and English readers, that 
 no further excuse is needed for quoting it at length : 
 
 " Tlie system of Protective legislation began in 1816, 
 and was maintained till towards the end of the decade 1830-40. 
 Tlie Compromise Act of 1S33 gradually undermined it. By 
 1S42 duties reached a lower point than that from which they 
 had started in 18 16. During this whole period the argument 
 for Protection to young industries had been essentially the 
 mainstay of the advocates of Protection, and the eventual 
 cheapness of the goods was the chief advantage which they 
 proposed to obtain. It goes without saying that this was
 
 238 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 not the only argument used, and that it was often expressed 
 loosely in connection with other arguments. One does not 
 find in the popular discussions of fifty years ago, more than in 
 those of the present, precision of thought or expression. The 
 'home market' argument, which, though essentially distinct 
 from that of young industries, naturally suggests itself in con- 
 nection with the latter, was much urged during the period we 
 are considering. The events of the war of 1812 had vividly 
 impressed on the minds of the people the possible incon- 
 venience, in case of war, of depending on foreign trade for the 
 supply of articles of common use ; this point also was much 
 urged by the Protectionists. Similarly the want of reciprocity, 
 and the possibility of securing, by retaliation, a relaxation of 
 the restrictive legislation of foreign countries, were often men- 
 tioned. But any one who is familiar with the Protective 
 literature of that day as illustrated, for instance, in the 
 columns of Ni/es's Register cannot fail to note the 
 prominent place held by the young-industries argument. The 
 form in which it most commonly appears is in the assertion 
 that Protection normally causes the prices of the Protected 
 articles to fall,i an assertion which was supposed, then as now, 
 to be sufificiently supported by the general tendency towards a 
 fall in the price of manufactured articles, consequent on the 
 great improvement in the methods of producing such articles. 
 
 " Shortly after 1832, the movement in favour of Protection, 
 which had had full sway in the Northern States since 1820, 
 began to lose strength. The young-industries argument at the 
 same time began to be less steadily pressed. About 1840 the 
 Protective controversy took a new turn. It seems to have 
 been felt by this time that manufactures had ceased to be 
 
 1 See, for instance, the temperate report of J. Q. Adams, in 1832, in which 
 this is discussed as tlie chief argument of the Protectionists. Adams, though 
 himself a Protectionist, refutes it, and bases his faith in Protection chiefly on 
 the loss and inconvenience suffered through the interruption of foreign trade 
 in time of war. The report is in " Reports of Committees, 22nd Congress, 
 1st Session, vol. v., No, 481,"
 
 The Political Argument. ^39 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. i., \ r.] 
 
 young industries, and that the argument for their Protection as 
 such was no longer conclusive. Another position was taken. 
 The argument was advanced that American labour should be pro- 
 tected from the competition of less highly paid foreign labour. 
 The labour argument had hardly been heard in the period 
 which has been treated in the preceding pages. Indeed, the 
 difference between the rate of wages in the United States and 
 in Europe, had furnished, during the early period, an argument 
 for the Free Traders, and not for the Protectionists. The Free 
 Traders were then accustomed to point to the higher wages of 
 labour in the United States as an insuperable obstacle to the 
 successful establishment of manufactures. They used the 
 wages argument as a foil to the young-industries argument, 
 asserting that as long as wages were so much lower in Europe, 
 manufacturers would not be able to maintain themselves 
 without aid from the Government. The Protectionists, on the 
 other hand, felt called on to explain away the difference of 
 wages ; they endeavoured to show that this difference was not 
 so great as was commonly supposed, and that, so far as it 
 existed, it afforded no good reason against adopting Protection. 1 
 About 1840, the positions of the contending parties began to 
 change.- The Protectionists began to take the offensive on 
 the labour question ; the Free Traders were forced to the 
 
 1 Some signs of the appeal for the benefit of labour appear as early as 
 1831 in a passage in Gallatin's " Memorial," p. 31, and again in a speech of 
 Webster's in 1833, "Works," I., 283. In the campaign of 1840, little was 
 heard of it, doubtless because other issues than Protection were in the fore- 
 ground. Yet Calhoun was led to make a keen answer to it in a speech of 
 1840, " Works," III., 434. In the debates on the Tariff Act of 1842, we hear 
 more of it ; see the speeches of Choate and Buchanan, Congr. Globe, 1841-42, 
 pp. 950, 953, and Calhoun's allusion to Choate, in Calhoun's "Works," IV., 
 207. In 1846 the argument appeared full-fledged, in the speeches of Winthrop, 
 Davis, and others, Congr. Globe, 1846, Appendi.x, pp. 967, 973, 11 14. 
 See also a characteristic letter in A'iles, Vol. 62, p. 262. Webster's speech in 
 1846, " Works," v., 231, had much about Protection and labour, but in a 
 form somewhat different from that of the argument we are nowadays familiar 
 with. 
 
 - See, among others, Clay's Tariff speech in 1824, "Works," I., 465, 466.
 
 240 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 defensive on this point. The Protectionists asserted that high 
 duties were necessary to shut out the competition of the ill-paid 
 labourers of Europe, and to maintain the high wages of thelabourers 
 of the United States. Their opponents had to explain and 
 defend on the wages question. Obviously this change in the 
 line of argument indicates a change in the industrial situation. 
 Such an argument in favour of Protection could not have arisen 
 at a time when Protective duties existed but in small degree, 
 and when wages nevertheless were high. Its use implies the 
 existence of industries which are supposed to be dependent on 
 l.ij^h duties. When the Protective system had been in force 
 for some time, and a body of industries had sprung up which 
 were thought to be able to pay current wages only if aided by 
 high duties, the wages argument naturally suggested itself 
 The fact that the iron manufacture, which had hitherto played 
 no great part in the Protective controversy, became, after 
 1S40, the most prominent applicant for aid, accounts in large 
 part for the new aspect of the controversy. The use of the 
 wages argument, and the rise of the economic school of Henry 
 C. Carey, show that the argument for young industries was felt 
 to be no longer sufficient to be the mainstay of the Protective 
 system. The economic situation had changed, and the dis- 
 cission of the tariff underwent a corresponding change." 
 
 h 3. This brilliant survey of the history of the Protective 
 movement in America might easily be illustrated from 
 Australian experience. In that country, also, the pauper- 
 1 ibour argument has been the last to come into prominence. 
 
 The argument which was most frequently used in the early 
 days of the Protectionist agitation in Victoria was drawn from 
 the supposed necessity of providing new avenues of employ- 
 ment for the mining population as the yield of gold 
 decreased.^ 
 
 The same cry was raised in New South "Wales when, 
 
 1 Victoria adopted a Protectionist taiiff in 1S66.
 
 The Political Argument. 241 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. ii., 5 I.] 
 
 owing to a reaction from a period of excessive expenditure on 
 public works, and to the effect of a Land Act in stopping im- 
 provements on Crown lands, a number of " Unemployed" 
 made their appearance in the streets of Sydney. Gradually, 
 however, as the agitation in each colony settled down, and as 
 industries began to be established in Victoria under Protection, 
 in New South Wales under Free Trade, the necessity was 
 felt for appealing to cupidity and self-interest by some other 
 means. The pauper-labour argument was admirably adapted 
 for such a jDurpose. Indeed, there is no other argument in 
 the Protectionist quiver which offers a politician such a rare 
 opportunity of doubling the parts of prophet and philan- 
 thropist. Cassandra-like predictions of desolation and ruin 
 are exceedingly efif'ective anodynes to the present incon- 
 veniences of higher prices. In Australia, however, as in 
 America, no one argument has ever been used to the exclusion 
 of others. The utmost that can be said is that in each 
 country the influence of the various arguments has varied at 
 different periods. 
 
 It will be necessary now to consider each by itself. 
 
 CHAPTER II. 
 
 THK INFANT-INDUSTRV ARGUMENT. 
 
 I. Thf: political argument which came first into use in 
 support of Protective tariffs is that which is generally known 
 as the " Infant Industry Argument," and which may be stated 
 in these terms : " Protection is desirable for a i^"^ years in 
 order to establish the industries which are naturally suited to 
 a young country." 
 
 It is apparent from its terms that this argument is not 
 intended to be a defence of Protection as a periuanent 
 Q
 
 242 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 policy, but that it is addressed to those who may be frightened 
 at the cost of a Protective tariff, or have other objections to 
 it, in order to induce them to submit to a temporary sacrifice 
 for the sake of a future permanent gain. The argument thus 
 becomes in part an admission that Protection is an evil, and 
 in part a prophecy that the evil will be temporary. 
 
 The admission is correct ; the prophecy is not. 
 
 Before examining this, the first political argument sub- 
 mitted for consideration, a warning must again be given of the 
 limited scope of our immediate investigation. We have to isolate 
 each political argument, and consider it apart from others, if 
 we would estimate its true value. In practice, of course, this 
 is seldom done. Men pass almost imperceptibly from one 
 argum.ent to another, and are apt to be angry if they are 
 pinned, even for a time, to the separate consideration of any. 
 If, then, any Protectionist who may read these pages should 
 be inclined at any point of the argument to charge the writer 
 with unfairness, he should reserve his final judgment until he 
 has perused the whole of the political discussion ; and even 
 then he should ask himself whether his own arguments and 
 phrases are, upon analysis, anything more than a compound of 
 two or more of those political fallacies whose nakedness he 
 is ready to admit when each is separately exposed. Further, 
 let it be remembered that a greater freedom of criticism is 
 permissible in dealing with political than with scientific 
 arguments, and that ad captandum statements may be fairly 
 answered in the same measure. 
 
 With these few words of warning and deprecation, let us 
 proceed to the consideration of the argument which owes its 
 name to the advocacy of Infant Industries. 
 
 The notion is, as has been said, that certain industries 
 cannot be established, under the circumstances ordinarily 
 existent in a young countr}', if they are exposed at the outset 
 to the competition of the older and stronger industries of 
 other lands. It is then answered that if the critical stages of
 
 The Political Argument. 243 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. ii., ? 2.] 
 
 struggle and difficulty can be successfully passed, the industries 
 in question will be able to sustain themselves without assist- 
 ance against all competitors. And, finally it being repre- 
 sented as a desirable thing that these industries should be 
 established the people \s\\q will have to pay for their estab- 
 lishment are exhorted to bear the burden for a short time, in 
 the assurance that they will reap benefits a hundredfold when 
 the period of pupilage is at an end. 
 
 2. It is obvious that this argument assumes that after a 
 reasonable time the Protected industries will be able to stand 
 alone. Accordingly, the first question which a voter ought to 
 ask when this argument is addressed to him is as to the length 
 of time for which the assistance of Protection will be needed; 
 because, as it must again be mentioned, this argument is 
 not addressed to those who advocate Protection as a permanent 
 policy, but to those who, regarding it as undesirable in itself, 
 are nevertheless prepared to submit to its inconvenience in 
 order to gain the advantages of new industries. It becomes, 
 therefore, a matter of chief importance to test the assumptions 
 of the argument by concrete instances, in order to form some 
 idea of the amount of sacrifice which is demanded to obtain 
 the promised benefits. 
 
 On this point let us first listen to Professor Sumner : 
 " I know of no case," says he, " where the hope that infant 
 industries can be nourished up to independence, and that they 
 tlien become productive, has been realised, although we have 
 been trying the experiment for nearly a century. I'he weakest 
 infants of to-day are those whom Alexander Hamilton set out 
 to jirotcct in 1791. As soon as the infants begin to get any 
 strength (if ever they do get any) the Protective system forces 
 them to bear the burden of other infants, and so on for ever, 
 The system superinduces hydrocephalus on the infimts, and 
 instead of ever growing to maturity, the longer they live the 
 bigger babies they are."' 
 I ) 2
 
 244 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 The " infant-industry " argument has never been disposed 
 of in fewer words, nor more completely ; and the treatment is 
 according to its deserts. Some persons, however, may require 
 to know the evidence by which the statement is supported. 
 This is given by the instances of the United States, A-'ictoria, 
 Germany, and every other country which has adopted the 
 Protective system. 
 
 Let us begin with the United States. 
 
 3. The history of the "infant-industry" argument in the 
 country of its birth is a singular record of human blindness 
 and popular forgetfulness. As might be expected, it first saw 
 light in the discussions which preceded the Tariff Act of 1789, 
 and had at once a complete success. Among the many and 
 various motives which induced the framers of the American 
 Constitution to submit to a federal tariff, not the least strong 
 was the belief that by taking this step they would raise up new 
 industries within their borders, and preserve them from the 
 crushing competition of Great Britain. Thus the Tariff Act 
 of 1789 contained a statement in its preamble that it was 
 passed for "the encouragement and protection of manu- 
 factures." Nor was the preamble the only portion of the Act 
 in which its framers displayed the honesty of their convictions. 
 A subsequent clause provided that the Act should expire in 
 1796, and that the duties, which were fixed at eight-and-a-half 
 per cent, ad valorem, should not be collected after that date 
 so confident were these clear-sighted men that at the expira- 
 tion of seven years Protection would no more be needed ! 
 The infant industries were to attain their majority in 
 seven years! This was tlie belief in 17 89. Never was the 
 vanity of Protectionist good-wishes more strikingly ex- 
 emplified I 
 
 The very year in which tlie Act was passed tlie "infants" 
 required a further assistance of two-and a half percent., and 
 two years later, in 1792, their Protection was raised to thirteen-
 
 The Political Argument. 245 
 
 Pt. IV. Ch. ii., \ 3.] 
 
 aiid-a-half per cent. The year 1796 arrived, but the coming 
 of age was indefinitely postponed ! 
 
 Between 1789 and 1S16 a period of twenty-six years 
 seventeen Acts were passed affecting duties, which generally 
 and steadily raised them.^ 
 
 Some Protectionists have said that these successive in- 
 creases in the rate of duty afford a proof of the beneficial 
 operation of Protection ; but those who assert this in Australia 
 need to be reminded that the present argument is not whether 
 Protection is permanently beneficial, but whether any period 
 can be ascertained at which Protection can be done without. 
 
 The second great fight upon the tariff" in the United States 
 occurred in 1816. After the experience of previous years, it 
 might have been thought that there would have been a certain 
 disinclination on the part of Protectionists to fix beforehand 
 any limits, either of time or amount, to the desire of manu- 
 facturers to get the most they could from a State that was 
 willing to give. Still, in those days of inexperience in Pro- 
 tective legislation, it was felt that the claim to special privileges 
 would have to be justified by some more plausible argument 
 than the bare assertion of an abstract right to plunder the 
 general body of citizens to the end of time. Consequently, 
 the old appeals to sympathy were renewed; and the old 
 I)romises were repeated, with even greater fervour, that the aid 
 would only be required for a few years. 
 
 Two great industries were particularly insistent in their 
 demands : viz., the cotton and the iron. Both of these had 
 established themselves under Free Trade with a fair measure 
 of success the iron industry, even in the old colonial days, 
 having been so profitable that its progress threatened the 
 superiority of the ICnglisli iron-masters, and led to the passing 
 
 ' It \\\\\ be obvious to all who nre acciiiainted with the subject that I am 
 much inckbted for this record of tlie ]5ractical application of the infant 
 arf;uMient in America to Professor .'^unmer's Lectures on the History of 
 Protection.
 
 246 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 of Acts of Parliament designed for its suppression. Changes, 
 however, in the mode of manufacture, and the disorganisation 
 consequent on the return of peace in 181 5, had thrown these 
 industries and several others into a condition of distress. 
 This state of things led to the tariff of 1816, and furnished 
 another example of the ease with which voters are misled by 
 promises which from their nature are incapable of fulfilment. 
 
 Our illustrations may be confined to the two leading 
 industries of cotton and iron. 
 
 The duty on cotton was fixed by the Act of 18 16 at 
 twenty-five per cent., but in order to conciliate purchasers it 
 was enacted that this Protective duty should only be levied for 
 three years.^ 
 
 The end of the three years came, but the duties remained. 
 
 So far from being removed, they were increased in 
 1824. They were again increased in 1828, again in 1832 ; 
 and from that date to this the manufocture of cotton in the 
 United States, where the raw material for the world is grown, 
 has been continuously protected by a tariff which is in some 
 lines almost prohibitory. Yet so little vigour has this "inf^mt" 
 been able to obtain in seventy-three years, that the imports of 
 cotton goods into the United States from Great Britain 
 amounted in the year 1888 to ^^5, 750,000 in value or nearly 
 twice as much as the total exports of cottons from America 
 to all the world ; in addition to which. Great Britain almost 
 monopolised the open markets of the world.- Surely, if 
 Protection was ever desirable, it would be in the case of the 
 cotton industry of the United States ? Yet if, after seventy- 
 three years of Protection, that industry is still an " infiint,'" and 
 so weakly, even for an infant of those tender years, that. 
 
 1 Taussig; "Tariff History of the United Status," p. 30 ((]. P. Putnam, 
 New York, 1888). 
 
 2 Taussig: " Tariff History of the United States," p. 40 : Tlie exiiorts 
 of cotton goods from Great Britain in 1888 were _^6o, 329, 000 ; the exports of 
 cotton goods from llie United States in 1888 were ^'2, 750, 000.
 
 The Political Argument. 247 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. ii., \ 3 ] 
 
 although it has its raw material on the spot, it cannot compete 
 with a little country like England, which has to convey the 
 raw material three thousand miles and send the manufactured 
 goods the same distance before they get into the market, it 
 is difficult to see what the industry can be which requires to 
 be nurtured into manhood by Protection. 
 
 But the loudest and most persistent beggar for Protective 
 duties has always been the iron industry. Despite the fact 
 that the manufacture of pig-iron was started in America in 
 the seventeenth century, and that it was a firmly established, 
 prosperous, and increasing industry before the first tariff, this 
 hoary infant of 250 years still demands and receives a Pro- 
 tective duty amounting to sixty per cent, ad valorem} The 
 increment in the tax has been gradual. Up to 1816 there 
 was no Protection on pig-iron, and the furnaces were numerous 
 and increasing;- but the revision of the tariff in that year 
 rendered the imposition of a duty inevitable. A duty on iron 
 is necessarily the keystone of a Protective system, partly 
 because of the close connection of that commodity with every 
 form of manufacturing process, and partly because its in- 
 dustrial importance easily attracts attention. For many years 
 the whole Protective system of the United States depended 
 upon the retention of the duties upon iron. 
 
 In the fervent words of Mr. E. J. Donnell, "the tariff 
 monopoly in iron is the tap-root of the upas-tree that has 
 poisoned both our industry and our politics. With free iron 
 the monopolies in otlier raw materials could not stand a day, 
 and the tariff on manufactures would soon cease to have a 
 single advocate, even among the manufacturers. In point 
 of fact, the tariffs on coal, copper, lead, wool, timber, and 
 many other articles whicli constitute the basis of various 
 branches of our industry, had their origin in what is called 
 
 1 Sic Taussig's " History of Protection." 
 
 - The iron products of the United States were valued at /i4,gco,ccq in 
 iSio.
 
 248 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 log-rolling they were supported by the iron monopoly as a 
 buttress to the iron tariff. . . . Iron is the key to the arch of 
 monopoly. Almost every branch of American industry can be 
 liberated by emancipating the one article, iron." 1 
 
 The iron industry in 18 16 was quite as moderate in its 
 demands as the cotton. Duties were fixed at twenty-five per 
 cent. ; but in 18 19 these were to be reduced to twenty per 
 cent. 
 
 When 1 81 9 arrived, the reduction was postponed, and 
 it is almost unnecessary to add that since that date the 
 duties have been increased and not diminished, until they 
 stand at the present, in some lines, as high as 100 and 250 
 per cent , - to the no small advantage of Mr. Carnegie and 
 other enthusiastic champions of Protective legislation. 
 
 In 1832 the tariff was again revised in the Protectionist 
 interest. At this date Protection had existed, in a greater or 
 less degree, for forty-three years, and still the "infant" argu- 
 ment was not abandoned ! It was only modified. That it 
 should have been used in any form and still more, that it 
 should be used in any country in the year 1890 is a striking 
 illustration of the great difficulty in the way of tariff reform 
 which arises from the indifference of the popular memory to 
 the details of so unattractive a subject. When, added to 
 this indifference, we have on the part of some a willingness 
 to be deceived by phrases, and on the part of others an 
 intense wish to gain advantage by deceiving the progress 
 of Free Trade in the United States and other countries, 
 slight as it is, becomes a matter of considerable surprise. 
 
 In 1832 the weakness of the '"infont" argument was 
 beginning to be felt, and Henry Clay, the Protectionist 
 champion, abandoned the seven years' minority, and named 
 twenty-five years as the period during which assistance might 
 
 1 Since the passing of the McKinley Tariff, wool has taken the place of iron 
 in this respect. (5^^ article by Prof. Taussig in Vol, I. of the Economic Journal.) 
 - e.g., nails.
 
 The Political Argument. 249 
 
 Pt. IV^, Ch. ii., \ 3.] 
 
 be legitimately demanded by a " Protected " industry. The 
 admirers of Henry Clay will not consider it an injustice to his 
 intellectual powers to believe that he was sincere in making 
 this prognostication. On the contrary, Mr. Horace Greeley, 
 the modern defender of Clay's principles, expressly declares 
 that Clay and all the earlier champions of Protection includ- 
 ing Hamilton, Carey, Niles, and the earlier presidents 
 "champion not the maintenance, but the creation of home 
 manufactures."^ 
 
 Possibly the modern champions of Protection would insist 
 on placing themselves in the same category. After all, there is 
 but a difference of degree between " the creation " of an 
 industry and its " maintenance " ; and who is more competent 
 to decide whether an industry has passed from the growing to 
 the mature stage than the manufacturer, who is to be paid for 
 attending to the growth ? This, at all events, seems to be the 
 view of the most modern teaching on this Protectionist argument. 
 
 In the last edition of his "Political Economy" (p. 233), 
 Professor Thompson, of the Pennsylvania University, tells us 
 that " it will ordinarily take the lifetime of two generations to 
 acclimatise thoroughly a new manufacture, and to bring the 
 native production up to the native demand." 
 
 From seven years to two generations is a long step ! Yet, 
 if this is the latest exposition of the gospel, Free Traders only 
 ask that it may be spread abroad. For, as Mr. George 
 suggests, it would hardly be a popular argument to address to 
 the present generation: that it should tax itself and its successor 
 for the benefit of a third. To such a demand we might well 
 ask, " What has posterity ever done for us ? " ~ 
 
 'Horace Greeley: " PoliUcal Sermons," p. 34; cited by Mr. George: 
 " rroteclion or Free Trade?" p. 103. 
 
 - TIk' latest writer on Protection, Professor Patten (1890), boldly aban- 
 dons the Infant argnnient, and takes his stand on the position that 
 Protection onyht to be a permanent policy. Free Traders, therefore, may 
 surely use language of derii>ion about this once famous argument without 
 incurring odium.
 
 250 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 4. Were it not for the numerous instances which history 
 offers of the truth of Dean Mihnan's theory of the immortahty 
 of humbug, it might have been thought impossible, after the 
 experience of the United States, that this tattered and fact- 
 riddled theory about infant industries should ever be dressed 
 up again for use in other countries. But it appeared in 
 Victoria in 1865 in all its old effrontery; and is still the 
 favourite catchword of Protectionist audiences in New South 
 Wales. Yet the history of Victoria has been in no whit 
 different from that of the United States as regards the falsifi- 
 cation of all prophecies that a time would come when a 
 Protected industry could stand alone. 
 
 Although the framers of the first Victorian tariff were wise 
 enough to fix no date for its repeal, they won for it no small 
 measure of support by the assurance that it would not be 
 needed for any length of time. Then, as in America in 1789 
 men believed or affected to believe that Protection might 
 be adopted as a temporary expedient, in order to give a start 
 to a few suitable industries. Then, as now, in New South 
 Wales, most Protectionists professed themselves to be " mo- 
 derate," or " discriminating." They would neither have high 
 duties nor maintain any duties permanently. 
 
 The result of these expectations ought to be a significant 
 warning to simple-minded people in other countries who allow 
 themselves to be persuaded into similar beliefs. The " tem- 
 porary " duties are in force to-day. The " moderate " duties 
 have been three times revised, and have been raised on each 
 revision. Protection has now been the law of Victoria for 
 twenty-three years, and during all that time the reductions of 
 duties have been almost imperceptible, while the increases of 
 duties have been steady and enormous. It is not too much to 
 say, if we accept the sincerity of the public professions of the 
 " moderate " men, that the tariff of 1865 would never have 
 become law if the same rate of duties had been asked for then 
 which was readily conceded in 1S89. Take the hat-making
 
 The Political Argument. 251 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. ii., 5 4.] 
 
 trade for an illustration. How many electors in 1865 would 
 have voted for a duty of 5s. apiece on hats ? And how many 
 candidates would have ventured to support it? Yet in 1889 
 the hat-makers obtained a duty of 60s. a dozen on hats, and 
 are grumbling still because they did not obtain one of 72s. 
 What the tax may be on hats in 1900 it is dangerous to con- 
 jecture. Similar instances of the unappeasable appetite of the 
 principal Victorian " infants " may be collected from every side. 
 
 The greatest cormorant is the woollen trade, which, in spite 
 of its contiguity to the source of its raw material, is in chronic 
 difficulties. In 1868 the duty on clothing imported into 
 Victoria was 10 per cent. After three years the duty was 
 raised to 12J per cent In 1872 it was raised again to 20 per 
 cent., at which figure it remained for eight years. But 20 per 
 cent, was not enough for this struggling industry, nor twelve 
 years sufficient to draw it from a state of pupilage. In 1880 
 the duty was again raised to 25 percent. In 1886 it was raised 
 again to 30 percent. ; and in 1889, after twenty years of a Pro- 
 tective tariff, the manufacturers of clothing, asking for a duty of 
 40 per cent., got one of 35 per cent. The duty on furniture, 
 again, has increased from 10 per cent, in 1866 to 25 per cent, 
 in 1888 ; and the duty on woollens has increased from 7.^ per 
 cent, in 187 1 to 35 pef cent, in 1889. 
 
 The subjoined table shows the changes in the Victorian 
 tariff from 1S66 to 1889 ui)on a few of the commoner necessi- 
 ties of life : 
 
 Article. 
 
 1806. 
 
 1 863. 
 
 P.O. 
 10 
 10 
 
 10 
 
 1872. 1S80. 
 p. C. p. c. 
 
 20 25 
 
 20 25 
 20 25 
 
 1SS6. 
 p. c. 
 
 25 
 25 
 
 1S88. 
 
 .S89. 
 
 Apparel and Slops 
 ]''urnitiire 
 Hats and Caps and 
 ISonnets . 
 
 4s. per cub. foot 
 10 per cent. 
 
 4s. per cul). foot 
 
 p.c. 
 
 35 
 
 25 
 
 25 
 
 p.c. 
 25 
 
 35 
 var. 
 
 Is there any reason to believe that we in New South 
 Wales would have a different experience from that of America
 
 252 Industrial Freedom. ' 
 
 and Victoria ? Would not any Protective duties, however low 
 they might be at first, inevitably increase in this country, as 
 they have done in others? Those who really are " moderate " 
 Protectionists should learn a lesson from experience, and vote 
 for P>ee Trade. 
 
 5. The illustrations which have already been offered from 
 the history of Protection in countries so different in their 
 conditions as the United States and Victoria, indicate 
 sufficiently the nature of the answer to the argument in 
 favour of Protection "that it may be temporarily useful in 
 assisting infant industries." The fatal objection to this 
 argument is its inapplicability to political facts. It takes no 
 account of the imperfection of human nature. It assumes that 
 every Government is incorruptible, and every manufacturer 
 disinterested. Whereas the truth is. that Governments are 
 squeezable, and manufacturers are very active in their own 
 interests. 
 
 There is one great, plain, i)ractical fact in respect to 
 Protection to "Infant industries " which is itself a sufficient 
 answer to all the arguments which may be advanced in its 
 favour. "Temporary" Protection, or "moderate" Protection, 
 or " diminishing " Protection never hasexisted, and never can 
 exist while human nature continues as it is. There cannot be 
 one single instance referred to in the history of any State, 
 nation, or people in which the Protected classes have volun- 
 tarily abandoned the assistance of Protection when the purpose 
 for which it was imposed has been achieved. This is owing 
 partly to the unchangeable characteristics of human nature, 
 partly to the economic consequences of all Protective legis- 
 lation. 
 
 No matter with what honesty of purpose Protection may 
 be first established, its continuance will always be secured by 
 the selfishness of vested interests. The men who deri\e 
 advantage from the right to tax their fellow-cilizens, being few
 
 The Political Argument. 253 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. ii.. \ 5.] 
 
 and powerful, will combine to support their privilege ; while 
 the majority of the people, being affected by the tariff in 
 different ways, and often unable to perceive its operation, 
 have no motive of equal strength to stir them into opposition. 1 
 
 The vested interests have also the further advantage, in any 
 contest, of being able to appeal to public sympathy with a fc rce 
 which is directly proportionate to their own weakness. When 
 once Protection has been established, its continuance can be 
 secured, not only by the illegitimate use of organised wealth 
 and power, but by drawing harrowing pictures of the loss and 
 hardship to innocent persons which would be inflicted by its 
 abolition. This consideration is naturally strongest in a small 
 community, \^here members of all classes are more or less 
 acquainted with each other. Kind-hearted and impetuous 
 persons, who would never have voted for the establishment of 
 Protection, are easily moved to support its continuance by 
 pictures of the miseries which would follow an " extermination " 
 of the Protected trader the ruined capitalists with useless 
 plants, the thousands of labourers " robbed of their livelihood." 
 Unfortunately, these good people do not stop to inquire 
 whether the return to Free Trade will really cause the industry 
 to stop, or whether the statement is not merely the unproved 
 assertion of an interested party. 
 
 It has been asserted by the Hon. David A. Wells and 
 the statement has never been disproved that from eighty to 
 ninety per cent, of American manufacturers are able, from their 
 
 ' The notorious corruptness of the Presidential election of 1888 illustrates 
 the text. The investigations conducted by the New York H 'wA/ in January 
 and I'cbruary, 1889, revealed a complete organisation on the part of the Pro- 
 tected manufacturers for purposes of corruption. As one of the Republican 
 organisers stated, "the fat was to be fried" from tlie manufacturers. The 
 Democratic parly were, no doubt, also corrupt ; but not l)eingaljle to stimulate 
 their supporters by ll;e same inducement, they could not collect the s.ime 
 amount of money, and so lost the election. The purchase of New York State 
 by tlie corrupt agreement of the Democratic leaders for the sale of the Irish 
 \ote for the Prcoidency in consideration that a Republican vote sliould he caft 
 for the Democrats in the State election, gave Presiient Harr'son the victory
 
 254 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 natural advantages, to under-sell foreign competitors without 
 assistance from the tariff; and that only ten to twenty per cent, 
 of them are in any degree subject to foreign competition.'^ 
 
 Nevertheless, the question must arise in any country where 
 Protection has been long established, whether a return to Free 
 Trade would not destroy some of the existing industries ; and 
 Free Traders must admit that such might be the case. Indus- 
 tries which are unsuited to the country, either owing to the 
 conditions of its civilisation such as handicrafts in a country 
 of highly developed mechanical appliances or to the natural 
 disadvantages of its climate such as tea-growing in the United 
 States must suffer by a change from Protection to Free 
 Trade if they cannot soon adapt themselves to the new 
 conditions. 
 
 A Free Trader has two replies to those who urge the 
 continuance of Protection upon this account : 
 
 First, he says, " Industries such as these are not worth 
 preserving our country cannot afford to keep them. They 
 belong to a lower grade of civilisation, in which our citizens 
 ought not to be compelled to live." 
 
 Secondly, he would say, " Even under Protection indus- 
 tries such as these are never prosperous. From the conditions of 
 their existence they can never export their articles of manu- 
 facture, and are therefore confined to a small and non-expansive 
 market. Of such industries distress and suffering is a chronic 
 complaint, and the continuance of the Protective system will, 
 in most cases, only make the misery of those who work in them 
 greater and more extended. The blame for this belongs 
 properly to the policy which made this ruin inevitable, and not 
 to that which sought to limit its effect?. If a choice has to be 
 made between the total abolition of Protective duties, after a 
 reasonable notice, and their gradual reduction, the truer 
 kindness, probably in every case, is to prefer the speedier 
 
 1 6'('(,' " Practical Economics " ([1. 142). Putnam, New York, 1888.
 
 The Political Argument. 255 
 
 Pt. IV,, Ch. ii., ? 7.] 
 
 process. Trade suffers less from a sharp shock than from a 
 protracted agony." 
 
 6. There is another reason for the want of finahty in all 
 Protective legislation, which has already been referred to 
 incidentally in the discussion of the economic argument : 
 namely, the close and often unforeseen dependence of one trade 
 upon another. 
 
 It is obvious that Protective duties upon iron, steel, cotton, 
 or any other raw material, necessitate compensating duties 
 upon the finished products of any of these articles ; but it is 
 not always easy to trace either the amount of compensation 
 which is requisite or the products which require it. The 
 processes of manufacture are so complicated, and the inter- 
 dependence of several trades upon each other is so intricate 
 and variable, that even experts find it difficult to say beforehand 
 on what lines, or to what amounts, compensating duties ought 
 to be imposed. The compensating duties placed on woollen 
 goods in the United States offer an illustration of this difficulty. 
 These are so numerous, and so delicately graduated, that no 
 person who is not in the trade can possibly understand either 
 their amount or their incidence, and even manufacturers 
 themselves have been disputing about them since 1869. The 
 whole matter is fully discussed by Professor Taussig in his 
 " Tariff History of the United States," in a chapter which will 
 well repay perusal. 
 
 ^ 7. But not only is there a legitimate connection between 
 duties upon raw materials and duties upon finished products, 
 but there is an illegitimate connection between all Protecti\-e 
 duties. It is not in human nature to stand by while another 
 person's industry receives Protection without demanding the 
 same privilege for oneself Such a demand is certain to receive 
 considerable attention. In tlie first place, it appeals to the 
 universal sense of fair play by asking that every class of
 
 256 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 industry should be treated alike ; and secondly, it gives new 
 allies to those who are already Protected. Thus is initiated 
 the system known as "log-rolling," by which one set of 
 manufacturers will help another set to get what duties 
 they want on condition of receiving similar assistance for 
 themselves. 
 
 Nor is this practice, although most destructive of political 
 purity, altogether without justification. It is not the men 
 who are to blame, but the system. For, as Professor Sumner 
 has pointed out, " if one industry should be set out in free 
 competition, while the rest were Protected, it would be found 
 . , . . that machinery, raw materials, and labour supplies 
 would be so dear that the exposed industry would have no fair 
 chance in competition with foreigners. Hence one long- 
 Protected industry, if it became independent by natural causes, 
 could not be left free unless the whole system were abandoned. 
 But then the cry goes up from those nurslings of recent begin- 
 ning that they are not yet ready. If you defer the introduction 
 of freedom for ten years longer on their account, a new 
 company of infants is meantime brought into being, and the 
 plea for further delay comes from them. Thus you go on for 
 ever, and the theory is reduced to an absurdity.'' (" History of 
 Protection," p. 44.) 
 
 A Senator of the United States the Hon. Samuel S. Cox 
 has described the practices which result from the interde- 
 pendence of Protected trades as " mutual brigandage and re- 
 ciprocity of robbery." After making all due allowances 
 for the warmth of the expression, we may still derive some 
 profit from the graphic illustrations by which the senator sup- 
 ports it : 
 
 "Kentucky," he says, "wants clieap copper stills for her 
 whisky. She gets even with the Miclii,c;an roljber by demanding a 
 tariff on hemp. . . . ?ilaine .steals on lumber to make up (or 
 the Massachusetts roguery on fabrics. Massachusetts hauls for cheap 
 coal ; Pennsylvania says no ; and so Massachusetts goes out with a 
 'Home Market Club' [referring to a political association of that
 
 The Political Argument. 257 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. ii., 5 8.] 
 
 name], and knocks down the West and South to rifle them of half 
 tlieir gains on raw cotton. Tennessee, Virginia, and North 
 Carolina, being fleeced all round in clothing, sugar, and what not, 
 go for goobers at a cent a pound. California demands a large 
 reprisal for her lumber, because she is fleeced on salt by IS'cw 
 York. . . , Pennsylvania, the Robert Macaire of the lot, steals 
 boldly on all articles, from a plate-glass to a locomotive ; and to 
 make up for the general loss, the North-West masks herself behind 
 her forests and demands timber reprisals ; and so on. Nothuig is 
 sacred. . . . Oh, the beauty of reciprocal rascality ! " 
 
 The same conflict of interests, pacified, if possible, by the 
 same methods, is seen wherever Protection exists. The result 
 is an impossible effort to satisfy a thousand Pauls by robbing 
 a thousand Peters. In attempting this, Protection is per- 
 petuated. 
 
 8. The conclusion is inevitable. Whether the infant-in- 
 dustry argument be tested by experience or by a pi'iori 
 reasoning, its emptiness and the unreality of its assumptions 
 are equally apparent. It is difficult, indeed, to understand how 
 any man who is acquainted with the history of tariff legislation, 
 or accustomed to reflect upon the springs of political action, 
 can with any honesty of conviction continue to maintain or lend 
 attention to the vain assertion that " Protection can be tried 
 for a short time, and laid aside after trial if it either performs 
 its object or proves unsatisfactory." 
 
 If Protection be once established, it will spread itself with 
 a silent and irresistible growth, which nothing short of a con- 
 vulsion of the State will be able to uproot. Each Protective 
 duty is the seed-nut of a hundred others, some of which propa- 
 gate themselves, while others are planted by industrious sowers. 
 Nor is resistance to this pernicious growth of much avail. Self- 
 interest, especially when it masquerades as patriotism and 
 phihmthropy, is ahnost irresistible in a conflict with disorganised 
 justice. The nation, therefore, which adopts Protection stands 
 on an inclined plane. Once let it be started on the downward 
 patli, it will slide inevitably to the bottom ; but where that 
 
 R
 
 258 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 bottom is no one yet knows, because no one has yet fathomed 
 the depths of human creduUty and greed. 
 
 It is true that the foregoing considerations can have no 
 weiglit with those who regard Protection as a scientific 
 doctrine. To such persons the permanency of Protection is 
 a thing to be desired for its own sake. 
 
 But it is the characteristic of a poHtical argument, such as 
 that at present under review, that it appeals differently to 
 different people. Thus, the "infant-industry" argument is 
 not directed to the true believers, but only to the doubters. 
 That it has effect on these is plain to any one who has lived in 
 the atmosphere of tariff controversies. Two-thirds of the Pro- 
 tectionist members of the present New South Wales Assembly 
 have described themselves in their addresses as " moderate 
 Protectionists," or have supported their views by making use of 
 the " infant " argument. To such men and to their hearers the 
 considerations which have been urged above ought to appeal 
 with force. 
 
 The argument has also a certain weight with scientific 
 writers on the tariff question a fact which probably accounts 
 for its political vitality. John Stuart Mill has notably given it 
 an undue prominence in his consideration of the case of 
 Protection in a young community. But it will be found upon 
 examination that the cases which Mill imagines, although they 
 are theoretically conceivable, are not such as have ever 
 occurred in New South Wales ; and that in any country his 
 argument assumes the existence of that which has never yet 
 been discovered : viz., a Government honest enough and 
 powerful enough to resist all claims to illegitimate Protection, 
 and to remove Protective duties directly they have done their 
 work.i 
 
 ' Sec .Appendix II. for a full examination of J. S. Mill's view of the 
 possible economic justification of Protection in a young country.
 
 The Political Argument. 259 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. iii., \ I.] 
 
 CHAPTER III. 
 
 THE " DIVERSIFICATION OF INDUSTRY " ARGUMENT. 
 
 I. It is probable that Protection gains the majority of its 
 supporters by appealing, in a more or less direct manner, 
 to the sentiment of national sufficiency. There is a general 
 desire ^which is especially strong in a young community 
 whose place among nations has not yet been recognised 
 to become independent of other countries by supplying all 
 its wants through the labour of its own citizens. 
 
 The industrial characteristics of a new country are very 
 visibly determined by its natural features. The attraction to 
 settlers is, in almost every instance, the possession in an 
 exceptional degree of some great natural advantage. The 
 consequence is that in the early days of the community the 
 population is fully employed in the production of raw material ; 
 and the high profit which this occupation returns enables 
 it to satisfy its wants very easily by trading with foreign 
 countries. 
 
 After a time, however, the extractive industries, as they are 
 called, become less profitable. The virgin soil gives out, the 
 surface ores are exhausted, the nearer forests are thinned, and 
 the special natural advantages which were possessed by the 
 young country grow gradually less. In the meantime, the 
 influx of population which is generally mucli behind the 
 demand for labour keeps up at the old rate, or probably in- 
 creases. Two currents of opinion are thus set in motion, the 
 one coming from the more far-seeing of the former inhabitants, 
 who observe the increasing difficulty in carrying on the old 
 pursuits ; the other from newly arrived immigrants, whose 
 expectations of an El Dorado are not realised. Each class 
 wants to find new avenues of employment. The older settlers 
 need openings for their children. The new-comers want 
 work at the trades to which they have been accustomed. 
 
 R 2
 
 26o Industrial Freewm. 
 
 Under such circumstances, it only needs the occurrence of a 
 commercial crisis, or a disorganisation of industry from one of 
 the causes to which young communities are especially exposed 
 namely, drought, over-speculation, or excessive borrowing 
 and the Protectionist manufacturer has ready to his 
 hand the very best of opportunities. He can point out 
 to the discontented the indisputable fact that a change 
 is coming, and that industry cannot continue in the old paths. 
 He will say that " it is the duty of the State to preserve the 
 industrial organisation, and to see that the capital which has 
 already been spent in the country be not wasted, or the 
 labourers forced to go away to other lands." He will, there- 
 fore, urge the necessity of opening up new channels for 
 employment and preventing the nation sinking into a state 
 of stagnation. He will maintain that, although it may be 
 cheaper to buy manufactures from abroad in exchange for raw 
 produce, yet the gain thus secured would be dearly bought by 
 the limits which this practice would impose upon the growth 
 of population, and by the injurious influence upon national 
 character which arises from a lack of variety in the occupations 
 of a people. He would say that the " extractive industries" 
 do not call forth the highest mental qualities ; and that in 
 any case they can only be followed by men who are suited to 
 outdoor work. Accordingly, to confine the labour of the 
 country to these pursuits would deprive many men who might 
 excel in handicrafts of the opportunity to iind employment, 
 and thus to cause a waste of industrial power. Nor would he 
 omit to mention that the establishment of manufactories 
 means the growth of towns, and that the social development 
 and progress of a country cannot be so rapid if the greater part of 
 the population be employed in field work and live in scattered 
 settlements. " Therefore," he would say, " seek a stimulus for 
 new industries in a Protective tariff, in the hope that the home 
 demand for manufactured goods may force home labour and 
 capital into a variety of new channels, until every natural
 
 The Political Argument. 261 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. ili., \ 2.] 
 
 resource is developed to its full extent and no native talent is 
 without a scope. The piteous cry of the farmer and miner, 
 * What shall we do with our boys ? ' will no longer be heard in 
 the land ; ^ but every lad, when he comes of age, will find 
 a calling suited to his powers, and every immigrant, on landing 
 at the wharf, can take a place in his own trade. By this 
 means, though the individual may suffer temporary loss, the 
 latent capacities of the nation as a whole will be developed, 
 and its attractiveness to immigrants will be increased." 
 
 This is undoubtedly a clever picture, which lacks no feature 
 of attraction for the public eye. Nor is the picture an in- 
 correct representation of what might be. It is part of the 
 truth, but not the whole. 
 
 2. It is evident that the reasoning which supports Pro- 
 tection because it gives a variety of industries, rests upon three 
 important but unexpressed, assumptions : viz. i. That there 
 is, in fact, no sufficient diversity of industry in any young 
 community which adheres to Free Trade. 2. That, without 
 Protection, no sufficient diversity of industry can either be 
 secured or maintained. 3. That, when a sufficient diversity of 
 industry is secured and maintained by means of Protection, 
 the country, as a whole, will be better off. 
 
 The burden of proving these assumptions to be sound 
 clearly rests on the Protectionist, because it is he, and not the 
 Free Trader, who proposes to interfere with the natural course 
 of trade. Consequently, until he discharges this burden the 
 diversity of industry argument counts for nothing. A pleasant 
 escape, indeed, from a long discussion ! 
 
 It is to be feared, howtver, that logic has Aery little 
 
 ' This ridiculous question is really p/Ut to Protectionist audience?, nnl 
 sadly passed by, as admitting of no satisf.ictory answer while Free Trade con- 
 tinurs. An irreverent believer in freedom once suggested, \slien llie (|iie>tion 
 was being put in n)oie than usually lugubrious tones, " Marry llicin to our 
 girls"; but the advice, though it has become historic, has never been well 
 received by the prophets of evil.
 
 262 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 influence in a tariff controversy. Certain it is that the diversity 
 argument loses none of its force by having its assumptions 
 taken for granted instead of proved. What Protectionist 
 orator or writer would stop, in his glowing catalogue of benefits 
 to be derived from a variety of industries, for any dull inquiry 
 whether this much-desired variety does not already exist to a 
 sufficient degree; or whether, if some industries are still wanting, 
 Free Trade is an absolute bar to their establishment ? Yet 
 these are, essentially, inquiries into facts, which cannot be 
 ignored by any man who wants to form a reasonable judgment 
 upon the value of this famous argument. 
 
 If, however, Free Traders ignore the diversity argument 
 until its assumptions are proved, they will never convince 
 voters. Let them, therefore, begin the attack. But first let 
 them survey the position. 
 
 3. The aim desired is a variety of occupations. Are Free 
 Traders to admit this aim to be desirable or not ? Professor 
 Sumner answers sturdily in the negative. " It is not," he says, 
 " an object to diversify industry, but to multiply and diversify 
 our satisfactions, comforts, enjoyments. If we can do this by 
 unifying our industry in greater measure than by diversifying 
 it, then we should do, and we will do, the former." (" Protec- 
 tionism," p. 116.) It would be difficult to find a more striking 
 instance of the divergent scopes of an economic and a political 
 argument. To Professor Sumner, "satisfactions, comforts, and 
 enjoyments" arc words of "economic" import. They are 
 products or sensations which are obtainable in exchange for 
 wealth. To the politician, and especially to the Protectionist, 
 they convey a different meaning. The " satisfactions " are 
 satisfactions of sentiment as well as of wants and no serious 
 politician will ignore the demands of national sentiment 
 while the "comforts and enjoyments" are not only of material 
 things, but of everything which occupies pleasantly the life of a 
 citizen, or relieves him from alarm. \'ague, illusory, and
 
 The Political Argument. 263 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. iii.,?4] 
 
 unobtainable these " satisfactions, comforts, and enjoyments " 
 may be in most instances, but they are sufificiently definite to 
 be the subject of argument, when they are of the kind which are 
 promised to the labouring classes through the establishment of a 
 variety of industries. The ambition to rise, the love of change, 
 the very difference of physical and mental qualities all conduce 
 to make men who have to live by wages look forward with 
 pleasure to the possibility of obtaining different kinds of work 
 for themselves and their children ; while the politician may 
 share with peasant and artisan the fear lest the temper of the 
 nation may be lowered and its talents wasted by a dull, 
 sluggish uniformity of occupation. 
 
 Accordingly, if we are to answer their political argument 
 with a political answer, we must, at the outset, frankly recognise 
 that the aim of the Protectionists in this instance is good ; and 
 that a variety of industrial occupation is, for many reasons, 
 advantageous to a community. 
 
 We may even, indeed, go further on the path of conciUation, 
 and also admit that, in some stages of national development. 
 Protection is very likely to create industries which either would 
 not otherwise come into existence, or would be delayed 
 in their birth for many years. 
 
 We start, therefore, by admitting that Protection in this 
 instance aims at effecting a good result, and partly succeeds in 
 its aim. But we are still far from a final agreement. Protection 
 may be one means to secure diversity of occupation, but Free 
 Trade may be a better. 
 
 >; 4. As in every political question, the point to be con- 
 sidered in judging of the expediency of adopting Protection, 
 in order to secure an early diversification of industry, is 
 " ^^'hcther, on a balance, the advantages exceed the dis- 
 advantages." 
 
 In order to ascertain tiiis, tlie present condition of the 
 country must first be examined. Thus, if the argument is
 
 264 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 being used to justify the abandonment of Free Trade, the 
 question will be, " Whether, as a fact, the industrial occupations 
 of the country have not already been so much diversified, 
 under a policy of freedom, as to give a reasonable ground 
 for the belief that no legislative interference is required to 
 prevent stagnation ?" If, again, it is used in a Protected 
 country to resist a return to freedom, the question at ihe 
 outset is equally one of fact; namely, "Whether Free Trade, 
 although it might alter the kinds of industries, would really 
 lessen their number ? " 
 
 These facts having been ascertained to form the basis of dis- 
 cussion, the question then assumes a wider scope, and invokes 
 a general consideration of the working of Protective policies. 
 Every circumstance which attends the operation of Protection 
 must be taken into account its effect upon existing industries, 
 as well as upon those which it seeks to create ; its effect upon 
 the relation between capital and labour generally in the 
 community ; its effect upon the industrial temper of the 
 people, their energy, honesty, and self-reliance ; its effect 
 upon the purity of political life ; its social effect in creating 
 "vested interests" and privileged classes- in a word, its 
 bearing generally on all the intricate relations of the industrial, 
 political, and social life of the community in which the experi- 
 ment is to be justified. 
 
 By thus considering, first, the actual industrial position 
 of the country, and next, the actual or probable effect of 
 Protection in all its bearings, some estimate can be formed of 
 its wisdom or unwisdom as a means for encouraging a variety 
 of industr}'. 
 
 It is the fate of every political measure to produce un- 
 expected consecjuences of evil. Protection, as a political 
 measure, cannot hope for better fortune; so that we may fairly 
 assume that the results of a Protectix'C measure in any country 
 will not be wholly good. Therefore, when we are asked to 
 support Protection because it causes a diversity of industry,
 
 The Political Argument. 265 
 
 Pt. IV , Ch. iii., \ 5.] 
 
 we cannot fix our attention on the one good result of the 
 poUcy and ignore all those that are bad. Admitting a diversity 
 of industries to be a good thing, and admitting it to be 
 attainable by Protection, still we must inquire, " Whether there 
 is not any other means which would give the same, or almost 
 the same, good, with less of the evil ? " 
 
 Applying these considerations to the particular argument 
 now under discussion, it follows that, although it may be true, 
 under ordinary circumstances, that Protection will cause an 
 earlier diversification of industry than would be established 
 naturally, that is not conclusive in its favour, even if it be 
 further admitted that an early diversification is desirable. The 
 Protectionist will also have to show that industry will not 
 diversify under Free Trade if not, perhaps, quite as rapidly, 
 yet with sufficient speed, and with more advantage on the 
 whole to the welfare of a young community. 
 
 The discussion of the validity of the diversity argument 
 will then take the following order : 
 
 First Whether, in fact, any Free Trade country has 
 suffered, or is likely to suffer^ from an insufficient variety of 
 industrial occupation ? 
 
 Secondly Whether, if a country is so suffering. Protection 
 is the only remedy ? 
 
 And thirdly If Protection be the only remedy, whether, 
 in any case. Protection is not too high a price to pay for the 
 advantage of diversity ? 
 
 A discussion of these questions will' occupy the remainder 
 of this chapter, 
 
 i; 5. 'J'hc first duty of a tarift" disputant is to verify his focts. 
 Vet, probably, in no other controversy professing to deal with 
 facts is tliere such an outspoken contempt for accin-atc inquiry, 
 or such a readiness to build large conclusions upon so slight 
 a basis of verified evidence. No doubt each })arty to the
 
 266 Industrial Freedom, 
 
 controversy brings this charge against the other, but we may 
 prove it against Protectionists in at least one instance. 
 
 The " diversity of industry " argument is intended to be used 
 as a general defence of a Protective system. The assumptions 
 upon which it rests are partly of existing facts and partly of 
 theories. The assumption, for instance, that a country either 
 is suffering, or is in imminent danger of suffering, from a lack 
 of variety in its industrial occupations, is purely an assumption of 
 present fact \ while the assumption that Free Trade destroys or 
 prevents diversity of occupation is a theory. No doubt, if the 
 theory is true, it will be an inference from facts ; but it does 
 not give rise to an inquiry into evidence of the same direct 
 and simple character as the assumption which was first 
 mentioned. 
 
 Now, it is plain that the use of the diversity argument in a 
 Free Trade country implies a belief, either proved or taken for 
 granted, that the variety of industries existing at the time is 
 insufficient to the wants of the community. It must also be 
 admitted that, if it can be shown that there never has in fact 
 been any country in which a sufficient variety of industries did 
 not grow up naturally without Protection, such a proof should 
 materially lessen the alarm of those who believe that a return 
 from Protection to Free Trade will cause employment to be 
 narrowed to a few extractive industries. 
 
 Let us, then, keep the argument to one point, and setting 
 aside for a moment the question whether it is conceivable that 
 Free Trade could preyent the growth of industrial variety let 
 us examine the actual condition of the United States of 
 America, Victoria, and New South "Wales at the time when the 
 argument was used in each of those three countries to justify 
 the abandonment of industrial freedom. Is it, or is it not, 
 the case that either of tliose countries ever suffered, or was 
 likely to suffer, because the efforts of its population were 
 limited to a few occupations? This is a simple matter of 
 evidence.
 
 The Political Argument. 267 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. iii., 5 6.] 
 
 6. Look, first, at the industrial condition of the United 
 States in 1789. During the existence of the British dependency 
 all American industries were exposed to the crippling influence 
 of the colonial system, under which the whole trade of the 
 colonies was at the mercy of the English Parliament. This 
 terrible power was used by the English Protectionists entirely 
 in the interests of English manufacturers. Thus, not only 
 were Americans forbidden to trade with any country except 
 England, but the moment an American manufacturing in- 
 dustry showed signs of growth, it was suppressed by Act of 
 Parliament. 
 
 Protectionists often ask what country ever reached the 
 manufacturing stage without Protection ? Seeing that the 
 principles of Free Trade may be said to have been unknown 
 until the close of last century, it would be just as reasonable to 
 inquire for the name of any country which attained to manu- 
 facturing eminence without a system of communication by 
 means of post-horses and hand-signals. Free Trade, like 
 telegraphs and railways, is a modern device, and is directed 
 to the object of all modern human invention : viz., the over- 
 coming of natural obstacles. Still, if this silly question is to 
 be pressed, an answer is easily found the United States of 
 America. 
 
 In the early colonial days, in spite of hostile legislation, 
 many manufacturing industries had so firmly established them- 
 selves that their products were able to undersell the English 
 manufacturer in his own market. The consequence in every 
 instance was the same : viz., that the English manufacturer 
 obtained an Act of Parliament prohibiting the export of the 
 American article. A list of the Acts referred to can be found 
 in Mr. Bancroft's " History of the United States," or in Mr. 
 Lecky's " History of England." 
 
 Yet, so irresistible is the tendency in a growing community 
 to diversify its occupations, that, in spite of this crushing 
 system of legislative interference, Hamilton, the father of
 
 268 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 American Protection, was able to enumerate, in his report on 
 manufactures, no less than seventeen industries as being "firmly 
 established" in the year 1792. The list of these speaks for 
 itself. It is sufificient to note that the iron industry was one of 
 those which had so become "established" without Protection. 
 
 , 7. The recent history of the United States furnishes 
 another instance of the spontaneous development of manu- 
 factures in a growing community, in despite of the competition 
 of older and powerful rivals. The Western States of America, 
 in their early days, stood towards the Eastern in precisely that 
 industrial relation Avhich, according to Protectionists, makes 
 diversity of industry impossible without Protection. In the 
 West the extractive industries were exceptionally profitable. 
 In the East there were old-established and important manu- 
 factures. In the West the average rate of wages was, and still 
 is in some States, about twice as high as that prevailing in the 
 East. The rate of interest in the East was, and is, from six to 
 two per cent, lower than in the West. The Eastern manu- 
 facturer thus has all the advantages which, according to 
 Protectionists, are essential to the successful establishment of 
 manufactures : viz., low wages, cheap capital, acquired skill, 
 established business connections, traditions of manufacturing 
 industry, a wealthy and settled population everything, in 
 short, which makes the competition of an older rival irre- 
 sistible. If the Protectionist theories are true, the Western 
 States would still be communities of miners, pastoral isls, or 
 farmers. They would never have enjoyed the blessings of a 
 varied industrial life unless they had been able to Protect 
 themselves by tariffs against the "inundation" of Eastern 
 goods. That bracing and delicious life within factory walls, 
 which (in Protectionist speeches) the fiirmer and the miner 
 are always supposed to be desiderating, could never have been 
 opened to the man of the ^^'est unless he had consented to 
 reduce his wages or to take a lower return for his capital 1
 
 The Political Argument, 269 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. ili., 5 7.] 
 
 Yet, what are the facts ? 
 
 There has always been absolute Free Trade between all 
 the States of the Union. Goods pass as freely from Penn- 
 sylvania to California as they would pass from Pennsylvania to 
 Toronto if the obstacles of legislation were removed. The 
 Western manufacturer has always been "at the mercy of" his 
 Eastern rival. In the meantime, the industry of the Western 
 States has been steadily diversified. Towns have grown up, at 
 first as reservoirs for agricultural produce or as mining centres; 
 and as population has come together, manufactures have been 
 established. At the present time a large number of manu- 
 facturing industries are carried on in California, giving employ- 
 ment to about twenty thousand persons. A similar development 
 is taking place in all the Western States. Their manufactures 
 of woollens, certain grades of leather and iron goods, are not 
 only able to supply the local demand, but to hold their own in 
 competition with the produce of Eastern factories in every part 
 of the Union. 
 
 This instance of industrial progress in the Western States 
 of America has a particular significance to Australians. 
 
 The only serious rival to Australian manufacturers is Great 
 Britain the imports from other countries being insignificant 
 compared with those from the motherland. Now, the diftcrencc 
 between the industrial conditions of Australia and Great Britain 
 is no greater than that between the conditions of California 
 and New York. 
 
 There is, no doubt, a greater difference between Australia 
 and England in the rates paid to the lowest grade of unskilled 
 labour than there is, in respect to the same class of labour, 
 Ijjtween any two States of the Union; but the difference 
 between wages in manufacturing industries in England and 
 Australia is not so great as the difference between the same 
 class of wages in Pennsylvania and California ; while in other 
 respects, the comparison between Australia and England is 
 strikingly similar to that between theEastern and^\'estern States.
 
 270 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 What reason, then, can be suggested why England and 
 Australia should not trade together, which would not equally 
 apply to trade across the American continent ? If in the face 
 of Eastern competition the Western States develop a variety of 
 industries, is not the alarm of Australian Protectionists lest 
 manufactures can never be established here in the face of 
 English competition, exaggerated and unfounded ? Can any 
 reason be suggested why the industrial progress of Australia 
 should be different from that of the Western States ? 
 
 If it be said that California and Pennsylvania are parts of a 
 *' political entity," to which the economic entity should be 
 compelled to correspond, the reply is obvious. England and 
 Australia are equally parts of a political entity ! And if it be 
 urged that the political connection between England and 
 Australia is not likely to continue, the value of the reply is not 
 lessened. The basis of any sound " political entity " must be 
 a living sentiment of national unity ; and, whatever may be the 
 future of Australia, no one can pretend at present that she is 
 not connected with England by ties of race, speech, and 
 nationality, which are stronger than any political forms. The 
 differences between the inhabitants of the Southern, Eastern, 
 and Western States of America in race, manners, religion, even 
 language itself, are far greater than the differences between 
 Englishmen and Australians; yet a "Nationalist" economist 
 allows Spanish Florida, French Louisiana, and Mexican Texas 
 to trade with one another and with Puritan New England, but 
 proi)hesies every sort of disaster if Australia continues to trade 
 with England. 
 
 8. Let us now turn from America to Australasia, and 
 examine the actual conditions of the latter country, in order 
 to ascertain whether they give any colour to the assertion 
 that a young country cannot diversify its industries without 
 Protection. 
 
 Australia furnishes a striking instance of two colonies, of
 
 The Political Argument. 271 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. iii., \ 8.] 
 
 similar industrial conditions, of no great inequality in natural 
 advantages since the physical advantages of New South 
 Wales are more than equalled by the advantages of early 
 development which Victoria owes to her concentrated and 
 well-watered territory living under similar forms of govern- 
 ment, and resembling each other in all respects save that one 
 has adopted Protection and the other has adhered to industrial 
 freedom. No other countries, past or present, offer so ex- 
 cellent an occasion for studying the effects of different fiscal 
 policies. At present we are only dealing with the supposed 
 effect of Protection in securing and maintaining a diversity of 
 industries. It is a striking illustration of the impotence of 
 legislation to control in any material degree the operation of 
 economic forces, that after twenty-five years of Protection in 
 Victoria and Free Trade in New South Wales, there is no 
 great difference between the two colonies in the diversification 
 of their industries. If any difference exists, it is in favour of 
 New South Wales. There is a greater variety of industry in 
 the Free Trade colony than in the Protected. This is, no 
 doubt, owing to the operation of other causes than the absence 
 of Protection, but it is a very strong piece of evidence against 
 the theory that industrial variety cannot exist in a young 
 community without Protection. 
 
 Even in Victoria, Protectionists will find it hard to prove 
 that the industrial diversification which now exists would not 
 have been without the tariff In 1866, the last year of Free 
 Trade, there were no less than 735 manufacturing establish- 
 ments within the colony, giving employment to 12,127 persons 
 out of a population of 651,899. 
 
 Who can say, with the experience of the Western States of 
 America before him, that the industries which have sprung up 
 during the last twenty-three years are wholly owing to the 
 tariff? And still more, who can count or estimate the in- 
 dustries which the tariff has destroyed or stifled in their l^irtli ? 
 A comparison of the industries in existence in 1866 with those
 
 272 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 of 1889 shows that, whatever Protection may have done in the 
 way of creating new industries, it has materially discouraged 
 some of the old industries notably the industries of ship- 
 building and meat-preserving. 
 
 But if there is little or nothing in the history of Victoria 
 to justify the belief that without Protection there must be 
 industrial uniformity, there is still less in the history of New 
 South Wales. 
 
 The " industrial uniformity " of Free Trade New South 
 ^Vales in 1889 consisted of 109 distinct varieties of manu- 
 facturing industries. The number of establishments was 
 3,106, and the number of hands employed was 45,564, while 
 the value of the plant was ^5,743,025, and the horse-power of 
 the machinery was 24,990. The list of manufactures in the 
 official returns made by the manufacturers, whose interest it is 
 to minimise their success, shows that, so far from New South 
 Wales being in any immediate risk of becoming a purely 
 pastoral community, the progress of manufactures has been 
 such that most articles of common use can now be made in 
 the country, from a pearl button to a steam-engine. 
 
 Still, it may be said, great as is the manufacturing progress 
 of New South Wales, it might have been even greater under a 
 ss'stem of Protection. Conceivably it might. But that is not 
 t'.ie question immediately at issue. Time enough later to 
 consider whether greater progress in that direction would have 
 been possible or healthy. The pressing question is, "Are 
 Protectionists right when they urge New South Wales to 
 abandon Free Trade in order to secure diversity of industry?" 
 A\'here, we ask, is the evidence that variety is lacking ? Where 
 i; the proof that your alarms are well founded? The i)ro- 
 l)ortion of our manufacturing to our agricultural and pastoral 
 l)opulation is well up to the average. The number of our 
 industries is large and increasing. Where, then, are the signs 
 that the cause of our inconveniences is an excessive concentra- 
 tion upon pastoral pursuits? Can they point to any country of
 
 The Political Argument. 273 
 
 t. IV., Ch. iii.,59.] 
 
 modern times which was prevented from diversifying its in- 
 dustries for want of Protection? If they cannot, the first and 
 principal assumption of the diversity argument, when it is used 
 in a Free Trade country, is unsupportable by facts. There is 
 not, in fact, any lack of variety in the industrial occupations of 
 a Free Trade people who inhabit a young community whose 
 resources are great and expanding. 
 
 Let us now test the argument by theory, in order to dis- 
 cover, if possible, to what extent it is probable that Protection 
 can ever be a necessary condition of industrial variety. 
 
 ^ 9. The first assumption of the diversity argument viz., 
 that without Protection there can be no sufficient industrial 
 variety in a young country has now been tested by reference 
 to facts, and it has been shown that the assumption is, at least, 
 not supported by evidence. All young countries with which 
 we are acquainted have developed many natural resources 
 without Protection, while there is no evidence that any of 
 them has been prevented from doing so by the existence of 
 Free Trade. It remains to test the assumption by reference 
 to theory. Protectionists cannot complain of this test, for 
 until they advance facts in support of their assertion it can 
 only be tested by the probabilities which are derived from a 
 consideration of general principles. 
 
 It has already been pointed out that when a State is first 
 settled the energies of its people are so largely directed to the 
 extractive industries that there is no supply of spare labour 
 available for manufactures on a large scale. 
 
 It docs not, however, follow that there will be no other 
 avenues of employment. Even a pastoral community and 
 pastoralism is tlie simplest of the extractive industries requires 
 houses, clothes, tools, and conveyances ; while, as Professor 
 Fawcett, among others, has pointed out, " However purely 
 agricultural the industry of a country may be, there must 
 always bo a great deal of work to be done which will provide 
 s
 
 274 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 many different kinds of employment besides the mere tilling of 
 the land. Houses and other buildings have to be erected, 
 roads have to be made, agricultural implements and machinery 
 have to be repaired, and the cost of carriage will make many 
 articles, especially those of a bulky kind, so expensive to 
 import that, although labour maybe dearer in a new country, it 
 will be found cheaper to make the articles at home. The 
 various trades and handicrafts which are thus called into 
 existence will create an increasing demand for skilled labour, 
 and in this way that industrial uniformity about which the 
 Protectionists express so much alarm will be avoided." 
 (" Free Trade and Protection," p. 77.) 
 
 But none of the young communities of modern times is 
 devoted exclusively either to pastoral or agricultural pursuits. 
 They follow all the extractive industries simultaneously. Now, 
 nothing more conduces to the concentration of the population 
 and the growth of towns than mining. Consequently, in any 
 country where minerals abound the domestic industries, which 
 are inevitably created by the growth of towns, are sure to gain 
 a firm footing. 
 
 It would therefore appear that under any conceivable 
 circumstances the cry about a country suffering " from the 
 stagnation of a single industry" is both exaggerated ar.d 
 ridiculous. No community can exist without a great variety 
 of industries which no foreign competition can destroy. The 
 true question, when the diversity argument is stripped of its 
 exaggerations, is, " Whether a State can pass from the agricul- 
 tural to the manufacturing stage without the assistance of a 
 Protective tariff." 
 
 |< lo. Now, the successful jjrosecuticn of manufactures on 
 a large scale dci)ends u[)on tlie concurrence of two conditions, 
 namely : 
 
 1. A large and concentrated population. 
 
 2. A supply of available capital.
 
 The Political Argument, 275 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. iii., ? 10.] 
 
 It is sometimes asserted that Protection encourages 
 immigration, and thus stimulates the increase of population. 
 This assertion, although it is not demonstrably incorrect, is not 
 supported by proof. Such evidence as can be obtained points 
 rathcn the other way. Since the adoption of Protection by 
 Victoria there has been a steady stream of emigration from 
 that colony to Free Trade New South Wales, as was disclosed 
 by the often-quoted report of Mr. Hayter on the census of 
 1 881.1 ^^he emigration of young men from the colony of 
 Victoria is particularly noticeable, in view of the Protectionist 
 assertion that Protection provides employment. 
 
 It will be imitating a Protectionist method of argument to 
 assert that New South Wales gained the whole of this 
 l^opulation from her southern neighbour on account of the 
 superior attractions of her Free Trade policy. But the fact of 
 the decrease in Victoria during ten years of Protection 
 certainly does not predispose the mind to a ready belief in the 
 unsupported prophecy of Protectionists, that their policy will 
 increase population. 
 
 Nor does American experience justify Protectionists in this 
 assertion. The figures of immigration into the United States 
 have been analysed by Professor Sumner (" Protectionism,' 
 p. 122), with the result that nine-tenths of the immigrants are 
 shown to be labourers, domestic servants, farmers, and others 
 who belong to trades which are not Protected, and whose 
 arrival cannot therefore be attributed to the operation of a 
 Protective duty. 
 
 Suppose, however, for a moment that Protection does 
 ericourage immigration. This is a curious rtsult to be brought 
 about by those who invariably declare themselves the 
 enemies of immigration. A tax to increase the supply of 
 labour very soon becomes a tax to lower wages; so that there 
 seems some inconsistency between the argument that Protection 
 
 ' 5tv below, .Appendix III.
 
 276 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 raises wages and the argument that it increases the number of 
 the wage-receivers. 
 
 Moreover, it is worth considering whether any rapid 
 increase of population even although it causes the establish- 
 ment of manufactures as one result is altogether desirable to 
 a young community. The absence of poverty, the easier 
 conditions of life, the higher standard of comfort, which are 
 characteristics of a young country, are owing in no small 
 degree to the strong position which the labourer occupies in 
 making his bargain with employers, in consequence of the 
 limited number of his competitors. The man who desires to 
 introduce the pressure of population into a young country 
 must also be prepared to face the evils of an old. 
 
 But if it is conceivable (although unproved) that Protection 
 may assist the encouragement of manufactures by stimulating 
 immigration, there is certainly no ground for any fear that 
 Free Trade will operate as a hindrance to new settlers. That 
 which attracts population to a young community is precisely 
 that which is an obstacle to the establishment of manufactures : 
 namely, the profitableness of the extractive industries. So 
 long as the natural fertility of the soil enables much to be 
 produced with little effort, so long will immigrants pour into a 
 country of high wages and large profits. It was the discovery 
 of gold, and not the Protective tariff, that caused the rush of 
 ])opulation to A^ictoria ; and it is the vast expanse of fertile land 
 that draws the annual stream of immigrants to the United Slates. 
 
 The second requisite to manufacturing development is an 
 abundance of capital. Now, the profits of capital in a young 
 country are usually large, because the demand of the old world 
 for raw produce is very great, and, owing to the assistance of 
 nature, is easily supplied. But, as cajjital accumulates, and 
 the natural advantages of the country become exhausted, new 
 openings for investment will naturally be sought. \\\\\ these 
 be sought in the country or outside ? Can the answer be in 
 doubt? At any rate, no one whose professed faith is belief
 
 The Political Argument. 277 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. iii., \ 10.] 
 
 in the nation as the industrial unit ought to hesitate a moment 
 in his reply ! 
 
 Let it, then, be granted that a time will come when the 
 spare capital of the country can no longer find a satisfectory 
 investment in the extractive industries what is more likely to 
 attract attention than a further development of natural 
 resources, in order to supply the young community with 
 articles that it has hitherto imported ? 
 
 But tlie more vigorous the foreign trade, the larger is the 
 home production ; and the larger the home production, the 
 greater the opportunities for saving money. Accordingly, a 
 large import trade is the surest sign that foreign industries will 
 soon be naturalised ; and the fear of industrial uniformity is 
 groundless so long as the capital of the community continues 
 reproductive, and natural resources remain to be developed. 
 
 '^I'he conclusion is thus reached that, just as there is no 
 known instance of industrial variety being prevented by Free 
 'i'radc, so is there no a priori reason that such should be the 
 case. Once grant that individuals seek their own gain, and 
 are alive to their own interests, and that the conditions of a 
 country are such as to encourage a rapid growth of population 
 and a large accumulation of capital and the tendency to 
 develop new industries continues with gathering strengtli until 
 every natural resource has been exhausted. 
 
 Manufactures will spring up in every State as need arise?', 
 for then the demand for their products will be sufficient to 
 ensure a profit. Protection, by creating an artificial demand, 
 may hurry their growth by a few years ; but Free Trade is not 
 an obstacle to manufactures, but rather an assurance that they 
 will be jjlanled in a health)- soil, and grow to maturity. "The 
 develoi)ment of society is as regular and as natural as that of a 
 plant, and there is no more need of human interference than 
 there is to make a bud l)urst into blossom at the proper time. 
 It is a develoi)ment, moreover, which cannot be hastened 
 without injury. A new country cannot have the higher social
 
 278 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 development until its population begins to grow dense. It is 
 so in America yet. We have not the literature, or the science, 
 or the fine arts of the old countries ; but we have not their 
 poverty and misery. We must take our advantages and dis- 
 advantages together." (Sumner's "History of Protection, "p. 26.) 
 This is the answer to Protectionists in a young community 
 who complain of its industrial uniformity. Free Trade is no 
 obstacle to a natural diversity of occupation which is sufficient 
 for the present needs of any growing country, and is free from 
 the risks and disorders of that rickety diversity which is the 
 untimely fruit of legislative labour. 
 
 II. We have already considered the argument that 
 Protection causes a diversity of industry by the tests of fact 
 and theory, and endeavoured to show that young countries do 
 not, in fact, suffer from industrial uniformity, and that, if they 
 did, there is no reason why they should not find a remedy 
 under a policy of unrestricted trade. 
 
 It remains to point out that, even if all the force is given 
 to the argument which Protectionists demand for it, there are 
 certain natural limits to diversity which no legislation can ever 
 pass. It must never be forgotten, when Protection is extolled 
 because it causes a diversity of industry, that there is an 
 impassable limit to diversification set by Nature herself. 
 
 It has been well said that " there is a natural law in opera- 
 tion which as surely determines the number required for each 
 great class of employment as do the natural laws which locally 
 determine the times and relative heights of the tide. No 
 social advancement . . . can ever alter the relative 
 numbers of the various branches of human service." ^ That 
 
 1 Extract from paper read by R. M. Johnston, Government Statistician 
 of Tasmania, before the Australasian Association for the Advancement of 
 Science, at Melbourne, 1890 (p. 9). Mr. Johnston gives (p. 11) a valuable 
 table showing the proportional classification of tiie occupation of all persons 
 engaged in the supply of home wants. The higlicst proportion employed 
 in industrial occupations is in Engl ind : viz., 24 "5, as against 7"6 in the United 
 States.
 
 The Political Argument. 279 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. iii., \ II.] 
 
 which determines the numbers required for each class in any 
 country is the condition of its leading industries. 
 
 In a country where dominating industries are pastoral or 
 agricultural, the proportion of industrial employees must be com- 
 paratively small ; while in a country like Great Britain, which 
 is pre-eminently a manufacturing country, the number will be 
 large. Until a country has exhausted the profitable occupation 
 of its soil, whether in the cultivation of iron or search for 
 minerals, no amount of Protection can draw labour and capital 
 to other industries without inflicting a dangerous check to 
 national development. 
 
 Even in the United States, where Protection has run 
 mad, the proportion of industrial bread-winners is, according to 
 Mr. Johnston's figures, only 7-6 of the entire population ; while 
 in England it is 24-5.1 While, if " industrial " occupations are 
 still further sub-divided so as to place manufactures in a 
 separate class, it is usually estimated that not more than one 
 person in ten can, under any circumstances, find employment 
 in that channel. Nor can this number be safely anticipated 
 in a country which, like the United States or Australia, is still 
 in the agricultural stage. But, whatever may be the precise 
 proportion which manufactures ought to bear to agriculture or 
 to mining, the point to remember is that it cannot be safely 
 exceeded. A country like England, which exports its manu- 
 factured goods to every corner of the world, can enlarge the 
 proportion which its manufacturing employees bear to its own 
 population, because they are engaged in supplying the wants 
 of other countries. But a country which cannot export its 
 manufactures can only safely permit the existence of a sufficient 
 number of employees to supply its own wants. 
 
 The practical rule to be deduced from these obvious 
 renections is that manufactures should be allowed to find their 
 own level. If an attempt is made to forcibly divert labour 
 from agricultural to manufacturing pursuits, there is an almost 
 
 1 In I'"rce Trad'.- Xcw South Wales in 1880 it was 6'^.
 
 28o Industrial Freedom. 
 
 certain danger of over-production ; wliile if manufactures are 
 allowed to grow up as they are required, they will be able, 
 having originated under open competition, to extend their 
 market as they increase their production. Nothing is moie 
 striking in commercial history than the inability of American 
 manufacturers to compete with England in a neutral market. 
 While England every year sends from twenty to thirty million 
 pounds' worth of manufactured goods into the United States, 
 in despite of the heavy tariff, the whole export of American 
 manufactures to all parts of the world seldom exceeds a value 
 of ten millions. 
 
 It is as certain as any forecast of the future can be, that so 
 long as America adheres to Protection Great Britain need have 
 no fear of her commercial rivalry ; but when America adopts 
 Free Trade the tables will be turned, and England, in all 
 probability, will be beaten out of many neutral markets. 
 
 The impossibility, then, of increasing manufacturing 
 industries beyond a certain point, unless the industries are such 
 that they can face the competition of the world, is a considera- 
 tion w'hich should make Protectionists pause before proposing 
 to hurry the establishment of many industries. The results of 
 interference with commerce are hardly ever calculable, and no 
 one can foresee in any country all the consequences of 
 Protection. We cannot accurately estimate either the demand 
 for manufactured goods or the supply of available labour ; we 
 cannot tell beforehand what would be the result of higher 
 prices for manufactures upon the dominating pursuits of the 
 country, and we hardly even know accurately the number or 
 strength of our existing industries. Under such circumstances, 
 the man takes upon himself a heavy responsibility who 
 proposes to interfere by Act of Parliament with the distribution 
 of employment. It may be true that the future is obscure, so 
 that even the clearest-sighted despair at times ; but steady faith 
 in man and nature is better than rash play with unknown 
 forces. Things may be bad, and the remedy may not be
 
 The Political Argument. 281 
 
 Pf. IV., ch. Hi., \ 12.] 
 
 visible ; but it would be the very blindness of unwisdom to 
 
 attempt to solve the problem without knowing the factors or 
 
 possessing any test of the result. 
 
 12. Nor must it be forgotten that, even if diversity be 
 gained, there is another aspect to the question besides that 
 which is presented by the manufacturers. It is possible to pay 
 too high a price even for the advantage of industrial diversity. 
 
 "Development of natural resources," "variety of occu- 
 pation," and such large phrases, bear a different significance to 
 the man who pays for the development and the variety and to 
 the man who receives the money. The natural-resource 
 theory is admirably comforting to the man who owns the 
 resource ; but the man who does not own it sees the theory in 
 another light. 
 
 Professor Sumner has thrown the question into an amusing 
 dialogue, which contains none the less of sound sense and 
 good economics than if it were expressed in a more professorial 
 style. 
 
 "A man," says Professor Sumner, " discovered iron when 
 there was no duty on imported iron. On the Protectionist 
 doctrine, he wonl collect tools and go to work. He goes to 
 Washington, he visits the statesman, and a dialogue takes 
 place : 
 
 " Ironman : Mr. Statesman, I have found an iron deposit 
 on my farm. 
 
 " Statesman : Have you, indeed ? Tliat is good news. 
 Our country is riclicr by one new natural resource than we had 
 supposed. 
 
 " Ironman : Yes ; and I now want to begin mining iron. 
 
 " Statesman : Very well ; go on. A\'e shall be glad to hear 
 that you are [)rospering and growing rich. 
 
 " Ironman : Ves, of course ; but I am now earning my 
 living by tilling the surface of the ground, and I am afraid that 
 I cannot make as much at mininc: as at farmin";.
 
 282 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 " Statesman : That is indeed another matter. Look into 
 that carefully, and do not leave a better industry for a worse. 
 
 " Ironman : But I want to mine that iron. It does not 
 seem right to leave it in the ground when we are importing 
 iron all the time ; but I cannot see a profit in it at the present 
 prices for imported iron. I thought perhaps that you would 
 put a tax on imported iron, so that I could sell mine at a 
 profit. Then I could see my way to give up farming, and go 
 in for mining. 
 
 " Statesman : You do not think what you ask. That 
 would be to throw on your neighbour the risk of working the 
 mine which you are afraid to take yourself. 
 
 " Ironman (aside) : I have not talked the right dialect to 
 this man. I must begin all over again. (y\loud.) Mr. 
 Statesman, the natural resources of this continent ought to be 
 developed. American industry must be protected. The 
 American miner must not be forced to compete with the 
 pauper labour of Europe. 
 
 " Statesman : Now I understand you. Now you talk 
 business. Why did you not say so before ? How much tax 
 do you want ? 
 
 " The next time that a buyer of pig iron goes to market to 
 get some, he finds that it costs thirty bushels of wheat per ton 
 instead of twenty. ' What has happened to pig iron ? ' says he. 
 'Oh! haven't you heard?' is tlie reply. 'Anew mine has 
 been found down in Pennsylvania. We have got a new 
 ' natural resource." ' 
 
 " ' I haven't got a new natural resource,' says he. ' It is as bad 
 for me as if the grasshoppers had eaten up one-third of my crop.' " 
 
 It would be a good day for the public if the discussion of 
 politics could always be conducted in this simple language. 
 At present, politicians are the only persons, except preachers 
 and art critics, who are thought the more of for talking 
 nonsense ! For the picture drawn by Professor Sumner is not 
 in the least exaggerated. The third chapter of Mr. Taussig's
 
 The Political Argument. 283 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. iii., \ 12.] 
 
 most useful work contains numerous illustrations from American 
 experience which are equally grotesque. The most instructive 
 are the duties upon emery, nickel, and copper. 
 
 Up to 1864, nickel had been admitted into the States 
 duty-free ; but shortly before this date a nickel mine was dis- 
 covered in Pennsylvania. The opportunity for developing a 
 natural resource was too great, especially as the mine was 
 owned by an influential politician. In 1864 a duty of 15 per 
 cent, was imposed on nickel, and in 1870 the duty was raised 
 to 30 cents per pound, or about 40 per cent, on the value. No 
 other nickel mine has been discovered, and the fortunate pro- 
 prietor, Mr. Joseph Wharton, is now a millionaire, and joins 
 with Mr. Carnegie in his praises of democracy. It is, perhaps, 
 needless to add that Mr. Wharton is a determined opponent of 
 any reduction of the duty upon nickel. Mr. Wharton is also 
 the founder of the " Wharton School of Finance and Economy " 
 in Philadelphia, and, in the opinion apparently that restrictions, 
 which are so desirable upon the sale of nickel, would be equally 
 applicable to the study of economics, he has expressly enjoined 
 that the professor shall teach Protection ; or, in the words of the 
 deed of gift, " how, by suitable tariff legislation, a nation may 
 keep its productive industry alive, cheapen the cost of com- 
 modities, and oblige foreigners to sell to it at low prices, while 
 contributing largely towards defraying the expense of its 
 government." It is not mentioned in the deed of gift whetlicr 
 tlie Wliartonian professor is allowed to teach the best means of 
 " cheapening the cost of the commodity," nickel. The present 
 holder of the Chair is the Mr. Patten whose work in defence of 
 Protection has already been referred to. 
 
 Copper has fared the same as nickel. Previously to 1869 
 copper ore was imported from Cliili, and was smelted and re- 
 fined in Boston and Paltimore. But during the years imme- 
 diately preceding 1869, the great copper mines of Pake 
 Superior had begun to be worked on a considerable scale.
 
 284 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 These mines, under ordinary conditions, could have supplied 
 the whole of the United States more cheaply and abundantly 
 than any other country; yet, as Professor Taussig points out, 
 " through the tariff policy these very mines have caused 
 Americans for many years to pay more for their copper than is 
 paid in any other country." The table compiled by Professor 
 Taussig (p. 263), from "The Mineral Resources of the United 
 States," of the prices of copper in London and New York from 
 1875 to 1886, is conclusive on this point. The process was 
 simple. The duty having shut out foreign copper, a copper 
 trust was formed, which has embraced the new mines one by 
 one as they were opened, and the output of copper was limited 
 o as to keep the price just below that at which copper would 
 have been imported. Needless to add that all the "copper 
 kings " are staunch Protectionists.^ 
 
 Put it is unnecessary to multiply examples. American 
 experience is open to all to see. Can Australians hope to 
 escape these evils? No wonder that, with the results before 
 his eyes of the discovery in America of nickel and copper, 
 
 1 The Hon. David A. Wells, on page 23 of his " Practical Economics," has 
 collected some of the more striking examples of American efforts to secure 
 industrial variety. '' .\bout 1826 to 1828." he says, "the discovery of the lead 
 mines at Galena, 111., became generally known, and as the first reports were 
 to the effect that the deposits were of such unparalleled richness, purity, 
 magnitude, and easy accessibility, as to make it only a matter of time when the 
 whole world, from sheer inability to compete, would become wholly dependent 
 for its supplies of lead on this one locality, it was at once considered desirable 
 Ijy many people to establish it, so far as fiscal legislation could do it, on a most 
 extraordinary economic jirinciple, and one whicli from that day to this has 
 proved popular in all tariff enactments in the United States : and this was to 
 make tlie (li--co\ery or recognition of the existence of any great natural advan- 
 tages citluT in the way of mines, soils, climatic advantages, forests, means of 
 interconnnunication, or national characteristics the immediate occasion for 
 cursing tlie cuuntiy by the creation or imposition of some new tax, thereby 
 making dear what was before clieap ; endeavouring to work up to a state of 
 abundance through conditions of scarcity artificially created and unnecessarily 
 perpetuated. In this particular instance the principle was exemplified by 
 raising tb.e duty on lead imported in pigs and bars from one cent a j50und to 
 three cents."
 
 The Political Argument. 285 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. iii., \ 13.] 
 
 Professor Sumner firmly hopes that tin may not be found. 
 " At the present time," he says, " we have all the tin that we 
 want above ground, because beneficent Nature has refrained 
 from putting any underground in our territory." In the metal 
 schedule, tin is alone free. Should a tin-mine be discovered, 
 the next thing will be a tax on tin of 40 per cent. "The 
 mine-owners say they want to exploit the mine. They do not. 
 They want to make the mine an excuse to exploit the tax- 
 payers." (" Protectionism," p. 53.) Since these words were 
 written, tin has been discovered in the States, and duties on tin- 
 plate have been a prominent feature in the M'Kinley tariff, as 
 many Western canners have already discovered, to their loss. 
 
 13. Finally, let the diversity argument have all the strength 
 Protectionists attribute to it : it can never be used as a general 
 defence of a restrictive policy. It rests, as we have seen, on 
 the three assumptions that industry has not, in fact, diversified 
 under Free Trade ; that it cannot do so ; and that Protection 
 is the best means of causing a diversification. 
 
 Now, it is plain that the first two of these assumptions may 
 be true of one industry and not of another ; accordingly, when- 
 ever the argument is used, it will be necessary to ask for more 
 precision. " What are the new industries which it is desired to 
 establish? and what is to be the rate of duty?" It is most 
 noticeable that Protectionists are always silent upon these 
 (questions when they are before constituencies. "The art of 
 taxation,"' Colbert is reported to have said, "is the art of 
 plucking the goose so as to get the largest possible amount 
 of feathers with the least possible squealing." It would never 
 do, tliereforc, to let the people know beforehand the nature of 
 the coming taxes. Mucli better to let everybody think that 
 the tax will fall on his neighbour's back. When gifted legisla- 
 tors meet in cau( us, matters t^n be arranged so much more 
 satisfactorily to the manufacturers certainly, and possibly to 
 the legislators ! Thus the policy of the Protectionist party on 
 the 1 ustings must always be a policy of silence and conceal
 
 286 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 ment. The strongest argument Free Traders can desire is that 
 no Protectionist leader ever dares to say beforehand either 
 what taxes he requires, or what is to be their amount, or for 
 how long they are to be imposed. 
 
 CHAPTER IV. 
 
 THE HOME-MARKET ARGUMENT. 
 
 I. The home-market argument is best known in the story of the 
 Irishman who complained that a dollar in New York went no 
 further than a shilling in Dublin. '' Then, why did you not stop 
 in Dublin ?" was the question of a bystander. " Because there 
 I couldn't get the shilling ! " was Pat's reply. This is the plat- 
 form presentation of the argument. In treatises which pretend 
 to be serious it has three distinct forms or varieties. Some- 
 times it is used in defence of Protection as a means of render- 
 ing a community less dependent upon foreigners in the event 
 of war ; at others, as a means of extending or strengthening the 
 market of the local agriculturist in time of peace ; while in its 
 more recent developments the necessity of enlarging the home 
 market is insisted upon as the only means of disposing of the 
 surplus from extractive industries. 
 
 The economic basis of the argument in all its varieties is 
 that misapprehension of the comparative importance of the 
 home and foreign trade of a community which confused even 
 Adam Smith. The passage is well known. " Capital," he 
 says, "employed in purchasing in one part of the country in 
 order to sell in another part the produce of the industries of 
 that country, generally replaces by such operation two distinct 
 capitals that had both been employed in its agriculture or 
 manufactures, and thus enables them to continue that employ- 
 ment The capital employed in purchasing foreign
 
 The Political Argument. 287 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. Iv., \ I.] 
 
 goods for home consumption, when the purchase is made by 
 the produce of domestic industry, replaces, too, Ijy every such 
 operation, two distinct capitals ; but one of them only is em- 
 ployed in supporting domestic industry. . . . The other sup- 
 ports foreign industry, and, therefore, foreign trade will give but 
 one-half the encouragement to the industry or productive 
 labour of a country that domestic or internal trade does." 
 
 The fallacy of this proposition is in the assumption that the 
 capital which is left unused in consequence of the diversion 
 of the capital, which set it in motion, from the home to the 
 foreign trade will continue to be unused after the diversion has 
 been effected. It is true that trade between England and 
 Scotland will replace both an English and a Scotch capital ; 
 and that if the trade be diverted from Scotland to Portugal, it 
 will replace an English and a Portuguese capital. But the 
 Scotch capital is not thereby destroyed, but remains available 
 for new undertakings. 
 
 Mr. Henry George ("Protection or Free Trade," p. 117) 
 exposes the fallacy with an admirable lucidity. " If,'' he says, 
 " we substitute for the terms used by Adam Smith other terms 
 of the same relation, we may obtain, with equal validity, such 
 propositions as this : If Episcopalians trade with Presbyterians, 
 two profits arc made by Protestants ; whereas, when Presby- 
 terians trade with Catholics, only one profit goes to Protestants. 
 Therefore, trade between Protestants is twice as profitable as 
 trade between Protestants and Catholics. 
 
 " In Adam Smith's illustration there are two quantities of 
 I'.ritish goods -one in Edinburgh and one in London. In the 
 domestic trade which he supposes, these two <|uantities of 
 British goods are exchanged ; but if the Scotch goods be sent 
 to Portugal instead of to I'^ngland, and Portuguese goods 
 brought back, only one ([uantity of British goods is exchanged. 
 There will be only one-half the replacement in Great Britain, 
 but there has been only one-half the dis[)lacement. The Edin- 
 burgh goods which have been sent away have been replaced
 
 2 88 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 with Portuguese goods ; but the London goods have not been 
 replaced with anything, because they are still there. In the 
 one case twice the amount of British capital is employed as in 
 the other, and consequently, double returns show equal 
 profitableness." 
 
 It is astonishing that such a patent fallacy should have 
 misled any one ; but Mr. Hoyt, in his eighth chapter, accepts 
 the argument with guileless confidence as a basis of his own 
 view of the theory that the " home market ought to be pre- 
 served for home producers : " a maxim which, as Mr. George 
 observes, is in the same category with " Keep our own 
 appetites for our own cookery^'' or " Keep our oivn transportation 
 for our oivn legs I '"' 
 
 2. Passing now from the supposed economic basis of the 
 home-market argument to its various political props, we 
 shall find that the earliest of these is the dread of an inter- 
 ception of foreign commerce in time of war. This alarm 
 underlies the older mercantile theory of commerce, and 
 pervades the writings of List, Carey, and the earlier Pro- 
 tectionists. 
 
 It is, indeed, as Professor P'awcett has observed (" Free 
 Trade and Protection," p. 82), "the only logical basis on which 
 a Protective system can be supported ; for if it could be 
 assumed that the normal condition of a country was to be 
 perpetually at war with its neighbours, it would become of the 
 first importance to make it, as far as possible, industrially 
 independent of them. Lnder such circumstances it might 
 be expedient, at whatever cost, to impose Protective duties 
 with the view of establishing and maintaining various branches 
 of home industiy." But can any such assumption be made? 
 Can any conjuncture of circumstances be imagined under 
 which a country with the extensive seaboard of Australia or 
 America, and with their means of commanding supplies from 
 all quarters of the globe, should be unable to import ? As
 
 The Political Argument. 289 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. iv., \ 2.] 
 
 Professor Fawcett points out, even when the faciUties of trans- 
 portation were far inferior to what they are at present namely, 
 during the wars of the first Napoleon " there was never a 
 moment even in his unparalleled career of military aggression 
 when all the coasts and all the frontiers of France were so 
 completely blockaded that no foreign product could find its 
 way to her markets." 
 
 Assuming, however, that the danger lest any "country, in 
 these days of steam and electricity, could be so completely 
 surrounded both by sea and land with foreign foes that it was 
 unable to import any foreign supplies is not wholly imaginary, 
 the question still remains whether the premium for insurance 
 against it is not excessive. The argument then descends into 
 the region of finance, and turns upon the cheapest means of 
 guaranteeing to a particular country the continuous supply cf 
 a certain quantity of goods. 
 
 Now, it is apparent that since this argument rests on the 
 assumption that the goods in question cannot be produced 
 against foreign competition, the profitable selling price of the 
 home-made article must be higher than that of the imported. 
 In other word:, Protection, in this case at any rate, will raise 
 prices. 
 
 It becomes, therefore, a simple matter of calculation 
 whether the cost to the community of this increase in prices 
 is not out of proportion to the risk which the expenditure is 
 thought to insure. The salt tax in France, which Professor 
 Fawcett mentions as an illustration of the argument, because 
 it is supported on the ground that without Protection 
 the French might be deprived of this necessity in time 
 of war, has raised the price of salt by a halfpenny a pound. 
 This means a burden of ^7; 20, 000 a year upon the iM-cnch 
 consumer. 
 
 Seeing that a war such as the alarmist contemplates 
 is not likely to happen more than once in one hundred years, it 
 would be manifestly cheaper to remit the tax and sp:-nd 
 
 T
 
 290 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 ;i^ioo,ooo a year in the purchase of salt, and distribute this 
 from the Government stores when the necessity arose. 
 It is difficult to deal with such considerations seriously. 
 
 3. The second form in which the home-market argu- 
 ment appeared has almost lost its force with the cheapening of 
 transport and the improvement in the means of locomotion. 
 It has, however, played a prominent part in the controversies, 
 and still retains a lingering vitality, so that some examination 
 of it is required. 
 
 It is thus stated by List, as usual, in many words (p. 262, 
 Eng. Trans.): 
 
 "The foreign commerce," he says, "of agricultural nations of 
 the temperate zone, so long as it is limited to provisions and raw 
 materials, cannot attain to importance. 
 
 "Firstly, because the exports of the agricultural nation are 
 directed to a few manufacturing nations, which themselves carry on 
 agriculture, and which, indeed, because of their manufactures and 
 their extended commerce, carry it on on a much more perfect 
 system than the mere agricultural nation. This export trade is there- 
 fore neither certain nor uniform. The trade in mere products is 
 always a matter of extraordinary speculation, whose benefits fall 
 most to the speculative merchants, but not to the agriculturists or 
 the productive power of the agricultural nation. 
 
 " Secondly, because the exchange of agricultural products for 
 foreign manufactured goods is liable to be greatly interrupted by the 
 commercial restrictions of foreign States and by wars. 
 
 "Thirdly, because the exports of mere products chiefly benefit 
 countries which are situated near sea-coasts and the banks of 
 navigable rivers, and does not benefit the inland territory, which 
 constitutes the greater part of the territory of the agricultural 
 nation. 
 
 "Fourth, and finally, because the foreign manufacturing nation 
 may find it to its interest to procure its means of subsistence and 
 raw materials from other countries and newly formed colonies." 
 
 The bare statement of these views is their best refutation. 
 
 In truth, commerce follows its natural channels. Tlic 
 foreign trade of a young country is in tlie surplus of its 
 extractive industries, and that trade is neitlier more nor less
 
 The Political Argument. 291 
 
 Pt, IV., Ch. iv., ? 3.] 
 
 uncertain or varied than trade in manufactured products. 
 The probabihty, indeed, is that a trade in the necessaries of 
 Hfe is likely to be larger and more steady than one in manu- 
 factured articles, which depends to some extent on fashion or 
 caprice, and is liable at any time to be disturbed by changes 
 in the processes of production, or in the pressure of new 
 competitors. 
 
 Secondly, a foreign trade in the export of raw materials is 
 far less likely to be interrupted by war than a trade in manu- 
 factures, on account of the greater value of such articles to 
 foreign countries. England, for example, would make more 
 strenuous efforts to maintain a continuous supply of raw 
 cotton than of Yankee notions yet, according to List, trade 
 in the former is more likely " to be interrupted by the com- 
 mercial restrictions of foreign States and by war." 
 
 List's third reason for preferring a home market -" that 
 exports of mere products chiefly benefit countries which are 
 situated near the sea-coasts" has entirely lost any value which 
 it might have once possessed, in consequence of the improve- 
 ment in the means of locomotion. The existence and pro- 
 sperity of the Western States of America and Canada is quite 
 a sufficient answer to the theory that a foreign trade in natural 
 products only benefits a coastal State. 
 
 As to List's fourth reason " that a foreign manufacturing 
 State may stop buying its food or raw materials from abroad" 
 can any one name any reason why there is not precisely the 
 same danger of an interruption to commerce when the articles 
 exchanged are manufactured goods ? Why should a country 
 be less likely to give up the importation of manufactured 
 goods than to give up tlie importation of food? Surely 
 these professors of Restriction have but little faith in their own 
 theories ! 
 
 If all countries became their discii)les, each would 
 manufacture for itself, and the country which would suffer 
 most from such a chanire would be that which had been the
 
 292 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 first to act upon their maxims, and replace the export of food 
 by the export of manufactures. 
 
 Again, the appeal must be made to common sense. 
 People abroad buy food and raw materials because they 
 require these things. The country which sells them does so 
 because the sale is profitable. The same rules affect a trade 
 in manufactured goods. Neither is, by its nature, more 
 profitable, more certain, or more steady than the other ; that 
 one is likely to possess these attributes in the highest degree 
 which arises out of natural conditions, and is pursued spon- 
 taneously by individuals seeking their own advantage. 
 
 4. But what shall be said of Mr. Patten the Whartonian 
 professor ? If List preferred a home market because a foreign 
 trade was precarious, the latest oracle warned, no doubt, by 
 the periodic recurrence of commercial crises, even within the 
 limits of Protected countries has abandoned this reason, and 
 justifies his preference on the ground that a home market 
 causes the land of a community to be put to new uses. These 
 are the steps of his reasoning : " There is a foreign demand 
 for one class of crops and not for another ; the foreigner takes 
 wheat, and whilst that demand lasts American land is put 
 under wheat, and will always remain under wheat until a home 
 market arises ; because until that event happens no one will 
 require any other product of the land. An extension of the 
 home market is required to find new uses for the land." And 
 the proof is that, since Protection corn has been grown in the 
 Western States, " the heavier lands were brought into cultiva- 
 tion, as the home market created a demand for corn instead of 
 wheat" !i 
 
 1 The full text of the argument is subjoined : " The first settlers, instead of 
 coming upon the best lands, are actually forced to cultivate many of the 
 poorer soils which are easily brought into cultivation, or which are peculiarly 
 adapted to the cultivation of those crops for which there is a foreign demand. 
 For this reason some change in the demand of food must precede the best use 
 of the land of a countrv. Some Vl&w market must be opened up which will
 
 The Political Argument. 293 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. iv., \ 5.] 
 
 What a blessed consummation of the Whartonian pohcy, 
 that the Western farmer should change his crop from wheat to 
 maize ! But does it really matter to the Western farmer what 
 he grows, provided he gets his price for it? And is the 
 American the only man on earth to whom he could have sold 
 his maize ? What, too, of the wheat-growers ? What consola- 
 tion is it to them for the fall in value of the lighter lands which 
 were first used for wheat that the heavier corn lands now 
 command a higher price ? 
 
 Surely the argument needs no serious answer ; and perhaps 
 Mr. Patten the professor who, by the terms of his appoint- 
 ment, is not allowed to be impartial ^ is more to be pitied 
 than blamed for having used it. 
 
 5. But it is not with arguments like those of Pro- 
 fessors List and Patten that the agricultural voter is beguiled, 
 but with others which are more enticing. Put in its most 
 
 afford a place where the new crops can be sold, thus enabling the producers to 
 use their land in a better manner ; with which extension of the home market 
 new uses for the land are found, and at the same time many classes of soil, 
 which were worthless while the few crops demanded by foreigners were pro- 
 duced, now become the more productive part of the land. This fact is clearly 
 illustrated in the changes of value in Western lands which have followed the 
 creation of home markets. The lighter soils were first occupied because better 
 adapted to the cultivation of wheat. These soils commanded a higher price 
 than the heavier lands so long as the main market for the West was in Europe. 
 But when the growth of home markets created a demand for corn instead of 
 wheat, the heavier lands were brought into use, and soon became to be 
 regarded as the better land ; and at the present time they command a much 
 higher price than do the lighter lands which were first used for wheat." 
 
 1 It will be remembered that Mr. Wharton, the founder of Mr. Patten's 
 Chair, was the fortunate owner of the only nickel deposit in the United States, 
 and in that capacity developed by means of a tax the natural resource of 
 nickel-mining " put the land, in fact, to a new use," as Mr. Patten would say 
 with the result that he became a millionaire, and founded a Chair to teach 
 "how by suitable tariff legislation a nation may keep its productive in- 
 diisti y alive, cheapen the cost of commodities, and oblige foreigners to sell to 
 it at low prices." What do foreigners sell to the Western farmer ? and how 
 has Protection lowered the price of nickel? These are practical questions for 
 Mr. Patten to answer.
 
 294 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 effective form, the home-market argument, as used at election- 
 time in country districts, is something like this : 
 
 " You are, at present, many miles away from the nearest city, 
 which is your only market. You cannot sell to your neighbours, who 
 are all farmers, but must carry all your produce to the city. The cost 
 of transportation will consume the bulk of your profit; and when 
 you get the goods to market you will find yourself undersold by the 
 man who lives a few miles outside the town. What is the remedy ? 
 Why, this : To make your market at your own doors, and keep it 
 when it's made. Agree to pay more than we pay now for woollens, 
 and so make it an object for some one to come here and start a 
 manufactory. Make the same agreement in respect of agricultural 
 machinery, furniture, and all farming and domestic implements, so 
 that you will have a town grow up in your midst, and a market at 
 your very doors. You needn't then depend on wheat, but can grow 
 vegetables and other perishable produce, while your wife will sell 
 eggs, and your children find employment in the factory."' 
 
 It is done. The mill is built : the town grows up. The 
 New England States become the home of manufacturers. 
 And the farmer what of him ? Strange to say, he sells his 
 homestead for less than cost, and flees to the wilds of Dakota. 
 Where is the mistake ? The theory is excellent ; why will it 
 not work ? It is the agreeing to pay ''just a little more " that 
 has done all the mischief If the farmers of this locality want 
 a woollen mill, those in that locality want a cotton mill, and 
 those in the next county an iron furnace, and so on. The 
 result is that the fanners everywhere pay ''a little more'''' for 
 everything they buy, until the cost of their living is increased 
 beyond any possible profit from an extended market. 
 
 The success of this argument is a remarkable instance of 
 what can be effected by using big words about simple matters. 
 Suppose that a Protectionist, instead of indulging in large 
 expressions about phrases such as a home market, the 
 development of industry, a concentrated population, and 
 
 I The writer is indebted for the form of this argument to a pamphlet by 
 Mr. Graham M'Adani on "The Protective System: what it costs the American 
 Farmer." (New York Free Trade Club, 1880.)
 
 The Political Argument. 295 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. iv 5 s.] 
 
 such-like, were to address a country audience in terms like 
 these : 
 
 " My friends, I am a poor man, but I am anxious to see you sell 
 all your products at a profit. I want nothing to be wasted because 
 of the cost of taking it to market. I propose to bring a market to 
 you by buying your stuff myself." 
 
 These sentiments should be received with cheers ; but let 
 the orator proceed : 
 
 " I propose to build myself a fine mansion on the most eligible 
 site in the country. This will give employment to stonecutters, 
 bricklayers, masons, carpenters, joiners, carters, upholsterers, and 
 many other kinds of tradesmen. I intend that all these men shall 
 do their work within the district. I mean that they shall all live 
 about here whilst they are engaged on my job ; and, as I intend 
 my mansion to be very large, I calculate that I shall have five 
 hundred men living here for the next ten years building it and putting 
 the grounds in order ; and when it is complete in all its adjuncts, I 
 expect to keep a staff of several hundred servants in the house and 
 about the grounds. Think what this means to you. All these men 
 and their families will want food, which you will supply. No more 
 fruit rotting on your trees, no more vegetables going to seed 
 because you can't afford to carry them to market ; you and your 
 wives and children will be busy for the rest of your lives in feeding 
 your own neighbours." 
 
 Again applause. The orator proceeds : 
 
 " But, as I said, I am a poor man. I cannot realise my patriotic 
 dreams without your aid. I am short in my necessary capital by 
 the sum of ten thousand pounds. You can have the privilege of 
 aiding in our national development by giving me this amount. I 
 do not ask for it all at once, but in trifling sums. Let each of you 
 give me a shilling a week for tlie rest of your lives, and I will get 
 to work at once at building my house and laying out its grounds. 
 None of you will feel the expense, and all of you will share in the 
 advantages." 
 
 If Protectionist speeches were made in these plain terms, 
 could any protestations of philanthropy disguise their naked 
 selfishness? And yet, instead of " mansion " read "factory,'' 
 and by the change of this one word we have a regular Protec- 
 tionist oration in favour of the home market.
 
 296 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 The argument, however it may be disguised, must ahvays 
 resolve itself into an appeal to the farmers to subsidise a 
 number of artisans to settle at the farm gate. " Pay them," 
 says the Protectionist, " for making goods at a loss, and out of 
 their profits they will purchase your abundance." A manu- 
 facturer who really believed in this argument would pension an 
 army of tramps to live beside his factory upon condition that 
 they spent their money in the purchase of his goods. The three 
 students of fable who hoped to earn a living by taking in each 
 other's washing were the earliest examples of a delusive faith 
 in a home market. The idea that a farmer, if he pays taxes to 
 bring into existence a factory which would not otherwise exist, 
 will win more than the taxes by selling farm produce to the 
 artisans, is, as Professor Sumner has tersely said, " an 
 arithmetical fallacy. It proposes to get three pints out of 
 a quart. The farmer is out for the tax and the farm produce, 
 and he cannot get back more than the tax, because, if the 
 factory owes its existence to the Protective taxes, it cannot 
 make any profit outside of the taxes. The proposition to the 
 farmer that he shall pay taxes to another man, who will bring 
 part of the tax back to buy produce with it : this is to 
 make the farmer rich. The man who owned slock in a 
 railroad, and who rode on it, paying his own fare, in the 
 hope of swelling his own dividends, was wise compared with 
 the farmer who believes that Protection can be a source of 
 gain to him." (" Protectionism," pp. 125-6.) 
 
 6. The latest form of this almost discredited home-market 
 argument is one which had a great vogue during the Presi- 
 dential campaign of 188S. Its author appears to be Mr. 
 Hoyt, who develops it from an American standpoint with great 
 assiduity.^ The argument is briefly this : 
 
 "Foreigners can only lake a certain amount of American pro- 
 ducts : /. ., food and raw materials. In return forthe^c, Americans 
 
 1 See pp. 193 and 199, an 1 Chapter XI.
 
 The Political Argument. 297 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. iv., \ 6.] 
 
 receive a certain quantity of foreign manufactures. But the American 
 demand for manufactured goods is far larger than the quantity 
 which is received from aljroad in return for American products. 
 Accordingly, unless the export of American products can be in- 
 creased, which ex-hypolhesi is impossible to any appreciable extent, 
 Americans must either go without a certain quantity of manufac- 
 tured goods or manufacture for themselves. Conclusion Encourage- 
 ment of manufactures by Protection is necessary." 
 
 The fallacy of this argunient which has been freely used 
 by Mr. Reed and Mr. Blaine lies in the assumption, first, 
 that the export of American products cannot be appreciably 
 increased ; and secondly, that if it cannot, manufactures will 
 not spring up without Protection. The first assumption is 
 probably true, if it is limited to the proposition that foreign 
 trade could not supply all the wants of a country like the 
 United States ; but the second has no foundation in fact. 
 Suppose it to l)e the case that the American demand for 
 manufactured goods is so vast that it cannot be satisfied by ex- 
 change, that fact is itself the strongest guarantee that home manu- 
 facturing will be profitable; because the greater the necessity 
 for manufactured goods, and the less the opportunity of getting 
 them, the better is the prospect for the manufacturer. Con.se- 
 quently, the very fact on which Protectionists rely to frighten 
 the farmers into accepting Protection namely, the fear that 
 w ithout Protection they will not be able to satisfy their require- 
 ments for manufactured articles is itself the best assurance 
 that Protection is unnecessary. 
 
 The argument, moreover, ignores another aspect of Protec- 
 tion which is being forcibly ol)truded upon the notice of 
 American manufacturers namely, the tendency of Protection 
 to destroy the foreign market by too much cultivation of 
 the home market. At tlie present time, the most serious 
 l)roblem before tlic manufacturers of the United States is how 
 to dispose of their manufactured goods. The home market 
 has been over-supplied for some years past, and yet, owing to 
 Protection, there is no outlet for their goods abroad. The last
 
 298 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 work of Mr. Wells " Practical Economics" the Congressional 
 speeches on the Mills tariff, and the collection of facts which 
 was published at the Conference of Free Traders held at 
 Chicago in 1888, contain abundant evidence of the truth of 
 this assertion, which is, indeed, not disputed by Protectionists. 
 It would lie beyond the scope of this work to multiply 
 instances. It is sufficient to refer to the words of Mr. Wells 
 upon this subject, which no one who has any knowledge 
 of current American literature is likely to dispute. 
 
 "No one," says Mr. Wells ("Practical Economics "p. 103), 
 " who has given the subject any attention, has any doubt that the 
 United States has, at present, more active capital, machinery, and 
 labour engaged in the so-called work of manufacturing, than is 
 necessary to supplyany present or immediate prospective demand for 
 increased consumption. And as general evidence confirmatory of 
 this position, citation may be made, first, of the general and in- 
 creasing complaint on the part of American manufacturers of over- 
 production. . . . Second, the interruption of great branches of 
 domestic industry, of which examples are to be found in the recent 
 suspension [written in 1883] of the entire business of cotton manufac- 
 ture in Philadelphia and vicinity ; of the discontinuance in all, or great 
 part, of the India-rubber and gunny-bagging manufacture ; of the 
 reduction of the sugar-refining industry to about 60 per cent, of its 
 existing capacity ; and the suspension or failure of some of the most 
 important iron-furnaces and rolling-mills of the country. And, 
 third, the actual or attempted reduction of wages in almost every 
 department of domestic manufacturing industry . the recent united 
 effort for this end of the representatives of all the i-on-works west 
 of the Alleghanies being especially noteworthy." 
 
 Mr. Wells might have added that the rapid growth of 
 trusts and combinations is further evidence in the same 
 direction. 
 
 In the meantime, while the enormous output of home 
 products is steadily increasing, there is an actual decline 
 even in the small proportion of home-made goods which the 
 tariff allows the Americans to send abroad. 
 
 The figures for the year ending June 30th, 1890, show that of 
 the total exports, valued at 845,293,000, only $151,293,000
 
 Th. Political Argument. 299 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. iv., \ 7.] 
 
 worth, or 17 "88 per cent., were of manufactured goods; while 
 the export of American manufactures in 1889 represented 
 18-99 psr cent, of the whole. Purely agricultural productions 
 gave but 72-87 per cent, of the export values in 1889 ; whereas 
 they gave 74-51 per cent, of the whole in 1890, and the ratio 
 of all natural productions increased from 81-01 to 82-12 per 
 cent.^ 
 
 7. The home-market argument fails at every turn. It 
 rests on a fallacious economic basis, and its political supports 
 are rotten. The foreign trade is not, from its nature, more 
 precarious than the home trade. The home demand does not 
 necessarily cause the land of a community to be put to more 
 profitable uses than a foreign demand would do. A home 
 market caused by Protection makes farmers pay more than 
 they receive ; while every variety of the argument ignores the 
 danger to manufactures of that glut in the home market which 
 is an inevitable consequence of a Protective tariff. 
 
 The theory, moreover, is in no instance borne out by facts. 
 Farmers do not, in fact, remain in the Eastern States, where, 
 according to the theory, they should find their market, but 
 emigrate to the West, and sell their products in Europe. 
 
 The theory is that the farmer will get a higher price by 
 selling his corn to the hands at a neighbouring factory. The 
 fact is that the farmer sells his produce at the price which 
 rules in Mark Lane ; and the neighbouring artisans will not 
 give him a penny more than the market rate for the sake of 
 neighbourliness. 
 
 The theory is that the demand of the home market keeps 
 up the prices of agricultural produce. The fact is that men 
 must eat, wherever they live ; and that it does not matter to 
 the farmer, who sells food, whether his customers live in 
 America or Europe. 
 
 ' In these calculations leather and lumber are included among manu- 
 factured products.
 
 300 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 The theory is that the farmer will gain an advantage by 
 being brought into direct relations with consumers, and so 
 save the cost of transportation. The fact is that farmers sell 
 their wheat to millers or produce merchants, and not direct to 
 artisans, whether the latter are neighbours or not. 
 
 The theory is that the farmer must be better off if there is 
 a home demand. The fact is, the farmer is best off when he 
 can sell his produce at the highest price, and buy what he 
 wants at the lowest. 
 
 The theory is that the American and Victorian farmer 
 ought to be exceptionally prosperous. The truth is that the 
 former is overwhelmed with debt, and the latter is emigrating 
 into New South Wales.^ 
 
 Whatever force the home -market argument has is owing to 
 union with other Protectionist arguments. Even when it is 
 stated by itself, it generally resolves itself, upon analysis, into 
 the statements that Protection causes a diversity of occupation, 
 and attracts population. In this meaning it may appeal to 
 farmers with a certain degree of force because every increase 
 of population, in whatever part of the world it occurs, may 
 become an a^/i.ntage to the producers of food. But, although 
 it may be admitted that Australian and American farmers are 
 likely to be benefited by the growth of towns, the questions 
 are still unanswered " Whether the towns would not grow up 
 as fast without Protection ?" and "Whether under Protection 
 the farmers, as a class, will not have to pay more in the form 
 of taxes than they receive back in the form of prices ? " 
 
 While the price of food all the world over is determined 
 by the ruling price in Mark Lane, the increased demand for 
 food of a few hundred thousand townsmen in Australia or 
 America will not make any appreciable difference in the price 
 
 1 An article in In-l/orJ's ALtgctzine, March, i83g, upon the state and 
 prospects of the American fanner, contains a mass of nsefiil information on 
 this subject. Current American Hterature is full of the grievances and distress 
 of- the farming population, who have to sell at London prices, and buy at 
 American.
 
 The Political Argument. 301 
 
 Pt. IV.,Ch. iv., ?7.] 
 
 of farm produce, unless either of these countries should sud- 
 denly cease to export agricultural products.^ In such a case 
 if Americans and Australians could only procure their food 
 over a tariff fence the farmer might, no doubt, raise his 
 prices, as English landlords raised rents in the days of the 
 Corn Laws ; but until the artisan and townsman consent to a 
 tax on food, farmers in a Protected country which exports 
 food can expect nothing else but low prices for the articles 
 they sell, and high prices for those they buy, No one will 
 find out sooner than the Protected farmer that the old English 
 proverb, "That the farmer pays for all," has a special signifi- 
 cance in a Protected country. 
 
 The writer of the paper on the " Decline of the Farmer," 
 which has been already referred to, shows the fate of the 
 farmer in every Protected country - when he thus summarises 
 the steps of the American farmer's decline : 
 
 " Captivated," he says, " by the promise of a home market 
 as the result of manufacturing development, which he was led 
 to believe would buy his products at highest price, and sell to 
 him in return at lowest, the American farmer departed from 
 the only true republican principle of strict equality in public 
 privileges and burdens. He consented to be taxed to a limited 
 extent for the encouragement of manufactures but only upon 
 the understanding that the arrangement was to be temporary : 
 only while the infant industries were struggling for a foothold. 
 The interest thus aided was then so weak and insignificant that 
 
 ' Victoria has been a grain-exporting country for many years ; while New 
 South Wales, owing to climatic disadvantages in the coastal districts, and the 
 remoteness of other wheat-growing lands, has to import about one-third of ht r 
 wheat supplies. The price of wheat in Melbourne is, on an average of many 
 years, sixpence a bushel less than the price in Sx-dney. Protectionists, observ- 
 ing this, tell a Sydney audience lh,!t Protection mcms cheap bread ; going 
 into the country, they tcU the farmers that Protection means dear wheat. 
 But how- cheap bread and dear wheat are to go together they have never 
 e.xp'.ained, 
 
 - See tb.e English Consular Reports on F<>rming in France and Italy for 
 any year from i83_;-;i.
 
 302 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 he never dreamt the day might come when it would dispute 
 his supremacy, and, taking him by the throat, demand as a 
 right what he had granted as a favour." 
 
 CHAPTER V. 
 
 THE PAUPER - LABOUR ARGUMENT. 
 
 I. The pauper-labour argument is the final refuge of all 
 Protectionist disputants, and tends to become relied upon 
 more and more as a justification of the permanent retention of 
 a Protective policy. Although it assumes a variety of forms, 
 its essence is always an assertion that the high rate of wages 
 which is characteristic of young countries cannot be main- 
 tained unless both labourers and capitalists are protected 
 against the competition of pauper labour and cheap capital. 
 
 " The claim is set up in warrant and justification of a 
 continued high-tariff policy, that the difference of wages in 
 favour of competitive foreign productions constitutes a good 
 and sufficient reason why compensating Protective duties 
 should be levied on their resulting products when imported 
 into this country ; and the assertion is further constantly and 
 conjointly made that unless such duties continue to be levied, 
 the American manufacturer will be unable to withstand foreign 
 competition : that our workshops and factories will be closed, 
 and our workmen and their families made dependent on public 
 charities."! 
 
 Such an argument as this is really the basis of every so- 
 called scientific treatise, such as Professor Patten's, of the 
 Wharton Scliool of Pxonoyiics, in favour of Protective tarifls ; 
 and, from its place in the historic system of Protectionist 
 arguments, may be taken as the last word which the advocates 
 
 1 lion. Davil A. Wells, "Practical Economics" (p. 132).
 
 The Political Argument. 303 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. v.. I I.] 
 
 of a restricted commerce are able to advance. It becomes 
 therefore, of the utmost importance to examine this argument 
 fully, both by reference to facts and theory. 
 
 First, however, as usual, careful disputants must verify 
 their facts. They must ascertain three things : 
 
 1. What difference in fact exists between the rates of wages 
 
 paid in the trade, which it is proposed to Protect, by 
 the native and the foreign producers ? 
 
 2. To what extent does this difference in the wage-rate 
 
 affect the relative costs of production ? 
 
 3. What evidence is there that the imposition of a Pro- 
 
 tective duty will prevent the rates of wages in the two 
 countries in question from assimilating ? 
 
 These facts, once ascertained and until they are ascer- 
 tained no argument is possible the last question, which has 
 always to be answered in the fiscal controversy, still remains 
 for consideration : viz.. Whether Protection may not be too 
 high a price to pay for the preservation of the industries in 
 question? This, however, can only be answered by a con- 
 sideration of matters which properly belong to a later chapter. 
 
 It would be beyond the scope of this work to examine the 
 fiicts of any country, or any particular trade, in order to see 
 whether the pauper-labour argument can justly be applied to 
 its conditions. All that can be done here is to indicate the 
 line of investigation, and to suggest certain general considera- 
 tions whicli must be taken into account. It will not, however, 
 be out of place to refer, in a general way, to the answers which 
 other inquiries in this field have obtained to the questions 
 which have already been suggested, and to mention those 
 which a student of economics would expect to obtain if the 
 working of economic principles were not disturbed 1)y local 
 causes. Let us first, then, examine into the nature of this 
 in(iuiry as to what difference does in fact exist between the 
 rates of wages paid in a young and an old community.
 
 304 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 2. No statistical information is more difficult to obtain 
 than accurate statements of the rates of wages, and no statis- 
 tics are more misleading or useless than so-called averages of 
 wage-rates. 
 
 Even when' the sources of information about wages are 
 above suspicion, wage-rates admit of so many qualifications 
 that it is difficult to use them for purposes of comparison. Ten 
 shillings in one country may not go so far as eight shillings in 
 another ; while in some mills workmen have advantages in 
 house-rent or allowances which are denied to others. 
 
 Any money-rate of daily or weekly wages must therefore of 
 necessity be misleading, unless we know : (i) the number of 
 days worked, (2) the cost of living in the district, (3) whether 
 the \> or!- nen have any special allowances in lieu of wages. 
 
 And finally, even when all this is known, it is quite useless 
 for controversial purposes to attempt to arrive at any average 
 rate of wages for a given country. 
 
 Even in a small country like England, wages in the same 
 industry differ by as much as thirty per cent, in different 
 localities. This is especially the case with agricultural labour ; 
 but the same holds true, in a less degree, of the wages in other 
 industries. In the United States the rates vary more or less 
 in every State ; and the wages in the West are sometimes 
 double those paid to the same class of workmen in the Eastern 
 States. For these reasons, as Mr. Wright, the chief of the 
 Labour Bureau, has often pointed out, it is idle to speak of an 
 "American rate of wages." There is one rate for New York, 
 and one for Pennsylvania, and a third for California ; but to 
 strike an average between all the States would give a rate 
 which no class of workmen ever receive, and which would 1)C 
 useless for any purposes of comparison. 
 
 Another reason why averages must be misleading is that 
 in all old countries the " residuum,"' as Mr. Bright called 
 them the class, that is, of hereditary paupers and hopeless 
 ne"er-do weels is much larger than in a young communit}-.
 
 Tjie Political Argument. 305 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. v., \ 2.] 
 
 But any average of national wages would have to take into 
 account the starvation rates paid to people of this class, with 
 the result of unfairly lowering the rewards of manufacturing 
 labour. 
 
 When, therefore, artisans and manufacturers in a young 
 country ask to be "protected" against the pauper labour of 
 more settled communities, they must, if their request is to 
 receive attention, ignore averages, and confine their compari- 
 son to specified industries. This warning will seem super- 
 fluous to those who have not lived in the midst of Protectionist 
 controversies nor read Protectionist speeches ; but hardly a 
 week passes in Australia or America where the wages of 
 London dockers are not the theme of some Protectionist 
 oration. It ought, however, to be self-evident that a com- 
 parison between the wages paid to the lowest class of unskilled 
 labour in London and those paid to skilled Australian artisans 
 is a comparison between two subjects of a diff'erent class. 
 Take, for instance, the iron trade. New South Wales Pro- 
 tectionists constantly aftirm that the difficulty in the iron trade 
 in that colony is owing to the high rate of wages. This 
 assertion may or may not be true ; but it is idle to use as 
 evidence in its support comparisons between the pay of 
 Sydney artisans and London dockers. 
 
 Nor is it a sufficient answer to these considerations to 
 reply that the existence of a residuum of low-paid wage- 
 earners reduces the wage of skilled artisans. Within certain 
 limits this statement is true. The reserve army of labour 
 may destroy the success of a strike for higher wages, as was 
 recently the case in Australia ; but as a rule, the underpaid 
 starveling has neither the physique nor the intelligence to come 
 into competition with workmen of higher grades. It is thus 
 unfair to argue that the lowest rate of wage in a country is 
 tlie determinant of its ability to compete with a country of 
 a higlicr rate. The comparison should be made in every 
 case between the wages paid in the two countries to the 
 u
 
 3o6 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 workmen of the particular trade for which Protective duties are 
 demanded. 
 
 Mr. Edwin Chadwick, in a passage quoted by Mr. Wells 
 in the work already referred to (p. 138), illustrates this view 
 by the following interesting example from his own ex- 
 perience : 
 
 " In Nottingham," he says, " the introduction of more 
 costly and complex machines for the manufacture of lace has, 
 while economising labour, augmented wages to the extent of 
 100 per cent. I asked a manufacturer of lace whether this 
 large machine could not be worked at the common lower 
 wages by any of the workers of the old machine ? ' Yes, it 
 might,' was the answer; 'but the capital invested on the new 
 machinery is very large, and if from drunkenness or misconduct 
 anything happened to the machine, the consequence would be 
 very serious.' Instead of taking any man out of the street, as 
 might be done with the low-priced machine, he (the em- 
 ployer) found it necessary to go abroad and look for one 
 of better condition, and for such a one higher wages must be 
 given." 
 
 When industrial activity is highly developed, employers 
 cannot afford to pay low wages. 
 
 3. It will be plain, from the foregoing observations, 
 that any statements of comparative wages ought to be received 
 with caution ; so that the first duty of a person dealing with 
 an argument which rests upon a difference in the rate of wages 
 in two countries is to verify the facts, and then confine the 
 comparison to the specific trades which are supposed to com- 
 pete with each other. This method, however, is impossible 
 in the present treatise ; and therefore, in order to carry the 
 argument further, we must make the admission that, although 
 the difference between Australian or American wages and 
 those of Great Britain is probably greatly exaggerated by 
 Protectionists, the wages of unskilled labour in a young
 
 The Political Argument. ^oy 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. v., ? 3.] 
 
 country are higher than the wages paid to the same class in 
 England. 
 
 We may admit, further, that the investigations of Mr. 
 Wright, chief of the Washington Labour Bureau, show almost 
 conclusively that both the nominal and the real rates of 
 wages in the chief manufacturing industries of Massachusetts 
 are higher than those of the same industries in Great Britain. 
 
 On the other hand, the wages of miners in Pennsylvania 
 are probably not as high as those of miners in Durham or 
 Northumberland, and are much lower than those paid in New 
 South Wales. 
 
 Still, however, it may fairly be assumed, as a basis for 
 discussion of the pauper-labour argument, that wages are 
 higher in a young country than they are in Europe. The 
 difference is greatest on the lowest grade of manual labour, 
 and lessens as the labour rises in the scale. As to skilled 
 labour, personal inquiries from both masters and men have 
 satisfied the writer that the highest grades of this class are less 
 well paid, even in money wages, in Australia than they are in 
 England. 
 
 The same is probably true of America,^ if we may draw 
 an inference from the statistics of immigration, which show 
 that the number of " skilled labourers" who come as immi- 
 grants is comparatively small. But the bulk of the labour 
 employed in manufactures is unskilled. The question, there- 
 fore, is Does the higher reward of this class prevent the 
 establishment of manufactures in a young community ? The 
 answer to this question will depend- upon the number of 
 manufactures which are exposed to foreign competition, and 
 the proportion borne in these by the cost of labour to the 
 price of goods. 
 
 ' Mr. Wells, writing in 1888, mentions that artisans imported into America 
 from foreign countries to work in certain employments (^..i'. , glass-making) 
 wore returning to I'.uropc with a view of bettering their co;ul'tion, (" Practical 
 Economics," p. 140.) Sec also above, p, 215.
 
 3o8 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 4. It has been estimated by Mr. Wells that of all the 
 manufactures in America not more than twenty per cent., and, 
 perhaps, not more than ten per cent., can ever be exposed to 
 foreign competition. Probably the number of Victorian in- 
 dustries which are able to stand alone bears a less proportion 
 to the whole ; but in every country there will be a certain 
 number of industries which, from advantages of climate, means 
 of communication, or acquired industrial skill, are in no 
 danger from foreign competition. These industries can, there- 
 fore, be left out of account in the discussion. The real matter 
 of importance is as to the industries which would not be able 
 to withstand foreign competition except by reducing wages. 
 Let us proceed to inquire what kind of industries these are 
 likely to be. 
 
 5. The fundamental assumption of those who use the 
 pauper-labour argument is that the price of goods depends 
 upon the rate of wages. It is not too much to say that this 
 theory is wholly incorrect. The price of goods depends not 
 upon the rate of wages, but upon the " cost of labour," which 
 is a very different thing. 
 
 Thus, Mr. Donnell, in his pamphlet, contributed to the 
 "Questions of the Day" series (Putnam, 1884), p. 54, says : 
 " It is a great mistake, though a common one, to suppose 
 that the highest-priced labourer is the dearest. High-priced 
 wages are the cheapest. ... I am satisfied by personal 
 observation and diligent inquiry that American labour esti- 
 mated in productiveness that is, the work accomplished in 
 proportion to wages paid is the cheapest in the world." 
 
 Mr. Edward Atkinson, of Boston, in his work, " The 
 Distribution of Products," after a careful investigation of the 
 cost of production in many industries, has laid it down as a 
 law " that a high rate of wages means a low cost of product, 
 and a low rate of wages means a high cost of product." Mr. 
 Prasscy, the famous contractor, said the same thing in another
 
 The Political Argument. 309 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. v., ? s.] 
 
 form when he stated that he found it cheaper to employ the 
 high-waged Enghsh navvy in preference to any number of low- 
 waged Germans and Asiatics. 
 
 The important matter, therefore, in considering whether 
 a particular industry requires Protection on account of the 
 higher rate of local wages, is not so much a knowledge of the 
 difference in money, or even in real wages, between the two 
 countries in question, but to ascertain the difference in labour- 
 cost. And the probability, which is almost a certainty, is that 
 high wages, instead of being evidence of a high cost of pro- 
 duction, are, on the contrary, direct evidence of a low cost of 
 production, and therefore, as Mr. Wells says, "in place of 
 being an argument in favour of the necessity of Protection, 
 they are a demonstration that none is needed." It would 
 unduly extend this work even to summarise the evidence on 
 which these statements rest. For further information the 
 reader is referred to Mr. Edward Atkinson's two works, 
 "The Distribution of Products," and "The Industrial Pro- 
 gress of the Nation" (New York and London, 1890).!^ 
 
 The question is thus narrowed to a comparison not of the 
 rates of wages in the competing countries, but of the pro- 
 portion which these bear in each case to the respective costs 
 of production. In otlier words, we have to deal not with 
 rates of wages, but with labour-cost. We are thus led to two 
 practical conclusions : 
 
 ' Mr. riirsch, in his pamphlet entitled " Protection in Victoria," which is 
 more fully referred to in tlie Appendix, makes the following sound observations 
 on this part of the question : "A comparatively high rate of wages is one of 
 the most important, if not the most important factor in reducing cost of pro- 
 duction, not only by forcing into use labour-saving machinery, which at a 
 lower r.ite of wages could not | ermit of a saving in wages, but also by tlic 
 greater intelligiMice and vigour of the woikmen, which high wages produce. 
 C'onscfiuenily, we find a nation's jxjwer in the markets of the world to be some- 
 what in accordance with the rate of wages to which its workers are accustomed. 
 Cluna, India, Mexico, export no manufactures, Russia least of all ICuropean 
 rations, Italv and Spain rank next, Austria stands by itself, (Germany and 
 France follow, and Great Britain stands at the apex ofinduUii.il power" (ji. 9).
 
 3 TO Industrial Freedom. 
 
 T. That Protectionists cannot establish even the appearance 
 of a rightful claim to any duty until they have proved that 
 the labour-cost of producing the article which it is proposed 
 to Protect is so much greater in the young community than it 
 is in other countries that its manufacture in the community 
 cannot be profitably carried on. 
 
 2. That when it can be proved that the production of 
 any article is prevented by differences between its labour- 
 cost in a young community and its labour-cost in Europe, then 
 a duty equivalent to the labour-cost, less the cost of importing 
 the article from Europe, might cause the establishment of a 
 manufactory of that article in the young community. 
 
 3. Consequently, if the labour-cost of producing any 
 article is lower in Europe than it is in America or Australia, 
 it must be for one of two reasons: Either (i) the European 
 labourer is more efficient on account of his greater intelligence 
 or on account of the greater assistance he derives from Nature 
 or machinery ; or (2) the article is one which is made entirely 
 by either unskilled manual labour, or by manual labour 
 assisted by only cheap and simple mechanical appliances. In 
 either case the difference in labour-cost affords no argument 
 for Protection. 
 
 6. The labour-cost of a finished article by which is 
 meant the proportion which the cost of labour bears to the 
 cost of the whole depends on two things : namely, (i) the 
 intelligence and ability of the human labourer; (2) the 
 amount of assistance he receives from Nature or machinery. 
 
 Pjut the average of education and intelligence is un- 
 doubtedly higher both in America and Australia than it is 
 in Great Britain or Europe. In this respect, therefore, the 
 advantage is on the side of the young community. Of the 
 amount of assistance received by cither country from natural 
 causes, or from the use of machinery, nothing can be pre- 
 dicate ^ There is, however, no a priori reason why this
 
 The Political Argument. 311 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. v., ? 6.] 
 
 assistance should be less in a young community than it is in 
 England. 
 
 In the first case, as we have seen, the European superiority 
 is very unlikely to be due to the superior intelligence of 
 the workmen or their better tools ; and must, therefore, be 
 attributed to the superior natural advantages of climate, soil, 
 or situation by which his labour is assisted. But if Protection 
 is demanded as a compensation for the want of natural 
 advantages, this is a clear admission that Protection is in- 
 tended to cause a waste of labour by making men in one 
 country do for themselves what Nature has done for them 
 elsewhere. 
 
 The competitor whose ravages the tariff is designed to 
 check is not, strictly speaking, " foreign labour," but the 
 natural advantages which foreign labour enjoys, and which, 
 under Free Trade, it would share with the world. Hence 
 follow all those extravagances which Bastiat was fond of 
 turning into ridicule, and which Protectionists always declare to 
 be irrelevant, by the contention that they only desire to Protect 
 industries which can be naturalised in the Protected country. 
 
 But it must be remembered that the argument now 
 under consideration is an argument in favour of Protection as 
 a permanent, and not as a temporary policy. If, therefore, any 
 industry demands Protection because its article is produced 
 abroad at a less labour-cost than that at which it would be pos- 
 sible to produce it at home ; and if it appear that the difference 
 in labour-cost is due to the possession by foreign labour of 
 superior natural advantages, the case becomes one in which 
 Protection can only be justified by the same arguments which 
 justified Bastiat's petition of the candle-makers against the 
 competition of the sun. If the difference in labour-cost is 
 due to the superiority of the foreign mechanical appliances, 
 the case is obviously equally unfit for permanent Protection, 
 because the same result could be obtained by the adoption in 
 the home ccruntry of the same appliances.
 
 312 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 There remains the case in which the difference in labour- 
 cost is due to the nature of the product being such that it is 
 the result of unaided manual labour, or of manual labour only 
 slightly aided by mechanical appliances. In such a case it is 
 plain that the labour-cost and the amount of money spent in 
 wages will very closely correspond. Accordingly, if the in- 
 dustry is one which does not admit of a high degree of skill, so 
 that one skilled workman at a high wage could not do the work 
 of several unskilled workmen at a low wage, the rate of wages 
 will be a fair test of the labour-cost of production ; and a 
 country of high wages will not be able to compete in this 
 particular line with a country of low wages. To this extent, 
 then, the Pauper-Labour argument may justify Protection in a 
 theoretical discussion. 
 
 The next question is, whether the common facts of in- 
 dustrial life give any ground for the belief that this theoretical 
 justification of Protection can have any but the narrowest 
 application ? To decide this, we must inquire what the in- 
 dustries are which owe their lower labour-cost to a lower rate 
 of wages. Manifestly, as we have seen, they are handicrafts, 
 such as the making of common pottery, where, as Mr. Wells 
 remarks, "the labourer works almost exactly as did his pre- 
 decessor 4,000 years ago." In such industries the moral and 
 physical standard of the labourer is necessarily at its lowest. 
 The trades are such as can be learnt by any one ; they require 
 neither skill, training, nor continuous effort, and they are 
 carried on for the most part under unhealthy conditions. Is 
 there really any need to establish industries such as these in a 
 young country? The question is purely political. Ought a 
 politician to encourage trades which will inevitably collect the 
 driftwood of society, and render possible in a new country the 
 worst abuses in the industrial history of the old world ? Should 
 it not rather be the aim to direct the labour of a young 
 community into channels where intelligence, skill, training, and 
 patience may enable every individual to satisfy the better
 
 The Political Argument. 313 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. v., \ 6.] 
 
 instincts of his nature ? Is it wise to offer to the lazy and 
 unthrifty the chance of making a bare Hving in a degrading 
 form of occupation ? Will not the existence of such a class of 
 workmen tend in time to drag the labourers of other classes 
 down to its own level ? 
 
 Suppose, however, that the Protectionist politician is ob- 
 durate, and passes by these questions without reply, still there 
 remains the consideration : What shall be done with these 
 workmen when they have supplied the home market ? Mani- 
 festly, their products cannot be exported, because, ex hypotkesi, 
 they cannot be produced at the same cost in the Protected 
 country as is possible abroad, unless the wages of the former 
 are reduced, which, according to Protectionists, Protection will 
 prevent. The consequence will be that a yearly increasing 
 number of unskilled labourers will join the army of the tramps 
 and unemployed. No other alternative will open to these 
 unfortunate persons, because the very nature of their former 
 employment will have destroyed their industrial aptitude. 
 Well may David Wells ask, " Why, in the name of common 
 sense, America, as a nation, should enter into competition 
 with these low-waged countries ?" " What possible reason," he 
 asks, " or inducement is there for wanting to introduce these 
 handicraft industries into this country, and of attempting to 
 keep men alive by means of enormous taxes levied under the 
 tariff upon the whole people, when we can buy all we want of 
 these products with a very small part of the excess of our 
 cotton and grain ?" 
 
 Finally, it must be remembered that the number of these 
 handicrafts is decreasing every year, as science, the great 
 leveller, elevates wages by increasing the efficiency of the 
 labourer. It follows that the force of the pauper-labour 
 argument, even in tlie one case where it. has a theoretic 
 validity, is constantly diminishing before tlic ap|)!ication to 
 industry of new mechanical appliances; and it is not a long 
 I)eriod to anticipate when the lowest and commonest forms of
 
 314 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 manual toil will have been rendered entirely unnecessary, and 
 men in all countries and of all classes will have the leisure and 
 the opportunity to train their intelligence and satisfy their 
 instincts in higher forms of industrial activity. 
 
 Summing up, then, the results of this discussion, we may 
 say First, That the pauper-labour argument, although it has a 
 certain theoretic validity, can seldom be applied in practice, 
 because the circumstances on which its assumptions rest 
 seldom co-exist ; Secondly, That even in the few cases in 
 which its application might be justified, the result of applying 
 it is both politically and economically harmful to the interests 
 of a young country ; Thirdly, That the argument must gradu- 
 ally lose what little force it ever possessed, as science lessens 
 the number of unskilled handicrafts. 
 
 7. But we have not yet done with the practical objections 
 to this argument. Any attempt to apply it not only reveals a 
 fatal inconsistency between its assumptions and its promises, but 
 carries the politician along a path of inextricable entanglement. 
 
 The theory of the argument, as we recall it, is that 
 manufacturers in a young community are prevented from 
 competing with their European rivals, on account of the high 
 local rates of wages. 
 
 Now, if high local wages are really an obstacle to manu- 
 factures, that can only be because they cause the prices of the 
 manufactured articles to be too high to find a market in the 
 face of open competition. In other words, the argument is 
 that high wages cause high prices. 
 
 But the constant assertion of Protectionists is that Pro- 
 tection will cause lower prices. How, if that be true, can 
 Protection secure higher wages? If wages and prices depend 
 on one another, as Protectionists assert, the same policy 
 cannot at one and the same time make wages high and prices 
 low. So nuicli for an inconsistency in theory ; now for a 
 difliculty in practice !
 
 The Political Argument. 315 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. v., ? 9 ] 
 
 8. If it be true that the ability of manufacturers to 
 compete with one another depends upon the rates of wages 
 which they respectively pay to their\vorkmen^ then it is evident 
 that any duties which are levied for the purpose of equalising 
 wages must vary according to the variations in the wages rates 
 of different countries. 
 
 If, for example, wages in any industry are 10 per cent. 
 higher in Australia than in England, a duty of 10 per cent, 
 will be more than sufficient to equalise the terms of competi- 
 tion ; but if wages in the same industry are 10 per cent, lower 
 in Germany than they are in England, the Protectionists ought 
 to impose two equalising duties namely, one of 10 per cent, 
 on English goods, and one of 20 per cent, on those which 
 come from Germany. And as the wages of any specified 
 industry differ in nearly all countries, the same article ought to 
 be exposed to many duties. Nor is this all. The duties 
 ought to be constantly revised, so as to adapt them to any 
 changes in the rates of wages which may occur in the foreign 
 competing countries. 
 
 It is difficult to see how any person who sincerely believes 
 and many profess to believe it that Protective duties are only 
 required to compensate the manufacturer for higher local 
 wages, can deny the force of the above reasoning. Such persons 
 indignantly repudiate any desire to give a manufacturer special 
 favours ; but it is obvious that a fixed duty, which is estimated 
 on the wages paid in a particular industry, say in India, will be 
 considerably more than is required to compensate him for the 
 difference between the local rate which he pays and the English 
 rate. He will therefore have the sole benefit of the duty on 
 all English goods up to the amount of the difference between 
 English and Indian wages, and Protection will be a clear 
 privilege to him by that amount. 
 
 But this is not the end of the entanglement. 
 
 9. The countries whose competition is most dangerous to
 
 3i6 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 a young community are precisely the countries of high wages. 
 Of the total imports into New South Wales from countries 
 beyond the sea for the year 1889, four-fifths were the products 
 of Great Britain and America. It is the same with the United 
 States. Her great commercial rival is not Germany or India, 
 but again Great Britain. 
 
 Now, whatever ill-will Protectionists may bear Great Britain 
 and Protection is openly recommended to the Irish voters 
 in America as a means of damaging British trade no one is 
 likely to dispute that manufacturing wages are higher in 
 that country than in any other part of Europe. The low- 
 waged countries, which Protectionists term the countries 
 of pauper labour, are not England, Switzerland, Holland, or 
 Norway these are the countries of industrial freedom, as 
 they are the countries of political and religious freedom but 
 soldier-ridden and Protected Germany, and harassed and 
 Protected France. How is it possible to admit this fact, and 
 yet maintain that high local wages are an impediment to local 
 manufactures unless foreign competition is forbidden ? 
 
 But the most disingenuous use of the pauper-labour argu- 
 ment is in New South Wales. In that colony the voters of the 
 cities and centres of population are Free Traders by a large 
 majority. The bulk of the farmers, on the other hand, are 
 Protectionists. The immediate causes of this are agricultural 
 distress and a bitter feeling of resentment against the border 
 duties levied by Victoria. The remoter ' cause is not im- 
 probably the premature settling of the lands by a too-scattered 
 population. But, whatever the cause of this Protectionist 
 feeling among the farmers, they, of all people, could not justify 
 it by the fear that their industry should be exposed to the 
 competition of jjaupers. 
 
 The only competitors of the New South ^Vales farmers are 
 tlie farmers of Victoria, South Australia, and New Zealand. For 
 a Protectionist orator to use the pauper -labour argument in such 
 a case, to justify the farmers in their present mistaken view of
 
 The Political ArguaMent. 317 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. v., 5 lo.] 
 
 their own interests, is either a wilful attempt at deceit, or an 
 assertion ihat the farmers in the Protected colonies are paupers, 
 whose chief products ought not to be admitted into New 
 South Wales, because wages in those Protected lands are at 
 "starvation rates." Protectionists must take their choice of 
 the alternative. 
 
 10. We are now in a position to finish off the pauper- 
 labour argument by considering the true causes of those high 
 wages which are declared to be the obstacle to manufacturing 
 growth in a young country. Wages being in their ultimate 
 analysis the labourer's share of the article produced, it is plain 
 that every increase in the efficiency of the labourer tends to 
 increase the quantity of that from which he must receive his 
 share. To ensure that the labourer's share shall be that to 
 which he is fairly entitled is one of the functions of trade- 
 unions ; but it is plain that his share cannot be lessened 
 by an increase in the quantity to be divided if everything else 
 remains the same. 
 
 Now, the efficiency of labour depends, as we have seen, 
 not only upon human ability to produce, but also upon the 
 amount of assistance received from Nature. Natural advan- 
 tages of climate, fertility, situation, and such-like, are free gifts 
 to man. The more of these a workman can gain, the less 
 expenditure of effort he requires to i)roduce a given result. 
 Nature does for him what men in less favoured situations have 
 to do for themselves. 
 
 But the characteristic of young countries is the possession 
 in exceptional abundance of one or more great natural advan- 
 tages. Labour is therefore exceedingly productive when it is 
 employed on any of these natural industries. Ten men, for 
 example, can raise more wool in Australia than could be raised 
 by twice that number in Great Britain. Thus, although the 
 wages of station hands are three and four times the wages 
 paid by luiglisli shccp-owncrs to their labourers, Australian
 
 3i8 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 wool competes successfully with that of England. Here is a 
 plain case in which higher wages are no bar to successful 
 competition. It is the same in all extractive industries which 
 are followed in a young country. The labourer is able to 
 appropriate a natural instrument of production for his own 
 advantage. 
 
 The question is, "How long will this advantage continue?" 
 To this the reply must be, " So long as Nature continues to be 
 bountiful, or so long as man continues by the ingenuity of his 
 hand and brain to make up for deficiency in Nature's gifts." 
 When work becomes less efficient, wages may fall ; but while 
 young countries enjoy their peculiar superiority in certain 
 dominating industries, the prevailing rates of wages will con- 
 tinue high. Or, to express the same thing in the words of the 
 market-place : " Men won't take less as artisans than they can 
 get as labourers." 
 
 Webster, in a stirring passage, has expressed the same idea. 
 " The chairman," he says, " says it would cost the nation 
 nothing as a nation to make our ore into iron. Now, I think it 
 would cost us precisely that which we can worst afford : that is, 
 great labour. . . . We have been asked ... in a tone 
 of some pathos, whether we will allow to the serfs of Russia 
 and Sweden the benefit of making our iron for us. Let me 
 inform the gentlemen that those same serfs do not earn more 
 than seven cents a day. . . . And let me ask the gentle- 
 man further, whether we have any labour in this country that 
 cannot be better employed than in a business which does not 
 yield the labourer more than seven cents a day ? . . . The 
 true reason why it is not our policy to compel our citizens 
 to manufacture our own iron is that they are far better em- 
 ployed. It is an unproductive business, and they are not poor 
 enough to be compelled to follow it. If we had more of 
 poverty, more of misery, and something of servitude ; if we 
 had an ignorant, idle, starving population, we might set up for 
 iron-makers against the world. . . . Multitudes of persons
 
 The Political Argument. 319 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. v., ? II.] 
 
 are willing to labour in the production of this article for us at 
 the rate of seven cents a day, while we have no labour which 
 will not command, upon the average, at least five or six times 
 that amount. The question is, then, shall we buy this article of 
 these manufacturers and suffer our own labour to earn its greater 
 reward ; or, shall we employ our own labour in a similar 
 manufacture, and make up to it, by a tax on consumers, the 
 loss which it must necessarily sustain ? " 
 
 11. If the preceding extracts and observations contain a 
 true view of the theory of wages, it is evident that wages will 
 continue to be high in a young country so long as the natural 
 extractive industries continue their exceptional productiveness. 
 
 Now, the productiveness of an industry or, what is the 
 same thing, the efficiency of the labour employed in it 
 depends to a considerable extent upon the obstacles which 
 labour has to overcome. The fewer these are, the more will 
 be produced by an equal effort. 
 
 But the object and effect of Protective duties is to create 
 obstacles where none existed. They are expressly designed 
 to prevent men making use of the free gifts which Nature has 
 bestowed on foreign countries. They thus constitute new and 
 artificial obstacles which labour has to overcome. If these 
 duties affect any of the instruments used in the extractive in- 
 dustries and it is hard to conceive of any Protective duties 
 which will not affect the farmer and the miner in his tools 
 or wants they are, clearly, an encumbrance on their natural 
 productiveness, and by that amount they lessen the efficiency 
 of labour. 
 
 But by lessening the efficiency of the labour employed in 
 the extractive industries, Protective duties lower the standard 
 of wages for the whole country. The standard of wages is 
 fixed by the profitableness of the dominating industries. These 
 require little skill, and are open to every one of a strong body. 
 Naturally, therefore, a man who has the chance of commanding
 
 320' Industrial Freedom, 
 
 a certain rate in an industry of this kind will not accept much 
 below it in any other. 
 
 It is not meant that every carpenter or joiner, if he cannot 
 get the current wages, will at once turn farmer. That would 
 be a grotesque misrepresentation of the argument. What is 
 contended for is the obvious truism that when, owing to the 
 natural superiority of a country in climate, soil, or mineral 
 wealth, unskilled labour can obtain a high reward, the 
 probability (which over a large number of men becomes a 
 certainty) is that the ruling rate for other kinds of labour will 
 be at least equal to that which prevails in the extractive 
 industries. If this be correct and it can hardly be denied the 
 extractive industries set a certain standard of wages, which will 
 not be reduced until these industries become less profitable. 
 
 12. The chief charge, therefore, against Protection, from 
 the view of tlie wage-earner, is that by making the extractive 
 industries less profitable it hastens a decline in wages 
 generally. 
 
 Nor is this the only way in which Protection operates in- 
 juriously on wages. 
 
 High wages depend not only on the cfiiciency of labour, 
 but on the number of labourers. " When two masters are 
 running after one man, wages rise ; when two men are running 
 after one master, wages fall," is a saying attributed to George 
 Ste))henson. But, whoever may be the author, the saying 
 expresses a portion of the truth which must not be over- 
 looked. 
 
 In most young countries the development of the natural 
 resources is still incomplete, so that every labourer who can 
 turn his hand to one of the extractive industries causes an 
 increase in the national productiveness. He does not displace 
 another workman, but himself adds by his labours to the store 
 from which all workmen are emjiloyed. Consecpently, there is 
 no fear at present of Australian or American wages being
 
 The Political ArgumMnT\ 321 
 
 tt. IV., Ch. v., 5 12.] 
 
 forced down by the competition of immigrants belonging to 
 the classes who will find employment on the soil or in other of 
 the extractive industries. Australia, indeed, is suffering from 
 an insufficiency in the supply of labour for these pursuits. She 
 could employ double the number of men in the extractive 
 industries ; and since every man would produce a far greater 
 value than he could consume, the rate of wages would not fall.^ 
 Competition, where labour is properly organised, only reduces 
 wages when the industry, for employment in which the labourers 
 are competing, has reached the limits of its productiveness. That 
 point is yet far distant in Australia and America. As was ob- 
 served in the course of the debate on the Mills' tariff proposals 
 in the American Piouse of Representatives in 188S: "Not until 
 the sixty millions of Americans become six hundred millions 
 will men crowd each other in the United States in the fierce 
 struggle for existence and wealth, as they do in Great Britain 
 to-day." When that time comes unless, as indeed will 
 probably be the case, if we may judge from past experience, 
 the instruments of production should enormously improve in 
 power wages will have fallen to the European rate. But 
 we may leave the incidents of that far-off time to speculative 
 dreamers. 
 
 But although the increase in the number of extractive 
 labourers in a young country is not likely to lower wages, 
 the effect of an increase of manufacturing labourers is entirely 
 different. 
 
 The market for manufactured goods in any young com- 
 munity must be smaller than the market for its raw produce. 
 The former is limited by the confines of the colony the 
 other is the world. Consec^uently, over-production of manu- 
 factured goods will be an early result of a Protective tariff. 
 
 ' This is, of course, on the assuinplion, which ouglit always to be made in 
 dealing with questions of wages, that trades unions exist in tlie country. If 
 there were no unions, advantage might be taken of local congestions of labour, 
 or of the ignorance of new-comers, to lower the rati.'s.
 
 322 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 Twenty years have been sufficient to supply the market of 
 Victoria, even althougli for the greater part of that time the 
 markets of the other colonies have been open to Victorian 
 produce. If New South Wales, where Victorians now find a 
 market for their surplus, were to adopt a Protective tariff and 
 should she take this fatal step, it will in no small degree be 
 owing to a just resentment against the provincial spirit of her 
 Southern neighbour many Victorian manufactories would run 
 half-time. 
 
 The effect of over-production of manufactures upon the 
 general rate of wages is easily understood. 
 
 The artisans, unable to find employment in their own 
 trades, flock to the extractive industries. These, being already 
 burdened with the Protective duties, do not respond with 
 elasticity to the new demand. Nor do the labourers them- 
 selves generally possess the training or physique which fit them 
 for these pursuits. They do, however^ form a large and 
 gradually increasing body of floating unorganised labour, 
 which always presses on the outskirts of trades unionism, and 
 offers to employers an encouragement to resist its just 
 demands. 
 
 Nor is this danger to the interests of organised labour 
 always left to its natural growth. The contrary is indeed the 
 case. The experience of America and Victoria shows that 
 Protected manufacturers most frequently import their labour. 
 
 The wage-earner is thus oppressed by Protection on every 
 side. The aid of Nature to his efforts has been lessened : the 
 purchasing power of his wages has been diminished : and the 
 number of his competitors has been increased. His old 
 prosperity is destroyed by the very means which he adopted 
 to peri)etuate it, until he learns by a bitter experience that 
 Nature is, after all, the best restorer of labour troubles, as of 
 other ills.
 
 The Political Argument. 323 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. vi.. \ I.] 
 
 CHAPTER VI. 
 
 THE COST OF PROTECTION. 
 
 I. The fiscal controversy has now been tracked through all 
 its windings. Starting on the broad and well-worn road of 
 economic demonstration, the argument has wandered into 
 every by-path of expediency and prejudice. None of the 
 appeals to interest, sentiment, or pride, by which Protectionists 
 have tried to cover their defeat in economic argument, has 
 been allowed to pass unnoticed, but each has been considered 
 separately, and has been tested both by experience and by 
 theory. The result is unaltered. The economic demonstra- 
 tion needs no qualification. Both political and economic 
 arguments lead to the same conclusion : namely, that Free 
 Trade which is voluntary trade means great trade, and 
 great trade means prosperity. 
 
 Nevertheless, where so much is at stake there will never be 
 finality. The theory and experience which seem conclusive 
 to-day will be distinguished tomorrow, if there is only a 
 difference in names to furnish an excuse. Self-interest will 
 never lack a means of working on fanaticism. Protection is 
 hydra-headed, as every Free Trade controversialist must know. 
 It seems useless to expose one fallacy, because the disputant 
 at once ignores what he has said before, and takes his stand 
 upon a frcsli position. Prove to a man that Free Trade 
 cannot lower wages, and lie will talk aljout diversity of 
 cccu[)ation ; quit the argument about wages to discuss di- 
 versity, and he is asking for a home market. (Juote statistics, 
 the authority is denied. Ask for facts, )ou ar*^ given phrases. 
 Reason logically about tlie very phrases that are given- all 
 reasoning is denounced as ' theory." 
 
 Fortunately, one resource remains to disregard the rents 
 and gaps in Protectionist arguments^ and treat the (question 
 \' 2
 
 324 Industrial Free do At. 
 
 simply as one of expediency. Assume that Protection will do 
 all that its advocates promise, is not the price too dear ? May 
 we not buy diversity of occupation at too high a rate, even if 
 we get infant industries and a home market thrown into the 
 bargain ? In short, let it be granted that Free Trade is bad, 
 and that Protection remedies its worst defects, and still the 
 question will remain is the game worth the candle? If it is 
 not, and if Protection prove too high a price to pay for all the 
 promised benefits, a permanent and comprehensive answer is 
 afforded to every form of Protectionist allurement. 
 
 Nor can Protectionists complain of this method of con- 
 troversy, since they themselves impliedly, if not expressly, 
 admit that Protection may be bouglit too dearly when they 
 protest against being supposed to advocate "extreme" Pro- 
 tection. Bastiat's famous petition of the candle-makers against 
 the competition of the sun, which seems to Free Traders such 
 an unanswerable redudio ad absnrdiiiii of Protectionist argu- 
 ment; can only be avoided by fixing some limit to the 
 operation of Protective doctrines. Unfortunately, no one 
 knows what that limit is. It can only be guessed at by a series 
 of rough inductions from Protectionist protests. 
 
 We know, for instance (to recur to the former illustration), 
 that Protectionists in France and Anierica would not advocate 
 the enclosure of a city in a dome of glass in order to give 
 employment to the makers of glass and the manufacturers of 
 artificial liglit. However much the light of the sun may 
 prejudice the sale of oils, candles, lamps, and resin, and an 
 infinity of kindred articles, Protectionists will not shut out the 
 competition of that foreign rival. And they will not be moved 
 to alter their decision even by the consideration that if access 
 to natural light were closed in a few of the principal cities, 
 there would be an increase of cattle and sheep to supply 
 tallow, that groves would be planted with resinous trees, that 
 there would be an extended cultivation of vegetable oils, 
 and that the demand for artificial lishtinsi; would encourage
 
 The Political Argument. 325 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. vi., 5 I.] 
 
 agriculture in many ways, and at the same time give a home 
 market to the farmer. 
 
 We know that Protectionists will not shut out sunlight, 
 because many of them have declared the proposal to be 
 absurd, and have given as their reason that sunlight is a free 
 gift of Nature. The reason is excellent, but it equally applies 
 to iron, coal, and every other natural product which, by reason 
 of the greater liberality of Nature, is cheaper in one place than 
 another. 
 
 But the same Protectionists who refuse to exclude cheap 
 light do exclude cheap firing and cheap iron, from which we 
 can only conclude that there are certain limits to the extent to 
 which Protectionists are ready to refuse the gifts of Nature. 
 Sunlight they will accept, because the price of that is always 
 zero ; but iron, coal, and corn will be refused, because the price 
 of these articles only ai)proximates to zero. If Nature does 
 the whole work, her gifts will be received ; if she does only a 
 part, they will be rejected : or, what comes to the same thing, a 
 tax, equal in amount to the equivalent of Nature's cftbrt, will 
 be imposed upon the import of the completed article. 
 
 But even this distinction is not quite exact. Protectionists 
 will accept some gifts of a part from Nature, but not others. 
 For instance, American Protectionists will accept the assistance 
 of Nature in the production of tea, but not of iron. They 
 are ready to recognise that tlie natural conditions for the 
 production of tea are better in China than in America, but 
 they refuse to recognise the superiority of Australia in pro- 
 ducing wool. ]jut the proof of the existence of superior 
 natural conditions for tlie production of any article must 
 always be the same, vi/., a lower price. Altliough American 
 Protectionists will not encourage the tea industry, it is only a 
 matter of money to grow enough tea under glass in the 
 Southern States to supply the wliole Unir)n. Nor would it 
 matter what the tea cost, because even if it cost twenty 
 dollars a pound, the money (according to the Protectionist
 
 326 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 theory) would not go out of the country ; so that instead of 
 America having the tea and China the money, as at present, 
 America would have both the money and the tea ! While 
 if there were any surplus production, bounties might be given 
 on its export to China, so as to destroy the foreigner in his 
 own market ! 
 
 Other instances of a similar character miglit be quoted 
 to show that Protectionists are not always ready to follow 
 arguments to their logical conclusion. There appears to be 
 some vague and variable limit be) ond which Protectionists 
 will not go, for the reason that, if they di<l, Protection would 
 cost too much. 
 
 2, Assuming, then, that Protectionists cannot fairly object 
 to an inquiry into the cost of Protective tariffs, we will 
 proceed in the next and concluding pages to enumerate in 
 order the objections, both economic and political, to this 
 most baneful form of interference with the course of trade. 
 
 Protection is indefensible on economic grounds, for the 
 reason that under whatever disguise it may be recommended 
 it is always a device for making work. If the device 
 succeeds, somebody must pay for it. To ignore this truism 
 is to commit the blunder of the alchemists who spent their 
 lives in endeavouring to find a way of making something out 
 of nothing. 
 
 But it is said with pride : " See what industries Protection 
 has created ! " Granted that they are splendid, whose is the 
 luu-den of their cost ? 
 
 If an industry can sell its ])roducts at the price of the 
 open market, it needs no Protection. If it caimot sell at 
 market prices, and has to get an Act (jf Parliament to allow 
 it to charge more, it becomes a parasite u[)on existing in- 
 dustries, and nuist be su[)i)orted out of their profits. The 
 difference between the prices charged by these Protectetl 
 industries and the price in the open market is a measure of
 
 The Political Argument. 327 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. vi., \ 2.] 
 
 their economic cost to the whole community. The industries 
 themselves may be very fine and large, and a credit to their 
 superintendents, but if they cannot stand alone they owe 
 their support to taxes, and ought to be reckoned in the same 
 category with hospitals, gaols, almshouses, and other kindred 
 institutions. 
 
 It must always be difficult to estimate the exact amount of 
 the burden which these parasitic industries cast u})on a people. 
 Sometimes, but in rare cases, internal competition so reduces 
 prices that the loss is nil ; but in such a case the industry can 
 exist without Protection, and the duty ought to be, but never 
 is, removed. More often the difference between the price 
 charged by the Protected industry and that of the open 
 market is something a little less than the amount of the duty. 
 At times it is equal to the whole of the duty. Put whatever 
 the difference between the two prices may be, if the industry 
 requires Protection and that is the basis of the argument on 
 both sides it is borne by the community. No consequences of 
 this seem to be too grotesque for a true Protectionist. It has 
 been shown by undeniable figures times out of number that the 
 tariff in many instances takes more from the pockets cf the people 
 than would be enough to pension every workman in the Protected 
 industry, and buy up all the capital employed. The kerosene 
 industry in New Soutli Wales has been mentioned as one 
 instance. The tables of Mr. Hayter, the statistician of Victoria, 
 contain many others. Yet no such demonstrations can weaken 
 the enthusiasm of the true believer. 
 
 Nor do the figures of the Custom House reveal the whole 
 of the loss. The increased price of the home-made article 
 by reason of the duty must also be added to the account. 
 
 There is also a further item of loss, which it is almost 
 impossible to estimate, in the value of the industries which the 
 tariff has destroyed or crippled. These are never mentioned 
 in the boastful calculations of Protectionists; yet it is cer- 
 tain that no tariff was ever passed which did not interfere
 
 328 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 prejudicially with some industries already in existence, and pre- 
 vent others from growing up. Why, then, should Protectionists 
 keep silent about this source of destruction and loss except 
 that it is in the nature of all men to " mark when they hit, but 
 not when they miss?"i 
 
 3. But the cost of a Protective tariff is beyond what can be 
 measured in mere money, because it weakens the fibre of 
 national life, by giving rise to political and social evils, which 
 must be counted as of graver consequence than any economic 
 loss. 
 
 From the standpoint of a politician it produces many evils, 
 which differ from each other only in degrees of harmfulness. 
 In the first place, it is a policy of inequality ; because it 
 confers special advantages upon certain classes without regard 
 to the value of the services which they render in return. 
 Under Protection every person, who is able to interest a 
 majority of legislators in his favour, can shield his industry 
 from foreign competition, and is allowed, with others in his 
 own trade, to sell certain goods at an artificially high price. 
 In other words, the tariff allows him and his fellows to 
 compel the rest of the community, who are in a large 
 majority, to deal exclusively with them, under penalty 
 of a fine in the shape of a customs duty should they 
 choose to purchase the goods which they desire from 
 some one else. Protectionists sometimes resent this 
 
 > I'reviou.^ly to the American tariff of 1862, there was a considerable 
 smelting industry carried on in the seaboard States. The duty on pig-iron 
 destroyed it. 'J lie decline of the American shipping trade is another familiar 
 instance. The tarilT has made iron and steel so deai', and so eahanced the 
 price of other raw materials, that shipbuilding has ceased to be jirofitable, and 
 the American marine, which once ranked next to that of England, has almost 
 disappeared. 
 
 The tariff has produced a similar result in Victoria. The shipbuilders 
 have openly asseited, and proved their assertion to the Ciavernment, that 
 they can no longer build ships to compete with those of New .Soutli Wales, 
 because of the high price of the raw material Q;:casioiied by the Protective 
 tariff.
 
 The Political Arcvmekt. 329 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. vi.,5 3.] 
 
 manner of stating the case, upon the ground (as they say) 
 that the internal competition of producers will reduce the 
 prices of Protected articles below those at which they could 
 be imported. Of course, if this were true, there would be no 
 need of Protection ; and the best proof of sincerity which 
 those who make the assertion could give, would be to become 
 Free Traders. But in fact, as so often happens with Protec- 
 tionist arguments, they are theoretically true under certain 
 assumed conditions, but in practice they have no bearing on 
 the controversy, because the conditions are absent. The 
 internal competition of which we hear so much seldom takes 
 place with sufficient activity to reduce prices. Rings, trusts, 
 combines, pools and every other device of a closed commerce 
 to secure for itself a profitable field of plunder, are resorted to 
 by the Protected manufacturers to prevent a decline in prices 
 through the competition of their own number. A Protected 
 country furnishes new illustrations every year of the old adage 
 that " where combination is possible competition is impossible." 
 It may, indeed, be put as the head and front of Protectionist 
 offending, that it destroys healthy competition in order to 
 create an unhealthy combination. The manufacturing 
 magnates of a Protected country arc as truly the privileged 
 class of to-day, as were their prototypes in the Rhine castles, 
 who exacted tolls from every passing trader. 
 
 Not only is Protection a policy of ine(|uality, but it is a 
 policy of ine([uality without system. It is a haphazard policy, 
 which confers its fiivours and strikes its blows equally at 
 random. This is inevitable from the nature of the object 
 which it sets before itself The selcriion of tliis or that 
 industry for special legislative favour places a i)Ower in the 
 hands of Parliament, which, even if it is not exercised cor- 
 ru])tly, must he exercised more or less blindl}-. The woollen 
 duties of the United States are the typical illustration of this 
 feature of Protection. They are so intricate and delicately 
 graduated tliat even experts in the trade are said to be unable
 
 330 INDUSTRIAL Freedom. 
 
 to estimate exactly either their amount or their incidence.* 
 What, then, must be the position of the legislator who imposed 
 the duties ? No man can be master of the technicalities of 
 every trade ; and the most honest legislator cannot fail to be 
 misled by the interested statements of commercial experts. 
 The settlement of a tariff has been described by an American 
 eye-witness as "a game of grab," in which each interest takes 
 what it can, and by combination with others secures the 
 utmost. The iron men support the farmers, if the farmers vote 
 for a duty on steel rails ; and the woollen manufacturers form 
 a close alliance with the copper trust in order to prevent the 
 pastoralists from getting too much for wool. How infinitely 
 hard, in such a chaos of no principles, to detect corruption or 
 insure wise judgment ! Ignorance attempting to legislate 
 according to the dictates of self-interest ! Grant that ignorance 
 acts honestly, yet into what an unseemly scramble for money- 
 aids is politics degraded ! 
 
 Unfortunately, however, ignorance is not always honest. 
 It would be assuming too much of human nature to look for 
 the continuance of a high standard of public integrity in any 
 Protected country. With whatever high motives men may at 
 first delude themselves into the support of a Protective tariff, 
 they run a constantly increasing risk of being conquered by 
 the temptations with which the policy surrounds them. The 
 virtue of a legislator must indeed be adamant, if, when he sees 
 others plundering all about him, he keeps his own hands pure 
 from bribes. Let the recent experience of Canada, or the 
 revelations of the methods of the contest for the United 
 States Presidency in 1888, be a sufficient warning! 
 
 Politically, then. Protection ought to be condemned, 
 because it creates vested interests, the existence of which is 
 dependent upon Acts of Parliament, and which tend mevitably 
 to become monopolies ; because it creates these interests without 
 
 ' See on this subject the chapter on the Woollen Duties in Professor 
 Taussig's " History of Protection."
 
 The Political Argument. 331 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. vi., \ 4.] 
 
 due regard to the evil which it inflicts on others, and because 
 it entrusts the power of enriching individuals to legislators, 
 who are all the more exposed to the influence of improper 
 motives, because their want of knowledge must prevent them 
 from acting with complete fairness, even if they had the best 
 intentions. 
 
 4. But it is as a social rather than a political evil, that the 
 baleful influence of Protection is the most apparent, h.% an 
 abuse of the law-making power, it injures respect for law by- 
 creating artificial offences against which both self interest and 
 the sense of justice equally rebel. There is no surer means 
 of accustoming citizens to view with complacency disobedience 
 to the laws, than by awarding heavy punishments for acts (such 
 as smuggling) which are not morally wrong. No one can 
 trace in detail or estimate in bulk how much is lost to a com- 
 munity, if the public once lose faith in its law-makers and respect 
 for its laws ; but that the loss is considerable few would attempt 
 to deny. Nor does the evil of Protection rest here. Men are 
 influenced by it also in the more self-regarding relations of 
 their lives ; because it tends to weaken tlie motives of self- 
 reliance and enterprise. x\fter a long course of Protection 
 manufacturers seem to lose the power of facing difficulties like 
 practical and courageous men. In the face of competition 
 they become like silly cliildren, and are scared by it as by a 
 ghost. Instead of calling their men together to devise new pro- 
 cesses, or calculating how to cheapen or improve their present 
 ones, they run whining to Parliament for help at the first sign 
 of successful rivalry. Instead of trusting to the old-foshioned 
 virtues of enterprise and self-reliance, they lean entirely on 
 Protective dulies. A system is thus initiated which, if it were 
 continued long enough upon a people whose numbers wore 
 not constantly recruited by energetic immigrants, could only 
 end in the destruction of national life. The vigour of a 
 pcojile wliich becomes accustomed t(j ai)ijly to (;(j\ernment
 
 332 IXDVSTKJAL FREEDOM. 
 
 in every difficulty, must be gradually sapped. Private energy 
 will put forth no power, when it is without assurance that it 
 will be allowed to reap success, and when a vote of the 
 Assembly may at any moment bring its enterprise to an un- 
 timely end. Thus Protection defeats the object of its advo- 
 cates ; and the very policy which is designed to stimulate new 
 qualities and develop the natural powers both of a country 
 and its citizens, becomes a subtle instrument for the destruction 
 of originality, ambition, and enterprise. For Protection is 
 essentially antagonistic to progress. 
 
 It runs counter to one of the most elementary and per- 
 manent of human instincts, viz., the desire to satisfy wants 
 at the least cost. We spend millions in dredging harbours, in 
 removing sand-bars, and by every means improving the 
 facilities for commercial intercourse. Yet, so soon as we 
 experience the effects of this work in a reduced cost of 
 foreign goods, the Protectionist would have us lay a new tax, 
 like restoring the sand-bars, in order to bring up prices. Well 
 may Professor Sumner saj', "To build sand-bars across our 
 harbours would be a far cheaper means of reaching the same 
 end." If the Protectionist theory be correct, all the thought, 
 energy, time and money devoted to imjiroving the means of 
 communication between foreign nations is wasteful and in- 
 jurious. A great steamship or an international railway only 
 exists to cheapen the cost of transportation ; improvements in 
 processes of manufacture are only designed to cheapen the 
 cost of production ; improved markets, co-operation, and 
 similar devices, are only resorted to in order to cheapen the 
 cost of distribution. The net result of this manifold exertion 
 of human power is a reduction in jjrices. ^'et, let prices fall 
 in any country save their own, Protectionists at once 
 declare that the result is ruin, not advantage, to their 
 fellow-citizens. The Cliinese are the true I'rotectionists, 
 for they build a wall around their territory and exclude 
 foreieners.
 
 The Political Argument. 333 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. V,, \ 5.] 
 
 5. Finally, Protection deserves to be condemned as a 
 moral abuse. 
 
 It is no doubt unfashionable, at present, to judge political 
 measures by ethical standards ; partly because the dominance 
 of reactionary ideas and the rule of force, of which Protection 
 is only one expression, are unfavourable to moral criticism, 
 and partly owing to a just resentment against the egotism, cant 
 and malice with which some prominent political moralists apply 
 the ethical test. Nevertheless, those who believe that the 
 foundations of a national policy must rest upon sound morality 
 will be compelled to give consideration to the ethical basis of 
 a Protective system. Yet it would seem as if Protectionists 
 always shrank from this duty. Their policy has no ethical 
 maxim connected with it. It is, on the contrary, an open 
 outrage on the moral sense of a community, and a defiance of 
 all moral maxims. It rests avowedly on seltishness " Germany 
 hav, nothing to do with Russia, nor Russia with Germany," 
 says List, its champion I^and it justifies its action by appeals 
 to national prejudice and class interests. Where Free Trade 
 preaches the brotherhood of man, and urges that, in foreign as 
 in private commerce, a nation should "Do unto others as it 
 wishes to be done by," Protection advocates national isolation, 
 and inculcates the doctrine of doing to others in commercial 
 matters as they do unto us. " Peace on earth, good-will 
 towards men,"' which is the motto of the Cobden Club, can 
 have no meaning to the ears of men who wage an internecine 
 warfare with every nation by the means of hostile tariffs, which 
 are not the less deadly than murderous weapons because they 
 do not leave their victims mangled on the ground. The 
 "nationalist" who rejoices over the distress which the 
 McKinley tariff has caused in Germany or Wales, and 
 claims every dislocation of foreign commerce and every 
 injury to foreign traders as a sign of a worthy triumph, 
 evidently stands upon a different moral plane from those 
 who hold tb.at each nation finds its own true slremzih
 
 334 IXDUSTRIAL I'REEDOM. 
 
 in a joint and peaceful progress with neighbouring 
 countries. 
 
 It is characteristic of those who view Avith satisfaction the 
 injurious effects of their pohcy on other countries, that they 
 should be indifferent to the liberties of their own people. Yet 
 the moral aspect of Protection is no brighter, if the policy is 
 contemplated only in its home results. Protection is an 
 interference with human liberty, of the same nature, and 
 differing from it only in degree, as human slavery. " If it is 
 criminal," said Cobden, with his usual insight, " to steal a man 
 and make him work for nothing, it is equally criminal to steal 
 from a free man the fair reward of his labour." Every increase 
 of price in a Protected article means an addition to the forced 
 labour of those who desire to buy it. Such an invasion of 
 human freedom may be justified (as negro slavery was 
 justified) by more or less sincere assertions that the interest 
 of the poor requires it ; but in its essence it is always, as in 
 practice the facts prove, a device to secure advantages for rich 
 men in which the poor do not share. 
 
 It is this consciousness of the deep-lying immorality of a 
 Protective policy that justifies the confident belief among Free 
 Traders in its ultimate destruction. Those who believe that 
 " morality is the nature of things " arc not likely to be much 
 disheartened by the passing victories of restrictive ])olicies. 
 Periods of reaction are inevitable ; and when the reaction 
 takes the form of military despotism and belief in force, tariffs, 
 which are the accompaniment of niilitarism and the denial of 
 justice, are necessary incidents of tlie reaction. Even already, 
 however, there are signs that the nightmare of Protection is 
 lifting ; while the causes of discouragement to Free Traders 
 have never been so great as tliose which darkened the days 
 of the Abolitionists only twenty years before the Civil 
 War. 
 
 6. It is no wonder, then, that, in every civilised country,
 
 The Political Argument. 335 
 
 Pt. IV., Ch. vi., \ 6.] 
 
 those who try to find the best expression of a nation's moral life in 
 its political system, and who recognise that sense of duty is the 
 safeguard of society, and not self-interest all, in fact, who are 
 men of ideas, with hardly one exception are waging an 
 undying battle with the creature Protection, It is no wonder, 
 also, if at times the language of the disputants grows heated, 
 " Protectionism," says Professor Sumner and his words will 
 find an echo in the heart of every one who has lived in a Pro- 
 tected country, and has seen the desperate shifts to which 
 Protectionists resort, or read the nonsense and the falsehoods 
 of their journalistic champions " is such an arrant piece of 
 economic quackery, and it masquerades under such an 
 affectation of learning and philosophy^ that it ought to be 
 treated as other quackeries are treated with scorn, contempt, 
 satire, and ridicule." If this method has not been adopted in 
 the present work, it has been out of deference to the feelings 
 of others, and from a real desire to see the matter as they see 
 it, and not from any belief that Protectionist arguments can 
 bear even the sound of plausibility to men who study the 
 course of trade and the growth of industrial life. Students of 
 economics are virtually unanimous in condemning the policy. 
 But voters are not students, and often lack the means of 
 information. Such persons, if they will reflect upon the matter, 
 need no study to become Free Traders. Protectionism is an 
 outrage on the moral sense. " It is a subtle, cruel, and 
 unjust invasion of one man's rights by another. It is done by 
 force of law. It is at the same time a social abuse, an economic 
 blunder, and a political evil." The system saps self-reliance, 
 because it leads men to deiJond upon the laws of Parliament 
 when they should be studying the laws of nature ; it is repug- 
 nant to justice, because it introduces artificial inequalities ; it 
 is destructive of political purity, because it turns the power of 
 law-making into an engine for enriching individuals. It is at 
 once the offspring and the parent of corruption. It lowers the 
 standard of wages and creates monopolies. It widens the
 
 ^^6 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 breach between classes by introducing systematic spoliation 
 under the forms of law. No possible advantage which Protec- 
 tion can give can compensate for these tremendous evils. The 
 true policy, therefore, is to trust in freedom, even when the 
 path seems lost, remembering that the confusion and obscurities 
 of industrial life cannot be relieved by efforts to turn back the 
 hands upon the clock of time. 
 
 The Free Trade controversy presents anew all the features 
 of the old controversy against ingrained abuses. The struggle, 
 which, in one form or another and under varied names, has 
 divided men into opposing camps, since the first existence of 
 political societies, is now waging round the issue of Free 
 Trade. Religious, political, and industrial freedom are the 
 constituent elements of a stable and prosperous State. Two 
 of these religious and political freedom have already been 
 achieved ; but the struggle is yet being waged around the third. 
 Yet, of the three, industrial freedom is of most importance to a 
 democratic State ; because under the modern conditions of civil 
 life, neither religious nor political freedom is likely to be long 
 enjoyed, if the fabric of liberty is once impaired upon the side 
 of industry. The matter of primary importance in any 
 industrial society is the preservation, against all attacks, of its 
 individual freedom. Those who, in their zeal for socialism, 
 temperance, or other objects^ refuse to take their part 
 in the fiscal battle, need to be reminded of Mr. John 
 Morley's advice to another class of earnest reformers, that 
 " They should not let the eternities bulk so big as to shut out 
 this perishable speck, the human race," and to be guided 
 in their practice by Cobden's sage direction that 'Mn politics we 
 must only do one thing at a time." The first thing to be done 
 now throughout the greater part of the English-speaking world 
 is, to destroy Protection. That once accomplished, the path 
 is clear, and other reforms will follow.
 
 APPENDIX I. 
 
 Tables of Wages in the English Cotton, Woollen, 
 Worsted, and Iron Trades. 
 
 In order to illustrate the statements in Chapter IV., Part I., relating 
 to the diffusion of wealth in Great Britain, some tables are sub- 
 joined, exhibiting the fluctuations in the wages of the four principal 
 English Industries the Cotton, Woollen, Worsted, and Iron 
 manufactures since 1830. The figures are extracted from the 
 Reports issued by the Board of Trade, under the title " Miscel- 
 laneous Statistics of the United Kingdom." Unfortunately, these 
 reports contain very little evidence upon which positive conclusions 
 can be based. They contain, it is true, a good deal of miscellaneous 
 information about wages ; but they appear at irregular intervals, 
 and their information is exhibited on miscellaneous principles of 
 inconvenience and confusion. In one report an industry is 
 scheduled by itself, which in the next is lost among a mass of 
 details of the state of trade in certain districts. Sometimes wages 
 are estimated by the hour, sometimes by the week, and sometimes 
 by the piece. Upon occasions the employments of workmen are 
 distributed ; while upon others an industry is treated as a whole, 
 and its rate of wages is expressed in averages ; and, not unfre- 
 qucntly, an ijiiportant trade, the condition of which has been 
 described for several years with a most useful fulness, drops out 
 entirely from the record, never to appear again.' 
 
 But, in spite of the impaired value of such ill-arranged statistics, 
 the figures are useful up to a certain point for purposes of com- 
 parison ; and, in respect of the four great industries already named, 
 they have been presented with some approach to an uniform 
 method. These trades together give employment to about one- 
 half of the working-class, so that the \-ai-\ ing rate of wages paid 
 in them during the last thirty years will indicate an approximate 
 an^iuer to the question '' Whctlicr wages in Knglantl have on the 
 wh'ilc risen or decreased ?'' 
 
 A. v"Ar;i:s IX Tin: co'I'I'on ixr>usTRV. 
 The wa;-;es paid in llie Cotton industry are particularly valuable 
 indications of the ratc,^ in other trades, lioth l)ecause for the last 
 
 ' Thcso (l.'fu'ioiicit'S !iav" l)cen remedied of Lite years; Imt the I'eniavk.s 
 a]";'ly t'l t!ie veai's f)\c;" wlach tl;ese jirrnres !ia\'e li-en taken. 
 
 W
 
 338 
 
 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 forty years that industry has maintained the same position of 
 importance, and because it has also, during that time, been singu- 
 larly free from any disturbing fluctuation in the number of hands 
 employed.^ This is mainly owing to the gradual introduction of 
 machinery', by which, in spite of the great increase in the production 
 of cotton goods, the necessity for employing more labour has been 
 avoided. 
 
 In examining the fluctuations, it is convenient to adopt a rough 
 division of the Cotton operatives into four classes, according to 
 the degree of skill required in their several occupations. 
 
 In the first class would come the overlookers and superior 
 artisans in each department, together with those spinners who, 
 according to the number of spindles each man can manage, would 
 be classed above No. loo in the technical language of the factory. 
 The bulk of the adult males would fall into the second class, as 
 being spinners and weavers of average skill. Women should be 
 ranked alone as a third class ; and, for greater clearness, the 
 wages of children under sixteen should also be considered separately. 
 
 The subjoined Tables are an attempt to carry out this principle 
 of division. 
 
 Table showing the Fluctuations in the Average Rate of 
 Weekly Wages paid to persons employed in the Cotton 
 Trade during the years 1839-77 in Manchester and the 
 Xeighbourhood : 
 
 Occupation. \ 
 
 1839. 
 
 "V 
 
 1849. 
 
 1859. 1874. 1 
 
 1S77. 
 
 
 1ST Class. j 
 
 
 
 
 1 
 
 
 
 Superior Operatives. i-. 
 
 d. s. 
 
 d.s. 
 
 d. s. 
 
 d. s. s. s. d, s. s. 
 
 d. s. 
 
 d. 
 
 (i.) Overlookers .. ..'24 
 
 to 25 
 
 028 
 
 
 
 28 '30 to 45 30 
 
 to 45 
 
 
 
 (ii.) Skilled spinners, above 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 No. 103 . . . . 40 
 
 to 45 
 
 036 
 
 to 40 
 
 40 to 45 45 to 50 
 
 45 
 
 to 55 
 
 
 
 (iii.) Engine-irs .. 24 
 
 
 
 
 28 
 
 
 
 ,30 ,43 
 
 58 
 
 3 
 
 
 2NT) Class. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Unskilled Operatives. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 (i.) Spinners below No. 10023 
 
 to 25 
 
 21 
 
 
 
 23 to 25 42 
 
 40 
 
 
 
 
 (ii.) lileachers . . . . 21 
 
 
 
 18 
 
 
 
 18 ^24 :28 
 
 
 
 
 (iii.) Strippers and grinders 11 
 
 to 13 
 
 12 
 
 to 13 
 
 12 to 13 22 to 2321 
 
 
 
 
 (iv.) Labourers .. 15 
 
 
 
 15 
 
 
 
 15 I y 5 I S 
 
 9 
 
 
 SRD Class. 
 
 
 
 
 1 
 
 
 
 Women. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 (i.) Carding Department . . 6 
 
 6 to 7 
 
 t 6 
 
 6 10 S 
 
 6 7 to 9 II to 16 10 
 
 6 to 18 
 
 7 
 
 (ii.) Doublers . . 7 
 
 
 
 7 
 
 6 
 
 9 10 to 13 12 
 
 
 
 
 (iii.) Weaving 
 
 9 
 
 to 17 
 63 
 
 9 
 
 to 16 
 60 
 
 10 to 20 
 
 12 
 
 to 24 
 
 
 
 Weekly hours of labour 
 
 
 
 
 60 59 1 
 
 
 56^ 
 
 
 ' The number of hands employed in all branches of the Cotton trade is 
 given at 420,000 for 1S74, and in 1840 it was estimated at 400,000.
 
 Appendix I. 339 
 
 It appears from these Tables that in the year 1839 the wages 
 of the highest paid overlooker, in any department, was 25s. for a week 
 of sixty-nine hours, which is twelve hours a day, with nine hours on 
 Saturday for a half-holiday. Ten years later after Free Trade 
 his wages had risen to 28s., and his hours of work had been re- 
 duced to sixty in the week. Since that date there has been a steady 
 improvement in wages, together with a further reduction in the 
 hours of work. The lowest paid overlooker now gets more for fifty- 
 six and a half hours' work than the best paid overlooker received in 
 1849 for sixty hours ; while the remuneration of the more skilled over- 
 lookers has increased more than fifty per cent, in the same period. 
 The increase in the wages of the engineers is even more remark- 
 able. They have more than doubled in the last thirty years. 
 The skilled spinners after a temporary fall, through the introduc- 
 tion of machinery are also better off than they were. Those who 
 are the least skilled among them are paid higher for less work, and 
 the rewards open to them for a higher exercise of skill are con- 
 siderably increased. Even the class of unskilled labourers, 
 whose progress, as already noted in the text,^ is generally slower, 
 have, in some cases, doubled their wages in the same thirty years ; 
 although, with reference to this class, it should not be forgotten 
 that many of its members are constantly pushing forward into 
 better paid employments, and that it is also being constantly re- 
 cruited from below by those who, in former days, would have lived 
 as paupers or vagabonds. 
 
 The figures which show the wages paid to women need no 
 further explanation. They will show, with sufficient clearness, 
 how low is the market \alue of woman's labour, and how little 
 has been done to raise that value by intelligent and power- 
 ful combination. Unlike men, women are not yet paid l)y 
 reference to any standard of class comfort, but arc content 
 with any pittance which may increase the family resources, 
 however insufficient that may be, by itself, to keep one ])erson 
 in a position of health and decency. By such ill-judged 
 economy, they only depress the general labour market, without 
 obtaining for thcmseh-es independence or security ; so that they 
 tempt men, wlio are heedless of tl;e impossibilit\- of bringing 
 women back to a state of subjection, to clamour fn- tlicir cx- 
 rlusion from male employments. 
 
 ' Src page 305.
 
 34 
 
 Industrial Freedom^ 
 
 c o 
 
 
 t^ 
 
 
 
 
 
 t^ 
 
 
 "uo 
 
 ut" 
 
 "^ V vS" 
 
 CO 
 
 
 CO 
 
 PI 
 
 M n 
 
 M 
 
 
 
 
 
 4- 
 
 
 
 
 
 t^. 
 
 
 00 
 
 " 
 
 "^ "m VO 
 
 CO 
 
 
 d 
 
 d 
 
 C4 CI Cl 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 6 
 
 "o 
 
 CI 
 
 c o 
 
 00 
 
 o 
 
 CO 
 
 o 
 
 CO 
 
 o 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 o 
 
 
 
 S3 "i" y 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 CI 
 
 o lo od" 
 
 
 
 M 
 
 M M W 
 
 
 
 .1 
 
 _1 
 
 J_ _^ o 
 
 
 s3 
 
 o 
 
 c7 
 
 M M To 
 
 o 
 
 CO 
 
 o 
 
 CO 
 
 o 
 
 CO 
 
 <M CI CI 
 
 o o o 
 
 o 
 
 ^ 
 
 *^ 
 
 ^ "^ ^ 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 CO" 
 
 ci 
 
 o lo CO 
 
 
 '-' 
 
 CI 
 
 1- l-l M 
 
 
 o 
 
 
 
 "o CO 
 
 
 CO 
 
 , 
 
 1 
 
 CI 1-1 , 
 
 g 
 
 s 
 
 CO 
 01 
 
 CI 
 
 o 2 "2^ 
 
 '"' 
 
 "c 
 
 
 
 o" o 
 
 
 o 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 O" CO 
 
 
 
 
 
 CI -^ 
 
 6 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 c 
 
 CO" 
 
 ^- 
 
 o o ,V 
 
 
 '"' 
 
 CI 
 
 ci 
 
 -^ -^ ^ 
 
 M 
 
 o 
 
 
 
 o 
 
 o 
 
 CO 
 
 
 
 " " 
 
 0" 
 
 
 
 o" cc 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 ^->-' 
 
 3 
 
 CO" 
 CI 
 
 -r 
 
 CI 
 
 2 2 ''"' 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 '^ 
 
 in 
 
 
 
 Co" >;.> 
 
 
 " 
 
 
 
 
 
 ^' 
 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 
 
 - ,1 
 
 ^ r^ 
 
 
 
 
 OCO -i. 
 
 
 
 
 cS 
 
 ",> CI \r. 
 
 
 
 C) 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 6 
 
 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 
 
 V , ' 
 
 
 
 'A 
 
 
 
 
 X 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 x : : : 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 ? =" 
 
 ~ 
 
 
 /"; J 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 s. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 j 
 
 _- 5 
 
 
 '1 
 
 r; :^ ^ ;" H 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 ' 
 
 ^ H 
 
 <'. 
 
 ~^ 
 
 - e: 8 i' -'"^ 
 
 
 - 3 
 
 
 s. 
 
 '^ C "/. '-' ^ 
 
 
 
 
 1 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 '/; --T 
 
 
 
 
 r. 
 
 
 
 y. i 
 
 r ' 
 
 
 r: ct 
 
 
 H 
 
 ~ 
 
 ^^ 
 
 U w 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 "^ 
 
 ~ 
 
 ^ 
 
 X S 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 ' 
 
 
 -
 
 Appendix I. 
 
 341 
 
 
 1 
 1- 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 "0" 
 
 
 -^ 
 
 vo" 
 
 
 'S' 
 
 
 cn 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 CJ 
 
 a 
 
 , 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 
 
 00 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 
 
 *^ 
 
 
 "CN 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 CO 
 
 00 
 
 
 "S 
 
 
 N 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 
 
 M 
 
 
 " 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 10 
 
 
 M 
 
 
 
 00 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 
 P) 
 
 
 
 M 
 
 t-^ 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 00 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 *-' 
 
 M 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 ." 
 
 
 .> 
 
 
 
 _^ 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 "o" 
 
 
 "10 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 00 
 
 1 
 
 
 
 
 10 
 
 
 CO 
 
 
 
 , 
 
 , 
 
 vO 
 
 
 "a 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 "0" 
 
 00 
 
 V; 
 
 00 
 
 CO 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 C) 
 
 
 
 M 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 "0 
 
 CO 
 
 
 CO 
 01 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 V 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 b/) 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 vd 
 
 ." 
 
 
 
 
 .> 
 
 ct 
 
 ^1 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 . 
 
 _ 
 
 
 
 
 
 10 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 E 
 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 00 
 
 CO 
 
 'O 
 
 ^ 
 
 CO 
 
 
 
 
 XJ^ 
 
 t- 
 
 
 t-t 
 
 M 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 < 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 1 
 
 1 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 1 
 
 
 CO 
 
 1 
 
 
 "0" 
 
 c 
 
 10 
 
 CO 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 b^ 
 c: 
 
 CO 
 
 
 
 
 "5" 
 
 Cl 
 
 CI 
 
 
 
 Sr 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 ^ 
 
 *^ 
 
 
 
 
 CJ 
 
 
 *^ 
 
 
 JT* 
 
 
 CO 
 
 "10 
 
 
 
 
 <' 
 
 
 
 CI 
 
 
 -F 
 
 "ij^ 
 
 
 IN 
 
 " 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 " 
 
 
 CI 
 
 l-l 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 _^l 
 
 
 "o~ 
 
 10 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 o" 
 
 
 ~^ 
 
 co" 
 
 ^ 
 
 T 
 
 CO 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 1 
 
 CI 
 
 w 
 
 -O 
 
 
 
 c 
 
 
 
 
 t^ 
 
 or 
 
 CO 
 
 
 
 
 CI 
 
 
 
 
 
 cc 
 
 *^ 
 
 *^ 
 
 
 
 
 CJ 
 
 
 
 
 *-* 
 
 
 co" 
 Pi 
 
 LT) 
 
 
 
 
 .^ 
 
 
 
 Cl 
 
 
 "0" 
 
 C) 
 
 10 
 
 
 "o" 
 
 >o 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 o" 
 
 
 _CO 
 
 co~ 
 
 00 
 
 -t- 
 
 CO 
 
 
 
 
 , 
 
 
 
 , 
 
 C) 
 
 >-* 
 
 c 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 
 2 
 
 CI 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 -^ 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 >o 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 CI 
 
 
 
 
 -r 
 
 
 
 
 " 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 " 
 
 
 CI 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 1 
 
 
 
 _^ 
 
 _. 
 
 1 
 
 
 t^ 
 
 t^ 
 
 
 
 
 
 vS~ 
 
 
 
 ^" 
 
 t< 
 
 CO 
 
 06 
 
 N 
 
 CI 
 
 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 
 
 Cl 
 
 Cl 
 
 
 >n 
 
 
 
 Q 
 
 
 
 ~o 
 
 CJ 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Q 
 
 
 
 00 
 
 ;;' 
 
 *- 
 
 
 
 
 *- 
 
 
 
 
 -* 
 
 *-' 
 
 M 
 
 a 
 
 -r 
 
 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 
 
 -r 
 
 CO" 
 
 iT 
 
 
 (^ 
 
 t^ 
 
 
 
 
 
 ^~ 
 
 
 "^ 
 
 "^= 
 
 "To 
 
 to" 
 
 C^ 
 
 CI 
 
 CI 
 
 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 
 CI 
 
 CI 
 
 Cl 
 
 
 iV) 
 
 Q 
 
 
 
 
 
 "0" 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 in 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 cc 
 
 
 
 
 
 CI 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 oi" 
 
 "^F 
 
 
 
 
 
 "o" 
 
 
 -F 
 
 "^ 
 
 To 
 
 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 '^ 
 
 " 
 
 
 
 
 U 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 cl 
 
 " 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 ft 
 
 ^^ 
 
 
 
 
 /: 
 
 ci 
 
 
 
 
 CO -n 
 
 ^ 
 
 in 
 
 '-) 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 a 
 
 in 
 
 
 
 /: 
 
 ri Cj 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 m 
 
 
 
 ZJ 
 
 
 
 
 
 n 
 
 
 
 lt: 
 
 ^ 
 
 '~> 
 
 
 ^ij 
 
 
 < 
 
 s 
 
 : 
 
 5 
 7-. 
 
 ^ r-- 
 
 
 
 C) 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 r 
 
 
 c^ 
 
 ^ 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 'm 
 
 
 rt 
 
 
 3 
 
 g 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 c; 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 y 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 d 
 
 ^ 
 
 1:^
 
 34 2 
 
 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 t 
 
 00 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 S" 
 
 " 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 1 
 
 
 , 
 
 
 , 
 
 
 CO 
 
 1 
 
 00 
 
 
 CO 
 
 
 CO 
 
 
 "o" 
 
 
 o 
 
 "ct; 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 H 
 
 
 
 
 VO" 
 
 
 
 "o" 
 
 
 "o" 
 
 CO 
 
 
 
 en 
 
 , 
 
 
 CO 
 
 
 t 
 
 CI 
 
 MD 
 
 
 
 o 
 
 00 
 
 
 o 
 
 
 o 
 
 
 
 00 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 "^ 
 
 
 
 "o" 
 
 
 oo 
 
 oo 
 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 
 
 C) 
 
 
 C4 
 
 " 
 
 
 
 
 vS~ 
 
 
 
 "o" 
 
 
 "o" 
 
 ;^^" 
 
 \o 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 , 
 
 
 <o 
 
 
 Tt- 
 
 N 
 
 o 
 
 
 
 o 
 
 00~ 
 
 
 o 
 
 
 o 
 
 O 
 
 00 
 
 
 
 *^ 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 M 
 
 
 
 "o" 
 
 
 CO 
 
 00 
 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 
 
 C4 
 
 
 C< 
 
 tH 
 
 
 
 
 
 ^*- u 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 O tu 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 V 0. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 
 ^o 
 
 
 " 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 oo 
 
 <! 
 
 
 CO 
 
 1= 2 
 
 Is 
 
 c 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 ^'^s 
 
 o 
 
 J3 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 o 
 
 o 
 
 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 ^1 
 
 VO 
 
 _ 
 
 *-I 
 
 c 
 
 G 
 
 
 
 
 oo 
 
 M 
 ^ 
 
 
 CO 
 
 
 4J 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 3 
 
 I 
 
 1 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 iS, 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 TJ- 
 
 
 o 
 
 
 
 
 .8 
 
 CO 
 
 * 
 
 
 CO 
 
 
 oo 
 
 
 O 
 
 
 CO 
 
 OO 
 
 
 
 
 
 M 
 
 
 c< 
 
 
 
 
 d 
 
 1 
 
 , 
 
 vO_ 
 
 , 
 
 
 
 
 , 
 
 , 
 
 00 
 
 "o" 
 
 CO 
 
 d 
 
 t^ 
 
 
 
 
 ^o" 
 
 CO 
 
 T 
 
 M 
 
 CO 
 
 PI 
 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 
 d 
 
 
 
 , 
 
 , 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 -t- 
 
 "5" 
 
 "c?) 
 
 "o^ 
 
 CI 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 CO 
 
 M 
 
 ^ 
 
 M 
 
 M 
 
 M 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 o 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 5 
 
 
 V* 
 
 
 ^_^ 
 
 
 
 C 
 
 
 
 u 
 
 
 o 
 
 
 o 
 
 
 
 E 
 
 
 
 
 
 3 
 
 
 c 
 
 
 "Z^ 
 
 
 
 
 c 
 
 1^ 
 
 
 O 
 
 
 - 
 
 
 
 o 
 
 
 o 
 
 fT. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 CJ 
 
 
 
 B 
 
 
 
 "rt 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 ij 
 
 
 
 
 o 
 
 o 
 
 
 OJ 
 
 
 S 
 
 u 
 
 
 
 
 _>- 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 
 
 o 
 
 
 
 
 
 'c 
 
 tC 
 
 "o 
 
 'c 
 
 
 _o^ 
 
 H 
 
 t-< 
 
 t~ 
 
 
 ^ 
 
 t 
 
 p2 
 
 u 
 
 
 S2 
 
 t: 
 
 OJ 
 
 
 
 OJ 
 
 o 
 
 
 o 
 
 
 o 
 
 
 c; 
 
 o 
 
 
 
 
 o 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 s 
 
 
 M 
 
 3 
 
 
 :/) 
 
 
 
 c 
 
 
 _c: 
 
 'o 
 
 
 _c: 
 
 
 'o 
 
 
 o 
 
 o 
 
 
 '" 
 
 J-. 
 
 
 
 r- 
 
 
 y. 
 
 
 'vJ 
 
 '-J
 
 APPENDIX II. 
 
 J. S. MILL AND PROTECTION. 
 
 The idea that the abnormal economic circumstances of a young 
 country justify the imposition of Protective duties is sometimes 
 supposed by Protectionists to have approved itself to no less 
 eminent a thinker than John Stuart Mill. Indeed, much of the 
 Protectionist argument from natural difficulties is professedly 
 adopted from one passage in the writings of this economist. As 
 this passage has been so much misunderstood, it will be well to 
 quote it in full before entering upon any criticism of Mr. Mill's 
 views. 
 
 " The only case," says he, " in which, on mere principles of 
 political economy, protecting duties can be defensible, is when they 
 are imposed temporarily (especially in a young and rising nation) 
 in hopes of naturalising a foreign industry in itself perfectly 
 suitable to the circumstances of the country. The superiority of 
 one country over another in a branch of production often arises 
 only from having begun it sooner. There may be no inherent 
 advantage on one part or disadvantage on the other, but only a 
 present superiority of acquired skill and experience. A country 
 which has this skill and experience yet to acquire may, in other 
 respects, be better adapted to the production than those which 
 were earlier in the field ; and, besides, it is a just remark that 
 nothing has a greater tendency to promote improvements in any 
 branch of production than its trial under a new set of conditions. 
 But it cannot be expected that individuals, at their own expense, 
 or, rather, at their certain loss, would introduce a new manufacture, 
 and bear the burden of carrying it on until the producers have been 
 educated up to the level of those with whom the processes are 
 traditional. A protecting duty continued for a reasonable time 
 will sometimes be the least inconvenient mode in which the nation 
 can tax itself for the support of such an experiment. But the Pro- 
 tection should be confined to cases in which there is good ground 
 of assurance that the industry which it fosters will, after a time, be 
 able to dispense with it ; nor should the domestic producers ever 
 be allowed to expect that it will be continued to them beyond the
 
 344 Jadvsthjal Freedom. 
 
 time necessary for a fair trial of what they are capable of 
 accomplishing." 
 
 As this passage has been so often misinterpreted to convey an 
 approval of the Protective policy in America and Australia, it may 
 be well to set out clearly at starting what are the conditions under 
 which Mill thinks Protection might be justifiable. They are four 
 in number : 
 
 (i) Where the tariff is imposed to start a new industry. 
 
 (2) Where such industry is plainly suitable to the 
 
 country. 
 
 (3) Where it is only the want of experience on the part of 
 
 either labourer or capitalist which deters individuals from 
 running the risk of establishing the industry. 
 
 (4) Where there is good reason to believe that the fostered 
 
 industry will soon be able to stand alone. 
 
 It is not an excessive admission that in such a case " Protection 
 might be one mode " in which a nation could tax itself in support 
 of an industrial experiment. Mill's error lay in thinking that it 
 could ever be " the least inconvenient mode " of raising such a tax. 
 The error of those that quote Mill lies in not perceiving that his 
 observations only apply to the cases in which the conditions which 
 he requires are present, and that in these cases he only contem- 
 plates giving Protection during that short interval in the history of 
 an industry between the first production of an article and the time 
 when the home manufacturer is able to compete with his foreign 
 rival both in quality and quantity. In the whole history of the 
 Protective movement in America and Australia it is, I believe, 
 impossible to cite a single industry, the circumstance of which 
 would have justified Protection according to the canons laid down 
 by Mr. Mill. 
 
 Even, however, if it be granted that the condition of things 
 concei\ed by Mr. Mill is theoictically possible, it cannot be too 
 strongly insisted upon that Protection is the most wasteful, unjust, 
 and inconvenient method of Government assistance. 
 
 In the first place, whatever aid it gives comes too late ; Ijecause 
 it cannot be of service in starting an industry, whatever advantages 
 it may give after the industry is set going. Take, for instance. 
 Mill's imaginary case of an industry which is delayed by want of 
 skilled labour. This labour must either be imported from abroad 
 or created at home by instruction ; and in neither case is the
 
 Append I. "^ 11. 345 
 
 object sought for immediately furthered by Protective duties. It 
 would be better for the Government either to pay the passages of 
 the imported labourers, if immigration were necessary, or to bear 
 the cost of giving the required instruction to a sufficient number 
 of home labourers. Either of these methods of aid would be 
 .directed immediately to the object aimed at, and would be free 
 from the grave objection to which Protection is open, of placing 
 difficulties in the way of every industry which requires to make use 
 of the Protected article. In fact, it must be plain that Protective 
 duties can be of no advantage until the producers have begun to 
 make the article ; but none the less they lay a heavy burden on the 
 community from the first day on which they are collected ; while 
 the benefits which they confer at a later stage in the history of an 
 industry after it has been started, but before it is able to hold its 
 own are open to the further objections that they come too late and 
 are scattered indiscriminately upon those who may deserve them 
 and those who certainly do not. 
 
 The founder of a new industry in a young country does un- 
 doubtedly confer a benefit upon the whole community at his own 
 personal expense and risk ; so that it may be sometimes desirable, 
 in the cases which Mr. Mill has put, that Government should 
 encourage men to make experiments in new industrial ventures. 
 But of all modes of giving this encouragement, Protection is the 
 most ill-advised, being at once unjust and unsuccessful. The help 
 which it gives comes after the time of difficulty has gone by, and 
 is given with equal readiness both to the enterprising originator of 
 the industry and every one who rushes into the business upon the 
 strength of his experience. By this competition prices are certain 
 to be reduced, until the originator of the industry may lose the 
 advantages of the monopoly, which was created as his reward 
 If Government aid is really required, either as a stimulus to new 
 experiments or a reward for successful ones, it ought to take a 
 form which will give the benefit with as much discrimination as 
 possible to those who deserve it, and witli as little hardship as 
 possible to the mass of the consumers. Either the ]iaymcnt of a 
 money sum by way of bonus for the first production of the required 
 article at home, or the granting of an allowance to the originator 
 of an industry to enable him to sell his goods at market rates 
 during his temporary inability to compete with the foreigner, or 
 the letting of a Government contract at a non-competitive rate 
 would serve the doulile purpose of reward and encouragement
 
 346 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 without much inconvenience to the mass of consumers. Any of 
 these methods of aid, moreover, has the advantage that it can be 
 easily withdrawn ; while a Protective tariff, once imposed, remains 
 an incubus which can only be removed by serious civil strife. The 
 essential ingredients in any form of Government assistance 
 should be that it was terminable at a fixed period, and that both 
 the persons who receive it and the amount which each receives 
 should be easily ascertainable. Protection does not satisfy either 
 of these requirements. 
 
 No form of Government aid, however, is free from objection. 
 Bonuses, bounties, special contracts, or any other form of subsidy, 
 are in the long run demoralising both to the recipients and to the 
 public life of the country, both as being premiums on laziness and 
 occasions for fraud. It is so easy for all concerned to receive and 
 pay money according to the terms of some agreement, that neither 
 can a manufacturer be expected to shorten this period of gratuitous 
 assistance nor a civil servant to watch very closely all the details 
 of a manufacturing process or check the figures of a ledger. In 
 any bargain of this kind with the State the manufacturer is sure to 
 get the best of it. 
 
 Fortunately, experience proves that Government assistance is 
 not required to start new industries in a young country. If there 
 is a risk of failure in a young country owing to the inexperience of 
 all concerned, the conditions of the country soften the failure very 
 much. In a small country new industries must be on a small 
 scale ; and no large expenditure, whether Government assistance 
 be extended or withheld, would be required to embark upon the 
 experimental stages of a new industry. Consequently, we may 
 watch every demand for State aid with more than ordinary suspicion, 
 without being haunted by any sentimental fear lest in protecting 
 the State purse against the raids of interested persons we are 
 delaying the development of our country. Healthy enterprises 
 and profitable trades are sure to be developed without assistance ; 
 while if there be any natural industry which ought to start at once, 
 and is prevented by the want of Government assistance, the 
 question must be still answered whether it is not better to lose 
 the industry than to enter on the perilous path of State aid.
 
 APPENDIX III. 
 
 Comparison between the Respective Rates of Progress 
 OF New South Wales and Victoria since 1866. 
 
 I. The risk of pressing too far any argument, which rests upon a 
 comparison between the condition of different countries, has been 
 already alluded to in these pages, and attention has been called to 
 the passage in which Mr. Giffen points out, with admirable lucidity, 
 the requisites under which alone any such comparison is admis- 
 sible. These requisites exist more nearly as between New South 
 Wales and Victoria than between any other countries, so that, if 
 the argument from comparison is ever admissible, it will be in 
 their case. Both of them are young countries, and are inhabited 
 by men of the same race, speech, and training : capital and labour 
 oscillate freely between them : both use substantially the same 
 methods and forms of government : while, against the larger terri- 
 tory of New South Wales may be set the superior climate and 
 easier development of its southern neighbour. Whatever may be 
 the balance of the natural advantages, whether of climate or popu- 
 lation, is on the side of Victoria, whose compact, fertile, and well- 
 watered territory gained for it, on its first discovery, the well- 
 deserved title of Australia Felix. The striking and ultimate point 
 of difference between the two countries is their fiscal policy. Since 
 1866 Victoria has lived under a system of gradually increasing 
 Protection, while the policy of New South Wales has been, in the 
 main, one of Free Trade. According to all Protectionist theory 
 Victoria should be prosperous and New South Wales distressed ; 
 there should be variety and growth in the one country, stagnation 
 in the other. At least the progress of Victoria ought to have been 
 more rapid than that of New South Wales, because she has added 
 to the natural advantages which she already enjoyed, the artificial 
 benefits which are claimed for a Protective tariff. 
 
 If, in fact, neither of these conclusions is correct, and, while 
 both countries have been phenomenally prosperous, New South 
 Wales has prospered the most, one of two conclusions is inevit- 
 able namely, either that certain special influences have caused 
 the more rapid progress of New South Wales which were not felt
 
 34^ Industrial Freedom. 
 
 in Victoria, or that Protection has retarded instead of assisted the 
 development of Victoria's natural superiority. 
 
 2. Writers of all schools admit that activity in certain depart- 
 ments of national life is a fair indication of prosperity and progress. 
 It is, for instance, generally allowed that an increase in popula- 
 tion, a development of agricultural and manufacturing industry, a 
 growth of foreign commerce, an increase in shipping, or an 
 improvement in the public revenue, are all signs of health 
 and well-being ; and that a concurrence of such symptoms 
 over a lengthened period indicates an increase in material 
 wealth. 
 
 Accepting these tests of progress, our comparison proceeds 
 thus : first, we examine the position of the two Colonies as regards 
 population, foreign commerce, shipping, agriculture, manufac- 
 tures, and revenue, at the time when both of them adhered to 
 Free Trade ; from which we find that, according to all these indi- 
 cations of prosperity, Victoria was then very much the better off : 
 In 1866 she outnumbered New South Wales in population by 
 200,000 souls : her foreign commerce was larger by /^8,3oo.ooo : she 
 had a greater area of land under cultivation : her manufactures were 
 well established, while those of New South Wales were few and 
 insignificant : she was ahead in shipping, and her revenue was 
 greater by one-third. 
 
 Passing next to the years which follow 1866, we observe that 
 New South Wales gradually bettered her position in every 
 province of national activity, and that, as the fetters of Protection 
 became tighter, V'ictoria receded in the race. She gave way first 
 in the department of foreign commerce, next in population, 
 shipping, and revenue, until, in 1887, she maintained her old 
 superiority in agriculture alone. 
 
 From this accumulation of facts and not from any one of 
 them we infer that the rate of progress in New South Wales 
 under Free Trade has been greater than that of \'ictoria under 
 Protection ; and we use this fact (without at present claiming the 
 credit of it for Free Trade, or seeking for its explanation) as one, 
 which, whatever its explanation may be, is proof by itself that the 
 Protectionist dogma as to the inability of a young country under 
 any circumstances to make rapid progress without Protection 
 is contrary to experience. " Either prosperity in a Free 
 Trade country, or distress in a Protectionist country, is," as
 
 Appendix III. 349 
 
 Professor Summer has said, " fatal to the Protectionist 
 theory." 
 
 3. Having established our facts, we next seek to explain 
 them ; and in doing so have first to consider the various explana- 
 tions offered by Protectionists. These are three in number. 
 P^irst, they say that the comparison between New South Wales 
 and Victoria ought not to be made, because the conditions of the 
 two countries are not similar; and they specially insist upon the 
 earlier foundation and the larger territory of the Free Trade 
 Colony. This argument we meet by a plea in confession and 
 avoidance, to drop for a moment into the apt language of the 
 lawyer's art ; the facts may be admitted, but the use which is made 
 of them must be contested. We shall have to show that whatever 
 advantages the circumstances referred to may give to New South 
 Wales are more than compensated for by other advantages 
 peculiar to Victoria. 
 
 The second argument by which Protectionists attempt to 
 depreciate the signiticance of the New South Wales superiority is 
 by insisting that her growth is due to certain special causes such 
 as the expenditure of borrowed money, and the sale of public 
 lands which have no connection with the fiscal dispute. Here, 
 again, the facts will be admitted, and it will be conceded that both 
 these and other causes have contributed most materially to the 
 rapid progress of New South Wales. But it will also be shown 
 that whatever influences besides Free Trade have aided New 
 South Wales, have also aided \^ictoria with even greater intensity. 
 Thus, the very facts which are advanced as a disparagement will 
 be used as further evidence of the efilcacy of a Free Trade 
 policy. 
 
 Having thus sketched the outline of the argument which 
 follows, we arc in a position to enter upon the details with less 
 risk of confusion. 
 
 POI'ULATIOX. 
 
 The first element of greatness to a young country is populalion. 
 .'\ new- land needs to Ijc (lc\clopcd b}' strou;;' arms, and e\ t!'\-\\ lu-re 
 ciics aloud foi" men. It is true that congestions iii the labour iiiarkcL 
 or; iir at limes in Australia as elsewhere, but tliey must not be taken 
 as an nidieation of o\'er-iioj)ula'ion. F\er\' new coimtr\- ' dutains 
 a resiiluun\ of ciinainals antl ne'cr-do-wcels who, from oni- cause or 
 atio'.her, arc unfit for work ; wliik; Austral;, i po::se~ ics. in a'lcliiion.a
 
 35 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 class of genuine lazzaroni, whose dislike of any steady occupa- 
 tion is encouraged by a genial climate and a reckless system oi 
 public and private almsgiving. During the greater part of the 
 year the shelter of a roof at night is neither requisite nor comfort- 
 able ; while for the inclement season, food and lodging can be had 
 in every capital either gratuitously or for a minimum of work. 
 Besides this voluntary pauperism, there is in every Colony a certain 
 element of casually employed persons, consisting of artisans and 
 clerks, who experience real suffering in times of depression, from 
 inability or unwillingness to leave the cities and seek new kinds of 
 occupation in the country. Still, after making every allowance for 
 temporary dislocations of industry, it is safe to say that the danger 
 of over-population is not within the limits of practical Australian 
 politics ; and that, even in times of greatest depression, thousands 
 of able-bodied men could always obtain work in any Colony at 
 good, and even high, wages. The growth of population is thus a 
 crucial test of Australian prosperity, which can be applied without 
 qualification to all the Colonies, because none has any pre-eminence 
 in "unemployed." The class of the "unemployed" contains the 
 same elements in all, and passes freely from one to the other, 
 as political agitation or other causes makes its existence no- 
 torious.^ 
 
 In 1866, the year in which Protection was introduced, the 
 
 1 An illustration of this occurred in Sydney towards the close of 1886, when 
 a Protectionist Government gave indiscriminate relief, without any labour test, 
 shortly before a general election. The natural consequence was that the float- 
 ing population of all the Colonies drifted to Sydney, where 6,000 men were at 
 one time being lodged and fed by the Government. After the elections, during 
 which this body of "unemployed" was freely used as an argument against 
 Free Trade, Sir Henry Parkes, who had succeeded to power, found himself 
 unable to disband so large an army in the streets of Sydney, and adopted the 
 plan of creating employment on Crown lands for all who wished it, while at the 
 same time he stopped the indiscriminate relief in Sydney. It was more than a 
 year before the labour market which had become quite disorganised by the 
 inducements offered to country labourers to throw up their work, either to 
 enjoy a visit to Sydney, or to earn (as good workmen could) more than their 
 usual wage by piece-work on the Crown lands resumed its normal condi- 
 tion. An incident occurred during this period which illustrates in an amusing 
 fashion the popular view of the " right to employment " as it finds expression in 
 Australia. In June, 1887, the "unemployed," who were then working at the 
 Field of Mars for 5s. a day, petitioned the Cabinet to be allowed "a day's 
 holiday to celebrate the Jubilee," so completely had they come to regard 
 themselves as a State institution.
 
 Appendix III. 351 
 
 population of Victoria amounted to 636,982 human beings, as against 
 431,412 in New South Wales. In 1881, the relative numbers were 
 862,346 and 751,468. In 1886 the numbers were estimated in both 
 Colonies at a million. Victoria then gained a little during the 
 Exhibition year in 1888, but in 1889 New South Wales again took 
 the lead with 1,122,200, as against 1,118,077, and has maintained it 
 to the present time. During the period from 1866-89, the increase 
 was only 75 per cent, for the Protected Colony, while it was 140 
 per cent, for the Free Trade Colony. The increase from 1871 to 
 1 88 1 was 30'9i per cent, in New South Wales, and only 18 per 
 cent, in Victoria ; and from 1881 to 1888 it was 44*43 per cent, in 
 the former, and only 26*50 per cent, in the latter Colony. While 
 in the former decade the difference in the rate of increase was 
 1 2*91 per cent., it was i8'43 per cent, during the latter period, 
 thus proving that the increase of Protective duties is not 
 necessarily accompanied pari passu by an increase in popu- 
 lation.^ 
 
 Popular prejudice, anxious to minimise as much as possible 
 this rapid growth in the numbers of a Free Trade Colony, where, 
 according to all theory, no man ought to be able to get a living, 
 has attributed it to State-assisted immigration. There were, how- 
 ever, during the period from 1881-87, when the increase in popula- 
 tion was most rapid, only 32,744 assisted immigrants ; while the 
 whole number of State-assisted immigrants between 1866 and 1889 
 only amounted to 59,000, as against a total increase of 690,788 
 souls. Assisted immigration can accordingly account for only 8'5 
 per cent, of the whole increase. 
 
 The real reasons must be sought elsewhere, and will be found in 
 the greater attractiveness of New South Wales as a place of resi- 
 dence, in its higher marriage rate, and its higher birth rate 
 three causes which, either separately or together, indicate a higher 
 range of material prosperity. We will treat of each sepa- 
 rately. 
 
 The most noticeable fact which is disclosed by the Victorian 
 Census of 1 87 1 and i88r, is that, next to the little island of Tasmania, 
 A'ictoria has the greatest proportion of females to males of any 
 Australian Colony, which is the more remarkable when we recall 
 
 ' I am iiidehted for tliese calculations, which are taken from the ofticial 
 records, to a pamphlet by W. Max Hirsch, entitled, " Protection in Victoria" 
 (Melljourne : Echo Publishing Company, 1891) sec p. 10.
 
 352 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 the circumstances of her origin in the gold fever of the early fifties. 
 Victoria in those days had an enormous excess of males. Further, 
 we find that this unhappy disproportion between the sexes is grow- 
 ing rather than diminishing in the Protected Colony. The follow- 
 ing table shows the figures as compared with those of New South 
 Wales ; 
 
 Percentage of 
 
 Fem.vles in the Total Population. 
 
 Year. 
 
 New South Wales. Victoria. 
 
 l88r 
 1888 
 1891 
 
 45 '8 47 '5 
 44 "3 466 
 
 46-5 47-8 
 
 Pursue the investigation a little further. 
 
 The census returns for 1881 showed that Victoria like the 
 exhausted countries of Europe was actually not sustaining her 
 own population ! During the ten years, 1871 to 1881, the returns 
 show that 53,000 persons emigrated to Victoria, but that 68,000 
 persons left. In other words, during these ten years of active Pro- 
 tection, adopted professedly in order to "give employment," 
 Victoria not only lost all her immigration, but also 15,000 of her 
 natural increase 1 The figures of the last census in 1891 will be 
 awaited with much interest. 
 
 r\Iorc significant still is the change in the quality of the A^ctorian 
 population. The class of citizen which every country wishes most 
 to keep is that of the "soldier's age,'' from 20 to 40. Yet in 1881, 
 in spite of her much larger population, Victoria was found to 
 possess about 18,000 fewer men at this desirable range of age than 
 New South Wales. On this point, Mr. Hayter, who certainly 
 cannot be accused of giving undue prominence to any fact which 
 tells against Victoria, makes the following remarks in his "General 
 Report" on the Census: "It will be noticed that the contingent 
 available from A'ictoria is smaller by 18,000 than that from New 
 .SdUth Wales, and a simple calculation will show that rclalivcl)- to 
 the total population, males at the soklier's age arc fewer in \'it:toria 
 than in any of the other Australasian Colonies. In fact, it may be 
 stated thai the deficiency of males, at this important period of life, 
 is the weakest |)(iint in the A'ictorian population."' U|)on this 
 passage Mr. h'dward I'ni>roi-d, who was the fii-.-^l to in\-e>tigate the 
 bearing of tlic Victorian ])opulaiion returns upon the fi.-^cal con- 
 1rovcr"v. remarks as follows- "Tlic rream (^{ the ' effecii\e '
 
 Appendix III. 353 
 
 
 
 population of a country may be said to be the males between 25 and 
 45. The changes in this portion of the people in the two Colonies 
 during the decade were simply extraordinary. New South Wales 
 showed a gain of 32,716, whilst Victoria showed a positive loss of 
 35,916. In 1871, Victoria was 52,138 ahead; in 1881, she was 
 16,494 behind a change against Victoria in the relative position of 
 no less than 68,632." 
 
 The following two tables will bring out more clearly still the 
 greater attraction which New South Wales exercises on men in the 
 prime of life, and the loss which Victoria sustains through the 
 emigration of this economically most valuable section of its 
 population : 
 
 Males in 1881. 
 
 ^'icloria. New South Wales. 
 
 Up to 25 years old 257,069 = 56 '86 per cent. ... 229,342 ^ 5578 per cent.. 
 From 25 to 45 years 
 
 old 99,497=^22 ,, ,, ... 115.991 = 28"22 ,, ,, 
 
 45 years old and over 95,579 = 21 '14 ,, ,, ... 65,816 = 16 ,, ,, 
 
 452,143 ... 411,149 
 
 Males between the Ages of 25 .\.\d 45 years. 
 
 \'ictoria. New South Wales. 
 
 1871 . . 135,413 = i8"i per cent. ... 83,275 = 107 per cent.. 
 
 1881 . . 99,497 = 11-5,, ,, ... 115,991 = 154,, 
 
 Loss . 35,916 ... Gain . 32,716 
 
 Mr. Hirsch makes the following remarks upon these figures : 
 " In the first of these tables the percentages are those of the male 
 population ; in the latter, the percentage of the males in their prime 
 to the total population is given. The first table shows the result^ 
 viz., the greater percentage of men in the prime of life in New 
 South Wales ; the latter table shows that the shifting took place 
 in the years during which ^'ictoria enjoyed Protection ; that on 
 account or in spite of Protection young men are avoiding and 
 leaving the Protected Colony in which, if Protectionists are right, 
 they ought to find it easiest to make a living- are flocking into the 
 Colony in which they ought to find it most difficult to make a 
 living. In estimating the significance of these figures, it must not 
 be forgotten that, according to the general increase of population, 
 we ought to have had [in \'ictoria] in 1881 20,987 more males of 
 from twent\--five tt^ forty-five years than in 1S71, making our total
 
 354 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 loss of men in the prime of life 56,903 surely a most disastrous 
 retrogression in one decade. There is, however, nothing new in 
 these tables ; they are merely a confirmation of what has long been 
 generally known. Every traveller remarks upon the number of 
 Victorians engaged in trade and agriculture in New South Wales 
 and other Colonies, and the paucity of natives or former inhabitants 
 of New South Wales similarly engaged in Victoria. A more 
 significant fact by which to measure the result of Protection can 
 scarcely be asked for, for if the Protective policy had added to the 
 natural advantages of Victoria, then surely Victoria would have 
 powerfully attracted the workers in the prime of life from every 
 Colony, and even from over-sea. But the opposite is the case ; the 
 strong, the hopeful, the energetic, leave the Protected Colony, and 
 flock into the Free Trade Colony instead, proving conclusively that 
 there it is easiest for them to gain a comfortable livelihood." 
 
 But gain by immigration is not the only cause of the more rapid 
 increase of population in New South Wales, which is due also to a 
 higher marriage rate and a higher birth rate. 
 
 Now, as Mr. Hirsch points out, "it is one of the most firmly 
 established facts in the science of statistics that under present 
 social and economic conditions the numbers of marriages and 
 births rise and fall with any fall in the nation's prosperity ; that 
 steady employment at decent wages especially has the invariable 
 result of increasing the number of marriages and births. And it 
 must be held as similarly true that in two nations of similar origin, 
 the members of which are constantly intermingling, the social and 
 political institutions of which are the same, the more prosperous 
 nation, the one in which employment is more constant and eft'ec- 
 tive, wages higher, will show the greater number of marriages and 
 births." Tried by this unerring test, New South Wales again holds 
 her superiority over her Protected neighbour. 
 
 The mean annual marriage rate per 1,000 during the years 
 1866-1889 was, for Victoria, 690; for New South Wales, o-oo. 
 While the annual birlh rate for the same period was, for A'ictoria. 
 34-54, and for New South Wales 38-90. 
 
 The excess of births over deaths tolls the same taie : its mean 
 per 1. 000 of the population for the ten years from 1878-87 being 
 112 for A'ictoria, and 14S for New South Wales. 
 
 Indeed, from whate\er standpoint the movements of population 
 and the vital statistics of the two Colonies are considered, it is clear 
 tliat under Free Trade New South Wales has yaineJ upon
 
 Appendix III, 355 
 
 Victoria, not only by immigration, but by a more rapid increase in 
 the number of her native-born a significant commentary indeed 
 upon the theory that " Protection gives employment.'' Why did 
 it not give employment to those thousands of young men, within 
 the soldier's age, who emigrated from her borders into New South 
 Wales ? Is it that New South Wales is the more attractive 
 because she has a larger territory ? But had she not just the 
 same extent of territory in 1866, when Victoria, under Free Trade, 
 was able to feed her own sons ? Or is Victoria, with its 87,884 
 square miles of territory, not able to find employment for more than 
 a million people? When Victoria is over-populated it will be time 
 enough to raise the cry that New South Wales is drawing young 
 Victorians to her territory because their own land does not give 
 them so good an opportunity of earning a livelihood. It is " Pro- 
 tection" that was to have given the employment ! It has done so ! 
 It has made every one who stayed in Victoria work longer for 
 what he wants, and has driven the cream of Victorian youth out of 
 the Colony to earn honest livings in a Free Trade country ! But 
 was that the kind of employment which was so fraudulently 
 promised ? 
 
 The truth is manifest to all who will not refuse to see it that 
 the labour-market has been better in New South Wales than in 
 Victoria, and that the Free Trade Colony has offered the most 
 employment. One would as soon expect water to run uphill as 
 labour to leave a country of good wages and steady work for one 
 of inferior attractiveness from either point of view. Accordingly, 
 if New South Wales has gained upon Victoria in population, both 
 by voluntary immigration and by natural increase, since the latter 
 adopted Protection, the reason must be that the Free Trade Colony 
 has been more prosperous, and better able to ofter work at good 
 wages ; and further evidence in support of the fact should be 
 superfluous. It may, however, be useful to pile up testimony upon 
 this crucial point, and to show by other tests that Victorians have 
 gone to New South Wales for one very good reason that 
 they were better off there than they would have been at 
 home. 
 
 First, as to the respective rates of wages in the two countries. 
 So far as any comparison can be made between these and the 
 difficulty of such a comparison has Ijcen already pointed out^ it is
 
 356 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 in favour of New South Wales. Mr. Hirsch has compiled a table 
 from the Victorian Year-Book, showing the fluctuations in the 
 nominal wages of 121 trades, as returned by the Government statist. 
 This table shows that between 1878 and 1888, during which period 
 new duties were imposed to the annual amount of ;^ 1 80,000, no 
 change in wages had taken place in 58 of these 121 industries. 
 The alteration in the rates of wages for the remaining 63 employ- 
 ments classify themselves as follows : 
 
 Jicrea.se. 
 
 Decrease. 
 
 13 
 
 26 
 
 16 
 
 9 
 
 Protected trades 
 Unprotected trades . 
 
 showing that, while there has been, on the whole, a decline rather 
 than a rise in wages during the decade, the fall has taken place 
 more in the protected than in the unprotected trades. The rise in 
 wages has occurred chiefly in the farm pursuits, owing to the 
 scarcity of this kind of labour. It should also be remembered that 
 the official wage rates make no disclosure of the condition of the 
 large number of home-workers, who, as recent revelations have 
 shown, are working in Melbourne dens for is. 6d. and 2s. a day 
 under conditions which the Age., the leading Protectionist journal, 
 has described as being " as bad as anything to be found in 
 London." 
 
 It is true that wages have also fallen in New South Wales from 
 the highest point which they reached since 1866 ; but the Free 
 Traders have never claimed to be possessors of a patent system for 
 keeping wages high. Besides, so far as comparisons are possible, 
 they are higher in New South Wales than in Victoria. There is a 
 special difficulty in the way of making any such comparison in this 
 case, owing to the different methods of collecting the returns in the 
 two Colonies, and the different designations of many trades. Still, 
 Mr. Hirsch has collected twenty-nine trades all which it was 
 possible to collect and found that in 1888 wages in four of these 
 were equal in the two Colonies, were higher in \'ictoria in ten, and 
 lower in \'ictoria in fifteen instances. As he properly remarks, 
 " If the assertion that Protection increases wages were well 
 founded, no such result of even a partial comparison would be 
 possible.'' But perhaps the best guide to the average wage rate of 
 the two Colonies is furnished by the wages paid by the Governments 
 of each. In each Colony the Government owns the railways, post- 
 office, telegraphs, roads, forests, and carries on a great quantity of
 
 Appendix III. 
 
 357 
 
 public works. In all the Government departments the wages are 
 from sixpence to a shilling a day higher in New South Wales than 
 in Victoria. It is impossible to believe that the highly organised 
 trades in Victoria would allow railway servants, for example, to 
 receive a shilling a day less than the same class of labour was 
 receiving in New South Wales, unless they were conscious that the 
 lower rate fairly represented the average wage rate of the Colony. 
 In addition to these sources of information must be added private 
 experience. It is matter of common observation that the wages 
 paid to miners are higher in New South Wales than in Victoria, 
 and the writer verified the same fact by personal inquiry in regard 
 to the building trades for the year 1889-90. 
 
 All other possible sources of information point to the same 
 conclusion. 
 
 The consumption of working-class luxuries, such as tea, coffee, 
 sugar, currants, raisins, beer, spirits, and tobacco, is larger per 
 head in the Free Trade country, showing the obvious truth that 
 men who receive more have more to spend. 
 
 The following are the figures for the year 1884-5, ^vhich is taken 
 as a normal year, being before the boom in Victoria and after that 
 in New South Wales: 
 
 Consumption of Luxuries in 16 
 New South Wales. 
 
 Tea . 
 Coffee 
 
 Sugar . 
 
 Currants, raisins, etc. 
 
 .Spirits 
 
 Beer ... 
 
 Tobacco 
 
 127 ozs. 
 
 II M 
 
 102 lbs. 
 Ill ozs. 
 
 20-4 gills. 
 
 16.2 gals. 
 
 46 ozs. 
 
 -5 PER HEAD. 
 
 Victoria. 
 no ozs. 
 
 16 ,, 
 
 92I lbs. 
 982 ozs. 
 18.L gills. 
 J 6 gals. 
 354 ozs. 
 
 Pointing, again, in the same direction are the figures which 
 show the quantity of postal and telegraphic communication in the 
 two Colonies. 
 
 In 1866 Victoria received and despatched nearly two million 
 more letters than New South Wales, the figures being 8,631,133 as 
 against 6,678,371. In 1885 the positions were reversed, and New 
 .South Wales received and despatched three million more letters than 
 Victoria, the figures being : New South Wales, 39,35 1,200, or 40 per 
 head of the population ; and 36,061,880, or 36 per head, for Victoria. 
 
 The number of telegrams sent in Victoria in 1S66 was 277,788, 
 as against 143,523 in New South Wales. In 18S5, New South 
 Wales sent 2,625,992, against 1,634,666.
 
 35^ Industrial Freedom. 
 
 In fact, to whatever test of progress we look, we arrive at the 
 same conclusion namely, that since Victoria adopted Protection, 
 New South Wales has been steadily gaining upon her. But some 
 of the tests are of sufficient importance to demand a detailed con- 
 sideration. Chief among them is the progress in either Colony of 
 the manufacturing industry. 
 
 MANUFACTURES. 
 
 No young country can pass from the agricultural or pastoral to 
 the manufacturing stage of its existence until it has obtained a 
 sufficient density of population to enable production to be carried 
 on with that effective cheapness which comes from the subdivision 
 of employments and the establishment of subsidiary industries for 
 using up bye-products. In 1866 the population of Victoria was 
 already concentrated in the mining centres ; while that of New 
 South Wales was scattered over a wide area, through which the 
 means of communication were few and primitive. As a natural 
 consequence A'ictoria became a manufacturing Colony earlier than 
 New South Wales. It is true that New South Wales has better 
 facilities for manufactures in her rich deposits of coal and iron ; 
 but the advantage of these may be easily overestimated, unless it 
 is remembered that the coal goes to both capitals by sea, and that 
 the cost of 500 miles longer sea carriage is not a serious item in 
 these days of fuel economy. It is accordingly not surprising to 
 find that, while there were 869 manufactories and works in Victoria 
 in 1866, exclusive of 1 14 flour mills, the manufactories and works 
 of New South Wales were at that date too insignificant to be 
 counted. 
 
 Since 1866 the whole energy of \'ictorian legislation has been 
 directed to the development of manufactures ; while, except as to a 
 few industries, such as the kerosene and candle, which have 
 benefited by duties originally imposed for revenue purposes, the 
 development of manufactures in New South Wales has taken a 
 natural growth. The figures speak for themselves. 
 
 In twenty-five years of Free Trade the pastoral Colony of New 
 South Wales had made so good an entrance into the manufacturing 
 stage of its existence that in 1890 it employed 46,135 hands, or 
 more than one-tenth of its adult population, in one or other of the 
 120 distinct varieties of manufacturing industries, in which the 
 plant and machinery was valued at ^4,526,821, and worked
 
 Appendix III. 
 
 359 
 
 to a horse-power of 24,662. Surely this would not be a 
 bad record, either of growth or diversity, even for a Protected 
 country ! 
 
 The record of V'ictoria is also good, but certainly not better 
 than, if, indeed, it is equal to, that of New South Wales.. It is 
 difficult, however, to decide this cjuestion, because the method of 
 classification, and the dates of making the returns of manufacturing 
 statistics, do not correspond in the two Colonies. The subjoined 
 table, however, will show the respective rates of progress of each. 
 
 YEAR. 
 
 1880. 
 
 1885. 
 Mctori.i.Iy. S. W. 
 
 1S89 
 
 1890. 
 
 \'ictoria. 
 
 N. S. W. 
 
 \-ictoria. '.\. S. W. 
 
 Victoria .V. S.W. 
 
 Number of hands 
 employed ... 
 
 Value of machinery, 
 
 plant, and land ... 
 
 (Thousands omitted) 
 
 Number of establish- 
 ments"! 
 
 Horse power 
 
 33,247 
 6,711 
 
 2,239 
 
 28,259 
 
 j 
 49,066 , 41,669 
 
 j 
 10,166 
 
 I 
 
 2,841 -- 
 
 39,169+ 
 15,612 
 
 3-137 
 
 46,135 
 11,603 
 
 2,926 
 
 58,175 + 
 
 46,525+ 
 .,_t83 
 
 * Where blank spaces are left the figures are either untrustwortliy or at present un- 
 attainable. I'he method of collecting New South Wales figures was radically altered 
 after i836, when the present statistician, Mr. Coghlan, was first appointed. 
 
 t These figures are from an estimate made by Mr. Hayter, the statistician of the 
 Victorian Government, as published in the Arg7/so( December 30th, 1891. 
 
 *\ Many of these employ very few hands. Thus over three hundred of the works 
 included in the Victorian returns emploj' less than six hands, and more than one thousand 
 employ less than ten. 
 
 The above table puts the case of the \'ictorian manufactories in 
 the most favourable light. Not only arc some 2,300 hands in- 
 cluded in the \'ictorian returns which are e.xcludcd from those of 
 New South Wales,' but these also include between four and five 
 thousand more females, whom the harder conditions of life in the 
 Protected Colony have dri\en from the home to the factory." 
 P\irther, the later Victorian figures are for a time of high pro- 
 sperity consequent upon the lavish expenditure of imported and 
 borrowed capital, while duiing the same period New .South Wales 
 was exi)ericncing the pangs of a period of economy, and was also 
 
 1 Xaniely, employees in cliaffcutting and corn-crushing establishments, in 
 flour mills, in cheese factories, and the Roval Mint. 
 
 - Tliere were <j02 females included in. tb.e Xew Stv.-.th Wale's returns f ^ r 
 l8r,o.
 
 6o Industrial Freedom. 
 
 recovering from the most severe drought known in her history'. 
 The figures for 1891 would show an increase for New South Wales 
 and a decrease for Victoria. Let us, however, pass by all these 
 considerations, and grant a superiority (and, if it be desired, even a 
 substantial superiority) to Victoria in manufactures : two questions 
 will still remain to be answered first, Whether this superiority is 
 as great now as it was in 1866, having regard to the increase of 
 population .' and, secondly. Whether, if it be so, such a superiority 
 has been worth the expenditure required to obtain it ? Let no 
 deductions be made on any score, and even count it a good thing 
 that women should be forced to leave their homes to seek employ- 
 ment in a factory ; let us,in short, admit that Victoria has an excess 
 over New South Wales of fully 12,000 manufacturing hands ; yet at 
 what cost has this excess been gained '^. The Customs duties levied 
 on Protected articles have by themselves amounted during the last 
 twenty-five years to twenty millions of pounds, without taking into 
 account the increase in the price of the home-made article, which 
 is consequent upon the tariff. May not Free Traders fairly ask 
 whether, if it was really necessary to Victorian prosperity that she 
 should confine 12,000 of her population (of whom one-third are 
 females) within the four walls of factories in order to be by that 
 number superior to New South Wales in the tale of manufacturing 
 employees, twenty millions of pounds sterling is not a high price to 
 have paid for this questionable advantage ? Twenty millions of 
 pounds would have pensioned those 12,000 working hands, men, 
 women, and children (and children, too, are being driven with their 
 mothers to enter the Protected factories, so hard is the stress of life 
 becoming in this Victorian paradise !), many times over, at more 
 than the rate which they are now receiving in wages from the 
 afflicted consumer ! If only the recipients of Protective charity 
 could be compelled to receive their alms, as honest beggars, in a 
 public manner ! 
 
 Nor is an inside view of the condition of ^"ictorian manufactures 
 any more encouraging. On the contrary, while the number of 
 employees is declining, and women and boys are taking the place 
 (if men, the exports of manufactured produce show a steady annual 
 decline, and the imports of foreign goods a steady increase. The 
 limit of consumption within the Colony has long ago been reached, 
 and although an outlet was afforded for several years into the 
 neighbouring Colonies by means of an elaljoratc system of fraud, 
 under which the drawbacks were manipulated in such a way as to
 
 Appendix III. 
 
 361 
 
 become a bonus upon exports,^ the productiveness of the Protected 
 industries is steadily decreasing. Year by year, Mr. Hayter, who 
 certainly cannot be accused of giving undue prominence to facts 
 which tell against Victoria, has pointed out the ominous decrease 
 in the value of Victorian exports, and the equally ominous increase 
 in Victorian indebtedness. The figures from 1880 are subjoined. 
 
 Exports of Articles Manufactured or 
 FROM 1880-90. 
 
 Produced in \'ictoria 
 
 
 Year. 
 
 Total Value, omitting 
 
 Value per 
 
 Hea 
 
 d of the 
 
 
 Thousands. 
 
 Population. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 s. 
 
 d. 
 
 
 1880 
 
 11,220,000 
 
 13 
 
 3 
 
 II 
 
 
 1881 
 
 12,480,000 
 
 14 
 
 7 
 
 3 
 
 
 1882 
 
 i2,57cf|ooo 
 
 14 
 
 2 
 
 5 
 
 
 1883 
 
 13,292,000 
 
 14 
 
 II 
 
 9 
 
 
 1884 
 
 13.t55.000 
 
 14 
 
 I 
 
 8 
 
 
 i88t 
 
 12,452,000 
 
 12 
 
 19 
 
 10 
 
 
 1886 
 
 9,054,000 
 
 9 
 
 3 
 
 6 
 
 
 1887 
 
 8,502,000 
 
 8 
 
 6 
 
 9 
 
 
 18S8 
 
 10,356,000 
 
 9 
 
 15 
 
 
 
 
 1889 
 
 9,776,000 
 
 8 
 
 17 
 
 I 
 
 
 1890 
 
 1891 
 
 
 
 
 
 In this table the exports of manufactured articles and of home 
 produce are lumped together. If the former were dealt with 
 separately, the decline would be still more apparent. On p. 131 of 
 vol. ii. of the "Victorian Year-Book" for 1889-90, Mr. Hayter gives 
 a list of thirty-five lines of Victorian articles of export. The 
 majority of these are raw materials, which are not afilected by 
 duties. More than half of the value in the list is provided by the 
 two articles of wool and gold, although more than one-half of the 
 wool exported as Victorian produce is grown in New South Wales 
 and shipjicd from Melbourne either because of its proximity, 
 or because ''Port Phillip" wool commands a traditionally high 
 price. Taking out from this list all articles which may, with a 
 
 1 Public attention was first called to this system of fraud in 1886 by Mr. 
 Edward Pulsford, Secretary of tlie Free Tratle Association of New .South 
 Wales, and Honorary Member of the Cobden Club. His assertions wore at 
 first denied and ridiculed ; but ultimately, after an official investigation, his 
 charges were verified. Many of tlie first firms in Melbourne were fotmd to be 
 implicated, but no prosecutions followed. Tliere could hardly be a better 
 llustration of the demoralisation which a tariff causes.
 
 ;62 
 
 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 stretch of the term, be classified as manufactured products, we get 
 at the following result : 
 
 Exports 
 
 OF Articles the Maxc! 
 
 ACTUKE OK Victoria 
 
 SINCE 1883. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Increase 
 
 Articles. 
 
 1883. 
 
 1884. 
 
 18S5. \ 
 
 1 386. 
 
 1887. 
 
 iS88. 
 
 1889. 
 
 + ; De- 
 crease 
 
 
 
 
 . 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Stationerj' 
 
 23,300 
 
 22,100 
 
 1 7, 900 
 
 14,300 
 
 13,200 
 
 15,400 
 
 1 6, coo 
 
 - 7,300 
 
 Agricultural Im- 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 plements 
 
 14,100 
 
 10,300 
 
 11,000 
 
 11,700 
 
 15,600 
 
 15,600 
 
 22,000 
 
 + 7,9=0 
 
 Machinery 
 
 138,000 
 
 98,000 
 
 73,000 
 
 48,000 
 
 90,000 
 
 56,000 
 
 62,000 
 
 76,000 
 
 Saddlery, Har- 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 ness 
 
 22,OC0 
 
 14,000 
 
 13,000 
 
 9,800 
 
 7,100 
 
 IO,OCO 
 
 6,Soo ' 
 
 15,200 
 
 Furniture and 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Upholstery ... 
 
 46,800 
 
 43,700 
 
 39,000 
 
 24,000 
 
 20,000 
 
 22,000 
 
 17,600 
 
 29,300 
 
 Drugs, Chemi- 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 cals 
 
 15,000 
 
 12,000 
 
 17,000 
 
 13,000 
 
 10,600 
 
 7,003 
 
 4,700 
 
 10,300 
 
 Woollen Piece 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Goods 
 
 12,000 
 
 10,600 
 
 4,100 
 
 2,700 
 
 1,800 
 
 9,003 
 
 2,600 
 
 9,400 
 
 Apparel & Slops 
 
 246,000 
 
 257,000 
 
 242,000 
 
 155,000 
 
 117,000 
 
 121,800 
 
 9S,ooo 
 
 - 148,000 
 
 Boots and Shoes 
 
 40,000 
 
 37,000 
 
 25,000 
 
 21,000 
 
 23,000 
 
 21,000 
 
 16, OCO 
 
 24,000 
 
 Cordage 
 
 27,600 
 
 29, OCO 
 
 20,600 
 
 9,000 
 
 5,000 
 
 4,000 
 
 4,600 
 
 23 030 
 
 Preserved Meats 
 
 76,000 
 
 116,000 
 
 99,800 
 
 88,000 
 
 41,000 
 
 16,000 
 
 16,030 
 
 5o,ooo 
 
 Confectionery... 
 
 15,700 
 
 13,000 
 
 11,000 
 
 6,700 
 
 3,700 
 
 2,800 
 
 2,7CO 
 
 13 000 
 
 Biscuits 
 
 27,600 
 
 40,000 
 
 45,coo , 
 
 37,600 
 
 26,800 
 
 20, 900 
 
 20,600 
 
 7,000 
 
 Bone dust 
 
 8,900 
 
 n,300 
 
 14,400 
 
 9,600 
 
 5,200 
 
 11,300 
 
 11,000 
 
 + 1,100 
 
 Candles 
 
 300 
 
 3,6oD 
 
 7,000 
 
 5,000 
 
 1,600 
 
 500 
 
 300 
 
 
 
 Glue Pieces 
 
 600 
 
 1,000 
 
 I, coo 
 
 1,700 
 
 1,700 
 
 1,500 
 
 900 
 
 -r 300 
 
 Leather 
 
 359,000 
 
 338,000 
 
 342,000 
 
 254,000 
 
 207,000 
 
 181,000 
 
 I9o,coo 
 
 -289,000 
 
 Soap 
 
 12,700 
 
 15,500 
 
 18,000 
 
 13,003 
 
 10,000 
 
 10,000 
 
 9, OCO 
 
 - 3,700 
 
 Stearine 
 
 13,000 
 
 6,000 
 
 
 5 
 
 96 
 
 503 
 
 85 
 
 - 12,900 
 
 Tallow 
 
 232,000 
 
 256,000 
 
 155,000 
 
 121,000 
 
 85,000 
 
 157,000 
 
 49, coo 
 
 
 
 Oil 
 
 8,000 
 
 9,000 
 
 7,6co 
 
 7,000 
 
 3,600 
 
 2, coo 
 
 1,803 
 
 6,2CO 
 
 Hardware 
 
 28,030 
 
 24,000 
 
 i9,cc'_ 
 
 20, Boo 
 
 16, coo 
 
 15,800 
 
 15,000 
 
 13,000 
 
 Oilmen's Stores 
 
 13, coo 
 
 I=,OOD 
 
 i4,o;o 
 
 11,800 
 
 13,600 
 
 11,000 
 
 9,000 
 
 - 4,000 
 
 All other Articles 
 
 410,700 
 
 439,000 
 
 1,570.?.:.:. I 
 
 324,000 
 
 265,000 
 
 222,000 
 
 234,003 
 
 - 1 70,000 
 
 Total 
 
 1,793,300 
 
 1,82 4,103 
 
 2.^.0,705 
 
 933,596 
 
 934,ico 
 
 819, ';85 
 
 - 1,1 io,3CO 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 -i- 9,300 
 
 The same conclusion as to the decline of Victorian manufac- 
 tures is given by another table in Mr. Hayter's book (p. 133)) '^i 
 which the total increase or decrease of exports of all articles of 
 home produce, as between 18S9 and 1888, is given in detail, with 
 the result of showing a nctt decrease on the year of ^579,963. It 
 is noticeable, however, that this nett decrease is kept down to this 
 comparatively low figure by reason of an increase of ^1,438,593 in 
 the value of wool exported, and of ;/^i 29,498 in the value of the 
 export of gold bullion. Deducting these two items, the nett 
 decrease in the year would be 7^2, 148,054 ; while if the nett 
 decrease on manufactured products only were considered, it would 
 amount to the large sum of /!2, 256,395. 
 
 These figures have a double significance. First they show that 
 the export of \'ictorian manufactures has not been anything to
 
 Appexdix III. 363 
 
 boast of during the last eight years, and that, in spite of every effort 
 to force manufactures, eleven-twelfths of the exports from Victoria 
 consist of food-stuffs and raw materials. They also show, in the 
 plainest manner, the withering influence of Protection upon the 
 aggregate of national industry. The export trade of a country is a 
 generally accepted test of the vigour of its national productiveness. 
 Consequently, a fall in eight years from ^14 us. gd. per head to 
 Z 17s. id. in the total export trade which is equivalent to a fall 
 of 39'303 per cent. and a fall of 32'925 per cent, during the same 
 period in the exports of manufactured produce, ought to shake 
 the confidence of the most infatuated believer in the infallibility of 
 the Protectionist dogma ! Further, when this decline in exports 
 which are the only means by which a borrowing country is able 
 to discharge its indebtedness and pay its interest on loans^is 
 accompanied by a rapidly increasing excess of imports, no one 
 who remembers that the excess of imports over exports represents 
 in a young country which does not receive much from foreign 
 investments, or for shipping, or other services rendered by its 
 citizens in other countries, or by immigration the amount of new 
 capital which it has borrowed can view the present condition of 
 Victorian commerce without alarm. Unless the tarift" is altered in 
 such a way as to give the natural industries of \'ictoria a better 
 opportunity of growth, or unless the irrigation experiments, which 
 are being pushed with so much vigour, falsify the predictions of 
 many experts and provide new articles of exports in the shape of 
 fruit and wine, it is certain that the task of dealing with the finances 
 of Victoria will tax the capacity and ingenuity of her rulers for 
 many years to come.^ The combination of Protection and borrow- 
 ing must result in a serious crisis. 
 
 ' The following figures show the excess of imports over exports since 1881, 
 omitting figures below five hundred : 
 
 ^. 
 81 ... ... ... 466,000 
 
 882 ... ... ... 2,554,000 
 
 803 ... ... ... 1,34^,900 Of thi.s .sum, ;^ii,2i9,coo re- 
 
 884 ... ... ... 3,151,000 presented an increase in 
 
 885 2,4j2,8oo the public indebtednes.s, not 
 
 886 ... ... ... 6,735,000 taking into account redemp- 
 
 8S7 ... ... ... 7,67i,o.:o tion loan.s, amounting to 
 
 883 ... ... ... io,iiS,oo3 ^5,800,000. 
 
 8S9 ii,668Joco 
 
 Total ... ... 46,200.700 
 
 Since 1873 the exports have only once exceeded tlie imports namely, in 
 1880. liearing in mind that between three and four million pounds' worth of 
 wool which is tlic product of Xew South Wales is shipped annually fron>
 
 364 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 agriculture. 
 The boast of Victorians is, rightly enough, in their agriculture ; 
 and in this great department of national activity their country has 
 maintained her lead over New South Wales, although she has not 
 succeeded in increasing it. Even this partial success cannot be 
 attributed to Protection, because Victoria was an exporter of food- 
 stuffs even in her Free Trade days, but is owing partly to the fact 
 that in the variable climate of New South Wales the land that is 
 good for crops is not near the markets, and the land that is near the 
 markets is not good for crops, and partly to the early alienation of 
 the best agricultural lands to large proprietors, who have not yet 
 shown themselves inclined to use it for any but pastoral purposes. 
 Even in this direction, however, there are already signs of decline,^ 
 and while the area of cultivation is increasing in New South Wales 
 it is declining in Victoria. Fortunately, the farmers have at last 
 realised their position, and during the years 1890-91 every 
 " Farmers' Protection Association " has omitted the word Protection 
 
 Port Phillip, and therefore included among the exports of Victorian produce, it 
 will be seen that the nett annual value of Victorian exports is between eight and 
 nine millions, as against an importation of nearly twenty-four millions for the 
 year 1889. Of the imports a certain sum which cannot, on the most liberal 
 estimate, exceed ^^500,000 must be allowed for freight due to Victorian ship- 
 owners ; an allowance must also be made for interest on Victorian capital 
 invested abroad. It is difificult to ascertain how much this should be ; it is, how- 
 ever, a rough but perhaps a fair estimate to take the value of New South Wales 
 wool shipped from Melbourne as equivalent to the value of the returns to 
 Victorian capital invested abroad. Most of the wool which comes to Mel- 
 bourne from the other Colonies is sent there because the stations are owned by 
 Victorians. The wool which is sent to Melbourne by New South Wales 
 station owners, may be set off against the proceeds of Victorian investments in 
 Queensland properties. But, after all these allowances are made, the fact 
 remains that durmg recent years the indebtedness of \'ictoria has increased 
 more rapidly than its exports. This increase has continued through 1890 and 
 1891, although the official returns are not available at the time of writing.- It 
 is this enormous expenditure of borrowed money, both by the Government 
 and by private persons, which has maintained the rate of wages in Victoria, and 
 successfully disguised from the multitude the evil influences of Protection. 
 
 1 Thf official figures for 1890-91 are not yet published, but unofficial 
 returns show a decline of more tlian 50,000 acres in the area of cultivation 
 during the last two years. 
 
 Exports. Imports. The incre.ise in exports in i8go .ind iSgi 
 
 will probably lie found clue to an in- 
 
 " 1890 ... 13,256,000 22,o5j,ooo cre.ise in the shipments from Melbourne 
 
 1S91 ... 15,679,000 2i,62?,030 of Xtw South Wales wool.
 
 Appendix III. 
 
 365 
 
 from its title, and declared in favour of Free Trade. It is one of 
 the most amazing instances of the power of words over unthink- 
 ing men that the farmers in any country should ever advocate Pro- 
 tection. The maxim that " the farmer pays for all " can never be 
 more plainly illustrated than by farmers who hope to get rich by 
 paying customers to buy their crops. If a young country exports 
 food, Protection can be of no use to the farmers, who have to buy 
 everything they want at Protective prices, and sell everything they 
 produce at Free Trade prices. If, on the other hand, a young 
 country requires to import food, the farmers have already the best 
 market they can desire, viz., one which is short supplied. For ex- 
 ample, the average price of wheat in Sydney has been for many 
 years 6d. a bushel more than in Melbourne. The following are 
 the figures relating to agriculture : 
 
 Area of Land in Cultivatio.n in Acres. 
 
 1866. 
 
 188S. 
 
 2,627,262 
 
 Victoria - . ' 592,915 ' 909,015 ' 1,997,943 1 2,405,157 ' 2,564,742 
 
 NewSouth; ' ' 
 
 Wales ... '. 451,223 426,976 710,337 868,093 999,298 I, 64,475 1.241,419 
 
 COMMERCE. 
 
 The figures which follow as to commerce, revenue, and 
 shipping, require no comment. They all point the same moral 
 that Victoria has not only failed to hold her superiority over New 
 South Wales, but has fallen far behind : 
 
 Imports and Exports of New South Wales and Victoria. 
 
 
 1 
 
 Import 
 
 s. 
 
 
 
 Export 
 
 
 
 
 Colony. ! Year. 
 
 
 
 
 
 1 
 
 
 
 
 1 
 
 Total Value. 
 
 Value per 
 Head. 
 
 s. d. 
 
 Total Value. 
 
 Value per 
 Head. 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 S. 
 
 (/. 
 
 1866 
 
 14,771,000 
 
 23 
 
 9 
 
 7 
 
 12,889,000 1 
 
 20 
 
 9 
 
 9 
 
 
 . 1880 
 
 14,556,000 
 
 17 
 
 2 
 
 4 
 
 15.954.000 , 
 
 18 
 
 15 
 
 ^ 
 
 ca 
 
 1885 
 
 18,044,000 
 
 18 
 
 16 
 
 b 
 
 15,551,000 j 
 
 16 
 
 4 
 
 6 
 
 / 
 
 1888 
 
 23,972,000 
 
 22 
 
 n 
 
 5 
 
 13,853,000 ! 
 
 i.S 
 
 
 
 II 
 
 '1 
 
 1889 
 
 24,402,000 
 
 22 
 
 2 
 
 
 
 12,734,000 ; 
 
 1 1 
 
 10 
 
 8 
 
 > 1890 
 
 22,953,000 
 
 
 
 
 13,256,000 i 
 
 
 
 
 1891 
 
 21,622,000 
 
 (estimated) 
 
 
 
 
 15,679,000 
 
 (estimated) 
 
 
 
 
 f! 1866 
 
 9,403,000 
 
 
 
 
 9,913,000 
 
 
 
 
 ~ \ 1880 
 
 13,950,000 
 
 19 
 
 4 
 
 b 
 
 15,525,000 
 
 21 
 
 7 
 
 II 
 
 g yj , 1885 
 
 23,365,000 
 
 2.S 
 
 2 
 
 
 
 16,541 ,00 J 
 
 17 
 
 15 
 
 4 
 
 '-r-~ ... { 1888 
 
 20,885,000 
 
 19 
 
 12 
 
 6 
 
 20,859,000 
 
 19 
 
 12 
 
 
 
 S > 
 
 1889 
 
 22,863,000 
 
 20 
 
 14 
 
 2 
 
 23,294,000 . 
 
 21 
 
 2 
 
 
 
 2; 
 
 1890 
 
 1891 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 

 
 366 
 
 Ind us TR /. J L Fr e edom. 
 Shipping. 
 
 j 
 
 Inwards. 
 
 Outwards. 
 
 Colony. Year. 
 
 No. of 
 
 Vessels. 
 
 Tonnage. 
 
 No. of 
 Vessels. 
 
 Tonnage. 
 
 New South Wales... 1866 
 Victoria 1866 
 
 2,099 
 2,078 
 
 730,354 
 649,979 
 
 2,259 
 2,203 
 
 784,381 
 675-741 
 
 New South Wales... 1889* 
 Victoria 1889 
 
 3,254 
 2,855 
 
 2,632,081 
 2,270,827 
 
 3,229 
 2,886 
 
 2,689,098 
 2,328,351 
 
 * The year i88g was one of great depression in New South Wales. Later years 
 would show a wider difference between the two Colonies. 
 
 REVENL'E.^ 
 
 Colony. 
 
 1S66. 
 
 2,012,079 
 3,079,160 
 
 1889. 
 
 1891. 
 
 New South Whales 
 Victoria 
 
 
 
 9-063,397 
 8,675,990 
 
 
 10,079,000 
 
 (estimated) 
 
 * The excess of revenue in New South Wales is due to the elasticity of her returns 
 and not to the weight of ta.xation. The charge of taxation per head in 1889 in the two 
 Colonies was as follows : Victoria, ^3 9s. id.; New South Wales, ,1 8s. fd. Thu~, 
 although every citizen of Victoria pays ^i os. 7d. more in taxes than his Free Trade 
 neighbour, the revenue of Victoria is about two millions less than that of New South 
 Wales. 
 
 The figures which have been set out in the preceding pages 
 have been treated by Protectionists in various ways at different 
 times. For a long period they were ignored ; then, after Mr. 
 Edward Pulsford, of Sydney, brought them into pubhc notice, 
 their accuracy was denied, and the Statistical Office of New South 
 Wales was assailed with scurrilous abuse. Finally, after Mr. 
 Hayter, the A'ictorian official statist, had verified their substantial 
 correctness, every effort was made to depreciate their significance. 
 It was alleged that the greater success of N^w South Wales was 
 owing to special causes such as her larger territory, her greater 
 expenditure of borrowed monc\", and her larger land revenue 
 which had not operated in A'ictoria to the same e.xtcnt. Here, 
 again, however, the Protectionists were foiled. Mr. Pulsford and 
 this is not among the least of the services which he has rendered 
 to the cause of P'ree Trade undertook an elaborate series of in- 
 vestigations into the statistical returns of the two colonies, and
 
 Appendix III. 367 
 
 demonstrated even to the satisfaction of Protectionists that the 
 " special causes" of prosperity, so far from being peculiar to New 
 South Wales, had operated with even greater intensity in Victoria 
 during the period under review. It is chiefly due to Mr. Pulsford's 
 untiring industry and clearness of exposition that the example of 
 Victoria is never cited now in the neighbouring colonies as an in- 
 stance of the benefits of a Protective policy. As, however, the 
 energy of Victorian rcclanie has not exhausted itself in other 
 fields, it may be well to indicate very briefly the heads of the 
 answer to Protectionist disparagements of the progress of New 
 South Wales. 
 
 First, it is said that New South Wales owes her success to her 
 earlier foundation. It is a sufficient reply to this that, in spite of 
 her earlier foundation, she was far behind Victoria in 1866, when 
 both colonies were Free Trade. The development of the Colony 
 was so slow in the transportation days, which ended in 1856, that 
 Victoria, in 1866, had gained from her active population of gold 
 diggers more of the advantages of roads, bridges, and other inci- 
 dents of civilisation, in ten years than New South Wales had by 
 two generations of convict labour. 
 
 Next it is said that New South Wales owes her more rapid 
 progress to her larger territory. To a certain extent this is true ; 
 but it is the merit and object of Free Trade to make use of natural 
 advantages. A large territory, however, is not altogether an ad- 
 vantage to a young country. There is a power in concentration, 
 and a weakness in scattered forces. "Wealth,"' as Mr. Pulsford 
 has well remarked, "grows richer by population than by square 
 mile, and, as a rule, it will be found that the most important and 
 wealthy countries are of limited area. A larg-er area is often a 
 great weakness." Certainly this has proved to be the case in New 
 South Wales, whose rural population is badly served in all local 
 requirement?, and grievously handicapped by the difficulty of pro- 
 vidingfor the wants of so vast a territory. The greater advantages 
 wiiich a settler enjoys in the compact territory of \^ictoria become 
 inimccliatcly apparent to any one who looks upon a railway map of 
 the two Colonies. In New South Wales the railways stretch in 
 three long lines, each to a distance of about 500 miles irom the 
 city to the sea-board. In \'ictoria the railways divide the country 
 in:o small rectangles and unite every little township with the 
 capita! : and where railways fail the Southern settler, ri\ers play 
 their part and gi\c him that assurance of a return to his annual
 
 368 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 labour which the resident in the more variable climate of New 
 South Wales is never able to anticipate. 
 
 Indeed, in physical and climatic advantages, Victoria is vastly 
 the superior of New South Wales. Not only does its compactness 
 make the former cheap to govern and easy to develop, but its 
 fertile and well-watered lands lie close to the markets. In New 
 South Wales, on the contrary, except a narrow strip upon the coast 
 of Ilavvarra, the good land lies beyond the coastal rang-es at a 
 distance of at least 200 miles from Sydney and the sea-board. 
 There are, moreover, in New South Wales no large mining town- 
 ships (except that of Broken Hill, which is, for practical purposes, 
 part of South Australia) where the farmers are able to find a 
 market. Moreover, even the best lands in New South Wales are 
 subject alternately to droughts and floods. Further, while the 
 lands of New South Wales are heavily timbered, so that the ex- 
 pense of preparing them for the plough is very great, most of the 
 arable land in Victoria was naturally clear. In fact, it is difficult 
 to exaggerate the natural advantages which are enjoyed by the 
 fertile, extensive, open, well-watered lands of Victoria, over those 
 of its larger, but more variable, neighbour. Nor does this com- 
 plete the catalogue of the natural superiorities of the favoured 
 province. Victoria has a distinct advantage in the character of its 
 early settlers. The renown of her gold-fields attracted the very 
 pick of the world, for energy, enterprise, and power. Through 
 their aid she gained a start in wealth and population, which, but 
 for the folly of her rulers, she would not have lost for many 
 generations. The richness of her alluvial gold-fields, and the 
 character of her early population, caused the easy establishment 
 and rapid growth of great cities, whose position rendered her 
 singularly fitted to be the seat of manufactures ; while the extent 
 of fertile land, which was immediately available, made her from 
 the outset rich in the more durable elements of natural pro- 
 sperity. 
 
 What wonder that in such a country progress has been rapid ? 
 The matter rather for remark is, that it has so soon ended. Of all 
 the lessons which Australia has given to the world in politics, 
 not the least instructive is to be drawn from the rise and 
 decline of the Colony of Victoria I The "might-have-beens" 
 of history are notoriously unjjrofitable matters of specula- 
 tion ; but no one can read the history of ^'ictoria, with 
 impartial mind, without being moved to wonder what her fate
 
 Appendix III. 369 
 
 might have been, if she had been left to expand to her 
 natural growth unhindered by the cruel restrictions of a cramp- 
 ing tariff. 
 
 Another strangely perverted argument is that New South Wales 
 owes her more rapid progress to her greater production of coal and 
 wool, which, it is said, are two raw materials, the production of 
 which could not be affected by any fiscal policy. Supposing this 
 were so, it is in the eyes of a Free Trader precisely a reason why 
 the Colony of New South Wales should make as much profit as it 
 can out of its natural industries instead of diverting its capital and 
 labour into less productive channels. As the facts stand, how- 
 ever, Victoria has produced a larger quantity of raw materials than 
 New South Wales during the period under review. The aggregate 
 production of wool and gold in Victoria from 1866 to 1885 ^ was 
 ^27,410,950 more than in New South Wales. The following are 
 the figures: 
 
 Gold and Wool. Total Production 1866-1885. 
 
 Victoria. New South Wales. 
 
 Gold raised ... ... 85,819,216 ... i5>763.365 
 
 Wool produced * ... 67,891,880 ... 110,536,781 
 
 Total ... ... 153,711,096 ... 126,300,146 
 
 * The figures representing wool are the aggregate of the exports after deducting the 
 imports. 
 
 The total value of the coal raised in New South Wales 
 from the foundation of the colony does not equal the excess 
 of Victoria in her production of the two articles of wool and 
 coal during the twenty years, 1866-1885, being only ;/^23,89 1,629. 
 The production of coal during that period amounted to 
 ^11,282,325. 
 
 The Protectionist theorist, driven to explain the, to him, 
 astounding fact that New South Wales has prospered more under 
 Free Trade than Victoria under Protection, finds his last refuge 
 in the assertion that New South Wales owes her more rapid 
 
 1 The year 1885 is taken to avoid errors on cither side on account of the 
 disturbing influence either of the New South Wales good seasons or the 
 Melbourne "boom." 
 
 \
 
 37 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 progress to a more lavish expenditure of borrowed money. "A 
 spurious prosperity," says the Age, in 1886, "or the appearance of 
 prosperity, has been kept up for some eight or ten years past by 
 a monstrously lavish expenditure of public money, which has 
 either been borrowed or obtained from the sale of land." Upon 
 this passage Mr. Pulsford ("Freedom in New South Wales v. 
 Oppression in Victoria," p. 49) makes the following observa- 
 tions : 
 
 " Believing that, perhaps, after all. New South Wales might not 
 be so black as she is painted, I have carefully investigated the 
 subject of the money obtained by sales of land, and by public 
 borrowing in the two colonies. The result of my investigations 
 will, I venture to say, be a surprise to all. I find that, for many 
 years, Victoria led the way in both sales of land and public borrow- 
 ings. That, in point of fact, Victoria for many years borrowed 
 more rapidly than New South Wales, and also sold land much 
 more rapidly. I confess I was very much surprised myself to find 
 that, up to the year 1883, the aggregate of the moneys obtained by 
 loans and land sales in New South Wales had always been ex- 
 ceeded in Victoria. It is perfectly obvious that the colony that 
 obtained the lead in the construction of useful public works had a 
 great advantage. I find that in the year when Victoria entered 
 upon her policy of Protection, she had received twenty-one mil- 
 lion pounds from the sources named, against only eleven millions 
 in New South Wales. The early expenditure of so much money 
 in Victoria represented a great advantage over this colony. It was 
 not till 1875 that is, nine years later that New South Wales 
 reached this sum of twenty-one millions, and then the Victorian 
 total had risen to thirty-one millions, or still the ten millions 
 ahead. In 1880 \'ictoria was six millions ahead. In 1885 the 
 tables were turned, so that New South Wales was eight millions in 
 advance of Victoria. 
 
 " When I come to take the totals of these twenty years 
 1 866-1 885 I find that Victoria has had the use of capital 
 equivalent to thirty-four millions for the whole period, against 
 only tiuenty-eight millions on the part of New South Wales. 
 I claim, therefore, that Victoria, and not New South Wales, 
 is the colony that has received the greatest impetus to- 
 wards prosperity from the expenditure of moneys obtained by 
 loans and land sales." A full table of these moneys is sub- 
 joined.
 
 Appendix HI. 
 
 371 
 
 New South Wales. 
 
 Year, 
 
 Loans. 
 
 Land Sales. 
 
 Total. 
 
 
 L 
 
 L 
 
 
 
 i860 to 1865 
 Average 
 
 1 5.212,771 
 
 .. 4,061,732 
 
 9.274.503 
 
 1866 
 
 ... 6,418,030 
 
 .. 4,781,653 . 
 
 .. 11,199,683 
 
 1867 
 
 ... 6,917,630 
 
 .. 5,046,313 . 
 
 .. 11,963.943 
 
 1868 
 
 ... 8,564,830 
 
 5.311.563 
 
 .. 13.876,393 
 
 1869 
 
 ... 9,546,030 . 
 
 .. S.631,176 
 
 15,177,206 
 
 1870 
 
 ... 9,681,130 
 
 5,882,019 
 
 15.563.149 
 
 1871 
 
 ... 10,614,330 
 
 6,143,420 
 
 16.757.750 
 
 1872 
 
 10,773,230 . 
 
 6,575,793 . 
 
 17.349.023 
 
 1873 
 
 ... 10,842,415 
 
 7,421,203 
 
 .. 18,263,618 
 
 1874 
 
 ... 10,516,371 
 
 8,532,244 . 
 
 .. 19,048,615 
 
 1875 
 
 ... 11,470,637 . 
 
 .. 10,292,814 
 
 21,763,451 
 
 1876 
 
 II. 759.519 
 
 .. 12,806,218 
 
 24,565,737 
 
 1877 
 
 ... 11,724,419 
 
 15.774.075 
 
 27,498,494 
 
 1878 
 
 .. 11,688,119 
 
 .. 17,850,086 
 
 .. 29,538,205 
 
 1879 
 
 14.937.419 
 
 19.236,773 
 
 .. 34,174,192 
 
 1880 
 
 ... 14,903,919 
 
 ,. 20,618,799 
 
 .. 35,522,718 
 
 1881 
 
 ... 16,924,019 
 
 .. 23,102,137 
 
 .. 40,026,156 
 
 1882 
 
 ... 16,721,219 
 
 25,557,178 
 
 .. 42,278,397 
 
 1883 
 
 21,632,459 
 
 ., 26,826,657 
 
 .. 48,459,116 
 
 1884 
 
 ... 24,601,959 
 
 28,190,150 
 
 .. 52,792,109 
 
 1885 
 
 ... 30,064,259 
 
 29,414,372 
 
 59.478,631 
 
 Average 1866 
 to 1886 
 
 } ^3.515.^97 
 
 - 14.249.732 
 
 .. 27,764,829 
 
 We are now in a position to appreciate the whole significance 
 of the tale which the preceding figures have disclosed. 
 
 Every Protectionist argument, either expressedly or impliedly, 
 assumes that no country can develop under natural conditions, 
 but that a home market, a diversity of industries, a high rate of 
 wages, and all other ingredients of prosperity, can only be secured 
 by means of a Protective tariff. It is not that Protectionists claim 
 a mere superiority for their policy over the policy of Free Trade as 
 an instrument of national development, but they insist that Free 
 Trade is a positive evil that prevents development. Consequently 
 when we find that a country, which is also one of those young coun- 
 tries in whose case Protection is declared to be most plainly 
 demanded, has, while faithfully adhering to Free Trade, developed 
 its resources, diversified its industries, maintained a high rate of 
 wages, given its farmers a profitable market for their produce, and 
 steadily advanced in prosperity in every path of progress, we are 
 entitled to question the truth of the assumptions which Protectionists 
 invariably take for granted. If wc can go further, and show that 
 another country which has enjoyed greater natural advantages, and 
 where the other influences which make for national welfare have
 
 372 Industrial Freedom. 
 
 operated with greater intensity, has advanced much more slowly 
 under Protection than our first example has under Free Trade, the 
 conclusion is irresistible that Protection, not Free Trade, is the 
 clog upon national progress. At the same time, no sensible Free 
 Trader would rest his case upon the records of any country during 
 the short period of twenty-five years. The example of New South 
 Wales is of importance in a Free Trade argument, not so much on 
 account of the support which it gives to P'ree Trade, as because it 
 pushes the rude thrust of fact into the cobweb of a Protectionist 
 theory. It has also this more limited value that it makes it im- 
 possible for restrictionists to make use of the undoubted progress of 
 Victoria since 1866 as an illustration in their favour, without also 
 attributing the still greater progress of New South Wales to the 
 opposite policy of Free Trade. 
 
 THE E\D. 
 
 PrINTICD by CaSSKLL & COMI'ANY, LIMITED, I. A P.EI.LE SaTVAGE, LonI)0\, E.C.
 
 ^^ 
 
 A SELECTED LIST 
 
 OF 
 
 Cassell & Company's 
 
 Publications. 
 
 KT 
 
 C) G 9. 01.
 
 Selections from Cassell ^ Company's Publications. 
 
 Abljeys and Churclies of England and Wales, The: Descriptive, Histoilcal, 
 
 FictOriaL Series I. and II. zis. each. 
 Adventure, The World of. Fully Illustrated. Complete in Three Vols. gs. each. 
 Anglomaniacs, The : a Story of New York Life of To-day. By Mrs. Burtov 
 
 Harrison. 3s. 6d. 
 Animal Painting in Water Colours. With Eighteen Coloured Plates by 
 
 Frederick Tayler. 5s. 
 Arahian Nights Entertainments (CasseU's). With about 400 Illustrations. los. 6d- 
 Architectural Drawing. By R. PHENfi Spiers. Illustrated. los. 6d. 
 Art, The Magazine o Yearly Volume. With several hundred Engravings, and 
 
 Twelve Etchings, Photogravures, &c. 16s. 
 Artistic Anatomy. By Prof. M. Duval. Translated by F. E. Fenton. 5s. 
 BashMrtseff, Marie, The Journal of. Translated from the French by Mathilde 
 
 Blind. With Portraits and an Autograph Letter. Cheap Edition, 7s. 6d. 
 
 Bashkirtseff, Marie, The Letters of. Translated by Mary J. SerrXno. 7s. 6d. 
 
 Birds' Nests, Eggs, and Egg-Collecting. By R. Kearton. Illustrated with 
 16 Coloured Plates of Eggs. 5s. 
 
 Black America. A Story of the ex-Slave and his late Master. By W. Laird 
 Clowes. Cloth, 6s. 
 
 Black Arrow, The. A Tale of the Two Roses. By R. L. Stevenson. Illus- 
 trated, 3s. 6d. 
 
 Blue Pavilions, The. By Q, Author of "Dead Man's Rock," &c. 5s. 
 
 British Ballads. 275 Original Illustrations. Two Vols. Cloth, 15s. 
 
 British Battles on Land and Sea. By James Grant. With about 600 
 
 Illustrations. Three Vols., 4to, 1 7s. ; Library Edition, i los. 
 British Battles, Recent. Illustrated. 4to, 9s. Library Edition, los. 
 Browning, An Introduction to the Study of. By Arthur Symons. 2s. 6d. 
 Butterflies and Moths, European. By W. F. Kirby. With 61 Coloured 
 
 Plates. Demy 4to, 35s. 
 
 Canaries and Cage-Birds, The Illustrated Book of. By W. A. Blakston, 
 
 W. SwAVSLAND, and A. F. Wiener. With 56 Fac-simile Coloured Plates, 35s. 
 CasseU's Family Magazine. Yearly Volume. Illustrated, gs. 
 Cathedrals, Abbeys, and Churches of England and Wales. Descriptive, 
 
 Historical, Pictorial. Edited by Prof. T. G. Bonnev, D.Sc, LL.D., F.R.S. With 
 
 nearly 500 Original Illustrations. Popular Edition. Two Vols. 25s. 
 Celebrities of the Century. Being a Dictionary of the Men and Women of the 
 
 Nineteenth Century. Cheap Edition, los. 6d. 
 Chess Problem, The. With Illustrations by C. Planck and others. 7s. 6d. 
 China Painting. By Florence Lewis. With Sixteen Coloiued Plates, and a 
 
 selection of Wood Engravings. VV'ith full Instructions. 5s. 
 
 Choice Dishes at Small Cost. By A. G. Payne. Cheap Edition, is. 
 
 Christianity and Socialism, Lectures on. By Bishop Barry. 3s. 6d. 
 
 Cities of the World. Four Vols. Illustrated. 7s. 6d. each. 
 
 Civil Service, Guide to Empl03rment In the. Ne^v and Enlarged Edition, 3s. 6d. 
 
 ClvU Service Guide to Female Emplojrment in Government Offices. Cloth, is. 
 
 Climate and Health Resorts. By Dr. Burney Yeo. 7s. 6d. 
 
 Clinical Manuals for Practitioners and Students of Medicine. [A List 0/ 
 
 I'olumes fo7-iuarded poitfree en application to the Publishers.) 
 
 Clothing, The Influence of, on Health. By Frederick Treves, F.R.C.S. 23. 
 Cobden Club, Works published for the. {A Complete List on application.) 
 Colonist's Medical Handbook, The. By E. Alfred Barton, M. R.C.S. 2s. 6d. 
 Colour. By Prof. A. H. Church. New and Enlarged Edition. 3s. 6d. 
 Commerce, The Year-Book of. Edited by Kenric B. Murray. 5s. 
 Commercial Botany of the Nineteenth Century. By J. R. Jackson, A.L.S. 
 
 Cloth gilt, 3s. 6d.
 
 Selections from Cassell <fc Company's Publications. 
 
 Conning Tower, In a. By H. O. Arnolu-Forster, Author of "The Citizen 
 Reader," &c. With Original Illustrations by W. H. Overend. is. 
 
 Conquests of the Cross. F^dited by Edwin Hodder. With numerous Original 
 Illustrations. Complete in Three Vols. gs. each. 
 
 Cookery, A Year's. By Phyllis Browne. New and Enlarged Edition. Cloth 
 gilt, 3S. 6d. 
 
 Cookery, Cassell's Dictionary ot Containing about Nine Thousand Recipes. 
 7s. 6d. ; roxburgh, ids. 6<1. 
 
 Cookery, Cassell's Shilling. %oth Thousand, is. 
 
 Cookery, Cassell's Popular. With Four Coloured Plates. Cloth gilt, 2s. 
 
 Cookery, Vegetarian. A Manual of Cheap and Wholesome Diet. By A. G. 
 Payne, is. 6d. 
 
 Cooking by Gas, The Art o By Marie J. Sugg. Illustrated. Cloth, 3s. 6d. 
 
 Copyright, The Law of Musical and Dramatic. By Edward Cutler, 
 Thomas Eustace Smith, and Frederic E. Weatherly. 3s. 6d. 
 
 Countries of the World, The. By Robert Brown, M.A., Ph.D., &c. Com- 
 plete in Six Vols., with about 750 Illustrations. 410, 7s. 6d. each. 
 
 Cremation and Um-Burial ; or, The Cemeteries of the Future. By W. 
 Robinson. With Plates and Illustrations, is. 
 
 Cromwell, Oliver: The Man and His Mission. By J. Allanson Picton, M.P. 
 
 Cheap Edition. With Steel Portrait. 5s. 
 Culmshire Folk. By the Author of " John Orlebar," &c. 3s. 6d. 
 Cyclopaedia, Cassell's Concise. Brought down to the latest date. With about 
 
 600 Illustrations. New and Cheap Edition, 7s. 6d. 
 Cyclopaedia, Cassell's Miniature. Containing 30,000 Subjects. Cloth, 3s. 6d.; 
 
 half roxburgh, 4s. 6d. 
 Dairy Farming. By Prof. J. P. Sheldon. With 25 Fac-simile Coloured Plates, 
 
 and numerous Wood Engravings. Demy 4to, 21s. 
 
 David Todd : The Romance of his Life and Loving. By David Maclure. 5s. 
 Dickens, Character Sketches from. First, Second, and Third Series. 
 
 With Six Original Drawings in each, by Frederick Barnard. In Portfolio. 21s. each. 
 Dictionaries. (For description see alphabetical letter.) Religion, Bible, 
 Celebrities, Encyclopaedic, Mechanical, Phrase and Fable, English, English History, 
 English Literature, Domestic, Cookery. (French, German, and Latin, see with 
 E'tucational Works.) 
 
 Disraeli, Benjamin, Personal Reminiscences o By Henry Lake. 3s. 6d. 
 
 Disraeli in Outline. By F. Carroll Brewster, LL.D. 7s. 6d. 
 
 Dog, Illustrated Book of the. By Vero Shaw, B.A. With 28 Coloured 
 
 Plates. Cloth bevelled, 35s. ; half-morocco, 45s. 
 Dog, The. By Idstone. Illustrated. 2s. 6d. 
 
 Domestic Dictionary, The. An Encyclopaedia for the Household. Cloth, 7s. 6d. 
 Dore Gallery, The. With 250 Illustrations by Gustave DoRfi. 410, 42s. 
 Dore's Dante's Inferno. Illustrated by Gustave Dor6. Popular Edition, 21s. 
 Dor6's Milton's Paradise Lost. Illustrated by Gustave Dor. 4to, 21s. 
 Dr. Dum^ny's Wife. A Novel. By Maurus Jokai. Translated from the 
 
 Hungarian by F. Steinitz. 7s, 6d. net. 
 Earth, Our, and its Story. Edited by Dr. Robert Brown, F.L.S. With 
 
 36 Coloured Plates and 740 Wood Engravings. Complete in Three Vols. 9s. each. 
 Edinburgh, Old and New, Cassell's. With 600 Illustrations. Three Vols. 
 
 9s. each ; library binding, ,1 los. the set. 
 
 Egypt: Descriptive, Historical, and Picturesque. By Prof. G. Ebers. 
 
 Translated by Clara Bell, with Notes by Samuel Bikch, LL.D., &c. Two Vols. 42s. 
 "89." A Novel. By Edgar Hknry. Cloth, 3s. 6d. 
 Electricity, Age of, from Amber Sotil to Telephone. By Park Benjamin, 
 
 Ph.D. 7s. 6d. 
 Electricity, Practical P.y Prof. W. E. Ayrton. Illustrated. 7s. 6d. 
 Electricity in the Service of Maui. A Popular and Practical Treatise. With 
 
 nearly 850 Illustrations. Cheap Edition, 9s. 
 
 Employment for Boys on Leaving School, Guide to. Bv W. S. Beard, 
 
 F.R.G.S. IS. 6d. 
 Encyclopaedic Dictionary, The. Comiilete in Fourteen Divisional Vols. , los. 6d. 
 
 each ; or Seven Vols., half-morocco, 21s. each ; half-russia, 25s. each. 
 
 England, Cassell's Illustrated History of. With 2,000 Illustrations. Ten 
 Vols., 4to, gs. each. Neiv and Revised Edition. Vols. I., II., III., and IV., gs. each.
 
 Selections from Cassell & Company's Publications. 
 
 English Dictionary, Cassell's. Containing Definitions of upwards of 100,000 
 Words and Phrases. Demy 8vo, 1,100 pages, cloth gilt, 7s. 6d. 
 
 Engllsb History, Tlie Dictionary ot Cheap Editioii, los. (A.; roxburgh, 155. 
 English Literature, Library of. By Prof. Henry Morlev. Complete in Five 
 
 Vols. 7s. 6d. each. 
 
 Vol. L Shorter English Poems. 
 Vol. II. IiLUSTRATiONS OF English 
 
 Religion. 
 Vol. III. P^nglish Plays. 
 
 Vol. IV. Shorter Works in English 
 Prose. 
 
 Vol. V. Sketches of Longer Works in- 
 English Verse and Prose. 
 
 English Literature, Morlesr's First Sketch of. Revised Edition, 7s. 6d. 
 English Literature, The Dictionary of. By W. Davenport Adams. Cheap 
 
 Edition, ys. 6d. ; roxburgh, los. 6d. 
 
 English Literature, The Story of. By Anna Buckland. 3s. 6d. 
 English Writers. By Henry Morley. Vols. L to Vni. 5s. each. 
 
 ^sop's Fahles. Illustrated by Ernest Griset. Cheap Edition. Cloth, 3s. 6d. ; 
 bevelled boards, gilt edges, 5s. 
 
 Etiquette of Good Society, is. ; cloth, is. 6d. 
 
 Eye, Ear, and Throat, The Management of the. 3s. 6d. 
 
 Faith Doctor, The. A Novel. By Edward Eggles ion. 7s. 6d. net. 
 
 Family Physician. By Eminent Physicians and Surgeons. New and 
 
 Revised Edition. Cloth, 21s. ; roxburgh, 25s. 
 
 Father Mathew: His Life and Times. By Frank J. Mathew. 2s. 6d. 
 Father Stafford. By Anthony Hope, Author of " A Man of Mark." 6s. 
 Fenn, G. Manvllle, Works by. Boards, 2s. each ; or cloth. 2s. 6d. 
 
 Dutch the Diver; or, a Man's Mistake. In I The Parson o' Dumford. In boards only. 
 
 boards onlj-. Poverty Corner. 
 
 My Patients. I The Vicar's People. In Cloth onlv. 
 
 Field Naturalist's Handbook, The. By Rev. J. G. Wood & Theodokk Wood. ss. 
 
 Figtiier's Popular Scientific Works. With Several Hundred Illustrations in 
 each. y,. 6d. each. 
 The Human Race. | Mammalia. | Ocean World. 
 
 The World before the Deluge. Revised Edition. 
 
 Figure Painting in Water Colours. With 16 Coloured Plates by Blanche 
 MacArthur and Jennie Moore. With full Instructions. 7s. 6d. 
 
 Flora's Feast. A Masque of Flowers. Penned and Pictured by Walter 
 Crane. With 40 pages in Colours. 5s. 
 
 Flower de Hundred. The Story of a Virginia Plantation. By Mrs. Burton 
 Harrison, Author of " The Anglomaniacs," &c. 3s. 6d. 
 
 Flower Painting, Elementary. With Eight Coloured Plates. 3s. 
 
 Flower Painting in Water Colovirs. With Coloured Plates. First and Second 
 
 Series. 5s. each. 
 
 Flower Painting in Water Colours. With Coloured Plates. First and Second 
 
 Series. 5s. each. 
 Flowers, and How to Paint Them. By Maud Naftel. With Coloured Plates. 5s. 
 
 Fossil Reptiles, A History of British. By Sir Richard Owen, K.C.B., F.R.S., 
 
 &c. With 268 Plates. In Four Vols. 1-2 12s. 
 
 Four Years in Parliament with Hard Labour. By C. W. Radcliffe 
 
 Cooke, M.P. Third Edition, is. 
 France as It Is. By Andre Lebon and Paul Pelet. With Maps. 7s. 6d. 
 Garden Flowers, Familiar. By Shirley Hibbekd. With Coloured Plates by 
 
 F. K. HrLME, F.L.S. Complete in Five Series, Cloth gilt, 12s. 6d. each. 
 Gardening, Cassell's Popular. Illustrated. Complete in Four Vols. 5s. each. 
 Geometrical Drawing for Army Candidates. By H. T. Lilley, M.A. 2s. 
 Geometry, First Elements of Experimental. By Paul Bert. is. 6d. 
 Geometry, Practical Solid. By Major Ross. 2s. 
 
 Gilbert, Elizabeth, and her Work for the Blind. By Frances Martin. 2s. 6d. 
 Gleanings from Popular Authors. Two Vols. With Original Illustrations. 
 
 4to, gs, each. I'wo Vols, in One, 15s. 
 
 Great Eastern Railway, The Official Illustrated Guide to the. is. ; cloth, 2s. 
 Great Northern Railway, The Official Illustrated Guide to the. is. ; cloth, 2s. 
 Great Western Railway, The Official Illustrated Guide to the. A'ejv and 
 
 Reviseii Edition, ts. ; cloth, 2<. 
 
 Gulliver's Travels. With 88 Engravings. Cloth, 3s. 6d. ; cloth gilt, 5s.
 
 Selections from Cassell <k Company's Publications. 
 
 Oim and its Deyelopment, The. By W. W. Greener. Illustrated. los. 6d. 
 
 Guns, Modem Shot. By W. W. Greener. Illustrated. 5s. 
 
 Health at School. By Clement Dukes, M.D., B.S. 7s. 6d. 
 
 Health, The Book of. By Eminent Physicians and Surgeons. Cloth, 21s. 
 
 Health, The Influence of Clothing on. By F. Treves, F.R.C.S. 2s. 
 
 Heavens, The Story of the. By Sir Robert Stawell Ball, LL.D., F.R.S. 
 
 With Coloured Plates and Wood Engravings. Popular Edition, 12s. 6d. 
 
 Heroes of Britain in Peace and War. With 300 Original Illustrations. Cheap 
 
 Edition. Vol. I. 3s. 6d. 
 
 Holiday Studies of Wordsworth. By F. A. Malleson, M.A. 5s. 
 Horse, The Book of the. By Samuel Sidney. With 28 Fac-simile Coloured 
 Plates. Demy 4to, 35s. ; ha'f-morocco, ;2 5s. 
 
 Houghton, Lord : The Life, Letters, and Friendships of Richard Monckton 
 Milnes, First Lord Houghton. By T. Wemyss Reid. Two Vols., with 
 
 Portraits, 32E. 
 
 Household, Cassell's Book of the. Illustrated. Complete in Four Vols. 5s. each. 
 How Women may Earn a Living. By Mercy Grogan. Cheap Edition, 6d. 
 Hygiene and Public Health. By B. Arthur Whitelegge, M. D. 7s. 6d. 
 India, Cassell's History of. By James Grant. With 400 Illustrations. 15s. 
 In-door Amusements, Card Games, and Fireside Fun, Cassells Book ot 
 
 With numerous Illustrations. Cheap Edition. Cloth, 2s. 
 Irish Leagues, The Work of the. The Speech of the Right Hon. Sir Henry 
 James, Q.C, M.P., Replying in the Parnell Commission Inquiry. 6s. 
 
 Irish Parliament, A Miniatvire History of the. By J. C. Haslam. 3d. 
 Irish Union, The : Before and After. By .\. K. Connell, M.A. 2s. 6d. 
 Italy from the Fall of Napoleon I. in 1815 to 1890. By J. W. Probyn. New 
 
 and Cheaper Edition. 3s. 6d. 
 "Japanese" Library, Cassell's. Consisting of 12 Popular Works bound in 
 Japanese style. Covers in water-colour pictures, is. 3d. each, net. 
 Handy Andy. Oliver Twist. Ivanhoe. Ingoldsby Legends. The Last of the 
 Mohicans. The Last Days of Pompeii. The Yellowplush. Papers. The Last Days of 
 Palmyra. Jack Hinton the G-uardsman. Selections from the W^orks of Thomas 
 Hooj. American Humour. Tower of London. 
 
 John Orlebar, Clk. By the Author of " Culmshire Folk." 2s. 
 
 John Parmelee's Curse. By Julian Hawthorne. 2s. 6d. 
 
 Karmel the Scout. A Novel. By Sylvanus Cobb, Junr. Cloth, 3s. 6d. 
 
 Kennel Guide, Practical By Dr. Gordon Stables. Illustrated. Cheap EdHio7i, is. 
 
 Khiva, A Ride to. By Col. Fred Burnaby. is. 6d. 
 
 Kidnapped. By R. L. Steven.son. Illustrated. 3s. 6d. 
 
 King Solomon's Mines. By H. Rider Haggard. Illustrated. 3s. 6d. 
 
 Ladies' Physician, The. By a London Physician. 6s. 
 
 Lake Dwellings of Europe. By Robert Munro, M.D., M..^. Cloth, 315. 6d. 
 
 Law, How to Avoid. By .\. J. Williams, M.P. Cheap Edition, is. 
 
 Legends for Lionel. With Coloured Plates by Walter Crane. 5s. 
 
 Letts's Diaries and other Time-saving Publications are now published exclu- 
 sively by Cassri.i. & Co.MPANY. (AList sent Post free on application.) 
 Little Minister, The. By J. M. Barrie. Three Vols. 31s. 6d. 
 Loans Manual. \\\ Charles P. Cotton. 5s. 
 Local Option in Norway. By Thomas M. Wilson, C.E. is. 
 Locomotive Engine, The Biography of a. By Henry Frith. 5s. 
 London and North Western Railway, Ofllcial Illustrated Guida is. 
 London and South Western Railway, Official Illustrated Guide, is. 
 London, Brighton and South Coast Railway, Official Illustrated Guide, is. 
 London, Greater. By Edward Walford. Two Vols. With about 400 
 
 Illustrations, gs. each. Library Edition. Two Vols, ^i the set. 
 
 London, Old and New. By Walter Thornbury and Edward Walford. 
 
 Six Vols., with about 1,200 Illustrations. Cloth, 9s. each. Library Edition, 2- 
 
 London Street Arabs. By Mrs. H. M. Stanley (Dorothy Tf.nnant). 
 
 With Pictures printed on a Tint. 5s. 
 
 Master of Ballantrae, The. Ry Robert Louis Stevenson. Illustrated. 3s. 6d. 
 Mechanics, The Practical Dictionary o Containing 13,000 Drawings. Four 
 
 Vols. 2 IS. each.
 
 Selections from Cassell dk Company s Publications. 
 Medical Handbook of Life Assurance. By James Edward Pollock, M.D., 
 
 F.R.C.P., and James Chisholm, Fellow of the Institute of Actuaries, London. 7s. 6d. 
 Medicine, Manuals for Students of. [A List forwarded post free on application.) 
 Metropolitan Year-Book, The, for 1892. Paper, is. ; cloth, 2s. 
 Metzerott, Shoemaker. A Socialistic Novel. 5s. 
 Midland Railway, The Official Illustrated Guide to the. Cloth, 2s. 
 Modem Europe, A History ot By C. A. Fyffe, M.A. Three Vols. 12s. each. 
 Music, Illustrated History of. By Emil Naumann. Edited by the Rev. 
 
 Sir F. A. Gore Ouseley, Bart. Illustrated. Two Vols. 31s. 6d. 
 National Library, Cassell's. In Volumes. Paper Covers, 3d. ; cloth, 6d. 
 
 (/4 Complete List of the P'oluines post free on application^ 
 
 Natural History, Cassell's Concise. By E. Pkrceval Wright, M.A., M.D., 
 
 F.L.S. With several Hundred Illustrations. 7s. 6d. ; roxburgh, los. 6d. 
 
 Natural History, Cassell's New. Edited by Prof. P. Martin Duncan, M.B., 
 
 F.R.S., F.G.S. Complete in Six Vols. With about 2,000 Illustrations. Cloth, gs. each. 
 
 Nature's Wonder Workers. By Kate R. Lovell. Illustrated, ss. 
 
 Naval War, The Last Great. By A. Nelson Seaforth. With Maps. 2s. 
 
 Navy, Royal, All About the. By W. Laird Clowes. Illustrated, is. 
 
 Nelson, The Life of. By Robert Southey. Illustrated with Eight Plates. 3s. 6d. 
 
 Nursing for the Home and for the Hospital, A Handbook of. By Cathe- 
 rine J. Wood. Cheap Edition, is. 6d. ; cloth, 2s. 
 
 Nursing of Sick Children, A Handbook for the. By Catherine J. Wood. 2s. 6d. 
 
 Orations and After-Dinner Speechea By the Hon. C. M. Depew. 7s. 6d. 
 
 Our Own Country. Six Vols. With 1,200 Illustrations. Cloth, 7s. 6d. each. 
 
 Pactolus Prime. A Novel. By Albion W. TouRciiE. 5s. 
 
 Painting, The English School of. By Ernest Chesneau. Translated by 
 L. N. Etherington. With an Introduction by Professor Ruskin. 5s. 
 
 Paxton's Flower Garden. With 100 Coloured Plates. {Price on application.) 
 
 People I've Smiled With. Recollections of a Merry Little Life. By Marshall 
 P. Wilder. 2s. 
 
 Peoples of the World, The. By Dr. Robert Brown. Complete in Six Volumes, 
 With Illustrations. 7s. 6d. each. 
 
 Phantom City, The. By W. Westall. 53. 
 
 Phillips, Watts. Artist and Playwright. By Miss E. Watts Phillips. With 
 
 32 Plates. IDS. 6d. 
 
 Photography for Amateurs. ByT. C. Hepworth. Illustrated, is. ; orcloth, is. 6d. 
 
 Phrase and Fable, Dictionary of. By the Rev. Dr. Brewer. Cheap Edition, 
 Enlarged, cloth, 3s. 6d. ; or with leather back, 4s. 6d. 
 
 Picturesque America. Complete in Four Vols., with 48 Exquisite Steel Plates, 
 and about Soo Original Wood Engravings. 7. 2s. each. 
 
 Picturesciue Australasia, Cassell's. With upwards of 1,000 Illustrations. Com- 
 plete in Four Vols. 7s. 6d. e.ich. 
 
 Picturesque Canada. With about 600 Original Illustrations. Two Vols. 
 P,-i 3s. each. 
 
 Picturesque Europe. Complete in Five Vols. Each containing ij) Exquisite Steel 
 Plates, from Original Drawings, and nearly 200 Original Illustrations. -2-1 ; half- 
 morocco, ;C3i los. ; morocco gilt, ;52 los. Popular Edition. In Five Vols. iSs. each. 
 
 Picturesque Mediterranean, The. With a Series of Magnificent Illustrations 
 from Original Designs by leading Artists of the day. Two Vols. Cloth, 2 2s each. 
 
 Pigeon Keeper, The Practical. By Lewis Wright. Illustrated. 3s. 6d. 
 
 Pigeons, The Book of. By Robert Fulton. Edited by Lewis Wright. With 
 50 Coloured Plates and numerous Wood Engravings. 31s. 6d. ; half-morocco, 2 2s. 
 
 Poems, Aubrey de Vere's. A Selection. Edited by John Dennis. 3s. 6d. 
 
 Poets, CasseUs Miniature Library of the : 
 
 Burns. Two \'ols. Cloth, is. each : or cloth, 
 
 fcfilt edges, 2S. 6d. the set. 
 Byron. Two Vols. Cl'^th, is. each; or cloth, 
 
 gilt edges, 2s. 6d. tlic set. 
 Hood. Two Vols. Cloth, is. each ; or cloth, 
 
 gilt edges, 2s. 6d. tlie set. 
 Longfellow. Two Vols. Cloth, is. each ; or 
 
 cloth, gilt edges, 2S. 6d. the set. 
 
 Milton. Two Vols. Cloth, is. each ; or cloth, 
 
 gilt edges, 2S. 6d. the set. 
 Scott. Two Vols. Cloth, IS. each ; or cloth, 
 
 gilt edges, 2s. 6d. the set. 
 Sheridan and Ooldsniith. 2 Vols. Cloth, is. 
 
 each : or cloth, gilt edges, 2S. 6d. the set. 
 Wordsworth. Two Vols. Cloth, is. e.Tch ; 
 
 or cloth, gilt edges, 2s. 6d. the set. 
 
 Shakespeare. Twelve Vols., half cloth, in box. 12s. 
 
 Political Questions of the Day, A Manual of. By Sydney Buxton, M.P. 
 
 New and Enlarged Edition. Paper Covers, is. ; or cloth ^ is. 6d.
 
 Selections from Cassell <fc Company's Publications. 
 
 Folyteclinic Series, The. Practical Illustrated Manuals specially prepared for 
 Students of the Polytechnic Institute, and suitable for the Use of all Students. 
 Forty Lessons in Carpentry 'Workshop Practice, is. 
 Practical Plane and Solid Geometry, including Graphic Arithmetic. Vol. I. 
 
 ELEMENTARY STAGE. 3S. 
 
 Forty Lessons in Engineering 'Workshop Practice, is. 6d. 
 
 Technical Scales. Set of Ten in cloth case, is. Also on celluloid (in case), los. 6d. the set 
 
 Elementary Chemistry for Science Schools and Classes, is. 6d. 
 
 Building Construction Plates. A Series of 40 Drawings, Royal Folio size, ijd. each. 
 
 Portrait Gallery, The Cabinet. First and Second Series, each containing 36 
 Cabinet Photographs of Eminent Men and Women of the day. With Biographical 
 Sketches. 15s. each. 
 
 Povdtry Keeper, The PracticaL By Lewis Wright. Illustrated. 3s. 6d. 
 
 Poultry, The Book of. By Lewis Wright. Popular Edition. Illustrated. los. 6d. 
 
 Poultry, The Illustrated Book of. By Lewis Wright. With Fifty Exquisite 
 
 Coloured Plates, and numerous Wood Engravings. Revised Edition. Cloth, 31s. 6d. 
 
 Public Libraries, Free. A^ew and Enlarged Edition. By Thomas Green- 
 wood, Author of " Museums and Art Galleries." Illustrated. 2S. 6d. 
 
 Queen Summer ; or, The Tourney of the Lily and the Rose. Penned and 
 
 Portrayed by Walter Crane. With 40 pages in Colours. 6s. Large Paper 
 Edition, 21S., net. 
 
 Queen Victoria, The Life and Times of. By Robert Wilson. Complete in 
 
 2 'Vols. With numerous Illustrations, gs. each. 
 
 Rabbit-Keeper, The Practical. By Cuniculus. Illustrated. 3s. 6d. 
 Rail'way Library, Cassell's. Crown 8vo, boards, 2s. each. 
 
 The Astonishing History of Troy Town. 
 ByQ. 
 
 The Admirable Lady Biddy Fane. By 
 
 Frank Barrett. 
 
 Commodore Junk. By G. ManviUe Fenn. 
 
 St. Cuthbert's Tower. By Florence War- 
 den. 
 
 The Man with a Thumb. By W. C. Hud- 
 son (Barclay North). 
 
 By Right Not Law. By R. Sherard. 
 
 'Within Souni of the Weir. By Thomas 
 St. E. Hake. 
 
 Under a Strange Mask. By Frank Barrett. 
 
 The Coombsberrow^Mystery. ByJ.Colwall. 
 
 Dead Man's Rook. By Q. 
 
 A Queer Race. By W. Westall. 
 
 Captain Trafalgar. By Westall and Laurie. 
 
 Jack Gordon, Knight Errant. By W. C 
 Hudson (Barclay North); 
 
 The Diamond Button : 'Whose Was It? 
 By W. C. Hudson (Barclay North). 
 
 Another's Crime. By Julian Hawthorne. 
 
 The Yoke of the Thorah. By Sidney 
 
 ^^ Luska. 
 
 Who is John Neman ? By C. Henry Beckett. 
 
 The Tragedy of Brinkwater. By Martha 
 L. Moodey. 
 
 An American Penman. By Julian Haw- 
 thorne. 
 
 Section 553; or. The Fatal Letter. By 
 Julian Hawthorne. 
 
 The Brown Stone Boy. By W. H. Bishop. 
 
 A Tragic Mystery. By Julian Hawthime. 
 
 The Great Bank Robbery. By Julbin 
 
 The Phantom City. By W. Westall. ' Hawthorne. 
 
 Redgrave, Richard, C.B., R.A. Memoir. By F. M. Redgrave, ids. 6d. 
 Richard, Henry, M.P. A Biography. By Charles Miall. With Portrait. 7s. 6d. 
 Rivers of Great Britain : Descriptive, Historical, Pictorial. RIVERS OF 
 
 THE EAST COAST. Roval 410. 42s. 
 Rivers of Great Britain : TPIE ROYAL RIVER; THE THAMES, FROM 
 
 SOURCE TO SEA. With Descriptive Text and a Series of beautiful Engravings. 
 
 Original Edition, 2 2s. Popular Edition. i6s. 
 Robinson Crusoe. Cassell's .Yew Fine-Art Edition. With upwards of 100 
 
 Original Illustrations. 7s. 6d. 
 
 Rossetti, Dante Gabriel, as Designer and Writer. Notes by William 
 
 Michael Rossetti. 7s. 6d. 
 Russia, Through, on a Mustang. By Thomas Stevens. 7s. 6d. 
 Russo-Tiirkish War, Cassell's History of. With about 500 Illustrations. Two 
 
 V^ols., gs. each ; library binding. One Vol., 15s. 
 Sanitary Institutions, English. By Sir John Simon, K.C.B., F.R.S. i8s. 
 Saturday Journal, Cassell's. Illustrated throughout. Yearly Volume, 7s. 6d. 
 Science for All. Edited Iw Dr. Robert Brown, M.A., F.'L.S., &c. Revised 
 
 Edition. With 1,500 Illustrations. Five Vols. gs. each. 
 
 Sea, The: its Stirring Story of Adventure, Peril, and Heroism. By 
 
 F. Whymper. With 400 Illustrations, Four Vols. 7s. 6d. each. 
 Secret of the Lamas, The. A Tale of Thibet. Crown 8vo, 53. 
 Sent Back by the Angels ; and other Ballads of Home and Homely Life. By 
 
 Frpiderick Langbkiogk, M.A. Fofyular Edition, \%. 
 
 Shaftesbury, The Seventh Earl of, K.G., The Life and Work of. By Edwin 
 
 HoDDKR. With Portraits. Three Vols., 36s. Popular Edition, in One Vol., 7s. 6d, 
 
 Shakespeare, Cassell's Quarto Edition. Edited by Charles and Mary Cowdkn 
 
 Clarkk, and containing about 600 Illustrations by H. C. Selous. Complete in 
 Three Vols., cloth gilt, -1, 3s. Also published in Three separate Volumes, in cloth, 
 viz. : The Comedihs, 21s. ; The Historical Plays, t8s. 6d. ; The Tragedies, 25s.
 
 Selections from Cassell <fc Company's Publications. 
 
 Bbakespeare, Miniature. Illustrated. In Twelve Vols., in box, 12s. ; or in 
 Red Paste Grain (box to match), with spring catch, lettered in gold, 21s. 
 
 Shakespeare, The Plays ot Edited by Prof. Henry Morley. Complete in 
 
 Thirteen Vols. Cloth, in box, 21s. ; half-morocco, cloth sides, 42s. 
 Shakespeare, The England o By E. Goadby. Illustrated. New Edition. 2%. 6d.. 
 Shakspere, The International. Edition de luxe. 
 
 " Othello." Illustrated by Frank Dicksee, R.A. ,-^ los. 
 J " King Henry IV." Illustrated by Herr EpuARD GrOtzner. ;S3 ios. 
 
 "As You Like It." Illustrated by Mons. Emile Bayard. -3, los. 
 
 "Romeo and Juliet." Illustrated by Frank Dicksee, R.A. Is now out of print. 
 Shakspere, The Leopold. With 400 Illustrations, and an Introduction by F. J. 
 
 FuRNiVALL. Cheap Edition, 3s. 6d. Cloth gilt, gilt edges, 5s. ; roxburgh, 7s. 6d. 
 Shakspere, The RoyaL With Exquisite Steel Plates and Wood Engravings. 
 
 Three Vols. 15s. each. 
 
 Skin and Hair, The Management of the. By Malcolm Morris, F. R. C.S. 2s. 
 Social Welfare, Subjects of. By the Rt. Hon. Sir Lyon Playfair, M.P. 7s. 6d. 
 South Eastern Railway, The Official Illustrated Guide to the. is. ; cloth, 2s. 
 Spectacles, How to Select. By Charles Bell Taylor, F.R.C.S. is. 
 Splendid Spur, The. By Q, Author of "Dead Man's Rock," &c. Illustrated. 3s.6d. 
 Sports and Pastimes, Cassell's Complete Book o With more than 900 
 
 Illustrations. Cheap Edition. 3s. 6d. 
 
 Standard Library, Cassell's. Stiff covers, is. each ; cloth, 2s. each. 
 
 Coningsby. The Prince of the House of David. 
 
 Mary Barton. 
 The Antiquary. 
 Nicholas Niokleby. Two Vols. 
 Jane Eyre. 
 Wutheriug Heights. 
 The Prairie. 
 
 Dombey and Son. Two Vols. 
 Night and Morning. 
 Kenilworth. 
 
 The Ingoldsby Ijegends. 
 Tower of London. 
 The Pioneers. 
 Charles O'Malley. 
 Barnaby Eudge. 
 Cakes and Ale. 
 The King's Own. 
 People I have Met. 
 The Pathfinder. 
 velina. 
 Scott's Poems. 
 Last of the Barons. 
 Adventures of Mr. Ledbury. 
 Ivanhoe. 
 OUver Twist. 
 
 Selections from Hood's Works. 
 Longfellow's Prose Works. 
 Sense and Sensibility. 
 Lytton's Plays. 
 
 Tales, Poems, and Sketches (Bret 
 Harte). 
 
 Sheridan's Plays. 
 TJnele Tom's Cabin. 
 Deerslayer. 
 Eugene Aram. 
 
 Jack Hinton, the G-uardsman. 
 Home and the Early Christiana. 
 The Trials of Margaret Lyndsay. 
 Edgar Allan Poe. Prose and Poetry, Selec- 
 tions from. 
 Old Mortality. 
 The Hour and the Man. 
 Washington Irving's Sketch-Book. 
 
 Pride and Prejudice. 
 
 Last of the Mohicans. 
 
 Heart of Midlothian. 
 
 Last Days of Pompeii. 
 
 Yellowplush Papers. 
 
 Handy Andy. 
 
 Selected Plays. 
 
 American Humour. 
 
 Sketches by Boz. 
 
 Macaulay's Lays and Selected Essay*. 
 
 Harry Lorrequer. 
 
 Old Curiosity Shop. 
 
 Kienzi. 
 
 The Talisman. 
 
 Piekw.ck. Two Vols. 
 
 Scarlet Letter. 
 
 Martin Chuzzlewit. Two Vols. 
 
 Stanley in East Africa, Scouting for. Being a Record of the Adventures of 
 Thomas Stevens in search of H. M. Stanley. With 14 Illustrations. Cloth, 7s. 6d. 
 
 Star-Land. By Sir Robert Stawell Ball, LL.D., &c. Illustrated. 6s. 
 
 Storehouse of General Information, Cassell's. Fully Illustrated with High- 
 Class Wood Engravings, and with Maps and Coloured Plates. In Vols. 5s. each. 
 
 Story of Francis Cludde, The. A Novel. By Stanley J. Weyman. 7s. 6d. net 
 
 Strange Doings in Strange Places. Complete Sensational Stories by Popular 
 
 .Authors. 5s. 
 
 Teaching in Three Continents. Personal Notes on the Educational Systems of 
 the World. By W. C. Grasby. 6s. 
 
 Thackeray, Character Sketches from. Si.x New and Original Drawings by 
 
 Frederick Barnard, reproduced in Photogravure. 21s. 
 The Short Story Library. 
 
 Noi.ghts a 'd Crosses. By Q. ss. 
 
 Otto the Kriight, &c. By Octave Thanf.t. 5s. 
 
 Fourteen 10 One, &c. By Elizabeii! Stuart 1'helps. 6s. 
 
 Eleven Possible Case?. By various Authors. 5s. 
 
 A Singer's Wife. By Miss I-.inny Mukikke 5s. 
 
 The Poet's Audience, and Delilah. By Clara Savile Clarke, 5s.
 
 Selections from Cassell dh Cotnpany's Publications. 
 
 Tot Book for all Public Examinations. By W. S. Thomson, M.A. is. . 
 Treasure Island. By R. L. Stevenson. Illustrated. 3s. 6d. 
 Treatment, The Year-Book o A Critical Review for Practitioners of Medicine 
 and Surgery. Greatly Enlarged. 503 pages. 7s. 6d. 
 
 Tree Painting in Water Colours. By W. H. J. Boot. With Eighteen 
 
 Coloured Plates, and valuable instructions by the Artist. 53. 
 Trees, Familiar. By Prof. G. S. Boulger, F.L.S., F.G.S. Two Series. With 
 Forty full-page Coloured Plates by W. H. J. Boot. 12s. 6d. each. 
 
 "Unicode": The Universal Teleg^raphic Phrase Book. Pocket and Desk 
 
 Editions. 2s. 6d. each. 
 
 United States, Cassell's History of the. By the late Edmund Ollier. With 600 
 
 Illustrations. Three Vols. gs. each. 
 
 Universal History, Cassell's Illustrated. With nearly One Thousand 
 Illustrations. Vol. I. Early and Greek History. Vol. II. The Roman Period. 
 Vol. III. The Middle Ages. Vol. IV. Modern History. 9s. each. 
 
 Vaccination Vindicated. By John C. McVail, M.D., D.P.H. Camb. 5s. 
 Verdict, The. A Tract on the Political Significance of the Report of the Parnell 
 
 Commission. By A. V. Dicey, Q.C. 2s. 6d. 
 Verses Grave and Gay. By Miss E. T. Fowler. 3s. 6d. 
 Vicar of Wakefield and other Works, by Oliver Goldsmith. Illustrated. 
 
 3s. 6d. ; cloth, gilt edges, 5s. 
 
 Vision of Saints, A. By Lewis Morris. Edition de luxe. With 20 Full- 
 Page Illustrations. 21s. 
 
 Water-Colour Painting, A Course of. With Twenty-four Coloured Plates by 
 R. P. Leitch, and full Instructions to the Pupil. 5s. 
 
 Waterloo Letters. Edited by Major-General H. T. Siborne, Late Colonel 
 R.E. With Numerous Plans of the Battlefield. 21s. 
 
 Web of Gold, A. By Katharine Pearson Woods. 6s. 
 
 What Girls Can Do. By Phyllis Browne. 2s. 6d. 
 
 Wild Birds, Familiar. By W. Swaysland. Four Series. With 40 Coloured 
 
 Plates in each. 12s. 6d. each. 
 Wild nowers, Familiar. By F. E. Hulme, F.L.S., F.S.A. Five Series. With 
 
 40 Coloured Plates in each. 12s. 6d. each. 
 
 Wood, The Life of the Rev. J. G. By his Son, the Rev. Theodore Wood. 
 
 With Portrait. Extra crown 8vo, cloth. Cheap Edition. 5s. 
 
 Work. An Illustrated Magazine of Practice and Theory for all Workmen, Pro- 
 fessional and Amateur. Yearly Voli:me, cloth, 7s. 6d. 
 
 World of Wit and Humour, The. With 400 Illustrations. Cloth, 7s. 6d. 
 
 World of Wonders, The. With 400 Illustrations. Two Vols. 7s. 6d. each. 
 
 World's Lumber Room, The. By Selina Gave. Illustrated. 2s. 6d. 
 
 Yule Tide. Cassell's Christmas Annual, is. 
 
 ILL USTRA TED MA GAZINES. 
 The Quiver^ for Sunday and General Uiadlag. Monthly, 6d. 
 
 CasseWs Family Magazine. Monthly, jd. 
 
 " Little Folks " 31<tgazine. Monthly, 6d. 
 
 The Magazine of Art. Monthly, is. 
 
 Cassell's Safui'dag Journal. Weekly, id. ; Monthly, 6d. 
 
 Work, An Illustrated Magazine of Practice and Theory for all Work- 
 men, Professional and Amateur. Weekly, id. ; ^Monthly, 6d. 
 
 ,' Full particulars of CASSELL & COMPANY'S Monthly Serial Publications 
 willbe/outidin Cassell & Company's COMPLETE C.A.TALOGUE. 
 
 Catalogues of Cassell & Comp.vny's Publications, which may be had at all 
 
 Booksellers', or will be sent post free on application to the Publishers : 
 Cassell's Complete Catalogue, containing particulars of upwards of- One 
 
 Thousand Volumes. 
 Cassell's Classified Catalogue, in which their Works are arranged according 
 
 to price, from Threepence to Fifty Guineas. 
 Cassell's Educational Catalogue, containing particulars of Cassell & 
 Company's Educational Works and Students' Manuals. 
 
 CASSELL & CO.MPANY, Limited, Ludgate Hill, London.
 
 Selections from Cassell <{, Company's Publications. 
 
 fStbl^s antr fliU0t0ua Morka. 
 
 KWe, Cassell's Illustrated Family. With 900 Illustrations. Leather, gilt 
 
 edges, ^z los. ; full morocco, !, los. 
 Bible Dictionary, Cassell's. With nearly 600 Illustrations. 7s. 6d. ; roxburgh, 
 
 IDS. 6ci. 
 Kble Educator, The. Edited by E. H. Plumptre, D.D. With Illustrations, 
 
 Maps, &c. Four Vols., cloth, 6s. each. 
 Bible Student in the British Museum, The. By the Rev. J. G. Kitchin, 
 
 M.A. IS. 
 Biblewomen and Nurses. Yearly Volume, 3s. 
 Bunyan's Pilgrim's Progress, and the Holy War, Cassell's Illustrated 
 
 Edition of. With 200 Original Illustrations. Demy 410, cloth, i6s. 
 
 Bunyan's Pilgrim's Progress (Cassell's Illustrated). 4to. 7s. 6d. 
 
 Bunyan's Pilgrim's Progress. With Illustrations. Cheap Edition, 2s. 6d. 
 
 Child's Bible, The. With 200 Illustrations. Demy 4to, 830 pp. 150//% Thousand. 
 Cheap Edition, 7s. 6d. Superior Edition, with 6 Coloured Plates, gilt edges, los. 6d. 
 
 Child's Life of Christ, The. Complete in One Handsome Volume, with about 
 200 Original Illustrations. Cheap Edition, cloth, 7s. 6d. ; or with 6 Coloured Plates, 
 cloth, gilt edges, los. 6d. Demy 410, gilt edges, 2is. 
 
 "Come, ye Children." By the Rev. Benjamin Waugh. Illustrated. 5s. 
 
 Commentary, The New Testament, for English Readers. Edited by the 
 Rt. Rev. C. J. Ellicott, D.D., Lord Bishop of Gloucester and Bristol. In Three 
 Volumes. 21s. each. 
 
 Vol. 1. The Four Gospels. 
 
 Vol. II. The Acts, Romans, Corinthians, Galatians. 
 
 Vol. III. The remaining Books of the New Testament. 
 
 Commentary, The Old Testament, for English Readers. Edited by the Rt 
 Rev. C. J. Ellicott, D.D., Lord Bishop of Gloucester and Bristol. Complete in 
 S Vols. 21s. each. 
 Vol. I. Genesis to Numbers. I Vol. III. Kings I. to Esther. 
 
 Vol. II. Deuteronomy to Samuel II. | Vol. IV. Job to Isaiah. 
 
 Vol. v. Jeremiah to Malachi. 
 
 Commentary, The New Testament. Edited by Bishop Ellicott. Handy 
 
 Volume Edition. Suitable for School and general use. 
 
 St. Matthew. 3s. 6d 
 
 St. Mark. 3s. 
 
 St. Luke. 3S. 6(1. 
 
 St. John. 3S. 6d. 
 
 The Acts of the Apostles. 
 
 Titus, Philemon, Hebrews, 
 
 and James. 3s. 
 Peter, Jude, and John. 3s. 
 
 The 6.evelation. 
 An Introduction to the New 
 Testament, as. 6d. 
 
 Romans, as. 6d. 
 Corinthians I. and II. 3s. 
 Galatians, Ephesians, and 
 
 Philippians. 35. 
 Colossians, Thessalonians, 
 3s. 6d. ' [ and Timothy. 3s. 
 
 Commentary, The Old Testament. Edited by Bishop Ellicott. Handy Volume 
 
 Edition. Suitable for School and general use. 
 Genesis. 3s. 6d. I Leviticus. 3s. I Deuteronomy. 2s. 6d. 
 
 Exodus. 3s. I Niunbers. as. 6d. ! 
 
 Dictionary of Religion, The. An Encyclopaedia of Christian and other 
 Religious Doctrines, Denominations, Sects, Heresies, Ecclesiastical Terms, History, 
 Biography, &c. &c. By the Rev. William Benham, B.D. Cheap Edition. los. 6d. 
 
 Dore Bible. With 230 Illustrations by Gustave DoRfi. Original Eaition. 
 
 Two Vols., best morocco, gilt edges, ^15. 
 Early Days of Christianity, The. By tlie Ven. Archdeacon Farrar, D.D., F. R.S. 
 
 LiBR.'^RY Edition. Two Vols., 24s. ; morocco, -2 2s. 
 
 Popular Edition'. Complete in One Volume, cloth, 6s. ; cloth, gilt edges, 
 7s. 6d. ; Persian morocco, los. fid. ; tree-calf, 15s. 
 
 Family Prayer-Book, The. Edited by the Rev. Canon Garbett, M.A., and 
 the Rev. S. Martin. Extra crown 4to, cloth, ss. ; morocco, iSs. 
 
 Gleanings after Harvest. Studies and Sketches. By the Rev. John R. Vernon, 
 
 M.A. Illustrated. 6s. 
 Gospel of Grace, The. By a Lindesie. Cloth, 2s. 6d. 
 "Graven in the Rock." By the Rev. Dr. Samuel Kinns, F.R.A.S., &c. &c. 
 
 Illustrated. 12s. fid.
 
 Selections from Cassell <fc Company's Publications. 
 
 ' Heart Chords." A Series of Works by Eminent Divines. Bound in cloth, red 
 edges, IS. each. 
 
 My Soul. By the Rev. P. B. Power, M.A. 
 
 My OroTSTtli in Divine Iiife. By the Rer. 
 
 Prebendary Reynolds, M.A. 
 My Hereafter. By the Very Rev. Dean Bicker- 
 
 steth. 
 My Walk with Q-od. By the Very Rev. Dean 
 
 Montgomery. 
 My Aids to the Divine Iiife. By the Very 
 
 Rev. Dean Boyle. 
 My Sources of Strength. By the Rev. E. E. 
 
 Jenkins, M.A., Secretary of the Wesleyan 
 
 Missionary Society. 
 
 THE MORALITY OF THE OLD TESTAMENT. By 
 the Kev. Newman Smyth, D.D. 
 
 THE Divinity of Our Lord. By the Lord 
 Bishop of Derry. 
 
 My Father. By the Right Rev. Ashton Oxenden, 
 late Bishop of Montreal. 
 
 My Bible. By the Rt. kev. \V. Boyd Carpenter, 
 Bishop of Ripon. 
 
 My Work for G-od. By the Right Rev. Bishop 
 Cotterill. 
 
 My Object in Life. By the Ven. Archdeacon 
 Farrar, D.D. 
 
 My Aspirations. By the Rev. G. Matheson, D.D. 
 
 My Emotional Life. By the Rev. Preb. Chad- 
 wick, D.D. 
 
 My Body. By the Rev. Prof. W. G. Blaikie, D.D. 
 
 Helps to Belief. A Series of Helpful Manuals on the Religious Difficulties of the 
 Day. Edited by the Rev. Teignmouth Shore, M.A., Canon of Worcester, and 
 Chaplain-in-Ordinary to the Queen. Cloth, is. each. 
 Creatio.v. By the Lord Bishop of Carlisle. 
 Miracles. By the Bev. Brownlow Mait- 
 
 land, M.A. 
 Prayer. By the Bev. T. Teismmouth Shore, 
 M.A. 
 The Atonement. By William Connor Magee, D.D., Late Archbishop of York. 
 
 Hid Treasure. By Richard Harris Hill. is. 
 
 Holy Land and the Bible, The. A Book of Scripture Illustrations gathered 
 in Palestine. By the Rev. Cunningham Geikie, D.D. With Map. Two Vols. 24s. 
 Illustrated Edition. One Vol. 21s. 
 
 Life of Christ, The. By the Ven. Archdeacon Farrar, D.D., F.R.S.,Chaplaia- 
 in-Ordinary to the Queen. 
 Illustrated Edition, with about 300 Original Illustrations. Extra crown 4to, 
 morocco antique, 42s. Cheap Illustrated Edition. Large 410, cloth, 7s 6d. 
 Cloth, full gilt, gilt edges, los. 6d. 
 Library Edition. Two Vols. Cloth, 24s.; morocco, 42s. 
 
 Popular Edition, in One Vol. 8vo, cloth, 6s.; cloth, gilt edges, 7s. 6d. ; Persian 
 morocco, gilt edges, los. 6d. ; tree-calf, 155. 
 
 Marriage Ring, The. By William Landels, D.D. Bound in white 
 
 leatherette. New and Cheaper Edition, 3s. 6d. 
 
 Moses and Geology ; or, the Harmony of the Bible with Science. By 
 
 the Rev. Samuel Kinns, Ph.D., F.R.A.S. Illustrated. Cheap Edition, 6s. 
 My Comfort in Sorrow. By Hugh Macmillan, D.D., LL.D., &c.. Author of 
 
 " Bible Teachings in Nature," &c. Cloth, is. 
 Protestantism, The History of. By the Rev. J. A. Wylie, LL.D. Containing 
 
 upwards of 600 Original Illustrations. Three Vols., 27s. ; Library Edition, 30s. 
 
 "Quiver" Yearly Volume, The. With about 600 Original Illustrations and 
 
 Coloured Frontispiece. 7s. 6d. Also Monthly, 6d. 
 St. George for England ; and other Sermons preached to Children. Fifth 
 
 Edition. By the Rev. T. Teignmouth Shore, M.A., Canon of Worcester. 5s. 
 St Paul, The Life and Work of. By the Ven. Archdeacon Farrar, D.D., 
 F.R.S., Chaplain-in-Ordinary to the Queen 
 Lii'.rary Edition. Two Vols., cloth, 24s. ; calf, 42s. 
 Illustrated Edition, complete in One Volume, with about 300 Illustrations, 
 
 \ IS. ; morocco, ,-2 2s. 
 Popular Edition. One Volume, 8vo, cloth, 6s. ; cloth, gilt edges, 7.S. 6d. ; 
 Persian morocco, 10s. 6d. ; tree-calf, 155. 
 
 Shall We Know One Another in Heaven ? By the Rt. Rev. J. C. Ryle, D.D., 
 
 Bi~!i')p of Liverpool. Kcw and Enlarged Edition. Paper Covers, 6d. 
 
 Shor ened Church Services and Hymns, suitable for use at Children's Services. 
 Compiled by the Rev. T. Teign.mouth Shore, M.A, Canon of Worcester. 
 Enlarged Edition, is. 
 
 Signa Christi : Evidences of Christianity set forth in the Person and Work of 
 Christ. By the Rev. James .\itchiso.v. 5s. 
 
 "Sunday:" Its Origin, History, and Present Obligation. By the Ven. Arch- 
 deacon Hessi.v, D.C.I.. Ftjth Edition, 7s. 6d. 
 
 TwUight of Life, The: Words of Counsel and Comfort for the Aged. By 
 
 John Ei.lkktok, M..A. is. 6d.
 
 Selections from Cassell dk Company's Publications. 
 
 CBiJucational Morks antr ^tu5mta' jHanualfi. 
 
 Agriculture Series, Cassell's. Edited byJoHN Wrightson, Prof, of Agriculture. 
 
 Soils and Manures. By J. M. H. Munro, D.Sc. (I-ondon), F.I.C., F.C.S. as. 6d. 
 Crops. By Professor Wriglitson. as. 6d. 
 
 Alphabet, Cassell's PictoriaL Size, 35 inches by 42J inches. Mounted on 
 Linen, with rollers. 3s. 6d. 
 
 Aritlunetic : Howard's Anglo-American Art of Reckoning. The Standard 
 
 Teacher and Referee of Shorthand Business Arithmetic. By C. F. Howard. 
 Paper, is. ; cloth, 2s. New Enlarged Edition, 5s. 
 
 Arithmetics, The Modem School. By George Ricks, B.Sc. Lond. With Test 
 
 Cards. (List on application.) 
 Atlas, Cassell's Popular. Containing 24 Coloured Maps, 3s. 6d. 
 Book-Keeping. By Theodore Jones. For Schools, 2s. ; or cloth, 3s. For 
 
 THE Million, 2s. ; or cloth, 3s. Books for Jones's System, Ruled Sets of, 2s. 
 
 Chemistry, The Public School. By J. H. Anderson, M.A. 2s. 6d. 
 Classical Texts for Schools, Cassell's. {A list sent post free on application.') 
 Cookery for Schools. By Lizzie Heritage. 6d. 
 Copy-Books, Cassell's Graduated. Complete in 18 Books. 2d. each. 
 Copy-Books, The Modem School. Complete in 12 Books. 2d. each. 
 Drawing Copies, Cassell's "New Standard." Complete in 14 Books. 2d., 3d., 
 
 and 4d. each. 
 
 Drawing Copies, Cassell's Modem School Freehand. First Grade, is. Second 
 
 Grade, 2S. 
 
 Electricity, Practical. By Prof. W. E. Ayrton. 7s. 6d. 
 
 Energy and Motion -. A Text-Book of Elementary Mechanics. By William 
 
 Paice, M.A. Illustrated, is. 6d. 
 English Literature, A First Sketch of, from the Earliest Period to the Present 
 
 Time. By Prof. Henry Morley. 7s. 6d. 
 Euclid, Cassell's. Edited by Prof. Wallace, M.A. is. 
 Euclid, The First Four Books ot New Edition. In paper, 6d. ; cloth, gd. 
 French, Cassell's Lessons in. New and Revised Edition. Parts I. and II,, each 
 
 2s. 6d. ; complete, 4s. 6d. Key, is. 6d. 
 
 French-English and English-French Dictionary. Entirely New and Enlarged 
 
 Edition. 1,150 pages, 8vo, cloth. 3s. 6d. 
 
 French Reader, Cassell's Public School. By Guillaume S. Conrad. 2s. 6d. 
 Galbraith and Haughton's Scientific Manuals. 
 
 Plane Trigonometry. 2s. 6d. Euclid. Books I., II., III. 2s. 6d. Books IV., V.. VI. 2s. 6d. 
 Mathematical Tables. 3s. 6d. Mechanios. 3s. 6d. Natural Philosophy. 3s. 6d. Optics. 
 2S. 6d. Hydrostatics. 35. 6d. Astronomy. 5s. Steam Engrine. 3s. 5d. Algebra. Part I., 
 cloth, 2S. 6d. Complete, 7s. 6d. Tides and Tidal Currents, with Tidal Cards, 3s. 
 
 Oaudeamus. Songs for Colleges and Schools. Edited by John Farmer. 5s. 
 
 Words only, paper, 6d. ; cloth, gd. 
 
 Geometry, First Elements of Experimental. By Paul Bert. Illustrated, is. 6d. 
 
 (Jeometry, Practical Solid. By Major Ross, R.E. 2s. 
 
 German Dictionary, Cassell's New. German-English, English German. Cheap 
 
 Edition, cloth, 3s. 6d. 
 
 German of To-Day. By Dr. Heinemann. is. 6d. 
 
 German Reading, First Lessons in. By A. Jagst. Illustrated, is. 
 
 Hand-and Eye Training. By G. Ricks, B.Sc. Two Vols., with 16 Coloured 
 
 PLites in each Vol Crown 410, 6s. each. 
 "Hand-and-Eye Training" Cards for Class Work. Five sets in case. is. each. 
 Handbook of New Code of Regulations. By John F. Moss. New and Revised 
 
 Edition, is. ; cloth, 2s. 
 
 Historical Cartoons, Cassell's Coloured. Size 45 in. x 35 in. 2s. each. Mounted 
 
 on canv.is and varnished, with rollers, 5s. each. (Descriptive pamphlet, 16 pp., id.) 
 
 Historical Course for Schools, Cassell's. Illustrated throughout. I. Stories 
 
 from English History, is. II. The Simple Outline of English History, is. 3d. 
 III. The Class History of England, 2s. 6d. 
 
 Latin-English Dictionary, Cassell's. Thoroughly revised and corrected, and in 
 
 part re-written by J. R. V. Makchant, M.A. 3s. 6d. 
 
 Latin Primer, The New. By Prof. J. P. Postgate. 23. 6d. 
 Latin Primer, The First. By Prof. Postgate. is. 
 Latin Prose for Lower Forms. By M. A. Bayfield, M..^. 2s. 6d. 
 Laundfy Work (How to Teach It). By Mrs. E. Lord. 6d.
 
 Selections from Cassell <k Company's Publications. 
 
 Laws of Every-Day Life. For the Use of Schools. By H. O. Arnold-Forster. 
 IS. 6d. 
 
 Little Folks' History of England. Bj' Isa Craig-Knox. Illustrated, is. 6d. 
 
 Making of the Home, The. By Mrs. Samuel A. Barnett. is. 6d. 
 
 Map-Building Series, Cassell's. Outline Maps prepared by H. O. Arnold- 
 Forster. Per set of 12, is. 
 
 BlarlbOrOUgh Books: Arithmetic Examples. 3S. Arithmetic Rules, is. 6d. Frenoli 
 Exercises. 3s. 6d. French Grammar. 2s. fid. Qerman Grammar. 3s. 6d. 
 
 Mechanics For Young Beginners, A First Book of. By the Rev. J. G. Easton, 
 
 M.A. 4s. 6d. 
 
 Mechanics and Machine Design, Numerical Examples in Practical By 
 
 R. G. Blaine, M.E. With Diagrams. Cloth, 2s. 6d. 
 "Model Joint" Wall Sheets, for Instruction in Manual Training. By S. 
 Barter. Eight Sheets, 2s. 6d. each. 
 
 Natural History Coloured Wall Sheets, Cassell's New. Consisting of 18 
 
 subjects. Size, 39 by 31 in. Mounted on rollers and varnished. 3s. each. 
 Object Lessons from Nature. By Prof. L. C. Mi all, F.L.S., F.G.S. Fully 
 
 Illustrated. 2.s. 6d. 
 
 Physiology lor Schools. By Alfred T. Schofield, M.D., M.R.C.S., &c. 
 
 With Wood Engravings and Coloured Plates, is. gd. Three Parts, paper covers, 
 
 5d. each ; or cloth limp, 6d. each. 
 Poetry Readers, Cassell's New. Illustrated. 12 Books, id. each. Cloth, is. 6d, 
 Popular Educator, Cassell's New. With Revised Text, New Maps, New Coloured 
 
 Plates, New Type, &c. To be completed in Eight Vols. ss. each. 
 
 Reader, The Citizen. By H. O. Arnold-Forster. is. 6d. 
 
 Reader, The Empire. By G. R. Parkin, is. 6d. 
 
 Reader, The Temperance. By Rev. J. Dennis Hikd. Crown 8vo, is. 6d. 
 
 Readers, Cassell's "Higher Class. " [List on application.) 
 
 Readers, Cassell's Historical. Illustrated. {List on application.) 
 
 Readers, Cassell's Readable. Illustrated. {^List on application.) 
 
 Readers for Infant Schools, Coloured. Three Books. 4d. each. 
 
 Readers, The Modern Geographical. Illustrated throughout. {Liston application.) 
 
 Readers, The Modern SchooL Illustrated. [List on application.) 
 
 Reading and Spelling Book, Cassell's Illustrated, is. 
 
 Round World, The. By H. O. Arnold-Forster. 3s. 6d. 
 
 School Bank Manual, A. By Agnes Lambert. 6d. 
 
 School Certificates, Cassell's. Three Colours, 6:^x4! in., id.; Five Colours, 
 
 . iij X 9^ in., 3d. ", Seven Colours and Gold, 9I x 6% in., 3d. 
 Science Applied to Work. By J. A. Bower. Illustrated, is. 
 Science of Every-Day Life. By J. A. Bower. Illustrated, is. 
 Sculpture, A Primer of. By E. Roscoe Mullins. Illustrated. 2s. 6d. 
 Shade from Models, Common Objects, and Casts of Ornament, How to. By 
 
 W. E. Si'ARKEs. With 25 Plates by the Author. 3s. 
 
 Shakspere Reading Book, The. By H. Courthope Bowen, M.A. Illustrated. 
 
 3s. 6d. Also issued in Three Books, is. each. 
 Shakspere's Plays for School Use. Illustrated. 5 Books. 6d. each. 
 Spelling, A Complete Manual o By J. D. Morell, LL.D. is. 
 Technical Educator, Cassell's. Illustrated throughout. Mew and Revised 
 
 Kdition. Four Vols. 5s. each. 
 
 Technical Manuals, Cassell's. Illustrated throughout. 16 Vols., from 2s. 1043. 6d- 
 
 [ List free en application.) 
 
 Technology, Manuals of. Edited by Prof. Ayrton, F. R.S., and Richard 
 WoRMELL, D.Sc, M.A. Illustrated throughout. 
 The Dyeing of TextUe Fabrics. By Prof. Desigu in TextUe Fabrics. By T. R. Ashen- 
 
 Huiiunel. 5s. hurst, 4s. 6d. 
 
 Witch and Clock Making. By D. (Glasgow. Spinning Woollen and Worsted. By W. 
 Vicc-I'residcuc of the British Horolojjical ' .^i ^V , ^iJ"' ^ '^^ o i> r o ., = 
 
 Institute 4S fid 1 Practical Mechanics. By Prof. Perry, M.E. 
 
 3s. fid. 
 
 Steel and Iron. By Prof. W. H. Greeimood. Cutting Tools 'Worked by Hand and Ma- 
 P.C.S., M.I.C.E.,&c. 5s. chine. By Prof. Smith. 3s. fid. 
 
 Test Cards, Cassell's Combination. In sets, is. each. 
 Test Cards, Cassell's Modern SchooL In sets, is. each.
 
 Selections from Cassell db Company's Publications. 
 
 180oks for ^0n0 ^m^\t, 
 
 "Little Folks" Half- Yearly Volume. Containing 432 pages of Letterpress, with 
 Pictures on nearly every page, together with Two Full-page Plates printed in Colours 
 and Four Tinted Plates. Coloured boards, 3s. 6d. ; or cloth gilt, gilt edges, 5s. 
 
 Bo-Peep. A Book for the Little Ones. With Original Stories and Verses. 
 Illustrated with beautiful Pictures on nearly every page, and Coloured Frontispiece. 
 Yearly Volume. Elegant pi:ture boards, 2s. 6d. ; cloth, 3s. 6d. 
 
 Story Poems for Yoimg and Old. By Miss E. Davenport Adams. 6s. 
 Pleasant Work for Busy Fingers. By Maggie Browne. Illustrated. 55. 
 Tlie Marvellous Budget: being 65,636 Stories of Jack and JUL By the 
 
 Rev. F. Bennett. Illustrated. Cloth gilt, 2s. 6d. 
 Maggie at Home. By Prof. Hoffman. Fully Illustrated. A Series of easy 
 and startling Conjuring Tricks for Beginners. Cloth gilt, 5s. 
 
 Schoolroom and Home Theatricals. By Arthur Waugh. With Illustra- 
 tions by H. A. J. Miles. Cloth, 2s. 6d. 
 Little Mother Bunch. By Mrs. Molesworth. Illustrated. Cloth, 3s. 6d. 
 Heroes of Every-Day Life. By Laura Lane. With about 20 Full-page 
 
 Illustrations. 256 pages, crown 8vo, cloth, 2s. 6d. 
 
 Ships, Sailors, and the Sea. By R. J. Cornewall-Jones. Illustrated 
 
 throughout, and containing a Coloured Plate of Naval Flags. Cheap Edition, 2S. 6d. 
 
 Famous Sailors of Former Times, History of the Sea Fathers. By Clements 
 
 Markham. Illustrated. 2s. 6d. 
 
 The Tales of the Sixty Mandarins. By P. V. Ramaswami Raju. 5s. 
 Gift Books for Yoimg People. By Popular Authors. With Four Original 
 Illustrations in each. Cloth gilt, is. 6d. each. 
 
 Tbe Boy Hunters of Kentucky. By 
 
 Edward S. Ellis. 
 Eed Feather: a Tale of the American 
 
 Frontier. By Edward S. Ellis. 
 Fritters ; or, " It's a Long Lane that has 
 
 no Turning." ^ . , 
 
 Trixy; or, "Those who Live m Qlass 
 
 Houses shouldn't throw Stones." 
 The Two Hardoastles. 
 Seeking a City. 
 Khoda's Reward. 
 
 Jack Marston's Anchor. 
 
 Frank's Life-Battle. 
 
 Major Monk's Motto; or, "Look Before 
 
 you Leap." 
 Tim Thomson's Trial; or, " All is not Gold 
 
 that Glitters." 
 Ursula's Stumbling-Bloek. 
 Kuth's Life-Work; or,"No Pains, no Gains." 
 Rags and Rainbows. 
 Uncle William's Charge. 
 Pretty Pink's Purpose. 
 
 "Golden Mottoes" Series, The. Each Book containing 208 pages, with Four 
 full-page Original Illustrations. Crown 8vo, cloth gilt, 2s. each. 
 
 ^ " 'Honour is my Guide." By Jeanie Hering 
 
 i Mrs. Adains-Acton), 
 ' Aim at a Sure End." By Emily Searclifield. 
 
 'Nil Desperandum." By the Rev. F. Lang- 
 bridge, M.A. 
 
 * Bear and Forbear." By Sarah Pitt. 
 
 ' Foremost if I Can." By Helen Atteridge. 
 
 'He Conquers vrho Endures." By the Author 
 of " May Cunningham's Trial," &c. 
 
 'Cross and Crown" Series, The. With Four Illustrations in each Book. Crown 
 8vo, 256 pages, 2S. 6d. each. 
 
 Heroes of the Indian Empire ; or. Stories of 
 Valour and Victory. By Ernest Foster. 
 
 Through Trial to Triumph; or, "The 
 Royal Way." By Madeline Bonavia Hunt. 
 
 In Letters of Flame ; A Story of the 
 Waldenses. By C. L. Matiaux. 
 
 Strong to Suffer; A Story of the Jews. By 
 
 By Fire and Sword; a Story of the Hugue- 
 nots. By Thomas Archer. 
 
 Adam Hepburn's Vow ; A Tale of Kirk and 
 Covenant. By Annie S. Swan. 
 
 No. XIII.; 01% the Story of the Lost Vestal. 
 A Tale of Early Christian Days. By Emma 
 Marshall. 
 
 Freedom's Sword; A Story of the Days of 
 
 E. Wynne. Wallace and Bruce. By Annie S. Swan. 
 
 Five Shilling Books for Young People. With Original Illustrations. Cloth 
 gilt, 5s. each. 
 Under Bayard's Banner. By Henry Frith. I Bound by a Spell; or, the Hunted Witch 
 The Champion of Odin ; or. Viking Life I of the Forest. By the Hon. Mrs. Greene. 
 
 in the Ijays of Old. By J. Fred. Hodgetts. ' The Romance of Invention. Byjas. Burnley. 
 
 Albums for Children. Price 3s. 6d. each 
 
 le Chit-chat Album. Illustrated, 
 le Album for Home, School, and Plaj 
 Set in bold type, and illustrated throughout. 
 
 The Chit-chat Album. Illustrated. I jiy Own Album of Animals. lUustrated. 
 
 ^^l.^'bum for Hoine Schoo. and K^^^^ Picture Album of All Sorts. lUustrated. 
 
 'Wanted a King" Series. Illustrated. 3s. 6d. each. 
 
 Robin's Ride. By Miss E. Dnenport .^dams. Wanted a King; or. How Merle set the 
 Great-Grandmimma and Els.e. By Geor- Nursery Rhymes to Eights. By M.iggie 
 
 ginaM. Sjnge. I Browne.
 
 Selections from Cassell <fc Company'' s Publications. 
 
 Crown 8vo Library. Cheap Editions. 
 
 Bambles Bound liOndon. By C. L. 
 
 Mat6aux. Illustrated. 
 
 Around and About Old England. By C. 
 L. Mat^aux. lUustiated. 
 
 Paws and Claws. By one of the Authors of 
 " Poems Written for a Child." Illustrated. 
 
 Decisive Events in History. By Thomas 
 Archer. With Original Illustrations. 
 
 The True Eobinson Crusoes. Cloth gilt. 
 
 Peeps Abroad for Folks at Home. Illus- 
 trated throughout 
 
 2S. 6d. each. 
 
 Wild Adventures in Wild Places. By Dr. 
 
 Gordon Stables, R.N. Illustrated. 
 
 Modern Explorers. By Thomas Frost. Illus- 
 trated. New and cheaper Edition, 
 
 Early Explorers. By Thomas Frost. 
 
 Home Chat with our Youog EoUls, Illus- 
 trated throughout. 
 
 Jungle, Peak, and Plain. Illustrated 
 throughout 
 
 The England of Shakespeare. By II. 
 Goadby. With Full-page Illustrations. 
 
 Three and Sixpenny Books for Young People. With Original Illustrations. 
 
 Cloth gilt, 3S. 6d. each. 
 The King's Command. A Story for Girls. 
 
 By Maggie Symington. 
 A Sweet Girl Graduate. By L. T. Meade. 
 The White House at Inch Gow. By Mrs. 
 
 Pitt 
 LoHt in Samoa. A Tale of Adventure in the 
 
 Navigator Islands. By E. S, Ellis. 
 Tad; or, "Getting Even" with Him. By 
 
 E. 5. Ellis. 
 
 PoUy. By L. T. Meade. 
 
 The Palace Beautiful. By L. T. Meade. 
 
 " Follow my Leader." 
 
 For Fortune and Glory. 
 
 The Cost of a Mistake. By Sarah Pitt. 
 
 On Board the "Esmeralda." 
 
 Lost among W^hite Africans. 
 
 In Quest of Gold. 
 
 A World of Girls. By L. T. Meade. 
 
 Books by Edward S. Kills, 
 
 The Hunters of the Ozark. 
 
 The Camp in the Moun- 
 tains. 
 
 Ned in the Woods. A Tale 
 of Early Days in the West 
 
 Cown the Mississippi. 
 
 Illustrated. Cloth, 2S. 6d. each, 
 The Last War Trail. 
 Ned on the River. A Tale 
 
 of Indian River Warfare. 
 Footprints in the Forest. 
 Up the Tapajos. 
 
 Ned in the Block House. 
 
 A Story of Pioneer Life in 
 
 Kentucky. 
 The Lost Trail. 
 Camp-Fire and Wigwam. 
 Lost in the WUds. 
 
 Sixpenny Story Books. By well-known Writers. All Illustrated. 
 
 My First Cruise. 
 
 The Smuggler's Cave. 
 Little Lizzie. 
 The Boat Club. 
 Luke Bamicott. 
 
 Little Bird. 
 Little Pickles. 
 The Elehester College 
 Boys. 
 
 The Little Peacemaker. 
 The Delft Jug. 
 
 Cassell's Picture Story Books. Each containing 60 pages. 6d. each, 
 
 Little Talks. Daisy's Story Book. Auntie's Stories. 
 
 Bright Stars. Dot's Story Book. Birdie's Story Book. 
 
 Ntirsery Joys. A Nest of Stories. Little Chimes. 
 
 Pet's Posy. Good Night Stories. A Sheaf of Tales. 
 
 Tiny Tales. Chats for Small Chatterers. Dewdrop Stories. 
 
 Illustrated Books for the Little Ones. Containing interesting Stories. All 
 Illustrated, is. each; or cloth gilt, is. 6d. 
 
 Those Golden Sands. 
 Little Mothers and their 
 
 Children. 
 Our Pretty Pets. 
 Our Schoolday Hours. 
 Creatures Tame. 
 
 Scrambles and Scrapes. 
 Tittle Tattle Tales. 
 Wandering Ways. 
 Dumb Friends. 
 Indoors and Out. 
 Some Farm Friends. 
 
 Creatures Wild. 
 Up and Down the Gardes 
 All Sorts of Adventures. 
 Our Sunday Stories. 
 Our HoUday Hours. 
 
 Shilling Story Books. 
 
 Seventeen Cats. 
 Bunty and the Bo vs. 
 The Heir of Blmdale. 
 The Mystery at Shonoliff 
 
 School. 
 Claimed at Last, and Boy's 
 
 Reward. 
 Thorns and Tangles. 
 
 All Illustrated, and containing 
 The Cuckoo in the Robin's 
 John's Mistake. [Nest. 
 
 Diamonds in the Sand. 
 Surly Bob. 
 The History of Five Little 
 
 Pitchers. 
 The Giant's Cradle. 
 Shag and DoU. 
 
 Interesting Stories. 
 
 Aunt Lucia's Locket 
 The Magic Mirror. 
 The Cost of Revenge. 
 Clever Frank. 
 Among the Redskins. 
 The Ferryman of Brill. 
 Harry MaxweU. 
 A Banished Monarch 
 
 Little Folks" Painting Books. With Text, and Outline Illustrations for 
 
 Water-Coloiir Painting, is. each. 
 Fruits and Blossoms for " Little Folks " 
 to Paint. 
 
 The "Little Folks' 
 
 I The "Little Folks' 
 I Book. Cloth only, as. 
 Illuminating Book. 
 
 Proverb Painting 
 
 Eighteenpenny Story Books. All Illustrated throughout. 
 
 W^ee W^Ulie W^inkie. 
 Ups and Downs of a Don- 
 key's Life. 
 Three Wee Ulster Lassies. 
 Up the Ladder. 
 Dick's Hero ; & other Stories. 
 The Chip Boy. 
 
 Raggles, Baggies, and the 
 
 Emperor. 
 Roses from Thorns. 
 Faith's Father. 
 By Land and Sea. 
 The Young Berringtons. 
 Jeff and Leff. 
 
 Tom Morris's Error. 
 
 Worth more than Gold. 
 
 " Through Flood Through 
 
 Fire." 
 The Girl with the Goldeu 
 
 Locks. 
 Stories of the Olden Time.
 
 Selections from Cassell <fc Company's Publications. 
 
 The "World in Pictures" Series. 
 
 A Bamble Bound France. 
 
 All the Bussias. 
 
 CJhats about Germany. 
 
 The Land of the Pyramids (Sgypt). 
 
 Peeps into China. 
 
 Illustrated throughout as. 6d. each.!"?- 
 The Eastern Wonderland (Japan). 
 Glimpses of South America. 
 Bound Africa. 
 
 The Land of Teniples (India). 
 The Isles of the Pacific. 
 
 Clieap Editions of Populax Volumes for Young People. Illustrated, as. 6d. 
 
 each. 
 Esther West. | Three Homes. I For Queen and King. | Working to Win. 
 Perils Afloat and Brigands Ashore. 
 
 Two-Shilling Story Books. All Illustrated, 
 stories of the Tower. 
 Mr. Burke's Nieces. 
 May Chinningham's TriaL 
 The Top of the Ladder: 
 
 How to Beach it. 
 Little Flotsam. 
 Madge and her Friends. 
 
 Half-Crown Story Books. 
 
 The Children of the Court. 
 A Moonbeam Tangle. 
 Maid Marjory. 
 The Four Cats of the Tip- 
 
 pertons. 
 Marion's Two Homes. 
 Little Folks' Sunday Book. 
 School Girls. 
 
 Two Fourpenny Bits. 
 
 Poor Nelly. 
 
 Tom Heriot. 
 
 Aunt Tabitha's Waifs. 
 
 In Mischief Again. 
 
 Through Peril to Fortune. 
 
 Peggy, and other Tales. 
 
 Little Hinges. 
 
 Margaret's Enemy. 
 
 Pen's Perplexities. 
 
 Notable Snipwrecks. 
 
 Golden Days. 
 
 Wonders of Common Things. 
 
 At the South Pole. 
 
 By 
 
 Truth wiU Out. 
 
 Pictures of School Life and Boyhood. 
 
 The Young Man in the Battle of Life, 
 
 the Rev. Dr. Landels. 
 The True Glory of Woman. By the Rev. 
 
 Dr. Landels. 
 Soldier and Patriot (George Washington). 
 
 Three-and-Sixpenny Library. 
 
 The Family Honour. 
 The Half-sisters. 
 
 Fairy Tales 
 
 Illustrated. Cloth gilt, gilt edges. 
 
 I Peggy Oglivie's Inheritance. 
 
 I Krilof and his Fables. 
 
 By Prof. Henry Morley. 
 
 Cassell's Pictorial Scrap Book. 
 
 cloth back, 3s. 6d. psr Vol. 
 Our Scrap Book. 
 The Seaside Scrap Book. 
 The Little Folks' Scrap B:ok. 
 
 In Six Sectional Volumes. Paper boards. 
 
 The Magpie Scrap Book. 
 Ihe Lion Scrap Book. 
 jLhe Elephant Scrap Book. 
 
 Library of Wonders. Illustrated Gift-books for Boys. Paper, is. ; cloth, is. 6d. 
 
 Wonderful Adventures. 
 Wonders of Animal Instinct. 
 
 I Wondeiful Balloon Ascents. 
 
 I W^onders of Bodily Strength and Skill. 
 
 Wonderful Escapes. 
 
 Books for the Little Ones. Fully Illustrated. 
 
 Bhymes for the Young Folk. By William 
 
 Allingliaiu. Beautifully Illustrated. 3s. 6d. 
 The Sunday Scrap Book. With One 1 hou- 
 
 sand Pictures. Boards, 5s. ; doth. 7s. 6d. 
 The History Scrap Book. With nearly 
 
 1,000 Hn^ravinjJS. 5s. ; cloth, 7s. 6d. 
 Cassell's Robinson Crusoe. With 100 
 
 Illustrations. Cloth, 3s. 6d. ; gilt edges, 5s. 
 
 The Old Fairy Tales. With Original Illus- 
 trations. Boards, is. ; cloth, is. 6d. 
 
 My Diary. With Twelve Coloured Plates and 
 366 Woodcuts. IS. 
 
 The Pilgrim's Progress. With Coloured 
 Illustrations. 2S. 6d. 
 
 Cassell's Swiss Family Robinson. Illus- 
 trated. Cloth, 3s. 6d. ; gilt edges, 5s. 
 
 The World's Workers. A Series of 
 
 Authors. With Portraits printed on a 
 Dr. Arnold of Rugby. By Rose E. Selle. 
 The Earl of Shaftesbury. 
 Sarah Robinson, Agnes Weston, and Mrs. 
 
 Meredith. 
 Thomas A. Edison and Samuel F. B. 
 
 Morse. 
 Mrs. SomervUle and Mary Carpenter. 
 General Gordon. 
 Charles Dickens. 
 
 Sir Titus Salt and George Moore. 
 Florence Nightingale, Catherine Marsh, 
 
 Frances Ridley Havergal, Mrs. Rau- 
 
 yard ("L. N. R."). 
 
 New and Original Volumes by Popul.ir 
 
 lint as Frontispiece, is. each. 
 
 Dr. Guthrie, Father Mathew, Elihu Bur- 
 
 ritt, Josepn Livesey. 
 Sir Henry Havelock and Colin Campbell 
 
 Lord Clyde. 
 Abraham Lincoln. 
 David Livingstone. 
 George MuIIer and Andrew Reed. 
 Richard Cobden. 
 Benjamin Franklin. 
 Handel. 
 
 Turner the Artist. 
 George and Robert Stephenson. 
 
 llu 
 
 v/;ra'i.4'- Richard Cobden) 1 
 
 '. also 
 
 I km in One Vjl., r!o:h. iri// g f. 
 
 CAi>SELL it COMI^ANV, Limited, Ludoate //ill, Lonton 
 laris iL Melbourne,
 
 
 Date Due 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 L 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 A 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 
 Library Burnai 
 
 Cat. No. 1137 
 
 
 .''SRARy FACILITY 
 
 465