CIHM Microfiche Series (IMonograplis) ICIMH Collection de microfiches (monographies) Canadian Instituta for Historical IWIcroraproductlon. / Inatltut Canadian da microraproduction. historiq uas i Technical and Bibliographic Notes / Notes techniques et bibllographiques Institute has attempted to obtain the best original ^ available for filming. Features of this copy which ' be bibliographicaliy unique, which may alter any of images in the reproduction, or which may lificantly change the usual method of filming are :ked below. Coloured covers / Couverture de couleur Covers danriaged / Cou* erture endommag^e Covers restored and/or laminated / Couverture restaurde et/ou pellicul^e Cover title missing / Le titre de couverture manque Coloured maps / Cartes g^ographiques en couleur Coloured ink (i.e. other than blue or black) / Encre de couleur (i.e. autre que bleue ou noire) Coloured plates and/or illustrations / Planches et/ou illustrations en couleur Bound with other material / Reli^ avep d'autres documents Only edition available / Seule Edition disponible Tight binding may cause shadows or distortion atong interior margin / La reliure serr^e peut causer de I'ombre ou de la distorsion le long de la marge intirieure. Blank leaves added during restorations may appear within the text. Whenever possible, these have been omitted from filming / II se peut que certaines pages blanches ajout^es lors d'une restauration apparaissent dans le texte, mais, lorsque cela Itait possible, ces pages n'ont pas M film^es. Addittonal comments / Commentaires suppl^mentaires: L'Institut a microfilm^ le meilleur exemplaire qu'il lui a 6\6 possible de se procurer. Les details de cet exem- plaire qui sont peut-6tre uniques du point de vue bibli- ographique, qui peuvent modifier une image reproduite, ou qui peuvent exiger une modification dans la m^tho- de normale de filmage sont indkju^s ci-dessous. j I Coloured pages / Pages de couleur I I Pages damaged / Pages endommag§es n Pages restored and/or laminated / Pages restaurSes et/ou pelliculdes Pages discoloured, stained or foxed / Pages d^olor^es, tachet^es ou piqu^es I I Pages detached / Pages d6tach6es \V\ Showthrough / Transparence j I Quality of print varies / D D D Quality in^gale de I'impression Includes supplementary material / Comprend du materiel suppl^mentaire Pages wholly or partially obscured by errata slips, tissues, etc., have been refilmed to ensure the best possible image / Les pages totalement ou parliellement obscurcies par un feuillet d'errata, une pelure, etc., ont 6\6 film^es h nouveau de fa^on h obtenir la meilleure image possible. Opposing pages with varying colouration or discolourations are filmed twice to ensure the best possible image / Les pages s'opposant ayant des colorations variables ou des decolorations sont film^es deux fois afin d'obtenir la meilleure image possible. im it fllm«d It lh« rtduclion ratio chacktd b«low / um*nl tit filin4 au Uui da reduction indlqui el-dtitoui. 14X IBX 12x 16k 20x 22x nn k6x 30x 24x 28x 32x The copy filmad h«r« has baan raproducad thanks to tha ganarosity of: National Library of Canada L'axamplaira filmA fut raproduit grica k la g4n4rosit* da: Bibliotheque nationale du Canada Tha jmagas appaaring hara ara tha bast quality possibia eonsidaring tha condition and lagibility of tha original copy and in kaaping with tha filming contract spacifications. Original capias in printad papar covars ara filmad baginning with tha front covar and anding on tha last paga with a printad or illustratad impraa- sion, or tha back covar whan appropriata. All othar original eopiaa ara filmad baginning on tha first paga with a printad or illustratad impraa- aion, and anding on tha last paga with a printad or illuatratad imprassion. Tha last racordad frama on aach microficha shall contain tha symbol -i«» (moaning "CON- TINUED"), or tha symbol V (moaning "END"). whichavar applias. Maps, platas, charts, ate. may ba filmad at diffarant raduction ratios. Thosa too larga to ba antiraly includad in ona axposura ara filmad baginning in tha uppar laft hand cornar, laft to right and top to bonom, as many framas as raquirad. Tha following diagrams illustrsta tha mathod: Las imagas suivantas ont M raprodultos avsc la plus grand soin, compta tanu da la condition at da la nattat* da l'axamplaira film*, at an conformity avac las conditions du contrat da filmaga. Laa axamplairaa originaux dont la couvartura an papiar aat imprim«a sont film«s an commancant par la pramiar plat at an tarminant soit par la darni*ra paga qui comporta una amprainta d'imprassion ou d'illustration. soit par la sacond plat, salon la caa. Tous las autras axamplairss originaux sont filmte an commanpant par la pramiAra paga qui comporta una amprainta d'imprassion ou d'illustration at an tsrminant par la darni*ra paga qui comporta una taila amprainta. Un daa symbolas suivants spparattra sur la darniira imaga da chaqua microficha, talon la cas: la symbols -i^> signifia "A SUIVRE". la symbols ▼ signifia "FIN". Las cartas, planchas. tablaaux. ate. pauvant itra filmis i daa taux da reduction diff«rants. Lorsqua la documant ast trap grand pour *tra raproduit an un saul clich«. il ast film* A partir da I'angia supAriaur gaucha. da gaucha i droita. at da haut an bas, an pranant la nombra d'imagaa nAcassaira. Las diagrammas suivants illustrant la mithoda. 1 2 3 1 2 3 4 5 6 MtCROCOPV RiSOlUTION TfST CHART lANSI ond ISO TEST CHART No. 2) L" n2s y. 1^5 12.2 li HUH. IMI 1.8 1.6 A APPLIED IM^GE Inc 161-' East Uoin 'jlrwt Rochester, N«« York ' - ,19 USA (716) 482 - 0300 - PHon, (7)6) 28B - 19B9 - fo. I INDUSTRIAL EVOLUTION BY CARL BUCHER Pnftsior of Political Economy, Unitersify of Leipeig TRAmtATED FROM THE THIRD GERMAN EDITION BY S. MORLEY WICKETT, Ph.D. Uciunr on Political Economy and Statistics. University of Toronto NEW YORK HENRY HOLT AND COMPANY 190 r 'J- •' < 1 57539 Copyright, 1901, BY HENRY HOLT & CO. Published Jult 1901. flOaCRT DrtuMMONb, pf^lNT£-', NLW fORfv. PREFATORY NOTE. The writings of Professor Bucher, in their German dress, require no introduction to economists. His ad- mirable work The Population of Frankfurt in the Fourteenth and Fifteenth Centuries, published in 1886, gave him immediate celebrity with economic historians, and left him without a rival in the field of historical statis- tics. In his treatment of economic theory he stands midway between the "younger historical school" of economists and the psychological Austrians.» A full list of his writings need not be given.2 But I may recall his amplified German edition of Laveleye's Primitive Property, his little volume The Insurrections of the Slave Labourers, 143-129 b.c, his original and suggestive Labour and Rhythm, discussing the relation between the • A few facts and dates regarding Professor BUcher's career may not be uninteresting. Professor BUcher was born in Prussian Rhineland in .tl: . . ""Pleted his undergraduate studies at Bonn and G6ttingen (1866-69). His rapid rise in the German scholastic world is evident frotn his academic appointments : special lecturer at GSttingen (i86<>- 72 . lecturer at Dortmund (1872-73), at Frankfurt Technical School (187,- S^r /p r""?J""^' ''"■"^'""^ °' ^'''''^''" ^' Dorpat. Russia (I3S2). of Political Economy and Finance at Basel (1883-90). at Karls- ruhe (1890-93). and at Leipsic (1893 to present). From 1878 to the close of 1880 he was Industrial and Social Editor of the Frankfurter Ztitung This may be found in the HandwSrterbuch d. Staatswiss IV PREFATORY NOTE. physiology and the psychology of labour, his investiga- tions into trusts, and his co-editorship of Wagner's Hand- book of Political Economy (the section Industry being in his charge) as indicating the general direction and scope of his researches. The present stimulating volume, which in the original bears the title Die Entstchiing der Volkswift- scliaft (The Rise of National Economy), gives the author's conclusions on general industrial development. Some- what similar ground has been worked over, among recent economic ])ul)licatioiis. alone by Professor Schmoller's comprehensive Crnndrisz dcr allgcmcincn Volksti'irtschafts- Ichrc, Pt. I. But the method of treatment and the results of the present work allow ii to maintain its unique position. Chapters I. and II. outline the prominent features of primitive economic life in the tropical zone. These real- istic accounts of the " pre-economic stage of industrial evo- lution," preceding the dawn of civilization, ably em- phasize the kinship of economics and ethnology. In chap- ter III. he presents brilliantly and concisely the suggestive series of economic developmental stages of household, town and national economy, based on the industrial rela- tion of producer to consumer; and Chapter IV. offers a masterly survey of industrial systems — domestic work, wage-work, handicraft, commission work (house indus- try), and the factory. With these chapters may be classed Chapter V. The Decline of the Handicrafts. The re- maining chapters analyze more specifically, from the viewpoints of the individual and society, some of the great processes of industrial evolution: union and division of labour; the intellectual integration of society as effected by the press; the formation of social classes; and the fur- ther adjustment of labour through internal migrations of population. At the same time they enrich economic terminology with many telling expressions. PREFATORY NOTE. v " The worst use of theory is to make men insensible to fact," Lord Acton remarked in the opening number of the English Historical Review. Our author, with his store of minute facts, his keen analysis and his broad and re- freshing generalizations, has known how to avoid the snare. His historical attitude is indicated by his advice that " our young political economists " be sent on jour- neys of investigation to the Russians, the Roumanians and the southern Slavs rather than to England and America. In the following pages, which in their present form I trust do not entirely obliterate the pleasing style of the original, his attention is, of course, devoted primarily to economic rather than to social and other considerations. The volume has had in Germany an unusually influ- ential circulation, and has recently been translated into French, Russian and Bohemian. As the preface notes, it has done extensive service as a general introduction to " economic thinking." Its use for this purpose, through the medium of special transcriptions, has already been re- marked at some American universities. The hope may be indulged that its merits will now receive wider recognition, and in some measure impart to the reader the stimulus felt by the writer during a two years' attendance on the author's lectures in 1895-97. Editorial annotations, it may be added, have been confined to the narrowest limits. In translating it I have had the valuable assistance of my colleague. Dr. G. H. Needier, Lecturer on German, University College, to whom I wish to express my deep obligations. My thanks are also due Professor Biicher for his patient answers to the many queries sent over the water to him, to Professor Mavor for varied aid during the work of revision, and to Mr. H. H. Langton and Mr. D. R. Keys for help in correcting proofs. VI PREFATORY NOTE. For the convenience of the general reader a short sup- plementary bibliography of recent works in English is appended. University of Toronto, April 9, 1901. S. M. W. Haddon, Evolution of Art (,895) ; Lloyd Morgmn. Animal Life andlntel- I'gfnce (1891). Habit and Instinct (1896) ; Kcane, Atan Past and Present (1899); Spencer and Gillen, The Native Triies 0/ Central Australia (ii<)t)) ■ Mackenzie, An Jntroducttm to Social Philosophy (2d ed.. 1895) ; Giddings,' I>imip!cs of Sociology' (1896); Gumplowicz, Outlines of Sociology ^trans! 1899); \.<^x\&. Economic Foundations of Society (ix2Ln^. i^^f))- Ashley Eco- nomic History (2 pts.. 1888-92). Surveys Historic and Economic (1900)- Gomme, The Village Community (1890) ; Cunningham, Growth of English Industry and Commerce (2 vols.. 1890-92), IVesterr. Civilization (1898) • ^ocx\,. Life and Labours of the People (9 vols.. 1889-97); Mayo-Smith' Emigration and Immigration (1890); Weber, The Growth of Cities (1899); Hobson, The Evolution of Modem Capitalism (1894). FROM THE PREFACES TO THE FIRST AND SECOND GERMAN EDITIONS. (April 1893 and November 1897.) The lectures in this volume were originally delivered before audiences that were not composed of specialists exclusively. . . . Each lecture is complete in itself; the same trains of thought are indeed occasionally repeated, but in a different setting. Yet it will readily be perceived that the different parts have an inner connection, and supplement each other both in subject and method. The fundamental idea running through them all is expressed in the third. As need scarcely be remarked, the lecture is not printed in the sum- mary form in which it was delivered. I trust that the gain in accuracy and fulness of statement has not been at the expense of clearness. The lectures are dominated by a uniform conception of the orderly nature of economic development, and by a sim- ilarity in the method of treating material. In both respects this accords with the practice which I have consistently followed ever since the inception of my academic activity and which during continued scientific work has become more and more clearly and firmly established. With the present publication I accede to the wish expressed by many of my former auditors in the only form at present possible. a form of whose insufficiency I myself am fully conscious. In preparing a second edition one thing was clear: the vii VIII PREFACE. book must be expanded in the direction in which it had been most effective. At its first appearance I had hoped that the little volume might exert some influence upon the method of treating scientific problems; and indeed there has appeared in recent years quite a series of writings by younger authors (some of whom were seemingly wholly unacquainted with my book), in which the resuUs of the in- vestigations here published are taken into account. Tliis is outwardly evidenced by the use of the concepts and the technical expressions that I introduced into the litera- ture of the subject, as if they were old. familiar, scientific furniture. It is perhaps justifiable to infer from this that the book has exercised some influence upon academic teaching. But it seems to have found its chief circulation in the wider circles of the educated public, particularly among college students, who have used it as a sort of introduc- tion to economics, and as a preparation for economic thinking. That naturally decided me to keep their wants very particularly in view in revising the book. In order to avoid misconceptions, however. I wish to state ex- pressly that the employment of the book for this purpose requires the concurrent use of a good systematic treatise on the principles of jwlitical economy. The better to meet the nee.I of the larger class just men- tionerl, I have given some of the lectures of the first edition a simpler form, expanding them where necessary and eliminating needless detail. Extensive alteration, 'how- ever, has been confmcd to the lecture on the Organization of W ork and the l-..rmation of Social Classes. Here uni- formity of treatment seemed to recommen.l a division into two chapters (YUl and IX). .md such extensive ad.litions as would serve to round off each in-lepen.lently of the other. 1 he lecture on the Social Organization of the Pop- PREFACE. iz ulation of Frankfurt in the Middle Ages has been omitted because it disturbed the greater uniformity aimed at for the complete work, and because, as a purely historical ac- count, it is better suited to a collection of sketches in social and economic history, for which opportunity may perhaps be found later. On the other hand three unpublished lectures have been added (Chaps. I, V, and VII). The fust of these deals with the pre-economic period, and is intended to furnish the substructure for the system of economic stages which is developed in the third chapter. Its main features were sketched as early as 1885, in a lecture I delivered at the University of Basel on the beginnings of social history. . . . The second agrees in the major part of its matter, and also to a large extent in its form, with the report upon handicrafts that I presented at the last general meeting of the Social Science Club in Cologne. It seems advisable to give it a place in order to afford the reader at one point at least an insight into the great changes that are in prog- ress in the held of modern industrial life. The third [en- titled " Union of Labour and Labour in Common "] is an attempt to lay before a wider circle of readers, in the form in which I finally presented it to my university classes, a chapter from the theory of labour to which I have given considerable attention. All the lectures in this volume, both old and new. were originally sections of university lectures. Every lecturer knows what a wonderful contpilation his note-book is. how from semester to semester certain portions must be re- moved and reconstructed, how some parts are never approached without an inward struggle, and how tinally the remaining ditViculties are surmounted and the whole given a form satisfactory alike to teacher and students. To the lecture-room first of all belono- the fruits of i * PREFACE. the scientific labours of the German university professor; but he also naturally wishes to submit what he has labori- ously accomplished to the critical judgment of specialists; and for my part I feel in such cases the further need of test- ing the maturity of my conceptions by seeing whether they can be made intelligibly acceptable to a wider range of readers. So th^t all the lectures that have been taken over from the first edition were actually delivered before a more popular audience, while Chapters I and VII are essays in the same style. In the extent of their subject-matter, how- ever, they all reach far beyond what can be offered directly to students in a university lecture. In conclusion I may allude to two attacks that have been delivered by historians against some parts of the third and fourth lectures. The blame surely does not rest with nie if these gentlemen have failed to perceive that this work treats of economic theor>-. not of economic history. I le who, in the outline of a period of de\'elopment extend- ing over thousands of years, expects a minute and ex- haustive presentation of the actual condition of any par- ticular people and centun-. need blame only himself if he is disappointed. In the first edition I expressed myself clearly enough. I think, regarding the logical character of the economic stages. In the present edition I have taken (H-casion. however, to give the passages in question such a form that in future they cannot with good intentions be misuii.lerstood. . . . Though fdr the central idea of my theory of development it is altogether immaterial whether I have in every particular characterized the economy of the (Ireeks and Romans correctly or not. or whether the guild handicraft of the Midille .\ges was chiefly wage-wx>rk or chiefly independent hand-work {,' price-work *'). PREFACE TO THE THIRD GERMAN EDITION. In the present edition, bearing in mini the way in which this book came into existence and has since expanded, I felt strongly impelled to mark my appreciation of the recognition it has gained, as indicated by several editions and by translations into French, English. Russian, and Bohemian, by preparing additional chapters to remove a number of gaps still noticeable in the last issue. If I have not yielded to the temptation, it is chiefly for the reason that a larger bulk would necessarily prejudice the wider circulation of the volume. The most disturbing want has been met by the insertion of a new chapter on the economic life of primitive peoples (Chapter II). The chapter differs from the more detailed one in volume 3 uf the Yearbook of the Gehe Stiftung in its more summar>- form and in the addition of some not unimportant facts. All the other chapters have been carefully revised and many slight improvements made. More extensive alter- ations are confmed to Chapters I. III. Vll, and VIII. May the book in its present form satisfy its old friends and add new ones to the number! C.\RL Pii'CHER. Lkipzk,. Oct. 15, 190a xi \y CONTENTS rAcs Prefatory Note iii From the Prefaces to First and Second Ge^.man Editions... vii Preface to Third German Edition xi Chapter I. — Primitive Economic Conditions i II. — The Economic Life ok Primitive Peoples 41 N^ III.— The Rise of National Economy 83 IV. — A Historical Survey of Industrial Systems... 150 V. — The Decline of the Handicrafts 185 VI. — The Genesis of Journalism 215 VII.— Union of Labour and Labour in Common 244 jt- VIII.— Division of Labour 282 IX.— Organization of Work and the Formaiion of Social Classes 315 X.— Internal Migrations of Population *ni) the Growth of Towns Considered Historically 345 Index 387 CHAPTER I. PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. All scientific investigation of industry starts with the assumption that man has a peculiar " economic nature " belonging to no other living creature. From this eco- nomic nature a principle is supposed to spring, which con- trols all his actions that are directed to the satisfaction of his wants. This is the economic principle, the fundamen- tal principle of economic activity. This principle reveals itself in man's endeavour always and everywhere to attain the highest possible satisfaction with the least possible sac- rifice (labour)— the " principle of least sacrifice." According to this view all man's economic actions are actions directed toward an end and guided by considera- tions of profit. Whether or not the final impulse to eco- nomic labour is to be sought in the instincts of man (the instinct of self-preservation and of self-interest), the satis- faction of these instincts is always the result of a series of successive mental operations. Man estimates the extent of the discomfort that -ould arise from the non-satisfac- tion of a want felt by him; he measures the discomfort that the labour necessary to meet the want can cause him; he compares tlie discomforts witli each <ithcr. and resolves to undertake the labour only when the accompanying sacrifice a PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. is less than the sacrifice of remaining unsatisfied. More- over, upon undertakmg the labour he again chooses the least burdensome among the various possible methods of procedure, and thus has a further series of considerations, estimations. comi)arisons, and judgments to enter upon. In fact the whole science of political economy proceeds on the assumption that economic actions have behind them a rational motive and call into play the higher mental facul- ties; and it ha-^ evolved a kind of psyciiology of labour, by means of whic.i it seeks to explain those actions in their typical progress. Economic activity is, therefore, some- thing especially human; indeed the question whether the lower animals display similar activity, seems never to have been broached. The economic nature of man is something absolute, inseparable from the very character of man.' Yet even among civilized mankind, from whose manifold activity the principle of economy has lieen deduced, indi- cations are not wanting to sl.ow that the economic nature must be characteristic of different individuals in different degree. Between the industrious and the indolent, the provident and the improvident, the sparing and the spend- thrift, there are innumerable gradations; and if we only observe the conduct of the child towards his possessions, we are easily convinced that the " economic nature " must be acquired anew by each human being, and that it is a result of education and custom, in which individuals dififer no less than in their whole physical and mental develop- ment. Having once reached this point, we shall scarcely be •"The elements of economic character are firmly rooted in the physical and intellectual (irKanization of man, and change just as little n-^ his (.utward character does, at least in the periods which come within the scope of the history of mankind." -Wagner, Grmdlegung d. polit. OekoHomk (,v Aufl.), I, p. 82. [As for animal sociology, it can hardly be said to have advanced as yet hcyond animal psychology.— Eu.] PRIMITII^E ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. be able to postpone the question, whether indeed that " eco- nomic nature " does not, for mankind in general, signify something acquired rather than something given by na- ture; and whether we must not assume at the beginning of human evolution a period of purely instinctive satisfac- tion of wants reaching over many thousands of years, such as we are accustomed to take for granted in the case of the lower animal. The answer to this question can be gained only by pro- ceeding inductively. The picture of primitive man that we make for ourselves must be not an imaginary one — no Robinson Crusoe story such as is so often encountered in the deductions of the " classical " economists. Its lines must all be drawn from reality; they must show us the actuality of the assumed conditions under which uncivil- ized man lives and the impulses under which he is con- ceived to act and later also think. Civilized man has al- ways had a great inclination to read his conceptions and feelings into the mind of primitive man; but he has only a limited capacity for understanding the latter's undevel- oped mental life and for interpreting, as it were, his nature. To be sure, aboriginal man in actual existence can no- where now be found. Great as is the number of primitive peoples that have gradually come within our ken. none of them stands any longer at the lowest stage of savagery; all show traces of the first step in civilization, for all know the use of fire. Many writers, it is true, have imagined, under the stim- ulus of evolutionist theories, that they hail succeeded, now here, now there, in discovering populations pre- serving the original animal state down to the present. As late a writer as Sir John Lubbock is inclined to deny to several tribes of the South Sea Islands a knowledge of fire, O. Peschel has been at pains to PRmiTlVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. prove that the instances adduced by Lubbock are in- correct; 2 and with him we may regard as vaHd the asser- tion that upon the whole earth the tribe that has not made use of fire is yet to be found. Even the prehistoric cave discoveries, which show us men of the Ice Age along with the bear, the aurochs, and the reindeer, show traces of the use of fire. Fire indeed is a powerful influence in the direc- tion of civilization. It enlarges man's sphere of suste- nance, teaches him to harden the points of the wooden arrows and spears, to hollow out the tree, and to frighten away the wild beasts. Other investi<:;fators have imagined they have discovered human beings who lived together in small groups in trees, had fruits for food, and used only stones and cudgels as weapons and instruments, after the fashion of the higher apes. Frederick Engels^ is of the opinion that by this as- sumption alone can we explain the continued existence of man alongside the great beasts of prey. Lippert,who inves- tigates the case more carefully,^ finds, it is true, that in the myth of the Egyptians the tree plays a certain role as an abode of spirits; inn he is prudent enough not to conclude from this that the ancestors of the Egyptians dwelt in trees, — more prudent than the philoloi^ist Lazarus Geiger, who discovered a relic of tree-dwelling in the hammock used by the South American Indians. It is true that in Sumatra, Luzon, New Guinea, the Solomon Islands, and 'Races of Man (New York. 1888), pp. 137 ff. I know, indeed, that the Anicricin writer Teale (quoted i)y Lippcrt. Kultwgcschichte der Mcnschhcit. I. p. 5_>) has cdntradicted him in one instance. Mundt- LaufT lias also, according to Pesclul in " Natiir " for the year 1879, p. 4-8, denied the ii^e of cooked food hy the Xei;ritos in tlte IMiilippines, but his assertions again liave been refuted by .\. Schadenberg in the Ztschr. f. Ethnologie, XII (1880), pp, 14,^4. [Xo ethnologist would now claim fireless tribes as known in actual existence. — En.] * Der Ursprung dcr Familic, des Privatcigciituws u. dcs Staats. p. 7. * As above, pp. 67 ff. PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 5 among the Gaberi negroes in Central Africa, huts have been found built in between the branches of large trees; » and the same is reported of individual forest tribes of South America.® But so far as these products of primitive archi- tecture are not mere temporary protective structures that are supplemented by permanent dwelling-places upon the ground, they are by no means the most unfinished of hab- itations, and the peoples using them prove by many kinds of implements, utensils, and domestic animals, and some of them even by the agriculture they carry on, that they no longer stand at the first dawn of civilization. After what has been said there can be no object in searching out uncivilized peoples and beginning with a description of them, after the example of Klemm who opens his General History of Civilization with the Fo'-est Indians of Brazil, although it is not to be denied that e stand at a very low cultural stajje indeed. In the & ne connection other investigators cite tribes standing at no higher stage: the Bushmen in South Africa, the Batuas in the Congo basin, the Veddahs in Ceylon, the ^lincopies in the Andaman Islands, the Negritos in the Philippines, the Australians of the continent, the now extinct Tas- manians, the Kubus in Sumatra, and the Tierra-del-Fue- gians. To whom to adjudge the palm for savagerv might be difficult to decide. O. Peschel ' finds individual ele- ments of civilization among them all, even among the Botokudos, whom he himself considers still nearest the primitive state. The assumption of such a primitive condition, in which. ' Nachtigal, Sahara u. Sudan, II, pp. 628 flf. Finsch. Samoafahrten. pp. 271 f. Ratzel. \-6lkerkunde. I. pp. loi, 105, 245, 386; li, p. 83. [Its different arrangement precludes citation from the admirable Eng- lish edition: The History of Mankind. 2 vol?., London, 1896-97.— Ed.] Waitz, Anthropologic d. Naturvolker. Ill, p. 393. ' Races of A/oi;, pp. 149 ff. PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. armed witli no other resources than are at the command of the lower animal, man has to join in tlie struggle for exist- ence, is one of the necessary expedients of all sciences that aim at a history of man's development; and this is true of sociology' and especially of political economy. We must, however, abandon the attempt to exemplify the primitive condition by any definite people. On the other hand, there is more prospect of scientific results in an endeavour to collect the common characteristics of the human beings standing lowest in the scale, in order, by starting with them, to arrive at a i)":ture of the beginnings of economic life and the formation of society. But in this it is by no means necessary to confine ourselves to the above-men- tioned representatives of the lowest manner of life; for every delimitation of that kind would challenge objections and contract the field of vision. Moreover the various ele- ments of mental culture and material civilization are by no means so mutually dependent that all must necessarily develop at an equal pace, and thus we find among almost all primitive peoples characteristics that can have sprung only from the most ancient mode of life. The collection of these characteristics, and their combination into a typical picture, must, however, be our first task. Hitherto the process has usually been made too simple by deriving the characteristics of primitive man from civil- ized economic man. The many wants of man in a state of nature, so it has been argued, demanded for their satisfac- tion exertions beyond the capacity of the individual; pro- tection from wild bea:;ts or from the unchained elements could likewise be attained only by the labour of many. Accordingly writers have spoken of a collective carrying- on of the struggle for existence, and thus have had " prim- itive society " and a sort of communistic economy com- plete. PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIJSS. But man has undoubtedly existed through immeasur- able periods of time without labouring. If so disposed, one can find plenty of districts upon the earth where the sago-palm, the plantain-tree, the breadfruit-tree, the cocoa- and date-palm, still allow him to live with a mini- mum of exertion. It is in such districts that tradition is fondest of placing paradise, the original home of mankind; and even modern research cannot dispense with the as- sumption that mankind was at first bound to such regions of natural existence and only by further development be- came capable of bringing the whole earth into subjection. Of unions into organized society we find, moreover, hardly a trace amon- the lowest races accessible to our observation. In little roups * like herds of animals they roam about in search of food, find a resting-place for the night in caves, beneath a tree, behind a screen of brush- wood erected in a few minutes to shelter them from the wind, or often in a mere hollow scooped in the ground, and nourish themselves chiefly with fruits and roots, though all kinds of animal food, even down to snails, mag- gots, irrasshoppers, and ants are eaten also. The men as a rule . t armed simply with bow and arrow or with a throwing-stick; the chief implement of the women is the digging-stick, a pointed piece of wood, which they use in searching for roots. Shy when they come in contact with members of a higher race, often malicious and cruel, they lead a restless life, in which the body, it is true, attains the maximum of agility and dexterity, but in which technical skill advances only with extreme sluggishness and one- sidedness. The majority of peoples of this type know nothing whatever of potter>- and the working of metals. Even of wood. bast, stone, and bone they make but limited 'Comp. en this point E. Grosse. DU Format dcr Familie und die fc ii: iicr ;; irtscn^r:. p. » PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. use, and this use leads in no way to a stock of utensils and tools, which indeed it would I)e impossible to carry about, I)ecause of their nomadic life, bearing as it does the char- acter of one continuous search for food." •In order to puppleniunt this general account by a few details I will here introduce ;i portion oi the description of the NcRritos in the Philippines published in the work by A. Scliadenberg. cited above. I Mive for the most par' his own words:— The women among the Etas bear easily and (piickiy. Until able to walk, the child is carried by the mother, generally on the left thiRh. in which case it assumes a sort of riding posture; or upon the back, as soon as it is able to hold Itself on. The mother nur^e^ it for about two years. .\t about the tenth year puberty comes; the Negrito youth is then tattooed, and from the moment when this decoration of his body is finished he IS iiiuependent. He accordingly hjoks about him for a male, who has in tile majority of cases been selected for h 'ii beforehand and who. if possible, belonRS to the same " family." The members of a " family," which generally numbers twenty to thirty persons, are under the con- trol of an elective chieftain, who decides upon the camping-places and the time for breaking up. The family life is patriarchal in char- acter The father has imlimitid power over the members of his family; he can chasiisi them and even barter away his children; the woman occupies a subordinate position and is treated as a chattel. The Negritos carry on barterni',,' wiih the Tagalas; in this way they get supplies, chiefly of iron, in exchange for honey and wa.\. By means of the iron thus ac(|uircd they i>reparc part of their weapons, whi-'h consist of hunting-knives, .irrows. bows, and -pears The Negritos ,ire also very clever at throwing stones, in which they arc greatly a--i-ted by their keenness of vision. .\ ston.- in the hand of an otherwise unarmed Negrito is thus an otTensive and defensive wenpon not to be despised. Their clothing is very scant, hardly more th.iii a lireich-clou; l)omestn- utensils f.ir periiMiieiU use are scarcely fotiiid at ill ;niio!ii.' the I'.i.is; soiiu'iimes ,i clay vessel got by barter witlt the M,il:i>>. ,in<l as a rule .' piei e of bimboo from tliree lii fiiiir fmtns in |. iigtii lor li.il.luig drinkiu'.; w;i<er. Their toes ,,rr pnlien-ile. :i"d iir-- of me it a-sis|:iiice to tlii'iii in cliiii!>:;i^; 111 t!ie iralicr (.f imul tlir> .ire not i.isiidioii^ ; it is both amm;il ,ind M'.M'iab'e 111 chai.utrr — roots. Iiuiiey, lr..g,, il.er, wild bo.ar. etc. .A Sp.ini-li e;iie-.i:i-iir dcM-rilfes tin ni ,i^ follow,: "Tin pure .\itos or Negrito, l.acl a s,c!u(lr.| life; th.y li.ive ii.. fised dwelling-place and d.. not l.irM ti;'?- Tli,- i.hIkt. tli.' iiiotlnr. and the children ;ire all pr.fvided wi'h arrows, each lining Ins tiwti. .md tiny -et out together PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 9 These peoples liave been designated "lower nomads"; but it can scarcely be proven that actual hunting forms their chief means of sustenance. They all make use of vegetable food as far as it is at all obtainable, and with those who live in a warmer climate this food seems to pre- dominate. Stores of such fruits and roots they do not gather, though a region of plentiful supplies attracts a greater number of members of the tribe, as a rich feeding- ground draws together many lower animals; when it is exhausted they scatter again. And similarly as to the mollusks and insects which they consume; each individ- ual at once swallows what he finds; joint household life is as little known as is a house. It is only when a large animal has been killed or found dead (the fondness for meat in a state of decay is widespread) that the whole group assemlile,"^* and each devours is much as he can; upon the hunt. When they kill ,1 dicr or a hoar, they halt at the spot where the animal has fallen, scoop a hole in the ground, place the animal in it and then build a fire. I'ach one takes the piece of the animal that suits his taste hest and roasts it at the fire. And so they go on eating until they have tilled their bellies, and when thus satiated they sleep on the earth which they have hollowed out, as pigs do when they have gorged themselves. W'heTi they awake they go through the same operation, and so on until ;ill the meat is dev.mrod: then they set out upon the hunt at;ain." They observe no fixed times for sleeping and eatmg, but follow necessity in both cases. They age early; at forty or fifty the mountain Xe^ritos are decrepit, white-haireil. bent old iiifii. — Compare further the de^rriptii>n> of the I?otokiidos by l^hrenreich, Zl^chr f. I-.;hnol , \1\. pii 1 tT; of the Hororo^ by K \. d Steinen. (itUr d Wititnolh. Ci-ntiiil-Hrjsii , PP- .iSS <T. : of the Riishmen by I•'rit^ch, a^ abo\e, pp 4iStT ; of the Veddahs by V. and I" Sarasin. /'iV U'cdJils foil ( rvA'/l; of the .\us- trdians by Hreniaiio. Ztschr, f. Sozial- ti. Win^rliaftsneschichte, I, PP- i.(.l-4 '" I'rom the custom prevalent among some of the lower tribc^ of procliiiniii),; the tindin.ir of food by means of lnuci call-. Lippert, as abo\e, I. p J4(), coiiclu'lc- tli.it "the coti^iile'i'ion dne to the fami'y " is cxprPNScd m ibn n iv It! ibi.. inmn-.-lMti il is in ti,. i li>rrv I'd ili.at lo rRlMlTiyE ECCSOMIC CONDITIONS. but tlic method nf hunting these animals strongly resem- bles the proce»lure of the wild beast stealing upon its prey. With their imperfect weapons these peoples are hardly ever in a position to kill an animal instantly; the chief task of the hunter consists in pursuing the wounded game until it sinks down exhau.-.ted." Regarding the constitution of the family among peo- ples of this class, there has been much discussion. Of late the opinion seems to be gaining ground that there exists among them a fellowship between man and wife that ex- onds beyond a mere -exual relationship and is of life-long duration; while upon the other hand it cannot be denied that in case of a scarcity of food those loose groups easily split up. or at least individual members detach themselves from them. Only between mother and child is the rela- tionship particularly close. The mother must always take her little one along with her on the march; and for that purpose she usually fastens it in some way on her back, a custom that is very general among all primitive peoples, even where they have gone over to agriculture. For sev- eral years the child must be nurtured at the breast or from the mother's mouth, but it soon acquires skill in procuring its food independently, and often separates itself from the community in its eighth or tenth year. All the tribes involved in our survey belong to the smaller races of mankind, and in bodily condition give the many animals (for ixaniple, our domestic fowl) have the :ame cus- tom. True, he lays stress upon the fact that no one thinks of collect- ing' stores of provision*. 'Inercfore, we are, lurther. not justified in agreeinff to the proposal that has recently been made from several sides t" designate these peoples is gatherers of stores {Samnilcr). " Ciinip. li. Fritsch. DU- lliitgeboretun Stid-.lfrikas, pp. Jti4. 4^5; Pofivre, Im Krichf d. Muatn Jiinin'o. pp. .128-0; W'issniann. /m Innem .-Jfri'i,?. (!•>. ::'(). -,41; Martins, Zur Lthiwgral'Ue Aiicrikas, cufflal Brasilu'is. pp. <'('5 ff. PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC COSDITIOSS. 1 1 impression of backward:, stunted gro-.vth. We are not on that account, howe'.er, ju^f.ne'i :n re.i'ar iing them as ce- generate race fragrr.en-s. The evylence rather goes to sho'.v that the more a'i anccl races o.ve their higher physical development merely to the reg"u',ar and more plentiful supply of food -Ahich agriculture and cattle- raising for centuries ;'.'a-t have placed within their reach, while the peoples here in question have always remained at the same stage. Subject to all the vicissitudes of the weather and the fortune of the chase, thev revel at times in abundance and devour incredible mas-es of food: :tiil oftener. however, they sufrer bitter wan:, and their only article of clothing, the breech-clout, is for them, really the ■"hunger-strap" ' " Schmachtnemien "i A Germ.an story, which they tighten -d^^ in order to alleviate the pangs of gnawing hunger.' - How from this stage of primitive existence the pa.h leads upward is manifest in countless typical e.\ample5 furnished by ethnology. In addition to the collection of wild fruits and roots, the womian takes over the cultiva- tion o: food-plants. This she carries on at nrst witli the customary digging-stick, later with a short-handled hoe. The man continues hi; hunting ani' ti-hing. which, in rich hunting-grounds and ui'h more ['Crfect v. eap'^n-. he can make so pr luctive that \'rt/ f-.irni-h the greater ---art of his food. .\t times he supplements these by cattle-raiding. In the procuring of :oo<i each sex has it- sharply denned -phete of duties ti> vvhioh with advancing technical skill there are added in each ca«e •- .iriou^ industrial arts, which a- .'i rule retain their connecti'.n witii the "riginal produc- tion and occupation .Among advanced primitive peoples "-c- the Bu^hr-.er. ccT.p Fr.!^;h. at i'--.': ;. 405. -jn the .Xus- •ra'i-i-- Pesch*!, PiCff f M:n p \u: r. the Botokud^j. Ehrenreich 12 PRlM/r/yE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. all economic activity may be traced back to combinations of these elements; but in its details such labour is entirely dependent ui^on local natural conditions. We should therefore not be justified in any attempt to construct sta-es of development intended to hold equally good for negroes Papuans, Polynesians, and Indians. But wherever we can observe it, the method in which primitive peoples satisfy their wants reminds us continu- ally in many of its features of the instinctive doings of the lower animals. Everywhere their existence is still far from settled, and even the unsubstantial huts they erect are for the majority only temporary structures which, however much they vary from place to place and from tribe to tribe, always remain true to a type, and remind us of the nests of birds, which are deserted as soon as the brood is fledged. When Lippert finds the fundamental and controlling impulse to cultural development in material foresight, he undoubtedly makes an advance upon earlier investigators; but the phrase itself is not happily chosen. It is utterly impossible to speak of foresight, in the sense of providing for the future, in connection with primitive peoples. Primitive man does not think of the future; he does not think at all; he only wills, that is, he wills to preserve his existence. Tlie instinct of self-preservation and self-grati- fication is the prime agent of development, compared with which even the sexual instinct takes quite a secondary place. Wherever it has been possiI)Ie for Europeans to observe men in primitive conditions for any k-ngth of time they tell us of the incomparable dulncss and mental inertness which strike the neholder; of their indifference tr. the sub- limcst phenomena of nature, their complete lack of interest in evcr\thing that lies outside the individual self. The savage is willing to cat. sleep, and. wh .tc ncccssarv. to pro PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 13 tect himself against the greatest inclemencies of the weather: this is his whole aim in life. It is therefore entirely false and contrary to numer- ous well-accredited observations when Peschel straightway ascribes to savages a peculiar wealth of fanciful imag- inings of a religious nature, and thinks that the closer the approach to the condition of nature the greater the range of belief. He evidently assumes that the course of the sun and the other phenomena of the heavens must be infinitely more impressive and stimulative of active thought to the primitive than to the civilized man. But that is by no means the case. Both among the Indians of Brazil and among the negroes, when travellers have asked about these things, the response has been that people never thought about them; and Herbert Spencer '•' has collected an abundance of examples which show that the lover races do not manifest any interest even in the most novel phe- nomena. The Patagonians, for example, displayed utter indifference when they were made to look into a mirror; and Dampier reports that the .\ustralians whom he had taken on board of his ship paid attention to nothing but what they got to eat. Burton'* calls the East .\fricans " Men who can think, but who, absorbed in providing for their bodily wants, hate the trouble of thinking. His [the East African's] mind, limited to the object seen, heard, and felt, will not, and apparently can not, cscaj^e from the circle of sense, nor will it occupy itself with aught but the present. Thus he is cut off from the pleasures of memory, and the world of fancy is altogether unknown to him." "■' The same force, then, that impels the lower animal, the " Prmciplcs of Sociology, vol. I. 8§ 45-6. I* The Lake Regions of Central Africa ( New York, iWx)), p 480. "Oiinp. tlie siniil.ir opinion of the mission.iry Cr.in?. Ifistorie von Cronlatid (Frankfurt. 1780). p. i6.i, at.d Lubbock. Oriem -f Civili:atioH (4th ed.). pp. 51^ 7, .^i0 M PRIMITiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. instinct for preserving its existence, is also the dominant instinctive impulse of primitive man. This instinct is lim- ited in scope to the single individual; in respect of time, to the moment at which the want is felt. In other words: the savage thinks only of himself, and thinks only of the present. What lies beyond that is as gootl as closed to his mental \ ision. When, therefore, many observers reproach him with a boundless egoism, hardness of heart towards his fellows, greed, thievishness, inertness, carelessness with re- gard to the future, and forgetfulness. it means that sym- pathy, memory, and reasoning power are still entirely un- developed. Nevertheless it will be wise for us to make these ver}' characteristics our starting-point, in order to comprehend the relation of primitive man to the external world. In the first place, as concerns the egoism of the savage and his harducs. of heart towards his nearest relations, this is a natural consequence of the restless nomadic life in which each individual cares only for himself. It shows itself most prominently in the extraordinarily widespread custom of infanticide, which extremely few primitive peo- ples are entirely free from.'* The children impede 'he horde on the march and in the search for food. Therein lies the chief reason for their removal. Once become a custom, infanticide lives on in later stages of civilization; indisputable traces of it have been found not merely among the primitive peoples of Asia, Africa, America, Australia, and Polynesia, but even among the Arabs, the Romans, and the Greeks. To infanticide is universally ascribed the exceptionally slow increase of the uncivilized races. But this is also de- pendent upon their short lives, and long lactation pe- "' Comp. Lippert, II, pp. 201 flf. ; R.itzcl, lolkcrkunde, I, pp. 108, J54, 252, 277, 306, 338, 425. PRlMITiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 15 riods, during which, as is well known, conception rarely occurs, and this it is which forms the chief cause of their protracted tarrying at the same stage of civilization. That the natural bond between parents and children is nowhere very firm is seen also in the extremely common custom of adoption.'^ It is even said, for example, that in the " fam- ilies " of the Mincopies the children of other parents are in the majority. It is significant that between thtir own and their adopted chililren they make, as a rule, not the slight- est difference. Adoption may have arisen from the substi- tution of child-exposure for infanticide. If the natural mother was not in a position to take the new-born child along with her. perhaps another woman who was childless could, and thus the life of the child was saved. Recent ethnographers have been at great pains to prove that the strength of maternal love is a feature common to all stages of civilization. It is, indeed, a matter of regret to us that we find wanting in our own si>ecie5 a feeling that exhibits itself in such a pleasing way among many families of lower animals. Rut there have l>een too many observations s!''owing that among the lower races the mere care for one's own existence outweighs all other mental emotions, in fact that be>i'!e it nothing e'^e is of the least importance. .Ml observers are amazed and even in- dignant at the ir.ditlerence with which children, when (;nce they can shift for themselves, separate from their blo^jd- relations.''* Vet we have here onlv the reverse side of that " Comp. Luhhook, Origin of Ci7i!i:atirii, pp. o;-6, "Co;iip. the strikintj example -n R.itzel. l',4kerkuttde, I, p. 677. of a tiny of Tierr.i iJel Fucro who, when taken on board a European ship, did nut show the slighte'-t grief over the separation, while his paretits were delighted to get a few necklace* and some bi-cuits in return fijr him. The seHing "f children and women into slaver>- doe.s not occur in .Vfrica alone. Martius. as above, p uj Cump. Pjit, Afr. Juris- frudeti:, I, p. 94. i6 PRIMlTiyE FCONOMIC CONDITIONS. hardness of lieart which " enables husbands to refuse food to tlieir wives, and fathers, to deny it to their hungering children, wlien they tliemselves would but feast upon it." This same trait of unbounded selfishness is manifest in the regardlessness with which many primitive peoples leave behind them on the march, or exjKise in solitary places, the sick and the aged who might be an impediment to the vigorous.'" This trait has often been interpreted as a sign of superstition, as due to the fear of evil powers to whom the illnesses are ascribed. And in fact in the case of tribes that have become settled and whose means of sub- sistence would admit of the care of the sick, appearances favour such an explanation. But at the same time it is forgotten that customs, once firmly rooted, perpetuate themselves with great persistence, even when the causes that gave rise to them have long since passed away. I'rom exposure to intentional killing is only a short step. Indeed we find even among peoples on a higher plane of civilization that old age is deplored as a state of extreme joylessness. Barbarism had no affection between relatives to alleviate this condition, but it had it in its power to shorten it; and so. along with exposure, we find the bury- ing, or the killing, or even the devouring of the aged and sick, as numberless examples from Herodotus down to modern times attest. Indeed primitive man was able to look upon the solenm performance of this horrible act as a behest of piety.-" When we see how this unbroken nomadic life forced man to devote his whole activity to the securing of food, '"Lippert. as above, pp, J20ff., has treated the subject so exhaus- tively thai I may nfrain ironi citiriK examples. Cotnp. also Fritsch, PP- ll6, ,^.i4, ,?5i; Wait/, :i> al)uve, II, p. 401. ■■■"Comp the examples cited by Lippert, p. ijj, and Martins, as above, p. I2(). Also l-:hrenreich, lieitrdge s. V'olkcrkundi' Brasil, pp. (y-i-yo.- W'.-iit;'. .Ts :ibi!Vf, I. ;i i.«4) .'r-'r.;.; '.-. )■,.'.':!•/-.,' {\t-\----~ \. '■. 161. PRJMlTiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. n and forbade the concurrent development of those feelings which we regard as the most natural, and how it even .suc- ceeded in giving the appearance of religious duty to what we consider the most abominable crime, we begin to con- ceive how loose must have been the personal bond that held together those little roving groups of human beings. Sexual intercourse could not grow to be such a bond; for what we call love was entirely wanting in it.^' Domestic life, the conception of property and labour in common were as good as non-existent. These could originate only when the circle of wants advanced beyond .he mere food requirement. But this took a much longer time than the majority are wi:!ing to admit. The needs of primitive peo- ples with regard to clothing and house-she'ter are most markedly of an altogether >eci.'ndary na:i;re. Turning now to the no less common characteristic of improzidcnce. we must cenainly at fir^t glance be struck with astonishment. One wr.iiid think that hunger, which often brings such great torture to the savage. wuuM of itself have been sufficient to induce him to store up tur future use the food that at time- he ix)~-e-se- in super- abundance. But the observation- tliat ha.c lieen made all indicate that he never thinks of that. " They are not accustomed." says Heckewelder -- of the North American Indians. " to laying in -tire- of provision- exce[)t -unie Indian corn, dry beans, and a few other articles. Hence they are -nmetimes reduced to great -trai:-. and are not seldom in absolute want of the necessaries of life, e-peciallv ^ The many wnttr- whu write Ti'^Aadays about the family pay j wn-cn prr,:n;ncrice lias altogether too httie attention to th;« p'.int. t' juniy been jfiven by Lubboek. a? ab..',e. pp. ;.; tT. In the -ame way they overlooked the connection between the tarnily and ;i;e econ..my of the honti 'Comp p. lo above. — F'^r>,' "Heckewelder. Induui XaiLf.s. t;c, .\ew edition (Phi;. i88n. pp. io8. 212 (Memoirs rA Hi-r .Soc >_ ' Penn . vn] 121. i8 PRlMlTiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. in the time of war." And of the South American tribes another observer reports:^' " It is contrary to their na- ture to be in possession of food-suppHes for longer than one day at most." With many negro tribes it is looked upon as improper to store up food for future need, which belief, it is true, they base upon the superstition that the fragments left over may attract spirits.^* Where these peoples, through the short-sighted greed of gain of Europeans, are placed in possession of modern weapons, they usually work incredible havoc with the game in their hunting-grounds. The extermination of tiie boundless buffalo herds of North America is well known. *' The greatest quantities of meat were left lying unused in the thickets," only for the natives in winter-time, when deep snow prevented hunting, to fall a prey to awful hunger, in which even the bark of trees and the roots of grass were not despised. And to-day the natives of Africa, in districts where they carry on a profitable trade with Europeans, are ruthlessly destroying ihe sources of their incomes, the elephant and the caoutchouc-tree. Even among the more advanced tribes and individuals this characteristic tloes not fail. " When the carriers re- ceived fresh rations." relates P. Pogge.-*"' " I am certain that they lived l>etter for the first few days than I did. The best goats and fowl were devoured. If I gave them rations for a fortnight, the rule was to consume them in riotous living (luring the first three or four days, only afterwards either to steal from the supply-trains, to beg from me, or to go hungry." In Wadai everything that remains over from the snhan's tabic is burie<l,^^ and at the sacrificial " Appun, I'nter den Tropen, p. ,365. '' I.ippert. ns nhdvc, I, pp. .VJ-40. "As above, p. 14; conip. p. 6. Also Wissniann, Wolf. etc. Im Itrncrn Afrikas. p. 29. " Nachtiira!. Sahara u. Sudan. III. p. 2,?o. PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 19 feasts of the Indians the guests were obliged to eat up their meat and bread clean. " Overloading of the stomach and vomiting are not unusual on such occasions." -*• Closely connected with this waste of supplies is the use that primitive man makes of his time. It is entirely errone- ous, though customary, to imagine that primitive people are particularly expert in measuring time uy the position of the sun. They do not measure time at all. and accord- ingly do not make divisions in it. No primitive people observe fixed meal-times, according to which civilized man regulates his time for work.^* Even such- a relatively advanced tribe as the Bedouins has no conception of time. They eat when they are hungry. Livingstone in one place calls Africa " the blissful region where time is absolutely of no account and where men may sit down and rest them- selves when they are tired." •''« " Even the most trivial work, though it is urgently necessary, is postponed by the negro to as late a date as possible. The native dreams away the day in laziness and idleness, although he knows quite well that for the night he needs his draught of water and his log of wood; nevertheless until sundown he will certainly not disturb himself, and onlv then, or perhaps not before darkness, will he hnally procure himself the necessaries." 3' In these words we have touched upon the reproach of mertia to which primitive man is universally subject." ='Hcckewelder. as above, p. 213. [Dr. Biicher. quoting from the German translafon, has evidently mistaken the meaning of the pas- sage c.ted. The vomiting and fasting referred to by Heckewelder are profKiratory to the ceremonies, the vomiting being seh-induced.-ED ] ^Comp. VV. VVun.lt, /:^/„V.-. I (London. i8g;), pp. j;,., ^^ hxtedit. to the Zambesi (N'ew York, 1866), p. 104. "^\\. Junker's Travels in Africa; comp. Eng, trans., II, p 168 ^or details see my work Arbeit u. Rhytlmus (2d ed.. Leipzig ^Ri* 90 PRIMlTiyp. ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. What has here appeared to observers as laziness is again lack of forethought, Hving for the moment. Why should the savage exert himself when once his wants are satisfied, particularly when he is no longer hungr)? This does not imply that he is inactive. With his wretched facilities the individual often performs on the whole as much work as the individual civilized man; but he does no' perform it regularly, nor in ordered succession, but by i. and starts, when necessity forces him to it, or a feeling of exaltation takes possession of him, and even then not as a serious duty of life, but rather in a playful fashion. In general, primitive man follows only the prompting of the moment; his conduct is purely impulsive, mere reflex action, so to speak. The nearer his wants and their satis- faction lie together, the better he feels. Primitive man is a child; he thinks not of the future, nor of the past; he forgets easily, each new pression blots out its predeces- sor. All the sufferings of life, \*hich he has to experience so often, can scarcely cloud for a moment his naturally cheerful temperament. "Of the New Caleu i 'ans. Fijians, Tahitians, and New Zealanders we read that they are al- ways laughing and joking. Throughout Africa the negro has the same trait, and of other races, in other lands, the descriptions of various travellers are: 'full of fun and merri- ment,' full of life and spirits." ' merry and talkative,' ' sky- larking in all ways,' ' boisterous gaiety,' ' laughing immod- erately at trifles." "" ^^ It is significant, as has often been remarked, that natives of Africa lose their cheerfulness when they have been for some time in the service of Europeans, and become sullen and morose. The explanation of Fritsch ^* is that servants " Spencer, as above. § 34. Considerable material also in his Descrip- tive Sociology in the chapter on '" Moral Sentiments." ** As above, p. 56. PRIMITiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 31 of this kind gradually acquire from their masters the habit of troubling themselves about things to come, and that their temperament cannot endure engrossment in such cares 38 Such a hand-to-mouth existence cannot be burdened with conceptions of valw, which always presupposes an act of judgment, an estimation of the future. It is well known how in America and Africa the natives often sold their land to foreign colonists for a gaudy trifle, a few glass beads of no value according to our economic standards; and even to-day the negro, though he stands no longer at the lowest stage, is in many instances ready to give away any piece of his property, no matter how important it may be for his existence, if he is offered some glittering bauble that hap- pens to catch his eye.^" On the other hand his covetous- ness knows no bounds, and it is a constant complaint of travellers that amid all the hospitality shown them they are simply plundered, because ever>' village chieftain de- sires to be presented with everything he sees.'' Here, again, is that naive egoism in its complete regardlessness of self and others, that unbounded covetousness which has nothing in common with the love of gain of economic man. The impression of the moment is ever the sole con- trolling force: what is further removed is not thought of. Primitive man is incapable, it would seem, of entertaining " Reference may also be made to the not infrequent examples of savages who had been brought up under civilized conditions volun- tarily returning to their tribes and to the complete savagery of their people. Comp. Peschel. as above, pp. 152-3: Fritsch, as above, p. +2.3; K. E. Jung in Petermanns Mitth.. XXIV (1878), p. 67. "Comp. Fritsch. as above, pp. ,?05-C. "Says Burton, as above, p. 490: "In trading with [the African] ... all display of wealth must be avoided. A man who would pur- chase the smallest article avoids showing anything beyond its equiva- lent." 22 PRIMITII^E ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. two thoughts at the same time and of weighing the one against the other; he is always possessed by one alone and follows it with startling consistency. The collection of exi)eriences, the transmission of knowl- edge, is therefore exceedingly difficult, and therein lies the chief reason why such peoples can remain at the same stage for thousands of years without showing any appre- ciable advance. The acquisition of the first elements of civilization is often conceived as an easy matter; it is im- agined that every invention, every advance in house-con- struction, in the art of clothing, in the use of tools, that an individual makes, must pass over as an imperishable treas- ure into the conunon possession of the tribe and there continue to. fructify. Tlie invention of pottery, the taming of domestic animals, the smelting of iron ore have even been made the beginnings of entirely new epochs of civil- ization. Yet how imperfectly does such a conception appreciate the conditions under which primitive man lives! We may indeed assume tliat he possesses a peculiar fondness for the stone T\t uliicli with endless exertion he has formed in the course perhaps of a whole year, and that it seems to him like ri fK.rt of his own being;""* but it is a mistake to think that the preoinis jK)ssession will now pass to chiMreti nnd children's children, and thus constitute the basis for f'jrther advance. However certain it is that in connection with such thinL;s the iirst notions of "mine and thine" are develoi.ed, yet many are the observations itidicating that these conceptions do not go beyc»n<l the individual, and tliat they perisli with him. Tlw f't'sscssiDu f^usscs into the f^ravc Ti'/V// the f'osscssor, whose personal equipment it fonned in lii'e. That is a custom which is met with in all parts of the 'Comp. Arbeit u. Rhythmus (jj rd ), p. 'rt. PRlMITjyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 23 earth, and of which many peoples* have preserved traces even down into civ'lized times. ■'*'* In the first p;'.:c :: i^ piovaient among all American peo- ples to such at extent that t!.e survivors are often left in extreme need. ' 'ic a!>ori{j:;nes of California, who are among the lo«\.it ;>et-j,le o^ iH'.ir rafe, place along with the dead all the weapons and utensils \vhich he had made use of in life. " It is a curious paraphernalia," says an ob- server, "that follows the Wintum into the grave: knives, forks, vinegar-jars, empty whiskey-bottles, preserve-jars, bows, arrows, etc.; and if the dead has been an industrious housewife, a few baskets of acorns arc scattered over as well." " At the grave of the Tehuelche " (Patagonia), runs another account, " ail his horses, dogs, and other ani- mals are killed. ..id his poncho, his ornaments, his bolas and implements of every kind arc brought together into a heap and burned." And of a third and still lower tribe, the I'.ororo in Brazil, a recent very reliable observer says: ^'^ " -^ great loss befalls a fanuly when one of its menibe s dies. For everything that the dead man used is burned, thrown into the river, or packed in with the corpse in order that the departed spirit may have no occasion whatever to return. The cabin is dien completely gutted. I'.nt the surviving members of the family receive fresh i)rcsents; bows and arrows are made for them, and when a jaguar is killed, the skin is given to the brother of the last deceased woman or to the uncle of the last deceased man." Among the Ragobos in southern Mindanao (one of the "Comp. in general, .Andrcc, lithnogr. I\j,aiklcn u. I'crgkiche (Siutt- Kart, i8;«), pp. A)-:\ Scluirl/, Urundru: rtih-r linlstch. Gcsch. d. iicldcs (Weimar, i8<)S). pp. sfi IT ; i'aii.knw. Ztsclir. d. Gts. f. Erdkunde 7U Ucrlin. XXXI. jni. i-.'-< " K. vdii ilcn .'^tciiitti. i iiirr din Witunolkcni Knisilints ( .'d id.), r- .^>^). Ci'inp. .-ilio i:hrenrui!'.. /'.^.'njcf :ur i .HkcrLun.U' Hrjsilinif, \'V ,U), (•(,; lltckcwtldtr. a- above, pp. .711-1, .',-4-5. r 24 PRIMITIVE ECOS'OMIC CONDiTlONS. Philippines) the dead man is buried in iiis best clothes, and with a slave, who h killed for the purpose. " The cooking- utensiLs that the deceased used during his lifetime are filled with rice and placed, along with his betel-sacks, upon the grave; his other things are left in the house untouched. On penalty of death no one may henceforth enter either the house or the burial-place; and it is equally forbidden to cut from the trees surrounding the house. The house itself is allowed to go to ruin." ** In Australia and .\frica the custom is very common for all the stores of the deceased to be eaten up by the assem- bly of the mourners; in other parts the utensils are de- stroyed, while the food is thrown away. Many negro tribes bury the dead in the hut in which he lived, and leave the dwelling, now deserted by the survivors, to decay; others destroy the hut.^'- If a chieftain dies, the whole vil- lage migrates: and this is true even of the principal towns of the more inip<jrtant kingdoms, such as those of the Muata-Yamwo and the Kasembe. In the Lunda kingdom the old royal Kipanga is biirned down, and a new pro- visional one at once erected, for which the newly chosen ruler has to kindle a fresh fire by rubl)ing together pieces of wood, as it is not permissible to use the old fire any longer. The principal or residence town changes its loca- tion with each new ruler." .\mong the ancient Peruvians, *' SclLidenlxTt; in tlie Ztsclir. f. Rthnol., XVII (188.S). )>p 12-1.1. Tlie same thiriK is found in Ilalam.ihora, p. 8.i; and anmng tlie lull tribes of India. JellinKhaus in llic same review, III, pp. 372, 374. " Fxaniples may be found in M. Buchrver, Kainerun, p 28; Frilseh, as above, p. 5.^5; Bastian, I.oangokiiste, I. j) 1(14; I-iviiiKstoiu', as above, p. 158 From /\ustraiia: Parkinson, Im lUsmarck-Archif>el, pp. 102-.1: Ztscbr. f. I'"tlinol.. XXI, p, 23; Kiibary. filhiwgr. Hcitrdnc sur Kfntltnij d KiirJiii. Inseigruppc u. Nachbarschaft ( Reriiii, 1885). pp. 70-71, iiiiti,'. '* I'liUKe. ,■!■. above, jip. 2-'8, 2,54, LivinKstone in I'etermanns Mittli., XXT (187s), p 104. PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 25 .3 as well, the conception prevailed that with each new Inca the world, so to speak, began anew. The palaces of the dead Inca, with all tlieir stores of wealth, were closed for ever; the ruler for the time l)eing never made use of the treasures that his ancestors had amassed. Though we see from this that the origin and preserva- tion of the first elements of civilization among primitive peoples were attended with the greatest difficulties, and that the possibility of rising to better conditions of exist- ence and higher modes of life could not even be conceived by them, yet it must not be forgotten that the observations that have been sifted and presented here have been taken from peoples of very varied character and different cultural stages. To raise himself of his own strengtli to the plane of the Tongan or Tahitian. the Australian of the continent would probably have required many thousands of years; and a similar gulf separates the Bushman from the Congo nesrro and Wanvamweza. But this verv fact, it seem . .-^ me. speaks for the persistence of the presumptive psycn.v: conditions under which the satisfaction of the wants of un- civilized man is accomplished: and we are undoubf^dly justified in tracing back the whole circle of this cla.s of conceptions to a condition that must have prevailed among mankind ior a-oiis before tribes and peoples could have originated. From all that we know of it. this condition means ex- actly the opposite of " economy." For economy implies always a community of men rendered possil)le by the pos- session of property; it i^ a taking counsel, a caring not only for the moment but also for the future, a careful divi- sion and suitable bestowal of time; economy means work, valuation of things, regulation of their use. accumulation of wealth, transmission of the achievements of civilization from generation to generation. And even among the i I: s6 PRIMITiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. higher primitive peoples we have found all this widely wanting; among the lower races we have hardly met ■with its faint beginnings. Let us strike out of the life of the Bushman or of the Veddah the use of fire, and bow and arrow, and nothing remains but a life made up of the individual search for food. Each indi- vidual has to rely entirely upon himself for his sustenance. Naked and unarmed he roams with his fellows, like cer- tain species of wild animals, through a limited stretch of territory-, and uses his feet for holding and climbing as dexterously as he uses his hands.'*^ All, male and female, devour raw what they catch with their hands or dig out of the ground with their nails: smaller animals, roots, and fruits. Mow they unite in little bands or larger herds; now they separate again, according to the richness of the pasturage or hunting-ground. But these unions do not develop into communities, nor do they lighten the exist- ence of the individual. This picture may not have many charms for him who shares the civilization of the present; hut we are simply forced by the material empirically gathered together so to construct it. Nor are any of its lines imaginative. We have eliminated from the life of the lowest tribes only what admittedly belongs to civilization — the use of weapons and of fire. Though we were obliged to admit that even among the higher primitive peoples there is exceeding much that is non-economic, that at all events the con- scious application of the economic principle forms with them rather the exception than the rule, we .shall not be able in the case of the so-called " lower nomads " and their predecessors just sketched to make use of the notion of economy at all. With them we have to fix a pre-econoniic •* R. Andrte, Iter Fuss als Greiforgan, in his lithnugr. Parallclftt u. Vcrgl. (New Series), pp. 228 flf. PRIMlTiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 27 Stage of development, that is not yet economy. As every child must have his name, we will call this the stage of in- dividual search for food. How economic activity was evolved from the individual search for food can to-day hardly be imagined. The thought may suggest itself that the tUiTiing-point must be where production with a more distant end in view takes the place of the mere seizing of the gifts of nature for im- mediate enjoyment, and where work, as the intelligent application of physical power, replaces the instinctive activity of the bodily organs. Ver\- little would be gained, however, by this purely theoretical distinction. Labour among primitive peoples is something very ill-defined. The further we follow it back, the more closely it ap- proaches in form and substance to play. In all probability there are instincts similar to those that are found among the more intelligent of the lower animals, that impel man to extend his activities beyond the mere search for food, especially the instinct for imitating and for experimenting.^" The taming of domestic animals, for example, begins not with the useful animals, but with such species as man keeps merely for amusement or the worship of gods. Industrial activity seems cvc-ywhere to start with the painting of the body, tattooing, piercing or other- wise disfiguring sei)arate parts of the body, and grad- ually to advance to the production of ornaments, masks, drawing on bark, petrograms, and similar play-products. In these things there is everywhere displayed a peculiar tendency to imitate the animals whicli the savage iiu-ets with in his immediate surroundings, and which he looks upon as his equals. The partly prehistoric rock dmwings and carvings of the Bushmen, the Indians, and the Australians Ton-.p K. Groof., Die Spide d. Ticre (Jena. 1896"). 23 PRlMITiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. represent chiefly animals and men;*® pottery, wood-carv- ing, and even wicker-work begin with the production of animal fornis.^" Even when the advance is made to the construction of objects of daily use (pots, stools, etc.), the animal figure is retained with remarkable regularity;''* and lastly, in the dances of primitive peoples, the imita- tion of the motions and the cries of animals plays the prin- cipal part.''" All regularly sustained activity finally takes on a rhythmir form and becomes fused with music and song in an indivisible whole.^'^ It is accordingly in play that technical skill is developed, and it turns to the useful only very gradually.^* The or- der of progression hitherto accepted must therefore be just reversed; play is older than work, art older than pro- "Andree. Elhnogr. Parallelen u. I'ergleiche, pp. 258-299. Ehrenreich, as above, pp. 46-7. " Comp. the interesting accounts by K. v. d. Steinen, as above, pp. 2JI ff., and particularly pp. 241 ff. " Abundant examples are afforded by every ethnographic pictur«*- collection. The incredulous are invited to take a glance at the fol- lowing works: J. Boas, The Central Eskimo (Washington, 1888); Sixth Annual Report of the Bureau of Ethnology to the Secretary of the Smithsonian Institution, 1884-5; Ethnogr. Beschrijving fan de West- •! Xonrdkust ran Ncderlandsch Xiew Guinea, by F. S. A. de Clercq and J. D. E. ScIinieltT: (Leiden, iSg^l; Joest, Ethnogr. atis Guyana (Suppl. to vol. 5 of the Intern, .\rchiv fiir Ethnogr.); and again Von den Steinen, as above, pp. 26r ff. Conip. also 7ritsch, as above, p. 7,3; Schweinfurth. The Heart of .Urica (.vl ed., London. 1878). I, pp. 129- 130; and Grosi^o, Pie Anfange d. Kunst. Chaps. \'I and VII. " Grosse. as abovi-, pp. 2o8-(), " Reference must here agniti be niaiio to my work on Arbeit u. Rhythmus. '* " On exaniinatioti of the primitive tools [of ihe Papuans] . . . we see that there is not a single one which does not hear testimony by S(inu' little design or ornament to the good taste of its maker, not an article which does not show some trifling accessories surpassing mere utility and present in it solely for beauty's sake." — Semon, In the Austral. Bush. p. 400. PRlMlTll^E ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 29 I duction for use.'^'' Even when among the higher primi- tive peoples the two elements begin to separate from each other, the dance still precedes or follows every more im- portant work (war-, hunting-, harvest-dance), and song ic- companies work. Just as economy, the further we have traced it back- wards in the development of peoples, has during our in- quiry assumed more and more the form of non-economy, so work also has finally resolved itself into its opposite (Nicht- arbeit). And we should probably have the same experi- ence with all the more important phenomena of economy, if we were to continue our inquiries regarding <^hem. One thing alone appears permanent — consumption. Wants man always had, and wants must be satisfied. But even our wants, considered from an economic point of view, exist only in very small part naturally; it is only in the matter of bodily nourishment that our consumption is a necessity of nature; all else is the product of civilization, the result of the free creative activity of the human mind. Without this activity man would always have remained a root-digging, fiuit-eating animal. Under these circumstances we must forego the attempt to fix upon some definite point at which simple search for food ceases and economy begins, in the history of human civilization there are no turning-points; here everything grows and decays as with the plant; the fixed or station- ary is only an abstraction which we need in order to make visible to our dim eye the wonders of nature and humanity. Indeed economy itself, like all else, is subject to constant changes. When it first presents itself in history, it appears as a form of communal life based upon material posses- m " [The general ctlmograpliic aspect nf art is. of course, another and wider problem than the one involved in this conclusion with regard ;0 "first things. " — Ed.] ! * 30 PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. sions. guided by definite rules of conduct, and closely con- nected with the personal and moral community of life of the family.'*^ It was under this form that it was seen by the people who first fixed its characteristics in language. Landlord is still in Middle High German synonymous with husband (Wirt, Ehemann), landlady is wife (Wirtin, Ehefrau), and the word economy, derived from the Greek, is formed in a similar way. We may therefore assume the existence of economy as certain where we find co-dwelling communities that pro- cure and utilize things adapted to their needs according to the dictates of the economic principle. Such a condition is certainly fulfilled by the higher primitive peoples, even though their carrying out of the economic principle always remains incomplete. But there is nevertheless much that still recalls the pre-economic period of individual search for food; economy has still, so to speak, gaps in- various places. Among all peoples of a lower cultural stage the dis- tribution of labour between the two sexes is firmly fixed bv custom, although difiference of natural aptitude seems by no means to have been the sole determining factor. At least it cannot be maintained that in all cases the lighter share of the work fell to the weaker sex. While in the normal domestic economy of civilized nations we have a cross-section, so to speak, which assigns to the man the productive work and to the woman the superintendence of consumption, the economy of these peoples seems to be divided in longitudinal section. Both sexes take part in " K. Grosse has in his recent book entitled Die Formal d. Familie u. die Fflrmen d. Wirtschafi (Leipzig, i8g6) investigated the connection of family with economic forms. In doing so he has, for the economic side of the \vori<. adhered to the altogetlicr external classification into nomadic, pastor.il, and agricultural, but has scarcely devoted due at- tention to the inner cc^nnnii:- life, particularly to that "f the household. PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 31 production, and frequently each has a particular depart- ment of the consumption for itself. It is particularly signif- icant in this connection that upon the woman de solves, as a rule, the jirocuring and preparing of the vegetable foods and for the most part also the building of the hut, while hunting and the working up of the products of the chase fall to the man. If cattle are kept, the tending of the ani- mals, the erection of inclosures for them, the milking, etc., are the business of the men. This division is often so sharply defined that we might almost speak of a cleavage of the family economy into a purely male and a purely female economy. In an interesting account of the useful plants of the Brazilian Shingu tribes, K. von den Stcincn ''* describes the outcome of the earlier development of these tribes in the following words: "Man followed the chase, and in the mean time woman invented agriculture. Here, as throughout Brazil, the women have exclusive charge not otily of the preparation of manioc in the house but also of its cultivation. Thty clear the ground of weeds with pointed sticks, place in position the stakes with which the manioc is planted, and fetch each day what they need, carrying it home in heavily laden wicker baskets. . . . The man is more courageous and skilful; to him belong the chase and the use of weapons. Where, then, hunt- ing and fishing ^. play an important part, the woman must attend, as far as a division of labour takes place at all, to the procuring, trans- porting, and preparing of the food. This division has a result that is not sufticiently appreciated, namely, that the woman in her field of labour ac(iuires special knowledge just as the man does in his. This must necessarily hold true for each lower or higher stage. The counterpart of the Indian woman cultivating her manioc with skill and intelligence is already found in the purely nomadic state. The wife of the Bororo vent into the forest armed with a pointed stick to search for roots and tubers: during wanderings through the camp- ing-ground, or whenever a cot.ipany of Indians changed its locality, sucli hunting fell to the wor .n, while the man tracked the game: she clinib''d the tree for cocoanuis. and carried heavy loads of them '^Unier d. Naturi'olk. Central-Brasil., pp. 206 ff. h i 32 PRIMlTiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. laboriously home. And though the Indian woman was the slave of her husband, this relation was certainly not to her advantage in re- gard to the division of the fish and meat; she still had to depend upon the supply of vegetables that she could gather for herself. On the Shingu the men made ready the roast and broiled fish and meat; the women baked the beijus (manioc cakes), prepared the warm drinks, cooked the fruits, and roasted tht cocoanuts. What other meaning could this division into animal cooking for the men and vegetable cooking for the women have than that each of the sexes had still kept to its original sphere?" If we add that the men also made the weapons for the chase, and that hunting and fishing were the source whence they drew all their iinplements for cutting, scraping, polish- ing, piercing, tracing, and carving, while the women pro- duced the pottery for cooking,-'*'' we have for each sex a naturally defined sphere of production upon which all their activity is independently expended. But this is not all. The consumption h also in one chief particular distinct: there are no common meals in the family. Each individual eats apart from the rest, and it is looked upon as improper to partake of food in the presence of others.*** Similar characteristics of an individual economy are also found among the North American Indians, who had al- ready arrived at a fully developed domestic economy. While they know nothing whatever of a special ownership " As above, pp. I97 ff-. 217 ff- 3i8. "Von den Steinen, as above, p. 69, and Ehrcnreich, Bcitriige s. V'61- kerkunde Brasil., p. 17: "Etiquette among the Karaya demands that each one shall eat by himself apart from the others." l.ating alone is almost suggestive of the animal. The savage acts like the dog, which grows cross when his meal is disturbed. Among the natives of Borneo " the men usually feed alone, attended on by the women, and always wash their mouths out when they have finished eating. They are very particular about being called away from their meals, and it takes . great deal to make a man set about doing anything before he has concluded his repast: to such an extent is this practice observed, that it is considered wrong to attack even an enemy whilst he is eat- ing, but the moment he has finished it is legitimate and proper to fall upon him." Hose, in Juurii. oi Amhiop^l. Inst., p. i6o. PRlMITiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 33 of the soil, " there is nothing in an Indian's house or family without its particular owner. Every individual knows what belongs to him, from the horse or cow down to the dog, cat, kitten, and little chicken. Parents make presents to their children, and they in return to their parents. A fatl r will sometimes ask his wife or one of his children for the loan of a horse to go a-hunting. For a litter of kittens or brood of chickens there are often as many dif- ferent owners as there are individual animals. In purchas- ing a hen with her brood one frequently has to deal for it with several children." ^^ " In cases where the Indians permitted polygamy, it was customar)' for a special hut to be erected for each wife; among tribes dwelling in common-houses each wife had at least her special fire."*® '' The same characteristics are presented by the economy of the Polynesians and Micronesians, except that here fish- ing and the raising of smaller live stock take the place of hunting. In New Pomerania the various duties are strictly divided between the men and boys on the one hand, and the women and girls on the other.^^ To the male portion of the population falls the labour of making and keep- ing in repair the weapons and the fishing-gear, especially the fishing-nets and the ropes necessary for them, of cast- ing the nets in the sea and caring for them daily, of build- ing canoes, erecting huts, and. in the wooded districts, of felling trees and clearing away the roots for the laying out of new plantations, as well as of protecting them by en- closures against wild boars." *" " Heckewelder, as above, p. 158. "VVaitz, Anthropologic, III, p. 109. "Parkinson, as above, pp. 113, 122. "These labours preparatory to the cultivation of the land are still often performed by the women. Parkinson, p. 118. 34 PRlMmVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. \ I Besides haviriig to care for their little children it de- volves upon the women to prepare the food, to dig and cultivate the ground, to raise and garner the produce of the field, and to carry the heavily laden baskets to market- places miles away. " In certain kinds of work both men and women take part. To these belong the twisting of the strong basten cordage of which the fishing-nets are woven, the plaiting of baskets with finely cut strips of rattan and padanus- leaves, the weaving of a very rough and coarse stuff called mal, made from the bark of the broussonetia-tree, in which the women wrap their infants to protect them from the cold." This latter is very significant: we have here to do with arrangements for the transformation of materials, such as could not have existed in the period of individual search for food. Separate preparation of food for men and women, and separate meals are also met with in the South Sea regions. In Fiji the men prepare such kinds of food as can be cooked out of doors by means of heated stones. " This is confined to-day to the roasting of swine's flesh; formerly the preparation of human flesh was also reserved for the men." ^- In the Palau Islands the cooking of the taro and the preparing of the sweetened foods fell to the lot of the women, the preparation of the meats to the men.*'^ In most parts of Oceania " it is neither permissible for women and men to eat in common, nor for the men to eat what the women have prepared. Eating with another from the same dish seems to be avoided with almost equal scrupu- lousness." "■* *• Biissler, Siidsce-Bildcr, pp. 226-7. " Kubary, as above, p. 17J. " Ratzel, V'olkerkundc, I. p. 240. "Separate; meals for men and women; Conip. Stanley, Ho-i; t ioitnd PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 35 The economy of many negro tribes shows a Hke arrange- ment ; a sharp division of the production and of many parts of the consumption according to sex, indeed even the ex- it nsion of this distinction to the sphere of barter. As P. Pogge,®' one of our most reliable observers, says concisely of the Congo negroes: " The woman has her own circle of duties independent of that of her husband." And in the description of the Bashilangas he observes:^" '" No mem- ber of the family troubles himself about another at meal- times: while some eat the others come and go just as it suits them; but the women and the smaller children gen- erally eat together." And finally he reports further re- garding the Lundas: " Under ordinary conditions, when a caravan has pitched its camp in a village, the wome:' of the place are accustomed to bring vegetables and fowl into the camp for sale, while goats, pigs, and sheep are usually sold only by the men."' It is similarly related by L. Wolf* that in the market at Tbaushi all the agricultural products .■;Tid 1 laterials. mats, and pottery are sold by the women, and only iL^oats and wine by the men. F.ach sex is thus possessor of its special proiluct of labour, and disposes of i: indejKjndentlN. ''■'•* The di\ ision of the labour of production between the two ^exe> in Africa varies in detail from tribe to tribe; as a rule, [f7Tt::fa>u (N w York, 1887). p. 550; Naclitigal, Sahara u. Sudan, I, " tm i's-iche :. Mnata Jamuo. p. 40. ' ^\»>«r:ar ' ntcr dcutsch. Flaggc qui-r durch Afrika, \t. ,^87. Im- Isnemt ^ Ifmua amzcu. pp. I"8, 2t,i. '' tm Hsjcnc J Muatd Jamu'O. p. 29. ""AST— sjair; etc.. Im Inticrn Afrikas. p. J4Q Conip. Livingstone, l.vrrn^ - -*f . jmhesi. pp. 122, 577; Paulitschkf, Ethnographie Nordost- **■ »•' — r family md the domestic establishment of the Wanyamwezis, w+r ji-sureti y ni longer stand upon a low plane, Burton gives the ■olkfmras picture: "Children are suckled till the end of the second Arter the fourth summer the boy begins to learn archery. ; j I' 36 PRIMlTjyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. however, agriculture ami the preparation of all the vegeta- ble foods are also assigned here to the woman, and hunting, cattle-raising, tanning, and weaving to the man.'^" This arrangement is often supporteil by superstitious usages. In Uganda the milking of the cows falls exclusively to the men; a woman is never permitted to touch the udder of a cow.'' In the Lunda territory, again, no man is allowed to take part in the extraction of oil from the ground-nut, as his presence is thought to frustrate the success of the operation."- As a rule the carriers whom Europeans en- ... As poon .IS [lu-l can walk he tends the flocks; after the age of ten he drives the cattle to pasture, and. considering himself independ- ent of his father, he plants a tobacco-plot and aspires to build a hut for himself. Unmarried (jirls live in the f.ithcr's house until puberty; after that period the spinsters of the village, who usually number from seven to a do/en. assemble toKether and build for themselves at a distance from their homes a hut where they can receive their friends withriut parental interference. . . . Marriage takes place when the youth can afford to pay the price for a wife. [The price] varies, ac- cording t'> circumstances, from one to ten cows. The wife is so far the property of the husband that he can claim damages from the adul- terer, but may not sell her except when in dilticulties. . . . Polygamy is the rule with the wealthy. There is little community of interest?, and apparently a lack of family affection in these tribes. The hus- band, when returning from the coast laden with cloth, will refuse a single sluikkah to his wife; .md the wife, sticceeding to an inheritance, will abandon her husband to starvation. The man takes charge of the cattle, goats, sluep. atul poultrj : the woman has power over the grain and the \egetatple'-; and each must grow tob.icco, liaving little hope of borrowing from the other. . . . The sexes do not eat to- gether: e\eii the boys would disdain to be seen sitting at meat with their motliirv The men feed either in their cottages or. more gen- erally, in the iw.m/a fpublic house, one being set apart for each sex]." (As above, pp. -•'»5>^: ii>mp pp, 41M-4 > '"Comp, e-pecially hVitseh. as above, pp. ;'» '^f ■ 'K?. •2-'0- ,U'.S; Living- ston*, as above, pp. 77, iif. .Iii-i-'. .\n cMended treatment now in H. Schurt/. Dat nfr. Ccwnh' (l.eip/ig, Kirxil. pp. 7 tT. " I'.min lUy. in IVienii.iniis Mitth, X N \' (1X70), p. .V)2. " Wi-SMiiann, V.O i, etc., hn Iniurii Afrikas. p. (>.\. PRIMlTiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 37 gage refuse to do women's work; Livingstone" even reports a case of famine among the men in a certain dis- trict because no women were there to grind the corn they had on hand. The separation of the two sexes in the prep- aration and consumption of food is often made still more rigid by regulations ''* of a semi-religious character, for- bidding the women the use of certain kinds of meat, which are thus reserved for the men alone. ''■''' Everywhere among primitive peoples the children become independent very early in youth and desert the society of their parents. They often live then for some years in special common-houses, of which there are others for married men. These common-hou.ses for the men-folk grouped ac- cording to age. and frequently also for the unmarried women grouped in the same way, are found very wiilely distributed in Africa and America, and especially in Oceania. They serve as common places of meeting, work, and amusement, and as sleeping-places for the younger people, and are used also for lodging strangers. They naturally form a further obstacle to the development of a common household economy based upon the family, for each family is generally subdivided into different parts "As above, pp. !88. 565. .Siniil.-irly amotiK the Tiuli.ins; comp. Wait/, as ahovp. III, p. 100. "More frequent still in Tolynesia. Comp. Andnc. nthiogr. Parol- Uk» u. I'crglciche. \^\^. ii4ff. "For a peculiar further development of this economy comp. Schweinfurth, Sahara u. Sudan. III. pp. i6j, .'44, 2^^). In some places the separation of the spheres of activity f)f the two sexes extends cv 1 to their intellectual life. AmonK' several Cariljic tribes the women and tlie men h;;'- ditTcrent names fur many things, wlience it was inferred that there existid distinct hmnuaKes for men and for women. More recently this phenomenon is suppoM'd to have its foundation in the didercnce in social portion of the sexes and in the sharp division between their two spheres of tniph'vmcnt Comp. Sapper, Intirn. f. Htl tinoKr. PI' si> !. 38 PRlMlTiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. vv-ith separate dwellings. In Yap. one of the Caroline Islands, for instance, we find besides the fcbays, or sleep- ing-houses of the unmarried, a principal house for each family which the father of the family uses, and also a dwell- ing-house for each wife; finally, " the preparation of food in the dwelling-house is forbidden and is transferred to a separate hut for each member of the family, which serves as a fire-cabin or cooking-house." ^« A similar arrangement prevails in Malekula in the New Hebrides." Further than this, economic individualism can hardly be carried. It may be asserted as a general rule for primitive peo- ples practising polvgamy that each wife has her own hut." Among the Zulus thev go so far as to build a separate hut for almost ever)- adult member of the household,— one for the husband, one for his mother, one for each of his wives and other adult members of his family. These huts all stand in a semicircle about the enclosed cattle- kraal in such a way that the man's dwelling is m the centre. Of course it is to be remembered that a hut of this kmd can be constructed in a few hours. Thus we see that everywhere, even among the more developed primitive peoples, there is still wanting much of that unified exclusiveness of domestic life with which the civilized peoples of Europe, from all we know of them, first appeared in history. Everywhere wide clefts still gape, and the individual preserver an economic independ- ence that strikes us with its strangeness. However much '• Kubary E.'hnogr. Btitriige z. Kennt. d. Karnl.-Archif. (Leiden), p. 39- "Journal o( the Anthropol. Inst, of Gr. Br.. X.XIII (i8«m). P- J8t- "This is tlic ca.se. to mention only a few instancts, in the Antilles: St.ircko' Tht Primilive Family (New York. 1SH9). p. 40: in Min- danao; Sch.-,dcnbcrK, Ztschr. f. Ethnol.. XVII. p. u; among the Bakuba: Wissmann, Im Innern Afrikas, p. J0.>: among the Monbuttoos: .Schweinfiirth, Ztschr. f. Ethnol.. V. p. 12; Tht Heart of Africa. II. pp. 17-18: Ca»a!i». La BMiuiot, p. ii2. PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 39 it behooves us, in our consideration of this minute eco- nomic separation, to guard against overlooking the unify- ing forces of working and caring for each other, and carefully as we must refrain from exaggerating the cen- trifugal forces here at work, it Is nevertheless not to be denied that they are all traceable to one common origin — to titc individual search for food practised through thousands of years by all these pcof^lcs. In this lies the justification of the method followed in this investigation, in which we have taken together peo- ples of very different stock and cultural stages, and con- sidered the economic phenomena separately. This procedure is, in political economy as in all social sciences, entirely justified; provided that, from the prodig- ious mass of disconnected facts that fill ethnolog}- like a great lumber-room, we succeed in bringing a considerable number under a common denominator and rescuing them from the mystic interpretations of curiosity-hunters and r.'.ythologizing visionaries. For political economy in par- ticular this method offers the further and not inconsider- able advantage, that the toy mannikin in the form of a savage freely invented by the imagination of civilized man vanishes from the scene, and gives place to forms that are taken from life, although the observations from which they are drawn mav leave much to be desired in point of ac- curacy. Our travellers have hitherto devoted little special atten- tion to the economy oi primitive peoples. In the midst of their attention to dress, forms of worship, morals, religious beliefs, marriage customs, art. and technical skill, they have often overlooked what lay closest at hand, and in the gossipy records of ethnographic compilations the word " economy " has no mf>re fotmd a place than has the word " household " in the chronicles of the numerous investi- 40 PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. f >: » .' gators into the constitution of the family. But just be- cause the observations we have utiHzed have been made for the most part only incidentally and not by trained economists, they possess a high measure of credibility. For they have on that account generally escaped the fate of being forced into some scheme categorically arranged in accordance with the conditions of our own civilization, and for that verj' reason unable to do justice to the differ- ently conditioned life of primitive peoples. m^ CHAPTER II. THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. The designation natural people seems a particularly- apt characterization of the lower races of men on their eco- nomic side. They stand in more immediate touch with nature than do we; they are more dependent upon her, are more directly susceptible to her powers, and succumb to tiiem more easily. Civilized man lays by stores for the future; for the preservation and embellishment of his ex- istence he possesses a wealth of implements; in the event of failure of his crops the harvests of half a world stand at his disposal through our highly perfected means of trans- portation; he subdues the powers of nature and impresses them into his service. Our commerce places the labour of a thousand men at the command of every individual amongst us, and in every household watchful eyes guard the careful and economical consumption of the goods destined for our bodily subsistence. Primitive man, as a rule, gath- ers no stores; a bad harvest or other failure of the natural sources of his sustenance strikes him with its full weight; he knows no labour-saving implements, no system in dis- posing of his time, no ordered consumption; limited to his meagre natural powers, threatened on all sides by hos- tile forces, each day he has to struggle anew for his exist- ence, and often knows not whether the morrow will vouch- safe him the means to still his hunger. Vet he does not regard the future with anxiety, he is a child of the moment; no cares torment him; his mind is fillcl with a boundless naive egoism. With thoughts extending 'o further, he 41 u I! Hi (I l 42 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITiyE PEOPLE. instinctively follows his impulses, and in this regard also stands closer to nature than ourselves.^ The former ♦■ 'le was to classify primitive peoples accord- ing to the manner in which they procured their sustenance into hunters, fishers, pastorals, and agriculturalists. In this it was believed that each people must traverse these four stages of economic development in its progress towards civilization. The starting-point was the tacit as- sumption that primitive man began with animal food and only gradually passed over, under the stress of necessity, to a vegetable diet. The procuring of vegetable food moreover was considered the more difficult inasmuch as the picture of our European system of agriculture was ever in mind with its draught-animals and artificial apparatus of implements and tools. But this conception is erroneous, just as is the assump- tion from which it proceeds. Certainly all economic activ- ity begins with the procuring of food, which is wholly de- pendent upon the local distribution of the gifts of nature. From the beginning man was primarily dependent upon vegetable nourishment, and wherever tree-fruits, berries, and roots were to be gained, he first made use of these. In case of need he turned to petty animals which could be consumed raw: shell-fish, worms, beetles, grasshoppers, ants, etc. Like the lower animal in continuous quest of food, he devoured at the moment what he found without providing for the future. If from this stage we seek the transition to the next, a little reflection tells us that it could not have been difficult ' Comp, in general R. Vierkandt, Nalurvolker u. KuUunvlker (Leip- zig. \M>). pp 2(0 ff. On the conception of natural peoples see further Panckow. Ztschr. d. Gcs. f. Erdkunde zu Berlin, XXXI (i8<)6>. pp. 158, ISO. Anyone inclined to find fault with the indefinitencss of the definition should not overlook the fact that no single case has pre- sented itscii fair-itiK tlie point whether a certain people was to be re- garded as primitive or not. THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIi^F PEOPLE. 43 to gain the practical knowledge that a buried bulb or nut furnishes a new plant, — certainly not more difficult than taming animals or inventing fish-hooks and bow and ar- row, which transition to the hunting stage required.- As regards technical skill many hunting and nomadic peoples stand far above so-called agricultural peoples. Of late men have come to believe that nomads should rather be considered savage agriculturalists; and as a matter of fact it is highly improbable that a tribe of hunters should first have hit upon the taming of animals before they could pro- cure milk, eggs, and meat. Moreover, except in the ex- treme north, there is probably no fishing, hunting, or pas- toral people that does not draw a more or less consider- able portion of its sustenance from the vegetable kingdom. For this supply many of them have long been dependent upon trade with more highly developed neighboring peo- ples. They thus lack that economic independence which our study requires if it is to arrive at conclusions univer- sally applicable. Now since the instances of hunting, fishing, and no- madic tribes, which are accepted as typical, are only to be found under special geographical and climatic conditions that hardly permit of a different manner of obtaining sustenance (hunters and fishers in the farthest north, nomads in the steppes and desert places of the Old World), it may be advisable in our further consideration to leave them wholly aside and limit the field of our investigation to the intertropical districts of America, Africa, Australia, the Malay Archipelago, Melanesia, and Polynesia. This is still an enormous circuit, within which the diversity of natural conditions surrounding primitive man pro- • Comp. in general E. Hahn, Die Hausthiere u. ihrc Besiehungen s. Wirthschaft d. Menschen (Leipzig, 1896); P. R. Bos, Jagd, Vicksucht u. Ackerbau ah Kulturstufen in Intern. Archiv f. Ethnographic, X (1897), pp. iHTfi. ill i s . j . i.. 3- a. 44 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. ru duces many j>eculiarities in his material existence. The differences between the individual tribes in this regard are, however, not so great as, for instance, between the Esqui- maux and the Polynesian. At any rate, notwithstanding the great differences of the races in conditions of life and •ways of living, they have still sufficient in common to oc- cupy our attention. In addition to this we have here the oldest ree:ions inhabited by man, which, however, in spite, or periiaps on account, of the bounties of tropical nature, also appear to be those in which their development has been most slow. At all stages of his development the primitive man of these regions manifestly finds in vegetable diet the l)asis of his sustenance. This is evident from the simple fact that he has always found animal food much more dif- ficult to obtain. This is not contradicted by the circum- stance that at times we notice an eagerness for flesh break forth among many savage races which appalls us, since it does not shrink even from its own kind. The explanation in all probability is that the definite quantity of salt requi- site for the normal maintenance of the human body can- not be conveyed to it through purely vegetable diet, while it is quite possible with occasional raw-flesh food to live without salt. The same desire for salt is manifested even by the purely herbivorous among our domestic animals. The need of nourishment [we have seen] is the most urgent, and originally the sole, force impelling man to activ- ity, and causing him to wander about incessantly until it is satisfied. The species of Jirision of labour between the two sexes, which this primitive search for food gives rise to, reaches its highest form when the wife procures the vegetable, the man the animal, portion of the food. And since, as a rule, the food gained is immediately devoured, and no one takes thought for the other as long as he him- THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 45 self is hungry, a difference in the nourishment of the two sexes arises that has perhaps contributed in an important degree to the differentiation of their bodily development. The division of labour of these primitive roaming hordes is continued at higher stages of development, and receives there such sharp expression that the rigidly limited spheres of activity of the man and the woman form almost a spe- cies of secondary sex-characteristics whose understanding gives us the key to the economic life of primitive peoples. In particular almost all their production of goods is dom- inated by it. Turning now to the latter, we should note by way of preface that by far the greater part of our primitive peo- ples, when they came under the view of Europeans, were acquainted with, and practised, agriculture. This is true, for instance, of all the negro races of Africa with but few exceptions, of the Malays, the Polynesians, and Mela- nesians, and of the primitive races of America, save those living at the extreme north and south of that hemisphere. It is a widely prevalent error, for which our youthful read- ing is responsible, that makes pure hunting races out of the North American Indians. All the tribes east of the Mississippi and south of the St. Lawrence were familiar with the cultivation of food-plants before the coming of Europeans; and, in the regions lying beyond, they at least gathered the grain of the water-rice (cicania aquatica) and ground meal from the berries of the manzanita shrub.'' The agriculture of primitive peoples is, however, pecu- liar.'* In the first p'ace it knows nothing of an implement that we think indispensable, namely, the plough. Wheel and wagon and draught-animals are likewise unknown. Furthermore, cattle-raising forms no integral part of their ' Waitz, .Utthrofvlogu' d. Xatunvlkcr. III. *Conip. E. Hahn. as above, pp. j88 ft. pp. 1 46 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRlMlTiyE PEOPLE. ll il - I I? I i ' I : t I agriculture. Fertilizing of the soil occurs at times, but it is extremely rare. More frequent are irrigation arrange- ments, especially for rice and taro plantations. As a rule, however, the cultivated land must be changed when its nutritive elements are exhausted; and the change is facili- tated by the absence of individual property in the soil, which belongs to the tribe or the village community as a vvhole. Lastly, [we may recall,] the preparing of the soil is almost exclusively woman's work. Only in the first clearing of a piece of lar.d do the men assist. Of late years this system of culture has been designated the hack or hoc system, a short-handled hoe being its chief implement. With .some tribes the primitive digging-stick still retains its place. At the basis of its plant production lie the tropical tuberous growths: manioc, yam, taro, sweet potato, pignut, and in addition bananas, various species of gourds (cucurbitacccc) , beans, and of the grains, rice, durra, and maize. Rice has its oldest home in South China probably, the durra in Africa, and maize, as is well known, in America. There belong, finally, to this system of agri- culture the tropical fruit-trees— sago , date-, and cocoa- palms, the breadfruit-tree, and the like. On account cf the imperfect nature and limited pro- ductivity of the implements, only small stretches of land can ever be taken into cultivation under the hack system. It is closely related externally, and also in the manner in which it is carried on. to our garden culture. The fields are generally divided into beds, which are often hilled in an exemplary fashion and kept perfectly free of weeds. The whole is surrounded with a hedge to keep out wild animals; against the grain-eating birds, which are particu- larly dangerous to the har\'ests of the tropics, the Malays set up ver\' ingeniously constructed scarecrows; in most places in Africa special waich-towcrs arc erected in the 'Si THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRJMITiyE PEOPLE. 47 fields from which the young girls make noises to frighten away the animals. As a rule a definite crop rotation is ob- served. In the Congo basin, for instance, when the land is newly broken up it is first planted with beans, and when these are harvested, millet is sown; interspersed with the latter the sprouts of the manioc are often set out. The manioc does not yield full returns for from one and a half to two years, and occupies the land until the roots com- mence to become ligneous, and virgin soil must be taken tip. In New Pomerania the rotation is yam roots first, then taro. and finally bananas, sugar-cane, and the like.® Travellers have often described the deep impression made upon them when, on coming out of the dreary primeval forest, they happened suddenly upon the well- tended fields of the natives. In the more thickly popu- latea parts of Africa these fields often stretch for many a mile, and the assiduous care of tlie negro women shines in all the brighter light when we consider the insecurity of life, the constant feuds and pillagings, in which no one knows whether he will in the end be able to harvest what he has sown. Livingstone gives somewhere a graphic description of the devastations wrought by the slave-hunts; the people were lying about slain, the dwellings were de- molished; in the fields, however, the grain was ripening, and there v.as none to harvest it. But as yet the life of these people is by no means firmly attached to the soil; seldom do their settlements remain for several generations on the same spot;^ their houses are fugitive structures of 'Descriptions of hack agriculture in Angola, Congo district: Pogge. pp. 8. 9; Wissmann, Unter deutsch. Flagge, pp. 34i ff-: among the Mon- buttos: Schweinfurth, In the Heart of Africa, II, pp. 37-39; in Mindanao: Ztschr f. Ethnol., XVII, pp. 19 ff-; in New Guinea: Finsch, Samoafahrten, pp. 56 ff.; in New Pomerania: Parkinson, Im Bismarck- Archipel, pp. 118 ff.; in South America: Martiub, Zur Ethnogr. Atner- ikas, pp. 84. 85. 489. 490. ' Ratzel, I, p. 85 ; Panckow, pp. 167 ff. 48 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. I I H IP 111 \\\ SB i J. li** poles and grass; their other possessions may easily be carried away on their backs or quickly replaced, and on another spot a new village in a few days can be erected in which nothing from the old is lacking save the vermin. Hack agriculture is exactly suited to just such a life. It requires no fixed capital beyond the small hoe and, where corn is cultivated, perhaps a knife to cut the ears. The keeping of supplies is scarcely necessary, since in many quarters the climate permits several harvests in the year. Where grain is grown, however, it is customary to store ' in small granaries built on posts, or in pits in the earth, or in great earthen vessels. But even where thus stored it must soon be used if it is not to be destroy».d through dampness, weevils, and termites. Livingstone thinks this explains why the negroes in case of abundant harvest brew so much beer.^ Hack agriculture is still one of the most widely prevalent systems of husbandry. It is to be found throughout all Ceni-al Africa (i8° N. lat. to 22° S. lat.). in South and Central America, in the whole of the Australian islands, in great sections of Further India and the East Indian Archipelago, Everywhere, [as already noted], it appears to have been originally woman's work; and as such it is a great factor in advancing civilization. Obviously through hunting for roots, which she had practised from the earliest times, woman was led on to agriculture. Farinaceous bulbs and root-crops form accordingly the chief part of her plan- tations. In this manner she gained technical experiences which the man did not enjoy. Her labour soon yielded the most important part of the requirements of life; and therewith was laid the foundation of a permanent family organization, in which the man undertook the offices of protection and the procuring of animal food. Only where * Expedit. to Zambesi, p. 253. THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PfUMUlvE PEOPLE. 49 there are no large quantities of game toes the man take part in the cultivation of th? soil, as, foi instance, among the Malays. Let us now turn to the second source of sustenance, hunting and fishing. Through the imperfect nature oi their weapons hunting has ever had among primiti'-'j peo- ples a strong resemblance to the method of the beast of prey stealing upon its victim. A larger animal can only be wounded by an arrow-shot or spear-thrust, not killed; and then it is the hunter's task to pursue the Vast until it sinks down exhausted. As this species of hunt may, however, under certain circumstances, become very dangerous, the most varied ways of trapping have been invented — pits, barricades, and falling trees; or in attacking the animal directly the hunt is carried on by whole tribes or village communities.^ Under such circumstances communal own- ership of the hunting-grounds and the establishment of very detailed rules for the distribution of the booty among the participants and the owners of the ground have been early developed; but on such matters we cannot enter here.**^ The essential thing for us to note is that the part of the duties pertaining to the providing of footl necessitates a certain organization of work conformable to the princi- ple of labour in common — a circumstance that has cer- tainly been of the greatest importance for the birth of primitive political communities. The same is to be said of fisliing,^^ especially where the industry is followed along the seashore with boats and large nets, which can be produced and handled only with the help of many. The Ne' / Zealanders, for instance, wove 'On the hunting methods of the Kaffirs cunip. Fritsch, pp. 81 ff. ; of the South Americans, Martins, pp. 8j, 101. '"Some particulars in Post, Afr. Juiistr.. II, pp. i6z. 163; Lubbock, Origin of Civilisation, p. 435. ■•' As to fishing comp. in general Katzel, 1, pp. ij4, 396, 506, 531. li so THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. ! ill in i I ^i < r « I i nets one thousand yards in length and it took hundreds of hands to use them. Innumerable are the modes of catch- ing fish which primitive peoples have invented; besides hook and net, arrows, spears, bow-nets, and methods of stunning the fish are resorted to. All our information on this subject indicates that fishing acquired a much more regular character among primitive peoples than hunting. On many islands of the South Sea, indeed, definite days of the week have once for all been set apart for the communal fishing; and the leatlers of the fishing expeditions are also the leaders in war. Stream-fishing has been especially de- veloped by the primitive inhabitants of South America, among whom there are tribes that have been called fish- ing nomads because they wander from stream to stream. The same also occurs here and there in Africa. The actual labour of fishing seems always to fall to the men; it is only in some districts of Polynesia that the women take a lim- ited part in it. Because of the very perishable nature of meat, hunt- ing and fishing in tropical regions can, in the majority cf cases, supplement the vegetable diet only occasionally. True, the drying and even the smoking of the fish and meat cut into strips was early learned and practised. This i.s the usage with the Polynesians as well as among the Malays and Americans, and even among the negroes and Australians. Yet the pan ci the food requirement which can be regularly met in this manner is so small that it is a rule among many tribes that only the more prominent persons may enjoy certain kinds of game. It is ([uite com- mon also for the use of certain kinds of meat to be for- bidden to the v.'omen. It is only small forest and coast tribes, who are able with their dried meat to carry on trade with agricultural neighbours, that find their support in hunting and fishing. THE ECONOM.'C LIFE OF PRIMlTIf^E PEOPLE. 51 It would accordingly be quite natural to assume that primitive peoples must early have hit upon the taming and raising of animals as a source of a regular food-supply. But we can speak of cattle-raising as a practice among the peoples of the tropical regions only in a very restricted sense. The hen alone, of our domestic animals, is to be found everywhere; besides it there is in Africa the goat, among the Malays and Polynesians the pig, and among the Americans the turkey, the musk-duck and the guinea- pig. Cattle are found only among one section of the Malays and in one strip, more or less broad, of East Africa, which runs through almost the whole continent, from the Dukas and Baris on the Upper Nile to the Hottentots ?nd Namaquas in the south. But most of these people o not use them as draught-animals; many of them do not even use their milk; many East African cattle-raisers never slaughter a beast except when they have captured it from another tribe.*' Here and there in Equatorial Africa the ox serves as a riding and pack animal; but, generally speaking, the possession of cattle is for the negro peoples merely " a representation of wealth and the object of an almost extravagant venera- tion," — merely a matter of fancy. Ami this in general is the character of cattle-keeping among primitive peoples. An Indian village in the inte- rior of Brazil, [as we have remarked in our last chapter], resembles a great menagerie; even the art of dyeing the plumage of birds is known; but none of the many animals are raised because of the meat or for other economic pur- pose; the very eggs of the hens, which are kept in large numbers, are not eiten.'-^ To the Indian the lower animals " Schweinfurth, I, pp. 59, 60; LivinRstonr, p. ssj; Pogge, p. 23; Wissmann, Im Inntrn Afrikas, pp. 25, 127. "Ehrenreich, pp. i.i, 14, 54; Martius, pp. 6;j ff.; K. v. d. Steinen, PP •Jio, 379. bimilariy amung the Oceanians: Ratzei, I, p. 2j6. 1 1? if >d 52 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. are beings closely related to man, and in which he delights; but, as is evident, this keeping of animals is much more closely allied to the hunt than to agriculture. Here we have to do with tamed, not with domestic, animals. With such a state of affairs the place of the pig in the domestic economy of the Oceanians has many cognate features; it is petted by the whole family; its young are not infrequently suckled by the women; and its flesh is eaten only on feast days and then by the more prominent people alone. The sole animal, [other than the hen], which is found among all primitive peoples is the dog; but it also is a pure luxury and is almost nowhere employed in the hunt; only a few tribes eat its flesh, and it has been claimed from ob- servation that these are always such as are devoted to cannibalism. On the whole, then, no importance can attach to cattle- raising in the production of the food-supplies of primitive peoples; in their husbandry it forms little more than an element of consumption. But the needs of these peoples are not confined to sus- tenance. Even the lowest among them paint, or in other ways decorate, their bodies, and make bow^ and arrows; the more advanced erect more or less substantial houses, plait and weave all kinds of stufTs. carve implements, make burnt earthen vessels; all prepare their food with fire, and with few exceptions know how to concoct intoxicatmg beverages. For all this labour of ditTcrcnt kinds is neces- sary which we can cluiracterize in a simple manner as the transformation or tt-or/, m/^' »/' of material, and which in the main embraces what we <lcsi-nate industry. Now what system did ami does such work exhibit among primitive peoples' If we arc to answer this (juestion we must distmguish sharplv the tcciinical and the economic sides of industry. THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 53 Technique in connection with the transformation of ma- terial is primarily dependent on natural conditions, and ac- cordingly develops among most primitive peoples only along special lines.'' Their implements are at first simple, natural objects, such as stones, animal bones, shells, sharp- ened pieces of wood, destined almost solely to increase the working power of the human members Of implements consisting of more than one part, we may mention the hand-mill and crushing-mortar. The first is merely a sta- tionary and a movable stone with which the grains of corn are ground in the same manner as our artisans grind paint in a mortar. The crushing-mortar is a hollowed tree-trunk with a wooden pestle. The simplest labour-saving me- chanical helps, such as wedge, lever, tongs, and screw, are unknown to them. Their boats are tree-trunks hollowed out with fire, or pieces of bark sewn together; the rudders are sf>oonlike pieces of wood with short handles represent- ing little more than a broadening out of the hand. The ai I of joining together pieces of wood or other hard mate- rial by pegs, nails, dovetailing, or glue they are ignorant of; for this purpose they use tough fibres or cords or even mere tendrils of climbing plants. Metal-working was un- known to the Australians, Melanesians, Polynesians, and the native inhabitants of .America before the coming of the Europeans. On the other hand the negro peoples are uni- versally familiar with the procuring and working up of iron, and here and there of copper as well. A more ad- vanced techni(|ue as regards metals is found only among the Malays. But even in the iron-forging of the negroes all the technical awkwardness of these peoples can be per- ceived. Their smiths did not even hit upon the idea of making their own tools out of iron. Hammers and anvils are stones, and very often the tnngs are only the rib of a palm-leaf. "On what foli'iw* romp. Arbeit u Nhythnius. pp. lo ff ■ jpWJiuiWPfWHW" 3> 1 11 1 "' . 54 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. In Spite of this technical backwardness many primitive peoples with their wretched tools produce wares of such quality and art^.stic taste as to arouse our highest admira- tion. This is possible only when the particular technical processes are applied in le simplest, and at the same time most comprehensive, manner. Preeminent are weavmg, pottery, and wcod-carving. What indeed do the tropical peoples not make out of the bast and fibrous material of their forests, of the tough grasses and rushes— from mats and clothing-stuflEs of bark to water-tight baskets, dishes, and bottles? What is not made by the East Indians and Eastern Asiatics fror.^ bamboo— from the timbers of the house to water-vesseis, blowing-tubes, and musical instru- ments? How highly developed is woodwork among the Papuans; ami what patience and perseverance it demands! To weave a pijce of stuff of raffia fibre in Madagascar often takes several months; and in South America the same time is required to finish a hammock. The polishing and pierc- ing of the milk-white pieces of quartz that the Uaupes of Brazil wear about their necks is frequently the work of two generations. This leads us directly to the industrial organisation in the working tit of material For such labour there are, with few exceptions, no distinctly professional craftsmen. Each household has to meet all economic requirements of its members with its o'-m labour; and this is accomplished by means of that peculiar division of dulies l)etween the two sexes, which we have come to know [in the preceding chapter]. Not only is it that a definite part of the provid- ing of food is assigned to either sex, but each looks after the preparing of such as is gained along with all at- tendant tasks. To the woman falls all that is connected with the procuring and preparing of the vegetable foods: to the man the makinp of wca])<.ii-,. .ui.l of implements for hunting, fishing, and cattle-raising, the working-up of ani- if THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRlMlTiyE PEOPLE. 55 mal bones and skins, and the building of canoes. As a rule the man also looks after the roasting of the meats and the drying of fish, while the woman must attend to the labor- ious grinding of the com, which she has grown, the brew- ing of beer, the shaping and burning of earthen pots for cooking, and in many instances the building of the huts as well. Besides these there are many species of the trans- forming of material, which are allotted now to one sex, now to the other. We may mention spinning, weaving, plaiting, the preparing of palm-wine and of bark stuffs. But, on the whole, this division of duties between the male and the female members of families is sharply drawn. In- deed it is continued even in consumption, for men and women never eat together; and, where polygamy exists, a separate hut must be provided for each wife.'* We cannot enter upon a more detailed discussion of this peculiarly evolved dualism in liouselwld economy among primitive peoples. It devolves upon us, however, to establish that the labour of the members of the house- hold, which is of such an individualistic character, cannot suffice for all tasks of their economic life. For under- takings that surpass the strength of the single household, assistance must therefore be obtained: either the help of the neighbours is solicited or all such labours are performed at one time by the whole village community. The latter is the rule in Africa, for instance, with the breaking of stretches of forest land for cultivation, the laying of barri- cades and pits for trapping wild animals, and elephant- hunting; in F'olynesia. with the weaving of large fishing- nets, the building of large houses, the baking of bread- fruit in a common oven, and the like. Where clanship or slavery or polygamy exists, there is offered a means for multiplying the domestic working strcncrth, and thus for ' Com p. •ve. rr 56 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. fe I ) r ,i' accomplishing services of a higher order for which the individual's strength does not suffice. Within the separate tribes, accordingly, the working and refining of the raw products does not lead to the de- velopment of distinct trades, in that such work is carried on with uniform independence in each separate household From the reports of travellers, who judged from appear- ances, the existence of artisans among various primitive peoples has indeed been asserted. Thus on certain islands of the South Sea there are said to be professional carpen- ters, shoemakers, net-knitters, stone-borers, and wood- car\'ers. On closer examination of the particular cases these observations are open to doubt; to me the case of the native metal-worker seems alone to be proved. Among the negroes of Africa, as far as I can judge, only among the semi-civilized peoples of the Soudan are there the be- ginnings of a special industrial class. Beyond this any traces of a specialized industry supposed to have been dis- covered among primitive peoples are to be thus ex- plained: either individuals manifesting special aptitude for some manufacture came under the observation of travellers, or entire tribes excelled in a particular kind of household occupation, as we shall see directly. Trades formed only under European influence must naturally be disregarded here. But from tribe to tribe we find great differences in this industrial working-up of materials. It may even be safely claimed that almost every tribe displays some favourite form of industrial activity, in which its members surpass the other tribes. This is due to the varied distribution of natural products. If good potter's clay is to be found in the district or village of a particular tribe, the women of this tribe or village readily acquire special skill in pottery; where native iron ore is discovered, smiths will appear; r \ t THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 57 while along well-wooded seacoasts boat-building will flour- ish. Other tribes or localities excel in the preparation of salt from vegetable ashes, in the making of palm-wine or leather or skin garments; others again in the making of calabashes, baskets, mats, and woven materials. All these forms of skill, however, are aptitudes such as every man or every woman of the particular tribe or locality knows and also practises on occasion. When these individuals are designated by travellers as smiths, salt-makers, basket- makers, weavers, etc., that is to be taken in the same sense as when we speak of ploughmen, reapers, mowers, thresh- ers among our peasants, according to the work in which they are for the time engaged. We have here to do not with special trades claiming the individual's whole activity, but with arrangements forming essential parts of the econ- omy of each separate family. This naturally does not preclude single individuals from surpassing in skilfulness the other members of the tribe, just as there are among our peasant women particularly adept spinners, and among the farmers horse-breeders and bee-keepers who win in prize competitions. Travellers have often observed this tribal or local de- vclopmait of industrial technique. " The native villages," relates a Belgian observer of the Lower Congo, " are often situated in groups. Their activities are based upon recip- rocality, and they are to a certain extent the complements of one another. Each group has its more or less strongly defined specialty. One carries on fishing, another pro- duces palm-wine; a third devotes itself to trade and is broker for the others, supplying the community with all products from outside; another has reserved to itself work in iron and copper, making weapons for war and hunting, various utensils, etc. None may, however, pass beyond the sphere of its own specialty without exposing itself to ■r I fill 1 - , ^ . ill ft, f ft-- 58 THE ECONOMIC UFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. the risk of being universally proscribed." From the Loango coast Bastian tells of a great number of similar centres for special products of domestic industry. Loango excels in mats and fishing-baskets, while the carving of elephants' tusks is specially followed in Chilungo. The so- called " Mafooka " hats with raised patterns are drawn chiefly from the bordering country of Kakongo and May- yumbe. In Bakunya are made potter's wares which are in great demand, in Basanza excellent swords, in Basundi especially beautiful ornamented copper rings, on the Zaire clever wood and tablet carvings, in Loango orna- mented cloths and intricately designed mats, in Mayumbe clothing of finely woven mat-work, in Kakongo embroid- ered hats and also burnt-clay pitchers, and among the Ba- yakas and Mantetjes stuffs of woven grass. Other similar accounts might be cited, not merely from Africa," but also from the South Sea Islands and even from Central and South America." We shall thus hardly err in assuming that in these tribal industries the controlling principle in the industrial development of prim- itive peoples has been discovered; that by them was furnished the means whereby the satisfaction of the needs of the individual and of whole groups was extended beyond their own immediate powers of production. For it may be taken for granted that an industrial product found only among those manufacturing it, especially if it attained to some importance in the simple life oi these uncivilized peo- ples, would soon be coveted by the surrounding tribes. '* H. Schurtz has made a collection of them in his Afr. Gewerbc, pp. 29-65. He has pursued further, though unfortunately not far enough, the subject of tribal industry. He has found such industry so exten- sively in evidence i.nat we may assume the conditions of industrial production here portrayed to exist wherever travellers do not ex- pressly report to the contrary. " Comp. K. Sapper. Das Hordl. Mittel-Amerika (1897'). pp. 200 flF.. and the further examples given by us. THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 59 But the way from the coveting of an article to its enjoy- ment is a longer one in an economical organization, based upon acquisition directly by the individual himself, than we are inclined to assume in our own social life, which rests upon trade. In fact decidedly unclear conceptions are widely preva- lent as to the system of exchange of primit've peoples. We know that throughout Central Africa, from the Portuguese possessions in the west to the German in the east, there is a market-place every few miles at which the neighbouring tribes meet every fourth to sixth day to make mutual ex- changes. Of the Malays in Borneo we are told that each larger village possesses its weekly market. The first dis- coverers of the South Sea Islands give us reports of distant " trading trips " which the natives undertake from island to island in order to make mutual exchanges of their wares. In America certain products, the raw material for which is to be found only in a single locality — for example, arrow- points and stone hatchets made of certain kinds of stone — have been met with scattered throughout a great part of the continent." Even among the aborigines of Australia there are instances of certain natural products, such as pitcher-plant leaves and ochre colour, which are found in but one place, and yet circulate through a g^eat part of the country. In such phenomena we have a new and interesting proof of the civilizing power of trade; and in the primeval history of Europe itself this power has everywhere been assumed as operative when industrial products have been brought to light through excavations or otherwise far from their original place of production. Our prehistoric studies have woven together a whole spider's web of suppositions and have even brought us to " Waitz. Ill, p 75; on markets in South America. Ill, p. 380: on others in Mexico, IV, pp. 99 ff. II m''i m ii- I I ^ i i ritfi I Hi! i: i ^1 tf I ^Sl 60 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMHWE PEOPLE. speak of prehistoric '* industrial districts." Our ethno- graphic literature speaks similarly of industrial localities for the manufacture of arms and the plaiting of mats in Borneo, for pottery at several points in New Guinea, for boat-building in several coast districts of the Duke of York Archipelago, for iron-working in negro countries, etc. In opposition to this it must be asserted positively that trade in the sense in which it is regarded by national econ- omy — that is, in the sense of the systematic purchase of wares with the object of a profitable re-sale as an organized vocation— can nowhere be discovered among primitive peoples. Where we meet native traders in Africa, it is a question either of intermediary activity prompted by Eu- ropean and Arabian merchants, or of occurrences peculiar to the semi-civilization of the Soudan. Otherwise the only exchange known to the natives everywhere is exchange from tribe to tribe. This is due to the unequal dis- tribution of the gifts of nature and to the varying develop- ment of industrial technique among the different tribes. As between the members of the same tribe, however, no regular exchange from one household establishment to another takes place. Nor can it arise, since that voca- tional division of the population is lacking which alone could give rise to an enduring interdependence of house- holds. One fancies the gemns of exchange to have been very easy because civilized man is accusiomed to find all that he needs ready made at the market or store and to be able to obtain it for money. With primitive man, however, before he became acquainted with more highly devel- oped peoples, value and price were by no means current conceptions. The first discoverers of Australia found in- variably, both on the continent and on the neighbouring islands that th« aborigines had no conception of ex- i f THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITiyE PEOPLE. 6i change." The ornaments offered them had no power whatever to arouse their interest; gifts pressed upon them were found later on strewn about in the woods where they had been cast in neglect. Ehrenreich ^^ and K. V. der Steinen 2" had as late as 1887 the same experi- ence among the Indian tribes of Brazil, Yet there was from tribe to tribe a brisk trade in pots, stone hatchets, hammocks, cotton threads, necklaces of mussel-shells, and many other products. How was this possible in the ab- sence of barter and trade? The solution oi this riddle is simple enough, and has now been confirmed by direct observation on the spot, while previously it could only be assumed. The transfer ensues by way of presevts, and also, according to circum- stances, by way of robbery, spoils of war, tribute, line, com- pensation, and winnings in gaming. As to sustenance, al- most a community of goods prevails between members ot the same tribes. It is looked upon as theft if a herd of cat- tle is slaughtered and not shared with one's neighbour, or if one is eating and neglects to invite a passer-by. Anyone can enter a hut at will and demand food; and he is never refused. Whole communities, if u poor harvest befall, visit their neighbours and look to them for temporary support. For articles of use and implements there exists the uni- versal custom of loaning which really assumes the character of a duty; and there is no private ownership of the soil. Thus within the tribe where all households produce similar commodities and, in case of need, assist each other, and •where surplus stores can only be utilized for consumption, there is no occasion for direct barter from establishment to establishment. Exceptions occur when purchasing a "Documentary proof in Ztschr. f. Sozial- u. Wirtschaftsgesch.. IV, pp. S flF. (Sartorius v. Waltershausen). " Beitrdge :. I'olkerkunde Rrasihens, p. 53, " Unler d. Natun>olkern Central- Brasiliens (2d ed.), pp. 287 ff. m ■11 ■ , I :■.;! 62 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. wife and making presents to tne medicine-man, the singer, the dancer, and the minstrel, who are the only persons carrying on a species of separate occupations. From tribe to tribe there prevail rules of hospitality,^^ which recur with tolerable imilarity among all primitive peoples. The stranger on arriving receives a present, which after a certain interval he reciprocates; and at his departure still another present is handed him.^' On both sides wishes may be expressed with regard to these gifts. In this way it is possible to obtain things required or de- sired; and success is the more assured inasmuch as neither party is absolved from the obligations of hospitality until the other declares himself satisfied with the presents. That this custom of reciprocal gifts of hospitality per- mits rare products of a land or artistic creations of a tribe to circulate from people to people, and to cover just as long distances from their place of origin as to-day does trade, will perhaps become more apparent to us when we consider how legends and myths have in the same way been enabled to spread over half the A^orld. It is almost inconceivable that this could have been so long overlooked when even in Homer the custom of gifts of hospitality is attested by so many examples. Telemachos brings home from Sparta as present from Menelaos a bowl of silver which the latter had himself received in Sidon as a gift of hospitality from King Phaidimos, and his father Odys- seus receives from the Phaiakes garments and linen and articles of gold as well as a whole collection of tripods and basins. All this he conceals on his arrival, as is well known, in the sacred grove of the nymphs in his native rocky island of Ithaca. Think of the poet's narration as " On this oo-.it cotnp. K. Haberland, Die Gastfrcundschaft auf nied. KuUurstufen: Ausland (1878), pp. 282 flF. "Gift-making without recompense Lciutigs un'iy fo a higher stage of civilization: A. M. Meyer, Ztschr. f. deutsch, Kuhurgesch., V, pp. 18 fT. .■*! THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 63 a''.;d toi 3U1 ()urt i. ■'"nr.i.ei; ir liOl. le . uy •■an. s have ion from 7.;ntral Aus- kes for a gift an object V. or of per- aaei an historical occurrence, and imagine what would have happened had Odysseus been recognised by the wooers at the right moment and slain; the presents of the Phaiakes would have rested well concealed in the gfrotio of the nymphs down to our own times, and would have been brought to light again by a moden; .archaeologist. Would he not have explained the wholf treasu -e as the storehouse of a travelling merchant of ' .e I- nif 15;^' ^.l 'Tellas, es- pecially as he could have app a' .;d tor 3ui purt w • le actual barter which occurs quite c Among many primitive ^, been preserved which cU r,^ ..!■ .1; ^'•: presents to exchange, ^ii.ory^ 'u 1 . tralia, for instance, a man < : > ■ "i present the task of procuring ?s recinrocii that another desires, or of buiu. ' loi Iii formi..^ some other service. The one thus bound is called yutschin, and until the fulfilment of the obligation wears a cord about his neck. As a rule the desired object is to be procured from a distance.^'" In New Zealand the natives on the Wanganui river make use of parrots, which they catch in great numbers, roast, and preserve in fat, in order to obtain dried fish from their fe!lo"'-countrymen in other parts of the island."^ Among the Indian tribes of Cen- tral Brazil trade is still an mterchange of gifts of hospi- tality; and the Bakairis translate the Portuguese cotr'>rcr, to btiy, by a word signifying ' to sit down,' becaub ■ the guest must be seated before he receives his present. In the countries of the Soudan the co.";stant giving of pres- ents frequently becomes burdensoine to the traveller " since it is often only a concealed begging." " The gifts of hospitality that are received in the camp," remarks "A \V. TTowitt in Journal of Anthrop. Inst, XX (1891), pp. 76 ff. ** Shortland, Tfaditions and Sttl'erst-.tijtt.i of Ike Nctv Zealanders (Lon- don, 1856), pp. 214, 215. : - i 1 ■ ' -* > 1 64 THE ECONOMIC UFE OF PRIMITiyE PEOPLE. Staudinger,^'' " are in accord with good custom and are often very welcome. But with every stop in a larger town things are frequently obtained from high and low which are ostensibly given as a mark of respect to the white man; in reality they arrive only because the donors expect a three- or four-fold response from the liberality of the Euro- pean. Indeed I am convinced that many a poor woman has herself first purchased the hen or duck that is to be presented in order to do a profitable piece of gift business with it." The Indians of British Guiana appear to stand at the in- termediate stage between gift-making and trading. Im Thurm reports of them: " •• There exists among the tribes of this, as oi probably every other similar district, a rough system of distribution of labour; and this serves not only its immediate purpose of supplying all the tribes with better-made articles than each could make for itself, but also brings the different tribes together and spreads among them ideas and news of general interest. . . . Each tribe has some manufacture peculiar to itself; and its members constantly visit the other tribes, often hostile, for the purpose of exchanging the products of their own labour for such as arc produced only by the other tribes. These trading Indians are allowed to pass unmolested through the enemy's country. . . Of the tribes on the coast, the Warraus make far the best canoes, and supply these to the neighbouring tribes. They also make hammocks of a peculiar kind, which are not, however, much in rctjuest e.xcept among tlicnisclvcs. In the same way, far in the interior, the Wapiaiias build boats for all the tribos in that district. The Macusis have two special products which are in great demand amongst all the tribes. One is the ourali. used for poisoning arrows and the darts of blowpipes, the other is an abundance of cotton ham- mocks; for, though these are now often made by the Wapianas .md True Caribs, the Macusis are the chief makers. The Arecunas grow, spin, and distribute most of the cotton which is used by the Macusis .ind others for hamnocks and other articles. The Arecunas also sup- ply all blowpipes; f(,r these are made of the stems of a palm which, "/m Hcrstn d. Ilaussaliindcr (2d cd). pp. 216. 217 Comp. Sachau, Retsen in Syricn u. Mesofotamien, p. loi; v. Hiigel, Kaschmir, pp. 406, 40;. " /trnong the Indians of Guiana (London, 188.O, pp. 270-273- THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITiyE PEOPLE. 65 growing only in and beyond the Venezuelan boundary of their terri- tory, are procured by the Arecunas, doubtless by exchange, from the Indians of the native district of that palm. The Tarumas and the Woyowais have a complete monopoly of the manufacture of the graters on which Indians of all the tribes grate their cassava. These two remote tribes are also the great breeders and trainers of hunting- dogs. . . . The True Caribs, again, are the most skilful potters; and though the Arawaks frequently, and the other Indians occasionally, make vessels for their own use, yet these are by no means as good as those which, whenever possible, they obtain from the Caribs. The Arawaks make fibre hammocks of a kind peculiar to them. . . . The Ackawoi alone, so far as I know, have no special product interchange- able for those of their neighbours. These Indians are especially dreaded and disliked by all the others; and it is possible that the want of intercourse thus occasioned between this tribe and the others forced the Ackawoi to produce for themselves all that they required. It is further possible that to this enforced self-dependence is due the miser- able condition of most of the Ackawoi. " To interchange their manufactures the Indians make long jour- neys. The Wapianas visit the countries of the Tarumas and the Woyowais, carrying with them canoes, cotton hamnn-cks, and now very frequently knives, beads, and other European goods; and, leav- ing their canoes and other merchandise, they walk back, carrying with them a supply of cassava-graters, and leading hunting-t'ogs, all which things they have received in i hange for the things which they took. The Macusis visit the Wapiana settlements to obtain graters i. \ dogs, for which they give ourali-poison and cotton hammocks; and they again carry such of these graters and dogs as they do not them- selves require, together with more of their own ouralt and of their cotton hammocks, to other Indians — to the Arecunas. wlio j;ivc in return balls of cotton or blowpipes; or to the True Caribs. who pay in pottery." Once originated exchange lonj? retains the marks of its descent in the rules that are attached to it and which are taken directly from the customs connected with gifts. This is manifested, in the fir.st place, in the custom of payment in advance which dominates trade nmonjT primitive pej- pies." The medicine-man does not stir his hand to .lelp " Even Europc.in merchants trading in .^fri^M must accommodate themselves to this custom 'by advancing to the black interniediarics whose services they call into re<|uisition the price of the commodities that arc .0 be supplied. Conip. Pogge. pp. 11, 140, 141; M. Buchner, 66 THE ECONOMIC UFE OF PRIMITIl^E PEOPLE. \ H ■ f the sick until he has received from the sick man's relatives his fee, which in this case closely resembles the present, and has openly announced his satisfaction. No purchase is complete until buyer and seller have before witnesses declared themselves satisfied with the objects received. Among many peoples a gift precedes or follows a deal; *• the " good measures " of our village storekeepers, and "treating" are survivals of this custom. To decline without grounds an exchange that has been offered passes among the negroes as an insult, just as the refusal of a gift among ourselves. The idea that services interchanged must be of equal value can hardly be made intelligible to primitive man. The boy who performs a bit of work ex- pects the same pay as the man, and the one who has assisted for one hour just as much as the one who has laboured a whole day; and as the greed on both sides knows no bounds, every trading transaction is preceded by long negotiations. Sii; lar negotiations, however, are also the rule in the discharge of gifts of hospitality if the recipient does not find the donation in keeping with his dignity. As time passes exchange creates from tribe to tribe its own contrivances for facilitating matters. The most im- portant of these are markets and money. Markets are uniformly held among negroes. East Indi- ans, and Polynesians in open places, often in the midst of the primeval forests, on the tribal borders. They form neu- tral districts within which all tribal hostilities must cease; whoever violates the market-peace exposes himself to the severest punishments. Each tribe brings to the market KamfTHH. pp. 98, 99. Even the sacrifice to the deity seems to the peo- ples of '.hi-s staKc only payment in advance for an expected service: Heckewtlder. Indian Xations. pp. 2ti fT. ; and comp. pp. j^i. j.^fi " Schurt/. F.ntslfh Gesch. d Geldes. pp. 67, 6a Landor, In the For- bidden Land (Tibe<), I, p. ,115: II. p. 7& THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRlMITiyE PEOPLE. 67 whatever is peculiar to it: one honey, another palm-wine, a third dried meat, still another earthenware or mats or woven stuffs." The object of the interchange is to ob- tain products that cannot be procured in one's own tribe at all, or at least -cannot be produced so well and so artis- tically as in neighbouring tribes. This must- agam lead each tribe to produce in greater quantities than it requires those products which are valued among the tribes, not pro- ducing them, because in exchange for these it is easiest to obtam that which one does not possess one's self, but which others manufacture in surplus quantities. In each tribe, however, every household produces the current market commodity of exchange that enjoys this prefer- ence. Hence it follows, when it is a question of a product of house industry, such as earthenware or wares made of bark, that whole villages and tribal areas appear to travel- lers to be great industrial districts, although there are no specialized artisans, and although each household pro- duces everything that it requires with tlie exception of the few articles made only among other tribes which they have grown accustomed to and which exchange procures for them merely as supplements to houshold production. Such is the simple mechmism of the market among primitive peoples. Now with regard to monfy. How much has been written and imagined about the many species of money among primitive peoples."" and yet how "AlthnuKh many primitive iH-.^.k-s ran l.c to.m.l roadv to jjive every tli.n^ for ICiiropcan wares that tlu-y have co,„e t,. kruw and value, yet their rev;„lar exchange remains alto^iether u„e -ulcd and cnnfmed to •, iVw artu-le.. Man> ohj^ct. of .l.nlv „-,. are nm t„ be had from them at any price, especially ol.ieets of a.lorn.nent Comp I'.nseh, Samoafahrtcn. pp. ,08. ,10, .«)(,, .-S,, f,, ,,,^: Martmx ctcd above, pp, K.). 5()(,; Zt-.lir f FlhnoKr.. WIl. pp _> , (,j. '-"!< .■\tMlrre, t-.thn,^^r. r,:n,llcl,„ ./. / VrcA ;,/).•, pp ...., (T O I.en/. I chcr i.dd hi-i d. \\UufVi.',k,-rn ( HamhnrK. 1S-J5). R Ilwof. Tausch- kiindd u Celdsurrogatc m alter u. neucr /.at (Gra/, 1882). II. Schurz, 68 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE, ' I i simple the explanation of their origin ! The money of each tribe is that trading commodity ivhich it does not itself produce, but which it regularly acquires from other tribes by way of exchange. For such article naturally becomes for it the universal medium of exchange for which it sur- renders its wares. It is its measure of value according to which it values its property, which could in no other way be made exchangeable. It is its wealth, for it cannot in- crease it at will. F°llow tribesmen soon come to employ it also in transferring values, for because of its scarcity it is equally welcome to all. Thus is explained what our trav- ellers have frequently observed, that in each tribe, often indeed from village to village, a different money is current, and that a species of mussel-shells or pearls or cotton stuf? for which everything can be purchased to-day, is in the locality of the following evening's camp no longer ac- cepted by anyone. The consetinence is that they must first purchase the current commodities of exchange before they can supply their own needs in the market. In this way, also, is to be explained the further fact, which has come under observation, that exchangeable commodities nat- urally scarce, such as salt, cauri shells, and bars of cop- per, or products of rare skill, such as brass wire, iron spades, and earthen cups, are taken as money by many tribes not possessing them; and above all is to be men- tioned the well-known circumstance of objects of foreign trade, such as European calicoes, guns, ponder, knives, becoming general mediums of exchange. Certain varieties of money thus secure a more extensive area of circulation. They can even make their way into the internal trade of the tribal members through employ- ment as mediums of payment \u the juirchase of a bride, for Balntge r. r.ntsli'huv-Rcsch d. („ldi\i: Deutsche Ucogr. Dldltcr (Bre- men). .\X (iSfj;), ip. 1-'/'. Itiicrn. Archiv f, Ethtiogr., VI, p. 57. ,: ft :•* THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITiyE PEOPLE. 69 compensations, taxes, and the like; certain kinds of con- tracts are concluded in them. But there is no instance of a primitive people, in the absence of European influence, attaining to a currency or legal medium of payment for obligations of every kind and extent. It is rather the rule that various species of money remain in concurrent circu- lation; and very often certain obligations can be paid only in certain kinds. Changes in the variety of money are not infrequent; but on the other hand we sometimes find that a species will long survive the trade of the tribes from which it has gone forth, and will continue to serve in the inner transactions of a tribe, playing a singular, almost demoniacal, role, although, as regards their means of sus- tenance, the members of the tribe have nothing to buy and sell to one another. From an old interrupted tribal trade of this nature is to be explained the employment as money of old Chinese porcelain vessels among the Bagobos in Mindanao and the Dyaks in Borneo, the shells (dewarra) of the Melanesians. and the peculiar kinds of money of the Caroline Archipelago, for which special laws and ad- ministrative contrivances are necessary in order to keep this dead possession in circulation at all.^* Otherwise the State does not interfere as a rule in these matters; and in the large territorial formations of Africa, such as the king- dom of Muata Yamwo. for instance, there are therefore different currencies from tribe to tribe. But even where one kind of money gains a greater area of circulation, its value fluctuates widely at the various market-places: generally, however, it advances in proportion to the dis- tance from its source.^*' " WV cannot rntir luri- more in dct.iil info these matters, and would refer to the interesting descriptions of Kubary, Etknog. Beitrdge s. Kcnntms d C:irfltmfn-Archi(<cls. pp. i fT.. and Parkinson, pp. 79, loi flf. '"Thus Ccrohi reports, funf Jahrc m Ostafrika. p. 2-\: " .Xccordinff to the higher or lower value of the salt bar in the markets of this 70 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. W iJ Markets and money are intimately related so far as money in its character as a medium of exchange comes un- der consideration. But not every individual species of money that is met with among a primitive people has necessarily arisen from market trade. In its full develop- ment money is such an involved social phenomenon that it is natural to suppose that various influences associated with its past have been united in it. Thus, for instance, the origin of cattle-money seems to be bound up with the fact that, among the peoples referred to, the domestic ani- mals represented the wealth and the means of gathering wealth. That for the purchase of a bride and for similar ends many tribes do not receive the current money, but f such purposes prescribe certain other objects of worth, a :)ears to point to the admissibility of the assumption that the complete development of money, along with the un current, various subsidiary streams may have played art 31 7rom the standpoint of the total cultural progress of 'f Ea • Africa one could roughly estimate the distance from the whe this money comes, and also judge of the more or less icabl' ature of the routes over which the caravans transport it. - in • reality of its origin, for one thaler one receives among the T.- cording to the statements of several travellers, several hii - bars. In Uorallu, the northern market of Schao, lying a <li--ta! 'f some two hundred miles from the country of the Taltal, ;'.> va hictuatcs between fifteen and twenty for the thaler. In .^n- coIkt. ciahty miles from Uorailu, the value sinks back to nine and nine ;ind a half, and in Gera, two hundred and thirty miles beyond Ancobcr, one receives, according to circumstances, only six. five. four, or three salt bars per thaler." "Perhaps Karl Marx rishtly expresses it when he tersely remarks: " The money-form attaches itself either to the most important articles of exchange from outside, and these in fact arc primuivc and natural forms in which the exchange-value of h<ime product" find-, expression; or else it attaches itself to the object of utility that f.)rnis, like cattle, the chief portion of indigenous alienable wealth." — Capital (London, 1891), p 6i. THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 71 mankind the most important result of this survey, how- ever, remains, that money as the favourite exchange com- modity furnished a medium that bound together men from tribe to tribe in regular peaceful trade, and prepared the way for a differentiation of tribes in the matter of produc- tion. In the circumstance that all members of the same tribe or village preferably carried on, along with the earn- ing of their sustenance, other work of a definite type, lay the possibility of an advance in technical knowledge and dexterity. It was an international, or interlocal, division of labour in miniature, which only much later was succeeded by division of labour from individual to individual within the nation, or the locality. Moreover the direct importance of the market for personal intercourse at this stage must not be undervalued, especially in lands where trading out- side the market is so unusual that even travellers wishing to buy something direct are regularly refused with the words " come to market." In this one is involuntarily re- minded of the prominent position that the market occu- pied in the social and political life of the peoples of classical antiquity. But it is always a very onesided development, permitting only to individual tribes the organization of production and trade just descriljed. In this way is to be explained that most extraordinary phenomenon that in the interior of continents where no difficulties in communication op- pose the passage of certain attainments in technical skill from tribe to tribe, it has been possible for jieoplcs of very primitive economic stamp to remain unchanged by the side of others of higher development throughout thousands of voars. One of the most remarkable exam- ples of this nature is ofTere<l in Central Africa by the pigmy race of the Batuas or Akkas. still standing at the stage of the lower nomads, which keeps strictiv within the zone of 72 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. the primitive forest, but on definite days appears at the market-places of the surrounding negro tribes to exchange its chief economic product, dried meat of animals killed in the hunt, for bananas, ground-nuts, maize, and the like. In fact in some parts even a more primitive form of trading has been maintained between these pigmy people and their neighbours, in that at the period when thd fruit is ripe the Batuas break into the fields of the negroes, steal bana- nas, tubers, and corn, and leave behind an equivalent in meat.3* The fact that the Batuas are clever hunters ap- pears here to have caused the neighbouring tribes to neg- lect the production of meat through hunting and cattle- raising. On the other hand it is said that the pigmies do not even make their own weapons, but procure them in trade from the Momsus and other tribes. Of this one-sided development another and much more wide-spread example is offered by the smiths, who not merely among many tribes of Africa but sporadically in Asia and in southeastern Europe form a hereditarily dis- tinct caste, whose members, whether regarded with bash- ful awe or contempt, can neither enter into a marital nor "Casati, Zehn Jahre in Aequatoria, I, p. 151. Schweinfurth, The Heart of Africa, II. pp. 83 ff. Dr. W. Junker's Travels in Africa, III, pp. 8s, 86. Wissmann, Wolf, etc., /m Intiern Afrikas, pp. 256, 258 ff. A. similar report is given by W. Geiger (Ceylon), Tagebuchbldttcr u. Reiseerittnerungen (Wiesbaden, 1897), of the Veddahs: "The method by which the Veddah is able to procure his arrow-points— which he does not make himself— is interesting. He betakes himself under cover of ni^ht to the dwelling of a Singhalese smith, and places in front of it a leaf t<) which the desired shape is given. To this he adds a present o^ some kind, wild honey, the skin of an animal, or some- thing similar. During one of the following nights he returns and expects to find the object ordered finished. If he is satisfied, he will deposit another special gift. The smiths never refuse to execute the orders at once. If they do. tluy may be certain at the next oppor- tunity to bo made the target f..^ :in arrow. Moreover their labour is abundantly rewarded by what t Veddah gives in return." THE ECONOMIC UFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 73 Other social alliance with the rest of the people." This strange phenomenon has hitherto been explained as a matter of remnants of subject tribes preserving to their conquerors the art of metal-working, which had other- wise perished, because the victorious race was ignorant of it. It is, however, also conceivable that a voluntary dis- persal of such tribes took place and that ti.e very differ- ence of nationality, coupled with the carrying on of an esoteric art, placed them wherever they settled outside the community of the people. In individual instances the carrying on of such a tribal industry in this exclusive manner leads to the rise of what travellers usually designate now as industrial peoples, be- cause they do work for all their neighbours; now as trading peoples, because one meets them in all the markets of a more extensive district, and because they monopolize the trade in certain wares. We have an instance of the former, when the consumers resort to the district where a special tribal industry flourishes, in order to get the desired wares at the seat of manufacture; of the latter, when the pro- ducers bring to the tribes lacking them such wares as they produce beyond their own requirements. As an example of the first form of this evolution, the little tribe of the Osakas may be cited, which has its home in the valley of the Ogowe to the east of the Lolo River. Lenz^* reports concerning it: " The Osakas are divided into five or six villages, each of which contains sixty to a hundred huts; compared with their numerically so im- portant neighbours, such as the Fans and the Oshebo- Adumas, they are thus destined to play an altogether passive role in the history of those countries. In spite of this, however, the Osakas appear to be not altogether in- " R. Andree. pp. 15,1 ff " Mittheil. d. gfogr Gesell. in Wien (i8r8), p. 476- 74 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMmVE PEOPLE. i m f I li « significant; for among them I found many individuals be- longing to the most widely different tribes, frequently from regions quite far distant. The Osakas are recognised as the best smiths, and all the surrounding tribes, — the Oshebo-Adumas, the Akelles, the Awanshis and even the Fans, — buy of them a great part of their implements for hunting and war, although the last-named tribe itself ex- cels at this handicraft. By the Oshebo-Adumas the iron wares of the Osakas are then brought down to the Okan- des and to the Apinshis and Okotas dwelhng between the rapids of the Ogowe, these last tribes on their part being but little skilled in iron-work and devoting themselves ex- clusively to the slave-trade. From there, through the me- dium of the Iningas and Galloas, weapons of this kind find their way as far as the sea-coast." " The Oshebo-Adumas generally pay for these weap- ons with palm-oil and ground-nuts, while the Fans, who are the most expert huntsmen of all these various tribes, give in exchange for the spears and swordlike knives dried and smoked meat, chiefly of the antelope, the* wild boar, the porcupine, the field rat and the monkey. In all the Osaka villages I saw a bustling life. As must always be the case where such widely diflferent tribes meet together, quarrelings were extremely frequent there and often as- sumed great proportions." A typical example of the second form is offered by the Kiocos and the Kanjocas in the southern part of the Congo basin. Of the latter Wissmann reports: ^^ "The Kanjoka country is particularly rich in iron, and there are some excellent smiths there. Salt also is produced, so that the Kanjokas, with the products of their countr>' and their iron manufacture, undertake commercial expeditions to the south as far as the Lunda country." The Kiocos dwell "My Second Journey through Equal. Africa (London, 1891), p. 105. 3 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMlTiyE PEOPLE. 75 in the kingdom of Lund itself, dispersed among the Ka- lundas, but have their own chiefs who are tributary to the Muata Yamwo. The Kiocos are partial to placing their villages in the woodland, for they are preeminently excel- lent hunters, gather gum from their forests, and to obtain wax carry on a species of wild-bee keeping. They are also clever smiths, and not only make good hatchets, but can also repair old flmtlocks and even fit them with new mounts and stocks. They clothe themselves in animal skins; the art of making vegetable cloths is little known to them. Their women plant chiefly manioc, maize, millet, ground- nuts, and beans. The products that the Kiocos obtain from the exploitation of their forests they exchange on the west coast for wares, chiefly powder, with which they then betake themselves into the far interior in order to buy ivory and slaves. The ivory obtained through trade they dispose of, while the slaves they procure they incorporate with their household. The Kiocos esteem slaves above all as property. They treat the slave women as they do their wives, and the men as members of the household, and part from them so very unwillingly that in the Kioco country it is quite exceptional for travellers to be offered slaves for sale. On their hunting voyages they have penetrated farthest towards the east; and there, before entering upon their journey homewards, they usually barter a part of their weapons for slaves. Then for the time being they arm themselves again with bow and arrow. They rightly enjoy the reputation of being as good hunters as they are crafty and unscrupulous traders; and in a masterful man- ner they understand how to overreach and dispossess the better-natured and more indolent Kalundas.^® This picture is often repeated in the negro countries. " Pogge, pp. 45, 46, 47, and Wissmann, Im Innern Afrikas, pp. 59, 62. Comp. also Schurtz, Afr. Cew., p. 50. MICROCOPY RiSOlUTION TiST CHAR) (ANSI and ISO TEST CHART No. 2) A /APPLIED IIVMGE Inc '653 foil Mom S<r««' Rochviltr. N»* York U609 USA (M6) 482 - 0300 - Pfion. ("6) 2M - i9«9 - To, 76 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. One readily sees that it does not adapt itself to any of the usual categories of economic history. The Kiocos are no hunting people, no nomads, no agriculturalists, no indus- trial and trading nation; they are all these at once. They act as intermediaries for a part of the trade with the Euro- pean factories on the coast. At the same time they carry on some mediary traffic of their own in which they dis- play the peculiar aptitude of the negro for barter, but nevertheless gain most of their living directly from hunt- ing and agriculture. Both forms of development are met with in the two pot- tery islands of New Guinea, Bilibi and Chas. The manu- facture is in both places in the hands of the women. The natives of the islands round about, and even of the more distant ones, come to Chas to barter their products for the earthenware; in Bilibi the men take whole boatloads to sell along the coast. Every woman makes a special mark on the pottery she produces; but whether with one European observer we are to regard this as a trade-mark seems very doubtful^*" In order to leave untouched no important part of the economic life of primitive peoples, let us take a rapid glance at their commercial contrivances and public adminis- tration. Both are intimately connected. For commerce is essentially a public matter; there are no private commer- cial arrangements whatever amoi..; these peoples. Indeed one can claim frankly that at this stage trade scarcely dis- plays an economic character at all. In the first place as concerns commercial routes, there are overland trade routes only when they have been tramped by the foot of man; the only artificial structures to facilitate land trade are primitive bridges, often consist- •*Comp Finsch, pp. 8i, 8.?, 281, 28-!: Scmon, In the Austral. Bush. pp. 317 fF. Similar pottery districts in Africa proven by Schurtz, p. S4 r THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITH^E PEOPLE. 77 ing merely of a single tree-trunk, or ferries at river fords, for the use of which the traveller has to pay a tax to the village chief. These dues as a rule open the door to heavy extortions.^^ On the other hand the natural waterways are everywhere diligently used, and there is hardly a prim- itive people that has not been led through its situation by the sea or on a river to the use of some peculiar kind of craft. The enumeration and description of these means of transportation would fill a volume; from the dugout and skin canoe of the Indians to the artistically carved rowboats and sailboats of the South Sea Islanders, all types are represented. On the whole, however, the tech- nique of boat-building and navigation has remained unde- veloped among these peoples; none of their vessels de- serv'e the name of ship in the proper sense. Thus their importance is everywhere restricted to personal transporta- tion and fishing, while nowhere has the development reached a freight transportation of any extent. Curiously among primitive peoples that branch of com- mercial communication has enjoyed the fullest develop- ment which we would naturally associate only with the highest culture, namelv. the communication of news. It forms indeed the sole kind of trade for which primitive peoples have created permanent organizations. We refer to the courier service and the contrivances for sending verbal messages. The despatching of couriers and embassies to neighbour- ing tribes in war and peace leads, even at a very low stage of culture, to the development of a complete system of symbolic signs and means of conveying intelligence.'" Thus among the rude tribes in the interior of Australia "Comp. Pogge. pp. 64. 70, 78, 95, 97, IIS, 169; Wissmann. Untcr dfutsck. Flaggc. pp. .^43, 361. 364, 394; and Second Journey, p. 71. "Comp. generally R. Andree, " Merkzeichen u. Knotenschrift " in his Ethnogr Parallel, pp. 184 ff.: Waitz. IV. p. 80. 78 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. Ill various kinds of body-painting, of head-dress and other conventional signs serve to apprise a neighbouring tribe of the occurrence of a death, of the holding of a feast, and of a threatening danger, or to summon the tribesmen tci- gether for any purpose.^* Among the aborigines of South America ingeniously knotted cords or leather strips (quippits), and among the North Americans the well- known wampum perform s'milar offices;*" in Africa cou- rier-staflFs with or without engraved signs are customary, and the same are found among the Malays and Poly- nesians. If need be, the couriers have to learn their mes- sage by heart and communicate it verbally.** In the negro kingdoms, where the administrative power of the ruler reaches only as far as he is able personally to intervene,*'' the couriers of the chiefs hold a very important position; for through them the sovereign chief is as if omnipresent, and new occurrences come to his knowledge with surpris- ing rapidity. But even for the communication of intelli- gence among members of the same tribe — for instance, in hunting and in war — a system of symbols exists which is often very ingeniously conceived, and which, as a rule, is hidden from the uninitiated. Not less remarkable are the telephonic contrivances rest- ing upon the ingenious employment of the drum, the "Details in Journ. of Anthropol. In^t.. XX, pp. "i ff. " Martius, pp. 98, 99, 694; Waitz, III, pp. 138 ff. On knot writing in West Africa: Bastian, Die Exp. «. d. Loango-Kustc, I, p. 181. *' Livingstone, p. 285. Comp. also the apt description by Casalis, Let Bassoulos, pp. 2.^, .235: " Ces niessagcrs sont gen ralement doues dune memoire prodigieuse, ct Ton peut s'attendre a ce qu'ils trans- mcttcnt tcxtucllcmcnt les depeches orales, dont ils se chargent." "This applies also to the political conditions of semi-civilization. G. Rohlfs, Land u. Volk in Afrika, p. 163: "The Abyssinian is accui- tomed to obey only when his master is near. Once out of reach of his voice little does he trouble himself about orders. This is the case in all half-civilized countries. To this Turkey, Morocco, Egypt, and Bornoo bear witness." THE ECONOMIC UFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 79 musical instrument in widest use among primitive peoples. In one sense they take the form of a developed signal- system, as among the East Indians** and the Melane- sians,*^ in another there is a real speaking of words by which detailed conversations can be carried on at great distances. The latter is very common in Africa.** As a rule only the chiefs and their relations are acquainted with this drum language; and the possession of the instrument used for this purpose is a mark of rank, like the crown and sceptre in civilized countries. Less extended is the em- ployment of fire-signs for summoning the tribe or com- municating news.*° There is no public economy, in our sense of the word. True, where their power is to some extent established, ♦he chiefs receive all kinds of dues in the form of shares, tra- ditionally fixed, in the products of the chase and of hus- bandry, fees for the use of bridges, ferries, market-place. In more extensive kingdoms the subordinate chieftains are bound to send tribute.*® But all this is more or less mani- festly clothed in the form of gift, for which the chief has to bestow a return present even if this consist only in the entertainment that he bestows upon the bearer. Even with the market-fees, which are payable by the sellers to the owner of the market-place, in the Congo district a "Martius, p. 65. For a remarkable telephonic contrivance of the Catuquinaru Indians, see .^rchiv f. Post u. Telegraphie (1899), pp. 87. 88. "Parkinson, p. 127, comp. pp. ~2. 121; Finsch, p. 68. Likewise in Africa: Schweinfurth, I, pp. 64, ago, 291. " Described in ^r^'ater detail by M. Buchner, Kaincrun. pp. 37, 38; Wissmann, Im Inncrn Afrikas, pp. 4, 228, 232; Betz in Mitthcil. aus d. dcutsch Schutcgcbkti-it. XI (1898), pp. 1-86; Wissmann. I'ntcr dculsch. rioRge, P- 215; Stanley, Through the Dark Continent. II, pp. 264, 279; Livingstone, p. 93. For a .signal-whistlinj? languaRC in Timor, sec Jacobsen, Reise in d. Inschcelt d. Buitda-Meers. p. 262. "Comp., for example. Petermanns Mittheil.. XXI (1875). p. 381. "Details in Post, Afr. Jurisprudens, I, pp. 261 flE. II 80 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITiyE PEOPLE. return service is rendered in that the chief performs a dance in front, and to the deHght, of those using the mar- ket. Of special interest to us are the presents that trav- ellers en route have to pay to the village chiefs whose territories they traverse, since from such payments our customs duty has sprung. Not less important is it to notice that in the larger kingdoms the tribute of the subject tribes consists of those products which are peculiar to each tribe, and which are usually marketed by it. In the Lunda country, for instance, some districts bring ivory or skins, others salt or copper; from the northern parts come plaited goods of straw, and from the subordinate chiefs nearer the coast at times even powder and European cot- ton stuffs.*^ Not infrequently has this led such sovereign chiefs to carry on a trade in these products, which accumu- late in large quantities in their hands, or to claim a monop- oly in them. The saying that makes the kings the greatest merchants thus gains a deeper significance. In general the financial prerogatives of the chiefs are limited only by their natural strength; and the wealth of the subject is without the protection that the civilized State assures to it by law. The expeditions sent out by the negro kings to collect the tribute and taxes degen- erate only too often into robber raids. The claim of the kings to fines frequently reduces the administration of justice to an institution for extortion, and the system of gifts, which prevails in all relationships of a public char- acter, too rapidly passes into a veritable system of bribery. This must naturally react injuriously upon private in- dustry. In the condition of constant feud in which the smaller tribes live with their neighbours under the arbi- " Pogge, pp. 226, 227. Comp. Wissmann, Im Inncrn Afrikas, pp. 171, 172, 202, 249, 267, 286, 289, .^08; Vnter deutsch. Flagge, pp. 95. 332, 339. The same is true of the Marutse country north of the Zambesi: E. Holub. Sieben Jakrc in Siidafrika. II. u-p. 173. 187. 253. 254, 257. 268. 271. II > THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 8i trary rule which in the interior usually accompanies the formation of larger states, most primitive peoples stand in peril of life and property. Through long habit this danger becomes endurable, yet economic advancement must as- suredly be retarded by it. The obligation to make pres- ents ever and everywhere, the custom of regarding food almost as free goods, leave but insufficient room for self- interest. An English writer makes the remark — from the standpoint of European life certainly not inaccurate — that this sharing-up, rendered necessary by custom, encourages the people in gluttony, since only that is safe which they have succeeded in stuffing into their bellies; it also pre- vents rational provision for the future, because it is diffi- cult to keep on hand supplies of any kind.^^ Assuredly with some reason have the begging proclivities and the " tendency to steal," which is said to animate many prim- itive peoples in dealing with Europeans, been associated with the custom of gifts and the insufficient distinction of " mine and thine." *® The immoderate use of alcoholic drinks is likewise a consequence of their slight forethought for their own welfare. If, however, the attempt is made to appreciate all these things apart from the conditions of cul- ture in which they arise, one readily recognises that they lie " beyond the bounds of good and evil," and that what appears from the standpoint of the modern Englishman as vice has concealed within it the beautiful virtues of dis- interestedness, benevolence, and generosity. For many who to-day pose as the bearers of civilization to their black and brown fellow men primitive man is the quintessence of all economic vices: lazy, disorderly, care- less, prodigal, untrustworthy, avaricious, thievish, heart- "Tindall, in Fritsch, p. 351; comp. p. 362. Waitz, II, p. 402; III, p. 80. "Comp. Waitz, III, pp. 163 flf. 8a THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. >1 J' 'f I .'"'4 1 ■ ;']• ii I — : less, and self-indulgent. It is true that primitive man lives only for the present, that he shuns all regular work, that he has not the conception of duty, nor of a vocation as a moral function in life. But it is not less true that with his wretched implements he accomplishes an amount of work that must excite our admiration, whether we contemplate with our own eyes the neat fruit-fields of the women or view in our museums the weapons and implements of the men, the products of infinite toil. Above all, his manner of working assures to primitive man a measure of enjoy- ment in life and a perpetual cheerfulness which the Euro- pean, worried with work and oppressed with care, must envy him. If since their acquaintance with European civilization so many primitive peoples have retrograded and some even become extinct, the cause lies, according to the view of those best acquainted with the matter, chiefly in the disturbing influence which our industrial methods and technique have exerted upon them. We carried into their childlike existence the nervous unrest of our commercial life, the hurried hunt for gain, our destructive pleasures, our religious wrangles and animosities. Our perfected im- plements relieved them suddenly of an immense burden of labour. What they had accomplished with their stone hatchets in months they performed with the iron one in a few hours; and a few muskets replaced in effectiveness hundreds of bows and arrows. Therewith fell away the beneficent tension in which the old method of work had continuously kept the body and mind of primitive man, particularly as the character of his needs remained at the same low level. Under these conditions has he gone to ruin, just as the plant that thrives in iu-. shade withers away when exposed to the glare of the noon-day sun. CHAPTER III. THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. Everyone knows that the modern man's way of satisfy- ing his numerous wants is subject to continual change. Many arrangements and contrivances that we find neces- sary were unknown to our grandparents; and our g^rand- children will find inadequate much that perhaps only a short time ago aroused our admiration. All those arrangements, contrivances, and processes called forth to satisfy a people's wants constitute national economy. National economy falls again into numerous individual economies united together by trade and depend- ent upon one another in many ways; for each undertakes certain duties for all the others, and leaves certain duties to each of them. As the outcome of auch a development, national econ- omy is a product of all past civilization; it is just as subject to change as every separate economy, whether private or public, and whether directly ministering to the wants of a larger or a smaller number of people. Furthermore, every phenomenon of national economy is aj)henomenon in the gygJ^Jj^lP" of. civilization. In scientifically defining it and in explaining the laws of its development we must always bear in mind that its essential features and its dynamic laws are not absolute in character; or, in other words, that they do not hold good for all periods and states of civ- ilization. 8s I* m 84 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. The first task, then, which national economy presents to science is to determine and explain the facts. But it must not be content with a merely dynamic treatment of economic processes; it must also seek to deduce their origin. A full understanding of any given group of facts in the history of a civilized people requires that we know how the facts arose. We shall, therefore, not escape the task of investigating the phases of development through which the economic activity of civilized peoples passed be- fore it assumed the form of the national economy of to- day, and the modifications undergone by each separate economic phenomenon during the process. The material for this second part of the task can be drawn only from the economic history of the civilized peoples of Europe; for these alone present a line of development which historical investigation has adequately disclosed, and which has not been deflected in its course by violent disturbances from without ; though, to be sure, this upward development has not always been without interruption or recoil. The first question for the political economist who seeks to understand the economic life of a people at a time long since past is this: Is this economy national economy; and are its phenomena substantially similar to those of our modern commercial world, or are the two essentially dif- ferent? An answer to this question can be had only if we do not disdain investigating the economic phenomena of the past by the same methods of analysis and deduction from intellectually isolated cases which have given such splendid results to the masters of the old " abstract " po- litical economy when applied to the economic life of tne present. The Modern " historical " school can hardly escape the reproach that, instead of penetrating into the life of earlier economic periods by investigations of this character, they THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 85 have almost unwittingly applied to past times the current classifications of modern national economy; or that they have kneaded away so long at conceptions of commercial life that these perforce appear applicable to all economic periods. In so doing they have without doubt greatly ob- structed the path to a scientific mastery of those historical phenomena. The material for economic history, which has been brought to light in such gteat quantities, has for this reason largely remamed an unprofitable treasure still awaiting scientific utilization. Nowhere is this more plainly evident than in the manner in which they characterize the differences between the present economic methods of civilized nations and the eco- nomic life of past epochs, or of peoples low in the scale of civilization. This they do by setting up so-called stages^ of development, with generic designations made to embrace the whole course of economic evolution. The institution of such " economic stages " is from the point of method indispensable. It is indeed only in this way that economic theory can turn to account the results of the investigations of economic history. But these stages of development are not to be confoimded with the time-periods of the historian. The stfrin- must not forget to relate in any period everytlv that occurred in it. while for his stages the theon i need notice only the normal, simply ignoring the cidental. In treating of the gradual transformation, f quently extending over centuries, which all economic } nomena and institutions undergo, his only object can to comprehend the whole development in its chief pliase^. while the so-called transition-periods, in which all phenom- ena are in a state of flux, must, for the time, be dis- regarded. By this means alone is it possible to discover I* 86 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. the fundamental features, or, let us say it boldly, the laws of development. All early attempts of this class suffer from the defect of not reaching the essentials, and touching only the surface. The best known series of stages is that originated by Frederick List, based upon the chief direction taken by production. It distinguishes five successive periods which the peoples of the temperate zone are supposed to have passed through before they attained their present economic condition, namely: (i) the period of nomadic life; (2) the period of pastoral life; (3) the period of agriculture; (4) the period of combined agriculture and manufacture; and (S) the period of agriculture, manufacture, and commerce. Another series evolved by Bntno Hi'Jcbrand, which makes the condition of exchange the distinguishing char- acteristic, comes somewhat closer to the root of the mat- ter. It assumes three stages of development: period of barter; period of monev; and period of credit. Both, however, take lor granted that as far back as his- tory reaches, with the sole exception of the '" primitive state," there has existed a national economy based upon exchange of goods, though at different periods the forms of production and exchange have varied. They have no doubt whatever that the fundamental features of economic life have always been essentially similar. Theit sole aim is to show that the various public regulations of trade in former times found their justitication in the changing char- acter of production or exchange, and thai likewise in the present different conditions demand different regulations. The most recent coherent presentations of economic theory that have proceeded from the members of the his- torical school remain content with this conception, al- though in reality it stands upon a scarcely higher plane THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. ^1 than the favourite historical creations of abstract English economics.' This we will endeavour briefly to prove. The condition of society uf>on which Adam Smith and Ricardo founded the earlier theory is that of a commercial Organization Jbased upon division of labour; or let us TatTier say simply, of national economy in the real sense of the term. It is that condition in which each individual does not produce the goods that he needs, but those which in his opinion others need, in order to obtain by way of trade the manifold things that he himself requires; or, in a word, the condition in which the cooperation of many or of all is necessary in order to provide for the individual. English political economy is thus in its essence a theory of exchange. The phenomena and laws of the division of labour, of capital, of price, of wages, of rent, and of profits on capital, form its chief field of investigation. The whole theory of production and especially of consumption re- ceives verj- inadequate treatment. All attention is centred upon the circulation of goods, in which term their distri- bution is included. That there may one* have existed a condition of society in which exchange was unknown does not occur to them; where their system makes such a view necessary they have recourse to the Robinson Crusoe fiction so much ridiculed by later WTiters. Usually, however, they deduce the most involved processes of exchange directly from the primitive state.^ Adam Smith supposes that man is born with a ' [Regarding the omission from special mention of Schmoller's ter- ritorial series: village, town, territory, and State, we may refer to Professor Schmoller's review of the first German edition and Profes- sor Bticher's reply in Jhb. f. Gesetzpeb.. etc.. XVII and XVIII (1893- 94). See also Schmoller, Grundris: d. I'Ms'iVirtscluiftslehrc, I (Leipzig, igoo"). — Ed.] 'The same is true also of the Physiocrats. Comp. Turgot. Reflexions, J§2ff. 88 THE RISE OF NATlON/tL ECONOMY. in natural instinct for trade, and considers the division of labour itself as but a result of it.^ Ricardo in several places treats the hunter and the fisher of primitive times as if they were two capitalistic entrepreneurs. He represents them as paying wages and making profits; he discusses the rise and fall of the cost, and the price, of their products. Tliii- nen, to mention also a prominent German of this school, in constructing his isolated State starts with the assumption of a commercial organization. Even the most distant region, which has not yet reached the agricultural stage, prosecutes its labours with the single end of selling its products in the metropolir, city. How widely such theoretical constructions vary from the actual economic conditions of primitive peoples must long ago have been patent in historical and ethnographical investigators had not the\ themselves been in the grasp of modern commercial ideas which they transferred to the past. A thorough-going study, which will sufficiently em- brace the conditions of life in the past, and not measure its phenomena by the standards of the present, must lead to this conclusion: National economy is the product of a dei'cl- opmcnt extending over thousands of years, and is not older thai! the modern State; for long epochs before it emerged man lived and laboured icithout any system of trade or under forms of exchange of products and services that cannot be designated national economy. If we are to gain a survey of this whole development, it can only be from a standpoint that afYords a direct view of the essential phenomena of national e-onomy, and at the same time discloses the organizing c'ement of the earlier economic i)erifx!s. This standpoint is none other than the relation which exists between the production and •Book I. Chap. 3. THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 89 the consumption of goods; or, to be more exact, the length of the route which the goods traverse in passing from pro- ducer to consumer. From this point of view we are able to divide the whole course of economic development, at least for the peoples of central and western Europe, where it may be historically traced with sufficient accuracy, into three stages: (i; The stage of independent domestic economy (produc- tion solely for one's own needs, absence of exchange), at which the goods are consumed where they are produced. (2) The stage of totvn economy (custom production, the stage of direct exchange), at which the goods pass directly from the producer to the consumer. (3) The stage of national economy (wholesale production, the stage of the circulation of goods), at which the goods must ordinarily pass through many hands before they reach the consumer. We will endeavour to define these three economic stages more precisely by seeking a true conception of the typical features of each without allowing ourselves to be misled by the casual appearance of transitional forms or particu- lar phenomena which, as relics of earlier or precursors of later conditions, project into any period, and whose exist- ence may perhaps be historically proved. In this way alone shall wc be able to understaiul clearly the funda- mental distinctions between the throe periods and the phe- nomena peculiar to each. The stage of independent domestic economy, as has already been pointed out, is characterized by restriction of the whole course of economic activity from production to con- sumption to the exclusive circle of the household (the family, the clan). The character and extent of the produc- tion of every household arc prescribed by the wants of its members as consumers. Every product passes through 9° THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. the whole process of its manufacture, from the procur- ing of the raw material to its final elaboration in the same domestic establishment, and reaches the consumer with- out any intermediary. Production and consumption are here inseparably interdependent: they form a single uninterrupted and indistinguishable process; and it is as impossible to differentiate them as to separate acquisitive and domestic activity from each other. The earnings of each communal group are one with the product of their labour, and this, again, one with the goods going to sat- isfy their wants, that is, with their consumption. Exchange was originally entirely unknown. Primitive man, far from possessing a natural instinct for trading, shows on the contrar)- an aversion to it. Exchange (tauschcn) and deceive (taiisclien) are in the older tongue one and the same word.* Thero is no universally recog- nised measure of value. Hence everyone must fear being duped in the bartering. Moreover, the product of labour is. as it were, a part of the person producing it. The man who transfers it to another alienates a part of his being and subjects himself to the evil powers. Far down into the Middle Ages exchange is protected by publicity, com- pletion before witnesses, and the use of symbolic forms. An autonomous economy of this kind is in the first place dependent upon the land under it^ control. Whether the chief as hunter or fisher appropriates the gifts voluntarilv offered by nature, whether he wanders as a nomad with his herds, whether he cultivates the soil as well, or even sup- ports himself by agriculture alone, his daily labour and care will be shaped in every case by the bit of land that he has brought under cultivation. The greater his advance * tCotnp also the e.irly signification of our words barter, truck, etc. New Oxford Diet.— Ed.] THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 91 in intelligence and technical skill, and the more method- ical and varied the satisfaction of his wants, so much the greater does this dependence become, until finally the soil brings into subjection the man who is bom to rule over it. This has been designated villenagc* We may here confine ourselves to proving that a' this stage the man who has direct possession of the soil can alone maintain economic independence. He who is not in this position can eke out his existence only by becoming the servant of the land- owner, and, as such, bound to the soil. In the independent domestic economy the members of the household have not merely to gather from the soil its products, but they must also by iheir labour produce all the necessary tools and implements, and, finally, work up and transform the new products and make them fit for use. All this leads to a diversity of employments, and, because of the primitive nature of the tools, demands a varied dex- terity and intelligence of which modern civilized man can scarcely form a proper conception.' The extent of the tasks * Verdinglichung. 'We must turn to descriptions of early peasant life in remote parts of Europe in order to gain a conception of such conditions. Comp. one example in H. F. Tiebe, Lief- u. Esthlands Ehrenrettung (Halle, 1804), p. icx>. Similar instances are met with still among the Coreans. Thus we read in M. A. Pogio, Korea (Vienna and Leipzig, 1895), p. 222: "Throughout Corea the real necessaries of life have been pro- duced within the household from time immemorial. Tlie wife and daughters spin not only hemp but silk. For the latter a silk-bee is usual in many houses. The head of the family must be ready for all tasks, and on occasion play the painter, stone-mason, or joiner. The production of spirits, vegetable fats, and colours, and the manufacture ot straw mats, hats, baskets, wooden shoes, and field iniplcmonts be- longs to domestic work. In a word, every one labours for himself and his own reiiuircments. Tli<inks to these conditions the Corean is .1 Jack of all trades who rndcrtakcs work only for the things that are In- dispens.-ible. and accordingly never becomes skilled in any special de- partment. 93 THE RISE OF N/1TIONj4L ECONOMY. falling to the various members of this autonomous house- hold community can be lessened only by division of labour and cooperation among themselves according to age and sex, or accori t. • to the strength and natural aptitudes of the individual, it is to this circumstance that we must ascribe that sharp division of domestic production accord- ing to sex, which we find universal among primitive peo- ples. On the other hand, owing to the unproductiveness of early methods of work the simultaneous cooperation of many individuals was in numerous instances necessary to the accomplishment of certain economic ends. Labour in common still plays, therefore, at this stage, a more im- portant role than division of labour. To neither, however, would the family have been able to give much scope had it been organized like our modern family, that is. limited to father and mother with children and possibly servant?. It wouKl also have had very little stability or capacity tor development if each individual in the family had been free to lead the independent existence of the present day. Signifioaiu is it then that when the present civilized na- tions of Europe appear on the horizon of history, the tribal constitution prevails among them.* The tribes (families, genres, clans, hous'.^ communities) arc moder- ately large groups consisiins;: of several generations of blood-relations, which, at t'lrst organized according to ma- ternal and later according to paternal succession, have common ownership of the soil, maintain a oommdu house- hold, and constitute a union for nnuual protection. Evtrv tribe is thus compnse<l of several smaller groups of rela- Conip, on tin- p.vint Fu-tel dc CouI.Tniio?. / i i l\\rx<. L.-v< /.I Prcfrii-ti- (4tli edition. rar:>. i8<)0: lS<'>4l: Hniilc ^h K. Grox-e. PiV ■■ r„-,-K ,i /,;ii;:7;i- u. d. [\'rmt-n d H'lrths.h^ift ( Leip.'is. iS'JO). e^T.cia'.v C\\?.n V!!I. THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 93 tives, each of which is formed of a man and wife with their children. Anyone living outside this tribe is an out- law; he has no legal or economic existence, no help in time of need, no avenger if he is slain, no funeral escort when he passes to his last rest.^ All the peoples in question, when they took up fixed abodes, were acquainted with the use of the plough. Their settlement came about usually by the establishment of large common dwelling-houses, farms, and villages by the n-.embers of a tribe. Once in secure possession of the land the sense of community soon weakened. Smaller patri- archal households with a limited number of members, such as are represented at the present day by the zadrngas of the south Slavs, and by the great family of the Russians, Caucasians, and Hindoos, separated from the larger unit. But for centuries the village house-communities continued to own the soil in common, and jointly tilled it probably for some time longer, while each household enjoyed the products apart. In large family groups of this kind, community and divi- sion of bbour may be carried out to a considerable extent. Men and women, mothers and children, fathers and grand- fathers — to each group is allotted its particular part in pro- duction and domestic work, and wherever special individ- ual skill displays itself, it finds scope and also a limit, in •C(imp. M. Buclinor. Kamerun. p. i88: "It i? a fund.imental point in the lejjal ontici'ptions of the noiirdes. that not tlic man him>ch' but the community, '.ho f.imily. the whole body of relative* is tlie int' id- tnl before the law. Within the community riKht? and duties are tran-fer:;Me to an a!mo~t '.m'iniiied extent. .\ debtor, a criminal, can be pimi-hed in tlie member- of liis community, and the liabihty of the corTuinitv f -■" 'be crime of one born a member of it does not lapse even with emigration or -epar.itim from it. Even the death- penalty can W executed upon • .ne other than the guilty." The same thing is found am.^ng t!ie South Sea Islanders. Sec Fat.i'nson. Im Bisniarik-.-itihipii. p^i. 50-i. f 1 94 THE RISE OF NATlONy4L ECONOMY. working for its own tribe. The feelings of brotherhood, of filial obedience, of respect for zgt, of loyalty and defer- ence reach their most beautiful development in such a community. Just as the tribe pays a debt or weregild for the individual or avenges a wrong done him, so on the other hand does the individual devote his whole life to the tribe and on its behalf subdue every impulse to independ- ent action. And even when the strength of these feelings declines, the modern separate family with its independent organiza- tion does not immediately spring into existence. For its appearance would inevitably have resulted in a diminished capacity for work, an abandonment of the autonomous life of the household, and perhaps a relapse into barbarism. Two ways there were of avoiding this. One was as follows: for such tasks as surpassed the pow- ers of the now diminished family, the original large tribal unions were continued as local organizations. These formed partial communities on the basis of common prop- erty and common usufruct of the same; but. when occa- sion demanded, they could also undertake duties which, if left to the care of each individual household, would have demanded an unpi ..".table expenditure of energy, as, for example, guarding the fields and tending cattle. There were also tasks which, though not of equal concern to each separate household of the local group, were never- theless too difficult for the individual. A house or a ship was to be built, a forest clearing made, a stream diverted, hunting or fishing engaged in at a distance; or perhaps the season of the year made some unusual work neces- sar>' for this or that house. In all such cases hidden- labour assisted; *» that is, among neighbours there sprang • Comp. Arbeit u. Rkylhmus (2d ed). pp. 198 ff. [and Ch. VII. be- low. — Ed.] THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 95 Up, on invitation of the head of the family, temporary labour communities which disappeared again on the completion of their work. Many institutions of this kind underwent subse- quent transformation, others perpetuated themselves. We would recall the labour communities of the Slavic tribes, the artel of the Russians, the tschcta or driisina of the Bul- garians, the moba of the Serbs, the voluntary assistance rendered by our peasants to each other in house-raising, sheep-shearing, flax-pulling, etc. Whatever the extent of such contrivances, the part they can play in the supplying of needs is comparatively un- important, and just as little prejudices the economic auton- omy of the individual household as the home production subsisting among our agrarian landlords to-day affects the supremacy of commerce. These temporary labour com- munities, moreover, are not business enterprises, but only expedients for satisfying immediate want^. Assistance is rendered now to one. now to another of the participants; or the product of the joint labour is distributed to the sep- arate families for their consumption. A definite case of bargain and sale will be sought for in vain, even where, as in the village community of India, we have a number of professional labourers performing communal functions similar to those of our village shepherds. They work for all and are in return maintained by all. The second method of avoiding the disadvantages aris- ing from the dissolution of the tribal communities con- sisted in the artificial extension, or numerical maintenance of the family circle. This was done by the adoption and incorporation of foreign (non-consangi inous) elements. Tims arose slavery and serfdom. We may leave undecided the question whether the en- slavemciu and setting to work of a captured enemy were more the cause or the result of the dissolution of the early 11 j 96 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. tribal community. It is certain that a means was thereby found of maintaining intact the independent household economy with its accustomed division of labour, and at the same time of making progress towards an increase in the number and variety of wants. For now the more numer- ous the slaves or villeins belonging to the household, the more completely could its labour be united or divided. In agriculture larger areas could be cultivated. Particular technical employments, such as grinding com, baking, spinning, weaving, making implements, or tending csttle, could be assigned to particular slaves for their whole life; they could be specially trained for this service. The more prominent the family, the more wealthy the lord, or the more extensive his husbandry, all the more possible was it to develop in variety and extent the technical skill employed in the procuring and working up of materials. The economic life of the Greeks, the Carthaginians, and the Romans was of this character.'' Rodbcrtus, who noticed ' For students of political economy it need scarcely be observed that in what follows the object is not to furnish a compendium of the economic history of ancient times, but, as the context shows, merely an outline of the most highly developed domestic economy as it presents itself in the system of slave labour among the ancients. In my work on the insurrections of the unfree labourers between 143 and 129 B.C. (Die Aufstdnde d. unfreien Arbeiter, 143-129 v. Chr„ Fr.-a.-M., 1874). I have shown that before the rise of slave-work on a large scale the economic life of antiquity furnished considerable scope for free labour, the formation of separate trades, and the exchange of goods. What progress had been made in the development of an in- dependent industry, I have set forth in the article " Industry " iGnverbe) in the Handwi'.rterbuch der Staatsw., Ill, pp. 926-7, 929- 931; and in my articles on the Edict of Diocletian on tax prices (Ztschr. f. d. gcs. Staatsw.. 1894, pp. 200-1) I have endeavoured to fix the position filled by trade in the system of independent domestic ecoromy at the time of the empire in Rome. Reference may also be mace, for an outline picture of the times, to the interesting address of M. Weber on Die sosialen Griinde d. Unter gangs d. antiken Cultur, Die Wahrhcit, VI, No. 3. !.r. THE RISE OF N/tTlONylL ECONOMY. 97 this a generation ago, designates it oikos husbandry, be- cause the oiWos, the house, represents the unit of the ero- nomic system. The oiKoi is not merely the dwelHng-place, but also the body of people carrying on their husbandry in common. Those belonging to them are the oiteirat, a word which, in its historic usage, it is significant to note, is confined to the household slaves upon whom the whole burden of the work of the house at that time rested. A similar meaning is attached to the Roman familia, the whole body of famuli, house-slaves, servants. The pater- familias is the slave-master into whose hands flows the whole revenue of the estate; in the patria potcstas the two conceptions of the power of the lord as husband and father and as slave-owner have been blended. A member of the household labours not for himself, but only for the pater- familias, who wields the same power of life and death over all. In the supreme power of the Roman paterfamilias, ex- tending as it did equally over all members of the house- hold, whether blood-relatives or not, the independent do- mestic economy was much more closely integrated and rendered capable of much greater productivity than the matriarchal or even the earlier patriarchal tribe, which consisted solely of blood-relatives. The individual as a separate entity has entirely disappeared; the State and the law recognise only family communities, groups of per- sons, and thus regulate the relations of family to family, not of individual to individual. As to what happens within the household they do not trouble themselves. In the economic autonomy of the slave-owning family lies the explanation of all the social and a great part of the political history of Rome. There are no separate classes of producers, as such, no farmers, no artisans. There are only large and small proprietors, rich and poor. If the 98 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. rich man wrests from the poor possession of the soil, he makes him a proletarian. The landless freeman is practically incapable of making a living. For there is no business capital to provide wages for the purchase of labour; there is no industry outside the exclusive circle of the household. The artificers of the early records are not freemen engaged in industry, but artisan slaves who receive from the hands of the agricultural and pastoral slaves the corn, wool, or wood which are to be transformed into bread, clothing, or implements. " Do not imagine that he buys anything," we read in Petronius of the rich novus homo, " everything is produced at his own house." ■ Hence that colossal development of latifundia, and, con- centrated in the hands of individual proprietors, those end- less companies of slaves amongst whom the subdivision of labour was so multiplex that their productions and ser- vices were capable of satisfying the most pampered taste. The Dutchman, T. Popma, who in the seventeenth cen- tury wrote an able book on the occupations of the Roman slaves, enumerates one hundred and forty-six different designations for the functions of these slave labourers of *Sat. 38: "Nee est quod putes ilium quicquam emere; omnia domi nascuntur." E. Meyer translates that, " everything is grown on his own land"! Now the satirist specifies wool, way (?), pepper, sheep, honey, mushrooms, mules, and cushions with covers of purple or scar- let. Do all of these things grow from the soil? Compare also Petro- nius, ch. 48, 52, and 53: "nam et comcedos emeram," etc. That this is all greatly exaggerated it is unnecessary to remind anyone who has really read Petronius. Ch. 50 speaks of the purchase of Corinthian jars, ch. 70 of knives made of Noric iron bought in Rome; ch. 76 of the shops of Trimalchio, who himself gives as his motto the words bene emo, bene vendo. But for a satirtist to venture such .in exaggera- tion as Petronius in ch. 38 would have been impossible if Roman eco- nomic life had been similar to that of to-d;iy. A modern satirist in a similar case would have made his boaster give the values of his hor^e^. v.ins'-s, cipar=, his stocks, etc. THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 99 the wealthy Roman households.' This number might to- day be considerably increased from inscriptions. One must go minutely into the details of this refined subdivi- sion of labour in order to understand the extent and pro- ductive power of those gigantic household establishments that placed at the free disposal of the owner goods and services such as to-day can be supplied only by the numer- ous business establishments of a metropolitan city in con- junction with the institutions of municipality and State. At the same time this extensive property in human beings afforded a means for the amassing of fortunes equalled only by the gigantic possessions of modern millionaires. The whole body of slaves in the house of a wealthy Roman was divided into two main groups, the familia rustica and the 'Mnilia urbana. The familia rustica en- gages in the Wo 'f production. On every large country estate there are a nanager and an assistant m-'nager with a staff of overseers and taskmasters who in tu. e un- der them a considerable company of field-labouiv and vine-dressers, shepherds and teni'ers of cattle, kitchen and house servants, women spinners, male and female weavers, fullers, tailors, carpenters, joiners, smiths, workers in metal and in the occupations connected with agriculture. On the larger estates each group of labourers is again divided into bands of ten each (decuricr) in charge of a leider or driver (dccurio. moniior)}° The familia urbatia is divided into the admi. ..strative staff, and the staff for the service of master and mistress within and without the house. First comes the superin- tendent of the revenue with his treasurer, bookkeepers, •Titi Popmse Phrysii de operis servorum liber. Editio novisstma. Atnstelodami 1672. '"Comp. the graphic account of work on a Roman estate during the empire, by M, Weber, Die Wahrheit, VI, pp. 65, 66. lOO THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. supervisors of rents, buyers, etc. If the proprietor takes over public leases or engages in the shipping trade, he keeps for that purpose a special staff of slave officials and labourers. Attached to the internal service of the house are house-administrator, porters, attendants in rooms and halls, guardians of the furniture, the plate, and the robes; the commissariat is in charge of the steward, the cellar- master, and the superintendent of supplies; the kitchen swarms with a great company of cooks, stokers, bakers of bread, cakes, and pastry; special table-setters, carvers, tasters, and butlers serve at the table, while a company of beautiful boys, dancing-girls, dwarfs and jesters amuse the guests. To the personal service of the proprietor are as- signed a master of ceremonies for introducing visitors, various valets, bath attendants, anointers, rubbers, sur- geons, physicians for almost every part of the body, barbers, readers, private secretaries, etc. For service in the household a savant or philosopher is kept, also archi- tects, painters, sculptors, and musicians; in the library are copyists, parchment-polishers, and bookbinders, who un- der the direction of the librarian n:ake books in 'le private manufactory of the house. Even slave letter-wti.^rs and stenographers must not be wanting in a wealthy house.^" When the master appears in public he is preceded by a large body of slaves (antcambiiloiics), while others follow him (fcdiscqiii); the nomcnclcitor tells him the name of those whom he meets and who are to be greeted; special dis- tribntorcs and tcsscrarii scatter bribes among the people and " istruct them Iiow to vote. These are the camclots of ancient Rome: and, what gives them special value, they are the property of the distinguislied asjiirant employing them. This system for exerting political influence is sup- "■ Comi'. ch. 6. it THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. loi plemented by the institution of plays, chariot-races, fights with wild beasts, and gladiatorial games, for which troops of slaves are specially trained. If the lord goes to a prov- ince as governor or sojourns on one of his country estates, slave couriers and letter-carriers maintain daily communi- cation with the capital. And how shall we begin to tell of the slave retinue of the mistress, on which Bottiger has written a whole book (Sabina), and of the endlessly spe- ciaHzed service for the care and education of the children! It was an incredible squandering of human energy that here took place. Lastly, by means of this many-armed organism of independent domestic economy, maintained as it was by a colossal system of breeding and training, the personal power of the slave-owner was increased a thou- sandfold, and this circumstance did much to render it pos- sible for a handful of aristocrats to gain control over half the world." The work of the State itself is not carried on otherwise. Both in Athens and Rome all subordinate officials and ser- vants are slaves. Slaves build the roads and aqueducts whose construction fell to the State, work in quarries and mines, and clean the sewers; slaves are the policemen, executioners and gaolers, the criers in public assemblies, the distributors of the public doles of corn, the attendants " Naturally this highly developed slavp system is only to be found among the most wealthy class; but with similar conditions it recurs everywhere. Ellis, for example, says in his History of Madagascar, I, p. 194: "When a family has numerous slaves, some attend to cat- tle, others are employed in cultivating esculent roots, others collect fuel; and of the females, some are cmnloycd in spinning, weaving and making nets, washing and other ( mesti: occupations." Even in the country of the Muata Yamwo, here, with the exception of smiths, there appear to have been no special craftsmen, the ruler had in his household his own musicians, fetich-doctors, smiths, hair- dressers, and female cooks. Pogge, Im Rciche d. Muata Jamwo, i p. 331, 187. I02 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. n of the colleges of priests in the temples and at sacrifices, the State treasurers, secretaries, the messengers of the magistrates; a retinue of public slaves accompanies every provincial officer or general to the scene of his duties. The means for their support came chiefly from the public domains, the tributes of the provinces (in Athens, of the allies), of which Cicero says that they are quasi prcedia populi Romani; and finally, from contributions resembling fees. Similar fundamental features are presented by the eco- nomic life of the Latin and Germanic peoples in the early Middle Ages. Here, too, necessary economic progress leads to a further development of the autonomous house- hold economy, which found expression in those large hus- bandries worked with serfs and villeins upon the exteujive landed possessions of the kings, the nobility, and the Church. In its details this manorial system has many points in common with the agricultural system of the later Roman Empire as developed by colonization. It has, also, considerable similarity with the centralized plantation sys- tem described above from the closing years of the Roman Republic. Tins rise of husbandry on a large scale with its subdivision of labour differs, however, in one important particular from the Roman. In Rome large estates engulf the small, and replace the arm of the peasant by that of the slave, who is later on transformed into the colonist. The economic advance involved in the extensive o/WoS husbandry had to be purchased by the proletarizing of the free peasant. In the manorial system of the Middle Ages the free owner of a small estate becomes, it is true, a vassal. But he is not ejected from possession; he preserves a cer- tain personal and economic independence, and, at the same time, shares in the fuller supply of goods which husbandry '•■iSiyiH. "»«-^»*"OF'WW Ji THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 103 on a large scale provides under the system of independent domestic economy. How did this come about? In ancient Italy the small cultivator was ruined through his inability to support certain public burdens, especially military service, and because the pressure of war and famine drove him into the lamentable servitude of the debtor. In the Germanic and Latin countries of the Mid- dle Ages he placed his homestead for like reasons under the control of the large landed proprietor from whom he received protection and assistance in time of need. We can best understand the mediaeval manor by pic- turing to ourselves the economic life of a whole vil- lage as a unit with the manor-house its central point.** "Though there were numerous villages whose inhabitants owed service to various proprietors, and many manors that included peas- ant holdings from various villages, yet the case here supposed must be regarded as the normal one. At the same time we must not for- get that most of the original evidence relating to these matters that we possess refers to the scattered possessions of the monasteries for which the manors formed the focal points, while for the estates of the great, and still more so for those of the smaller temporal proprietors in ancient times, we have scarcely any matt rial at all. For these, however, our supposed case is to be regarded as normal in so far as the villages arose through a colony grouping itself about a single es- tate. For the purposes of our sketch we may also leave out of view the many distinctions in the legal position of those owing rent and service dues, especially the distinction between those belonging to the manor and those belonging to the ni.irk. The latter, by virtue of the lord's supreme proprietorship over the common land, were also included in the economic system of the ntanor. Finally, I do not fail to appreciate the difference between the constitution of the villas of Charles the Great and the later administrative organization of the large landowners, though I am of the opinion that the latter has only superficinl points of contact with the economic life of the individual farm. For ;ill further details I must refer the reader to Maurer, Ccsch. il. I roiihofc: Inaiua-Sternegg, Die AusbiUiung d. grosscn Grund- hrrrnbaftcH i» Drutsihland; and Lamprecht, Dcutschfs IVtrtschaflskben im Af A s'-prr-nlly !, pp. 719 ff- I04 THE RISE OF NMTION/tL ECONOMY. 'i Under this systerrf the small landowner supervises in person, the large landowner through an overseer. The demesne land lying immediately about the manor-house is cultivated by serfs permanently attached to it, who there find food and lodging, and arc employed in agricultural and industrial production, household duties, and the per- sonal service of the lord, under a many-sided division of labour. The demesne land is intermixed with the holdings of a larger or smaller number of unfree peasants, each of whom tills his hide of land independently while all share with the lord the use of pasture, wooc' and water. At the same time, however, every peasant-holding binds its occupant to perform certain services and to furnish cer- tain dues in natural products to the estate. These services consist of labour reckoned at first according to require- ment, later according to time, whether given in the fields at seed-time or harvest, on the pasture-land, in the vine- yard, garden or forest, or in the manorial workshops or the women's building where the daughters of the serfs are spinning, weaving, sewing, baking, brewing beer, etc. On the days devoted to manorial service the unfree labourers receive their meals at the manor-house just as do the manor-folk themselves. They are further bound to keep in repair the enclosures about the manor-house and its fields, to keep watch over the house, and to undertake slie carrying of messages ami the transport of goods. The dues in kind to be paid to the estate are partly agricultural products, such as grain of all kinds, wool, fla.x. honey, wax, wine, cattle, hogs, fowl, or eggs; partly wood cut in the forests of the mark and made rea<ly for use. such as fire- wood, timber, vine-stakes, torch-wood, shingles, staves and hoops; partly the products of industry, such as wool- len and linen cloth, stocking^., shoes, bread, beer, casks, plates, dishes, goblets, iron, pots rind knives. This pre- THE RISE OF N/ITION/IL ECONOMY. los supposes alike among the serfs and those bound by feudal service a certain specialization of industry, that would oi necessny hereditarily attacii to the hides of land in ques- tion and prove advantageous not merely to the lord's e:- tate, but also to the occupants of the hides in supplying commodities. Intermediate between service and rent are duties of various kinds, such as hauling manure from the peasant's farm to the fields of the lord, keeping cattle over •winter, providing entertainment for the guests of the manor. Oa the other har the lord renders economic as- sistance to the peasant i^y keeping breeding-stock, by esta'olishing ferries, mills, and ovens for general use, by securing protection from violence and injustice to all, and by giving succour from his stores, in accordance with his pledge, when crops failed or other need arose. We hav. here a small economic organism quite suffi- cient uni .self, which avoids the rigid concentration of the Roman slave estates and employs slaves only to the extent necessary for the private husbandry of the landlord conceived in its strictest sense.' ^ For this reason it is able to secure to the general body of manorial labourers sep- arate agricultural establishments for their owr domestic needs, and therewith a certain personal independence. This is an instance of small partial private estates within the economy of the independent household similar to that which occurs, though of course on a much smaller scale, within the aadruga of the South Slavs when conjugal couples establish separate households.''^ When the man- » According to La.nprecht, I. p. 78^. the field lahuur-scrvices of the serfs were applied to the cultivation of tla- individual strclches of manorial land aUundax) or b-aU^ [unplou«hed ^'.npsl >n the com- mon land, while the manorial serfs were employed only for the cul- tivation of the demesne, " Comp. Laveleye, as above, p. -ifi^- i: 1, kk :»■ !? ; ••! 1 06 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. orial group coincides in membership with the people of a mark, the members are in a certain sense, owing to the regulations forbidding the alienation of land or mark servitudes to non-residents, economically shut off from their neighbours. Internal unity is realized by means of separate weights and measures, which, however, serve not for safeguarding trade, but for measuring the dues in kind coming to the lord. For we must always bear in mind that the economic relation of the lord to those attached to his land, however much it may be regarded from the general point of view of mutual service, is entirely removed from the class of economic relations that arise -.-om a system of exchange. Here there are no prices, no wages for labour, no land or house rent, no profits on capital, and accordingly neither entrepreneurs nor wage-workers. We have in this case peculiar economic processes and phenomena to which his- torical political economy must not do violence, after such frequent con plaints of harsh treatment in the past at the hands of jurisprudence. The surpluses of the manorial husbandry are the prop- erty of the lord. They consist entirely of goods for consumption which cannot be long stored up or turned into capital. On the estates of the king they are devoted as a rule to supplying the needs of the royal household, and the king, travelling with his retinue from castle to castle, claims them in person; while the large landed pro- prietors among the religious corporations and the higher nobility have them forwarded by a well-organized trans- port of their villeins to their chief seats, where as a rule they are likewise consumed. Thus in this economic system we have many of the phe- nom.na of commerce, such as weights and measures, the carriage of persons, news, and goods. !io«te!r!es, nn;' the THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 107 transference of goods and services In all, however, there is lacking the characteristic feature of economic exchange, namely, the direct connection of each single service with its reciprocal service, and the freedom of action on the part of the individual units carrying on trade with one another. But it matters not to what extent independent house- hold economy may be developed through the introduction of slave or villein labour, it will never succeed even in its highest development, to say nothing of its less perfect forms, in adapting itself sufficiently to the needs of human society for all time. Here we have continuously unfilled gaps in supply, there surpluses which are not consumed on the estates producing them, or fixed instruments of pro- duction and skilled labour which cannot be fully utilized. Out of this state of things arise fresh commercial phe- nomena of a particular kind. The landlord, whose harvest has failed, borrows corn and straw from his neighbour until the next harvest, when he returns an equal quantity. The man reduced to distress through fire or the loss of his cattle is assisted by the others on the tacit understanding that he will show the like favour in the like event. If any- one has a particularly expert slave, he lends him to a neighbour, just as he would a horse, a vessel, or a ladder; in this case the slave is fed by the neighbour. The owner of a wine-press, a malt-kiln, or an oven allovvs his poorer fellow villager the temporary use of it, in retprn for which the latter, on occasion, makes a rake, helps at sheep-shear- ing, or runs some errand. It is a mutual rendering of assistance; and no one will think of classifying such occur- rences under the head of exchange.'** " On the social duty of lending amonK primitive peoples, comp. Kubary, Ethnogr. Btitrdge s. Kenntnis d. Karolmcn-Archiptls, p. i6ji. i' 1 io8 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. W I 3 I ii '! Finally, however, real exchange does appear. The transi- tion-stage is formed of such processes as the following: the owner of slaves lends his neighbour a slave weaver or carpenter, and receives in return a quantity of wine or wood of which his neighbour has a surplus. Or the slave shoemaker or tailor, whose labour cannot be fully turned to account, is settled upon a holding, on the condition that he work each year a certain number of days at the manor. At times when he has no labour dues to pay and little to do on his own land, he gives his fellow villeins in their peasant houses the benefit of his skill, receiving from them his keep, and in addition a quantity of bread or bacon for his family. Formerly he was merely the servant of the manor; now he is successively the servant of all, but of each only for a short time.*^ At an early stage barter in kind, aiming at a mutual levelling of wants and surpluses, is also met with, as corn for wine, a horse for grain, a piece cf linen cloth for a quj.ntity of salt. This trading process expands owing to the Hmited occurrence of many natural products and to the localization of the production of goods for which there is a large demand; and if the various household establishments are small, and the adjoining dis- tricts markedly dissimilar in natural endowments, it may attain quite a development.' » Certain articles of this trade become, as has often been described, general mediums of exchange, such as skins, woollen goods, mats, cattle, arti- "On the corresponding conditions in Greece and Rome. comp. my accounts in the Handwort. d. Staatswiss. fjd ed.). IV, pp. ,^6g-7i. "To this circumstance is to be ascribed the relatively hi^'hly de- veloped weekly market trade of ancient Greece and of the negro countries of l.i-day; in Oceania the small size of the islands and the uneciual development among their inhabitants of both household work and riculture even calls forth in places an active maritime trade. Similarly is the oft-cited maritime commerce of the ancient Greeks to be regarded. THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 109 i cles of adornment, and finally the precious metals. Money comes into existence, markets and peddling trade arise; the beginnings of buying and selling on credit appear. But all this affects only the surface of the independent household economy; and, though the literature on the early history of trade and of markets has hitherto been far from familiarizing us with a proper estimate of these things, yet it cannot be too strongly emphasized that neither among the peoples of ancient times nor in the early Middle Ages were the articles of daily use the subject of regular exchange. Rare natural products, and locally manu- factured goods of a high specific value form the few articles of commerce. If these become objects of general demand, as amber, metal implements, ceramic products, spices and ointments in ancient times, or wine, salt, dried fish, and woollen wares in the Middle Ages, then undertakings must arise aiming at the production of a surplus of these articles. This means that the other husbandries will produce be- yond their own immediate requirements the trade equiva- lents of those articles as do the northern peoples their skins and vadhmdl, and the modern Africans their wares of bark and cotton, their kola nuts and their bars of salt. Where the population concentrates in town? there may even come into being an active market trade in the neces- saries of life, as is seen in classic antiquity, and in many negro countries of to-day. In fact even the carrying on of industry and trade as a vocation is to a certain extent possible. Still this does not affect the inner structure of economic life. The labour of each separate household continues to receive its im, .ilse and direction from the >vants of its own members: it must itself pro('-ice what it can for the satis- faction of these wants. Its only regulator is utility. " That no THE RISE OF NATION/IL ECONOMY. > I I i i I I landlord is a worthless fellow," says the elder Pliny, " who buys what his own husbandry can furnish him "; and this principle held good for many centuries after. One must not be led away from a proper conception of this economic stage by the apparently extensive use of money in early historic times. Money is not merely a me- dium of exchange, it is also a measure of value, a medium for making payments and for storing up wealth. Payments must also constantly be made apart from trade, such as fines, tribute-money, fees, taxes, indemnities, gifts of hon- our or hospitality; and these are originally paid in products of one's own estate, as grain, dried meat, cloth, salt, cattle, and slaves, which pass directly into the household of the recipient. Accordingly all earlier forms of money, and for a long time the precious metals themselves, circulate in a form in which they can be used by the particular household either for the immediate satisfaction of its wants or for the acquisition by trade of other articles of consump- tion. Those of special stability of value are pre-eminently serviceable in the formation of a treasure. This is es- pecially true of the precious metals, which in time of pros- perity assumed the form of rude articles of adornment, and as quickly lost it in time of adversity. Finally, it is man- ifest that the office of a measure of value can be performed by metal money even when sales are actually made in terms of other commodities, as is shown by the use in ancient Egypt of uten, a piece of wound copper wire according to which prices were fixed, while payment was made in the greatest variety of needful articles.^" This is also shown by numerous medi.Tval i ;cords in which, far beyond the epoch here under review, prices are fixed partly in money and partly in horses, dogs, wine, grain, etc., or the pur- " Frman. Aegypten u. agypi. Leben in: Alierium, pp, 175, 6«7, THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. Ill I I chaser is left at liberty to make a money payment " in what he can " (in quo potiierit).^^ Lamprecht, discussing economic life in France in the eleventh century, affirms that purchases were made only in cases of want;2» the same holds in the main for sales as well. Exchange is an element foreign to independent household economy, and its entrance was resisted as long and as stubbornly as possible. Purchase always means purchase with immediate payment, and it is attended with solemn and cumbrous formalities. The earliest municipal law of Rome prescribes that the purchase must take place before five adult Roman citizens as witnesses. The rough copper that measures the price is weighed out to the seller by a trained weigh-master Qibripens), while the purchaser makes a solemn declaration as he takes posses- sion of the purchased article. Contrasting with this the formal minuteness of early German trade laws, we are eas- ily convinced that in the economic period which witnessed the creation of this rigid legal formalism buying and sell- ing, and the renting of land or house, could not be every- day affairs. Exchange value accordingly exercised no deep or decisive influence on the internal economy of the separate household. The latter knev; only production for its own requirements; or, when sncn production fell short, the practice of making gifts with the expectation of re- ceiving others in return, of borrowing needful articles and " Under similar circumstances the same is true to-day. " Through- out West, Central, and East Africa quite definite and often quite com- plex standards for the exchange of goods have been formed, just as among ourselves, but with this diflference. that coined money is gen- erally wanting. This, however, by no means prevents the existence of a system of intermediate values, though it be but as notions and names."— Buchner, Kamerun. p. 93. "Fransos. Wirtsckaftsleben, p. 132. Comp. further his Deutsches Wirtschaftsleben im M. A., II, pp. 374 S- Ill 112 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. implements, and, if need be, of plundering. The develop- ment of hospitality, the legitimizing of begging, the union of nomadic life and early sea-trade with robbery, the ex- traordinary prevalence of raids on field and cattle among primitive agricultural peoples, are accordingly the usual concomitants of the indep>endent household economy. From what has been said it will be clear that under this method of satisfying needs the fundamental economic phe- nomena must be dissimilar to those of modern national economy. Wants, labour, production, means of produ''- tion, product, stores for use, value in use, consumption — these few notions exhaust the circle of economic phenom- ena in the regular course of things. As there is no social division of labour, there are consequently no professional classes, no industrial establishments, no capital in the sense of a store of goods devoted to acquisitive purposes. Our classification of capital into business and trade capital, loan and consumption capital, is entirely excluded. If, conform- ably to widely accepted usage, th< expression capital is restricted to means of production, then it must in any case be limited to tools and implements, the so-called fixed capital. What modern theorists usually designate circu- lating capital is in the independent household economy merely a store of consumption goods in process of prep- aration, unfinished or half-finisbed products. In the regu- lar course of affairs, moreover, there are no sale-goods, no price, no circulation of commodities, no distribution of income, and. therefore, no labour wages, no earnings of management, and no interest as particular varieties of in- come.^^ Rent alone begins to differentiate itself from the 1 " For most of the conceptions here mentioned there are no ex- pressions in Greek or Latin. They must be expressed by circumlo- cutions or by viTv ccneral terms. This is true, in the first instance, of the conception income itself. The Latin rcditus denotes the returns from the land. Tacitus makes use of a similar liberty wher. (Ann., THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. "J return from the soil, still appearing, however, only in com- bination with other elements of income. Perhaps, indeed, it is improper at this stage to speak of income at all. What we call income is normally the fruit of commerce; in independent domestic economy it is the sum of the consumption goods produced, the gross return. This return, however, is all the more inseparable from general wealth the more the subjection of the husbandry to the hazard of the elements compels the accumulation of a store of goods. Income and wealth form indistinguish- able parts of a whole, one part of which is ever moving upward towards availability for use, another part down- ward to consumption, while a third is stored up in chest and box, in cellar or storehouse, as a kind of assurance fund. To the last belongs money. In so far as it is used in trade it is for the recipient as a rule not a provisional but a final equivalent. It plays its chief part not as an intermedi- ary of exchange, but as a store of value and as a means of measuring and transferring values. Loans from one eco- nomic unit to another do indeed take place; but as a rule they bear no interest, and are made only for purposes of consumption. Productive credit is incompatible with this economic system. Where money-lending on interest in- trudes itself it appears unnatural, and, as we know from Greek and Roman history, is ultimately ruinous to the debtor. The canonical prohibition of usury thus had its origin not in moral or theological inclination, but in eco- nomic necessity. IV, 6, 3) he designates the revenues of the state as fructus publici. Compare with this the numerous and finely distiuKui^hed expressions for the conception wealth. Mcrccs means not only waf^es. but also land-rent, house-rent, interest, price. So also the Greek nurdot. For the expressions vocation, occupation, undertaking, industry, neither of the classic languages has corresponding itniis. 114 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. I r! I Where a direct state tax arose, it was regularly a tax on wealth, generally a species of land-tax. Such was the Athenian ei(T<t>opd, the Roman tributum civium, and the scot or the bede of the Middle Ages. Along with these demand was made upon the wealth of the individual for direct services to the State or community, such as the furnishing ships, the institution of festivals an.d enter- tainments (liturgies). The idea of taxing income, how- ever natural and self-evident it may appear to us, would have been simply inconceivable to our ancestors. By a process extending over centuries this independent household economy is transformed into the system of direct exchange; in the place of production solely for domestic use steps custom production. We have designated this stage town economy, because it reached its typical develop- ment in the towns of the Germanic and Latin countries during the Middle Ages. Still it must not be forgotten that even in ancient times beginnings of such a develop- ment ?r- [t ceptibic-, ind that at a later date they also appeared in the more advanced Slavic countries, albeit in considerably divergent form. The transition to this economic stage is seen at the stage of domestic economy itself in the loss by the sep- arate household, founded upon the cultivation of the soil, of a part of its independence through inability longer to satisfy all its needs with its own labour, and through the necessity of permanent and regular reinforcement from the products of other estates. Yet there do not spring up at once establishments independent of the soil, whose members would derive their income entirely from the working up of industrial commodities for others, or the professional performance of services, or the conducting of exchange. On the contrary, each proprietor still seeks, as far as possible, to gain his livelihood from the land; if THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. "S t' % 4 I his wants go beyond this, he calls into requisition any special manual skill he may possess, or any particular pro- ductive advantage of his district, whether in field, forest, or water, in order to produce a surplus of some particular article. One will produce grain, another wine, a third salt, a fourth fisli, a fifth iinen or some other product of domes- tic industry. In this manner separate establishments come into existence specially developed in some one direction, and dependent upon a regular, reciprocal barter of their surplus products. This exchange does not at first demand an organized system of trade. But it does require more flexible commercial methods than were offered by the early laws. These are furnished by markets which still arise, in the main, under the household system. A market is the coming together of a large number of buyers and sellers in a definite place and at a definite time. Whether this occur in connection with religious feasts and other popular gatherings, or whether it owes its origin to the favourable commercial situation of a locality, it is al- ways an opportunity for producer and consumer to meet with their mutual trade requirements; and such in its gen- eral features it has remained down to the present day. Markets and fixed trade are mutually exclusive. Where a merchant class exists, no markets are needed; where there are markets, merchants are superfluous. Only in cases where a country must imf>ort articles for which there is a demand and which it does not itself produce can there be developed at the early stage of household economy a distinct though not very numerous class, uniting under their control the purchase, transport, and sale of these goods, and utilizing for this last purpose the trade oppor- tunities presented by the markets. What changes, t •=■ i, were wrought in this condition of things by the medu^val town, and in what does the eco- in Ml no THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. nomic system which we have designated as exclusive town economy consist? The medi;c\al town is al)ove all things a biirg, that is. a place fortified with nails and moats which serves as a ref- uge and shelter for the inhabitants of the unprotected places round about. Every lown thus presupposes the existence of a defensive union which forms the ru^al sei- tlements lying within a greater or narrower radius into a sort of mihtary community with definite rights and duties. It devolves upoi. all the places belonging to this commun- ity to cooperate in maintaining imact the town fortifica- tions bv furnishing workmen and horses, and in time of war in 'defending them with their arms. In return they have the right, whenever occasion arises, to shelter them- selves their wives and children, their cattle and movables, within its walls. This right is called the right of burgess, and he who enjoys it is a burgher {hurgcnsis). Oi-iginallv the permanent inhabitants of the town differ in nowise, not even in their occupations, from those living in the rural hamlets. Like the latter they follow farming and cattle-raising; thcv use wood, water, and pasture in common; their dwellings, as may =^ill be seen in the structural arrangement of many old cities, are farmhouses with barns and stables and large yards !)etween. But their communal life is not exhausted in the regulation of com- mon pasturage and other agricultural interests. They arc. so to speak, a permanent garrison stationed in the burg, and perform in rotation the daily watch-service on tower and at gate. Whoever wishes to settle permanently in the town must therefore not only be possessed of land, or a house at least: he must also be provided rvilh weapons and armour. The s< -icl service and the extensive area of the tovM. rcn. rcr cc^^ary by the law of burgess demanded THE RISE OF NATION /tL ECONOMY. 117 a great number of men; and soon ihc ,. vn limits no longer srfticed for tlieir maintenance. Then it was that the one-sided dcvclopnient of the household establish- ments, already described, lent its intlnence. and the town became the seat of the industries and of the markets as well. In the latter the country peasant continued to dis- pose of his surplus supplies, obtaining from the townsman that which he himself could no longer provide and which the latter now exclusively or almost exclusively produced, namely, industrial products. The burgess rights underwent a consetiucnt extension. All who enjoyed them were exempt from market dues and town tolls. The right of free purchase and sale in the town market is thus in its origin an emanation from the rights of burgess. In this way the military defensive union be- came a territorial economic comnumity based upon mutual and direct exchange of agricultural and industrial products by the respecti-, c producers and consumers. All market traders on their way to and from a market enjoyed — doubtless also in the period previous to the rise of towns — a particularly active royal protection, which was further extended to the market itself and to the whole market-town. The effects of this market-peace were to secure the market tradesmen during the time of their so- journ in the town against legal prosecution for debts previ ously incurred, and to visit injuries inflicted upon their property or person with doubly severe punishment as be- ing extraordmary breaches of the peace. The market tra<lcsnien arc commonly known as Kattflcutc. niciratorrs. fici^otiatoirs, cmf'forcs.'^ '* Recent litcr.iture nlatinpr to the oriRin nf the constitution of Ticr- m.in (owns h.is overlooked the very wi<!e significance of the word Kaufmann and ini.TKincd that the innnmerablo towns cxistin^r within the tJn'iiiaii Iiini>irc lort.irils iht liuM- of lilt? Miiliiic; .'\k*;>, lloul m li } I ii8 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. Inasmuch as the town inhabitai.cj were themselves pecu- liarly dependent upon the market for their buying and Cologne and Augsburg down to Medebach and Radolfzell, were in- habited by merchants in the modern sense of the term, that is, by a specialized class of professional tradesmen, who are as a rule still represented as wholesale merchants. All economic history revolts against such a conception. What did these people deal in, and in what did they make payment for their wares? Besides, the very terms used are opposed to it The most prominent characteristic of the professional merchant in his relation to the public is not his custom of buying, but of selling. Yet the chapman (Kaufmann) of the Mid- dle Ages is named from the word for buying— fea«/fn. In the State records of Otto III. for Dortmund from 99° to looo a.d. the emptores Trotmannice, whose municipal laws, like those of Cologne and Mainz, are said to serve as a model for other cities, are spoken of in the same connection as mercatores or negotiatores in other records. If the abbot of Reichenau in the year I07b can with a stroke of the pen transform the peasants of Allensbach and their descendants into mer- chants (ut »7>« et eorum posteri sint mercatores), no possible ingenuity of interpretation can explain this if we have in mind professional tradesmen. That in point of fact merchant meant any man who sold wares in the market, no matter whether he himself had produced them or bought the greater part of them, is evident, for example, from an unprinted declaration of the Council of Frankfurt in 1420 regarding the toll called Marklrerhl (in Book No. 3 of the Municipal Archives, Fol. 80). There we find at the beginning that this toll is to be paid by " every merchant who stands on the street with his merchan- dise, whatsoever it be." Then follow, specified in detail, the in- dividual " merchants " or the " merchandise " affected by this toll. From the lengthy list the following instances may be given: dealers in old clothes, pastry-books, food-vendors, rope-makers, hazelnut- sellers, egg- and chet'se-scllcrs with their carts, poultry-vendors who carry about their baskets on thoir backs, strangers having in their possession more than a maltcr of cheese, cobblers, money-changers, bakers who use the market-stalls, strangers with bread-carts, geese, wagons of vitch (fodder), straw, hay, cabbages, all vendors of linen, flax, hemp, yarn, who sell their wares upon the street. Here we have a confused medley of small tradesmen of the town, artisans and peas- ants. That buyers as well as .sellers on the market were designated as KauAeute (merchants) is evident from numerous records; in fact, pas sages might be cited in which, when the merchant is spoken of, it is the buyer that seems to be chicHy meant. THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECO'"OMY. 119 selling, the specific name of market people or merchants was more and more applied to thtxii as the importance of the market as their source of sinply increased. Propor- tionately with this change, however, the region from which this market drew its supplies and to which it sold extended farther into the country. No longer did it coincide with the domain of burgess rights, whose importance for the rural population must of itself have diminished with the incre-sing security of the whole country against external attack. On the other hand, with the growth of the indus- tries the whole town, and not merely the space originally set apart for the exclusive purpose, became the market; market-peace became town-peace, and for the maintenance of the latter the town was separated from the general state administration as a special judicial district. " City air makes free " became r. principle. Thus arose a social and legal gu'f between burgher and peasant which the thirteenth anJ. ^urteenth centuries vainly sought to bridge over by an extramural and intramural citizenship. The name burgher was finally restricted to the members of the communit, settled within the town limits; and the times lent to this title a legal and Moral significance in vhich the state idea of the ancient Greeks appeared to have returned to lif?. We cannot here occupy ourselves further either with the development of the municipal constitution and its self- administration ba.sed upon corporative gr?''ations, or with the political power which the towns of Germany, France, and Italy obtained in the later Middle Ages. We have to do only with the matured economic organization of which these towns fonned the central points. If we take a map of the old German Empire and mark upon it the places that, up to the close of the Middle Ages, had received grants of municipal rights — there were prob- il I20 TH JSB OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. ably some three thousand of them — we see the country dotted with towns at an average distance of four to five hours' journev in the south ami west, and in the north and east of seven to eight. All were not of equal importance; but the majority of them in their time were, or at least en- deavoured to be, the economic centres for their territory, leading just as independent an existence as the manor be- fore them. In order to form a conception of the size of these districts, let us imagine the whole country evenly divided among the existing municipalities. In this way each town in southwestern Germany has on the average forty to somewhat over fifty square miles, in the central antl northeastern parts between sixty and eighty-five, and in the eastern from somewhat over one hundred to one hundred and seventy. Let us imagine the town as always situated in the centre of such a section of country, and it becomes plain that in almost every part of Germany the peasant from the most distant rural settlement was able to reach the town market in one day. and be home again by nightfall.-"' The whole body of municipal market law. as formulated in early times by the lords of the town and later by the ^'.MthouRh since the Middle Ages muny places have lost their town franchises, while others have gained them for the first time, yet the number of places that to-day bear the name of town (Stadt) furnishes a pretty correct idea of what it then was. There is in Baden at pres- ent one city t'> every 132 s(iuare kilometres of territory [i s(i. km. = about I S(|. nii'el. in Wiirtemberg to i.M. in Alsace-Lorraine to 137, in Ifessc to 118. in the kingdom of Saxony to 105. in Hesse-N'assau to 145. in the Rhine Province to 19J. in Westphalia to ig6. in the province of Saxony to i;5, in Brandenburg to Jgi. in the kingdom of Bavaria to 328. in Hanover to 341. in Schleswig-Holstein to 350. in Pomcrania to 41J, in West Prussia to 473. and in East Prussia to 552. The fever for founding tnunicipalities. which racked many medixval rulers, called into existence a multitude of towns that lacked vitality. Well known is the prohibition in the Saihsensfiegel that " No market shall be founded within a mile of anoih..." Weiske, III, 66, 1 1. THE RISE OF 1^ AT ION A L ECONOMY. 121 town councillors, is summed up in the two principles, that, as far as at all possible, sales must be public and at first hand, and that everything ixjhich can be produced zvithin the toz^'n itself shall be produced there. For products of local manu- 'acture intermediary trade was forbidden to everyone, even to the artisans; it was permitted with imported goods only when they had already been vainly offered on the '^- .et. The constant aim was to meet amply and at a just price the wants of the home consumers, and to give full satis- faction to the foreign customers of local industry. The territory from which supplies were drawn for the town market, and that to which it furnished commodities, was identical. The inhabitants of the countr\- brought in victuals and raw materials, and with what they realized paiil for the labour of the town craftsmen, either in the direct form of wage-work or in the indirect form of finished products, which had been previously ordered or were se- lected in the open market from the artisan's stand. Burgher and peasant thus stood in the relationship of mu- tual customers: what the one produced the other always needed; and a large part of this exchange trade was per- formed without the mediation of money, or in such a way that money was introduced only to adjust differences in value. Town handicraft had an exclusive right of sale on the market. The productions of other places were aumitted only when the industry in cpiestion had no representatives within the town. They were usually offered for sale by the foreign producers at the annual fairs; at this one point the spheres of the various town tvuirkcts overlap. But even here the most essential feature, the direct sale by producer to consume*, is also observed, though only in exceptional instances. If a trade capable of supporting a craftsman was not represented in the town, the council i2a THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. ^■% called in a skilled master workman from outside and in- duced him to settle by exemption from taxation and other privileges. If he required considerable initial capital, the town itself came to his aid, and at its own expense built work- and sale-shops and established mills, grin^.ing- works, cloth-frames, bleaching-places, dye-houses, fulling- mills, etc., — all with a view to satisfying the greatest pos- sible variety of wants by home production. Although direct dealing with the consumer of his wares ^^ tended necessarily to keep alive in the artisan a sense of personal responsibility, an effort was made to brace this moral relationship by .special ordinances. Hand- work is an office that must be administered for the general welfare. The master shall furnish " honest " work. So far as the personal services of the craftsman remained avail- able to his customers, a regular rate was fixed governing the amount he could claim in wages and board while on his itinerancy. In cases where the customer furnished him with the raw material in his own home, as, for instance, tin to the pewterer, silver and gold to the goldsmith, or yarn to the weaver, provision was made that it should not be adulterated. Where, on the contrary, the artisan supplied the material there were erected in the market, about the churches, at the town gates, or in particular streets, public sale-booths which often served also as work-shops (bread- stands, meat-stalls, drapers' and cloth shops, furriers' booths, shoemakers' benches, etc.). It was a market rule that those vending the same wares should do their selling alongside one another in open and mutual competition and under the supervision of the market wardens and over- " Here and there this was further secured by the regulation that not even the wife of the craftsman might represent him in selling. Comp. Gramich, V'erf. h. Verw. d- St. Wiirsburg vom. XIII. bis XF. Jkdt., pp. 38 f. THE RISE OF NATION/IL ECONOMY. X23 seers, and this rule was extended to craftsmen who merely worked at home on orders, in that for the most part they lived side by side on the same street. Many cities have preserved to the present day the remembrance of this con- dition of things in the names of their streets (such as Shoe- maker, Turner, Weaver, Cooper, Butcher, Fisher Streets), many of which led directly into the old market square. In this way the greatest part of the town, or even the whole of it, bore the outward aspect of one large market. It is well known that the many prescriptions regarding the raw material to be used, the method of doing work, the length and breadth of cloths, and the direct regulation of prices must have served for the protection of the con- sumer.^® Just as the urban craftsman enjoyed within the town and the extramural judicial district {Banmneile) the ex- clusive right of selling the products of his handicraft, so the urban consumer possessed for the same area the ex- clusive right to purchase imported commodities. This right can be exercised, to be sure, only when the imported goods actually come to market and stand on sale for the proper length of time. To effect this a law of staple is introduced; foreselling in the country places or before the town gates is forbidden; selling to middlemen, artisans, and strangers is permitted only after the consumers are supplied, and then usually with the limitation that the lat- ter, if they so wish, may have a share; and lastly, the withdrawing of goods once brought to market was for- bidden, or permitted only after they had remained three days unsold.^^ ** For the sake of brevity we refer for all details in this connection to Stieda in the Jhb. f. N.-6k. u. Statistik, XXVII. pp. 91 «• "These ordinances were most carefully wrought out for the corn trade. Sec Schmolkr, Jhb. f. Gcsetzg. Verw, u. Volksw., XX. pp. 708 flf. 124 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. I 1 I '•*• 3 » But against the foreign 'seller there always prevails a deep-rooted mistrust. To t lis is due the existence of that peculiar system of exchange through official interme- diaries, measurers, and weighers. To-day the State con- trols weights and measures by official standards and pui^lic inspections, and leaves the terms to the buyers and sellers themselves. In the Middle Ages the technical means for constructing exact measures and ensuring their accuracy were wanting. Common field-stones — and at the Frank- furt fairs as late as the fifteenth century even wooden blocks — were used as weights. In order, however, to de- termine accurately the amount of goods exchanged, the handling of the measures was withdrawn from the parties themselves and entrusted to special officers, whose pres- ence was made obligatory at every sale made by an out- sider. It was the duty of these intermediaries to bring buyer and seller together, to assist in fixing the price, to test the goods for possible defects, to select for the pur- chaser the quantity he had bought, and to see to its propci- delivery. The intermediary was forbidden to trade for himself; he was not even allowed at the departure of the foreign tradesnnn, whom he generally lodged, to purchase remnants of goods remaining unsold. This system of direct exchange is found, though with many local peculiarities, carried out to the most min- ute details in all mediaeval towns. This means. that the actual circumstances in which its principles were devel- oped render it inevitable. How far it was really prac- ticable can only be decided when we are able to determine what proportions trade assumed under it. It is beyond question that a retail trade had taken root in the town;,. To it belonged all who " sel! pennyworths for the poor man." To understand this, we nvast bear in mind that all well-to-do townspeople were accustomed THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 1 = 5 to purchase their supplies directly from foreign merchants at the weekly and yearly markets. The poor man was unable to make provision for any length of time; he lived, as he does to-day, " from hand to mouth." For him the retail tradesman, accordingly, undertook the keeping of stores for daily sale. We can distinguish three groups of such small trades- men, namely, grocers, peddlers, and cloth-dealers. In the earlier half of the period of town economy the last were the most important, as, in many towns there was no local wool-weaving done. With its development their activity was limited to the handling of the finer kinds of Dutch cloths, silks, and cottons, or else they made room for the weavers in their shops. The ti'holcsalc trade was exclusively itinerant and market or fair trade; and down to the close of the Middle Ages the majority of the towns probably saw no merchants settled within their walls who carried on wholesale trade from permanent headquarters. Only commodities not pro- duced within the more or less extensive district from which a town drew its supplies were the subject of whole- sale trade. We know of but five kinds: (i) spices and southern fruits, (2) dried and salted fish, which were then a staple food of the people, (3) furs, (4) fine cloths, (5) for the North German towns, wine. In certain parts of Ger- many salt would also have to be included. In most cases, however, the town council ordered it in large quantities directly from the places of production, stored it in the municipal salt warehouses, and after a monopolistic ad- vance of its price gave it out to be disposed of by peddler and saltman, who paid a fee for the privilege. Usually the foreign wholesale dealers" were permitted to sell their "In Jhb. f. Nat.-6k. u. Stat., 3 F- XX (1900). pp. i ff., G. v. Below attempts to prove that in the Middle Ages there existed no class ot 126 THE RISE OF Ny4TION/4L ECONOMY. ft 'a !!' 1-1 wares only in large lots or in minimum quantities — in the case of spices, for example, not under 1 2^ pounds. The local retailers and peddlers then carried on the sale in detail. This also holds good for many large producers, as, for instance, hammersmiths, who might sell o founders the iron they had failed to persuade smith-j and private indi- viduals to buy. Though the limits of the territory from which the mar- ket of a mediaeval town drew its supplies and to which its sales were made cannot be determined with precision, see- ing that they varied for different wares, yet from the eco- nom.ic point of view they formed none the less an inde- pendent region. Each town with its surrounding country constituted an autonomous economic unit within which its whole course of economic Hfe was on an independent foot- ing. This independence is based upon special currency, and special weights and measures for each locality. The relation between town and country is as a matter of fact a compulsory relation such as that between the head and the limbs of the body, and it displays strong tendencies to assume the forms of legalized compulsion. The extra- mural jurisdiction of the town, the prohibitions of export and import already met with, the differential tolls, and the direct acquisition of territory on the part of the large towns plainly point in that direction. Many as are the objections which may be urged against deducing the constitution of the town from that of the manor, the economic system of the town can be properly wholesale merchants, and that the characteristic feature of those times was for wholesale and reUil trade to be carried on by the same person. He therefore takes exception to our use of the term wholesale mer- chant. I cannot, however, see why when these persons appeared as wholesalers they should not receive the name, particularly as there is no evidersce to show that wholesale merchants were ever met with who were not at the same time retail traders. THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. ia7 '% understood and explained only as a continuation of the manorial system. What existed in the latter ia mere germs and beginnings grew into finished organisms and systems of organisms; factors that under the independent household economy were found grouped in primitive shapelessness, have now been differentiated by subdivision and made independent. The forced division of labour of the manor has broadened into a free division of production between peasants and burghers, displaying morever among the latter a varied multiplicity of separate trades. The manorial workman carrying on domestic labour has become the wage-earning craftsman, who in time comes to possess his own business capital in addition to his tools. The vital thread connecting manorial and cottier economy has at length been severed; the separate household estab- lishments have gained an independent existence; trade between them is no longer conducted on the basis of a gen- eral return, but on the basis of a specific payment for ser- vices given and received. To be sure they have not yet fully emancipated themselves from the soil, even in the town; production is still dependent in large measure upon the domestic husbandry; but there have been formed the distinct vocations of agriculturalist, artisan, and trades- Uian which have given a specific direction to the activities and lives of those following them. Society has become differentiated; classes now exist; and these were unknown before. T he whole circ le of economic Jife has_gained in fulness and variety in comparison with the independent domestic economy; the membership of the separate household es- taMshments has become smaller; the individuals are inter- dependent ; they undertake certain functions for each other; exchange value is already forcing its way as a leter- mining factor into their inner life. But the producingjrom- 128 TH'z RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY, i ^1 I .tflllm I it !i .i munity still coincules with the consuming community; the handicraftsman's assistants drawn from outside, and even the tradesmen, are meml)ers of their employer's house- hold, subject to his disciplinary control. He is their " mas- ter," they are his " servants." And still, as ever, by far the greater proportion of com- modities does not pass beyond the lintels of the place of production. A small part finds its way l)y the process of exchange into other establishments, but the way travelled is a very short one. namely, from producer to consumer. There is no circulation of goods. The sole exceptions are the articles of foreign trade few in number, and of the petty retail trade. They alone became wares. They alone must frequently take on the form of money before reach- ing their domestic destination. But here we deal with an exception to the system of direct exchange, not with a con- stituent element of the whole economic order. Jhough at this early point there is a social division of labour, and also an interrc'.ationship of rades. there are as yeTneitTier fixed Industrial undertakings nor the neces- sary industrial capital. At most wt are justified in speak- ing of trade capital. Handicraft undertakes work, but it is no business undertaking. In the form? of itinerant handicraft and home work it almo^^t totally acks capital. It means wage-labour embodied in t:-€ material of another. Even where the craftsman works w-'h iis nvr :ools the product does not increase m value -rrwr :^tt> c nftant in- corporation of fresh increme nts of -ztxzi^ nn :v m: the fact that labour is being inve-tcu in it. The amount of loar .ivA c-nstnnrrnjon -trsxtsi -^ also ex- ceedingly small. It ma; ve- m dmsnf" -E-T^^ner in medi- jeval trade credit open.Tiosi- :ui: »e ^^t^Hve- of at all. Early exchange is base( ip»^ ^eat:^- TE^-menr nothing is given except \MiCrC a ;- U=::— : =rxz;-^ . i:r-_ - -» 1» THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 129 received. Almost the entire credit system is clothed in the forms of purchase. This was the case with the heredi- tary peasant holding and with the giving of town building- sites in return for a ground-rent, in which instances the land was looked upon as the purchase-price for the right to levy rent.-" So it was also under the earlier law where the land placed at the disposal of the money-lender passes as a temporary equivalent into the keeping of the " cred- itor " and becomes his property if the debtor fails to repay the loan. Economically considered, this commercial act dififers in no way from selling in order to buy again; and it is admitted that it is now >carcely possible to discover a legal distinction between theitwo. A similar character is borne by tl.'' most common of urban credit transactions, the purchase of rents or stocks,-" as the name itself indi- cates. The price is the capital loaned; the commodity exchanged is the right to draw a yearly rent, which the borrower on the security of a house transfers in such a manner that the owner for the time being receives the rent. The rent is of the nature of a charge up< r, the soil, and is for a long time incapable of release; the party responsi- ble answers for it with the house or land upon which it is fixed, but not with his other assets. It is thus a charge only upon the real properly that carries it, whose rcntabil- ity'it proportionately diminishes. The person entitled to the rent has absolutely resigned the purchase-price paid; the document conferring the right to draw the rent can be transferred without formality, just as a bill payable to bearer. Every personal relationship is thus eliminated from the wdiole transaction, which lacks that element of " Compare in connection with this whole section the luminous ex- planation by A. Heusler, Instituiionen d. deutsch. Privatrechls, II, pp. 128 ff. "Rcntcnkauf and Giiltkr.uf. 13° THE RISE OF NAT!ONAL ECONOMY. m trust peculiar to credit. The right of redemption bears the same character; it is the sale of the rent under reserva- tion of the privilege of re-purchase. As in dealings in real property, so also with mov- ables, the credit transaction is but a variation of ready pay- ment. The security, as Heusler says, is a provisional transfer on the part of the debtor of an equivalent that is still redeemable (forfeitable security), not a covering of the debt, which may eventually be claimed by the creditor and realized upon by being converted into money (saleable security). The pawnbroking business of the Jews •** is in fact similar to our modern sale with right of redemption, and the " goods credit " extended to-day by craftsmen and shopkeepers, takes in the Middle Ages the form of purchase on security." If at the same time we con- sider that when personal credit was given in those times the debtor almost always had to agree to submit to the creditor's right of security; that in most instances he could get money only by furnishing the best security un- der pledges to the lender and similar burdensome condi- tions; that the creditor in addition reserved the right, in case of default, to obtain the money from Jews at the debt- or's expense; and that the fellow citizens or heirs of the foreign debtor could be distrained upon for the amount of his debt, — we see plainly that in the town economy of the Middle Ages a credit syrtem in the modem sense cannot be spoken of.'* •■ Comp. my Bev'nlkerung von Frankfurt, I, pp. 573 ff- " Comp. the interesting examples in Stieda. as cited above, p. 104. " A striking resemblance to the mediaeval credit system is offered by the Greek system and its legal forms. Here likewise purchase and loan are largely synonymous terms, and the language has not arrived at the stage of distinguishing sharply the notions of buying, pledging, renting, and subjecting to conditions. The Greek mortgage laws coincide in all important points with the early German. Comp. K. F. THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 131 ^1 1 There are two things in connection with this that must appear especially strange to a student of modem political economy, namely, the frequency with which immaterial things (relationships) become economic commodities and subjects of exchange, and their treatment under commer- cial law as real property. These show clearly how primi- tive exchange sought to enlarge the sphere denied it un- der the existing conditions of production by awkwardly transforming, into negotiable property, almost everything it could lay hold upon, and thus extending infinitely the domain of private law. What an endless variety of things in mediaeval times were lent, bestowed, sold, and pawned! — the sovereign power over territories and towns; county and bailiff's rip^hts; jun&uiction over hundreds and can- tons; church dignities and patronages; suburban monoi>- oly rights; ferry and road privileges; prerogatives of mint- age and toll, of hunting and fishing; wood-cutting rights, tithes, statute labour, ground-rents, and revenues; in fact charges of ever>' kind falling upon the land. Economi- cally considered, all these rights and "relationships" share with land the peculiarity that they cannot be removed from the place where they are enjoyed, and that t^ey can- not be multiplied at will. Income and wealth are at this stage not yet clearly distin- guished from each other. When in Basel in the year 145 1 the " new pound-toll " was introduced it was prescribed that it should be paid: (i) from the selling-price of wares, (2) from the capital invested in the purchase of rents, and (3) from the amount of rents received.'" On every pound Hermann. Lchrbuch dcr gritch. Privalaltcriumer mil Rinschluss der Rechls- altcrhnncr, » 67 and (rt<. The old Roman fiducia and its later form as tignus may be mentioned for purpose of comparison. Comp. Schonbere, Finansrtrhdltnisst d. Stadt Basel im XIV. und A J- . JHdt., p. 367. 13a THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. four pfennigs were to be paid, no matter whether the com- modity had changed hands as purchase-money, as capital, or as interest. In the first instance we have to do, accord- ing to our terminology, with gross revenue, in the second with property, in the third with net income; and yet all three cases are treated alike. Similar examples might be adduced from the tax-regulations of other cities." Two of our modern classes of income, however, now come more clearly into view, namely, ground-rent and wages. The latter bears, to be sure, a peculiar character; it is handicraft-wage, compensation for the use of the craftsman's labour on behalf of the consumer, and not, as to-day, the price paid to the wage-worker by the en- trepreneur. Still this price already exists in germ in the slight money-wage that the artisan gives to his journey- man in addition to free maintenance, thus enabling the latter to supply independently a limited proportion of his wants. Earnings of management appear only in the sphere of trade, and thus, like it, are the exception; more- over through connection with transportation they are more coloured by elements of labour-wage than are the earnings from trade to-day. As a rule interest takes on the form of ground-rent; and the same is true of the many kinds of revenues arising from the juridical rela- tionships that enter into trade. As credit operations usually take the form of purchase, they almost always mean for the creditor the actual transfer of a portion of his property, in order that he may receive a yearly income or a continuous usufruct. This is a rule, for example, of enfeoffment; with mortgaged property, according to the early law. it involved the transfer of the natural yield of - For details see my paper on two medixval tax-regulations. Klcinert Bdtriigf z. Gfschich. von Doccnitn d. Uipsiger HochschuU. Ftstscknft --. ('■ill. Hislorikertage (Leipzig. i8o4>. PP- >^3ff. THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. »33 the land, and with rent-purchases, of the ground-rent or rent. On this basis arose the earliest type of personal in- surance and at the same time the chief form of public credit: the negotiating of annuities. Public economy is still mainly of a private character: revenues from domains, sovereign prerogatives, tithes, statute labour, services, ground-rents, and fees preponder- ate in the State, market revenues and imports on con- sumption in the towns. The general property-tax con- tinues to be the only direct tax, and mingled with it here and there are elements of an income-tax. It is indeed levied more frequently than in the preceding period, but -.till it is not regular. In Germany the economic supremacy of the towns over the surrounding country blossomed only in a few places into political sovereignty. In Italy a parallel development led to the formation of a tyranny of the cities; in France the beginnings of autonomy on the part of free municipal communities were early suppressed by the kings with the aid of the feudal nobility. The reason is that in Germany, as in France, everything that lay without the town wall was overlaid with a mass of feudal institutions. True the great landed proprietors had long since given up the per- sonal management of their manorial estates. — which be- came for the owner, just as the town land and house prop- erty for the patrician families, nothing more than a source of income. But their original economic power had now be- come political, the landed proprietors were now territorial princes, and in the course of this transformation there had arisen a new and widely ramified class of small titled pro- prietors whose interests, purely agrarian in character, were closely linked to those uf the princes. Henc that keen struffgle in Germany between burj^her and n )!e whicl; »34 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. ■ m 1 fills the closing centuries of the Middle Ages, and in which the towns maintain the political autonomy they had for the most part acquired from their lords by purchase and unredeemed pleilges, though they fail to wrest the peasant clabs from the feudal powers. It can thus be said that the economic development of the towns in Germany and France remained incomplete; and that they did not accomplish what the most vigorous types of the period of autonomous household economy had actually achieved, namely, the transmuting of their eco- nomic power into political indepei'ui-nce. This was perhaps fortunate for us. In Italy the wealth of the cities expropriated in all directions the possessions of the peasant, and down to the present has continued to exploit him as a wretched metayer. In Germany the nobility were, indeed, able to make of him a feudatorj-; but the con- ception of nationality, which first came to life in the terri- torial sovereignties, served to prevent his proletarization. The final development of national economy is in its es- sence a fruit of the political centralization that begins at the close of the Middle Ages with the rise of territorial state organizations, and now finds its completion in the creation of the unified national State. Economic unifica- tion of forces goes hand in hand with the bowing of private political interests to the higher aims of the nation as a whole. In Germany it is the more powerful territorial prtnces, as opposed to the rural nobles and the towns, who seek to realize the modern national idea, often certainly under j;rcat diffictilties. especially when their territories were widely scattered. From the second half of the fifteenth century we have many indications of a closer economic union, such as the cre.ition of a territorial currency in place of the numerous town currencies, the issue of tcrri- THE RISE OF N/ITION/fL ECONOMY. 1 35 torial regulations regarding trade, markets, industry, for- estry, mining, hunting, and fishing, the gradual formation of a system of sovereign prerogatives and concessions, the promulgation of territorial laws, conducive to greater legal unity, and the emergence of an ordered public economy. But for centuries longer agricultural interests predom- inate in Germany, and as against them the exertions of the imperial power in the direction of a national economic policy lamentably failed. On the other hand the Western European states, — Spain, Portugal, England, France, and the Netherlands, — from the sixteenth century on appear externally as economic units, developing a vigorous colo- nial policy in order to turn to account the rich resources of their newly acquired possessions over sea. In all these lands, though with varying degrees of se- verity, appears the struggle with the independent powers of the Middle Ages, — the greater nobility, the towns, the provinces, the religious and secular corporations. The immediate question, to be sure, was the annihilation of the independent territorial circles which blocked the way to political unification. Put deep down beneath the move- ment leading to the development of princely absolutism, slumbers the universal idea that the greater tasks con- fronting modern civilization demanded an organized union of whole peoples, a grand living community of interests; and this could arise only upon the basis of common eco- nomic action. Each portion of the country, each section of the population, must in the service of the whole take over those duties that its natural endowments best fitted it to perform. A comprehensive partitioning of functions was necessary, a division into callings embracing the whole population; and this division itself presupposed a highly developed commerce and an active interchange of goods amongst the population. If the sole aim of all economic 136 THE RISE OF NATION /I L ECONOMY. I ! Ill effort was in ancient times to make the house autonomous in the satisfaction of its wants, and in later mediaeval times to supply the needs of the town, there now comes into being an exceedingly complex and ingenious system for meeting the wants of the entire nation. The carrying out of this system is from the sixteenth to the eighteenth century the economic effort of all the ad- vanced European states. The measures employed to at- tain this object are modelled in almost every detail upon the economic policy of the mediaeval towns.^* They are generally summed up under the name of the mercantile system. This latter has long been regarded as a theoretical edifice culminating in the principle that the wealth of a country consists in the amount of coin within its borders. To-day, in all probability, this conception is universally abandoned. Mercantilism is no dead dogma, but the active practice of all leading statesmen from Charles V. to Frederick the Great. It found its typical development in the economic policy of Colbert. He sought the removal or reduction of the internal customs and tolls, the intro- duction of a unified customs system on the national bor- ders; the assuring to the country of a supply of the neces- sary raw materials and means of sustenance by hindrances to export, and the institution of the forest regalia. He fostered industry on a large scale by the establishment of new industrial branches with state support and technical supervision, by the exclusion of foreign competition through prohibitive tariffs, and by the building of roads, canals, and harbours. With the same end in view he strove to unify the system of weights and measures, and to regu- late commercial law and the commercial news-service. •* For the German states this development is excellently portrayed by Schmoller in the Jhb. f. Gesetzgeb. Verw. u. Volksw. VIII (1884). pp. 22 a. THE RISE OF N/fTlONML ECONOMY. 137 The cultivation of the technical arts, fine arts, and science in special state institutions; the systematizing of state and communal expenditure, the removal of inequalities in taxa- tion, also served his one purpose — to create an independent national economy which should satisfy all the needs of the citi- zens of France by national labour, and by an active internal trade bring all the natural resources of the country and all the separate forces of the people into the service of the whole. In considering the special encouragement given by " Colbertism " to foreign commerce, the marine, and colonial trade, it has all too often been overlooked that these measures also strengthened the inner resources of the country, and that the theory of the balance of trade became a necessity at a time when the transition from the still predominant household production to the system of universal exchange indispensably postulated the in- crease of the monetary medium of circulation. Along with the state measures we must not fail to take account of the social forces working in the same direction. These naturally had their starting-point in the towns. Here, by a gradual process of transformation, 'waning at interest had been evolved from the purchase o! rents; and thus in the course of the sixteenth century a true credit system arose. In this we may see the influence of whole- sale trade, which first discovered the secret of making money with money. Through the liberation of capi- tal invested in rents tlic wealth of the rich townsmen acquired a greatly increased mobility and accumulative power. Loan capital now took its place at the side of trade capital, hitherto the only kind of capital; and the two supplemented and supported each other in their fur- ther development. The immediate result was a notablejexpansion p£ tra4e^ Certain towns began to rear their heads above the uniform ) f] X38 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. mass of mediaeval market and handicraft towns as centres of state administration or as emporiums of trade. In Ger- many, which through the decline of the Hansa and the change in the highways of the world's trade, had lost most of its importance as an intermediary of trade with the North, the change manifests itself to some extent in the growmg importance of the great fairs, and in the decad- ence of the local markets. The Frankfurt fair reached its zenith in the sixteenth century, that of Leipzig consider- ably later. But soon trade capital is no longer content with the importation and handling of foreign products; it becomes, for native industry and the surplus products of the peasant's domestic labour, commission capital. Wholesale production with division of labour in manu- factories and factories comes into life, and with it the wage-earning class. In place of the mediaeval exchange bank there is developed first the bank of deposit and cir- culation, then the modern credit bank. The transport of goods, which earlier was an integral part of trade, now becomes independent. The state posts, newspapers, and the national marine arise, and the insurance system is de- veloped. On all sides are new organizations whose pur- pose is to satisfy wide-spread economic wants; a national industry, a national market, national commercial institu- tions,— everywhere the capitalistic principle of business enterprise in trade. Everybody knows how the absolutist State furthered this movement, ai d how not infrequently in the effort to accelerate it it gave an artificial existence to what would not flourish of its own strength. Nevertheless, though limited in manifold ways by state legislation, the old eco- nomic organization of the towns with its guild and monop- oly privileges and the sharp separation of town and country, persisted on until about the end of the eighteenth i« THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 139 '^ century, heedless of the new economic life springing up roundabout and of the variety of new commercial forms which it had nurtured. When the Physiocrats and Adam Smith made these latter for the first time the subject of scientific observation, they entirely overlooked the ob- vious fact that they were not dealing with a spontaneous product of mere social activity, but with a fruit of the paternal government of the State. The barriers whose removal they demanded were either the fossilized survivals of earlier economic epochs, such as charges upon the soil, guilds, local coercive rights, restrictions on freedom of mi- gration; or they were devices of mercantilism for assisting production, such as monopolies and privileges, which might cease to operate after having fulfilled their purpose. As far as the development of national economy is con- cerned, the liberalism of the last hundred years has only continued what absolutism began. Expressed in this way, the assertion may easily seem paradoxical. For liberalism, outwardly considered, has only demolished; it has over- thrown the antiquated forms upon which household and town economy were founded, and constructed nothing new. It has destroyed the special position and special privileges of individual territorial districts and individual social groups, and in their stead established free competi- tion and equality before the law. But though it has thus decomposed into its elements the heritage of the past, it has at the same time cleared the way for new economic combinations of a truly national character, and made it possible for every energy, according to the technical devel- opment of the time, to enter into the service of the whole at the point where it is of the greatest usefulness. If liberalism has made the progress of national economy absolutely contingent upon social freedom of action, and thus taken an attitude in many respects hostile to I40 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. v.^ii the State, it has nevertheless failed to prevent the modern State, as such, from pursuing the path chosen by it as early as the sixteenth century, and leading to an ever-closer union of all sections of the people and of the national ter- ritory for the accomplishment of the steadily expanding tasks' of civilization. All the great statesmen of the last three centuries, from Cromwell and Colbert to Cavour and Bismarck, have worked towards this end. The French Revolution has been no less centralizing in its effects than the political upheavals of recent decades. In the latest phase of this evolution the principle of nationality has be- come a principle of mighty unifying power. The small separate States of earlier times were no longer equal to the comprehensive economic tasks of the present. They had either to disappear in one large national State, as in Italy, or surrender considerable portions of their inde- pendence, especially in economic legislation, to a federal State, as did the individual States in the German Empire, and the cantons in Switzerland. We err, if we imagine ourselves justified in concluding 1 from the extent to which international -trade, has been facilitated during the epoch of liberalism that the period of national economy is on the decline and is giving place to the period of world-ec ononix. The very latest political development of the States of Europe has resulted in a return to the ideas of mercantilism and, to a certain extent, of the old town economy. The revival of protective duties, the retention of national currency and of national labour legislation, the public ownership of the machinery of trans- portation already achieved or still aimed at, the national control of workman's insurance and of the banking sys- tem, the growing activity of the State in economic matters generallv.— all this indicates that we have passed the ab- solutist and liberalist periods and entered upon a third THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 141 period of national economy. Socially this period bears a peculiar aspect. It is no longer merely a question of meet- ing national wants as independently and completely as possible by national production, but a question of the just distribution of goods, of the direct action of the State in the economic interests of the whole, and for the purpose of securing to all its subjects according to their economic services a share in the benefits of civilization. The requi- site measures can be carried out only on a grand scale; they demand an intimate union of all individual forces,' such as a great national State alone can furnish. With this we might fittingly close. For to present here the multitude of new phenomena springing up under the touch of national as opposed to household and town econ- omy one would need to reproduce almost the whole con- tents of a text-book on political economy. It will never- theless contribute to a better understanding of the subject if, by a comparison of some of the leading phenomena we concisely review the fundamental features of the whole in the three stages of its development. The most prominent of these features is, that in the course of history mankind sets before itself ever higher economic aims and finds the means of attaining these in a division of the burden of labour, which constantly extends until finally it embraces the whole people and requires the services of all for all. This cooperation is based, in the *^^51^L!!P-"!?1^°1^^ economy, upon blood-relationship, of town economy upon contiguity, and of national economy upon nationality. It is the road traversed by mankind in passing from clanship to society, which, as far as we can see, ends in an ever-ti,q:htening social organization. On this road the means for satisfying the wants of the indi- vidual continually grow in fulness and variety, and at the same time in dependence and complexity. The life and 142 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. labour of every individual becomes more and more en- twined with the Hfe and labour of many others. At the stage of household economy every commodity is consumed in the place of its origin; at the stage of town economy it passes immediately from the producer to the consumer; at the stage of national economy, both in its production and thereafter, it passes through various hands it circulates. In the course of the whole evolution the distance between production and consumption increases. At the first stage all commodities are consumption goods; at the second part of them become articles of exchange; at the third most of then^ are wares. The individual household at the first stage is a producing and consuming community in one; at the stage of town economy this state of things continues in so far as the journeyman craftsman and the peasant workman make part of the household of the person employing them; in national economy community in production and com- munity in consumption become distinct. The former is a business undertaking from whose returns as a rule several independent households are supported. When outside labour is necessary, it is at the first stage in a permanent relation of subjection to the producer (as slaves and serfs), at the second in one of service, and at the third the relationship is contractual. Under the inde- pendent household system the consumer is either himself a labourer, or the owner of the labourer; in town economy he makes a direct purchase of the workman's labour (wage-work), or of the product of his labour (handicraft); in national economy he ceases to stand in any relation to the labourer, and purchaser his goods from the entrepre- neur or merchant, by whom the labourer is paid. As for money, it is in independent domestic economy either entirely absent, or an article of direct use and a THE RISE OF NATION /tL ECONOMY. M3 means for storing up wealth. In town economy it is es- sentially a medium of exchange; in national economy it becomes a means of circulation and of profit-making as well. The three categories, payment in kind, money pay- ment Hnd payment based upon credit, correspond with the variouj roles played by money, though they do not ex- haust them. Capital scarcely exists at the first stage; we meet only with consumption goods. At the second stage implements of labour may be classed under the usual head of business capital, but this is by no means generally true of the raw materials. Acquisitive capital proper exists only in the form of trade capital. At the third, acquisitive capital rep- resents the means whereby goods are raised from ona stage of division of labour to the next and impelled through the whole process of circulation.'® Here every- thing becomes capital. From this point of view we might describe the independent household economy as lacking capital, town economy as hostile to capital, and national economy as capitalistic. Income and zvcalth under the household system com- pose an undivided and indivisible whole; though the be- ginnings of ground-rent are already perceptible. In town economy interest also usually appears as ground-rent; business profits are confined almost entirely to trade; the chief form of labour-wage is the wage paid to the crafts- man by the consumer. But even yet most commodities do not pass from their place of production into other es- tablishments. Pure income can be realized only by one who dehnitely surrenders a portion of his wealth in the purchase of rents. At the stage of national economy the four branches of income are definitely separated. Almost ' Cotnp. also Chaps v an d VII 144 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. m V the whole return from production is liquidated through trade. Under wealth, rent and acquisitive capital are dis- tinct from stores for consumption, which are kept at the lowest imaginable limit, since commerce frees individuals from the keeping of supplies. On the other hand the un- used surpluses of income, which at the first and second stages necessarily remained over from the wealth available for consumption, are now either directly added to business capital or transformed by means of saving- and other banks into interest-bearing loans, — that is, they are, in any case, converted into capital. At the stage of household economy the division of labour is confined to the household establishment; at the stage of town economy it consists either in the forma a of, and division into, trades within the town, or in a partition of production between town and country; while the promi- nent features of the stage of national economy are increas- ing division of production, subdivision of work within the various establishments, and displacement of labour from one business to another.^" Jndustry as an independent occupation is not found at the first stage, the whole transformation of raw material being merely housework. In the town economy we indeed find labourers pursuing some special industrial occupa- tion, but entrepreneurs are lacking; industry is either wage-work or handicraft, and he who wishes to ply it must first master it. In national economy industry carried on in factories and under the commission system is preponder- ant; and this presupposes extensive capital and an entre- preneur with mercantile skill. Technical mastery of the process of production by the entrepreneur is not indis- pensable.'* " For further details see Chap. VIII. " Comp. Chap IV. THE RISE OF N/ITIONAL ECONOMY. 145 In similar fashion a change occurs in the forms under which trade is pursued. Corresponding to the household system is itinerant trade, to town economy market trade, and to national economy trade with permanent establish- ment. If at the first two stages trade is merely supple- mentary to an otherwise autonomous system of produc- tion, it becomes in national economy a necessary link between production and consimiption. It draws away from transportation, which now attains an independent position and organization. Commercial services were, to be sure, not lacking in the ancienTsTave and the mediaeval manorial systems; they de- volved upon special slaves or serfs. In the Middle Ages we find town messengers who were originally in the ex- clusive service of the municipal authorities, but later added the carriage of private correspondence. At the threshold of modem times stands the postal service, at first restricted to state purposes, by-and-bye extended to the public. In our century follow the railway, telegraph, telephone, and steamship lines — with which the State interferes in the interest of economy — and along with them the most varied private undertakings for facilitating communication." AfaJlthestages, however, certain commercial services have been organized by the sovereign administration, in the initial instance always for its own special requirements. Credit is at the first stage purely consumption credit; and can be obtained only by the person pledging himself and all his property. At the second stage, in the matter of personal credit, servitude for debt is softened to imprison- ment for debt. Along with consumption credit appears a type of credit on the return from immovables which is met in garb of a purchase, and must be considered as the ■ For the analogous development in the newspaper press see Chap. 146 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. normal form of credit under town economy. Business or productive credit, the distinctive form of credit in modern times, is first developed in trade, whence it spreads to every sphere of industrial life. State credit appears in the States of antiquity naturally as a forced loan; in the medi- aeval towns as the sale of annuities and redeemable claims; in the modern States as the disposing of perpetual rents or of redeemable interest-bearing bonds. In the domain of public services similar stages may also be pointed out. Legal protection is at first a matter for the clan, later for the feudal lord; in the Middle Ages the towns form districts of separate jurisdiction; at present the enforcement of law and police protection are functions of the State. The same is the case with education. At the first stage education devolves upon the family, as it does to-day still in Iceland. The Roman pccdagogus is a slave. In the Middle Ages it is autonomous household establish- ments, namely, the monasteries, that organize the educa- tional system; later arise the municipal and cathedral schools; peculiar to modem times are the concentration and supervision of instruction in state institutions. This development is even more apparent in the arrangements for defence. Among many peoples still at the stage of eco- nomic isolation each separate house is fortified (for ex- ample, the palisades c' the Malays and Polynesians), and in early medijcval times the manor is protected by wall and moat. At the second economic stage each city is a fort- ress; at the th'rd a few fortifications along the borders secure the whole State. It is sufficiently significant that Louvois, the creator of the first system of border fortifica- tion, was a coiitemporary of Colbert, the founder of mod- ern French national economy. These parallels might be multiplied. As in moving into a new building one's first care is to introduce order for THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 147 the time being, so with regard to the subject-matter of this chapter no fair-minded person will expect that everything has been exhaustively treated and every detail assigned its proper place. The writer clearly perceives how inade- quately the various phenomena of the two earlier stages of industrial evolution have as yet been worked over, and how very seriously their economic significance still de- mands accurate ascertainment. But for the present it may suffice If we have made clear the regularity of development both generally and in detail. Only one thing further would we particularly em- phasize. Household economy, town economy, national economy— these phrases do not denote a series whose terms are mutually exclusive. One kind of economic life has always been the predominant, and in the eyes of con- temporaries the normal, one. Many elements of town economy, and even of independent domestic economy still project into the present. Even to-day a very consid- erable part of the national production does not pass into general circulation, but is consumed in the households where it is produced; another po-tion. again, circulates no farther than from one establishment to another. Hence it would almost appear as if those people were in error who regard the task of political economy to be the explanation of the nature and coherence of commercial phenomena, and those right who confine themselves to a descriptior of economic forms and their historical trans- formations. Vet that would be a fatal error, involving the sur- render of the scientific labours of over a century, as wHl ar a complete misconception of our economic prosf^nl. To-day not a sack of wheat is produced even on the most remote farm, that is not directly linked to the industrial hfe nf the nation as a whole. Even if it be consumed m 148 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. the house of the producer, nevertheless a large portion of the means of its production (the plough, the scythe, the threshing-machine, the artificial fertilizers, the draught- animals, etc.) is obtained through trade; and the con- sumption of one's own products takes place only when from market conditions it seems economically advisable. Thus the sack of wheat is knit by a strong cord to the great intricate web of national commerce. And so are we all in our every economic thought and deed. It is therefore a matter of great satisfaction that, after a period of diligent collection of material, the economic problems of modern commerce have in recent times been zealously taken up again, and that an attempt is being made to correct and develop the old system in the same way in which it arose, with the aid, however, of a much larger store of facts. For the only method of investigation which will enable us to approach the complex causes of commercial phenomena is that of abstract isolation, and logical deduction. The sole inductive process that can likewise be considered, namely, the statistical, is not suffi- ciently exact and penetrating for most of the problems that have to be handled here, and can be employed only to supplement or control. For the economic periods of the past the task will not be different. Here, to be sure, it will be even more necessary first to collect the facts and present them according to form and function; next we must gain a proper conception of the nature of the phenomena; and then we may logically dissect them and investigate their casual connection. We will thus have to advance by the same method that " classi- cal political economy " has applied to the industry of the present. For some phases of the economic life of the an- cient oUos this has already been done in a masterful man- ner by Rodbcrtus; for the economic life of the Middle THE RISE OF N^ITIONML ECONOMY. 149 Ages such a task has yet scarcely been essayed. The at- tempt can succeed only with investigators fully able to grasp the actual assumptions of past economic periods and our ancestors' ways of thinking on economic matters; it can but fail if the half understood, half arbitrarily recon- structed economic conditions of the past continue to be reflected in terms of the modem theory of exchange. Only in this way, in our opinion, can investigations in economic history and the theory of contemporary eco- nomics be mutually helpful; only thus can we gain a clearer insight into the regularity both of economic devel- opment and of economic phenomena. i CHAPTER IV. A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. In economic and social matters most people have very definite opinions on what should be, often much more definite than on what is. What in their view should be is by no means an ideal state of affairs, an imaginative crea- tion that has never been realized. Very frequently indeed it is a conception drawn from the conditions that prevailed in times more or less remote, which long custom has led us to consider normal. Such is the case, if we mistake not, with many of our contemporaries regarding what we call handicraft and the so-called handicraft problem. One has become accus- tomed to look upon handicraft as the normal form of in- dustry, after it has dominated five centuries or more of the life of the burgher class of Germany. The proverb says " Handicraft stands on golden ground "; and obser- vation teaches us that this ground is, according to present- day valuation, no longer golden. We ask ourselves how that happy condition can be restored, how handicraft can be " resuscitated." Rut what right has one to regard handicraft as the normal form of industry and thus as it were to strive after an ideal whose realization belongs to the past? The earlier political economists represent handicraft as the original form of industrial production. " In a tribe of 150 A HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 151 hunters or shepherds," says Adam Smith/ " a particular person makes bows and arrows with more readiness and dexterity than any other. He frequently exchanges them for cattle or venison with his companions; and he finds at last that he can in this manner get more cattle and venison than if he himself went to the field to catch them." Finally, " the making of bows and arrows grows to be his chief business and he becomes a sort of armourer." If we follow this historical progress a couple of stages further, the original handicraftsman will after a time probably take an apprentice, and when the latter has learned his trade, a second, while the first becomes his journeyman. Seek as we may, we find nothing added by subsequent development. When we speak of a craftsman to-day we have in mind a business undertaker on a small scale, who has passed by regular stages of transition from apprentice to journeyman and from journeyman to master workman, who produces with his own hand and his own capital for a locally limited circle of customers, and into whose hands flows undiminished the whole pi .duct of his labour. Everything that one can demand of an industrial system founded on justice seems realized in the life of the typical craftsman— gradual social progress, independence, an in- come corresponding to services rendered. And those forms of industry that vary from this primal type, namely, house industry and factory production, may readily ap- pear abnormal; and the social stratification of those em- ployed, and the accompanying unequal distribution of income out of harmony with the idea of economic justice. Even later economists are rarely free from this popular conception. In contrasting the three industrial systems that they recognise, handicraft, house industry, and factory " Bk. I, ch. 2. 152 A HISTORICAL SURf^EY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. n P production, they almost unwittingly draw from the funda- mental institutions of handicraft the criterion for judging the others. Until quite recently house industry was for many of them merely a degenerate handicraft or a transi- tional form, and the factory a necessary evil of the age of machinery. This narrowness of view was prejudicial to the scientific understanding of even modern industrial meth- ods, open as these are to direct observation. An historically constructive view, such as we will here present, must from the start shake off the idea that any particular form in any department of economic activity can be the norm for all times and peoples. Even handi- craft is for it only one phenomenon in the great stream of history, with its origin, continuance, and success de- pendent upon certain given economic conditions. It is neither the original nor even a necessary form in the his- torical evolution of industrial production. It is, in other words, just as little necessary that the industry of a country shall have passed through the handicraft phase before ar- riving at house industry or factory manufacture as that every people shall have been hunters or nomads before passing over to settled agriculture. Among us handicraft has been preceded by other industrial systems, which, in- deed, even in Europe, still exist in part. The great historical significance of these primitive in- dustrial forms in the evolution of economic conditions has hitherto been almost wholly ignored, although they shaped for thousands of years the economic life of the nations and left lasting marks upon their social organizations. Only a comparatively small portion of the history of industry, namely, that part which written laws have enabled us to know, has been at all cleared up; and this. too. much more on its formal side than as regards its inner life, its method of operation. Even the guild handicraft of the Middle ■ M HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 153 Ages, to which in recent times so much persevering and penetrating labour has been devoted, has, on the side of its actual operation, enjoyed scarcely more accurate in- vestigation. In this domain arbitrary theoretical con- structions based upon the postulates and concepts of modern commercial economy still widely prevail. Our " historical " political enonomy, it is true, has a wealth of material for the economic history of the classical and modem peoples. But it has hardly yet been duly noted that the complex nature of all social phenomena ren- ders it just as difficult for the investigator of to-day to re- construct the economic conditions of the life of the na- tions of antiquity and of the Middle Ages as to forecast even with the most lively and powerful imagination the ultimate consequences of the " socialist State of the fu- ture." We shall not arrive at an understanding of whole epochs of early economic history until we study the eco- nomic side of the life of primitive and uncivilized peoples of the present with the care we to-day devote to English- men and Americans. Instead of sending our young politi- cal economists on journeys of investigation to these latter, we should rather send them to the Russians, the Rumani- ans, or the South Slavs; we should study the characteristic features of primitive economic life and the legal concep- tions of the peoples of our newly acquired colonies before such features and conceptions disappear under the influ- ence of European trade. It is almost a fortunate circumstance that such external influences rarely aflFect deeply the real life of the people, but are confined chiefly to the more privileged classes. Hence it is that in extensive regions of eastern and north- ern Europe, which the unheeding traveller courses through by rail, there may still be observed among the 154 A HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. rural population primiiive forms of production that mod- em commerce has caused to vary but slightly. In the attempt made in the following pages to give a compact presentation of what we know of the industrial methods of "-uch " backward " tribes and the present C' n- clusions of industrial history, our sole aim is to present in clear outline the chief stages of development.* In or- der to have a guiding thread through the perplexing va- riety and wealth of forms of individual ethnographical observations, it is most necessary to separate i} ^lical and casual, to disregard subsidiary and transitional forms, and to consider a new phase of development as beginning only where changes in industrial technique call forth economic phenomena that imply a radical alteration in the organ- ization of society. In this way we arrive at five main sys- tems of industrj-. In historical succession they are: 1. Housework (Domestic Work). 2. Wage-work. 3. Handicraft. 4. Commission Work (House Industry). 5. Factory Work. We shall first attempt to give a concise outline of the characteristic economic peculiarities of these indus- trial systems, merely indicating the socio-historical im- port of the whole development. The filling out of oc- casional gaps and the explanation of the transitions from one system to the other may be left to detailed investiga- tion. In our sketch we shall, naturally, devote most time to the two industrial systems precedent to handicraft, 'The present sketch brings together in popular form only the most important features. Further discussion, and references to the most essential literature, will be found in my article under the head " Ge- werbe" in the Handwort. der Staatswiss. (2d ed.), IV, pp. 360-393. A HISTORICAL SURyEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 155 while for the later a brief account may suffice. We begin with housework.' Housework is industrial production in and for the house from raw materials furnished by the household itself. In its original and purest form it presupposes the absence of exchange, and the ability of each household to satisfy by its own labour the wants of its members. Each com- modity passes through all the stages of production in the establishment in which it is to be consumed. Production is consequently undertaken only according to the needs of the house itself. There is still neither circulation of goods nor capital. The wealth of the house consists entirely in consumption goods in various stages of completion, such as corn, meal, bread, flax, yarn, cloth, and clothes. It also possesses auxiliary means of production, such as the hand- mill, the :i <e, the distafif, and the weaver's loom, but no goods with which it could procure other goods by pro- cess of exchange. All it has it owes to its own lalwur, ' It is from Norway and Sweden that the expression HausAeiss (housework) has been transplanted into Germany, where during the last twenty years it has become current. In those countries it was employed for certain occupations of the members of the domestic circle, such as spinning, weaving, sewing, the making of wooden utensils, and tl. ° like. It is the application of industrial technique that, favoured by climate and settlement, has from early times become indigenous in those parts. Through it the peasant household works up for its own use the raw material from field and wood. As this technique threatened to disappear under the influence of modern com- mercial conditions it was the opinion in Denmark and Norway that it should he reanimated through school instruction. Few, indeed, of the promoters of manual instruction — this new branch of instruction, whose pedagogical importance cannot be denied— have formed a clear conception of what housework really signified and in part still signifies for the Northern peoples. Here and there, especially at its inaugura- tion, manual tr ining was regarded as a means for establishing new house industries. But housework and house industry are two indus- trial systems separated historically from one another (at least among us) by two centuries. 156 A HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. aiul it is scarcely possible to separate the operations of the household from those of production. In the fonn of housework, intlustry is older than agri- culture. Wherever explorers of new countries have come into contact with primitive peoples, they have found many forms of industrial skill, such as the making of bow and arrow, the wea\ mg of mats and vessels out of reeds, bast, and tough roots, a primitive pottery, tanning skins, crush- ing farinaceous strains on the grinding-stone, smelting iron ore, the building of houses. To-day the huntini, tribes of Norti< America, the tisher tribes of the South Se;i the nomad hordes of Siberia, and the agricultural neg-^ tribes of Africa make similar display of varied technical skill without possessi ig actual artisans. Even the wretched naked forest tribes of Central Brazil make their clubs and bows and arrows, build houses and >ark canoes, make tools of bone and stoae, weave baskets for carrying and storing, scoop out gourd dishes, spin, knit, and weave, form artistically ornamented clay vessels without a knowl- edge of the potter's wheel, carve ornamented digging- sticks, stools, flutes, combs, and masks, and prepare many kinds of ornaments out of feathers, skins, etc. In the temperate and colder countries with the advance to the use of the plough, this activity loses more and more the character of the accidental; the whole husbandry ac- quires a settled character; the mild period of the year must be devoted to the procuring of raw material and to out- door work: in winter the working up of this material clusters the members of the household around the hearth. For each kind of work there is developed a definite method which is incorporated into the domestic life according to the natural and imperative demand; of economy; about it custom weaves its fine golden ethical thread: it enriches and ennobles the lite of men among whom, with its sim- A HtSTORIC/iL SURREY OF INDUSTRI/1L SYSTEMS. 157 4 pie technique and archaic forms, it is transmitted from gen- eration to generation. As people labour only for their own requirements, the interest of the producer in the work of his hands long survives the completion r i the work. His highest technical skill and his whole ariistic sense are em- bodied in it. It is for this reason that the products of do- ■^estic work throughout Germany have become for our v. of artistic industry such a rich mine of models of pop- u a style. '' le Norwegian peasant is not merely his own smith and j ; ler, like the Westphalian Hofschulzc in Immermann's ' Munchhauset. "; with his own hands he also builds his V joden house, makes his field-implements, wagons and ■sleighs, tans leather, carves from wood various kinds of 'louse utensils, and even makes metal ones." In Iceland the very peasants" are skilful workers in silver. In the Highlands of Scotland, up to the close of last century, every man was his own weaver, fuller, tanner, and shoe- maker. In Galicia and Bukowina, in many parts of Hun- gary and Siebenbiirgen, in Rumania, and among the southern Slav peoples there could scar ely be found, down to recent times, any other craftsman than the smith, and he was usually a gypsy. In Greece and other lands of the Balkan peninsula the only additional craftsmen were oc- casional vandering builders.'' Numberless examples of a 'Eile I Sundt. Om Hu.1iden i Norge (Christiania, 1867). Blom, Das Konign .\on.'ege» (Leipzig, 1843), P- 237. Forester, Xoru<ay in i84f end 1849 (London, 1850), p. 113. E- Sidenbladh. Schweden, Statist. Mitteiiungen s. ll'icner IVeltausstellung, 1873. •[Dr. Biicher is evidenUy speaking of the Icelandic peasant of an earlier time. — En.] ' On the Austrian populations compare Die Hausmduslrie Oesterreichs. Ein Kommcntar z. hausindustrieUen Abteilung auf d. allgemeinen land- u. forJ.wirtschaftlich. Ausstdluug su IV'"*!. 1890, ed. by W. Exner; also Oesterreichische Monatsschritt fiir Gesellschaftswissenschaft, IV, 90 ff.. VIII, 22. IX. 98 and 331; A. Riegl, Textile hausindustrie in f?>.ti 158 A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. similar kind might be adduced from other peoples. The wonderful adroitness and dexterity of the Russian and Swedish peasants, to cite a striking instance, has its un- doubted origin in the varied technical tasks of their own households. The industrial employments of women in ancient and modern times, such as spinning, weaving, bak- ing, etc., are too well known to call for further reference. In order to obtain an idea of the wealth of domestic in- dustrial skill that charactenzes the life of less civilized peo- ples a detailed description would be necessary. Lack of space unfortunately forbids that here. It will suffice, how- ever, to reproduce the following sentences from an account of household work in Bukowina:* •' In the narrow circle of the family, or at least within the limits of his little village, the Bukowina countryman supplies all his own necessaries. In building a house the husband, as a rule, can do the work of carpenter, roofer, etc., while the wife must attend to plastering the woven and slatted walls or stopping the chinks in the log wa..:> with moss, pounding out of the floor, and many other dilated duties. From the cultivation of the plant from which cloth is spun or the raising of sheep down to the Oesterreich in the Mi.tciluPgT. d. k. k. tistcrreich. Museums, New Series, IV, pp. .,11 ff.; Braar und Krejesi. Der Hausdeiss in Ungarn (Leipzig, 1886); Schwic'<cr, i:tatistik d. Kbnigreichs Vngarn, pp. 403 ff-. 411, 426 flf.; J. Tanet, Luiartt u. Siebcnburgen (Leipzig, 184^), H, pp. i6j! 173. 264. J69; Franz Joseph Prinz \->n BaUenberg, Die I'olks- wirtschafll EntwicMung Hulgaricns (Leipzig, iSgi. ; Iwantschoff, Primitive Formen d. Ccwerbcbctriebs in liulgaricn (Leipzig, 1896). On the other lands of the Balkan peninsula sec Reports from Her Majesty's Diflomalic and Consular Agents Abroad, respecting the Condition ot the Industrial Classes in Foreign Countries (London, 1870-72); Tarajanz, Das Ceu'erbe bei d. Armeniern (Leipzig, 1897): Petri, Ehstland u. d. Ehslcn (r.ntli.i. i«o.'). II. pp. 2,10- 1. "C. A. RomMorfcr in Kxner, Die llausinduslrie Oesterreuhs. pp. iSOfT. Comp. H. Wiglitzky. Die Uukoumacr I'ausindustrie u. d. MiUtl N. IVege :. Hebung derselb. (Czernowitz, 1888). A HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 159 making of bed and other clothes out of linen, wool or furs, leather, felt, or plaited straw, the Bukowina country folk produce everything, including dyes from plants of their own culture, as well as the necessary though, indeed, ex- tremely primitive utensils. The same holds in general of the food-supply. With a rather heavy expenditure of labour the peasant cultivates his field of maize, and with his handmill grinds the kukuruz meal used by him in bak- ing mamaliga, his chief article of food, which resembles polenta. His simple farming implements, the dishes and utensils for household and kitchen, he, or, if not he, some self-taught villager, is also able to make. The working of iron, alone, a substance that the native population uses in exceedingly small quantities, he generally leaves to the gypsies scattered through the country." Yet whatever the industrial skill developed by the self- sufficing household, such a method of supply was destined to prove inadequate when the household diminished to the smaller cii ' ? of blood-relations, which we call the family. The ancient family group, it is true, was broader than our present family; but just at the time when wants are in- creasing in extent and variety, the tribal organization of many peoples breaks down and a more minute division of labour among the members of the househo]<l is rendered iinnossible. The transition to specialized production and a system of exchange would at this point have been un- avoidable had it not been possible, by adopting slaves or by utilizing serf labour, to enlarge artificially the house- hold circle. The greater the number of these unfrce mem- bers of ti.c household, the easier it is to introduce a varied division of labour among them atul to train each person for a definite industrial employment. Thus we find among the house-slaves of the wealthy I tl l6o A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. Greeks and Romans industrial workers of various kinds;* and in the famous instructions of Charles the Great regard- ing the management of his country estates we have definite rules prescribing what kinds of unfree workers shall be maintained at each villa. " Each steward," we read, " shall have in his service good workmen, such as smiths, workers in gold and silver, shoemakers, turners, car- penters, shield-makers, fishers, fowlers, soap-boilers, brew- ers of mead {siccratorcs), bakers, and net-makers," Co- pious evidence of a similar kind is available for the manors of the nobility and the monasteries. The handicraftsmen maintained by them are at their exclusive service; in some cases they are merely domestic servants receiving their board and lodging in the manor-house, in others they are settled and gain their living on their own holdings, and in return render villein services in that branch of labour in which they have special skill. In token that they are en- gaged to hold their skill at the service of the manor, they bear the title ofUcialcs, ofliciati, i.e., officials. Hou.sework, we see, has here obtained an extensive or- ganization, which allows the lord of the manor a relatively large and varied consumption of industrial products. But housework does not remain mere production for direct consumption. At a very early stage inequality of natural endowment causes a varied development of techni- cal skill. One tribe produces pottery, stone implements, or arrows, and a neighbouring tribe does not. Such industrial products are then scattered among other tribes as gifts of hospitality, or as spoils of war. and later as the objects of exchange." .\mong the ancient Greeks wealthy slave- owners cansed a considerable number of their dependent •Comp H. Fr.incotte, l.'lnduslric dans la Crhc andenne, I (Briissels. iqoo); Walloti, Hist, de Uisclavagc dans I /InliquiU ( 2(\ cd.. Vans, iS/g). • Comp. above, pp. 54 IT. A HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. i6i labourers, whom they did not need for their o»vn estates, to be trained for a special industry, and then to produce for the market. In a similar fashion peasant families exchange the surplus products of their household industry more fre- quently than the surpluses from their apfriculture or cattle- raising. As in the Old Testament it is one of the good qualities of the virtuous wife to dispose of the wares that her own hands have produced,** so to-day the negro wife in Central Africa carries to the weekly market the pots or basketware she produces in order to exchange them for salt or pearls. In like manner, in many parts of Germany the rural population have from the beginning of the Middle Ages sold their linen cloths at the town mar- kets and fairs; and in the era of mercantilism measures were taken by the government in Silesia and West- phalia to facilitate the export of home-made linen. So also in the Baltic provinces during the Middle Ages the coarse woollen cloth, Vadhmal, which is still woven by the peasant women, was one of the best known articles of trade, and actually served as money. Similarly among many African peoples domestic products made by neigh- bouring tribes serve as general mediums of exchange. In almost every villager's house in Japan yarn is spun and cloth woven out of cotton grown in his own fields, and of this a portion comes into exchange. In Sweden the West Goths and Smalanders wander through almost the whole country offering for sale home-woven stuffs. In Hungary, Galicia, Rumania, and the southern Slav countries. ever>'- where one can meet with pe.i'^ants oflfering for sale at the weekly town markets their earthen and wooden wares, and peasant women selling, along with vegetables and eggs, aprons, embroidered ribbons, and laces which they them- .«elves have made. ' F. Buhl, Dit social I'crhdltnisse d IsratUtcn (LeipziR, iftyK), p. 34, wmm ■ i62 A HISTORICAL SURyEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. It is especially when the land owned by a family be- comes divided up and no longer suffices for its mainte- nance, that a part of the rural population take up a special branch of housework and produce for the market in ex- actly the same way as our small peasants in South Ger- many produce wine, hops, or tobacco. At first the neces- sary raw material is gained from their own land or drawn from the communal forests; later on, if need be, it is also purchased. All sorts of allied branches of produc- tion are added ; and thus there develops out of housework, as in many parts of Russia, an endlessly varied system of peasant industry on a small scale. But the evolution may take another course, and an in- dependent professional class of industrial labourers arise, and with them our second industrial system — zvage-work. Whereas all industrial skill has hitherto been exercised in close association with property in land and tillage, the adept house-labourer now frees himself from this associa- tion, and upon his technical skill founds for himself an ex- istence that gradually becomes independent of property in land. But he has only his simple tools for work; he has no business capital. He therefore always exercise^ his skill upon raw material furnished him by the producer of the raw material, who is at the same time the consumer of the finished product. Here again two distinct forms of this relationship are possible. In one ca.se the wage-worker is taken tem- porarily into the house, receives his board and, if he does not belong to the place, his lodging as well, together with the daily wage; and leaves when the needs of his customer are satisfied. In South Germany we call this going on one's itinerancy iuuf die Star j^chcn), and may accordingly designate the wlmle industrial phase as that of ititirrancy (Stor), and the labourer carrying on work in this manner A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 163 as the itinerata (Storer). The dressmakers and seam- stresses wham our women in many places are accustomed to take inter the house may serve as an illustration. On the otijcr hand, the wage-worker may have his own place of business, and the raw material be given out to him. For working it iip he receives piece-work wage. In the country the linen-weaver, the miller, and the baker work- ing for a wage are examples. We will designate this form of work home work.'' It is met with chiefly in industries that demand permanent means of production difficult to transport, such as mills, ovens, weavers' looms, forges, etc. Both forms of wage-work are still very common in all parts of the world. Examples might be drawn from In- dia and Japan, from Morocco and the Sudan, and from almost all European countries. The system can be traced m Babylonian temple records and in ancient Egypt; it can be followed in literature from Homer down through an- cient and mediaeval times to the present day. The whole conception of the relation of the customer to the independ- ent (personally free or unfree) artisan in early Greek and Roman law rests upon wage-work; »° and only by it are numerous ordinances of mediaeval guild law to be ex- plained. In the .\lpine lands it is still the predominant industrial method in the country. The Styrian writer P. K. Roseg- ger lias, in an interesting book, •> given a picture of his ex- periences as apprentice to a peripatetic tailor carrying on his trade among the peasants. " The peasant craftsmen," * Heimwtrk. " in Diocletian's edict de pretiis rtrum venaHum of the year 301 it appears as the prevailing industrial form. Comp. my articles in the dit ges. Slaatswissenschaft. 67.1 flr. "A Jakob H'ilde SO (1894), especially pp 4us meinem Handwerk Schnetballen, F Kirschen, p. 347. •erleben (LeipziR. 1880). C^ Series (Popular Ed ). pp. 12-ij. omp. also Hans- 219-224. i64 A HISTORICAL SURyEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. he says in the preface, " such as the cobbler, the tailor, the weaver, the cooper (in other places also the saddler, the wheelwright, the carpenter, and, in general, all artisan builders), are in many Alpine districts a sort of nomad folk. Each of them has, indeed, a definite abode somewhere, either in his own little house or in the rented room of a peasant's home, where his family lives, where he has safe- keeping for his possessions, and where he spends his Sun- days and holidays. On Monday morning, however, he puts his tools upon his back or in his pocket and starts out upon his rounds; that is, he goes out for work and takes up his quarters in the home of the peasant by whom he has been engaged, and there remains until he has satisfied the household needs. Then he wends his way to another farm. The handicraftsman in his temporary abode is looked upon as belonging to the family." Every peasant's house has a special room with a " handicraftsman's bed " for his quarters overnight; wherever he has been working during the week, he is invited to Sunday dinner. We find described in almost the same words the indus- trial conditions of rural Sweden and many parts of Nor- way. In Russia and the southern Slav countries there are hundreds of thousands of wage-workers, belonging espe- cially to the building and clothing trades, who lead a con- tinuous migratory life and who, on account of the great distances travelled, often remain away from home half a year or more. From the point of view of development these two forms of wage-work have different origins. Itinerant labour is based upon the exclusive possession of aptitude for a spe- cial kind of work, homework upon the exchisive posses- sion of fixed means of production. Upon this basis there now arises all sorts of mixed forms between housework and wage-work. A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 165 The itinerant labourer is at first an experienced neigh- bour whose advice is sought in carrying out an important piece of work, the actual work, however, still being per- formed by the members of the household.^^ ^^^^ j^j^j. j^ is long the practice for the members of the customer's family to give the necessary assistance to the craftsman and his journeyman; and this is still met with in the country, for example, in the raising of a frame building. In the case of hontezvork the later tradesman is at first merely the owner of the business plant and technical director of the production, the customer doing the actual work. This frequently remains true in the country to-day with oil-presses, flax-mills, mills for husking barley and oats, and cider-mills. In many North German towns the mediaeval maltsters and brewers were merely the owners of malt-kilns and brewing-houses, who for a fee gave the citizens the opportunity of malting their own barley and brewing their own beer. In the flour-mills the customer at least sup- plied the handler who attended to the sifting of the meal. Even to-day it is customary in many localities for the peasant's wife, after kneading the dough, to mould the bread-loaves in her own house; the baker simply places his oven at her disposal, heats it and attends to the baking. In French and western Swiss towns the public washing places are managed in much the same fashion, merely pro- "The same is true of house-building in the Caroline Islands, where the takelbay, or master builder, is scarcely more than the exerciser of the evil powers that threaten the new structure. Sec Kubary, Ethnogr. Beitrdge, pp. 227 ff. The case is different with wagon-building in Armenia, where the skilled neighbour, in return for a present, directs the putting together of the vehicle after the separate parts have been made ready by the members of the household: Tarajanz, as above, p. 27. Similarly with house-building in Faror; Ztschr. d. Ver. f. Volksk.. Ill (1893), p. 163. I II ■lill ' V i66 yt HISTORJCAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. viding their customers with washing-apparatus and hot water, and frequently a drying-place in addition, while the work is done by the servants or female members of the customer's household. These afterwards bring the washed and dried linen to the mangle to be smoothed out, in which process the owner assists by working the handle. Pay- ment is made by the hour. In Posen and West Prussia until recently it was the custom for the owner of a smithy merely to supply fire, tools, and iron, leaving the actual work to his customers.^' From the economic point of view the essential feature of the wage-work system is that there is no business capital. Neither the raw material nor the finished industrial product is for its producer ever a means of profit. The character and extent of the production are still deter- mined in every case by the owner of the soil, who pro- duces the raw material; he also superintends the whole process of production. The peasant grows, threshes, and cleans the rye and then turns it over to the miller to be ground, paying him in kind; the meal is given to the baker, who delivers, on receipt of a baker's wage and in- demnification for the firing, a certain number of loaves made from it. From the sowing of the seed until the mo- ment the bread is consumed the product has never been " F.rlcbnisse ewes Geistlichen im iistl. Grensgebiet. in the Tagl. Rund- schau, L'nterh. Beilage. 1879. Mo 2S8. A point of interest here is the supplying of the iron by the owner of the business, this method of carrying on work thus forming a transition to handicraft. There are also forms in which itinerancy and homework are mingled. To this class belongs the Russian migratory tailor, who in each vil- lage where he has customers rents a room for a time and does work for wages. So also, according to Tarajanz, the silversmiths in Ar- menia. In the latter country the owner of an oil-press has to provide his machine, the necessary uirkmen. and the oxen for drivitig it; the customer not only assists in the work himself, but he pays, and also boards, the workmen and supplies the fodder for the oxen. A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 167 capital, but always a mere article for use in course of prep- aration. No earnings of management and interest charges or middleman's profits attach to the finished product, but only wages for work done. Under certain social conditions, «nd where needs are very simple, this is a thoroughly economic method of pro- duction and, like housework, secures the excellence of the product and the complete adjustment of supply to demand. It avoids exchange, where this would lead only to a round- about method of supplying the producer of the raw mate- rial with wares prepared from his own products. But it also forces the consumer to run the risk attaching to indus- trial production, as only those needs that can be foreseen can find suitable and prompt satisfaction, while a sudden need must often remain unsatisfied because the wage- worker happens at the very time to be elsewhere engaged. In the case of homework there is the additional danger that a portion of the material furnished may be embezzled or changed. The system has also many disadvantages for the wage-worker. Amongst these are the inconveniences and loss of time suffered in his itinerancy from place to place; also the irregularity of employment, which leads now to the overwork, now to the complete idleness, of the workman. Both forms of wage-work thus act satisfac- torily only when the unoccupied hours can be turned to account in some allied branch of agriculture. In the Middle Ages, when this could be done, wage- work greatly facilitated the emancipation of the artisan from serfdom and feudal obligations, as it requires prac- tically no capital to start an independent business. It is a great mistake still common to look upon the class of guild handicraftsmen of the Middle Ages as a class of small capitalists. It was in essence rather an industrial labour- ing class, distinguished from the labourers of to-day by the i68 A HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. fact that each worked not for a single employer but for a large number of consumers. The supplying of the mate- rial by the customer is common to almost all mediaeval liandicrafts; in many instances, indeed, it continues for centuries, even after the customer has ceased to produce the raw material himself and must buy it, as, for example, the leather for the shoemaker and the cloth for the tailor. The furnishing of the material by the master workman is a practice that takes slow root; at first it holds only for the poorer customers, but later for the wealthy as well. Thus arises handicraft in the sense in which it is generally under- stood to-day; but alongiide it wage-work maintains itself for a long time, even entering, in many cases, into the service of handicraft. Thus the tanner is wage-worker for the shoemaker and saddler, the miller for the baker, the wool-beater, the dyer, and the fuller wage-workers for the cloth-maker. In the towns itinerancy is the first of the two forms of wage-work to decline. This decline is considerably hastened by the interference of the guilds.** The itiner- ancy was too suggestive of early villenage. In it the workman is, so to speak, only a special kind of day- labourer, who must temporarily become a subordinate member of another household. Consequently from the fourteenth century on we find the guild ordinances fre- quently prohibiting the master from working in private houses. To the same cause is to be ascribed the hatred " In this connection it may not be out of place to point out that, in the industrial limitation of those entitled to the privilcRes of the guild, the old housework was at the same time aflfected. In very many of the guild ordinances we find the regulation that the non-guildsman may do handicraftsman's work, but only in so far as the needs of his household demand, not for purposes of sale. The surplus house pro- duction for the market described above (pp. i6o, i6l) was thereby made impossible. A HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 169 displayed by the town craftsmen towards those of the country, because the migratory labour of the latter could not well be forbidden. Eventually itinerant or botcher^'" becomes a general term of contempt for those who work without regular credentials from the guilds. In the North German towns the guild masters claimed the right of en- tering the houses of their customers to ferret out the itiner- ant artisans and call them to account, — the so-called " botcherhunt "; and the public authorities were often weak enough to wink at this breach of the domestic rights of the citizen. But the guilds did not everywhere have such an easy task in supplanting one industrial system by another. As early as the middle of the fourteenth century the sovereign authority in the Austrian duchy takes vigorous measures against them. In the statutes of the electorate of Saxony for the year 1482 shoemakers, tailors, furriers, joiners, glaziers, and other handicraftsmen who shall refuse with- out sufficient reason to work in the house of their cus- tomer are made liable to a fine of three florins, a high sum for those times. In Basel a definite statute governing house tailors was enacted in 1526 for the maintenance of " ancient and honourable customs." In many German ter- ritories definite ordinances were made regulating the charges of the various kinds of wage-workers. Thus in many crafts, especially in the building trade, wage-work has persisted down to the present time. In the majority, however, its place has been taken by the industrial system that to-day is customarily desig- nated handicraft, whose nature we have indicated at the beginning of the present* chapter. It might also be called pricc-zvork,^^ which would mark the contrast with wage- " Bonhast. " Prciswerk. Miarocorv rbmution test chart (ANSI ond ISO TEST CHART No 2) A /APPLIED INA^GE 'eS] foil Main StrMi »0<:hMl»r. N«« torh U609 IJ« ("6) »a2 - 0300 Phon« ("6) JM 5»g9 - ro. nr m i I 170 y4 HISTORIC/IL SURREY OF INDUSTRJylL SYSTEMS. work. For the handicraftsman is distinguished from the wage-worker only by the fact that he possesses all the means of production, and sells for a definite price the fin- ished article which is the product of his own raw material and his own incorporated labour, while the wage-worker merely receives a recompense for his labour. All the important characteristics of handicraft may be summed up in the single expression custom production. It is the method of sale that distinguishes this industrial sys- tem from all later ones. The handicraftsman always works for the consumer of his product whether it be that the latter by placing separate orders affords the occasion for the work, or that the two meet at the weekly or yearly market. Ordered work and work for the market must supplement each other if " dull times " are to be avoided. As a rule the region of sale is local, namely, the town and its more immediate neighbourhood. The customer buys at first hand, the handicraftsman sells to the actual con- sumer. This assures a proper adjustment of supply and demand and introduces an ethical feature into the whole relationship; the producer in the presence of the con- sumer feels responsibility for his work. With the rise of handicraft a wide cleft, so to speak, appears in the economic process of production. Hitherto the owner of the land, though perhaps calling in the aid of other wage-workers, had conducted this whole process; now there are two classes of economic activity, each of which embraces only a part of the process of production, one producing the raw material, the other the manu- factured article. It is a principle that handicraft endeav- oured to carry out wherever possible — an article should pass through all the stages of its f)reparation in the same workshop. In this way the needed capital is diminished and frecjuent additions of profit to price avoided. Bv the A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 171 acquisition of an independent business capital the artisan class is changed from a mere wage-earning class of labour- ers into a capitalistic producing class; and the movable property now, dissociated from land-ownership, accumu- lates in its hands and becomes the basis of an independent social and political reputability which is embodied in the burgher class. The direct relationship between the handicraftsman and the consumer of his products makes it necessary that the business remain small. Whenever any one line of handi- craft threatens to become too large, new handicrafts split off from it and appropriate part of its sphere of produc- tion. This is the medieval division of labour,'^ which con- tinually creates new and independent trades and which led later to that jealous delimitation of the spheres of work that caused a large portion of the energy of the guild system to be consumed in internal bickerings. Handicraft is a phenomenon peculiar to the town. Peo- ples which, like the Russians, have developed no real town life, know likewise no national handicraft. And tlis also explains why, with the formation of large centralized States and unified commercial territories, handicraft was doomed to decline. In the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries there was developed a new industrial system, based no longer on the local but on the national and inter- national market. Our ancestors have denoted this sys- tem by the two names manufactories and factories, without distinguishing between the two terms. When viewed more closely these are seen to indicate two quite distinct industrial systems. The one hitherto characterized by the misleading phrase house industry we prefer to call the com- " For details sec my work, Pit Bnolkerung von Frankfurt a. M im Xir. und AT. Jahrhundcrt, I. p. jj8. Compare also Chapters III .ind VIII. 172 A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. mission systcm,^^ the other is our factory system. Both systems undertake the work of supplying a wide market with industrial products, and both require for this purpose a large number of labourers; they diflfer only in the man- ner in which they accomplish the work and organize the labourers. In this respect the method of the commission system is the simplest. In the first place, it leaves the exist- ing method of production quite undisturbed and confines itself to organizing the market. The business undertaker is a commercial entrepreneur who regularly employs a large number of labourers in their own homes, away from his place of business. These labourers are either former handicraftsmen who now produce for a single tradesman instead of for a number of consumers, or former wage- workers who now receive their raw material, not from the consumer, but from the merchant; or, finally, they are peasant families, the former products of whose domestic work are now produced as market wares and by the en- trepreneur introduced into the markets of the world. In some cases the entrepreneur advances *® to the small producers, who at first enjoy a fairly independent position, the purchase price of their products; in some cases he fur- nishes them with the raw material, and then pays piece- work wage; while in others he owns even the principal machinery, such as the weaver's loom, the embroidering machine, etc. As the small producers have only the one customer they graduall\ sink into ever-greater depend- ence. The entrepreneur becomes their employer, and they are employees, even when they supply the raw material themselves. It is scarcely necessary fo describe in detail the "I'crlag. " 1 crlcgcr cunies from I crlag, i.e. supplying or advancing. A HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 173 commission system and its contingent method of work, house industry. We have plenty of examples in tho moun- tain districts of Germany, for instance, the straw-plating and the clock and brush industries in the Black Forest, the wood-carving of Upper Bavaria, the toy manufacture in the Meiningen Oberland,the embroidery of the Voigtland, the lace-making of the Erzgebirge, etc. The history and present condition of these industries have been fairly well investigated in recent times. But we can no more enter into them than into the great variety of phases presented by this form of industry. The essential feature is ever the transformation of the industrial product, before it reaches the consumer, into capital — that is, into ? means of acquisition for one or more intermediary merchants. Whether the entrepreneur place the product on the general market, or keep a town ware- room from which to sell it ; whether he receive the wares from the houseworker ready for sale, or himself subject them to a last finishing process; whether the workman call himself master and keep journeymen, or whether he be a tiller of the soil as well — the house workman is always far removed from the real market of his product and from a knowledge of market conditions, and therein lies the chief cause of his hopeless weakness. If under the connnission system capital has merely as- sumed control of the marketing of the products, under the factory system it grasi)s the whole process of production. The former system, in order to accomplish the productive task fallii / to it, draws loosely together a large number of liomogeneous labourers, imparts to their production a defi- nite direction, approximately the same for each, and causes the product of their labour to flow, as it were, into a great reservoir before distributing it in all directions. The factory system organizes the whole process of pro- 174 A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. I 4 ■■■4 U s (!'■■* 1'- ( ^1 1"^ 1 ,?; duction; it unites various kinds of workers, by mutual relations of control and subjection, into a compact and well-disciplined body, brings them together in a special business establishment, provides them with an extensive and complex outfit of the machinery of production, and thereby immensely increases their productive power. The factory system is as distinguishable from the commission system as the well-organized, uniformly equipped regular army from the motley volunteer militia. Just as in an army corps ready for battle, troops of varied training and accoutrement — infantry, cavalry, and artillery regiments, pioneers, engineers, ammunition col- uirins and commissariat are welded into one, so under the factory system groups of workers of varied skill and equip- ment are united together and enabled to accomplish the most difficult tasks of production. The secret of the factory's strength as an institution for production thus lies in the effective utilisation of labour. In order to accomplish this it takes a peculiar road, which at first sight appears circuitous. It divides as far as pos- sible all the work necessary to a process of production into its simplest elements, separates the difficult from the easy, the mechanical from the intellectual, the skilled from the rude. It thus arrives at a system of successive functions, and is enabled to employ simultaneously and successively human powers of the most varied kind — trained and un- trained men, women and children, workers with the hand and head, workers possessing technical, artistic and com- mercial skill. The restriction of each individual to a small section of the labouring process effects a mighty increase in the volume of work turned out. A hundred workmen in a factory accomplish in a given process of production more than a hundred independent master craftsmen, al- though ench of the latter understands the whole process, A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. I7S while none of the former understands more than a small portion of it. As far as the struggle between handicraft and factory is fought out on the ground of technical skill, it is an evidence how the weak overcome the strong when guided by superior intellectual power. The machine is not the essential feature of the factory, although the subdivision of zvork just described has, by breaking up the sum of labour into simple movements, end- lessly assisted and multiplied the appHcation of machinery. From early times machines for performing tasks and for furnishing power have been employed in industry. In connection with the factory, however, their application attained its present importance only when men succeeded in securing a motive power that would work unintermit- tently, uniformly and ubiquitously, namely, steam; and even here its full importance is felt only in connection with the peculiar industrial form of factory manufacture. An example will serve to illustrate what has just been said. In the year 1787 the canton of Zurich had 34,000 male and female hand-spinners producing cotton yarn. After the introduction of the English spinning-machines a few factories produced an equal or greater quantity of thread, and the number of their workers (chiefly women and children) fell to scarcely a third of what it had been before. What is the explanation? The machines? But was not the then-existing spinning-wheel a machine? Cer- tainly it was; and, moreover, a very ingenious one. Ma- chine was thus ousted by machine. Or better, what had hitherto been done by the woman hand-spinner with her wheel was now done by successive collaboration of a whole series of various kinds of workers and machines. The entire spinning process had been decomjiosed into its sim- plest elements, and perfectly new operations had arisen for which even immature powers could in part be utilized. p-^t* i '( 1 \ , r IS' rP pi I I . I I 'I : 176 ^ HISTORICAL SURyEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. In the suI)division of work originate these further pc- cuHarities of factory production — the necessity of manu- facture on a large scale, the requirement of a large capital, and the economic dependence of the workman. With regard to the two last points we easily perceive an important difference between the factory and the com- mission system. Its large fixed capital assures to factory work greater steadiness in production. Under the com- mission system the house-workers can at any moment be deprived of employment without the entrepreneur running any risk of losing capital; but the manufacturer must in like case go on producing, because he fears loss of inter- est and shrinkage in the value of his fixed capital, and because he cannot afiford to lose his trained body of work- men. This is the reason why it is probable that the com- mission system will long maintain itself alongside factory production in those branches of industry in which the demand is liable to sudden change, and in which the articles produced are of great variety. If, in conclusion, we were briefly to characterize these five industrial systems, we might say that housework is production for one's own needs, wage-work is custom work, handicraft is custom production, commission work is decentralized, and factory labour centralized production of wares. As no economic phenomenon stands iso- lated, each of these systems of industry is at the same time but a section of a great economic and social order. House- work is the transformation of materials in the autonomous household economy; wage-work belongs to the period of transition from independent household economy to town economy: the hey-day of handicraft coincides with the period when town economy reached its full development; the commission system is a connecting link between town economy and national economy (independent State econ- A HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 177 omy), and the factory system is the industrial system of fully developed national economy. It would lead us too far to explain in this chapter how each industrial system fits organically into the contem- porary method of production and how it is mutually deter- mined by a series of allied phenomena in the spheres of agriculture, personal services, trade and transportation. It can scarcely escape the observant eye that all the elements of the evolution here broadly sketched are contained in the primitive cell of society, the family; or, in economic phrase, in the conditions of production in the independent house- hold. From this primitive social unit, teeming with life and swallowing up all individual existence, parts have continu- ally detached themselves through differentiation and in- tegration, and become more and more independent. Wage- work is only a sprout from the root of the tree of independ- ent household economy; handicraft still needs its protec- tion in order to flourish; commission work makes the mar- keting of products a special business, while production sinks back almost to the first stages of development. Fac- tory manufacture, on the other hand, permeates with the entrepreneur principle the whole process of production; it is an independent economic system freed from all ele- ments of consumption, and separated as regards commod- ities and locality from the household life of those engaged in it. The position of the worker changes in a similar way. With the commencement of wage-work the industrial worker separates himself personally from the independent household economy of the landed proprietor; with the transition to handicraft he also becomes, through the elim- ination of business capital, materially free and independent. Through the commission system he enters into a fresh per- sonal subjection, he falls into dependence upon the capi- Il f 1 178 A HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. talistic entrepreneur; under the factory system he becomes also materially dependent upon him. By four stages of evolution he passes from manorial servitude to factory servitude. There is a sort of parallelism in this evolution. The re- lation between the unfree houseworker and the ancient landowner bears a certain resemblance to the relation be- tween the factory hand and the modern manufacturer; and the wage-worker occupies much the same position with regard to the economy of the landed proprietor that the worker engaged in house industry does to the entrepreneur giving out commission work. In the middle of this ascend- ing and descending series stands handicraft as its founda- tion and comer-stone. From housework to handicraft we see the gradual emancipation of the worker from the soil and the formation of capital; from handicraft to the factory system a gradual separation of capital from work, and the subjection of the worker to capital. At the stage of housework capital has not yet emerged; there are only consumption goods at various stages of ripeness. Everything belongs to the household— raw ma- terial, tools, the manufactured article, often the worker himself. In the case of wage-work the tools are the only capital in the hands of the worker; the raw and auxiliary materials are household stores not yet ready for consump- tion; the work-place belongs, under the system of migra- tory labour, to the domestic establishment that is to con- sume the finished product, or, under the housework sys- tem, to the worker who produces the article. In the case of handicraft the tools, worl.-place, and raw material are capital in the possession of the worker; the latter is master of the product, though he invariably sells it to the imme- diate consumer. In the commission system the product also becomes capital— not the capital of the worker, how- A HISTORICAL SURREY OS INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 179 ever, but of quite a new figure on the scene, the commercial entrepreneur; the worker either retains all his means of production, or he loses possession successively of his goods, capilal, and his implements of production. Thus all the elements of capital finally unite in the hand of the manu- facturer, and serve him as a foundation for the reorganiza- tion of industrial production. In his hands even the worker's share in the product becomes a part of the busi- ness capital. This share of the worker consists, at the stage of house- work, in a participation in the consumption of the finished products; in the case of wage-work it consists in board, together with a time- or piece-work wage, which even at this point includes compensation for wear and tear of tools; in handicraft it consists in the full returns from production. Under the commission system the commercial undertaker takes away a portion of the latter as profit on his business capital; under the factory system all the elements of pro- duction which can be turned into capital become crystal- lizing centres for further profits on capital, while for the worker there remains only the stipulated wage. We must not, however, imagine the historical evolution of the industrial system to have been such that each new industrial method absolutely superseded its predecessor. That would be just as far astray as. for example, to suppose that a new means of communication supplants those already existing. Railways have done away neither with conveyances on the highways, nor with transportation by means of ships, pack-animals or the human back; they have only confined each of these older methods of trans- portation to the field in which it can best develop its pe- culiar advantages: it is probable that not only abso- lutely but relatively more horses and men are employed in I So /I HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. I- ' the work of transportation in our civilized countries to-day than there were in the year 1830. The very same causes that have produced such an enor- mous increase in traffic are also at work in the sphere of industry; and in spite of the continual improvement of the mechanical means of production they demand an ever-in- creasing number of persons. From two quarters, how- ev^r, the sphere of productive industry is constantly re- ceiving accessions; first, from the old household economy and agriculture, from which even to-day parts are always separating themselves and becoming independent branches of industry; secondly, from the continual improvement ^^ and increase in range of articles serving for the satisfac- tion of our wants. As regards the first point, there have sprung up in the industrial world during the last generation dozens of new trades for takiig over such kinds of work as >.. • J formerly to fall to the women of the household or to the servants, such as vegetable and fruit preserving, fancy baking and preparation of meats, making and mending women's and children's clothes, cleaning windows, feather beds and cur- tains, chemical cleaning and dyeing, painting and polishing floors, gas and water installation, etc. Under the heading "Art and Market Gardening," the latest statistics of trades in the German Empire give thirty-five, and under the head- ing " Stock-raising," thirty-one, independent occupations, many of which are of very recent origin. With regard to the second point, we will mention only the bicycle industry, which within a short time has not only '° In reply to a criticism of this expression in the Revue d'economie politique (or November, i8q2 (p. 1228, note), we will not omit making it more definite by saying that we do not mean by it the improvement of the quality of already existing species of goods, but the supplant- ing of existing poods by others which better and more cheaply supply thv demand, A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. i8i necessitated the erection of a great number of factories, but has already given rise to special repair-shops and sep- arate establishments for the manufacture of rubber tires, cyclometers and bicycle spokes. A still more striking ex- ample is afforded by the application of electricity. In the industrial census of 1895 there are enumerated names of twenty-two electrical occupations that did not exist in 1882. The production of electrical machines, apparatus and plant in the German Empire gave employment in 1895 to 14-494 persons, with 18.449 members of their families and serv- ants—thus furnishing a hving for nearly 33,000 persons." In metal-work, in the manufacture of machinery, chemicals, paper, in the building industries, the clothing and cleaning industries the number of recorded occupations more than doubled itself between 1882 and 1895. It is, at the same time, to be remembered not only that specialization has made immense strides, but that in many instances subsid- iary articles of production and trade which have hitherto been produced by the businesses using them are the ob- jects of separate enterprises. In these fields industry not only meets demand but frequently outruns it, as has at all times been the case. In the patent lists %xe find significant expression of this effort to improve the world of com- modities; and though many of the new inventions prove deficient in vitality, there always remains a considerable number whereby life is permanently enriched. "In a report appearing in the newspapers of August. 1900 Dr. R. Burner estimates the total capital of German firms manufacturing electr.cal apparatus, in round numbers, at 800 million marks ^200 million dollars), and the stock of the so-called finanaal corpora wns which- are taken up with the laymg of electric car lines and works^ at 450 million marks (.12 million dollars). The electr.c Imes, electric works and block stations in Germany are credited, in round numbers, with I 250 million marks (312 million dollars). So that the whole electrical plant of Germany represents a capital of about two and a half milliards oi marks (b-'3 million dollars). l82 A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. <R ''I IS Si m If we were able statistically to bring together the whole sum of industrial products produced yearly in Germany in such a way that we could separate the output of factories, of house ir.dustry, and of handicraft, wage-work and housework, we should without doubt find that the greater part of the factory wares embraces goods which were never produced under any of the other industrial sys- tems, and that handicraft produces to-day an absolutely greater quantity than ever before. The commission and faciory systems, it is true, have completely absorbed some of the lesser handicrafts and robbed many others of por- tions of their sphere of production. But all the great guild handicrafts that existed at the close of the iHth century, with perhaps the single exception of weaving, ill exist to-day. Handicraft is constantly being displaced by the more perfect industrial systems, just as in mediaeval times housework and wage-work were ousted by h" iidicraft, only now it occurs in a less violent manner, on the field of free competition. This competition of all with all, sup- ported as it is by a perfected system of transf)ortation and communication, often compels the transition from custom to wholesale production, even where from the technical standpoint the former might still have been possible. Many independent master workmen enter the service of the entrepreneur carrying on commission or factory work just as their predecessors a thousand years ago became manorial labourers. Handicraft has thus been relegated economically and so- cially to a secondary position. But even if it will no longer flourish in the large towns, it has in compensation spread all the more in the country, and here called forth, in com- bination with agriculture, numerous industries upon which the eye of the philanthropist can rest with delight. Handi- craft, it mav 1)0 said with certaintv, will no more disappear A HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 183 than wage-work and housework have disappeared. What it has won for society in a time of universal feudalization, namely, a robust class of people independent of landed property, whose existence is based upon personal worth and a small amount of movables, and who are a repository of popular morality and upr- ;htness — that will and must remain a lasting possession, even though the existence of those whom these virtues will in future adorn may rest upon a different basis. In recent times there has been raised with rare persist- ence a cry for the uprooting of the older industry. Handi- craft, house industry, in general all forms of work on a small scale are, we are told, a drag upon the national pro- ductive power; they are "antiquated, superseded, rude, not to say socially impeditive methods of production," which in the best interests of those who follow them must be re- placed by a " rational and judicious organization and regu- lation of human activities on a large scale," if the actual national production is not to lag far behind what is tech- nically possible. This short-sighted economico-political theorizing is not new. There was once a time when every peasant shoe- maker who raised his own potatoes and cabbage was looked upon as a sort of enemy to the highest possible na- tional wealth, and when people would have liked to force him by police regulation to stick to his last, even though at the same time he ran the risk of starving. Truly, it has al- ways been much easier to censure than to understand. If. instead of such dogmatic pronouncements, a willing- ness had been shown to make an unbiassed investigation of the conditions governing those older and supposedly an- tiquated systems of production, the conviction would soon have arisen that in the majority of cases where they still persist they arc economically and socially justifiable; and »84 A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. the means for the removal of the existing- evils would be sought in the soil in which these industrial forms are rooted instead of such drastic remedies being applied to them. In this way we should undoubtedly preserve the good of each of these individual systems and be striving only to re- move their disadvantages. For, after all, the comforting result of every serious con- sideration of history is. that no single element of culture which has once entered into the life of men is lost; that even after the hour of its predominance has expired, it continues in some more modest position to cooperate in the realization of the great end in which we all believe, the helping of mankind towards more and more perfect forms of existence. CHAPTER V. THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. There are in Germany two handicraft problems. One is a problem belonging to the newspapers and the legisla- tures, which since 1848 has repeatedly occupied the liveliest public attention. For it the question is the extent to which the particular interests of hand-workers as a class should be given legislative expression. What the answer shall be depends upon the relative strength of political parties. The other problem relates to the vitality of hand-work as a form of industrial activity. It is the query of Ham- let's soliloquy: " To be or not to be! " The answer de- pends upon actual conditions. Stated more explicitly, the question would read: How far has hand-work up to the present shown itself capable of holding its own? What de- partment of industry does it still dominate? So long as public policy weighs, not merely wishes and votes, but also the facts of the case, it will not venture to decide the first of these questions until the second has been answered. Until lately the necessary established data have been lacking. Recently, however, the German Social Science Club has conducted a most comprehensive investi- gation into those branches of industry belonging to the old class of handicrafts.' It is therefore opportune to give a ' Investieations as to the Condition of Hnnd.jork m Germany, tvith sptcial Reference to its Ability to compete u-ith industrial Undertakings on a Inrf '^'c'e in S>hr.ft<!i d,'^ V.r(in>; fur Sozialpolitik. Vols. 62-70 " 185 l'-' it Ji :.i,ait 1 86 THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. general survey of the findings. In this it is not our inten- tion to enter upon a discussion of the p. >'--it position and future prospects of particular industrial tranches,* but rather to present the common characteristics of the de- velopment that has taken place during the past hundred years or more. This will make it possible to appreciate in their full strength and manifold modes of operation the forces in modem national economy that act as solvents and as creative agents. A century ago handicraft still held undisputed sway over all its mediaeval inheritance and over its sixteenth and seventeenth century conquests as well. There existed be- sides, it is true, a few manufactories and factories. But they had developed apart from hand-work; what they produced had never been handicraft work. Rivalry between these new forms of industry and the guild hand-work there had never been. Nor had the guilds as such been interfered with by the State; they had only been made amenable to its laws, and thus been in part stripped of their local municipal character. Their scope indeed had been ex- tended, in that those handicrafts were subjected to the guild constitution, which, because of the limited number of their representatives, had not as yet been able to form local guilds in the various towns. Through the territorial guilds, i 1 had been constituted for these "minor handi- crafts," aiid through the " general guild articles " com- pactly summarizing uniform trade regulations for all local guilds, the requirements of modern national economy had (Ltip^iR, 1804-1807). A further volume (Vol 71) relates to Austria. SupplcTTientinK this is the inquiry into the conditions of handwork, undertaken in the summer of 1805. and edited by the Imperial Statis- tics lUire.iu (.( niiiTiber<=, Rtrlin. iSg:^. 'The results of the itivestiRations of FI. Grandke alon^ this line are presentiil In Sclimoller's Jalirbuch I'ur GesetZKe''. V'erwa't. u, Volksw., Vol. XXI Ci8g;), pp. loji iT. THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 187 been at least formally asserted. In practice, however, the local and craft prerogatives of sale, the town monopoly and extra-mural rights of jurisdiction ^ remained in force. Competition between the members of the same handicraft from different towns and of the different crafts of the same towns was entirely lacking; settlement in rural parts was for most crafts forbidden, and to gain independence was made a matter of extreme difficulty for all journeymen who were not masters' sons or sons-in-law. But what was the condition of the master craftsmen in exclusive possession of these privileges? Most of those who discuss handicraft to-day depict the masters " of the golden era of handicraft " as well-to-do people carrying on business " with considerable capital for those times," owning " their own dwellings and extensive workshops," working along with master journeymen and apprentices, personally capable, honourable, respected. All the painters dip their brush in glowing colours, so neces- sary for the portrayal of a condition of prosperity. Whence have they this picture? We have vainly sought it in the eighteenth or seventeenth century. Moreover, our classical poets could not have had it before their eyes; for their " gossiping tailors and glovers " are petty, insig- nificant apparitions. In the multitude of small towns the masters were able to maintain themselves only through their bit of farming and the lucrative brewing privilege, and in the larger towns through the little counter kept by many of them in connection with their workshop. Even for a town of such commercial, prominence as Leipzig, the mass of administrative records from the last two centuries do not allow the impression that the craftsmen of that place were on the average well off; and the extensive liter- • [Comp. on the latter Roscher. System der Volksvi., 5th ed. Vol. 3. S ii8.-ED.3 i88 THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. \aiii. ature on guilds that has come down from the close of the last and the beginning of the present century, the " Pa- triotische Phantasien " of Justus Moser, points in many in- stances to very narrow circumstances. The barriers erected against admission to mastership, though extensive, had not been successfully defended. Among the bakers and butchers, whom it is customary to cite as types of prosperity, baking and killing in rotation was the almost universal rule; that is, there were so many masters that each baker could not bake afresh each day, nor each butcher kill a head of cattle per week. As late as 1 817 a writer cites as a normal case from Bavaria that in a town with ten master bakers three bakings of bread were consumed daily, so that every week the turn fell to each twice. The butchers could slaughter regularly only the smaller kinds of stock. In North German towns mat- ters appear to have been in a favourable condition if one beef were sold every week for every five or six masters. Almost all crafts with a guild organization had a clause in their statutes fixing the maximum number of journey- men and apprentices which a master might ' -"ep. As a rule he was limited to two. In the i8th century this number was rarely exceeded. Under normal conditions, however, the grci t majority of trades could not attain to this number. Assuming that all who learned the handicraft acquired master's standing, that a master lived on the average thirty years after he attained that rank, and that ordinarily a man became independent between the twenty-eighth and thir- tieth year of his life, there could not have been at any time more than half as many journeymen and apprentices as masters. The actual proportion at the end of the century was often much smaller still. In the year 1784 there were in the duchy of Magdeburg 27,050 independent masters and THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 189 only 4,285 assistants and apprentices. About the same time, in the principality of Wurzburg (in Bavaria), 13762 masters with 2,176 assistants and apprentices were re- turned." In both territories there were for every hundred masters but 15.8 journeymen and apprentices. Thus, if we assume that the assistants were equally distributed among the masters, one journeyman or apprentice hardly fell to each sixth master. In more than five-sixths of the instances the master carried on his work single-handed. In 1780 the town of Bochum (in Westphalia) counted for every five master masons one; in the other crafts they were for every twenty-six master shoemakers three, for every twenty-one master bakers, every eight carpenters and every five master masons one; in the other crafts they were altogether lacking. In some parts of Prussia, especially in Berlin, the con- ditions were indeed somewhat more favourable. But in general the idea must be abandoned that our modern in- dustrial development began with the handicrafts in a con- dition of general prosperity. The best that past times could of?er the craftsmen was a modest competence, se- curity against lack of work and against over-severe com- petition from their fellows. They deal directly with their customers, in quiet times work up a stock and take it to market, and stand firmly together in the guild if it is a question of voting down a new application for mastership, taking action against an itinerant workman or resisting an encroachment on the part of a neighbouring craft. To- wards one another, however, they are possessed with the pettiest bread-and-butter jealousy, and give a great deal of trouble to the courts and administrative ofificials. Such was the early handicraft. ♦AccordinK to Sclimoller, Zur Gcsch. d. dculsch KUingewerbe vn jy. Jhdt., pp. 21. 22. 190 THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. Down to the fourth decade of last century there was no really great change. After the time of Napoleon, the old industrial policy was repeatedly moderated, but in most parts of Germany it was not abolished until the sixties. It gave place to industrial freedom. Anyone might now carry on any business anywhere and on any desired scale. The local prc'^ibitive powers fell to the ground. Each trades- man could dispose of his products where he would, and in his own locality had to tolerate all external competition. The barriers between the different branches of industry dropped away, and everyone could manufacture what was to his advantage. All this took place with the full assent of the craftsmen themselves. The conviction that the old industrial polity had become untenable was shared in at least the more ad- vanced parts of Germany by all. If ever an old insti- tution was abolished with the approbation of the whole nation, it was the guild system. The sole sporadic mis- giving was that apprenticeship might fall into decay, and that many would establish themselves as independent craftsmen who had not regularly learned their trade. This apprehension has proved groundless. According to the results of the inquiry made into handicraft in various districts of Germany, ninety-seven per cent, of those con- sidered as still carrying on an independent handicraft had enjoyed a preparatory training as hand-workers. The small remainder consisted mainly of those who had re- ceived their technical training in apprentice shops and technical schools, asylums for the blind, institutions for the deaf and dumb, in prison and in barracks. The influence of the new conditions on the number, local distribution, and extent of undertakings assumed a differ- ent form. At first it was feared that the establishment of numerous petty master workmen without capital would THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 191 lead to a mass of half-developed business undertakings; but this has in nowise proved the case. On the contrary, after a brief transitional period, the undertakings in the towns have on the average during the last generation numerically diminished, while in financial strength and in the number of assistants, so far as their existence has not been in general jeopardized by causes lying outside the province of industrial legislation, the respective branches of trade have increased. At the same time hand-work has made striking advances in the country, and to-day is ap- proximately as strong there as in the towns. This equalization between town and country, however, had been foreseen and aimed at at the time by the advo- cates of industrial freedom. If there was the further expectation that through industrial freedom the way of the artisan would be opened to technical progress and to economic advancement, this also has not lacked fulfilment. Thousands of urban master workmen have in the last two o-enerations become large manufacturers, or at least capi- talistic entrepreneurs, and have participated fully in the technical advances of the period. Freedom of mdustry and enterprise has made it possible for them to broaden their sphere of production and sale, and to utilize fully their personal ability. This fact men to-day are only too prone to overlook. To be sure, the number of those who have not risen in the world, but remained stationar>-, and of those reduced to the level of master jobbers and homeworkers. or forced to become factory employees, is much larger still. Whole branches of industrv formeriy carried on as hand-work are almost ruined, or at least are lost to handicraft as a par- ticular industrial form. Others are still struggling for their existence. A great weathering and transforming process has here come into operation: in its train handicraft is 192 THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. h2 yielding place to other forms of business, such as the fac- tory and commission systems, or the hybrid forms that every period of transition begets. The public at large is content to include all involved in these processes under the simple headings: displacement of hand-work by machinery, annihilation of handicraft by the factory! The smaller cost of production by machinery is looked upon as the sole cause. The reduction of these expressions to their true value, and the demonstration that a large part of the changes which have taken place has its cau^e not in the advances of manufacturing technique but in the direction taken by economic consumption, and that so far as this is the case handicraft disappears even without machine-work coming into competition with it — this will remain one of the greatest services rendered by recent investigators of hand- work. It will be necessary first to present a summary view of these changes in consumption, since they, so to speak, condition the whole development. In the first place, a local concentration of demand has taken place. The aggregations of human beings that have been formed in great cities in the course of the last half cen- tury, furthermore the standing armies, the large state and municipal institutiotis. prisons, hospitals, technical schools, etc., the extensive establishments for transportation, fac- tories, and large undertakings in the departments of trade, banking and insurance, all form centres of wholesale de- mand for industrial products. To these are to be added the great departmental warehouses, export businesses and cooperative societies, focussing the demand of large sec- tions of the population at a few points. This demand they are no longer able to satisfy as customers of individual craftsmen. There comes then as a secnnd cnn-sideration the many THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 193 instances in which modern civilization has propounded such colossal tasks for industry that they cannot be accom- plished at all with the implements and methods of handi- craft, although each of them generally requires consid- erable hand-work. The manufacture of a locomotive, of a steam crane, of a rapid press, the building of a river bridge or of a warship, the equipment of a street railway with rails and rolling stock cannot be carried out with mere hand apparatus and manual labour. They require im- mensely powerful mechanical appliances, highly trained engineers and craftsmen of exceedingly varied qualitica- tions. Even where technically such tasks might still be accom- plished with the implements of hand-work, the entrusting of them to master craftsmen is economic mj)ossihle be- cause of the consequent heavy loss of erest. In the Middle Ages the building of a cathedral might occupy two or three generations, indeed, several centuries. Imagine one to-day wishing to take as much time for the erection of a railway station! When in 1896 the contract for the main building of the Saxon-Thuringian Industrial Exhil)i- tion in Leipzig was to be let, it was first offered to the master carpenters of the city — contractors who carry on work with considerable capital and are accustomed to large undertakings. But all hesitated because of the short- ness of the term for building and the extent of the risk. Negotiations were thereupon entered into with a large firm of builders in Frankfurt-on-Main. In a few hours the con- tract was closed. The same evening the telegraph was working in all directions. A week later the steam rams were busy on the building site, and whole trains were ar- riving from Galicia with the necessary timber. In fact, one can say that to-day there are industrial tasks of such magnitude that they can be performed by only a 194 THE DECLINE OF THE HASDICRAFTS. few, perhaps indeed by but one or two firms in Europe. Hence the development, beside the earHer type of factory, which finds its strength in the wholesale production of similar articles, of a new type whose raison d'etre lies in the magnitude of the task of production. This more recent kind of large industrial undertaking we might designate by the already current er.pression, manufacturing estab- lishment.^ At the head stands a staff of technically trained men, with extensive mechanical appliances at command, and with the necessary hand-work in most effective com- bination. But the demand for industrial labour has been not merely locally concentrated and condensed to meet the extensive requirements of production; it has also become more uniform, and therefore more massive. A tendency tozvards uniformity runs through our age, eliminating the differences of habits and customs in the various strata of society. Characteristic peasant costumes have disappeared down to unimportant survivals; the furnishing of the dwell- ing, of the kitchen, has become, it is true, more extensive, but likewise more uniform. Even in the smallest home one finds the petroleum lamp, the coffee-mill, some enam- elled cooking utensils, a pair of framed photographs. To make the desired ware accessible to the poorer classes, it must be easily and cheaply produced. If an article is lifted on the crest of a wave of fashion, the demand for it in a cheap form advances even up to the better situated grades of society, and thus the outlay for the folly of fash- ion is made endurable. In ti iS way there arises a large demand for cheap goods for whose manufacture the earlier type of factory is naturally adapted. Hand-work is for such too expensive; where it remains technically possible it must ' Fabrikationsansialt. THE DECUSE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 195 be extremely specialized, and then it necessarily loses the ground of custom work from beneath its feet. There is finally another consideration to be alluded to. which belongs to the sphere of domestic economy. The home is being relieved more and more of the vestigial elements of production, and is restricting itself to the regulation of consumption. If our grandparents required a sofa, they first had the joiner make the frame, then purchased the leather, the horsehair and the feathers, and had the up- holsterer finish the work in the house. The procedure was similar for almost every more important piece of work. To-day s' -cialized work demanding the whole strength of each indr lual, frequently to exhaustion, no longer per- mits such a participation in production. We will and must purchase what we need ready-made. We desire to be quickly supplied, and preferably renounce idiosyncrasies of personal taste, rather than undertake the risk of order- ing from different producers. Industry has to adapt itself accordingly. The same evolutionary process also asserts itself in de- partments where the individual craftsman had been accus- tomed from time immemorial to supply finished wares. Here again the modern city consumer will no longer trade directly with him by ordering the single piece that he re- quires. He is averse to waiting; he knows that often the work does not turn out as desired, and prefers to choose and compare before he buys. Thus the craftsman can no longer remain a custom worker even in those departments in which technically he is fully able to cope with the demands of production. He no longer works on individual orders, but exclusively for stock — which formerly he did only in case of necessity. To reach the consumer he needs the intervention of the store. By the discontinuance of personal contact be- 196 THE DECLINE OF THE H/INDICRAFTS. i' i 1 tween producer and consumer, hand-work as a phase of in- dustry disappears. It becomes a capitalistic undertaking, and demands management in accord with mercantile prin- ciples. All now depends upon the question whether busi- ness on a large or a small scale offers the greater advan- tages. In the first case the department of work formerly represented by handicraft falls to the factory, in the latter to domestic industry. For even where modern demand has not yet appeared as wholesale concentrated demand, or become condensed to meet the necessities of production on a grand scale, it is universally well adapted, by virtue of its great uniformity and its emancipation from household labour, to localization at a few points. The perfected commercial machinery of modern times, the low tariffs for post and telegraph, tha rapidity and regularity of freight and news transportation, the innumerable means of advertising and of making an- nouncements afford here their mighty assistance. Indus- trial freedom thus found a well-prepared soil when it sprang mto life. It but created the legal forms that voice the character of modern economic demand. All those circles of consumers of the craftsmen so long kept arti- ficially asunder could now be united through the interven- tion of commerce into a large manufactory and commis- sion clientele, not necessarily limited to national boundaries. Concentrated demand does not permit of satisfaction by scattered production. Along with the process of concen- tration of demand must go a process of concentration in the department of industrial production. It is to this that handi- craft on every side succumbs. But this process is very complicated, and it is not alto- gether easy to separate from one another the individual processes of which it is composed. Wc will nevertheless essav the task, choosinir the fate of hand-work as the deter- THE DECLINE OF THE H/INDICRAFTS. 197 mining factor in the divisions made by us. We thus arrive at the five following cases: 1. Supplanting of hand-work by similar factory produc- tion. 2. Curtailment of its department of production by fac- tory or commission. 3. Incorporation of hand-work with the large undertak- ing. 4. Impoverishment of hand-work by shifting of demand. 5. Reduction of hand-work by way of the warehouse to home and sweat-work. Several of these processes often go on simultaneously. In our consideration of the subject, however, we will keep thom as far as possible apart. I. The case in which capitalistic production on a large scale attacks handicraft along its whole front, in order to expel it completely from its sphere of production is compara- tively rare. From earlier times we may mention weaving, clock and gun making, and also the sm'dler industries of the pin-makers, button-makers, tool-smiths, card-makers, hosiers; from recent times hatmaking, shoemaking, dyeing, soap manufacture, rope-making, nail and cutlery smithing, comb-making: to a certain extent beer-brewing and coopering also belong to the list. The process of displacement assumes now a quicker now a less rapid character, according as the handicraft in ques- tion formerly carried on manufacture for stock along with market and ^'u,p sale, or restricted itself to custom work. Thus the making of shoes for market sale paved the way for the manufacture of shoes by machinery, because it had long accustomed certain classes of the people to the pur- chase of ready-made footwear. For handicraft the result of such a development varies accordin"- n^ th<' f:!'.-tnry product, after being worn out. 193 THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. at permits of repair or not. In the latter case handicraft dis- appears altogether; in the former it evolves into a repair trade, with or without a sale shop. The carrying on by a hand-worker of a shop trade with factory goods in his own line is not exactly an unfavourable metamorphosis; but only craftsmen with considerable capital can manage it. On the oiher hand, pure repair trade very easily loses the ground of hand-work beneath its feet, if the factory- product passes completely into the control of retail mer- chants. For then the majority of consumers prefer to have repairs made in the shop in which they have purchased the new ware. The proprietor of the shop keeiis a journey- man or sends out the mending to a petty master workman. This greatly diminishes their return, and makes them com- pletely dependent. Moreover, repairing can also be car- ried on on a large scale, as with the so-called rag-dyeing, which works with considerable capital and independent collecting points. Finally, the repairing can become quite superfluous through very cheap i)roduction of new wares, as. for example, with clocks and shoes; repair would cost more than a new article. 2. Much more frequently does the second group of evo- lutionary processes make its appearance. Here it is not a ([uestion of the com])lete loss of the new manufacture, but merelv of the curtailment of the department of production fall- ing to handicraft through factory or commission business. The causes of this process may be very diverse. While recognising the impossibility of being exhaustive, we will distinguish four of them: ia) I'arious handicrafts are fused into a single manufac- turing establishment : for example, joi-icrs, wood-carvers, turners, upholsterers, painters. !ac<|uerers into a furniture factory; wheelwrights, smiths, saddlers, glaziers into a car- riage manufactory; bnsket-inakers. joiners, wheelwrights, THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 199 saddlers, smiths, locksmiths, lacquerers into a baby-car- riage factory. We may mention further all kinds of ma- chine-shops, locomotive and car-works, piano factories, trunk factories, billiard-taLle factories, and also the estab- lishments for the production of whole factory plants — dis- tillery, brewery, sugar-refinery, etc. As a rule the part of production withdrawn from the individual handicraft through such an incorporation forms but a small frap^ment of its previous sphere of work and of its market. J how- ever, such blood-lettings are frequent, as among the turners, saddlers and locksmiths, there finally remains very little, and the handicraft may die of exhaustion. (/;) Various remunerative articles adapted to zJiolcsalc pro- duction by factory or house industry are withdrawn from hand-work. Thus bookbinding has 1 1 to resign ah.iost its whole extensive department of pro iction to more than forty kinds of special trades; there remains but the indi- vidual binding for private customers. Basket-making has surrendered the fine wares to homework, baby-carriages and the like to factories, and only the coarse willow wicker- work remains to handicraft. The locksmith has even lost the article, the lock, from which he has his name; the brush-maker the manufacture of paint, tooth, and nail brushes; the cabinet-maker has been compelled to re- nounce the intermediate wares (Berim furniture), and ordinary pine furniture has become a stock-in-trade of the store; confectionery is threatened, in the cities at least, with being despoiled by the factories of the manu- facture of bread; the tinsmith no longer makes his vessels; in short there arc likely but few handicrafts that have not similar losses to record. (f) The factory takes over the primary stages of production. It was precisely the first rough working of the material which demands the greatest exi)enditurc of strength, it 200 THE DECLINE OF THE HAKDICRAFTS. was exactly this primary handling that suggested the ap- plication of machinery, while the finer and individual shaping of the product in the later stages of the process of production tempted the entrepreneur but slightly. In almost all metal and wood industries the raw material is now used only in the form of half-manufactured wares. The furriers work up skins already prepared, the smith purchases the finished horseshoe, the glazier ready-made window-frames, the brush-maker cut and bored wooden parts and prepared bristles, the contracting carpenter in- laid flooring cut as desired and doors all ready to ha*"^. At first such a loss is generally felt by the handicraft con- cerned as an alleviation rather than an injury. The process of production is shortened; the individual master can pro- duce a greater quantity of finished articles than formerly; and if he reckons on each piece the same profit as for- merly, his income can easily advance provided he retains sufficient work. A locksmith, who procures all door- mountings ready-made from the hardware shop, can readily finish several buildings in one summer, while pre- viously, when he had first to make these wares, he perhaps completed only one. But still, in most cases, through such a cutting into the roots of hand-work, not a few of the mas- ter craftsmen become superthious. At the same time, how- ever, the amount of busiuf'ss cai)ital rec|uired increases, since the craftsman has now to make disl)ursements not merely for the raw inaterial. but also for the costs of pro- <luction of the ]iart!y manufactured jiroduct. and further- more. Ir ■ to furnish the manufacturer's ami tra-I :r's profits as well. This is all the more vital, since just in the first-hand pur- chase of the raw material and in its proper selection the greatest profit is often made. For this reason trading l^oi.'.ce* b.avc v,ot infre!j!!!-!'.'!v tnki-!'. over the preparatory THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 20X Stages in production even where a partial manufacture with machinery is not to be thought of. There is abso- lutely no doubt that the hand-worker in wood was in a better position when he could purchase his wood in the form of logs in the forest than now, when he procures it in the form of boards, laths, and veneers from lumber-dealers; and that the brush-maker worked to greater advantage when he bought the rough bristles from the butcher than now, when he must buy them arranged by the dealer in innumerable classes. Of course this trade in partly finished goods is very con- venient for the craftsman; he can obtain from the dealer even the smallest quantities. But it is exactly this that has contributed not a little to the decline of the handicrafts, since the journeyman can now go into business almost without capital. Thus, for instance, in the shoe trade the manufacture of vamps at first greatly promoted business on a small scale, not because it shortened the manufactur- ing process for the shoemaker, but because it placed him in a positior to purchase a single pair of uppers at the shoefinder's where formerly he had to procure from the tanner at least a whole skin. This cooperation of mechanical preparatory work and handicraft assumes a particularly interesting form where the wliolc productive part of the labour process drops away from hand-work. The craftsman can then continue to maintain himself only if the product needs to be set in place or fitted. But he sinks back once more almost to the state of the wage-worker. Thus the locksmith and the joiner (the latter for ready-made doors and inlaid flooring) are now but " fitters ""; and the role of the horseshoer nail- ing on ready-made horseshoes is not very dilTerent. On the other '..and, the shortci.lng of the process of manufacture makes the business more capitalistic and the 303 THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. turnover more rapid. The vital element of handicraft, however, is not the profit on capital, but the labour earn- ings, and these under all circumstances are being curtailed. {d) The appearance of nciv rmv materials and methods of production better adapted for manufacture on a large scale than those prev'ously employed in hand-work, handi- caps the latter for a part of this sphere of production. We may cite among other instances the appearance of the curved (Vienna) furniture, the manufacture of wire nails and its influence on nail-smithing, the wire-rope manufacture in opposition to the hempen rope, the in- vasion by gutta percha of the consumption sphere of leather and linen. The enamelled cooking utensil has en- croached simultaneously upon the manufacture of pottery, tinsmithing and the business of the coppersmith; and the invention of linen for bookbinding in place of leather and parchment has smoothed the way for wholesale book- binding by machinery. Thus at the most diverse points handicraft is being as- sailed by the modern, more progressive, forms of manu- facture. The attacks, generally delivered in a manner to disarm opposition, are not infrequently made under the fair mask of the stronger friend taking a load from its shoulders, until finally nothing remains to tempt the capi- talistic appetite of the entrepreneur. 3. We come now to those cases in which handicraft loses it*; independence through being appended to a large business. Every more extensive undertaking, be it manu- facturing, trading, or a general commercial establishment, requires for its own business various kinds of hand-work. As long as such tasks are few i- number, they are given out to master craftsmen. But if they grow more numerous and regular, it becomes advantageous to organize a sub- department for them within the walls nf the establishm.ent. THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 203 1 Today every large brewery or wine-house has its own cooperage; the street-railway companies maintain work- shops for smiths, saddlers, wheelwrights and machinists; canning factories have their own tinshops; a shipyard keeps cabinet-makers and upholsterers for the internal fur- nishing of its passenger steamers; almost every large manufactory has a machine and repair shop. The master who enters such a large establishment as foreman of the special workshop ceases, of course, to be free from the con- trol of others, but enjoys, on the other hand, a position that is to a certain extent independent, and, above all, se- cure. By the free craftsmen, however, the loss of such strong purchasers is most bitterly felt. Indeed, the system de- scribed can lead to the starving out of whole crafts — a fate that has overtaken, for example, turning, which is being appended to all trades using its products in the par- tially manufactured state. But this process is too much in the interests of a good economy to make it possible to check i;. The workmen for such subdepartments of a large in- dustrial establishment, be it further remarked, receive as a rule a training in their handicaft as long as it continues to have an independent existence. An abnormally large number of ai)prentices can thus be employed by it, while the journeymen have a much more extended labour market than the handicraft alone could offer. This is the explana- tion, for instance, of the occasional discovery in the lock- smith's trade of ten times as many apprentices as journey- men. 4. Handicraft is impoverished through shifting of demana, and entirely ruined through cessation of demand. Such shiftings have occurred at all epochs — we may recall the use of parchment and periwigs — hut perhaps never tnnre 204 THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. frequently than in our own rapidly moving times. We will give only a few instances. The cooper prq)ared for the household of our grand- parents divers vessels now sought for in vain, at least in a city home: meat-barrels, tubs for sauerkraut and beans, washtubs, water-buckets, rain-barrels, even bathtubs and washing vessels. We no longer keep supplies of meat and preserved vegetables; water is furnished us by the water- works system; and the place of the small wooden vessels has been taken by those of tin, china, or crockery. A sec- ond example is offered by the turner, who formerly had to supply almost every household with a spinning-wheel or two, spools and reels. To-day the spinning-wheel has sunk to the position of an " old German " show-piece. Botli in- dustries have, of course, found fresh purchasers for those they have lost, especially coopering, through the increase of barrel-packing. But the new customers are factories that at the earliest opportunity incorporate the cooperage as a subsidiary department. The industry of the pewterer presents a third example. The pewter plates and dishes that were to be found in almost every house throughout town and country have passed out of fashion. In their place have come porcelain and stoneware, and the pewter- er's trade has thus to all intents lost the very foundation of its existence. Finally, we may recall the shiftings in demand which the great revolutions in the sphere of travel have lirought about, and which have fallen with especial severity on the saddler, trunk-maker and furrier. 5. In a last group --f instances handicraft come, into com- plete dependence on trade; the master becomes a home- worker, shice his products can now reach the consumers only through the store. The cause of this phenomenon is of a double nature: on the one hand, the high rents of city business sites, whicli force the master to live and pen THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 205 up his workshop in a garret or a rear house where he is with difficulty found, and where at no time is he sought out by his better customers; on the other, the inchna- tion of the pubUc to buy only where a larger selection is to be had, and where the merchant is " accommodating," that is, sends goods for inspection, takes back if they do not suit, articles like brushes, combs, fine basket-maker's wares and leather goods, small wooden and metal articles which in larger towns are now scarcely ever purchased from the producer or outside the fancy-goods and hard- ware stores. Indeed, we even give our orders to the stores if we wish to have a special article made. Who to-day or- ders his visiting cards from the printer, or a smoker's table from the cabinet-maker? Anyone who has the oppor- tunity of seeing, along the streets that he must traverse perhaps several times a day, so complete a display of every- thing necessary for his wants that he can in a few minutes procure any desired article, will seldom care out of love for a declinirg handicraft to betake himself to a distant suburb and there, after a long inquiry and search, climb three or four gloomy staircases before he can deliver his order, in the execution of wliich the appointed time will perhaps even then be disregarded. And shall, for instance, anyone who finds in a furniture stock everything that is in any way necessary to the furnishing of a room, shall a young housewife who in a few hours can gather together in a housefurnishing estajlishment a complete kitchen outfit, shall these preferably seek out a half dozen hand- workers from whom they can obtain what they want only after weeks of waiting? Such may be regarded as the chief features of the process of transformation that is taking place to-day in hand- icraft. We may, in conclusion, scate it as a matured con- 'Mi 206 THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. viction compelled by the results of the investigations, that in all cases xvhcre it suttH^'S finished goods zi'liicli arc not very perishable, and which can he manufactured in definite styles for average requirements, hand-zcork is endangered in the highest degree. This applies even ivhere a technical superiority on the part of tlic large undertaking does not exist. These are, in short, cases in which the product is suited to immediate consumption without further assistance from the producer. In all these instances trade in its various branches, down to that of hawking, will more and more form the uni- versal clearing-house for industrial wares. Handicraft must specialize as far as possible; and it can save itself from the fate of dependence upon the store only by becoming a cap- italized industry on a small scale. The union of a sale shop with the workshop is then indispensable. In the contrary instances, where the product of handi- craft must be placed in position or separately fitted, the crafts- man at least does not lose touch with the consumers. But even in such cases he can maintain himself in the large towns only if the demand is strongly centralized (as with locksmiths and generally all craftsmen connected with building in the widest sense), or again if he keeps a shop (as with tinsmithing. saddlery, or ordered tailoring), which serves as a collecting bureau for orders. In both cases a business without some capital lacks sufficient vitality to exist. With this conclusion correspond the results of the " In- vestigations into the Conditions of the Handicrafts." Everywhere in the tozvns the relative number of masters has greatly diminished, the number of their assistants in- creased: that is, the businesses have grown. In a still higher degree must their capital have advanced. Mani- festly it is the upper stratum of city handicraftsmen which has here maintained itself by adopting business methods THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICR/tFTS. 207 suited to the requirements of the present, and which probably has prospects of holdinj? its own for some time to come. Where an equal variety is ofifered, the public will always prefer the shop of the master craftsman to that of the pure tradesman, if for no other reason, because of the convenience for repairs and the greater technical knowledge of the master. The latter, moreover, through the custom coming to the workshop, remains protected from that officious idleness to which the city shopkeeper so readily falls a victim. In the country conditions have a fairly different aspect. Those causes of repression of hand-work that result from the altered form of demand and the conditions of life in the towns prevail here only in a lesser degree. Rural de- mand is not yet so very concentrated; it is to a large extent of an individual nature; everyone knows the hand-worker and his household personally. Connections with neigh- bours, school comrades or family relatives likewise play a part in holding trade. Here real handicraft soil is still to be found. The craftsman cultivates in many cases a bit of land; at the harvest he will assist his neighbour in mowmg and the like; he possesses a cottage of his own; in short, for his sustenance he is not exclusively dependent upon his trade. In his business wage-work and the system of credit balances « still largely prevail. Most of the crafts that have any real footing in the coun- try are in our opinion secure as far as the future can be forecasted. Of course, they cannot completely escape the revolutions in urban industry. In the country the tin- smith, as a rule, no longer makes the tinware he sells, •[For a general discussion of credit balances (Gcs^enrcchuMig) as a feature of public ^inancini^ conip. an instructive article by the anttnir in Ztschr. d. Resamt. Staatswiss. for 1896, pp. i fT.: Dcr jffentl. Haus- hatt d. StadI t'r. «»i MilU-iilU-r.—ED.] 3o8 THE DECLINE OF THE HASDICRAFTS. and ♦he smith uses horseshoes purchased ready for use. But the customs connected with consumption change here but slowly; the demand remains more individual, and there is relatively far more repair work; indeed, the agri- cultural machines have brought fresh w rk of the latter type for iron-worker, smith, tinsmiti., cooper, joiner. About fifty-two per cent, of the master craftsmen in Ger- many to-day are found in the country. The country has come to equal the cities in density of hand-worker popula- tion. Certainly the number of separate shops i.. the coun- try is particularly large. In Prussia the average num- ber of persons as assistants has seemingly diminished some- what since 1861; the number of apprentices is relatively high. But in this there is no ground for anxiety. The relation between th .lumber of assistants and the number of masters is much more favourable to-day in rural parts than it was in the cities at the beginning of this century; and the condition of the rural cxsui^n.^ accorair.g to all that has been published on the subject, though modest, is still satisfactory. In this the reports to hand from Silesia, Saxony, East Friesland, Baden, and Alsace agree. There are certainly some village craftsmen leading very meagre lives; but such there have been in handicraft at all times. Among those who consider handicraft the ideal form of industrial activity two means have long been extolled for restoring solid footing and strength to the tottering industrial middle class; and there are many who still believe in their efficacy. The first is the "return to artistic zcork." Efforts of this kind have been diligently fostered for well-nigh twenty- five years. For their encouragement museums, technical schools, and apprentice workshops have been instituted. But experience has soon taught, and the investigations of THE DECLINE OF THE HANDlCR/tFTS. 309 the Social Science Club have confirmed it anew, that these efforts have borne very little fruit for the small trader. Ironwork alone has gained at a few points through the re- newed employment of wrought-iron trellis-work, stair bal- ustrades, chandeliers, and the like. Otherwise all establish- ments successfully carrying on artistic industry are manu- facturing businesses of a large, and indeed of the largest, type. This is the case, for example, with bookbinding, art furniture, pottery The second means is the extension of small power ma- chines and the electrical transmission of power, which shall enable the smallest master to obtain the most impor- tant labour-saving machines. Even men like Sir William Siemens and F. Reuleaux have placed the greatest hopes on the popularizing of these technical achievements. These expectations they have based upon the beliet that success is simply a question of removing the technical superiority of the large undertaking, this superiority resting indeed in great part upon the employment of labour-saving ma- chines. In this they have curiously overlooked the fact that mechanical power is the more costly the smaller the scale on which it is employed. According to a table given by Riedel in the Ccntralblatt deutschcr Ingenieurc for 1891, the conparative expenses of a small motor working ten hours per day and horse-power are as follows (in cents — four pfennigs equal one cent): Type of Motor.' Small steam Gas Compressed air. Electrical Petroleum Horse-power of Motor. 1/4 13 10} 9j ..1 / 1 i3i 20 7i 6 61- Ili 15 4i 5 10 8| 4t 4i 4i 9t 6i 3i 'si* 'The price of gas is taken at 3 cents per cubic metre. 2IO THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. f To place two businesses on a footing of technical equal- ity is thus not to give them industrial equality. A machine must be fully utilized and able to pay for itself if it is to cheapen producton. As it cannot take over the whole process of production, but only individual parts of it, it presuppo.es, if it is to remain continuously in action, an expansion of the business, the employment of a larger number of workmen, greater outlays for raw material, rent of workshop, etc. For this tiie sma.i master generally lacks the capital. Did he possess it. the advantages of more favourable purchase of raw material, of greater di- vision of work, of employment of the most capable tech- nical and artistic workmen, and of l^etter chances of sale would always remain with the large undertaking.* It is difficult to imagine how shrewd men could o^'erlook r.ll this. Has the tailor's, shoemaker's, or saddler's handicraft gained in vitality through the sewing-machine? The hDpe of finding through these two devices a new ba>is for handicraft must be abandoned; in most indus- trial branches in the larger cities there is no longer any such footing. Only in so far as the conditions of custom work continue unaltered does there remain room for a limited number of businesses leavened with capital. In these other persons take the place of the craftsmen; small and moderately large entrepreneurs, foremen of the fac- ' An interest! riR proof of what has been said is oflfered by the wood- turninn machines in cal)inet-makinn. None of the many larger handi- craft shoi)s in the cabinet trade of Berlin (anions which are also some wdl-'ounded businesses of niu.lerate si/c. with twenty or more work- men) have adopted tin ^e machines in their work, although mechanical piiwer of anv strength is to be rented in many worlshoi."! in the city at a c.miparatively moderate price. It sr - rather to be the case that small independent want-paying shops 1 been opened which take charge of the cutting and fitting; and y t'l- largest furniture fac- tories and cabinet-making establishmcn ha- ' up those machines in their !in<ines<. THE DECLIUE OF THE H/INDICR/IFTS. 21 I tory v'O '..shops and skilled factory hands, contractors and hoLic-workcr,-? Fxternally all these groups, with the ex- cef .'\o\ of the last, are better situated than the majority of tr.e ^niall master? of the past. Whether they are better satisfied anci i-iii^picr is another question. Here, however, we are dealing rather with the tendency of the development than with the actual conditions of to- day. But we must not be deceived. The decline takes place slowly and silently; great misery, such as prevailed among the hand-weavers when they fought their forlorn battle against the mechanical spinning-mule, is found, with rare exceptions, only in the clothing industries. Certain grades of city population have ever remained true to the handicraftsman, and will be faithful for some time to come. There thus remains time for the coming generation to adapt itself to the new conditions. What it needs for the transition is a better general, mercantile and technical edu- cation. The thrifty, cautious person still finas opportunity to carry on work and gain a position; he is not so destitute and at a loss as those who leave school and workshop with insufficient equipment for life. It is our conviction that the process in question cai.not be arrested by legislation, though it may perhaps be re- tarded. But would that be a gain? In the preceding chapter the evolution of systems of industry was compared with the development of the ma- chinery of commerce, in which the earlier forms were, it is true, pressed ba'k. though not destroyed, by the new. The comparison is applicable likewise to handicraft. Handicraft as a form of work is not perishing::; it is only be- ing restricted to that sphere in which it can make the most of its peculiar advantages. That sphere to-day is the country, the districts where it still finds the conditions of existence that gave birth to it in the Middle .\ges. Zl2 THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. * In rural Germany we have at present, according to tol- erably exact estimates, some six hundred and evemy rousand maste. craftsmen and more than a half m.lhon housana m • ^, together about one and journeymen and apprentices, or i ^ kaa\„„ the one-f^fth millions engaged in active worl. Adding the n^embers of the masters' households we have at a low estimate, a total of over three million persons. The largest paTof this numerical success has been achieved by haiidi- craft in our own century. From the socio-pol.tical stand- pott there is no ground for weeping with the masters of {^he small country hamlets who have lost their rural cus- tomers. Rather the contrary. During the period of the jealous exclusiveness oi the town guilds, when one could pass on the highway t ou- sands of journevmen who could nowhere obtam admit- ance to mastership, the journeymen smiths had a saying which the stranger at the meeting-house had to recite to the head journev man." It ran: " A master I have not been as vet. but hope to become one in time, if not here, then elsewhere. A league from the ring, where the dogs leap and break the hedges [town limits], there it is good to be a master." ... u _ Settlement in the country, at that time the sheet-anchor of the journevman smith, still saves many thousands of craftsmen who do not feel themselves ec,ual to the demands of citv life For the country an important social and eco- nomic a.lvance lies in this admixture of industrial elements among the people; and the livelihoods there resting upon the foundation of handicraft are among the most whole- some ofTered by present society. Of course, they are to be measured by the natural standanl of early hand-work, •Comp. L. Stock, C.rund-.ugc d. Vcrfassung d. Gcscllenwcscs d. deulsch. Handwtrker. \k >*-' THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 213 not by the artificial standard taken from the phantasy of economic and political romancers. For just there lies the seat of the complaints and griev- ances which since the beginnings of modern development have been raised so persistently by the surviving repre- sentatives of urban craftsmen, that they have given rise to a false impression of the degree of comfort that handicraft as an industrial system can possibly attord its representa- tives. This standard was comparatively high in the Mid- dle Ages, because the hand-worker's position in life was then measured by the position of those in the social grade lying next below his own, from which he himself had often come — the class of villein peasantry, the " poor people " of the country. Compared with this unspeakably op- pressed class, handicraft had "golden soil." for it regu- larly yielded a money return and secured its members civil freedom, while the peasant was exj d to all the vicissitudes of agriculture and to the oppressions of the owners of the soil. It would be false to assume that the mediaeval craftsmen had on the average considerable cap- ital ; and it was almost the same with the smaller tradei . With what lay beyond — patrician families and nobility — the craftsman did not compare himself: under the system of classes founded upon birth the individual is satisfied if he obtains what is due his class. Our social system of to-day rests upon classes deter- mined by occupation. In such a system everyone com- pares himself with all others, because no legal barrier sep- arates him from the rest. In comparison with the other classes of modern society, the position of handicraft, even where it is still capable of holding its own, ap- pears a very modest one. A*! other classes would seem to have raised themselves, and the hand-worker class alone to have remained stationary. Where hand-work is strug- 1 I -A fflp^- ^^ "wS np J H Hi In fe l|H H 1 *!^'l 1h i mm li i >'V^9 ^m- .-iS-j K i 8I4 r«£ DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. gling for its very existence, it presents a sad picture of oppression. It is certainly not a spectacle to be viewed with com- posure to see that broad stratum of small independent persons who formed the heart of the early town popula- tions disappear and yield place to a disconnected mass of dependent labourers. It is a loss to society for which we find in urban soil no present compensation. CHAPTER VI. THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. The close connection existing in Germany between scientific investigation and university instruction, while exhibiting many unquestionably pleasing features, has this one gjeat disadvantage, that those departments of knowl- edge which cannot foim the basis of an academic career are inadequately investigated. This is the fate of journalism. While in France and England the history of journalism presents an extraordinarily rich and developed literature, we in Germany possess but two essays worthy of mention, one treating of the beginnings, the other, in a decidedly fragmentary manner, of the later development of the daily press.* In this condition of affairs there would be little profit in determining to which of the existing departments of scientific research this neglected tUok really falls. A sub- ject so complex as journalism can be treated with advan- tage from very different standpoints: from the standpoint of political history, of literary history, of bibliography, of law. of philology even, as writings on the slovenliness of journalistic style give proof. The subject is, without doubt, of most direct concern to the political economist. ' The little book by Ludwig Salomon. Ctsck. d. deulsch. Zeitungs- tcesciis von J. erst. Anfang. b\s s. Wicderaufricht. d. Deutsch Retches, I, igoo. with its incomplete treatment of the subject, cannot materially alter this opinion. «I5 2l6 THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. For the newspaper is primarily a commercial contrivance, forming one of the most important pillars of contemporary- economic activity. But in vain do we search economic text-books, and even commercial manuals in a narrower sense, for a paragraph on the daily press. If, under these circumstances, we venture a brief and summary treatment of the beginnmgs of journalism, we are ourselves most fully conscious of our inability to make more than a partial presentation, and in so far as economic method is incapable of exhausting the material in all its phases, of the possible necessity of deceiving legitimate expectations. Our descriptions of the beginnings of journalism will vary with our conceptions of what a newspaper is. If the question. What is a newspaper? be put to ten different persons, perhaps ten different answers will be received. On the other hand, no one who is asked to name the agencies that weave the great web of intellectual and ma- terial influences and counter-influences by which modern humanity is combined into the unity of society will need much reflection to give first rank to the newspaper, along with post, railroad, and telegraph. In fact, the newspaper forms a link in the chain of mod- ern commercial machinery; it is one of those contrivances by which in society the exchange of intellectual and ma- terial goods is facilitated. Yet it is not an instrument of commercial intercourse in the sense of the post or the rail- way, both of which have to do with the transport of per- sons, goods, and news, but rat'ier in the sense of the letter 3nd circular. These make the news capable of transport, only l)€cause they are enabled by the help of writing and printing to cut it adrift, as it were, from its originator, and give it corporeal independence. However great the difference l)etween letter, circular, and newspaper 5nay appear to-d.iy, .a little reflection shows THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 217 that all three are essentially similar products, originating in the necessity of communicating news and in the em- ployment of writing in its satisfaction. The sole difference consists in the letter bemg addressed to individuals, the circular to several specified persons, the newspaper to many unspecified persons. Or, in other words, while letter and circular are instruments for the private communication of news, the newspaper is an instrument for its publication. To-day we are, of course, accustomed to the regular printing of the newspaper and its periodical appearance at brief intervals. But neither of these is an essential char- acteristic of the newspaper as a means of news publication. On the contrary, it will become apparent directly that the primitive paper from which this mighty instrument of commercial intercourse is sprung appeared neither in printed form nor periodically, but that it closely resembled the letter from which, indeed, it can scarcely be distin- guished. To be sure, repeated appearance at l^rief inter- vals is involved in the very nature of news publication. For news has value only so long as it is fresh; and to pre- serve for it the charm of novelty its publication must follow in the footsteps of '.^' events. We shall, however, soon see that the periodicity of these intervals, as far as it can be noticed in the infancy of journalism, depended upon the regular recurrence of opportunities to transport the news, and was in no way connected with the essential nature of the newspaper. The regular collection and despatch of news presupposes a wide-spread interest in pul-lic affairs, or an extensive area of trade exhibiting numerous commercial connec- tions and combinations of interest, or both at once. Such interest is not realized until people are united by some more or less extensive political organization into a certain community of life-interest. The city republics of ancient 2l8 THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. times required no newspaper; all their needs of publica- tion could be met by the herald and by inscriptions as oc- casion demanded. Only when Roman supremacy had em- braced or subjected to its influence all the countries of the Mediterranean was there need of some means by which those members of the ruling class who had gone to the provinces as ofificials, tax-farmers and in other occupa- tions, might receive the current news of the capital. It is significant that Caesar, the creator of the military mon- archy and of the administrative centralization of Rome, is regarded as the founder of the first contrivance resembling a newspaper.^ We say resembling a newspaper, for journalism as now understood did not exist among the Romans; and Momm- sen's mention of a " Roman Intelligence Sheet " ^ is but a distorted modernization. Caesar's innovations are to be compared rather with the bulletins and " laundry-lists " which the literary bureaux of our own governments supply for the use of journalists, than with our modern news- papers. Thus in his case it was not a question of founding journalism, but of influencing the newspapers already in existence. Indeed, long before Caesar's consulate it had become customary for Romans in the provinces to keep one or more correspondents at the capital to send them written reports on the course of political movement, and on other events of the day. Such a correspondent was generally an * Leclerc, Des journaux ches les Romains (Paris. 18,38). Lieberkiihn, De diurnis Romanorum actis (Vitnar. 1840). .'\. Schmidt, Das Staats- ecitungs'iccsen d. Rihtier, in Zt«chr. f. Gcschichtsw.. I, p. 303 ff. N. Zell, Ober d. Zcitungcn d. alien Rlimcr u. d. DoduiTschen Fragwcnte. in his Ferienschriften, pp. i ff., 109 ff. Hiibner, Pc sciiatus toptiUq^e Romani actis, in Fleckeiscn's Jhrb. f. Philol.. Suppl. III. pp. 5^4 ff. Heinze. Df spuriis diurttorum actorum fragmcnHs (Grcifswald, i860). ' Monimjtii. JVuiii. Gcsch., Ill (4ih cd.), p. 60;. THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 219 intelligent slave or freedman intimately acquainted with affairs at the capital, who, moreover, often made a business of reporting for several. He was thus a species of primitive reporter, differing from those of to-day only in writing not for a newspaper, but directly for readers. On recom- mendation of their employers, these reporters enjoyed at times admission even to the senate discussions. Antony kept such a man, whose duty it was to report to him not merely on the senate's resolutions, but also on the speeches and votes of the senators. Cicero, when pro-consul, re- ceived through his friend, M. Ca^lius, the reports of a cer- tain Chrestus, but seems not to have been particularly well satisfied with the latter's accounts of gladiatorial sports, law-court proceedings, and the various pieces of city gos- sip. As in this case, such correspondence never extended beyond a rude relation of facts that required supplement- ing through letters from party friends of the absent per- son. These friends, as we know from Cicero, supplied the real report on political feeling. The innovation made by Caesar consisted in instituting the publication of a brief record of the transactions and rcbolutions of the senate, and in his causing to be pub- lished the transactions of the assemblies of the Plebs, as well as other important matters of public concern. The first were the Acta senatus, the latter the Acta diurna populi Romani. The publication was made by painting the text on a white tablet smeared with gypsum. The tablet was displayed publicly, and for the inhabitants of the cap- ital was thus what we call a placard. For those abroad copies wer^" made by numerous writers and forwarded to their employers. After a certain interval the original was placed in the archives of the state. This Roman Public Bulletin was thus not in itself a newspaper, though it attained the importance of such by 220 THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. what we would consider the cumbersome device of private correspondence to the provinces. The Acta senatus -ivtre pubHshed for but a short time, being suppressd by Augustus. On the other hand, the Acta dinrna populi Romani obtained such favour in the eyes of the people that their contents could be made much more comprehensive, while their publication was long con- tinued under the Empire. They more and more developed, however, into a kind of court circular, and their contents began to resemble the matter ofifered by the official or semi-ofificial sheets of many European capitals to-day. On the whole, the; confined themselves to imparting facts; their one noti-eable tendency was to ignore the disagree- i.b1e. . The contents still continued to reach the provmces by way of correspondence; and, as Tacitus tells us, the people had regard not merely for what the official gazette con- tained but also for what it left unrecorded: people read between the lines. How long the whole system lasted we do not know. Probably after the removal of the court to Constantinople it gradually came to an end. The Germanic peoples who, after the Romans, assumed the lead in the history of Europe, were neither in civiliza- tion nor in political organization fitted to maintain a sim- ilar constitution of the news service; nor did they require it. All through the Middle Ages the political and social life of men was bounded by a narrow horizon; culture re- tired to the cloisters, and for centuries afifected only the people of prominence. There were no trade interests be- yond the narrow walls of their own town or manor to draw men together. It is only in the later centuries of the MiddleAges that extensive social combinations once more appear. It is first the church, embracing with her hierarchy all the countries of Germanic and Latin civilization, next THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 221 the burgher class with its city confederacies and common trade interests, and, finally, as a counter-influence to these, the secular territorial powers, who succeed in gradually realizing some form of union. In the twelfth and thir- teenth centuries we notice the first traces of an organized service for transmission of news and letters in the messen- gers of monasteries, the universities, and the various spirit- ual dignitaries; in the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries we have advanced to a comprehensive, almost postlike, organ- ization of local messenger bureaux for the epistolary inter- course of traders and of municipal authorities. And now, for the first time, we meet with the word Zcitung, or news- paper. The word meant originally that which was happen- ing at the time {Zcit — time), a present occurrence; then information on such an event, a message, a report, news. In particular do we find the word .ised for the com- munications on current political events which were re- ceived by the town clerks from other towns or from indi- vidual friends in the councils of those towns, either as let- ters or as supplements to them, and which are still fre- quently found in their archives. Thus the municipal archives of Frankfurt-on-Main possess as many as i88 let- ters relating to the raids of the Armagnacs in the early forties of the fifteenth century; they are mostly descrip- tions of sufferings and appeals for help from towns in Al- sace and Switzerland. Among them are not less than three accounts of the battle of St. Jacob, one from Ziirich, one from Strassburg. and one from the council of Basel.* •Wiilkor, Vrkundcn u. Schrcibcn. bctreff. d. Zug d. Armagnaken: in Neujahrsblatt d. Vcreins f. Gesch. u. Altertumsk. 7.11 Frankfurt-a.-M. for 187,^. On the followins section consult: Hatin. Ilistoire politique et Uttcrairc dc la frcssc en France (Paris, i85(H)i), Vol. I, pp. 28 ff., and his Biblio- graphic historiquc ct critique dc la prcsse pcriodique fran(;aisc. prcccdce d'Mn Ess!! hi^ti-'rique ct sUitixtique sur la fiaissance et Ics progrcs dc la 223 THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. This reporting is voluntary, and rests upon a basis of reciprocity. It sprang from the common interest uniting the towns against the noble and the territorial powers, and found effective support in the numerous town- messengers who maintained in regular courses — for this reason called " ordinary " messengers— the connection between Upper and Lower Germany. In the fifteenth century we find a similar exchange of news by letter between people of high standing— princes, statesmen, university professors — which reaches its high- est development during the era of the Reformation. It is now good form to add to a letter a special rubric, or to insert on special sheets. '" Noz-issima," " Tidings," " New Tidings " or " News." " Advices." Moreover, we already notice how people have ceased to give each other mere casual information abo-n the troubles and distress of the time, and aim at a systematic collection of news. It was especially to the great commercial centres and the trading towns wnich were the centres of messenger activity and the seat of higher education that news items flowed from all quarters, there to be collected and re-edited into letters and supplements, and thence to be diverted in streams in all directions. Ever>-where these written tidings bear the name of newspaper (Zcitini^ or natc Zeitungen). The largest part of this correspondence is of a T)rivate frcsse pcriodiquc dans Ics Deux Mondes (Paris, 1866), pp. xlv ff.; Leber Dc Vctat red dc la prcsse et des pamphlets depuis ''^^cois JHsqua Louis XIV (Paris. 1834). Alex. Andrews. The .-nrnry ' Bnlish Journalism (London. T850). Vol. I. pp. i^ ff.; Ott.no ... sta^^ periodica, il commercio dci llbri e latipographia tn Italm (Milan- i>* ^ p 7; Roh. Pnit7, r,e!:chichie d. dcutsch. Jouriialismus (Ilanovc- iH^ Vol 1- J Wincklcr, Pie period. Presse Ocstcrrcichs (Vienna, ih^O. ,"C 10 ff; Gm>shofT, Pic hncHtehe Zcitung d. XVI. Jah-hundcrts .^ii^£. 1877): Steinhauscn, in Archiv f. Post u. Telegraphic. 1895. P' .Ur*. and lli^ Gcschichtc d. dcutsch. Bficfes. 2 vol?. THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 223 character. Men at the centre of political and ecclesiastical activity communicated to each other the news that had come to hand. It was a reciprocal giving and receiving which did not prevent those with a heavy correspondence from multiplying their news-sheets in order to append them to letters to different persons, nor the recipients from redespatching copies of them or circulating them amongst their acquaintances. Princes, it would seem, al- ready maintained at important commercial points their own paid correspondents. For a time these written newspapers did not find their way among the masses. The circles for which they were intended were: (i) princes and statesmen, as also town- councillors; (2) university instructors and their immediate cooperators in the public service in school and church; (3) the financiers of the time, the great merchants. Almost all reformers and humanists are diligent news- paper correspondents and regular recipients of newspaper reports. This is especially true of Melancthon, whose numerous connections throughout all parts of Germany and the neighbouring countries continually brought him a plentiful store of fresh news, with which he in turn sup- plied his friends, and certain princes in particular. In comparison with his. Luther's and Zwingli's correspond- ence is relatively poor in such tnatter. On the other hand, John and Jacob Stunn. Bucer and Capito of otrassburg, Oecolampadin.N and Beatus Rhenanus of Basel. Hiitzer and Ur'hanus Rhegiu- of Augsburg, Ilier. Baumgartner of NtTremberg, Joachim Camerarius, Bngcnhagen. and oth- ers were very zealous and active in this direction. The sources for their news are manifold. Besides oral or written conmuuiications from friends, we know of nar- ratives of incoming merchants, particularly of book-dealers who had visited the Frankfurt fair, reports of letter-car- m^ v\ ,24 :he genesis of journalism. riers accounts from soldiers returning home from their campaigns, communications from strangers passing through their town or from visiting friends, and especially from students coming from foreign lands to study at Ger- man universities; finally, any items gleaned from foreign ambassadors who happen to be passing through; from chancellors, secretaries, and agents of important person- ^^Naturally such oral news collected at random varied creatly in worth, and had first to undergo the editona criticism of the correspondent before being circulated further The news-items based upon written mformation were of much greater importance. It may be of some interest, by following Melancthon's correspondence, to in- quire somewhat into the sources of them.'' , , . ., We soon perceive that there were a number of definite collecting centres for the various classes of news. In the forefront of interest at that time stood the Eastern ques- tion, that is, the threatening of the countries of Central Europe by the Turks. Ncv^s of the engagements with the latter came either from Hungary through Vienna, Cra- cow or Breslau, or from Constantinople by sea by way of Venice. The reporters are mostly ecclesiastics, adherents of the New Learning. On affairs in the South communications came from Rome, Venice, and Genoa, as well as from learned friends in Padua and Bologna. News from France and Spam was procured by way of Lyons. Genoa, and Strassburg; from England and the Netherlands by way of Antwerp and Co- logne; from the countries c.f the North by way of Bremen Hamburg, and Lubeck; from the Northeast by way of Konigsberg and Riga. •According to Grasshoff. cited above, pp. 2i^. THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 225 In Germany, Nuremberg was the chief collecting centre for news, partly by reason of its central position, partly because of its extensive trade connections. Anyone de- sirous of receiving reliable and definite information on the doings of the world wrote to Nuremberg or sent thither a representative. Princes like Duke Albert of Prussia and Christian III of Denmark there maintained resident correspondents, whose duty it was to collect and report any fresh items of news. Town officials, councillors, and reputable merchants frequently undertook such an office. Besides Nuremberg. Frankfurt, Augsburg, Regensburg, Worms, and Speier were also important news centres. The newspapers that Meiancthon compiled from these various sources are simply historical memoranc'a, selecteo with some care and interspersed at rare intervals with discussions of a political nature, and more frequently with all kinds of complaints and fears, wishes and hopes. Along with the important news from the Emperor's court, from the various seats of war and on the progress of the Reformation, we meet with others reflecting the complete naivete and incredulity of the times: reports of political prophecies, strange natural phenomena, missbirths, earth- quakes, showers of blood, comets and other celestial ap- paritions. In the second half of the sixteenth century this species of news-agency received definite form and organization as a business, not merely in Germany, but, apparently even earlier, in Italy, especially in Venice and R^me. Venice was long regarded as the birthplace of the news- paper in the modern acceptation of the word. This opin- ion was supported by the extensive use of the name ga- zctta or gazcUc amongst the Latin nations for a newspaper: and this word is to be found eariiest in Venice as the name of the small coin. if 326 THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. M. We will not enter into the accounts — at times rather romantic— that have been given to justify the derivation (in itself improbable) of the name of the newspaper from the name of the coin.' In itself, however, there is much to be said for the pre- sumption that journalism, as described above, v»as first de- veloped as a business in Venice. As the channel of trade between the East and West, as the seat of a govern- ment that first organized the political news service and the consular system in the modern sense, the old city of lagoons formed a natural collecting centre for important news-items from all lands of the known vvorld. Even early in the fifteenth century, as has been shown by the investigations of Valentinelli, the librarian of St. Mark's Library, collections of news had been made at the instance of the council of Venice regarding events that had either occurred within the republic or been reported by ambassadors, consuls, and officials, by ships' captains, mer- chants and the like. These were sent as circular despatches to the Venetian representatives abroad to keep them posted on international affairs. Such collections of news were called fogli d'azi'isi. Later on, duplicates of these official collections were made, though evidently not for public circulation, but rather for the use of prominent citizens of Venice who sought to derive advantage from them in tiicir commercial operations, and also communicated them by letter to their business friends in other lands. This appending of political news to commercial corre- spondence, or the enclosing of the same on special sheets, soon became the practice also among the lartjc traders of Augsburg. Nureniburg. and the other German towns. • Comp. Hatin, Bibliograpkie dt la presse perioduiue, p. xlvii. 19 I THE GENESIS OF JOURN/fUSM. 227 By and by it occurred to some that the collection and transmission of news by letter could be made a source of profit. In the sixteenth century we find on the Venetian Rialto, between the booths of the changers and gold- smiths, an independent news-bureau that made a business of gathering and distributing to interested parties polit- ical and trade news: information as to arrival and clearance of vessels, on prices of wares, on the safety of the high- ways, and also on political events.'' Indeed, a whole guild of scrittori d'awisi grew up. In a short time we meet with the same people in Rome, where they bear the name nov- ellanti or gazettanti. Here their activity, whether because they circulated disagreeable f' ':ts or accompanied their facts with their own comments, became discomforting to the Curia. In the year 1572 not less than two papal bulls were issued against them (by Pius V and Gregory XIII); the writing of " advices " was strictly forbidden, and its continuance threatened with branding and the galleys. Nevertheless we continue to meet numerous indications of a news service from Rome to the Upper Italian cities and to Germany. In the meantime, newspaper writing had also become a business in Germany with an organization that, for the existing conditions of trade, is really wonderful. This organization is connected on the one hand with the further develojjment of despatch by courier, and on the otner with Emperor Maximilian's institution of the post from the Austrian Netherlands to the capital, Vienna, by which the regular receipt of news was greatly facilitated. We thus find, at various places, in the second half of the sixteenth century, special correspondence bureaux which collect .md communicate news by letter to their subscribers. Several 'According to Prutz, Ctsch. d. Journalismus, I, p m. ml s\ 228 THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. collections of these epistolary newspapers have been pre- served: for instance, one from 1582 to 1591 in the Grand Ducal library in Weimar, and two in the University li- brary at Leipzig from the two last decades of the same century.® Let us refer briefly to the oldest year of the Leipzig col- lection. It bears the heading: " News to hand from Nuremberg from the 26th of October Anno '87 to the 26th of October Anno '88." Then follow in independent group- ings transcripts of the news received weekly from Rome, Venice, Antwerp, and Cologne at the office of the Nurem- berg firm of merchants, Reiner Volckhardt and Florian von der Bruckh, and thence given out again either by the house itself or by a special publisher. The person who re- ceived the present collection was probably the chief city clerk of Leipzig, Ludwig Triib. The communications from Rome are as a rule da*ed about six days earlier than those from Venice, and the Antwerp correspondence about five days earlier than that from Cologne. All four places lay on the great post-routes from Italy and the Netherlands to Germany. Along with these periodical communications irregular ones appear now and then, for instance, from Prague and Breslau, and particularly often from Frankfurt-on-Main. Examining the contents of these news-items more closely we soon find that we have to do not with events occurring in Rome, Venice, Antwerp, etc.. but with re- ports collected at these places. Thus the correspondence from Antwerp contained not merely news from the Neth- erlands, but also from France, England, and Denmark; by way of Rome came news not only from Italy, but from Spain and the south of France as well; from Venice came " Comp. Jyt. Oixl, Die Anfangf d deulsch. /Uilungstrcsst in Archiv f C;t:bch. d. d'jlU- !>. Miu-Iihaiuiels. \'ol. Ill (1^50). THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 229 news from the Orient. The reports are soberly descriptive and commercial in tone. Political items preponderate; communications on trade and commerce appear less fre- quently. There is no trace of the favourite tales of won- ders and ghosts. But how was the news service in these four great collect- ing points organized? Who were the collectors and the intermediaries? How were they paid? What were their sources of information? Unfortunately we can answer only part of these questions. In the first place, as to the sources from which the au- thors of the letters derive their information, they them- selves appeal at times even to the last mail or to the regular messenger service, the " Ordinari." Thus we read in a letter from Cologne dated February 28, 1591: "The let- ters from Holland and Zeeland, and also from Italy, have not yet appeared." In a similar letter from Rome of date February 17, 1590, we are informed that the postmaster there has contracted with the Pope to establish a weekly post to and from Lyons; and at the close we read, " In this way we shall have news from France every week." Nothing more than this is to be gleaned from the collec- tion itself. When, however, we notice contemporaneously in several German cities that it is the heads of the town- couriers and the imperial postmasters who in particular de- vote themselves to the business of editing and despatching news-letters, the supposition gains greatly in probability that the collection of news is in most intimate connection with the nail service of the time. The messenger mas- ters and the postmasters probably exchanged at regular intervals the news they had collected, in order to pass it on to their particular clients. But the whole matter stands greatly in need of closer investigation." •Steinhausen in Archiv f. Post u. T\\.. 1S.J5, p. J55. expresses merely f' ! 230 THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. The relations between wholesale trade and newspapers somewhat clearer. Like the Nuremberg merchants mentioned above, some large trading houses in other local- ities had also organized an independent news service. Es- pecially prominent were the Welsers and Fuggers, whose news reports we find in the celebrated letter-book of the Nuremberg jurist, Christoph Scheurl,»° along with the Nuremberg correspondence. In the second half of the six- teenth century the Fuggers had the news coming to them from all parts of the world, regularly collected and appar- ently also published. The title of the regular numbers was " Ordinari-Zeittungen." There were also supplements, or " specials." with the latest items. The price of one num- ber was four kreuzer; the yearly cost in Augsburg, includ- ing delivery, was 25 florins, and for the ordinari numbers alone, 14 florins. One Jeremiah Krasser, of Augsburg, burgher and newspaper writer, is named as editor. He informs us that he supplied many other gentlemen m Augsburg and district with his news. A file of this organ of publication, so rich in material, for the years 1568 to 1604 is found in the Vienna library.'* The newspapers of the Fuggers regularly contain news from all parts of Europe and the East, and also from places still further removed: Persia, China and Japan, America. Besides the political correspondence, we have frequent re- ports of har\'ests and memoranda of prices, now and then even communications in the nature of advertisements, and a long list of Vienna firms— how and where all things could now be procured in Vienna. Even literary notices a supposition, though indeed a very well grrounded and probable one. on the course of development. , „ , " Christoph Scheurl: Brxffbuch. fin Bcilrag :. Geschich. d. Reforma- tion u. ihrer Zett (Sooden u Knaake, Potsdam. 1867-187^). " S.cket. Weimar Jahrb. f. dcutsche Sprache «. Litteratur. I. p. M^ THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 231 of recent and noteworthy books appear; and there is one account of the presentation of a new drama. As in Augsburg, so in other places in Germany we meet individual correspondents — ^journalists (Zeitunger), novel- ists — who carry on their newspaper writing in the service of princes or of cities. Thus in 1609 the elector of Saxony, Christian II, made a contract with Joh. Rudolf Ehinger, of Balzhein in Ulm, whereby the latter undertook for a yearly fee of 100 florins to furnish reports upon events in Switzerland and France, Swabia naturally being included. In the year 1613 Hans Zeidler, of Prague, received from the Saxon court for similar service a yearly salary of 300 florins, together with 3319 thalers 6 g. gr. for expenses incurred in collecting his news.'^ In the same year the sovereign bishop of Bamberg had newspapers forwarded to him by a Dr. Gugel, of Nuremberg, for a fee of 20 flor- ins. In the year 1625 the town of Halle paid the news cor- respondent. Hieronymus Teuthorn, of Leipzig, the sum of two schock, eight groschen. as quarterly fee; and as late as 1662 the council of the town of Delitzsch was subscriber to a newspaper correspondence from Leipzig at a quarterly fee of two thalers. The postmasters and messenger chiefs appear to have been paid somewhat l>etter for their ser- vices, which were indeed more valuable. At least, we know that in the year 1615 the postmaster at Frankfurt, Johann von der Birghden. who furnished a great number of German princes with news.*'' was in receipt of a yearly salary of 60 florins for supplying the electoral court of Mainz with the weekly newspapers.'* "C. D. V. Witzk'bcn. Gesch. d. Leifsiger Zeitung (Leipzig, i860), pp. 5-6. The Saxon court in i6.'9 maintained similar agents in Vienna, Berlin. Brunswick, .\ugsburg. Ulm, Breslau, Hamburg, Liibec, Prague, Amsterdam, at the Hapiie. and in Hungary. "Comp. Opel, as above, pp 28, (6 "'* Fauthaber, Gesch. </. I'vst m Irankiurl-a.-M. (Archiv, f. Frankf. Gesch. u. Kunst. New Series, XI. pp. 31, toff. ill 232 THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. Even in the seventeenth century the wrritten newspapers appear not to have made their way to wider circles. They were still too costly for that. At the close of the sixteenth and in the seventeenth century we find written newspapers in France and Eng- land, as well as in Germany and Italy. In France they are -" " ed nouvellcs a la main; in England, news-letters. In both countries they are confined to the capital city. The line of development in Paris is the more interest- ing: it may be said indeed that the most primitive of all newspapers, the precursor of the written newspaper, is to be found there. It is the related, or spoken, paper." In the turbulent times of the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries groups of Parisian burghers would assemble each evening on the street corners, on the Pont Neuf, and on the public squares, bringing together the news of the day and making their own comments upon it. As is easily conceivable, there were among these groups individuals who became adepts in the collection and repetition of news. Gradually method and organization were introduced; the so-called nouvellistes held regular meetings, exchanged their news with each other, and made comments thereon, discussed politics, and laid plans. " Comp. Hatin, Histoire de la presse en France, Vol. I, pp. 32-33- I An interesting present-day instance of the " spoken " newspaper, which may indeed nut be so very rare a phenomenon, is given in a sketch of Swiss life in the little village of Champcry by a recent writer in the Canadian Magazine. " On three of the houses of the village," it is stated. " are curious balconies, which are in reality old pulpits, once used for open-air preaching. They now serve the place of the country newspaper, for en Sundays, after mass, a man calls out from them the news of the week, what there is for sale, what cattle have been stolen or have strayed, and other items of interest to those who have come down for the day from the isolation of the high moun- tains."— .S"7t»M Ufe and Scenery, by E. Fanny Jones. Can. Mag., Aug. 1898, p. 287.— Ed. i THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 233 The writers of the time treat these groups with never- ending satire; the comic dramatists seize the fruitful theme, and even Montesquieu devotes to them one of the most entertaining of his Lettres Persancs}^ What was at the outset a mere pastime for news-hunters and idlers, enterprising brains soon developed into a busi- ness. They undertook to supply regular news to people of rank and standing. Men in high station kept a nouvel- liste as they kept a hair-dresser or surgeon. Mazarin, for instance, paid such a servant 10 livres per month. These groups of nouvellistes soon began to seek cus- tomers in the Provinces also, and these, of course, could be supplied only by letter. Each group had its particular editorial and copying bureau, and its special sources for court and official news. The subscribers paid a fixed sum, according to the number of pages that they desired each week. Thus originated the celebrated nouvellcs a la main, which, in spite of many prosecutions on the part of the government, lasted till well towards the end of last cen- tury, and which were often sent abroad as well.'^ That which gave them a firm footing along with the printed newspapers was, to a certain extent, the circumstance that they rendered the secrecy of the government system largely illusory, and further, took the liberty now and then of animadverting on public conditions.'^ In England likewise the nczvs-lcttcrs, more especially devoted to furnishing the country nobility with the news of the capital anrl the court, maintained themselves well "(Euvres computes (Paris, 1857), p. 87, Lettre CXXX. "La Gasette de la Rcgencc. janvicr iriS—juin ///p. publicf d'apres le manuscrit inedit conserre a la Ribliolhcque royale de La Uaye. par Le Comte E. de Barthilemy (Paris, 1887) gives a description of the contents of these sheets. '* Similarly in Austria: Joh. Winckler, Die period. Presse Oesterreichs (Vienna, 1875), pp ag-q. ft ft! 234 THE GENESIS OF JOURNAUSM. into the eighteenth century. The printed newspapers of that epoch indeed adapted themselves to the system to the extent of appearing with two printed and two un- printed pages, thereby enabling their subscribers to send them to others, enriched with additional notes m writing. Thus we see that at about the same time in all the ad- vanced countries of Europe the written newspaper anses as a medium-of course, as yet a decidedly restricted me- dium-of news publication, and maintains itself for more than two hundred years. It is, however, most remarkable that the production of these written news-sheets as a busi- ness can nowhere be traced beyond the period of the in- vention of printing. In this connection the question naturally arises, why the printing-press was not taken into the service of the regular news publication. The question is answered by the simple fact that even in young colonial countries with an European population ac- customed at home to printed newspapers, the written pre- ceded the printed news-sheets. This was true of the English colonies in America at the beginning of the eigh- teenth century,- and of the colony of West Australia in 18^0 " This proves that it could not have been so much the pressure of the censorship, that so long delayed the employment of the press for news publication, as the lack pp, 14 ft.; Hatm. a» *<'"■ P^ ' ' ,,„, ,bat likc«ise in (New York. 1873). PP- 5' «• " Andrews, as above, Vul. IT, pp. 3'- ff- ^ THE GENESIS OF JOURNjIUSM. 23S ; of a sufficiently large circle of readers to guarantee the sale necessary to meet the cost of printing. However, since as far back as the close of the fifteenth century, special numbers of those written newspapers con- taining matter of a presumably broader interest were fre- quently printed. These were the one-page prints issued by enterprising publishers under the name of " Ncue Zeitmtg," and disposed of at fairs and markets. Collections are to be found in every old library.22 The oldest of these prints is a report of the obsequies of Emperor Frederick III from the year 1493. From that time till the sixteenth century had run its course they continued to hold their own; but with the growth of periodical news-sheets, they became rarer, and finally, in the eighteenth, disap- peared. The earliest numbers bear either no title at all or take their title from the contents. The name Zeitung, or newspaper, for such a loose sheet appears for the first time in 1505. We find, however, various other appella- tions; for example, Letter, Relation, Tale, News, Descrip- tion, Report, Advice, Post, Postilion, Courier, Rumour, Despatch, Letter-bag.^^ To these all kinds of qualifying titles are frequently added, such as Circumstantial News, Truthful and Reliable Description, Faithful Description, Truthful Relation, Review and Contents, Historical Dis- course, and Detailed Explanation; very often we have: New and Truthful Tidings, Truthful and terrible Tidings, Wonderful, terrible, pitiful Tidings. In England some of the titles are: Newes, Newe Newes, Thiding, Woful Newes, Wonderful and strange News, Lamentable News; "Treated bibiographically by Weller, Die erstcn deutsch. Zcituugen (Bibliothek d. Iterar. Vereins, Vol. LXI). Supple'..ent to same in the " Germania," XXVI, p. 106. "Brief. Relatiot,, Mar, Nachricht, Beschreihung. Bericht. Aviso. Post, Postillion, Kurier, Fama, Depesehe. FeUHsen. . -.tli.l . iilii' 836 THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. and in France: Discours, Memorable Discours, Nouvelles, Recit, Courier, Messager, Postilion, Mercure, etc. The titles, we notice, are sensational and pretentious. The contents vary greatly. In the great majority of cases they consist of political news; argument remains altogether in the background. The written news-letters are the chief, though not the sole, source for these fugitive productions of the printing-press. Ordinarily, the one-page prints are independent of each other; and only here and there at the end of the sixteenth century can several consecutive num- bers be instanced; but this is not sufficient to justify us in supposing a periodical issue. These loose sheets, however, at least prepare the way, as regards form and matter, for the printed newspaper with its regular issues. And they render a like service in so far as they awakened among the masses an interest in occurrences reaching beyond mere parish affairs. The first printed periodical news collections begin as early as the sixteenth century. They are annual publica- tions, the so-called Postreuter (postilions) or news epit- omes whose contents may in a manner be compared with the political reviews of the year in our popular calendars.** These are supplemented by semi-annual news sum- maries, the so-called Relationcs semestralcs or Fair Reports. They were begun between 1580 and 1590 by Michael von Aitzing. They drew their information chiefly from the regular post and traders' newspapers, and for more than two centuries formed one of the chief articles of sale at the Frankfurt fair, and later on at the Leipzig spring and fall fairs as well.^^ The first printed weekly of which we "According to Prutz, cited above, p. 179. they appeared as early as the middle of the sixteenth century. " F. Stieve, Ueber d. dltest. halbj'dhrig. Zeitungen odtr Missrelationen, u. ir.sbesond. iiber derm Rcgriindcr. Frhm. Michael <on Aitzing: Abh, THE GENESIS OF jOURNAUSM. 237 have direct information is a Strassburg sheet, whose num- bers for the year 1609 are found in the University library at Heidelberg, while fragments of later years are pre- served in the public library at Zurich.2« Jt corresponds exactly in matter and form with the regular despatches Y.hich the post brought weekly from :..e chief collecting places of the news trade. It was soon imitated; and after the beginning of the Thirty Years' War the growth in the number of pnnted weeklies was particularly rapid. We have evidence of the exisience of about two dozen in the second and third decades 01 the seventeenth century. They were established chiefly by book-printers; though in numerous places the post assumed, naturally with varying success, the right of printing despatches as a part of its prerogative. While in Frankfurt, Leipzig, Munich. Col- logue, and Hamburg the old connection between post and newspaper continued for a considerable time, the publica- tion of news was in many other towns completely absorbed by the book-printers, a fact of the greatest moment for its further development. Germany is the first country that can show printed newspapers appearing regularly at brief intervals. The English and the Dutch claims to the honour of having produced the earliest printed weeklies are now generally abandoned. England can point to nothing similar before the year 1622: the first French weeklv sheet appeared in 163 1. 2T '* der k. bayer Akad. d. Wiss., III. CI. XVI, p. , (Munich. 1881). Cotnp. also Ort.i. Ausfiihrl Abhand. von d. bcriihmtcn zwocn Reichs- *"^sse„ so ,n d. ieichsstadt Frankfurt-a.-M . jahrlk: abgehaltm werden (Frankfurt, 1765] pp. 7,4 ff.; Prutz, as above, pp. 188 IT • J von Schwarzkopf, Ueb^r potitische u. gelehrte Zeitungen in Frankf'urt-a -M 1802. ' Opel, as above, pp. 44 ff. ' [See article Nmspapers in the hncy. Brit, and the literature th given, — Ed.1 ere *;H 338 THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. !■ iiill!' It will perhaps seem strange that a leap was made di- rectly from half-yearly reports to weekly publications without a transitional stage of monthly reports. It must, however, not be forgotten that the collection of news, as well as the distribution of the news-sheets, had to conform to the peculiar commercial facilities of the time. The most important of these were the fairs and the stage-posts. The semi-annual fairs made possible the distribution of the printed news from one great centre of trade and travel to even the most remote points. But the stage-posts tra- versed the chief trade-routes once a week each way. The leap from the half-yearly to the weekly reports lay thus in the nature of things. By the weekly newspapers the impetus was given to the essentially modern development of the press. Yet it was a considerable time before the first daily newspapers ap- peared. This occurred in Germany in 1660 {Leipziger Zcitung), in England in 1702 {Daily Courant), in France in I jjj {Journal de Paris). We need not pursue this theme down to our cosmopol- itan papers that appear three times a day. The distin- guishing feature of the latter as contrasted with the written newspaper of the sixteenth century is not so much the magnitude of ♦'^e organization for procuring news and the rapidity in trar.smitting it, as the transformation in the nature of the contents, particularly the advertising, and the influence thereby exerted on pul)lic opinion, and, con- sequently, on the course of the world's history. For the sixteenth century the network of agencies for the regular collection of news already described, was with- out doubt magnificent. There runs through it a modern characteristic, the characteristic of uniting individual forces in divided labour towards a single end. In the de- partment of news collection there has been little advance THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. »39 since the sixteenth century. The whole subsequent de- velopment of the newspaper in this direction rests on the separation of news collection from news despatch (post), and on the commercial organization of the former into correspondence bureaux and telegraph agencies. To the telegraph agencies have fallen the duties of the earlier postmasters and news-scribes, but with this difference, that they no longer labour directly for the newspaper readers, but supply the publishing house with half-finished wares, making use in such woik of the perfected commercial ma- chinery of modem times. Again, the further development of news publication in the field that it has occupied since the more general ioption of the printing-press, has been peculiar. At the outset the publisher of a periodical printed newspaper dif- fered in no wise from the publisher of any other printed work— for instance, of a pamphlet or a book. He was but the multiplier and seller of a literary product, over whose content he had no control. The newspaper publisher mar- keted the regular post-news in its printed form just as an- other publisher oflFered the public a herbal or an edition of an old writer. But this soon changed. It was readily perceived that the contents of a newspaper number did not form an entity in the same sense as the contents of a book or pam- phlet. The news-items there brought together, taken from different sources, were of varying reliability. They needed to be used judicially and critically: in this a polit- ical or religious bias could find ready expression. In a still higher degree was this the case when men began to discuss contempoiary political questions in the newspapers and to employ them as a medium for disseminating party opinions. This took place first in England during the Long Parlia- n %*\ 240 THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. m ment and the Revolution of 1649. The Netherlands and a part of the imperial free towns of Germany followed later. In France the change was not consummated before the era of the great Revolution: in most other countries it oc- curred in the nineteenth century. The newspaper, from being a mere vehicle for the publication of news, became an instrument for supporting and shaping public opinion and a weapon of party politics. The effect of this upon the internal organization of the newspaper undertaking was to introduce a third depart- ment, the editorship, between news collecting and news publication. For the newspaper publisher, however, it sig- nified that from a mere seller of news he had become a dealer in public opinion as well. At first this meant nothing more than that the publisher was placed in a position to shift a portion of the risk of his undertaking upon a party organization, a circle of inter- ested persons, or a government. If the leanings of the paper were distasteful to the readers they ceased to buy the paper. Their wishes thus remained, in the final analy- sis, the determining factor for the contents of the news- papers. The gradually expanding circulation of the pnnted newspapers nevertheless soon led to their employment by the authorities for making public announcements. With this came, in the first quarter of last century, the extension of private announcements,'^ which have now attained, through the so-called advertising bureattx,^^ some such or- ganization as political news collecting possesses in the cor- respondence bureaux. " At first, it would seem, in special advice or intelligence sheets which in many cases come from general agencies (Inquiry of!ices, Bureaux of Information). Comp. F. Mangold, in Basler Jhrb., 1897. " AHno»ccn-Exi>ediliontn. THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 241 By admitting advertisements the newspaper fell into a peculiarly ambiguous position. For the subscription price it formerly published only news and opinions of general in- terest; now, through all sorts of advertisements, for which it receives special remuneration, it also serves private trade and private interests. It sells news to its readers, and it sells its circle of readers to any private interest capable of paying the price. In the same paper, often on the same page, where the highest interests of mankind are, or at least should be, represented, buyers and sellers ply their vocations in ignoble greed of gain. For the uninitiated it is often difficult to distinguish where the interests of the public cease and private interests begin. This is all the more dangerous in that in the course of the past century the subjects discussed on the editorial page of the newspapers have grown to embrace almost the whole range of human interests. Statecraft, provincial and local administration, the administration of justice, art in all its manifestations, technology, economic and social life in its manifold phases, are reflected in the daily press; and since the development of the feuilleton, a good pro- portion of literary and even of scientific products flows into this great stream of contemporary social and mental life. The book as a form of publication — we may have no doubts on the point — loses ground from year to year. It is impossible to enter into these matters at greater length. The sole aim of this cursory survey of the mod- ern development of journalism has been to give, from the view-point of historical evolution, the beginnings of the newspaper press their proper setting, and at the same time to show how the gathering of news has been con- ditioned at each epoch by general conditions of trade. The Roman newspaper is one feature in the autonomous administration of the wealthy and aristocratic household. K^\ I i|' I 242 WE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. A news-clerk was kept, just as was a body-surgeon or a librarian. In most cases he is the property, the slave, of the news-reader, working according to the directions of his master. In the written newspaper of the sixteenth century there is exhibited the same handicraft character then domi- nating all branches of higher economic activity. The news- writer, on demand and for a definite price, furnishes di- rectly to a circle of patrons the news that he had gathered —in which proceeding he doubtless suits the amount to the latter's needs. He is reporter, editor, and publisher in one. The modem newspaper is a capitalistic enterprise, a sort of news-factory in which a great number of people (cor- respondents, editors, typesetters, correctors, machine- tenders, collectors of advertisements, office-clerks, messen- gers, etc.) are employed on wage, under a single adminis- tration, at very specialized work. This paper produces wares for an unknown circle of readers, from whom it is, furthermore', frequently separated by intermediaries, such as delivery agencies and postal institutions. The simple needs of the reader or of the circle of patrons no longer de- termine the quality of these wares; it is now the very com- plicated conditions of competition in the publication mar- ket. In this market, however, as generally in wholesale markets, the consumers of the goods, the newspaper readers, take no direct part; the determining factors are the wholesale dealers and the speculators in news: the gov- ernments, the telegraph bureaux dependent upon their special correspondents, the political parties, artistic and scientific cliques, men on 'change, and last but not least, the advertising agencies and large individual advertisers. Each number of a great journal which appears to-day is a m.^rvpl of economic division of labour, capitalistic organ- THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 243 ization, and mechanical technique; it is an instrument of in- tellectual and economic intercourse, in which the potencies of all other instruments of commerce — the railway, the post, the telegraph, and the telephone — are united as in a focus. But our eyes can linger with satisfaction on no spot where capitalism comes into contact with intellectual life; and so we can take but half-hearted pleasure in this ac- quisition of modem civilization. It would indeed be diffi- cult for us to believe that the newspaper in its present de- velopment is destined to constitute the highest and final medium for the supplying of news.** ** [Comp. Mr. Alfred Harmsworth on The Newspapers of the Twen- tieth Century in North Amer. Rev., Jan. 1901. — Ed.] SI • i i Uu CHAPTER VII. UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. There is in Germany perhaps scarcely a modern text- book or contemporary course of university lectures on political economy in which some ment.on ,s "ot m^le o the principle of union of labour and some remark offe e thereon. No one has really much to say about it. \ et it is there, and has its traditional place after the section on the division of labour, where, if it be thought at all worthy of it it receives with regularity its paragraph, to come to light' no more in the later text of the book or lecture. And so it has been for more than half a century. But a science cannot be lenient with concepts that are not fitted to give a deeper insight into a series of phenomena, simply because thev have once gained currency, it is at length time for a closer investigation of this ancient inyentonal item in order, if it is really unserviceable, to discard ,t. or to assign it its proper place should it be found useful in fur- thering our knowledge. . According to the text-books, union of labour is nothmg more nor less than "the other side of division of labour; or " division of labour viewe.l from the standpoint o the or^- ganizing unit;" ' the " correlative of division of labour; "the reverse side of the medal whose obverse side is the > Roll, in Philippovicb. (:ru„dr,ss </. toUt. (V/;. (2A cd.). p. 78. • M Mt Crun^irUs d. lolks-.v^rthschaftslfhre. 9 29. UNlOhl OF L/tBOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 24S division of labour," ^ These are all somewhat vague ex- pressions, which on the whole ^>eem to have their origin in the view that if labour is divided it must also be reunited, since the separate parts cannot exist independently. Here then the idea of division of labour is either conceived of very restrictedly — somewhat after the manner of Adam Smith's pin-manufactory — in which case the unifying force is supplied by the capital of the entrepreneur; or the con- ception is broadened to embrace the so-called social division of labour, in which case the labour-uniting element must be furnished by trade; so that union of labour would be synonymous with commercial organization generally. In fact, Roscher, who gives the most detailed treatment of the subject, and to whom all later writers resort, re- garded the subject in this light.* Division of labour and union of labour are in his view, " but two different aspects of the same conception, namely, social labour: separation of tasks so far as they would incommode one another, and their union in so far as they aid one another." " The vine- dresser and the flax-grower," he continues, " would neces- sarily die of hunger if they could not count for certain on the grower of grain; the workman in the pin-factory who merely prepares the pin-heads must be sure of his comrade who sharpens the points if his labour is not to be entirely in vain; while the labour of a merchant simply cannot be conceived of without that of the different producers be- tween whom he acts as intermediary." The whole phenomenon is thus shrouded in the mists of processes of commerce and of organization; it is made synonymous with economy generally. In particular it alto- gether loses its correlation with the notion of division of • Kleinwachter. Die rolksw. Produktion in Schonberg's Handbook, * Pnncifks of Foiiiical Economy (New York, 187S), I, pp. 203-4. I if ir 1 ■' I V 1 246 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. labour. For the rest, Roscher discusses at length only the constancy of the progress of civilization — which is realized by each generation leaving to its successors the augmented inheritance of its predecessors; and further, the advantage of large undertakings and the association of small ones whereby labour ultimately disappears almost completely from the horizon. Roscher in all this goes back to Frederick List,* who, in his theor>- of the development of national productive powers, was the first in Germany, as far as I am aware, to use the expression " union of labour." Moreover, he turned it to peculiar account. Starting from a criticism of the " natural law " of division of labour, neither Adam Smith nor any of his successors have, in List's opinion, thoroughly investigated the essential nature and character of this law or followed it out to its most important conse- quences. The very expression " division of labour " was inadequate, he says, and necessarily produced a false con- ception. He then continues: " It is division of labour if one savage on one and the same day goes hunting or fish- ing, cuts down wood, repairs his wigwam, and makes ready arrows, nets, and clothes; but it is also division of labour if, as in the example cited by Adam Smith, ten different persons share in the different occupations connected with the manufacture of a p:.i. The former is an objective, and the latter a subjective division of labour; the former hin- ders, the latter furthers production. The essential differ- ence between the two is that in the former one person (liviles his work so as to produce various objects, while in the latter several persons share in the production of a single object." " Both operations, on the other hand," we read further, ' The National System of Political Economy (London, 1885), pp. 149 ff- UNION OF LABOUR /1ND LABOUR IN COMMON. 247 " may with equal correctness be called a union of labour; the savage unites various tasks in his person, while in the case of the pin-manufacture various persons are united in one work of production in common. The essential charac- ter of the natural law from which the popular school ex- plains such important phenomena in social economy, is evidently not merely a division of labour but a division of different commercial operations among several indi- viduals, and at the same time a federation or union of various energies, intelligences and powers in a common production. The cause of the productiveness of these opera- tions is not merely the division, but essentially this union." This latter List develops further, and upon it endeavours to base the demand for the establishment of a harmony of the productive pozvers in the nation. The highest division of occupations and the highest unification of the productive powers in material production are found in agriculture and manufacturing. '' A nation devoting itself exclusively to agriculture is like an individual engaged in material production with one arm gone," etc. Free these explanations from the ingenious rhetoric of the great agitator, and we find, as so often, that he has been unjust towards Adam Smith. The latter in no way overlooks the fact, as List is frank enough to admit, that division of lal)our postulates a cooperation of forces; and at the close of his celebrated chapter on division of labour he explains expressly that by means of this joint labour the meanest person in a civilized country may attain a more ample accommodation than an African king." But he was keen-sighted enough not to regard this fact, which was involved in the nature of division of labour and iden- tical with it, as an independent economic phenomenon. -^.J • Book I, Chapter I, towards end. a48 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. i H m '1' ., - What purpose would it serve to call the same thing at one time division of labour and at another union of labour, ac- cording as it was viewed from one side or the other? In a young science that would have been only a source of con- fusion. Of course the procedure of the Indian who successively hunts, fishes, fells trees, etc., would never have been recog- nised by Adam Smith as a particular instance of division of labour. On the contrar>', he would have designated it undivided labour,^ a condition such as preceded division of labour throughout society. Division of labour is for him something else than division of time. Of the factor of time in the disposal of labour List speaks more at length in another place.* He there explains that the individual branches of industry in a country only gradually gain possession of improved processes, machin- ery, buildings, advantages in production, experiences and skill, and all those details of information and connections that insure to them the profitable purchase of their raw material and the profitable sale of their products. It is easier, he believes, to perfect and extend a business already established than to found a new one; easier to produce superior goods at moderate prices in a branch of industry long domiciled in a country than in a newly-established one. " A- in all human institutions, so in industry there lies at the root of important achievements a law of nature that has much in common with the natural law of the division of laboi"- and of the federation of productive forces. Its es- sential feature consists in several successive generations as it were uniting their forces towards one and the same end, and as it were dividing among them the expenditure of energy necessary to its attainment." List calls this the 'On his conception of division of labour, compare following chapter. UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 249 principle of stability and continuity of work, and seeks to prove its operation in history by a series of examples: the superiority in strength of a hereditary over an elective monarchy, the transmission of the acquisitions of human knowledge *hrough printing, the influence of the caste system upon the maintenance and development of indus- trial skill, the building of cathedrals in the Middle Ages during several generations. The system of public debts by which " the present generation makes a draft on a future gent- ation " is also cited as a peculiariy apt instance of the application of the principle of continuity in work. It is easily seen that List here is dealing only with a rhetorically clad analogy to union of labour. This, how- ever, has not prevented later writers from forming out of " continuity of work " a special type of union of labour, although a little reflection might have taught them that it is a phenomenon not at all peculiar to economic activity. Continuity of work is the universal historical principle of social development by which man is distin<^uished from the animal. With each lower animal begins anew a similar existence which runs its course, so far as we know, to-day as thousands of years ago. leaving not a record, not a trace. But each human generation takes over the fruits of the civilization of all preceding generations, and iiands them down with an increase to the succeeding age. This is true not merely of material production but also of art, science, religion, law, and custom. Continuity of work thus forms one of the essential conditions and first postulates of hu- man existence, and there is no reason fo; giving it special treatment in the theory of the econnmic employment of labour, particulariy since it offers for the latter no new instructive points of view. Sundry text-books recognise stili a third t\ pe of union of labour, which is said to arise "when several do •-■ jj -■' ^i r ^ I*' »50 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. similar work concurrently, and by virtue of union ob- tain a greater result than would be possible to them work- ing inaividually." Heinrich Rau, who incidenta'ly men- tions this case,* instances temporary companies of forest wood-cutters, of raftsmen, and of reapers. In reality he here singles out a procedure that is not division of labour, although an increased productivity in the labour of the individual results from the simultaneous cooperation of several. This case then, like the one of the varied activity of the Indian mentioned by List, caimot be summarily dismissed as already embraced under the conception of division of labour and as ill-adapted to special scientific treatment. Without doubt the real reason for the formation of the concept union of labour and for its long retention in the literature of the science is the vague feeling that there must be an economic principle forming the counterpart rf division of labour. Cooperation it cannot be, for that is identical with certain 'irms of division of labour,^ <^ its " other side." What then is this principle? All division of labour is an accommodation of work to limited human capacity. It takes place when a qualitative *Grundsatce der I'olksxvxrthschaftslehrc, I. § ii6 (a). Rau appeals to Gioja, who had studied the matter somewhat in his Nuovo prospeUo ddle scienze economiche, I, 87 ff. Moreover Hermann, Staatstv. Untcr- suchungcit, new edition, p. 217, had also given it some attention. He designates it as " the simplest combination of labour." Similarly by the French who distinguish co-operation simple and co-operation cottpkxe, and make the latter identical with division of labour. Comp. Cauwes, Cours d'Econ. pal, I, S 225. " For example, subdivision ef labour and division of production, but not division of trade. If various specialists take the place of a general practitioner no cooperation takes place amongst them either in com- mercial dealings or in any other way similar to that amongst the different workers in a factory. UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 2^1 \^■iti jil; vvould in part lie fal- ndciiii'; of strength would . >r,l(i not, perhaps, form the ;uioi! The labourer, even lil 'e driven to help himself , tiic first a second activity to • r'-. y suitably call this union disproportion exists between the work to be done and the individual's capability." But there may aiso be a quantitative disproportion be- tween the two factors in two ways: (i) the quantity of work to be done may be less than the available labour- power, and it may jb-. (2) be more than equal to the strength of a sinji, i-idividual. In the arst cp tl v ;)'' sic: 1 to e would not be com- pletely utilized \i 1 iu '.-oo-'.er .1,1. d himself to this one line of work. H- c <,>: low, and ai^ ni. ju<. / n- >ir.r. result. Th'^' •, rl< <' - nu basis for a I'l— lUj, in his own pri> ate ii by combining or t re- fill out his leisure lin or combination of labour }- In the second case the individual by himself cannot pos- sibly perform the task, or can do so only with a dispropor- tionate expenditure of time and energy. A single work- man, for instance, might, if necessity demanded, succeed in cutting the trunk of a large tree into boards with a hand- saw-; but with what t. uble and needless expenditure of time! If two rien and a whip-saw are called into service, however, the work goes forward not only absolutely but relatively better. Th^ picture of the s w-pit then arises, which at times can still be seen in rural i nber-yards. The union of the workers organizes the lauour of each indi- vidual more productively. If we are to avoid the most lamentable confusions we must no longer designate this procedure union of labour," but at most union of labour- "Comp. following chapter. " Arbeiisvereinigun^. "To distinguish from the first case we would then have to saj W ' 15 ll 11 If 25a UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. ers. More accurate does it seem, especially in view of the varieties of this process to be mentioned later, to employ the expression labour in common}* In this phrase the personal element, which here comes into prominence, is more clearly expressed. Union of labour is then tlie union of different classes of work in one person; labour in common is the concurrent em- ployment of several zcorkers in the accomplishment of one task. In union of labour the same producer turns out various products or combines production with trading or with personal service; in labour in common various labourers produce in common the like product. In the one case the uniting point is in the subject of the work, the labourer, in the other the community lies in the object of the labour. The two processes are independent of each other and of division ot labour. They, of course, play their chief role during primitive stages of development and in the lower strata of economically organized society. Two great stages in the economic life of nations might indeed be (liitinguished: a lower one. in which the principle of union of labour and labour in common comes preeminently into play; and a higher one. with the principle of division of labotir predominant. In the same way two sphe-es ot social existence may be distinguished in contemporary economic life: one with pronounced division of labour, the other with union of labour and labour in common. In a separate consideration of each of these two phe- nomena \vc had better begin with union of hihoiir. It appears early in the history of peoples. It is universally met with directly the stage of individual search for food is passed. "subjective" (personal) uninn of labour; while the first case would be desiKnatcfl as ■ (.l.iective " (material) uiiioti of labour. '♦ Arbciltgctncinichaft. UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 253 and when economic motives, be they even of the crudest kind, become discernible in men's transactions. For at that point we everywhere notice the sharp separation of two distinct spheres of production, each of which again contains many subdepartments. One embraces men's work, the other women's work." Essentially the same arrangement, with unimportant variations in detail, is found among all more advanced primitive peoples, and we cannot deny that there is a certain instinctive system about it. Of a division of labour between man and wife one can- not seriously speak, for from all we know none of the occu- pations assigned to either of the two sexes has ever been carried on by the other. It must be assumed that this condition of things de- veloped quite naturally. In at., case the statement is false that the stronger man " imposed " ui)on the woman the tasks falling to him. Much rather is it correct to say that each sex 1 s of its own impulse — it might perhaps be said under the stress of environment — created 1 the course of time its own department of production, developed the technical details connected with it, collected the experi- ences, and transmitted them to the following generation of the same sex. Thus these two combinations of tasks, through contiinicd hereditary transmission within the same sex, Iiave almost been evoived into sexual character- istics or functions. The hereditary ta. k of the woman, in which the man was not instructed, formed a species of natural equipment that made her valued by the man and gave her a i)rice. Though it is true that from this grew the conception of the wife as propyl ty of the husband, it is none the less true that the important part played by the wife in production has been not the least important A (k'tailcd (liscii^iion of tlu-so, pp. .V» ff., 55. 254 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. factor in the gradual elevation of the rude primaeval union of the sexes to a community of life in which the woman has finally raised herself to equality of rights with the hus- band. The economic importance of the union of various tasks in the hands of each sex is essentially of an educational and disciplinary nature. It compelled as it were of itself, at least on the part of the wife, attention to the elements of time at seed-time and at harvest, and finally to a di- vision of time, very crude though it was, for the single day. It is a matter of particular moment in this connection that the preparaiion of grain by means of the primitive rubbing- stone, which is the method employed by most primitive peoples down to :lie present day, makes exceedingly heavy demands upon the operator's time, so that the mere main- tenance of three or four persons required the labuur of one woman.'" 1 1 - ih one of the most important supports of polygamy among these peoi)lcs, and renders it tolerable for the wife. I''or a new spouse brought home Ijy the hus- band always appears to the other wives as a helper to lighten their lot. It is thus comprehen.sible that the posses- .'ion of numerous wives nnist serve as an indication of wealth. We may even assert that the careful employment of time, with which systematic economic action first be- gins, finds its starting-point in the union of labour on the part of the women. Moreover, when in the course of subsctiuent develop- ment considerable shiftings took place in the boundaries (if the spiieres of work of both sexes, forcing the wife ever more towards the side of supervising consumption within the household and placing almost all the production in the hands of the husband, the principle of division of "Comp Dr \V. Junkir's Travels in Africa, II, pp. 170, 171, and my Arbeit u. Hhylhmm. pp. jS, (». 6l. UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 255 labour made itself felt almost solely in man's sphere of work, while to the wife's household management remained the most varied duties of preparing, disposing, cleaning, and repairing. The course of these latter really deter- mines the division of time in our daily life. To be sure, union of labour has not on that account dis- appeared completely from the economic world. Agricul- ture still embraces occupations varying greatly from one another; everywhere in civilized lands its development has been intimately connected with cattle-raising, while sub- sidiary industries are often included within its sphere. It is indeed one of the most important tasks of the farm- director so to arrange matters that the working powers of man and beast can he turned to full account in as many ways and in as regular a manner as possible. In the change of activity following the seasons of the year there is, even in large agricultural undertakings, but little room for sub- division of work and specialization; different kinds of oc- cupations must always be united in one person, and among the women workers a clear division into farm hands and household servants is not feasible. Similar considerations hold for forestry, in which keen practical men condemn the system still common in many places of having specialized labour for each season.'^ and demand the employment throughout the whole year of a permanent staff of all-round workmen. Such a require- ment can be met only on the basis of union of labour. In industry handicraft has frotn time itnmemorial been founded on union of labour. It was not the highest pro- ductivity that determined the mutual delimitation of the departments of pro<luction. but regard for the daily bread which each master was to find in his craft. The number- " Comp. Fr. Jentsch, Die Arbeiten'erhiilt. in d. Forstwirth. d. Staats (Berlin. i88j). 256 UNION OF L/IBOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. less disputes between different guilds as to the limits of their trade which fill the pages of industrial history during the last few centuries continually raised discussions on the practicableness of this or that combination. In the age of industrial freedom handicraft has also advanced in the large cities in the direction of specialization; in the smaller towns the old combinations have been retained, and m countrv parts new ones are still arising each year. The ma- son is here often plasterer, painter, and paper-hanger as well, while in winter he serves for wage as butcher; the smith is at the same time locksmith and chief engineer of the threshmg-machinc; paper-hanging is cared for now by the saddler, now by the painter, now by the bookbinder. In the towns the greatest variety of combinations are made by the new occupations. Gas-fitting and plumbhig are undertaken now by the locksmith, now by the tinsmith, and electric services are installed in houses by craftsmen of most diverse types. Everywhere the craftsman appears willing to ad<l to his workshop a small counter trade, especially with wares of his own <lepartment of labour no longer produced by hand-work, but often with various other articles as well. Justus Moser long since remarked the sound economic idea realized in this union: and would willinglv have seen all petty retailing transferred to hand- workers and their wives.' ^ If we a.ld t« this the various alliances that handicraft makes with services of a personal character, especially minor civil offices, and in the country as a regular thing with agriculture, we are rea<li1y con- vinced that the union of labour still commands a very ex- tended field.'" Men of " modern mind " may deplore the " Patrwitsche I'hintastcn. Vo!, II. No. XXXVIl. '"( ,.j.t(.ii> m.-itirial on the c.niilMiKHions of tra.les and si-oundary ocnuMiions of haiuKsorkcr^ .» ofTcritl in I nlcrsurhungni ubcr d. La^e d. Ua,idiitrhs i« IhuUckUnd. edited by r.iy;elf. in Schrif'.en 0. Verc.ns fe«S'< WF!PPiWPP iP UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 2$^ great number of such " backward trades " ; pessimists may see in them a sign of the " distress in handicraft " ; fanatics on production may regret that under such ramditions the highest possible measure of productivity is not reaHzed in every branch of industry. But an unprejudiced judgment, based upon an investigation of the facts, will rind that in the union of labour the middle class of small independent workmen has its firmest footing; it will find too that in the majority of cases the due observance of sound business principles has not been wanting. For as a rule it is really a question of making use of time that is not taken up by the chief occupation, and of giving employment to capabil- ities that would otherwise lie dormant. Union of labour is relatively still more common in house industrx where the women employed at the same time at- tend to their doincstic duties, and where the men often follow agriculture or some other business as primary occu- pation. Indeed the origin of many commission industries rests finally upon the consideration that persons not fully occupied could profitably combine them with their other business. Trading primarily is always union of labour, since in the earlier stages of its development it regularly includes transportation. Caravan trade is an example. In modern commercial life division of labour li.is strongly asserted it- self in wholesale trade, and also in tlie retail trade of large cities. But along with these are numerous businesses, such as hardware and house-furnishing shops, which bring together the most varied articles. In the wholesale ware- houses and export businesses, in the sixpenny bazaars and cash stores this devclojiment has reached its highest point. These ^iant undertakings of course lie beyond the range f. Socialp.ilitik. Vols LXIULXX, especially in the descriptions of in- dustries in small towns and country districts. i- i^ii 258 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. of our Study, since with them the work is generally ar- ranged in strict accordance with the principle of division of labour. On the other hand, the numerous small retail businesses carried on in suburban places, in small towns, and in the country usually as the sole occupation of one person lie within its survey, because here the owner deals in every possible article that will bring in money. Indeed one would have to write a detailed account of the sale shops to explain all that is to be found gathered to- gether there. Certain wares are specially prized for filling out the stock, such as canes, cigar-holders, combs, brushes, and straw hats; and it is often difficult to learn how they have come into the company they keep. Many tradesmen of such a class at the same time carry on commission busi- nesses, insurance and news agencies, sell lottery and theatre tickets, receive advertisements and savings-bank deposits, and the like. In the great world of commerce there are various spe- cialized occupations that can hardly be carried on with profit by themselves, and therefore are always followed in conjunction with another pursuit. What village could support a special precentor, village clerk, or sexton; what rural loan association maintain a treasurer; what insurance company pay its army of sub-agents sufficient for their support? Without the possibility of union of labour these and many other economic functions would simply have to remain unperformed. The consideration determining the combination in each case could only be gleaned from a minute statistical and descriptive investigation. In most cases the influence that decides the person devoting himself to different kinds of work is the full employment of his time and the gaining of a full livelihood. For the method of combina- tion, however, many other considerations come into play. UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 259 Now it is to take advantage of a clientele already existing, now to utilize a particular talent or skill possessed by the workman for a further object. The economic principle will in these cases in one way or another always come into play. The actual extent of union of labour in national economy is not easy to determine. Statistics have sought to answer the need by creating the rather unsatisfactory category of the auxiliary occupations; but it is easy to see that this designation does not exhaust the total number of cases that come here into question; it gives at most only those in which the auxiliary occupation ranks in some degree as an independent vocation. A union of occupations might be spoken of in this case.-" Yet some conception of the im- mense economic importance of the union of labour may be gained when we learn from the results of the last German industrial census that on June 14, 1895, there were almost five million persons in the German Empire who had some secondary occupation, and that agriculture alone was an auxiliary pursuit for 3,648,237. Of 3.999,023 proprietors and managers in some branch of agriculture, industry, or trade, 36.9 per cent. (1,475.023) had an auxiliary occupa- tion, while 2,928,530 carried on these branches as auxiliary work. The following table gives a survey of the whole field of industrial activity covered by that census. In it those car- rying on independent and dependent work are grouped together. Ffdm this table we find that out of every 100 persons pursuing their chief occupation in one of the classes indi- On the occurrence of combined occupation"; in town life in the Middle Apes there are some details in my Bcfiilkerung von Frankfurt, I. pp. Jj2ff., 41; ff. a6o UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. DIVISIONS OF THE INDUSTRIAL POPULATION OF THE GERMAN EMPIRE ACCORDING TO CHIEF AND AUXILIMIY OCCUPATIONS ON 14TH OF JUNE, 1895. CUuof Occupation. No. of Per- lont finding tbeir Chief Occupation in Clan indicated. No. of Pettoni having a Secondary Occupa- tion. A. Agriculture, forestry, stock- raising, fishing. B. Mining and in dustries C. Trade and com meice D. Domestic ser- vice, hired labour of various kinds. E. Public service, liberal profes- sions 8,292,692 8,281,220 a.338.S»i 432.491 i,4as.96i no Sccondaty Occupation, No. of fersont making tbeir Occupation indicated in Col. t Secondary. 4 ToUl No. in the Variout Diviaiont. Total. Of these were : Males Females 20,770.875 15,506,482 5.264,393 1,049.542 1,491.865 384.105 31.333 115,266 3,072,111 2,816,655 255.456 7.243.150 6,789.355 1,954,406 401,158 1,310,695 17,698,764 12,689,827 5.008,937 3,648,237 619,386 569.877 16.765 95.436 4,949,701 11,940,929 8,908,606 a,908,388 449.256 1.521,397 25,720,576 3.203.375 1.746,326 18,709,857 7,010,719 cated, whether as proprietor or workman in any capacity, a second or third (auxiliary) occupation was added— In agriculture, forestry, stock-raising, fishing, by 12.6 persons In mining and industry by |°® In trade and co.nmcrce by ,'■".' 'C Z. In domestic service and hired labour of various kinds by. 72 ^ In public service and liberal professions by 8.1 Of the total number of persons following an occupation (either chief or auxiliary) in one of the said classes, a secondary pursuit from the same class was chosen— In agriculture, forestry, stock-raising, fishing, by 30.6% In mining atrl industry by ig't'fc In trade and )mmerre by ,' ■" a"u •. -% In domestic > -vke and hired labour of -.anous kinds by 3-/^ In public service and liberal professions by °-'7° MlilHH lanfti.V..4H "TTV'-iEiaB'EW. UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. a6i Even from the returns of occupations, which unfortu- nately are not sufificiently detailed for this purpose, it is clear that many occupations are carried on chiefly in con- junction with other pursuits. For exam^ile, in the table next presented the total number of persons following the vocation are contrasted, by percentages, with those fol- lowing it either as principal or subsidiary, along with an- other occupation.^^ Stock-raising 83.4% Inland fishing 69.370 Turf cutting and preparing 93-9% Stone cutting and carving 57-2% Marble, stone, and slate quarrying and the manufacture of rough wares from these materials 78.6% Manufacture of fine stone wares 50-2% Brick and clay-pipe making 86.9% Butchering S8.i% Insurance 68.7% Personal transport and post 53-2% Freight delivery 75-7% Pottery 57-5% Manufacture of earthenware and glass toys 56.0% Nail-manufacture 67 o7o Blacksmithing 7f>.^% Wagon-making 74-8% Flaying 85.9^0 Charcoal-burning 81.2% Flour-milling 9'-6% Baking 61.6% Turning 52.7% Advertisement and labour-agency work 54-4% Inn-keeping and refreshments 64.4% These figures naturally are far from giving a true picture of the results of combined and divided labour in the oc- cupation classes indicated. It is at once apparent that in a statistical return on extractive production a country shoe- maker who devotes a quarter of his time to land-cultivation " Columns 6 and 8 of Reichistatiitxk, Tab. I. 262 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. has necessarily the other three-quarters of his time left out of account. This, however, is not the point; it is rather the question of the number of human beings to whom a combination of occupations assures more abun- dant sustenance and also in most cases a more satisfying existence, both as regards health and morals, than a one- sided employment in full agreement with the principle of division of labour. In the German Empire this num- ber is large beyond expectation, amounting almost to one- third of all persons engaged in earning their living. The principle of union of labour, despite the wealth of forms in which it appears, is quite simple: how shall surplus strength be productively employed? The principle of labour in common cannot be reduced to such a smooth for- mula. In general, its aim is so to supplement the insuffi- cient strength of the individual that the task presented can be accomplished. But the individual workman's insuffi- ciency of strength may again have different causes. It may be based on a definite mental disposition that pre- vents the workman labouring continuously by himself; it may rest on lack of bodily strength; or, finally, it may re- sult from technical conditions rendering it impossible for one piece of work to be performed unless accompanied by a second of a different character. Each of these three cases produces a distinct kind of labour in common. The first may he called companionship or fraternal labour, the second, labour aggregation, and the third, joint labour. We will consider them in order. I. Companionship or fraternal labour^- occurs when sev- eral workers come together and labour without the indi- vidual 1 ecoming in the progress of his task in any way " Gesi u-hiflsiirli,:! nr j,'.mt/(1I,'(' .-Irbeil. UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 263 dependent upon the others. Each thus labours for himself independently and adopts any tempo he pleases. The sole aim in union is to have the company of fellow-workmen, to be able to talk, joke and sing with them, and to avoid soli- tary work alone with one's thoughts. The student whose work thrives best in undisturbed soli- tude will on hearing this probably shrug his sympathetic shoulders in pitying contempt, and find the subject hardly worth serious consideration. But anyone who has ever observed a group of village women braking flax, or doing their washing at the brookside, or watched a troop of Saxon field-workers hoeing turnips, or a line of reapers at work, or listened to the singing of a group of house-paint- ers, or of women at work in an Italian vineyard, will be of a different opinion. The lower the stage of a man's cul- ture the more difficult is it for him to stick to continuous and regular labour, if he is to be left by himself. But the best proof of the importance of fraternal labour lies in its having found some sort of organization in all parts of the earth. We may call to mind the public work- ing-places and common-houses of the savages,^^ the com- mon workrooms of the house-workers in Russia, the spin- ning-rooms of our peasant girls which the bureaucracy of the eighteenth century so fatuously opposed, but which live on in many villages to the present day in the evening gatherings for work in common. Custom everywhere "K. V. d. Steinen, Unter d. Naturvdlk. Brasil. p. 374. Erman in Ztschr. f. Ethnol., II, p. ,v8 (on the Coljusches in Sitka). Jacobsen. Reise in d. InsclwcU d. Banda-Meeres. p. 213. Finsch. Samoafahrten. p. 357. Burton, as above, pp. 54. 2<i7, 461. Nachtigal. Sahara u. Sudan. II. p. 624; III. pp. 146, 244. Count Schweinitz, Durch Ostafrika im Krieg u. Frieden, p. 171. Stanley. Through the Dark Continent, II. p. 82, and How I found Livingstone, pp. 546 flf. Semon, In the Australian Bush, p. 324. Comp. also Arbal u. Rhythmus, pp. 38, 39. 71 ; and above, P 37. HI I MCKOCOrV ttSOWTION TEST CHART (ANSI and ISO TEST CHART No. 2) 1^ tii 1^ |3j2 ■ 2.2 tii Im ■■■ IK ■fi 1 Um 1.6 /1PPLIED IIVMGE Inc 1653 toti Mom Strwt Roch«t«r, N*« York U609 USA ('16) *S2 - 0300 - PhoM ('16) 2U - S»a9 - r<i« a64 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. I II ;i joins to these gatherings dancing, feasting or other practice tending to make the work more agreeable. A few instances will serve to show the wide extent of such institutions. In the Fiji Islands " several women always unite in the preparation of tapa; frequently all the women of the place sit together," and in net-fishing " women always work to- gether in small groups; the work is at the same time a recreation, and there is often a merry time in the cooling bath." '* Among many negro tribes in Africa women can be seen at public work-places pounding or grinding corn in common. A more circumstantial report is given by a missionary as to the North American Indians: *" " The till- ing of the ground, getting of the fire-wood, and pounding of com in mortars is frequently done by female parties, much in the manner of . . . husking, quilting, and other frolics. . . . The labour is thus quickly and easily per- formed; when it is over, and sometimes in intervals, they sit down together to enjoy themselves by feasting on some good victuals prepared for them by the person or family for whom they work, and which the man has taken care to provide beforehand from the woods; for this is consid- ered a principal part of the business, as there are generally more or I'^^s of the females assembled who have not, per- haps, for a long time tasted a morsel of meat, being either widows or orphans, or otherwise in straitened circum- stances. Even the chat which passes during their joint IaI>our is highly diverting to them, and .so they seek to be employed in this way as long as they can l)y going round to all the villagers who have ground to till." The same linking of work and pleasure is found in the "A. Biisslcr, Sudste-Ptldcr. pp 224-6 ** HeckfWflder, as above, p. 156. Similar report from South Amer- ica in Elu<nreich, Beitriigr ~ I'Hlkcrkund. IWasiL. p. .'S. UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 265 lie social houses that are met with almost universally among primitive peoples. Divided regularly according to the sexes, they are most frequently built for unmarried men and girls. They serve not merely as places of resort for common tasks, but often as sleeping places as well, and always as places for dancing and play. There singing and joking and chatting go on ; the fruitless efforts of the awk- ward are ridiculed and the successful work of the diligent and skilful applauded. A distant parallel to this institution has been retained among ourselves almost down to the present in the spin- ning-rooms of peasant girls.'** These rooms had in every part of Germany their well-defined though unwritten rules ** But with similar conditions these are met with everywhere. Henry Savage Landor (In the ForbiddeH Land, an Account of a Journey in Tibet, I, pp. 109 flF.) found them even in the southern Himalayas among the Shokas, where girls and young men come together at night in particular meeting-places (Rambangs), for the sake of better acquaint- ance, prior to entering into matrimony. " Each village possesses one or more institutions of this kind, and they are indiscriminately patron- ized by all well-to-do people, who recognise the institution as a sound basis nn which marriage can be arranged. The Rambang houses are either in the village itself, or half-way between one village and the next, the young women of one village thus entering into amicable relations with the young men of the other and vice versa. I visited many of these in company with Shokas, and found them very inter- esting. Round a big fire in the centre of the room men and women sat in couples, spinning wool and chattinp merrily, for everything ap- peared decorous and cheerful. With the small hours of the morning, they seemed to become more sentimental, and began singing songs without instrumental accompaniment, the rise and fall of the voices sounding weird and haunting to a degree. . . Smoking was general, each couple sharing the same pipe. . . . Signs of sleepiness became evident as morning came, and soon tliey all retired in couples, and went to sleep in their clothes on a soft layer of straw and grass. . . . At these gatherings every Shoka girl regularly meets with young men: and while she entertains the idea of selecting among them a suitable partner for life, she also does a considerable quantity of work with her spinning-wheel." 1 if 266 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. and laws. " In Brunswick the spinning-rooms began with the approach of winter, when the field-work was ended. In many villages this occurred at Martinmas. They lasted then till Lent, or at latest till Palm Sunday, when other work had to be done. The evening gatherings were held in rotation at the houses of the different members of the particular weaving-circle. The membership of such a circle was made up of four, or at most of eight girls, who were fi lends or relatives of each other. The majority consisted of servants, though the daughters of peasants also joined in. The old folks spun by themselves. In the early part of the evening the girls were alone; for not till later on, about eight o'clock, did the male visitors, who by that time had finished their work, put in an appearance and take part in the company, at first with reserve, and then more and more boldly. The institution has as its basis a laudable diHgence on the part of the girls." " Generally there was a fixed amount of work for the week reckoned in yarn; anyone not doing it received a nickname. At times a spinning contest was arranged, while a feeling of lively emulation always prevailed.^* Indeed a species of labour police was maintained over the individual members. In the district of Nassau a moustache was painted with a piece of charcoal on the spinne. who fell asleep; if she let the thread break and slip from her a lad might take her distaff, which she had to redeem with a kiss.^^ "R. Andrec, Braunsch-veig. I'olkskunde. pp. 168 ff, Comp. K. Frei- herr v. LeoprcchtiriK, Aus d. Lcchraiii. pp. 201-2; Ztschr. d. Ver. f. Volkskundf. III. pp. 2qi. 202. VIII, p. 366; and in detail Biickel. I'olks- Ixedcr aus Oherhcsscn. pp. cxxiii flf. " IntiTcstinK nnti s on competitive Ramcs in spinninj? in Ztschr d. Ver. f. Volksk., VIII. pp. .'15, 216. Comp. Arbeit u. /?A.v//imi<,t. pp. 91 flf. " .\monR the Wends in Lusatia on the l.Tt .'pinning nitjht before Christmas the slow and lazy ones are brouelit to trial: Haupt and Srhm.Tler, I'olkslicdrr d. Wnidcii in d. Oher- u. Xicdcr-I.nusit:. II. p. 220. Similar instances of l.ibour supervision by coniraiKs are found in UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 267 The spinning-room has fallen a sacrifice to the technical revolutions of modem times; but all through the country during long winter evenings the young girls still congre- gate with their work in the house of a friend. This is also the case with several house industries carried on in the coun- try, for instance, with lace-making in the Erz mountains, where this kind of gathering of working girls is still re- ferred to as " go spinning." ^° This practice is full^ devel- oped in the system of house industry in Russia.'^ Here male and female Kustaris frequently work together outside their homes. Large companies, often composed wholly of house-workers of the one village engaged in a similar trade, gather together in a particuL. workroom, which is either a large room rented in a peasant's house or a shop erected for the purpose. Such a common workroom is still most frequently termed " spinning-room" {Szvetjolka), and often " factory." It is to be found, for instance, in do- mestic cotton-weaving, cloth-making, silk-spooling, and the making of shoes and toys. In women's work only young girls, as a rule, attend, while the married women work at home. " According to the statements of the oldest people, cot- ton-weaving was at first carried on exclusively in the swet- jolka, because the technical handling of the loom could be learned more quickly and easily under the constant super- vision of one skilled in weaving. The living-room of the house served at first as swetjolka, but later on a swetjolka separate from the house was built. To-day the young peo- ple and the diligent weavers still prefer to work in the other classes of peasant working groups. Conip. Hormann, D. TiroUr Baucrnjahr (Innsbruck, iSqq). pp. 50. 5-2, 66, 70, 71, 75, I2g. "Arbeit u. Rhylhmus. pp. 99, 100. " Details in Stellmachcr, Ilin Beitrag a. Darstelluite d. Hausindustrit in Russhtid. pp. 106 ff. M. GorbunoflF. C'bcr russischr Spitscnindustrit (Vienna, 1886). pp. J,^ ff. ^1 268 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. swetjolka rather than at home; the former because it is more sociable, the others because they can work more regularly and to greater advantage. At home the weaver is often called away to domestic affairs; the Uving- room there is not so spacious and bright, the air not so pure, since calves and lambs are not infrequently co- dwellers with the folks; in the swetjolka, also, the cotton, which at home is very liable to become moist and mouldy, can be better preserved." Thus fraternal labour accords very well with the eco- nomic principle, even though it originates primarily in the social instinct. In the company of others people work with greater persistence than they would alone, and in general because of the rivalry, also better. Work becomes pleas- ure, and the final result is an advance in production. 2. By labour aggregation^^ we mean the engaging of several workmen of similar capacity in the performance of a united task, such as loading a heavy burden, shifting a beam, mowing a meadow, beating for the hunt. In order to make the employment of a plurality of workers profit- able, the work to be done need not be of itself too heavy for the strength of one person; it is only necessary that it cannot be done by such an one in a reasonable time. La- bour aggregation is of special importance for seasonal work or for work that is dependent upon the weather. Social conditions can also play a part in expediting certain tasks. These circumstances have early led to a species of social organization of aggregated labour, founded on the duty recognised the world over of mutual assistance among neighbours. We may use the expression current among the south Slavs and call it bidden labour.^' Whenever any- ** Arbeitskiiufutig. •* Bttlarbeit. UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 269 one has work to be done for which his own household is not adequate, the assistance of the neighbours is sought. They give it at the time without further reward than their entertainment, which the head of the house offers in the accustomed way, solely in the expectation that when need arises they, too, will be aided by their neighbours. The work is carried out in sprightly competition amid jokes and song, and at night there is often added a dance or like merry-making.^^ This is a world-wide practice. Traces of it can even be found among the South Sea Islanders. In New Pomer- ania, for example, it is the custom for several families to cooperate in plaiting the fishing-baskets and large fishing- nets. " Before the basket receives its first dip in the water a meal in common is g^ven, in which all who were engaged in the making participate." '* In Djailolo (Halamahera) when a piece of land belong- ing to a local community is to be cleared, ten to twenty relatives are called together to assist in felling the trees, their services being compensated later in other work. So it is at the planting of paddy, and at the rice harvest.^' " Whenever anyone wants to build a house he solicits some of his relative? to help cut the building material while the tide is out, he providing them the while with food. For the roofing, which is done with sago leaves, more helpers are invited. These then hold a feast, at which the chiefs are generally present." ^^ " Numerous instances of this custom in Chapter V of my Arbeit u. Rhythmus. •* Parkinson, Im Bismarck-Archipel, p. 115. "Riedel, in Ztschr. f. Ethnol., XVII (1885), pp. 7ofI. Similarly in New Guinea, Finsch, Samoafahrten, pp. 56 ff. Among the Bagobos in South Mindanao: SchadenberR in Ztschr. f. Ethnol., XVII, pp. 19 ff. •* Riedel, as above, p. 61. Kubary, Ethnogr. Beilrdge z. Kenntnis d. Karolinen-Archipels, p. 264. C. Hose, The Natives of Borneo, in Journ, of Anthrop. Inst., XXIII (1894). pp. 161, 162. 270 UNION OF LMBOUR y4ND LABOUR IN COMMON. Among the Madis or Morus in Central Africa each culti- vates his own land; if it is of considerable extent, and re- quires more hands than his family can furnish, he calls his friends and neighbours to his assistance. On such occa- sions payment is neither given nor expected, but all are ready to render such help and to receive it." This cus- tom appears to be prevalent throughout Africa; the pos- sessor of the land has, as a rule, to supply generous enter- tainment to the whole company.^s Among the Gallas the inhabitants of a village assemble on the threshing-place to thresh the panicles of the durra and to root up the corn amid the singing of melodious songs adapted to the strokes in threshing.3» Bidden labour is also common in building a house.*" Among the Hovas of Madagascar when the grave of an important man is to be built, not the relatives and members of his tribe alone assist in trans- porting the heavy rocks, but all the inhabitants of the vil- lage in which he lived. There is no money-payment for such services; in its stead, however, great masses of pro- visions must be supplied during the transport of the heavy stones, which usually lasts many days, often for long inter- mediate periods; and above all many oxen must be killed. As the people are accustomed to help one another, no in- considerable part of their time is spent in such services. On the highways of the country one often meets great processions of two to three hundred men, women and slaves, who pull by starts on the strong ropes by which "Robert Felkin in Proceedings of Roy. Society of Edin. 1883/4 p. 310. " Endemann in Zt=, hr. f. Ethnol., VI. 1874, p. 27. Pogge in Wiss- mann, ( -utcr deutsch. Plagge quer durch Afrika. p. 311. Nachtigal. Sahara u. Sudan. III. p. 240. Post, Afr. Jurisprudens, II, p. 172. •• Paulitschke, Ethnogr. Nordost-Afrikas. I, pp. 134, 217. "Schurtz, Afr. Gmrrbe, p. 21. UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 271 means the stone, placed on a rough boat, is drawn for- ward.*^ The Georgians (Central Transcaucasia) resort to bidden labour at the vintage, in sowing and harvesting maize and wheat, in hewing and drawing wood from the forest. In Servia it is customary at grass-mowing, maize-cutting, plum harvest, the vintage, and also with spinning, weaving and carpet-making; in many parts of Russia at the hay and grain harvests, in hoeing turnips, felling timber, transport- ing manure and in ploughing, as well as with the women in spinning and even in scrubbing the house. In Germany it remains quite general in the country in house-building and locally in minor agncultural tasks (flax-pulling, bean- cutting, sheep-washing). It is an expedient of independ- ent household economy, as is readily seen, and recedes more and more with the appearance and advance of the entrepreneur system. But in most cases where bidden labour was formerly usual the large landowner will still engage a number of labourers if he is not able to hurry along the work fast enough with his machines. Labour aggregation becomes particularly important for him in the early stages of a process of production whose final stages can be more cheaply completed when carried on concurrently. A meadow could perhaps be mowed by one labourer in three days. Yet where possible the owner will employ six or more mowers who dispose of the work in a forenoon, be- cause all the grass should lie dried uniformly and all the hay drawn in at once. Frequent drawings would increase the costs of production. Even where there are no such reasons the farmer whose fields are intermixed with those of others will always " Sibree, Madagaskar, pp. 255, 236. 872 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. prefer to undertake the fields in succession with all his help rather than divide it among the different fields. The work goes forward better and more briskly in company than in solitude, for no one will lag behind the others; moreover, of itself the rapid progress of the work 'Enlivens the work- ers, while a piece of work in which no progress can be recognised, and the end is not in sight, always disheartens. Thus the six mowers in the instance just given will, with average diligence, finish th^ meadow not in one-sixth of the time that the single mower with the same diligence would require, but in a shorter time. Moreover with large undertakings in which the proprietor does not work along with the others, it has further to be considered that with dispersion of the workers the costs of supervision per unit of acre increase.*^ Labour aggregation belongs almost exclusively to the class of work requiring little skill, and which can be exe- cuted with simple manual implements, or even without any tools whatever. It is thus found in its widest extension *• Even in the Grundsdtse d. rationetten Landwirthschaft (4th edition, Berlin, 1847), I, pp. 112 ff., of A. Thaer we find the following rules: " Large tasks are never to be undertaken many at a time, especially in places at a considerable distance. As far as possible they must be finished in succession, and in every case with all possible energy, partly on account of the superintendence, partly because a certain rivalry can be awakened among the workers if many of them are un- der supervision together. On the other hand, if the task is extensive and only a few of them are set to work, they become almost fright- ened at its extent and its slow progress and even lose courage, and believe that, because of its magnitude, t leir absence will not be no- ticed. In such extensive tasks one man or one team too many is always better than one too few. In smaller tasks, on the contrary, care must be taken not to employ more than are necessary. The men easily get in each other's way, depend upon one another, readily be- lieve that their work has been thought heavier than it really is." Similarly, H. Settegast, Die LandwirihsclMft u. ihr Bctrieb, I, p. 313; III, p. 138. i UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 2 75 in epochs of undeveloped technique,*' declining as the im- plements of labour are improved. Yet a considerable sphere still remains to it. The grandest instance of labour aggregation is at all times presented by the standing armies. When a large number of persons labour together two kinds of labour aggregation are possible. In the first the individual workmen remain independent of one another during the moments their strength is called into play, and work together only for the more speedy disposition of the task. We will designate this first species simple aggrega- tion of labour. Instances are presented in several masons working on a new structure, a number of pavers on a road, a group of diggers or snow-shovellers, a row of mowers or turnip-hoers. An intermediate form is offered by a band of African carriers marching one after the other in single file, by beaters at a hunt, by several ploughers in a field. In the second case the activities of the different work- men do not proceed independently of one another, but either simultaneously or with regular alternations, that is, they always proceed rhythmically We ^ '1 name this kind of labour agglomeration concateiation iboiir, because it, so to speak, links each one taking pan neighbour through the succession ol '' combining all by means of the tempo makes it, as it were, an automatical! All tasks falling under this head must. \ time, adopt a rhythmical course. The- sure, that are completed with a sm 1 the work to his movemeris, and mity ( system, kg virganism. ;e(l for some -e some, to be exertion of ,: "This was the case especially among the anc • details on this have been gathered together w pp. 109, 1 10. itian' Some Kh_ "US, I; 1 If- 'I; ii : '* l! a 874 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. Strength, such as several lifting a heavy weight by word of command or pulling down the trunk of a tree with a rope. The tasks of this class, which are performed rhythmic- ally, can be sub-divided according as the powers of the in- dividual workers are exerted simultaneously or alternately into labours with coticurrent tempo and labours with alternate tempo.** Labours Zi'ith concurrent tempo are performed, for in- stance, by the two lines of rowers in propelling a boat by oars, by sailors in heaving an anchor, in hoisting sail, in towing a boat against the stream, by carpenters, who, in laying a foundation with a pile-driver, drive great posts into the earth, by those drawing up barrels, and generally by all groups of workmen who have to move a weight by pulling together on a rope, by the two, four, six, or eight people carrying a hand-barrow or a sedan-chair, and by .soldiers on the march. Very frequently the keeping of tune during the work is assisted by simple counting, by a chorus among the workers, or by the sound of a musical instrument, especially of the drum. Examples of workmen labouring with alternate tempo are: three stone-setters hammering in time the pavement stones with their paving-beetles; three or four threshers on the barn floor, two smiths hammering, two woodmen in the saw-pit or chopping a tree, two maids blueing linen or beating carpets. In tasks to be performed with concurrent tempo the problem is to accomplish by combination a task far surpass- ing the strength of one person, with the smallest number of labourers possible, so that all taking part in the work i V ** More in detail in my paper already frequently mentioned, Arbeit u. Rhythmus. to which reference may once for all be made for the follow- ing paragraphs as well. UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 275 shall be led to apply the utmost amount of energy at the same moment. In tasks with alternate tempo we meet as a rule with labours that in themselves could be performed by a single individual. Generally they are fatiguing tasks in which the various motions, such as raising and lowering the arms in striking with the threshing-flail, require more or less time. The individual worker here is always tempted to allow himself a brief pause for rest after each stroke or thrust, and thus loses the rhythm of the movements. The strokes or blows then succeed one another with unequal force and at irregular intervals, whereby the work is much more tiring in its results. If now a second or third work- man be added, the motions of each individual will regulate themselves by the rhythnnc sound that the instruments give forth in striking the material worked upon. A quicker tempo is realized, which can be maintained with little diffi- culty. Each workman remains indeed independent; but he must adapt his movements to those of his comrades. The import of the matter is thus not that the magnitude of the task demands a doubling or tripling of forces, but that a single person working alone cannot maintain a definite rhythmical motion. To be sure, the sole consequence of calling in a second or third workman one would imagine to be the doubling or tripHng of the eflfect of one workman's expenditure, yet this kind of labour concatenation results in a heightened production, inasmuch as it regulates equably for each the expenditure of force and the pauses for rest. The single workman lets his hands fall when he grows tired, or at least lengthens the tempo of his movements. Quick lempo in work enlivens; the men working in common are stimu- lated to rivalry; none will fall behind the other in strength and endurance. !: 276 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. !, i ; i i This pressure upon the weaker workman to equal the stronger becomes prominent in some tasks with a some- what free rhythm in which the concatenation is realized by grouping the workmen in rows and making the progress of the work of the one row dependent upon the activity of the other. In a line of mowers in a meadow each man must perform his task uniformly with the rest if he is not to retard the man following him or run the risk of being struck with his scythe. In a line of labourers handing or tossing each other the bricks for building, each one in a se' 'cs must receive with equal speed if he does not want to bring the whole work to a standstill. This mutual accommodation of workmen to each other, which is peculiar to all kinds of labour concatenation, thus becomes a disciplinary element of the greatest importance, especially for unskilled work, such as preponderated at primitive stages of economic and technical development. 1 1 can, indeed, be instituted also as a means of discipline to accelerate the work in those cases of labour aggregation that in themselves do not require such a linking of move- ments. For these there are artificial means of marking the tempo (counting, singing, accompaniment of music), by means of which simple labour aggregation is changed into labour concatenation. This is the case with slave labour, which, for obvious reasons, must always be carried on by gangs, and with the public labours of primitive people. In Camerun " the chief Ngilla, a well-known Moham- medan slave-hunter, drew up his people in companies of one hundred, and had his hoeing done to the beat of music which followed. Behind these workmen marched the sow- ers to the same beats, throwing see<ls from a sack which was hung about them." *^ Tlie Basutos assemble every " Meinecke, />. deutsch. KoUmien in Wort u. Pild. p 35, with illustra- tion. UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 277 year to cultivate the fields necessary for the personal sus- tenance of their chief and his principal wife. " It is a re- markable picture, "writes the missionar>- Casalis,*" " to see on such an occasion hundreds of black men drawn up in straight lines moving their hoes up and down in unison. The air resounds with the songs by which the workers are enlivened, and by which they can keep the proper time. The chief makes a point to be present and sees to it that several fat oxen are killed and made ready for the labour- ers. All classes adopt the same plan to lighten and ex- pedite their work; but among the common people it rests on reciprocity." The last example shows very clearly the transition from bidden to manorial labour. We find the same thing in the Soudan, where the erection and repairing of the village walls in particular is carried out to the accompaniment of music; and again among the Malays and the Chinese, who, since early times, have directed the public manorial services by the beat of the drum. In Europe also this means has been essayed. In the Baltic provinces down to the end of the eighteenth century landowners had their harvesting done by the serfs to the rhythm of the bagpipes, and traces of similar usage are at hand from other countries. In our modem States we meet with this species of labour concatenation brought about by artificial means only in the measured cadence of military forces, where the aim is al- ways to train a number of men to complete unanimity in their exercise of strength, and where the breaking of the tempo by a single person detracts from the general effect, " Les Bassoutos, p. 171, with illustration. Another can be seen in Gerland. Atlas d. Ethnographie (Leipzig, 1876). Tab. XXII, No. 25. Similar reports by K. Endemann of the Sotho negroes in Ztschr. f. Ethnol., VI. pp. 26 and yo: Paulitsclike. as above, I, p. 216; from the Gallas by Harar; and on the Bagabos in Southern Mindanao by Schadcnberg in the «amc publication. XV'II, pp. 19, 20. 278 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. H,i il » 3. We come now to the last kind of labour in com- mon, which we have designated joint labour*'' Certain tasks in production require for their performance the simultaneous cooperation of various classes of labour. These latter supplement one another, and may be called complementary phases of labour. Since they cannot possibly be performed by one workman, several workmen of various kinds must be combined in one group to form an organized and indivisible whole. Such a group is some- times called gang, company, band. (In Bavaria and Aus- tria Pass; *^ in other parts, Rotte, Truppe, Bande.) Instances from agriculture are quite numerous. Thus in drawing in hay or corn, the load-builder, the pitcher, the after-raker, in binding, the binder and the gatherer, form natural groups; in mowing grain a second person is re- quired to glean, in digging potatoes another gathers them up. From the sphere of industry may be mentioned the smith and the bellows-man, the rope-maker and the man who turns the wheel, mason and hod-carrier, those placing and those pounding in the paving-stones; from other spheres: the cook and the turnspit; inn-keeper, waiter, and house-boy; on the street-car, driver and conductor; in the row-boat, oarsman and steersman, likewise hunters and beaters, musician and dancer, blower and organist, drum- mers and pipers, judge, bailiffs and clerk, doctor and at- tendants, a theatrical troupe, an orchestra. The list could be continued much further. In all these cases it is not a question of processes that have arisen through division of labour and then been re- united, but of activities of quite different kinds, none of which could ever exist by itself, and which, therefore, have ' " Arbeilsvrrbitidung. "Comp. Schmeller, Bayer. H'orterbuch, I. p. words is not clear. 409. The origin ot the UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 2 79 come conjointly into being. In their advancement these occupations are dependent on one another, support one another and only together from a coordinated whole. The workers engaged must therefore accommodate themselves to each other; the one must work into the hands of the other, without whom he could accomplish nothing at all. In most cases his labour by itself would be quite unpro- ductive. As a rule there will be in such associations of labour an activity that can be designated the leading or dominant one, while the other is subordinate and auxiliary. Ac- cordingly th<; personal relationship between the workmen employed will also take the form of a dependent relation- ship. If the directing workman is independent, the work- man who in technical matters is dependent will frequently stand in the relation of employee. If the associated labour is made part of an undertaking it is usual for the whole work (" team-work," collective piece-work) to have assigned to it a collective wage, as is the case with the cigar bunch-breaker and roller, the glass-blower and at- tendant. The plan thus offers a means of applying the system of piece-wage even in cases where the work of one labourer cannot be separated from that of another or of several others; but it results in most cases to the disad- vantage of those who perform the subordinate labour.*" On the whole, this form of labour in common belongs also to the stage of undeveloped technique in the instru- ments of production. With advancing development the supplanting of the subordinate labour by animal or me- chanical power is aimed at. The most familar example is offered by the plough, which was formerly drawn by hu- man beings, later by oxen. In this, however, the combina- " Comp. Schloss, Methods of Industrial Remuneration, rp- (>i ff- S! j; I im I ' I a8o i/WO// OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. tion of labour endured some time longer, inasmuch as a second driver or several drivers were required besides the ploughman, until at length a more perfect construction of the plough made them superfluous.^" In conclusion, it is again to be emphasized that the whole sphere of labour in common belongs, like that of union of labour, preeminently to the departments and the epochs of labour possessing little or no capital. They are the re- source of the economically frail. As such, however, their great evolutionary and historical importance lies in their training of man to methodical division and economy of time, to self-subordination to a general aim, and to regular and intensive labour. These supplement each other in that the inherent weakness of union of labour, pervading the life of each man in primitive times, everywhere finds its counterpart in the temporary communities of labour that arise wherever the variously employed skill of the indi- vidual is inadequate to a given task. Resting originally on custom alone, they lead in course of time to relation- ships capable of legal compulsion, such as slavery and serf- dom. The principles of union of labour and labour in common have in other respects contributed little to the creation of permanent organizations, but they have left permanent works. The pyramids and stone monuments of Egypt, the *" Interesting modifications of the system of combination of labour are found in the cases where more expensive implements are neces- sary, and only one of the parties pc sesses them, while the others merely contribute their labour. In North Russia this is particularly the case in fishing, and again in the work of ploughing, where the hitching together of six to eight animals is rendered advisable from the heaviness of the soil. Examples from Wales, Ireland, and Scot- land in Secbohm, Village Communities (4th cd). p. 81. Meitzen, Sicde- lung u. Agrarwesen d. IVestgermanen u. Ostgcrmancn. d. Kelten. etc., I, pp. 212 fT.; II. pp. ijo. 1.^0 Similarly on the Bogos in the mountains of Abyssinia, in Post. Afr. Jurispimiens, II, pp. 184, 185. UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 2S1 ruins of the giant cities of Mesopotamia, tlie structures of the peoples of early American civilization must be ob- served if we would know what human beings are capable of performing, even without the knowledge of iron, with- out draught animals, and without such simple mechanical expedients as lever, screw, or pulley, when united by one mighty mind in community of work. For science also the two phenomena here referred to, now that they have been defined, maj prove themselves upon unbiassed testing not altogether useless building stones. The theory of labour still stands in need of further extension. The development of the points of view, which in this chapter it has been possible in most cases only to indicate, would probably show that there is still much to be harvested in this region. For we have even now an inkling of the truth, that in union of labour and labour in common much more subtle psychical influences cooperate than in the division of labour, which has hitherto been the almost exclusive object of our attention. To discover them all is, indeed, possibly only to the reflecting and self-observant worker. ;i ; CHAPTER VIII. DIVISION OF LABOUR. - i 5 i' In most of the sciences nowadays there are popular truths. They consist as a rule of general principles, to which their propounders have given such initial complete- ness of form and substance that it would seem as if they might be added at once to our store of knowledge as an as- sured acquisition of the human mind incapable of being either shaken or lost. Such truths become the mental property of the educated with a rapidity often surprising. The convenient impress they bear from the beginning makes them coins for intellectual exchange that gain cur- rency far beyond the department of knowledge for which they were issued. On the other hand, their passage over into the intellectual and linguistic circulation of the edu- cated world serves again to confirm their validity within the narrow department of study from which they have sprung. If knowledge is making rapid progress in this department it comes to pass that these now popular truths remain inviolate while all the remaining structure of the science is demolished and rebuilt. They are like inorganic bodies overrun and enveloped by the luxuriant growth of living organisms. Such is the case, if we are not mistaken, with the theory of division of labour in political economy. In its present form this theory dates from Adam Smith, and its popular- ity is indeed due in no small measure to the external cir- cumstance that it is presented in the first chapter of Book I 282 DIVISION OF LABOUR. 283 of his classical work, where it could not escape even the le- gion of those who merely " read at " books. Adam Smith is, of course, not the originator of the theory. He borrows it in its essential features from the Essay on the History of Civil Society, which his countryman, Adam Ferguson, pub- lished in 1767. Yet the theory has been adopted by all later students in the agreeable form in which Smith pre- sented it. In this form it has also gone over into other sciences and become familiar to every educated person. In essaying then to subject the economic theory of di- vision of labour to a critical examination, and to supple- ment this examination by the application that this theory has quite recently received in the department of sociology, we count upon dealing with a circle of ideas familiar to many.^ For this last application marks at the same time one of the few attempts made by economic science to ad- vance on this point beyond Adam Smith. In other re- spects students have contented themselves with correcting Smith's theory of division of labour in subsidiary points, tracing it back historically and dogmatically to the ancient Greeks, adapting explanatory examples to the technical advances of the present, and besides its bright sides, bring- ing forward the dark sides as well. On the whole, how- ever, our remarks on popularized scientific truths hold good for this theor>-. While round about it the structure of economic theory has been diligently altered and extended, it has remained intact. Only recently a reputable economic writer, in a critical survey of the pro- gress of political economy since Adam Smith, stated that the subject is exhausted; that regarding it one can but re- peat what has been already said by others.^ ' Comp. following chapter. ' M. Block, Le progrcs de la science rconomique dcpuis Adam Smith (Paris, 2d ed., 1897). I. P- 533- ix^^ II ■ M ^' fi' ff r "• ■' lit 384 DIVISION OF LABOUR. Under these circumstances it will suffice for us to discuss the subject in direct connection with the celebrated Scotch- man's presentation of it. We will, however, not cover the whole subject, but attempt merely to answer the two ques- tions: What is division of labour? and How does it operate? What division of labour is we can nowhere learn from Adam Smith. He illustrates the process that he designates by this name only by individual examples, and from them deduces directly the statement which has since been termed the " law " of division of labour, and which can be summarized in the words, that in every industry the pro- ductivity of labour increases proportionately with the ex- tension of labour.' His examples, however, when closely scrutinized by no means illustrate similar economic processes. There is first the celebrated instance of the pin-manufac- tory. With the ordinary workman, who is not particularly adept at this special branch of business and who perhaps could, with his utmost industry, make scarcely one pin in a day, and certainly could not make twenty, Smith con- trasts the factory in which a considerable number of work- men with divided labour produce similar wares. " One man draws out the wire; another straights it; a third cuts it; a fourth points it; a fifth grinds it at the top for receiv- ing the head; to make the head requires two or three dis- tinct operations," etc. In this manner there result up to the completion of the pin eighteen distinct operations, each of which can be transferred to a particular hand. Smith finds that in such a cooperating group of workers the out- put of each individual, as compared with that of the la- 'The correctness of this sharp formulation is manifest from the wo'ds of the first chapter: " The division of labour, so far as it can be introduced, occasions in every part a proportionable increase of the productive powers of labour." DIVISION OF LABOUR.] 28s bourer working separately and prodacing the whole pro- duct, is increased a hundred, indeed a thousandfold. This example has been repeated even to wer-iness; it has become, in general, the classic type of division of labour. Most people can conceive of it only in this one form, the form of a factory in which the total labour necessary to the production of the ware is divided into as many simple operations as possible, carried on simultane- ously by different persons in the same establishment.* But Adam Smith has not confined himself to this exam- ple. He calls it also division of labour when a product has to pass through various trades and employments in a coun- try, from the procuring of the raw material till it is ready for use; as, for instance, the wool through the hands of the sheep-breeder, the spinner, the weaver, and the dyer. In a rude state of society all this, he points out, is the work of one man; in every improved society, on the contrary, the farmer is generally nothing but a farmer; the manufacturer nothing but a manufacturer. The labour, too, that is necessary to produce any complete manufacture, is almost always divided among a great number of hands. Smith makes no distinction between the two kinds of division of labour, and ascribes to both the same effects. But it does not require lengthy consideration to recog- nise that we are here dealing with two distinct processes. In the case of the manufacture of woollen cloth a whole process in production is separated into various depart- ments. Each of these departments becomes an inde- pendent economic organism; and a ware must, from the • Helmolt, De laboris divisione, 1840, (a Doctor's Dissertation from the University of Utrecht,) pp. 38, 39: " Ubi plures operarii siinul opus quoddam conficiunt. singuli vero continue eadem operis parte sunt occupati, ut, si aliquid perfecerint eandem rem de novo aggrediantur." And yet Ferguson had previously entitled his chapter on the division of labour: " On the Separation of Arts and Professions." 286 DiyiSION OF LABOUR. 'I 1° procuring of the raw material on, pass through a series of trades before it can be offered ready for consumption, each change in ownership involving a charge for profits. In the case of the pin, on the contrary, the manufacture of the object of the division of labour does not constitute a com- plete process in production, but merely a single depart- ment. For its raw material, the wire, is already well ad- vanced towards completion. The result of the division is not a series of new trades, but a chain of dependent em- ployments whose successful utilization under present con- ditions postulates the existence of wage-workers held to- gether by one entrepreneur. The product, before it is completed, passes, it is tnie, through a larger number of hands than previously, but it undergoes no change of pro- prietorship. Two industrial processes so thoroughly different de- mand different names. We will designate the division of a whole process of production into several industrially inde- pendent sections division of production; and the breaking up of a department of production into simple dependent labour elements subdivision of labour.'^ Finally Adam Smith cites a third example that is neither division of production nor subdivision of labour. He com- pares three smiths: a common smith, who can handle the hammer well, but has never been accustomed to make nails, a second smith who has been accustomed to make nails, but has not this for his sole or principal occupation, and finally a nail-smith who has never followed any other calling. He finds that if all three make nails for a definite period the work done increases according as the workman limits himself to the production of one product. It is this hmitation to the exclusive production of a single line of goods that he calls division of labour. * Produktwnsteilmg and Arbeitszcrlegung. DIVISION OF L/1BOUR. 287 i The justification for this nomenclature is not at once apparent. What is divided? Where are the parts? Manifestly Smith conceives the whole business of a smith who, as in olden times, makes horseshoes, plough- shares, and wheel-tires, as well as axes, spades, and nails, as the subject of the division. From this comprehensive department of production a line of products is separated, and their production taken over by a special workmar nail-smith, while the remaining products continue to part of the smith's work. The articles formerly prod jointly in the one business of the smith are for the k. manufactured in two different businesses. In the plact one industry there are now two; and each forms £0* .4 individual a separate business or vocation. It is clear that in this case it is neither a question ot cut- ting a somewhat extensive process of production into va- rious sections, nor of si. ling such a section ittto its simplest elements. For, as h himself explair^N the labour process of the nailer is neither shorter nor less complex than the smith's: each for himself blov he bel- lows, stirs the fire, heats the iron, and forges ev pan >t the product. A change has taken place only m one re- spect: each applies this process to fewer classes of good- Under the system of divided labour, however, the goo.Ls produced, taken singly, do •, )t pass through more hands than formerly. We will cal! this third species of division of labour specialization or division of trades. How specialization is distinguished from subdivision of labour is readily perceived. The one is a division of the whole task of production between different businesses; the other takes place within a single business. It is per- haps more difficult at first sight to distinguish division of production and specialization of trades. In division of production cross-cuts, as it were, are made through a I;' i'-'V m ii I 288 DIVISION OF LABOUR. somewhat extensive process of production; in specializa- tion a distinct department of business is split lengthwise. To offer a simple example, the production of leather articles of use was originally confined to the one estab- lishment. The Siberian nomad and the Southern .Slav peasant still procure the hides, tan them, and out of the leather make footwear, harness, etc., within their own household establishment. In the countries of Western Europe the trades of the tanner and the currier had arisen by the early Middle Ages. Leather goods down to their finished condition then passed through three trades, — that of the furnisher of the hides, of the tanner, and of the currier. That was divis. i of produc- tion. In time the special handicrafts of the shoemaker, the saddler, the strap-maker, the maker of fine leather goods, etc., have separated themselves from the large industry of the currier; and each produces a particu- lar class of leathei wares by approximately the same process of work. That is specialization, or division of trades. In division of production, o use a simile, the whole stream of production of gooas is from time to time dammed up by weirs; with specialization it is diverted into numerous small channels and rivulets. In his explanatory examples Smith goes no farther than this. We may also for the present pause here and lay before ourselves the question: What led the " father of political economy " to embrace under the one name division of labour three processes so different as division of production, subdivision of work, and specializa- tion? Wherein are these processes, whose fundamental differences we have been able only briefly to indicate, es- sentially similar? The true response to this question will at the same time DIVISION OF LABOUR. 289 furnish us with the simplest and broadest definition of division of labour, a definition which must be accepted by all who, on this point, have followed Adam Smith, that is, by all scientific political economists." Manifestly those three different kinds of division of labour have only the following in common with each other: all three are f^rocesses in the economic evolution of society which have orif;inated through acts of human volition, and in which an eco'wnic task is transferred from tlie one person hitherto performing it to several persons, the transfer being so made that each of these performs but a separate part of the previous total labour. Division of labour will ac- cordingly always be characterized by an increase in the number of labourers necessar}' for the accomplishment of a definite economic end, and at the same time by a differ- entiation of work. The economic tasks become simplified, better adapted to limited human capacities; they become, as it were, individualized. Hence division of labour is al- ways at the same time classification of labour, organiza- tion of labour in accord with the economic principle; its result is ever the cooperation of varied energies in a com- * Those savants of course excepted who no longer define at all. Most later definitions overlook the causal force of the word division, and in place of the process of division put the realized condition. Schmoller, for instance, understands by division of labour "the per- manent adaptation of the individual to a specialized life-work affecting and dominating the whole life " (Jhrb. f. Gesetzg., Verw. u. Volksw., XIV, 47). He thus forces under division what can be but its result. E. V. Philippovich states in his Grundriss d. Pol. Gel:., I, 50: " Division of labour is the actual divided performance of tasks leading to a com- mon end. It assun s, lik- every division, a unity from whose stand- point the labour of tie individual appears not as something exclusive and self-contained, but as a part of a larger whole. This unity is de- termined either by society as a whole, or by some organization of society into separate parts." But why first construct this totality? Why not begin with it? Society and tbe business undertaking have surely not been divided; they are but results of the division of labour. \4 290 DiyiSION OF LABOUR. I'll if 1 i n ? f mon work which could formerly only be performed by a single pair of hands. Keeping this clearly in mind, and passing in review from this standpoint the whole field of the economic employ- ment of labour in its historical and contemporary develop- ment, we soon recognise that with the typical examples of Adam Smith and the three kinds of division of labour deduced by us from them, the range of the latter is by no means exhausted. We find, on the contrary, a fourth and a fifth type of division of labour, which we will designate respectively the formation of trades and the displacement of labour. Let us begin with the fonnation of trades, which should indeed rank first in an enumeration of the kinds of division of labour. For it forms the beginning of all eco- nomic development. To understand it one must start from the conception, that before the origin of a national economy the different peoples pass through a condition of pure private economy in which each house has to produce through the labour of its members all that is required. This labour can be divided among the members of the household in various ways, according to age, sex, and physical strength, and according also to their relation to the father of the family. But this distribution of labour is not division of lal)Our from the standpoint of society, for its eflfects remain restricted to the household and exert no creative influence upon other economies; nor does it in- fluence the formation of classes in society. At this stage there are. therefore, all varieties of agricultural and in- dustrial techniciue: but there is no system of agriculture, no industry, no trade as a separate branch of business: there are no peasants, no industrial classes, no merchants as social business groups. This state of affairs is altered as soon as individual tasks DIVISION OF LABOUR. 291 :s separate from this many-sided activity and become sub- jects of vocations, the bases of particular business occupa- tions. The way for this advance is prepared by the division of labour of the great slave and serf husbandries. We cannot, however, treat of these here. The part that detaches itself from the range of work of the autonomous domestic establishment and becomes a separate and inde- pendent business is at one time a complete process of production, for example, pottery; or again, a single section in production, for example, cloth-fulling, corn- grinding; • or still again, a species of personal service, for example, surgical work. Most frequently, however, it is the productive part of the domestic labours that is abridged through the formation of trades; and in the course of centuries these labours are more and more re- stricted to the province of consumption. On the other hand, there arise the different branches of production and the various industries which through specialization and division of production become multiplied ad infinitum. It would be a mistake, however, to imagine that this process of the formation of vocations which begins with us in the early Middle Ages has long been completed. Parts of the old domestic economy are still falling away; in the country, slowly; in the towns, more rapidly. Every city directory can disclose to us a series of inde- pendent industries which have come into existence only within the present century, through the splitting up of former single phases of domestic activity. Of course it wouUl be erroneous to assume that each instance of a new trade which is not division of an old trade or <if a branch o\ production is to bi> traced hack to divi- sion of labour between household and new business occu- *In this case the formation of a trade is at tlif same time division of production. I ^f I I 25a DIVISION OF LABOUR. nations. A bicycle-factoiy, a galvanizing or electrical establishment, an ice-factory, and a photographic atelier are industrial undertakings owing their origin not to division of labour, but to the rise of entirely new species of goods. They must accordingly be excluded from this sur- vey Yet they are not on that account beyond the mflu- ence of division of labour, since from the beginning they accommodate themselves to the forms of production con- ditioned by such divisi^ n. . , ^ Connected only ex rnally with this process is the phe- nomenon that we have already termed displacement of labour It accompanies the invention of new machines and other f^xed tools of labour. The division of labour here operates in the following manner: With the introduction into a branch of production of a newly-invented machine there is a complete displacement of the previous organization of work. As a rule the mechanism undertakes only separate movements that un- til then have fallen to the human hand; and m the busmess installing the machine the sole initial change is generally the transfer of the workman, who formerly performed those muscular motions, to attendance upon the machine, which demands from him other muscular motions. In this way, for instance, after the intr. .duction of the sewing- machine, the labourer in the tailoring establishment works with hand and foot, while formeriy his hand alone was called into action, and then, moreover, in a difTereat man- ner. But even previously to that there were many more per- sons engaged in the making of a coat than the tailor. There were in the first place the producers of the ma- terials used bv the tailor: the wool-producer, the spinner, the weaver, the dyer, etc.: then the producers of fine im- plements: the needle-manufacturer, the scissors-manufac- DiyiSION OF LABOUR. 293 turer, and many others. All these producers still continue active after the introduction of a sewing machine. But a new one is added, the machine-manufacturer; or, since the machine is produced through subdivision of work, at once a whole group: the machine-fitter, the founder, the metal- turner, the carpenter for the models, the mounter, the var- nisher, etc. We have, if we embrace under our view the whole pr- ess of production, a part of the total labour pushed back from a later to an earlier stage. The work oi tailoring is in part transferred from the tailoring estab- lishment to the machine factory. The whole process is typical, and undoubtedly exhibits the characteristics of division of labour. If we employ for it the exnression displacement of labour the phrase must be understood in a local and temporal sense. As regards locality, displacement of labour means the partial trans- ference of the manufacture of an article from one place of production to another; as regards time, it signifies the substitution of work that has been previously performed for work being performed now, the pushing back of a sec- tion of the work that was formerly devoted to the pro- duction of consumption goods to the furnishing of the means of production. In this, however, it is not at all necessary that a new undertaking should be formed to produce the new implement of labour exclusively. For, as in the case of the sewing-machine, a machine-factory already in existence can undertake its production. The essential thing to note is that the new process for the pro- duction of clothing contains an increased number of dif- ferent employments, and accordingly claims the service of more labourers. We have now become acquainted with five diflfercr.t kinds of economic processes falling under the head of division of labour, which are still in operation every 294 DIVISION OF LABOUR. I nr «:• \4 i i IP ■ |H : ^- day before our eyes. This is of course saying very little as to their relative importance in modern industrial life. For the latter is itself the result of a long process of develop- ment; and he who regards it with the eye of an historical student will find everywhere side by side the most primi- tive and the most modern: the one with a modest, the other with a ubiquitously prominent sphere of influence. Society in its long evolution from the isolated to the social economy has ever been seeking and finding new methods of organization in work. But it has not on that account discarc ' the old, nor will it discard them so long as their roles have not been completely played. For here too the great law of economy prevails; nothing is lost that is still capable of being at any point advantageously employed. This also holds for the various forms of division of labour. Even though subdivision of work and displace- ment of labour at present surpass in importance specializa- tion and division of production, and even though forma- tion of trades as a species of division of labour need hardly be longer taken into account, none of these piinciples of economic organization has ceased to operate. Each con- tinues active in the places where it can still assert its force. In economic history each of them has had a period of preponderance. Formation of trades appears with us in the early Middle Ages. The chief activity of specializa- tion is coincident, with the prime of municipal develop- ment. Division tl production begins at the same time. Its whole force in the economy of capital, however, is de- veloped only after subdivision of work and displacement of labour begin to operate, and neither of these can with certainty be trared back beyond the seventeenth century. It is with reluctance that we refrain from a detailed presentation of the historical conditions governing ihem, as well as of the causes and consequences nf their appear- DIVISION OF LABOUR. 295 ance. We are the more loth because only in this way can the sharp distinctions we have made between the different processes find their full justification, and the traditional abstract treatment of the whole matter its refutation. We must, however, devote a few general words to the cause and result of division of labour. For the distinguishing of those five kinds of the latter would necessarily appear scientifically unimportant, or an idle nicety of refinement, if all stood in like casual connection with the economic phenomena that precede or follow them. Adam Smith derives all division of labour from one com- mon origin: man's natural propensity to trade. He does not determine whether this is the result of instinct or of conscious mental action. He thus renounces a sharp psy- chological analysis of economic action, and contents him- self with considering division of labour as deep-rooted in the dark depths of instinct. In this, however, he falls foul of his own examples. For if division of labour has its origin in an immemorial in- stinct of man. then it is a fundamental factor of economic life, which must assert itself whenever and wherever men exist. Yet Adam Smith's examples regularly set over against the condition of divided labour a condition of un- divided labour, and deduce the former from the latter. For this has to be inferred from the dynamic employment of the word division. There actually existed for centuries, as we already know, a condition of society in which divi- sion of labour was wanthig: and the different kinds of the latter can be pretty definitely determined by the time of their origin. Social division of labour is thus generally a historical category-, and not an elemental economic phe- nomenon. The same is true of exchange. Just as there have been epochs without economic division of labour, so there have 396 DiyiSlON OF LABOUR. l\%" M I »2 I 1 been epochs without exchange. The first acts of trade do not appear simultaneously with division of labour, but long precede it. They serve the purpose of equalizing casual surpluses and deficiencies that have made their ap- pearance in otherwise autonomous economies. Exchange is here something accidental; it is not a necessary con- comitant of the husbandry of the time. Even when with the formation of trades social division of labour arises, ex- change is still very active in forms which it is the evident purpose to exclude as far as possible. The housewife of early time uses the hand-mill to grind the corn she herself has grown, and from the flour thus produced she bakes her bread. After the industries of the miller and the baker have been established the grinding is turned over to the miller, and the baker then receives the flour to make bread of. From raw material to finished product the new article of consumption has never changed its proprietor. For their pains, miller and baker are allowed to retain a definite part of their product. In the whole process of production with divided labour this is the sole occurrence partaking of the nature of exchange. From this one readily recognises that the alleged pro- pensity to trade is for Adam Smith only a means of extri- cating himself from an embarrassment. We can the more readily spare ourselves the trouble of entering further into this point since recent economists have not accepted this tenet of their Scottish master. They rather prefer to re- gard exchange as the unintentional result of division of labour. This we can accept, with the limitation that v/ith <livided labour exchange becomes necessary from the mo- ment that the producer possesses all the means of jifoduc- tion. It tlien becomes a vital element of each economy; and from this point on almost cver>' advance in division of labour increases the number of necessary acts of exchange. I -%i DIVISION OF LABOUR. 297 But this Stage of development is not reached tiJ centuries after the earliest origin of economic division of labour. Even to-day, for example, it is by no means the rule m country parts for the miller to own the corn and the baker the flour, and a triple exchange to be necessary before the consumers can come into possession of the bread. If then exchange is merely a secondary phenomenon m the evolutionary processes of social division of labour, we are by this very fact compelled to seek another motive for man's efforts toward this division. In this we are led back directly to the fundamental facts of economy: the boundless extent of human needs, and the limited means of satisfying them. Human needs are capable of an infinite multiplication and subdivision; they are never at rest; they increase in degree and extent with the progress of civilization. The material suitable for human ends is limited, as is also human labour which in- vests it with the qualities of a marketable ware and in- creases its quantity. With the increase in the number of human beings the relation of the total demand to the mass of raw material capable of profitable utilization which nature can offer becomes even more unfavourable. The quantity of labour necessary to satisfy the total re- quirement thus increases for a double reason: more and better goods are to be produced: and they are to be turned out under more unfavorable conditions. The share in head-work falling to each one engaged in the under- taking would thus become at length intolerable were it not possible to reduce it through an economic employment o. labour. Now simi 'e observation teaches that every person is not equally' qualified by nature for every employment. The differing bodily and intellectual tendencies of indi- viduals necessarilv occasion important differences in the 298 DmSION OF LABOUR. .1 f products of labour; and these differences become ever more marked with advancing social development or, what is the same, with increasing variety of work to be per- formed. The principle of economy requires that every- one's employment befit one's capabilities; for only in this way can labour yield its highest service. To have " the right man in the right place " becomes all the easier as the tasks increase in number and each is permanently con- signed to a special hand. Along with the multiplication of occupations comes a simplification. Every composite work means for the indi- vidual executing it a frequent change of motions, and every such change a waste of energy. For passing from one kind of movement to another calls for mental and bodily accommodation to the new class of work, which means an outlay of strength yielding in itself no useful return. With muscular movements pursuing a uniform course, however, the mind's share in the work can be eliminated, and an automatic performance of those movements soon enters, which, with increasing practice, removes farther and farther the limits of fatigue. At the same time the intensity of automatic labour can be greatly increased, so that not only can the movements be continued longer, but a larger numl)er of them is pos- sible within a given unit of time. An extraordinary ad- vance in the effectiveness of labour is the result.'' All this makes it. as it were, a command of economy to narrow the labour tasks if we are to utilize every kind of end wment.and avoid every bootless waste of strength. In most processes of production, however, we find decidedly heterogeneous employments united: hand-work and head- work; operations demanding great muscular power along I \rf.,p ;^. ;t..tp.;t in Arbeit «. Rhythmua, pp. 24 ff. DIVISION OF LABOUR. 299 with those in which suppleness of the finger, delicacy of touch, keenness of sight come in question; tasks requir- ing a skill gained through theory and practice, and those that even the unpracticed is in a position to undertake. In early times when these different tasks were placed in one hand a great waste of skilled labour resulted, and the productive part of the population was limited to those who had mastered some one branch of technique in all its parts. By separating the qualitatively unequal labour ele- ments from one another, division of labour succeeds in utilizing the weakest as well as the strongest workers, and in inciting them to the development of the highest special % skill. . Thus division of labour is, in the last analysis, nothmg but one of those processes of adaptation that play so great a part in the evolutionary historj- of the whole in- habited world: adaptation of the tasks of labour to the variety of human powers, adaptation of individual powers to the tasks to be performed, continued differentiation of the one and of the other. Therewith the whole process advances out of the twilight of instinctive life into the bright day of conscious human activity. Yet one fact still requires special mention. It is, that the personal casual element in division of labour stands out more clearly the further back we go in the history of man- kind. For this reason the predominant forms of division of labour in the early stages of development are those in which the individual is assigned an independent task that can be carried cut without any extensive material equip- ment. It is more especially the intellectual and artistic activities that expand earliest into vocations. The priest, the prophet, the magician, the singer, and the dancer are the first to gain a separate position on account of special gifts. 300 DIVISION OF LABOUR. u If an unfree system of labour exists, division of labour develops first within the slave family; and it is with the as- sistance of a personal and moral feature hitherto hardly heeded that it comes into being. Wherever the system of supervised labour in common is inapplicable, the master must provide every unfree worker with a particular range of duties, for which he can be held responsible. He must impose on him a single definite kmd of work if he wishes to profit by his labour. Hence among the Romans that almost over-refined specialization of work in the familia urbana,* the careful selection of slaves according to bodily and mental endowment for the different agricultural em- ployments;* and among the serfs of the Middle Ages the extreme frequency with which the rent paid in kind was fixed in very special products of domestic work.^" The man acting in the slave household exclusively as field- worker or smith, barber or scribe, the rent-collector and the man whosp sole duty it was to supply the court with casks or vesseii, knives or linen cloth, acquired a special dexterity wherewith, when the hour of emancipation sounded, they entered society as professional workers. Thus in the individual task rendered necessary by the slave economy of the stage of exclusive domestic husbandry, and in the specialization that it conditions, lay the seed- time for the social division of labour of the following stage. It is at a much later date that material cletnents supple- ment the personal element of endowment and adaptation ' Compare above, p. 99. • Compare on this the fine remarks of Columella, I, 9: " Sed et illud censeo, ne confundantur opera familia;, sec ut omnes omnia exsequantur; nam id minime conducit agricolae, seu quia nemo suum proprium aliquod esse opus credit, seu quia, cum enisus est, non suo sed communi officio proficit ideoque labori multum se substrahit; nee tamen viritim malefactum deprehenditur, quod fit a multis," etc. '° A Hit ii given above, on page ,04. DiyiSlON OF LABOUR. 301 in originating division of labour." Formerly it was men alone, now things also become diflferentiated, — tools, raw materials, products. Each advance in division of labour seeks to adapt itself to the existing tools and implements, or to provide new ones for the particular task. Let one but think of the innumerable kinds of hammers, tongs, and chisels used in the different branches of metal- and wood-working! The division of labour among persons finds its counterpart in a division of use among the instru- ments of work. But as long as the tool is merely a rein- forcement of the human agent, the personal adjustment will dominate the process of production. It is only when artificial appliances are introduced which enable man to subdue natural powers to his service that the labour in- strument gains control over the labourer's social indi- viduality, as well as over his bodily movements. And now the impetus for a fresh advance along the path of division of labour can as readily originate in a newly-invented im- plement of labour as in the possession or acquisition of a particular personal qualification. Most newly-invented machines require the attendance of workmen possessing a qualification not previously represented in the business. Then, joined to this, comes the saving consequent upon the growing extension of production, a feature of impor- tance from the standpoint of capital. But this saving can take place only on the assumption of a unification and con- centration of demand sufficient to make the wholesale " Oh what follows compare Arbeit u. Rhythmus, Chap. IX. How strongly the personal element still predominated in the division of labour in the town economy of the Middle Ages is seen from the con- ditions for admission into a guild. As far as the carrying on of a trade came in question only persona! requirements were made— ability to do the work with one's own hand. Material requirements had to be met by the person seeking admission only as a citizen— possession of a house and of arms: and as a Christian— entrance-fee in wax. 302 DiyiSlON OF L/1BOUR. production, which perhaps has long been technically pos- sible, economically possible also. Many labour-processes cause approximately the same costs whether they embrace many or few pieces, as is the case, for example, with dye- ing, grinding, drying, postal delivery. But if the method of work can be so contrived that masses of the raw or half- manufactured material which are to be worked over are collected at definite points, the employment of hands at these points solely for this purpose becomes profitable, with, on the whole, a considerable saving in costs. How far in such matters the social principles of immo- bility of labour and of free competition may cooperate to retard or to advance is not to be investigated here. A warning is merely to be given against observing and judg- ing these matters solely in the light of modern industrial conditions. Division of labour reaches out far beyond the sphere of material things. It can show in recent times, espcc'ally in the field of intellectual work, advances and results far surpassing those in the department of manu- facturing technique. Indeed, the former are largely the direct cause and occasion of the latter. On the other hand, in the whole broad field lying beyond the limits of material production the material aids to labour play only an unimportant part. The personal element is here con- tinually decisive for the further developrrent of division of labour; and we thus have to recognise it as paramount in the whole great process of advancing civiHzation. As to the universal originating cause of division of labour more than this cannot be said. The particular conditions of origin under which the various kinds and forms make their appearance will be briefly discussed in another place. At this point we can make but like cursory reference also to the economic consequences of division of labour, al- DIVISION OF LABOUR. 303 though it is in this very particular that the various forms most vddely diverge Adam Smith knows but one effect of division of labour: the increased productivity of labour. He thus restricts its influence to the s,.here of production. In this he is right. Division of labour permits the production of more and better goods with a given expenditure of hu- man strength than was possible with undivided labour. Production becomes cheaper; its costs diminish as far as labour is concerned. And since Smith considers labour the true measure of exchange value, he can dispense with investigating whether under all circumstances division of labour also insures a cheaper satisfaction of the wants of the customer. . , However narrow this conception may appear, it is cer- tainly more reasonable than the unlimited extension g-en by many recent economists " to the effects of division of labour when they derive the whole of our present com- m;:rcial organization directly from division of labour, and think to characterize it sufficiently by caUing it, as they commonly do, the " economy of divided labour." In this they allow themselves to be guided by the opinion that in their present form and method of action the most im- portant economic phenomena are determined by division of labour; that in the highly refined subdivision of trades occasioned by it division of labour is, so to speak, the skeleton supporting the economic organism, while trade and commerce represent the ligaments and muscles that hold it together and enable it to functionate like a great living body. Commerce, however, they say, is occasioned (':-ectly by division of labour; division of labour is its ?. ase. " Schmoller may again serve as an example: Grundriss, I. pp. 304 ff- h III 304 DIVISION OF LABOUR. Therein lies a great mistake. By i'^^self, division of labour does not create trade. And iverscly, ii condition of undivided labour may easily be inngiiied concurrent with a relatively well-developed traf . Let us elucidate the last sentence nrsi. \Vc nay recall that peoples standing at the stage of private domestic economy can have a relatively weli-developed exchange of goods — for profit or otherwise, if smallness of the household membership or extraordinar>- inequality in the distribution o. the gifts of nature give occasion for it. Each house and each worker produces, in a condition of complete union of labour, everything that the natural ad- vantages of the place of habitation permit of. Exchange but fills up the gaps of home-produci.on; its objects are merely surpluses of otherwise autonomous establishments. The weaker the different households are numerically and the oftener unfavourable seasons— dying of cattle, spoiling of the stores, or sickness of members of the household — threaten at particular points the satisfaction of their needs, the more frequently will surplus ware be drawn from an outside source in exchange for the excess commodity in one's own sphere. Thus tlie negro races of Central Africa have a great number of weekly markets, which are usually held under special peace protection in the midst of the primieval forest. Yet among them there is scarcely a single in- dustry carried on as a business; and every species of di- vision of labour is lacking, save the separation of the spheres of work according to sex. The same state of things has been observed in different parts of Oceania. Even in the countries of Western Europe a fairly brisk market trade must seemingly be assumed for the early Middle Ages, notwithstanding the complete absence of a developed subdivision of labour. DIVISION OF LABOUR. 305 i f 1 On the other hand, as aiready frequently remarked, when the existence of slavery or serfdom calls into bemg households numerically extensive, division of labour can establish itself at the same stage of domestic work without giving rise to exchange. On the estates of wealthy Romans there were workmen of very different grades of skill, perhaps even some who produced accord- ing to the principle of subdivision of work; but exchange neither united them with each other nor with the con- sumers of their products. The power holding the-n to- gether was the authority of the head of the family. Under slavery this power lay in the ownership of the persons, under serfdom, in the ownership of the soil. An establish- ment thus organized is a permanent community for produc- tion and consumption. What it produces it also consumes. Indeed, division of labour really appears for it a welcome means of avoiding exchange. In such large households regular division of labour ac- cording to employment paves the way for the succeeding economic stage. It is the starting-point lor the formation of trades. On the latter is baged the origin of special economic life-vocations. It liberates a section of humanity from the soil, on the possession of which its existence had solely depended. It furnishes the burghe- s well as the peasant with the means of livelihood. cialization in- creases the number of opportunities for trade, it supplies the framework within which higher mechanical skill is developed. And at first division of production has no other efTect. Formation of trades, specialization, and division of production— all three together— are indeed able of themselves to create an economy based upon di- vided labour, but this economy is not at once national economy. For, first of all. it still lacks the circulation of goods. 3o6 DiyiSION OF LABOUR. The whole process of division of labour up to this point proceeds, as we know, by the method of workers separat- ing from the independent household of the proprietor of the soil, and in the service of other households turning to account any special skill in the form of wage-work. They are, it is true, tradesmen living from the earnings of their special trade; but the raw material that they work up is owned by the person who will finally consume the product in his own house. Now there are certain cases in which several of such wage-workers must cooperate in one process of manufacture if the commodity is to be com- pletely finished; for example, in preparing bread, the miller and the baker; in making a garment, the weaver, the dyer, and the tailor. In the exercise of their technical skill all these labourers engaged in independent trades are united with one another through the product which passes through their hands in different stages of its manu- facture. The whole employment of the one is to con- tinue the work of the other. Their economic coopera- tion, however, is effected by the owner of the raw ma- terial, who has himself generally produced it, and to whom the finished product returns— that is, by the consumer. The means, however, by which the same person attracts to his service the various part-producers is the wage that he pays to each. This payment, moreover, represents the sole commercial act involved in this kind of division of labour. In b'lilding a house one employs successively on wage the mason, the carpenter, the roofer, the glazier, the joiner, the locksmith, and the decorators, and supplies them with the material necessary for their work. Their objective point of union they all find in the new structure; their personal point of union they possess in the builder. He unites them, so to speak, into a temporary community on SION OF LABOUR. 307 of production. J-ut their union is a loose and constantly changing one. No permanent economic organization of society arises fiom it. To-day they serve this builder, to- morrow that. Division of labour makes the producers so- cially dependent neither upon one another nor upon the contractor. They remain " master workmen." Nor is there much change in this regard when the wage- worker rises to the position of craftsman and himself sup- plies the raw material for his labour. A wagon, for in- stance, is ordered from the wagon-maker, is ironed by the smith, and painted by the painter. The wagon-maker fur- nishes the wood, the smith the iron, the painte*- the paint. The payment that they receive at this stage is a remunera- tion for the labour and the material furnished by each. But the one guiding the production is still, as ever, the consumer of the commodity produced by divided labour. Through all earlier forms of division of labour, as one perceives, there runs an obvious endeavour to restrict the number of commercial transactions evoked by it to those absolutely necessary. In the midst of all trades originatiii, in division of labour stands domestic work, the mother of them all, with its primeval community of labour dissolving but slowly. Alongside it, even through- out the stage of town economy, the particular manufac- turing establishments and professional workmen called forth by formation of trades, specialization, and di- vision of production continue to be firmly and clo«ely united. From the customer's house they receive the com- missions which tl.ey execute; and even then during the performance of the work they frequently enter into a tem- porary consuming community}' In the stage of national economy the consumer with- "[Comp. Chap. IV, remarks on i/iWraHO'— Ed.1 3o8 DIVISION OF LABOUR. iii draws more and more from his century-old position as director and uniter of divided production. These duties now develop into a vocation. This vocation, however, can be independently exercised by those alone in whose hands the means of production — or at least the circulating means of production — are at the same time found, that is, by the capitalists. Because of the double duties that thus fall to them — procuring capital and directing the produc- tion — they are called business undertakers or entrepre- neurs. In their hands the division of labour undergoes a com- plete transformation. In so far as it is division of produc- tion each part-producer now disposes of the products of his own raw material to his successor. They become for each a source of profit, that is, circulating capital. Thus arises along with the trade in certain classes of finished wares, a series of exchanges of raw material or unfinished goods with no other aim than to unite the various stages of division of labour with each other. This exchanging is in character quite unlike the one between the consumer and the various producers in succession, which previously held exclusive possession of the field. The earlier ex- change, at least for the one acquiring the product, is pure exchange for use, in which he is concerned with the com- modity as an object of consumption. The later exchange is for purchaser and seller always a business transaction in which the utility of the object of exchange is of secondary, and its character as capital — the profit to be gaine<l by it — of primary, importance. The forms of division of labour, displacement of labour, and subdivision of work now aris- ing for the first time have by their mutual relationship the effect of imparting the quality of capital to the fixed means of product" n as well. The subdivision of work makes necessary a permanently dependent labouring class. It DIVISION OF LABOUR. 309 alone gives to the method of capitalistic production its full expansion. Although, on the other hand, it largely de- stroys, in the department accessible to it, that which the formation of trades and specialization had previously cre- ated — the independence of the petty traders. This new phase of division of laL- , accordingly, raises commerce to a height unknown before. In trade, in trans- portation, in credit negotiation, in insurance, it calls forth numberless other phenomena of division of labour under the shadow of the entrepreneur system, which lead in turn to fresh commercial services of a manifold kind. But in itself division of labour does not create this new com- merce. The impelling and creative element in modem national economy is not division of labour, but business capital, and commerce is its spring of life. The point at which capital in its primal form of money first displayed its earning power was trade. From there it has encroached upon production by enabling the trader to take the consumer's place as director of production. In this way that commission system first took its rise in the world of industry in which the commission manufac- turer enters into the same ouier relationship with wage- worker and craftsman that the father of the household formerly held. To the one he advances the raw material, from the other he purchases the finished products made from self-supplied material, with the object of further dis- posing of them. Where a productive process falls into different sections he guides the product from one to the other, and finally places it on the market as finichcd war". As a rule, he operates merely with circulating capital. He has to do permanently with fixed capital only when it becomes profitable to pass over from commission to fac- tory production. While, however, in the provi.ice of industry trading capital was merely a transforming agency, .4 3IO DiyiSlON OF LABOUR. m ■■ Bl ■ 1 n^^^K ii w^m ii ^^B 1 HI 1 pvp in the departments of banking, transportation, and in- surance it has been creative. These departments of busi- ness are really, when ve consider them from the side of division of labour, only ramifications of trade. Thus, it seems to us, we have to recognise capital as the creative influence in modem national economy, and division of labour as the medium through which it operates. Its support and representative is the entrepreneur. That the latter has been able to utilize this medium of division of labour to much greater purpose than the head of the household before him is plainly evident. To-day the entrepreneur determines what we shall eat and drink, read in the papers and see at the theatre^ how we shall lodge and dress. That means everything. For a great part of the goods we consume the right of self-determining is taken away. And since uniform production on a large scale is most advantageous to the manufacturer, there is operative in the sphere of consumption an increasingly active uniforming process. In contrast with ihis the province of labour exhibits a continually advancing differentiation. The field of work of each individual is ever growing more restricted. It is only when broken up on the basis of technique into its parts, that labouring skill can furnish workable building material for the task of the entrepreneur. Every business establishment is a union of various fragmentary activities, originating through division of labour, into an organic whole. It unites workmen economically and technically dependent into a permanent community of production. This community of production, however, luis ceased to be at the same time a community of consumption. On the contrary, its members belong to distinct households which have been freed from all the burdens of production, and which are in DIVISION OF LABOUR. 3" no wise connected with one another or with the employer's household. In the formation of those communities of production the entrepreneur's plan of action varies according to the presence or absence of the earlier forms of division of labour in the manufacture in which he wishes to place his capital. In the first case he absorbs into his undertaking all the independent branches of business that up to that time had to do with the wares to be produced. He specializes their workers and permanently allots to them the performance, side by side, of the part-tasks required by the business. As an example, take the furniture-factory, in which joiners, turners, wood-carvers, upholsterers, glaziers, painters, and finishers are incorporated in a common productive process. In the second case he first organises the work according to the principles of subdivision of labour, in the branch of production concerned, and furnishes the business with a comprehensive outfit of machinery. In both instances there are in the fully-equipped busi- ness, in addition to the entrepreneur, only subject part- workmen whom the technical arrarpement of the work renders dependent. In the one case they have been inde- pendent craftsmen, and the task of the entrepreneur con- sists in combining them into one industrial imit; in the other the business unit already exists, and its component parts are to be sought. Very soon the employees of either origin are no longer to be distinguished from one another. Early handicraft had as a basis a few workmen of similar training who, even though at different stages (ap- prentices, journeymen, master workmen), worked side by side. The qualifications of the groups so composed bear, 312 DIVISION OF LABOUR. from handicraft to handicraft, no resemblance to each other. It is impossible for a transfer to be made from one species of employment to another; for instance, the smith cannot be wheelwright. The law recognises this by the sharp dividing lines it dravvs between them. Modern industrial activity unites workers difTering in skill and strength into cooperative harmony within the undertaking. Their grouping for business purposes fol- lows the same principles of organization from branch to branch of production: there are no sharp boundary lines between industries. A distinction of vocations hardly oc- curs among entrepreneurs, though to a certain extent it exists among the workmen. As far as the entrepreneur's functions are concerned, it is almost a matter of indiffer- ence whether he manages a street-railway, iron-works, or a weaving factory. Among the employees, on the con- trary, in consequence of the continued subdivision of work, there are now numerous specialists who are required in very different branches of production. The locksmith, the metal-turner, the moulder, the planer, and the cutter ap- pear in all branches of well-ad\ iced metal industry, in each special department of machine-construction, in rail- way workshops, etc. Fireman and engineer are neces- sary in every large establishment, whether it produces cotton thread or illustrated papers. Joiners, tinsmiths, coopers can be incorporated into or attached to under- takings of the most varied type, and office-clerks, pattern- artists, and engineers have a similarly varied usefulness. To these is to be added the mass of unskilled labour that is swallowed up by the large manufac curing establish- ments. For many entrepreneurs almost the sole remain- ing question is how to apportion and arrange these labour elements in such a way that they may cooperate as a me- chanical unit. ^' DiyiSION OF LABOUR. ;i3 This cursory survey has taught us how at different epochs division of labour has exerted an influence upon the industry of peoples, and upon the existence of in- dividuals, varying according to the organizing principles dtDminating the different economic stages. During the stage of independent household economy there prevails either union of labour in the hands of the father and mother of the family, or division of labour de- veloped upon the basis of slavery or serfdom. In both cases the household represents a permanent community of production and consumption. The principle holds good: who works with me shall eat with me. In the stage of town economy specialization and division of production predominate. The part-producers are per- sonally free ; but the consumer of their wares, who unites them under favourable circumstances into temporary com- munities of production, determines in the main the nature and time of their production. During the period of com- mon production he often provides them with their keep. During the stage of developed national economy the entrepreneur controls the production of wares under di- vision of labour. The part-producers are personally free labourers. They are united by the employer into per- manent communities of production. All other community of living is excluded; and if perchance on occasion of a business jubilee the entrepreneur gives a dinner to his workmen, the newspapers report how he ate and drank with them at the same table, and consider it a particular condescension on his part. These are different economic worlds, separated from one another by a deep gulf. If there breathes in the prim- itive union of labour of the home, and. in part, in the eariier division of labour as well, a warm breath of social fellowship, there surge through the modern division of i 3»4 DiyiSION OF LABOUR. labour the cold, cutting winds of calculation, contract, and greed of gain. If the older division of labour was the caryatid of economic independence, the modern is ever forcing large masses ir o a condition of dependence. The pressure of capital is making men's occupations increas- ingly dissimilar; it is making the men, as consumers, ever more alike. If in the olden time the individual's portion of goods was shaped by his own hands and head, and was, so to say, a component part of his being that had taken objective form, the consumption goods surrounding us to-day are the work of many hands and heads. As to the workers, we are supremely indiflf erent ; and as to their work, when once we have paid its last possessor the mar- ket price, we for the most part reck but little. In the narrow circle of a life-vocation the mind becomes nar- rowed, frequently to obtuseness. In our sphere of activ- ity we have lost in fulness of life, and the worker has not the old joy in his work. Are we sufficiently compensated for these losses by the variety of articles which it is ours to use because thousands of hands labour for us, because thousands of heads think for us? Or has division of labour merely made life richer in pleasures, but poorer m real joy? CHAPTER IX. ORGANIZATION OF WORK AND THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. The economic processes involved in the organization of work are processes of adaptation. Whether they fall under the head of union of labour, of labour in common, or of division of labour/ they all originate in the effort to remove the disproportion perchance existing between the labour to be performed at a given moment and the powers of the individual labourers, and to bring them into agree- ment with each other. They must accordingly react upon the individual in compelling him to adapt, to accommo- date himself mentally and physically to a definite work. In this adaptation certain resistances on the part of human nature are first to be overcome. Once vanquished, how- ever, this negative element is, usually by virtue of con- tinued practice, replaced by a positive one. The individual ' It will assist to an understanding of the present and the two pre- ceding chapters if we present here the various kinds and varieties of labour organization in tabular survey. [Comp. Chapters VII and VIII.— Edu] A. Union of Labour. B. Labour in Common. I C. Diviiion of Labour. • I. Fraternal labour. 3. Labour aggregation. 3. Joint labour. 1. Formation of trades. 2. Specialization. 3. Division of production. 4. Subdivision of work. 5. Displacement of labour. (a) Simple aggre- gation. {t) Concatenation of labour. 3«5 3i6 ORGANIZATION OF H^ORK AND I ^HlfO ■ 1 ^^K,p mi d. i^^E^ '-^ gains insight into the special character of his work; he develops a particular dexterity for it; his mental powers are directed continuously towards the same goal, and therefore expand in a definite direction; in short, his adaptation to the work becomes a part of his being and distinguishes him from other individuals. If, then, the class of work to which the workman de- votes himself be of such a nature as to accentuate the special character of the individual man in society, the question naturally arises, how fai such individual charac- teristics arising from work react upon the social life of the species. More specifically stated, the question would be: Is there a definite organization of society corresponding to a definite organization of work; and what is the nature of the influence exerted by the one upon the other? The question is not so simple as it may perlKips at first sight appear. Nothin/, for instance, seems easier than to trace back the caste system of India to the hereditary character of occupations, and accordingly to seek its origin in division of labour. But we know positively that the lower and the higher castes have different origins; and many indications favour the view that place of resi- dence and possts^ior of property have cooperated in the genesis of that hi -^ecitar- str aification of society. Finally we see that the --^^^f^r^zii^i na nrt- of the caste lay in purity of hiooc and < --oil •rla.!onshi])s. Difference in caste excindt ! eatrair n TEiJincn .-specially, although it does nor ■'crr t< ni; e i-.^^-nTr- a similarity of occupation. Ai; nis ^v«s j^.o«i ir^fiTSL for the assumption that the sepamtim ai-cnrriinir t- ermlovments was only a result of the fn^5??wi iTm- -a^-^ wftidi had ori.^inated in differences in rz^t.- A srniiar course of development can be shown for r-e ssiciai crosses c th* Middle Ages. -^ ~e -^rTTSiSr "sir o:: pp. ;:.4 f?. regarding tribal indus- tries «3vt at the THE FORMATION OF SOCI/tL CLASSES. 317 In considering tlie relations between economic activity and society generally, it is never to be forgotten that they are reciprocal, and that with them we can seldom deter- mine with certainty action and reaction. Just as a particular kind of organization of work, when it lays hold of the individual for life, furnishes specially dif- ferentiated men to society, so society on the other hand has from its stratifications and its individuals to provide the plastic material used by organization of work. Cer- tain strata of society will favour distinct forms of labour in common and division of labour, others will place ob- stacles in the way of their operation. Slavery, for in- stance, encourages the concatenation of labour; the pres- ence of a numerous class of unpropertied wage-workers promotes subdivision of work. But those social influences alone are not able to produce these results; others of a technical and a general civilizing nature must be assumed, for instance, with subdivided labour, a highly specialized equipment of instruments of production. All these relationships are thus of an extraordinarily in- tricate nature and demand the most circumspect treat- ment. As a rule we can tell what features in the economic and social world are found side by side, but it is seldom that we can determine how they are mutually connected. In attempting, then, to discover the social bearings of organization of work in its various forms, we enter a field as yet little investigated, in which each step aside from the path leads into an impenetrable thicket of confused ideas. At first the oldest system of organization of work, union of labour, seems to have been socially unimportant. Its earliest appearance reaches back into the pre-economic period where the individual Jias to perform all the labour necessary to his maintenance. It is to be found more ex- 3i8 ORGANIZATION OF IVORK AND tensively, then, in the earlier stages of independent do- mestic economy. The tools are simple and few, each must serve the most varied purposes, and everyone must be acquainted with their use. From work of such a type the impulse to a division of society, to a formation of re- lations of social dependence, manifestly cannot come. Society, it appears, must consist of a uniform mass of indi- vidual households; and such is its actual constitution as long as collective ownership of the soil prevails. Within the individual households, on the other hand, a separation of male and female work can take place. But this is not transferred to society; each household is in this respect an exact replica of the other. If social differences never- theless exist, their cause is to be sought in other con- ditions. Union of labour maintains this [socially trivial] charac- ter in the higher stages of development even up to the highest. To-day it is met nith almost exclusively in the humbler spheres of economic life and in the lower strata of society. Here it arises in most cases from the striving for independence; it is the support, the stay, and the com- fort of the common folk. Indeed, it can appear here even as recoil from an excessive division of labour.' If it were the sole active factor in the economic life of a people, it would lead to a society of lifeless uniformity and render a successful struggle from the lower to the higher im- possible. With labour in common it is different. To be sure, in its loosest form of fraternal labou»- it exists between equals only temporarily, and therefore can have scarcely any effect upon the organization of society. At the most, it can l)ut suggest it. The two forms of labour aggrega- * Comp. our remarks in the Handwort. d. Staatswiss., IV, p. 377. THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 319 tion, on the contrary, become a means to the formation of special groups; they create and maintain relations of social dependence or, at least, assure their continuance where they have been developed from other causes. The same can be said, although not with equal definiteness, of many forms of union of labour. In both cases cooperation amongst a plurality of persons depends upon the extent of the work to be performed as compared with the im- perfect nature of the tools; and where those tasks are of a permanent nature or, at least, are frequently repeated in any one department of economic labour — for example, in agriculture — they require for their stability permanent social j^roupings secured by some controlling power. On this rests, in large part, the long continuance of slavery and serfdom, although it cannot be said that the necessity for union of labour originally created these in- stitutions. Nevertheless wherever property in man and hereditary dependence of the labouring population have existed, we notice in the early stages that master and slave are distinguished but slightly from one another; that they perform their work together; that the dependent class is, in numbers, hardly stronger, .ndeed often weaker, than the ruling one. But in the course of time this is changed; the enslaved part of the population becomes more numer- ous, though less through natural internal increase than artificial augmentation from without by means of wars of conquest, men-stealing, the slave trade, and misuse of power against weaker freemen. At the same time the class of propertied frc -nen is ever more sharply distin- guished from that of ti unfree; labour becomes in the eyes of the former a disgrace, while for the latter it de- velops into a burden of constantly growing oppressive- ness. A deep gulf rends society, and there is no means of bridging it other than release from the condition ii'ii 320 ORGANIZATION OF U^ORK AND of compulsory labour. Frequently even this does not suffice, as is shown, for instance, by the sharp distinction between freemen and freed men among the Romans. The necessity for this graded progress lies in the tech- nical conditions affecting the developed forms of labour in common. The natural consequence of the imperfect character of the implements * is that larger tasks can be accomplished only through the application of combined human labour on a large scale. Each advance of the household economy thus necessarily presupposes an in- crease in the number of its unfree workers. Each rise in the standard of life of the ruling class involves a waste of human material, which, according to our conceptions, is monstrous. To realize an effective union of labour this material must be organized and disciplined. The necessity of working slaves in gangs has from time immemorial been deduced from their unreliability and lazi- ness which compelled the strict supervision of their work. It is indeed true that these features everywhere character- ize servitude. But not it alone; they are rather phenom- ena incident to a half-developed culture in general, which at such a stage may be found even among free people. Moreover the slave-holder applies the system of division of labour along with labour in common whenever this can result in such an assignment of definite duties to the individual workman that he can be made responsible for the performance of them." But in the sphere of produc- tion the allotment of particular tasks to the individual is usually either impossible or inadvisable, because profitless. 'Comp. also A. Loria, Dit Sklaventuirtkschaft im modem. Amtrika u. im turopiiisck. AUertum, in Ztschr. f. Sozial. u. WirthRchaftsgesch., IV, pp. 68fl. 'This indeed takes place especially with housework and personal •ervicei. See above, pp. 98, 99, 299, 300. THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 321 Thus at this stage we see labour in common assuming extensive proportions and becoming by far the most potent organizing principle of unfree labour. David Hume long since remarked ' that slavery neces- sitated a strict military discipline; and our investigations are corroborative of this observation. In early Egypt " each of the great administrative offices possessed its own craftsmen and workmen. These were divided into bands. We even meet with such a company on the estates of the more prominent men of the ancient empire, and notice how, led by their ensign, they draw up on parade before the lord of the estate. The galley- slaves of every larger ship likewise form a company, and even the demons that nightly propel the ship of the sun through the lower world bear this name. The craftsmen of the temple and of the necropolis are similarly organized. The Egyptian magistrate cannot think of these people of lower rank otherwise than collectively; the individual workman exists for him no more than the individual sol- dier exists for our high army officers. Just as these free or half-f.ee workers always appear in companies, so the slaves of the temple and the necropolis and the unfree peasants of the manors are duly organized in military fashion and regarded as a part of the army." ^ The large Roman slave estates exhibit like phe- nomena. On the rural estates the unfree workers are divided into groups according to their occupation; each group falls again into trains of not more than ten men under a " driver " ; the villicus is commander-in-chief over all. Their day's work is performed with military discip- line; at night they are lodged in barracks. In the wealthiest homes the urban 'imily likewise exhibits such * Essays, p. 252. ' Erman. Aegypten und agyptisckes .ibcn im Altertum, pp. 180-186. 322 ORGANIZATION OF IVORK AND ordered gp'oups; in the Imperial household the separate slave groups are expressly designated colleges or cor- porations.* We see here how the need for labour in common led to permanent organizations among the unfree; and this need was met in the same way by the agriculturalist of later Roman times, by the manorial constitution of the Middle Ages, and by the more modem servile tenure. In each of these the labourers necessary for the large rural estates were united into distinct corporate groups at- tached to the soil, in order that they might always be ready for seed-time and for harvest. One can really say that manorial servitude, attachment to the soil, and per- sonal subjection " owed their ascendancy to the necessity of labour in common, and that their great extension and long duration were conditioned by this necessity. A reaction of labour in common upon the organization of society is thus established beyond doubt, giving it not merely a peculiar socio-judicial impress, but also deeply influencing the mental disposition of the associated work- ers. One of the keenest observers of agrarian conditions in North Germany'** found as a prominent trait in the character of the peasants " that they cling very closely to •Thus mention is made of collegia {corpora) kctkariorum, taber- Hoclariorum, cocorum, pragustatorum, decuriones or prapositi cvbiculario- rum, velariorum, fricliniariorum, structorum, ministratorum, balntariorum, UHctorum, etc. On all this comp. Marquardt, PrivatUben der Romer, pp. 144 ff., 154. The remarks in text do not contradict what was said above on pp. 98, 9Q resarding division of labour in the slave family of the Romans. This sprang from the necessity of having for each piece ol work required by the household a responsible person — not from the knowledge of the greater productivity of divided work — while labour in common had its basis in technical considerations. ' ilorigkeit, SchollenpAichtigkeit. Leibeigenschaft. " Christian Garve, Utber d. Charakter d. Bauern u. ihr Verhattnis gegtn d. Cutskerrn u. gegen d. Rtgierung (Breslau, 1786), pp. 14 ff. THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 323 each other." They live much more sociably among them- selves than the ordinary citizens of the towns. They see each other daily at each piece of demesne work, in summer in the field, in winter in the barn and in the spinning-room. Like soldiers, they constitute a corps, and like them gain an esprit de corps. The same may be said of all unfree conditions; uniformity and the disciplining of work create uniform herd-like masses which become more dull and in- dolent the more hopeless their condition. This explains the small productiveness of their labour, which in turn leads to inhumanly harsh treatment, re- ducing the labourers to the level of the animal. Genera- tion after generation of like labour perpetuates the same way of thinking, the same feelings and sensations towards the oppressors. The ruling race is now markedly distinct, both intellectually and physically, from the subject one, just as the vigorous tree in the forest stands out from the weakling. But in this evolutionary process causes and consequences are confused as in a tangled skein; one perceives only a labyrinth of economic and social factors, acting and reacting, and nowhere a thread to guide with certainty the investigating eye. There are close relation- ships existing between the two spheres; that is all that we can with some measure of assurance determine. The problem offered by the third primal form of or- ganization of labour, division of labour, would seem rela- tively much easier of solution. Moreover, each indi- vidual in the world of to-day has a certain interest in it, inasmuch as he is personally affected by it. For every- one, if he does not wish to be a useless member of society, has to accommodate himself to a particular task; and the more completely he succeeds in this, the more diversified do men themselves become in their every action and thought. 384 ORG/INIZATION OF U^ORK j4ND The German census of occupations of 1895 recorded in all 10,298 distinct trade designations. Now one may as- sume that different names are current for many trades in different parts of the country, and that a deduction is ac- cordingly to be made for double counts. On the other hand, one must also remember that very different kinds of work, especially in the public service and the liberal professions, are designated by the same name, and that the numerous individual tasks which have arisen within the separate industrial undertakings through division of work and which have been transferred to special work- men, can be but imperfectly taken into account in the re- turns. Thus the census figures should rather be increased than reduced. We have thus in round numbers 10,000 kinds of human activity, each of which can become in our modern society a life-work, and subject the whole person- ality to its sway. New special trades, moreover, are being formed con- tinually." Each new process of production, each advance " From 1882 to 1895 the number of trade designations in the Ger- man census of occupations has been increased by 4"9. The returns were as follows: Aceordias to the Ceniui For the CtaM of Occupations. ol OccupmUont lor iWa. •'95* A. Agriculture, gardening, cattle-raising, forestry, fisheries ••••• 35a 465 B. Mining and quarrying industry, and building trades ^,661 5.406 C. Trade and commerce ••• L^is 2,216 D. Domestic services and wagework of varying kind. 75 8i E. Military, court, civil, and ecclesiastical service, liberal professions ^>^T^ *'°79 Total 6.179 10.398 How far this growth in figures is to be traced to an actual increase m trades, how far to greater exactness in statistical census work, cannot be determined. A part of the diflTerence, however, is certainly to be attributed to increasing division of labour. t f THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 3*5 465 5.406 2,216 82 2,079 of technique and science, is subjected to the universal di- vision of labour. Thinking and feeling men are thus forced into the restricted field of trade interests of the narrowest and pettiest sort. The time foreseen by Fer- guson, when even thinking would become a special busi- ness, has long since been reached.'* The scope of uni- versal human interests grows narrower the greater the divergence of the special interests of the numerous spheres in life from one another, and the greater the severity of the struggle for existence. The differences among men due to nature and culture without doubt assist this divergence in the most varied spheres of life; yet, in our opinion, this is true to a much smaller extent than is frequently assumed. Of course, as everyone knows, a jockey must differ from a carrier, a brewer from a tailor, a dancer from a singer, a poet from a merchant, if he is to be competent for his vocation. But what natural talents cause one man to appear destined to be an inspector of diseased meat, another a bookbinder, and a third a chiropodist, hosiery Vianufacturer, or tobac- conist, will likely be as difficult to fix as to determine beforehand the success of a particular individual in any given liberal profession. Although, then, many classes of occupations are adapted to bringa particular talent to the highest develop- ment, with many others the presence of such a talent will he of no perceptible importance. All, however, through continuous practice and use, will produce a certain differentiation of the men devoting themselves to them; " Most notoriously in politics, where the majority of men procure their ideas ready made from some newspaper editorial. But also to no inconsiderable degree in scientific circles, where on this account the last is always right; for example, the reviewer of a book over the au- thor. ■-,Wi 3a6 ORGANIZATION OF WORK AND . I certain organs will become enfeebled through lack of use, while others, through constant exercise, will be developed to greater perfection; according to his task the individual will be attuned physically, intellectually, and morally, to a definite key; through his occupation he will be given a particular impress which will often be even externally dis- cernible. This we all recognise when we come into con- tact with strangers and involuntarily classify them to our- selves according to callings. With this personal differentiation, however, the eco- nomic graduation is transferred also to society at large. Similar occupations and views of life, similar economic position and social habit lead to a new distribution of social groups. They produce classes based on occupation and a community of interests which dominate them even in their most minute social ramifications, and are strong enough to cover up inherited diflferences in position due to birth, or to reduce them to insignificance. We have even seen how these new social aggregations reach out beyond the political boundaries, and how the social interests and feelings of kinship resting on di- vision into trades overtop those of nationality based upon similarity of blood. Under these circumstances we may raise the question, which recent biology has brought into close connection: whether, and to what extent, in a society with free choice of occupation, the personal variations developed through division of labour are hereditary, just as under the system of castes and of classes according to birth such peculiar- ities are transmissible. In this it is not merely a question of natural capacities which may be utilized in one's occu- pation and in which the possibility of hereditary transmis- sion — though not more — is readily admitted. It is a question rather of tlic whole physic.il and mental aptitude THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 327 for a vocation, of the skill gained through accommodating oneself to a circumscribed task, of the intellectual plane consequent upon such work, of the conception of life, and the direction of the mind resulting from the character of one's vocation. From the latter point of view, ever since Shakespeare's " Winter's Tale," the problem has frequently been treated in literature. Generally this has been done by making educational influences that counteract upon the character and social position of the parents determine events. Views as to the issue havt greatly changed in the course of the last century. It would certainly be a profitable undertaking for a literary historian to take up this prob- lem of education and heredity, and investigate more closely the dependence of literature upon the spirit of the times and upon the position in life of the writers.*^ While Lindau in Countess Lea makes the daughter of the usurer develop, in spite of the paternal education, into a paragon of nobleness, in a story by Arsene Houssaye (Les trots Duchesses), of three children interchanged directly after birth, the son of the peasant woman remains peasant in understanding and in way of thinking, although edu- cated as a prince; the daughter of the frivolous actress becomes a courtesan, and the daughter of the duchess, even in humble surroundings, displays the native eleva- tion of her character. The question has also been touched upon in numerous ways in more serious literature. But a short time ago W. H. Riehl, in his Culturgeschichtliche Characterk'dpfe, drew a contrast between the " peasant youngsters with limited capabilities " who had graduated from the gym- "The latest treatment of this subject is to be found in Ludwig Ganghofer's tale, Der Klosttrj'dger (Stuttgart, 1893). It is exception- ally healthy and subtle. " IF Si I; 1:11 iil Hit 3a8 ORGANIZATION OF tyORK AND nasium with highest standing and the " intellectually highly trained sons of cultured parents," between whom, class for class, there arises an insurmountable wall. The former, he believes, would develop at the university into mediocre students, whom the " cultured son of cultured parents," if he went to the university at all, would soon overtake. Finally the former peasant youth becomes " a very mediocre though clerically efficient civil servant." What becomes of the son of the cultured parents, " who has already been favoured by the manifold educational in- terests of his parents' home," we are, unhappily, not in- formed. The first to discuss the subject with a claim of strict scientific treatment,^* which, to be sure, is not made in the above case, was Professor Gustav Schmoller, who, in a very confident manner, rendered his decision that " the adaptation of individuals to various activities, increased through heredity during centuries and thousands of years, has produced men of ever more individual and diverse types." All higher social organizations, it is claimed, rest upon continued differentiation produced by division of labour. " The castes, the aristocracies of priests, of warriors, of traders, the guild system, the whole constitu- tion of labour to-day are but forms diflfering according to the times, which division of labour and differentiation "Schmoller has objected to this expression in his review of my book in Jhrb. f. Gesetzg. Verw. und Volksw., XVII (1893). pp. 303 ff He desires to have his remarks regarded as but " a kind of essay in philosophical history." I can perceive in this characterization no re- pugnancy to the expression used by myself. Nor can I discover that the further remarks of Schmoller in the paper cited have furnished proof that I have misunderstood him in essential points. I believe, therefore, that I am acting most correctly in allowing the following remarks to appear again word for word as they stood in the first edi- tion, and in directing the attention of the reader to Schmoller's re- marks on the same in the article indicated. I'i THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 329 have imprinted upon society; and each individual has ar- rived at his peculiar function not merely through indi- vidual adroitness and fate, but also through his physical and mental disposition, his nerves, and his muscles, which rest upon hereditary tendencies and are determined by a causal chain of many generations. The differences in social rank and property, in social esteem, and in income are only a secondary consequence of social differentiation." ^' One will perhaps expect that the proof for these sur- prising sentences has been attempted with the help of biology. But, aside from cursory reference to biological analogies, that path is avoided. Yet it would certainly have been useful to pursue it further, because it must have led inevitably to a point where the conception of heredity must needs have been defined and its sphere marked off from that of imitation and education." On this account we also will have to avoid this path, and enter upon an examination of the elaborate historical and ethnographical material that Schmoller adduces for his assertions. Such historical proofs are of a nature peculiar to them- selves. To the eye of one gazing backwards things get shifted from their proper place. Cause and effect appear equally near in point of time. One finds oneself in a posi- " Comp. Schmoller's articles on the division of labour in his Jhrb., XIII, pp. 1003-1074; XIV, pp. 45-105; and a short summary of his conclusions in the Preuss. Jhrb., LXIX, p. 464. [See further his Grundriss, pp. 395-411— Ed.]. " Such an attempt, though indeed with but meagre results, is to be found in Felix, Entwickelungsgesch. d. Eigenlhums, I, pp. 130 flf. Among the more recent biologists this point in the problem of heredity i» really no longer a matter of controversy; especially Weismann (The Germ-plasm, Eng. ed., London. 1893) has decidedly contested the trans- missibility of acquired characteristics. Comp. also Galton, A Theory of Heredity, in Journal of Anthropolog. Institute, V, pp. 329 ff.; James, The Principles of Psychology, II, 678. 33° ORG/INIZATIOS OF IVORK AND tion similar to that of the man who looks away into ti:« distance and sees a church steeple that really rises far behind a group of houses apparently standing directly over the nearest building. After a similar fashion, we fear, SchmoUer in the critical instances of his comprehensive investigations has viewed the causal relationship of the historical processes in an in- verted succession as regards reality. So far as th' ^e are occurrences that do not reach back into epochs be- yond the range of historical investigation, such as the origin of castes, of the priesthood, of the oldest nobility, we would venture to believe that one might unhesitatingly reverse his surprising conclusion and say: the diversity of possession and of income is not the result of division of labour, but its chief cause. For the past, in so far as it lies open to our eyes, this can be demonstrated with absolute certainty. Inequality in the extent and tenure of landed property forms among the ancient Greeks and Romans, and even among our own people from the early Middle Ages onward, the basis of class organization. The noble, the peasant class, the class of villeins and serfs are at first mere classes based on prop- erty; it is only after a considerable time that they de- velop into a species of classes based on occupation." When in the Middle Ages along with the rise of the crafts- man class the definite formation of trades sets in, it pro- ceeds again from distribution of property. The demesne servants, the landless villeins who h^ve learned an indus- trial art, begin to turn their industrial skill to independent account. The industrial process followed must adapt itself to their poverty; it is pure wage-work, in which th" work- "The presence of the unpropertied noble in the service of others (Dienstadef) is a proof, not against, but for, this conception. It would be inconceivable that the landed noble had not preceded him. 'H 1 THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 33» man receives the raw material from the customer. Only later do we have a real division of production between agriculturalist and craftsman. The latter acquires a busi- ness capital of his own. But how trifling this is, is best indicated by the circumstance that, as a rule, the crafts- man works only on ordered piece-work, and that the whole industrial process for liansforming the raw into the finished product Hes usually in one hand." The industrial undertakings were exclusively small undertakings. Where the great extent of the sphere of production of a handi- craft called for an increased supply of ccpital, men did not turn to production on a large scale with subdivisi' n of work, but to specialization which limited the demanc for capital and kept the business small. As one observes, each step taken by mediava! division of labour in industry was conditioned by the possession of wealth. It is the same with trade. The tradinp^ c isi of the Middle Ages is derived from the class of ur m land- owners, who had become, through the introduction of rents on houses and the practice of rent-purchase>, pos- sessors of movable capital. It is from this class c' • )ck- holders and tradesmen that the present manufacturing class has sprung since the seventeenth century. T) rough "The longer the duration of the process of production th- aller the business capital that the single producer requires, but th. gr -ater the mass of labour which the completed product contains In he Middle Ages, to cite a very familiar example, the shoemaker w.. re- quently tanner as well. The whole process of industrial elaboration from the raw hide to the finished footwear thus lay in one hand. Ai suniing new that the tanning of the hide required 'lalf ihe time tha- was necessary to its transformation into shoewarc, a shoenr kcr d' siring to carry on tanning alone would have required thrte limes much business capital as the tanner who at the same time mad, sho But if he wished merely to make up into shoes leather already tanned, his business capital must amount to one and a Naif times the former, together with w.iges and profits. ..tJ ! I' 33J ORGANIZATION OF IVORK AND the fertilizing of industry with their capital, the two new forms of division of labour— subdivision and displacement of labour— arise, and the division of production for the first time realizes its full efficiency. Half-manufactured products now wander in masses from workshop to workshop; in each place they become capital, in each they yield a return; from one department of pro- duction to another fresh outlays in interest and other charges are added, and through them profits on cap;- tal are made.*» Subdivision of labour presupposes a class of non-propertied wage-workers. This class comes from that section of the aftsmen who, through the capi- talistic character assume*, ay division of labour, have be- come incapable of competing, and from the landless peasant population. In industry, indeed, the dependence of division of labour upon possession of property becomes especially manifest. In the Middle Ages each advance of industrial division of labour augmented the number of urban " livelihoods," because it diminished the business capital; at the present time the progress of division of labour diminishes the num- ber of independent existences since it increases either the fixed or the business capital, or both. In the Middle Ages the effort was made to keep each industrial product as long as possible in one establishment in order to embody in it as much labour as was feasible; nowadays, by di- vision of work, the business capital is carried with the utmost rapidity through the separate stages of production in order to make the relation between interest expended and profit realized the most favourable possible. In the "The connection of capital with division of labour has been pre- sented in a masterly manner by Rodbertus (Aus d. lilttf. ^<"*'f *■ "• pp. 255 flf.); but in this he has not adequately distinguished the dif- ferent kinds of division of labour. THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 333 Middle Ages dearth of capital led to specialization; in our time abundance of capital imnels to subdivision of work and displacement of labour. Thus from the varied distribution of property have the general features of our organization of society according to occupation been developed historically; and on this foundation, which our present industrial organization is ever strengthening and solidifying, they continue to rest. The latter is explained very simply from the following cir- cumstance: I. Every vocation under our industrial or- ganization yields an income; and only the propertied per- son is in a situation to seek out for himself the more lucra- tive positions within the universal organization of labour, while the unpropertied person must be content with the inferior positions."" 2. Property itself, by virtue of its cap- italistic nature, furnishes an income to its owner, even without work on his part, and transmits itself from gen- eration to generation with this capability. In so far as our propertied classes are also social classes according to occupation, they are not such because their cccupation creates property, but rather because property determines the selection of a vocation, and because as a rule the in- come that the calling yields is graded much the same way as the property on which the vocation is founded. True, there is no novelty in this statement. Each of us acts conformably to this view. Daily experience readily suggests it; and scientific political economy has always recognised it. The whole wage-theory il'.elf rests on the assumption that the son of the workman can become nothing else than a workman. This is a conse- •• This means, then. " that those whom poverty drives to seek a profitable vocation are compelled by their very poverty to abandon that vocation." Lotmar, Di* FrrihtH d. BtrufswaU (Leipzig. 1898). p. 27- liiil; ! I'lii: ■if 334 ORGylNIZylTION OF fVORK AND quence of his poverty, not of hereditary adaptation to his trade. Must one then really prove now for the first time that occupations whose inception and conduct re- quire capital, or whose acquisition demands large outlays, are as good as closed to those without capital? The much-boasted " freedom of enterprise " thus exists only within very narrow limits. In very exceptional cases these indeed are now and then transgressed; but as a rule it is not the particular vocation, but rather the general vocational class ^* to which the individual is to belong in society that is indicated for each person by the wealth of the paternal house. The " social rank " that in popular estimation is enjoyed by a particular class, however, can hardly be maintained without corresponding financial equipment — a proof that it also is not a secondary conse- quence of social differentiation (resting upon division of labour), but essentially a child of the rational union of wealth and vocation. No matter how many vocational classes may be dis- tinguished in society, occupations of very diverse charac- ter will still be represented in each, and between these callings a rontinuous exchange of labour will take place. This exchange extends as far as the classes of work de- mand approximately the same equipment of wealth, and as far. therefore, as they stand in the same " social rank "; one might also say that it extends as far as people marry among each other, or regularly associate with one an- other, or as there is approximately the same plane of cul- ture. All these things stand together in a mutual rela- tionship. It is an every-day occurrence for a high public " On this concept, in which we attempted to express the reciprocally conditioned existence of property and vocation lonR before we were ac(iuainted with Schmoller's wot';, compare my Btvolktnmg d. Kantons Bastl-Sladt, p. 70. THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 335 I I 1- official to destine his son for agriculture in order, later on, to purchase him an estate, for the son of a large land- holder or manufacturer to enter upon an academic career, for the son of a clergyman to become a civil engineer, the son of the engineer a physician, the son of the physi- cian a merchant, the son of the merchant a lawyer or an architect. Just as easy and frequent is the transition from peasant to schoolmaster or to brewer, from baker to watchmaker, from blacksmith to bookbinder, from miner to factory-hand, from farm-hand to station-hand or coach- man, etc. We all look upon these transitions, in spite of the great diflferences in labour skill, as socially proper and industrially unobjectionable, although there can hardly be men " differentiated " more widely through division of labour than a statesman and a farmer, a manufacturer and a professor, a merchant and an architect, and so forth. When the son of the manufacturer in turn becomes manufacturer, and the son of the peasant again a peasant, we know that in many cases the financial means once consonant with this vocation have dictated the occupation without regard to the fitness or unfitness of the individual for the role thrust upon him. This glance at practical life must restrain us from con- ceiving in too narrow a sense Schmoller's theory oi .h hereditary transmission of personal differentiation conse- quent upon division of labour. That the son of the shoe- maker by virtue of inherited adaptation should be in a better position to produce shoes than, let us say, picture- frames; that the clergytnan's son. tliough his father had been taken from him on the <lay i)f his birth, will, of all classes of occupation, exhil)it the greater natural aptitude for the clerical calling, cannot possibly be meant by that theory, even if in the last-mentioned case the forefathers of the clergyman during the previous two centuries had ^ ntf^ it 336 ORGANIZATION OF (VORK AND handed down the spiritual office to each other from gen- eration to generation. For if we hold strictly to the bi- ological idea the adaptation to occupation would neces- sarily increase from age to age, and reveal itself in continually improving performance of duties. It will, however, hardly be seriously maintained that the numer- ous clerical families of Protestant Germany, who are in the position just described, furnish to-day relatively better pulpit speakers and more efficient pastors than in the seventeenth century. In the domain of the guild handicraft of our towns, in consequence of the jealous exclusiveness of the different trades, the positions of master-craftsmen, with but few ex- ceptions, have been actually passed down from father to son from the sixteenth to the eighteenth century. The technique, however, not only has not improved, but has lamentably degenerated, and now languishes, as Schmol- ler himself m an earlier treatise has shown.** Far from augmenting the technical acquisitions of their fathers, the sons have not even been able to maintain the standard of professional aptitude reached by them. We must therefore look upon the new theory, if we would not be unjust to it, as referring to the inheritance of bodily and intellectual characteristics by the members of social classes grouped according to occupation. But these classes arc, as a rule, likewise based upon property and income, since the standard of their life, both material and intellectual, is conditioned by property and income. Ac- cordingly one must demand of the originator of the the- ory to distinguish between the consequence of the charac- ter of sustenance and education rendered possible for each class by the possession of wealth, and the result of heredi- "Znr Gfsck. d. deutsch. Kkingeucrhr im 19 Jhdt.. pp. 14. 667 AF. THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 337 i -i ■i I % I tary adaptation to occupation. If such a distinction of the probable and possible causes is not undertaken, or if without examination there is ascribed to division of labour that which can be traced back with greater probability to the apportionment of wealth, the whole theory must be content in its undeniable weakness in " historical proof " to be treated as an inexact Darwinian analogy, as a thesis advanced without proof. That within a whole social class of this kind a trans- mission of the " bodily and intellectual constitution," of the " nerves and muscles " takes place from one genera- tion to another no one has as yet doubted. One may in- deed term this heredity, but in this he must not overlook that each fresh generation must be raised through theo- retical and practical education to the inte'lectual and moral level of the parents. Though in this the elements of culture " fly to " them, to use Riehl's expressive phrase,^' though the example of their surroundings in- cites them to imitation, though much is appropriated without trouble which under other conditions must first be learned with effort, it is still a question of the acquired, not of the innate. This holds to a certain extent even of the bodily constitution — the "nerves and muscles" — so far as it rests upon the character of sustenance and edu- cation.'^ Elements of adaptation to a vocation can certainly be transferred by the indicated paths of " unconscious ab- " AnHiegtn. "Schiiffle, Bau u. Lthen d. sot. Korpers (i. Aufl.), II, p. aoi, desig- nates that the physical side of pedagogy. He says: "The physical education of each new generation and its schooling in the external graces of the parents or ancestors cotnes as an immense additional task to the procreative activity of the sexes. ... In this second act physical adaptations are obtained that were unknown to the parents themselves." * li ' ii 338 ORGANIZATION OF WORK AND sorption " and imitation, just as well as other elements of education. But this process is fundamentally different from inheritance in the biological sense.'^" That which in this sense is said to be hereditary must make its appear- ance even when the offspring are completely removed at the moment of birth from the influence of their pro- genitors. We know not whether there are people who consider the physical and intellectual peculiarities constituting the plane of culture of our six or eight vocational classes in society as transmissable in the sense that they must ap- pear among the descendants of each class even when brought up within another class. It is only individual in- stances of this kind that practical life is ever presenting; and as yet no one has taken the trouble to collect them. They are generally cases of children of the humbler classes who are brought up or formally adopted by members of a higher class. There will scarcely be anyone bold enough to maintain that these persons, artificially united to social groups of higher rank, are later on distinguishable from the members of these groups by birth by reason of less business ability or of a lower plane of culture. A further series of observations of this nature is offered by the instances in which descendants of one class have by their own energy raised themselves into a higher class. Everyone knows what difticulties the era of capitalistic production opposes to such an attempt, and frequently only too successfully. Everyone, too, can readily call up the picture of the " upstart " who, with all the technical "This latter is the real question with Schmollcr, as he plainly indi- cates in Preuss. Jhrb.. Vol. 69. p. 464- The sociological conception of inheritance which Schaffle has constructed in works cited (II. pp. 308 ff.) is not treated l>y Schtnolltr, tiiongli many of his remarks re- call it. THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 339 ability he shows for his trade, is defeated in his effort to reach the intellectual and moral level of his new class. This serves again to illustrate the truth that the adapta- tion to an occupation enjoined by division of labour — the prime condition of business success — is accomplished by each individually, and without too much difficulty. But the moral and intellectual adaptation demanded by the plane of culture of the class ripens slowly even amid favourable surroundings, and comes to full maturity only in the second or third generation. A strict proof of the fallacy of SchmoUer's theory of heredity cannot be adduced; but the proofs hitherto advanced in favour of its accuracy fall equally short of conclusiveness. Before venturing to dogmatize one would perhaps have to pass in review the great men of a nation and note the vocations of their parents, and the number who have issued from classes of humble occupa- tion. At the same t-me one would need to determine for the dififerent classes the degree of probability of their members attaining a prominent position in which they alone could display high ability. Finally one would have to ascertain what relation the number of promi- nent men who have actually come forth from any given class of tradesmen bears to the number obtained by the calculation of probabilities. It does not need to be demon- strated that for such an investigation all the data are lack- ing. But it may be maintained that the new theory contra- dicts the belief of modern civilized people based, as it is, upon the observation of many generations. How often the complaint is made that so much talent pines under the weight of adversity? If to this dictum we oppose the other that real talent will always find a way, wc may indeed offer a formula to (latter the egoism i1^: .: i i 340 ORG/tNlZATION OF fVORK AND of successful competitors, though in reality it meets all too rarely with confirmation. Our whole socio-juridical development since the French Revolution is based on the assumption that admission to every free calling and to all public offices, which latter, after all, we still regard as tJie pinnacle of class divisions, shall be free to all. This principle of free choice of voca- tion, whose recognition has been gained only after severe struggles, would be a great mistake, and every endeavour towards its realization lost labour, if beside the inequality in distribution of wealth the hereditability of vocational aptitudes likewise stood in the way of its establishment. Even many of our oldest academic arrangements must, in the light of this theory, necessarily appear funda- mentally erroneous. To what a high degree the costli- ness of preparation narrows admission to the favoured positions of the business world is well known. From time immemorial, however, a great peril to the efficiency of the official and the scholastic class has likewise been per- ceived; and an effort has been made to obviate this danger through scholarships, free board, remission of fees, and similar arrangements for rendering study possible to those without means. The practical results of these arrange- ments may be a subject of dispute. Yet in judging them it is essential to remember that advancement in the voca- tion enjoying popular esteem depends not only upon per- sonal integrity, but also upon the social education of the individual, upon his ability to make his own strength felt; that in this imperfect world even the capable man who too modestly holds back may all too easily be outdistanced by the mediocre man who is boldly self-assertive; that he who seeks to climb the social ladder from the lower rungs will find it much more difficult to reach the top than the man who starts halfway up. The German language has an THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 341 expression for denoting distinction in a line of business which happily characterizes the importance of the personal element in the achievement of success. It is sich hervortlnin [literally, to do oneself forwardj. Thus it may indeed be that the student sons of the peasant in Riehl's story failed to distinguish themselves in their vocations because they lacked capacity. It is none the less true that many of them missed success because they did not know how to " do themselves forward " in the right place, how to bring their personality into play. , In every social grouping in which the occupation exerts an influence there is generally formed within the different classes a community of feeling that turns instinctively against the intruder, and in spite of all his talent frequently dooms him to failure; while, on the other hand, it supports and carries along weaklings belonging by birth to the group in question. Thus, as concerns advancement in the public service, which still bears in a preeminent degree the sign manual of a class characterized purely by its voca- tion, personal and family connections often play, along with financial standing, a decisive part. Where these become a cloak for nepotism they can indeed impress upon it the characteristics of an hereditary class. In the broad realm of labour, organized according to occupation and extending beyond it, property will indeed remain, as long as the present economic system lasts, the prime cause of social class-formation. And just such an accessory im- portance as fell in the stages of unfree labour to com- munity of labour, will here attach to division of labour. If the employment is inherited it is not because the adapta- tion to the vocation has been inherited, but because the property is transmitted by which membership in it is con- ditioned. The above theory of heredity consequently bears. :ilr mi i ;i ■ m '" "1 f 342 ORGANIZATION OF f^ORK AND though certainly unknown to its originator, the cheerless lineaments of a social philosophy of beati poss^dentes It calls to the man of humble birth who hinks he has m hmi the power to occupy a higher position in life: Abandon all hope- your physical and intellectual constitution, your nerves, your muscles, the causal chain of many genera- tions, hold you fast to the ground. For centuries your ancestors have been serfs; yoar father and grandfather were day-labourers, and you are destined for a l>ke posi- tion " We need not recite how the consequences of this new theory do violence to our moral consciousness, to our ideal of social justice. In the ^tate of improved thesis in which it at present stands, the theory, in our opinion, falls to the ground from the very fact that, as is frequently enough observed, in a single generation the whole road from zero to the highest point of modem culture, from the lowest to the highest stage of division of labour, from the foot to the summit of the social ladder is traversed, and vice versa. One must indeed wonder that such a theory could originate among a people who count among their intellectual heroes a Luther the son of a miner, a Kant the son of a saddler, a Fichte the son of a poor village weaver, a Winckelmann the son of a cobbler, a Gauss the son of a gardener, not to mention many others." , .u 1 j There is an old anecdote of a cardinal whose father had -Valerius Maximus wrote a chapter (III, 4). de humililoconatis, aui clari evaserunt, that begins thus: " Sxpe even.t ut et hum.l. loco Tati ad summam dignitatem consurgant et generosiss.marum 'naagmum foetus in aliquod revoluti dedecus acceptam a majonbus lucem in tenebras convertant."-In the most recent presentat.on of h.s theory, which shows considerable modification, (Grundnss. pp. 396ff..) SchmoUer rests the fact "that talents and great "^e", ^"^^ f^^") ^' classes of a generally hishb cultured -rtety ' upon thf peculiar .« fiuences of variation." But this explains nothmg. THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 343 -A tended swine, and a French ambassador filled with the pride of noble birth. In a difficult negotiation in which the cardinal represented the interests of the church with adroitness and tenacity the ambassador was so carried away that he taunted the other with his origin. The cardinal answered: " It is true that my father tended swine; but if your father had done so, you would be tend- ing them too." This little story has perhaps expressed better than a long disquisition could have done what the observation of many generations has established: that the virtues by which the fathers rise are as a rule not handed down to grandson and great grandson; that even if the occu- pation is inherited, the ability to carry it on disappears. Each aristocracy, be it aristocracy of property or of occu- pation, degenerates in the course of time like the plant growing in too fertile soil. In this it is not at all necessary to think of a moral decay; it suffices if the physical and in- tellectual powers decline, and procreation grows weak. The introduction of uncorrupted blood, ascending from the lower to the higher vocations, appears then a condition fundamental to the healthy exchange of social material. The great problem of the century, indeed, we have always considered to be the ensuring that a gradual rise in the so- cial scale is made pjossible; that a continuous regeneration of the higher vocational classes takes place. -• the caste system, which would be a necessary consequence of the theory of heredity, we have ever seen the beginning, not the end of the progress of civilization. We will not allow ourselves to be led astray in this con- ception. The solution of the problem just mentioned is for modern civilized peoples a question of their very ex- istence. For if history has taught anything with insistence it is, that for a people that can no longer bt renewed I SI hi 344 tyORK AND SOCIAL CLASSES. from the fresh spring of pure physical and intellectual strength flowing in the lower classes, the statement once made by B. G. Niebuhr with regard to England and Hol- land holds good: the marrow has departed fvoi;' their bones, they are doomed to inevitable decay. "Ml I ,.'! CHAPTER X. INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE GROWTH OF TOWNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. All prehistoric investigation, as far as it relates to the pJienomena of the animate world, necessarily rests upon the hypothesis of migration. The distribution of plants, of the lower animals and of men over the surface of the earth; the relationships existing between the different languages, religious conceptions, myths and legends, cus- toms and social institutions; all these seem ir this one assumption to find their common explanation. In the history of mankind we have, to be sure, aban- doned the view that nomad life is to be regarded as a universal phase in the r rowth of civilization, which each people necessarily traversed before making fix'^ settle- ments, and which served, along with the taming of domestic animals, as the " natural " pathway of a people passing from the hunting stage to agriculture. Ethno- graphic research has made it sufficiently clear that all primitive peoples, whatever the economic foundations of their existence, readily, often, indeed, for very insig- nificant reasons, shift their habitations, and that they exhibit an extraordinary number of stages intermediate between nomadic and settled life.' The northern and southern limits of the inhabited world are stiU peopled Comp. Z. Dimti off. Die Geringschatsung d. menscklichcn Lebens u. ihre Ursathen bei d. Naturvclk. (Leipzig, 1891), pp. 33 ff. 345 u 346 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE by races without fixed abode; and even in its midst there are broad areas in which a condition of continual migra- tion prevails. Most civilized peoples have proverbs or other historic bequests from such a time. In the German language this far-distant period of univer- sal mobility has left distinct traces. The word for " healthy" {gcsnnd) meant originally " ready for the road." « Gesmde, signifying to-day household servants, is, in the olden speech, a travelling retinue; companions (Gcfdhrtc and Gefdhrtin) means, in the strictly literal sense, the fellow- traveller. Ertahrmg (experience) is what one has ob- tained on the journey {fahmi); and bcwandcrt (skilled) is applied to the person who has wandered much. With these the list of such expressions is far from ex hausted. In the general significance attached to them to-day the universality of the concrete range of concep- tions and observations from which v ey originally sprang finds expression. It is natural to suppose that this condition of general nomadic wandering, with its deep-rooted nomadic cus- toms, did not suddenly cease; that, in all probability, the wiiolc course of further development down to our own day has been a gradual progress towards a settled condi- tion and an ever-closer attachment of the man to the spot wner* he was born. Various indications support this view. Among our forefathers the house is reckoned movable property; and it is demonstrable that many settlements have within historic times changed their locations. Despite the lack of artificial roads and comfortable means of transporta- tion.the individual appears in the Middle Ages much more migratory than ac a later time. This is supported by the * [From sendtn, meaning to go, to travel.— Ed.1 GROIVTH OF TOH^NS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 347 numerous pilgrimages that extended as far as St. lago, in Spain, by the crusades, by the great bands of travellers, the migratory life of king and court, the rights of hospi- tality of the marquisates and the developed system of escorts. Each fresh advance in culture commences, so to speak, with a new period of wandering. The most primitive agri- culture is nomadic, with a yearly abandonment of the cul- tivated area; the earliest trade is migratory trade; the first industries that free themselves from the household husbandry and become the special occupations of separate individuals are carried on itinerantly. The great founders of reHgion, the earliest poets and philosophers, the musi- cians and actors of past epochs are all great wanderers. Even to-day, do not the inventor, the preacher of a new doctrine, and the virtuoso travel from place to place in search of adherents and admirers — notwithstanding the immense recent development in the means of communi- cating information? As civilization grows older, settlement becomes more permanent. The Greek was more settled than the Phoe- nician, the Roman than the Greek, because one was al- ways the inheritor of the culture of the other. Conditions have not changed. The German is more migratory than the Latin, the Slav than the (Jernian. The Frenchman cleaves to his native soil; the Russian leaves it with a light heart to seek in other parts of his broad Fatherland more favourable conditions of living. Even the factory work- man is but a periodically wandering peasant. To all that can be adduced from experience in support of the statement that in the course of history mankind has been ever growing more settled, there comes a gen- eral consideration of a twofold nature. In tlie first place the extent of fixed capital g'ows with advancing culture; » \ 348 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE the producer becomes stationary with his means of pro- duction. The itinerant smith of the souther Slav coun- tries and the Westphalian ironworks, the pack-horses of the Middle Ages and the great warehouses of our cities, the Thespian carts and the resident theatre mark the starting and the terminal points of this evolution. In the second place the modern machinery of transportation has in a far higher degree facilitated the transport of goods than of persons. The distribution of labour de- termined by locality thereby attains greater importance than the natural distribution of the means of production; the latter in many cases draws the former after it, where previously the reverse occurred. To these statements there are, of course, some consider- ations and facts opposed. First, the extent to which man was by law tied to the soil in the earlier agrarian period — the unfree nature of all his economic and legal relation- ships in contrast with the modern freedom of person and property. Further, and in part as a result of this, we have in modem times the entire dependence of many individuals upon movable capital or personal skill. Still further, the growing ease of transfer of landed property which to-day allows the peasant to convert house and land into money and on the other side of the ocean to start life anew; while the villein of the Middle Ages could at most attach himself as an c.xtra-nuiral citizen to a ncigli- bouring town whence he either contiimed to carr>- on his work in the village personally, or leased it in some form or other to a second person for a yearly rent. Finally. the increase one observes in the flow of rural popula- tion to the to\<ns which has been manifesting itself for half a centurv in a remarkably rapid rise in nrhan. and at some pc^ints in a stationary or even declining rural, poi)ulation. \\ itli .ill these circuinstatv> ?s in mind, many GROIVTH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 349 consider themselves justified in speaking of the steadily advancing mobility of society. How are these two series of phenomena to be recon- ciled? Is it a question of two principles of development mutually opposed? Or is it possible that modern migra- tions and those of past centuries are of essential!} diflferent types? One would almost be inclined to believe the latter The migrations occurring at the opening of the history of European peoples are migrations of whole tribes, a push- ing and pressing of collective units from east tc; west which lasted for centuries. The migrations of the Middle Ages ever affect individual classes alone; the knights in the crusades, the merchants, the wage craftsmen, the journey- men hand-workers, the jugglers and minstrels, the villeins seeking protection within the walls of a town. Modern migrat'ons, on the contrary, are generally a matter of pri- vate concern, the individuals being led by the most varied motives. They are almost invarialily without organiza- tion. The process repeating itself daily a thousand times is united only throu}^!-]! the one characteristic, that it is everywhere a question of change of locality by per- sons seeking more favourable conditions of life. Yet such a distinction would not be fully in accord with the nature of either modern or media-val migrations. If we would grasp their true importance in historical evolu- tion we must fust thin out the tangled thicket of con- fused contemporar) opinions that still surrounds the whole subject ilespite all the ctTorts of statistics and politi- cal economy. Among all the phenomena of masses in sticial life suited to statistical treatment there is without tloubt scarcely one that appears to fall of itself so complett'Iy under the general law of causality as migrations; and likeuisc hardly til 1' ' !" ^1 350 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE one concerning whose real cause such misty conceptions prevail. Yet, not merely in popular circles and in the press, but even in scientific works, migratory instincis are spoken of; and thus those movements of men from place to place are put without the pale of deliberate action. Indeed, a statis- tician once entitled an article in the Journal of the Prus- sian Statistical Bureau of 1873 "The Affection for the Homestead and the Migratory Instinct of the Prussian People," just as if home-keeping depended merely upon natural disposition, and the abandoning of it upon an irresistible instinctive impulse stronger with one race than another! In strange contradiction to this, to be sure, is the fact that while the great bulk of official statistical compila- tions remains unheeded by wider circles, the publication of the emigration returns generally excites a most active expression of public opinion. The rising and faUing of the figures bring fear and hope, approbation and disapproba- tion, editorial leaders and speeches in Parliament. Here naturally we hear less about migrator>- instincts and the love of home; people have avague feeling that behind those Huctuating phenomena stand very concrete causes. Cut how little they comprehend the nature of these causes is evident when we recall, for example, that a few years ago it was a matter of grave debate in the (lerman Reichs- tag whether people emigrated because they were getting along well or because they were not. With regard to this jjfoblem one cannot say that as yet statistics have succeeded in escaping from the turbid -waters of confuse<l popular opinions to the firm conclti- sions of exact observation. From the statistical stand- point migration is above all an economic and social phe- nomenon of masse>^; .iiul stritistin;.ns. in our opinion, have W^. awngyami lji.i: >*«» . GROU^TH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 35 » been precipitate in abandoning the attempt to discover with their peculiar machinery the causes of these migra- tions and turning to investigation by inquiry before the resources of the statistical method were exhausted. A perusal of the perfunctory remarks that Quetelet' devotes to the phenomenon of emigration will readily con- vmce anyone that his exposition of the subject hardly rises above the prosaic commonplace. True, one finds on go- ing through the official publications of recent date that detailed systematic interrogations on the " causes " and " grounds " of emigration, which would not even perplex the less intelligent of the communal officials consulted, are by no means infrequent. But one immediately feels that such suggestive (|uestions mean the substitution of a series of subjective presumptions for the objective results of in- vestigation. Before resorting, however, to a means of information that reads into the numbers only a strained interpre- tation not following of itself, we should rather tr>' to determine the phenomena of migrations themselves. We should classify them according to numerical regu- larity, and connect them with other mass-phenomena of difTerent times and places accessible to statistics (for ex- ample, the density of population, its division into trades, the .listrihution oi landed property, the rate of labour wages, the oscillation in food prices); that is, undertake the statistical experiment of drawing up parallel lines of isolated series of figures. From even these first steps on the road to an exact method we are. however, still far removed. The whole de- partment of migrations has never yet undergone system- atic statistical observation; exclusive attention has hith- • D« systime social ft des lots qui It ri-gissent, pp. 186-190. !!■' V- p 3Si INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE erto been centred upon remarkable individual occur- rences of such phenomena. Even a rational classification of migrations in accord with the demand of social science is at the present moment lacking. Such a classification would have to take as its starting- point the result of migrations from the point of view of population. On this basis they would fall into these groups: — 1. Migrations with continuous change of locality. 2. " '■ temporary change of settlement. 3.' " " permanent settlement. To the first i^roup belong gypsy life, peddling, the carry- ing on of itinerant trades, tramp life; to the second, the wandering of journeymen craftsmen, domestic servants, tradesmen seeking the most favourable spots for tempo- rary undertakings, officials to whom a definite office is for a time entrusted, scholars attending foreign institu- tions of learning; to the third, migration from place to place within the same countr>' or province and to foreign parts, especially across the ocean. An intermediate stage between the first and second group is found in the periodical migrations. To this stage belong the migrations of farm labourers at harvest-time, of the sugar labourers at the time of the campagne, of the masons of Upper Italy and the Ticmo district, common day-labourers, potters, chimney-sweeps, chestnut-roast- ers, etc.. which recur at definite seasons. In this division the influence of the natural and political insulation of the different countries is. it is true, neglected. It must not. however, be overlooked that in the era of nationalism and protection of national labour political al- lej^iance has a certain importance in connection with the objective point of the migrations. It would, therefore, in '-•v»!^Tr-Ear jz»:*wfe r /x. . .ta'n.*i"»r?n^». "wrj" CROIVTH OF TOfVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 353 our opinion, be more just to make another division, taking as a basis the politico-geographical extent of the migrations. From this point of view migrations would fall into internal and foreign. Internal migrations are those whose points of departure and destination lie within the same national limits; for- eign, those extending beyond these. The foreign may again be divided into continental and extra-European (generally transmaritime) emigration. One can, however, in a larger sense designate all migrations that do not leave the limits of the ODntinent as internal, and contrast with them real emigration, or transfer of domicile to other parts of the globe. Of all these manifold kinds of migration, the trans- maritime alone has regularly been the subject of official statistics; and even it has been but imperfectly treated, as every student of this subject knows. The periodic emigrations of labour and the peddling trade have occa- sionally been also subjected to statistical investigation — mostly with the secondary aim of legislative restriction. The Government of Italy alone has long been endeavour- ing to clear up the subject of the periodic migration of a part of her population to other European lands through local investigations, exchange of tabulation-cards and consular reports. The migrations involving permanent and temporary transfer of settlement between the different European countries are but very imperfectly noticed in the publica- tions of the population census by means of the returns of births and of nationality. As for internal migrations, they have only in rare instances met with serious consideration. Yet these migrations from place to place within the same country are vastly more numerous and in their con- .i,'B'»»rei*sS5« f!'V II i ii 354 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE sequences vastly more important than all other kinds of migration put together.* Of the total population of the Kingdom of Belgium there were, according to the results of the census of 31st December, 1880, not less than 32.8 per cent, who were born outside the municipality in which they had their tem- porary domicile;' of the population of Austria (1890), 34.8 per cent. The actual population of Prussia on the first of December, 1880, was divided as follows: — No. of Per ct. of whole PUcc of Birth. Peisona. Population. 1. In the municipality where enumerated 1S.721.S88 57-6 2. Elsewhere in census district (.Krtis) 4.S99.664 16.9 3. Elsewhere in enumerated province 4.556.124 i6.7 4. Elsewhere in Prussia 1,658,187 6.1 5. Elsewhere in Germany 526,037 1.9 6. In foreign parts under German flag 212,021 0.8 Of 27,279,111 persons, 11,552,033. or 42-4 per cent., were born outside the municipality where they were domi- ciled." More than two-fifths of the population had changed their municipality at least once. Of the popula- tion of Switzerland on the first of December, 1888, there were born in the commune where then domiciled 56.4. in another commune of the same canton 25.7. in another canton 11. 5, in foreign parts 6.4 per cent.^ The commune in this enumeration is an administrative centre, which in many parts of the State embraces several places of resi- dence. The figures here given thus exclude altogether the numerous class of migrations from locality to locality within the commune itself. •Comp. now also G. von Mayr. Statistik m. GeselUckaftsUhre, II, pp. li6fT. 354 ff- _^ " \ntiuairt statist, de la Belgique. XVI (1885). p. 76. •Ztschr d. k. preus^ statist, Bureaus, XXI (1881), Beilage I, pp. 46.47 ♦Statist. Jhrb. <! Schweiz. II (1892), p. 57. GROIVTH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 355 This latter class of internal migrations, as far as we are aware, has been but once a subject of investigation. This was in connection with the Bavarian birth statistics of 1871.* According to these the total actual population of Bavaria was divided as follows: — Place of Birth. No. of Pw ct. of whole Penom. Population. 1. In the municipality where enumerated 2,975,146 61.2 2. Elsewhere in census district (Kreis) 143,186 3.0 3. Elsewhere in enumerated province 677,752 13.9 4. Elsewhere in Bavaria 944, loi 19.4 5. Elsewhere in Germany 78,241 1.6 6. In foreign parts 44,150 0.9 The Bavarian population of 1871 thus appears some- what more settled than the Prussian of 1880 and the Swiss of 1888, a circumstance perhaps due to the earlier year of the census. Nevertheless, two-fifths of the inhabitants (1,888,000 out of 4,863,000) were not native to the place in which they were living; that is, had migrated thither at some time or other. In the larger cities the number of people not of local birth amounted to as much as 54.5 per cent., in the small rural towns 43.2 per cent.; even in the communes of the open country it sank to merely 35.6 per cent. These are colossal migrations that we are dealing with. If one may venture an estimate, the data for which cannot be. gfiven in detail here, we believe ourselves justified in maintaining that the number of the inhabitants of Europe owing their present place of domicile not to birth, but to migration, reaches far over one hundred millions. How small do the oft-cited figures of transmaritime emigration appear in comparison! ® ' Die bayerische Bevdlkerung nock d. Gebiirtigkeit. Bearbeitet von Dr. G. Mayr (No. XXXII of Beitrdge s. Statistik d. Konigr. Bayem), p. 10. *In the seventy years, 1821-1891, the United States of America re- W !'i f *! (:•<' 356 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE That such enormous movements of population must draw after them far-reaching consequences is obvious. These consequences are chiefly economic and social. The economic result of all kinds of migrations is a local exchange of labour and, as people cannot be dissociated from their economic equipment, a considerable transfer of capital as well. Or we may say, since we must presume that in these matters also men's actions have definite pur- poses behind them, that they bring about more effective distribution and combination of labour and capital throughout the whole inhabited world. In this regard it is indifferent whether labour follows capital or favourable natural conditions, or capital seeks unemployed hands. Their social result is great shiftings of the population, which with an endless, undulatory motion seeks to pre- serve the equilibrium between itself and existing advan- tages for trade. These shiftings retard the increase in population at certain points, and accelerate it at others,— at once a thinning out and a concentration. The local distribution of the population, which is ordinarily deter- mined by natural organic increase, through surplus of births over deaths, is broken through. But in this very respect there is for the individual State an important difference between internal migration and emigration. The immediate effect of emigration upon the mother country shows itself in only one way: it thins out the pop- ulation and gives elbow-room to the remainder. That at the same time the settlement and development of thinly- peopled colonial territories is accelerated only indirectly affects the mother country when ultimately by the prac- tice of agriculture on a virgin soil the emigrants create a ceived from all countries of Europe 13.692.576 immigrants, v. Mayr, as above, p. 344- CROIVTH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 357 dangerous competition for home agricultural products, or by the transference of industrial skill and means of pro- duction into foreign lands cut off the market of home in- dustry. The effects of internal migrations, on the other hand, are always of two kinds: those displaying themselves at the points of departure; those perceptible at the objec- tive points. In the one case they reduce, in the other they increase, the density of the population. They thus cause, as it were, a division of the popula- tion centres and districts into t'.iose producing and those consuming human beings. Our producing centre" are generally the country places and smaller towns; our consuming centres, the large cities and industrial districts. The latter increase in population beyond the natural rate of the birth surplus, while the former remain noticeably behind it. Taking a yearly average for the period of eigh- teen years from 1867 to 1885, the total population of the German Empire has increased by 0.86 per cent, of the mean population." Yet when we look at the details we see that the average yearly increase amounted: In the large cities (pop. loo.cxn and over) to a.6 per cent. " " medium-siied cities ( " 30,000 to 100,000) " 3.4 " " " " small cities ( " 5,000" 30,000) " 1.8 " " " " country towns ( " a.ooo •' s.ooo) " i.o " '• " " villages (below 8,000) •' But of course the phenomenon of inland migrations is really not so simple and clear as this row of figures would seem to indicate. It certainly vividly illumines the much- talked-of " inHux to the cities." This expression, however, tells only half the truth. It overlooks the great number of internal migrations that counterbalance one another, and "According to Schumann in Mayr's Allg. statist. Archiv., II (1890), P- 518. MKIOCOnr RtSOUJTION TEST CHAtT (ANSI and ISO TEST CHART No. 2) A /APPLIED IM/QE I <6S3 Eoit Main Strnt RochMttr, N«w Torh 1 4609 USA ('!«) *82 - 0300 - Phon« ("«) 2M- 5989 -Fo, ;iil (r 358 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE therefore find no expression in a change in the number of inhabitants of individual localities. If we take a collective view of the internal migrations of a large country, without regard to their effect on the distribution of the inhabitants over the surface, their routes appear to us as a close variegated web in which the interwoven threads cross and recross continually. Into the rather simple warp stretched from the country places and towns to the large cities and industrial centres is woven a many-coloured woof whose threads run hither and thither between the smaller centres of population. Or, to use a different figure, the broad and majestically surg- ing surface-current, which alone we see, is not the only one; beneath it numerous lesser currents sport at will. Up to the present these latter have received scarcely any attention, certainly not so much as they deserve, even in cases where they happen to have been statistically as- certained. The Bavarian census of 1871 shows the follow- ing situation: Retidcnti native •>„_ toLoc»lilyof pi^I^„ ToUl. EnumeiatfoD. E^^'h^"- In the self-governing cities ^. . 301, 494 361.899 663.393 In other places of over 2,000 population. 205,887 iS7.o<» 36^,887 Total 507,381 518,899 T j6,28o In the rural municipalities 2,467,765 i.3S7.98l J,«-25,746 Grand total 3,975.146 1,876,880 4.852,026 From these figures it is plainly evident that the abso- lute number of persons who during the last generation migrated into rural municipalities is far more than twice as great as the number who had migrated to the cities. The same relation probably holds good for all larger countries. But the significant feature in this connection is not that CROU^TH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 359 the country places receive as well as give in this inter- change of population; it lies in two other considerations. The one is that they give out a larger population than they receive; the other, that their additions are made chiefly from the rural municipalities, while those leaving them find their way in part to the more distant cities. The excess of decrease over increase thus accrues to the bene- fit of communities of higher order; so much of the popu- lation enters into a sphere of life economically and socially diflferent. If we call the total population born in a given place and domiciled anywhere within the borders of the coun- try that locality's native population, then according to the conditions of interchange of population just presented the native population of the country places is greater than their actual population, that of the cities, smaller. Thus in Bavaria, according to the census of 187 1, the native population of the rural municipalities amounted to 103.5 per cent, of the enumerated population, that of the cities to only 61 per cent." In the Grand Duchy of Olden- burg '* according to the census of December ist, 1880, The influx from other places amounted in the citiei to 25,370 persons The exodus to " " cities " io,ao8 " The influx from " " " " " country " 57,366 " The exodus to " " " •• " country "72,528 " A balancing of the account of the internal migrations thus gives the cities a surplus, and the country municipal- ities a deficit, of 15,162 persons. In the economy of popu- lation one is the complement of the other, just as in the case of two brothers of different temperament, one of whom regularly spends what the other has laboriously " Mayr, as above, pp. 5.1, 54 of the introduction. "Comp. Statist. Nachrickten iiber d. Grosch. Oldtnbwt, XIX, p. 64. :l 360 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE saved. To this extent then we are quite justified from the point of view of population in designating the cities man-consuming and the country municipalities man-pro- ducing social organisms. But the total remaining loss of population of the coun- try municipalities exceeds the surplus that they furnish to the cities, even in the example here given from a small State, by almost four times. And the amount that they receive from one another is just as great. However large this mutual exchange of population by the country places may appear, only a relatively limited scientific interest really attaches to it. For here we are dealing with a species of migration which arises from the social limita- tions of the rural places, and which accordingly gains in importance the smaller the communities. In the whole Grand Duchy of Oldenburg the number of persons not bom where at the time residing amounted in: Municipalities of less than 500 inhabitants to SS-of» " " 500 to 1,000 " " 37-4% " i.oooto i.soo " " 417% " " 1,500 to 2,000 " " 40.4% " 2,000 to 3,ooo " " 387% " " 3,000 to 4.000 " " 22.2% " " 4,000 to 5,000 " " ao.6% « " over 5.000 " " 29-4% From this we notice that in the smaller municipalities (up to 4000 inhabitants), as the absolute size of the mu nicipality increases the influx from other places decreases relatively to the native population, while in the larger places it increases. Mayr has shown that the same holds for Bavaria. There in the year 1871 in the lartjer rural municipalities (of 2000 and more inlubitants) the number of those resident in the place of birth was 66.9 per cent., but in the smaller mu- GROWTH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 361 nicipalities only 64.4 per cent.,*^ while in the cities the exact opposite was the case. For in the self-governing cities 45.5 per cent, of the population were found to have been born where enumerated, but in the other (smaller) towns 56.8 per cent. Mayr accordingly sets up the prop- osition that in the cities the proportion of persons born where residing decreases with the sice of the place, while in the rural municipalities, on the contrary, it increases}* There is a very natural explanation for this condition of affairs in the country. Where the peasant, on account of the small population of his place of residence, is much restricted in his local choice of help, adjoining com- munities must supplement one another. In like man- ner the inhabitants of small places will intermarry more frequently than the inhabitants of larger places where there is a greater choice among the native population. Here we have the occasion for very numerous migrations to places not far removed. Such migrations, however, only mean a local exchange of socially allied elements. This is again clearly shown by the "work, already fre- quently referred to, on the native-born population of Oldenburg. In it the foreign-born population of Wadde- warden, Holle and Cappeln, three communities chosen at "Die bayer. Bevolkerung nack d. Gebiirtigkeit. Introduction, p. 15. "This proposition has been corroborated by the Austrian census of 1890. According to the excellent treatise on it by H. Rauchberg, Die Bevolkerung Oesterreichs auf Grutid d. Ergebnisse d. Volkss. v. 31. Des. iS<)0 (Vienna, 1895), p. 105, of every 100 persons bom where enumer- ated there were in places: Of less than 500 inhabitants 65.7% SCO to 2,000 " 735% 2,000 to s.ooo " 69.9% 5,000 to 10,000 " SS-6% 10,000 to 20,000 " 46.4% over 20.000 inhabitants 43-1% 362 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE Holle. CappelD 1298 1423 445 388 267 324 60.1 83.5 178 64 39-9 16.5 544 387 490 33a 90.0 85.9 54 55 10. 14 I random, is arrar.ged according to zones of distance from the place of birth. The figures are as follows: *' Waddewardea, Total population 861 From other places 270 Of these latter there j ^^^^.^^^ „^^t,„ g come from places upj p„ „„, ^5.6 to 9 miles distant ( " _ • J- . i Absolute number 12 From greater distances j pg^ cent 4.4 Migrated to other places 400 Of those up to a dis- ( Absolute number 332 tance of 9 miles ( Per cent 83.0 Migrated to a greater j Absolute number 68 distance \ Percent 17.0 How entirely different are conditions in this regard in the capital, Oldenburg, which with its 20,575 inhabi- tants is after all to be looked upon as only a small city. Of its total foreign-born population (13,364 persons, or 64.9 per cent.) there come: From a Distance of— Persons. Per cent. Less than 9 miles 2916 31.8 From 9-4S " 5625 42.1 Over 45 " 4823 36.1 Here the greater part of the influx of population is from a distance; the entry of the stranger-born into a new community means at the same time an entry into new social and economical conditions; and this urban com- munity does not give as many of its native inhabitants to other districts as it receives from them.*® On the contrary, it absorbs from a wide region round about the surplus of emigration over immigration, and repays it only in very small part. ^^ Stati.t. Niuh.ichtai iibcr d. Grossh. Oldenburg, p. 65 [i Germati mile is taken — 4.5 Ln^lish miles, although actually = 4.6. — EdI. "The city of Oldenburg in the year 1880 received from other munici- palities of the Grand Duchy 8,725 inhabitants, and gave up to them only 1,925. See, as above, p. 212. or CROIVTH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. . 363 This is the characteristic of modem cities. If in our consideration of this problem we pay particular attention to this urban characteristic and to a like feature of the factory districts — ^where the conditions as to internal mi- grations are almost similar — we shall be amply repaid by the discovery that in such settlements the result of internal shiftings of population receives its clearest expression. Here, where the immigrant elements are most numerous, there develops between them and the native population a social struggle, — a struggle for the best conditions of earning a livelihood or, if you will, for existence, which ends with the adaptation of one part to the other, or perhaps with the final subjugation of the one by the other. Thus, according to Schliemann,*" the city of Smyrna had in the year 1846 a population of 80,000 Turks and 8,000 Greeks; in the year 1881, on the con- trary, there were 23,000 Turks and 76,000 Greeks. Tlie Turkish portion of the population had thus in 35 years decreased by 71 per cent., while the Greeks had increased nine-fold. Not everywhere, to be sure, do those struggles take the form of such a general process of displacement; but in individual cases it will occur with endless frequency within a country that the stronger and better equipped element will overcome the weaker and less well equipped. In the year 1871, for instance, there were, in round numbers, 86,000 Bavarians living in Munich not born in the city; and at the same time some 18,000 na- tives of Munich were to be found in other places in Bavaria. In the year 1890 55.3 per cent, of the popula- tion of the twenty-six largest cities of Germany was found to have been born in other places, while 22.3 per cent, of J " Reiit in d, Troas im Mai 1881, pp. 29 aoff. ill' I ' V 1 1 364 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE their native population was living in other parts of the empire.*^ Still more striking is the fact shown by the English census of 188 1, that there were living in England and Wales (outside of the metropolis) just about half as many persons native to London as England and Wales had supplied to that city.*" Thus we have here a case similar to that occurring so fre- quently in nature; on the same terrain where a more highly organized plant or animal has no longer room for subsistence, others less exacting in their demands take up their position and flourish. The coming of the new is in fact not infrequently the cause of the disappearance of those already there and of their withdrawal to more favourable surroundings. This process need not, however, in the world of human society necessarily be a process of displacement, a con- sequence of the imperfect equipment of the native ele- ments and of the superiority of the foreign ones. The reverse will perhaps occur quite as frequently, and in the examples cited is probably the rule. On account of the endless differentiation of labour in modern national "Comp. von Mayr, Statistik u. GeseUschaftslekre, II, pp. 122 flF. "London had in i88i, 3,816,483 inhabitants. Of these there were born: D.—™.. P«' cent, of the Penou. Population. In London 2,401,955 62.9 In the immediate neighbourhood.. 384,871 lai Elsewhere in England and Wales . . 787,699 ao.6 In Scotland 49-554 1.3 In Ireland 80,778 3.1 In other countries 111,626 a.9 On the other hand, 584,700 natives of London were counted in other parts of England and Wales. For every 100 persons from these terri- tories who had settled in London, 51 natives of London had left the metropolis. — According to the Ztschr. des preuss. statist. Bureaus, XXVI (j886), Statist. Correspondens, p, xviii. \- GROIVTH OF TOfVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 3^5 economy it is the skilled labourers who experience most trouble in finding suitable employment and compensation for their labour where they live and have received their training, because it is there that the competition is keen- est. They emigrate and seek more favourable surround- ings, better conditions of competition, while at these points less highly qualified labour may at the same time be in demand, which demand must be met by importation of labour from outside places. This less skilled labour may, on the other hand, however, form the stronger, bet- ter equipped element in its own locality; and though it may lack here the opportunity for a profitable utilization of its skill, its departure may, nevertheless, leave a void that it is impossible to fill. Thus the emigration of more highly trained technical labour from the cities was perhaps never greater than in the period of the so-called industrial boom of the seventies. At the same time, however, those same cities received an immense influx of labouring population from the country; and the departure of the latter again caused in the dis- tricts of great landed estates a serious dearth of agricul- tural labourers, an advance in wages, and in some places a lamentable condition of agriculture. Here, in every case, it was the relatively stronger that had emigrated, the rela- tively weaker that had remained; there could be no ques- tion at all of mutual displacement. Still less is there ground for such a view with regard to those internal migrations that have their origin not in the effort to find a better place for carrying on work, but in the search for more favourable conditions of living. The pensioned civil servant or military man who leaves the expensive metropolitan city for the country or a cheaper rural town; the speculator who has become suddenly rich and exchanged his fluctuating stocks for a solid country i H \' t 4 ) 366 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE estate; the Parisian shopkeeper who enjoys his more la- boriously earned income in the quietude of his modest country cottage; and also, on the other hand, the Jewish cattle-dealer who has become wealthy and seeks the city in order to speculate on the exchange; Fritz Reuter's ex- cellently portrayed Mechlenburg " Fctthammcl " or rich farmer, who after disposing of his farm will enjoy the pleasures of city life; the poor clergyman's widow who moves into the city in order to give her children a better education and supplement her scant pension by keeping boarders; — none of these in their new places of residence enters into dangerous competition with the native labour- ing population. And yet at the objective points of the migration, even where the danger of displacement cannot enter into the question, there are innumerable struggles and endless fric- tion, all originating in the process of social amalgamation which is here always going on between the native popu- lation and the new-comers. The stranger has to adapt himself to his environment, to the peculiar local economic methods, to customs, speech and the political, religious and social institutions of his new abode. And the inhabi- tants of the latter place again, however settled in char- acter and peculiar in type cannot altogether escape the influences that rush in upon them from without. Though these influences often mean for them an increase of working energy, an expansion of the horizon, a breeze bringing freshness into corrupt local conditions, yet per- haps much more frequently they result in a loss of good old customs, of solid business qjalities, of interest in the common weal, and, above all, of social characteristics. Now there can be no doubt that these struggles for mutual adaptation will take a vastly different form and course when waged between similar and between diver- GROIVTH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 367 gent elements. For this verj' reason the division used in municipal statistics for marking the distinction between native and resident population does not suffice for more exact socio-statistical investigations. For if, for example, it has been ascertained that the native-born inhabitants of the city of Munich in 1890 amounted to 36 per cent, of the whole, while in Hamburg they consiituted 47.5 per cent., the mere fact that in the former city there are 11.5 per cent, more citizens of extra- mural birth is far from proving that the population of Munich is to this extent more heterogeneous than that of Hamburg, and that in the former the process of mutual social adaptation is attended with more violent friction and struggles than in the latter. In like manner the fact that two cities — for example, Dresden and Frankfurt- on-Main — show the same proportion of non-native to na- tive-born citizens does not mean that this process takes the same course in both. It is easy to conceive that the strangers in one city may show a greater homogeneity of customs and speech, economic energy and social habits amongst themselves and with the native population on account of coming from a neighbourhood more nearly akin, while in the other city heterogeneous elements from more distant localities are mingled together. The final result of the mutual adaptation of non-native and native population will be altogether different in each of these cases. While in the former individuals and groups of persons of approximately like economic equipment and similar social character enjoy peacefully together the ex- isting conditions for business, in the latter perhaps the more robust, energetic, easily contented race will vanquish the decrepit, weaker and more pretentious in its ancient home, or at least eject it from the most favourable fields of industry. Especially is it true that a lower standard 1 l( 368 INTERN/tL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE of living can give the incomers a superiority over the na- tive labour in the competitive struggle, which involves the latter in the most deplorable consequences. The im- migration of the Polish labourers into the provinces on their west, of the Italians into Switzerland and south Ger- many, and of the Chinese into the cities of the North American Union are well-known examples of this. But even when the economic and social assimilation takes place without severe struggles there may persist be- tween incomers and natives differences that simply can- not be removed, invading and disturbing the original homogeneity of the population. We have especially in mind differences of creed, of language and of political allegiance. The two largest cities of Switzerland, Geneva and Basel, both of which we are accustomed to look upon as strongholds of Protestantism, have to-day, in conse- quence of inKax from without, a population which over a third is foreign. In Geneva about 20 per cent, of the population have a mother tongue other than French. Finally, since 1837 the Roman Catholics have increased in Basel from 15 up to 30 per cent, of the population, while in Geneva they have reached 42 per cent. Even he who has no detailed knowledge of the internal history of these small municipalities will be obliged to admit that such differences are not void of danger. If these considerations show that by no means the ma- jority of internal migrations find their objective point in the cities, they at the s;ame time prove that the trend towards the great centres of population can in itself be looked upon as having an extensive social and economic importance. It produces an alteration in the distribution of population throughout the State; and at its originating and objective points it gives rise to difficulties which legis- lative and executive authority have hitherto laboured. ■*!! CROIVTH OF TOU^NS CONSIDERED HlSTORlC/iLLY. 369 usually with but very moderate success to overcome. It transfers large numbers of persons almost directly from a sphere of life where barter predominates into one where money and credit exchange prevail, thereby affecting the social conditions of life and the social customs of the manual labouring classes in a manner to fill the philan- thropist with grave anxiety. This mighty flow of the country population into the cities and the universally rapid rise of the latter in volume is looked upon by many as an entirely modern phenom- enon. In a certain sense this is true. The eighteenth cen- tury knew nothing of it, at least in Germany. The famous founder of population statistics, J. P. Sussmilch, did not succeed in discovering any regular law governing the movement of population in cities. He is of the opinion that they rise and fall in size according to the will of God.2° J jj Q yQj^ Justi deems it hardly possible that a city should increase unless special privileges be granted to the incoming settlers.** This is in accord with such population statistics as we have been able to collect for individual cities from the second half of the seventeenth century to about 1820;" these show retrogression and growth in irregular alternation. In France, on the other hand, the modern movement seems to have begun about one hundred and fifty years earlier; and men already spoke " " Thus does the mighty ruler of the universe impart to states and cities m ght, riches, and glory. He takes from them again and gives to others according to his good will. He pulleth down the mighty from their seat and exalteth them of low degree."— Co«/«cAe Ordnung, II, § 546 (2d ed., pp. 477. 478). " Grunds'dtst d. Polieeiwiss., 1 54. Comp. also Gesammelle polit. u. Finansschriftcn, III, pp. 449^- '" Much material relating to the subject has been collected by Inama- Sternegg in the Handwort. d. Staatsw., II, pp. 433 ff. 370 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE IP in the eighteenth century, according to familiar phrase- ology, of the " depopulation of the open country." " If on the other hand we go farther back into the history of man in Europe we find two periods showing the same phenomenon on a grand scale: ancient times, especially the era of the Roman Empire; the later Middle Ages, in particular, the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries. Between them lie great epochs of quiescence, if not of retrogression ar d decay. How are these earlier periods of migration tc he cities to be regarded from the standpoint of the history of their evolution? Are they premature starts toward a goal whose attainment was reserved for our own time and its perfected means of communication? Or are they the out- flow of other impulses than those behind the correspond- ing movement of the present, and did they on that ac- count also lead to other results? Above all, was their influence upon population and their economic character the same? As concerns ancient times it would seem as if we must assume, in spite of the uncertainty of the population record handed down to us, that a consequence of the inHux of the rural population was the inordinate growth of the cities.'* But it must not be overlooked that only a part of that population migrated of its own free will, namely, the free- men. The remaining and much larger portion, the slaves, were collected by their masters in the cities, or brought thither by the slave trade. " Evidence collected by LeRoyt, Du progrh des agglonUralions ur- baines et r^migration rurale (Marseilles, 1870), pp. 8 flf, " On what here follows compare particularly R. Polilmann. Die Veberviilkerung d. antiken Grossstiidte im Zusammt'iange mil d. Gesamt- entwick. stddlischer Civilisation (Leipzig, 1884); also Roscher, System d. Volksw., III. Introduction, and Biicher, Die Aufstdnde d. unfrei. Ar- beiter 143-1^9 ''• Chr. GROIVTH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 371 Where freemen moved in from the country they usually came not because a better prospect of economic advance in the cities beckoned them, but because they were deprived of their lands through the growth of the great slave estates. In the cities, it is true, they found all the lucrative branches of tr^ '.e in the hands of slaves and freedmen ; but they were here in less danger of starva- tion, inasmuch as the proletarian masses of the cities in whose midst they settled were supported by public and private largesses. The large cities of antiquity are essentially communities for consumption. They owe their size to the political cen- tralization which collected the surplus products of the ex- tensive areas cultivated by individual husbandry at one point where the governing class was domiciled. They are imperial, or at least provincial, capitals. Accordingly they first arise in the time of the successors of Alexander and reach their height under the Roman Empire. The capital, Rome, itself depends for its food-supply upon the taxes in kind from the provinces; and the same is later on true of Constantinople.^" It is a communistic and im- perialistic system of provisioning, such as the world has not seen a second time. The extortions of the ofiicials, the farming of the revenues, the usurious practices, the great estates of wealthy individuals worked by slaves, the state-recognised obligation to supply largesses of bread, meat and wino to the masses — all these placed the pro- ductive labour of half a world at the service of the capital city and left open to the private activity of its inhabitants " Krakauer, Das I'erffiegungstvesen d. Stndt Rom i» d. sfiiter. Kaiser- stit (Leipzig, 18-4). and E. Gebhardt, Studicn iiber d. I'ert^HcRungs- wcsen von Rom u. Konstantinopel in d. spdter. Kaiserseit (Dorpit, i88i). Also Rodbertus, Zur Gesch d. nm. Trtbutsteucrn in the Jhrb. f. N.-Oek. Oek. u. SUt.. VIII, especially pp. 400 fT. !N' 372 INTERNytL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE nothing but the sphere of personal services. From what we know of the larger provincial cities we may conclude that in them similar conditions prevail.''® A favourable market for free labour, a place for the skilled production of goods on a large scale for export, the ancient metropolitan city was not." Anything resem- bling factory work rests, as does the extensive agricultural production, upon slave labour. Accordingly among the motives mentioned by the ancient writers as impelling the free rural population toward the cities the very one that is commonest to-day— the prospect of higher wages- plays no part. " Consider this body of people," writes Seneca" to his mother; "the houses of the immense city are scarcely sufficient for them. From municipia and colonies, in short from the world over, have they come together. Some have been drawn hither by ambition, some have come on public business, others as envoys, others again have been attracted by luxurious tastes seek- ing an apt and ample field for indulgence, others by fond- ness for liberal studies, others by the shows; some have been led by friendship, others by enterprise, which here finds extended fields for displaying personal merit;" some have brought their personal beauty for sale, others their eloquence. There is no class of people which has not streamed to the city, where the prizes are great for virtue and vice alike." "E. Kuhn. Die siddtische u. biirgcrliche Verfassung d. Rom. Reichs, I. pp. 46 (T.. points lo an organization of the cura annona similar to that in the capital. " Frat.cotti-, i: Industrie dans la Crice ancicnne, I, esp. pp. 14Q-IS8. has now established this fur the Greek cities. "• Ad Hchiam. 6. ... "Quosdam industria lalam ostendcndce virtuli ttacta matenam. It is competition that is meant, not " industry." as Pohlmann, cited above, p. 17, translates it. CROIVTH OF TOH^NS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 373 Quite different was it with the town-ward flow of popu- lation in the Middle Ages. Taken as a whole, it is per- haps not less voluminous than that at the time of the Roman Empire. It did not result, however, in the forma- tion of a few central points of consumption, but in the con- struction of a large number of fortified places distributed pretty evenly throughout the country, uniting within their walls all the organized industrial activity of the na- tion which was not attached to the soil. The mediaeval towns are originally mere places of refuge for the sur- rounding rural population;^*' their permanent inhabi- tants are the burghers, or people of the burg. Everything else — the market, the prosecution of trade, monetary dealings, the personal freedom of the town inhabitants and their special privileges before the law — is only a later consequence of this extra-mural military relationship. The defensive union became in course of time a territorially circumscribed economic union, for which the town or city was the trade centre and the seat of all specialized labour. The mediaeval cities'* accordingly bear a great simi- larity to each other in the social and economic organiza- tion of their population, and differ, as far as we can see, only slightly in the number of their inhabitants. At their original founding the influx of the rural population seems often to have been far from voluntary. Later on the chief factor determining their growth was the greater security of person and property and the more varied op- portunities for earning a livelihood which they afforded " Comp. above, pp. 1 16 flf. " That is, so far as they really deserve the name. It is a peculiar in- consistency to attempt to-day to demonstrate the character of the mediaeval city by taking as examples places which never arrived at a true city status and which can bring forward no better claim to the name of city than that they were endowed with city privileges. ■ I 374 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE landless freemen and serfs. Their whole development, economically and numerically, came t -n ^nd, however, the moment all the handicrafts that the limited extent of the city-market areas was capable of sustaining were rep- resented and supplied with a sufficient number of master- workmen. Up to this point the cities oflfered complete freedom of movement and almost unimpeded access to guild privileges and burgess rights, while the rural land- owners, on the other hand, sought through limitations of the right of removal to secure themselves against the loss of their serfs. When, however, the cities were able to sup- ply all branches of trade from the internal growth of their population, they also exhibited a willingness to check ac- cessions from without, and hence brought about those numerous obstacles to settlement and to entry upon a trade which have persisted into modern times. There arose a sharp division between city and country. Migration to and fro naturally continued to a certain extent, but it was confined in the main to an exchange of labourers among the cities themselves. City development had fallen, as it were, into a condition of numbness from which it could be roused only through transition to a new economic order. We are in a position to prove statistically for a few locaIit=-« Hie statement just made. There have been in- stitii :haustive investigations into the origin of the medi.-eval population of Frankfurt-on-Main,^^ a^j fg. cently also regarding certain sections of the population of Cologne." From these it appears that the majority of the persons received by these two cities as burghers « Biichcr, Beiolkcrung von Fr.. pp. 163 flf., 304 flF., 4" ff-. S2> A- SQi ff . 627 fi. "A. Dorcn, Unlcrstichwigen :. Cesch. d. Kaufmannsguden d Mttlciiltcts (in Schmoller's Forschungen, XII. 2), Appendix 1; and now aho H. Bunfecr's Beitriige s. mittelalt. Topograph., Rechtsgeschich. u. Sozialstatishk. d. Stadi Koln (Leipzig, 1896), Sec. 3. GROIVTH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 375 during the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries migrated from the country. Of every loo new burghers there came to: In the Period. From Cities. ''™'",S»i" ""* Cologne 1356- 1479 37-4 62.6 Frankfurt 1311-1400 28.2 71.8 " 1401-1500 43.9 56.1 We see from this that in the last two centuries of the Middle Ages the movement of population from the coun- try to the cities, though it continued, was on the wane, while the admixture of town elements among the new burghers increased. Thus as early as the fifteenth century certain strata of the population of Frankfurt received their chief increment through emigration from other cities. Of the incoming Jews, for example, 90 per cent., and of the members of a fraternity of journeymen metal-workers 79.3 per cent., came from cities. The material from which the last percentage is deduced also covers, it should be said, the first quarter of the sixteenth century. Unfortunately, further figures regarding the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries are not available. But for the period from the beginning of the eighteenth till after the middle of the nineteenth century we can offer some fig- ures which serve to show that thee was an epoch when the urban handicrafts received their workers almost ex- clusively from other towns. The Frankfurt municipal archives contain a number of books regarding the lodg- ing-places of the bookbinders, in which are recorded the names and places of origin ot all the journeymen of this craft who came to Frankfurt between 1712 and 1867 (14,342 persons in all). Some years ago we worked over this extremely valuable statistical material and found that of every 100 incoming journeymen bookbinders there came: '' « Ijif \ i 4*!- 376 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE Periods. From Cities. ^™"h^i|S! "^ 1712-1750 97.5 2.5 1751-1800 94-3 5-7 1801-1835 89.2 10.8 1836-1850 36.0 14.0 1851-1867 81.3 18.8 We see here how, in a trade of a specifically urban char- acter, within a period of rather more than a century and a half, the proportion of workers drawn from the country has continuously increased. Had it been possible to con- tinue the investigation for the period from 1867 down to the present time, we should undoubtedly have found that the balance h^s inclined more and more in favour of the journeymen from rural localities. In the contemporary migrations to the cities a fusion of town and country strongly resembling that established by us for the fifteenth century seems to have set in.'* Of every 100 of the inhabitants born in other places there were in: Year. Of City Birth. Of Country Birth. Leipzig 188s 50.6 49.4 Basel 1888 23.5 76.S As in the Middle Ages, the city element relatively in- creas* s ^nd the country element decreases according to the distance of place of birth from place of settlement. The various classes of the population show but slight differ- ences in this regard. Generally speaking those occupa- tions that demand a special training have a stronger ad- " Only the simplest results of these investigations can be given here. Details may be found in my Beviilkerung d. Kantons Basel-Stadt am i, Dez. 1888, pp. 62 flF. We may also refer to Hasse's Ergebnisse d. Volkssdhlmg vom 1. Dez. 1885 in der Stadt Leipsig, Pt. II, pp. 7(T. The higher figures in the rural accessions for Basel are explained by the fact that in the above work the city limits are made to include only 3,000 inhabitants. CROl^TH OF TOMANS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 377 mixture o' city elements than the spheres of simple manual labour. It is greatly to be regretted that similar statistical in- vestigations have not been carried out for a larger number of modern cities. From the evidence at present to hand we are apparently driven to conclude that the number of incomers of city origin is relatively greater in the large cities than in the medium-sized and smaller ones.^' The explanation of this phenomenon is a simple one. A large city exercises upon the population of the smaller cities the same power of attraction that the latter have for the pop- ulation of the country. In this way the transitions from one social and economic sphere to another are rendered less violent. ThUs a gradual elevation of the migrating masses takes place, as also from generation to genera- tion a continuous preparation for the demands of life in a great city, which must render less violent the conflicts inevitable to the process of mutual adaptation within the new sphere. But if the cities of to-day exhibit a process of redis- tribution of population similar to that of their mediaeval prototypes, the resemblance is only superficial. In the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries we have to do with the last stages of an evolution whose ultimate result was the formation of numerous small autonomous spheres of economic activity, each of which exactly resembled the other in its harmonious development of production; in the nineteenth rentury we have to deal with an increas- ing differentiation of the individual centres of population, •* Besides the work on Leipsig already mentioned, a later exhaustive treatise on the accessions to, and losses of, population in Frankfurt-on- Main in the year 1891, published by Dr. Bleicher in the Beitr. 2. Stalislik d. SI. Frkf., II, pp. 29 ff., gives interesting information re- garding this point. 378 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE in accord with the designs of a greater whole, namely, of a state-regulated national economy. This process begins with the development of the mod- ern State and modern national administration. Hitherto each city had developed within itself all the branches of city life not forbidden by local conditions; now one city bee* mes a permanent royal residence, others be- come seats of district and provincial administrations, of prisons, of higher educational institutions and of all kinds of special branches of administration, while still others become garrison cities, border fortresses, fair-towns, watering-places, junction-points of commercial routes, etc. They take over definite functions for the whole coun- try and for all other places, though these functions are not always specifically urban. The cities may also form alliances with rural residence centres. This process has been especially prominent since the fuller development of city industry on a large scale and the extraordi- nary increase and perfection of the means of communica- tion. In this new national era the total national produc- tion endeavours so to distribute itself over the territory controlled by it that each of its branches may find the location best suited to it. Factory and house-industry districts arise, and separate valleys and whole regions take on a semi-urban character. Certain cities develop special branches of industry and trade reaching out far beyond the local, and often even the national, demand. In others, again, all industry and business life decline; they sink down to the level of villages, so that the historical rights of burgess that still attach +0 their name appear in striking contrast with their position as places of trade and with the number of their inhabitants. The distinctions between city and country are blotted out. This happens in the neighbourhood of rising industrial cities through the CROiyTH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 379 planting of factories and workmen's dwellings in the sub- urbs and beyond; in the neighbourhood of the declining " rural cities " through the approach of the latter to the condition of surrounding country places, and through the rise of populous industrial towns. On the whole, how- ever, the number of centres of population and of objective points for internal migrations is to-day relatively much smaller than in the second half of the Middle Ages.^® But in still another respect does the redistribution of population resulting from the internal migrations of the present time differ from that witnessed by our ancestors from the tenth to the fifteenth centuries. In consequence of the greater certainty of a living and of far-reaching measures for the health of the people the increase in pop- ulation is to-day more rapid than in mediaeval times. It •* The German Empire had in 1890 a total of 2,285 " cities." Of these there were 26 with more than 100,000 inhabitants, 22 with from 50,000 to 100,000, 104 with from 20,000 to 50.000, and 169 with between 10,000 and 20,000. Besides these there were 56 villages and suburban municipalities with from 10,000 to 50,000 inhabitants, 11 of them with more than 20,000. — In Prussia there were in that year 46 " cities " with less than 1,000 inhabitants, 14 of these being in the Province of Posen, 12 in Silesia, 10 in Hesse-Nassau. 3 in Brandenburg, 2 each in West Prussia and Westphalia, i each in Saxony, Hanover and the Rhine- land (Schleiden with 515 inhabitants). Alongside these dwarflike cities there were 37 rural municipalities with more than 10,000 inhabi- tants. — How far some of the old cities have declined is shown by the following figures for the Grand Duchy of Baden. There the census of 1885 gave 114 " cities," only 63 of these having a population of over 2,000, and 9 with over 10,000. Of the remaining 51 " cities " 42 had from 1,000 to 2,000 inhabitants, 4 had from 500 to 1,000, and 5 below 500 (among these last being Kleinlaufenburg with 441, Neufreistett with 427, Blumenfeld with 349, Fiirstenberg with 341, Hauenstein with 157). For every city there were on an average 14 villages. On the other hand, there were altogether 129 municipalities with over 2,000 inhabi- tants, 66 of these being " villages." Of the old cities only 55 are thus cities according to the modern idea, and of the villages four per cent are from the point of view of population to be reckoned in with the cities. 38o INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE is safe from those heavy reverses so frequently resulting in those ages from harvest failure, feuds and plague. On that account the modern migrations into the large cities and industrial districts in many cases absorb only a surplus population that would not find sufficient room for earning a livelihood in the places of its origin. At these points tney retard or completely check the con- gestion of population; while on the other hand at the points of agglomeration no economic obstacles bar the way to a continuous and rapid increase. In mediaeval times, on the contrary, the migratory ac- cession of population was distributed among a multitude of walled places scattered at fixed intervals over the whole country. The increase in many cases continued only until the city was full. When once it had as many inhabitants as it needed to man its walls and towers and supply all the branches of industry, there was no room for more. Extensions of the city limits often did take place in mediaeval times, it is true; they are the result of the increasing formation and subdivision of special trades. But the Middle Ages developed no large cities; the mediaeval economic and commercial system forbade it. The country was often deprived of the population neces- sary for the cultivation of the soil; yet even with such accessions the frequency of extensive losses kept the city populations stationary. From these remarks it will indeed remain uncertain whether or not the internal migrations that accompanied the development of the industrial life of the mediaeval town were relatively more extensive than the corresponding territorial movements and shiftings of population that result to-day from the more national character of settle- ments. On the other hand, it cannot be doubted that the attraction of the great cities of modern times for the pop- GROIVTH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORIC/tLLY. 381 ulation of the smaller towns and the country is exerted over greater expanses of territory than the mediaeval towns held within the circle of their influence. One is not in a position to say, however, that the recruiting territory for the population of a city has expanded since the begin- ning of modern times in direct ratio to the number of its inhabitants. On the contrary, one is astonished to find what a slight effect the perfecting of the means of com- munication and the introduction of freedom of movement have had upon the extent of the territory covered by the regular internal migrations. A few figures will make this clear. Of f.wtvy hundred new settlers coming to Frankfurt, Oldenburg and Basel the numbers according to distances are as f-^'' vs: City. Frankfurt . II Oldenburg. Basel Class of Population, New citizens II II Metal workers Citizens born in other places Citizens born in other places Journeymen craftsmen . . Factory laborers Period. 0-9 Miles. 9-45 Allies. 14th century 46.7 39-3 15th 23.1 52.7 iSthandi6th centuries 2.7 45-0 1880 31.8 42.1 1888 16.7 50.2 1888 13.9 40.0 1888 17.1 59-6 Miles. 14.0 24. a 52.3 36.1 33.1 46.1 23-3 Of the three recruiting zones distinguished here the outermost at present contributes more to the total popu- lation and the inner less than in mediaeval times. The reason probably is that to-day the population in the more immediate neighbourhood of a city takes advantage of the city's labour market without settling in the city itself, whether it be that they go daily to their places of work in the city by special workmen's trains or other con- venient means of transportation, or that the great indus- tries of the towns erect their workshops in neighbouring 382 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE places. The recruiting territory for journeymen has rather contracted as compared with mediaeval times. With this is linked the circumstance that at present three- fourths of this class of workmen are drawn from the coun- try, while at the close of the Middle Ages less than one- quarter of them came from villages and hamlets. Of the Frankfurt journeymen metal-workers in the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries only 20.7 per cent, were born in the country; of the Basel bakers and butchers in 1888, on the contrary, 78.7 per cent, and of the journeymen of other handicrafts 75.2 per cent, were of country birth. Even to-day journeymen craftsmen still migrate in much larger numbers and to greater distances than the typical work- man class of the present, the factory hands. Of the factory workingmen in Basel in 1888, 25.8 per cent, were born in the city itself; of the handicraft journeymen, only 16.3 per cent. How many of them were bom and still domiciled in the immediate neighbourhood the statistics unfortunately do not show. But all modern industrial development tends in the direction of producing a per- manent labouring class, which through the custom of early marriage is already much less mobile than the jour- neymen of the early handicrafts, and which in future will doubtless be as firmly attached to the factory as were the servile labourers of the mediaeval manor to the glebe.^^ If this is not very noticeable at present it is because the majority of large industries have not yet attained their growth, and because it is net. -ssary Tor them, as long as they extend their works, to meet the increased demand " The construction of workingmen's dwellings by the great man- ufacturing establishments, whether these pass over into the possession of the labourers or arc rented to them, is even now begetting a sort of factory bondage, which has an appalling resemblance to the old bond- age to the soil. Comp. my article on the Belgian social legislation in Braun's Archiv. f. soz. Gesetzg. u. Stat, IV, pp. 484, 485. GROIVTH OF TOfVN^ CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 383 for labourers by drawing further upon the surplus popu- lation of the rural districts. These remarks point to the conclusion that we are not justified in attributing a growing migratory character to society as a result of the closer network of commercial routes and the invention of perfected means of communi- cation. Rather should we say that at present we are in the midst of a transition period in which the yet un- completed transformation of the town and territorial economic structure into a national one involves a con- tinuous displacement of the boundaries of division of labour and ^''.e centres of the various branches of pro- duction, and -.nsequently displacements of the labouring population. After a period of economic and social ossification ex- tending over centuries, in which all sorts of limitations upon migration and settlement held the population fast to the original ancestral seats, it is not surprising that many view with anxiety the great movements of popu- lation which to-day extend over whole territories. It seems almost as if the early times of universal migration were returning. But in this they forget that it is only a part — the rural part — of the population that has become more migratory; that up to the early year:, of last century a great number of these were bound to the soil. The merchant, the craftsman and the scholar are to-day much less mobile than, for instance, in the time of the Reformation; and the industrial labourers move relatively less often and to shorter distances than they did even a century ago. Only their number has become much greater and is still steadily increasing. This growth of in- dustry displaces a part of the rural labouring population from their usual places of abode, to which nothing now holds them but the interests of those who profit by their IK. 384 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE helplessness. The further progress of this movement will probably show, even in a few decades, that the human race in the course of its evolution has on the whole be- come more stationary. We may thus say in conclusion: In this general influx to the cities and their suburbs we are to-day undergoing what our ancestors experienced in the second half of the Middle Ages, the transition to a new economic and social order and a fresh distribution of population. At that time the movement inaugurated the period of town economy and of sharp separation of town and country; the movement in the midst of which we now live is the outward sign that we have entered upon a new period of development,— the period of organic distribu- tion of population, the period of national division of labour and of national satisfaction of wants, in which the distinctions between city and country as places of abode are being obliterated by numerous transitional forma- tions. This fact has long since been recognised by statis- ticians who have dropped the historico-juridical concep- tion of city and substituted a statistical one in which places are distinguished according t i the number of their inhabitants. Every transitional epoch has its inconveniences and its suffering. But the modern movement of population, in so far as it is expressed in the influx into the cities, will, like that of mediaeval times, reach its goal and then sub- side. This goal can be none other than to assign to every individual capacity and to every local group of per- sons that place and that role in the great national life in which its endowments and the altered technical con- ditions of economic activity best fit it to contribute to the general welfare. Thus from a consideration of internal migrations, de- GROH^TH OF TOl^NS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 385 spite the fact that the conditions accompanying them are often far from pleasant to contemplate, we may gain the assurance that _they too mean, from the wider stand- point, an advance towards higher and better forms of social existence, both for the individual and for the race. mu INDEX. Aboriginal man, no longer exist- ing, 3 Acta diurna populi Roman!, aio, 220 Acta senatus, 219, aio Adoption, 15 Advertising Bureaux, 240 Aged, exposure of the, 16 Agriculture, 4S, 255; savage .igri- cuUuralists, 43 V. Ailzing, 236 Andree, 23, 26, 28. 37, 67, 73, 77, 266 Andrews, Alex., 232, 234 Animal sortD'ogy, 2 note. Annuities, 133 Appun, 18 Art, 28, 29 note. Artel, gs Artifiters, 98 " Artistic Work," return t j, 208 Bank, evolution of, 138 BannrnfiU, 123 de Barthilemy, 233 .Ussier, 34, 264 Rastian. 24, 78 Battenberg. Frani Joseph von, 158 Peati fossidentts, philosophy of, 34a Below, 126 lleti, 79 Ftunittn, 105 Hey, Fmin, 36 Itiilcicn Labour. Str Labour. Hlcirhcr, 377 ni'ick, 283' Itlmn, 157 noas, 28 Backcl, 266 Bos, 43 Botcher, botcher-hunt, 169 Bottiger, loi Baun , 158 Btlcher, works cited, 19, 22, a8, 53, 87, 94, 96, 108, 130, 132, 154, 163, 171, 207, J54. »56. »63. sW), 267, 269, 273, 274. 298. 30'. 318. 334. 370, 374. 376. 382 Buchner, 24, 6$, 79, 93, iii Buffalo herds, extermination of, 18 Buhl, l6i Hunger, 374 Burg, 116, 373 Burgess rights, 116 119, 374. 37^ Burgher, 116, 119, 13J, 373-375 Burner, 181 Hurton, 13, 21, 35. 263 Musiness Undertakers, 308 Cxsar, 218, 219 Camelots, 100 CamfagHt, 352 Capital, 112, 128, 129, 137, 143, 162, 173. >76. 309. 3«o. 333 Capitalists, 308 Cappeln, 361, 362 Casalis, 38, 78, 277 Casati, 72 Caste system, 343 Cattle-raising, 11, 45, 51 Cauwii, 250 Cecchi, 69 Census: Bavarian, 358 (T.; English, 364; Oldenburg, 359 ff. Sft Oc- cupations, census of. Cicero, loa, 219 Circulation of goods, ta8, 305 Cities: characteristic of modern, 363; in German Empire, 379 note; in Middle Ages, 380. Set Towns. Classes: rise of, 127; vocational, 334; labeurlnf, 38a de Clercq, 28 S«7 388 INDEX. Colbert, 136. M^ ; Clbcrtism, 137 Columella, 300 Commerce, 303, 309 Commercial contrivances, 76, 145 Commission Work (Syr.tcm), 154. 171. 173. O'). 257 Common-houses of savages, 37- .Vic Houses. Common, Labour in. See Labour. Communities: partial, 94; labour, 95 Community for I'rofiuction and Consumption, 305, 3o<J. 3io. 372 Comprar, to sit down, 63 Conceptions of value of primitive man Consumption, 29. 192 Covetousness of the savage <lc Coulanges, Fustel, 92 Couriers, 77 Cranz, 13 Credit, 129, 137. 145; Crc.lit-bal- ances, 207 Crop-rotation, 47 Currency, national, 131. .SVf Money. Custom-production, 170 Customs Duty, 80 Dampicr, 13 Defence, arrangements for, 14''> I).-m.ind, conccniratinn of, 192 niensliiiiel, 33° "o'c- Dipui'iK stick, 7, 11 Diinilruff, 345 Division of Labour. See Labour; of Troduction. See Production. Division of Use 'with tools\ 301 Domestic animals, laming of, 22, 27 Dorcn, 374 Drum, use of, 7S Druzina, 95 Dualism in household. 55 F.conomic tivity, 2 F.conomic nature of man, I, 2, 3 " Kconomic piinriplr," the, I r.conomic method, 14^; stai;c-<, R5. See Stages. Economy, 25, C). 3"'. 3'); m--^;I<M led bv cthnogr.iiilu . n " Economy ' 1 IKvi.l'-l I.;ibotir " Fconomy. n.Tii' ■' ;!, "■ ■■ " , 3^ v •' '■■ Stages. Editorship, 240 Education, 146 Egoism of savage, 14, 21 Ehrenreich, 9. 11. 16, 23,28,32, 51, 61, 264 Ellis, loi Embassies, 77 Endemann, 270, 277 Enfeoffment, 132 Engels, 4 Entrepreneur, 172, 17S, 308, 312 Erman, no, 263, 321 , Exchange, genesis of, to; primi- tive, 59, 65. 9". >c'6. I"?. •"/ system of direct, 114. and divi- sion of labour, 295, 301 Exner. 157, 158 Extra-mural jurisdiction, 124 171; districts, 37S; hands, 172, Factory 3''2 Factory Work (SystenO, 154 173. 'i7f> Fair Reports, 236 Fomilia tusti<a, 99; urbatta, 99, 300 Family, primitive, 10, 48, t5'r. of Negritos, 8 note; Roman. 97 Fiiuihaber, 231 FebtfySy 38 Fcliit, 329 Felkin, 270 Ferguson, Adam, 2«3, 2S5, 326 Finsch, 5. 47. 67. if-. 79. 263. 269 Fire, use of, 3. '<• 26, 79 Fire-cabin, 38 Fishing, 49, 77 Food, separate preparation of. 32 - 38; procuring of, 42, 4». AuUse Stage of Individual Search for. Fof^li dCiivvisi, 226 Foresight, lack of by savage, 12, Si Forester, I57 Forestry, 255 Francotte, 160, 372 "Freedom of luilerprisc," 334; free choice of vocation, 340 Itil'ch, 9, 10. II, I'', -o, 21, ?.t. ""^ 3^'. 49 Gallon, 329 Gang. 27S Ganphofer, 337 Garve, 322 w INDEX. 389 Gazetta (Gazette), 225; C^z.itanti, 327 Gebhardt, 371 Geiger, 4, 72 Gerland, 277 Gifts. See Presents. Gioja, 250 Gorbunoff, 267 Gramich, 122 Grandke, 186 Grasshoif, 222, 224 Groos, 27 Grosse, 7, 28, 30, g2 Guilds, 168, 171, i32, igo, 374 Haberland, 62 Hack or Hoe System, 4*"'. 4S Hahii. 43, 45 Handicraft (!land-work), 121, 150, 152, 168, 169, 171, 176. 1S2. 185. 311; displaceinent of, 192; sup- planting, curtailment, incorpora- tion, impoverishment, etc., of, 197-207 Handicraftsman (Craftsman), modern, 151 Hansa. The. 138 Hansjakob, 163 Harar, 277 Hardness of heart of snv.ige, 14 Hasse, 376 Hatin, 221, 226, 232, 234 Haupt, 266 f/ausjieisz, 155 HeckcwL-lder, 17, nj, 23. 33. ''''■ 264 Heiiize. 2x3 Helmolt. 2S5 ileredity, 326. 335, 336 Hermann, 131, 250 Herodotus, 16 Heusler, t2g, 130 Higher primitive peoples, 29, 31) Hildebrand, 86 Historical School, 84, 86 Hofsihulie, l?7 Holle, 361, 302 Holub, 80 Homer, 62 Home-work, ifi3. '''5. 'f>7. ''^7 llcirinutiii , 2(17 Hose, CIi.uIps, 32, 269 llospitaliiy, lilies of, (i2 Household, nt(;lccted by cthnoK raphy, 39 House Industry (see Commission Work), 154. i/i. 257. 2f'7 Houses, public social, 36 note, 205 Housework, 154. I55; i" Buko- wina 153, 176 Houssaye, 327 Howitt, 63 HUbner, 218 Hudson, 234 HUgel, 64 Hume, 321 " Hunger-strap," il Hunting, 49 Hwof, 67 Imitating, by savages, 27 Immermann, 157 Improvidence of savage, 17 Im Thurm, 64 Inama-Sternegg, 103, 369 Income, 112 note, 113, 131, 143 Individual econc my, 32 Individual Search for Food, staj c of, 26, 27, 30, 39 Industrial Organizaliun. 54, 3'=. peoples, 73 Industry, 52. 57. 5*. 144. i5f>- 255: systems of, 154 Infanticide, 14, 15 Influx to the titles. 357 Insurance, 133 Interest, 132 Intermediaries, nlfici.il. 124 Iron smelting, 22, working. 159 Itinerancy, 162, lo-* Itinerant, 162. i(.5-i69 Iwantschofl. 158 /?('(;;/:.;. 3O note. Jacobsen, 79, 263 James, 329 Icllin,t;haus, 24 jentsch, 255 loest, 23 Jones, F. F:UHiy, 232 Jung, 21 Junker, 19, 72. '^lA V. Justi, 369 K-iufiriann. 1 17 Klenim. 5 Kleinw.ichter, 245 Krakauer, 371 krejcsi, ir,S 39° INDEX. Kubary. 34. 34. 38. 69. 107. «65. 269 Kuhn, 37a Labour. 142. 3'°: aggregation. 2O2. 368. 371-273: bidden. 94. 2o3- 273; companionship. 262; conca- tenation. 273; in common. 49. 93. 352. (extent) 259. 262. 280. 3«». 322; communities. 94. 95. 280; displacement of. 390-394, 333; distribution between sexes. 30- 37. 44. S4. 353: division of. (in- terlocal) 71. 93. >44. «7t. 350-353. 284. 386, (defined) 389. 295. (so- cial) 112. 128, 295. 299. (conse- quences of) 302, 305. 310. 333. 331. 332; fraternal. 363. 318; in- corporation of. 311; joint. 362, 378; social, 245; subdivision of, 286, 394, 333; union (combina- tion) of, 344. 251. 253. 280, 317; with a.iernate and with concur- rent tfmfo, 274 Lamprecht, 103. 105. iii Land in autonomous economy, 90 Landlord, landlady, 30 Landor, 66, 365 Latifundia. 98, 331 Laveliye. 93. 105 Laziness of savage, 30 " Least sacrifice, • principle of, I Leber. 332 Leclerc, 3i8 Legoyt, 370 Leni, 67. 73 V. Leoprechting, 366 Liberalism, modern, 139 LieberkUbn. 3i8 Lindau. 327 Lippert. 4. 9. ". 14. «6. 18 List, 86, 346, 347. 250 Livingstone, 19. 24, 35. 3°. 37. 47. 48. 5«. 7». 79 Loaning. 61 Loria. 330 Lotmar. 333 Lduvois, 14s '• Lower nomads," 9, 36 Lubbock. 3. 4. «3. '5. '7 49 Luther, 333, 343 Machines. I75. 29»; small power. 209 Mangold, 240 MangolJt. 2i4 Manor. 102 «., 126, 137. 383 Manufactory, 171 M -.rket-law. 120 Markets. 59, 66. 115, 373 Marquardt, 322 Martius. 10. 15. 16, 47. 49. 5i. 67. 78, 79 Marx Karl. 70 Material foresight and cultural progress. 12 Maternal love. 10. 15. I7 Maurer, 103 V. Mayr, 354. 355. 359. 360. 364 Melancthon. 323. 324. 325 Meinecke, 3v6 Meitzen, 38o Mercantile system, 136, 140 Meyer, 63, 98 Migration, 345; economic and social results of, 356 ff., 377; goal of modern, 384; kinds of, 349. 352. 353; periods of, 370, 373 , . Migratory character of society, 383 Moha, 95 Mobility of society, query as to. 349 Momnistn, aiS Money, 67ff., ii'-. 13. 143- ^" also Currency. Montesquieu. 233 Mciser. 186, 256 Mundt-Lautf. 4 Nachtigal, 5. 19. 35. 263,270 National economy (see Economy) era, 134. 378 Nationality, principle of, 140 Natural peoples, 41, 43 note. Nepotism. 341 News, communication of. 77". P""" licatiun of, i39 News-letters. 232, 233 Newspaper, 3i6. 221 Ni-^buhr. 344 Nl .ad life, 16, 345, ^^i> iVouvellauti, 217 ,\ouvtlUs <\ lit main, 233, 233 A\uvtllist(s, 232, 233 Occupations, German census of. 1 181. 260, 324 I INDEX. 39» OHin husbandry, 97 One page prints, 235 Opel. 228, 231. 237 Ordinari ("ordinary messen- gers), 222, 229; Ord. ZtitUHgtn, 230 Orth, 237 Ottino, 222 Paget, 158 Panckow, 23, 42, 47 Parkinson. 24. 33. 47. 69. 79. 93. »9 Pasz, 278 Pattrfamilias, 97 Paulitschke, 35. 270. 277 Peschel, 3, 4. 5. ". »3. ai Petri, 158 Petronius, 98 V. Philippovich, 244, 289 Physiocrats, 87, I39 Piece-work, collective, 279 Play, 27, 28 Pliny, lie Pogge, 10, 18, 24, 35, 47. Ji. «>5. 75. 77, 80, loi, 270 Pogio, 91 POhlmann, 370. 37» Polygamy, 55. ^54 Popma, 98, 99 Population, Hutive, 359 Post, 15. 49. 79. 270. aSo Postreuter, 236 Pottery, invention of, 22 Presents (gifts), 61. 6a note, 79. 81 Price-work, 169 Primitive man, 12 ff., 41 " ; Peo- ples, classification of, 42 Printing, invention of, 234 Production, 196; division of. 280, 294, 331, 33' , Productive powers, harmony ot, 347 Property, immaterial, 131 Pruti, 222, 227. 336, 237 Public administration, 76, 79, 140 Quetelet, 351 Quippus, 73 Rambangs, 265 Ratiel. 5. U. »5. 34. 47. 49. 51 Rau, 2S0 Raucbberg, 3^1 Ready-made goods, 19S Recruiting territory for city, 381 Rtlationes semestraUs, 236 Rent, 112; purchases, 331 Repair trade, 198 Reuter, Fritr, 366 Ricardo, 83 Riedel, 269 Riegl, 157 Riehl, 327. 337. 341 Rodbertus, 96, 148. 33«. 37i Rohlfs, 78 Romstorfer, 158 Roscher. 187. 245. 246. 37o Rosegger, 163 Potu, 278 Sachau, 64 Sale-shop, 198 Salomon, Ludwig, 2i8 Sapper. 37, 58 Sarasin, 9 Schadenberg, 4. 8. 24. 38. 269, 277 Schaffle. 337. 338 Scheurl, 230 Schliemann, 363 Schloss, 279 Schmaler, 266 Schmeller, 278 Schmeltz, 28 Schmidt. A., 218 Schmoller, 87. 123. 136. 189. 289, 303. 328, 329. 330. 336-338. 342 Schiinberg, I3« Schumann, 357 , Schur'i, 23. 3*^. 58. 66. 67. 75. 76, 270 Schwarzkopf. 234. 237 Schweinfurth, 28. 37. 38, 47. 5J. 72. '9 , . Schweinitz, 263 Schwicker, 158 Seebohm, 280 Semon, 23, 76. 263 Seneca, 372 Serfdom, 95. 167. 280, 305, 322 Settegast, 272 Sexes, distribution of labour De- tween, 30-37. 44. 54, 253 Shortland, 63 Sibree, 271 Sick, exposure of, by savages, 16 Sickel, 230 Sidenbladh, I57 Slavery, 55. 95. 280, 305. 3«7 I't 39* INDEX. Smith. Adam. 87, 139. 151. 245-248, 282-290. 295-O, 303 Smiths, 72 Social differentiation {see Labour, social). 290, 295, 329; rank, 334 Society, organization of. 7. 213, 3^(>. 333 Spedalhation, 287, 294, 305 Spencer, 13, 20 Spinning-rooms. 265-267 Spoken paper, 233 Stage of Individual Search for Food (see Individual); of Inde- pendent Household Economy. 89. 114. 142. 313; of Town Econ- omy, 89, 114. 126, 313. 384; of National Economy, 89, 134, I37i 141.313.383. „ ,. _ Stages, not universally applicable, 12 Stanley. 34, 7Q, '^3 Staple, law of. 123 Starcke. 38 State, absolutist. 138; modern, 378. See Economy, National. Staudinger. 64 Steam, as motive power, 175 V. d. Steinen. 9, 23. 28. 31. 32, 5'. 61, 263 Steinhausen. 222, 229 Stellmacher, 267 Stieda, 123, 130 Stieve. 236 Stock, L., 212 Struggles for adaptation. 366 ff. Sundt, IS7 SUssmilch, 3(19 Sweat-work, 197 Swetjolka, 267 Tacitus, 112, 220 Tarajanz, 158. 165. 166 Tax on land, 114; on general prop- erty, 133 Teale, 4 ".Team-work," 279 Technical skill, development of. 28 Technique. 53 Telephonic contrivances, 78 Thaer. 272 Throwing-stick, 7 ThOnen, 88 Tiebe, 9I Time, use of. 19 Tindall, 81 Town: constitution of, 126; simi- larity of. 273; supremacy of, 133, 373. See Cities. Trade, 59. 124. 125. 145, 206, 257, 309. 331. 373 Trades: division of. 287; formation of. 290, 294 Trading peoples. 73 Trade-mark. 76 Transmission of knowledge among savages. 22 Transportation, 77 Tree-dwelling, 4 Tscheta, 93 Turgot, 87 Uniformity, tendency towards, 194, 310 Usury, prohibition of, 113 Uten, no Vadhmal, 109. 161 Valentinelli. 226 Valerius Maximus, 342 Value, conceptions of. among sav- ages, 21 Verdinglichung, 91 Vierkandt, 42 Villenage. 91 Vocations: rise of, 127; free choice of. 340 Vocational class. 334 Waddewarden. 361. 362 Wages. 132; of management, 132, 167 Wage-work, 154. 162, i63, 176 Wage-workers, class of, 332 Wagner, Adolf. 3 Waitz, 5, 16, 33. 37. 45. 59. 77. 78, Si Wallon, 160 v. Waltershausen, 61 Waterways, 77 Wealth, 131, 143 Weber, 96, 99 Weekly (newspaper). 236-238 Weiske, 120 Welsmann. 329 W Her. 235 We'sers. 230 Wiglitzsky, 158 Winckler. 322, 233 INDEX. 393 Wissmann, lo, i8, 35. S^, 38. 47. SL 72. 74. 75. 77, 79. 80 Witzlebcn, 231 Wolf. 35 , ^.,. . Work: principle of stability and coniinuiiy of, 249; subdivision of, 175. 3«7 Wiilkcr, 221 Wundl, KJ Zadru^v!, 03. 105 Zell, 218 Zwingli -23