CIHM 
 Microfiche 
 Series 
 (IMonograplis) 
 
 ICIMH 
 
 Collection de 
 microfiches 
 (monographies) 
 
 Canadian Instituta for Historical IWIcroraproductlon. / Inatltut Canadian da microraproduction. historiq 
 
 uas 
 
 i 
 
Technical and Bibliographic Notes / Notes techniques et bibllographiques 
 
 Institute has attempted to obtain the best original 
 ^ available for filming. Features of this copy which 
 ' be bibliographicaliy unique, which may alter any of 
 
 images in the reproduction, or which may 
 lificantly change the usual method of filming are 
 :ked below. 
 
 Coloured covers / 
 Couverture de couleur 
 
 Covers danriaged / 
 
 Cou* erture endommag^e 
 
 Covers restored and/or laminated / 
 Couverture restaurde et/ou pellicul^e 
 
 Cover title missing / Le titre de couverture manque 
 
 Coloured maps / Cartes g^ographiques en couleur 
 
 Coloured ink (i.e. other than blue or black) / 
 Encre de couleur (i.e. autre que bleue ou noire) 
 
 Coloured plates and/or illustrations / 
 Planches et/ou illustrations en couleur 
 
 Bound with other material / 
 Reli^ avep d'autres documents 
 
 Only edition available / 
 Seule Edition disponible 
 
 Tight binding may cause shadows or distortion atong 
 interior margin / La reliure serr^e peut causer de 
 I'ombre ou de la distorsion le long de la marge 
 intirieure. 
 
 Blank leaves added during restorations may appear 
 within the text. Whenever possible, these have been 
 omitted from filming / II se peut que certaines pages 
 blanches ajout^es lors d'une restauration 
 apparaissent dans le texte, mais, lorsque cela Itait 
 possible, ces pages n'ont pas M film^es. 
 
 Addittonal comments / 
 Commentaires suppl^mentaires: 
 
 L'Institut a microfilm^ le meilleur exemplaire qu'il lui a 
 6\6 possible de se procurer. Les details de cet exem- 
 plaire qui sont peut-6tre uniques du point de vue bibli- 
 ographique, qui peuvent modifier une image reproduite, 
 ou qui peuvent exiger une modification dans la m^tho- 
 de normale de filmage sont indkju^s ci-dessous. 
 
 j I Coloured pages / Pages de couleur 
 
 I I Pages damaged / Pages endommag§es 
 
 n 
 
 Pages restored and/or laminated / 
 Pages restaurSes et/ou pelliculdes 
 
 Pages discoloured, stained or foxed / 
 Pages d^olor^es, tachet^es ou piqu^es 
 
 I I Pages detached / Pages d6tach6es 
 
 \V\ Showthrough / Transparence 
 
 j I Quality of print varies / 
 
 D 
 D 
 
 D 
 
 Quality in^gale de I'impression 
 
 Includes supplementary material / 
 Comprend du materiel suppl^mentaire 
 
 Pages wholly or partially obscured by errata slips, 
 tissues, etc., have been refilmed to ensure the best 
 possible image / Les pages totalement ou 
 parliellement obscurcies par un feuillet d'errata, une 
 pelure, etc., ont 6\6 film^es h nouveau de fa^on h 
 obtenir la meilleure image possible. 
 
 Opposing pages with varying colouration or 
 discolourations are filmed twice to ensure the best 
 possible image / Les pages s'opposant ayant des 
 colorations variables ou des decolorations sont 
 film^es deux fois afin d'obtenir la meilleure image 
 possible. 
 
 im it fllm«d It lh« rtduclion ratio chacktd b«low / 
 um*nl tit filin4 au Uui da reduction indlqui el-dtitoui. 
 
 14X 
 
 IBX 
 
 12x 
 
 16k 
 
 20x 
 
 22x 
 
 nn 
 
 k6x 
 
 30x 
 
 24x 
 
 28x 
 
 32x 
 
The copy filmad h«r« has baan raproducad thanks 
 to tha ganarosity of: 
 
 National Library of Canada 
 
 L'axamplaira filmA fut raproduit grica k la 
 g4n4rosit* da: 
 
 Bibliotheque nationale du Canada 
 
 Tha jmagas appaaring hara ara tha bast quality 
 possibia eonsidaring tha condition and lagibility 
 of tha original copy and in kaaping with tha 
 filming contract spacifications. 
 
 Original capias in printad papar covars ara filmad 
 baginning with tha front covar and anding on 
 tha last paga with a printad or illustratad impraa- 
 sion, or tha back covar whan appropriata. All 
 othar original eopiaa ara filmad baginning on tha 
 first paga with a printad or illustratad impraa- 
 aion, and anding on tha last paga with a printad 
 or illuatratad imprassion. 
 
 Tha last racordad frama on aach microficha 
 shall contain tha symbol -i«» (moaning "CON- 
 TINUED"), or tha symbol V (moaning "END"). 
 whichavar applias. 
 
 Maps, platas, charts, ate. may ba filmad at 
 diffarant raduction ratios. Thosa too larga to ba 
 antiraly includad in ona axposura ara filmad 
 baginning in tha uppar laft hand cornar, laft to 
 right and top to bonom, as many framas as 
 raquirad. Tha following diagrams illustrsta tha 
 mathod: 
 
 Las imagas suivantas ont M raprodultos avsc la 
 plus grand soin, compta tanu da la condition at 
 da la nattat* da l'axamplaira film*, at an 
 conformity avac las conditions du contrat da 
 filmaga. 
 
 Laa axamplairaa originaux dont la couvartura an 
 papiar aat imprim«a sont film«s an commancant 
 par la pramiar plat at an tarminant soit par la 
 darni*ra paga qui comporta una amprainta 
 d'imprassion ou d'illustration. soit par la sacond 
 plat, salon la caa. Tous las autras axamplairss 
 originaux sont filmte an commanpant par la 
 pramiAra paga qui comporta una amprainta 
 d'imprassion ou d'illustration at an tsrminant par 
 la darni*ra paga qui comporta una taila 
 amprainta. 
 
 Un daa symbolas suivants spparattra sur la 
 darniira imaga da chaqua microficha, talon la 
 cas: la symbols -i^> signifia "A SUIVRE". la 
 symbols ▼ signifia "FIN". 
 
 Las cartas, planchas. tablaaux. ate. pauvant itra 
 filmis i daa taux da reduction diff«rants. 
 Lorsqua la documant ast trap grand pour *tra 
 raproduit an un saul clich«. il ast film* A partir 
 da I'angia supAriaur gaucha. da gaucha i droita. 
 at da haut an bas, an pranant la nombra 
 d'imagaa nAcassaira. Las diagrammas suivants 
 illustrant la mithoda. 
 
 1 
 
 2 
 
 3 
 
 1 
 
 2 
 
 3 
 
 4 
 
 5 
 
 6 
 
MtCROCOPV RiSOlUTION TfST CHART 
 
 lANSI ond ISO TEST CHART No. 2) 
 
 L" n2s 
 
 y. 1^5 
 
 
 12.2 
 
 li 
 
 HUH. 
 
 IMI 1.8 
 
 1.6 
 
 A APPLIED IM^GE Inc 
 
 161-' East Uoin 'jlrwt 
 
 Rochester, N«« York ' - ,19 USA 
 
 (716) 482 - 0300 - PHon, 
 
 (7)6) 28B - 19B9 - fo. 
 
I 
 
 INDUSTRIAL EVOLUTION 
 
 BY 
 
 CARL BUCHER 
 
 Pnftsior of Political Economy, Unitersify of Leipeig 
 
 TRAmtATED FROM THE THIRD GERMAN EDITION 
 
 BY 
 
 S. MORLEY WICKETT, Ph.D. 
 Uciunr on Political Economy and Statistics. University of Toronto 
 
 NEW YORK 
 
 HENRY HOLT AND COMPANY 
 190 r 
 
'J- •' 
 
 < 1 
 
 57539 
 
 Copyright, 1901, 
 
 BY 
 HENRY HOLT & CO. 
 
 Published Jult 1901. 
 
 flOaCRT DrtuMMONb, pf^lNT£-', NLW fORfv. 
 
PREFATORY NOTE. 
 
 The writings of Professor Bucher, in their German 
 dress, require no introduction to economists. His ad- 
 mirable work The Population of Frankfurt in the Fourteenth 
 and Fifteenth Centuries, published in 1886, gave him 
 immediate celebrity with economic historians, and 
 left him without a rival in the field of historical statis- 
 tics. In his treatment of economic theory he stands 
 midway between the "younger historical school" of 
 economists and the psychological Austrians.» A full list 
 of his writings need not be given.2 But I may recall 
 his amplified German edition of Laveleye's Primitive 
 Property, his little volume The Insurrections of the Slave 
 Labourers, 143-129 b.c, his original and suggestive 
 Labour and Rhythm, discussing the relation between the 
 
 • A few facts and dates regarding Professor BUcher's career may not 
 be uninteresting. Professor BUcher was born in Prussian Rhineland in 
 .tl: . . ""Pleted his undergraduate studies at Bonn and G6ttingen 
 (1866-69). His rapid rise in the German scholastic world is evident 
 frotn his academic appointments : special lecturer at GSttingen (i86<>- 
 72 . lecturer at Dortmund (1872-73), at Frankfurt Technical School (187,- 
 
 S^r /p r""?J""^' ''"■"^'""^ °' ^'''''^''" ^' Dorpat. Russia 
 (I3S2). of Political Economy and Finance at Basel (1883-90). at Karls- 
 ruhe (1890-93). and at Leipsic (1893 to present). From 1878 to the close 
 of 1880 he was Industrial and Social Editor of the Frankfurter Ztitung 
 This may be found in the HandwSrterbuch d. Staatswiss 
 
IV 
 
 PREFATORY NOTE. 
 
 physiology and the psychology of labour, his investiga- 
 tions into trusts, and his co-editorship of Wagner's Hand- 
 book of Political Economy (the section Industry being in 
 his charge) as indicating the general direction and scope 
 of his researches. The present stimulating volume, which 
 in the original bears the title Die Entstchiing der Volkswift- 
 scliaft (The Rise of National Economy), gives the author's 
 conclusions on general industrial development. Some- 
 what similar ground has been worked over, among recent 
 economic ])ul)licatioiis. alone by Professor Schmoller's 
 comprehensive Crnndrisz dcr allgcmcincn Volksti'irtschafts- 
 Ichrc, Pt. I. But the method of treatment and the results 
 of the present work allow ii to maintain its unique position. 
 Chapters I. and II. outline the prominent features of 
 primitive economic life in the tropical zone. These real- 
 istic accounts of the " pre-economic stage of industrial evo- 
 lution," preceding the dawn of civilization, ably em- 
 phasize the kinship of economics and ethnology. In chap- 
 ter III. he presents brilliantly and concisely the suggestive 
 series of economic developmental stages of household, 
 town and national economy, based on the industrial rela- 
 tion of producer to consumer; and Chapter IV. offers a 
 masterly survey of industrial systems — domestic work, 
 wage-work, handicraft, commission work (house indus- 
 try), and the factory. With these chapters may be classed 
 Chapter V. The Decline of the Handicrafts. The re- 
 maining chapters analyze more specifically, from the 
 viewpoints of the individual and society, some of the great 
 processes of industrial evolution: union and division of 
 labour; the intellectual integration of society as effected 
 by the press; the formation of social classes; and the fur- 
 ther adjustment of labour through internal migrations of 
 population. At the same time they enrich economic 
 terminology with many telling expressions. 
 
PREFATORY NOTE. v 
 
 " The worst use of theory is to make men insensible to 
 fact," Lord Acton remarked in the opening number of the 
 English Historical Review. Our author, with his store 
 of minute facts, his keen analysis and his broad and re- 
 freshing generalizations, has known how to avoid the 
 snare. His historical attitude is indicated by his advice 
 that " our young political economists " be sent on jour- 
 neys of investigation to the Russians, the Roumanians and 
 the southern Slavs rather than to England and America. 
 In the following pages, which in their present form I 
 trust do not entirely obliterate the pleasing style of the 
 original, his attention is, of course, devoted primarily to 
 economic rather than to social and other considerations. 
 The volume has had in Germany an unusually influ- 
 ential circulation, and has recently been translated into 
 French, Russian and Bohemian. As the preface notes, 
 it has done extensive service as a general introduction to 
 " economic thinking." Its use for this purpose, through 
 the medium of special transcriptions, has already been re- 
 marked at some American universities. The hope may be 
 indulged that its merits will now receive wider recognition, 
 and in some measure impart to the reader the stimulus 
 felt by the writer during a two years' attendance on the 
 author's lectures in 1895-97. Editorial annotations, it may 
 be added, have been confined to the narrowest limits. 
 
 In translating it I have had the valuable assistance of 
 my colleague. Dr. G. H. Needier, Lecturer on German, 
 University College, to whom I wish to express my deep 
 obligations. My thanks are also due Professor Biicher for 
 his patient answers to the many queries sent over the water 
 to him, to Professor Mavor for varied aid during the work 
 of revision, and to Mr. H. H. Langton and Mr. D. 
 R. Keys for help in correcting proofs. 
 
VI 
 
 PREFATORY NOTE. 
 
 For the convenience of the general reader a short sup- 
 plementary bibliography of recent works in English is 
 appended. 
 
 University of Toronto, 
 April 9, 1901. 
 
 S. M. W. 
 
 Haddon, Evolution of Art (,895) ; Lloyd Morgmn. Animal Life andlntel- 
 I'gfnce (1891). Habit and Instinct (1896) ; Kcane, Atan Past and Present 
 (1899); Spencer and Gillen, The Native Triies 0/ Central Australia (ii<)t)) ■ 
 Mackenzie, An Jntroducttm to Social Philosophy (2d ed.. 1895) ; Giddings,' 
 I>imip!cs of Sociology' (1896); Gumplowicz, Outlines of Sociology ^trans! 
 1899); \.<^x\&. Economic Foundations of Society (ix2Ln^. i^^f))- Ashley Eco- 
 nomic History (2 pts.. 1888-92). Surveys Historic and Economic (1900)- 
 Gomme, The Village Community (1890) ; Cunningham, Growth of English 
 Industry and Commerce (2 vols.. 1890-92), IVesterr. Civilization (1898) • 
 ^ocx\,. Life and Labours of the People (9 vols.. 1889-97); Mayo-Smith' 
 Emigration and Immigration (1890); Weber, The Growth of Cities (1899); 
 Hobson, The Evolution of Modem Capitalism (1894). 
 
FROM THE PREFACES TO THE FIRST AND 
 SECOND GERMAN EDITIONS. 
 
 (April 1893 and November 1897.) 
 
 The lectures in this volume were originally delivered 
 before audiences that were not composed of specialists 
 exclusively. . . . Each lecture is complete in itself; the 
 same trains of thought are indeed occasionally repeated, 
 but in a different setting. 
 
 Yet it will readily be perceived that the different parts 
 have an inner connection, and supplement each other both 
 in subject and method. The fundamental idea running 
 through them all is expressed in the third. As need 
 scarcely be remarked, the lecture is not printed in the sum- 
 mary form in which it was delivered. I trust that the gain 
 in accuracy and fulness of statement has not been at the 
 expense of clearness. 
 
 The lectures are dominated by a uniform conception of 
 the orderly nature of economic development, and by a sim- 
 ilarity in the method of treating material. In both respects 
 this accords with the practice which I have consistently 
 followed ever since the inception of my academic activity 
 and which during continued scientific work has become 
 more and more clearly and firmly established. With the 
 present publication I accede to the wish expressed by many 
 of my former auditors in the only form at present possible. 
 a form of whose insufficiency I myself am fully conscious. 
 
 In preparing a second edition one thing was clear: the 
 
 vii 
 
VIII 
 
 PREFACE. 
 
 book must be expanded in the direction in which it had 
 been most effective. At its first appearance I had hoped 
 that the little volume might exert some influence upon the 
 method of treating scientific problems; and indeed there 
 has appeared in recent years quite a series of writings by 
 younger authors (some of whom were seemingly wholly 
 unacquainted with my book), in which the resuUs of the in- 
 vestigations here published are taken into account. Tliis is 
 outwardly evidenced by the use of the concepts and the 
 technical expressions that I introduced into the litera- 
 ture of the subject, as if they were old. familiar, scientific 
 furniture. It is perhaps justifiable to infer from this that 
 the book has exercised some influence upon academic 
 teaching. 
 
 But it seems to have found its chief circulation in the 
 wider circles of the educated public, particularly among 
 college students, who have used it as a sort of introduc- 
 tion to economics, and as a preparation for economic 
 thinking. That naturally decided me to keep their wants 
 very particularly in view in revising the book. In order 
 to avoid misconceptions, however. I wish to state ex- 
 pressly that the employment of the book for this purpose 
 requires the concurrent use of a good systematic treatise 
 on the principles of jwlitical economy. 
 
 The better to meet the nee.I of the larger class just men- 
 tionerl, I have given some of the lectures of the first edition 
 a simpler form, expanding them where necessary and 
 eliminating needless detail. Extensive alteration, 'how- 
 ever, has been confmcd to the lecture on the Organization 
 of W ork and the l-..rmation of Social Classes. Here uni- 
 formity of treatment seemed to recommen.l a division into 
 two chapters (YUl and IX). .md such extensive ad.litions 
 as would serve to round off each in-lepen.lently of the 
 other. 1 he lecture on the Social Organization of the Pop- 
 
PREFACE. 
 
 iz 
 
 ulation of Frankfurt in the Middle Ages has been omitted 
 because it disturbed the greater uniformity aimed at for 
 the complete work, and because, as a purely historical ac- 
 count, it is better suited to a collection of sketches in social 
 and economic history, for which opportunity may perhaps 
 be found later. 
 
 On the other hand three unpublished lectures have been 
 added (Chaps. I, V, and VII). The fust of these deals 
 with the pre-economic period, and is intended to furnish 
 the substructure for the system of economic stages which 
 is developed in the third chapter. Its main features were 
 sketched as early as 1885, in a lecture I delivered at the 
 University of Basel on the beginnings of social history. 
 . . . The second agrees in the major part of its matter, 
 and also to a large extent in its form, with the report upon 
 handicrafts that I presented at the last general meeting 
 of the Social Science Club in Cologne. It seems advisable 
 to give it a place in order to afford the reader at one point 
 at least an insight into the great changes that are in prog- 
 ress in the held of modern industrial life. The third [en- 
 titled " Union of Labour and Labour in Common "] is an 
 attempt to lay before a wider circle of readers, in the form 
 in which I finally presented it to my university classes, a 
 chapter from the theory of labour to which I have given 
 considerable attention. 
 
 All the lectures in this volume, both old and new. were 
 originally sections of university lectures. Every lecturer 
 knows what a wonderful contpilation his note-book is. how 
 from semester to semester certain portions must be re- 
 moved and reconstructed, how some parts are never 
 approached without an inward struggle, and how tinally 
 the remaining ditViculties are surmounted and the whole 
 given a form satisfactory alike to teacher and students. 
 To the lecture-room first of all belono- the fruits of 
 
 i 
 
* PREFACE. 
 
 the scientific labours of the German university professor; 
 but he also naturally wishes to submit what he has labori- 
 ously accomplished to the critical judgment of specialists; 
 and for my part I feel in such cases the further need of test- 
 ing the maturity of my conceptions by seeing whether they 
 can be made intelligibly acceptable to a wider range of 
 readers. So th^t all the lectures that have been taken over 
 from the first edition were actually delivered before a more 
 popular audience, while Chapters I and VII are essays in 
 the same style. In the extent of their subject-matter, how- 
 ever, they all reach far beyond what can be offered directly 
 to students in a university lecture. 
 
 In conclusion I may allude to two attacks that have 
 been delivered by historians against some parts of the third 
 and fourth lectures. The blame surely does not rest with 
 nie if these gentlemen have failed to perceive that this 
 work treats of economic theor>-. not of economic history. 
 I le who, in the outline of a period of de\'elopment extend- 
 ing over thousands of years, expects a minute and ex- 
 haustive presentation of the actual condition of any par- 
 ticular people and centun-. need blame only himself if he 
 is disappointed. In the first edition I expressed myself 
 clearly enough. I think, regarding the logical character of 
 the economic stages. In the present edition I have taken 
 (H-casion. however, to give the passages in question such a 
 form that in future they cannot with good intentions be 
 misuii.lerstood. . . . Though fdr the central idea of my 
 theory of development it is altogether immaterial whether 
 I have in every particular characterized the economy of 
 the (Ireeks and Romans correctly or not. or whether the 
 guild handicraft of the Midille .\ges was chiefly wage-wx>rk 
 or chiefly independent hand-work {,' price-work *'). 
 
PREFACE TO THE THIRD GERMAN EDITION. 
 
 In the present edition, bearing in mini the way in which 
 this book came into existence and has since expanded, I 
 felt strongly impelled to mark my appreciation of the 
 recognition it has gained, as indicated by several editions 
 and by translations into French, English. Russian, and 
 Bohemian, by preparing additional chapters to remove a 
 number of gaps still noticeable in the last issue. If I have 
 not yielded to the temptation, it is chiefly for the reason 
 that a larger bulk would necessarily prejudice the wider 
 circulation of the volume. 
 
 The most disturbing want has been met by the insertion 
 of a new chapter on the economic life of primitive peoples 
 (Chapter II). The chapter differs from the more detailed 
 one in volume 3 uf the Yearbook of the Gehe Stiftung 
 in its more summar>- form and in the addition of some not 
 unimportant facts. 
 
 All the other chapters have been carefully revised and 
 many slight improvements made. More extensive alter- 
 ations are confmed to Chapters I. III. Vll, and VIII. 
 
 May the book in its present form satisfy its old friends 
 and add new ones to the number! 
 
 C.\RL Pii'CHER. 
 Lkipzk,. Oct. 15, 190a 
 
 xi 
 
\y 
 
 CONTENTS 
 
 rAcs 
 
 Prefatory Note iii 
 
 From the Prefaces to First and Second Ge^.man Editions... vii 
 
 Preface to Third German Edition xi 
 
 Chapter I. — Primitive Economic Conditions i 
 
 II. — The Economic Life ok Primitive Peoples 41 
 
 N^ III.— The Rise of National Economy 83 
 
 IV. — A Historical Survey of Industrial Systems... 150 
 
 V. — The Decline of the Handicrafts 185 
 
 VI. — The Genesis of Journalism 215 
 
 VII.— Union of Labour and Labour in Common 244 
 
 jt- VIII.— Division of Labour 282 
 
 IX.— Organization of Work and the Formaiion of 
 
 Social Classes 315 
 
 X.— Internal Migrations of Population *ni) the 
 
 Growth of Towns Considered Historically 345 
 
 Index 387 
 
CHAPTER I. 
 
 PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 All scientific investigation of industry starts with the 
 assumption that man has a peculiar " economic nature " 
 belonging to no other living creature. From this eco- 
 nomic nature a principle is supposed to spring, which con- 
 trols all his actions that are directed to the satisfaction of 
 his wants. This is the economic principle, the fundamen- 
 tal principle of economic activity. This principle reveals 
 itself in man's endeavour always and everywhere to attain 
 the highest possible satisfaction with the least possible sac- 
 rifice (labour)— the " principle of least sacrifice." 
 
 According to this view all man's economic actions are 
 actions directed toward an end and guided by considera- 
 tions of profit. Whether or not the final impulse to eco- 
 nomic labour is to be sought in the instincts of man (the 
 instinct of self-preservation and of self-interest), the satis- 
 faction of these instincts is always the result of a series of 
 successive mental operations. Man estimates the extent 
 of the discomfort that -ould arise from the non-satisfac- 
 tion of a want felt by him; he measures the discomfort that 
 the labour necessary to meet the want can cause him; he 
 compares tlie discomforts witli each <ithcr. and resolves to 
 undertake the labour only when the accompanying sacrifice 
 
a PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 is less than the sacrifice of remaining unsatisfied. More- 
 over, upon undertakmg the labour he again chooses the 
 least burdensome among the various possible methods of 
 procedure, and thus has a further series of considerations, 
 estimations. comi)arisons, and judgments to enter upon. 
 
 In fact the whole science of political economy proceeds 
 on the assumption that economic actions have behind them 
 a rational motive and call into play the higher mental facul- 
 ties; and it ha-^ evolved a kind of psyciiology of labour, by 
 means of whic.i it seeks to explain those actions in their 
 typical progress. Economic activity is, therefore, some- 
 thing especially human; indeed the question whether the 
 lower animals display similar activity, seems never to have 
 been broached. The economic nature of man is something 
 absolute, inseparable from the very character of man.' 
 
 Yet even among civilized mankind, from whose manifold 
 activity the principle of economy has lieen deduced, indi- 
 cations are not wanting to sl.ow that the economic nature 
 must be characteristic of different individuals in different 
 degree. Between the industrious and the indolent, the 
 provident and the improvident, the sparing and the spend- 
 thrift, there are innumerable gradations; and if we only 
 observe the conduct of the child towards his possessions, 
 we are easily convinced that the " economic nature " must 
 be acquired anew by each human being, and that it is a 
 result of education and custom, in which individuals dififer 
 no less than in their whole physical and mental develop- 
 ment. 
 
 Having once reached this point, we shall scarcely be 
 
 •"The elements of economic character are firmly rooted in the 
 physical and intellectual (irKanization of man, and change just as little 
 n-^ his (.utward character does, at least in the periods which come within 
 the scope of the history of mankind." -Wagner, Grmdlegung d. polit. 
 OekoHomk (,v Aufl.), I, p. 82. [As for animal sociology, it can hardly 
 be said to have advanced as yet hcyond animal psychology.— Eu.] 
 
PRIMITII^E ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 be 
 
 able to postpone the question, whether indeed that " eco- 
 nomic nature " does not, for mankind in general, signify 
 something acquired rather than something given by na- 
 ture; and whether we must not assume at the beginning 
 of human evolution a period of purely instinctive satisfac- 
 tion of wants reaching over many thousands of years, such 
 as we are accustomed to take for granted in the case of the 
 lower animal. 
 
 The answer to this question can be gained only by pro- 
 ceeding inductively. The picture of primitive man that we 
 make for ourselves must be not an imaginary one — no 
 Robinson Crusoe story such as is so often encountered in 
 the deductions of the " classical " economists. Its lines 
 must all be drawn from reality; they must show us the 
 actuality of the assumed conditions under which uncivil- 
 ized man lives and the impulses under which he is con- 
 ceived to act and later also think. Civilized man has al- 
 ways had a great inclination to read his conceptions and 
 feelings into the mind of primitive man; but he has only 
 a limited capacity for understanding the latter's undevel- 
 oped mental life and for interpreting, as it were, his nature. 
 
 To be sure, aboriginal man in actual existence can no- 
 where now be found. Great as is the number of primitive 
 peoples that have gradually come within our ken. none of 
 them stands any longer at the lowest stage of savagery; 
 all show traces of the first step in civilization, for all know 
 the use of fire. 
 
 Many writers, it is true, have imagined, under the stim- 
 ulus of evolutionist theories, that they hail succeeded, 
 now here, now there, in discovering populations pre- 
 serving the original animal state down to the present. 
 As late a writer as Sir John Lubbock is inclined to 
 deny to several tribes of the South Sea Islands a 
 knowledge of fire, O. Peschel has been at pains to 
 
PRmiTlVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 prove that the instances adduced by Lubbock are in- 
 correct; 2 and with him we may regard as vaHd the asser- 
 tion that upon the whole earth the tribe that has not made 
 use of fire is yet to be found. Even the prehistoric cave 
 discoveries, which show us men of the Ice Age along with 
 the bear, the aurochs, and the reindeer, show traces of the 
 use of fire. Fire indeed is a powerful influence in the direc- 
 tion of civilization. It enlarges man's sphere of suste- 
 nance, teaches him to harden the points of the wooden 
 arrows and spears, to hollow out the tree, and to frighten 
 away the wild beasts. 
 
 Other investi<:;fators have imagined they have discovered 
 human beings who lived together in small groups in trees, 
 had fruits for food, and used only stones and cudgels as 
 weapons and instruments, after the fashion of the higher 
 apes. Frederick Engels^ is of the opinion that by this as- 
 sumption alone can we explain the continued existence of 
 man alongside the great beasts of prey. Lippert,who inves- 
 tigates the case more carefully,^ finds, it is true, that in the 
 myth of the Egyptians the tree plays a certain role as an 
 abode of spirits; inn he is prudent enough not to conclude 
 from this that the ancestors of the Egyptians dwelt in 
 trees, — more prudent than the philoloi^ist Lazarus Geiger, 
 who discovered a relic of tree-dwelling in the hammock 
 used by the South American Indians. It is true that in 
 Sumatra, Luzon, New Guinea, the Solomon Islands, and 
 
 'Races of Man (New York. 1888), pp. 137 ff. I know, indeed, that 
 the Anicricin writer Teale (quoted i)y Lippcrt. Kultwgcschichte der 
 Mcnschhcit. I. p. 5_>) has cdntradicted him in one instance. Mundt- 
 LaufT lias also, according to Pesclul in " Natiir " for the year 1879, p. 
 4-8, denied the ii^e of cooked food hy the Xei;ritos in tlte IMiilippines, 
 but his assertions again liave been refuted by .\. Schadenberg in the 
 Ztschr. f. Ethnologie, XII (1880), pp, 14,^4. [Xo ethnologist would 
 now claim fireless tribes as known in actual existence. — En.] 
 
 * Der Ursprung dcr Familic, des Privatcigciituws u. dcs Staats. p. 7. 
 
 * As above, pp. 67 ff. 
 
PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 5 
 
 among the Gaberi negroes in Central Africa, huts have 
 been found built in between the branches of large trees; » 
 and the same is reported of individual forest tribes of South 
 America.® But so far as these products of primitive archi- 
 tecture are not mere temporary protective structures that 
 are supplemented by permanent dwelling-places upon the 
 ground, they are by no means the most unfinished of hab- 
 itations, and the peoples using them prove by many kinds 
 of implements, utensils, and domestic animals, and some 
 of them even by the agriculture they carry on, that they no 
 longer stand at the first dawn of civilization. 
 
 After what has been said there can be no object in 
 searching out uncivilized peoples and beginning with a 
 description of them, after the example of Klemm who 
 opens his General History of Civilization with the Fo'-est 
 Indians of Brazil, although it is not to be denied that e 
 stand at a very low cultural stajje indeed. In the & ne 
 connection other investigators cite tribes standing at no 
 higher stage: the Bushmen in South Africa, the Batuas 
 in the Congo basin, the Veddahs in Ceylon, the ^lincopies 
 in the Andaman Islands, the Negritos in the Philippines, 
 the Australians of the continent, the now extinct Tas- 
 manians, the Kubus in Sumatra, and the Tierra-del-Fue- 
 gians. To whom to adjudge the palm for savagerv might 
 be difficult to decide. O. Peschel ' finds individual ele- 
 ments of civilization among them all, even among the 
 Botokudos, whom he himself considers still nearest the 
 primitive state. 
 The assumption of such a primitive condition, in which. 
 
 ' Nachtigal, Sahara u. Sudan, II, pp. 628 flf. Finsch. Samoafahrten. 
 pp. 271 f. Ratzel. \-6lkerkunde. I. pp. loi, 105, 245, 386; li, p. 83. 
 [Its different arrangement precludes citation from the admirable Eng- 
 lish edition: The History of Mankind. 2 vol?., London, 1896-97.— Ed.] 
 Waitz, Anthropologic d. Naturvolker. Ill, p. 393. 
 
 ' Races of A/oi;, pp. 149 ff. 
 
PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 armed witli no other resources than are at the command of 
 the lower animal, man has to join in tlie struggle for exist- 
 ence, is one of the necessary expedients of all sciences that 
 aim at a history of man's development; and this is true of 
 sociology' and especially of political economy. We must, 
 however, abandon the attempt to exemplify the primitive 
 condition by any definite people. On the other hand, there 
 is more prospect of scientific results in an endeavour to 
 collect the common characteristics of the human beings 
 standing lowest in the scale, in order, by starting with 
 them, to arrive at a i)":ture of the beginnings of economic 
 life and the formation of society. But in this it is by no 
 means necessary to confine ourselves to the above-men- 
 tioned representatives of the lowest manner of life; for 
 every delimitation of that kind would challenge objections 
 and contract the field of vision. Moreover the various ele- 
 ments of mental culture and material civilization are by 
 no means so mutually dependent that all must necessarily 
 develop at an equal pace, and thus we find among almost 
 all primitive peoples characteristics that can have sprung 
 only from the most ancient mode of life. The collection 
 of these characteristics, and their combination into a 
 typical picture, must, however, be our first task. 
 
 Hitherto the process has usually been made too simple 
 by deriving the characteristics of primitive man from civil- 
 ized economic man. The many wants of man in a state of 
 nature, so it has been argued, demanded for their satisfac- 
 tion exertions beyond the capacity of the individual; pro- 
 tection from wild bea:;ts or from the unchained elements 
 could likewise be attained only by the labour of many. 
 Accordingly writers have spoken of a collective carrying- 
 on of the struggle for existence, and thus have had " prim- 
 itive society " and a sort of communistic economy com- 
 plete. 
 
PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIJSS. 
 
 But man has undoubtedly existed through immeasur- 
 able periods of time without labouring. If so disposed, 
 one can find plenty of districts upon the earth where 
 the sago-palm, the plantain-tree, the breadfruit-tree, the 
 cocoa- and date-palm, still allow him to live with a mini- 
 mum of exertion. It is in such districts that tradition is 
 fondest of placing paradise, the original home of mankind; 
 and even modern research cannot dispense with the as- 
 sumption that mankind was at first bound to such regions 
 of natural existence and only by further development be- 
 came capable of bringing the whole earth into subjection. 
 Of unions into organized society we find, moreover, 
 hardly a trace amon- the lowest races accessible to our 
 observation. In little roups * like herds of animals they 
 roam about in search of food, find a resting-place for the 
 night in caves, beneath a tree, behind a screen of brush- 
 wood erected in a few minutes to shelter them from the 
 wind, or often in a mere hollow scooped in the ground, 
 and nourish themselves chiefly with fruits and roots, 
 though all kinds of animal food, even down to snails, mag- 
 gots, irrasshoppers, and ants are eaten also. The men as 
 a rule . t armed simply with bow and arrow or with a 
 throwing-stick; the chief implement of the women is the 
 digging-stick, a pointed piece of wood, which they use in 
 searching for roots. Shy when they come in contact with 
 members of a higher race, often malicious and cruel, they 
 lead a restless life, in which the body, it is true, attains the 
 maximum of agility and dexterity, but in which technical 
 skill advances only with extreme sluggishness and one- 
 sidedness. The majority of peoples of this type know 
 nothing whatever of potter>- and the working of metals. 
 Even of wood. bast, stone, and bone they make but limited 
 'Comp. en this point E. Grosse. DU Format dcr Familie und die 
 
 fc 
 
 ii: iicr ;; irtscn^r:. p. 
 
» PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 use, and this use leads in no way to a stock of utensils and 
 tools, which indeed it would I)e impossible to carry about, 
 I)ecause of their nomadic life, bearing as it does the char- 
 acter of one continuous search for food." 
 
 •In order to puppleniunt this general account by a few details I will 
 here introduce ;i portion oi the description of the NcRritos in the 
 Philippines published in the work by A. Scliadenberg. cited above. 
 I Mive for the most par' his own words:— The women among the 
 Etas bear easily and (piickiy. Until able to walk, the child is carried 
 by the mother, generally on the left thiRh. in which case it assumes 
 a sort of riding posture; or upon the back, as soon as it is able to 
 hold Itself on. The mother nur^e^ it for about two years. .\t about 
 the tenth year puberty comes; the Negrito youth is then tattooed, 
 and from the moment when this decoration of his body is finished he 
 IS iiiuependent. He accordingly hjoks about him for a male, who has 
 in tile majority of cases been selected for h 'ii beforehand and who. 
 if possible, belonRS to the same " family." The members of a " family," 
 which generally numbers twenty to thirty persons, are under the con- 
 trol of an elective chieftain, who decides upon the camping-places 
 and the time for breaking up. The family life is patriarchal in char- 
 acter The father has imlimitid power over the members of his 
 family; he can chasiisi them and even barter away his children; the 
 woman occupies a subordinate position and is treated as a chattel. 
 The Negritos carry on barterni',,' wiih the Tagalas; in this way they 
 get supplies, chiefly of iron, in exchange for honey and wa.\. By 
 means of the iron thus ac(|uircd they i>reparc part of their weapons, 
 whi-'h consist of hunting-knives, .irrows. bows, and -pears The 
 Negritos ,ire also very clever at throwing stones, in which they arc 
 greatly a--i-ted by their keenness of vision. .\ ston.- in the hand of 
 an otherwise unarmed Negrito is thus an otTensive and defensive 
 wenpon not to be despised. Their clothing is very scant, hardly more 
 th.iii a lireich-clou; l)omestn- utensils f.ir periiMiieiU use are 
 scarcely fotiiid at ill ;niio!ii.' the I'.i.is; soiiu'iimes ,i clay vessel got 
 by barter witlt the M,il:i>>. ,in<l as a rule .' piei e of bimboo from 
 tliree lii fiiiir fmtns in |. iigtii lor li.il.luig drinkiu'.; w;i<er. Their 
 toes ,,rr pnlien-ile. :i"d iir-- of me it a-sis|:iiice to tlii'iii in cliiii!>:;i^; 
 111 t!ie iralicr (.f imul tlir> .ire not i.isiidioii^ ; it is both amm;il ,ind 
 M'.M'iab'e 111 chai.utrr — roots. Iiuiiey, lr..g,, il.er, wild bo.ar. etc. .A 
 Sp.ini-li e;iie-.i:i-iir dcM-rilfes tin ni ,i^ follow,: "Tin pure .\itos or 
 Negrito, l.acl a s,c!u(lr.| life; th.y li.ive ii.. fised dwelling-place and 
 d.. not l.irM ti;'?- Tli,- i.hIkt. tli.' iiiotlnr. and the children ;ire all 
 pr.fvided wi'h arrows, each lining Ins tiwti. .md tiny -et out together 
 
PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 9 
 
 These peoples liave been designated "lower nomads"; 
 but it can scarcely be proven that actual hunting forms 
 their chief means of sustenance. They all make use of 
 vegetable food as far as it is at all obtainable, and with 
 those who live in a warmer climate this food seems to pre- 
 dominate. Stores of such fruits and roots they do not 
 gather, though a region of plentiful supplies attracts a 
 greater number of members of the tribe, as a rich feeding- 
 ground draws together many lower animals; when it is 
 exhausted they scatter again. And similarly as to the 
 mollusks and insects which they consume; each individ- 
 ual at once swallows what he finds; joint household life 
 is as little known as is a house. It is only when a large 
 animal has been killed or found dead (the fondness for 
 meat in a state of decay is widespread) that the whole 
 group assemlile,"^* and each devours is much as he can; 
 
 upon the hunt. When they kill ,1 dicr or a hoar, they halt at the 
 spot where the animal has fallen, scoop a hole in the ground, place 
 the animal in it and then build a fire. I'ach one takes the piece of 
 the animal that suits his taste hest and roasts it at the fire. And so 
 they go on eating until they have tilled their bellies, and when thus 
 satiated they sleep on the earth which they have hollowed out, as 
 pigs do when they have gorged themselves. W'heTi they awake 
 they go through the same operation, and so on until ;ill the meat is 
 dev.mrod: then they set out upon the hunt at;ain." They observe no 
 fixed times for sleeping and eatmg, but follow necessity in both cases. 
 They age early; at forty or fifty the mountain Xe^ritos are decrepit, 
 white-haireil. bent old iiifii. — Compare further the de^rriptii>n> of 
 the I?otokiidos by l^hrenreich, Zl^chr f. I-.;hnol , \1\. pii 1 tT; of 
 the Hororo^ by K \. d Steinen. (itUr d Wititnolh. Ci-ntiiil-Hrjsii , 
 PP- .iSS <T. : of the Riishmen by I•'rit^ch, a^ abo\e, pp 4iStT ; of the 
 Veddahs by V. and I" Sarasin. /'iV U'cdJils foil ( rvA'/l; of the .\us- 
 trdians by Hreniaiio. Ztschr, f. Sozial- ti. Win^rliaftsneschichte, I, 
 
 PP- i.(.l-4 
 
 '" I'rom the custom prevalent among some of the lower tribc^ of 
 procliiiniii),; the tindin.ir of food by means of lnuci call-. Lippert, as 
 abo\e, I. p J4(), coiiclu'lc- tli.it "the coti^iile'i'ion dne to the fami'y " 
 is cxprPNScd m ibn n iv It! ibi.. inmn-.-lMti il is in ti,. i li>rrv I'd ili.at 
 
lo 
 
 rRlMlTiyE ECCSOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 but tlic method nf hunting these animals strongly resem- 
 bles the proce»lure of the wild beast stealing upon its prey. 
 
 With their imperfect weapons these peoples are hardly 
 ever in a position to kill an animal instantly; the chief 
 task of the hunter consists in pursuing the wounded game 
 until it sinks down exhau.-.ted." 
 
 Regarding the constitution of the family among peo- 
 ples of this class, there has been much discussion. Of late 
 the opinion seems to be gaining ground that there exists 
 among them a fellowship between man and wife that ex- 
 
 onds beyond a mere -exual relationship and is of life-long 
 duration; while upon the other hand it cannot be denied 
 that in case of a scarcity of food those loose groups easily 
 split up. or at least individual members detach themselves 
 from them. Only between mother and child is the rela- 
 tionship particularly close. The mother must always take 
 her little one along with her on the march; and for that 
 purpose she usually fastens it in some way on her back, a 
 custom that is very general among all primitive peoples, 
 even where they have gone over to agriculture. For sev- 
 eral years the child must be nurtured at the breast or from 
 the mother's mouth, but it soon acquires skill in procuring 
 its food independently, and often separates itself from the 
 community in its eighth or tenth year. 
 
 All the tribes involved in our survey belong to the 
 smaller races of mankind, and in bodily condition give the 
 
 many animals (for ixaniple, our domestic fowl) have the :ame cus- 
 tom. True, he lays stress upon the fact that no one thinks of collect- 
 ing' stores of provision*. 'Inercfore, we are, lurther. not justified in 
 agreeinff to the proposal that has recently been made from several 
 sides t" designate these peoples is gatherers of stores {Samnilcr). 
 
 " Ciinip. li. Fritsch. DU- lliitgeboretun Stid-.lfrikas, pp. Jti4. 4^5; 
 Pofivre, Im Krichf d. Muatn Jiinin'o. pp. .128-0; W'issniann. /m Innem 
 .-Jfri'i,?. (!•>. ::'(). -,41; Martins, Zur Lthiwgral'Ue Aiicrikas, cufflal 
 Brasilu'is. pp. <'('5 ff. 
 
PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC COSDITIOSS. 
 
 1 1 
 
 impression of backward:, stunted gro-.vth. We are not on 
 that account, howe'.er, ju^f.ne'i :n re.i'ar iing them as ce- 
 generate race fragrr.en-s. The evylence rather goes to 
 sho'.v that the more a'i anccl races o.ve their higher 
 physical development merely to the reg"u',ar and more 
 plentiful supply of food -Ahich agriculture and cattle- 
 raising for centuries ;'.'a-t have placed within their reach, 
 while the peoples here in question have always remained 
 at the same stage. Subject to all the vicissitudes of the 
 weather and the fortune of the chase, thev revel at times 
 in abundance and devour incredible mas-es of food: :tiil 
 oftener. however, they sufrer bitter wan:, and their only 
 article of clothing, the breech-clout, is for them, really the 
 ■"hunger-strap" ' " Schmachtnemien "i A Germ.an story, 
 which they tighten -d^^ in order to alleviate the pangs of 
 gnawing hunger.' - 
 
 How from this stage of primitive existence the pa.h 
 leads upward is manifest in countless typical e.\ample5 
 furnished by ethnology. In addition to the collection of 
 wild fruits and roots, the womian takes over the cultiva- 
 tion o: food-plants. This she carries on at nrst witli the 
 customary digging-stick, later with a short-handled hoe. 
 The man continues hi; hunting ani' ti-hing. which, in rich 
 hunting-grounds and ui'h more ['Crfect v. eap'^n-. he can 
 make so pr luctive that \'rt/ f-.irni-h the greater ---art of 
 his food. .\t times he supplements these by cattle-raiding. 
 In the procuring of :oo<i each sex has it- sharply denned 
 -phete of duties ti> vvhioh with advancing technical skill 
 there are added in each ca«e •- .iriou^ industrial arts, which 
 a- .'i rule retain their connecti'.n witii the "riginal produc- 
 tion and occupation .Among advanced primitive peoples 
 
 "-c- the Bu^hr-.er. ccT.p Fr.!^;h. at i'--.': ;. 405. -jn the .Xus- 
 •ra'i-i-- Pesch*!, PiCff f M:n p \u: r. the Botokud^j. Ehrenreich 
 
12 
 
 PRlM/r/yE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 all economic activity may be traced back to combinations 
 of these elements; but in its details such labour is entirely 
 dependent ui^on local natural conditions. We should 
 therefore not be justified in any attempt to construct sta-es 
 of development intended to hold equally good for negroes 
 Papuans, Polynesians, and Indians. 
 
 But wherever we can observe it, the method in which 
 primitive peoples satisfy their wants reminds us continu- 
 ally in many of its features of the instinctive doings of the 
 lower animals. Everywhere their existence is still far from 
 settled, and even the unsubstantial huts they erect are for 
 the majority only temporary structures which, however 
 much they vary from place to place and from tribe to tribe, 
 always remain true to a type, and remind us of the nests of 
 birds, which are deserted as soon as the brood is fledged. 
 When Lippert finds the fundamental and controlling 
 impulse to cultural development in material foresight, he 
 undoubtedly makes an advance upon earlier investigators; 
 but the phrase itself is not happily chosen. It is utterly 
 impossible to speak of foresight, in the sense of providing 
 for the future, in connection with primitive peoples. 
 Primitive man does not think of the future; he does not 
 think at all; he only wills, that is, he wills to preserve his 
 existence. Tlie instinct of self-preservation and self-grati- 
 fication is the prime agent of development, compared with 
 which even the sexual instinct takes quite a secondary 
 place. 
 
 Wherever it has been possiI)Ie for Europeans to observe 
 men in primitive conditions for any k-ngth of time they 
 tell us of the incomparable dulncss and mental inertness 
 which strike the neholder; of their indifference tr. the sub- 
 limcst phenomena of nature, their complete lack of interest 
 in evcr\thing that lies outside the individual self. The 
 savage is willing to cat. sleep, and. wh .tc ncccssarv. to pro 
 
PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 13 
 
 tect himself against the greatest inclemencies of the 
 weather: this is his whole aim in life. 
 
 It is therefore entirely false and contrary to numer- 
 ous well-accredited observations when Peschel straightway 
 ascribes to savages a peculiar wealth of fanciful imag- 
 inings of a religious nature, and thinks that the closer the 
 approach to the condition of nature the greater the range 
 of belief. He evidently assumes that the course of the sun 
 and the other phenomena of the heavens must be infinitely 
 more impressive and stimulative of active thought to the 
 primitive than to the civilized man. But that is by no 
 means the case. Both among the Indians of Brazil and 
 among the negroes, when travellers have asked about 
 these things, the response has been that people never 
 thought about them; and Herbert Spencer '•' has collected 
 an abundance of examples which show that the lover races 
 do not manifest any interest even in the most novel phe- 
 nomena. The Patagonians, for example, displayed utter 
 indifference when they were made to look into a mirror; 
 and Dampier reports that the .\ustralians whom he had 
 taken on board of his ship paid attention to nothing but 
 what they got to eat. Burton'* calls the East .\fricans 
 " Men who can think, but who, absorbed in providing for 
 their bodily wants, hate the trouble of thinking. His [the 
 East African's] mind, limited to the object seen, heard, 
 and felt, will not, and apparently can not, cscaj^e from the 
 circle of sense, nor will it occupy itself with aught but the 
 present. Thus he is cut off from the pleasures of memory, 
 and the world of fancy is altogether unknown to him." "■' 
 The same force, then, that impels the lower animal, the 
 
 " Prmciplcs of Sociology, vol. I. 8§ 45-6. 
 
 I* The Lake Regions of Central Africa ( New York, iWx)), p 480. 
 
 "Oiinp. tlie siniil.ir opinion of the mission.iry Cr.in?. Ifistorie von 
 Cronlatid (Frankfurt. 1780). p. i6.i, at.d Lubbock. Oriem -f Civili:atioH 
 (4th ed.). pp. 51^ 7, 
 
 .^i0 
 
M 
 
 PRIMITiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 instinct for preserving its existence, is also the dominant 
 instinctive impulse of primitive man. This instinct is lim- 
 ited in scope to the single individual; in respect of time, 
 to the moment at which the want is felt. In other words: 
 the savage thinks only of himself, and thinks only of the 
 present. What lies beyond that is as gootl as closed to his 
 mental \ ision. When, therefore, many observers reproach 
 him with a boundless egoism, hardness of heart towards his 
 fellows, greed, thievishness, inertness, carelessness with re- 
 gard to the future, and forgetfulness. it means that sym- 
 pathy, memory, and reasoning power are still entirely un- 
 developed. Nevertheless it will be wise for us to make 
 these ver}' characteristics our starting-point, in order to 
 comprehend the relation of primitive man to the external 
 world. 
 
 In the first place, as concerns the egoism of the savage 
 and his harducs. of heart towards his nearest relations, this 
 is a natural consequence of the restless nomadic life in 
 which each individual cares only for himself. It shows 
 itself most prominently in the extraordinarily widespread 
 custom of infanticide, which extremely few primitive peo- 
 ples are entirely free from.'* The children impede 'he 
 horde on the march and in the search for food. Therein 
 lies the chief reason for their removal. Once become a 
 custom, infanticide lives on in later stages of civilization; 
 indisputable traces of it have been found not merely among 
 the primitive peoples of Asia, Africa, America, Australia, 
 and Polynesia, but even among the Arabs, the Romans, 
 and the Greeks. 
 
 To infanticide is universally ascribed the exceptionally 
 slow increase of the uncivilized races. But this is also de- 
 pendent upon their short lives, and long lactation pe- 
 
 "' Comp. Lippert, II, pp. 201 flf. ; R.itzcl, lolkcrkunde, I, pp. 108, J54, 
 252, 277, 306, 338, 425. 
 
PRlMITiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 15 
 
 riods, during which, as is well known, conception rarely 
 occurs, and this it is which forms the chief cause of their 
 protracted tarrying at the same stage of civilization. That 
 the natural bond between parents and children is nowhere 
 very firm is seen also in the extremely common custom of 
 adoption.'^ It is even said, for example, that in the " fam- 
 ilies " of the Mincopies the children of other parents are in 
 the majority. It is significant that between thtir own and 
 their adopted chililren they make, as a rule, not the slight- 
 est difference. Adoption may have arisen from the substi- 
 tution of child-exposure for infanticide. If the natural 
 mother was not in a position to take the new-born child 
 along with her. perhaps another woman who was childless 
 could, and thus the life of the child was saved. 
 
 Recent ethnographers have been at great pains to prove 
 that the strength of maternal love is a feature common 
 to all stages of civilization. It is, indeed, a matter of 
 regret to us that we find wanting in our own si>ecie5 a 
 feeling that exhibits itself in such a pleasing way among 
 many families of lower animals. Rut there have l>een too 
 many observations s!''owing that among the lower races 
 the mere care for one's own existence outweighs all other 
 mental emotions, in fact that be>i'!e it nothing e'^e is of the 
 least importance. .Ml observers are amazed and even in- 
 dignant at the ir.ditlerence with which children, when (;nce 
 they can shift for themselves, separate from their blo^jd- 
 relations.''* Vet we have here onlv the reverse side of that 
 
 " Comp. Luhhook, Origin of Ci7i!i:atirii, pp. o;-6, 
 
 "Co;iip. the strikintj example -n R.itzel. l',4kerkuttde, I, p. 677. of a 
 tiny of Tierr.i iJel Fucro who, when taken on board a European ship, 
 did nut show the slighte'-t grief over the separation, while his paretits 
 were delighted to get a few necklace* and some bi-cuits in return fijr 
 him. The seHing "f children and women into slaver>- doe.s not occur 
 in .Vfrica alone. Martius. as above, p uj Cump. Pjit, Afr. Juris- 
 frudeti:, I, p. 94. 
 
i6 
 
 PRIMlTiyE FCONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 hardness of lieart which " enables husbands to refuse food 
 to tlieir wives, and fathers, to deny it to their hungering 
 children, wlien they tliemselves would but feast upon it." 
 
 This same trait of unbounded selfishness is manifest in 
 the regardlessness with which many primitive peoples 
 leave behind them on the march, or exjKise in solitary 
 places, the sick and the aged who might be an impediment 
 to the vigorous.'" This trait has often been interpreted 
 as a sign of superstition, as due to the fear of evil powers 
 to whom the illnesses are ascribed. And in fact in the case 
 of tribes that have become settled and whose means of sub- 
 sistence would admit of the care of the sick, appearances 
 favour such an explanation. But at the same time it is 
 forgotten that customs, once firmly rooted, perpetuate 
 themselves with great persistence, even when the causes 
 that gave rise to them have long since passed away. 
 
 I'rom exposure to intentional killing is only a short step. 
 Indeed we find even among peoples on a higher plane of 
 civilization that old age is deplored as a state of extreme 
 joylessness. Barbarism had no affection between relatives 
 to alleviate this condition, but it had it in its power to 
 shorten it; and so. along with exposure, we find the bury- 
 ing, or the killing, or even the devouring of the aged and 
 sick, as numberless examples from Herodotus down to 
 modern times attest. Indeed primitive man was able to 
 look upon the solenm performance of this horrible act as 
 a behest of piety.-" 
 
 When we see how this unbroken nomadic life forced 
 man to devote his whole activity to the securing of food, 
 
 '"Lippert. as above, pp, J20ff., has treated the subject so exhaus- 
 tively thai I may nfrain ironi citiriK examples. Cotnp. also Fritsch, 
 PP- ll6, ,^.i4, ,?5i; Wait/, :i> al)uve, II, p. 401. 
 
 ■■■"Comp the examples cited by Lippert, p. ijj, and Martins, as 
 above, p. I2(). Also l-:hrenreich, lieitrdge s. V'olkcrkundi' Brasil, pp. 
 (y-i-yo.- W'.-iit;'. .Ts :ibi!Vf, I. ;i i.«4) .'r-'r.;.; '.-. )■,.'.':!•/-.,' {\t-\----~ \. '■. 161. 
 
PRJMlTiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 n 
 
 and forbade the concurrent development of those feelings 
 which we regard as the most natural, and how it even .suc- 
 ceeded in giving the appearance of religious duty to what 
 we consider the most abominable crime, we begin to con- 
 ceive how loose must have been the personal bond that 
 held together those little roving groups of human beings. 
 Sexual intercourse could not grow to be such a bond; for 
 what we call love was entirely wanting in it.^' Domestic 
 life, the conception of property and labour in common 
 were as good as non-existent. These could originate only 
 when the circle of wants advanced beyond .he mere food 
 requirement. But this took a much longer time than the 
 majority are wi:!ing to admit. The needs of primitive peo- 
 ples with regard to clothing and house-she'ter are most 
 markedly of an altogether >eci.'ndary na:i;re. 
 
 Turning now to the no less common characteristic of 
 improzidcnce. we must cenainly at fir^t glance be struck 
 with astonishment. One wr.iiid think that hunger, which 
 often brings such great torture to the savage. wuuM of 
 itself have been sufficient to induce him to store up tur 
 future use the food that at time- he ix)~-e-se- in super- 
 abundance. But the observation- tliat ha.c lieen made 
 all indicate that he never thinks of that. " They are not 
 accustomed." says Heckewelder -- of the North American 
 Indians. " to laying in -tire- of provision- exce[)t -unie 
 Indian corn, dry beans, and a few other articles. Hence 
 they are -nmetimes reduced to great -trai:-. and are not 
 seldom in absolute want of the necessaries of life, e-peciallv 
 
 ^ The many wnttr- whu write Ti'^Aadays about the family pay 
 
 j wn-cn prr,:n;ncrice lias 
 
 altogether too httie attention to th;« p'.int. t' 
 
 juniy been jfiven by Lubboek. a? ab..',e. pp. ;.; tT. In the -ame way 
 they overlooked the connection between the tarnily and ;i;e econ..my 
 of the honti 'Comp p. lo above. — F'^r>,' 
 
 "Heckewelder. Induui XaiLf.s. t;c, .\ew edition (Phi;. i88n. pp. 
 io8. 212 (Memoirs rA Hi-r .Soc >_ ' Penn . vn] 121. 
 
i8 
 
 PRlMlTiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 in the time of war." And of the South American tribes 
 another observer reports:^' " It is contrary to their na- 
 ture to be in possession of food-suppHes for longer than 
 one day at most." With many negro tribes it is looked 
 upon as improper to store up food for future need, which 
 belief, it is true, they base upon the superstition that the 
 fragments left over may attract spirits.^* 
 
 Where these peoples, through the short-sighted greed 
 of gain of Europeans, are placed in possession of modern 
 weapons, they usually work incredible havoc with the game 
 in their hunting-grounds. The extermination of tiie 
 boundless buffalo herds of North America is well known. 
 *' The greatest quantities of meat were left lying unused 
 in the thickets," only for the natives in winter-time, when 
 deep snow prevented hunting, to fall a prey to awful 
 hunger, in which even the bark of trees and the roots of 
 grass were not despised. And to-day the natives of Africa, 
 in districts where they carry on a profitable trade with 
 Europeans, are ruthlessly destroying ihe sources of their 
 incomes, the elephant and the caoutchouc-tree. 
 
 Even among the more advanced tribes and individuals 
 this characteristic tloes not fail. " When the carriers re- 
 ceived fresh rations." relates P. Pogge.-*"' " I am certain 
 that they lived l>etter for the first few days than I did. The 
 best goats and fowl were devoured. If I gave them rations 
 for a fortnight, the rule was to consume them in riotous 
 living (luring the first three or four days, only afterwards 
 either to steal from the supply-trains, to beg from me, or 
 to go hungry." In Wadai everything that remains over 
 from the snhan's tabic is burie<l,^^ and at the sacrificial 
 
 " Appun, I'nter den Tropen, p. ,365. 
 
 '' I.ippert. ns nhdvc, I, pp. .VJ-40. 
 
 "As above, p. 14; conip. p. 6. Also Wissniann, Wolf. etc. Im 
 Itrncrn Afrikas. p. 29. 
 
 " Nachtiira!. Sahara u. Sudan. III. p. 2,?o. 
 
PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 19 
 
 feasts of the Indians the guests were obliged to eat up their 
 meat and bread clean. " Overloading of the stomach and 
 vomiting are not unusual on such occasions." -*• 
 
 Closely connected with this waste of supplies is the use 
 that primitive man makes of his time. It is entirely errone- 
 ous, though customary, to imagine that primitive people 
 are particularly expert in measuring time uy the position 
 of the sun. They do not measure time at all. and accord- 
 ingly do not make divisions in it. No primitive people 
 observe fixed meal-times, according to which civilized 
 man regulates his time for work.^* Even such- a relatively 
 advanced tribe as the Bedouins has no conception of time. 
 They eat when they are hungry. Livingstone in one place 
 calls Africa " the blissful region where time is absolutely 
 of no account and where men may sit down and rest them- 
 selves when they are tired." •''« " Even the most trivial work, 
 though it is urgently necessary, is postponed by the negro 
 to as late a date as possible. The native dreams away 
 the day in laziness and idleness, although he knows quite 
 well that for the night he needs his draught of water 
 and his log of wood; nevertheless until sundown he will 
 certainly not disturb himself, and onlv then, or perhaps 
 not before darkness, will he hnally procure himself the 
 necessaries." 3' 
 
 In these words we have touched upon the reproach of 
 mertia to which primitive man is universally subject." 
 
 ='Hcckewelder. as above, p. 213. [Dr. Biicher. quoting from the 
 German translafon, has evidently mistaken the meaning of the pas- 
 sage c.ted. The vomiting and fasting referred to by Heckewelder are 
 profKiratory to the ceremonies, the vomiting being seh-induced.-ED ] 
 
 ^Comp. VV. VVun.lt, /:^/„V.-. I (London. i8g;), pp. j;,., 
 
 ^^ hxtedit. to the Zambesi (N'ew York, 1866), p. 104. 
 
 "^\\. Junker's Travels in Africa; comp. Eng, trans., II, p 168 
 ^or details see my work Arbeit u. Rhytlmus (2d ed.. Leipzig 
 
^Ri* 
 
 90 
 
 PRIMlTiyp. ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 What has here appeared to observers as laziness is again 
 lack of forethought, Hving for the moment. Why should 
 the savage exert himself when once his wants are satisfied, 
 particularly when he is no longer hungr)? This does not 
 imply that he is inactive. With his wretched facilities the 
 individual often performs on the whole as much work as 
 the individual civilized man; but he does no' perform it 
 regularly, nor in ordered succession, but by i. and starts, 
 when necessity forces him to it, or a feeling of exaltation 
 takes possession of him, and even then not as a serious 
 duty of life, but rather in a playful fashion. 
 
 In general, primitive man follows only the prompting of 
 the moment; his conduct is purely impulsive, mere reflex 
 action, so to speak. The nearer his wants and their satis- 
 faction lie together, the better he feels. Primitive man is 
 a child; he thinks not of the future, nor of the past; he 
 forgets easily, each new pression blots out its predeces- 
 sor. All the sufferings of life, \*hich he has to experience 
 so often, can scarcely cloud for a moment his naturally 
 cheerful temperament. "Of the New Caleu i 'ans. Fijians, 
 Tahitians, and New Zealanders we read that they are al- 
 ways laughing and joking. Throughout Africa the negro 
 has the same trait, and of other races, in other lands, the 
 descriptions of various travellers are: 'full of fun and merri- 
 ment,' full of life and spirits." ' merry and talkative,' ' sky- 
 larking in all ways,' ' boisterous gaiety,' ' laughing immod- 
 erately at trifles." "" ^^ 
 
 It is significant, as has often been remarked, that natives 
 of Africa lose their cheerfulness when they have been for 
 some time in the service of Europeans, and become sullen 
 and morose. The explanation of Fritsch ^* is that servants 
 
 " Spencer, as above. § 34. Considerable material also in his Descrip- 
 tive Sociology in the chapter on '" Moral Sentiments." 
 ** As above, p. 56. 
 
PRIMITiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 31 
 
 of this kind gradually acquire from their masters the habit 
 of troubling themselves about things to come, and that 
 their temperament cannot endure engrossment in such 
 
 cares 
 
 38 
 
 Such a hand-to-mouth existence cannot be burdened 
 with conceptions of valw, which always presupposes an act 
 of judgment, an estimation of the future. It is well known 
 how in America and Africa the natives often sold their land 
 to foreign colonists for a gaudy trifle, a few glass beads of 
 no value according to our economic standards; and even 
 to-day the negro, though he stands no longer at the lowest 
 stage, is in many instances ready to give away any piece 
 of his property, no matter how important it may be for his 
 existence, if he is offered some glittering bauble that hap- 
 pens to catch his eye.^" On the other hand his covetous- 
 ness knows no bounds, and it is a constant complaint of 
 travellers that amid all the hospitality shown them they 
 are simply plundered, because ever>' village chieftain de- 
 sires to be presented with everything he sees.'' Here, 
 again, is that naive egoism in its complete regardlessness 
 of self and others, that unbounded covetousness which has 
 nothing in common with the love of gain of economic 
 man. The impression of the moment is ever the sole con- 
 trolling force: what is further removed is not thought of. 
 Primitive man is incapable, it would seem, of entertaining 
 
 " Reference may also be made to the not infrequent examples of 
 savages who had been brought up under civilized conditions volun- 
 tarily returning to their tribes and to the complete savagery of their 
 people. Comp. Peschel. as above, pp. 152-3: Fritsch, as above, p. 
 +2.3; K. E. Jung in Petermanns Mitth.. XXIV (1878), p. 67. 
 
 "Comp. Fritsch. as above, pp. ,?05-C. 
 
 "Says Burton, as above, p. 490: "In trading with [the African] 
 ... all display of wealth must be avoided. A man who would pur- 
 chase the smallest article avoids showing anything beyond its equiva- 
 lent." 
 
22 
 
 PRIMITII^E ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 two thoughts at the same time and of weighing the one 
 against the other; he is always possessed by one alone and 
 follows it with startling consistency. 
 
 The collection of exi)eriences, the transmission of knowl- 
 edge, is therefore exceedingly difficult, and therein lies the 
 chief reason why such peoples can remain at the same 
 stage for thousands of years without showing any appre- 
 ciable advance. The acquisition of the first elements of 
 civilization is often conceived as an easy matter; it is im- 
 agined that every invention, every advance in house-con- 
 struction, in the art of clothing, in the use of tools, that an 
 individual makes, must pass over as an imperishable treas- 
 ure into the conunon possession of the tribe and there 
 continue to. fructify. Tlie invention of pottery, the taming 
 of domestic animals, the smelting of iron ore have even 
 been made the beginnings of entirely new epochs of civil- 
 ization. 
 
 Yet how imperfectly does such a conception appreciate 
 the conditions under which primitive man lives! We may 
 indeed assume tliat he possesses a peculiar fondness for the 
 stone T\t uliicli with endless exertion he has formed in the 
 course perhaps of a whole year, and that it seems to him 
 like ri fK.rt of his own being;""* but it is a mistake to think 
 that the preoinis jK)ssession will now pass to chiMreti 
 nnd children's children, and thus constitute the basis for 
 f'jrther advance. However certain it is that in connection 
 with such thinL;s the iirst notions of "mine and thine" are 
 develoi.ed, yet many are the observations itidicating that 
 these conceptions do not go beyc»n<l the individual, and tliat 
 they perisli with him. Tlw f't'sscssiDu f^usscs into the f^ravc 
 Ti'/V// the f'osscssor, whose personal equipment it fonned in 
 lii'e. That is a custom which is met with in all parts of the 
 
 'Comp. Arbeit u. Rhythmus (jj rd ), p. 'rt. 
 
PRlMITjyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 23 
 
 earth, and of which many peoples* have preserved traces 
 even down into civ'lized times. ■'*'* 
 
 In the first p;'.:c :: i^ piovaient among all American peo- 
 ples to such at extent that t!.e survivors are often left in 
 extreme need. ' 'ic a!>ori{j:;nes of California, who are 
 among the lo«\.it ;>et-j,le o^ iH'.ir rafe, place along with 
 the dead all the weapons and utensils \vhich he had made 
 use of in life. " It is a curious paraphernalia," says an ob- 
 server, "that follows the Wintum into the grave: knives, 
 forks, vinegar-jars, empty whiskey-bottles, preserve-jars, 
 bows, arrows, etc.; and if the dead has been an industrious 
 housewife, a few baskets of acorns arc scattered over 
 as well." " At the grave of the Tehuelche " (Patagonia), 
 runs another account, " ail his horses, dogs, and other ani- 
 mals are killed. ..id his poncho, his ornaments, his bolas 
 and implements of every kind arc brought together into a 
 heap and burned." And of a third and still lower tribe, 
 the I'.ororo in Brazil, a recent very reliable observer says: ^'^ 
 " -^ great loss befalls a fanuly when one of its menibe s 
 dies. For everything that the dead man used is burned, 
 thrown into the river, or packed in with the corpse in order 
 that the departed spirit may have no occasion whatever to 
 return. The cabin is dien completely gutted. I'.nt the 
 surviving members of the family receive fresh i)rcsents; 
 bows and arrows are made for them, and when a jaguar 
 is killed, the skin is given to the brother of the last deceased 
 woman or to the uncle of the last deceased man." 
 
 Among the Ragobos in southern Mindanao (one of the 
 
 "Comp. in general, .Andrcc, lithnogr. I\j,aiklcn u. I'crgkiche (Siutt- 
 Kart, i8;«), pp. A)-:\ Scluirl/, Urundru: rtih-r linlstch. Gcsch. d. 
 iicldcs (Weimar, i8<)S). pp. sfi IT ; i'aii.knw. Ztsclir. d. Gts. f. Erdkunde 
 7U Ucrlin. XXXI. jni. i-.'-< 
 
 " K. vdii ilcn .'^tciiitti. i iiirr din Witunolkcni Knisilints ( .'d id.), 
 r- .^>^). Ci'inp. .-ilio i:hrenrui!'.. /'.^.'njcf :ur i .HkcrLun.U' Hrjsilinif, 
 \'V ,U), (•(,; lltckcwtldtr. a- above, pp. .711-1, .',-4-5. 
 
r 
 
 24 
 
 PRIMITIVE ECOS'OMIC CONDiTlONS. 
 
 Philippines) the dead man is buried in iiis best clothes, and 
 with a slave, who h killed for the purpose. " The cooking- 
 utensiLs that the deceased used during his lifetime are filled 
 with rice and placed, along with his betel-sacks, upon the 
 grave; his other things are left in the house untouched. 
 On penalty of death no one may henceforth enter either 
 the house or the burial-place; and it is equally forbidden 
 to cut from the trees surrounding the house. The house 
 itself is allowed to go to ruin." ** 
 
 In Australia and .\frica the custom is very common for 
 all the stores of the deceased to be eaten up by the assem- 
 bly of the mourners; in other parts the utensils are de- 
 stroyed, while the food is thrown away. Many negro 
 tribes bury the dead in the hut in which he lived, and leave 
 the dwelling, now deserted by the survivors, to decay; 
 others destroy the hut.^'- If a chieftain dies, the whole vil- 
 lage migrates: and this is true even of the principal towns 
 of the more inip<jrtant kingdoms, such as those of the 
 Muata-Yamwo and the Kasembe. In the Lunda kingdom 
 the old royal Kipanga is biirned down, and a new pro- 
 visional one at once erected, for which the newly chosen 
 ruler has to kindle a fresh fire by rubl)ing together pieces 
 of wood, as it is not permissible to use the old fire any 
 longer. The principal or residence town changes its loca- 
 tion with each new ruler." .\mong the ancient Peruvians, 
 
 *' SclLidenlxTt; in tlie Ztsclir. f. Rthnol., XVII (188.S). )>p 12-1.1. Tlie 
 same thiriK is found in Ilalam.ihora, p. 8.i; and anmng tlie lull tribes 
 of India. JellinKhaus in llic same review, III, pp. 372, 374. 
 
 " Fxaniples may be found in M. Buchrver, Kainerun, p 28; Frilseh, 
 as above, p. 5.^5; Bastian, I.oangokiiste, I. j) 1(14; I-iviiiKstoiu', as 
 above, p. 158 From /\ustraiia: Parkinson, Im lUsmarck-Archif>el, pp. 
 102-.1: Ztscbr. f. I'"tlinol.. XXI, p, 23; Kiibary. filhiwgr. Hcitrdnc sur 
 Kfntltnij d KiirJiii. Inseigruppc u. Nachbarschaft ( Reriiii, 1885). pp. 
 70-71, iiiiti,'. 
 
 '* I'liUKe. ,■!■. above, jip. 2-'8, 2,54, LivinKstone in I'etermanns Mittli., 
 XXT (187s), p 104. 
 
PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 25 
 
 .3 
 
 as well, the conception prevailed that with each new Inca 
 the world, so to speak, began anew. The palaces of the 
 dead Inca, with all tlieir stores of wealth, were closed for 
 ever; the ruler for the time l)eing never made use of the 
 treasures that his ancestors had amassed. 
 
 Though we see from this that the origin and preserva- 
 tion of the first elements of civilization among primitive 
 peoples were attended with the greatest difficulties, and 
 that the possibility of rising to better conditions of exist- 
 ence and higher modes of life could not even be conceived 
 by them, yet it must not be forgotten that the observations 
 that have been sifted and presented here have been taken 
 from peoples of very varied character and different cultural 
 stages. To raise himself of his own strengtli to the plane 
 of the Tongan or Tahitian. the Australian of the continent 
 would probably have required many thousands of years; 
 and a similar gulf separates the Bushman from the Congo 
 nesrro and Wanvamweza. But this verv fact, it seem . .-^ 
 me. speaks for the persistence of the presumptive psycn.v: 
 conditions under which the satisfaction of the wants of un- 
 civilized man is accomplished: and we are undoubf^dly 
 justified in tracing back the whole circle of this cla.s of 
 conceptions to a condition that must have prevailed 
 among mankind ior a-oiis before tribes and peoples could 
 have originated. 
 
 From all that we know of it. this condition means ex- 
 actly the opposite of " economy." For economy implies 
 always a community of men rendered possil)le by the pos- 
 session of property; it i^ a taking counsel, a caring not 
 only for the moment but also for the future, a careful divi- 
 sion and suitable bestowal of time; economy means work, 
 valuation of things, regulation of their use. accumulation 
 of wealth, transmission of the achievements of civilization 
 from generation to generation. And even among the 
 
i I: 
 
 s6 
 
 PRIMITiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 higher primitive peoples we have found all this widely 
 wanting; among the lower races we have hardly met 
 ■with its faint beginnings. Let us strike out of the 
 life of the Bushman or of the Veddah the use of fire, 
 and bow and arrow, and nothing remains but a life 
 made up of the individual search for food. Each indi- 
 vidual has to rely entirely upon himself for his sustenance. 
 Naked and unarmed he roams with his fellows, like cer- 
 tain species of wild animals, through a limited stretch of 
 territory-, and uses his feet for holding and climbing as 
 dexterously as he uses his hands.'*^ All, male and female, 
 devour raw what they catch with their hands or dig out of 
 the ground with their nails: smaller animals, roots, and 
 fruits. Mow they unite in little bands or larger herds; 
 now they separate again, according to the richness of the 
 pasturage or hunting-ground. But these unions do not 
 develop into communities, nor do they lighten the exist- 
 ence of the individual. 
 
 This picture may not have many charms for him who 
 shares the civilization of the present; hut we are simply 
 forced by the material empirically gathered together so to 
 construct it. Nor are any of its lines imaginative. We 
 have eliminated from the life of the lowest tribes only what 
 admittedly belongs to civilization — the use of weapons and 
 of fire. Though we were obliged to admit that even 
 among the higher primitive peoples there is exceeding 
 much that is non-economic, that at all events the con- 
 scious application of the economic principle forms with 
 them rather the exception than the rule, we .shall not be 
 able in the case of the so-called " lower nomads " and their 
 predecessors just sketched to make use of the notion of 
 economy at all. With them we have to fix a pre-econoniic 
 
 •* R. Andrte, Iter Fuss als Greiforgan, in his lithnugr. Parallclftt u. 
 Vcrgl. (New Series), pp. 228 flf. 
 
PRIMlTiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 27 
 
 Stage of development, that is not yet economy. As every 
 child must have his name, we will call this the stage of in- 
 dividual search for food. 
 
 How economic activity was evolved from the individual 
 search for food can to-day hardly be imagined. The 
 thought may suggest itself that the tUiTiing-point must 
 be where production with a more distant end in view takes 
 the place of the mere seizing of the gifts of nature for im- 
 mediate enjoyment, and where work, as the intelligent 
 application of physical power, replaces the instinctive 
 activity of the bodily organs. Ver\- little would be gained, 
 however, by this purely theoretical distinction. Labour 
 among primitive peoples is something very ill-defined. 
 The further we follow it back, the more closely it ap- 
 proaches in form and substance to play. 
 
 In all probability there are instincts similar to those that 
 are found among the more intelligent of the lower animals, 
 that impel man to extend his activities beyond the mere 
 search for food, especially the instinct for imitating and 
 for experimenting.^" The taming of domestic animals, for 
 example, begins not with the useful animals, but with such 
 species as man keeps merely for amusement or the worship 
 of gods. Industrial activity seems cvc-ywhere to start 
 with the painting of the body, tattooing, piercing or other- 
 wise disfiguring sei)arate parts of the body, and grad- 
 ually to advance to the production of ornaments, masks, 
 drawing on bark, petrograms, and similar play-products. 
 In these things there is everywhere displayed a peculiar 
 tendency to imitate the animals whicli the savage iiu-ets with 
 in his immediate surroundings, and which he looks upon 
 as his equals. The partly prehistoric rock dmwings and 
 carvings of the Bushmen, the Indians, and the Australians 
 
 Ton-.p K. Groof., Die Spide d. Ticre (Jena. 1896"). 
 
23 
 
 PRlMITiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 represent chiefly animals and men;*® pottery, wood-carv- 
 ing, and even wicker-work begin with the production of 
 animal fornis.^" Even when the advance is made to the 
 construction of objects of daily use (pots, stools, etc.), the 
 animal figure is retained with remarkable regularity;''* 
 and lastly, in the dances of primitive peoples, the imita- 
 tion of the motions and the cries of animals plays the prin- 
 cipal part.''" All regularly sustained activity finally takes 
 on a rhythmir form and becomes fused with music and 
 song in an indivisible whole.^'^ 
 
 It is accordingly in play that technical skill is developed, 
 and it turns to the useful only very gradually.^* The or- 
 der of progression hitherto accepted must therefore be 
 just reversed; play is older than work, art older than pro- 
 
 "Andree. Elhnogr. Parallelen u. I'ergleiche, pp. 258-299. Ehrenreich, 
 as above, pp. 46-7. 
 
 " Comp. the interesting accounts by K. v. d. Steinen, as above, 
 pp. 2JI ff., and particularly pp. 241 ff. 
 
 " Abundant examples are afforded by every ethnographic pictur«*- 
 collection. The incredulous are invited to take a glance at the fol- 
 lowing works: J. Boas, The Central Eskimo (Washington, 1888); 
 Sixth Annual Report of the Bureau of Ethnology to the Secretary 
 of the Smithsonian Institution, 1884-5; Ethnogr. Beschrijving fan de 
 West- •! Xonrdkust ran Ncderlandsch Xiew Guinea, by F. S. A. de Clercq 
 and J. D. E. ScIinieltT: (Leiden, iSg^l; Joest, Ethnogr. atis Guyana 
 (Suppl. to vol. 5 of the Intern, .\rchiv fiir Ethnogr.); and again Von 
 den Steinen, as above, pp. 26r ff. Conip. also 7ritsch, as above, p. 7,3; 
 Schweinfurth. The Heart of .Urica (.vl ed., London. 1878). I, pp. 129- 
 130; and Grosi^o, Pie Anfange d. Kunst. Chaps. \'I and VII. 
 
 " Grosse. as abovi-, pp. 2o8-(), 
 
 " Reference must here agniti be niaiio to my work on Arbeit u. 
 Rhythmus. 
 
 '* " On exaniinatioti of the primitive tools [of ihe Papuans] . . . 
 we see that there is not a single one which does not hear testimony by 
 S(inu' little design or ornament to the good taste of its maker, not an 
 article which does not show some trifling accessories surpassing mere 
 utility and present in it solely for beauty's sake." — Semon, In the 
 Austral. Bush. p. 400. 
 
PRlMlTll^E ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 29 
 
 
 I 
 
 duction for use.'^'' Even when among the higher primi- 
 tive peoples the two elements begin to separate from each 
 other, the dance still precedes or follows every more im- 
 portant work (war-, hunting-, harvest-dance), and song ic- 
 companies work. 
 
 Just as economy, the further we have traced it back- 
 wards in the development of peoples, has during our in- 
 quiry assumed more and more the form of non-economy, so 
 work also has finally resolved itself into its opposite (Nicht- 
 arbeit). And we should probably have the same experi- 
 ence with all the more important phenomena of economy, 
 if we were to continue our inquiries regarding <^hem. One 
 thing alone appears permanent — consumption. Wants 
 man always had, and wants must be satisfied. But even 
 our wants, considered from an economic point of view, 
 exist only in very small part naturally; it is only in the 
 matter of bodily nourishment that our consumption is a 
 necessity of nature; all else is the product of civilization, 
 the result of the free creative activity of the human mind. 
 Without this activity man would always have remained a 
 root-digging, fiuit-eating animal. 
 
 Under these circumstances we must forego the attempt 
 to fix upon some definite point at which simple search for 
 food ceases and economy begins, in the history of human 
 civilization there are no turning-points; here everything 
 grows and decays as with the plant; the fixed or station- 
 ary is only an abstraction which we need in order to make 
 visible to our dim eye the wonders of nature and humanity. 
 Indeed economy itself, like all else, is subject to constant 
 changes. When it first presents itself in history, it appears 
 as a form of communal life based upon material posses- 
 
 m 
 
 " [The general ctlmograpliic aspect nf art is. of course, another and 
 wider problem than the one involved in this conclusion with regard 
 ;0 "first things. " — Ed.] 
 
! * 
 
 30 PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 sions. guided by definite rules of conduct, and closely con- 
 nected with the personal and moral community of life of 
 the family.'*^ It was under this form that it was seen by 
 the people who first fixed its characteristics in language. 
 Landlord is still in Middle High German synonymous 
 with husband (Wirt, Ehemann), landlady is wife (Wirtin, 
 Ehefrau), and the word economy, derived from the Greek, 
 is formed in a similar way. 
 
 We may therefore assume the existence of economy as 
 certain where we find co-dwelling communities that pro- 
 cure and utilize things adapted to their needs according to 
 the dictates of the economic principle. Such a condition 
 is certainly fulfilled by the higher primitive peoples, even 
 though their carrying out of the economic principle always 
 remains incomplete. But there is nevertheless much that 
 still recalls the pre-economic period of individual search 
 for food; economy has still, so to speak, gaps in- various 
 
 places. 
 
 Among all peoples of a lower cultural stage the dis- 
 tribution of labour between the two sexes is firmly fixed 
 bv custom, although difiference of natural aptitude seems 
 by no means to have been the sole determining factor. 
 At least it cannot be maintained that in all cases the lighter 
 share of the work fell to the weaker sex. While in the 
 normal domestic economy of civilized nations we have a 
 cross-section, so to speak, which assigns to the man the 
 productive work and to the woman the superintendence 
 of consumption, the economy of these peoples seems to be 
 divided in longitudinal section. Both sexes take part in 
 
 " K. Grosse has in his recent book entitled Die Formal d. Familie 
 u. die Fflrmen d. Wirtschafi (Leipzig, i8g6) investigated the connection 
 of family with economic forms. In doing so he has, for the economic 
 side of the \vori<. adhered to the altogetlicr external classification into 
 nomadic, pastor.il, and agricultural, but has scarcely devoted due at- 
 tention to the inner cc^nnnii:- life, particularly to that "f the household. 
 
PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 31 
 
 production, and frequently each has a particular depart- 
 ment of the consumption for itself. It is particularly signif- 
 icant in this connection that upon the woman de solves, as a 
 rule, the jirocuring and preparing of the vegetable foods 
 and for the most part also the building of the hut, while 
 hunting and the working up of the products of the chase 
 fall to the man. If cattle are kept, the tending of the ani- 
 mals, the erection of inclosures for them, the milking, etc., 
 are the business of the men. This division is often so 
 sharply defined that we might almost speak of a cleavage 
 of the family economy into a purely male and a purely 
 female economy. 
 
 In an interesting account of the useful plants of the 
 Brazilian Shingu tribes, K. von den Stcincn ''* describes 
 the outcome of the earlier development of these tribes in 
 the following words: 
 
 "Man followed the chase, and in the mean time woman invented 
 agriculture. Here, as throughout Brazil, the women have exclusive 
 charge not otily of the preparation of manioc in the house but also 
 of its cultivation. Thty clear the ground of weeds with pointed sticks, 
 place in position the stakes with which the manioc is planted, and 
 fetch each day what they need, carrying it home in heavily laden 
 wicker baskets. . . . The man is more courageous and skilful; to 
 him belong the chase and the use of weapons. Where, then, hunt- 
 ing and fishing ^. play an important part, the woman must attend, 
 as far as a division of labour takes place at all, to the procuring, trans- 
 porting, and preparing of the food. This division has a result that is 
 not sufticiently appreciated, namely, that the woman in her field of 
 labour ac(iuires special knowledge just as the man does in his. This 
 must necessarily hold true for each lower or higher stage. The 
 counterpart of the Indian woman cultivating her manioc with skill 
 and intelligence is already found in the purely nomadic state. The 
 wife of the Bororo vent into the forest armed with a pointed stick to 
 search for roots and tubers: during wanderings through the camp- 
 ing-ground, or whenever a cot.ipany of Indians changed its locality, 
 sucli hunting fell to the wor .n, while the man tracked the game: she 
 clinib''d the tree for cocoanuis. and carried heavy loads of them 
 
 '^Unier d. Naturi'olk. Central-Brasil., pp. 206 ff. 
 
h i 
 
 32 PRIMlTiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 laboriously home. And though the Indian woman was the slave of 
 her husband, this relation was certainly not to her advantage in re- 
 gard to the division of the fish and meat; she still had to depend 
 upon the supply of vegetables that she could gather for herself. On 
 the Shingu the men made ready the roast and broiled fish and meat; 
 the women baked the beijus (manioc cakes), prepared the warm 
 drinks, cooked the fruits, and roasted tht cocoanuts. What other 
 meaning could this division into animal cooking for the men and 
 vegetable cooking for the women have than that each of the sexes had 
 still kept to its original sphere?" 
 
 If we add that the men also made the weapons for the 
 chase, and that hunting and fishing were the source whence 
 they drew all their iinplements for cutting, scraping, polish- 
 ing, piercing, tracing, and carving, while the women pro- 
 duced the pottery for cooking,-'*'' we have for each sex a 
 naturally defined sphere of production upon which all their 
 activity is independently expended. But this is not all. The 
 consumption h also in one chief particular distinct: there 
 are no common meals in the family. Each individual eats 
 apart from the rest, and it is looked upon as improper to 
 partake of food in the presence of others.*** 
 
 Similar characteristics of an individual economy are also 
 found among the North American Indians, who had al- 
 ready arrived at a fully developed domestic economy. 
 While they know nothing whatever of a special ownership 
 
 " As above, pp. I97 ff-. 217 ff- 3i8. 
 
 "Von den Steinen, as above, p. 69, and Ehrcnreich, Bcitriige s. V'61- 
 kerkunde Brasil., p. 17: "Etiquette among the Karaya demands that 
 each one shall eat by himself apart from the others." l.ating alone 
 is almost suggestive of the animal. The savage acts like the dog, 
 which grows cross when his meal is disturbed. Among the natives of 
 Borneo " the men usually feed alone, attended on by the women, and 
 always wash their mouths out when they have finished eating. They 
 are very particular about being called away from their meals, and it 
 takes . great deal to make a man set about doing anything before he 
 has concluded his repast: to such an extent is this practice observed, 
 that it is considered wrong to attack even an enemy whilst he is eat- 
 ing, but the moment he has finished it is legitimate and proper to fall 
 upon him." Hose, in Juurii. oi Amhiop^l. Inst., p. i6o. 
 
PRlMITiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 33 
 
 of the soil, " there is nothing in an Indian's house or family 
 without its particular owner. Every individual knows 
 what belongs to him, from the horse or cow down to the 
 dog, cat, kitten, and little chicken. Parents make presents 
 to their children, and they in return to their parents. A 
 fatl r will sometimes ask his wife or one of his children 
 for the loan of a horse to go a-hunting. For a litter of 
 kittens or brood of chickens there are often as many dif- 
 ferent owners as there are individual animals. In purchas- 
 ing a hen with her brood one frequently has to deal for it 
 with several children." ^^ 
 
 " In cases where the Indians permitted polygamy, it was 
 customar)' for a special hut to be erected for each wife; 
 among tribes dwelling in common-houses each wife had at 
 least her special fire."*® 
 
 '' The same characteristics are presented by the economy 
 of the Polynesians and Micronesians, except that here fish- 
 ing and the raising of smaller live stock take the place of 
 hunting. In New Pomerania the various duties are strictly 
 divided between the men and boys on the one hand, and 
 the women and girls on the other.^^ To the male portion 
 of the population falls the labour of making and keep- 
 ing in repair the weapons and the fishing-gear, especially 
 the fishing-nets and the ropes necessary for them, of cast- 
 ing the nets in the sea and caring for them daily, of build- 
 ing canoes, erecting huts, and. in the wooded districts, of 
 felling trees and clearing away the roots for the laying out 
 of new plantations, as well as of protecting them by en- 
 closures against wild boars." *" 
 
 " Heckewelder, as above, p. 158. 
 "VVaitz, Anthropologic, III, p. 109. 
 "Parkinson, as above, pp. 113, 122. 
 
 "These labours preparatory to the cultivation of the land are still 
 often performed by the women. Parkinson, p. 118. 
 
34 
 
 PRlMmVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 \ I 
 
 Besides haviriig to care for their little children it de- 
 volves upon the women to prepare the food, to dig and 
 cultivate the ground, to raise and garner the produce of the 
 field, and to carry the heavily laden baskets to market- 
 places miles away. 
 
 " In certain kinds of work both men and women take 
 part. To these belong the twisting of the strong basten 
 cordage of which the fishing-nets are woven, the plaiting 
 of baskets with finely cut strips of rattan and padanus- 
 leaves, the weaving of a very rough and coarse stuff called 
 mal, made from the bark of the broussonetia-tree, in which 
 the women wrap their infants to protect them from the 
 cold." 
 
 This latter is very significant: we have here to do with 
 arrangements for the transformation of materials, such as 
 could not have existed in the period of individual search 
 for food. 
 
 Separate preparation of food for men and women, and 
 separate meals are also met with in the South Sea regions. 
 In Fiji the men prepare such kinds of food as can be 
 cooked out of doors by means of heated stones. " This is 
 confined to-day to the roasting of swine's flesh; formerly 
 the preparation of human flesh was also reserved for the 
 men." ^- In the Palau Islands the cooking of the taro and 
 the preparing of the sweetened foods fell to the lot of the 
 women, the preparation of the meats to the men.*'^ In 
 most parts of Oceania " it is neither permissible for women 
 and men to eat in common, nor for the men to eat what 
 the women have prepared. Eating with another from the 
 same dish seems to be avoided with almost equal scrupu- 
 lousness." "■* 
 
 *• Biissler, Siidsce-Bildcr, pp. 226-7. 
 
 " Kubary, as above, p. 17J. 
 
 " Ratzel, V'olkerkundc, I. p. 240. 
 
 "Separate; meals for men and women; Conip. Stanley, Ho-i; t ioitnd 
 
PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 35 
 
 The economy of many negro tribes shows a Hke arrange- 
 ment ; a sharp division of the production and of many parts 
 of the consumption according to sex, indeed even the ex- 
 it nsion of this distinction to the sphere of barter. As P. 
 Pogge,®' one of our most reliable observers, says concisely 
 of the Congo negroes: " The woman has her own circle 
 of duties independent of that of her husband." And in the 
 description of the Bashilangas he observes:^" '" No mem- 
 ber of the family troubles himself about another at meal- 
 times: while some eat the others come and go just as it 
 suits them; but the women and the smaller children gen- 
 erally eat together." And finally he reports further re- 
 garding the Lundas: " Under ordinary conditions, when 
 a caravan has pitched its camp in a village, the wome:' of 
 the place are accustomed to bring vegetables and fowl into 
 the camp for sale, while goats, pigs, and sheep are usually 
 sold only by the men."' It is similarly related by L. Wolf* 
 that in the market at Tbaushi all the agricultural products 
 .■;Tid 1 laterials. mats, and pottery are sold by the women, 
 and only iL^oats and wine by the men. F.ach sex is thus 
 possessor of its special proiluct of labour, and disposes of 
 i: indejKjndentlN. ''■'•* 
 
 The di\ ision of the labour of production between the two 
 ^exe> in Africa varies in detail from tribe to tribe; as a rule, 
 
 [f7Tt::fa>u (N w York, 1887). p. 550; Naclitigal, Sahara u. Sudan, I, 
 
 " tm i's-iche :. Mnata Jamuo. p. 40. 
 
 ' ^\»>«r:ar ' ntcr dcutsch. Flaggc qui-r durch Afrika, \t. ,^87. Im- 
 Isnemt ^ Ifmua amzcu. pp. I"8, 2t,i. 
 
 '' tm Hsjcnc J Muatd Jamu'O. p. 29. 
 
 ""AST— sjair; etc.. Im Inticrn Afrikas. p. J4Q Conip. Livingstone, 
 l.vrrn^ - -*f . jmhesi. pp. 122, 577; Paulitschkf, Ethnographie Nordost- 
 
 **■ »•' — r family md the domestic establishment of the Wanyamwezis, 
 w+r ji-sureti y ni longer stand upon a low plane, Burton gives the 
 ■olkfmras picture: "Children are suckled till the end of the second 
 Arter the fourth summer the boy begins to learn archery. 
 
; 
 
 j 
 
 I' 
 
 36 
 
 PRIMlTjyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 however, agriculture ami the preparation of all the vegeta- 
 ble foods are also assigned here to the woman, and hunting, 
 cattle-raising, tanning, and weaving to the man.'^" This 
 arrangement is often supporteil by superstitious usages. 
 In Uganda the milking of the cows falls exclusively to the 
 men; a woman is never permitted to touch the udder of 
 a cow.'' In the Lunda territory, again, no man is allowed 
 to take part in the extraction of oil from the ground-nut, 
 as his presence is thought to frustrate the success of the 
 operation."- As a rule the carriers whom Europeans en- 
 
 ... As poon .IS [lu-l can walk he tends the flocks; after the age of 
 ten he drives the cattle to pasture, and. considering himself independ- 
 ent of his father, he plants a tobacco-plot and aspires to build a hut 
 for himself. Unmarried (jirls live in the f.ithcr's house until puberty; 
 after that period the spinsters of the village, who usually number from 
 seven to a do/en. assemble toKether and build for themselves at a 
 distance from their homes a hut where they can receive their friends 
 withriut parental interference. . . . Marriage takes place when the 
 youth can afford to pay the price for a wife. [The price] varies, ac- 
 cording t'> circumstances, from one to ten cows. The wife is so far 
 the property of the husband that he can claim damages from the adul- 
 terer, but may not sell her except when in dilticulties. . . . Polygamy 
 is the rule with the wealthy. There is little community of interest?, 
 and apparently a lack of family affection in these tribes. The hus- 
 band, when returning from the coast laden with cloth, will refuse a 
 single sluikkah to his wife; .md the wife, sticceeding to an inheritance, 
 will abandon her husband to starvation. The man takes charge of the 
 cattle, goats, sluep. atul poultrj : the woman has power over the 
 grain and the \egetatple'-; and each must grow tob.icco, liaving little 
 hope of borrowing from the other. . . . The sexes do not eat to- 
 gether: e\eii the boys would disdain to be seen sitting at meat with 
 their motliirv The men feed either in their cottages or. more gen- 
 erally, in the iw.m/a fpublic house, one being set apart for each sex]." 
 (As above, pp. -•'»5>^: ii>mp pp, 41M-4 > 
 
 '"Comp, e-pecially hVitseh. as above, pp. ;'» '^f ■ 'K?. •2-'0- ,U'.S; Living- 
 ston*, as above, pp. 77, iif. .Iii-i-'. .\n cMended treatment now in 
 H. Schurt/. Dat nfr. Ccwnh' (l.eip/ig, Kirxil. pp. 7 tT. 
 
 " I'.min lUy. in IVienii.iniis Mitth, X N \' (1X70), p. .V)2. 
 
 " Wi-SMiiann, V.O i, etc., hn Iniurii Afrikas. p. (>.\. 
 
PRIMlTiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 37 
 
 gage refuse to do women's work; Livingstone" even 
 reports a case of famine among the men in a certain dis- 
 trict because no women were there to grind the corn they 
 had on hand. The separation of the two sexes in the prep- 
 aration and consumption of food is often made still more 
 rigid by regulations ''* of a semi-religious character, for- 
 bidding the women the use of certain kinds of meat, which 
 are thus reserved for the men alone. ''■''' 
 
 Everywhere among primitive peoples the children become 
 independent very early in youth and desert the society of 
 their parents. They often live then for some years in special 
 common-houses, of which there are others for married 
 men. These common-hou.ses for the men-folk grouped ac- 
 cording to age. and frequently also for the unmarried 
 women grouped in the same way, are found very wiilely 
 distributed in Africa and America, and especially in 
 Oceania. They serve as common places of meeting, work, 
 and amusement, and as sleeping-places for the younger 
 people, and are used also for lodging strangers. They 
 naturally form a further obstacle to the development of a 
 common household economy based upon the family, for 
 each family is generally subdivided into different parts 
 
 "As above, pp. !88. 565. .Siniil.-irly amotiK the Tiuli.ins; comp. 
 Wait/, as ahovp. III, p. 100. 
 
 "More frequent still in Tolynesia. Comp. Andnc. nthiogr. Parol- 
 Uk» u. I'crglciche. \^\^. ii4ff. 
 
 "For a peculiar further development of this economy comp. 
 Schweinfurth, Sahara u. Sudan. III. pp. i6j, .'44, 2^^). In some places 
 the separation of the spheres of activity f)f the two sexes extends cv 1 
 to their intellectual life. AmonK' several Cariljic tribes the women 
 and tlie men h;;'- ditTcrent names fur many things, wlience it was 
 inferred that there existid distinct hmnuaKes for men and for women. 
 More recently this phenomenon is suppoM'd to have its foundation in 
 the didercnce in social portion of the sexes and in the sharp division 
 between their two spheres of tniph'vmcnt Comp. Sapper, Intirn. 
 
 f. Htl 
 
 tinoKr. 
 
 PI' 
 
 si> !. 
 
38 PRlMlTiyE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 vv-ith separate dwellings. In Yap. one of the Caroline 
 Islands, for instance, we find besides the fcbays, or sleep- 
 ing-houses of the unmarried, a principal house for each 
 family which the father of the family uses, and also a dwell- 
 ing-house for each wife; finally, " the preparation of food 
 in the dwelling-house is forbidden and is transferred to a 
 separate hut for each member of the family, which serves as 
 a fire-cabin or cooking-house." ^« A similar arrangement 
 prevails in Malekula in the New Hebrides." Further than 
 this, economic individualism can hardly be carried. 
 
 It may be asserted as a general rule for primitive peo- 
 ples practising polvgamy that each wife has her own hut." 
 Among the Zulus thev go so far as to build a separate 
 hut for almost ever)- adult member of the household,— 
 one for the husband, one for his mother, one for each of 
 his wives and other adult members of his family. These 
 huts all stand in a semicircle about the enclosed cattle- 
 kraal in such a way that the man's dwelling is m the centre. 
 Of course it is to be remembered that a hut of this kmd 
 can be constructed in a few hours. 
 
 Thus we see that everywhere, even among the more 
 developed primitive peoples, there is still wanting much of 
 that unified exclusiveness of domestic life with which the 
 civilized peoples of Europe, from all we know of them, 
 first appeared in history. Everywhere wide clefts still 
 gape, and the individual preserver an economic independ- 
 ence that strikes us with its strangeness. However much 
 
 '• Kubary E.'hnogr. Btitriige z. Kennt. d. Karnl.-Archif. (Leiden), p. 39- 
 "Journal o( the Anthropol. Inst, of Gr. Br.. X.XIII (i8«m). P- J8t- 
 "This is tlic ca.se. to mention only a few instancts, in the Antilles: 
 St.ircko' Tht Primilive Family (New York. 1SH9). p. 40: in Min- 
 danao; Sch.-,dcnbcrK, Ztschr. f. Ethnol.. XVII. p. u; among the 
 Bakuba: Wissmann, Im Innern Afrikas, p. J0.>: among the Monbuttoos: 
 .Schweinfiirth, Ztschr. f. Ethnol.. V. p. 12; Tht Heart of Africa. II. pp. 
 17-18: Ca»a!i». La BMiuiot, p. ii2. 
 
PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 39 
 
 
 it behooves us, in our consideration of this minute eco- 
 nomic separation, to guard against overlooking the unify- 
 ing forces of working and caring for each other, and 
 carefully as we must refrain from exaggerating the cen- 
 trifugal forces here at work, it Is nevertheless not to be 
 denied that they are all traceable to one common origin — to 
 titc individual search for food practised through thousands of 
 years by all these pcof^lcs. 
 
 In this lies the justification of the method followed in 
 this investigation, in which we have taken together peo- 
 ples of very different stock and cultural stages, and con- 
 sidered the economic phenomena separately. 
 
 This procedure is, in political economy as in all social 
 sciences, entirely justified; provided that, from the prodig- 
 ious mass of disconnected facts that fill ethnolog}- like a 
 great lumber-room, we succeed in bringing a considerable 
 number under a common denominator and rescuing them 
 from the mystic interpretations of curiosity-hunters and 
 r.'.ythologizing visionaries. For political economy in par- 
 ticular this method offers the further and not inconsider- 
 able advantage, that the toy mannikin in the form of a 
 savage freely invented by the imagination of civilized man 
 vanishes from the scene, and gives place to forms that are 
 taken from life, although the observations from which they 
 are drawn mav leave much to be desired in point of ac- 
 curacy. 
 
 Our travellers have hitherto devoted little special atten- 
 tion to the economy oi primitive peoples. In the midst of 
 their attention to dress, forms of worship, morals, religious 
 beliefs, marriage customs, art. and technical skill, they 
 have often overlooked what lay closest at hand, and in the 
 gossipy records of ethnographic compilations the word 
 " economy " has no mf>re fotmd a place than has the word 
 " household " in the chronicles of the numerous investi- 
 
40 
 
 PRIMITIVE ECONOMIC CONDITIONS. 
 
 f >: 
 » .' 
 
 gators into the constitution of the family. But just be- 
 cause the observations we have utiHzed have been made 
 for the most part only incidentally and not by trained 
 economists, they possess a high measure of credibility. 
 For they have on that account generally escaped the fate 
 of being forced into some scheme categorically arranged 
 in accordance with the conditions of our own civilization, 
 and for that verj' reason unable to do justice to the differ- 
 ently conditioned life of primitive peoples. 
 
m^ 
 
 CHAPTER II. 
 
 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 
 
 The designation natural people seems a particularly- 
 apt characterization of the lower races of men on their eco- 
 nomic side. They stand in more immediate touch with 
 nature than do we; they are more dependent upon her, 
 are more directly susceptible to her powers, and succumb 
 to tiiem more easily. Civilized man lays by stores for the 
 future; for the preservation and embellishment of his ex- 
 istence he possesses a wealth of implements; in the event 
 of failure of his crops the harvests of half a world stand at 
 his disposal through our highly perfected means of trans- 
 portation; he subdues the powers of nature and impresses 
 them into his service. Our commerce places the labour 
 of a thousand men at the command of every individual 
 amongst us, and in every household watchful eyes guard the 
 careful and economical consumption of the goods destined 
 for our bodily subsistence. Primitive man, as a rule, gath- 
 ers no stores; a bad harvest or other failure of the natural 
 sources of his sustenance strikes him with its full weight; 
 he knows no labour-saving implements, no system in dis- 
 posing of his time, no ordered consumption; limited to 
 his meagre natural powers, threatened on all sides by hos- 
 tile forces, each day he has to struggle anew for his exist- 
 ence, and often knows not whether the morrow will vouch- 
 safe him the means to still his hunger. Vet he does not 
 regard the future with anxiety, he is a child of the moment; 
 no cares torment him; his mind is fillcl with a boundless 
 naive egoism. With thoughts extending 'o further, he 
 
 41 
 
 u 
 
 I! 
 
 Hi 
 

 (I l 
 
 42 
 
 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITiyE PEOPLE. 
 
 instinctively follows his impulses, and in this regard also 
 stands closer to nature than ourselves.^ 
 
 The former ♦■ 'le was to classify primitive peoples accord- 
 ing to the manner in which they procured their sustenance 
 into hunters, fishers, pastorals, and agriculturalists. In 
 this it was believed that each people must traverse these 
 four stages of economic development in its progress 
 towards civilization. The starting-point was the tacit as- 
 sumption that primitive man began with animal food and 
 only gradually passed over, under the stress of necessity, 
 to a vegetable diet. The procuring of vegetable food 
 moreover was considered the more difficult inasmuch as 
 the picture of our European system of agriculture was ever 
 in mind with its draught-animals and artificial apparatus 
 of implements and tools. 
 
 But this conception is erroneous, just as is the assump- 
 tion from which it proceeds. Certainly all economic activ- 
 ity begins with the procuring of food, which is wholly de- 
 pendent upon the local distribution of the gifts of nature. 
 From the beginning man was primarily dependent upon 
 vegetable nourishment, and wherever tree-fruits, berries, 
 and roots were to be gained, he first made use of these. In 
 case of need he turned to petty animals which could be 
 consumed raw: shell-fish, worms, beetles, grasshoppers, 
 ants, etc. Like the lower animal in continuous quest of 
 food, he devoured at the moment what he found without 
 providing for the future. 
 
 If from this stage we seek the transition to the next, a 
 little reflection tells us that it could not have been difficult 
 ' Comp, in general R. Vierkandt, Nalurvolker u. KuUunvlker (Leip- 
 zig. \M>). pp 2(0 ff. On the conception of natural peoples see further 
 Panckow. Ztschr. d. Gcs. f. Erdkunde zu Berlin, XXXI (i8<)6>. pp. 
 158, ISO. Anyone inclined to find fault with the indefinitencss of the 
 definition should not overlook the fact that no single case has pre- 
 sented itscii fair-itiK tlie point whether a certain people was to be re- 
 garded as primitive or not. 
 
THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIi^F PEOPLE. 
 
 43 
 
 to gain the practical knowledge that a buried bulb or nut 
 furnishes a new plant, — certainly not more difficult than 
 taming animals or inventing fish-hooks and bow and ar- 
 row, which transition to the hunting stage required.- As 
 regards technical skill many hunting and nomadic peoples 
 stand far above so-called agricultural peoples. Of late 
 men have come to believe that nomads should rather be 
 considered savage agriculturalists; and as a matter of fact 
 it is highly improbable that a tribe of hunters should first 
 have hit upon the taming of animals before they could pro- 
 cure milk, eggs, and meat. Moreover, except in the ex- 
 treme north, there is probably no fishing, hunting, or pas- 
 toral people that does not draw a more or less consider- 
 able portion of its sustenance from the vegetable kingdom. 
 For this supply many of them have long been dependent 
 upon trade with more highly developed neighboring peo- 
 ples. They thus lack that economic independence which 
 our study requires if it is to arrive at conclusions univer- 
 sally applicable. 
 
 Now since the instances of hunting, fishing, and no- 
 madic tribes, which are accepted as typical, are only to be 
 found under special geographical and climatic conditions 
 that hardly permit of a different manner of obtaining 
 sustenance (hunters and fishers in the farthest north, 
 nomads in the steppes and desert places of the Old World), 
 it may be advisable in our further consideration to leave 
 them wholly aside and limit the field of our investigation 
 to the intertropical districts of America, Africa, Australia, 
 the Malay Archipelago, Melanesia, and Polynesia. This 
 is still an enormous circuit, within which the diversity 
 of natural conditions surrounding primitive man pro- 
 
 • Comp. in general E. Hahn, Die Hausthiere u. ihrc Besiehungen s. 
 Wirthschaft d. Menschen (Leipzig, 1896); P. R. Bos, Jagd, Vicksucht u. 
 Ackerbau ah Kulturstufen in Intern. Archiv f. Ethnographic, X (1897), 
 pp. iHTfi. 
 
 ill 
 
 i 
 s . 
 
 j . 
 
 i.. 
 
 3- a. 
 
44 
 
 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 
 
 ru 
 
 
 duces many j>eculiarities in his material existence. The 
 differences between the individual tribes in this regard are, 
 however, not so great as, for instance, between the Esqui- 
 maux and the Polynesian. At any rate, notwithstanding 
 the great differences of the races in conditions of life and 
 •ways of living, they have still sufficient in common to oc- 
 cupy our attention. In addition to this we have here 
 the oldest ree:ions inhabited by man, which, however, in 
 spite, or periiaps on account, of the bounties of tropical 
 nature, also appear to be those in which their development 
 has been most slow. 
 
 At all stages of his development the primitive man of 
 these regions manifestly finds in vegetable diet the l)asis 
 of his sustenance. This is evident from the simple 
 fact that he has always found animal food much more dif- 
 ficult to obtain. This is not contradicted by the circum- 
 stance that at times we notice an eagerness for flesh break 
 forth among many savage races which appalls us, since it 
 does not shrink even from its own kind. The explanation 
 in all probability is that the definite quantity of salt requi- 
 site for the normal maintenance of the human body can- 
 not be conveyed to it through purely vegetable diet, while 
 it is quite possible with occasional raw-flesh food to live 
 without salt. The same desire for salt is manifested even 
 by the purely herbivorous among our domestic animals. 
 
 The need of nourishment [we have seen] is the most 
 urgent, and originally the sole, force impelling man to activ- 
 ity, and causing him to wander about incessantly until it is 
 satisfied. The species of Jirision of labour between the 
 two sexes, which this primitive search for food gives rise 
 to, reaches its highest form when the wife procures the 
 vegetable, the man the animal, portion of the food. And 
 since, as a rule, the food gained is immediately devoured, 
 and no one takes thought for the other as long as he him- 
 
THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 
 
 45 
 
 self is hungry, a difference in the nourishment of the two 
 sexes arises that has perhaps contributed in an important 
 degree to the differentiation of their bodily development. 
 
 The division of labour of these primitive roaming hordes 
 is continued at higher stages of development, and receives 
 there such sharp expression that the rigidly limited spheres 
 of activity of the man and the woman form almost a spe- 
 cies of secondary sex-characteristics whose understanding 
 gives us the key to the economic life of primitive peoples. 
 In particular almost all their production of goods is dom- 
 inated by it. 
 
 Turning now to the latter, we should note by way of 
 preface that by far the greater part of our primitive peo- 
 ples, when they came under the view of Europeans, were 
 acquainted with, and practised, agriculture. This is true, 
 for instance, of all the negro races of Africa with but few 
 exceptions, of the Malays, the Polynesians, and Mela- 
 nesians, and of the primitive races of America, save those 
 living at the extreme north and south of that hemisphere. 
 It is a widely prevalent error, for which our youthful read- 
 ing is responsible, that makes pure hunting races out of 
 the North American Indians. All the tribes east of the 
 Mississippi and south of the St. Lawrence were familiar 
 with the cultivation of food-plants before the coming of 
 Europeans; and, in the regions lying beyond, they at least 
 gathered the grain of the water-rice (cicania aquatica) and 
 ground meal from the berries of the manzanita shrub.'' 
 
 The agriculture of primitive peoples is, however, pecu- 
 liar.'* In the first p'ace it knows nothing of an implement 
 that we think indispensable, namely, the plough. Wheel 
 and wagon and draught-animals are likewise unknown. 
 Furthermore, cattle-raising forms no integral part of their 
 
 ' Waitz, .Utthrofvlogu' d. Xatunvlkcr. III. 
 *Conip. E. Hahn. as above, pp. j88 ft. 
 
 pp. 
 
 1 
 
46 
 
 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRlMlTiyE PEOPLE. 
 
 
 ll 
 
 il 
 
 - I 
 
 I? 
 
 I i ' 
 
 I : 
 
 t I 
 
 agriculture. Fertilizing of the soil occurs at times, but it 
 is extremely rare. More frequent are irrigation arrange- 
 ments, especially for rice and taro plantations. As a rule, 
 however, the cultivated land must be changed when its 
 nutritive elements are exhausted; and the change is facili- 
 tated by the absence of individual property in the soil, 
 which belongs to the tribe or the village community as a 
 vvhole. Lastly, [we may recall,] the preparing of the soil 
 is almost exclusively woman's work. Only in the first 
 clearing of a piece of lar.d do the men assist. 
 
 Of late years this system of culture has been designated 
 the hack or hoc system, a short-handled hoe being its chief 
 implement. With .some tribes the primitive digging-stick 
 still retains its place. At the basis of its plant production 
 lie the tropical tuberous growths: manioc, yam, taro, sweet 
 potato, pignut, and in addition bananas, various species of 
 gourds (cucurbitacccc) , beans, and of the grains, rice, 
 durra, and maize. Rice has its oldest home in South China 
 probably, the durra in Africa, and maize, as is well known, 
 in America. There belong, finally, to this system of agri- 
 culture the tropical fruit-trees— sago , date-, and cocoa- 
 palms, the breadfruit-tree, and the like. 
 
 On account cf the imperfect nature and limited pro- 
 ductivity of the implements, only small stretches of land 
 can ever be taken into cultivation under the hack system. 
 It is closely related externally, and also in the manner in 
 which it is carried on. to our garden culture. The fields 
 are generally divided into beds, which are often hilled in 
 an exemplary fashion and kept perfectly free of weeds. 
 The whole is surrounded with a hedge to keep out wild 
 animals; against the grain-eating birds, which are particu- 
 larly dangerous to the har\'ests of the tropics, the Malays 
 set up ver\' ingeniously constructed scarecrows; in most 
 places in Africa special waich-towcrs arc erected in the 
 
'Si 
 
 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRJMITiyE PEOPLE. 
 
 47 
 
 
 
 fields from which the young girls make noises to frighten 
 away the animals. As a rule a definite crop rotation is ob- 
 served. In the Congo basin, for instance, when the land 
 is newly broken up it is first planted with beans, and when 
 these are harvested, millet is sown; interspersed with the 
 latter the sprouts of the manioc are often set out. The 
 manioc does not yield full returns for from one and a half 
 to two years, and occupies the land until the roots com- 
 mence to become ligneous, and virgin soil must be taken 
 tip. In New Pomerania the rotation is yam roots first, 
 then taro. and finally bananas, sugar-cane, and the like.® 
 
 Travellers have often described the deep impression 
 made upon them when, on coming out of the dreary 
 primeval forest, they happened suddenly upon the well- 
 tended fields of the natives. In the more thickly popu- 
 latea parts of Africa these fields often stretch for many a 
 mile, and the assiduous care of tlie negro women shines 
 in all the brighter light when we consider the insecurity of 
 life, the constant feuds and pillagings, in which no one 
 knows whether he will in the end be able to harvest what 
 he has sown. Livingstone gives somewhere a graphic 
 description of the devastations wrought by the slave-hunts; 
 the people were lying about slain, the dwellings were de- 
 molished; in the fields, however, the grain was ripening, 
 and there v.as none to harvest it. But as yet the life of 
 these people is by no means firmly attached to the soil; 
 seldom do their settlements remain for several generations 
 on the same spot;^ their houses are fugitive structures of 
 
 'Descriptions of hack agriculture in Angola, Congo district: Pogge. 
 pp. 8. 9; Wissmann, Unter deutsch. Flagge, pp. 34i ff-: among the Mon- 
 buttos: Schweinfurth, In the Heart of Africa, II, pp. 37-39; in 
 Mindanao: Ztschr f. Ethnol., XVII, pp. 19 ff-; in New Guinea: Finsch, 
 Samoafahrten, pp. 56 ff.; in New Pomerania: Parkinson, Im Bismarck- 
 Archipel, pp. 118 ff.; in South America: Martiub, Zur Ethnogr. Atner- 
 ikas, pp. 84. 85. 489. 490. 
 
 ' Ratzel, I, p. 85 ; Panckow, pp. 167 ff. 
 
48 
 
 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 
 
 I I 
 
 H 
 
 IP 
 111 
 \\\ 
 
 SB i J. 
 
 li** 
 
 poles and grass; their other possessions may easily be 
 carried away on their backs or quickly replaced, and on 
 another spot a new village in a few days can be erected 
 in which nothing from the old is lacking save the vermin. 
 
 Hack agriculture is exactly suited to just such a life. 
 It requires no fixed capital beyond the small hoe and, 
 where corn is cultivated, perhaps a knife to cut the ears. 
 The keeping of supplies is scarcely necessary, since in 
 many quarters the climate permits several harvests in the 
 year. Where grain is grown, however, it is customary to 
 store ' in small granaries built on posts, or in pits in the 
 earth, or in great earthen vessels. But even where thus 
 stored it must soon be used if it is not to be destroy».d 
 through dampness, weevils, and termites. Livingstone 
 thinks this explains why the negroes in case of abundant 
 harvest brew so much beer.^ 
 
 Hack agriculture is still one of the most widely prevalent 
 systems of husbandry. It is to be found throughout all 
 Ceni-al Africa (i8° N. lat. to 22° S. lat.). in South and 
 Central America, in the whole of the Australian islands, 
 in great sections of Further India and the East Indian 
 Archipelago, Everywhere, [as already noted], it appears 
 to have been originally woman's work; and as such it is 
 a great factor in advancing civilization. Obviously through 
 hunting for roots, which she had practised from the earliest 
 times, woman was led on to agriculture. Farinaceous bulbs 
 and root-crops form accordingly the chief part of her plan- 
 tations. In this manner she gained technical experiences 
 which the man did not enjoy. Her labour soon yielded 
 the most important part of the requirements of life; and 
 therewith was laid the foundation of a permanent family 
 organization, in which the man undertook the offices of 
 protection and the procuring of animal food. Only where 
 
 * Expedit. to Zambesi, p. 253. 
 
THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PfUMUlvE PEOPLE. 
 
 49 
 
 there are no large quantities of game toes the man take 
 part in the cultivation of th? soil, as, foi instance, among 
 the Malays. 
 
 Let us now turn to the second source of sustenance, 
 hunting and fishing. Through the imperfect nature oi 
 their weapons hunting has ever had among primiti'-'j peo- 
 ples a strong resemblance to the method of the beast of 
 prey stealing upon its victim. A larger animal can only be 
 wounded by an arrow-shot or spear-thrust, not killed; and 
 then it is the hunter's task to pursue the Vast until it sinks 
 down exhausted. As this species of hunt may, however, 
 under certain circumstances, become very dangerous, the 
 most varied ways of trapping have been invented — pits, 
 barricades, and falling trees; or in attacking the animal 
 directly the hunt is carried on by whole tribes or village 
 communities.^ Under such circumstances communal own- 
 ership of the hunting-grounds and the establishment of 
 very detailed rules for the distribution of the booty among 
 the participants and the owners of the ground have been 
 early developed; but on such matters we cannot enter 
 here.**^ The essential thing for us to note is that the part of 
 the duties pertaining to the providing of footl necessitates 
 a certain organization of work conformable to the princi- 
 ple of labour in common — a circumstance that has cer- 
 tainly been of the greatest importance for the birth of 
 primitive political communities. 
 
 The same is to be said of fisliing,^^ especially where the 
 industry is followed along the seashore with boats and 
 large nets, which can be produced and handled only with 
 the help of many. The Ne' / Zealanders, for instance, wove 
 
 'On the hunting methods of the Kaffirs cunip. Fritsch, pp. 81 ff. ; of 
 the South Americans, Martins, pp. 8j, 101. 
 
 '"Some particulars in Post, Afr. Juiistr.. II, pp. i6z. 163; Lubbock, 
 Origin of Civilisation, p. 435. 
 
 ■•' As to fishing comp. in general Katzel, 1, pp. ij4, 396, 506, 531. 
 
 li 
 
so 
 
 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 
 
 ! ill 
 
 in 
 
 
 i I ^i 
 
 < r « 
 
 I i 
 
 nets one thousand yards in length and it took hundreds of 
 hands to use them. Innumerable are the modes of catch- 
 ing fish which primitive peoples have invented; besides 
 hook and net, arrows, spears, bow-nets, and methods of 
 stunning the fish are resorted to. All our information on 
 this subject indicates that fishing acquired a much more 
 regular character among primitive peoples than hunting. 
 On many islands of the South Sea, indeed, definite days of 
 the week have once for all been set apart for the communal 
 fishing; and the leatlers of the fishing expeditions are also 
 the leaders in war. Stream-fishing has been especially de- 
 veloped by the primitive inhabitants of South America, 
 among whom there are tribes that have been called fish- 
 ing nomads because they wander from stream to stream. 
 The same also occurs here and there in Africa. The actual 
 labour of fishing seems always to fall to the men; it is only 
 in some districts of Polynesia that the women take a lim- 
 ited part in it. 
 
 Because of the very perishable nature of meat, hunt- 
 ing and fishing in tropical regions can, in the majority cf 
 cases, supplement the vegetable diet only occasionally. 
 True, the drying and even the smoking of the fish and 
 meat cut into strips was early learned and practised. This 
 i.s the usage with the Polynesians as well as among the 
 Malays and Americans, and even among the negroes and 
 Australians. Yet the pan ci the food requirement which 
 can be regularly met in this manner is so small that it is 
 a rule among many tribes that only the more prominent 
 persons may enjoy certain kinds of game. It is ([uite com- 
 mon also for the use of certain kinds of meat to be for- 
 bidden to the v.'omen. It is only small forest and coast 
 tribes, who are able with their dried meat to carry on trade 
 with agricultural neighbours, that find their support in 
 hunting and fishing. 
 
THE ECONOM.'C LIFE OF PRIMlTIf^E PEOPLE. 
 
 51 
 
 It would accordingly be quite natural to assume that 
 primitive peoples must early have hit upon the taming and 
 raising of animals as a source of a regular food-supply. 
 But we can speak of cattle-raising as a practice among the 
 peoples of the tropical regions only in a very restricted 
 sense. The hen alone, of our domestic animals, is to be 
 found everywhere; besides it there is in Africa the goat, 
 among the Malays and Polynesians the pig, and among 
 the Americans the turkey, the musk-duck and the guinea- 
 pig. Cattle are found only among one section of the 
 Malays and in one strip, more or less broad, of East 
 Africa, which runs through almost the whole continent, 
 from the Dukas and Baris on the Upper Nile to the 
 Hottentots ?nd Namaquas in the south. But most of 
 these people o not use them as draught-animals; many 
 of them do not even use their milk; many East African 
 cattle-raisers never slaughter a beast except when they 
 have captured it from another tribe.*' Here and 
 there in Equatorial Africa the ox serves as a riding and 
 pack animal; but, generally speaking, the possession of 
 cattle is for the negro peoples merely " a representation of 
 wealth and the object of an almost extravagant venera- 
 tion," — merely a matter of fancy. 
 
 Ami this in general is the character of cattle-keeping 
 among primitive peoples. An Indian village in the inte- 
 rior of Brazil, [as we have remarked in our last chapter], 
 resembles a great menagerie; even the art of dyeing the 
 plumage of birds is known; but none of the many animals 
 are raised because of the meat or for other economic pur- 
 pose; the very eggs of the hens, which are kept in large 
 numbers, are not eiten.'-^ To the Indian the lower animals 
 
 " Schweinfurth, I, pp. 59, 60; LivinRstonr, p. ssj; Pogge, p. 23; 
 Wissmann, Im Inntrn Afrikas, pp. 25, 127. 
 
 "Ehrenreich, pp. i.i, 14, 54; Martius, pp. 6;j ff.; K. v. d. Steinen, 
 PP •Jio, 379. bimilariy amung the Oceanians: Ratzei, I, p. 2j6. 
 
1 1? 
 
 if 
 
 >d 
 
 52 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 
 
 are beings closely related to man, and in which he delights; 
 but, as is evident, this keeping of animals is much more 
 closely allied to the hunt than to agriculture. Here we 
 have to do with tamed, not with domestic, animals. With 
 such a state of affairs the place of the pig in the domestic 
 economy of the Oceanians has many cognate features; it is 
 petted by the whole family; its young are not infrequently 
 suckled by the women; and its flesh is eaten only on feast 
 days and then by the more prominent people alone. The 
 sole animal, [other than the hen], which is found among 
 all primitive peoples is the dog; but it also is a pure luxury 
 and is almost nowhere employed in the hunt; only a few 
 tribes eat its flesh, and it has been claimed from ob- 
 servation that these are always such as are devoted to 
 
 cannibalism. 
 
 On the whole, then, no importance can attach to cattle- 
 raising in the production of the food-supplies of primitive 
 peoples; in their husbandry it forms little more than an 
 element of consumption. 
 
 But the needs of these peoples are not confined to sus- 
 tenance. Even the lowest among them paint, or in other 
 ways decorate, their bodies, and make bow^ and arrows; 
 the more advanced erect more or less substantial houses, 
 plait and weave all kinds of stufTs. carve implements, make 
 burnt earthen vessels; all prepare their food with fire, and 
 with few exceptions know how to concoct intoxicatmg 
 beverages. For all this labour of ditTcrcnt kinds is neces- 
 sary which we can cluiracterize in a simple manner as the 
 transformation or tt-or/, m/^' »/' of material, and which in the 
 main embraces what we <lcsi-nate industry. Now what 
 system did ami does such work exhibit among primitive 
 
 peoples' 
 
 If we arc to answer this (juestion we must distmguish 
 sharplv the tcciinical and the economic sides of industry. 
 
THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 
 
 53 
 
 Technique in connection with the transformation of ma- 
 terial is primarily dependent on natural conditions, and ac- 
 cordingly develops among most primitive peoples only 
 along special lines.'' Their implements are at first simple, 
 natural objects, such as stones, animal bones, shells, sharp- 
 ened pieces of wood, destined almost solely to increase the 
 working power of the human members Of implements 
 consisting of more than one part, we may mention the 
 hand-mill and crushing-mortar. The first is merely a sta- 
 tionary and a movable stone with which the grains of corn 
 are ground in the same manner as our artisans grind paint 
 in a mortar. The crushing-mortar is a hollowed tree-trunk 
 with a wooden pestle. The simplest labour-saving me- 
 chanical helps, such as wedge, lever, tongs, and screw, are 
 unknown to them. Their boats are tree-trunks hollowed 
 out with fire, or pieces of bark sewn together; the rudders 
 are sf>oonlike pieces of wood with short handles represent- 
 ing little more than a broadening out of the hand. The 
 ai I of joining together pieces of wood or other hard mate- 
 rial by pegs, nails, dovetailing, or glue they are ignorant 
 of; for this purpose they use tough fibres or cords or even 
 mere tendrils of climbing plants. Metal-working was un- 
 known to the Australians, Melanesians, Polynesians, and 
 the native inhabitants of .America before the coming of the 
 Europeans. On the other hand the negro peoples are uni- 
 versally familiar with the procuring and working up of 
 iron, and here and there of copper as well. A more ad- 
 vanced techni(|ue as regards metals is found only among 
 the Malays. But even in the iron-forging of the negroes 
 all the technical awkwardness of these peoples can be per- 
 ceived. Their smiths did not even hit upon the idea of 
 making their own tools out of iron. Hammers and anvils 
 are stones, and very often the tnngs are only the rib of a 
 palm-leaf. 
 
 "On what foli'iw* romp. Arbeit u Nhythnius. pp. lo ff 
 
■ jpWJiuiWPfWHW" 
 
 3> 1 
 
 11 
 
 1 "' . 
 
 54 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 
 
 In Spite of this technical backwardness many primitive 
 peoples with their wretched tools produce wares of such 
 quality and art^.stic taste as to arouse our highest admira- 
 tion. This is possible only when the particular technical 
 processes are applied in le simplest, and at the same time 
 most comprehensive, manner. Preeminent are weavmg, 
 pottery, and wcod-carving. What indeed do the tropical 
 peoples not make out of the bast and fibrous material of 
 their forests, of the tough grasses and rushes— from mats 
 and clothing-stuflEs of bark to water-tight baskets, dishes, 
 and bottles? What is not made by the East Indians and 
 Eastern Asiatics fror.^ bamboo— from the timbers of the 
 house to water-vesseis, blowing-tubes, and musical instru- 
 ments? How highly developed is woodwork among the 
 Papuans; ami what patience and perseverance it demands! 
 To weave a pijce of stuff of raffia fibre in Madagascar often 
 takes several months; and in South America the same time 
 is required to finish a hammock. The polishing and pierc- 
 ing of the milk-white pieces of quartz that the Uaupes 
 of Brazil wear about their necks is frequently the work of 
 two generations. 
 
 This leads us directly to the industrial organisation in the 
 working tit of material For such labour there are, with 
 few exceptions, no distinctly professional craftsmen. Each 
 household has to meet all economic requirements of its 
 members with its o'-m labour; and this is accomplished 
 by means of that peculiar division of dulies l)etween the 
 two sexes, which we have come to know [in the preceding 
 chapter]. Not only is it that a definite part of the provid- 
 ing of food is assigned to either sex, but each looks 
 after the preparing of such as is gained along with all at- 
 tendant tasks. To the woman falls all that is connected 
 with the procuring and preparing of the vegetable foods: 
 to the man the makinp of wca])<.ii-,. .ui.l of implements for 
 hunting, fishing, and cattle-raising, the working-up of ani- 
 
if 
 
 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRlMlTiyE PEOPLE. 
 
 55 
 
 mal bones and skins, and the building of canoes. As a rule 
 the man also looks after the roasting of the meats and the 
 drying of fish, while the woman must attend to the labor- 
 ious grinding of the com, which she has grown, the brew- 
 ing of beer, the shaping and burning of earthen pots for 
 cooking, and in many instances the building of the huts as 
 well. Besides these there are many species of the trans- 
 forming of material, which are allotted now to one sex, 
 now to the other. We may mention spinning, weaving, 
 plaiting, the preparing of palm-wine and of bark stuffs. 
 But, on the whole, this division of duties between the male 
 and the female members of families is sharply drawn. In- 
 deed it is continued even in consumption, for men and 
 women never eat together; and, where polygamy exists, a 
 separate hut must be provided for each wife.'* 
 
 We cannot enter upon a more detailed discussion 
 of this peculiarly evolved dualism in liouselwld economy 
 among primitive peoples. It devolves upon us, however, 
 to establish that the labour of the members of the house- 
 hold, which is of such an individualistic character, cannot 
 suffice for all tasks of their economic life. For under- 
 takings that surpass the strength of the single household, 
 assistance must therefore be obtained: either the help of the 
 neighbours is solicited or all such labours are performed 
 at one time by the whole village community. The latter 
 is the rule in Africa, for instance, with the breaking of 
 stretches of forest land for cultivation, the laying of barri- 
 cades and pits for trapping wild animals, and elephant- 
 hunting; in F'olynesia. with the weaving of large fishing- 
 nets, the building of large houses, the baking of bread- 
 fruit in a common oven, and the like. Where clanship or 
 slavery or polygamy exists, there is offered a means for 
 multiplying the domestic working strcncrth, and thus for 
 
 ' Com p. 
 
 •ve. rr 
 
56 
 
 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 
 
 fe I 
 
 ) r ,i' 
 
 accomplishing services of a higher order for which the 
 individual's strength does not suffice. 
 
 Within the separate tribes, accordingly, the working 
 and refining of the raw products does not lead to the de- 
 velopment of distinct trades, in that such work is carried 
 on with uniform independence in each separate household 
 From the reports of travellers, who judged from appear- 
 ances, the existence of artisans among various primitive 
 peoples has indeed been asserted. Thus on certain islands 
 of the South Sea there are said to be professional carpen- 
 ters, shoemakers, net-knitters, stone-borers, and wood- 
 car\'ers. On closer examination of the particular cases 
 these observations are open to doubt; to me the case of 
 the native metal-worker seems alone to be proved. Among 
 the negroes of Africa, as far as I can judge, only among 
 the semi-civilized peoples of the Soudan are there the be- 
 ginnings of a special industrial class. Beyond this any 
 traces of a specialized industry supposed to have been dis- 
 covered among primitive peoples are to be thus ex- 
 plained: either individuals manifesting special aptitude 
 for some manufacture came under the observation of 
 travellers, or entire tribes excelled in a particular kind of 
 household occupation, as we shall see directly. Trades 
 formed only under European influence must naturally be 
 disregarded here. 
 
 But from tribe to tribe we find great differences in this 
 industrial working-up of materials. It may even be safely 
 claimed that almost every tribe displays some favourite 
 form of industrial activity, in which its members surpass 
 the other tribes. This is due to the varied distribution of 
 natural products. If good potter's clay is to be found in 
 the district or village of a particular tribe, the women of 
 this tribe or village readily acquire special skill in pottery; 
 where native iron ore is discovered, smiths will appear; 
 
 r \ t 
 
THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 
 
 57 
 
 while along well-wooded seacoasts boat-building will flour- 
 ish. Other tribes or localities excel in the preparation of 
 salt from vegetable ashes, in the making of palm-wine or 
 leather or skin garments; others again in the making of 
 calabashes, baskets, mats, and woven materials. All these 
 forms of skill, however, are aptitudes such as every man or 
 every woman of the particular tribe or locality knows and 
 also practises on occasion. When these individuals are 
 designated by travellers as smiths, salt-makers, basket- 
 makers, weavers, etc., that is to be taken in the same sense 
 as when we speak of ploughmen, reapers, mowers, thresh- 
 ers among our peasants, according to the work in which 
 they are for the time engaged. We have here to do not 
 with special trades claiming the individual's whole activity, 
 but with arrangements forming essential parts of the econ- 
 omy of each separate family. This naturally does not 
 preclude single individuals from surpassing in skilfulness 
 the other members of the tribe, just as there are among 
 our peasant women particularly adept spinners, and among 
 the farmers horse-breeders and bee-keepers who win in 
 prize competitions. 
 
 Travellers have often observed this tribal or local de- 
 vclopmait of industrial technique. " The native villages," 
 relates a Belgian observer of the Lower Congo, " are often 
 situated in groups. Their activities are based upon recip- 
 rocality, and they are to a certain extent the complements 
 of one another. Each group has its more or less strongly 
 defined specialty. One carries on fishing, another pro- 
 duces palm-wine; a third devotes itself to trade and is 
 broker for the others, supplying the community with all 
 products from outside; another has reserved to itself work 
 in iron and copper, making weapons for war and hunting, 
 various utensils, etc. None may, however, pass beyond 
 the sphere of its own specialty without exposing itself to 
 
■r 
 I 
 
 fill 
 
 1 - , ^ . 
 
 ill 
 
 ft, 
 f ft-- 
 
 
 58 
 
 THE ECONOMIC UFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 
 
 the risk of being universally proscribed." From the 
 Loango coast Bastian tells of a great number of similar 
 centres for special products of domestic industry. Loango 
 excels in mats and fishing-baskets, while the carving of 
 elephants' tusks is specially followed in Chilungo. The so- 
 called " Mafooka " hats with raised patterns are drawn 
 chiefly from the bordering country of Kakongo and May- 
 yumbe. In Bakunya are made potter's wares which are in 
 great demand, in Basanza excellent swords, in Basundi 
 especially beautiful ornamented copper rings, on the 
 Zaire clever wood and tablet carvings, in Loango orna- 
 mented cloths and intricately designed mats, in Mayumbe 
 clothing of finely woven mat-work, in Kakongo embroid- 
 ered hats and also burnt-clay pitchers, and among the Ba- 
 yakas and Mantetjes stuffs of woven grass. 
 
 Other similar accounts might be cited, not merely 
 from Africa," but also from the South Sea Islands and 
 even from Central and South America." We shall thus 
 hardly err in assuming that in these tribal industries the 
 controlling principle in the industrial development of prim- 
 itive peoples has been discovered; that by them was 
 furnished the means whereby the satisfaction of the needs 
 of the individual and of whole groups was extended beyond 
 their own immediate powers of production. For it may 
 be taken for granted that an industrial product found only 
 among those manufacturing it, especially if it attained to 
 some importance in the simple life oi these uncivilized peo- 
 ples, would soon be coveted by the surrounding tribes. 
 
 '* H. Schurtz has made a collection of them in his Afr. Gewerbc, pp. 
 29-65. He has pursued further, though unfortunately not far enough, 
 the subject of tribal industry. He has found such industry so exten- 
 sively in evidence i.nat we may assume the conditions of industrial 
 production here portrayed to exist wherever travellers do not ex- 
 pressly report to the contrary. 
 
 " Comp. K. Sapper. Das Hordl. Mittel-Amerika (1897'). pp. 200 flF.. and 
 the further examples given by us. 
 
THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 
 
 59 
 
 But the way from the coveting of an article to its enjoy- 
 ment is a longer one in an economical organization, based 
 upon acquisition directly by the individual himself, than 
 we are inclined to assume in our own social life, which rests 
 upon trade. 
 
 In fact decidedly unclear conceptions are widely preva- 
 lent as to the system of exchange of primit've peoples. We 
 know that throughout Central Africa, from the Portuguese 
 possessions in the west to the German in the east, there is a 
 market-place every few miles at which the neighbouring 
 tribes meet every fourth to sixth day to make mutual ex- 
 changes. Of the Malays in Borneo we are told that each 
 larger village possesses its weekly market. The first dis- 
 coverers of the South Sea Islands give us reports of distant 
 " trading trips " which the natives undertake from island 
 to island in order to make mutual exchanges of their wares. 
 In America certain products, the raw material for which is 
 to be found only in a single locality — for example, arrow- 
 points and stone hatchets made of certain kinds of stone 
 — have been met with scattered throughout a great part of 
 the continent." Even among the aborigines of Australia 
 there are instances of certain natural products, such as 
 pitcher-plant leaves and ochre colour, which are found 
 in but one place, and yet circulate through a g^eat part 
 of the country. In such phenomena we have a new and 
 interesting proof of the civilizing power of trade; and 
 in the primeval history of Europe itself this power has 
 everywhere been assumed as operative when industrial 
 products have been brought to light through excavations 
 or otherwise far from their original place of production. 
 Our prehistoric studies have woven together a whole 
 spider's web of suppositions and have even brought us to 
 
 " Waitz. Ill, p 75; on markets in South America. Ill, p. 380: on 
 others in Mexico, IV, pp. 99 ff. 
 
 II 
 
m''i 
 
 m 
 
 ii- 
 
 I I ^ 
 
 i 
 i 
 
 ritfi 
 
 I Hi! 
 
 i: i ^1 
 
 tf 
 
 I ^Sl 
 
 60 
 
 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMHWE PEOPLE. 
 
 speak of prehistoric '* industrial districts." Our ethno- 
 graphic literature speaks similarly of industrial localities 
 for the manufacture of arms and the plaiting of mats in 
 Borneo, for pottery at several points in New Guinea, for 
 boat-building in several coast districts of the Duke of York 
 Archipelago, for iron-working in negro countries, etc. 
 
 In opposition to this it must be asserted positively that 
 trade in the sense in which it is regarded by national econ- 
 omy — that is, in the sense of the systematic purchase of 
 wares with the object of a profitable re-sale as an organized 
 vocation— can nowhere be discovered among primitive 
 peoples. Where we meet native traders in Africa, it is a 
 question either of intermediary activity prompted by Eu- 
 ropean and Arabian merchants, or of occurrences peculiar 
 to the semi-civilization of the Soudan. Otherwise the only 
 exchange known to the natives everywhere is exchange 
 from tribe to tribe. This is due to the unequal dis- 
 tribution of the gifts of nature and to the varying develop- 
 ment of industrial technique among the different tribes. 
 As between the members of the same tribe, however, no 
 regular exchange from one household establishment to 
 another takes place. Nor can it arise, since that voca- 
 tional division of the population is lacking which alone 
 could give rise to an enduring interdependence of house- 
 holds. 
 
 One fancies the gemns of exchange to have been very 
 easy because civilized man is accusiomed to find all that 
 he needs ready made at the market or store and to be able 
 to obtain it for money. With primitive man, however, 
 before he became acquainted with more highly devel- 
 oped peoples, value and price were by no means current 
 conceptions. The first discoverers of Australia found in- 
 variably, both on the continent and on the neighbouring 
 islands that th« aborigines had no conception of ex- 
 
 i f 
 
THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITiyE PEOPLE. 
 
 6i 
 
 change." The ornaments offered them had no power 
 whatever to arouse their interest; gifts pressed upon 
 them were found later on strewn about in the woods 
 where they had been cast in neglect. Ehrenreich ^^ and 
 K. V. der Steinen 2" had as late as 1887 the same experi- 
 ence among the Indian tribes of Brazil, Yet there 
 was from tribe to tribe a brisk trade in pots, stone hatchets, 
 hammocks, cotton threads, necklaces of mussel-shells, and 
 many other products. How was this possible in the ab- 
 sence of barter and trade? 
 
 The solution oi this riddle is simple enough, and has 
 now been confirmed by direct observation on the spot, 
 while previously it could only be assumed. The transfer 
 ensues by way of presevts, and also, according to circum- 
 stances, by way of robbery, spoils of war, tribute, line, com- 
 pensation, and winnings in gaming. As to sustenance, al- 
 most a community of goods prevails between members ot 
 the same tribes. It is looked upon as theft if a herd of cat- 
 tle is slaughtered and not shared with one's neighbour, or 
 if one is eating and neglects to invite a passer-by. Anyone 
 can enter a hut at will and demand food; and he is never 
 refused. Whole communities, if u poor harvest befall, visit 
 their neighbours and look to them for temporary support. 
 For articles of use and implements there exists the uni- 
 versal custom of loaning which really assumes the character 
 of a duty; and there is no private ownership of the soil. 
 Thus within the tribe where all households produce similar 
 commodities and, in case of need, assist each other, and 
 •where surplus stores can only be utilized for consumption, 
 there is no occasion for direct barter from establishment 
 to establishment. Exceptions occur when purchasing a 
 
 "Documentary proof in Ztschr. f. Sozial- u. Wirtschaftsgesch.. IV, 
 pp. S flF. (Sartorius v. Waltershausen). 
 " Beitrdge :. I'olkerkunde Rrasihens, p. 53, 
 " Unler d. Natun>olkern Central- Brasiliens (2d ed.), pp. 287 ff. 
 
m 
 
 ■11 
 
 ■ , I 
 
 :■.;! 
 
 62 
 
 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 
 
 wife and making presents to tne medicine-man, the singer, 
 the dancer, and the minstrel, who are the only persons 
 carrying on a species of separate occupations. 
 
 From tribe to tribe there prevail rules of hospitality,^^ 
 which recur with tolerable imilarity among all primitive 
 peoples. The stranger on arriving receives a present, 
 which after a certain interval he reciprocates; and at his 
 departure still another present is handed him.^' On both 
 sides wishes may be expressed with regard to these gifts. 
 In this way it is possible to obtain things required or de- 
 sired; and success is the more assured inasmuch as neither 
 party is absolved from the obligations of hospitality until 
 the other declares himself satisfied with the presents. 
 
 That this custom of reciprocal gifts of hospitality per- 
 mits rare products of a land or artistic creations of a tribe 
 to circulate from people to people, and to cover just as 
 long distances from their place of origin as to-day does 
 trade, will perhaps become more apparent to us when we 
 consider how legends and myths have in the same way 
 been enabled to spread over half the A^orld. It is almost 
 inconceivable that this could have been so long overlooked 
 when even in Homer the custom of gifts of hospitality is 
 attested by so many examples. Telemachos brings home 
 from Sparta as present from Menelaos a bowl of silver 
 which the latter had himself received in Sidon as a gift of 
 hospitality from King Phaidimos, and his father Odys- 
 seus receives from the Phaiakes garments and linen and 
 articles of gold as well as a whole collection of tripods and 
 basins. All this he conceals on his arrival, as is well 
 known, in the sacred grove of the nymphs in his native 
 rocky island of Ithaca. Think of the poet's narration as 
 
 " On this oo-.it cotnp. K. Haberland, Die Gastfrcundschaft auf nied. 
 KuUurstufen: Ausland (1878), pp. 282 flF. 
 
 "Gift-making without recompense Lciutigs un'iy fo a higher stage of 
 civilization: A. M. Meyer, Ztschr. f. deutsch, Kuhurgesch., V, pp. 18 fT. 
 
 .■*! 
 
 
THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 
 
 63 
 
 a''.;d toi 3U1 ()urt i. 
 
 ■'"nr.i.ei; ir 
 
 liOl. 
 
 le 
 
 . uy 
 
 •■an. 
 
 s have 
 
 ion from 
 
 7.;ntral Aus- 
 
 kes for a 
 
 gift an object 
 
 V. or of per- 
 
 aaei 
 
 an historical occurrence, and imagine what would have 
 happened had Odysseus been recognised by the wooers at 
 the right moment and slain; the presents of the Phaiakes 
 would have rested well concealed in the gfrotio of the 
 nymphs down to our own times, and would have been 
 brought to light again by a moden; .archaeologist. Would 
 he not have explained the wholf treasu -e as the storehouse 
 of a travelling merchant of ' .e I- nif 15;^' ^.l 'Tellas, es- 
 pecially as he could have app a' .;d tor 3ui purt w • le actual 
 barter which occurs quite c 
 Among many primitive ^, 
 been preserved which cU r,^ ..!■ .1; ^'•: 
 presents to exchange, ^ii.ory^ 'u 1 . 
 tralia, for instance, a man < : > ■ "i 
 present the task of procuring ?s recinrocii 
 that another desires, or of buiu. ' loi Iii 
 formi..^ some other service. The one thus bound is called 
 yutschin, and until the fulfilment of the obligation wears a 
 cord about his neck. As a rule the desired object is to be 
 procured from a distance.^'" In New Zealand the natives 
 on the Wanganui river make use of parrots, which they 
 catch in great numbers, roast, and preserve in fat, in order 
 to obtain dried fish from their fe!lo"'-countrymen in other 
 parts of the island."^ Among the Indian tribes of Cen- 
 tral Brazil trade is still an mterchange of gifts of hospi- 
 tality; and the Bakairis translate the Portuguese cotr'>rcr, 
 to btiy, by a word signifying ' to sit down,' becaub ■ the 
 guest must be seated before he receives his present. In 
 the countries of the Soudan the co.";stant giving of pres- 
 ents frequently becomes burdensoine to the traveller 
 " since it is often only a concealed begging." " The gifts 
 of hospitality that are received in the camp," remarks 
 
 "A \V. TTowitt in Journal of Anthrop. Inst, XX (1891), pp. 76 ff. 
 
 ** Shortland, Tfaditions and Sttl'erst-.tijtt.i of Ike Nctv Zealanders (Lon- 
 don, 1856), pp. 214, 215. 
 
: - i 
 1 ■ ' -* 
 
 > 1 
 
 64 
 
 THE ECONOMIC UFE OF PRIMITiyE PEOPLE. 
 
 Staudinger,^'' " are in accord with good custom and are 
 often very welcome. But with every stop in a larger town 
 things are frequently obtained from high and low which are 
 ostensibly given as a mark of respect to the white man; 
 in reality they arrive only because the donors expect a 
 three- or four-fold response from the liberality of the Euro- 
 pean. Indeed I am convinced that many a poor woman 
 has herself first purchased the hen or duck that is to be 
 presented in order to do a profitable piece of gift business 
 with it." 
 
 The Indians of British Guiana appear to stand at the in- 
 termediate stage between gift-making and trading. Im 
 Thurm reports of them: " 
 
 •• There exists among the tribes of this, as oi probably every other 
 similar district, a rough system of distribution of labour; and this 
 serves not only its immediate purpose of supplying all the tribes with 
 better-made articles than each could make for itself, but also brings 
 the different tribes together and spreads among them ideas and news 
 of general interest. . . . Each tribe has some manufacture peculiar 
 to itself; and its members constantly visit the other tribes, often 
 hostile, for the purpose of exchanging the products of their own 
 labour for such as arc produced only by the other tribes. These 
 trading Indians are allowed to pass unmolested through the enemy's 
 country. . . Of the tribes on the coast, the Warraus make far the 
 best canoes, and supply these to the neighbouring tribes. They also 
 make hammocks of a peculiar kind, which are not, however, much 
 in rctjuest e.xcept among tlicnisclvcs. In the same way, far in the 
 interior, the Wapiaiias build boats for all the tribos in that district. 
 The Macusis have two special products which are in great demand 
 amongst all the tribes. One is the ourali. used for poisoning arrows 
 and the darts of blowpipes, the other is an abundance of cotton ham- 
 mocks; for, though these are now often made by the Wapianas .md 
 True Caribs, the Macusis are the chief makers. The Arecunas grow, 
 spin, and distribute most of the cotton which is used by the Macusis 
 .ind others for hamnocks and other articles. The Arecunas also sup- 
 ply all blowpipes; f(,r these are made of the stems of a palm which, 
 
 "/m Hcrstn d. Ilaussaliindcr (2d cd). pp. 216. 217 Comp. Sachau, 
 Retsen in Syricn u. Mesofotamien, p. loi; v. Hiigel, Kaschmir, pp. 406, 
 40;. 
 
 " /trnong the Indians of Guiana (London, 188.O, pp. 270-273- 
 
THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITiyE PEOPLE. 
 
 65 
 
 growing only in and beyond the Venezuelan boundary of their terri- 
 tory, are procured by the Arecunas, doubtless by exchange, from the 
 Indians of the native district of that palm. The Tarumas and the 
 Woyowais have a complete monopoly of the manufacture of the 
 graters on which Indians of all the tribes grate their cassava. These 
 two remote tribes are also the great breeders and trainers of hunting- 
 dogs. . . . The True Caribs, again, are the most skilful potters; and 
 though the Arawaks frequently, and the other Indians occasionally, 
 make vessels for their own use, yet these are by no means as good as 
 those which, whenever possible, they obtain from the Caribs. The 
 Arawaks make fibre hammocks of a kind peculiar to them. . . . The 
 Ackawoi alone, so far as I know, have no special product interchange- 
 able for those of their neighbours. These Indians are especially 
 dreaded and disliked by all the others; and it is possible that the want 
 of intercourse thus occasioned between this tribe and the others forced 
 the Ackawoi to produce for themselves all that they required. It is 
 further possible that to this enforced self-dependence is due the miser- 
 able condition of most of the Ackawoi. 
 
 " To interchange their manufactures the Indians make long jour- 
 neys. The Wapianas visit the countries of the Tarumas and the 
 Woyowais, carrying with them canoes, cotton hamnn-cks, and now 
 very frequently knives, beads, and other European goods; and, leav- 
 ing their canoes and other merchandise, they walk back, carrying with 
 them a supply of cassava-graters, and leading hunting-t'ogs, all which 
 things they have received in i hange for the things which they took. 
 The Macusis visit the Wapiana settlements to obtain graters i. \ 
 dogs, for which they give ourali-poison and cotton hammocks; and 
 they again carry such of these graters and dogs as they do not them- 
 selves require, together with more of their own ouralt and of their 
 cotton hammocks, to other Indians — to the Arecunas. wlio j;ivc in 
 return balls of cotton or blowpipes; or to the True Caribs. who pay 
 in pottery." 
 
 Once originated exchange lonj? retains the marks of its 
 
 descent in the rules that are attached to it and which are 
 
 taken directly from the customs connected with gifts. This 
 
 is manifested, in the fir.st place, in the custom of payment 
 
 in advance which dominates trade nmonjT primitive pej- 
 
 pies." The medicine-man does not stir his hand to .lelp 
 
 " Even Europc.in merchants trading in .^fri^M must accommodate 
 themselves to this custom 'by advancing to the black interniediarics 
 whose services they call into re<|uisition the price of the commodities 
 that arc .0 be supplied. Conip. Pogge. pp. 11, 140, 141; M. Buchner, 
 
66 
 
 THE ECONOMIC UFE OF PRIMITIl^E PEOPLE. 
 
 \ H 
 
 ■ f 
 
 the sick until he has received from the sick man's relatives 
 his fee, which in this case closely resembles the present, 
 and has openly announced his satisfaction. No purchase 
 is complete until buyer and seller have before witnesses 
 declared themselves satisfied with the objects received. 
 Among many peoples a gift precedes or follows a deal; *• 
 the " good measures " of our village storekeepers, and 
 "treating" are survivals of this custom. To decline 
 without grounds an exchange that has been offered passes 
 among the negroes as an insult, just as the refusal of a 
 gift among ourselves. The idea that services interchanged 
 must be of equal value can hardly be made intelligible to 
 primitive man. The boy who performs a bit of work ex- 
 pects the same pay as the man, and the one who has 
 assisted for one hour just as much as the one who has 
 laboured a whole day; and as the greed on both sides 
 knows no bounds, every trading transaction is preceded 
 by long negotiations. Sii; lar negotiations, however, are 
 also the rule in the discharge of gifts of hospitality if the 
 recipient does not find the donation in keeping with his 
 dignity. 
 
 As time passes exchange creates from tribe to tribe its 
 own contrivances for facilitating matters. The most im- 
 portant of these are markets and money. 
 
 Markets are uniformly held among negroes. East Indi- 
 ans, and Polynesians in open places, often in the midst of 
 the primeval forests, on the tribal borders. They form neu- 
 tral districts within which all tribal hostilities must cease; 
 whoever violates the market-peace exposes himself to the 
 severest punishments. Each tribe brings to the market 
 KamfTHH. pp. 98, 99. Even the sacrifice to the deity seems to the peo- 
 ples of '.hi-s staKc only payment in advance for an expected service: 
 Heckewtlder. Indian Xations. pp. 2ti fT. ; and comp. pp. j^i. j.^fi 
 
 " Schurt/. F.ntslfh Gesch. d Geldes. pp. 67, 6a Landor, In the For- 
 bidden Land (Tibe<), I, p. ,115: II. p. 7& 
 
THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRlMITiyE PEOPLE. 67 
 
 whatever is peculiar to it: one honey, another palm-wine, 
 a third dried meat, still another earthenware or mats or 
 woven stuffs." The object of the interchange is to ob- 
 tain products that cannot be procured in one's own tribe 
 at all, or at least -cannot be produced so well and so artis- 
 tically as in neighbouring tribes. This must- agam lead 
 each tribe to produce in greater quantities than it requires 
 those products which are valued among the tribes, not pro- 
 ducing them, because in exchange for these it is easiest to 
 obtam that which one does not possess one's self, but 
 which others manufacture in surplus quantities. In each 
 tribe, however, every household produces the current 
 market commodity of exchange that enjoys this prefer- 
 ence. Hence it follows, when it is a question of a product 
 of house industry, such as earthenware or wares made of 
 bark, that whole villages and tribal areas appear to travel- 
 lers to be great industrial districts, although there are no 
 specialized artisans, and although each household pro- 
 duces everything that it requires with tlie exception of the 
 few articles made only among other tribes which they have 
 grown accustomed to and which exchange procures for 
 them merely as supplements to houshold production. 
 
 Such is the simple mechmism of the market among 
 primitive peoples. Now with regard to monfy. How 
 much has been written and imagined about the many 
 species of money among primitive peoples."" and yet how 
 
 "AlthnuKh many primitive iH-.^.k-s ran l.c to.m.l roadv to jjive 
 every tli.n^ for ICiiropcan wares that tlu-y have co,„e t,. kruw and 
 value, yet their rev;„lar exchange remains alto^iether u„e -ulcd and 
 cnnfmed to •, iVw artu-le.. Man> ohj^ct. of .l.nlv „-,. are nm t„ be 
 had from them at any price, especially ol.ieets of a.lorn.nent Comp 
 I'.nseh, Samoafahrtcn. pp. ,08. ,10, .«)(,, .-S,, f,, ,,,^: Martmx ctcd 
 above, pp, K.). 5()(,; Zt-.lir f FlhnoKr.. WIl. pp _> , (,j. 
 
 '-"!< .■\tMlrre, t-.thn,^^r. r,:n,llcl,„ ./. / VrcA ;,/).•, pp ...., (T O I.en/. 
 I chcr i.dd hi-i d. \\UufVi.',k,-rn ( HamhnrK. 1S-J5). R Ilwof. Tausch- 
 kiindd u Celdsurrogatc m alter u. neucr /.at (Gra/, 1882). II. Schurz, 
 
68 
 
 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE, 
 
 ' I 
 
 i 
 
 simple the explanation of their origin ! The money of each 
 tribe is that trading commodity ivhich it does not itself 
 produce, but which it regularly acquires from other tribes 
 by way of exchange. For such article naturally becomes 
 for it the universal medium of exchange for which it sur- 
 renders its wares. It is its measure of value according to 
 which it values its property, which could in no other way 
 be made exchangeable. It is its wealth, for it cannot in- 
 crease it at will. F°llow tribesmen soon come to employ 
 it also in transferring values, for because of its scarcity it 
 is equally welcome to all. Thus is explained what our trav- 
 ellers have frequently observed, that in each tribe, often 
 indeed from village to village, a different money is current, 
 and that a species of mussel-shells or pearls or cotton stuf? 
 for which everything can be purchased to-day, is in the 
 locality of the following evening's camp no longer ac- 
 cepted by anyone. The consetinence is that they must first 
 purchase the current commodities of exchange before they 
 can supply their own needs in the market. In this way, 
 also, is to be explained the further fact, which has come 
 under observation, that exchangeable commodities nat- 
 urally scarce, such as salt, cauri shells, and bars of cop- 
 per, or products of rare skill, such as brass wire, iron 
 spades, and earthen cups, are taken as money by many 
 tribes not possessing them; and above all is to be men- 
 tioned the well-known circumstance of objects of foreign 
 trade, such as European calicoes, guns, ponder, knives, 
 becoming general mediums of exchange. 
 
 Certain varieties of money thus secure a more extensive 
 area of circulation. They can even make their way into 
 the internal trade of the tribal members through employ- 
 ment as mediums of payment \u the juirchase of a bride, for 
 
 Balntge r. r.ntsli'huv-Rcsch d. („ldi\i: Deutsche Ucogr. Dldltcr (Bre- 
 men). .\X (iSfj;), ip. 1-'/'. Itiicrn. Archiv f, Ethtiogr., VI, p. 57. 
 
 ,: ft 
 
 :•* 
 
THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITiyE PEOPLE. 
 
 69 
 
 compensations, taxes, and the like; certain kinds of con- 
 tracts are concluded in them. But there is no instance 
 of a primitive people, in the absence of European influence, 
 attaining to a currency or legal medium of payment for 
 obligations of every kind and extent. It is rather the rule 
 that various species of money remain in concurrent circu- 
 lation; and very often certain obligations can be paid only 
 in certain kinds. Changes in the variety of money are 
 not infrequent; but on the other hand we sometimes find 
 that a species will long survive the trade of the tribes from 
 which it has gone forth, and will continue to serve in the 
 inner transactions of a tribe, playing a singular, almost 
 demoniacal, role, although, as regards their means of sus- 
 tenance, the members of the tribe have nothing to buy and 
 sell to one another. From an old interrupted tribal trade 
 of this nature is to be explained the employment as money 
 of old Chinese porcelain vessels among the Bagobos in 
 Mindanao and the Dyaks in Borneo, the shells (dewarra) 
 of the Melanesians. and the peculiar kinds of money of 
 the Caroline Archipelago, for which special laws and ad- 
 ministrative contrivances are necessary in order to keep 
 this dead possession in circulation at all.^* Otherwise the 
 State does not interfere as a rule in these matters; and in 
 the large territorial formations of Africa, such as the king- 
 dom of Muata Yamwo. for instance, there are therefore 
 different currencies from tribe to tribe. But even where 
 one kind of money gains a greater area of circulation, its 
 value fluctuates widely at the various market-places: 
 generally, however, it advances in proportion to the dis- 
 tance from its source.^*' 
 
 " WV cannot rntir luri- more in dct.iil info these matters, and would 
 refer to the interesting descriptions of Kubary, Etknog. Beitrdge s. 
 Kcnntms d C:irfltmfn-Archi(<cls. pp. i fT.. and Parkinson, pp. 79, loi flf. 
 
 '"Thus Ccrohi reports, funf Jahrc m Ostafrika. p. 2-\: " .Xccordinff 
 to the higher or lower value of the salt bar in the markets of this 
 
70 
 
 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 
 
 W 
 
 iJ 
 
 Markets and money are intimately related so far as 
 money in its character as a medium of exchange comes un- 
 der consideration. But not every individual species of 
 money that is met with among a primitive people has 
 necessarily arisen from market trade. In its full develop- 
 ment money is such an involved social phenomenon that 
 it is natural to suppose that various influences associated 
 with its past have been united in it. Thus, for instance, 
 the origin of cattle-money seems to be bound up with the 
 fact that, among the peoples referred to, the domestic ani- 
 mals represented the wealth and the means of gathering 
 wealth. That for the purchase of a bride and for similar 
 ends many tribes do not receive the current money, but 
 f such purposes prescribe certain other objects of worth, 
 a :)ears to point to the admissibility of the assumption that 
 the complete development of money, along with the 
 
 un current, various subsidiary streams may have played 
 
 art 
 
 31 
 
 7rom the standpoint of the total cultural progress of 
 
 'f Ea • Africa one could roughly estimate the distance from the 
 
 whe this money comes, and also judge of the more or less 
 
 icabl' ature of the routes over which the caravans transport it. 
 
 - in • reality of its origin, for one thaler one receives among 
 
 the T.- cording to the statements of several travellers, several 
 
 hii - bars. In Uorallu, the northern market of Schao, lying a 
 
 <li--ta! 'f some two hundred miles from the country of the Taltal, 
 
 ;'.> va hictuatcs between fifteen and twenty for the thaler. In .^n- 
 
 coIkt. ciahty miles from Uorailu, the value sinks back to nine and 
 
 nine ;ind a half, and in Gera, two hundred and thirty miles beyond 
 
 Ancobcr, one receives, according to circumstances, only six. five. 
 
 four, or three salt bars per thaler." 
 
 "Perhaps Karl Marx rishtly expresses it when he tersely remarks: 
 " The money-form attaches itself either to the most important articles 
 of exchange from outside, and these in fact arc primuivc and natural 
 forms in which the exchange-value of h<ime product" find-, expression; 
 or else it attaches itself to the object of utility that f.)rnis, like cattle, 
 the chief portion of indigenous alienable wealth." — Capital (London, 
 1891), p 6i. 
 
THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 
 
 71 
 
 mankind the most important result of this survey, how- 
 ever, remains, that money as the favourite exchange com- 
 modity furnished a medium that bound together men from 
 tribe to tribe in regular peaceful trade, and prepared the 
 way for a differentiation of tribes in the matter of produc- 
 tion. In the circumstance that all members of the same 
 tribe or village preferably carried on, along with the earn- 
 ing of their sustenance, other work of a definite type, lay 
 the possibility of an advance in technical knowledge and 
 dexterity. It was an international, or interlocal, division of 
 labour in miniature, which only much later was succeeded 
 by division of labour from individual to individual within 
 the nation, or the locality. Moreover the direct importance 
 of the market for personal intercourse at this stage must 
 not be undervalued, especially in lands where trading out- 
 side the market is so unusual that even travellers wishing 
 to buy something direct are regularly refused with the 
 words " come to market." In this one is involuntarily re- 
 minded of the prominent position that the market occu- 
 pied in the social and political life of the peoples of classical 
 antiquity. 
 
 But it is always a very onesided development, permitting 
 only to individual tribes the organization of production 
 and trade just descriljed. In this way is to be explained 
 that most extraordinary phenomenon that in the interior 
 of continents where no difficulties in communication op- 
 pose the passage of certain attainments in technical skill 
 from tribe to tribe, it has been possible for jieoplcs of 
 very primitive economic stamp to remain unchanged by 
 the side of others of higher development throughout 
 thousands of voars. One of the most remarkable exam- 
 ples of this nature is ofTere<l in Central Africa by the pigmy 
 race of the Batuas or Akkas. still standing at the stage of 
 the lower nomads, which keeps strictiv within the zone of 
 
72 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 
 
 the primitive forest, but on definite days appears at the 
 market-places of the surrounding negro tribes to exchange 
 its chief economic product, dried meat of animals killed in 
 the hunt, for bananas, ground-nuts, maize, and the like. In 
 fact in some parts even a more primitive form of trading 
 has been maintained between these pigmy people and their 
 neighbours, in that at the period when thd fruit is ripe 
 the Batuas break into the fields of the negroes, steal bana- 
 nas, tubers, and corn, and leave behind an equivalent in 
 meat.3* The fact that the Batuas are clever hunters ap- 
 pears here to have caused the neighbouring tribes to neg- 
 lect the production of meat through hunting and cattle- 
 raising. On the other hand it is said that the pigmies do 
 not even make their own weapons, but procure them in 
 trade from the Momsus and other tribes. 
 
 Of this one-sided development another and much more 
 wide-spread example is offered by the smiths, who not 
 merely among many tribes of Africa but sporadically in 
 Asia and in southeastern Europe form a hereditarily dis- 
 tinct caste, whose members, whether regarded with bash- 
 ful awe or contempt, can neither enter into a marital nor 
 
 "Casati, Zehn Jahre in Aequatoria, I, p. 151. Schweinfurth, The 
 Heart of Africa, II. pp. 83 ff. Dr. W. Junker's Travels in Africa, III, 
 pp. 8s, 86. Wissmann, Wolf, etc., /m Intiern Afrikas, pp. 256, 258 ff. A. 
 similar report is given by W. Geiger (Ceylon), Tagebuchbldttcr u. 
 Reiseerittnerungen (Wiesbaden, 1897), of the Veddahs: "The method 
 by which the Veddah is able to procure his arrow-points— which he 
 does not make himself— is interesting. He betakes himself under 
 cover of ni^ht to the dwelling of a Singhalese smith, and places in 
 front of it a leaf t<) which the desired shape is given. To this he adds 
 a present o^ some kind, wild honey, the skin of an animal, or some- 
 thing similar. During one of the following nights he returns and 
 expects to find the object ordered finished. If he is satisfied, he will 
 deposit another special gift. The smiths never refuse to execute the 
 orders at once. If they do. tluy may be certain at the next oppor- 
 tunity to bo made the target f..^ :in arrow. Moreover their labour is 
 abundantly rewarded by what t Veddah gives in return." 
 
THE ECONOMIC UFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 
 
 73 
 
 Other social alliance with the rest of the people." This 
 strange phenomenon has hitherto been explained as a 
 matter of remnants of subject tribes preserving to their 
 conquerors the art of metal-working, which had other- 
 wise perished, because the victorious race was ignorant of 
 it. It is, however, also conceivable that a voluntary dis- 
 persal of such tribes took place and that ti.e very differ- 
 ence of nationality, coupled with the carrying on of an 
 esoteric art, placed them wherever they settled outside the 
 community of the people. 
 
 In individual instances the carrying on of such a tribal 
 industry in this exclusive manner leads to the rise of what 
 travellers usually designate now as industrial peoples, be- 
 cause they do work for all their neighbours; now as trading 
 peoples, because one meets them in all the markets of a 
 more extensive district, and because they monopolize the 
 trade in certain wares. We have an instance of the former, 
 when the consumers resort to the district where a special 
 tribal industry flourishes, in order to get the desired wares 
 at the seat of manufacture; of the latter, when the pro- 
 ducers bring to the tribes lacking them such wares as they 
 produce beyond their own requirements. 
 
 As an example of the first form of this evolution, the 
 little tribe of the Osakas may be cited, which has its home 
 in the valley of the Ogowe to the east of the Lolo River. 
 Lenz^* reports concerning it: " The Osakas are divided 
 into five or six villages, each of which contains sixty to a 
 hundred huts; compared with their numerically so im- 
 portant neighbours, such as the Fans and the Oshebo- 
 Adumas, they are thus destined to play an altogether 
 passive role in the history of those countries. In spite of 
 this, however, the Osakas appear to be not altogether in- 
 
 " R. Andree. pp. 15,1 ff 
 
 " Mittheil. d. gfogr Gesell. in Wien (i8r8), p. 476- 
 
74 
 
 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMmVE PEOPLE. 
 
 i m 
 
 f 
 
 I 
 
 li « 
 
 significant; for among them I found many individuals be- 
 longing to the most widely different tribes, frequently 
 from regions quite far distant. The Osakas are recognised 
 as the best smiths, and all the surrounding tribes, — the 
 Oshebo-Adumas, the Akelles, the Awanshis and even the 
 Fans, — buy of them a great part of their implements for 
 hunting and war, although the last-named tribe itself ex- 
 cels at this handicraft. By the Oshebo-Adumas the iron 
 wares of the Osakas are then brought down to the Okan- 
 des and to the Apinshis and Okotas dwelhng between the 
 rapids of the Ogowe, these last tribes on their part being 
 but little skilled in iron-work and devoting themselves ex- 
 clusively to the slave-trade. From there, through the me- 
 dium of the Iningas and Galloas, weapons of this kind find 
 their way as far as the sea-coast." 
 
 " The Oshebo-Adumas generally pay for these weap- 
 ons with palm-oil and ground-nuts, while the Fans, who 
 are the most expert huntsmen of all these various tribes, 
 give in exchange for the spears and swordlike knives dried 
 and smoked meat, chiefly of the antelope, the* wild boar, 
 the porcupine, the field rat and the monkey. In all the 
 Osaka villages I saw a bustling life. As must always be 
 the case where such widely diflferent tribes meet together, 
 quarrelings were extremely frequent there and often as- 
 sumed great proportions." 
 
 A typical example of the second form is offered by the 
 Kiocos and the Kanjocas in the southern part of the 
 Congo basin. Of the latter Wissmann reports: ^^ "The 
 Kanjoka country is particularly rich in iron, and there are 
 some excellent smiths there. Salt also is produced, so that 
 the Kanjokas, with the products of their countr>' and their 
 iron manufacture, undertake commercial expeditions to 
 the south as far as the Lunda country." The Kiocos dwell 
 
 "My Second Journey through Equal. Africa (London, 1891), p. 105. 
 
 3 
 
THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMlTiyE PEOPLE. 
 
 75 
 
 in the kingdom of Lund itself, dispersed among the Ka- 
 lundas, but have their own chiefs who are tributary to the 
 Muata Yamwo. The Kiocos are partial to placing their 
 villages in the woodland, for they are preeminently excel- 
 lent hunters, gather gum from their forests, and to obtain 
 wax carry on a species of wild-bee keeping. They are also 
 clever smiths, and not only make good hatchets, but can 
 also repair old flmtlocks and even fit them with new mounts 
 and stocks. They clothe themselves in animal skins; the 
 art of making vegetable cloths is little known to them. 
 Their women plant chiefly manioc, maize, millet, ground- 
 nuts, and beans. The products that the Kiocos obtain 
 from the exploitation of their forests they exchange on the 
 west coast for wares, chiefly powder, with which they then 
 betake themselves into the far interior in order to buy 
 ivory and slaves. The ivory obtained through trade they 
 dispose of, while the slaves they procure they incorporate 
 with their household. The Kiocos esteem slaves above all 
 as property. They treat the slave women as they do their 
 wives, and the men as members of the household, and part 
 from them so very unwillingly that in the Kioco country 
 it is quite exceptional for travellers to be offered slaves for 
 sale. On their hunting voyages they have penetrated 
 farthest towards the east; and there, before entering upon 
 their journey homewards, they usually barter a part of 
 their weapons for slaves. Then for the time being they 
 arm themselves again with bow and arrow. They rightly 
 enjoy the reputation of being as good hunters as they are 
 crafty and unscrupulous traders; and in a masterful man- 
 ner they understand how to overreach and dispossess the 
 better-natured and more indolent Kalundas.^® 
 
 This picture is often repeated in the negro countries. 
 
 " Pogge, pp. 45, 46, 47, and Wissmann, Im Innern Afrikas, pp. 59, 62. 
 Comp. also Schurtz, Afr. Cew., p. 50. 
 
MICROCOPY RiSOlUTION TiST CHAR) 
 
 (ANSI and ISO TEST CHART No. 2) 
 
 A 
 
 /APPLIED IIVMGE Inc 
 
 '653 foil Mom S<r««' 
 
 Rochviltr. N»* York U609 USA 
 
 (M6) 482 - 0300 - Pfion. 
 
 ("6) 2M - i9«9 - To, 
 
76 
 
 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 
 
 One readily sees that it does not adapt itself to any of the 
 usual categories of economic history. The Kiocos are no 
 hunting people, no nomads, no agriculturalists, no indus- 
 trial and trading nation; they are all these at once. They 
 act as intermediaries for a part of the trade with the Euro- 
 pean factories on the coast. At the same time they carry 
 on some mediary traffic of their own in which they dis- 
 play the peculiar aptitude of the negro for barter, but 
 nevertheless gain most of their living directly from hunt- 
 ing and agriculture. 
 
 Both forms of development are met with in the two pot- 
 tery islands of New Guinea, Bilibi and Chas. The manu- 
 facture is in both places in the hands of the women. The 
 natives of the islands round about, and even of the more 
 distant ones, come to Chas to barter their products for the 
 earthenware; in Bilibi the men take whole boatloads to sell 
 along the coast. Every woman makes a special mark on 
 the pottery she produces; but whether with one European 
 observer we are to regard this as a trade-mark seems very 
 doubtful^*" 
 
 In order to leave untouched no important part of the 
 economic life of primitive peoples, let us take a rapid 
 glance at their commercial contrivances and public adminis- 
 tration. Both are intimately connected. For commerce is 
 essentially a public matter; there are no private commer- 
 cial arrangements whatever amoi..; these peoples. Indeed 
 one can claim frankly that at this stage trade scarcely dis- 
 plays an economic character at all. 
 
 In the first place as concerns commercial routes, there 
 are overland trade routes only when they have been 
 tramped by the foot of man; the only artificial structures 
 to facilitate land trade are primitive bridges, often consist- 
 
 •*Comp Finsch, pp. 8i, 8.?, 281, 28-!: Scmon, In the Austral. Bush. pp. 
 317 fF. Similar pottery districts in Africa proven by Schurtz, p. S4 
 
 r 
 
THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITH^E PEOPLE. 
 
 77 
 
 ing merely of a single tree-trunk, or ferries at river fords, 
 for the use of which the traveller has to pay a tax to the 
 village chief. These dues as a rule open the door to heavy 
 extortions.^^ On the other hand the natural waterways 
 are everywhere diligently used, and there is hardly a prim- 
 itive people that has not been led through its situation 
 by the sea or on a river to the use of some peculiar kind 
 of craft. The enumeration and description of these means 
 of transportation would fill a volume; from the dugout 
 and skin canoe of the Indians to the artistically carved 
 rowboats and sailboats of the South Sea Islanders, all 
 types are represented. On the whole, however, the tech- 
 nique of boat-building and navigation has remained unde- 
 veloped among these peoples; none of their vessels de- 
 serv'e the name of ship in the proper sense. Thus their 
 importance is everywhere restricted to personal transporta- 
 tion and fishing, while nowhere has the development 
 reached a freight transportation of any extent. 
 
 Curiously among primitive peoples that branch of com- 
 mercial communication has enjoyed the fullest develop- 
 ment which we would naturally associate only with the 
 highest culture, namelv. the communication of news. It 
 forms indeed the sole kind of trade for which primitive 
 peoples have created permanent organizations. We refer 
 to the courier service and the contrivances for sending 
 verbal messages. 
 
 The despatching of couriers and embassies to neighbour- 
 ing tribes in war and peace leads, even at a very low stage 
 of culture, to the development of a complete system of 
 symbolic signs and means of conveying intelligence.'" 
 Thus among the rude tribes in the interior of Australia 
 
 "Comp. Pogge. pp. 64. 70, 78, 95, 97, IIS, 169; Wissmann. Untcr 
 dfutsck. Flaggc. pp. .^43, 361. 364, 394; and Second Journey, p. 71. 
 
 "Comp. generally R. Andree, " Merkzeichen u. Knotenschrift " in 
 his Ethnogr Parallel, pp. 184 ff.: Waitz. IV. p. 80. 
 
78 
 
 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 
 
 Ill 
 
 various kinds of body-painting, of head-dress and other 
 conventional signs serve to apprise a neighbouring tribe of 
 the occurrence of a death, of the holding of a feast, and of 
 a threatening danger, or to summon the tribesmen tci- 
 gether for any purpose.^* Among the aborigines of South 
 America ingeniously knotted cords or leather strips 
 (quippits), and among the North Americans the well- 
 known wampum perform s'milar offices;*" in Africa cou- 
 rier-staflFs with or without engraved signs are customary, 
 and the same are found among the Malays and Poly- 
 nesians. If need be, the couriers have to learn their mes- 
 sage by heart and communicate it verbally.** In the negro 
 kingdoms, where the administrative power of the ruler 
 reaches only as far as he is able personally to intervene,*'' 
 the couriers of the chiefs hold a very important position; 
 for through them the sovereign chief is as if omnipresent, 
 and new occurrences come to his knowledge with surpris- 
 ing rapidity. But even for the communication of intelli- 
 gence among members of the same tribe — for instance, in 
 hunting and in war — a system of symbols exists which is 
 often very ingeniously conceived, and which, as a rule, is 
 hidden from the uninitiated. 
 
 Not less remarkable are the telephonic contrivances rest- 
 ing upon the ingenious employment of the drum, the 
 
 "Details in Journ. of Anthropol. In^t.. XX, pp. "i ff. 
 
 " Martius, pp. 98, 99, 694; Waitz, III, pp. 138 ff. On knot writing in 
 West Africa: Bastian, Die Exp. «. d. Loango-Kustc, I, p. 181. 
 
 *' Livingstone, p. 285. Comp. also the apt description by Casalis, 
 Let Bassoulos, pp. 2.^, .235: " Ces niessagcrs sont gen ralement doues 
 dune memoire prodigieuse, ct Ton peut s'attendre a ce qu'ils trans- 
 mcttcnt tcxtucllcmcnt les depeches orales, dont ils se chargent." 
 
 "This applies also to the political conditions of semi-civilization. 
 G. Rohlfs, Land u. Volk in Afrika, p. 163: "The Abyssinian is accui- 
 tomed to obey only when his master is near. Once out of reach of his 
 voice little does he trouble himself about orders. This is the case in 
 all half-civilized countries. To this Turkey, Morocco, Egypt, and 
 Bornoo bear witness." 
 
THE ECONOMIC UFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 
 
 79 
 
 musical instrument in widest use among primitive peoples. 
 In one sense they take the form of a developed signal- 
 system, as among the East Indians** and the Melane- 
 sians,*^ in another there is a real speaking of words by 
 which detailed conversations can be carried on at great 
 distances. The latter is very common in Africa.** As a 
 rule only the chiefs and their relations are acquainted with 
 this drum language; and the possession of the instrument 
 used for this purpose is a mark of rank, like the crown and 
 sceptre in civilized countries. Less extended is the em- 
 ployment of fire-signs for summoning the tribe or com- 
 municating news.*° 
 
 There is no public economy, in our sense of the word. 
 True, where their power is to some extent established, ♦he 
 chiefs receive all kinds of dues in the form of shares, tra- 
 ditionally fixed, in the products of the chase and of hus- 
 bandry, fees for the use of bridges, ferries, market-place. In 
 more extensive kingdoms the subordinate chieftains are 
 bound to send tribute.*® But all this is more or less mani- 
 festly clothed in the form of gift, for which the chief has to 
 bestow a return present even if this consist only in the 
 entertainment that he bestows upon the bearer. Even 
 with the market-fees, which are payable by the sellers to 
 the owner of the market-place, in the Congo district a 
 
 "Martius, p. 65. For a remarkable telephonic contrivance of the 
 Catuquinaru Indians, see .^rchiv f. Post u. Telegraphie (1899), pp. 
 87. 88. 
 
 "Parkinson, p. 127, comp. pp. ~2. 121; Finsch, p. 68. Likewise in 
 Africa: Schweinfurth, I, pp. 64, ago, 291. 
 
 " Described in ^r^'ater detail by M. Buchner, Kaincrun. pp. 37, 38; 
 Wissmann, Im Inncrn Afrikas, pp. 4, 228, 232; Betz in Mitthcil. aus d. 
 dcutsch Schutcgcbkti-it. XI (1898), pp. 1-86; Wissmann. I'ntcr dculsch. 
 rioRge, P- 215; Stanley, Through the Dark Continent. II, pp. 264, 279; 
 Livingstone, p. 93. For a .signal-whistlinj? languaRC in Timor, sec 
 Jacobsen, Reise in d. Inschcelt d. Buitda-Meers. p. 262. 
 
 "Comp., for example. Petermanns Mittheil.. XXI (1875). p. 381. 
 
 "Details in Post, Afr. Jurisprudens, I, pp. 261 flE. 
 
II 
 
 80 
 
 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITiyE PEOPLE. 
 
 return service is rendered in that the chief performs a 
 dance in front, and to the deHght, of those using the mar- 
 ket. Of special interest to us are the presents that trav- 
 ellers en route have to pay to the village chiefs whose 
 territories they traverse, since from such payments our 
 customs duty has sprung. Not less important is it to notice 
 that in the larger kingdoms the tribute of the subject 
 tribes consists of those products which are peculiar to 
 each tribe, and which are usually marketed by it. In the 
 Lunda country, for instance, some districts bring ivory or 
 skins, others salt or copper; from the northern parts come 
 plaited goods of straw, and from the subordinate chiefs 
 nearer the coast at times even powder and European cot- 
 ton stuffs.*^ Not infrequently has this led such sovereign 
 chiefs to carry on a trade in these products, which accumu- 
 late in large quantities in their hands, or to claim a monop- 
 oly in them. The saying that makes the kings the greatest 
 merchants thus gains a deeper significance. 
 
 In general the financial prerogatives of the chiefs are 
 limited only by their natural strength; and the wealth of 
 the subject is without the protection that the civilized 
 State assures to it by law. The expeditions sent out by 
 the negro kings to collect the tribute and taxes degen- 
 erate only too often into robber raids. The claim of the 
 kings to fines frequently reduces the administration of 
 justice to an institution for extortion, and the system of 
 gifts, which prevails in all relationships of a public char- 
 acter, too rapidly passes into a veritable system of bribery. 
 
 This must naturally react injuriously upon private in- 
 dustry. In the condition of constant feud in which the 
 smaller tribes live with their neighbours under the arbi- 
 
 " Pogge, pp. 226, 227. Comp. Wissmann, Im Inncrn Afrikas, pp. 
 171, 172, 202, 249, 267, 286, 289, .^08; Vnter deutsch. Flagge, pp. 95. 332, 339. 
 The same is true of the Marutse country north of the Zambesi: E. 
 Holub. Sieben Jakrc in Siidafrika. II. u-p. 173. 187. 253. 254, 257. 268. 271. 
 
 II > 
 
THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 
 
 8i 
 
 trary rule which in the interior usually accompanies the 
 formation of larger states, most primitive peoples stand in 
 peril of life and property. Through long habit this danger 
 becomes endurable, yet economic advancement must as- 
 suredly be retarded by it. The obligation to make pres- 
 ents ever and everywhere, the custom of regarding food 
 almost as free goods, leave but insufficient room for self- 
 interest. An English writer makes the remark — from the 
 standpoint of European life certainly not inaccurate — that 
 this sharing-up, rendered necessary by custom, encourages 
 the people in gluttony, since only that is safe which they 
 have succeeded in stuffing into their bellies; it also pre- 
 vents rational provision for the future, because it is diffi- 
 cult to keep on hand supplies of any kind.^^ Assuredly 
 with some reason have the begging proclivities and the 
 " tendency to steal," which is said to animate many prim- 
 itive peoples in dealing with Europeans, been associated 
 with the custom of gifts and the insufficient distinction of 
 " mine and thine." *® The immoderate use of alcoholic 
 drinks is likewise a consequence of their slight forethought 
 for their own welfare. If, however, the attempt is made to 
 appreciate all these things apart from the conditions of cul- 
 ture in which they arise, one readily recognises that they 
 lie " beyond the bounds of good and evil," and that what 
 appears from the standpoint of the modern Englishman 
 as vice has concealed within it the beautiful virtues of dis- 
 interestedness, benevolence, and generosity. 
 
 For many who to-day pose as the bearers of civilization 
 to their black and brown fellow men primitive man is the 
 quintessence of all economic vices: lazy, disorderly, care- 
 less, prodigal, untrustworthy, avaricious, thievish, heart- 
 
 "Tindall, in Fritsch, p. 351; comp. p. 362. Waitz, II, p. 402; III, 
 p. 80. 
 "Comp. Waitz, III, pp. 163 flf. 
 
8a 
 
 THE ECONOMIC LIFE OF PRIMITIVE PEOPLE. 
 
 
 >1 
 
 J' 
 'f 
 
 I .'"'4 
 1 
 
 ■ ;']• 
 
 ii 
 
 I — : 
 
 less, and self-indulgent. It is true that primitive man lives 
 only for the present, that he shuns all regular work, that 
 he has not the conception of duty, nor of a vocation as a 
 moral function in life. But it is not less true that with his 
 wretched implements he accomplishes an amount of work 
 that must excite our admiration, whether we contemplate 
 with our own eyes the neat fruit-fields of the women or 
 view in our museums the weapons and implements of the 
 men, the products of infinite toil. Above all, his manner 
 of working assures to primitive man a measure of enjoy- 
 ment in life and a perpetual cheerfulness which the Euro- 
 pean, worried with work and oppressed with care, must 
 envy him. 
 
 If since their acquaintance with European civilization 
 so many primitive peoples have retrograded and some 
 even become extinct, the cause lies, according to the 
 view of those best acquainted with the matter, chiefly in 
 the disturbing influence which our industrial methods and 
 technique have exerted upon them. We carried into their 
 childlike existence the nervous unrest of our commercial 
 life, the hurried hunt for gain, our destructive pleasures, 
 our religious wrangles and animosities. Our perfected im- 
 plements relieved them suddenly of an immense burden of 
 labour. What they had accomplished with their stone 
 hatchets in months they performed with the iron one in a 
 few hours; and a few muskets replaced in effectiveness 
 hundreds of bows and arrows. Therewith fell away the 
 beneficent tension in which the old method of work had 
 continuously kept the body and mind of primitive man, 
 particularly as the character of his needs remained at the 
 same low level. Under these conditions has he gone to 
 ruin, just as the plant that thrives in iu-. shade withers 
 away when exposed to the glare of the noon-day sun. 
 
CHAPTER III. 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 Everyone knows that the modern man's way of satisfy- 
 ing his numerous wants is subject to continual change. 
 Many arrangements and contrivances that we find neces- 
 sary were unknown to our grandparents; and our g^rand- 
 children will find inadequate much that perhaps only a 
 short time ago aroused our admiration. 
 
 All those arrangements, contrivances, and processes 
 called forth to satisfy a people's wants constitute national 
 economy. National economy falls again into numerous 
 individual economies united together by trade and depend- 
 ent upon one another in many ways; for each undertakes 
 certain duties for all the others, and leaves certain duties 
 to each of them. 
 
 As the outcome of auch a development, national econ- 
 omy is a product of all past civilization; it is just as subject 
 to change as every separate economy, whether private or 
 public, and whether directly ministering to the wants of a 
 larger or a smaller number of people. Furthermore, every 
 phenomenon of national economy is aj)henomenon in the 
 gygJ^Jj^lP" of. civilization. In scientifically defining it and 
 in explaining the laws of its development we must always 
 bear in mind that its essential features and its dynamic 
 laws are not absolute in character; or, in other words, that 
 they do not hold good for all periods and states of civ- 
 ilization. 
 
 8s 
 
I* 
 
 
 m 
 
 
 84 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 The first task, then, which national economy presents 
 to science is to determine and explain the facts. But it 
 must not be content with a merely dynamic treatment of 
 economic processes; it must also seek to deduce their 
 origin. A full understanding of any given group of facts 
 in the history of a civilized people requires that we know 
 how the facts arose. We shall, therefore, not escape the 
 task of investigating the phases of development through 
 which the economic activity of civilized peoples passed be- 
 fore it assumed the form of the national economy of to- 
 day, and the modifications undergone by each separate 
 economic phenomenon during the process. The material 
 for this second part of the task can be drawn only from the 
 economic history of the civilized peoples of Europe; for 
 these alone present a line of development which historical 
 investigation has adequately disclosed, and which has not 
 been deflected in its course by violent disturbances from 
 without ; though, to be sure, this upward development has 
 not always been without interruption or recoil. 
 
 The first question for the political economist who seeks 
 to understand the economic life of a people at a time long 
 since past is this: Is this economy national economy; and 
 are its phenomena substantially similar to those of our 
 modern commercial world, or are the two essentially dif- 
 ferent? An answer to this question can be had only if we 
 do not disdain investigating the economic phenomena of 
 the past by the same methods of analysis and deduction 
 from intellectually isolated cases which have given such 
 splendid results to the masters of the old " abstract " po- 
 litical economy when applied to the economic life of tne 
 present. 
 
 The Modern " historical " school can hardly escape the 
 reproach that, instead of penetrating into the life of earlier 
 economic periods by investigations of this character, they 
 
THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 85 
 
 have almost unwittingly applied to past times the current 
 classifications of modern national economy; or that they 
 have kneaded away so long at conceptions of commercial 
 life that these perforce appear applicable to all economic 
 periods. In so doing they have without doubt greatly ob- 
 structed the path to a scientific mastery of those historical 
 phenomena. The material for economic history, which 
 has been brought to light in such gteat quantities, has for 
 this reason largely remamed an unprofitable treasure still 
 awaiting scientific utilization. 
 
 Nowhere is this more plainly evident than in the manner 
 in which they characterize the differences between the 
 present economic methods of civilized nations and the eco- 
 nomic life of past epochs, or of peoples low in the scale of 
 civilization. This they do by setting up so-called stages^ 
 of development, with generic designations made to embrace 
 the whole course of economic evolution. 
 
 The institution of such " economic stages " is from the 
 point of method indispensable. It is indeed only in this 
 way that economic theory can turn to account the 
 results of the investigations of economic history. But 
 these stages of development are not to be confoimded 
 with the time-periods of the historian. The stfrin- 
 must not forget to relate in any period everytlv 
 that occurred in it. while for his stages the theon i 
 need notice only the normal, simply ignoring the 
 cidental. In treating of the gradual transformation, f 
 quently extending over centuries, which all economic } 
 nomena and institutions undergo, his only object can 
 to comprehend the whole development in its chief pliase^. 
 while the so-called transition-periods, in which all phenom- 
 ena are in a state of flux, must, for the time, be dis- 
 regarded. By this means alone is it possible to discover 
 
I* 
 
 86 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 the fundamental features, or, let us say it boldly, the laws 
 of development. 
 
 All early attempts of this class suffer from the defect of 
 not reaching the essentials, and touching only the surface. 
 The best known series of stages is that originated by 
 Frederick List, based upon the chief direction taken by 
 production. It distinguishes five successive periods which 
 the peoples of the temperate zone are supposed to have 
 passed through before they attained their present economic 
 condition, namely: (i) the period of nomadic life; (2) the 
 period of pastoral life; (3) the period of agriculture; (4) 
 the period of combined agriculture and manufacture; and 
 (S) the period of agriculture, manufacture, and commerce. 
 Another series evolved by Bntno Hi'Jcbrand, which 
 makes the condition of exchange the distinguishing char- 
 acteristic, comes somewhat closer to the root of the mat- 
 ter. It assumes three stages of development: period of 
 barter; period of monev; and period of credit. 
 
 Both, however, take lor granted that as far back as his- 
 tory reaches, with the sole exception of the '" primitive 
 state," there has existed a national economy based upon 
 exchange of goods, though at different periods the forms 
 of production and exchange have varied. They have no 
 doubt whatever that the fundamental features of economic 
 life have always been essentially similar. Theit sole aim 
 is to show that the various public regulations of trade in 
 former times found their justitication in the changing char- 
 acter of production or exchange, and thai likewise in the 
 present different conditions demand different regulations. 
 The most recent coherent presentations of economic 
 theory that have proceeded from the members of the his- 
 torical school remain content with this conception, al- 
 though in reality it stands upon a scarcely higher plane 
 
THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 ^1 
 
 than the favourite historical creations of abstract English 
 economics.' This we will endeavour briefly to prove. 
 
 The condition of society uf>on which Adam Smith and 
 Ricardo founded the earlier theory is that of a commercial 
 Organization Jbased upon division of labour; or let us 
 TatTier say simply, of national economy in the real sense of 
 the term. It is that condition in which each individual 
 does not produce the goods that he needs, but those which 
 in his opinion others need, in order to obtain by way of 
 trade the manifold things that he himself requires; or, in 
 a word, the condition in which the cooperation of many 
 or of all is necessary in order to provide for the individual. 
 English political economy is thus in its essence a theory of 
 exchange. The phenomena and laws of the division of 
 labour, of capital, of price, of wages, of rent, and of profits 
 on capital, form its chief field of investigation. The whole 
 theory of production and especially of consumption re- 
 ceives verj- inadequate treatment. All attention is centred 
 upon the circulation of goods, in which term their distri- 
 bution is included. 
 
 That there may one* have existed a condition of society 
 in which exchange was unknown does not occur to them; 
 where their system makes such a view necessary they have 
 recourse to the Robinson Crusoe fiction so much ridiculed 
 by later WTiters. Usually, however, they deduce the most 
 involved processes of exchange directly from the primitive 
 state.^ Adam Smith supposes that man is born with a 
 
 ' [Regarding the omission from special mention of Schmoller's ter- 
 ritorial series: village, town, territory, and State, we may refer to 
 Professor Schmoller's review of the first German edition and Profes- 
 sor Bticher's reply in Jhb. f. Gesetzpeb.. etc.. XVII and XVIII (1893- 
 94). See also Schmoller, Grundris: d. I'Ms'iVirtscluiftslehrc, I (Leipzig, 
 igoo"). — Ed.] 
 
 'The same is true also of the Physiocrats. Comp. Turgot. Reflexions, 
 J§2ff. 
 
88 
 
 THE RISE OF NATlON/tL ECONOMY. 
 
 in 
 
 natural instinct for trade, and considers the division of 
 labour itself as but a result of it.^ Ricardo in several places 
 treats the hunter and the fisher of primitive times as if they 
 were two capitalistic entrepreneurs. He represents them 
 as paying wages and making profits; he discusses the rise 
 and fall of the cost, and the price, of their products. Tliii- 
 nen, to mention also a prominent German of this school, in 
 constructing his isolated State starts with the assumption 
 of a commercial organization. Even the most distant 
 region, which has not yet reached the agricultural stage, 
 prosecutes its labours with the single end of selling its 
 products in the metropolir, city. 
 
 How widely such theoretical constructions vary from 
 the actual economic conditions of primitive peoples must 
 long ago have been patent in historical and ethnographical 
 investigators had not the\ themselves been in the grasp 
 of modern commercial ideas which they transferred to the 
 past. A thorough-going study, which will sufficiently em- 
 brace the conditions of life in the past, and not measure its 
 phenomena by the standards of the present, must lead to 
 this conclusion: National economy is the product of a dei'cl- 
 opmcnt extending over thousands of years, and is not older 
 thai! the modern State; for long epochs before it emerged man 
 lived and laboured icithout any system of trade or under forms 
 of exchange of products and services that cannot be designated 
 national economy. 
 
 If we are to gain a survey of this whole development, it 
 can only be from a standpoint that afYords a direct view 
 of the essential phenomena of national e-onomy, and at 
 the same time discloses the organizing c'ement of the 
 earlier economic i)erifx!s. This standpoint is none other 
 than the relation which exists between the production and 
 
 •Book I. Chap. 3. 
 
THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 89 
 
 the consumption of goods; or, to be more exact, the length 
 of the route which the goods traverse in passing from pro- 
 ducer to consumer. From this point of view we are able 
 to divide the whole course of economic development, at 
 least for the peoples of central and western Europe, where 
 it may be historically traced with sufficient accuracy, into 
 three stages: 
 
 (i; The stage of independent domestic economy (produc- 
 tion solely for one's own needs, absence of exchange), at 
 which the goods are consumed where they are produced. 
 
 (2) The stage of totvn economy (custom production, the 
 stage of direct exchange), at which the goods pass directly 
 from the producer to the consumer. 
 
 (3) The stage of national economy (wholesale production, 
 the stage of the circulation of goods), at which the goods 
 must ordinarily pass through many hands before they 
 reach the consumer. 
 
 We will endeavour to define these three economic stages 
 more precisely by seeking a true conception of the typical 
 features of each without allowing ourselves to be misled 
 by the casual appearance of transitional forms or particu- 
 lar phenomena which, as relics of earlier or precursors of 
 later conditions, project into any period, and whose exist- 
 ence may perhaps be historically proved. In this way 
 alone shall wc be able to understaiul clearly the funda- 
 mental distinctions between the throe periods and the phe- 
 nomena peculiar to each. 
 
 The stage of independent domestic economy, as has already 
 been pointed out, is characterized by restriction of the 
 whole course of economic activity from production to con- 
 sumption to the exclusive circle of the household (the 
 family, the clan). The character and extent of the produc- 
 tion of every household arc prescribed by the wants of its 
 members as consumers. Every product passes through 
 
9° 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 the whole process of its manufacture, from the procur- 
 ing of the raw material to its final elaboration in the same 
 domestic establishment, and reaches the consumer with- 
 out any intermediary. Production and consumption are 
 here inseparably interdependent: they form a single 
 uninterrupted and indistinguishable process; and it is as 
 impossible to differentiate them as to separate acquisitive 
 and domestic activity from each other. The earnings of 
 each communal group are one with the product of their 
 labour, and this, again, one with the goods going to sat- 
 isfy their wants, that is, with their consumption. 
 
 Exchange was originally entirely unknown. Primitive 
 man, far from possessing a natural instinct for trading, 
 shows on the contrar)- an aversion to it. Exchange 
 (tauschcn) and deceive (taiisclien) are in the older tongue 
 one and the same word.* Thero is no universally recog- 
 nised measure of value. Hence everyone must fear being 
 duped in the bartering. Moreover, the product of labour 
 is. as it were, a part of the person producing it. The man 
 who transfers it to another alienates a part of his being 
 and subjects himself to the evil powers. Far down into 
 the Middle Ages exchange is protected by publicity, com- 
 pletion before witnesses, and the use of symbolic forms. 
 
 An autonomous economy of this kind is in the first place 
 dependent upon the land under it^ control. Whether the 
 chief as hunter or fisher appropriates the gifts voluntarilv 
 offered by nature, whether he wanders as a nomad with his 
 herds, whether he cultivates the soil as well, or even sup- 
 ports himself by agriculture alone, his daily labour and 
 care will be shaped in every case by the bit of land that he 
 has brought under cultivation. The greater his advance 
 
 * tCotnp also the e.irly signification of our words barter, truck, etc. 
 New Oxford Diet.— Ed.] 
 
THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 91 
 
 in intelligence and technical skill, and the more method- 
 ical and varied the satisfaction of his wants, so much the 
 greater does this dependence become, until finally the soil 
 brings into subjection the man who is bom to rule over it. 
 This has been designated villenagc* We may here confine 
 ourselves to proving that a' this stage the man who has 
 direct possession of the soil can alone maintain economic 
 independence. He who is not in this position can eke out 
 his existence only by becoming the servant of the land- 
 owner, and, as such, bound to the soil. 
 
 In the independent domestic economy the members of 
 the household have not merely to gather from the soil its 
 products, but they must also by iheir labour produce all the 
 necessary tools and implements, and, finally, work up and 
 transform the new products and make them fit for use. All 
 this leads to a diversity of employments, and, because of 
 the primitive nature of the tools, demands a varied dex- 
 terity and intelligence of which modern civilized man can 
 scarcely form a proper conception.' The extent of the tasks 
 
 * Verdinglichung. 
 
 'We must turn to descriptions of early peasant life in remote parts 
 of Europe in order to gain a conception of such conditions. Comp. 
 one example in H. F. Tiebe, Lief- u. Esthlands Ehrenrettung (Halle, 
 1804), p. icx>. Similar instances are met with still among the Coreans. 
 Thus we read in M. A. Pogio, Korea (Vienna and Leipzig, 1895), p. 
 222: "Throughout Corea the real necessaries of life have been pro- 
 duced within the household from time immemorial. Tlie wife and 
 daughters spin not only hemp but silk. For the latter a silk-bee is 
 usual in many houses. The head of the family must be ready for all 
 tasks, and on occasion play the painter, stone-mason, or joiner. The 
 production of spirits, vegetable fats, and colours, and the manufacture 
 ot straw mats, hats, baskets, wooden shoes, and field iniplcmonts be- 
 longs to domestic work. In a word, every one labours for himself and 
 his own reiiuircments. Tli<inks to these conditions the Corean is .1 
 Jack of all trades who rndcrtakcs work only for the things that are In- 
 dispens.-ible. and accordingly never becomes skilled in any special de- 
 partment. 
 
93 
 
 THE RISE OF N/1TIONj4L ECONOMY. 
 
 falling to the various members of this autonomous house- 
 hold community can be lessened only by division of labour 
 and cooperation among themselves according to age and 
 sex, or accori t. • to the strength and natural aptitudes of 
 the individual, it is to this circumstance that we must 
 ascribe that sharp division of domestic production accord- 
 ing to sex, which we find universal among primitive peo- 
 ples. On the other hand, owing to the unproductiveness 
 of early methods of work the simultaneous cooperation of 
 many individuals was in numerous instances necessary to 
 the accomplishment of certain economic ends. Labour in 
 common still plays, therefore, at this stage, a more im- 
 portant role than division of labour. 
 
 To neither, however, would the family have been able 
 to give much scope had it been organized like our modern 
 family, that is. limited to father and mother with children 
 and possibly servant?. It wouKl also have had very little 
 stability or capacity tor development if each individual in 
 the family had been free to lead the independent existence 
 of the present day. 
 
 Signifioaiu is it then that when the present civilized na- 
 tions of Europe appear on the horizon of history, the 
 tribal constitution prevails among them.* The tribes 
 (families, genres, clans, hous'.^ communities) arc moder- 
 ately large groups consisiins;: of several generations of 
 blood-relations, which, at t'lrst organized according to ma- 
 ternal and later according to paternal succession, have 
 common ownership of the soil, maintain a oommdu house- 
 hold, and constitute a union for nnuual protection. Evtrv 
 tribe is thus compnse<l of several smaller groups of rela- 
 
 Conip, on tin- p.vint Fu-tel dc CouI.Tniio?. / i 
 
 i l\\rx<. 
 
 L.-v< 
 
 /.I Prcfrii-ti- (4tli edition. rar:>. i8<)0: 
 
 lS<'>4l: Hniilc ^h 
 
 K. Grox-e. PiV ■■ r„-,-K ,i /,;ii;:7;i- u. d. [\'rmt-n d H'lrths.h^ift ( Leip.'is. 
 
 iS'JO). e^T.cia'.v C\\?.n V!!I. 
 
THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 93 
 
 tives, each of which is formed of a man and wife with their 
 children. Anyone living outside this tribe is an out- 
 law; he has no legal or economic existence, no help in time 
 of need, no avenger if he is slain, no funeral escort when 
 he passes to his last rest.^ 
 
 All the peoples in question, when they took up fixed 
 abodes, were acquainted with the use of the plough. Their 
 settlement came about usually by the establishment of 
 large common dwelling-houses, farms, and villages by the 
 n-.embers of a tribe. Once in secure possession of the land 
 the sense of community soon weakened. Smaller patri- 
 archal households with a limited number of members, such 
 as are represented at the present day by the zadrngas of 
 the south Slavs, and by the great family of the Russians, 
 Caucasians, and Hindoos, separated from the larger unit. 
 But for centuries the village house-communities continued 
 to own the soil in common, and jointly tilled it probably 
 for some time longer, while each household enjoyed the 
 products apart. 
 
 In large family groups of this kind, community and divi- 
 sion of bbour may be carried out to a considerable extent. 
 Men and women, mothers and children, fathers and grand- 
 fathers — to each group is allotted its particular part in pro- 
 duction and domestic work, and wherever special individ- 
 ual skill displays itself, it finds scope and also a limit, in 
 
 •C(imp. M. Buclinor. Kamerun. p. i88: "It i? a fund.imental point 
 in the lejjal ontici'ptions of the noiirdes. that not tlic man him>ch' but 
 the community, '.ho f.imily. the whole body of relative* is tlie int' id- 
 tnl before the law. Within the community riKht? and duties are 
 tran-fer:;Me to an a!mo~t '.m'iniiied extent. .\ debtor, a criminal, can 
 be pimi-hed in tlie member- of liis community, and the liabihty of 
 the corTuinitv f -■" 'be crime of one born a member of it does not 
 lapse even with emigration or -epar.itim from it. Even the death- 
 penalty can W executed upon • .ne other than the guilty." The same 
 thing is found am.^ng t!ie South Sea Islanders. Sec Fat.i'nson. Im 
 Bisniarik-.-itihipii. p^i. 50-i. 
 
f 1 
 
 94 
 
 THE RISE OF NATlONy4L ECONOMY. 
 
 working for its own tribe. The feelings of brotherhood, 
 of filial obedience, of respect for zgt, of loyalty and defer- 
 ence reach their most beautiful development in such a 
 community. Just as the tribe pays a debt or weregild for 
 the individual or avenges a wrong done him, so on the 
 other hand does the individual devote his whole life to the 
 tribe and on its behalf subdue every impulse to independ- 
 ent action. 
 
 And even when the strength of these feelings declines, 
 the modern separate family with its independent organiza- 
 tion does not immediately spring into existence. For its 
 appearance would inevitably have resulted in a diminished 
 capacity for work, an abandonment of the autonomous life 
 of the household, and perhaps a relapse into barbarism. 
 Two ways there were of avoiding this. 
 
 One was as follows: for such tasks as surpassed the pow- 
 ers of the now diminished family, the original large tribal 
 unions were continued as local organizations. These 
 formed partial communities on the basis of common prop- 
 erty and common usufruct of the same; but. when occa- 
 sion demanded, they could also undertake duties which, if 
 left to the care of each individual household, would have 
 demanded an unpi ..".table expenditure of energy, as, for 
 example, guarding the fields and tending cattle. There 
 were also tasks which, though not of equal concern to 
 each separate household of the local group, were never- 
 theless too difficult for the individual. A house or a ship 
 was to be built, a forest clearing made, a stream diverted, 
 hunting or fishing engaged in at a distance; or perhaps 
 the season of the year made some unusual work neces- 
 sar>' for this or that house. In all such cases hidden- 
 labour assisted; *» that is, among neighbours there sprang 
 
 • Comp. Arbeit u. Rkylhmus (2d ed). pp. 198 ff. [and Ch. VII. be- 
 low. — Ed.] 
 
THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 95 
 
 Up, on invitation of the head of the family, temporary labour 
 communities which disappeared again on the completion of 
 their work. Many institutions of this kind underwent subse- 
 quent transformation, others perpetuated themselves. We 
 would recall the labour communities of the Slavic tribes, 
 the artel of the Russians, the tschcta or driisina of the Bul- 
 garians, the moba of the Serbs, the voluntary assistance 
 rendered by our peasants to each other in house-raising, 
 sheep-shearing, flax-pulling, etc. 
 
 Whatever the extent of such contrivances, the part they 
 can play in the supplying of needs is comparatively un- 
 important, and just as little prejudices the economic auton- 
 omy of the individual household as the home production 
 subsisting among our agrarian landlords to-day affects the 
 supremacy of commerce. These temporary labour com- 
 munities, moreover, are not business enterprises, but only 
 expedients for satisfying immediate want^. Assistance is 
 rendered now to one. now to another of the participants; 
 or the product of the joint labour is distributed to the sep- 
 arate families for their consumption. A definite case of 
 bargain and sale will be sought for in vain, even where, as 
 in the village community of India, we have a number of 
 professional labourers performing communal functions 
 similar to those of our village shepherds. They work for 
 all and are in return maintained by all. 
 
 The second method of avoiding the disadvantages aris- 
 ing from the dissolution of the tribal communities con- 
 sisted in the artificial extension, or numerical maintenance 
 of the family circle. This was done by the adoption and 
 incorporation of foreign (non-consangi inous) elements. 
 Tims arose slavery and serfdom. 
 
 We may leave undecided the question whether the en- 
 slavemciu and setting to work of a captured enemy were 
 more the cause or the result of the dissolution of the early 
 
11 j 
 
 96 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 tribal community. It is certain that a means was thereby 
 found of maintaining intact the independent household 
 economy with its accustomed division of labour, and at the 
 same time of making progress towards an increase in the 
 number and variety of wants. For now the more numer- 
 ous the slaves or villeins belonging to the household, the 
 more completely could its labour be united or divided. In 
 agriculture larger areas could be cultivated. Particular 
 technical employments, such as grinding com, baking, 
 spinning, weaving, making implements, or tending csttle, 
 could be assigned to particular slaves for their whole life; 
 they could be specially trained for this service. The 
 more prominent the family, the more wealthy the lord, or 
 the more extensive his husbandry, all the more possible 
 was it to develop in variety and extent the technical skill 
 employed in the procuring and working up of materials. 
 The economic life of the Greeks, the Carthaginians, and 
 the Romans was of this character.'' Rodbcrtus, who noticed 
 
 ' For students of political economy it need scarcely be observed 
 that in what follows the object is not to furnish a compendium of the 
 economic history of ancient times, but, as the context shows, merely 
 an outline of the most highly developed domestic economy as it 
 presents itself in the system of slave labour among the ancients. In 
 my work on the insurrections of the unfree labourers between 143 and 
 129 B.C. (Die Aufstdnde d. unfreien Arbeiter, 143-129 v. Chr„ Fr.-a.-M., 
 1874). I have shown that before the rise of slave-work on a large 
 scale the economic life of antiquity furnished considerable scope for 
 free labour, the formation of separate trades, and the exchange of 
 goods. What progress had been made in the development of an in- 
 dependent industry, I have set forth in the article " Industry " 
 iGnverbe) in the Handwi'.rterbuch der Staatsw., Ill, pp. 926-7, 929- 
 931; and in my articles on the Edict of Diocletian on tax prices 
 (Ztschr. f. d. gcs. Staatsw.. 1894, pp. 200-1) I have endeavoured to fix 
 the position filled by trade in the system of independent domestic 
 ecoromy at the time of the empire in Rome. Reference may also be 
 mace, for an outline picture of the times, to the interesting address 
 of M. Weber on Die sosialen Griinde d. Unter gangs d. antiken Cultur, Die 
 Wahrhcit, VI, No. 3. 
 
 !.r. 
 
THE RISE OF N/tTlONylL ECONOMY. 
 
 97 
 
 this a generation ago, designates it oikos husbandry, be- 
 cause the oiWos, the house, represents the unit of the ero- 
 nomic system. The oiKoi is not merely the dwelHng-place, 
 but also the body of people carrying on their husbandry in 
 common. Those belonging to them are the oiteirat, a 
 word which, in its historic usage, it is significant to note, 
 is confined to the household slaves upon whom the whole 
 burden of the work of the house at that time rested. A 
 similar meaning is attached to the Roman familia, the 
 whole body of famuli, house-slaves, servants. The pater- 
 familias is the slave-master into whose hands flows the 
 whole revenue of the estate; in the patria potcstas the two 
 conceptions of the power of the lord as husband and father 
 and as slave-owner have been blended. A member of the 
 household labours not for himself, but only for the pater- 
 familias, who wields the same power of life and death 
 over all. 
 
 In the supreme power of the Roman paterfamilias, ex- 
 tending as it did equally over all members of the house- 
 hold, whether blood-relatives or not, the independent do- 
 mestic economy was much more closely integrated and 
 rendered capable of much greater productivity than the 
 matriarchal or even the earlier patriarchal tribe, which 
 consisted solely of blood-relatives. The individual as a 
 separate entity has entirely disappeared; the State and the 
 law recognise only family communities, groups of per- 
 sons, and thus regulate the relations of family to family, 
 not of individual to individual. As to what happens within 
 the household they do not trouble themselves. 
 
 In the economic autonomy of the slave-owning family 
 lies the explanation of all the social and a great part of the 
 political history of Rome. There are no separate classes 
 of producers, as such, no farmers, no artisans. There 
 are only large and small proprietors, rich and poor. If the 
 
98 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 rich man wrests from the poor possession of the soil, he 
 makes him a proletarian. The landless freeman is 
 practically incapable of making a living. For there is no 
 business capital to provide wages for the purchase of 
 labour; there is no industry outside the exclusive circle 
 of the household. The artificers of the early records are 
 not freemen engaged in industry, but artisan slaves who 
 receive from the hands of the agricultural and pastoral 
 slaves the corn, wool, or wood which are to be transformed 
 into bread, clothing, or implements. " Do not imagine 
 that he buys anything," we read in Petronius of the rich 
 novus homo, " everything is produced at his own house." ■ 
 Hence that colossal development of latifundia, and, con- 
 centrated in the hands of individual proprietors, those end- 
 less companies of slaves amongst whom the subdivision of 
 labour was so multiplex that their productions and ser- 
 vices were capable of satisfying the most pampered taste. 
 The Dutchman, T. Popma, who in the seventeenth cen- 
 tury wrote an able book on the occupations of the Roman 
 slaves, enumerates one hundred and forty-six different 
 designations for the functions of these slave labourers of 
 
 *Sat. 38: "Nee est quod putes ilium quicquam emere; omnia domi 
 nascuntur." E. Meyer translates that, " everything is grown on his 
 own land"! Now the satirist specifies wool, way (?), pepper, sheep, 
 honey, mushrooms, mules, and cushions with covers of purple or scar- 
 let. Do all of these things grow from the soil? Compare also Petro- 
 nius, ch. 48, 52, and 53: "nam et comcedos emeram," etc. That this 
 is all greatly exaggerated it is unnecessary to remind anyone who has 
 really read Petronius. Ch. 50 speaks of the purchase of Corinthian 
 jars, ch. 70 of knives made of Noric iron bought in Rome; ch. 76 
 of the shops of Trimalchio, who himself gives as his motto the words 
 bene emo, bene vendo. But for a satirtist to venture such .in exaggera- 
 tion as Petronius in ch. 38 would have been impossible if Roman eco- 
 nomic life had been similar to that of to-d;iy. A modern satirist in 
 a similar case would have made his boaster give the values of his 
 hor^e^. v.ins'-s, cipar=, his stocks, etc. 
 
THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 99 
 
 the wealthy Roman households.' This number might to- 
 day be considerably increased from inscriptions. One 
 must go minutely into the details of this refined subdivi- 
 sion of labour in order to understand the extent and pro- 
 ductive power of those gigantic household establishments 
 that placed at the free disposal of the owner goods and 
 services such as to-day can be supplied only by the numer- 
 ous business establishments of a metropolitan city in con- 
 junction with the institutions of municipality and State. 
 At the same time this extensive property in human beings 
 afforded a means for the amassing of fortunes equalled 
 only by the gigantic possessions of modern millionaires. 
 
 The whole body of slaves in the house of a wealthy 
 Roman was divided into two main groups, the familia 
 rustica and the 'Mnilia urbana. The familia rustica en- 
 gages in the Wo 'f production. On every large country 
 estate there are a nanager and an assistant m-'nager with 
 a staff of overseers and taskmasters who in tu. e un- 
 
 der them a considerable company of field-labouiv and 
 vine-dressers, shepherds and teni'ers of cattle, kitchen and 
 house servants, women spinners, male and female weavers, 
 fullers, tailors, carpenters, joiners, smiths, workers in metal 
 and in the occupations connected with agriculture. On 
 the larger estates each group of labourers is again divided 
 into bands of ten each (decuricr) in charge of a leider or 
 driver (dccurio. moniior)}° 
 
 The familia urbatia is divided into the admi. ..strative 
 staff, and the staff for the service of master and mistress 
 within and without the house. First comes the superin- 
 tendent of the revenue with his treasurer, bookkeepers, 
 
 •Titi Popmse Phrysii de operis servorum liber. Editio novisstma. 
 Atnstelodami 1672. 
 
 '"Comp. the graphic account of work on a Roman estate during 
 the empire, by M, Weber, Die Wahrheit, VI, pp. 65, 66. 
 
lOO 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 supervisors of rents, buyers, etc. If the proprietor takes 
 over public leases or engages in the shipping trade, he 
 keeps for that purpose a special staff of slave officials and 
 labourers. Attached to the internal service of the house 
 are house-administrator, porters, attendants in rooms and 
 halls, guardians of the furniture, the plate, and the robes; 
 the commissariat is in charge of the steward, the cellar- 
 master, and the superintendent of supplies; the kitchen 
 swarms with a great company of cooks, stokers, bakers of 
 bread, cakes, and pastry; special table-setters, carvers, 
 tasters, and butlers serve at the table, while a company of 
 beautiful boys, dancing-girls, dwarfs and jesters amuse the 
 guests. To the personal service of the proprietor are as- 
 signed a master of ceremonies for introducing visitors, 
 various valets, bath attendants, anointers, rubbers, sur- 
 geons, physicians for almost every part of the body, 
 barbers, readers, private secretaries, etc. For service in 
 the household a savant or philosopher is kept, also archi- 
 tects, painters, sculptors, and musicians; in the library are 
 copyists, parchment-polishers, and bookbinders, who un- 
 der the direction of the librarian n:ake books in 'le private 
 manufactory of the house. Even slave letter-wti.^rs and 
 stenographers must not be wanting in a wealthy house.^" 
 When the master appears in public he is preceded by a 
 large body of slaves (antcambiiloiics), while others follow 
 him (fcdiscqiii); the nomcnclcitor tells him the name of those 
 whom he meets and who are to be greeted; special dis- 
 tribntorcs and tcsscrarii scatter bribes among the people 
 and " istruct them Iiow to vote. These are the camclots of 
 ancient Rome: and, what gives them special value, they 
 are the property of the distinguislied asjiirant employing 
 them. This system for exerting political influence is sup- 
 
 "■ Comi'. ch. 6. 
 
 it 
 
THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 loi 
 
 plemented by the institution of plays, chariot-races, fights 
 with wild beasts, and gladiatorial games, for which troops 
 of slaves are specially trained. If the lord goes to a prov- 
 ince as governor or sojourns on one of his country estates, 
 slave couriers and letter-carriers maintain daily communi- 
 cation with the capital. And how shall we begin to tell of 
 the slave retinue of the mistress, on which Bottiger has 
 written a whole book (Sabina), and of the endlessly spe- 
 ciaHzed service for the care and education of the children! 
 It was an incredible squandering of human energy that 
 here took place. Lastly, by means of this many-armed 
 organism of independent domestic economy, maintained 
 as it was by a colossal system of breeding and training, the 
 personal power of the slave-owner was increased a thou- 
 sandfold, and this circumstance did much to render it pos- 
 sible for a handful of aristocrats to gain control over half 
 the world." 
 
 The work of the State itself is not carried on otherwise. 
 Both in Athens and Rome all subordinate officials and ser- 
 vants are slaves. Slaves build the roads and aqueducts 
 whose construction fell to the State, work in quarries and 
 mines, and clean the sewers; slaves are the policemen, 
 executioners and gaolers, the criers in public assemblies, 
 the distributors of the public doles of corn, the attendants 
 
 " Naturally this highly developed slavp system is only to be found 
 among the most wealthy class; but with similar conditions it recurs 
 everywhere. Ellis, for example, says in his History of Madagascar, 
 I, p. 194: "When a family has numerous slaves, some attend to cat- 
 tle, others are employed in cultivating esculent roots, others collect 
 fuel; and of the females, some are cmnloycd in spinning, weaving 
 and making nets, washing and other ( mesti: occupations." Even 
 in the country of the Muata Yamwo, here, with the exception of 
 smiths, there appear to have been no special craftsmen, the ruler had 
 in his household his own musicians, fetich-doctors, smiths, hair- 
 dressers, and female cooks. Pogge, Im Rciche d. Muata Jamwo, i p. 
 331, 187. 
 
I02 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 n 
 
 of the colleges of priests in the temples and at sacrifices, 
 the State treasurers, secretaries, the messengers of the 
 magistrates; a retinue of public slaves accompanies every 
 provincial officer or general to the scene of his duties. 
 The means for their support came chiefly from the public 
 domains, the tributes of the provinces (in Athens, of the 
 allies), of which Cicero says that they are quasi prcedia 
 populi Romani; and finally, from contributions resembling 
 fees. 
 
 Similar fundamental features are presented by the eco- 
 nomic life of the Latin and Germanic peoples in the early 
 Middle Ages. Here, too, necessary economic progress 
 leads to a further development of the autonomous house- 
 hold economy, which found expression in those large hus- 
 bandries worked with serfs and villeins upon the exteujive 
 landed possessions of the kings, the nobility, and the 
 Church. In its details this manorial system has many points 
 in common with the agricultural system of the later 
 Roman Empire as developed by colonization. It has, also, 
 considerable similarity with the centralized plantation sys- 
 tem described above from the closing years of the Roman 
 Republic. Tins rise of husbandry on a large scale with its 
 subdivision of labour differs, however, in one important 
 particular from the Roman. In Rome large estates engulf 
 the small, and replace the arm of the peasant by that of 
 the slave, who is later on transformed into the colonist. 
 The economic advance involved in the extensive o/WoS 
 husbandry had to be purchased by the proletarizing of the 
 free peasant. In the manorial system of the Middle Ages 
 the free owner of a small estate becomes, it is true, a vassal. 
 But he is not ejected from possession; he preserves a cer- 
 tain personal and economic independence, and, at the same 
 time, shares in the fuller supply of goods which husbandry 
 
 '•■iSiyiH. "»«-^»*"OF'WW 
 
Ji 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 103 
 
 on a large scale provides under the system of independent 
 domestic economy. 
 
 How did this come about? 
 
 In ancient Italy the small cultivator was ruined through 
 his inability to support certain public burdens, especially 
 military service, and because the pressure of war and 
 famine drove him into the lamentable servitude of the 
 debtor. In the Germanic and Latin countries of the Mid- 
 dle Ages he placed his homestead for like reasons under 
 the control of the large landed proprietor from whom he 
 received protection and assistance in time of need. 
 
 We can best understand the mediaeval manor by pic- 
 turing to ourselves the economic life of a whole vil- 
 lage as a unit with the manor-house its central point.** 
 
 "Though there were numerous villages whose inhabitants owed 
 service to various proprietors, and many manors that included peas- 
 ant holdings from various villages, yet the case here supposed must 
 be regarded as the normal one. At the same time we must not for- 
 get that most of the original evidence relating to these matters that 
 we possess refers to the scattered possessions of the monasteries for 
 which the manors formed the focal points, while for the estates of the 
 great, and still more so for those of the smaller temporal proprietors 
 in ancient times, we have scarcely any matt rial at all. For these, 
 however, our supposed case is to be regarded as normal in so far as 
 the villages arose through a colony grouping itself about a single es- 
 tate. For the purposes of our sketch we may also leave out of view 
 the many distinctions in the legal position of those owing rent and 
 service dues, especially the distinction between those belonging to the 
 manor and those belonging to the ni.irk. The latter, by virtue of 
 the lord's supreme proprietorship over the common land, were also 
 included in the economic system of the ntanor. Finally, I do not fail 
 to appreciate the difference between the constitution of the villas of 
 Charles the Great and the later administrative organization of the 
 large landowners, though I am of the opinion that the latter has only 
 superficinl points of contact with the economic life of the individual 
 farm. For ;ill further details I must refer the reader to Maurer, 
 Ccsch. il. I roiihofc: Inaiua-Sternegg, Die AusbiUiung d. grosscn Grund- 
 hrrrnbaftcH i» Drutsihland; and Lamprecht, Dcutschfs IVtrtschaflskben 
 im Af A s'-prr-nlly !, pp. 719 ff- 
 
 
I04 
 
 THE RISE OF NMTION/tL ECONOMY. 
 
 'i 
 
 Under this systerrf the small landowner supervises in 
 person, the large landowner through an overseer. The 
 demesne land lying immediately about the manor-house 
 is cultivated by serfs permanently attached to it, who there 
 find food and lodging, and arc employed in agricultural 
 and industrial production, household duties, and the per- 
 sonal service of the lord, under a many-sided division of 
 labour. The demesne land is intermixed with the holdings 
 of a larger or smaller number of unfree peasants, each of 
 whom tills his hide of land independently while all share 
 with the lord the use of pasture, wooc' and water. At 
 the same time, however, every peasant-holding binds its 
 occupant to perform certain services and to furnish cer- 
 tain dues in natural products to the estate. These services 
 consist of labour reckoned at first according to require- 
 ment, later according to time, whether given in the fields 
 at seed-time or harvest, on the pasture-land, in the vine- 
 yard, garden or forest, or in the manorial workshops or 
 the women's building where the daughters of the serfs are 
 spinning, weaving, sewing, baking, brewing beer, etc. On 
 the days devoted to manorial service the unfree labourers 
 receive their meals at the manor-house just as do the 
 manor-folk themselves. They are further bound to keep 
 in repair the enclosures about the manor-house and its 
 fields, to keep watch over the house, and to undertake slie 
 carrying of messages ami the transport of goods. The 
 dues in kind to be paid to the estate are partly agricultural 
 products, such as grain of all kinds, wool, fla.x. honey, wax, 
 wine, cattle, hogs, fowl, or eggs; partly wood cut in the 
 forests of the mark and made rea<ly for use. such as fire- 
 wood, timber, vine-stakes, torch-wood, shingles, staves 
 and hoops; partly the products of industry, such as wool- 
 len and linen cloth, stocking^., shoes, bread, beer, casks, 
 plates, dishes, goblets, iron, pots rind knives. This pre- 
 
THE RISE OF N/ITION/IL ECONOMY. 
 
 los 
 
 supposes alike among the serfs and those bound by feudal 
 service a certain specialization of industry, that would oi 
 necessny hereditarily attacii to the hides of land in ques- 
 tion and prove advantageous not merely to the lord's e:- 
 tate, but also to the occupants of the hides in supplying 
 commodities. Intermediate between service and rent are 
 duties of various kinds, such as hauling manure from the 
 peasant's farm to the fields of the lord, keeping cattle over 
 •winter, providing entertainment for the guests of the 
 manor. Oa the other har the lord renders economic as- 
 sistance to the peasant i^y keeping breeding-stock, by 
 esta'olishing ferries, mills, and ovens for general use, by 
 securing protection from violence and injustice to all, and 
 by giving succour from his stores, in accordance with his 
 pledge, when crops failed or other need arose. 
 
 We hav. here a small economic organism quite suffi- 
 cient uni .self, which avoids the rigid concentration of 
 the Roman slave estates and employs slaves only to the 
 extent necessary for the private husbandry of the landlord 
 conceived in its strictest sense.' ^ For this reason it is able 
 to secure to the general body of manorial labourers sep- 
 arate agricultural establishments for their owr domestic 
 needs, and therewith a certain personal independence. 
 This is an instance of small partial private estates within 
 the economy of the independent household similar to that 
 which occurs, though of course on a much smaller scale, 
 within the aadruga of the South Slavs when conjugal 
 couples establish separate households.''^ When the man- 
 
 » According to La.nprecht, I. p. 78^. the field lahuur-scrvices of 
 the serfs were applied to the cultivation of tla- individual strclches of 
 manorial land aUundax) or b-aU^ [unplou«hed ^'.npsl >n the com- 
 mon land, while the manorial serfs were employed only for the cul- 
 tivation of the demesne, 
 
 " Comp. Laveleye, as above, p. -ifi^- 
 
i: 1, 
 
 kk :»■ 
 
 !? ; ••! 
 
 1 06 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 orial group coincides in membership with the people of a 
 mark, the members are in a certain sense, owing to the 
 regulations forbidding the alienation of land or mark 
 servitudes to non-residents, economically shut off from 
 their neighbours. Internal unity is realized by means of 
 separate weights and measures, which, however, serve not 
 for safeguarding trade, but for measuring the dues in kind 
 coming to the lord. 
 
 For we must always bear in mind that the economic 
 relation of the lord to those attached to his land, however 
 much it may be regarded from the general point of view 
 of mutual service, is entirely removed from the class of 
 economic relations that arise -.-om a system of exchange. 
 Here there are no prices, no wages for labour, no land or 
 house rent, no profits on capital, and accordingly neither 
 entrepreneurs nor wage-workers. We have in this case 
 peculiar economic processes and phenomena to which his- 
 torical political economy must not do violence, after such 
 frequent con plaints of harsh treatment in the past at the 
 hands of jurisprudence. 
 
 The surpluses of the manorial husbandry are the prop- 
 erty of the lord. They consist entirely of goods for 
 consumption which cannot be long stored up or turned 
 into capital. On the estates of the king they are devoted 
 as a rule to supplying the needs of the royal household, 
 and the king, travelling with his retinue from castle to 
 castle, claims them in person; while the large landed pro- 
 prietors among the religious corporations and the higher 
 nobility have them forwarded by a well-organized trans- 
 port of their villeins to their chief seats, where as a rule 
 they are likewise consumed. 
 
 Thus in this economic system we have many of the phe- 
 nom.na of commerce, such as weights and measures, the 
 carriage of persons, news, and goods. !io«te!r!es, nn;' the 
 
THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 107 
 
 transference of goods and services In all, however, there 
 is lacking the characteristic feature of economic exchange, 
 namely, the direct connection of each single service with 
 its reciprocal service, and the freedom of action on the 
 part of the individual units carrying on trade with one 
 another. 
 
 But it matters not to what extent independent house- 
 hold economy may be developed through the introduction 
 of slave or villein labour, it will never succeed even in its 
 highest development, to say nothing of its less perfect 
 forms, in adapting itself sufficiently to the needs of human 
 society for all time. Here we have continuously unfilled 
 gaps in supply, there surpluses which are not consumed on 
 the estates producing them, or fixed instruments of pro- 
 duction and skilled labour which cannot be fully utilized. 
 
 Out of this state of things arise fresh commercial phe- 
 nomena of a particular kind. The landlord, whose harvest 
 has failed, borrows corn and straw from his neighbour 
 until the next harvest, when he returns an equal quantity. 
 The man reduced to distress through fire or the loss of his 
 cattle is assisted by the others on the tacit understanding 
 that he will show the like favour in the like event. If any- 
 one has a particularly expert slave, he lends him to a 
 neighbour, just as he would a horse, a vessel, or a ladder; 
 in this case the slave is fed by the neighbour. The owner 
 of a wine-press, a malt-kiln, or an oven allovvs his poorer 
 fellow villager the temporary use of it, in retprn for which 
 the latter, on occasion, makes a rake, helps at sheep-shear- 
 ing, or runs some errand. It is a mutual rendering of 
 assistance; and no one will think of classifying such occur- 
 rences under the head of exchange.'** 
 
 " On the social duty of lending amonK primitive peoples, comp. 
 Kubary, Ethnogr. Btitrdge s. Kenntnis d. Karolmcn-Archiptls, p. i6ji. 
 
i' 1 
 
 io8 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 W I 
 
 3 I 
 ii '! 
 
 Finally, however, real exchange does appear. The transi- 
 tion-stage is formed of such processes as the following: 
 the owner of slaves lends his neighbour a slave weaver or 
 carpenter, and receives in return a quantity of wine or 
 wood of which his neighbour has a surplus. Or the slave 
 shoemaker or tailor, whose labour cannot be fully turned 
 to account, is settled upon a holding, on the condition 
 that he work each year a certain number of days at the 
 manor. At times when he has no labour dues to pay and 
 little to do on his own land, he gives his fellow villeins in 
 their peasant houses the benefit of his skill, receiving from 
 them his keep, and in addition a quantity of bread or bacon 
 for his family. Formerly he was merely the servant of the 
 manor; now he is successively the servant of all, but of 
 each only for a short time.*^ At an early stage barter in 
 kind, aiming at a mutual levelling of wants and surpluses, 
 is also met with, as corn for wine, a horse for grain, a piece 
 cf linen cloth for a quj.ntity of salt. This trading process 
 expands owing to the Hmited occurrence of many natural 
 products and to the localization of the production of goods 
 for which there is a large demand; and if the various 
 household establishments are small, and the adjoining dis- 
 tricts markedly dissimilar in natural endowments, it may 
 attain quite a development.' » Certain articles of this trade 
 become, as has often been described, general mediums of 
 exchange, such as skins, woollen goods, mats, cattle, arti- 
 
 "On the corresponding conditions in Greece and Rome. comp. my 
 accounts in the Handwort. d. Staatswiss. fjd ed.). IV, pp. ,^6g-7i. 
 
 "To this circumstance is to be ascribed the relatively hi^'hly de- 
 veloped weekly market trade of ancient Greece and of the negro 
 countries of l.i-day; in Oceania the small size of the islands and the 
 uneciual development among their inhabitants of both household work 
 and riculture even calls forth in places an active maritime trade. 
 Similarly is the oft-cited maritime commerce of the ancient Greeks to 
 be regarded. 
 
THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 109 
 
 i 
 
 cles of adornment, and finally the precious metals. Money 
 comes into existence, markets and peddling trade arise; 
 the beginnings of buying and selling on credit appear. 
 
 But all this affects only the surface of the independent 
 household economy; and, though the literature on the 
 early history of trade and of markets has hitherto been 
 far from familiarizing us with a proper estimate of these 
 things, yet it cannot be too strongly emphasized that 
 neither among the peoples of ancient times nor in the early 
 Middle Ages were the articles of daily use the subject of 
 regular exchange. Rare natural products, and locally manu- 
 factured goods of a high specific value form the few articles 
 of commerce. If these become objects of general demand, 
 as amber, metal implements, ceramic products, spices and 
 ointments in ancient times, or wine, salt, dried fish, and 
 woollen wares in the Middle Ages, then undertakings must 
 arise aiming at the production of a surplus of these articles. 
 This means that the other husbandries will produce be- 
 yond their own immediate requirements the trade equiva- 
 lents of those articles as do the northern peoples their 
 skins and vadhmdl, and the modern Africans their wares 
 of bark and cotton, their kola nuts and their bars of salt. 
 Where the population concentrates in town? there may 
 even come into being an active market trade in the neces- 
 saries of life, as is seen in classic antiquity, and in many 
 negro countries of to-day. In fact even the carrying on 
 of industry and trade as a vocation is to a certain extent 
 possible. 
 
 Still this does not affect the inner structure of economic 
 life. The labour of each separate household continues to 
 receive its im, .ilse and direction from the >vants of its own 
 members: it must itself pro('-ice what it can for the satis- 
 faction of these wants. Its only regulator is utility. " That 
 
no 
 
 THE RISE OF NATION/IL ECONOMY. 
 
 > I I 
 
 i i 
 I I 
 
 landlord is a worthless fellow," says the elder Pliny, " who 
 buys what his own husbandry can furnish him "; and this 
 principle held good for many centuries after. 
 
 One must not be led away from a proper conception of 
 this economic stage by the apparently extensive use of 
 money in early historic times. Money is not merely a me- 
 dium of exchange, it is also a measure of value, a medium 
 for making payments and for storing up wealth. Payments 
 must also constantly be made apart from trade, such as 
 fines, tribute-money, fees, taxes, indemnities, gifts of hon- 
 our or hospitality; and these are originally paid in products 
 of one's own estate, as grain, dried meat, cloth, salt, cattle, 
 and slaves, which pass directly into the household of the 
 recipient. Accordingly all earlier forms of money, and 
 for a long time the precious metals themselves, circulate 
 in a form in which they can be used by the particular 
 household either for the immediate satisfaction of its wants 
 or for the acquisition by trade of other articles of consump- 
 tion. Those of special stability of value are pre-eminently 
 serviceable in the formation of a treasure. This is es- 
 pecially true of the precious metals, which in time of pros- 
 perity assumed the form of rude articles of adornment, and 
 as quickly lost it in time of adversity. Finally, it is man- 
 ifest that the office of a measure of value can be performed 
 by metal money even when sales are actually made in terms 
 of other commodities, as is shown by the use in ancient 
 Egypt of uten, a piece of wound copper wire according to 
 which prices were fixed, while payment was made in the 
 greatest variety of needful articles.^" This is also shown 
 by numerous medi.Tval i ;cords in which, far beyond the 
 epoch here under review, prices are fixed partly in money 
 and partly in horses, dogs, wine, grain, etc., or the pur- 
 
 " Frman. Aegypten u. agypi. Leben in: Alierium, pp, 175, 6«7, 
 
THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 Ill 
 
 I 
 
 I 
 
 chaser is left at liberty to make a money payment " in what 
 he can " (in quo potiierit).^^ 
 
 Lamprecht, discussing economic life in France in the 
 eleventh century, affirms that purchases were made only 
 in cases of want;2» the same holds in the main for sales 
 as well. Exchange is an element foreign to independent 
 household economy, and its entrance was resisted as long 
 and as stubbornly as possible. Purchase always means 
 purchase with immediate payment, and it is attended with 
 solemn and cumbrous formalities. The earliest municipal 
 law of Rome prescribes that the purchase must take 
 place before five adult Roman citizens as witnesses. The 
 rough copper that measures the price is weighed out 
 to the seller by a trained weigh-master Qibripens), while the 
 purchaser makes a solemn declaration as he takes posses- 
 sion of the purchased article. Contrasting with this the 
 formal minuteness of early German trade laws, we are eas- 
 ily convinced that in the economic period which witnessed 
 the creation of this rigid legal formalism buying and sell- 
 ing, and the renting of land or house, could not be every- 
 day affairs. Exchange value accordingly exercised no 
 deep or decisive influence on the internal economy of the 
 separate household. The latter knev; only production for 
 its own requirements; or, when sncn production fell short, 
 the practice of making gifts with the expectation of re- 
 ceiving others in return, of borrowing needful articles and 
 
 " Under similar circumstances the same is true to-day. " Through- 
 out West, Central, and East Africa quite definite and often quite com- 
 plex standards for the exchange of goods have been formed, just as 
 among ourselves, but with this diflference. that coined money is gen- 
 erally wanting. This, however, by no means prevents the existence 
 of a system of intermediate values, though it be but as notions and 
 names."— Buchner, Kamerun. p. 93. 
 
 "Fransos. Wirtsckaftsleben, p. 132. Comp. further his Deutsches 
 Wirtschaftsleben im M. A., II, pp. 374 S- 
 
Ill 
 
 112 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 implements, and, if need be, of plundering. The develop- 
 ment of hospitality, the legitimizing of begging, the union 
 of nomadic life and early sea-trade with robbery, the ex- 
 traordinary prevalence of raids on field and cattle among 
 primitive agricultural peoples, are accordingly the usual 
 concomitants of the indep>endent household economy. 
 
 From what has been said it will be clear that under this 
 method of satisfying needs the fundamental economic phe- 
 nomena must be dissimilar to those of modern national 
 economy. Wants, labour, production, means of produ''- 
 tion, product, stores for use, value in use, consumption — 
 these few notions exhaust the circle of economic phenom- 
 ena in the regular course of things. As there is no social 
 division of labour, there are consequently no professional 
 classes, no industrial establishments, no capital in the sense 
 of a store of goods devoted to acquisitive purposes. Our 
 classification of capital into business and trade capital, loan 
 and consumption capital, is entirely excluded. If, conform- 
 ably to widely accepted usage, th< expression capital is 
 restricted to means of production, then it must in any case 
 be limited to tools and implements, the so-called fixed 
 capital. What modern theorists usually designate circu- 
 lating capital is in the independent household economy 
 merely a store of consumption goods in process of prep- 
 aration, unfinished or half-finisbed products. In the regu- 
 lar course of affairs, moreover, there are no sale-goods, no 
 price, no circulation of commodities, no distribution of 
 income, and. therefore, no labour wages, no earnings of 
 management, and no interest as particular varieties of in- 
 come.^^ Rent alone begins to differentiate itself from the 
 
 1 
 
 " For most of the conceptions here mentioned there are no ex- 
 pressions in Greek or Latin. They must be expressed by circumlo- 
 cutions or by viTv ccneral terms. This is true, in the first instance, 
 of the conception income itself. The Latin rcditus denotes the returns 
 from the land. Tacitus makes use of a similar liberty wher. (Ann., 
 
THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 "J 
 
 return from the soil, still appearing, however, only in com- 
 bination with other elements of income. 
 
 Perhaps, indeed, it is improper at this stage to speak of 
 income at all. What we call income is normally the fruit 
 of commerce; in independent domestic economy it is the 
 sum of the consumption goods produced, the gross return. 
 This return, however, is all the more inseparable from 
 general wealth the more the subjection of the husbandry 
 to the hazard of the elements compels the accumulation of 
 a store of goods. Income and wealth form indistinguish- 
 able parts of a whole, one part of which is ever moving 
 upward towards availability for use, another part down- 
 ward to consumption, while a third is stored up in chest 
 and box, in cellar or storehouse, as a kind of assurance 
 fund. 
 
 To the last belongs money. In so far as it is used in 
 trade it is for the recipient as a rule not a provisional but a 
 final equivalent. It plays its chief part not as an intermedi- 
 ary of exchange, but as a store of value and as a means of 
 measuring and transferring values. Loans from one eco- 
 nomic unit to another do indeed take place; but as a rule 
 they bear no interest, and are made only for purposes of 
 consumption. Productive credit is incompatible with this 
 economic system. Where money-lending on interest in- 
 trudes itself it appears unnatural, and, as we know from 
 Greek and Roman history, is ultimately ruinous to the 
 debtor. The canonical prohibition of usury thus had its 
 origin not in moral or theological inclination, but in eco- 
 nomic necessity. 
 
 IV, 6, 3) he designates the revenues of the state as fructus publici. 
 Compare with this the numerous and finely distiuKui^hed expressions 
 for the conception wealth. Mcrccs means not only waf^es. but also 
 land-rent, house-rent, interest, price. So also the Greek nurdot. 
 For the expressions vocation, occupation, undertaking, industry, 
 neither of the classic languages has corresponding itniis. 
 
114 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 I 
 
 r! I 
 
 Where a direct state tax arose, it was regularly a tax on 
 wealth, generally a species of land-tax. Such was the 
 Athenian ei(T<t>opd, the Roman tributum civium, and the 
 scot or the bede of the Middle Ages. Along with these 
 demand was made upon the wealth of the individual for 
 direct services to the State or community, such as the 
 furnishing ships, the institution of festivals an.d enter- 
 tainments (liturgies). The idea of taxing income, how- 
 ever natural and self-evident it may appear to us, would 
 have been simply inconceivable to our ancestors. 
 
 By a process extending over centuries this independent 
 household economy is transformed into the system of direct 
 exchange; in the place of production solely for domestic 
 use steps custom production. We have designated this 
 stage town economy, because it reached its typical develop- 
 ment in the towns of the Germanic and Latin countries 
 during the Middle Ages. Still it must not be forgotten 
 that even in ancient times beginnings of such a develop- 
 ment ?r- [t ceptibic-, ind that at a later date they also 
 appeared in the more advanced Slavic countries, albeit in 
 considerably divergent form. 
 
 The transition to this economic stage is seen at the 
 stage of domestic economy itself in the loss by the sep- 
 arate household, founded upon the cultivation of the soil, 
 of a part of its independence through inability longer to 
 satisfy all its needs with its own labour, and through the 
 necessity of permanent and regular reinforcement from 
 the products of other estates. Yet there do not spring up 
 at once establishments independent of the soil, whose 
 members would derive their income entirely from the 
 working up of industrial commodities for others, or the 
 professional performance of services, or the conducting 
 of exchange. On the contrary, each proprietor still seeks, 
 as far as possible, to gain his livelihood from the land; if 
 
THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 "S 
 
 t' 
 
 % 
 
 4 
 
 I 
 
 his wants go beyond this, he calls into requisition any 
 special manual skill he may possess, or any particular pro- 
 ductive advantage of his district, whether in field, forest, 
 or water, in order to produce a surplus of some particular 
 article. One will produce grain, another wine, a third salt, 
 a fourth fisli, a fifth iinen or some other product of domes- 
 tic industry. In this manner separate establishments come 
 into existence specially developed in some one direction, 
 and dependent upon a regular, reciprocal barter of their 
 surplus products. This exchange does not at first demand 
 an organized system of trade. But it does require more 
 flexible commercial methods than were offered by the 
 early laws. These are furnished by markets which still 
 arise, in the main, under the household system. 
 
 A market is the coming together of a large number of 
 buyers and sellers in a definite place and at a definite time. 
 Whether this occur in connection with religious feasts and 
 other popular gatherings, or whether it owes its origin to 
 the favourable commercial situation of a locality, it is al- 
 ways an opportunity for producer and consumer to meet 
 with their mutual trade requirements; and such in its gen- 
 eral features it has remained down to the present day. 
 Markets and fixed trade are mutually exclusive. Where 
 a merchant class exists, no markets are needed; where 
 there are markets, merchants are superfluous. Only in 
 cases where a country must imf>ort articles for which there 
 is a demand and which it does not itself produce can there 
 be developed at the early stage of household economy a 
 distinct though not very numerous class, uniting under 
 their control the purchase, transport, and sale of these 
 goods, and utilizing for this last purpose the trade oppor- 
 tunities presented by the markets. 
 
 What changes, t •=■ i, were wrought in this condition of 
 things by the medu^val town, and in what does the eco- 
 
in 
 
 Ml 
 
 no 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 nomic system which we have designated as exclusive town 
 economy consist? 
 
 The medi;c\al town is al)ove all things a biirg, that is. 
 a place fortified with nails and moats which serves as a ref- 
 uge and shelter for the inhabitants of the unprotected 
 places round about. Every lown thus presupposes the 
 existence of a defensive union which forms the ru^al sei- 
 tlements lying within a greater or narrower radius into a 
 sort of mihtary community with definite rights and duties. 
 It devolves upoi. all the places belonging to this commun- 
 ity to cooperate in maintaining imact the town fortifica- 
 tions bv furnishing workmen and horses, and in time of 
 war in 'defending them with their arms. In return they 
 have the right, whenever occasion arises, to shelter them- 
 selves their wives and children, their cattle and movables, 
 within its walls. This right is called the right of burgess, 
 and he who enjoys it is a burgher {hurgcnsis). 
 
 Oi-iginallv the permanent inhabitants of the town differ 
 in nowise, not even in their occupations, from those living 
 in the rural hamlets. Like the latter they follow farming 
 and cattle-raising; thcv use wood, water, and pasture in 
 common; their dwellings, as may =^ill be seen in the 
 structural arrangement of many old cities, are farmhouses 
 with barns and stables and large yards !)etween. But their 
 communal life is not exhausted in the regulation of com- 
 mon pasturage and other agricultural interests. They arc. 
 so to speak, a permanent garrison stationed in the burg, 
 and perform in rotation the daily watch-service on tower 
 and at gate. Whoever wishes to settle permanently in the 
 town must therefore not only be possessed of land, or a 
 house at least: he must also be provided rvilh weapons and 
 
 armour. 
 
 The s< -icl service and the extensive area of the 
 tovM. rcn. rcr cc^^ary by the law of burgess demanded 
 
THE RISE OF NATION /tL ECONOMY. 
 
 117 
 
 a great number of men; and soon ihc ,. vn limits no 
 longer srfticed for tlieir maintenance. Then it was that 
 the one-sided dcvclopnient of the household establish- 
 ments, already described, lent its intlnence. and the town 
 became the seat of the industries and of the markets as 
 well. In the latter the country peasant continued to dis- 
 pose of his surplus supplies, obtaining from the townsman 
 that which he himself could no longer provide and which 
 the latter now exclusively or almost exclusively produced, 
 namely, industrial products. 
 
 The burgess rights underwent a consetiucnt extension. 
 All who enjoyed them were exempt from market dues and 
 town tolls. The right of free purchase and sale in the town 
 market is thus in its origin an emanation from the rights 
 of burgess. In this way the military defensive union be- 
 came a territorial economic comnumity based upon mutual 
 and direct exchange of agricultural and industrial products 
 by the respecti-, c producers and consumers. 
 
 All market traders on their way to and from a market 
 enjoyed — doubtless also in the period previous to the rise 
 of towns — a particularly active royal protection, which was 
 further extended to the market itself and to the whole 
 market-town. The effects of this market-peace were to 
 secure the market tradesmen during the time of their so- 
 journ in the town against legal prosecution for debts previ 
 ously incurred, and to visit injuries inflicted upon their 
 property or person with doubly severe punishment as be- 
 ing extraordmary breaches of the peace. The market 
 tra<lcsnien arc commonly known as Kattflcutc. niciratorrs. 
 fici^otiatoirs, cmf'forcs.'^ 
 
 '* Recent litcr.iture nlatinpr to the oriRin nf the constitution of Ticr- 
 m.in (owns h.is overlooked the very wi<!e significance of the word 
 Kaufmann and ini.TKincd that the innnmerablo towns cxistin^r within 
 the tJn'iiiaii Iiini>irc lort.irils iht liuM- of lilt? Miiliiic; .'\k*;>, lloul 
 
m 
 
 li } 
 
 
 I 
 
 ii8 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 Inasmuch as the town inhabitai.cj were themselves pecu- 
 liarly dependent upon the market for their buying and 
 
 Cologne and Augsburg down to Medebach and Radolfzell, were in- 
 habited by merchants in the modern sense of the term, that is, by a 
 specialized class of professional tradesmen, who are as a rule still 
 represented as wholesale merchants. All economic history revolts 
 against such a conception. What did these people deal in, and in 
 what did they make payment for their wares? Besides, the very terms 
 used are opposed to it The most prominent characteristic of the 
 professional merchant in his relation to the public is not his custom 
 of buying, but of selling. Yet the chapman (Kaufmann) of the Mid- 
 dle Ages is named from the word for buying— fea«/fn. In the State 
 records of Otto III. for Dortmund from 99° to looo a.d. the emptores 
 Trotmannice, whose municipal laws, like those of Cologne and Mainz, 
 are said to serve as a model for other cities, are spoken of in the 
 same connection as mercatores or negotiatores in other records. If the 
 abbot of Reichenau in the year I07b can with a stroke of the pen 
 transform the peasants of Allensbach and their descendants into mer- 
 chants (ut »7>« et eorum posteri sint mercatores), no possible ingenuity 
 of interpretation can explain this if we have in mind professional 
 tradesmen. That in point of fact merchant meant any man who sold 
 wares in the market, no matter whether he himself had produced them 
 or bought the greater part of them, is evident, for example, from an 
 unprinted declaration of the Council of Frankfurt in 1420 regarding 
 the toll called Marklrerhl (in Book No. 3 of the Municipal Archives, 
 Fol. 80). There we find at the beginning that this toll is to be 
 paid by " every merchant who stands on the street with his merchan- 
 dise, whatsoever it be." Then follow, specified in detail, the in- 
 dividual " merchants " or the " merchandise " affected by this toll. 
 From the lengthy list the following instances may be given: dealers 
 in old clothes, pastry-books, food-vendors, rope-makers, hazelnut- 
 sellers, egg- and chet'se-scllcrs with their carts, poultry-vendors who 
 carry about their baskets on thoir backs, strangers having in their 
 possession more than a maltcr of cheese, cobblers, money-changers, 
 bakers who use the market-stalls, strangers with bread-carts, geese, 
 wagons of vitch (fodder), straw, hay, cabbages, all vendors of linen, 
 flax, hemp, yarn, who sell their wares upon the street. Here we have 
 a confused medley of small tradesmen of the town, artisans and peas- 
 ants. That buyers as well as .sellers on the market were designated as 
 KauAeute (merchants) is evident from numerous records; in fact, pas 
 sages might be cited in which, when the merchant is spoken of, it is 
 the buyer that seems to be chicHy meant. 
 
THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECO'"OMY. 
 
 119 
 
 selling, the specific name of market people or merchants 
 was more and more applied to thtxii as the importance of 
 the market as their source of sinply increased. Propor- 
 tionately with this change, however, the region from which 
 this market drew its supplies and to which it sold extended 
 farther into the country. No longer did it coincide with 
 the domain of burgess rights, whose importance for the 
 rural population must of itself have diminished with the 
 incre-sing security of the whole country against external 
 attack. On the other hand, with the growth of the indus- 
 tries the whole town, and not merely the space originally 
 set apart for the exclusive purpose, became the market; 
 market-peace became town-peace, and for the maintenance 
 of the latter the town was separated from the general state 
 administration as a special judicial district. " City air 
 makes free " became r. principle. Thus arose a social 
 and legal gu'f between burgher and peasant which the 
 thirteenth anJ. ^urteenth centuries vainly sought to bridge 
 over by an extramural and intramural citizenship. The 
 name burgher was finally restricted to the members of the 
 communit, settled within the town limits; and the times 
 lent to this title a legal and Moral significance in vhich the 
 state idea of the ancient Greeks appeared to have returned 
 
 to lif?. 
 
 We cannot here occupy ourselves further either with the 
 development of the municipal constitution and its self- 
 administration ba.sed upon corporative gr?''ations, or with 
 the political power which the towns of Germany, France, 
 and Italy obtained in the later Middle Ages. We have to 
 do only with the matured economic organization of which 
 these towns fonned the central points. 
 
 If we take a map of the old German Empire and mark 
 upon it the places that, up to the close of the Middle Ages, 
 had received grants of municipal rights — there were prob- 
 
 il 
 
I20 
 
 TH JSB OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 ably some three thousand of them — we see the country 
 dotted with towns at an average distance of four to five 
 hours' journev in the south ami west, and in the north and 
 east of seven to eight. All were not of equal importance; 
 but the majority of them in their time were, or at least en- 
 deavoured to be, the economic centres for their territory, 
 leading just as independent an existence as the manor be- 
 fore them. In order to form a conception of the size of 
 these districts, let us imagine the whole country evenly 
 divided among the existing municipalities. In this way 
 each town in southwestern Germany has on the average 
 forty to somewhat over fifty square miles, in the central 
 antl northeastern parts between sixty and eighty-five, and 
 in the eastern from somewhat over one hundred to one 
 hundred and seventy. Let us imagine the town as always 
 situated in the centre of such a section of country, and it 
 becomes plain that in almost every part of Germany the 
 peasant from the most distant rural settlement was able 
 to reach the town market in one day. and be home again 
 by nightfall.-"' 
 
 The whole body of municipal market law. as formulated 
 in early times by the lords of the town and later by the 
 
 ^'.MthouRh since the Middle Ages muny places have lost their town 
 franchises, while others have gained them for the first time, yet the 
 number of places that to-day bear the name of town (Stadt) furnishes 
 a pretty correct idea of what it then was. There is in Baden at pres- 
 ent one city t'> every 132 s(iuare kilometres of territory [i s(i. km. = 
 about I S(|. nii'el. in Wiirtemberg to i.M. in Alsace-Lorraine to 137, 
 in Ifessc to 118. in the kingdom of Saxony to 105. in Hesse-N'assau 
 to 145. in the Rhine Province to 19J. in Westphalia to ig6. in the 
 province of Saxony to i;5, in Brandenburg to Jgi. in the kingdom of 
 Bavaria to 328. in Hanover to 341. in Schleswig-Holstein to 350. in 
 Pomcrania to 41J, in West Prussia to 473. and in East Prussia to 552. 
 The fever for founding tnunicipalities. which racked many medixval 
 rulers, called into existence a multitude of towns that lacked vitality. 
 Well known is the prohibition in the Saihsensfiegel that " No market 
 shall be founded within a mile of anoih..." Weiske, III, 66, 1 1. 
 
THE RISE OF 1^ AT ION A L ECONOMY. 
 
 121 
 
 town councillors, is summed up in the two principles, that, 
 as far as at all possible, sales must be public and at first hand, 
 and that everything ixjhich can be produced zvithin the toz^'n 
 itself shall be produced there. For products of local manu- 
 'acture intermediary trade was forbidden to everyone, even 
 to the artisans; it was permitted with imported goods only 
 when they had already been vainly offered on the '^- .et. 
 The constant aim was to meet amply and at a just price 
 the wants of the home consumers, and to give full satis- 
 faction to the foreign customers of local industry. 
 
 The territory from which supplies were drawn for the 
 town market, and that to which it furnished commodities, 
 was identical. The inhabitants of the countr\- brought in 
 victuals and raw materials, and with what they realized 
 paiil for the labour of the town craftsmen, either in the 
 direct form of wage-work or in the indirect form of finished 
 products, which had been previously ordered or were se- 
 lected in the open market from the artisan's stand. 
 Burgher and peasant thus stood in the relationship of mu- 
 tual customers: what the one produced the other always 
 needed; and a large part of this exchange trade was per- 
 formed without the mediation of money, or in such a way 
 that money was introduced only to adjust differences in 
 value. 
 
 Town handicraft had an exclusive right of sale on the 
 market. The productions of other places were aumitted 
 only when the industry in cpiestion had no representatives 
 within the town. They were usually offered for sale by the 
 foreign producers at the annual fairs; at this one point 
 the spheres of the various town tvuirkcts overlap. But 
 even here the most essential feature, the direct sale by 
 producer to consume*, is also observed, though only in 
 exceptional instances. If a trade capable of supporting a 
 craftsman was not represented in the town, the council 
 
i2a 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 ^■% 
 
 called in a skilled master workman from outside and in- 
 duced him to settle by exemption from taxation and other 
 privileges. If he required considerable initial capital, the 
 town itself came to his aid, and at its own expense built 
 work- and sale-shops and established mills, grin^.ing- 
 works, cloth-frames, bleaching-places, dye-houses, fulling- 
 mills, etc., — all with a view to satisfying the greatest pos- 
 sible variety of wants by home production. 
 
 Although direct dealing with the consumer of his 
 wares ^^ tended necessarily to keep alive in the artisan a 
 sense of personal responsibility, an effort was made to 
 brace this moral relationship by .special ordinances. Hand- 
 work is an office that must be administered for the general 
 welfare. The master shall furnish " honest " work. So far 
 as the personal services of the craftsman remained avail- 
 able to his customers, a regular rate was fixed governing 
 the amount he could claim in wages and board while on his 
 itinerancy. In cases where the customer furnished him 
 with the raw material in his own home, as, for instance, tin 
 to the pewterer, silver and gold to the goldsmith, or yarn 
 to the weaver, provision was made that it should not be 
 adulterated. Where, on the contrary, the artisan supplied 
 the material there were erected in the market, about the 
 churches, at the town gates, or in particular streets, public 
 sale-booths which often served also as work-shops (bread- 
 stands, meat-stalls, drapers' and cloth shops, furriers' 
 booths, shoemakers' benches, etc.). It was a market rule 
 that those vending the same wares should do their selling 
 alongside one another in open and mutual competition 
 and under the supervision of the market wardens and over- 
 
 " Here and there this was further secured by the regulation that 
 not even the wife of the craftsman might represent him in selling. 
 Comp. Gramich, V'erf. h. Verw. d- St. Wiirsburg vom. XIII. bis XF. 
 Jkdt., pp. 38 f. 
 
THE RISE OF NATION/IL ECONOMY. 
 
 X23 
 
 seers, and this rule was extended to craftsmen who merely 
 worked at home on orders, in that for the most part they 
 lived side by side on the same street. Many cities have 
 preserved to the present day the remembrance of this con- 
 dition of things in the names of their streets (such as Shoe- 
 maker, Turner, Weaver, Cooper, Butcher, Fisher Streets), 
 many of which led directly into the old market square. In 
 this way the greatest part of the town, or even the whole of 
 it, bore the outward aspect of one large market. It 
 is well known that the many prescriptions regarding the 
 raw material to be used, the method of doing work, the 
 length and breadth of cloths, and the direct regulation of 
 prices must have served for the protection of the con- 
 sumer.^® 
 
 Just as the urban craftsman enjoyed within the town 
 and the extramural judicial district {Banmneile) the ex- 
 clusive right of selling the products of his handicraft, so 
 the urban consumer possessed for the same area the ex- 
 clusive right to purchase imported commodities. This 
 right can be exercised, to be sure, only when the imported 
 goods actually come to market and stand on sale for the 
 proper length of time. To effect this a law of staple is 
 introduced; foreselling in the country places or before the 
 town gates is forbidden; selling to middlemen, artisans, 
 and strangers is permitted only after the consumers are 
 supplied, and then usually with the limitation that the lat- 
 ter, if they so wish, may have a share; and lastly, the 
 withdrawing of goods once brought to market was for- 
 bidden, or permitted only after they had remained three 
 days unsold.^^ 
 
 ** For the sake of brevity we refer for all details in this connection 
 to Stieda in the Jhb. f. N.-6k. u. Statistik, XXVII. pp. 91 «• 
 
 "These ordinances were most carefully wrought out for the corn 
 trade. Sec Schmolkr, Jhb. f. Gcsetzg. Verw, u. Volksw., XX. pp. 
 708 flf. 
 
124 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 I 1 
 
 I 
 
 '•*• 3 » 
 
 
 But against the foreign 'seller there always prevails a 
 deep-rooted mistrust. To t lis is due the existence of that 
 peculiar system of exchange through official interme- 
 diaries, measurers, and weighers. To-day the State con- 
 trols weights and measures by official standards and pui^lic 
 inspections, and leaves the terms to the buyers and sellers 
 themselves. In the Middle Ages the technical means for 
 constructing exact measures and ensuring their accuracy 
 were wanting. Common field-stones — and at the Frank- 
 furt fairs as late as the fifteenth century even wooden 
 blocks — were used as weights. In order, however, to de- 
 termine accurately the amount of goods exchanged, the 
 handling of the measures was withdrawn from the parties 
 themselves and entrusted to special officers, whose pres- 
 ence was made obligatory at every sale made by an out- 
 sider. It was the duty of these intermediaries to bring 
 buyer and seller together, to assist in fixing the price, to 
 test the goods for possible defects, to select for the pur- 
 chaser the quantity he had bought, and to see to its propci- 
 delivery. The intermediary was forbidden to trade for 
 himself; he was not even allowed at the departure of the 
 foreign tradesnnn, whom he generally lodged, to purchase 
 remnants of goods remaining unsold. 
 
 This system of direct exchange is found, though with 
 many local peculiarities, carried out to the most min- 
 ute details in all mediaeval towns. This means. that the 
 actual circumstances in which its principles were devel- 
 oped render it inevitable. How far it was really prac- 
 ticable can only be decided when we are able to determine 
 what proportions trade assumed under it. 
 
 It is beyond question that a retail trade had taken root 
 in the town;,. To it belonged all who " sel! pennyworths 
 for the poor man." To understand this, we nvast bear in 
 mind that all well-to-do townspeople were accustomed 
 
THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 1 = 5 
 
 to purchase their supplies directly from foreign merchants 
 at the weekly and yearly markets. The poor man was 
 unable to make provision for any length of time; he lived, 
 as he does to-day, " from hand to mouth." For him the 
 retail tradesman, accordingly, undertook the keeping of 
 stores for daily sale. 
 
 We can distinguish three groups of such small trades- 
 men, namely, grocers, peddlers, and cloth-dealers. In the 
 earlier half of the period of town economy the last were 
 the most important, as, in many towns there was no local 
 wool-weaving done. With its development their activity 
 was limited to the handling of the finer kinds of Dutch 
 cloths, silks, and cottons, or else they made room for the 
 weavers in their shops. 
 
 The ti'holcsalc trade was exclusively itinerant and market 
 or fair trade; and down to the close of the Middle Ages 
 the majority of the towns probably saw no merchants 
 settled within their walls who carried on wholesale trade 
 from permanent headquarters. Only commodities not pro- 
 duced within the more or less extensive district from 
 which a town drew its supplies were the subject of whole- 
 sale trade. We know of but five kinds: (i) spices and 
 southern fruits, (2) dried and salted fish, which were then 
 a staple food of the people, (3) furs, (4) fine cloths, (5) for 
 the North German towns, wine. In certain parts of Ger- 
 many salt would also have to be included. In most cases, 
 however, the town council ordered it in large quantities 
 directly from the places of production, stored it in the 
 municipal salt warehouses, and after a monopolistic ad- 
 vance of its price gave it out to be disposed of by peddler 
 and saltman, who paid a fee for the privilege. Usually the 
 foreign wholesale dealers" were permitted to sell their 
 
 "In Jhb. f. Nat.-6k. u. Stat., 3 F- XX (1900). pp. i ff., G. v. Below 
 attempts to prove that in the Middle Ages there existed no class ot 
 
126 
 
 THE RISE OF Ny4TION/4L ECONOMY. 
 
 ft 'a 
 
 !!' 
 
 1-1 
 
 wares only in large lots or in minimum quantities — in the 
 case of spices, for example, not under 1 2^ pounds. The local 
 retailers and peddlers then carried on the sale in detail. 
 This also holds good for many large producers, as, for 
 instance, hammersmiths, who might sell o founders the 
 iron they had failed to persuade smith-j and private indi- 
 viduals to buy. 
 
 Though the limits of the territory from which the mar- 
 ket of a mediaeval town drew its supplies and to which its 
 sales were made cannot be determined with precision, see- 
 ing that they varied for different wares, yet from the eco- 
 nom.ic point of view they formed none the less an inde- 
 pendent region. Each town with its surrounding country 
 constituted an autonomous economic unit within which its 
 whole course of economic Hfe was on an independent foot- 
 ing. This independence is based upon special currency, 
 and special weights and measures for each locality. The 
 relation between town and country is as a matter of fact 
 a compulsory relation such as that between the head and 
 the limbs of the body, and it displays strong tendencies to 
 assume the forms of legalized compulsion. The extra- 
 mural jurisdiction of the town, the prohibitions of export 
 and import already met with, the differential tolls, and the 
 direct acquisition of territory on the part of the large towns 
 plainly point in that direction. 
 
 Many as are the objections which may be urged against 
 deducing the constitution of the town from that of the 
 manor, the economic system of the town can be properly 
 
 wholesale merchants, and that the characteristic feature of those times 
 was for wholesale and reUil trade to be carried on by the same person. 
 He therefore takes exception to our use of the term wholesale mer- 
 chant. I cannot, however, see why when these persons appeared as 
 wholesalers they should not receive the name, particularly as there is 
 no evidersce to show that wholesale merchants were ever met with who 
 were not at the same time retail traders. 
 
THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 ia7 
 
 '% 
 
 understood and explained only as a continuation of the 
 manorial system. What existed in the latter ia mere 
 germs and beginnings grew into finished organisms and 
 systems of organisms; factors that under the independent 
 household economy were found grouped in primitive 
 shapelessness, have now been differentiated by subdivision 
 and made independent. The forced division of labour of 
 the manor has broadened into a free division of production 
 between peasants and burghers, displaying morever 
 among the latter a varied multiplicity of separate trades. 
 The manorial workman carrying on domestic labour has 
 become the wage-earning craftsman, who in time comes 
 to possess his own business capital in addition to his tools. 
 The vital thread connecting manorial and cottier economy 
 has at length been severed; the separate household estab- 
 lishments have gained an independent existence; trade 
 between them is no longer conducted on the basis of a gen- 
 eral return, but on the basis of a specific payment for ser- 
 vices given and received. To be sure they have not yet 
 fully emancipated themselves from the soil, even in the 
 town; production is still dependent in large measure upon 
 the domestic husbandry; but there have been formed the 
 distinct vocations of agriculturalist, artisan, and trades- 
 Uian which have given a specific direction to the activities 
 and lives of those following them. Society has become 
 differentiated; classes now exist; and these were unknown 
 before. 
 
 T he whole circ le of economic Jife has_gained in fulness 
 and variety in comparison with the independent domestic 
 economy; the membership of the separate household es- 
 taMshments has become smaller; the individuals are inter- 
 dependent ; they undertake certain functions for each 
 other; exchange value is already forcing its way as a leter- 
 mining factor into their inner life. But the producingjrom- 
 
128 
 
 TH'z RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY, 
 
 i 
 
 ^1 
 
 I 
 
 .tflllm I 
 
 it 
 
 !i 
 
 .i 
 
 munity still coincules with the consuming community; the 
 handicraftsman's assistants drawn from outside, and even 
 the tradesmen, are meml)ers of their employer's house- 
 hold, subject to his disciplinary control. He is their " mas- 
 ter," they are his " servants." 
 
 And still, as ever, by far the greater proportion of com- 
 modities does not pass beyond the lintels of the place of 
 production. A small part finds its way l)y the process of 
 exchange into other establishments, but the way travelled 
 is a very short one. namely, from producer to consumer. 
 There is no circulation of goods. The sole exceptions are 
 the articles of foreign trade few in number, and of the 
 petty retail trade. They alone became wares. They alone 
 must frequently take on the form of money before reach- 
 ing their domestic destination. But here we deal with an 
 exception to the system of direct exchange, not with a con- 
 stituent element of the whole economic order. 
 
 Jhough at this early point there is a social division 
 of labour, and also an interrc'.ationship of rades. there are 
 as yeTneitTier fixed Industrial undertakings nor the neces- 
 sary industrial capital. At most wt are justified in speak- 
 ing of trade capital. Handicraft undertakes work, but it 
 is no business undertaking. In the form? of itinerant 
 handicraft and home work it almo^^t totally acks capital. 
 It means wage-labour embodied in t:-€ material of another. 
 Even where the craftsman works w-'h iis nvr :ools the 
 product does not increase m value -rrwr :^tt> c nftant in- 
 corporation of fresh increme nts of -ztxzi^ nn :v m: the fact 
 that labour is being inve-tcu in it. 
 
 The amount of loar .ivA c-nstnnrrnjon -trsxtsi -^ also ex- 
 ceedingly small. It ma; ve- m dmsnf" -E-T^^ner in medi- 
 jeval trade credit open.Tiosi- :ui: »e ^^t^Hve- of at all. 
 Early exchange is base( ip»^ ^eat:^- TE^-menr nothing is 
 
 given except \MiCrC a ;- U=::— : =rxz;-^ . i:r-_ - -» 1» 
 
THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 129 
 
 received. Almost the entire credit system is clothed in 
 the forms of purchase. This was the case with the heredi- 
 tary peasant holding and with the giving of town building- 
 sites in return for a ground-rent, in which instances the 
 land was looked upon as the purchase-price for the right 
 to levy rent.-" So it was also under the earlier law where 
 the land placed at the disposal of the money-lender passes 
 as a temporary equivalent into the keeping of the " cred- 
 itor " and becomes his property if the debtor fails to repay 
 the loan. Economically considered, this commercial act 
 dififers in no way from selling in order to buy again; and 
 it is admitted that it is now >carcely possible to discover a 
 legal distinction between theitwo. A similar character is 
 borne by tl.'' most common of urban credit transactions, 
 the purchase of rents or stocks,-" as the name itself indi- 
 cates. The price is the capital loaned; the commodity 
 exchanged is the right to draw a yearly rent, which the 
 borrower on the security of a house transfers in such a 
 manner that the owner for the time being receives the rent. 
 The rent is of the nature of a charge up< r, the soil, and is 
 for a long time incapable of release; the party responsi- 
 ble answers for it with the house or land upon which it is 
 fixed, but not with his other assets. It is thus a charge 
 only upon the real properly that carries it, whose rcntabil- 
 ity'it proportionately diminishes. The person entitled to 
 the rent has absolutely resigned the purchase-price paid; 
 the document conferring the right to draw the rent can 
 be transferred without formality, just as a bill payable to 
 bearer. Every personal relationship is thus eliminated 
 from the wdiole transaction, which lacks that element of 
 
 " Compare in connection with this whole section the luminous ex- 
 planation by A. Heusler, Instituiionen d. deutsch. Privatrechls, II, pp. 
 
 128 ff. 
 "Rcntcnkauf and Giiltkr.uf. 
 
13° 
 
 THE RISE OF NAT!ONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 m 
 
 trust peculiar to credit. The right of redemption bears 
 the same character; it is the sale of the rent under reserva- 
 tion of the privilege of re-purchase. 
 
 As in dealings in real property, so also with mov- 
 ables, the credit transaction is but a variation of ready pay- 
 ment. The security, as Heusler says, is a provisional 
 transfer on the part of the debtor of an equivalent that is 
 still redeemable (forfeitable security), not a covering of the 
 debt, which may eventually be claimed by the creditor and 
 realized upon by being converted into money (saleable 
 security). The pawnbroking business of the Jews •** is in 
 fact similar to our modern sale with right of redemption, 
 and the " goods credit " extended to-day by craftsmen 
 and shopkeepers, takes in the Middle Ages the form of 
 purchase on security." If at the same time we con- 
 sider that when personal credit was given in those times 
 the debtor almost always had to agree to submit to the 
 creditor's right of security; that in most instances he 
 could get money only by furnishing the best security un- 
 der pledges to the lender and similar burdensome condi- 
 tions; that the creditor in addition reserved the right, in 
 case of default, to obtain the money from Jews at the debt- 
 or's expense; and that the fellow citizens or heirs of the 
 foreign debtor could be distrained upon for the amount of 
 his debt, — we see plainly that in the town economy of the 
 Middle Ages a credit syrtem in the modem sense cannot 
 be spoken of.'* 
 
 •■ Comp. my Bev'nlkerung von Frankfurt, I, pp. 573 ff- 
 " Comp. the interesting examples in Stieda. as cited above, p. 104. 
 " A striking resemblance to the mediaeval credit system is offered 
 by the Greek system and its legal forms. Here likewise purchase and 
 loan are largely synonymous terms, and the language has not arrived 
 at the stage of distinguishing sharply the notions of buying, pledging, 
 renting, and subjecting to conditions. The Greek mortgage laws 
 coincide in all important points with the early German. Comp. K. F. 
 
THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 131 
 
 ^1 
 1 
 
 There are two things in connection with this that must 
 appear especially strange to a student of modem political 
 economy, namely, the frequency with which immaterial 
 things (relationships) become economic commodities and 
 subjects of exchange, and their treatment under commer- 
 cial law as real property. These show clearly how primi- 
 tive exchange sought to enlarge the sphere denied it un- 
 der the existing conditions of production by awkwardly 
 transforming, into negotiable property, almost everything 
 it could lay hold upon, and thus extending infinitely the 
 domain of private law. What an endless variety of things 
 in mediaeval times were lent, bestowed, sold, and pawned! 
 — the sovereign power over territories and towns; county 
 and bailiff's rip^hts; jun&uiction over hundreds and can- 
 tons; church dignities and patronages; suburban monoi>- 
 oly rights; ferry and road privileges; prerogatives of mint- 
 age and toll, of hunting and fishing; wood-cutting rights, 
 tithes, statute labour, ground-rents, and revenues; in fact 
 charges of ever>' kind falling upon the land. Economi- 
 cally considered, all these rights and "relationships" share 
 with land the peculiarity that they cannot be removed 
 from the place where they are enjoyed, and that t^ey can- 
 not be multiplied at will. 
 
 Income and wealth are at this stage not yet clearly distin- 
 guished from each other. When in Basel in the year 145 1 
 the " new pound-toll " was introduced it was prescribed 
 that it should be paid: (i) from the selling-price of wares, 
 
 (2) from the capital invested in the purchase of rents, and 
 
 (3) from the amount of rents received.'" On every pound 
 
 Hermann. Lchrbuch dcr gritch. Privalaltcriumer mil Rinschluss der Rechls- 
 altcrhnncr, » 67 and (rt<. The old Roman fiducia and its later form as 
 tignus may be mentioned for purpose of comparison. 
 
 Comp. Schonbere, Finansrtrhdltnisst d. Stadt Basel im XIV. und 
 A J- . JHdt., p. 367. 
 
13a THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 four pfennigs were to be paid, no matter whether the com- 
 modity had changed hands as purchase-money, as capital, 
 or as interest. In the first instance we have to do, accord- 
 ing to our terminology, with gross revenue, in the second 
 with property, in the third with net income; and yet all 
 three cases are treated alike. Similar examples might be 
 adduced from the tax-regulations of other cities." 
 
 Two of our modern classes of income, however, now 
 come more clearly into view, namely, ground-rent and 
 wages. The latter bears, to be sure, a peculiar character; 
 it is handicraft-wage, compensation for the use of the 
 craftsman's labour on behalf of the consumer, and not, as 
 to-day, the price paid to the wage-worker by the en- 
 trepreneur. Still this price already exists in germ in the 
 slight money-wage that the artisan gives to his journey- 
 man in addition to free maintenance, thus enabling the 
 latter to supply independently a limited proportion of his 
 wants. Earnings of management appear only in the 
 sphere of trade, and thus, like it, are the exception; more- 
 over through connection with transportation they are 
 more coloured by elements of labour-wage than are the 
 earnings from trade to-day. As a rule interest takes 
 on the form of ground-rent; and the same is true of the 
 many kinds of revenues arising from the juridical rela- 
 tionships that enter into trade. As credit operations 
 usually take the form of purchase, they almost always 
 mean for the creditor the actual transfer of a portion of 
 his property, in order that he may receive a yearly income 
 or a continuous usufruct. This is a rule, for example, of 
 enfeoffment; with mortgaged property, according to the 
 early law. it involved the transfer of the natural yield of 
 
 - For details see my paper on two medixval tax-regulations. Klcinert 
 Bdtriigf z. Gfschich. von Doccnitn d. Uipsiger HochschuU. Ftstscknft --. 
 ('■ill. Hislorikertage (Leipzig. i8o4>. PP- >^3ff. 
 
THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 »33 
 
 the land, and with rent-purchases, of the ground-rent or 
 rent. On this basis arose the earliest type of personal in- 
 surance and at the same time the chief form of public 
 credit: the negotiating of annuities. 
 
 Public economy is still mainly of a private character: 
 revenues from domains, sovereign prerogatives, tithes, 
 statute labour, services, ground-rents, and fees preponder- 
 ate in the State, market revenues and imports on con- 
 sumption in the towns. The general property-tax con- 
 tinues to be the only direct tax, and mingled with it here 
 and there are elements of an income-tax. It is indeed 
 levied more frequently than in the preceding period, but 
 -.till it is not regular. 
 
 In Germany the economic supremacy of the towns over 
 the surrounding country blossomed only in a few places 
 into political sovereignty. In Italy a parallel development 
 led to the formation of a tyranny of the cities; in France 
 the beginnings of autonomy on the part of free municipal 
 communities were early suppressed by the kings with the 
 aid of the feudal nobility. The reason is that in Germany, 
 as in France, everything that lay without the town wall 
 was overlaid with a mass of feudal institutions. True the 
 great landed proprietors had long since given up the per- 
 sonal management of their manorial estates. — which be- 
 came for the owner, just as the town land and house prop- 
 erty for the patrician families, nothing more than a source 
 of income. But their original economic power had now be- 
 come political, the landed proprietors were now territorial 
 princes, and in the course of this transformation there had 
 arisen a new and widely ramified class of small titled pro- 
 prietors whose interests, purely agrarian in character, were 
 closely linked to those uf the princes. Henc that keen 
 struffgle in Germany between burj^her and n )!e whicl; 
 
»34 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 ■ m 
 
 1 
 
 fills the closing centuries of the Middle Ages, and in which 
 the towns maintain the political autonomy they had for 
 the most part acquired from their lords by purchase and 
 unredeemed pleilges, though they fail to wrest the peasant 
 clabs from the feudal powers. 
 
 It can thus be said that the economic development of the 
 towns in Germany and France remained incomplete; and 
 that they did not accomplish what the most vigorous 
 types of the period of autonomous household economy had 
 actually achieved, namely, the transmuting of their eco- 
 nomic power into political indepei'ui-nce. This was 
 perhaps fortunate for us. In Italy the wealth of the 
 cities expropriated in all directions the possessions of the 
 peasant, and down to the present has continued to exploit 
 him as a wretched metayer. In Germany the nobility were, 
 indeed, able to make of him a feudatorj-; but the con- 
 ception of nationality, which first came to life in the terri- 
 torial sovereignties, served to prevent his proletarization. 
 
 The final development of national economy is in its es- 
 sence a fruit of the political centralization that begins at 
 the close of the Middle Ages with the rise of territorial 
 state organizations, and now finds its completion in the 
 creation of the unified national State. Economic unifica- 
 tion of forces goes hand in hand with the bowing of private 
 political interests to the higher aims of the nation as a 
 
 whole. 
 
 In Germany it is the more powerful territorial prtnces, 
 as opposed to the rural nobles and the towns, who seek 
 to realize the modern national idea, often certainly under 
 j;rcat diffictilties. especially when their territories were 
 widely scattered. From the second half of the fifteenth 
 century we have many indications of a closer economic 
 union, such as the cre.ition of a territorial currency in 
 place of the numerous town currencies, the issue of tcrri- 
 
THE RISE OF N/ITION/fL ECONOMY. 
 
 1 35 
 
 torial regulations regarding trade, markets, industry, for- 
 estry, mining, hunting, and fishing, the gradual formation 
 of a system of sovereign prerogatives and concessions, the 
 promulgation of territorial laws, conducive to greater legal 
 unity, and the emergence of an ordered public economy. 
 
 But for centuries longer agricultural interests predom- 
 inate in Germany, and as against them the exertions of the 
 imperial power in the direction of a national economic 
 policy lamentably failed. On the other hand the Western 
 European states, — Spain, Portugal, England, France, and 
 the Netherlands, — from the sixteenth century on appear 
 externally as economic units, developing a vigorous colo- 
 nial policy in order to turn to account the rich resources of 
 their newly acquired possessions over sea. 
 
 In all these lands, though with varying degrees of se- 
 verity, appears the struggle with the independent powers 
 of the Middle Ages, — the greater nobility, the towns, the 
 provinces, the religious and secular corporations. The 
 immediate question, to be sure, was the annihilation of the 
 independent territorial circles which blocked the way to 
 political unification. Put deep down beneath the move- 
 ment leading to the development of princely absolutism, 
 slumbers the universal idea that the greater tasks con- 
 fronting modern civilization demanded an organized union 
 of whole peoples, a grand living community of interests; 
 and this could arise only upon the basis of common eco- 
 nomic action. Each portion of the country, each section 
 of the population, must in the service of the whole take 
 over those duties that its natural endowments best fitted 
 it to perform. A comprehensive partitioning of functions 
 was necessary, a division into callings embracing the whole 
 population; and this division itself presupposed a highly 
 developed commerce and an active interchange of goods 
 amongst the population. If the sole aim of all economic 
 
136 
 
 THE RISE OF NATION /I L ECONOMY. 
 
 I ! 
 
 Ill 
 
 effort was in ancient times to make the house autonomous 
 in the satisfaction of its wants, and in later mediaeval times 
 to supply the needs of the town, there now comes into 
 being an exceedingly complex and ingenious system for 
 meeting the wants of the entire nation. 
 
 The carrying out of this system is from the sixteenth to 
 the eighteenth century the economic effort of all the ad- 
 vanced European states. The measures employed to at- 
 tain this object are modelled in almost every detail upon 
 the economic policy of the mediaeval towns.^* They are 
 generally summed up under the name of the mercantile 
 system. This latter has long been regarded as a theoretical 
 edifice culminating in the principle that the wealth of a 
 country consists in the amount of coin within its borders. 
 To-day, in all probability, this conception is universally 
 abandoned. Mercantilism is no dead dogma, but the 
 active practice of all leading statesmen from Charles V. 
 to Frederick the Great. It found its typical development 
 in the economic policy of Colbert. He sought the removal 
 or reduction of the internal customs and tolls, the intro- 
 duction of a unified customs system on the national bor- 
 ders; the assuring to the country of a supply of the neces- 
 sary raw materials and means of sustenance by hindrances 
 to export, and the institution of the forest regalia. He 
 fostered industry on a large scale by the establishment of 
 new industrial branches with state support and technical 
 supervision, by the exclusion of foreign competition 
 through prohibitive tariffs, and by the building of roads, 
 canals, and harbours. With the same end in view he strove 
 to unify the system of weights and measures, and to regu- 
 late commercial law and the commercial news-service. 
 
 •* For the German states this development is excellently portrayed 
 by Schmoller in the Jhb. f. Gesetzgeb. Verw. u. Volksw. VIII (1884). 
 
 pp. 22 a. 
 
THE RISE OF N/fTlONML ECONOMY. 
 
 137 
 
 The cultivation of the technical arts, fine arts, and science 
 in special state institutions; the systematizing of state and 
 communal expenditure, the removal of inequalities in taxa- 
 tion, also served his one purpose — to create an independent 
 national economy which should satisfy all the needs of the citi- 
 zens of France by national labour, and by an active internal 
 trade bring all the natural resources of the country and all 
 the separate forces of the people into the service of the 
 whole. In considering the special encouragement given 
 by " Colbertism " to foreign commerce, the marine, and 
 colonial trade, it has all too often been overlooked that 
 these measures also strengthened the inner resources of 
 the country, and that the theory of the balance of trade 
 became a necessity at a time when the transition from 
 the still predominant household production to the system 
 of universal exchange indispensably postulated the in- 
 crease of the monetary medium of circulation. 
 
 Along with the state measures we must not fail to take 
 account of the social forces working in the same direction. 
 These naturally had their starting-point in the towns. 
 Here, by a gradual process of transformation, 'waning at 
 interest had been evolved from the purchase o! rents; and 
 thus in the course of the sixteenth century a true credit 
 system arose. In this we may see the influence of whole- 
 sale trade, which first discovered the secret of making 
 money with money. Through the liberation of capi- 
 tal invested in rents tlic wealth of the rich townsmen 
 acquired a greatly increased mobility and accumulative 
 power. Loan capital now took its place at the side of 
 trade capital, hitherto the only kind of capital; and the 
 two supplemented and supported each other in their fur- 
 ther development. 
 
 The immediate result was a notablejexpansion p£ tra4e^ 
 Certain towns began to rear their heads above the uniform 
 
 ) f] 
 
X38 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 mass of mediaeval market and handicraft towns as centres 
 of state administration or as emporiums of trade. In Ger- 
 many, which through the decline of the Hansa and the 
 change in the highways of the world's trade, had lost most 
 of its importance as an intermediary of trade with the 
 North, the change manifests itself to some extent in the 
 growmg importance of the great fairs, and in the decad- 
 ence of the local markets. The Frankfurt fair reached its 
 zenith in the sixteenth century, that of Leipzig consider- 
 ably later. But soon trade capital is no longer content 
 with the importation and handling of foreign products; 
 it becomes, for native industry and the surplus products 
 of the peasant's domestic labour, commission capital. 
 Wholesale production with division of labour in manu- 
 factories and factories comes into life, and with it the 
 wage-earning class. In place of the mediaeval exchange 
 bank there is developed first the bank of deposit and cir- 
 culation, then the modern credit bank. The transport of 
 goods, which earlier was an integral part of trade, now 
 becomes independent. The state posts, newspapers, and 
 the national marine arise, and the insurance system is de- 
 veloped. On all sides are new organizations whose pur- 
 pose is to satisfy wide-spread economic wants; a national 
 industry, a national market, national commercial institu- 
 tions,— everywhere the capitalistic principle of business 
 
 enterprise in trade. 
 
 Everybody knows how the absolutist State furthered 
 this movement, ai d how not infrequently in the effort to 
 accelerate it it gave an artificial existence to what would 
 not flourish of its own strength. Nevertheless, though 
 limited in manifold ways by state legislation, the old eco- 
 nomic organization of the towns with its guild and monop- 
 oly privileges and the sharp separation of town and 
 country, persisted on until about the end of the eighteenth 
 
i« 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 139 
 
 '^ 
 
 century, heedless of the new economic life springing up 
 roundabout and of the variety of new commercial forms 
 which it had nurtured. When the Physiocrats and Adam 
 Smith made these latter for the first time the subject of 
 scientific observation, they entirely overlooked the ob- 
 vious fact that they were not dealing with a spontaneous 
 product of mere social activity, but with a fruit of the 
 paternal government of the State. The barriers whose 
 removal they demanded were either the fossilized survivals 
 of earlier economic epochs, such as charges upon the soil, 
 guilds, local coercive rights, restrictions on freedom of mi- 
 gration; or they were devices of mercantilism for assisting 
 production, such as monopolies and privileges, which 
 might cease to operate after having fulfilled their purpose. 
 As far as the development of national economy is con- 
 cerned, the liberalism of the last hundred years has only 
 continued what absolutism began. Expressed in this way, 
 the assertion may easily seem paradoxical. For liberalism, 
 outwardly considered, has only demolished; it has over- 
 thrown the antiquated forms upon which household and 
 town economy were founded, and constructed nothing 
 new. It has destroyed the special position and special 
 privileges of individual territorial districts and individual 
 social groups, and in their stead established free competi- 
 tion and equality before the law. But though it has thus 
 decomposed into its elements the heritage of the past, it 
 has at the same time cleared the way for new economic 
 combinations of a truly national character, and made it 
 possible for every energy, according to the technical devel- 
 opment of the time, to enter into the service of the whole 
 at the point where it is of the greatest usefulness. 
 
 If liberalism has made the progress of national economy 
 absolutely contingent upon social freedom of action, and 
 thus taken an attitude in many respects hostile to 
 
I40 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 v.^ii 
 
 the State, it has nevertheless failed to prevent the modern 
 State, as such, from pursuing the path chosen by it as early 
 as the sixteenth century, and leading to an ever-closer 
 union of all sections of the people and of the national ter- 
 ritory for the accomplishment of the steadily expanding 
 tasks' of civilization. All the great statesmen of the last 
 three centuries, from Cromwell and Colbert to Cavour and 
 Bismarck, have worked towards this end. The French 
 Revolution has been no less centralizing in its effects than 
 the political upheavals of recent decades. In the latest 
 phase of this evolution the principle of nationality has be- 
 come a principle of mighty unifying power. The small 
 separate States of earlier times were no longer equal to 
 the comprehensive economic tasks of the present. They 
 had either to disappear in one large national State, as in 
 Italy, or surrender considerable portions of their inde- 
 pendence, especially in economic legislation, to a federal 
 State, as did the individual States in the German Empire, 
 and the cantons in Switzerland. 
 
 We err, if we imagine ourselves justified in concluding 
 1 from the extent to which international -trade, has been 
 facilitated during the epoch of liberalism that the period 
 of national economy is on the decline and is giving place 
 to the period of world-ec ononix. The very latest political 
 development of the States of Europe has resulted in a 
 return to the ideas of mercantilism and, to a certain extent, 
 of the old town economy. The revival of protective duties, 
 the retention of national currency and of national labour 
 legislation, the public ownership of the machinery of trans- 
 portation already achieved or still aimed at, the national 
 control of workman's insurance and of the banking sys- 
 tem, the growing activity of the State in economic matters 
 generallv.— all this indicates that we have passed the ab- 
 solutist and liberalist periods and entered upon a third 
 

 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 141 
 
 period of national economy. Socially this period bears a 
 peculiar aspect. It is no longer merely a question of meet- 
 ing national wants as independently and completely as 
 possible by national production, but a question of the just 
 distribution of goods, of the direct action of the State in 
 the economic interests of the whole, and for the purpose 
 of securing to all its subjects according to their economic 
 services a share in the benefits of civilization. The requi- 
 site measures can be carried out only on a grand scale; 
 they demand an intimate union of all individual forces,' 
 such as a great national State alone can furnish. 
 
 With this we might fittingly close. For to present here 
 the multitude of new phenomena springing up under the 
 touch of national as opposed to household and town econ- 
 omy one would need to reproduce almost the whole con- 
 tents of a text-book on political economy. It will never- 
 theless contribute to a better understanding of the subject 
 if, by a comparison of some of the leading phenomena we 
 concisely review the fundamental features of the whole in 
 the three stages of its development. 
 
 The most prominent of these features is, that in the 
 course of history mankind sets before itself ever higher 
 economic aims and finds the means of attaining these in a 
 division of the burden of labour, which constantly extends 
 until finally it embraces the whole people and requires the 
 services of all for all. This cooperation is based, in the 
 *^^51^L!!P-"!?1^°1^^ economy, upon blood-relationship, of 
 town economy upon contiguity, and of national economy 
 upon nationality. It is the road traversed by mankind in 
 passing from clanship to society, which, as far as we 
 can see, ends in an ever-ti,q:htening social organization. On 
 this road the means for satisfying the wants of the indi- 
 vidual continually grow in fulness and variety, and at the 
 same time in dependence and complexity. The life and 
 
142 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 labour of every individual becomes more and more en- 
 twined with the Hfe and labour of many others. 
 
 At the stage of household economy every commodity is 
 consumed in the place of its origin; at the stage of town 
 economy it passes immediately from the producer to the 
 consumer; at the stage of national economy, both in its 
 production and thereafter, it passes through various hands 
 
 it circulates. In the course of the whole evolution the 
 
 distance between production and consumption increases. 
 At the first stage all commodities are consumption goods; 
 at the second part of them become articles of exchange; 
 at the third most of then^ are wares. 
 
 The individual household at the first stage is a producing 
 and consuming community in one; at the stage of town 
 economy this state of things continues in so far as the 
 journeyman craftsman and the peasant workman make 
 part of the household of the person employing them; in 
 national economy community in production and com- 
 munity in consumption become distinct. The former is a 
 business undertaking from whose returns as a rule several 
 independent households are supported. 
 
 When outside labour is necessary, it is at the first stage 
 in a permanent relation of subjection to the producer (as 
 slaves and serfs), at the second in one of service, and at the 
 third the relationship is contractual. Under the inde- 
 pendent household system the consumer is either himself 
 a labourer, or the owner of the labourer; in town economy 
 he makes a direct purchase of the workman's labour 
 (wage-work), or of the product of his labour (handicraft); 
 in national economy he ceases to stand in any relation to 
 the labourer, and purchaser his goods from the entrepre- 
 neur or merchant, by whom the labourer is paid. 
 
 As for money, it is in independent domestic economy 
 either entirely absent, or an article of direct use and a 
 
THE RISE OF NATION /tL ECONOMY. 
 
 M3 
 
 means for storing up wealth. In town economy it is es- 
 sentially a medium of exchange; in national economy it 
 becomes a means of circulation and of profit-making as 
 well. The three categories, payment in kind, money pay- 
 ment Hnd payment based upon credit, correspond with the 
 variouj roles played by money, though they do not ex- 
 haust them. 
 
 Capital scarcely exists at the first stage; we meet only 
 with consumption goods. At the second stage implements 
 of labour may be classed under the usual head of business 
 capital, but this is by no means generally true of the raw 
 materials. Acquisitive capital proper exists only in the 
 form of trade capital. At the third, acquisitive capital rep- 
 resents the means whereby goods are raised from ona 
 stage of division of labour to the next and impelled 
 through the whole process of circulation.'® Here every- 
 thing becomes capital. From this point of view we might 
 describe the independent household economy as lacking 
 capital, town economy as hostile to capital, and national 
 economy as capitalistic. 
 
 Income and zvcalth under the household system com- 
 pose an undivided and indivisible whole; though the be- 
 ginnings of ground-rent are already perceptible. In town 
 economy interest also usually appears as ground-rent; 
 business profits are confined almost entirely to trade; the 
 chief form of labour-wage is the wage paid to the crafts- 
 man by the consumer. But even yet most commodities 
 do not pass from their place of production into other es- 
 tablishments. Pure income can be realized only by one 
 who dehnitely surrenders a portion of his wealth in the 
 purchase of rents. At the stage of national economy the 
 four branches of income are definitely separated. Almost 
 
 ' Cotnp. also Chaps 
 
 v an 
 
 d VII 
 
144 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 m V 
 
 the whole return from production is liquidated through 
 trade. Under wealth, rent and acquisitive capital are dis- 
 tinct from stores for consumption, which are kept at the 
 lowest imaginable limit, since commerce frees individuals 
 from the keeping of supplies. On the other hand the un- 
 used surpluses of income, which at the first and second 
 stages necessarily remained over from the wealth available 
 for consumption, are now either directly added to business 
 capital or transformed by means of saving- and other 
 banks into interest-bearing loans, — that is, they are, in 
 any case, converted into capital. 
 
 At the stage of household economy the division of labour 
 is confined to the household establishment; at the stage of 
 town economy it consists either in the forma a of, and 
 division into, trades within the town, or in a partition of 
 production between town and country; while the promi- 
 nent features of the stage of national economy are increas- 
 ing division of production, subdivision of work within the 
 various establishments, and displacement of labour from 
 one business to another.^" 
 
 Jndustry as an independent occupation is not found at 
 the first stage, the whole transformation of raw material 
 being merely housework. In the town economy we indeed 
 find labourers pursuing some special industrial occupa- 
 tion, but entrepreneurs are lacking; industry is either 
 wage-work or handicraft, and he who wishes to ply it must 
 first master it. In national economy industry carried on in 
 factories and under the commission system is preponder- 
 ant; and this presupposes extensive capital and an entre- 
 preneur with mercantile skill. Technical mastery of the 
 process of production by the entrepreneur is not indis- 
 pensable.'* 
 
 " For further details see Chap. VIII. 
 " Comp. Chap IV. 
 
THE RISE OF N/ITIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 145 
 
 In similar fashion a change occurs in the forms under 
 which trade is pursued. Corresponding to the household 
 system is itinerant trade, to town economy market trade, 
 and to national economy trade with permanent establish- 
 ment. If at the first two stages trade is merely supple- 
 mentary to an otherwise autonomous system of produc- 
 tion, it becomes in national economy a necessary link 
 between production and consimiption. It draws away 
 from transportation, which now attains an independent 
 position and organization. 
 
 Commercial services were, to be sure, not lacking in the 
 ancienTsTave and the mediaeval manorial systems; they de- 
 volved upon special slaves or serfs. In the Middle Ages 
 we find town messengers who were originally in the ex- 
 clusive service of the municipal authorities, but later added 
 the carriage of private correspondence. At the threshold 
 of modem times stands the postal service, at first restricted 
 to state purposes, by-and-bye extended to the public. In 
 our century follow the railway, telegraph, telephone, and 
 steamship lines — with which the State interferes in the 
 interest of economy — and along with them the most varied 
 private undertakings for facilitating communication." 
 AfaJlthestages, however, certain commercial services have 
 been organized by the sovereign administration, in the 
 initial instance always for its own special requirements. 
 
 Credit is at the first stage purely consumption credit; 
 and can be obtained only by the person pledging himself 
 and all his property. At the second stage, in the matter of 
 personal credit, servitude for debt is softened to imprison- 
 ment for debt. Along with consumption credit appears a 
 type of credit on the return from immovables which is 
 met in garb of a purchase, and must be considered as the 
 ■ For the analogous development in the newspaper press see Chap. 
 
146 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 normal form of credit under town economy. Business or 
 productive credit, the distinctive form of credit in modern 
 times, is first developed in trade, whence it spreads to 
 every sphere of industrial life. State credit appears in the 
 States of antiquity naturally as a forced loan; in the medi- 
 aeval towns as the sale of annuities and redeemable claims; 
 in the modern States as the disposing of perpetual rents 
 or of redeemable interest-bearing bonds. 
 
 In the domain of public services similar stages may also 
 be pointed out. Legal protection is at first a matter for 
 the clan, later for the feudal lord; in the Middle Ages the 
 towns form districts of separate jurisdiction; at present 
 the enforcement of law and police protection are functions 
 of the State. The same is the case with education. At 
 the first stage education devolves upon the family, as it does 
 to-day still in Iceland. The Roman pccdagogus is a slave. 
 In the Middle Ages it is autonomous household establish- 
 ments, namely, the monasteries, that organize the educa- 
 tional system; later arise the municipal and cathedral 
 schools; peculiar to modem times are the concentration 
 and supervision of instruction in state institutions. This 
 development is even more apparent in the arrangements for 
 defence. Among many peoples still at the stage of eco- 
 nomic isolation each separate house is fortified (for ex- 
 ample, the palisades c' the Malays and Polynesians), and 
 in early medijcval times the manor is protected by wall and 
 moat. At the second economic stage each city is a fort- 
 ress; at the th'rd a few fortifications along the borders 
 secure the whole State. It is sufficiently significant that 
 Louvois, the creator of the first system of border fortifica- 
 tion, was a coiitemporary of Colbert, the founder of mod- 
 ern French national economy. 
 
 These parallels might be multiplied. As in moving into 
 a new building one's first care is to introduce order for 
 
THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 147 
 
 the time being, so with regard to the subject-matter of this 
 chapter no fair-minded person will expect that everything 
 has been exhaustively treated and every detail assigned its 
 proper place. The writer clearly perceives how inade- 
 quately the various phenomena of the two earlier stages 
 of industrial evolution have as yet been worked over, and 
 how very seriously their economic significance still de- 
 mands accurate ascertainment. But for the present it may 
 suffice If we have made clear the regularity of development 
 both generally and in detail. 
 
 Only one thing further would we particularly em- 
 phasize. Household economy, town economy, national 
 economy— these phrases do not denote a series whose 
 terms are mutually exclusive. One kind of economic life 
 has always been the predominant, and in the eyes of con- 
 temporaries the normal, one. Many elements of town 
 economy, and even of independent domestic economy 
 still project into the present. Even to-day a very consid- 
 erable part of the national production does not pass into 
 general circulation, but is consumed in the households 
 where it is produced; another po-tion. again, circulates 
 no farther than from one establishment to another. 
 
 Hence it would almost appear as if those people were 
 in error who regard the task of political economy to be 
 the explanation of the nature and coherence of commercial 
 phenomena, and those right who confine themselves to a 
 descriptior of economic forms and their historical trans- 
 formations. 
 
 Vet that would be a fatal error, involving the sur- 
 render of the scientific labours of over a century, as wHl 
 ar a complete misconception of our economic prosf^nl. 
 To-day not a sack of wheat is produced even on the most 
 remote farm, that is not directly linked to the industrial 
 hfe nf the nation as a whole. Even if it be consumed m 
 
148 
 
 THE RISE OF NATIONAL ECONOMY. 
 
 the house of the producer, nevertheless a large portion of 
 the means of its production (the plough, the scythe, the 
 threshing-machine, the artificial fertilizers, the draught- 
 animals, etc.) is obtained through trade; and the con- 
 sumption of one's own products takes place only when 
 from market conditions it seems economically advisable. 
 Thus the sack of wheat is knit by a strong cord to the great 
 intricate web of national commerce. And so are we all in 
 our every economic thought and deed. 
 
 It is therefore a matter of great satisfaction that, after 
 a period of diligent collection of material, the economic 
 problems of modern commerce have in recent times been 
 zealously taken up again, and that an attempt is being 
 made to correct and develop the old system in the same 
 way in which it arose, with the aid, however, of a much 
 larger store of facts. For the only method of investigation 
 which will enable us to approach the complex causes of 
 commercial phenomena is that of abstract isolation, and 
 logical deduction. The sole inductive process that can 
 likewise be considered, namely, the statistical, is not suffi- 
 ciently exact and penetrating for most of the problems 
 that have to be handled here, and can be employed only 
 to supplement or control. 
 
 For the economic periods of the past the task will not be 
 different. Here, to be sure, it will be even more necessary 
 first to collect the facts and present them according to 
 form and function; next we must gain a proper conception 
 of the nature of the phenomena; and then we may logically 
 dissect them and investigate their casual connection. We 
 will thus have to advance by the same method that " classi- 
 cal political economy " has applied to the industry of the 
 present. For some phases of the economic life of the an- 
 cient oUos this has already been done in a masterful man- 
 ner by Rodbcrtus; for the economic life of the Middle 
 
THE RISE OF N^ITIONML ECONOMY. 
 
 149 
 
 Ages such a task has yet scarcely been essayed. The at- 
 tempt can succeed only with investigators fully able to 
 grasp the actual assumptions of past economic periods 
 and our ancestors' ways of thinking on economic matters; 
 it can but fail if the half understood, half arbitrarily recon- 
 structed economic conditions of the past continue to be 
 reflected in terms of the modem theory of exchange. 
 
 Only in this way, in our opinion, can investigations in 
 economic history and the theory of contemporary eco- 
 nomics be mutually helpful; only thus can we gain a 
 clearer insight into the regularity both of economic devel- 
 opment and of economic phenomena. 
 
 i 
 
CHAPTER IV. 
 
 A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 
 
 In economic and social matters most people have very 
 definite opinions on what should be, often much more 
 definite than on what is. What in their view should be is 
 by no means an ideal state of affairs, an imaginative crea- 
 tion that has never been realized. Very frequently indeed 
 it is a conception drawn from the conditions that prevailed 
 in times more or less remote, which long custom has led 
 us to consider normal. 
 
 Such is the case, if we mistake not, with many of our 
 contemporaries regarding what we call handicraft and the 
 so-called handicraft problem. One has become accus- 
 tomed to look upon handicraft as the normal form of in- 
 dustry, after it has dominated five centuries or more of 
 the life of the burgher class of Germany. The proverb 
 says " Handicraft stands on golden ground "; and obser- 
 vation teaches us that this ground is, according to present- 
 day valuation, no longer golden. We ask ourselves how 
 that happy condition can be restored, how handicraft can 
 be " resuscitated." 
 
 Rut what right has one to regard handicraft as the 
 normal form of industry and thus as it were to strive after 
 an ideal whose realization belongs to the past? 
 
 The earlier political economists represent handicraft as 
 
 the original form of industrial production. " In a tribe of 
 
 150 
 
A HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 151 
 
 hunters or shepherds," says Adam Smith/ " a particular 
 person makes bows and arrows with more readiness and 
 dexterity than any other. He frequently exchanges them 
 for cattle or venison with his companions; and he finds at 
 last that he can in this manner get more cattle and venison 
 than if he himself went to the field to catch them." 
 Finally, " the making of bows and arrows grows to be his 
 chief business and he becomes a sort of armourer." If we 
 follow this historical progress a couple of stages further, 
 the original handicraftsman will after a time probably take 
 an apprentice, and when the latter has learned his trade, a 
 second, while the first becomes his journeyman. 
 
 Seek as we may, we find nothing added by subsequent 
 development. When we speak of a craftsman to-day we 
 have in mind a business undertaker on a small scale, who 
 has passed by regular stages of transition from apprentice 
 to journeyman and from journeyman to master workman, 
 who produces with his own hand and his own capital for 
 a locally limited circle of customers, and into whose hands 
 flows undiminished the whole pi .duct of his labour. 
 Everything that one can demand of an industrial system 
 founded on justice seems realized in the life of the typical 
 craftsman— gradual social progress, independence, an in- 
 come corresponding to services rendered. And those 
 forms of industry that vary from this primal type, namely, 
 house industry and factory production, may readily ap- 
 pear abnormal; and the social stratification of those em- 
 ployed, and the accompanying unequal distribution of 
 income out of harmony with the idea of economic justice. 
 Even later economists are rarely free from this popular 
 conception. In contrasting the three industrial systems 
 that they recognise, handicraft, house industry, and factory 
 
 " Bk. I, ch. 2. 
 
152 A HISTORICAL SURf^EY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 
 
 n P 
 
 production, they almost unwittingly draw from the funda- 
 mental institutions of handicraft the criterion for judging 
 the others. Until quite recently house industry was for 
 many of them merely a degenerate handicraft or a transi- 
 tional form, and the factory a necessary evil of the age of 
 machinery. This narrowness of view was prejudicial to the 
 scientific understanding of even modern industrial meth- 
 ods, open as these are to direct observation. 
 
 An historically constructive view, such as we will here 
 present, must from the start shake off the idea that any 
 particular form in any department of economic activity 
 can be the norm for all times and peoples. Even handi- 
 craft is for it only one phenomenon in the great stream 
 of history, with its origin, continuance, and success de- 
 pendent upon certain given economic conditions. It is 
 neither the original nor even a necessary form in the his- 
 torical evolution of industrial production. It is, in other 
 words, just as little necessary that the industry of a country 
 shall have passed through the handicraft phase before ar- 
 riving at house industry or factory manufacture as that 
 every people shall have been hunters or nomads before 
 passing over to settled agriculture. Among us handicraft 
 has been preceded by other industrial systems, which, in- 
 deed, even in Europe, still exist in part. 
 
 The great historical significance of these primitive in- 
 dustrial forms in the evolution of economic conditions has 
 hitherto been almost wholly ignored, although they shaped 
 for thousands of years the economic life of the nations and 
 left lasting marks upon their social organizations. Only a 
 comparatively small portion of the history of industry, 
 namely, that part which written laws have enabled us to 
 know, has been at all cleared up; and this. too. much more 
 on its formal side than as regards its inner life, its method 
 of operation. Even the guild handicraft of the Middle 
 
■ 
 
 M HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 153 
 
 Ages, to which in recent times so much persevering and 
 penetrating labour has been devoted, has, on the side of 
 its actual operation, enjoyed scarcely more accurate in- 
 vestigation. In this domain arbitrary theoretical con- 
 structions based upon the postulates and concepts of 
 modern commercial economy still widely prevail. 
 
 Our " historical " political enonomy, it is true, has a 
 wealth of material for the economic history of the classical 
 and modem peoples. But it has hardly yet been duly 
 noted that the complex nature of all social phenomena ren- 
 ders it just as difficult for the investigator of to-day to re- 
 construct the economic conditions of the life of the na- 
 tions of antiquity and of the Middle Ages as to forecast 
 even with the most lively and powerful imagination the 
 ultimate consequences of the " socialist State of the fu- 
 ture." We shall not arrive at an understanding of whole 
 epochs of early economic history until we study the eco- 
 nomic side of the life of primitive and uncivilized peoples 
 of the present with the care we to-day devote to English- 
 men and Americans. Instead of sending our young politi- 
 cal economists on journeys of investigation to these latter, 
 we should rather send them to the Russians, the Rumani- 
 ans, or the South Slavs; we should study the characteristic 
 features of primitive economic life and the legal concep- 
 tions of the peoples of our newly acquired colonies before 
 such features and conceptions disappear under the influ- 
 ence of European trade. 
 
 It is almost a fortunate circumstance that such external 
 influences rarely aflFect deeply the real life of the people, 
 but are confined chiefly to the more privileged classes. 
 Hence it is that in extensive regions of eastern and north- 
 ern Europe, which the unheeding traveller courses 
 through by rail, there may still be observed among the 
 
154 A HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 
 
 rural population primiiive forms of production that mod- 
 em commerce has caused to vary but slightly. 
 
 In the attempt made in the following pages to give a 
 compact presentation of what we know of the industrial 
 methods of "-uch " backward " tribes and the present C' n- 
 clusions of industrial history, our sole aim is to present 
 in clear outline the chief stages of development.* In or- 
 der to have a guiding thread through the perplexing va- 
 riety and wealth of forms of individual ethnographical 
 observations, it is most necessary to separate i} ^lical and 
 casual, to disregard subsidiary and transitional forms, and 
 to consider a new phase of development as beginning only 
 where changes in industrial technique call forth economic 
 phenomena that imply a radical alteration in the organ- 
 ization of society. In this way we arrive at five main sys- 
 tems of industrj-. In historical succession they are: 
 
 1. Housework (Domestic Work). 
 
 2. Wage-work. 
 
 3. Handicraft. 
 
 4. Commission Work (House Industry). 
 
 5. Factory Work. 
 
 We shall first attempt to give a concise outline of 
 the characteristic economic peculiarities of these indus- 
 trial systems, merely indicating the socio-historical im- 
 port of the whole development. The filling out of oc- 
 casional gaps and the explanation of the transitions from 
 one system to the other may be left to detailed investiga- 
 tion. In our sketch we shall, naturally, devote most time 
 to the two industrial systems precedent to handicraft, 
 
 'The present sketch brings together in popular form only the most 
 important features. Further discussion, and references to the most 
 essential literature, will be found in my article under the head " Ge- 
 werbe" in the Handwort. der Staatswiss. (2d ed.), IV, pp. 360-393. 
 
A HISTORICAL SURyEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 155 
 
 while for the later a brief account may suffice. We begin 
 with housework.' 
 
 Housework is industrial production in and for the house 
 from raw materials furnished by the household itself. In 
 its original and purest form it presupposes the absence 
 of exchange, and the ability of each household to satisfy 
 by its own labour the wants of its members. Each com- 
 modity passes through all the stages of production in the 
 establishment in which it is to be consumed. Production 
 is consequently undertaken only according to the needs of 
 the house itself. There is still neither circulation of goods 
 nor capital. The wealth of the house consists entirely in 
 consumption goods in various stages of completion, such 
 as corn, meal, bread, flax, yarn, cloth, and clothes. It also 
 possesses auxiliary means of production, such as the hand- 
 mill, the :i <e, the distafif, and the weaver's loom, but no 
 goods with which it could procure other goods by pro- 
 cess of exchange. All it has it owes to its own lalwur, 
 
 ' It is from Norway and Sweden that the expression HausAeiss 
 (housework) has been transplanted into Germany, where during the 
 last twenty years it has become current. In those countries it was 
 employed for certain occupations of the members of the domestic 
 circle, such as spinning, weaving, sewing, the making of wooden 
 utensils, and tl. ° like. It is the application of industrial technique 
 that, favoured by climate and settlement, has from early times become 
 indigenous in those parts. Through it the peasant household works 
 up for its own use the raw material from field and wood. As this 
 technique threatened to disappear under the influence of modern com- 
 mercial conditions it was the opinion in Denmark and Norway that 
 it should he reanimated through school instruction. Few, indeed, of 
 the promoters of manual instruction — this new branch of instruction, 
 whose pedagogical importance cannot be denied— have formed a clear 
 conception of what housework really signified and in part still signifies 
 for the Northern peoples. Here and there, especially at its inaugura- 
 tion, manual tr ining was regarded as a means for establishing new 
 house industries. But housework and house industry are two indus- 
 trial systems separated historically from one another (at least among 
 us) by two centuries. 
 
156 A HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 
 
 aiul it is scarcely possible to separate the operations of the 
 household from those of production. 
 
 In the fonn of housework, intlustry is older than agri- 
 culture. Wherever explorers of new countries have come 
 into contact with primitive peoples, they have found many 
 forms of industrial skill, such as the making of bow and 
 arrow, the wea\ mg of mats and vessels out of reeds, bast, 
 and tough roots, a primitive pottery, tanning skins, crush- 
 ing farinaceous strains on the grinding-stone, smelting 
 iron ore, the building of houses. To-day the huntini, 
 tribes of Norti< America, the tisher tribes of the South Se;i 
 the nomad hordes of Siberia, and the agricultural neg-^ 
 tribes of Africa make similar display of varied technical 
 skill without possessi ig actual artisans. Even the wretched 
 naked forest tribes of Central Brazil make their clubs and 
 bows and arrows, build houses and >ark canoes, make 
 tools of bone and stoae, weave baskets for carrying and 
 storing, scoop out gourd dishes, spin, knit, and weave, 
 form artistically ornamented clay vessels without a knowl- 
 edge of the potter's wheel, carve ornamented digging- 
 sticks, stools, flutes, combs, and masks, and prepare many 
 kinds of ornaments out of feathers, skins, etc. 
 
 In the temperate and colder countries with the advance 
 to the use of the plough, this activity loses more and more 
 the character of the accidental; the whole husbandry ac- 
 quires a settled character; the mild period of the year must 
 be devoted to the procuring of raw material and to out- 
 door work: in winter the working up of this material 
 clusters the members of the household around the hearth. 
 For each kind of work there is developed a definite method 
 which is incorporated into the domestic life according to 
 the natural and imperative demand; of economy; about it 
 custom weaves its fine golden ethical thread: it enriches 
 and ennobles the lite of men among whom, with its sim- 
 
A HtSTORIC/iL SURREY OF INDUSTRI/1L SYSTEMS. 157 
 
 4 
 
 pie technique and archaic forms, it is transmitted from gen- 
 eration to generation. As people labour only for their 
 own requirements, the interest of the producer in the work 
 of his hands long survives the completion r i the work. His 
 highest technical skill and his whole ariistic sense are em- 
 bodied in it. It is for this reason that the products of do- 
 ■^estic work throughout Germany have become for our 
 v. of artistic industry such a rich mine of models of pop- 
 u a style. 
 
 '' le Norwegian peasant is not merely his own smith and 
 j ; ler, like the Westphalian Hofschulzc in Immermann's 
 ' Munchhauset. "; with his own hands he also builds his 
 V joden house, makes his field-implements, wagons and 
 ■sleighs, tans leather, carves from wood various kinds of 
 'louse utensils, and even makes metal ones." In Iceland 
 the very peasants" are skilful workers in silver. In the 
 Highlands of Scotland, up to the close of last century, 
 every man was his own weaver, fuller, tanner, and shoe- 
 maker. In Galicia and Bukowina, in many parts of Hun- 
 gary and Siebenbiirgen, in Rumania, and among the 
 southern Slav peoples there could scar ely be found, down 
 to recent times, any other craftsman than the smith, and 
 he was usually a gypsy. In Greece and other lands of the 
 Balkan peninsula the only additional craftsmen were oc- 
 casional vandering builders.'' Numberless examples of a 
 
 'Eile I Sundt. Om Hu.1iden i Norge (Christiania, 1867). Blom, Das 
 Konign .\on.'ege» (Leipzig, 1843), P- 237. Forester, Xoru<ay in 
 i84f end 1849 (London, 1850), p. 113. E- Sidenbladh. Schweden, Statist. 
 Mitteiiungen s. ll'icner IVeltausstellung, 1873. 
 
 •[Dr. Biicher is evidenUy speaking of the Icelandic peasant of an 
 earlier time. — En.] 
 
 ' On the Austrian populations compare Die Hausmduslrie Oesterreichs. 
 Ein Kommcntar z. hausindustrieUen Abteilung auf d. allgemeinen land- u. 
 forJ.wirtschaftlich. Ausstdluug su IV'"*!. 1890, ed. by W. Exner; also 
 Oesterreichische Monatsschritt fiir Gesellschaftswissenschaft, IV, 
 90 ff.. VIII, 22. IX. 98 and 331; A. Riegl, Textile hausindustrie in 
 
f?>.ti 
 
 158 A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 
 
 similar kind might be adduced from other peoples. The 
 wonderful adroitness and dexterity of the Russian and 
 Swedish peasants, to cite a striking instance, has its un- 
 doubted origin in the varied technical tasks of their own 
 households. The industrial employments of women in 
 ancient and modern times, such as spinning, weaving, bak- 
 ing, etc., are too well known to call for further reference. 
 
 In order to obtain an idea of the wealth of domestic in- 
 dustrial skill that charactenzes the life of less civilized peo- 
 ples a detailed description would be necessary. Lack of 
 space unfortunately forbids that here. It will suffice, how- 
 ever, to reproduce the following sentences from an account 
 of household work in Bukowina:* 
 
 •' In the narrow circle of the family, or at least within 
 the limits of his little village, the Bukowina countryman 
 supplies all his own necessaries. In building a house the 
 husband, as a rule, can do the work of carpenter, roofer, 
 etc., while the wife must attend to plastering the woven 
 and slatted walls or stopping the chinks in the log wa..:> 
 with moss, pounding out of the floor, and many other 
 dilated duties. From the cultivation of the plant from 
 which cloth is spun or the raising of sheep down to the 
 
 Oesterreich in the Mi.tciluPgT. d. k. k. tistcrreich. Museums, New 
 Series, IV, pp. .,11 ff.; Braar und Krejesi. Der Hausdeiss in Ungarn 
 (Leipzig, 1886); Schwic'<cr, i:tatistik d. Kbnigreichs Vngarn, pp. 403 ff-. 
 411, 426 flf.; J. Tanet, Luiartt u. Siebcnburgen (Leipzig, 184^), H, pp. 
 i6j! 173. 264. J69; Franz Joseph Prinz \->n BaUenberg, Die I'olks- 
 wirtschafll EntwicMung Hulgaricns (Leipzig, iSgi. ; Iwantschoff, 
 Primitive Formen d. Ccwerbcbctriebs in liulgaricn (Leipzig, 1896). On 
 the other lands of the Balkan peninsula sec Reports from Her Majesty's 
 Diflomalic and Consular Agents Abroad, respecting the Condition ot the 
 Industrial Classes in Foreign Countries (London, 1870-72); Tarajanz, 
 Das Ceu'erbe bei d. Armeniern (Leipzig, 1897): Petri, Ehstland u. d. 
 Ehslcn (r.ntli.i. i«o.'). II. pp. 2,10- 1. 
 
 "C. A. RomMorfcr in Kxner, Die llausinduslrie Oesterreuhs. pp. 
 iSOfT. Comp. H. Wiglitzky. Die Uukoumacr I'ausindustrie u. d. MiUtl 
 N. IVege :. Hebung derselb. (Czernowitz, 1888). 
 
A HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 159 
 
 making of bed and other clothes out of linen, wool or furs, 
 leather, felt, or plaited straw, the Bukowina country folk 
 produce everything, including dyes from plants of their 
 own culture, as well as the necessary though, indeed, ex- 
 tremely primitive utensils. The same holds in general 
 of the food-supply. With a rather heavy expenditure of 
 labour the peasant cultivates his field of maize, and with 
 his handmill grinds the kukuruz meal used by him in bak- 
 ing mamaliga, his chief article of food, which resembles 
 polenta. His simple farming implements, the dishes and 
 utensils for household and kitchen, he, or, if not he, some 
 self-taught villager, is also able to make. The working of 
 iron, alone, a substance that the native population uses in 
 exceedingly small quantities, he generally leaves to the 
 gypsies scattered through the country." 
 
 Yet whatever the industrial skill developed by the self- 
 sufficing household, such a method of supply was destined 
 to prove inadequate when the household diminished to the 
 smaller cii ' ? of blood-relations, which we call the family. 
 The ancient family group, it is true, was broader than our 
 present family; but just at the time when wants are in- 
 creasing in extent and variety, the tribal organization of 
 many peoples breaks down and a more minute division of 
 labour among the members of the househo]<l is rendered 
 iinnossible. The transition to specialized production and 
 a system of exchange would at this point have been un- 
 avoidable had it not been possible, by adopting slaves or 
 by utilizing serf labour, to enlarge artificially the house- 
 hold circle. The greater the number of these unfrce mem- 
 bers of ti.c household, the easier it is to introduce a varied 
 division of labour among them atul to train each person 
 for a definite industrial employment. 
 
 Thus we find among the house-slaves of the wealthy 
 
I tl 
 
 l6o A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 
 
 Greeks and Romans industrial workers of various kinds;* 
 and in the famous instructions of Charles the Great regard- 
 ing the management of his country estates we have definite 
 rules prescribing what kinds of unfree workers shall be 
 maintained at each villa. " Each steward," we read, 
 " shall have in his service good workmen, such as smiths, 
 workers in gold and silver, shoemakers, turners, car- 
 penters, shield-makers, fishers, fowlers, soap-boilers, brew- 
 ers of mead {siccratorcs), bakers, and net-makers," Co- 
 pious evidence of a similar kind is available for the manors 
 of the nobility and the monasteries. The handicraftsmen 
 maintained by them are at their exclusive service; in some 
 cases they are merely domestic servants receiving their 
 board and lodging in the manor-house, in others they are 
 settled and gain their living on their own holdings, and in 
 return render villein services in that branch of labour in 
 which they have special skill. In token that they are en- 
 gaged to hold their skill at the service of the manor, they 
 bear the title ofUcialcs, ofliciati, i.e., officials. 
 
 Hou.sework, we see, has here obtained an extensive or- 
 ganization, which allows the lord of the manor a relatively 
 large and varied consumption of industrial products. 
 
 But housework does not remain mere production for 
 direct consumption. At a very early stage inequality of 
 natural endowment causes a varied development of techni- 
 cal skill. One tribe produces pottery, stone implements, or 
 arrows, and a neighbouring tribe does not. Such industrial 
 products are then scattered among other tribes as gifts 
 of hospitality, or as spoils of war. and later as the objects 
 of exchange." .\mong the ancient Greeks wealthy slave- 
 owners cansed a considerable number of their dependent 
 
 •Comp H. Fr.incotte, l.'lnduslric dans la Crhc andenne, I (Briissels. 
 iqoo); Walloti, Hist, de Uisclavagc dans I /InliquiU ( 2(\ cd.. Vans, iS/g). 
 • Comp. above, pp. 54 IT. 
 
A HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. i6i 
 
 labourers, whom they did not need for their o»vn estates, to 
 be trained for a special industry, and then to produce for 
 the market. In a similar fashion peasant families exchange 
 the surplus products of their household industry more fre- 
 quently than the surpluses from their apfriculture or cattle- 
 raising. As in the Old Testament it is one of the good 
 qualities of the virtuous wife to dispose of the wares that 
 her own hands have produced,** so to-day the negro wife in 
 Central Africa carries to the weekly market the pots or 
 basketware she produces in order to exchange them for 
 salt or pearls. In like manner, in many parts of Germany 
 the rural population have from the beginning of the 
 Middle Ages sold their linen cloths at the town mar- 
 kets and fairs; and in the era of mercantilism measures 
 were taken by the government in Silesia and West- 
 phalia to facilitate the export of home-made linen. So 
 also in the Baltic provinces during the Middle Ages the 
 coarse woollen cloth, Vadhmal, which is still woven by the 
 peasant women, was one of the best known articles of 
 trade, and actually served as money. Similarly among 
 many African peoples domestic products made by neigh- 
 bouring tribes serve as general mediums of exchange. In 
 almost every villager's house in Japan yarn is spun and 
 cloth woven out of cotton grown in his own fields, and of 
 this a portion comes into exchange. In Sweden the West 
 Goths and Smalanders wander through almost the whole 
 country offering for sale home-woven stuffs. In Hungary, 
 Galicia, Rumania, and the southern Slav countries. ever>'- 
 where one can meet with pe.i'^ants oflfering for sale at the 
 weekly town markets their earthen and wooden wares, and 
 peasant women selling, along with vegetables and eggs, 
 aprons, embroidered ribbons, and laces which they them- 
 .«elves have made. 
 
 ' F. Buhl, Dit social I'crhdltnisse d IsratUtcn (LeipziR, iftyK), p. 34, 
 
 wmm 
 
■ 
 
 i62 A HISTORICAL SURyEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 
 
 It is especially when the land owned by a family be- 
 comes divided up and no longer suffices for its mainte- 
 nance, that a part of the rural population take up a special 
 branch of housework and produce for the market in ex- 
 actly the same way as our small peasants in South Ger- 
 many produce wine, hops, or tobacco. At first the neces- 
 sary raw material is gained from their own land or 
 drawn from the communal forests; later on, if need be, it 
 is also purchased. All sorts of allied branches of produc- 
 tion are added ; and thus there develops out of housework, 
 as in many parts of Russia, an endlessly varied system of 
 peasant industry on a small scale. 
 
 But the evolution may take another course, and an in- 
 dependent professional class of industrial labourers arise, 
 and with them our second industrial system — zvage-work. 
 Whereas all industrial skill has hitherto been exercised in 
 close association with property in land and tillage, the 
 adept house-labourer now frees himself from this associa- 
 tion, and upon his technical skill founds for himself an ex- 
 istence that gradually becomes independent of property 
 in land. But he has only his simple tools for work; he has 
 no business capital. He therefore always exercise^ his 
 skill upon raw material furnished him by the producer of 
 the raw material, who is at the same time the consumer of 
 the finished product. 
 
 Here again two distinct forms of this relationship 
 are possible. In one ca.se the wage-worker is taken tem- 
 porarily into the house, receives his board and, if he does 
 not belong to the place, his lodging as well, together with 
 the daily wage; and leaves when the needs of his customer 
 are satisfied. In South Germany we call this going on 
 one's itinerancy iuuf die Star j^chcn), and may accordingly 
 designate the wlmle industrial phase as that of ititirrancy 
 (Stor), and the labourer carrying on work in this manner 
 
A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 163 
 
 as the itinerata (Storer). The dressmakers and seam- 
 stresses wham our women in many places are accustomed 
 to take inter the house may serve as an illustration. 
 
 On the otijcr hand, the wage-worker may have his own 
 place of business, and the raw material be given out to him. 
 For working it iip he receives piece-work wage. In the 
 country the linen-weaver, the miller, and the baker work- 
 ing for a wage are examples. We will designate this form 
 of work home work.'' It is met with chiefly in industries 
 that demand permanent means of production difficult to 
 transport, such as mills, ovens, weavers' looms, forges, etc. 
 
 Both forms of wage-work are still very common in all 
 parts of the world. Examples might be drawn from In- 
 dia and Japan, from Morocco and the Sudan, and from 
 almost all European countries. The system can be traced 
 m Babylonian temple records and in ancient Egypt; it can 
 be followed in literature from Homer down through an- 
 cient and mediaeval times to the present day. The whole 
 conception of the relation of the customer to the independ- 
 ent (personally free or unfree) artisan in early Greek and 
 Roman law rests upon wage-work; »° and only by it are 
 numerous ordinances of mediaeval guild law to be ex- 
 plained. 
 
 In the .\lpine lands it is still the predominant industrial 
 method in the country. The Styrian writer P. K. Roseg- 
 ger lias, in an interesting book, •> given a picture of his ex- 
 periences as apprentice to a peripatetic tailor carrying on 
 his trade among the peasants. " The peasant craftsmen," 
 * Heimwtrk. 
 
 " in Diocletian's edict de pretiis rtrum venaHum of the year 301 it 
 appears as the prevailing industrial form. Comp. my articles in the 
 dit ges. Slaatswissenschaft. 
 
 67.1 flr. 
 
 "A 
 Jakob 
 H'ilde 
 
 SO (1894), especially pp 
 
 4us meinem Handwerk 
 Schnetballen, F 
 Kirschen, p. 347. 
 
 •erleben (LeipziR. 1880). C^ 
 
 Series (Popular Ed ). pp. 12-ij. 
 
 omp. also Hans- 
 
 219-224. 
 
i64 A HISTORICAL SURyEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 
 
 he says in the preface, " such as the cobbler, the tailor, the 
 weaver, the cooper (in other places also the saddler, the 
 wheelwright, the carpenter, and, in general, all artisan 
 builders), are in many Alpine districts a sort of nomad folk. 
 Each of them has, indeed, a definite abode somewhere, 
 either in his own little house or in the rented room of a 
 peasant's home, where his family lives, where he has safe- 
 keeping for his possessions, and where he spends his Sun- 
 days and holidays. On Monday morning, however, he puts 
 his tools upon his back or in his pocket and starts out upon 
 his rounds; that is, he goes out for work and takes up his 
 quarters in the home of the peasant by whom he has been 
 engaged, and there remains until he has satisfied the 
 household needs. Then he wends his way to another farm. 
 The handicraftsman in his temporary abode is looked upon 
 as belonging to the family." Every peasant's house has a 
 special room with a " handicraftsman's bed " for his 
 quarters overnight; wherever he has been working during 
 the week, he is invited to Sunday dinner. 
 
 We find described in almost the same words the indus- 
 trial conditions of rural Sweden and many parts of Nor- 
 way. In Russia and the southern Slav countries there are 
 hundreds of thousands of wage-workers, belonging espe- 
 cially to the building and clothing trades, who lead a con- 
 tinuous migratory life and who, on account of the great 
 distances travelled, often remain away from home half a 
 year or more. 
 
 From the point of view of development these two forms 
 of wage-work have different origins. Itinerant labour is 
 based upon the exclusive possession of aptitude for a spe- 
 cial kind of work, homework upon the exchisive posses- 
 sion of fixed means of production. Upon this basis there 
 now arises all sorts of mixed forms between housework 
 and wage-work. 
 
A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 165 
 
 The itinerant labourer is at first an experienced neigh- 
 bour whose advice is sought in carrying out an important 
 piece of work, the actual work, however, still being per- 
 formed by the members of the household.^^ ^^^^ j^j^j. j^ 
 is long the practice for the members of the customer's 
 family to give the necessary assistance to the craftsman 
 and his journeyman; and this is still met with in the 
 country, for example, in the raising of a frame building. 
 
 In the case of hontezvork the later tradesman is at first 
 merely the owner of the business plant and technical 
 director of the production, the customer doing the actual 
 work. This frequently remains true in the country to-day 
 with oil-presses, flax-mills, mills for husking barley and 
 oats, and cider-mills. 
 
 In many North German towns the mediaeval maltsters 
 and brewers were merely the owners of malt-kilns and 
 brewing-houses, who for a fee gave the citizens the 
 opportunity of malting their own barley and brewing their 
 own beer. In the flour-mills the customer at least sup- 
 plied the handler who attended to the sifting of the meal. 
 Even to-day it is customary in many localities for the 
 peasant's wife, after kneading the dough, to mould the 
 bread-loaves in her own house; the baker simply places 
 his oven at her disposal, heats it and attends to the baking. 
 In French and western Swiss towns the public washing 
 places are managed in much the same fashion, merely pro- 
 
 "The same is true of house-building in the Caroline Islands, where 
 the takelbay, or master builder, is scarcely more than the exerciser of 
 the evil powers that threaten the new structure. Sec Kubary, Ethnogr. 
 Beitrdge, pp. 227 ff. The case is different with wagon-building in 
 Armenia, where the skilled neighbour, in return for a present, directs 
 the putting together of the vehicle after the separate parts have been 
 made ready by the members of the household: Tarajanz, as above, 
 p. 27. Similarly with house-building in Faror; Ztschr. d. Ver. f. 
 Volksk.. Ill (1893), p. 163. 
 
I 
 
 II 
 ■lill 
 
 ' V 
 
 i66 yt HISTORJCAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 
 
 viding their customers with washing-apparatus and hot 
 water, and frequently a drying-place in addition, while the 
 work is done by the servants or female members of the 
 customer's household. These afterwards bring the washed 
 and dried linen to the mangle to be smoothed out, in which 
 process the owner assists by working the handle. Pay- 
 ment is made by the hour. In Posen and West Prussia 
 until recently it was the custom for the owner of a smithy 
 merely to supply fire, tools, and iron, leaving the actual 
 work to his customers.^' 
 
 From the economic point of view the essential feature of 
 the wage-work system is that there is no business capital. 
 Neither the raw material nor the finished industrial 
 product is for its producer ever a means of profit. 
 The character and extent of the production are still deter- 
 mined in every case by the owner of the soil, who pro- 
 duces the raw material; he also superintends the whole 
 process of production. The peasant grows, threshes, and 
 cleans the rye and then turns it over to the miller to be 
 ground, paying him in kind; the meal is given to the 
 baker, who delivers, on receipt of a baker's wage and in- 
 demnification for the firing, a certain number of loaves 
 made from it. From the sowing of the seed until the mo- 
 ment the bread is consumed the product has never been 
 
 " F.rlcbnisse ewes Geistlichen im iistl. Grensgebiet. in the Tagl. Rund- 
 schau, L'nterh. Beilage. 1879. Mo 2S8. A point of interest here is 
 the supplying of the iron by the owner of the business, this method 
 of carrying on work thus forming a transition to handicraft. There 
 are also forms in which itinerancy and homework are mingled. To 
 this class belongs the Russian migratory tailor, who in each vil- 
 lage where he has customers rents a room for a time and does work 
 for wages. So also, according to Tarajanz, the silversmiths in Ar- 
 menia. In the latter country the owner of an oil-press has to provide 
 his machine, the necessary uirkmen. and the oxen for drivitig it; the 
 customer not only assists in the work himself, but he pays, and also 
 boards, the workmen and supplies the fodder for the oxen. 
 
A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 167 
 
 capital, but always a mere article for use in course of prep- 
 aration. No earnings of management and interest charges 
 or middleman's profits attach to the finished product, but 
 only wages for work done. 
 
 Under certain social conditions, «nd where needs are 
 very simple, this is a thoroughly economic method of pro- 
 duction and, like housework, secures the excellence of the 
 product and the complete adjustment of supply to demand. 
 It avoids exchange, where this would lead only to a round- 
 about method of supplying the producer of the raw mate- 
 rial with wares prepared from his own products. But it 
 also forces the consumer to run the risk attaching to indus- 
 trial production, as only those needs that can be foreseen 
 can find suitable and prompt satisfaction, while a sudden 
 need must often remain unsatisfied because the wage- 
 worker happens at the very time to be elsewhere engaged. 
 In the case of homework there is the additional danger 
 that a portion of the material furnished may be embezzled 
 or changed. The system has also many disadvantages for 
 the wage-worker. Amongst these are the inconveniences 
 and loss of time suffered in his itinerancy from place to 
 place; also the irregularity of employment, which leads 
 now to the overwork, now to the complete idleness, of the 
 workman. Both forms of wage-work thus act satisfac- 
 torily only when the unoccupied hours can be turned to 
 account in some allied branch of agriculture. 
 
 In the Middle Ages, when this could be done, wage- 
 work greatly facilitated the emancipation of the artisan 
 from serfdom and feudal obligations, as it requires prac- 
 tically no capital to start an independent business. It is a 
 great mistake still common to look upon the class of 
 guild handicraftsmen of the Middle Ages as a class of small 
 capitalists. It was in essence rather an industrial labour- 
 ing class, distinguished from the labourers of to-day by the 
 

 i68 A HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 
 
 fact that each worked not for a single employer but for a 
 large number of consumers. The supplying of the mate- 
 rial by the customer is common to almost all mediaeval 
 liandicrafts; in many instances, indeed, it continues for 
 centuries, even after the customer has ceased to produce 
 the raw material himself and must buy it, as, for example, 
 the leather for the shoemaker and the cloth for the tailor. 
 The furnishing of the material by the master workman is a 
 practice that takes slow root; at first it holds only for the 
 poorer customers, but later for the wealthy as well. Thus 
 arises handicraft in the sense in which it is generally under- 
 stood to-day; but alongiide it wage-work maintains 
 itself for a long time, even entering, in many cases, into 
 the service of handicraft. Thus the tanner is wage-worker 
 for the shoemaker and saddler, the miller for the baker, the 
 wool-beater, the dyer, and the fuller wage-workers for the 
 cloth-maker. 
 
 In the towns itinerancy is the first of the two forms 
 of wage-work to decline. This decline is considerably 
 hastened by the interference of the guilds.** The itiner- 
 ancy was too suggestive of early villenage. In it the 
 workman is, so to speak, only a special kind of day- 
 labourer, who must temporarily become a subordinate 
 member of another household. Consequently from the 
 fourteenth century on we find the guild ordinances fre- 
 quently prohibiting the master from working in private 
 houses. To the same cause is to be ascribed the hatred 
 
 " In this connection it may not be out of place to point out that, 
 in the industrial limitation of those entitled to the privilcRes of the 
 guild, the old housework was at the same time aflfected. In very many 
 of the guild ordinances we find the regulation that the non-guildsman 
 may do handicraftsman's work, but only in so far as the needs of his 
 household demand, not for purposes of sale. The surplus house pro- 
 duction for the market described above (pp. i6o, i6l) was thereby 
 made impossible. 
 
A HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 169 
 
 displayed by the town craftsmen towards those of the 
 country, because the migratory labour of the latter could 
 not well be forbidden. Eventually itinerant or botcher^'" 
 becomes a general term of contempt for those who work 
 without regular credentials from the guilds. In the North 
 German towns the guild masters claimed the right of en- 
 tering the houses of their customers to ferret out the itiner- 
 ant artisans and call them to account, — the so-called 
 " botcherhunt "; and the public authorities were often 
 weak enough to wink at this breach of the domestic rights 
 of the citizen. 
 
 But the guilds did not everywhere have such an easy 
 task in supplanting one industrial system by another. As 
 early as the middle of the fourteenth century the sovereign 
 authority in the Austrian duchy takes vigorous measures 
 against them. In the statutes of the electorate of Saxony 
 for the year 1482 shoemakers, tailors, furriers, joiners, 
 glaziers, and other handicraftsmen who shall refuse with- 
 out sufficient reason to work in the house of their cus- 
 tomer are made liable to a fine of three florins, a high sum 
 for those times. In Basel a definite statute governing 
 house tailors was enacted in 1526 for the maintenance of 
 " ancient and honourable customs." In many German ter- 
 ritories definite ordinances were made regulating the 
 charges of the various kinds of wage-workers. Thus in 
 many crafts, especially in the building trade, wage-work 
 has persisted down to the present time. 
 
 In the majority, however, its place has been taken by 
 the industrial system that to-day is customarily desig- 
 nated handicraft, whose nature we have indicated at the 
 beginning of the present* chapter. It might also be called 
 pricc-zvork,^^ which would mark the contrast with wage- 
 
 " Bonhast. 
 " Prciswerk. 
 
Miarocorv rbmution test chart 
 
 (ANSI ond ISO TEST CHART No 2) 
 
 A 
 
 /APPLIED INA^GE 
 
 'eS] foil Main StrMi 
 »0<:hMl»r. N«« torh U609 IJ« 
 ("6) »a2 - 0300 Phon« 
 ("6) JM 5»g9 - ro. 
 
nr 
 
 m 
 
 i 
 I 
 
 170 y4 HISTORIC/IL SURREY OF INDUSTRJylL SYSTEMS. 
 
 work. For the handicraftsman is distinguished from the 
 wage-worker only by the fact that he possesses all the 
 means of production, and sells for a definite price the fin- 
 ished article which is the product of his own raw material 
 and his own incorporated labour, while the wage-worker 
 merely receives a recompense for his labour. 
 
 All the important characteristics of handicraft may be 
 summed up in the single expression custom production. It 
 is the method of sale that distinguishes this industrial sys- 
 tem from all later ones. The handicraftsman always works 
 for the consumer of his product whether it be that the 
 latter by placing separate orders affords the occasion for 
 the work, or that the two meet at the weekly or yearly 
 market. Ordered work and work for the market must 
 supplement each other if " dull times " are to be avoided. 
 As a rule the region of sale is local, namely, the town and 
 its more immediate neighbourhood. The customer buys 
 at first hand, the handicraftsman sells to the actual con- 
 sumer. This assures a proper adjustment of supply and 
 demand and introduces an ethical feature into the whole 
 relationship; the producer in the presence of the con- 
 sumer feels responsibility for his work. 
 
 With the rise of handicraft a wide cleft, so to speak, 
 appears in the economic process of production. Hitherto 
 the owner of the land, though perhaps calling in the aid 
 of other wage-workers, had conducted this whole process; 
 now there are two classes of economic activity, each of 
 which embraces only a part of the process of production, 
 one producing the raw material, the other the manu- 
 factured article. It is a principle that handicraft endeav- 
 oured to carry out wherever possible — an article should 
 pass through all the stages of its f)reparation in the same 
 workshop. In this way the needed capital is diminished 
 and frecjuent additions of profit to price avoided. Bv the 
 
A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 171 
 
 acquisition of an independent business capital the artisan 
 class is changed from a mere wage-earning class of labour- 
 ers into a capitalistic producing class; and the movable 
 property now, dissociated from land-ownership, accumu- 
 lates in its hands and becomes the basis of an independent 
 social and political reputability which is embodied in the 
 burgher class. 
 
 The direct relationship between the handicraftsman and 
 the consumer of his products makes it necessary that the 
 business remain small. Whenever any one line of handi- 
 craft threatens to become too large, new handicrafts split 
 off from it and appropriate part of its sphere of produc- 
 tion. This is the medieval division of labour,'^ which con- 
 tinually creates new and independent trades and which led 
 later to that jealous delimitation of the spheres of work 
 that caused a large portion of the energy of the guild 
 system to be consumed in internal bickerings. 
 
 Handicraft is a phenomenon peculiar to the town. Peo- 
 ples which, like the Russians, have developed no real town 
 life, know likewise no national handicraft. And tlis also 
 explains why, with the formation of large centralized 
 States and unified commercial territories, handicraft was 
 doomed to decline. In the seventeenth and eighteenth 
 centuries there was developed a new industrial system, 
 based no longer on the local but on the national and inter- 
 national market. Our ancestors have denoted this sys- 
 tem by the two names manufactories and factories, without 
 distinguishing between the two terms. When viewed 
 more closely these are seen to indicate two quite distinct 
 industrial systems. The one hitherto characterized by the 
 misleading phrase house industry we prefer to call the com- 
 
 " For details sec my work, Pit Bnolkerung von Frankfurt a. M im 
 Xir. und AT. Jahrhundcrt, I. p. jj8. Compare also Chapters III .ind 
 VIII. 
 
172 A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 
 
 mission systcm,^^ the other is our factory system. Both 
 systems undertake the work of supplying a wide market 
 with industrial products, and both require for this purpose 
 a large number of labourers; they diflfer only in the man- 
 ner in which they accomplish the work and organize the 
 labourers. 
 
 In this respect the method of the commission system 
 is the simplest. In the first place, it leaves the exist- 
 ing method of production quite undisturbed and confines 
 itself to organizing the market. The business undertaker 
 is a commercial entrepreneur who regularly employs a 
 large number of labourers in their own homes, away from 
 his place of business. These labourers are either former 
 handicraftsmen who now produce for a single tradesman 
 instead of for a number of consumers, or former wage- 
 workers who now receive their raw material, not from the 
 consumer, but from the merchant; or, finally, they are 
 peasant families, the former products of whose domestic 
 work are now produced as market wares and by the en- 
 trepreneur introduced into the markets of the world. 
 
 In some cases the entrepreneur advances *® to the small 
 producers, who at first enjoy a fairly independent position, 
 the purchase price of their products; in some cases he fur- 
 nishes them with the raw material, and then pays piece- 
 work wage; while in others he owns even the principal 
 machinery, such as the weaver's loom, the embroidering 
 machine, etc. As the small producers have only the one 
 customer they graduall\ sink into ever-greater depend- 
 ence. The entrepreneur becomes their employer, and they 
 are employees, even when they supply the raw material 
 themselves. 
 
 It is scarcely necessary fo describe in detail the 
 
 "I'crlag. 
 
 " 1 crlcgcr cunies from I crlag, i.e. supplying or advancing. 
 
A HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 173 
 
 commission system and its contingent method of work, 
 house industry. We have plenty of examples in tho moun- 
 tain districts of Germany, for instance, the straw-plating 
 and the clock and brush industries in the Black Forest, the 
 wood-carving of Upper Bavaria, the toy manufacture in 
 the Meiningen Oberland,the embroidery of the Voigtland, 
 the lace-making of the Erzgebirge, etc. The history and 
 present condition of these industries have been fairly well 
 investigated in recent times. But we can no more enter 
 into them than into the great variety of phases presented 
 by this form of industry. 
 
 The essential feature is ever the transformation of the 
 industrial product, before it reaches the consumer, into 
 capital — that is, into ? means of acquisition for one or more 
 intermediary merchants. Whether the entrepreneur place 
 the product on the general market, or keep a town ware- 
 room from which to sell it ; whether he receive the wares 
 from the houseworker ready for sale, or himself subject 
 them to a last finishing process; whether the workman call 
 himself master and keep journeymen, or whether he be a 
 tiller of the soil as well — the house workman is always far 
 removed from the real market of his product and from a 
 knowledge of market conditions, and therein lies the chief 
 cause of his hopeless weakness. 
 
 If under the connnission system capital has merely as- 
 sumed control of the marketing of the products, under the 
 factory system it grasi)s the whole process of production. 
 The former system, in order to accomplish the productive 
 task fallii / to it, draws loosely together a large number of 
 liomogeneous labourers, imparts to their production a defi- 
 nite direction, approximately the same for each, and 
 causes the product of their labour to flow, as it were, into 
 a great reservoir before distributing it in all directions. 
 The factory system organizes the whole process of pro- 
 

 174 A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 
 
 I 4 
 
 ■■■4 
 U s 
 
 (!'■■* 
 
 1'- ( 
 
 
 ^1 
 
 1"^ 1 
 
 ,?; 
 
 duction; it unites various kinds of workers, by mutual 
 relations of control and subjection, into a compact and 
 well-disciplined body, brings them together in a special 
 business establishment, provides them with an extensive 
 and complex outfit of the machinery of production, and 
 thereby immensely increases their productive power. The 
 factory system is as distinguishable from the commission 
 system as the well-organized, uniformly equipped regular 
 army from the motley volunteer militia. 
 
 Just as in an army corps ready for battle, troops of 
 varied training and accoutrement — infantry, cavalry, and 
 artillery regiments, pioneers, engineers, ammunition col- 
 uirins and commissariat are welded into one, so under the 
 factory system groups of workers of varied skill and equip- 
 ment are united together and enabled to accomplish the 
 most difficult tasks of production. 
 
 The secret of the factory's strength as an institution 
 for production thus lies in the effective utilisation of labour. 
 In order to accomplish this it takes a peculiar road, which 
 at first sight appears circuitous. It divides as far as pos- 
 sible all the work necessary to a process of production into 
 its simplest elements, separates the difficult from the easy, 
 the mechanical from the intellectual, the skilled from the 
 rude. It thus arrives at a system of successive functions, 
 and is enabled to employ simultaneously and successively 
 human powers of the most varied kind — trained and un- 
 trained men, women and children, workers with the hand 
 and head, workers possessing technical, artistic and com- 
 mercial skill. The restriction of each individual to a small 
 section of the labouring process effects a mighty increase 
 in the volume of work turned out. A hundred workmen 
 in a factory accomplish in a given process of production 
 more than a hundred independent master craftsmen, al- 
 though ench of the latter understands the whole process, 
 
A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. I7S 
 
 while none of the former understands more than a small 
 portion of it. As far as the struggle between handicraft 
 and factory is fought out on the ground of technical skill, 
 it is an evidence how the weak overcome the strong when 
 guided by superior intellectual power. 
 
 The machine is not the essential feature of the factory, 
 although the subdivision of zvork just described has, by 
 breaking up the sum of labour into simple movements, end- 
 lessly assisted and multiplied the appHcation of machinery. 
 From early times machines for performing tasks and for 
 furnishing power have been employed in industry. In 
 connection with the factory, however, their application 
 attained its present importance only when men succeeded 
 in securing a motive power that would work unintermit- 
 tently, uniformly and ubiquitously, namely, steam; and 
 even here its full importance is felt only in connection 
 with the peculiar industrial form of factory manufacture. 
 
 An example will serve to illustrate what has just been 
 said. In the year 1787 the canton of Zurich had 34,000 
 male and female hand-spinners producing cotton yarn. 
 After the introduction of the English spinning-machines 
 a few factories produced an equal or greater quantity of 
 thread, and the number of their workers (chiefly women 
 and children) fell to scarcely a third of what it had been 
 before. What is the explanation? The machines? But 
 was not the then-existing spinning-wheel a machine? Cer- 
 tainly it was; and, moreover, a very ingenious one. Ma- 
 chine was thus ousted by machine. Or better, what had 
 hitherto been done by the woman hand-spinner with her 
 wheel was now done by successive collaboration of a whole 
 series of various kinds of workers and machines. The 
 entire spinning process had been decomjiosed into its sim- 
 plest elements, and perfectly new operations had arisen for 
 which even immature powers could in part be utilized. 
 
p-^t* 
 
 i 
 
 '( 
 
 1 \ 
 
 , r 
 
 IS' 
 
 rP pi 
 
 I 
 
 I . 
 
 I I 
 
 'I : 
 
 176 ^ HISTORICAL SURyEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 
 
 In the suI)division of work originate these further pc- 
 cuHarities of factory production — the necessity of manu- 
 facture on a large scale, the requirement of a large capital, 
 and the economic dependence of the workman. 
 
 With regard to the two last points we easily perceive 
 an important difference between the factory and the com- 
 mission system. Its large fixed capital assures to factory 
 work greater steadiness in production. Under the com- 
 mission system the house-workers can at any moment be 
 deprived of employment without the entrepreneur running 
 any risk of losing capital; but the manufacturer must in 
 like case go on producing, because he fears loss of inter- 
 est and shrinkage in the value of his fixed capital, and 
 because he cannot afiford to lose his trained body of work- 
 men. This is the reason why it is probable that the com- 
 mission system will long maintain itself alongside factory 
 production in those branches of industry in which the 
 demand is liable to sudden change, and in which the articles 
 produced are of great variety. 
 
 If, in conclusion, we were briefly to characterize these 
 five industrial systems, we might say that housework is 
 production for one's own needs, wage-work is custom 
 work, handicraft is custom production, commission work 
 is decentralized, and factory labour centralized production 
 of wares. As no economic phenomenon stands iso- 
 lated, each of these systems of industry is at the same time 
 but a section of a great economic and social order. House- 
 work is the transformation of materials in the autonomous 
 household economy; wage-work belongs to the period of 
 transition from independent household economy to town 
 economy: the hey-day of handicraft coincides with the 
 period when town economy reached its full development; 
 the commission system is a connecting link between town 
 economy and national economy (independent State econ- 
 
A HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 177 
 
 omy), and the factory system is the industrial system of 
 fully developed national economy. 
 
 It would lead us too far to explain in this chapter how 
 each industrial system fits organically into the contem- 
 porary method of production and how it is mutually deter- 
 mined by a series of allied phenomena in the spheres of 
 agriculture, personal services, trade and transportation. It 
 can scarcely escape the observant eye that all the elements 
 of the evolution here broadly sketched are contained in the 
 primitive cell of society, the family; or, in economic phrase, 
 in the conditions of production in the independent house- 
 hold. From this primitive social unit, teeming with life and 
 swallowing up all individual existence, parts have continu- 
 ally detached themselves through differentiation and in- 
 tegration, and become more and more independent. Wage- 
 work is only a sprout from the root of the tree of independ- 
 ent household economy; handicraft still needs its protec- 
 tion in order to flourish; commission work makes the mar- 
 keting of products a special business, while production 
 sinks back almost to the first stages of development. Fac- 
 tory manufacture, on the other hand, permeates with the 
 entrepreneur principle the whole process of production; 
 it is an independent economic system freed from all ele- 
 ments of consumption, and separated as regards commod- 
 ities and locality from the household life of those engaged 
 in it. 
 
 The position of the worker changes in a similar way. 
 With the commencement of wage-work the industrial 
 worker separates himself personally from the independent 
 household economy of the landed proprietor; with the 
 transition to handicraft he also becomes, through the elim- 
 ination of business capital, materially free and independent. 
 Through the commission system he enters into a fresh per- 
 sonal subjection, he falls into dependence upon the capi- 
 
Il 
 
 f 1 
 
 178 A HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 
 
 talistic entrepreneur; under the factory system he becomes 
 also materially dependent upon him. By four stages of 
 evolution he passes from manorial servitude to factory 
 servitude. 
 
 There is a sort of parallelism in this evolution. The re- 
 lation between the unfree houseworker and the ancient 
 landowner bears a certain resemblance to the relation be- 
 tween the factory hand and the modern manufacturer; and 
 the wage-worker occupies much the same position with 
 regard to the economy of the landed proprietor that the 
 worker engaged in house industry does to the entrepreneur 
 giving out commission work. In the middle of this ascend- 
 ing and descending series stands handicraft as its founda- 
 tion and comer-stone. From housework to handicraft we 
 see the gradual emancipation of the worker from the soil 
 and the formation of capital; from handicraft to the factory 
 system a gradual separation of capital from work, and the 
 subjection of the worker to capital. 
 
 At the stage of housework capital has not yet emerged; 
 there are only consumption goods at various stages of 
 ripeness. Everything belongs to the household— raw ma- 
 terial, tools, the manufactured article, often the worker 
 himself. In the case of wage-work the tools are the only 
 capital in the hands of the worker; the raw and auxiliary 
 materials are household stores not yet ready for consump- 
 tion; the work-place belongs, under the system of migra- 
 tory labour, to the domestic establishment that is to con- 
 sume the finished product, or, under the housework sys- 
 tem, to the worker who produces the article. In the case 
 of handicraft the tools, worl.-place, and raw material are 
 capital in the possession of the worker; the latter is master 
 of the product, though he invariably sells it to the imme- 
 diate consumer. In the commission system the product 
 also becomes capital— not the capital of the worker, how- 
 
A HISTORICAL SURREY OS INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 179 
 
 ever, but of quite a new figure on the scene, the commercial 
 entrepreneur; the worker either retains all his means of 
 production, or he loses possession successively of his goods, 
 capilal, and his implements of production. Thus all the 
 elements of capital finally unite in the hand of the manu- 
 facturer, and serve him as a foundation for the reorganiza- 
 tion of industrial production. In his hands even the 
 worker's share in the product becomes a part of the busi- 
 ness capital. 
 
 This share of the worker consists, at the stage of house- 
 work, in a participation in the consumption of the finished 
 products; in the case of wage-work it consists in board, 
 together with a time- or piece-work wage, which even at 
 this point includes compensation for wear and tear of tools; 
 in handicraft it consists in the full returns from production. 
 Under the commission system the commercial undertaker 
 takes away a portion of the latter as profit on his business 
 capital; under the factory system all the elements of pro- 
 duction which can be turned into capital become crystal- 
 lizing centres for further profits on capital, while for the 
 worker there remains only the stipulated wage. 
 
 We must not, however, imagine the historical evolution 
 of the industrial system to have been such that each new 
 industrial method absolutely superseded its predecessor. 
 That would be just as far astray as. for example, to suppose 
 that a new means of communication supplants those 
 already existing. Railways have done away neither with 
 conveyances on the highways, nor with transportation by 
 means of ships, pack-animals or the human back; they 
 have only confined each of these older methods of trans- 
 portation to the field in which it can best develop its pe- 
 culiar advantages: it is probable that not only abso- 
 lutely but relatively more horses and men are employed in 
 
I So /I HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 
 
 I- ' 
 
 the work of transportation in our civilized countries to-day 
 than there were in the year 1830. 
 
 The very same causes that have produced such an enor- 
 mous increase in traffic are also at work in the sphere of 
 industry; and in spite of the continual improvement of the 
 mechanical means of production they demand an ever-in- 
 creasing number of persons. From two quarters, how- 
 ev^r, the sphere of productive industry is constantly re- 
 ceiving accessions; first, from the old household economy 
 and agriculture, from which even to-day parts are always 
 separating themselves and becoming independent branches 
 of industry; secondly, from the continual improvement ^^ 
 and increase in range of articles serving for the satisfac- 
 tion of our wants. 
 
 As regards the first point, there have sprung up in the 
 industrial world during the last generation dozens of new 
 trades for takiig over such kinds of work as >.. • J formerly 
 to fall to the women of the household or to the servants, 
 such as vegetable and fruit preserving, fancy baking and 
 preparation of meats, making and mending women's and 
 children's clothes, cleaning windows, feather beds and cur- 
 tains, chemical cleaning and dyeing, painting and polishing 
 floors, gas and water installation, etc. Under the heading 
 "Art and Market Gardening," the latest statistics of trades 
 in the German Empire give thirty-five, and under the head- 
 ing " Stock-raising," thirty-one, independent occupations, 
 many of which are of very recent origin. 
 
 With regard to the second point, we will mention only 
 the bicycle industry, which within a short time has not only 
 
 '° In reply to a criticism of this expression in the Revue d'economie 
 politique (or November, i8q2 (p. 1228, note), we will not omit making 
 it more definite by saying that we do not mean by it the improvement 
 of the quality of already existing species of goods, but the supplant- 
 ing of existing poods by others which better and more cheaply supply 
 thv demand, 
 
A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 
 
 i8i 
 
 necessitated the erection of a great number of factories, 
 but has already given rise to special repair-shops and sep- 
 arate establishments for the manufacture of rubber tires, 
 cyclometers and bicycle spokes. A still more striking ex- 
 ample is afforded by the application of electricity. In the 
 industrial census of 1895 there are enumerated names of 
 twenty-two electrical occupations that did not exist in 1882. 
 The production of electrical machines, apparatus and plant 
 in the German Empire gave employment in 1895 to 14-494 
 persons, with 18.449 members of their families and serv- 
 ants—thus furnishing a hving for nearly 33,000 persons." 
 In metal-work, in the manufacture of machinery, chemicals, 
 paper, in the building industries, the clothing and cleaning 
 industries the number of recorded occupations more than 
 doubled itself between 1882 and 1895. It is, at the same 
 time, to be remembered not only that specialization has 
 made immense strides, but that in many instances subsid- 
 iary articles of production and trade which have hitherto 
 been produced by the businesses using them are the ob- 
 jects of separate enterprises. In these fields industry not 
 only meets demand but frequently outruns it, as has at all 
 times been the case. In the patent lists %xe find significant 
 expression of this effort to improve the world of com- 
 modities; and though many of the new inventions prove 
 deficient in vitality, there always remains a considerable 
 number whereby life is permanently enriched. 
 
 "In a report appearing in the newspapers of August. 1900 Dr. R. 
 Burner estimates the total capital of German firms manufacturing 
 electr.cal apparatus, in round numbers, at 800 million marks ^200 
 million dollars), and the stock of the so-called finanaal corpora wns 
 which- are taken up with the laymg of electric car lines and works^ at 
 450 million marks (.12 million dollars). The electr.c Imes, electric 
 works and block stations in Germany are credited, in round numbers, 
 with I 250 million marks (312 million dollars). So that the whole 
 electrical plant of Germany represents a capital of about two and a 
 half milliards oi marks (b-'3 million dollars). 
 
l82 A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 
 
 <R ''I 
 
 IS 
 
 
 Si 
 
 m 
 
 If we were able statistically to bring together the whole 
 sum of industrial products produced yearly in Germany in 
 such a way that we could separate the output of factories, 
 of house ir.dustry, and of handicraft, wage-work and 
 housework, we should without doubt find that the 
 greater part of the factory wares embraces goods which 
 were never produced under any of the other industrial sys- 
 tems, and that handicraft produces to-day an absolutely 
 greater quantity than ever before. The commission and 
 faciory systems, it is true, have completely absorbed some 
 of the lesser handicrafts and robbed many others of por- 
 tions of their sphere of production. But all the great guild 
 handicrafts that existed at the close of the iHth century, 
 with perhaps the single exception of weaving, ill exist 
 to-day. Handicraft is constantly being displaced by the 
 more perfect industrial systems, just as in mediaeval times 
 housework and wage-work were ousted by h" iidicraft, 
 only now it occurs in a less violent manner, on the field of 
 free competition. This competition of all with all, sup- 
 ported as it is by a perfected system of transf)ortation and 
 communication, often compels the transition from custom 
 to wholesale production, even where from the technical 
 standpoint the former might still have been possible. 
 Many independent master workmen enter the service of 
 the entrepreneur carrying on commission or factory work 
 just as their predecessors a thousand years ago became 
 manorial labourers. 
 
 Handicraft has thus been relegated economically and so- 
 cially to a secondary position. But even if it will no longer 
 flourish in the large towns, it has in compensation spread 
 all the more in the country, and here called forth, in com- 
 bination with agriculture, numerous industries upon which 
 the eye of the philanthropist can rest with delight. Handi- 
 craft, it mav 1)0 said with certaintv, will no more disappear 
 
A HISTORICAL SURREY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 183 
 
 than wage-work and housework have disappeared. What 
 it has won for society in a time of universal feudalization, 
 namely, a robust class of people independent of landed 
 property, whose existence is based upon personal worth 
 and a small amount of movables, and who are a repository 
 of popular morality and upr- ;htness — that will and must 
 remain a lasting possession, even though the existence of 
 those whom these virtues will in future adorn may rest 
 upon a different basis. 
 
 In recent times there has been raised with rare persist- 
 ence a cry for the uprooting of the older industry. Handi- 
 craft, house industry, in general all forms of work on a 
 small scale are, we are told, a drag upon the national pro- 
 ductive power; they are "antiquated, superseded, rude, not 
 to say socially impeditive methods of production," which 
 in the best interests of those who follow them must be re- 
 placed by a " rational and judicious organization and regu- 
 lation of human activities on a large scale," if the actual 
 national production is not to lag far behind what is tech- 
 nically possible. 
 
 This short-sighted economico-political theorizing is not 
 new. There was once a time when every peasant shoe- 
 maker who raised his own potatoes and cabbage was 
 looked upon as a sort of enemy to the highest possible na- 
 tional wealth, and when people would have liked to force 
 him by police regulation to stick to his last, even though at 
 the same time he ran the risk of starving. Truly, it has al- 
 ways been much easier to censure than to understand. 
 
 If. instead of such dogmatic pronouncements, a willing- 
 ness had been shown to make an unbiassed investigation of 
 the conditions governing those older and supposedly an- 
 tiquated systems of production, the conviction would soon 
 have arisen that in the majority of cases where they still 
 persist they arc economically and socially justifiable; and 
 
»84 A HISTORICAL SURVEY OF INDUSTRIAL SYSTEMS. 
 
 the means for the removal of the existing- evils would be 
 sought in the soil in which these industrial forms are rooted 
 instead of such drastic remedies being applied to them. 
 In this way we should undoubtedly preserve the good of 
 each of these individual systems and be striving only to re- 
 move their disadvantages. 
 
 For, after all, the comforting result of every serious con- 
 sideration of history is. that no single element of culture 
 which has once entered into the life of men is lost; that 
 even after the hour of its predominance has expired, it 
 continues in some more modest position to cooperate in 
 the realization of the great end in which we all believe, the 
 helping of mankind towards more and more perfect forms 
 of existence. 
 
CHAPTER V. 
 
 THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 
 
 There are in Germany two handicraft problems. One 
 is a problem belonging to the newspapers and the legisla- 
 tures, which since 1848 has repeatedly occupied the liveliest 
 public attention. For it the question is the extent to which 
 the particular interests of hand-workers as a class should be 
 given legislative expression. What the answer shall be 
 depends upon the relative strength of political parties. 
 
 The other problem relates to the vitality of hand-work 
 as a form of industrial activity. It is the query of Ham- 
 let's soliloquy: " To be or not to be! " The answer de- 
 pends upon actual conditions. Stated more explicitly, the 
 question would read: How far has hand-work up to the 
 present shown itself capable of holding its own? What de- 
 partment of industry does it still dominate? 
 
 So long as public policy weighs, not merely wishes and 
 votes, but also the facts of the case, it will not venture to 
 decide the first of these questions until the second has been 
 answered. Until lately the necessary established data 
 have been lacking. Recently, however, the German Social 
 Science Club has conducted a most comprehensive investi- 
 gation into those branches of industry belonging to the old 
 class of handicrafts.' It is therefore opportune to give a 
 
 ' Investieations as to the Condition of Hnnd.jork m Germany, tvith 
 sptcial Reference to its Ability to compete u-ith industrial Undertakings on 
 a Inrf '^'c'e in S>hr.ft<!i d,'^ V.r(in>; fur Sozialpolitik. Vols. 62-70 
 " 185 
 
l'-' 
 
 
 it 
 
 Ji 
 
 :.i,ait 
 
 1 86 
 
 THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 
 
 general survey of the findings. In this it is not our inten- 
 tion to enter upon a discussion of the p. >'--it position and 
 future prospects of particular industrial tranches,* but 
 rather to present the common characteristics of the de- 
 velopment that has taken place during the past hundred 
 years or more. This will make it possible to appreciate in 
 their full strength and manifold modes of operation the 
 forces in modem national economy that act as solvents and 
 as creative agents. 
 
 A century ago handicraft still held undisputed sway over 
 all its mediaeval inheritance and over its sixteenth and 
 seventeenth century conquests as well. There existed be- 
 sides, it is true, a few manufactories and factories. But they 
 had developed apart from hand-work; what they produced 
 had never been handicraft work. Rivalry between these 
 new forms of industry and the guild hand-work there had 
 never been. Nor had the guilds as such been interfered 
 with by the State; they had only been made amenable 
 to its laws, and thus been in part stripped of their local 
 municipal character. Their scope indeed had been ex- 
 tended, in that those handicrafts were subjected to the 
 guild constitution, which, because of the limited number of 
 their representatives, had not as yet been able to form 
 local guilds in the various towns. Through the territorial 
 guilds, i 1 had been constituted for these "minor handi- 
 crafts," aiid through the " general guild articles " com- 
 pactly summarizing uniform trade regulations for all local 
 guilds, the requirements of modern national economy had 
 
 (Ltip^iR, 1804-1807). A further volume (Vol 71) relates to Austria. 
 SupplcTTientinK this is the inquiry into the conditions of handwork, 
 undertaken in the summer of 1805. and edited by the Imperial Statis- 
 tics lUire.iu (.( niiiTiber<=, Rtrlin. iSg:^. 
 
 'The results of the itivestiRations of FI. Grandke alon^ this line are 
 presentiil In Sclimoller's Jalirbuch I'ur GesetZKe''. V'erwa't. u, Volksw., 
 Vol. XXI Ci8g;), pp. loji iT. 
 
THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 
 
 187 
 
 been at least formally asserted. In practice, however, the 
 local and craft prerogatives of sale, the town monopoly 
 and extra-mural rights of jurisdiction ^ remained in force. 
 Competition between the members of the same handicraft 
 from different towns and of the different crafts of the same 
 towns was entirely lacking; settlement in rural parts was 
 for most crafts forbidden, and to gain independence was 
 made a matter of extreme difficulty for all journeymen 
 who were not masters' sons or sons-in-law. 
 
 But what was the condition of the master craftsmen in 
 exclusive possession of these privileges? 
 
 Most of those who discuss handicraft to-day depict the 
 masters " of the golden era of handicraft " as well-to-do 
 people carrying on business " with considerable capital for 
 those times," owning " their own dwellings and extensive 
 workshops," working along with master journeymen and 
 apprentices, personally capable, honourable, respected. All 
 the painters dip their brush in glowing colours, so neces- 
 sary for the portrayal of a condition of prosperity. 
 
 Whence have they this picture? We have vainly sought 
 it in the eighteenth or seventeenth century. Moreover, 
 our classical poets could not have had it before their eyes; 
 for their " gossiping tailors and glovers " are petty, insig- 
 nificant apparitions. In the multitude of small towns the 
 masters were able to maintain themselves only through 
 their bit of farming and the lucrative brewing privilege, 
 and in the larger towns through the little counter kept by 
 many of them in connection with their workshop. Even 
 for a town of such commercial, prominence as Leipzig, the 
 mass of administrative records from the last two centuries 
 do not allow the impression that the craftsmen of that 
 place were on the average well off; and the extensive liter- 
 
 • [Comp. on the latter Roscher. System der Volksvi., 5th ed. Vol. 3. 
 S ii8.-ED.3 
 
i88 
 
 THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 
 
 \aiii. 
 
 ature on guilds that has come down from the close of the 
 last and the beginning of the present century, the " Pa- 
 triotische Phantasien " of Justus Moser, points in many in- 
 stances to very narrow circumstances. 
 
 The barriers erected against admission to mastership, 
 though extensive, had not been successfully defended. 
 Among the bakers and butchers, whom it is customary to 
 cite as types of prosperity, baking and killing in rotation 
 was the almost universal rule; that is, there were so many 
 masters that each baker could not bake afresh each day, 
 nor each butcher kill a head of cattle per week. As late 
 as 1 817 a writer cites as a normal case from Bavaria that 
 in a town with ten master bakers three bakings of bread 
 were consumed daily, so that every week the turn fell to 
 each twice. The butchers could slaughter regularly only 
 the smaller kinds of stock. In North German towns mat- 
 ters appear to have been in a favourable condition if one 
 beef were sold every week for every five or six masters. 
 
 Almost all crafts with a guild organization had a clause 
 in their statutes fixing the maximum number of journey- 
 men and apprentices which a master might ' -"ep. As a rule 
 he was limited to two. In the i8th century this number was 
 rarely exceeded. Under normal conditions, however, the 
 grci t majority of trades could not attain to this number. 
 Assuming that all who learned the handicraft acquired 
 master's standing, that a master lived on the average thirty 
 years after he attained that rank, and that ordinarily a man 
 became independent between the twenty-eighth and thir- 
 tieth year of his life, there could not have been at any time 
 more than half as many journeymen and apprentices as 
 masters. 
 
 The actual proportion at the end of the century was 
 often much smaller still. In the year 1784 there were in 
 the duchy of Magdeburg 27,050 independent masters and 
 
THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 
 
 189 
 
 only 4,285 assistants and apprentices. About the same 
 time, in the principality of Wurzburg (in Bavaria), 13762 
 masters with 2,176 assistants and apprentices were re- 
 turned." In both territories there were for every hundred 
 masters but 15.8 journeymen and apprentices. Thus, if 
 we assume that the assistants were equally distributed 
 among the masters, one journeyman or apprentice hardly 
 fell to each sixth master. In more than five-sixths of the 
 instances the master carried on his work single-handed. 
 In 1780 the town of Bochum (in Westphalia) counted for 
 every five master masons one; in the other crafts they were 
 for every twenty-six master shoemakers three, for every 
 twenty-one master bakers, every eight carpenters and 
 every five master masons one; in the other crafts they 
 were altogether lacking. 
 
 In some parts of Prussia, especially in Berlin, the con- 
 ditions were indeed somewhat more favourable. But in 
 general the idea must be abandoned that our modern in- 
 dustrial development began with the handicrafts in a con- 
 dition of general prosperity. The best that past times 
 could of?er the craftsmen was a modest competence, se- 
 curity against lack of work and against over-severe com- 
 petition from their fellows. They deal directly with their 
 customers, in quiet times work up a stock and take it to 
 market, and stand firmly together in the guild if it is a 
 question of voting down a new application for mastership, 
 taking action against an itinerant workman or resisting 
 an encroachment on the part of a neighbouring craft. To- 
 wards one another, however, they are possessed with the 
 pettiest bread-and-butter jealousy, and give a great deal of 
 trouble to the courts and administrative ofificials. Such 
 was the early handicraft. 
 
 ♦AccordinK to Sclimoller, Zur Gcsch. d. dculsch KUingewerbe vn 
 
 jy. Jhdt., pp. 21. 22. 
 
190 
 
 THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 
 
 Down to the fourth decade of last century there was 
 no really great change. After the time of Napoleon, the 
 old industrial policy was repeatedly moderated, but in most 
 parts of Germany it was not abolished until the sixties. It 
 gave place to industrial freedom. Anyone might now carry 
 on any business anywhere and on any desired scale. The 
 local prc'^ibitive powers fell to the ground. Each trades- 
 man could dispose of his products where he would, and in 
 his own locality had to tolerate all external competition. 
 The barriers between the different branches of industry 
 dropped away, and everyone could manufacture what was 
 to his advantage. 
 
 All this took place with the full assent of the craftsmen 
 themselves. The conviction that the old industrial polity 
 had become untenable was shared in at least the more ad- 
 vanced parts of Germany by all. If ever an old insti- 
 tution was abolished with the approbation of the whole 
 nation, it was the guild system. The sole sporadic mis- 
 giving was that apprenticeship might fall into decay, and 
 that many would establish themselves as independent 
 craftsmen who had not regularly learned their trade. This 
 apprehension has proved groundless. According to the 
 results of the inquiry made into handicraft in various 
 districts of Germany, ninety-seven per cent, of those con- 
 sidered as still carrying on an independent handicraft had 
 enjoyed a preparatory training as hand-workers. The 
 small remainder consisted mainly of those who had re- 
 ceived their technical training in apprentice shops and 
 technical schools, asylums for the blind, institutions for the 
 deaf and dumb, in prison and in barracks. 
 
 The influence of the new conditions on the number, local 
 distribution, and extent of undertakings assumed a differ- 
 ent form. At first it was feared that the establishment of 
 numerous petty master workmen without capital would 
 
THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 
 
 191 
 
 lead to a mass of half-developed business undertakings; 
 but this has in nowise proved the case. On the contrary, 
 after a brief transitional period, the undertakings in the 
 towns have on the average during the last generation 
 numerically diminished, while in financial strength and in 
 the number of assistants, so far as their existence has not 
 been in general jeopardized by causes lying outside the 
 province of industrial legislation, the respective branches 
 of trade have increased. At the same time hand-work has 
 made striking advances in the country, and to-day is ap- 
 proximately as strong there as in the towns. 
 
 This equalization between town and country, however, 
 had been foreseen and aimed at at the time by the advo- 
 cates of industrial freedom. If there was the further 
 expectation that through industrial freedom the way of 
 the artisan would be opened to technical progress and to 
 economic advancement, this also has not lacked fulfilment. 
 Thousands of urban master workmen have in the last two 
 o-enerations become large manufacturers, or at least capi- 
 talistic entrepreneurs, and have participated fully in the 
 technical advances of the period. Freedom of mdustry 
 and enterprise has made it possible for them to broaden 
 their sphere of production and sale, and to utilize fully their 
 personal ability. This fact men to-day are only too prone 
 
 to overlook. 
 
 To be sure, the number of those who have not risen in 
 the world, but remained stationar>-, and of those reduced 
 to the level of master jobbers and homeworkers. or forced 
 to become factory employees, is much larger still. Whole 
 branches of industrv formeriy carried on as hand-work are 
 almost ruined, or at least are lost to handicraft as a par- 
 ticular industrial form. Others are still struggling for their 
 existence. A great weathering and transforming process 
 has here come into operation: in its train handicraft is 
 
192 
 
 THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 
 
 h2 
 
 yielding place to other forms of business, such as the fac- 
 tory and commission systems, or the hybrid forms that 
 every period of transition begets. 
 
 The public at large is content to include all involved in 
 these processes under the simple headings: displacement 
 of hand-work by machinery, annihilation of handicraft by 
 the factory! The smaller cost of production by machinery 
 is looked upon as the sole cause. 
 
 The reduction of these expressions to their true value, 
 and the demonstration that a large part of the changes 
 which have taken place has its cau^e not in the advances of 
 manufacturing technique but in the direction taken by 
 economic consumption, and that so far as this is the case 
 handicraft disappears even without machine-work coming 
 into competition with it — this will remain one of the 
 greatest services rendered by recent investigators of hand- 
 work. It will be necessary first to present a summary view 
 of these changes in consumption, since they, so to speak, 
 condition the whole development. 
 
 In the first place, a local concentration of demand has taken 
 place. The aggregations of human beings that have been 
 formed in great cities in the course of the last half cen- 
 tury, furthermore the standing armies, the large state and 
 municipal institutiotis. prisons, hospitals, technical schools, 
 etc., the extensive establishments for transportation, fac- 
 tories, and large undertakings in the departments of trade, 
 banking and insurance, all form centres of wholesale de- 
 mand for industrial products. To these are to be added 
 the great departmental warehouses, export businesses and 
 cooperative societies, focussing the demand of large sec- 
 tions of the population at a few points. This demand they 
 are no longer able to satisfy as customers of individual 
 craftsmen. 
 
 There comes then as a secnnd cnn-sideration the many 
 
THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 
 
 193 
 
 instances in which modern civilization has propounded 
 such colossal tasks for industry that they cannot be accom- 
 plished at all with the implements and methods of handi- 
 craft, although each of them generally requires consid- 
 erable hand-work. The manufacture of a locomotive, of a 
 steam crane, of a rapid press, the building of a river bridge 
 or of a warship, the equipment of a street railway with 
 rails and rolling stock cannot be carried out with mere 
 hand apparatus and manual labour. They require im- 
 mensely powerful mechanical appliances, highly trained 
 engineers and craftsmen of exceedingly varied qualitica- 
 tions. 
 
 Even where technically such tasks might still be accom- 
 plished with the implements of hand-work, the entrusting 
 of them to master craftsmen is economic mj)ossihle be- 
 cause of the consequent heavy loss of erest. In the 
 Middle Ages the building of a cathedral might occupy two 
 or three generations, indeed, several centuries. Imagine 
 one to-day wishing to take as much time for the erection 
 of a railway station! When in 1896 the contract for the 
 main building of the Saxon-Thuringian Industrial Exhil)i- 
 tion in Leipzig was to be let, it was first offered to the 
 master carpenters of the city — contractors who carry 
 on work with considerable capital and are accustomed to 
 large undertakings. But all hesitated because of the short- 
 ness of the term for building and the extent of the risk. 
 Negotiations were thereupon entered into with a large firm 
 of builders in Frankfurt-on-Main. In a few hours the con- 
 tract was closed. The same evening the telegraph was 
 working in all directions. A week later the steam rams 
 were busy on the building site, and whole trains were ar- 
 riving from Galicia with the necessary timber. 
 
 In fact, one can say that to-day there are industrial tasks 
 of such magnitude that they can be performed by only a 
 
194 
 
 THE DECLINE OF THE HASDICRAFTS. 
 
 few, perhaps indeed by but one or two firms in Europe. 
 Hence the development, beside the earHer type of factory, 
 which finds its strength in the wholesale production of 
 similar articles, of a new type whose raison d'etre lies in 
 the magnitude of the task of production. This more recent 
 kind of large industrial undertaking we might designate 
 by the already current er.pression, manufacturing estab- 
 lishment.^ At the head stands a staff of technically trained 
 men, with extensive mechanical appliances at command, 
 and with the necessary hand-work in most effective com- 
 bination. 
 
 But the demand for industrial labour has been not 
 merely locally concentrated and condensed to meet the 
 extensive requirements of production; it has also become 
 more uniform, and therefore more massive. A tendency 
 tozvards uniformity runs through our age, eliminating the 
 differences of habits and customs in the various strata of 
 society. Characteristic peasant costumes have disappeared 
 down to unimportant survivals; the furnishing of the dwell- 
 ing, of the kitchen, has become, it is true, more extensive, 
 but likewise more uniform. Even in the smallest home 
 one finds the petroleum lamp, the coffee-mill, some enam- 
 elled cooking utensils, a pair of framed photographs. 
 To make the desired ware accessible to the poorer classes, 
 it must be easily and cheaply produced. If an article is 
 lifted on the crest of a wave of fashion, the demand for it 
 in a cheap form advances even up to the better situated 
 grades of society, and thus the outlay for the folly of fash- 
 ion is made endurable. In ti iS way there arises a large 
 demand for cheap goods for whose manufacture the earlier 
 type of factory is naturally adapted. Hand-work is for such 
 too expensive; where it remains technically possible it must 
 
 ' Fabrikationsansialt. 
 
THE DECUSE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 
 
 195 
 
 be extremely specialized, and then it necessarily loses the 
 ground of custom work from beneath its feet. 
 
 There is finally another consideration to be alluded to. 
 which belongs to the sphere of domestic economy. The home 
 is being relieved more and more of the vestigial elements 
 of production, and is restricting itself to the regulation of 
 consumption. If our grandparents required a sofa, they 
 first had the joiner make the frame, then purchased the 
 leather, the horsehair and the feathers, and had the up- 
 holsterer finish the work in the house. The procedure was 
 similar for almost every more important piece of work. 
 To-day s' -cialized work demanding the whole strength of 
 each indr lual, frequently to exhaustion, no longer per- 
 mits such a participation in production. We will and must 
 purchase what we need ready-made. We desire to be 
 quickly supplied, and preferably renounce idiosyncrasies 
 of personal taste, rather than undertake the risk of order- 
 ing from different producers. Industry has to adapt itself 
 accordingly. 
 
 The same evolutionary process also asserts itself in de- 
 partments where the individual craftsman had been accus- 
 tomed from time immemorial to supply finished wares. 
 Here again the modern city consumer will no longer trade 
 directly with him by ordering the single piece that he re- 
 quires. He is averse to waiting; he knows that often the 
 work does not turn out as desired, and prefers to choose 
 and compare before he buys. 
 
 Thus the craftsman can no longer remain a custom 
 worker even in those departments in which technically he 
 is fully able to cope with the demands of production. He 
 no longer works on individual orders, but exclusively for 
 stock — which formerly he did only in case of necessity. 
 To reach the consumer he needs the intervention of 
 the store. By the discontinuance of personal contact be- 
 
196 
 
 THE DECLINE OF THE H/INDICRAFTS. 
 
 
 i' i 1 
 
 
 tween producer and consumer, hand-work as a phase of in- 
 dustry disappears. It becomes a capitalistic undertaking, 
 and demands management in accord with mercantile prin- 
 ciples. All now depends upon the question whether busi- 
 ness on a large or a small scale offers the greater advan- 
 tages. In the first case the department of work formerly 
 represented by handicraft falls to the factory, in the latter 
 to domestic industry. 
 
 For even where modern demand has not yet appeared 
 as wholesale concentrated demand, or become condensed 
 to meet the necessities of production on a grand scale, it 
 is universally well adapted, by virtue of its great uniformity 
 and its emancipation from household labour, to localization 
 at a few points. The perfected commercial machinery of 
 modern times, the low tariffs for post and telegraph, tha 
 rapidity and regularity of freight and news transportation, 
 the innumerable means of advertising and of making an- 
 nouncements afford here their mighty assistance. Indus- 
 trial freedom thus found a well-prepared soil when it 
 sprang mto life. It but created the legal forms that voice 
 the character of modern economic demand. All those 
 circles of consumers of the craftsmen so long kept arti- 
 ficially asunder could now be united through the interven- 
 tion of commerce into a large manufactory and commis- 
 sion clientele, not necessarily limited to national boundaries. 
 
 Concentrated demand does not permit of satisfaction by 
 scattered production. Along with the process of concen- 
 tration of demand must go a process of concentration in the 
 department of industrial production. It is to this that handi- 
 craft on every side succumbs. 
 
 But this process is very complicated, and it is not alto- 
 gether easy to separate from one another the individual 
 processes of which it is composed. Wc will nevertheless 
 essav the task, choosinir the fate of hand-work as the deter- 
 
THE DECLINE OF THE H/INDICRAFTS. 
 
 197 
 
 mining factor in the divisions made by us. We thus arrive 
 at the five following cases: 
 
 1. Supplanting of hand-work by similar factory produc- 
 tion. 
 
 2. Curtailment of its department of production by fac- 
 tory or commission. 
 
 3. Incorporation of hand-work with the large undertak- 
 ing. 
 
 4. Impoverishment of hand-work by shifting of demand. 
 
 5. Reduction of hand-work by way of the warehouse to 
 home and sweat-work. 
 
 Several of these processes often go on simultaneously. 
 In our consideration of the subject, however, we will keep 
 thom as far as possible apart. 
 
 I. The case in which capitalistic production on a large 
 scale attacks handicraft along its whole front, in order to 
 expel it completely from its sphere of production is compara- 
 tively rare. From earlier times we may mention weaving, 
 clock and gun making, and also the sm'dler industries of 
 the pin-makers, button-makers, tool-smiths, card-makers, 
 hosiers; from recent times hatmaking, shoemaking, dyeing, 
 soap manufacture, rope-making, nail and cutlery smithing, 
 comb-making: to a certain extent beer-brewing and 
 coopering also belong to the list. 
 
 The process of displacement assumes now a quicker now 
 a less rapid character, according as the handicraft in ques- 
 tion formerly carried on manufacture for stock along with 
 market and ^'u,p sale, or restricted itself to custom work. 
 Thus the making of shoes for market sale paved the way 
 for the manufacture of shoes by machinery, because it had 
 long accustomed certain classes of the people to the pur- 
 chase of ready-made footwear. 
 
 For handicraft the result of such a development varies 
 accordin"- n^ th<' f:!'.-tnry product, after being worn out. 
 
193 
 
 THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 
 
 at 
 
 permits of repair or not. In the latter case handicraft dis- 
 appears altogether; in the former it evolves into a repair 
 trade, with or without a sale shop. The carrying on by a 
 hand-worker of a shop trade with factory goods in his own 
 line is not exactly an unfavourable metamorphosis; but 
 only craftsmen with considerable capital can manage it. 
 On the oiher hand, pure repair trade very easily loses 
 the ground of hand-work beneath its feet, if the factory- 
 product passes completely into the control of retail mer- 
 chants. For then the majority of consumers prefer to have 
 repairs made in the shop in which they have purchased the 
 new ware. The proprietor of the shop keeiis a journey- 
 man or sends out the mending to a petty master workman. 
 This greatly diminishes their return, and makes them com- 
 pletely dependent. Moreover, repairing can also be car- 
 ried on on a large scale, as with the so-called rag-dyeing, 
 which works with considerable capital and independent 
 collecting points. Finally, the repairing can become quite 
 superfluous through very cheap i)roduction of new wares, 
 as. for example, with clocks and shoes; repair would cost 
 more than a new article. 
 
 2. Much more frequently does the second group of evo- 
 lutionary processes make its appearance. Here it is not a 
 ([uestion of the com])lete loss of the new manufacture, but 
 merelv of the curtailment of the department of production fall- 
 ing to handicraft through factory or commission business. 
 The causes of this process may be very diverse. While 
 recognising the impossibility of being exhaustive, we will 
 distinguish four of them: 
 
 ia) I'arious handicrafts are fused into a single manufac- 
 turing establishment : for example, joi-icrs, wood-carvers, 
 turners, upholsterers, painters. !ac<|uerers into a furniture 
 factory; wheelwrights, smiths, saddlers, glaziers into a car- 
 riage manufactory; bnsket-inakers. joiners, wheelwrights, 
 
THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 
 
 199 
 
 saddlers, smiths, locksmiths, lacquerers into a baby-car- 
 riage factory. We may mention further all kinds of ma- 
 chine-shops, locomotive and car-works, piano factories, 
 trunk factories, billiard-taLle factories, and also the estab- 
 lishments for the production of whole factory plants — dis- 
 tillery, brewery, sugar-refinery, etc. As a rule the part of 
 production withdrawn from the individual handicraft 
 through such an incorporation forms but a small frap^ment 
 of its previous sphere of work and of its market. J how- 
 ever, such blood-lettings are frequent, as among the 
 turners, saddlers and locksmiths, there finally remains 
 very little, and the handicraft may die of exhaustion. 
 
 (/;) Various remunerative articles adapted to zJiolcsalc pro- 
 duction by factory or house industry are withdrawn from 
 hand-work. Thus bookbinding has 1 1 to resign ah.iost its 
 whole extensive department of pro iction to more than 
 forty kinds of special trades; there remains but the indi- 
 vidual binding for private customers. Basket-making has 
 surrendered the fine wares to homework, baby-carriages 
 and the like to factories, and only the coarse willow wicker- 
 work remains to handicraft. The locksmith has even lost 
 the article, the lock, from which he has his name; the 
 brush-maker the manufacture of paint, tooth, and nail 
 brushes; the cabinet-maker has been compelled to re- 
 nounce the intermediate wares (Berim furniture), and 
 ordinary pine furniture has become a stock-in-trade of 
 the store; confectionery is threatened, in the cities at 
 least, with being despoiled by the factories of the manu- 
 facture of bread; the tinsmith no longer makes his vessels; 
 in short there arc likely but few handicrafts that have not 
 similar losses to record. 
 
 (f) The factory takes over the primary stages of production. 
 It was precisely the first rough working of the material 
 which demands the greatest exi)enditurc of strength, it 
 
200 
 
 THE DECLINE OF THE HAKDICRAFTS. 
 
 was exactly this primary handling that suggested the ap- 
 plication of machinery, while the finer and individual 
 shaping of the product in the later stages of the process 
 of production tempted the entrepreneur but slightly. In 
 almost all metal and wood industries the raw material is 
 now used only in the form of half-manufactured wares. 
 The furriers work up skins already prepared, the smith 
 purchases the finished horseshoe, the glazier ready-made 
 window-frames, the brush-maker cut and bored wooden 
 parts and prepared bristles, the contracting carpenter in- 
 laid flooring cut as desired and doors all ready to ha*"^. 
 
 At first such a loss is generally felt by the handicraft con- 
 cerned as an alleviation rather than an injury. The process 
 of production is shortened; the individual master can pro- 
 duce a greater quantity of finished articles than formerly; 
 and if he reckons on each piece the same profit as for- 
 merly, his income can easily advance provided he retains 
 sufficient work. A locksmith, who procures all door- 
 mountings ready-made from the hardware shop, can 
 readily finish several buildings in one summer, while pre- 
 viously, when he had first to make these wares, he perhaps 
 completed only one. But still, in most cases, through such 
 a cutting into the roots of hand-work, not a few of the mas- 
 ter craftsmen become superthious. At the same time, how- 
 ever, the amount of busiuf'ss cai)ital rec|uired increases, 
 since the craftsman has now to make disl)ursements not 
 merely for the raw inaterial. but also for the costs of pro- 
 <luction of the ]iart!y manufactured jiroduct. and further- 
 more. Ir ■ to furnish the manufacturer's ami tra-I :r's profits 
 as well. 
 
 This is all the more vital, since just in the first-hand pur- 
 chase of the raw material and in its proper selection the 
 greatest profit is often made. For this reason trading 
 l^oi.'.ce* b.avc v,ot infre!j!!!-!'.'!v tnki-!'. over the preparatory 
 
THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 
 
 20X 
 
 Stages in production even where a partial manufacture 
 with machinery is not to be thought of. There is abso- 
 lutely no doubt that the hand-worker in wood was in a 
 better position when he could purchase his wood in the 
 form of logs in the forest than now, when he procures it in 
 the form of boards, laths, and veneers from lumber-dealers; 
 and that the brush-maker worked to greater advantage 
 when he bought the rough bristles from the butcher than 
 now, when he must buy them arranged by the dealer in 
 innumerable classes. 
 
 Of course this trade in partly finished goods is very con- 
 venient for the craftsman; he can obtain from the dealer 
 even the smallest quantities. But it is exactly this that has 
 contributed not a little to the decline of the handicrafts, 
 since the journeyman can now go into business almost 
 without capital. Thus, for instance, in the shoe trade the 
 manufacture of vamps at first greatly promoted business 
 on a small scale, not because it shortened the manufactur- 
 ing process for the shoemaker, but because it placed him 
 in a positior to purchase a single pair of uppers at the 
 shoefinder's where formerly he had to procure from the 
 tanner at least a whole skin. 
 
 This cooperation of mechanical preparatory work and 
 handicraft assumes a particularly interesting form where 
 the wliolc productive part of the labour process drops 
 away from hand-work. The craftsman can then continue 
 to maintain himself only if the product needs to be set in 
 place or fitted. But he sinks back once more almost to the 
 state of the wage-worker. Thus the locksmith and the 
 joiner (the latter for ready-made doors and inlaid flooring) 
 are now but " fitters ""; and the role of the horseshoer nail- 
 ing on ready-made horseshoes is not very dilTerent. 
 
 On the other '..and, the shortci.lng of the process of 
 manufacture makes the business more capitalistic and the 
 
303 
 
 THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 
 
 turnover more rapid. The vital element of handicraft, 
 however, is not the profit on capital, but the labour earn- 
 ings, and these under all circumstances are being curtailed. 
 
 {d) The appearance of nciv rmv materials and methods of 
 production better adapted for manufacture on a large 
 scale than those prev'ously employed in hand-work, handi- 
 caps the latter for a part of this sphere of production. 
 We may cite among other instances the appearance of 
 the curved (Vienna) furniture, the manufacture of wire 
 nails and its influence on nail-smithing, the wire-rope 
 manufacture in opposition to the hempen rope, the in- 
 vasion by gutta percha of the consumption sphere of 
 leather and linen. The enamelled cooking utensil has en- 
 croached simultaneously upon the manufacture of pottery, 
 tinsmithing and the business of the coppersmith; and the 
 invention of linen for bookbinding in place of leather and 
 parchment has smoothed the way for wholesale book- 
 binding by machinery. 
 
 Thus at the most diverse points handicraft is being as- 
 sailed by the modern, more progressive, forms of manu- 
 facture. The attacks, generally delivered in a manner to 
 disarm opposition, are not infrequently made under the 
 fair mask of the stronger friend taking a load from its 
 shoulders, until finally nothing remains to tempt the capi- 
 talistic appetite of the entrepreneur. 
 
 3. We come now to those cases in which handicraft 
 loses it*; independence through being appended to a large 
 business. Every more extensive undertaking, be it manu- 
 facturing, trading, or a general commercial establishment, 
 requires for its own business various kinds of hand-work. 
 As long as such tasks are few i- number, they are given 
 out to master craftsmen. But if they grow more numerous 
 and regular, it becomes advantageous to organize a sub- 
 department for them within the walls nf the establishm.ent. 
 
THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 
 
 203 
 
 1 
 
 Today every large brewery or wine-house has its own 
 cooperage; the street-railway companies maintain work- 
 shops for smiths, saddlers, wheelwrights and machinists; 
 canning factories have their own tinshops; a shipyard 
 keeps cabinet-makers and upholsterers for the internal fur- 
 nishing of its passenger steamers; almost every large 
 manufactory has a machine and repair shop. The master 
 who enters such a large establishment as foreman of the 
 special workshop ceases, of course, to be free from the con- 
 trol of others, but enjoys, on the other hand, a position 
 that is to a certain extent independent, and, above all, se- 
 cure. 
 
 By the free craftsmen, however, the loss of such strong 
 purchasers is most bitterly felt. Indeed, the system de- 
 scribed can lead to the starving out of whole crafts — a fate 
 that has overtaken, for example, turning, which is being 
 appended to all trades using its products in the par- 
 tially manufactured state. But this process is too much in 
 the interests of a good economy to make it possible to 
 check i;. 
 
 The workmen for such subdepartments of a large in- 
 dustrial establishment, be it further remarked, receive as 
 a rule a training in their handicaft as long as it continues 
 to have an independent existence. An abnormally large 
 number of ai)prentices can thus be employed by it, while 
 the journeymen have a much more extended labour market 
 than the handicraft alone could offer. This is the explana- 
 tion, for instance, of the occasional discovery in the lock- 
 smith's trade of ten times as many apprentices as journey- 
 men. 
 
 4. Handicraft is impoverished through shifting of demana, 
 and entirely ruined through cessation of demand. Such 
 shiftings have occurred at all epochs — we may recall the 
 use of parchment and periwigs — hut perhaps never tnnre 
 
204 
 
 THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 
 
 frequently than in our own rapidly moving times. We will 
 give only a few instances. 
 
 The cooper prq)ared for the household of our grand- 
 parents divers vessels now sought for in vain, at least in 
 a city home: meat-barrels, tubs for sauerkraut and beans, 
 washtubs, water-buckets, rain-barrels, even bathtubs and 
 washing vessels. We no longer keep supplies of meat and 
 preserved vegetables; water is furnished us by the water- 
 works system; and the place of the small wooden vessels 
 has been taken by those of tin, china, or crockery. A sec- 
 ond example is offered by the turner, who formerly had to 
 supply almost every household with a spinning-wheel or 
 two, spools and reels. To-day the spinning-wheel has sunk 
 to the position of an " old German " show-piece. Botli in- 
 dustries have, of course, found fresh purchasers for those 
 they have lost, especially coopering, through the increase 
 of barrel-packing. But the new customers are factories 
 that at the earliest opportunity incorporate the cooperage 
 as a subsidiary department. The industry of the pewterer 
 presents a third example. The pewter plates and dishes 
 that were to be found in almost every house throughout 
 town and country have passed out of fashion. In their 
 place have come porcelain and stoneware, and the pewter- 
 er's trade has thus to all intents lost the very foundation 
 of its existence. Finally, we may recall the shiftings in 
 demand which the great revolutions in the sphere of travel 
 have lirought about, and which have fallen with especial 
 severity on the saddler, trunk-maker and furrier. 
 
 5. In a last group --f instances handicraft come, into com- 
 plete dependence on trade; the master becomes a home- 
 worker, shice his products can now reach the consumers 
 only through the store. The cause of this phenomenon 
 is of a double nature: on the one hand, the high rents of 
 city business sites, whicli force the master to live and pen 
 
THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 
 
 205 
 
 up his workshop in a garret or a rear house where he is 
 with difficulty found, and where at no time is he sought 
 out by his better customers; on the other, the inchna- 
 tion of the pubUc to buy only where a larger selection is 
 to be had, and where the merchant is " accommodating," 
 that is, sends goods for inspection, takes back if they do 
 not suit, articles like brushes, combs, fine basket-maker's 
 wares and leather goods, small wooden and metal articles 
 which in larger towns are now scarcely ever purchased 
 from the producer or outside the fancy-goods and hard- 
 ware stores. Indeed, we even give our orders to the stores 
 if we wish to have a special article made. Who to-day or- 
 ders his visiting cards from the printer, or a smoker's table 
 from the cabinet-maker? Anyone who has the oppor- 
 tunity of seeing, along the streets that he must traverse 
 perhaps several times a day, so complete a display of every- 
 thing necessary for his wants that he can in a few minutes 
 procure any desired article, will seldom care out of love 
 for a declinirg handicraft to betake himself to a distant 
 suburb and there, after a long inquiry and search, climb 
 three or four gloomy staircases before he can deliver his 
 order, in the execution of wliich the appointed time will 
 perhaps even then be disregarded. And shall, for instance, 
 anyone who finds in a furniture stock everything that is in 
 any way necessary to the furnishing of a room, shall a 
 young housewife who in a few hours can gather together 
 in a housefurnishing estajlishment a complete kitchen 
 outfit, shall these preferably seek out a half dozen hand- 
 workers from whom they can obtain what they want only 
 after weeks of waiting? 
 
 Such may be regarded as the chief features of the process 
 of transformation that is taking place to-day in hand- 
 icraft. We may, in conclusion, scate it as a matured con- 
 
'Mi 
 
 206 
 
 THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 
 
 viction compelled by the results of the investigations, that 
 in all cases xvhcre it suttH^'S finished goods zi'liicli arc not very 
 perishable, and which can he manufactured in definite styles for 
 average requirements, hand-zcork is endangered in the highest 
 degree. This applies even ivhere a technical superiority on the 
 part of tlic large undertaking does not exist. These are, in 
 short, cases in which the product is suited to immediate 
 consumption without further assistance from the producer. 
 
 In all these instances trade in its various branches, down 
 to that of hawking, will more and more form the uni- 
 versal clearing-house for industrial wares. Handicraft must 
 specialize as far as possible; and it can save itself from the 
 fate of dependence upon the store only by becoming a cap- 
 italized industry on a small scale. The union of a sale shop 
 with the workshop is then indispensable. 
 
 In the contrary instances, where the product of handi- 
 craft must be placed in position or separately fitted, the crafts- 
 man at least does not lose touch with the consumers. But 
 even in such cases he can maintain himself in the large 
 towns only if the demand is strongly centralized (as with 
 locksmiths and generally all craftsmen connected with 
 building in the widest sense), or again if he keeps a shop 
 (as with tinsmithing. saddlery, or ordered tailoring), which 
 serves as a collecting bureau for orders. In both cases a 
 business without some capital lacks sufficient vitality to 
 exist. 
 
 With this conclusion correspond the results of the " In- 
 vestigations into the Conditions of the Handicrafts." 
 Everywhere in the tozvns the relative number of masters 
 has greatly diminished, the number of their assistants in- 
 creased: that is, the businesses have grown. In a still 
 higher degree must their capital have advanced. Mani- 
 festly it is the upper stratum of city handicraftsmen which 
 has here maintained itself by adopting business methods 
 
THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICR/tFTS. 
 
 207 
 
 suited to the requirements of the present, and which 
 probably has prospects of holdinj? its own for some time 
 to come. Where an equal variety is ofifered, the public 
 will always prefer the shop of the master craftsman to that 
 of the pure tradesman, if for no other reason, because of 
 the convenience for repairs and the greater technical 
 knowledge of the master. The latter, moreover, through 
 the custom coming to the workshop, remains protected 
 from that officious idleness to which the city shopkeeper 
 so readily falls a victim. 
 
 In the country conditions have a fairly different aspect. 
 Those causes of repression of hand-work that result from 
 the altered form of demand and the conditions of life in 
 the towns prevail here only in a lesser degree. Rural de- 
 mand is not yet so very concentrated; it is to a large extent 
 of an individual nature; everyone knows the hand-worker 
 and his household personally. Connections with neigh- 
 bours, school comrades or family relatives likewise play 
 a part in holding trade. Here real handicraft soil is still 
 to be found. The craftsman cultivates in many cases a 
 bit of land; at the harvest he will assist his neighbour in 
 mowmg and the like; he possesses a cottage of his own; 
 in short, for his sustenance he is not exclusively dependent 
 upon his trade. In his business wage-work and the system 
 of credit balances « still largely prevail. 
 
 Most of the crafts that have any real footing in the coun- 
 try are in our opinion secure as far as the future can be 
 forecasted. Of course, they cannot completely escape the 
 revolutions in urban industry. In the country the tin- 
 smith, as a rule, no longer makes the tinware he sells, 
 
 •[For a general discussion of credit balances (Gcs^enrcchuMig) as a 
 feature of public ^inancini^ conip. an instructive article by the anttnir 
 in Ztschr. d. Resamt. Staatswiss. for 1896, pp. i fT.: Dcr jffentl. Haus- 
 hatt d. StadI t'r. «»i MilU-iilU-r.—ED.] 
 
3o8 
 
 THE DECLINE OF THE HASDICRAFTS. 
 
 and ♦he smith uses horseshoes purchased ready for 
 use. But the customs connected with consumption change 
 here but slowly; the demand remains more individual, and 
 there is relatively far more repair work; indeed, the agri- 
 cultural machines have brought fresh w rk of the latter 
 type for iron-worker, smith, tinsmiti., cooper, joiner. 
 About fifty-two per cent, of the master craftsmen in Ger- 
 many to-day are found in the country. The country has 
 come to equal the cities in density of hand-worker popula- 
 tion. Certainly the number of separate shops i.. the coun- 
 try is particularly large. In Prussia the average num- 
 ber of persons as assistants has seemingly diminished some- 
 what since 1861; the number of apprentices is relatively 
 high. But in this there is no ground for anxiety. The 
 relation between th .lumber of assistants and the number 
 of masters is much more favourable to-day in rural parts 
 than it was in the cities at the beginning of this century; 
 and the condition of the rural cxsui^n.^ accorair.g to all 
 that has been published on the subject, though modest, is 
 still satisfactory. In this the reports to hand from 
 Silesia, Saxony, East Friesland, Baden, and Alsace agree. 
 There are certainly some village craftsmen leading very 
 meagre lives; but such there have been in handicraft at 
 
 all times. 
 
 Among those who consider handicraft the ideal form 
 of industrial activity two means have long been extolled 
 for restoring solid footing and strength to the tottering 
 industrial middle class; and there are many who still believe 
 in their efficacy. 
 
 The first is the "return to artistic zcork." Efforts of this 
 kind have been diligently fostered for well-nigh twenty- 
 five years. For their encouragement museums, technical 
 schools, and apprentice workshops have been instituted. 
 But experience has soon taught, and the investigations of 
 
THE DECLINE OF THE HANDlCR/tFTS. 
 
 309 
 
 the Social Science Club have confirmed it anew, that these 
 efforts have borne very little fruit for the small trader. 
 Ironwork alone has gained at a few points through the re- 
 newed employment of wrought-iron trellis-work, stair bal- 
 ustrades, chandeliers, and the like. Otherwise all establish- 
 ments successfully carrying on artistic industry are manu- 
 facturing businesses of a large, and indeed of the largest, 
 type. This is the case, for example, with bookbinding, art 
 furniture, pottery 
 
 The second means is the extension of small power ma- 
 chines and the electrical transmission of power, which shall 
 enable the smallest master to obtain the most impor- 
 tant labour-saving machines. Even men like Sir William 
 Siemens and F. Reuleaux have placed the greatest hopes 
 on the popularizing of these technical achievements. These 
 expectations they have based upon the beliet that success 
 is simply a question of removing the technical superiority 
 of the large undertaking, this superiority resting indeed 
 in great part upon the employment of labour-saving ma- 
 chines. 
 
 In this they have curiously overlooked the fact that 
 mechanical power is the more costly the smaller the scale 
 on which it is employed. According to a table given by 
 Riedel in the Ccntralblatt deutschcr Ingenieurc for 1891, 
 the conparative expenses of a small motor working ten 
 hours per day and horse-power are as follows (in cents — 
 four pfennigs equal one cent): 
 
 Type of Motor.' 
 
 Small steam 
 
 Gas 
 
 Compressed air. 
 
 Electrical 
 
 Petroleum 
 
 Horse-power of Motor. 
 
 1/4 
 
 13 
 10} 
 
 9j 
 ..1 
 / 1 
 
 i3i 
 20 
 
 7i 
 
 6 
 
 61- 
 Ili 
 15 
 
 4i 
 5 
 10 
 8| 
 
 4t 
 4i 
 4i 
 
 9t 
 
 6i 
 
 3i 
 
 'si* 
 
 'The price of gas is taken at 3 cents per cubic metre. 
 
2IO 
 
 THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 
 
 f 
 
 To place two businesses on a footing of technical equal- 
 ity is thus not to give them industrial equality. A machine 
 must be fully utilized and able to pay for itself if it is to 
 cheapen producton. As it cannot take over the whole 
 process of production, but only individual parts of it, it 
 presuppo.es, if it is to remain continuously in action, an 
 expansion of the business, the employment of a larger 
 number of workmen, greater outlays for raw material, 
 rent of workshop, etc. For this tiie sma.i master generally 
 lacks the capital. Did he possess it. the advantages 
 of more favourable purchase of raw material, of greater di- 
 vision of work, of employment of the most capable tech- 
 nical and artistic workmen, and of l^etter chances of sale 
 would always remain with the large undertaking.* It is 
 difficult to imagine how shrewd men could o^'erlook r.ll 
 this. Has the tailor's, shoemaker's, or saddler's handicraft 
 gained in vitality through the sewing-machine? 
 
 The hDpe of finding through these two devices a new 
 ba>is for handicraft must be abandoned; in most indus- 
 trial branches in the larger cities there is no longer any 
 such footing. Only in so far as the conditions of custom 
 work continue unaltered does there remain room for a 
 limited number of businesses leavened with capital. In 
 these other persons take the place of the craftsmen; small 
 and moderately large entrepreneurs, foremen of the fac- 
 
 ' An interest! riR proof of what has been said is oflfered by the wood- 
 turninn machines in cal)inet-makinn. None of the many larger handi- 
 craft shoi)s in the cabinet trade of Berlin (anions which are also some 
 wdl-'ounded businesses of niu.lerate si/c. with twenty or more work- 
 men) have adopted tin ^e machines in their work, although mechanical 
 piiwer of anv strength is to be rented in many worlshoi."! in the city 
 at a c.miparatively moderate price. It sr - rather to be the case that 
 small independent want-paying shops 1 been opened which take 
 
 charge of the cutting and fitting; and y t'l- largest furniture fac- 
 tories and cabinet-making establishmcn ha- ' up those machines 
 in their !in<ines<. 
 
THE DECLIUE OF THE H/INDICR/IFTS. 
 
 21 I 
 
 
 tory v'O '..shops and skilled factory hands, contractors and 
 hoLic-workcr,-? Fxternally all these groups, with the ex- 
 cef .'\o\ of the last, are better situated than the majority 
 of tr.e ^niall master? of the past. Whether they are better 
 satisfied anci i-iii^picr is another question. 
 
 Here, however, we are dealing rather with the tendency 
 of the development than with the actual conditions of to- 
 day. But we must not be deceived. The decline takes 
 place slowly and silently; great misery, such as prevailed 
 among the hand-weavers when they fought their forlorn 
 battle against the mechanical spinning-mule, is found, with 
 rare exceptions, only in the clothing industries. Certain 
 grades of city population have ever remained true to the 
 handicraftsman, and will be faithful for some time to come. 
 There thus remains time for the coming generation to 
 adapt itself to the new conditions. What it needs for the 
 transition is a better general, mercantile and technical edu- 
 cation. The thrifty, cautious person still finas opportunity 
 to carry on work and gain a position; he is not so destitute 
 and at a loss as those who leave school and workshop with 
 insufficient equipment for life. 
 
 It is our conviction that the process in question cai.not 
 be arrested by legislation, though it may perhaps be re- 
 tarded. But would that be a gain? 
 
 In the preceding chapter the evolution of systems of 
 industry was compared with the development of the ma- 
 chinery of commerce, in which the earlier forms were, it 
 is true, pressed ba'k. though not destroyed, by the new. 
 The comparison is applicable likewise to handicraft. 
 Handicraft as a form of work is not perishing::; it is only be- 
 ing restricted to that sphere in which it can make the most 
 of its peculiar advantages. That sphere to-day is the 
 country, the districts where it still finds the conditions of 
 existence that gave birth to it in the Middle .\ges. 
 
Zl2 
 
 THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. * 
 
 In rural Germany we have at present, according to tol- 
 erably exact estimates, some six hundred and evemy 
 rousand maste. craftsmen and more than a half m.lhon 
 housana m • ^, together about one and 
 
 journeymen and apprentices, or i ^ kaa\„„ the 
 
 one-f^fth millions engaged in active worl. Adding the 
 n^embers of the masters' households we have at a low 
 estimate, a total of over three million persons. The largest 
 paTof this numerical success has been achieved by haiidi- 
 craft in our own century. From the socio-pol.tical stand- 
 pott there is no ground for weeping with the masters of 
 {^he small country hamlets who have lost their rural cus- 
 tomers. Rather the contrary. 
 
 During the period of the jealous exclusiveness oi the 
 town guilds, when one could pass on the highway t ou- 
 sands of journevmen who could nowhere obtam admit- 
 ance to mastership, the journeymen smiths had a saying 
 which the stranger at the meeting-house had to recite to 
 the head journev man." It ran: " A master I have not 
 been as vet. but hope to become one in time, if not here, 
 then elsewhere. A league from the ring, where the dogs 
 leap and break the hedges [town limits], there it is good 
 
 to be a master." ... u _ 
 
 Settlement in the country, at that time the sheet-anchor 
 of the journevman smith, still saves many thousands of 
 craftsmen who do not feel themselves ec,ual to the demands 
 of citv life For the country an important social and eco- 
 nomic a.lvance lies in this admixture of industrial elements 
 among the people; and the livelihoods there resting upon 
 the foundation of handicraft are among the most whole- 
 some ofTered by present society. Of course, they are to 
 be measured by the natural standanl of early hand-work, 
 
 •Comp. L. Stock, C.rund-.ugc d. Vcrfassung d. Gcscllenwcscs d. 
 deulsch. Handwtrker. \k >*-' 
 
THE DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 
 
 213 
 
 not by the artificial standard taken from the phantasy of 
 economic and political romancers. 
 
 For just there lies the seat of the complaints and griev- 
 ances which since the beginnings of modern development 
 have been raised so persistently by the surviving repre- 
 sentatives of urban craftsmen, that they have given rise to 
 a false impression of the degree of comfort that handicraft 
 as an industrial system can possibly attord its representa- 
 tives. This standard was comparatively high in the Mid- 
 dle Ages, because the hand-worker's position in life was 
 then measured by the position of those in the social grade 
 lying next below his own, from which he himself had often 
 come — the class of villein peasantry, the " poor people " 
 of the country. Compared with this unspeakably op- 
 pressed class, handicraft had "golden soil." for it regu- 
 larly yielded a money return and secured its members 
 civil freedom, while the peasant was exj d to all the 
 vicissitudes of agriculture and to the oppressions of the 
 owners of the soil. It would be false to assume that the 
 mediaeval craftsmen had on the average considerable cap- 
 ital ; and it was almost the same with the smaller tradei . 
 With what lay beyond — patrician families and nobility — 
 the craftsman did not compare himself: under the system 
 of classes founded upon birth the individual is satisfied if 
 he obtains what is due his class. 
 
 Our social system of to-day rests upon classes deter- 
 mined by occupation. In such a system everyone com- 
 pares himself with all others, because no legal barrier sep- 
 arates him from the rest. In comparison with the other 
 classes of modern society, the position of handicraft, 
 even where it is still capable of holding its own, ap- 
 pears a very modest one. A*! other classes would seem 
 to have raised themselves, and the hand-worker class alone 
 to have remained stationary. Where hand-work is strug- 
 
 1 
 I 
 
 -A 
 
fflp^- 
 
 ^^ 
 
 "wS 
 
 np J 
 
 H 
 
 Hi 
 
 In 
 
 fe 
 
 l|H 
 
 H 1 
 
 *!^'l 
 
 1h i 
 
 mm 
 
 li 
 
 i >'V^9 
 
 ^m- 
 
 .-iS-j 
 
 K i 
 
 8I4 
 
 r«£ DECLINE OF THE HANDICRAFTS. 
 
 gling for its very existence, it presents a sad picture of 
 oppression. 
 
 It is certainly not a spectacle to be viewed with com- 
 posure to see that broad stratum of small independent 
 persons who formed the heart of the early town popula- 
 tions disappear and yield place to a disconnected mass of 
 dependent labourers. It is a loss to society for which we 
 find in urban soil no present compensation. 
 
CHAPTER VI. 
 
 THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 
 
 The close connection existing in Germany between 
 scientific investigation and university instruction, while 
 exhibiting many unquestionably pleasing features, has this 
 one gjeat disadvantage, that those departments of knowl- 
 edge which cannot foim the basis of an academic career are 
 inadequately investigated. This is the fate of journalism. 
 While in France and England the history of journalism 
 presents an extraordinarily rich and developed literature, 
 we in Germany possess but two essays worthy of mention, 
 one treating of the beginnings, the other, in a decidedly 
 fragmentary manner, of the later development of the daily 
 press.* 
 
 In this condition of affairs there would be little profit 
 in determining to which of the existing departments of 
 scientific research this neglected tUok really falls. A sub- 
 ject so complex as journalism can be treated with advan- 
 tage from very different standpoints: from the standpoint 
 of political history, of literary history, of bibliography, of 
 law. of philology even, as writings on the slovenliness of 
 journalistic style give proof. The subject is, without 
 doubt, of most direct concern to the political economist. 
 
 ' The little book by Ludwig Salomon. Ctsck. d. deulsch. Zeitungs- 
 tcesciis von J. erst. Anfang. b\s s. Wicderaufricht. d. Deutsch Retches, 
 I, igoo. with its incomplete treatment of the subject, cannot materially 
 alter this opinion. 
 
 «I5 
 
2l6 
 
 THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 
 
 For the newspaper is primarily a commercial contrivance, 
 forming one of the most important pillars of contemporary- 
 economic activity. But in vain do we search economic 
 text-books, and even commercial manuals in a narrower 
 sense, for a paragraph on the daily press. If, under these 
 circumstances, we venture a brief and summary treatment 
 of the beginnmgs of journalism, we are ourselves most 
 fully conscious of our inability to make more than a partial 
 presentation, and in so far as economic method is incapable 
 of exhausting the material in all its phases, of the possible 
 necessity of deceiving legitimate expectations. 
 
 Our descriptions of the beginnings of journalism will 
 vary with our conceptions of what a newspaper is. If the 
 question. What is a newspaper? be put to ten different 
 persons, perhaps ten different answers will be received. 
 On the other hand, no one who is asked to name the 
 agencies that weave the great web of intellectual and ma- 
 terial influences and counter-influences by which modern 
 humanity is combined into the unity of society will need 
 much reflection to give first rank to the newspaper, along 
 with post, railroad, and telegraph. 
 
 In fact, the newspaper forms a link in the chain of mod- 
 ern commercial machinery; it is one of those contrivances 
 by which in society the exchange of intellectual and ma- 
 terial goods is facilitated. Yet it is not an instrument of 
 commercial intercourse in the sense of the post or the rail- 
 way, both of which have to do with the transport of per- 
 sons, goods, and news, but rat'ier in the sense of the letter 
 3nd circular. These make the news capable of transport, 
 only l)€cause they are enabled by the help of writing and 
 printing to cut it adrift, as it were, from its originator, and 
 give it corporeal independence. 
 
 However great the difference l)etween letter, circular, 
 and newspaper 5nay appear to-d.iy, .a little reflection shows 
 
THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 
 
 217 
 
 that all three are essentially similar products, originating 
 in the necessity of communicating news and in the em- 
 ployment of writing in its satisfaction. The sole difference 
 consists in the letter bemg addressed to individuals, the 
 circular to several specified persons, the newspaper to 
 many unspecified persons. Or, in other words, while letter 
 and circular are instruments for the private communication 
 of news, the newspaper is an instrument for its publication. 
 
 To-day we are, of course, accustomed to the regular 
 printing of the newspaper and its periodical appearance 
 at brief intervals. But neither of these is an essential char- 
 acteristic of the newspaper as a means of news publication. 
 On the contrary, it will become apparent directly that the 
 primitive paper from which this mighty instrument of 
 commercial intercourse is sprung appeared neither in 
 printed form nor periodically, but that it closely resembled 
 the letter from which, indeed, it can scarcely be distin- 
 guished. To be sure, repeated appearance at l^rief inter- 
 vals is involved in the very nature of news publication. 
 For news has value only so long as it is fresh; and to pre- 
 serve for it the charm of novelty its publication must follow 
 in the footsteps of '.^' events. We shall, however, soon 
 see that the periodicity of these intervals, as far as it can 
 be noticed in the infancy of journalism, depended upon the 
 regular recurrence of opportunities to transport the news, 
 and was in no way connected with the essential nature of 
 the newspaper. 
 
 The regular collection and despatch of news presupposes 
 a wide-spread interest in pul-lic affairs, or an extensive 
 area of trade exhibiting numerous commercial connec- 
 tions and combinations of interest, or both at once. Such 
 interest is not realized until people are united by some 
 more or less extensive political organization into a certain 
 community of life-interest. The city republics of ancient 
 
2l8 
 
 THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 
 
 times required no newspaper; all their needs of publica- 
 tion could be met by the herald and by inscriptions as oc- 
 casion demanded. Only when Roman supremacy had em- 
 braced or subjected to its influence all the countries of the 
 Mediterranean was there need of some means by which 
 those members of the ruling class who had gone to the 
 provinces as ofificials, tax-farmers and in other occupa- 
 tions, might receive the current news of the capital. It is 
 significant that Caesar, the creator of the military mon- 
 archy and of the administrative centralization of Rome, is 
 regarded as the founder of the first contrivance resembling 
 a newspaper.^ 
 
 We say resembling a newspaper, for journalism as now 
 understood did not exist among the Romans; and Momm- 
 sen's mention of a " Roman Intelligence Sheet " ^ is but a 
 distorted modernization. Caesar's innovations are to be 
 compared rather with the bulletins and " laundry-lists " 
 which the literary bureaux of our own governments supply 
 for the use of journalists, than with our modern news- 
 papers. Thus in his case it was not a question of founding 
 journalism, but of influencing the newspapers already in 
 existence. 
 
 Indeed, long before Caesar's consulate it had become 
 customary for Romans in the provinces to keep one or 
 more correspondents at the capital to send them written 
 reports on the course of political movement, and on other 
 events of the day. Such a correspondent was generally an 
 
 * Leclerc, Des journaux ches les Romains (Paris. 18,38). Lieberkiihn, 
 De diurnis Romanorum actis (Vitnar. 1840). .'\. Schmidt, Das Staats- 
 ecitungs'iccsen d. Rihtier, in Zt«chr. f. Gcschichtsw.. I, p. 303 ff. N. Zell, 
 Ober d. Zcitungcn d. alien Rlimcr u. d. DoduiTschen Fragwcnte. in his 
 Ferienschriften, pp. i ff., 109 ff. Hiibner, Pc sciiatus toptiUq^e Romani 
 actis, in Fleckeiscn's Jhrb. f. Philol.. Suppl. III. pp. 5^4 ff. Heinze. 
 Df spuriis diurttorum actorum fragmcnHs (Grcifswald, i860). 
 
 ' Monimjtii. JVuiii. Gcsch., Ill (4ih cd.), p. 60;. 
 
THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 
 
 219 
 
 intelligent slave or freedman intimately acquainted with 
 affairs at the capital, who, moreover, often made a business 
 of reporting for several. He was thus a species of primitive 
 reporter, differing from those of to-day only in writing not 
 for a newspaper, but directly for readers. On recom- 
 mendation of their employers, these reporters enjoyed at 
 times admission even to the senate discussions. Antony 
 kept such a man, whose duty it was to report to him not 
 merely on the senate's resolutions, but also on the speeches 
 and votes of the senators. Cicero, when pro-consul, re- 
 ceived through his friend, M. Ca^lius, the reports of a cer- 
 tain Chrestus, but seems not to have been particularly well 
 satisfied with the latter's accounts of gladiatorial sports, 
 law-court proceedings, and the various pieces of city gos- 
 sip. As in this case, such correspondence never extended 
 beyond a rude relation of facts that required supplement- 
 ing through letters from party friends of the absent per- 
 son. These friends, as we know from Cicero, supplied the 
 real report on political feeling. 
 
 The innovation made by Caesar consisted in instituting 
 the publication of a brief record of the transactions and 
 rcbolutions of the senate, and in his causing to be pub- 
 lished the transactions of the assemblies of the Plebs, as 
 well as other important matters of public concern. 
 
 The first were the Acta senatus, the latter the Acta diurna 
 populi Romani. The publication was made by painting the 
 text on a white tablet smeared with gypsum. The tablet 
 was displayed publicly, and for the inhabitants of the cap- 
 ital was thus what we call a placard. For those abroad 
 copies wer^" made by numerous writers and forwarded to 
 their employers. After a certain interval the original was 
 placed in the archives of the state. 
 
 This Roman Public Bulletin was thus not in itself a 
 newspaper, though it attained the importance of such by 
 
220 
 
 THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 
 
 what we would consider the cumbersome device of private 
 correspondence to the provinces. 
 
 The Acta senatus -ivtre pubHshed for but a short time, 
 being suppressd by Augustus. On the other hand, the 
 Acta dinrna populi Romani obtained such favour in the eyes 
 of the people that their contents could be made much more 
 comprehensive, while their publication was long con- 
 tinued under the Empire. They more and more developed, 
 however, into a kind of court circular, and their contents 
 began to resemble the matter ofifered by the official or 
 semi-ofificial sheets of many European capitals to-day. On 
 the whole, the; confined themselves to imparting facts; 
 their one noti-eable tendency was to ignore the disagree- 
 
 i.b1e. . 
 
 The contents still continued to reach the provmces by 
 way of correspondence; and, as Tacitus tells us, the people 
 had regard not merely for what the official gazette con- 
 tained but also for what it left unrecorded: people read 
 between the lines. How long the whole system lasted we 
 do not know. Probably after the removal of the court to 
 Constantinople it gradually came to an end. 
 
 The Germanic peoples who, after the Romans, assumed 
 the lead in the history of Europe, were neither in civiliza- 
 tion nor in political organization fitted to maintain a sim- 
 ilar constitution of the news service; nor did they require 
 it. All through the Middle Ages the political and social 
 life of men was bounded by a narrow horizon; culture re- 
 tired to the cloisters, and for centuries afifected only the 
 people of prominence. There were no trade interests be- 
 yond the narrow walls of their own town or manor to draw 
 men together. It is only in the later centuries of the 
 MiddleAges that extensive social combinations once more 
 appear. It is first the church, embracing with her hierarchy 
 all the countries of Germanic and Latin civilization, next 
 
THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 
 
 221 
 
 the burgher class with its city confederacies and common 
 trade interests, and, finally, as a counter-influence to these, 
 the secular territorial powers, who succeed in gradually 
 realizing some form of union. In the twelfth and thir- 
 teenth centuries we notice the first traces of an organized 
 service for transmission of news and letters in the messen- 
 gers of monasteries, the universities, and the various spirit- 
 ual dignitaries; in the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries we 
 have advanced to a comprehensive, almost postlike, organ- 
 ization of local messenger bureaux for the epistolary inter- 
 course of traders and of municipal authorities. And now, 
 for the first time, we meet with the word Zcitung, or news- 
 paper. The word meant originally that which was happen- 
 ing at the time {Zcit — time), a present occurrence; then 
 information on such an event, a message, a report, news. 
 
 In particular do we find the word .ised for the com- 
 munications on current political events which were re- 
 ceived by the town clerks from other towns or from indi- 
 vidual friends in the councils of those towns, either as let- 
 ters or as supplements to them, and which are still fre- 
 quently found in their archives. Thus the municipal 
 archives of Frankfurt-on-Main possess as many as i88 let- 
 ters relating to the raids of the Armagnacs in the early 
 forties of the fifteenth century; they are mostly descrip- 
 tions of sufferings and appeals for help from towns in Al- 
 sace and Switzerland. Among them are not less than 
 three accounts of the battle of St. Jacob, one from Ziirich, 
 one from Strassburg. and one from the council of Basel.* 
 
 •Wiilkor, Vrkundcn u. Schrcibcn. bctreff. d. Zug d. Armagnaken: in 
 Neujahrsblatt d. Vcreins f. Gesch. u. Altertumsk. 7.11 Frankfurt-a.-M. 
 for 187,^. 
 
 On the followins section consult: Hatin. Ilistoire politique et Uttcrairc 
 dc la frcssc en France (Paris, i85(H)i), Vol. I, pp. 28 ff., and his Biblio- 
 graphic historiquc ct critique dc la prcsse pcriodique fran(;aisc. prcccdce 
 d'Mn Ess!! hi^ti-'rique ct sUitixtique sur la fiaissance et Ics progrcs dc la 
 
223 
 
 THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 
 
 This reporting is voluntary, and rests upon a basis of 
 reciprocity. It sprang from the common interest uniting 
 the towns against the noble and the territorial powers, 
 and found effective support in the numerous town- 
 messengers who maintained in regular courses — for this 
 reason called " ordinary " messengers— the connection 
 between Upper and Lower Germany. 
 
 In the fifteenth century we find a similar exchange of 
 news by letter between people of high standing— princes, 
 statesmen, university professors — which reaches its high- 
 est development during the era of the Reformation. It is 
 now good form to add to a letter a special rubric, or to 
 insert on special sheets. '" Noz-issima," " Tidings," " New 
 Tidings " or " News." " Advices." Moreover, we already 
 notice how people have ceased to give each other mere 
 casual information abo-n the troubles and distress of the 
 time, and aim at a systematic collection of news. It was 
 especially to the great commercial centres and the trading 
 towns wnich were the centres of messenger activity and 
 the seat of higher education that news items flowed from 
 all quarters, there to be collected and re-edited into letters 
 and supplements, and thence to be diverted in streams in 
 all directions. Ever>-where these written tidings bear the 
 name of newspaper (Zcitini^ or natc Zeitungen). 
 
 The largest part of this correspondence is of a T)rivate 
 
 frcsse pcriodiquc dans Ics Deux Mondes (Paris, 1866), pp. xlv ff.; 
 Leber Dc Vctat red dc la prcsse et des pamphlets depuis ''^^cois 
 JHsqua Louis XIV (Paris. 1834). Alex. Andrews. The .-nrnry ' 
 Bnlish Journalism (London. T850). Vol. I. pp. i^ ff.; Ott.no ... sta^^ 
 periodica, il commercio dci llbri e latipographia tn Italm (Milan- i>* ^ 
 p 7; Roh. Pnit7, r,e!:chichie d. dcutsch. Jouriialismus (Ilanovc- iH^ 
 Vol 1- J Wincklcr, Pie period. Presse Ocstcrrcichs (Vienna, ih^O. ,"C 
 10 ff; Gm>shofT, Pic hncHtehe Zcitung d. XVI. Jah-hundcrts .^ii^£. 
 1877): Steinhauscn, in Archiv f. Post u. Telegraphic. 1895. P' .Ur*. 
 and lli^ Gcschichtc d. dcutsch. Bficfes. 2 vol?. 
 
THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 
 
 223 
 
 character. Men at the centre of political and ecclesiastical 
 activity communicated to each other the news that had 
 come to hand. It was a reciprocal giving and receiving 
 which did not prevent those with a heavy correspondence 
 from multiplying their news-sheets in order to append 
 them to letters to different persons, nor the recipients 
 from redespatching copies of them or circulating them 
 amongst their acquaintances. Princes, it would seem, al- 
 ready maintained at important commercial points their 
 own paid correspondents. 
 
 For a time these written newspapers did not find their 
 way among the masses. The circles for which they were 
 intended were: (i) princes and statesmen, as also town- 
 councillors; (2) university instructors and their immediate 
 cooperators in the public service in school and church; 
 (3) the financiers of the time, the great merchants. 
 
 Almost all reformers and humanists are diligent news- 
 paper correspondents and regular recipients of newspaper 
 reports. This is especially true of Melancthon, whose 
 numerous connections throughout all parts of Germany 
 and the neighbouring countries continually brought him a 
 plentiful store of fresh news, with which he in turn sup- 
 plied his friends, and certain princes in particular. In 
 comparison with his. Luther's and Zwingli's correspond- 
 ence is relatively poor in such tnatter. On the other hand, 
 John and Jacob Stunn. Bucer and Capito of otrassburg, 
 Oecolampadin.N and Beatus Rhenanus of Basel. Hiitzer and 
 Ur'hanus Rhegiu- of Augsburg, Ilier. Baumgartner of 
 NtTremberg, Joachim Camerarius, Bngcnhagen. and oth- 
 ers were very zealous and active in this direction. 
 
 The sources for their news are manifold. Besides oral 
 or written conmuuiications from friends, we know of nar- 
 ratives of incoming merchants, particularly of book-dealers 
 who had visited the Frankfurt fair, reports of letter-car- 
 
m^ 
 
 v\ 
 
 ,24 :he genesis of journalism. 
 
 riers accounts from soldiers returning home from their 
 campaigns, communications from strangers passing 
 through their town or from visiting friends, and especially 
 from students coming from foreign lands to study at Ger- 
 man universities; finally, any items gleaned from foreign 
 ambassadors who happen to be passing through; from 
 chancellors, secretaries, and agents of important person- 
 
 ^^Naturally such oral news collected at random varied 
 creatly in worth, and had first to undergo the editona 
 criticism of the correspondent before being circulated 
 further The news-items based upon written mformation 
 were of much greater importance. It may be of some 
 interest, by following Melancthon's correspondence, to in- 
 quire somewhat into the sources of them.'' , , . ., 
 
 We soon perceive that there were a number of definite 
 collecting centres for the various classes of news. In the 
 forefront of interest at that time stood the Eastern ques- 
 tion, that is, the threatening of the countries of Central 
 Europe by the Turks. Ncv^s of the engagements with the 
 latter came either from Hungary through Vienna, Cra- 
 cow or Breslau, or from Constantinople by sea by way of 
 Venice. The reporters are mostly ecclesiastics, adherents 
 
 of the New Learning. 
 
 On affairs in the South communications came from 
 Rome, Venice, and Genoa, as well as from learned friends 
 in Padua and Bologna. News from France and Spam was 
 procured by way of Lyons. Genoa, and Strassburg; from 
 England and the Netherlands by way of Antwerp and Co- 
 logne; from the countries c.f the North by way of Bremen 
 Hamburg, and Lubeck; from the Northeast by way of 
 Konigsberg and Riga. 
 
 •According to Grasshoff. cited above, pp. 2i^. 
 
THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 
 
 225 
 
 In Germany, Nuremberg was the chief collecting centre 
 for news, partly by reason of its central position, partly 
 because of its extensive trade connections. Anyone de- 
 sirous of receiving reliable and definite information on the 
 doings of the world wrote to Nuremberg or sent thither 
 a representative. Princes like Duke Albert of Prussia 
 and Christian III of Denmark there maintained resident 
 correspondents, whose duty it was to collect and report 
 any fresh items of news. Town officials, councillors, and 
 reputable merchants frequently undertook such an office. 
 Besides Nuremberg. Frankfurt, Augsburg, Regensburg, 
 Worms, and Speier were also important news centres. 
 
 The newspapers that Meiancthon compiled from these 
 various sources are simply historical memoranc'a, selecteo 
 with some care and interspersed at rare intervals with 
 discussions of a political nature, and more frequently 
 with all kinds of complaints and fears, wishes and hopes. 
 Along with the important news from the Emperor's court, 
 from the various seats of war and on the progress of the 
 Reformation, we meet with others reflecting the complete 
 naivete and incredulity of the times: reports of political 
 prophecies, strange natural phenomena, missbirths, earth- 
 quakes, showers of blood, comets and other celestial ap- 
 paritions. 
 
 In the second half of the sixteenth century this species 
 of news-agency received definite form and organization as 
 a business, not merely in Germany, but, apparently even 
 earlier, in Italy, especially in Venice and R^me. 
 
 Venice was long regarded as the birthplace of the news- 
 paper in the modern acceptation of the word. This opin- 
 ion was supported by the extensive use of the name ga- 
 zctta or gazcUc amongst the Latin nations for a newspaper: 
 and this word is to be found eariiest in Venice as the name 
 of the small coin. 
 
 if 
 
326 
 
 THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 
 
 M. 
 
 We will not enter into the accounts — at times rather 
 romantic— that have been given to justify the derivation 
 (in itself improbable) of the name of the newspaper from 
 the name of the coin.' 
 
 In itself, however, there is much to be said for the pre- 
 sumption that journalism, as described above, v»as first de- 
 veloped as a business in Venice. As the channel of trade 
 between the East and West, as the seat of a govern- 
 ment that first organized the political news service and 
 the consular system in the modern sense, the old city of 
 lagoons formed a natural collecting centre for important 
 news-items from all lands of the known vvorld. Even 
 early in the fifteenth century, as has been shown by the 
 investigations of Valentinelli, the librarian of St. Mark's 
 Library, collections of news had been made at the instance 
 of the council of Venice regarding events that had 
 either occurred within the republic or been reported by 
 ambassadors, consuls, and officials, by ships' captains, mer- 
 chants and the like. These were sent as circular despatches 
 to the Venetian representatives abroad to keep them 
 posted on international affairs. Such collections of news 
 were called fogli d'azi'isi. 
 
 Later on, duplicates of these official collections were 
 made, though evidently not for public circulation, but 
 rather for the use of prominent citizens of Venice who 
 sought to derive advantage from them in tiicir commercial 
 operations, and also communicated them by letter to their 
 business friends in other lands. 
 
 This appending of political news to commercial corre- 
 spondence, or the enclosing of the same on special sheets, 
 soon became the practice also among the lartjc traders 
 of Augsburg. Nureniburg. and the other German towns. 
 
 • Comp. Hatin, Bibliograpkie dt la presse perioduiue, p. xlvii. 
 
 19 I 
 
THE GENESIS OF JOURN/fUSM. 
 
 227 
 
 By and by it occurred to some that the collection and 
 transmission of news by letter could be made a source of 
 profit. In the sixteenth century we find on the Venetian 
 Rialto, between the booths of the changers and gold- 
 smiths, an independent news-bureau that made a business 
 of gathering and distributing to interested parties polit- 
 ical and trade news: information as to arrival and clearance 
 of vessels, on prices of wares, on the safety of the high- 
 ways, and also on political events.'' Indeed, a whole guild 
 of scrittori d'awisi grew up. In a short time we meet with 
 the same people in Rome, where they bear the name nov- 
 ellanti or gazettanti. Here their activity, whether because 
 they circulated disagreeable f' ':ts or accompanied their 
 facts with their own comments, became discomforting to 
 the Curia. In the year 1572 not less than two papal bulls 
 were issued against them (by Pius V and Gregory XIII); 
 the writing of " advices " was strictly forbidden, and its 
 continuance threatened with branding and the galleys. 
 Nevertheless we continue to meet numerous indications 
 of a news service from Rome to the Upper Italian cities 
 and to Germany. 
 
 In the meantime, newspaper writing had also become a 
 business in Germany with an organization that, for the 
 existing conditions of trade, is really wonderful. This 
 organization is connected on the one hand with the further 
 develojjment of despatch by courier, and on the otner with 
 Emperor Maximilian's institution of the post from the 
 Austrian Netherlands to the capital, Vienna, by which the 
 regular receipt of news was greatly facilitated. We thus 
 find, at various places, in the second half of the sixteenth 
 century, special correspondence bureaux which collect .md 
 communicate news by letter to their subscribers. Several 
 
 'According to Prutz, Ctsch. d. Journalismus, I, p m. 
 
ml 
 
 s\ 
 
 228 
 
 THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 
 
 collections of these epistolary newspapers have been pre- 
 served: for instance, one from 1582 to 1591 in the Grand 
 Ducal library in Weimar, and two in the University li- 
 brary at Leipzig from the two last decades of the same 
 century.® 
 
 Let us refer briefly to the oldest year of the Leipzig col- 
 lection. It bears the heading: " News to hand from 
 Nuremberg from the 26th of October Anno '87 to the 26th 
 of October Anno '88." Then follow in independent group- 
 ings transcripts of the news received weekly from Rome, 
 Venice, Antwerp, and Cologne at the office of the Nurem- 
 berg firm of merchants, Reiner Volckhardt and Florian 
 von der Bruckh, and thence given out again either by the 
 house itself or by a special publisher. The person who re- 
 ceived the present collection was probably the chief city 
 clerk of Leipzig, Ludwig Triib. 
 
 The communications from Rome are as a rule da*ed 
 about six days earlier than those from Venice, and the 
 Antwerp correspondence about five days earlier than that 
 from Cologne. All four places lay on the great post-routes 
 from Italy and the Netherlands to Germany. Along with 
 these periodical communications irregular ones appear 
 now and then, for instance, from Prague and Breslau, and 
 particularly often from Frankfurt-on-Main. 
 
 Examining the contents of these news-items more 
 closely we soon find that we have to do not with events 
 occurring in Rome, Venice, Antwerp, etc.. but with re- 
 ports collected at these places. Thus the correspondence 
 from Antwerp contained not merely news from the Neth- 
 erlands, but also from France, England, and Denmark; by 
 way of Rome came news not only from Italy, but from 
 Spain and the south of France as well; from Venice came 
 
 " Comp. Jyt. Oixl, Die Anfangf d deulsch. /Uilungstrcsst in Archiv 
 f C;t:bch. d. d'jlU- !>. Miu-Iihaiuiels. \'ol. Ill (1^50). 
 
THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 229 
 
 news from the Orient. The reports are soberly descriptive 
 and commercial in tone. Political items preponderate; 
 communications on trade and commerce appear less fre- 
 quently. There is no trace of the favourite tales of won- 
 ders and ghosts. 
 
 But how was the news service in these four great collect- 
 ing points organized? Who were the collectors and the 
 intermediaries? How were they paid? What were their 
 sources of information? Unfortunately we can answer 
 only part of these questions. 
 
 In the first place, as to the sources from which the au- 
 thors of the letters derive their information, they them- 
 selves appeal at times even to the last mail or to the regular 
 messenger service, the " Ordinari." Thus we read in a 
 letter from Cologne dated February 28, 1591: "The let- 
 ters from Holland and Zeeland, and also from Italy, have 
 not yet appeared." In a similar letter from Rome of date 
 February 17, 1590, we are informed that the postmaster 
 there has contracted with the Pope to establish a weekly 
 post to and from Lyons; and at the close we read, " In this 
 way we shall have news from France every week." 
 
 Nothing more than this is to be gleaned from the collec- 
 tion itself. When, however, we notice contemporaneously 
 in several German cities that it is the heads of the town- 
 couriers and the imperial postmasters who in particular de- 
 vote themselves to the business of editing and despatching 
 news-letters, the supposition gains greatly in probability 
 that the collection of news is in most intimate connection 
 with the nail service of the time. The messenger mas- 
 ters and the postmasters probably exchanged at regular 
 intervals the news they had collected, in order to pass it 
 on to their particular clients. But the whole matter 
 stands greatly in need of closer investigation." 
 •Steinhausen in Archiv f. Post u. T\\.. 1S.J5, p. J55. expresses merely 
 
f' ! 
 
 230 
 
 THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 
 
 The relations between wholesale trade and newspapers 
 somewhat clearer. Like the Nuremberg merchants 
 mentioned above, some large trading houses in other local- 
 ities had also organized an independent news service. Es- 
 pecially prominent were the Welsers and Fuggers, whose 
 news reports we find in the celebrated letter-book of 
 the Nuremberg jurist, Christoph Scheurl,»° along with the 
 Nuremberg correspondence. In the second half of the six- 
 teenth century the Fuggers had the news coming to them 
 from all parts of the world, regularly collected and appar- 
 ently also published. The title of the regular numbers was 
 " Ordinari-Zeittungen." There were also supplements, or 
 " specials." with the latest items. The price of one num- 
 ber was four kreuzer; the yearly cost in Augsburg, includ- 
 ing delivery, was 25 florins, and for the ordinari numbers 
 alone, 14 florins. One Jeremiah Krasser, of Augsburg, 
 burgher and newspaper writer, is named as editor. He 
 informs us that he supplied many other gentlemen m 
 Augsburg and district with his news. A file of this organ 
 of publication, so rich in material, for the years 1568 to 
 1604 is found in the Vienna library.'* 
 
 The newspapers of the Fuggers regularly contain news 
 from all parts of Europe and the East, and also from places 
 still further removed: Persia, China and Japan, America. 
 Besides the political correspondence, we have frequent re- 
 ports of har\'ests and memoranda of prices, now and then 
 even communications in the nature of advertisements, and 
 a long list of Vienna firms— how and where all things 
 could now be procured in Vienna. Even literary notices 
 
 a supposition, though indeed a very well grrounded and probable one. 
 on the course of development. , „ , 
 
 " Christoph Scheurl: Brxffbuch. fin Bcilrag :. Geschich. d. Reforma- 
 tion u. ihrer Zett (Sooden u Knaake, Potsdam. 1867-187^). 
 
 " S.cket. Weimar Jahrb. f. dcutsche Sprache «. Litteratur. I. p. M^ 
 
THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 
 
 231 
 
 of recent and noteworthy books appear; and there is one 
 account of the presentation of a new drama. 
 
 As in Augsburg, so in other places in Germany we meet 
 individual correspondents — ^journalists (Zeitunger), novel- 
 ists — who carry on their newspaper writing in the service 
 of princes or of cities. Thus in 1609 the elector of Saxony, 
 Christian II, made a contract with Joh. Rudolf Ehinger, 
 of Balzhein in Ulm, whereby the latter undertook for a 
 yearly fee of 100 florins to furnish reports upon events in 
 Switzerland and France, Swabia naturally being included. 
 In the year 1613 Hans Zeidler, of Prague, received from 
 the Saxon court for similar service a yearly salary of 300 
 florins, together with 3319 thalers 6 g. gr. for expenses 
 incurred in collecting his news.'^ In the same year the 
 sovereign bishop of Bamberg had newspapers forwarded 
 to him by a Dr. Gugel, of Nuremberg, for a fee of 20 flor- 
 ins. In the year 1625 the town of Halle paid the news cor- 
 respondent. Hieronymus Teuthorn, of Leipzig, the sum of 
 two schock, eight groschen. as quarterly fee; and as late as 
 1662 the council of the town of Delitzsch was subscriber to 
 a newspaper correspondence from Leipzig at a quarterly 
 fee of two thalers. The postmasters and messenger chiefs 
 appear to have been paid somewhat l>etter for their ser- 
 vices, which were indeed more valuable. At least, we 
 know that in the year 1615 the postmaster at Frankfurt, 
 Johann von der Birghden. who furnished a great number 
 of German princes with news.*'' was in receipt of a yearly 
 salary of 60 florins for supplying the electoral court of 
 Mainz with the weekly newspapers.'* 
 
 "C. D. V. Witzk'bcn. Gesch. d. Leifsiger Zeitung (Leipzig, i860), pp. 
 5-6. The Saxon court in i6.'9 maintained similar agents in Vienna, 
 Berlin. Brunswick, .\ugsburg. Ulm, Breslau, Hamburg, Liibec, 
 Prague, Amsterdam, at the Hapiie. and in Hungary. 
 
 "Comp. Opel, as above, pp 28, (6 
 
 "'* Fauthaber, Gesch. </. I'vst m Irankiurl-a.-M. (Archiv, f. Frankf. 
 Gesch. u. Kunst. New Series, XI. pp. 31, toff. 
 
ill 
 
 232 
 
 THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 
 
 Even in the seventeenth century the wrritten newspapers 
 appear not to have made their way to wider circles. They 
 were still too costly for that. 
 
 At the close of the sixteenth and in the seventeenth 
 century we find written newspapers in France and Eng- 
 land, as well as in Germany and Italy. In France they are 
 -" " ed nouvellcs a la main; in England, news-letters. In both 
 countries they are confined to the capital city. 
 
 The line of development in Paris is the more interest- 
 ing: it may be said indeed that the most primitive of all 
 newspapers, the precursor of the written newspaper, is to 
 be found there. It is the related, or spoken, paper." 
 
 In the turbulent times of the sixteenth and seventeenth 
 centuries groups of Parisian burghers would assemble each 
 evening on the street corners, on the Pont Neuf, and on 
 the public squares, bringing together the news of the day 
 and making their own comments upon it. As is easily 
 conceivable, there were among these groups individuals 
 who became adepts in the collection and repetition of news. 
 Gradually method and organization were introduced; the 
 so-called nouvellistes held regular meetings, exchanged 
 their news with each other, and made comments thereon, 
 discussed politics, and laid plans. 
 
 " Comp. Hatin, Histoire de la presse en France, Vol. I, pp. 32-33- I An 
 interesting present-day instance of the " spoken " newspaper, which 
 may indeed nut be so very rare a phenomenon, is given in a sketch 
 of Swiss life in the little village of Champcry by a recent writer in 
 the Canadian Magazine. " On three of the houses of the village," it 
 is stated. " are curious balconies, which are in reality old pulpits, 
 once used for open-air preaching. They now serve the place of the 
 country newspaper, for en Sundays, after mass, a man calls out from 
 them the news of the week, what there is for sale, what cattle have 
 been stolen or have strayed, and other items of interest to those who 
 have come down for the day from the isolation of the high moun- 
 tains."— .S"7t»M Ufe and Scenery, by E. Fanny Jones. Can. Mag., Aug. 
 1898, p. 287.— Ed. i 
 
THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 
 
 233 
 
 The writers of the time treat these groups with never- 
 ending satire; the comic dramatists seize the fruitful theme, 
 and even Montesquieu devotes to them one of the most 
 entertaining of his Lettres Persancs}^ 
 
 What was at the outset a mere pastime for news-hunters 
 and idlers, enterprising brains soon developed into a busi- 
 ness. They undertook to supply regular news to people 
 of rank and standing. Men in high station kept a nouvel- 
 liste as they kept a hair-dresser or surgeon. Mazarin, for 
 instance, paid such a servant 10 livres per month. 
 
 These groups of nouvellistes soon began to seek cus- 
 tomers in the Provinces also, and these, of course, could be 
 supplied only by letter. Each group had its particular 
 editorial and copying bureau, and its special sources for 
 court and official news. The subscribers paid a fixed sum, 
 according to the number of pages that they desired each 
 week. Thus originated the celebrated nouvellcs a la main, 
 which, in spite of many prosecutions on the part of the 
 government, lasted till well towards the end of last cen- 
 tury, and which were often sent abroad as well.'^ That 
 which gave them a firm footing along with the printed 
 newspapers was, to a certain extent, the circumstance that 
 they rendered the secrecy of the government system 
 largely illusory, and further, took the liberty now and 
 then of animadverting on public conditions.'^ 
 
 In England likewise the nczvs-lcttcrs, more especially 
 devoted to furnishing the country nobility with the news 
 of the capital anrl the court, maintained themselves well 
 "(Euvres computes (Paris, 1857), p. 87, Lettre CXXX. 
 "La Gasette de la Rcgencc. janvicr iriS—juin ///p. publicf d'apres le 
 manuscrit inedit conserre a la Ribliolhcque royale de La Uaye. par Le Comte 
 E. de Barthilemy (Paris, 1887) gives a description of the contents of 
 these sheets. 
 
 '* Similarly in Austria: Joh. Winckler, Die period. Presse Oesterreichs 
 (Vienna, 1875), pp ag-q. 
 
 ft 
 
 ft! 
 
234 THE GENESIS OF JOURNAUSM. 
 
 into the eighteenth century. The printed newspapers of 
 that epoch indeed adapted themselves to the system to 
 the extent of appearing with two printed and two un- 
 printed pages, thereby enabling their subscribers to send 
 them to others, enriched with additional notes m writing. 
 
 Thus we see that at about the same time in all the ad- 
 vanced countries of Europe the written newspaper anses 
 as a medium-of course, as yet a decidedly restricted me- 
 dium-of news publication, and maintains itself for more 
 than two hundred years. It is, however, most remarkable 
 that the production of these written news-sheets as a busi- 
 ness can nowhere be traced beyond the period of the in- 
 vention of printing. In this connection the question 
 naturally arises, why the printing-press was not taken into 
 the service of the regular news publication. 
 
 The question is answered by the simple fact that even in 
 young colonial countries with an European population ac- 
 customed at home to printed newspapers, the written pre- 
 ceded the printed news-sheets. This was true of the 
 English colonies in America at the beginning of the eigh- 
 teenth century,- and of the colony of West Australia in 
 18^0 " This proves that it could not have been so much 
 the pressure of the censorship, that so long delayed the 
 employment of the press for news publication, as the lack 
 
 pp, 14 ft.; Hatm. a» *<'"■ P^ ' ' ,,„, ,bat likc«ise in 
 
 (New York. 1873). PP- 5' «• 
 " Andrews, as above, Vul. IT, pp. 3'- ff- ^ 
 
THE GENESIS OF JOURNjIUSM. 
 
 23S 
 
 ; 
 
 of a sufficiently large circle of readers to guarantee the 
 sale necessary to meet the cost of printing. 
 
 However, since as far back as the close of the fifteenth 
 century, special numbers of those written newspapers con- 
 taining matter of a presumably broader interest were fre- 
 quently printed. These were the one-page prints issued by 
 enterprising publishers under the name of " Ncue Zeitmtg," 
 and disposed of at fairs and markets. Collections are to 
 be found in every old library.22 The oldest of these 
 prints is a report of the obsequies of Emperor Frederick 
 III from the year 1493. From that time till the sixteenth 
 century had run its course they continued to hold their 
 own; but with the growth of periodical news-sheets, 
 they became rarer, and finally, in the eighteenth, disap- 
 peared. The earliest numbers bear either no title at all or 
 take their title from the contents. The name Zeitung, 
 or newspaper, for such a loose sheet appears for the first 
 time in 1505. We find, however, various other appella- 
 tions; for example, Letter, Relation, Tale, News, Descrip- 
 tion, Report, Advice, Post, Postilion, Courier, Rumour, 
 Despatch, Letter-bag.^^ To these all kinds of qualifying 
 titles are frequently added, such as Circumstantial News, 
 Truthful and Reliable Description, Faithful Description, 
 Truthful Relation, Review and Contents, Historical Dis- 
 course, and Detailed Explanation; very often we have: 
 New and Truthful Tidings, Truthful and terrible Tidings, 
 Wonderful, terrible, pitiful Tidings. In England some of 
 the titles are: Newes, Newe Newes, Thiding, Woful 
 Newes, Wonderful and strange News, Lamentable News; 
 
 "Treated bibiographically by Weller, Die erstcn deutsch. Zcituugen 
 (Bibliothek d. Iterar. Vereins, Vol. LXI). Supple'..ent to same in 
 the " Germania," XXVI, p. 106. 
 
 "Brief. Relatiot,, Mar, Nachricht, Beschreihung. Bericht. Aviso. Post, 
 Postillion, Kurier, Fama, Depesehe. FeUHsen. 
 
. -.tli.l . 
 
 iilii' 
 
 836 
 
 THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 
 
 and in France: Discours, Memorable Discours, Nouvelles, 
 Recit, Courier, Messager, Postilion, Mercure, etc. 
 
 The titles, we notice, are sensational and pretentious. 
 The contents vary greatly. In the great majority of cases 
 they consist of political news; argument remains altogether 
 in the background. The written news-letters are the chief, 
 though not the sole, source for these fugitive productions 
 of the printing-press. Ordinarily, the one-page prints are 
 independent of each other; and only here and there at the 
 end of the sixteenth century can several consecutive num- 
 bers be instanced; but this is not sufficient to justify us in 
 supposing a periodical issue. These loose sheets, however, 
 at least prepare the way, as regards form and matter, for 
 the printed newspaper with its regular issues. And they 
 render a like service in so far as they awakened among the 
 masses an interest in occurrences reaching beyond mere 
 parish affairs. 
 
 The first printed periodical news collections begin as 
 early as the sixteenth century. They are annual publica- 
 tions, the so-called Postreuter (postilions) or news epit- 
 omes whose contents may in a manner be compared with 
 the political reviews of the year in our popular calendars.** 
 
 These are supplemented by semi-annual news sum- 
 maries, the so-called Relationcs semestralcs or Fair Reports. 
 They were begun between 1580 and 1590 by Michael von 
 Aitzing. They drew their information chiefly from the 
 regular post and traders' newspapers, and for more than 
 two centuries formed one of the chief articles of sale at 
 the Frankfurt fair, and later on at the Leipzig spring and 
 fall fairs as well.^^ The first printed weekly of which we 
 
 "According to Prutz, cited above, p. 179. they appeared as early as 
 the middle of the sixteenth century. 
 
 " F. Stieve, Ueber d. dltest. halbj'dhrig. Zeitungen odtr Missrelationen, 
 u. ir.sbesond. iiber derm Rcgriindcr. Frhm. Michael <on Aitzing: Abh, 
 
THE GENESIS OF jOURNAUSM. 237 
 
 have direct information is a Strassburg sheet, whose num- 
 bers for the year 1609 are found in the University library 
 at Heidelberg, while fragments of later years are pre- 
 served in the public library at Zurich.2« Jt corresponds 
 exactly in matter and form with the regular despatches 
 Y.hich the post brought weekly from :..e chief collecting 
 places of the news trade. It was soon imitated; and after 
 the beginning of the Thirty Years' War the growth in the 
 number of pnnted weeklies was particularly rapid. We 
 have evidence of the exisience of about two dozen in the 
 second and third decades 01 the seventeenth century. They 
 were established chiefly by book-printers; though in 
 numerous places the post assumed, naturally with varying 
 success, the right of printing despatches as a part of its 
 prerogative. While in Frankfurt, Leipzig, Munich. Col- 
 logue, and Hamburg the old connection between post and 
 newspaper continued for a considerable time, the publica- 
 tion of news was in many other towns completely absorbed 
 by the book-printers, a fact of the greatest moment for its 
 further development. 
 
 Germany is the first country that can show printed 
 newspapers appearing regularly at brief intervals. The 
 English and the Dutch claims to the honour of having 
 produced the earliest printed weeklies are now generally 
 abandoned. England can point to nothing similar before 
 
 the year 1622: the first French weeklv sheet appeared in 
 163 1. 2T '* 
 
 der k. bayer Akad. d. Wiss., III. CI. XVI, p. , (Munich. 1881). 
 Cotnp. also Ort.i. Ausfiihrl Abhand. von d. bcriihmtcn zwocn Reichs- 
 *"^sse„ so ,n d. ieichsstadt Frankfurt-a.-M . jahrlk: abgehaltm werden 
 (Frankfurt, 1765] pp. 7,4 ff.; Prutz, as above, pp. 188 IT • J von 
 Schwarzkopf, Ueb^r potitische u. gelehrte Zeitungen in Frankf'urt-a -M 
 
 1802. 
 
 ' Opel, as above, pp. 44 ff. 
 
 ' [See article Nmspapers in the hncy. Brit, and the literature th 
 
 given, — Ed.1 
 
 ere 
 
 *;H 
 
338 
 
 THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 
 
 !■ 
 
 iiill!' 
 
 It will perhaps seem strange that a leap was made di- 
 rectly from half-yearly reports to weekly publications 
 without a transitional stage of monthly reports. It must, 
 however, not be forgotten that the collection of news, as 
 well as the distribution of the news-sheets, had to conform 
 to the peculiar commercial facilities of the time. The most 
 important of these were the fairs and the stage-posts. The 
 semi-annual fairs made possible the distribution of the 
 printed news from one great centre of trade and travel to 
 even the most remote points. But the stage-posts tra- 
 versed the chief trade-routes once a week each way. The 
 leap from the half-yearly to the weekly reports lay thus in 
 the nature of things. 
 
 By the weekly newspapers the impetus was given to the 
 essentially modern development of the press. Yet it was a 
 considerable time before the first daily newspapers ap- 
 peared. This occurred in Germany in 1660 {Leipziger 
 Zcitung), in England in 1702 {Daily Courant), in France in 
 I jjj {Journal de Paris). 
 
 We need not pursue this theme down to our cosmopol- 
 itan papers that appear three times a day. The distin- 
 guishing feature of the latter as contrasted with the written 
 newspaper of the sixteenth century is not so much the 
 magnitude of ♦'^e organization for procuring news and the 
 rapidity in trar.smitting it, as the transformation in the 
 nature of the contents, particularly the advertising, and 
 the influence thereby exerted on pul)lic opinion, and, con- 
 sequently, on the course of the world's history. 
 
 For the sixteenth century the network of agencies for 
 the regular collection of news already described, was with- 
 out doubt magnificent. There runs through it a modern 
 characteristic, the characteristic of uniting individual 
 forces in divided labour towards a single end. In the de- 
 partment of news collection there has been little advance 
 
THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 
 
 »39 
 
 since the sixteenth century. The whole subsequent de- 
 velopment of the newspaper in this direction rests on the 
 separation of news collection from news despatch (post), 
 and on the commercial organization of the former into 
 correspondence bureaux and telegraph agencies. To the 
 telegraph agencies have fallen the duties of the earlier 
 postmasters and news-scribes, but with this difference, that 
 they no longer labour directly for the newspaper readers, 
 but supply the publishing house with half-finished wares, 
 making use in such woik of the perfected commercial ma- 
 chinery of modem times. 
 
 Again, the further development of news publication in 
 the field that it has occupied since the more general 
 ioption of the printing-press, has been peculiar. At the 
 outset the publisher of a periodical printed newspaper dif- 
 fered in no wise from the publisher of any other printed 
 work— for instance, of a pamphlet or a book. He was but 
 the multiplier and seller of a literary product, over whose 
 content he had no control. The newspaper publisher mar- 
 keted the regular post-news in its printed form just as an- 
 other publisher oflFered the public a herbal or an edition of 
 an old writer. 
 
 But this soon changed. It was readily perceived that 
 the contents of a newspaper number did not form an 
 entity in the same sense as the contents of a book or pam- 
 phlet. The news-items there brought together, taken 
 from different sources, were of varying reliability. They 
 needed to be used judicially and critically: in this a polit- 
 ical or religious bias could find ready expression. In a still 
 higher degree was this the case when men began to discuss 
 contempoiary political questions in the newspapers and 
 to employ them as a medium for disseminating party 
 opinions. 
 
 This took place first in England during the Long Parlia- 
 
 n 
 
 %*\ 
 
240 
 
 THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 
 
 m 
 
 ment and the Revolution of 1649. The Netherlands and a 
 part of the imperial free towns of Germany followed later. 
 In France the change was not consummated before the era 
 of the great Revolution: in most other countries it oc- 
 curred in the nineteenth century. The newspaper, from 
 being a mere vehicle for the publication of news, became 
 an instrument for supporting and shaping public opinion 
 and a weapon of party politics. 
 
 The effect of this upon the internal organization of the 
 newspaper undertaking was to introduce a third depart- 
 ment, the editorship, between news collecting and news 
 publication. For the newspaper publisher, however, it sig- 
 nified that from a mere seller of news he had become a 
 dealer in public opinion as well. 
 
 At first this meant nothing more than that the publisher 
 was placed in a position to shift a portion of the risk of his 
 undertaking upon a party organization, a circle of inter- 
 ested persons, or a government. If the leanings of the 
 paper were distasteful to the readers they ceased to buy 
 the paper. Their wishes thus remained, in the final analy- 
 sis, the determining factor for the contents of the news- 
 papers. 
 
 The gradually expanding circulation of the pnnted 
 newspapers nevertheless soon led to their employment by 
 the authorities for making public announcements. With 
 this came, in the first quarter of last century, the extension 
 of private announcements,'^ which have now attained, 
 through the so-called advertising bureattx,^^ some such or- 
 ganization as political news collecting possesses in the cor- 
 respondence bureaux. 
 
 " At first, it would seem, in special advice or intelligence sheets 
 which in many cases come from general agencies (Inquiry of!ices, 
 Bureaux of Information). Comp. F. Mangold, in Basler Jhrb., 1897. 
 
 " AHno»ccn-Exi>ediliontn. 
 
THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 241 
 
 By admitting advertisements the newspaper fell into a 
 peculiarly ambiguous position. For the subscription price 
 it formerly published only news and opinions of general in- 
 terest; now, through all sorts of advertisements, for which 
 it receives special remuneration, it also serves private trade 
 and private interests. It sells news to its readers, and it 
 sells its circle of readers to any private interest capable of 
 paying the price. In the same paper, often on the same 
 page, where the highest interests of mankind are, or at 
 least should be, represented, buyers and sellers ply their 
 vocations in ignoble greed of gain. For the uninitiated 
 it is often difficult to distinguish where the interests of the 
 public cease and private interests begin. 
 
 This is all the more dangerous in that in the course of 
 the past century the subjects discussed on the editorial 
 page of the newspapers have grown to embrace almost the 
 whole range of human interests. Statecraft, provincial 
 and local administration, the administration of justice, art 
 in all its manifestations, technology, economic and social 
 life in its manifold phases, are reflected in the daily press; 
 and since the development of the feuilleton, a good pro- 
 portion of literary and even of scientific products flows 
 into this great stream of contemporary social and mental 
 life. The book as a form of publication — we may have 
 no doubts on the point — loses ground from year to year. 
 
 It is impossible to enter into these matters at greater 
 length. The sole aim of this cursory survey of the mod- 
 ern development of journalism has been to give, from 
 the view-point of historical evolution, the beginnings of 
 the newspaper press their proper setting, and at the same 
 time to show how the gathering of news has been con- 
 ditioned at each epoch by general conditions of trade. 
 
 The Roman newspaper is one feature in the autonomous 
 administration of the wealthy and aristocratic household. 
 
 
 K^\ 
 

 I 
 
 i|' 
 
 I 
 
 
 242 WE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 
 
 A news-clerk was kept, just as was a body-surgeon or a 
 librarian. In most cases he is the property, the slave, of 
 the news-reader, working according to the directions of 
 
 his master. 
 
 In the written newspaper of the sixteenth century there 
 is exhibited the same handicraft character then domi- 
 nating all branches of higher economic activity. The news- 
 writer, on demand and for a definite price, furnishes di- 
 rectly to a circle of patrons the news that he had gathered 
 —in which proceeding he doubtless suits the amount to 
 the latter's needs. He is reporter, editor, and publisher in 
 
 one. 
 
 The modem newspaper is a capitalistic enterprise, a sort 
 of news-factory in which a great number of people (cor- 
 respondents, editors, typesetters, correctors, machine- 
 tenders, collectors of advertisements, office-clerks, messen- 
 gers, etc.) are employed on wage, under a single adminis- 
 tration, at very specialized work. This paper produces 
 wares for an unknown circle of readers, from whom it is, 
 furthermore', frequently separated by intermediaries, such 
 as delivery agencies and postal institutions. The simple 
 needs of the reader or of the circle of patrons no longer de- 
 termine the quality of these wares; it is now the very com- 
 plicated conditions of competition in the publication mar- 
 ket. In this market, however, as generally in wholesale 
 markets, the consumers of the goods, the newspaper 
 readers, take no direct part; the determining factors are 
 the wholesale dealers and the speculators in news: the gov- 
 ernments, the telegraph bureaux dependent upon their 
 special correspondents, the political parties, artistic and 
 scientific cliques, men on 'change, and last but not least, 
 the advertising agencies and large individual advertisers. 
 
 Each number of a great journal which appears to-day is 
 a m.^rvpl of economic division of labour, capitalistic organ- 
 
THE GENESIS OF JOURNALISM. 
 
 243 
 
 ization, and mechanical technique; it is an instrument of in- 
 tellectual and economic intercourse, in which the potencies 
 of all other instruments of commerce — the railway, the 
 post, the telegraph, and the telephone — are united as in a 
 focus. But our eyes can linger with satisfaction on no spot 
 where capitalism comes into contact with intellectual life; 
 and so we can take but half-hearted pleasure in this ac- 
 quisition of modem civilization. It would indeed be diffi- 
 cult for us to believe that the newspaper in its present de- 
 velopment is destined to constitute the highest and final 
 medium for the supplying of news.** 
 
 ** [Comp. Mr. Alfred Harmsworth on The Newspapers of the Twen- 
 tieth Century in North Amer. Rev., Jan. 1901. — Ed.] 
 
 SI 
 
 
• i 
 
 i Uu 
 
 CHAPTER VII. 
 
 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 There is in Germany perhaps scarcely a modern text- 
 book or contemporary course of university lectures on 
 political economy in which some ment.on ,s "ot m^le o 
 the principle of union of labour and some remark offe e 
 thereon. No one has really much to say about it. \ et it 
 is there, and has its traditional place after the section on 
 the division of labour, where, if it be thought at all worthy 
 of it it receives with regularity its paragraph, to come to 
 light' no more in the later text of the book or lecture. 
 
 And so it has been for more than half a century. But a 
 science cannot be lenient with concepts that are not fitted 
 to give a deeper insight into a series of phenomena, simply 
 because thev have once gained currency, it is at length 
 time for a closer investigation of this ancient inyentonal 
 item in order, if it is really unserviceable, to discard ,t. or to 
 assign it its proper place should it be found useful in fur- 
 thering our knowledge. . 
 
 According to the text-books, union of labour is nothmg 
 more nor less than "the other side of division of labour; or 
 " division of labour viewe.l from the standpoint o the or^- 
 ganizing unit;" ' the " correlative of division of labour; 
 "the reverse side of the medal whose obverse side is the 
 
 > Roll, in Philippovicb. (:ru„dr,ss </. toUt. (V/;. (2A cd.). p. 78. 
 • M Mt Crun^irUs d. lolks-.v^rthschaftslfhre. 9 29. 
 
UNlOhl OF L/tBOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 24S 
 
 division of labour," ^ These are all somewhat vague ex- 
 pressions, which on the whole ^>eem to have their origin in 
 the view that if labour is divided it must also be reunited, 
 since the separate parts cannot exist independently. Here 
 then the idea of division of labour is either conceived of 
 very restrictedly — somewhat after the manner of Adam 
 Smith's pin-manufactory — in which case the unifying force 
 is supplied by the capital of the entrepreneur; or the con- 
 ception is broadened to embrace the so-called social 
 division of labour, in which case the labour-uniting element 
 must be furnished by trade; so that union of labour would 
 be synonymous with commercial organization generally. 
 
 In fact, Roscher, who gives the most detailed treatment 
 of the subject, and to whom all later writers resort, re- 
 garded the subject in this light.* Division of labour and 
 union of labour are in his view, " but two different aspects 
 of the same conception, namely, social labour: separation of 
 tasks so far as they would incommode one another, and 
 their union in so far as they aid one another." " The vine- 
 dresser and the flax-grower," he continues, " would neces- 
 sarily die of hunger if they could not count for certain on 
 the grower of grain; the workman in the pin-factory who 
 merely prepares the pin-heads must be sure of his comrade 
 who sharpens the points if his labour is not to be entirely 
 in vain; while the labour of a merchant simply cannot be 
 conceived of without that of the different producers be- 
 tween whom he acts as intermediary." 
 
 The whole phenomenon is thus shrouded in the mists of 
 processes of commerce and of organization; it is made 
 synonymous with economy generally. In particular it alto- 
 gether loses its correlation with the notion of division of 
 
 • Kleinwachter. Die rolksw. Produktion in Schonberg's Handbook, 
 * Pnncifks of Foiiiical Economy (New York, 187S), I, pp. 203-4. 
 
 I 
 
 if 
 
ir 1 ■' 
 
 I 
 
 V 1 
 
 246 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 labour. For the rest, Roscher discusses at length only the 
 constancy of the progress of civilization — which is realized 
 by each generation leaving to its successors the augmented 
 inheritance of its predecessors; and further, the advantage 
 of large undertakings and the association of small ones 
 whereby labour ultimately disappears almost completely 
 from the horizon. 
 
 Roscher in all this goes back to Frederick List,* who, 
 in his theor>- of the development of national productive 
 powers, was the first in Germany, as far as I am aware, to 
 use the expression " union of labour." Moreover, he 
 turned it to peculiar account. Starting from a criticism of 
 the " natural law " of division of labour, neither Adam 
 Smith nor any of his successors have, in List's opinion, 
 thoroughly investigated the essential nature and character 
 of this law or followed it out to its most important conse- 
 quences. The very expression " division of labour " was 
 inadequate, he says, and necessarily produced a false con- 
 ception. He then continues: " It is division of labour if 
 one savage on one and the same day goes hunting or fish- 
 ing, cuts down wood, repairs his wigwam, and makes ready 
 arrows, nets, and clothes; but it is also division of labour 
 if, as in the example cited by Adam Smith, ten different 
 persons share in the different occupations connected with 
 the manufacture of a p:.i. The former is an objective, and 
 the latter a subjective division of labour; the former hin- 
 ders, the latter furthers production. The essential differ- 
 ence between the two is that in the former one person 
 (liviles his work so as to produce various objects, while in 
 the latter several persons share in the production of a single 
 object." 
 
 " Both operations, on the other hand," we read further, 
 
 ' The National System of Political Economy (London, 1885), pp. 149 ff- 
 
UNION OF LABOUR /1ND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 247 
 
 " may with equal correctness be called a union of labour; 
 the savage unites various tasks in his person, while in the 
 case of the pin-manufacture various persons are united in 
 one work of production in common. The essential charac- 
 ter of the natural law from which the popular school ex- 
 plains such important phenomena in social economy, is 
 evidently not merely a division of labour but a division 
 of different commercial operations among several indi- 
 viduals, and at the same time a federation or union of 
 various energies, intelligences and powers in a common 
 production. The cause of the productiveness of these opera- 
 tions is not merely the division, but essentially this union." 
 
 This latter List develops further, and upon it endeavours 
 to base the demand for the establishment of a harmony of 
 the productive pozvers in the nation. The highest division of 
 occupations and the highest unification of the productive 
 powers in material production are found in agriculture 
 and manufacturing. '' A nation devoting itself exclusively 
 to agriculture is like an individual engaged in material 
 production with one arm gone," etc. 
 
 Free these explanations from the ingenious rhetoric of 
 the great agitator, and we find, as so often, that he has 
 been unjust towards Adam Smith. The latter in no way 
 overlooks the fact, as List is frank enough to admit, that 
 division of lal)our postulates a cooperation of forces; and 
 at the close of his celebrated chapter on division of labour 
 he explains expressly that by means of this joint labour 
 the meanest person in a civilized country may attain a 
 more ample accommodation than an African king." But 
 he was keen-sighted enough not to regard this fact, which 
 was involved in the nature of division of labour and iden- 
 tical with it, as an independent economic phenomenon. 
 
 -^.J 
 
 • Book I, Chapter I, towards end. 
 
 
a48 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 i 
 
 H 
 
 m 
 
 '1' ., - 
 
 What purpose would it serve to call the same thing at one 
 time division of labour and at another union of labour, ac- 
 cording as it was viewed from one side or the other? In a 
 young science that would have been only a source of con- 
 fusion. 
 
 Of course the procedure of the Indian who successively 
 hunts, fishes, fells trees, etc., would never have been recog- 
 nised by Adam Smith as a particular instance of division 
 of labour. On the contrar>', he would have designated it 
 undivided labour,^ a condition such as preceded division 
 of labour throughout society. Division of labour is for 
 him something else than division of time. 
 
 Of the factor of time in the disposal of labour List speaks 
 more at length in another place.* He there explains that 
 the individual branches of industry in a country only 
 gradually gain possession of improved processes, machin- 
 ery, buildings, advantages in production, experiences and 
 skill, and all those details of information and connections 
 that insure to them the profitable purchase of their raw 
 material and the profitable sale of their products. It is 
 easier, he believes, to perfect and extend a business already 
 established than to found a new one; easier to produce 
 superior goods at moderate prices in a branch of industry 
 long domiciled in a country than in a newly-established 
 one. " A- in all human institutions, so in industry there lies 
 at the root of important achievements a law of nature that 
 has much in common with the natural law of the division of 
 laboi"- and of the federation of productive forces. Its es- 
 sential feature consists in several successive generations 
 as it were uniting their forces towards one and the same 
 end, and as it were dividing among them the expenditure 
 of energy necessary to its attainment." List calls this the 
 'On his conception of division of labour, compare following chapter. 
 
UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 249 
 
 principle of stability and continuity of work, and seeks to 
 prove its operation in history by a series of examples: the 
 superiority in strength of a hereditary over an elective 
 monarchy, the transmission of the acquisitions of human 
 knowledge *hrough printing, the influence of the caste 
 system upon the maintenance and development of indus- 
 trial skill, the building of cathedrals in the Middle Ages 
 during several generations. The system of public debts by 
 which " the present generation makes a draft on a future 
 gent- ation " is also cited as a peculiariy apt instance of 
 the application of the principle of continuity in work. 
 
 It is easily seen that List here is dealing only with a 
 rhetorically clad analogy to union of labour. This, how- 
 ever, has not prevented later writers from forming out of 
 " continuity of work " a special type of union of labour, 
 although a little reflection might have taught them that it 
 is a phenomenon not at all peculiar to economic activity. 
 Continuity of work is the universal historical principle of 
 social development by which man is distin<^uished from the 
 animal. With each lower animal begins anew a similar 
 existence which runs its course, so far as we know, to-day 
 as thousands of years ago. leaving not a record, not a trace. 
 But each human generation takes over the fruits of the 
 civilization of all preceding generations, and iiands them 
 down with an increase to the succeeding age. This is true 
 not merely of material production but also of art, science, 
 religion, law, and custom. Continuity of work thus forms 
 one of the essential conditions and first postulates of hu- 
 man existence, and there is no reason fo; giving it special 
 treatment in the theory of the econnmic employment of 
 labour, particulariy since it offers for the latter no new 
 instructive points of view. 
 
 Sundry text-books recognise stili a third t\ pe of union 
 of labour, which is said to arise "when several do 
 
 •-■ jj 
 
 -■' ^i 
 
r ^ 
 
 I*' 
 
 »50 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 similar work concurrently, and by virtue of union ob- 
 tain a greater result than would be possible to them work- 
 ing inaividually." Heinrich Rau, who incidenta'ly men- 
 tions this case,* instances temporary companies of forest 
 wood-cutters, of raftsmen, and of reapers. In reality he 
 here singles out a procedure that is not division of labour, 
 although an increased productivity in the labour of the 
 individual results from the simultaneous cooperation of 
 several. This case then, like the one of the varied activity 
 of the Indian mentioned by List, caimot be summarily 
 dismissed as already embraced under the conception of 
 division of labour and as ill-adapted to special scientific 
 treatment. 
 
 Without doubt the real reason for the formation of the 
 concept union of labour and for its long retention in the 
 literature of the science is the vague feeling that there 
 must be an economic principle forming the counterpart rf 
 division of labour. Cooperation it cannot be, for that is 
 identical with certain 'irms of division of labour,^ <^ its 
 " other side." What then is this principle? 
 
 All division of labour is an accommodation of work to 
 limited human capacity. It takes place when a qualitative 
 
 *Grundsatce der I'olksxvxrthschaftslehrc, I. § ii6 (a). Rau appeals to 
 Gioja, who had studied the matter somewhat in his Nuovo prospeUo 
 ddle scienze economiche, I, 87 ff. Moreover Hermann, Staatstv. Untcr- 
 suchungcit, new edition, p. 217, had also given it some attention. He 
 designates it as " the simplest combination of labour." Similarly by 
 the French who distinguish co-operation simple and co-operation cottpkxe, 
 and make the latter identical with division of labour. Comp. Cauwes, 
 Cours d'Econ. pal, I, S 225. 
 
 " For example, subdivision ef labour and division of production, but 
 not division of trade. If various specialists take the place of a general 
 practitioner no cooperation takes place amongst them either in com- 
 mercial dealings or in any other way similar to that amongst the 
 different workers in a factory. 
 
UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 2^1 
 
 \^■iti 
 
 jil; vvould in part lie fal- 
 
 ndciiii'; of strength would 
 
 . >r,l(i not, perhaps, form the 
 
 ;uioi! The labourer, even 
 
 lil 'e driven to help himself 
 
 , tiic first a second activity to 
 
 • r'-. y suitably call this union 
 
 disproportion exists between the work to be done and the 
 individual's capability." 
 
 But there may aiso be a quantitative disproportion be- 
 tween the two factors in two ways: (i) the quantity of 
 work to be done may be less than the available labour- 
 power, and it may jb-. (2) be more than equal to the 
 strength of a sinji, i-idividual. 
 
 In the arst cp tl v ;)'' sic: 1 to e would not be com- 
 pletely utilized \i 1 iu '.-oo-'.er .1,1. d himself to this one 
 line of work. H- c <,>: 
 low, and ai^ ni. ju<. / n- >ir.r. 
 result. Th'^' •, rl< <' - nu 
 basis for a I'l— lUj, 
 in his own pri> ate ii 
 by combining or t re- 
 fill out his leisure lin 
 or combination of labour }- 
 
 In the second case the individual by himself cannot pos- 
 sibly perform the task, or can do so only with a dispropor- 
 tionate expenditure of time and energy. A single work- 
 man, for instance, might, if necessity demanded, succeed in 
 cutting the trunk of a large tree into boards with a hand- 
 saw-; but with what t. uble and needless expenditure of 
 time! If two rien and a whip-saw are called into service, 
 however, the work goes forward not only absolutely but 
 relatively better. Th^ picture of the s w-pit then arises, 
 which at times can still be seen in rural i nber-yards. The 
 union of the workers organizes the lauour of each indi- 
 vidual more productively. If we are to avoid the most 
 lamentable confusions we must no longer designate this 
 procedure union of labour," but at most union of labour- 
 
 "Comp. following chapter. 
 
 " Arbeiisvereinigun^. 
 
 "To distinguish from the first case we would then have to saj 
 
W ' 
 
 15 ll 
 11 If 
 
 
 25a UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 ers. More accurate does it seem, especially in view of the 
 varieties of this process to be mentioned later, to employ 
 the expression labour in common}* In this phrase the 
 personal element, which here comes into prominence, is 
 more clearly expressed. 
 
 Union of labour is then tlie union of different classes of 
 work in one person; labour in common is the concurrent em- 
 ployment of several zcorkers in the accomplishment of one task. 
 In union of labour the same producer turns out various 
 products or combines production with trading or with 
 personal service; in labour in common various labourers 
 produce in common the like product. In the one case the 
 uniting point is in the subject of the work, the labourer, in 
 the other the community lies in the object of the labour. 
 
 The two processes are independent of each other and of 
 division ot labour. They, of course, play their chief 
 role during primitive stages of development and in the 
 lower strata of economically organized society. Two 
 great stages in the economic life of nations might indeed 
 be (liitinguished: a lower one. in which the principle of 
 union of labour and labour in common comes preeminently 
 into play; and a higher one. with the principle of division 
 of labotir predominant. In the same way two sphe-es ot 
 social existence may be distinguished in contemporary 
 economic life: one with pronounced division of labour, the 
 other with union of labour and labour in common. 
 
 In a separate consideration of each of these two phe- 
 nomena \vc had better begin with union of hihoiir. It appears 
 early in the history of peoples. It is universally met with 
 directly the stage of individual search for food is passed. 
 
 "subjective" (personal) uninn of labour; while the first case would be 
 desiKnatcfl as ■ (.l.iective " (material) uiiioti of labour. 
 '♦ Arbciltgctncinichaft. 
 
UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 253 
 
 and when economic motives, be they even of the crudest 
 kind, become discernible in men's transactions. For at 
 that point we everywhere notice the sharp separation of 
 two distinct spheres of production, each of which again 
 contains many subdepartments. One embraces men's 
 work, the other women's work." Essentially the same 
 arrangement, with unimportant variations in detail, is 
 found among all more advanced primitive peoples, and we 
 cannot deny that there is a certain instinctive system about 
 it. Of a division of labour between man and wife one can- 
 not seriously speak, for from all we know none of the occu- 
 pations assigned to either of the two sexes has ever been 
 carried on by the other. 
 
 It must be assumed that this condition of things de- 
 veloped quite naturally. In at., case the statement is false 
 that the stronger man " imposed " ui)on the woman the 
 tasks falling to him. Much rather is it correct to say that 
 each sex 1 s of its own impulse — it might perhaps be said 
 under the stress of environment — created 1 the course of 
 time its own department of production, developed the 
 technical details connected with it, collected the experi- 
 ences, and transmitted them to the following generation of 
 the same sex. Thus these two combinations of tasks, 
 through contiinicd hereditary transmission within the 
 same sex, Iiave almost been evoived into sexual character- 
 istics or functions. The hereditary ta. k of the woman, in 
 which the man was not instructed, formed a species of 
 natural equipment that made her valued by the man and 
 gave her a i)rice. Though it is true that from this 
 grew the conception of the wife as propyl ty of the husband, 
 it is none the less true that the important part played by 
 the wife in production has been not the least important 
 
 A (k'tailcd (liscii^iion of tlu-so, pp. .V» ff., 55. 
 
254 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 factor in the gradual elevation of the rude primaeval union 
 of the sexes to a community of life in which the woman 
 has finally raised herself to equality of rights with the hus- 
 band. 
 
 The economic importance of the union of various tasks 
 in the hands of each sex is essentially of an educational and 
 disciplinary nature. It compelled as it were of itself, at 
 least on the part of the wife, attention to the elements of 
 time at seed-time and at harvest, and finally to a di- 
 vision of time, very crude though it was, for the single day. 
 It is a matter of particular moment in this connection that 
 the preparaiion of grain by means of the primitive rubbing- 
 stone, which is the method employed by most primitive 
 peoples down to :lie present day, makes exceedingly heavy 
 demands upon the operator's time, so that the mere main- 
 tenance of three or four persons required the labuur of one 
 woman.'" 1 1 - ih one of the most important supports of 
 polygamy among these peoi)lcs, and renders it tolerable 
 for the wife. I''or a new spouse brought home Ijy the hus- 
 band always appears to the other wives as a helper to 
 lighten their lot. It is thus comprehen.sible that the posses- 
 .'ion of numerous wives nnist serve as an indication of 
 wealth. We may even assert that the careful employment 
 of time, with which systematic economic action first be- 
 gins, finds its starting-point in the union of labour on the 
 part of the women. 
 
 Moreover, when in the course of subsctiuent develop- 
 ment considerable shiftings took place in the boundaries 
 (if the spiieres of work of both sexes, forcing the wife ever 
 more towards the side of supervising consumption within 
 the household and placing almost all the production in 
 the hands of the husband, the principle of division of 
 
 "Comp Dr \V. Junkir's Travels in Africa, II, pp. 170, 171, and my 
 Arbeit u. Hhylhmm. pp. jS, (». 6l. 
 
UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 255 
 
 labour made itself felt almost solely in man's sphere of 
 work, while to the wife's household management remained 
 the most varied duties of preparing, disposing, cleaning, 
 and repairing. The course of these latter really deter- 
 mines the division of time in our daily life. 
 
 To be sure, union of labour has not on that account dis- 
 appeared completely from the economic world. Agricul- 
 ture still embraces occupations varying greatly from one 
 another; everywhere in civilized lands its development has 
 been intimately connected with cattle-raising, while sub- 
 sidiary industries are often included within its sphere. 
 It is indeed one of the most important tasks of the farm- 
 director so to arrange matters that the working powers of 
 man and beast can he turned to full account in as many 
 ways and in as regular a manner as possible. In the change 
 of activity following the seasons of the year there is, even 
 in large agricultural undertakings, but little room for sub- 
 division of work and specialization; different kinds of oc- 
 cupations must always be united in one person, and among 
 the women workers a clear division into farm hands and 
 household servants is not feasible. 
 
 Similar considerations hold for forestry, in which keen 
 practical men condemn the system still common in many 
 places of having specialized labour for each season.'^ and 
 demand the employment throughout the whole year of a 
 permanent staff of all-round workmen. Such a require- 
 ment can be met only on the basis of union of labour. 
 
 In industry handicraft has frotn time itnmemorial been 
 founded on union of labour. It was not the highest pro- 
 ductivity that determined the mutual delimitation of the 
 departments of pro<luction. but regard for the daily bread 
 which each master was to find in his craft. The number- 
 
 " Comp. Fr. Jentsch, Die Arbeiten'erhiilt. in d. Forstwirth. d. Staats 
 (Berlin. i88j). 
 
256 UNION OF L/IBOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 less disputes between different guilds as to the limits of 
 their trade which fill the pages of industrial history during 
 the last few centuries continually raised discussions on the 
 practicableness of this or that combination. In the age 
 of industrial freedom handicraft has also advanced in the 
 large cities in the direction of specialization; in the smaller 
 towns the old combinations have been retained, and m 
 countrv parts new ones are still arising each year. The ma- 
 son is here often plasterer, painter, and paper-hanger as 
 well, while in winter he serves for wage as butcher; the 
 smith is at the same time locksmith and chief engineer of 
 the threshmg-machinc; paper-hanging is cared for now by 
 the saddler, now by the painter, now by the bookbinder. 
 In the towns the greatest variety of combinations are 
 made by the new occupations. Gas-fitting and plumbhig 
 are undertaken now by the locksmith, now by the tinsmith, 
 and electric services are installed in houses by craftsmen of 
 most diverse types. Everywhere the craftsman appears 
 willing to ad<l to his workshop a small counter trade, 
 especially with wares of his own <lepartment of labour no 
 longer produced by hand-work, but often with various 
 other articles as well. Justus Moser long since remarked 
 the sound economic idea realized in this union: and would 
 willinglv have seen all petty retailing transferred to hand- 
 workers and their wives.' ^ If we a.ld t« this the various 
 alliances that handicraft makes with services of a personal 
 character, especially minor civil offices, and in the country 
 as a regular thing with agriculture, we are rea<li1y con- 
 vinced that the union of labour still commands a very ex- 
 tended field.'" Men of " modern mind " may deplore the 
 
 " Patrwitsche I'hintastcn. Vo!, II. No. XXXVIl. 
 
 '"( ,.j.t(.ii> m.-itirial on the c.niilMiKHions of tra.les and si-oundary 
 ocnuMiions of haiuKsorkcr^ .» ofTcritl in I nlcrsurhungni ubcr d. La^e 
 d. Ua,idiitrhs i« IhuUckUnd. edited by r.iy;elf. in Schrif'.en 0. Verc.ns 
 
 fe«S'< 
 
 WF!PPiWPP 
 
 iP 
 
UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 2$^ 
 
 great number of such " backward trades " ; pessimists may 
 see in them a sign of the " distress in handicraft " ; fanatics 
 on production may regret that under such ramditions the 
 highest possible measure of productivity is not reaHzed in 
 every branch of industry. But an unprejudiced judgment, 
 based upon an investigation of the facts, will rind that in 
 the union of labour the middle class of small independent 
 workmen has its firmest footing; it will find too that in 
 the majority of cases the due observance of sound business 
 principles has not been wanting. For as a rule it is really 
 a question of making use of time that is not taken up by 
 the chief occupation, and of giving employment to capabil- 
 ities that would otherwise lie dormant. 
 
 Union of labour is relatively still more common in house 
 industrx where the women employed at the same time at- 
 tend to their doincstic duties, and where the men often 
 follow agriculture or some other business as primary occu- 
 pation. Indeed the origin of many commission industries 
 rests finally upon the consideration that persons not fully 
 occupied could profitably combine them with their other 
 business. 
 
 Trading primarily is always union of labour, since in the 
 earlier stages of its development it regularly includes 
 transportation. Caravan trade is an example. In modern 
 commercial life division of labour li.is strongly asserted it- 
 self in wholesale trade, and also in tlie retail trade of large 
 cities. But along with these are numerous businesses, 
 such as hardware and house-furnishing shops, which bring 
 together the most varied articles. In the wholesale ware- 
 houses and export businesses, in the sixpenny bazaars and 
 cash stores this devclojiment has reached its highest point. 
 These ^iant undertakings of course lie beyond the range 
 
 f. Socialp.ilitik. Vols LXIULXX, especially in the descriptions of in- 
 dustries in small towns and country districts. 
 
i- 
 
 i^ii 
 
 258 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 of our Study, since with them the work is generally ar- 
 ranged in strict accordance with the principle of division 
 of labour. On the other hand, the numerous small retail 
 businesses carried on in suburban places, in small towns, 
 and in the country usually as the sole occupation of one 
 person lie within its survey, because here the owner 
 deals in every possible article that will bring in money. 
 Indeed one would have to write a detailed account of the 
 sale shops to explain all that is to be found gathered to- 
 gether there. Certain wares are specially prized for filling 
 out the stock, such as canes, cigar-holders, combs, brushes, 
 and straw hats; and it is often difficult to learn how they 
 have come into the company they keep. Many tradesmen 
 of such a class at the same time carry on commission busi- 
 nesses, insurance and news agencies, sell lottery and 
 theatre tickets, receive advertisements and savings-bank 
 deposits, and the like. 
 
 In the great world of commerce there are various spe- 
 cialized occupations that can hardly be carried on with 
 profit by themselves, and therefore are always followed in 
 conjunction with another pursuit. What village could 
 support a special precentor, village clerk, or sexton; what 
 rural loan association maintain a treasurer; what insurance 
 company pay its army of sub-agents sufficient for their 
 support? Without the possibility of union of labour these 
 and many other economic functions would simply have to 
 remain unperformed. 
 
 The consideration determining the combination in each 
 case could only be gleaned from a minute statistical and 
 descriptive investigation. In most cases the influence 
 that decides the person devoting himself to different 
 kinds of work is the full employment of his time and the 
 gaining of a full livelihood. For the method of combina- 
 tion, however, many other considerations come into play. 
 
UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 259 
 
 Now it is to take advantage of a clientele already existing, 
 now to utilize a particular talent or skill possessed by the 
 workman for a further object. The economic principle 
 will in these cases in one way or another always come into 
 play. 
 
 The actual extent of union of labour in national economy 
 is not easy to determine. Statistics have sought to answer 
 the need by creating the rather unsatisfactory category of 
 the auxiliary occupations; but it is easy to see that this 
 designation does not exhaust the total number of cases 
 that come here into question; it gives at most only those 
 in which the auxiliary occupation ranks in some degree as 
 an independent vocation. A union of occupations might be 
 spoken of in this case.-" Yet some conception of the im- 
 mense economic importance of the union of labour may be 
 gained when we learn from the results of the last German 
 industrial census that on June 14, 1895, there were almost 
 five million persons in the German Empire who had some 
 secondary occupation, and that agriculture alone was an 
 auxiliary pursuit for 3,648,237. Of 3.999,023 proprietors 
 and managers in some branch of agriculture, industry, or 
 trade, 36.9 per cent. (1,475.023) had an auxiliary occupa- 
 tion, while 2,928,530 carried on these branches as auxiliary 
 work. 
 
 The following table gives a survey of the whole field of 
 industrial activity covered by that census. In it those car- 
 rying on independent and dependent work are grouped 
 together. 
 
 Ffdm this table we find that out of every 100 persons 
 pursuing their chief occupation in one of the classes indi- 
 
 On the occurrence of combined occupation"; in town life in the 
 Middle Apes there are some details in my Bcfiilkerung von Frankfurt, 
 I. pp. Jj2ff., 41; ff. 
 
a6o UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 DIVISIONS OF THE INDUSTRIAL POPULATION OF THE GERMAN EMPIRE 
 ACCORDING TO CHIEF AND AUXILIMIY OCCUPATIONS ON 14TH 
 OF JUNE, 1895. 
 
 CUuof 
 Occupation. 
 
 No. of Per- 
 lont finding 
 tbeir Chief 
 Occupation 
 in Clan 
 indicated. 
 
 No. of Pettoni having 
 
 a 
 Secondary 
 Occupa- 
 tion. 
 
 A. Agriculture, 
 forestry, stock- 
 raising, fishing. 
 
 B. Mining and in 
 dustries 
 
 C. Trade and com 
 meice 
 
 D. Domestic ser- 
 vice, hired labour 
 of various kinds. 
 
 E. Public service, 
 liberal profes- 
 sions 
 
 8,292,692 
 8,281,220 
 a.338.S»i 
 
 432.491 
 
 i,4as.96i 
 
 no 
 Sccondaty 
 Occupation, 
 
 No. of 
 
 fersont 
 
 making 
 
 tbeir 
 
 Occupation 
 
 indicated 
 
 in Col. t 
 
 Secondary. 
 
 4 
 
 ToUl No. 
 
 in the 
 Variout 
 Diviaiont. 
 
 Total. 
 
 Of these were : 
 
 Males 
 
 Females 
 
 20,770.875 
 
 15,506,482 
 5.264,393 
 
 1,049.542 
 
 1,491.865 
 
 384.105 
 
 31.333 
 115,266 
 
 3,072,111 
 
 2,816,655 
 255.456 
 
 7.243.150 
 6,789.355 
 1,954,406 
 
 401,158 
 
 1,310,695 
 
 17,698,764 
 
 12,689,827 
 5.008,937 
 
 3,648,237 
 619,386 
 
 569.877 
 
 16.765 
 
 95.436 
 4,949,701 
 
 11,940,929 
 8,908,606 
 a,908,388 
 
 449.256 
 
 1.521,397 
 
 25,720,576 
 
 3.203.375 
 1.746,326 
 
 18,709,857 
 7,010,719 
 
 cated, whether as proprietor or workman in any capacity, 
 a second or third (auxiliary) occupation was added— 
 
 In agriculture, forestry, stock-raising, fishing, by 12.6 persons 
 
 In mining and industry by |°® 
 
 In trade and co.nmcrce by ,'■".' 'C Z. 
 
 In domestic service and hired labour of various kinds by. 72 ^ 
 
 In public service and liberal professions by 8.1 
 
 Of the total number of persons following an occupation 
 (either chief or auxiliary) in one of the said classes, a 
 secondary pursuit from the same class was chosen— 
 
 In agriculture, forestry, stock-raising, fishing, by 30.6% 
 
 In mining atrl industry by ig't'fc 
 
 In trade and )mmerre by ,' ■" a"u •. -% 
 
 In domestic > -vke and hired labour of -.anous kinds by 3-/^ 
 
 In public service and liberal professions by °-'7° 
 
 MlilHH 
 
 lanfti.V..4H 
 
 "TTV'-iEiaB'EW. 
 
UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. a6i 
 
 Even from the returns of occupations, which unfortu- 
 nately are not sufificiently detailed for this purpose, it is 
 clear that many occupations are carried on chiefly in con- 
 junction with other pursuits. For exam^ile, in the table 
 next presented the total number of persons following the 
 vocation are contrasted, by percentages, with those fol- 
 lowing it either as principal or subsidiary, along with an- 
 other occupation.^^ 
 
 Stock-raising 83.4% 
 
 Inland fishing 69.370 
 
 Turf cutting and preparing 93-9% 
 
 Stone cutting and carving 57-2% 
 
 Marble, stone, and slate quarrying and the manufacture of rough 
 
 wares from these materials 78.6% 
 
 Manufacture of fine stone wares 50-2% 
 
 Brick and clay-pipe making 86.9% 
 
 Butchering S8.i% 
 
 Insurance 68.7% 
 
 Personal transport and post 53-2% 
 
 Freight delivery 75-7% 
 
 Pottery 57-5% 
 
 Manufacture of earthenware and glass toys 56.0% 
 
 Nail-manufacture 67 o7o 
 
 Blacksmithing 7f>.^% 
 
 Wagon-making 74-8% 
 
 Flaying 85.9^0 
 
 Charcoal-burning 81.2% 
 
 Flour-milling 9'-6% 
 
 Baking 61.6% 
 
 Turning 52.7% 
 
 Advertisement and labour-agency work 54-4% 
 
 Inn-keeping and refreshments 64.4% 
 
 These figures naturally are far from giving a true picture 
 of the results of combined and divided labour in the oc- 
 cupation classes indicated. It is at once apparent that in a 
 statistical return on extractive production a country shoe- 
 maker who devotes a quarter of his time to land-cultivation 
 
 " Columns 6 and 8 of Reichistatiitxk, Tab. I. 
 
262 
 
 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 has necessarily the other three-quarters of his time left 
 out of account. This, however, is not the point; it is 
 rather the question of the number of human beings to 
 whom a combination of occupations assures more abun- 
 dant sustenance and also in most cases a more satisfying 
 existence, both as regards health and morals, than a one- 
 sided employment in full agreement with the principle of 
 division of labour. In the German Empire this num- 
 ber is large beyond expectation, amounting almost to one- 
 third of all persons engaged in earning their living. 
 
 The principle of union of labour, despite the wealth of 
 forms in which it appears, is quite simple: how shall surplus 
 strength be productively employed? The principle of 
 labour in common cannot be reduced to such a smooth for- 
 mula. In general, its aim is so to supplement the insuffi- 
 cient strength of the individual that the task presented can 
 be accomplished. But the individual workman's insuffi- 
 ciency of strength may again have different causes. It 
 may be based on a definite mental disposition that pre- 
 vents the workman labouring continuously by himself; it 
 may rest on lack of bodily strength; or, finally, it may re- 
 sult from technical conditions rendering it impossible 
 for one piece of work to be performed unless accompanied 
 by a second of a different character. Each of these three 
 cases produces a distinct kind of labour in common. The 
 first may he called companionship or fraternal labour, the 
 second, labour aggregation, and the third, joint labour. We 
 will consider them in order. 
 
 I. Companionship or fraternal labour^- occurs when sev- 
 eral workers come together and labour without the indi- 
 vidual 1 ecoming in the progress of his task in any way 
 
 " Gesi u-hiflsiirli,:! nr j,'.mt/(1I,'(' .-Irbeil. 
 
UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 263 
 
 dependent upon the others. Each thus labours for himself 
 independently and adopts any tempo he pleases. The sole 
 aim in union is to have the company of fellow-workmen, to 
 be able to talk, joke and sing with them, and to avoid soli- 
 tary work alone with one's thoughts. 
 
 The student whose work thrives best in undisturbed soli- 
 tude will on hearing this probably shrug his sympathetic 
 shoulders in pitying contempt, and find the subject hardly 
 worth serious consideration. But anyone who has ever 
 observed a group of village women braking flax, or doing 
 their washing at the brookside, or watched a troop of 
 Saxon field-workers hoeing turnips, or a line of reapers at 
 work, or listened to the singing of a group of house-paint- 
 ers, or of women at work in an Italian vineyard, will be of 
 a different opinion. The lower the stage of a man's cul- 
 ture the more difficult is it for him to stick to continuous 
 and regular labour, if he is to be left by himself. 
 
 But the best proof of the importance of fraternal labour 
 lies in its having found some sort of organization in all 
 parts of the earth. We may call to mind the public work- 
 ing-places and common-houses of the savages,^^ the com- 
 mon workrooms of the house-workers in Russia, the spin- 
 ning-rooms of our peasant girls which the bureaucracy of 
 the eighteenth century so fatuously opposed, but which 
 live on in many villages to the present day in the evening 
 gatherings for work in common. Custom everywhere 
 
 "K. V. d. Steinen, Unter d. Naturvdlk. Brasil. p. 374. Erman in 
 Ztschr. f. Ethnol., II, p. ,v8 (on the Coljusches in Sitka). Jacobsen. 
 Reise in d. InsclwcU d. Banda-Meeres. p. 213. Finsch. Samoafahrten. p. 357. 
 Burton, as above, pp. 54. 2<i7, 461. Nachtigal. Sahara u. Sudan. II. 
 p. 624; III. pp. 146, 244. Count Schweinitz, Durch Ostafrika im Krieg 
 u. Frieden, p. 171. Stanley. Through the Dark Continent, II. p. 82, and 
 How I found Livingstone, pp. 546 flf. Semon, In the Australian Bush, 
 p. 324. Comp. also Arbal u. Rhythmus, pp. 38, 39. 71 ; and above, 
 P 37. 
 
 HI 
 
 I 
 
MCKOCOrV ttSOWTION TEST CHART 
 
 (ANSI and ISO TEST CHART No. 2) 
 
 
 1^ 
 
 tii 
 
 1^ 
 
 |3j2 
 
 ■ 2.2 
 
 tii 
 
 Im 
 
 ■■■ 
 
 IK 
 
 ■fi 1 
 
 Um 
 
 1.6 
 
 /1PPLIED IIVMGE Inc 
 
 1653 toti Mom Strwt 
 
 Roch«t«r, N*« York U609 USA 
 
 ('16) *S2 - 0300 - PhoM 
 
 ('16) 2U - S»a9 - r<i« 
 
a64 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 
 I 
 
 II 
 
 ;i 
 
 joins to these gatherings dancing, feasting or other 
 practice tending to make the work more agreeable. A 
 few instances will serve to show the wide extent of such 
 institutions. 
 
 In the Fiji Islands " several women always unite in the 
 preparation of tapa; frequently all the women of the place 
 sit together," and in net-fishing " women always work to- 
 gether in small groups; the work is at the same time a 
 recreation, and there is often a merry time in the cooling 
 bath." '* Among many negro tribes in Africa women can 
 be seen at public work-places pounding or grinding corn 
 in common. A more circumstantial report is given by a 
 missionary as to the North American Indians: *" " The till- 
 ing of the ground, getting of the fire-wood, and pounding 
 of com in mortars is frequently done by female parties, 
 much in the manner of . . . husking, quilting, and other 
 frolics. . . . The labour is thus quickly and easily per- 
 formed; when it is over, and sometimes in intervals, they 
 sit down together to enjoy themselves by feasting on some 
 good victuals prepared for them by the person or family 
 for whom they work, and which the man has taken care 
 to provide beforehand from the woods; for this is consid- 
 ered a principal part of the business, as there are generally 
 more or I'^^s of the females assembled who have not, per- 
 haps, for a long time tasted a morsel of meat, being either 
 widows or orphans, or otherwise in straitened circum- 
 stances. Even the chat which passes during their joint 
 IaI>our is highly diverting to them, and .so they seek to be 
 employed in this way as long as they can l)y going round 
 to all the villagers who have ground to till." 
 
 The same linking of work and pleasure is found in the 
 
 "A. Biisslcr, Sudste-Ptldcr. pp 224-6 
 
 ** HeckfWflder, as above, p. 156. Similar report from South Amer- 
 ica in Elu<nreich, Beitriigr ~ I'Hlkcrkund. IWasiL. p. .'S. 
 
UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 265 
 
 lie social houses that are met with almost universally 
 among primitive peoples. Divided regularly according to 
 the sexes, they are most frequently built for unmarried 
 men and girls. They serve not merely as places of resort 
 for common tasks, but often as sleeping places as well, and 
 always as places for dancing and play. There singing and 
 joking and chatting go on ; the fruitless efforts of the awk- 
 ward are ridiculed and the successful work of the diligent 
 and skilful applauded. 
 
 A distant parallel to this institution has been retained 
 among ourselves almost down to the present in the spin- 
 ning-rooms of peasant girls.'** These rooms had in every 
 part of Germany their well-defined though unwritten rules 
 
 ** But with similar conditions these are met with everywhere. Henry 
 Savage Landor (In the ForbiddeH Land, an Account of a Journey in Tibet, 
 I, pp. 109 flF.) found them even in the southern Himalayas among 
 the Shokas, where girls and young men come together at night in 
 particular meeting-places (Rambangs), for the sake of better acquaint- 
 ance, prior to entering into matrimony. " Each village possesses one 
 or more institutions of this kind, and they are indiscriminately patron- 
 ized by all well-to-do people, who recognise the institution as a sound 
 basis nn which marriage can be arranged. The Rambang houses are 
 either in the village itself, or half-way between one village and the 
 next, the young women of one village thus entering into amicable 
 relations with the young men of the other and vice versa. I visited 
 many of these in company with Shokas, and found them very inter- 
 esting. Round a big fire in the centre of the room men and women 
 sat in couples, spinning wool and chattinp merrily, for everything ap- 
 peared decorous and cheerful. With the small hours of the morning, 
 they seemed to become more sentimental, and began singing songs 
 without instrumental accompaniment, the rise and fall of the voices 
 sounding weird and haunting to a degree. . . Smoking was general, 
 each couple sharing the same pipe. . . . Signs of sleepiness became 
 evident as morning came, and soon tliey all retired in couples, and 
 went to sleep in their clothes on a soft layer of straw and grass. . . . 
 At these gatherings every Shoka girl regularly meets with young men: 
 and while she entertains the idea of selecting among them a suitable 
 partner for life, she also does a considerable quantity of work with her 
 spinning-wheel." 
 
1 if 
 
 266 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 and laws. " In Brunswick the spinning-rooms began with 
 
 the approach of winter, when the field-work was ended. In 
 
 many villages this occurred at Martinmas. They lasted 
 
 then till Lent, or at latest till Palm Sunday, when other 
 
 work had to be done. The evening gatherings were held 
 
 in rotation at the houses of the different members of the 
 
 particular weaving-circle. The membership of such a circle 
 
 was made up of four, or at most of eight girls, who were 
 
 fi lends or relatives of each other. The majority consisted 
 
 of servants, though the daughters of peasants also joined 
 
 in. The old folks spun by themselves. In the early part 
 
 of the evening the girls were alone; for not till later on, 
 
 about eight o'clock, did the male visitors, who by that time 
 
 had finished their work, put in an appearance and take 
 
 part in the company, at first with reserve, and then more 
 
 and more boldly. The institution has as its basis a 
 
 laudable diHgence on the part of the girls." " Generally 
 
 there was a fixed amount of work for the week reckoned in 
 
 yarn; anyone not doing it received a nickname. At times 
 
 a spinning contest was arranged, while a feeling of lively 
 
 emulation always prevailed.^* Indeed a species of labour 
 
 police was maintained over the individual members. In 
 
 the district of Nassau a moustache was painted with a piece 
 
 of charcoal on the spinne. who fell asleep; if she let the 
 
 thread break and slip from her a lad might take her distaff, 
 
 which she had to redeem with a kiss.^^ 
 
 "R. Andrec, Braunsch-veig. I'olkskunde. pp. 168 ff, Comp. K. Frei- 
 herr v. LeoprcchtiriK, Aus d. Lcchraiii. pp. 201-2; Ztschr. d. Ver. f. 
 Volkskundf. III. pp. 2qi. 202. VIII, p. 366; and in detail Biickel. I'olks- 
 Ixedcr aus Oherhcsscn. pp. cxxiii flf. 
 
 " IntiTcstinK nnti s on competitive Ramcs in spinninj? in Ztschr d. 
 Ver. f. Volksk., VIII. pp. .'15, 216. Comp. Arbeit u. /?A.v//imi<,t. pp. 91 flf. 
 
 " .\monR the Wends in Lusatia on the l.Tt .'pinning nitjht before 
 Christmas the slow and lazy ones are brouelit to trial: Haupt and 
 Srhm.Tler, I'olkslicdrr d. Wnidcii in d. Oher- u. Xicdcr-I.nusit:. II. p. 220. 
 Similar instances of l.ibour supervision by coniraiKs are found in 
 
UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 267 
 
 The spinning-room has fallen a sacrifice to the technical 
 revolutions of modem times; but all through the country 
 during long winter evenings the young girls still congre- 
 gate with their work in the house of a friend. This is also 
 the case with several house industries carried on in the coun- 
 try, for instance, with lace-making in the Erz mountains, 
 where this kind of gathering of working girls is still re- 
 ferred to as " go spinning." ^° This practice is full^ devel- 
 oped in the system of house industry in Russia.'^ Here 
 male and female Kustaris frequently work together outside 
 their homes. Large companies, often composed wholly of 
 house-workers of the one village engaged in a similar 
 trade, gather together in a particuL. workroom, which is 
 either a large room rented in a peasant's house or a shop 
 erected for the purpose. Such a common workroom is still 
 most frequently termed " spinning-room" {Szvetjolka), and 
 often " factory." It is to be found, for instance, in do- 
 mestic cotton-weaving, cloth-making, silk-spooling, and 
 the making of shoes and toys. In women's work only 
 young girls, as a rule, attend, while the married women 
 work at home. 
 
 " According to the statements of the oldest people, cot- 
 ton-weaving was at first carried on exclusively in the swet- 
 jolka, because the technical handling of the loom could be 
 learned more quickly and easily under the constant super- 
 vision of one skilled in weaving. The living-room of the 
 house served at first as swetjolka, but later on a swetjolka 
 separate from the house was built. To-day the young peo- 
 ple and the diligent weavers still prefer to work in the 
 
 other classes of peasant working groups. Conip. Hormann, D. TiroUr 
 Baucrnjahr (Innsbruck, iSqq). pp. 50. 5-2, 66, 70, 71, 75, I2g. 
 
 "Arbeit u. Rhylhmus. pp. 99, 100. 
 
 " Details in Stellmachcr, Ilin Beitrag a. Darstelluite d. Hausindustrit 
 in Russhtid. pp. 106 ff. M. GorbunoflF. C'bcr russischr Spitscnindustrit 
 (Vienna, 1886). pp. J,^ ff. 
 
^1 
 
 268 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 swetjolka rather than at home; the former because it is 
 more sociable, the others because they can work more 
 regularly and to greater advantage. At home the weaver 
 is often called away to domestic affairs; the Uving- 
 room there is not so spacious and bright, the air not so 
 pure, since calves and lambs are not infrequently co- 
 dwellers with the folks; in the swetjolka, also, the cotton, 
 which at home is very liable to become moist and mouldy, 
 can be better preserved." 
 
 Thus fraternal labour accords very well with the eco- 
 nomic principle, even though it originates primarily in the 
 social instinct. In the company of others people work with 
 greater persistence than they would alone, and in general 
 because of the rivalry, also better. Work becomes pleas- 
 ure, and the final result is an advance in production. 
 
 2. By labour aggregation^^ we mean the engaging of 
 several workmen of similar capacity in the performance of 
 a united task, such as loading a heavy burden, shifting a 
 beam, mowing a meadow, beating for the hunt. In order 
 to make the employment of a plurality of workers profit- 
 able, the work to be done need not be of itself too heavy 
 for the strength of one person; it is only necessary that it 
 cannot be done by such an one in a reasonable time. La- 
 bour aggregation is of special importance for seasonal 
 work or for work that is dependent upon the weather. 
 Social conditions can also play a part in expediting certain 
 tasks. 
 
 These circumstances have early led to a species of social 
 organization of aggregated labour, founded on the duty 
 recognised the world over of mutual assistance among 
 neighbours. We may use the expression current among 
 the south Slavs and call it bidden labour.^' Whenever any- 
 
 ** Arbeitskiiufutig. 
 •* Bttlarbeit. 
 
UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 269 
 
 one has work to be done for which his own household is 
 not adequate, the assistance of the neighbours is sought. 
 They give it at the time without further reward than their 
 entertainment, which the head of the house offers in the 
 accustomed way, solely in the expectation that when need 
 arises they, too, will be aided by their neighbours. The 
 work is carried out in sprightly competition amid jokes 
 and song, and at night there is often added a dance or like 
 merry-making.^^ 
 
 This is a world-wide practice. Traces of it can even be 
 found among the South Sea Islanders. In New Pomer- 
 ania, for example, it is the custom for several families to 
 cooperate in plaiting the fishing-baskets and large fishing- 
 nets. " Before the basket receives its first dip in the water 
 a meal in common is g^ven, in which all who were engaged 
 in the making participate." '* 
 
 In Djailolo (Halamahera) when a piece of land belong- 
 ing to a local community is to be cleared, ten to twenty 
 relatives are called together to assist in felling the trees, 
 their services being compensated later in other work. So 
 it is at the planting of paddy, and at the rice harvest.^' 
 " Whenever anyone wants to build a house he solicits some 
 of his relative? to help cut the building material while the 
 tide is out, he providing them the while with food. For 
 the roofing, which is done with sago leaves, more helpers 
 are invited. These then hold a feast, at which the chiefs 
 are generally present." ^^ 
 
 " Numerous instances of this custom in Chapter V of my Arbeit u. 
 Rhythmus. 
 
 •* Parkinson, Im Bismarck-Archipel, p. 115. 
 
 "Riedel, in Ztschr. f. Ethnol., XVII (1885), pp. 7ofI. Similarly in 
 New Guinea, Finsch, Samoafahrten, pp. 56 ff. Among the Bagobos in 
 South Mindanao: SchadenberR in Ztschr. f. Ethnol., XVII, pp. 19 ff. 
 
 •* Riedel, as above, p. 61. Kubary, Ethnogr. Beilrdge z. Kenntnis d. 
 Karolinen-Archipels, p. 264. C. Hose, The Natives of Borneo, in Journ, 
 of Anthrop. Inst., XXIII (1894). pp. 161, 162. 
 
270 UNION OF LMBOUR y4ND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 Among the Madis or Morus in Central Africa each culti- 
 vates his own land; if it is of considerable extent, and re- 
 quires more hands than his family can furnish, he calls his 
 friends and neighbours to his assistance. On such occa- 
 sions payment is neither given nor expected, but all are 
 ready to render such help and to receive it." This cus- 
 tom appears to be prevalent throughout Africa; the pos- 
 sessor of the land has, as a rule, to supply generous enter- 
 tainment to the whole company.^s Among the Gallas the 
 inhabitants of a village assemble on the threshing-place to 
 thresh the panicles of the durra and to root up the 
 corn amid the singing of melodious songs adapted to 
 the strokes in threshing.3» Bidden labour is also common 
 in building a house.*" Among the Hovas of Madagascar 
 when the grave of an important man is to be built, not the 
 relatives and members of his tribe alone assist in trans- 
 porting the heavy rocks, but all the inhabitants of the vil- 
 lage in which he lived. There is no money-payment for 
 such services; in its stead, however, great masses of pro- 
 visions must be supplied during the transport of the heavy 
 stones, which usually lasts many days, often for long inter- 
 mediate periods; and above all many oxen must be killed. 
 As the people are accustomed to help one another, no in- 
 considerable part of their time is spent in such services. 
 On the highways of the country one often meets great 
 processions of two to three hundred men, women and 
 slaves, who pull by starts on the strong ropes by which 
 
 "Robert Felkin in Proceedings of Roy. Society of Edin. 1883/4 
 p. 310. 
 
 " Endemann in Zt=, hr. f. Ethnol., VI. 1874, p. 27. Pogge in Wiss- 
 mann, ( -utcr deutsch. Plagge quer durch Afrika. p. 311. Nachtigal. Sahara 
 u. Sudan. III. p. 240. Post, Afr. Jurisprudens, II, p. 172. 
 
 •• Paulitschke, Ethnogr. Nordost-Afrikas. I, pp. 134, 217. 
 
 "Schurtz, Afr. Gmrrbe, p. 21. 
 
UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 271 
 
 means the stone, placed on a rough boat, is drawn for- 
 ward.*^ 
 
 The Georgians (Central Transcaucasia) resort to bidden 
 labour at the vintage, in sowing and harvesting maize and 
 wheat, in hewing and drawing wood from the forest. In 
 Servia it is customary at grass-mowing, maize-cutting, 
 plum harvest, the vintage, and also with spinning, weaving 
 and carpet-making; in many parts of Russia at the hay and 
 grain harvests, in hoeing turnips, felling timber, transport- 
 ing manure and in ploughing, as well as with the women 
 in spinning and even in scrubbing the house. In Germany 
 it remains quite general in the country in house-building 
 and locally in minor agncultural tasks (flax-pulling, bean- 
 cutting, sheep-washing). It is an expedient of independ- 
 ent household economy, as is readily seen, and recedes 
 more and more with the appearance and advance of the 
 entrepreneur system. 
 
 But in most cases where bidden labour was formerly 
 usual the large landowner will still engage a number 
 of labourers if he is not able to hurry along the work fast 
 enough with his machines. Labour aggregation becomes 
 particularly important for him in the early stages of a 
 process of production whose final stages can be more 
 cheaply completed when carried on concurrently. A 
 meadow could perhaps be mowed by one labourer in three 
 days. Yet where possible the owner will employ six or 
 more mowers who dispose of the work in a forenoon, be- 
 cause all the grass should lie dried uniformly and all the 
 hay drawn in at once. Frequent drawings would increase 
 the costs of production. 
 
 Even where there are no such reasons the farmer 
 whose fields are intermixed with those of others will always 
 
 " Sibree, Madagaskar, pp. 255, 236. 
 
872 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 prefer to undertake the fields in succession with all his help 
 rather than divide it among the different fields. The work 
 goes forward better and more briskly in company than in 
 solitude, for no one will lag behind the others; moreover, 
 of itself the rapid progress of the work 'Enlivens the work- 
 ers, while a piece of work in which no progress can be 
 recognised, and the end is not in sight, always disheartens. 
 Thus the six mowers in the instance just given will, with 
 average diligence, finish th^ meadow not in one-sixth of 
 the time that the single mower with the same diligence 
 would require, but in a shorter time. Moreover with large 
 undertakings in which the proprietor does not work along 
 with the others, it has further to be considered that with 
 dispersion of the workers the costs of supervision per unit 
 of acre increase.*^ 
 
 Labour aggregation belongs almost exclusively to the 
 class of work requiring little skill, and which can be exe- 
 cuted with simple manual implements, or even without 
 any tools whatever. It is thus found in its widest extension 
 
 *• Even in the Grundsdtse d. rationetten Landwirthschaft (4th edition, 
 Berlin, 1847), I, pp. 112 ff., of A. Thaer we find the following rules: 
 " Large tasks are never to be undertaken many at a time, especially in 
 places at a considerable distance. As far as possible they must be 
 finished in succession, and in every case with all possible energy, 
 partly on account of the superintendence, partly because a certain 
 rivalry can be awakened among the workers if many of them are un- 
 der supervision together. On the other hand, if the task is extensive 
 and only a few of them are set to work, they become almost fright- 
 ened at its extent and its slow progress and even lose courage, and 
 believe that, because of its magnitude, t leir absence will not be no- 
 ticed. In such extensive tasks one man or one team too many is 
 always better than one too few. In smaller tasks, on the contrary, 
 care must be taken not to employ more than are necessary. The men 
 easily get in each other's way, depend upon one another, readily be- 
 lieve that their work has been thought heavier than it really is." 
 Similarly, H. Settegast, Die LandwirihsclMft u. ihr Bctrieb, I, p. 313; 
 III, p. 138. 
 
i 
 
 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 2 75 
 
 in epochs of undeveloped technique,*' declining as the im- 
 plements of labour are improved. Yet a considerable 
 sphere still remains to it. The grandest instance of labour 
 aggregation is at all times presented by the standing 
 armies. 
 
 When a large number of persons labour together two 
 kinds of labour aggregation are possible. In the first the 
 individual workmen remain independent of one another 
 during the moments their strength is called into play, and 
 work together only for the more speedy disposition of the 
 task. We will designate this first species simple aggrega- 
 tion of labour. Instances are presented in several masons 
 working on a new structure, a number of pavers on a road, 
 a group of diggers or snow-shovellers, a row of mowers 
 or turnip-hoers. An intermediate form is offered by a 
 band of African carriers marching one after the other in 
 single file, by beaters at a hunt, by several ploughers in a 
 field. 
 
 In the second case the activities of the different work- 
 men do not proceed independently of one another, but 
 either simultaneously or with regular alternations, that is, 
 they always proceed rhythmically We ^ '1 name this kind 
 of labour agglomeration concateiation iboiir, because it, 
 so to speak, links each one taking pan 
 neighbour through the succession ol '' 
 combining all by means of the tempo 
 makes it, as it were, an automatical! 
 All tasks falling under this head must. \ 
 time, adopt a rhythmical course. The- 
 sure, that are completed with a sm 
 
 1 the work to his 
 
 movemeris, and 
 
 mity ( system, 
 
 kg virganism. 
 
 ;e(l for some 
 
 -e some, to be 
 
 exertion of 
 
 ,: 
 
 "This was the case especially among the anc • 
 details on this have been gathered together w 
 pp. 109, 1 10. 
 
 itian' Some 
 Kh_ "US, 
 
I; 1 
 
 If- 'I; 
 
 ii 
 
 : '* 
 
 l! 
 
 a 
 
 874 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 Strength, such as several lifting a heavy weight by word of 
 command or pulling down the trunk of a tree with a rope. 
 
 The tasks of this class, which are performed rhythmic- 
 ally, can be sub-divided according as the powers of the in- 
 dividual workers are exerted simultaneously or alternately 
 into labours with coticurrent tempo and labours with alternate 
 tempo.** 
 
 Labours Zi'ith concurrent tempo are performed, for in- 
 stance, by the two lines of rowers in propelling a boat by 
 oars, by sailors in heaving an anchor, in hoisting sail, in 
 towing a boat against the stream, by carpenters, who, in 
 laying a foundation with a pile-driver, drive great posts 
 into the earth, by those drawing up barrels, and generally 
 by all groups of workmen who have to move a weight by 
 pulling together on a rope, by the two, four, six, or eight 
 people carrying a hand-barrow or a sedan-chair, and by 
 .soldiers on the march. Very frequently the keeping of 
 tune during the work is assisted by simple counting, by a 
 chorus among the workers, or by the sound of a musical 
 instrument, especially of the drum. 
 
 Examples of workmen labouring with alternate tempo 
 are: three stone-setters hammering in time the pavement 
 stones with their paving-beetles; three or four threshers 
 on the barn floor, two smiths hammering, two woodmen in 
 the saw-pit or chopping a tree, two maids blueing linen or 
 beating carpets. 
 
 In tasks to be performed with concurrent tempo the 
 problem is to accomplish by combination a task far surpass- 
 ing the strength of one person, with the smallest number of 
 labourers possible, so that all taking part in the work 
 
 i V 
 
 ** More in detail in my paper already frequently mentioned, Arbeit u. 
 Rhythmus. to which reference may once for all be made for the follow- 
 ing paragraphs as well. 
 
UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 275 
 
 shall be led to apply the utmost amount of energy at the 
 same moment. 
 
 In tasks with alternate tempo we meet as a rule with 
 labours that in themselves could be performed by a single 
 individual. Generally they are fatiguing tasks in which 
 the various motions, such as raising and lowering the arms 
 in striking with the threshing-flail, require more or less 
 time. The individual worker here is always tempted to 
 allow himself a brief pause for rest after each stroke or 
 thrust, and thus loses the rhythm of the movements. The 
 strokes or blows then succeed one another with unequal 
 force and at irregular intervals, whereby the work is much 
 more tiring in its results. If now a second or third work- 
 man be added, the motions of each individual will regulate 
 themselves by the rhythnnc sound that the instruments 
 give forth in striking the material worked upon. A quicker 
 tempo is realized, which can be maintained with little diffi- 
 culty. Each workman remains indeed independent; but 
 he must adapt his movements to those of his comrades. 
 The import of the matter is thus not that the magnitude 
 of the task demands a doubling or tripling of forces, but 
 that a single person working alone cannot maintain a 
 definite rhythmical motion. 
 
 To be sure, the sole consequence of calling in a second 
 or third workman one would imagine to be the doubling 
 or tripHng of the eflfect of one workman's expenditure, yet 
 this kind of labour concatenation results in a heightened 
 production, inasmuch as it regulates equably for each the 
 expenditure of force and the pauses for rest. The single 
 workman lets his hands fall when he grows tired, or at 
 least lengthens the tempo of his movements. Quick lempo 
 in work enlivens; the men working in common are stimu- 
 lated to rivalry; none will fall behind the other in strength 
 and endurance. 
 
!: 
 
 276 
 
 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 !, 
 
 i ; 
 i i 
 
 This pressure upon the weaker workman to equal the 
 stronger becomes prominent in some tasks with a some- 
 what free rhythm in which the concatenation is realized by 
 grouping the workmen in rows and making the progress 
 of the work of the one row dependent upon the activity of 
 the other. In a line of mowers in a meadow each man 
 must perform his task uniformly with the rest if he is not 
 to retard the man following him or run the risk of being 
 struck with his scythe. In a line of labourers handing or 
 tossing each other the bricks for building, each one in a 
 se' 'cs must receive with equal speed if he does not want to 
 bring the whole work to a standstill. 
 
 This mutual accommodation of workmen to each other, 
 which is peculiar to all kinds of labour concatenation, thus 
 becomes a disciplinary element of the greatest importance, 
 especially for unskilled work, such as preponderated at 
 primitive stages of economic and technical development. 
 1 1 can, indeed, be instituted also as a means of discipline 
 to accelerate the work in those cases of labour aggregation 
 that in themselves do not require such a linking of move- 
 ments. For these there are artificial means of marking the 
 tempo (counting, singing, accompaniment of music), by 
 means of which simple labour aggregation is changed into 
 labour concatenation. This is the case with slave labour, 
 which, for obvious reasons, must always be carried on by 
 gangs, and with the public labours of primitive people. 
 
 In Camerun " the chief Ngilla, a well-known Moham- 
 medan slave-hunter, drew up his people in companies of 
 one hundred, and had his hoeing done to the beat of music 
 which followed. Behind these workmen marched the sow- 
 ers to the same beats, throwing see<ls from a sack which 
 was hung about them." *^ Tlie Basutos assemble every 
 " Meinecke, />. deutsch. KoUmien in Wort u. Pild. p 35, with illustra- 
 
 tion. 
 
UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 277 
 
 year to cultivate the fields necessary for the personal sus- 
 tenance of their chief and his principal wife. " It is a re- 
 markable picture, "writes the missionar>- Casalis,*" " to see 
 on such an occasion hundreds of black men drawn up in 
 straight lines moving their hoes up and down in unison. 
 The air resounds with the songs by which the workers are 
 enlivened, and by which they can keep the proper time. 
 The chief makes a point to be present and sees to it that 
 several fat oxen are killed and made ready for the labour- 
 ers. All classes adopt the same plan to lighten and ex- 
 pedite their work; but among the common people it rests 
 on reciprocity." 
 
 The last example shows very clearly the transition from 
 bidden to manorial labour. We find the same thing in 
 the Soudan, where the erection and repairing of the village 
 walls in particular is carried out to the accompaniment of 
 music; and again among the Malays and the Chinese, who, 
 since early times, have directed the public manorial services 
 by the beat of the drum. In Europe also this means has 
 been essayed. In the Baltic provinces down to the end of 
 the eighteenth century landowners had their harvesting 
 done by the serfs to the rhythm of the bagpipes, and 
 traces of similar usage are at hand from other countries. 
 In our modem States we meet with this species of labour 
 concatenation brought about by artificial means only in the 
 measured cadence of military forces, where the aim is al- 
 ways to train a number of men to complete unanimity in 
 their exercise of strength, and where the breaking of the 
 tempo by a single person detracts from the general effect, 
 
 " Les Bassoutos, p. 171, with illustration. Another can be seen in 
 Gerland. Atlas d. Ethnographie (Leipzig, 1876). Tab. XXII, No. 25. 
 Similar reports by K. Endemann of the Sotho negroes in Ztschr. f. 
 Ethnol., VI. pp. 26 and yo: Paulitsclike. as above, I, p. 216; from the 
 Gallas by Harar; and on the Bagabos in Southern Mindanao by 
 Schadcnberg in the «amc publication. XV'II, pp. 19, 20. 
 
278 
 
 UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 
 H,i 
 
 il » 
 
 
 3. We come now to the last kind of labour in com- 
 mon, which we have designated joint labour*'' Certain 
 tasks in production require for their performance the 
 simultaneous cooperation of various classes of labour. 
 These latter supplement one another, and may be called 
 complementary phases of labour. Since they cannot 
 possibly be performed by one workman, several workmen 
 of various kinds must be combined in one group to form 
 an organized and indivisible whole. Such a group is some- 
 times called gang, company, band. (In Bavaria and Aus- 
 tria Pass; *^ in other parts, Rotte, Truppe, Bande.) 
 
 Instances from agriculture are quite numerous. Thus in 
 drawing in hay or corn, the load-builder, the pitcher, the 
 after-raker, in binding, the binder and the gatherer, form 
 natural groups; in mowing grain a second person is re- 
 quired to glean, in digging potatoes another gathers them 
 up. From the sphere of industry may be mentioned the 
 smith and the bellows-man, the rope-maker and the man 
 who turns the wheel, mason and hod-carrier, those placing 
 and those pounding in the paving-stones; from other 
 spheres: the cook and the turnspit; inn-keeper, waiter, and 
 house-boy; on the street-car, driver and conductor; in the 
 row-boat, oarsman and steersman, likewise hunters and 
 beaters, musician and dancer, blower and organist, drum- 
 mers and pipers, judge, bailiffs and clerk, doctor and at- 
 tendants, a theatrical troupe, an orchestra. The list could 
 be continued much further. 
 
 In all these cases it is not a question of processes that 
 have arisen through division of labour and then been re- 
 united, but of activities of quite different kinds, none of 
 which could ever exist by itself, and which, therefore, have 
 
 ' 
 
 " Arbeilsvrrbitidung. 
 
 "Comp. Schmeller, Bayer. H'orterbuch, I. p. 
 words is not clear. 
 
 409. The origin ot the 
 
UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 2 79 
 
 come conjointly into being. In their advancement these 
 occupations are dependent on one another, support one 
 another and only together from a coordinated whole. The 
 workers engaged must therefore accommodate themselves 
 to each other; the one must work into the hands of the 
 other, without whom he could accomplish nothing at all. 
 In most cases his labour by itself would be quite unpro- 
 ductive. 
 
 As a rule there will be in such associations of labour an 
 activity that can be designated the leading or dominant 
 one, while the other is subordinate and auxiliary. Ac- 
 cordingly th<; personal relationship between the workmen 
 employed will also take the form of a dependent relation- 
 ship. If the directing workman is independent, the work- 
 man who in technical matters is dependent will frequently 
 stand in the relation of employee. If the associated 
 labour is made part of an undertaking it is usual for the 
 whole work (" team-work," collective piece-work) to have 
 assigned to it a collective wage, as is the case with the 
 cigar bunch-breaker and roller, the glass-blower and at- 
 tendant. The plan thus offers a means of applying the 
 system of piece-wage even in cases where the work of one 
 labourer cannot be separated from that of another or of 
 several others; but it results in most cases to the disad- 
 vantage of those who perform the subordinate labour.*" 
 
 On the whole, this form of labour in common belongs 
 also to the stage of undeveloped technique in the instru- 
 ments of production. With advancing development the 
 supplanting of the subordinate labour by animal or me- 
 chanical power is aimed at. The most familar example is 
 offered by the plough, which was formerly drawn by hu- 
 man beings, later by oxen. In this, however, the combina- 
 
 " Comp. Schloss, Methods of Industrial Remuneration, rp- (>i ff- 
 
S! 
 
 j; 
 
 I 
 
 im 
 
 I ' I 
 
 a8o i/WO// OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 
 
 tion of labour endured some time longer, inasmuch as a 
 second driver or several drivers were required besides the 
 ploughman, until at length a more perfect construction of 
 the plough made them superfluous.^" 
 
 In conclusion, it is again to be emphasized that the whole 
 sphere of labour in common belongs, like that of union of 
 labour, preeminently to the departments and the epochs of 
 labour possessing little or no capital. They are the re- 
 source of the economically frail. As such, however, their 
 great evolutionary and historical importance lies in their 
 training of man to methodical division and economy of 
 time, to self-subordination to a general aim, and to regular 
 and intensive labour. These supplement each other in that 
 the inherent weakness of union of labour, pervading 
 the life of each man in primitive times, everywhere finds its 
 counterpart in the temporary communities of labour that 
 arise wherever the variously employed skill of the indi- 
 vidual is inadequate to a given task. Resting originally 
 on custom alone, they lead in course of time to relation- 
 ships capable of legal compulsion, such as slavery and serf- 
 dom. 
 
 The principles of union of labour and labour in common 
 have in other respects contributed little to the creation of 
 permanent organizations, but they have left permanent 
 works. The pyramids and stone monuments of Egypt, the 
 
 *" Interesting modifications of the system of combination of labour 
 are found in the cases where more expensive implements are neces- 
 sary, and only one of the parties pc sesses them, while the others 
 merely contribute their labour. In North Russia this is particularly 
 the case in fishing, and again in the work of ploughing, where the 
 hitching together of six to eight animals is rendered advisable from 
 the heaviness of the soil. Examples from Wales, Ireland, and Scot- 
 land in Secbohm, Village Communities (4th cd). p. 81. Meitzen, Sicde- 
 lung u. Agrarwesen d. IVestgermanen u. Ostgcrmancn. d. Kelten. etc., I, 
 pp. 212 fT.; II. pp. ijo. 1.^0 Similarly on the Bogos in the mountains of 
 Abyssinia, in Post. Afr. Jurispimiens, II, pp. 184, 185. 
 
UNION OF LABOUR AND LABOUR IN COMMON. 2S1 
 
 ruins of the giant cities of Mesopotamia, tlie structures 
 of the peoples of early American civilization must be ob- 
 served if we would know what human beings are capable 
 of performing, even without the knowledge of iron, with- 
 out draught animals, and without such simple mechanical 
 expedients as lever, screw, or pulley, when united by one 
 mighty mind in community of work. 
 
 For science also the two phenomena here referred to, 
 now that they have been defined, maj prove themselves 
 upon unbiassed testing not altogether useless building 
 stones. The theory of labour still stands in need of further 
 extension. The development of the points of view, which 
 in this chapter it has been possible in most cases only to 
 indicate, would probably show that there is still much to be 
 harvested in this region. For we have even now an inkling 
 of the truth, that in union of labour and labour in common 
 much more subtle psychical influences cooperate than in 
 the division of labour, which has hitherto been the almost 
 exclusive object of our attention. To discover them all is, 
 indeed, possibly only to the reflecting and self-observant 
 worker. 
 
;i ; 
 
 CHAPTER VIII. 
 
 DIVISION OF LABOUR. 
 
 
 - i 
 
 5 i' 
 
 In most of the sciences nowadays there are popular 
 truths. They consist as a rule of general principles, to 
 which their propounders have given such initial complete- 
 ness of form and substance that it would seem as if they 
 might be added at once to our store of knowledge as an as- 
 sured acquisition of the human mind incapable of being 
 either shaken or lost. Such truths become the mental 
 property of the educated with a rapidity often surprising. 
 The convenient impress they bear from the beginning 
 makes them coins for intellectual exchange that gain cur- 
 rency far beyond the department of knowledge for which 
 they were issued. On the other hand, their passage over 
 into the intellectual and linguistic circulation of the edu- 
 cated world serves again to confirm their validity within 
 the narrow department of study from which they have 
 sprung. If knowledge is making rapid progress in this 
 department it comes to pass that these now popular truths 
 remain inviolate while all the remaining structure of the 
 science is demolished and rebuilt. They are like inorganic 
 bodies overrun and enveloped by the luxuriant growth of 
 living organisms. 
 
 Such is the case, if we are not mistaken, with the theory 
 of division of labour in political economy. In its present 
 form this theory dates from Adam Smith, and its popular- 
 ity is indeed due in no small measure to the external cir- 
 cumstance that it is presented in the first chapter of Book I 
 
 282 
 
DIVISION OF LABOUR. 
 
 283 
 
 of his classical work, where it could not escape even the le- 
 gion of those who merely " read at " books. Adam Smith 
 is, of course, not the originator of the theory. He borrows 
 it in its essential features from the Essay on the History of 
 Civil Society, which his countryman, Adam Ferguson, pub- 
 lished in 1767. Yet the theory has been adopted by all 
 later students in the agreeable form in which Smith pre- 
 sented it. In this form it has also gone over into other 
 sciences and become familiar to every educated person. 
 
 In essaying then to subject the economic theory of di- 
 vision of labour to a critical examination, and to supple- 
 ment this examination by the application that this theory 
 has quite recently received in the department of sociology, 
 we count upon dealing with a circle of ideas familiar to 
 many.^ For this last application marks at the same time 
 one of the few attempts made by economic science to ad- 
 vance on this point beyond Adam Smith. In other re- 
 spects students have contented themselves with correcting 
 Smith's theory of division of labour in subsidiary points, 
 tracing it back historically and dogmatically to the ancient 
 Greeks, adapting explanatory examples to the technical 
 advances of the present, and besides its bright sides, bring- 
 ing forward the dark sides as well. On the whole, how- 
 ever, our remarks on popularized scientific truths hold 
 good for this theor>-. While round about it the structure 
 of economic theory has been diligently altered and 
 extended, it has remained intact. Only recently a 
 reputable economic writer, in a critical survey of the pro- 
 gress of political economy since Adam Smith, stated that 
 the subject is exhausted; that regarding it one can but re- 
 peat what has been already said by others.^ 
 
 ' Comp. following chapter. 
 
 ' M. Block, Le progrcs de la science rconomique dcpuis Adam Smith 
 (Paris, 2d ed., 1897). I. P- 533- 
 
ix^^ 
 
 
 II 
 
 ■ M 
 
 ^' fi' 
 
 ff 
 
 r "• ■' 
 
 lit 
 
 384 
 
 DIVISION OF LABOUR. 
 
 Under these circumstances it will suffice for us to discuss 
 the subject in direct connection with the celebrated Scotch- 
 man's presentation of it. We will, however, not cover the 
 whole subject, but attempt merely to answer the two ques- 
 tions: What is division of labour? and How does it operate? 
 
 What division of labour is we can nowhere learn from 
 Adam Smith. He illustrates the process that he designates 
 by this name only by individual examples, and from them 
 deduces directly the statement which has since been 
 termed the " law " of division of labour, and which can be 
 summarized in the words, that in every industry the pro- 
 ductivity of labour increases proportionately with the ex- 
 tension of labour.' His examples, however, when closely 
 scrutinized by no means illustrate similar economic 
 processes. 
 
 There is first the celebrated instance of the pin-manufac- 
 tory. With the ordinary workman, who is not particularly 
 adept at this special branch of business and who perhaps 
 could, with his utmost industry, make scarcely one pin in 
 a day, and certainly could not make twenty, Smith con- 
 trasts the factory in which a considerable number of work- 
 men with divided labour produce similar wares. " One 
 man draws out the wire; another straights it; a third cuts 
 it; a fourth points it; a fifth grinds it at the top for receiv- 
 ing the head; to make the head requires two or three dis- 
 tinct operations," etc. In this manner there result up to 
 the completion of the pin eighteen distinct operations, each 
 of which can be transferred to a particular hand. Smith 
 finds that in such a cooperating group of workers the out- 
 put of each individual, as compared with that of the la- 
 
 'The correctness of this sharp formulation is manifest from the 
 wo'ds of the first chapter: " The division of labour, so far as it can 
 be introduced, occasions in every part a proportionable increase of the 
 productive powers of labour." 
 
DIVISION OF LABOUR.] 
 
 28s 
 
 bourer working separately and prodacing the whole pro- 
 duct, is increased a hundred, indeed a thousandfold. 
 
 This example has been repeated even to wer-iness; it 
 has become, in general, the classic type of division of 
 labour. Most people can conceive of it only in this 
 one form, the form of a factory in which the total labour 
 necessary to the production of the ware is divided into as 
 many simple operations as possible, carried on simultane- 
 ously by different persons in the same establishment.* 
 
 But Adam Smith has not confined himself to this exam- 
 ple. He calls it also division of labour when a product has 
 to pass through various trades and employments in a coun- 
 try, from the procuring of the raw material till it is ready 
 for use; as, for instance, the wool through the hands of the 
 sheep-breeder, the spinner, the weaver, and the dyer. In 
 a rude state of society all this, he points out, is the work of 
 one man; in every improved society, on the contrary, the 
 farmer is generally nothing but a farmer; the manufacturer 
 nothing but a manufacturer. The labour, too, that is 
 necessary to produce any complete manufacture, is almost 
 always divided among a great number of hands. 
 
 Smith makes no distinction between the two kinds of 
 division of labour, and ascribes to both the same effects. 
 But it does not require lengthy consideration to recog- 
 nise that we are here dealing with two distinct processes. 
 In the case of the manufacture of woollen cloth a whole 
 process in production is separated into various depart- 
 ments. Each of these departments becomes an inde- 
 pendent economic organism; and a ware must, from the 
 
 • Helmolt, De laboris divisione, 1840, (a Doctor's Dissertation from 
 the University of Utrecht,) pp. 38, 39: " Ubi plures operarii siinul opus 
 quoddam conficiunt. singuli vero continue eadem operis parte sunt 
 occupati, ut, si aliquid perfecerint eandem rem de novo aggrediantur." 
 And yet Ferguson had previously entitled his chapter on the division 
 of labour: " On the Separation of Arts and Professions." 
 
286 
 
 DiyiSION OF LABOUR. 
 
 'I 1° 
 
 procuring of the raw material on, pass through a series of 
 trades before it can be offered ready for consumption, each 
 change in ownership involving a charge for profits. In the 
 case of the pin, on the contrary, the manufacture of the 
 object of the division of labour does not constitute a com- 
 plete process in production, but merely a single depart- 
 ment. For its raw material, the wire, is already well ad- 
 vanced towards completion. The result of the division is 
 not a series of new trades, but a chain of dependent em- 
 ployments whose successful utilization under present con- 
 ditions postulates the existence of wage-workers held to- 
 gether by one entrepreneur. The product, before it is 
 completed, passes, it is tnie, through a larger number of 
 hands than previously, but it undergoes no change of pro- 
 prietorship. 
 
 Two industrial processes so thoroughly different de- 
 mand different names. We will designate the division of a 
 whole process of production into several industrially inde- 
 pendent sections division of production; and the breaking 
 up of a department of production into simple dependent 
 labour elements subdivision of labour.'^ 
 
 Finally Adam Smith cites a third example that is neither 
 division of production nor subdivision of labour. He com- 
 pares three smiths: a common smith, who can handle the 
 hammer well, but has never been accustomed to make 
 nails, a second smith who has been accustomed to make 
 nails, but has not this for his sole or principal occupation, 
 and finally a nail-smith who has never followed any other 
 calling. He finds that if all three make nails for a definite 
 period the work done increases according as the workman 
 limits himself to the production of one product. It is this 
 hmitation to the exclusive production of a single line of 
 goods that he calls division of labour. 
 
 * Produktwnsteilmg and Arbeitszcrlegung. 
 
DIVISION OF L/1BOUR. 
 
 287 
 
 i 
 
 The justification for this nomenclature is not at once 
 apparent. What is divided? Where are the parts? 
 
 Manifestly Smith conceives the whole business of a 
 smith who, as in olden times, makes horseshoes, plough- 
 shares, and wheel-tires, as well as axes, spades, and nails, 
 as the subject of the division. From this comprehensive 
 department of production a line of products is separated, 
 and their production taken over by a special workmar 
 nail-smith, while the remaining products continue to 
 part of the smith's work. The articles formerly prod 
 jointly in the one business of the smith are for the k. 
 manufactured in two different businesses. In the plact 
 one industry there are now two; and each forms £0* .4 
 individual a separate business or vocation. 
 
 It is clear that in this case it is neither a question ot cut- 
 ting a somewhat extensive process of production into va- 
 rious sections, nor of si. ling such a section ittto its 
 simplest elements. For, as h himself explair^N the 
 labour process of the nailer is neither shorter nor less 
 complex than the smith's: each for himself blov he bel- 
 lows, stirs the fire, heats the iron, and forges ev pan >t 
 the product. A change has taken place only m one re- 
 spect: each applies this process to fewer classes of good- 
 Under the system of divided labour, however, the goo.Ls 
 produced, taken singly, do •, )t pass through more hands 
 than formerly. We will cal! this third species of division 
 of labour specialization or division of trades. 
 
 How specialization is distinguished from subdivision of 
 labour is readily perceived. The one is a division of the 
 whole task of production between different businesses; 
 the other takes place within a single business. It is per- 
 haps more difficult at first sight to distinguish division of 
 production and specialization of trades. In division of 
 production cross-cuts, as it were, are made through a 
 

 I;' i'-'V 
 
 m 
 
 ii I 
 
 288 
 
 DIVISION OF LABOUR. 
 
 somewhat extensive process of production; in specializa- 
 tion a distinct department of business is split lengthwise. 
 
 To offer a simple example, the production of leather 
 articles of use was originally confined to the one estab- 
 lishment. The Siberian nomad and the Southern .Slav 
 peasant still procure the hides, tan them, and out of the 
 leather make footwear, harness, etc., within their own 
 household establishment. In the countries of Western 
 Europe the trades of the tanner and the currier had 
 arisen by the early Middle Ages. Leather goods 
 down to their finished condition then passed through 
 three trades, — that of the furnisher of the hides, of the 
 tanner, and of the currier. That was divis. i of produc- 
 tion. In time the special handicrafts of the shoemaker, 
 the saddler, the strap-maker, the maker of fine leather 
 goods, etc., have separated themselves from the large 
 industry of the currier; and each produces a particu- 
 lar class of leathei wares by approximately the same 
 process of work. That is specialization, or division of 
 trades. 
 
 In division of production, o use a simile, the whole 
 stream of production of gooas is from time to time 
 dammed up by weirs; with specialization it is diverted into 
 numerous small channels and rivulets. 
 
 In his explanatory examples Smith goes no farther 
 than this. We may also for the present pause here 
 and lay before ourselves the question: What led the 
 " father of political economy " to embrace under the one 
 name division of labour three processes so different as 
 division of production, subdivision of work, and specializa- 
 tion? Wherein are these processes, whose fundamental 
 differences we have been able only briefly to indicate, es- 
 sentially similar? 
 
 The true response to this question will at the same time 
 
DIVISION OF LABOUR. 
 
 289 
 
 furnish us with the simplest and broadest definition of 
 division of labour, a definition which must be accepted by 
 all who, on this point, have followed Adam Smith, that is, 
 by all scientific political economists." 
 
 Manifestly those three different kinds of division of 
 labour have only the following in common with each 
 other: all three are f^rocesses in the economic evolution of 
 society which have orif;inated through acts of human volition, 
 and in which an eco'wnic task is transferred from tlie one 
 person hitherto performing it to several persons, the transfer 
 being so made that each of these performs but a separate part 
 of the previous total labour. Division of labour will ac- 
 cordingly always be characterized by an increase in the 
 number of labourers necessar}' for the accomplishment of 
 a definite economic end, and at the same time by a differ- 
 entiation of work. The economic tasks become simplified, 
 better adapted to limited human capacities; they become, 
 as it were, individualized. Hence division of labour is al- 
 ways at the same time classification of labour, organiza- 
 tion of labour in accord with the economic principle; its 
 result is ever the cooperation of varied energies in a com- 
 
 * Those savants of course excepted who no longer define at all. 
 Most later definitions overlook the causal force of the word division, 
 and in place of the process of division put the realized condition. 
 Schmoller, for instance, understands by division of labour "the per- 
 manent adaptation of the individual to a specialized life-work affecting 
 and dominating the whole life " (Jhrb. f. Gesetzg., Verw. u. Volksw., 
 XIV, 47). He thus forces under division what can be but its result. 
 E. V. Philippovich states in his Grundriss d. Pol. Gel:., I, 50: " Division 
 of labour is the actual divided performance of tasks leading to a com- 
 mon end. It assun s, lik- every division, a unity from whose stand- 
 point the labour of tie individual appears not as something exclusive 
 and self-contained, but as a part of a larger whole. This unity is de- 
 termined either by society as a whole, or by some organization of 
 society into separate parts." But why first construct this totality? 
 Why not begin with it? Society and tbe business undertaking have 
 surely not been divided; they are but results of the division of labour. 
 
 \4 
 
290 
 
 DiyiSION OF LABOUR. 
 
 
 
 I'll 
 
 if 
 
 1 i 
 
 n 
 
 
 ? f 
 
 mon work which could formerly only be performed by a 
 single pair of hands. 
 
 Keeping this clearly in mind, and passing in review from 
 this standpoint the whole field of the economic employ- 
 ment of labour in its historical and contemporary develop- 
 ment, we soon recognise that with the typical examples 
 of Adam Smith and the three kinds of division of labour 
 deduced by us from them, the range of the latter is by no 
 means exhausted. We find, on the contrary, a fourth and 
 a fifth type of division of labour, which we will designate 
 respectively the formation of trades and the displacement of 
 labour. 
 
 Let us begin with the fonnation of trades, which should 
 indeed rank first in an enumeration of the kinds of 
 division of labour. For it forms the beginning of all eco- 
 nomic development. To understand it one must start 
 from the conception, that before the origin of a national 
 economy the different peoples pass through a condition of 
 pure private economy in which each house has to produce 
 through the labour of its members all that is required. 
 This labour can be divided among the members of the 
 household in various ways, according to age, sex, and 
 physical strength, and according also to their relation to 
 the father of the family. But this distribution of labour is 
 not division of lal)Our from the standpoint of society, for its 
 eflfects remain restricted to the household and exert no 
 creative influence upon other economies; nor does it in- 
 fluence the formation of classes in society. At this stage 
 there are. therefore, all varieties of agricultural and in- 
 dustrial techniciue: but there is no system of agriculture, 
 no industry, no trade as a separate branch of business: 
 there are no peasants, no industrial classes, no merchants 
 as social business groups. 
 
 This state of affairs is altered as soon as individual tasks 
 
DIVISION OF LABOUR. 
 
 291 
 
 :s 
 
 separate from this many-sided activity and become sub- 
 jects of vocations, the bases of particular business occupa- 
 tions. The way for this advance is prepared by the 
 division of labour of the great slave and serf husbandries. 
 We cannot, however, treat of these here. The part that 
 detaches itself from the range of work of the autonomous 
 domestic establishment and becomes a separate and inde- 
 pendent business is at one time a complete process of 
 production, for example, pottery; or again, a single 
 section in production, for example, cloth-fulling, corn- 
 grinding; • or still again, a species of personal service, for 
 example, surgical work. Most frequently, however, it is 
 the productive part of the domestic labours that is 
 abridged through the formation of trades; and in the 
 course of centuries these labours are more and more re- 
 stricted to the province of consumption. On the other 
 hand, there arise the different branches of production and 
 the various industries which through specialization and 
 division of production become multiplied ad infinitum. 
 
 It would be a mistake, however, to imagine that this 
 process of the formation of vocations which begins with 
 us in the early Middle Ages has long been completed. 
 Parts of the old domestic economy are still falling 
 away; in the country, slowly; in the towns, more rapidly. 
 Every city directory can disclose to us a series of inde- 
 pendent industries which have come into existence only 
 within the present century, through the splitting up of 
 former single phases of domestic activity. 
 
 Of course it wouUl be erroneous to assume that each 
 instance of a new trade which is not division of an old trade 
 or <if a branch o\ production is to bi> traced hack to divi- 
 sion of labour between household and new business occu- 
 
 *In this case the formation of a trade is at tlif same time division 
 of production. 
 
I ^f 
 
 I I 
 
 25a DIVISION OF LABOUR. 
 
 nations. A bicycle-factoiy, a galvanizing or electrical 
 establishment, an ice-factory, and a photographic atelier 
 are industrial undertakings owing their origin not to 
 division of labour, but to the rise of entirely new species of 
 goods. They must accordingly be excluded from this sur- 
 vey Yet they are not on that account beyond the mflu- 
 ence of division of labour, since from the beginning they 
 accommodate themselves to the forms of production con- 
 ditioned by such divisi^ n. . , ^ 
 
 Connected only ex rnally with this process is the phe- 
 nomenon that we have already termed displacement of 
 labour It accompanies the invention of new machines and 
 other f^xed tools of labour. The division of labour here 
 operates in the following manner: 
 
 With the introduction into a branch of production of a 
 newly-invented machine there is a complete displacement 
 of the previous organization of work. As a rule the 
 mechanism undertakes only separate movements that un- 
 til then have fallen to the human hand; and m the busmess 
 installing the machine the sole initial change is generally 
 the transfer of the workman, who formerly performed 
 those muscular motions, to attendance upon the machine, 
 which demands from him other muscular motions. In 
 this way, for instance, after the intr. .duction of the sewing- 
 machine, the labourer in the tailoring establishment works 
 with hand and foot, while formeriy his hand alone was 
 called into action, and then, moreover, in a difTereat man- 
 ner. 
 
 But even previously to that there were many more per- 
 sons engaged in the making of a coat than the tailor. 
 There were in the first place the producers of the ma- 
 terials used bv the tailor: the wool-producer, the spinner, 
 the weaver, the dyer, etc.: then the producers of fine im- 
 plements: the needle-manufacturer, the scissors-manufac- 
 
DiyiSION OF LABOUR. 
 
 293 
 
 turer, and many others. All these producers still continue 
 active after the introduction of a sewing machine. But a 
 new one is added, the machine-manufacturer; or, since the 
 machine is produced through subdivision of work, at once 
 a whole group: the machine-fitter, the founder, the metal- 
 turner, the carpenter for the models, the mounter, the var- 
 nisher, etc. We have, if we embrace under our view the 
 whole pr- ess of production, a part of the total labour 
 pushed back from a later to an earlier stage. The work 
 oi tailoring is in part transferred from the tailoring estab- 
 lishment to the machine factory. 
 
 The whole process is typical, and undoubtedly exhibits 
 the characteristics of division of labour. If we employ for 
 it the exnression displacement of labour the phrase must be 
 understood in a local and temporal sense. As regards 
 locality, displacement of labour means the partial trans- 
 ference of the manufacture of an article from one place 
 of production to another; as regards time, it signifies the 
 substitution of work that has been previously performed 
 for work being performed now, the pushing back of a sec- 
 tion of the work that was formerly devoted to the pro- 
 duction of consumption goods to the furnishing of the 
 means of production. In this, however, it is not at all 
 necessary that a new undertaking should be formed to 
 produce the new implement of labour exclusively. For, 
 as in the case of the sewing-machine, a machine-factory 
 already in existence can undertake its production. The 
 essential thing to note is that the new process for the pro- 
 duction of clothing contains an increased number of dif- 
 ferent employments, and accordingly claims the service of 
 more labourers. 
 
 We have now become acquainted with five diflfercr.t 
 kinds of economic processes falling under the head of 
 division of labour, which are still in operation every 
 
294 
 
 DIVISION OF LABOUR. 
 
 I 
 
 nr 
 
 «:• 
 
 \4 
 
 
 i i 
 IP 
 
 ■ |H 
 
 : ^- 
 
 day before our eyes. This is of course saying very little as 
 to their relative importance in modern industrial life. For 
 the latter is itself the result of a long process of develop- 
 ment; and he who regards it with the eye of an historical 
 student will find everywhere side by side the most primi- 
 tive and the most modern: the one with a modest, the 
 other with a ubiquitously prominent sphere of influence. 
 Society in its long evolution from the isolated to the social 
 economy has ever been seeking and finding new methods 
 of organization in work. But it has not on that account 
 discarc ' the old, nor will it discard them so long as their 
 roles have not been completely played. For here too the 
 great law of economy prevails; nothing is lost that is still 
 capable of being at any point advantageously employed. 
 
 This also holds for the various forms of division of 
 labour. Even though subdivision of work and displace- 
 ment of labour at present surpass in importance specializa- 
 tion and division of production, and even though forma- 
 tion of trades as a species of division of labour need hardly 
 be longer taken into account, none of these piinciples of 
 economic organization has ceased to operate. Each con- 
 tinues active in the places where it can still assert its force. 
 In economic history each of them has had a period of 
 preponderance. Formation of trades appears with us in 
 the early Middle Ages. The chief activity of specializa- 
 tion is coincident, with the prime of municipal develop- 
 ment. Division tl production begins at the same time. 
 Its whole force in the economy of capital, however, is de- 
 veloped only after subdivision of work and displacement 
 of labour begin to operate, and neither of these can with 
 certainty be trared back beyond the seventeenth century. 
 It is with reluctance that we refrain from a detailed 
 presentation of the historical conditions governing ihem, 
 as well as of the causes and consequences nf their appear- 
 
DIVISION OF LABOUR. 
 
 295 
 
 ance. We are the more loth because only in this way can 
 the sharp distinctions we have made between the different 
 processes find their full justification, and the traditional 
 abstract treatment of the whole matter its refutation. We 
 must, however, devote a few general words to the cause 
 and result of division of labour. For the distinguishing of 
 those five kinds of the latter would necessarily appear 
 scientifically unimportant, or an idle nicety of refinement, 
 if all stood in like casual connection with the economic 
 phenomena that precede or follow them. 
 
 Adam Smith derives all division of labour from one com- 
 mon origin: man's natural propensity to trade. He does 
 not determine whether this is the result of instinct or of 
 conscious mental action. He thus renounces a sharp psy- 
 chological analysis of economic action, and contents him- 
 self with considering division of labour as deep-rooted in 
 the dark depths of instinct. 
 
 In this, however, he falls foul of his own examples. For 
 if division of labour has its origin in an immemorial in- 
 stinct of man. then it is a fundamental factor of economic 
 life, which must assert itself whenever and wherever men 
 exist. Yet Adam Smith's examples regularly set over 
 against the condition of divided labour a condition of un- 
 divided labour, and deduce the former from the latter. 
 For this has to be inferred from the dynamic employment 
 of the word division. There actually existed for centuries, 
 as we already know, a condition of society in which divi- 
 sion of labour was wanthig: and the different kinds of the 
 latter can be pretty definitely determined by the time of 
 their origin. Social division of labour is thus generally a 
 historical category-, and not an elemental economic phe- 
 nomenon. 
 
 The same is true of exchange. Just as there have been 
 epochs without economic division of labour, so there have 
 
396 
 
 DiyiSlON OF LABOUR. 
 
 l\%" 
 
 M 
 
 I »2 
 I 
 
 1 
 
 been epochs without exchange. The first acts of trade do 
 not appear simultaneously with division of labour, but 
 long precede it. They serve the purpose of equalizing 
 casual surpluses and deficiencies that have made their ap- 
 pearance in otherwise autonomous economies. Exchange 
 is here something accidental; it is not a necessary con- 
 comitant of the husbandry of the time. Even when with 
 the formation of trades social division of labour arises, ex- 
 change is still very active in forms which it is the evident 
 purpose to exclude as far as possible. The housewife of 
 early time uses the hand-mill to grind the corn she herself 
 has grown, and from the flour thus produced she bakes 
 her bread. After the industries of the miller and the baker 
 have been established the grinding is turned over to the 
 miller, and the baker then receives the flour to make 
 bread of. From raw material to finished product the new 
 article of consumption has never changed its proprietor. 
 For their pains, miller and baker are allowed to retain a 
 definite part of their product. In the whole process of 
 production with divided labour this is the sole occurrence 
 partaking of the nature of exchange. 
 
 From this one readily recognises that the alleged pro- 
 pensity to trade is for Adam Smith only a means of extri- 
 cating himself from an embarrassment. We can the more 
 readily spare ourselves the trouble of entering further into 
 this point since recent economists have not accepted this 
 tenet of their Scottish master. They rather prefer to re- 
 gard exchange as the unintentional result of division of 
 labour. This we can accept, with the limitation that v/ith 
 <livided labour exchange becomes necessary from the mo- 
 ment that the producer possesses all the means of jifoduc- 
 tion. It tlien becomes a vital element of each economy; 
 and from this point on almost cver>' advance in division of 
 labour increases the number of necessary acts of exchange. 
 
 I -%i 
 
DIVISION OF LABOUR. 
 
 297 
 
 But this Stage of development is not reached tiJ centuries 
 after the earliest origin of economic division of labour. 
 Even to-day, for example, it is by no means the rule m 
 country parts for the miller to own the corn and the baker 
 the flour, and a triple exchange to be necessary before the 
 consumers can come into possession of the bread. 
 
 If then exchange is merely a secondary phenomenon m 
 the evolutionary processes of social division of labour, we 
 are by this very fact compelled to seek another motive 
 for man's efforts toward this division. 
 
 In this we are led back directly to the fundamental facts 
 of economy: the boundless extent of human needs, and 
 the limited means of satisfying them. Human needs are 
 capable of an infinite multiplication and subdivision; they 
 are never at rest; they increase in degree and extent with 
 the progress of civilization. The material suitable for 
 human ends is limited, as is also human labour which in- 
 vests it with the qualities of a marketable ware and in- 
 creases its quantity. With the increase in the number of 
 human beings the relation of the total demand to the 
 mass of raw material capable of profitable utilization 
 which nature can offer becomes even more unfavourable. 
 The quantity of labour necessary to satisfy the total re- 
 quirement thus increases for a double reason: more and 
 better goods are to be produced: and they are to be 
 turned out under more unfavorable conditions. The share 
 in head-work falling to each one engaged in the under- 
 taking would thus become at length intolerable were it not 
 possible to reduce it through an economic employment o. 
 
 labour. 
 
 Now simi 'e observation teaches that every person is 
 not equally' qualified by nature for every employment. 
 The differing bodily and intellectual tendencies of indi- 
 viduals necessarilv occasion important differences in the 
 
298 
 
 DmSION OF LABOUR. 
 
 .1 
 f 
 
 products of labour; and these differences become ever 
 more marked with advancing social development or, what 
 is the same, with increasing variety of work to be per- 
 formed. The principle of economy requires that every- 
 one's employment befit one's capabilities; for only in this 
 way can labour yield its highest service. To have " the 
 right man in the right place " becomes all the easier as the 
 tasks increase in number and each is permanently con- 
 signed to a special hand. 
 
 Along with the multiplication of occupations comes a 
 simplification. Every composite work means for the indi- 
 vidual executing it a frequent change of motions, and 
 every such change a waste of energy. For passing 
 from one kind of movement to another calls for mental 
 and bodily accommodation to the new class of work, which 
 means an outlay of strength yielding in itself no useful 
 return. With muscular movements pursuing a uniform 
 course, however, the mind's share in the work can be 
 eliminated, and an automatic performance of those 
 movements soon enters, which, with increasing practice, 
 removes farther and farther the limits of fatigue. At the 
 same time the intensity of automatic labour can be greatly 
 increased, so that not only can the movements be 
 continued longer, but a larger numl)er of them is pos- 
 sible within a given unit of time. An extraordinary ad- 
 vance in the effectiveness of labour is the result.'' 
 
 All this makes it. as it were, a command of economy to 
 narrow the labour tasks if we are to utilize every kind of 
 end wment.and avoid every bootless waste of strength. In 
 most processes of production, however, we find decidedly 
 heterogeneous employments united: hand-work and head- 
 work; operations demanding great muscular power along 
 
 I \rf.,p ;^. ;t..tp.;t in Arbeit «. Rhythmua, pp. 24 ff. 
 
DIVISION OF LABOUR. 
 
 299 
 
 with those in which suppleness of the finger, delicacy of 
 touch, keenness of sight come in question; tasks requir- 
 ing a skill gained through theory and practice, and those 
 that even the unpracticed is in a position to undertake. 
 In early times when these different tasks were placed in 
 one hand a great waste of skilled labour resulted, and the 
 productive part of the population was limited to those 
 who had mastered some one branch of technique in all its 
 parts. By separating the qualitatively unequal labour ele- 
 ments from one another, division of labour succeeds in 
 utilizing the weakest as well as the strongest workers, and 
 in inciting them to the development of the highest special 
 
 % skill. . 
 
 Thus division of labour is, in the last analysis, nothmg 
 but one of those processes of adaptation that play so 
 great a part in the evolutionary historj- of the whole in- 
 habited world: adaptation of the tasks of labour to the 
 variety of human powers, adaptation of individual powers 
 to the tasks to be performed, continued differentiation 
 of the one and of the other. Therewith the whole 
 process advances out of the twilight of instinctive life into 
 the bright day of conscious human activity. 
 
 Yet one fact still requires special mention. It is, that 
 the personal casual element in division of labour stands out 
 more clearly the further back we go in the history of man- 
 kind. For this reason the predominant forms of division 
 of labour in the early stages of development are those in 
 which the individual is assigned an independent task that 
 can be carried cut without any extensive material equip- 
 ment. It is more especially the intellectual and artistic 
 activities that expand earliest into vocations. The priest, 
 the prophet, the magician, the singer, and the dancer are 
 the first to gain a separate position on account of special 
 gifts. 
 
300 
 
 DIVISION OF LABOUR. 
 
 u 
 
 If an unfree system of labour exists, division of labour 
 develops first within the slave family; and it is with the as- 
 sistance of a personal and moral feature hitherto hardly 
 heeded that it comes into being. Wherever the system of 
 supervised labour in common is inapplicable, the master 
 must provide every unfree worker with a particular range 
 of duties, for which he can be held responsible. He must 
 impose on him a single definite kmd of work if he wishes 
 to profit by his labour. Hence among the Romans that 
 almost over-refined specialization of work in the familia 
 urbana,* the careful selection of slaves according to bodily 
 and mental endowment for the different agricultural em- 
 ployments;* and among the serfs of the Middle Ages the 
 extreme frequency with which the rent paid in kind was 
 fixed in very special products of domestic work.^" The 
 man acting in the slave household exclusively as field- 
 worker or smith, barber or scribe, the rent-collector and 
 the man whosp sole duty it was to supply the court with 
 casks or vesseii, knives or linen cloth, acquired a special 
 dexterity wherewith, when the hour of emancipation 
 sounded, they entered society as professional workers. 
 Thus in the individual task rendered necessary by the slave 
 economy of the stage of exclusive domestic husbandry, 
 and in the specialization that it conditions, lay the seed- 
 time for the social division of labour of the following stage. 
 
 It is at a much later date that material cletnents supple- 
 ment the personal element of endowment and adaptation 
 
 ' Compare above, p. 99. 
 
 • Compare on this the fine remarks of Columella, I, 9: " Sed et 
 illud censeo, ne confundantur opera familia;, sec ut omnes omnia 
 exsequantur; nam id minime conducit agricolae, seu quia nemo suum 
 proprium aliquod esse opus credit, seu quia, cum enisus est, non suo 
 sed communi officio proficit ideoque labori multum se substrahit; nee 
 tamen viritim malefactum deprehenditur, quod fit a multis," etc. 
 
 '° A Hit ii given above, on page ,04. 
 
DiyiSlON OF LABOUR. 
 
 301 
 
 in originating division of labour." Formerly it was men 
 alone, now things also become diflferentiated, — tools, raw 
 materials, products. Each advance in division of labour 
 seeks to adapt itself to the existing tools and implements, 
 or to provide new ones for the particular task. Let one 
 but think of the innumerable kinds of hammers, tongs, 
 and chisels used in the different branches of metal- and 
 wood-working! The division of labour among persons 
 finds its counterpart in a division of use among the instru- 
 ments of work. But as long as the tool is merely a rein- 
 forcement of the human agent, the personal adjustment 
 will dominate the process of production. It is only when 
 artificial appliances are introduced which enable man to 
 subdue natural powers to his service that the labour in- 
 strument gains control over the labourer's social indi- 
 viduality, as well as over his bodily movements. And now 
 the impetus for a fresh advance along the path of division 
 of labour can as readily originate in a newly-invented im- 
 plement of labour as in the possession or acquisition of a 
 particular personal qualification. Most newly-invented 
 machines require the attendance of workmen possessing a 
 qualification not previously represented in the business. 
 Then, joined to this, comes the saving consequent upon 
 the growing extension of production, a feature of impor- 
 tance from the standpoint of capital. But this saving can 
 take place only on the assumption of a unification and con- 
 centration of demand sufficient to make the wholesale 
 
 " Oh what follows compare Arbeit u. Rhythmus, Chap. IX. How 
 strongly the personal element still predominated in the division of 
 labour in the town economy of the Middle Ages is seen from the con- 
 ditions for admission into a guild. As far as the carrying on of a trade 
 came in question only persona! requirements were made— ability to do 
 the work with one's own hand. Material requirements had to be met 
 by the person seeking admission only as a citizen— possession of a 
 house and of arms: and as a Christian— entrance-fee in wax. 
 
302 
 
 DiyiSlON OF L/1BOUR. 
 
 
 production, which perhaps has long been technically pos- 
 sible, economically possible also. Many labour-processes 
 cause approximately the same costs whether they embrace 
 many or few pieces, as is the case, for example, with dye- 
 ing, grinding, drying, postal delivery. But if the method 
 of work can be so contrived that masses of the raw or half- 
 manufactured material which are to be worked over are 
 collected at definite points, the employment of hands at 
 these points solely for this purpose becomes profitable, 
 with, on the whole, a considerable saving in costs. 
 
 How far in such matters the social principles of immo- 
 bility of labour and of free competition may cooperate to 
 retard or to advance is not to be investigated here. A 
 warning is merely to be given against observing and judg- 
 ing these matters solely in the light of modern industrial 
 conditions. Division of labour reaches out far beyond the 
 sphere of material things. It can show in recent times, 
 espcc'ally in the field of intellectual work, advances and 
 results far surpassing those in the department of manu- 
 facturing technique. Indeed, the former are largely the 
 direct cause and occasion of the latter. On the other 
 hand, in the whole broad field lying beyond the limits of 
 material production the material aids to labour play only 
 an unimportant part. The personal element is here con- 
 tinually decisive for the further developrrent of division 
 of labour; and we thus have to recognise it as paramount 
 in the whole great process of advancing civiHzation. 
 
 As to the universal originating cause of division of 
 labour more than this cannot be said. The particular 
 conditions of origin under which the various kinds and 
 forms make their appearance will be briefly discussed in 
 another place. 
 
 At this point we can make but like cursory reference 
 also to the economic consequences of division of labour, al- 
 
DIVISION OF LABOUR. 
 
 303 
 
 though it is in this very particular that the various forms 
 most vddely diverge 
 
 Adam Smith knows but one effect of division of labour: 
 the increased productivity of labour. He thus restricts 
 its influence to the s,.here of production. In this he is 
 right. Division of labour permits the production of 
 more and better goods with a given expenditure of hu- 
 man strength than was possible with undivided labour. 
 Production becomes cheaper; its costs diminish as far as 
 labour is concerned. And since Smith considers labour 
 the true measure of exchange value, he can dispense with 
 investigating whether under all circumstances division of 
 labour also insures a cheaper satisfaction of the wants of 
 the customer. . , 
 
 However narrow this conception may appear, it is cer- 
 tainly more reasonable than the unlimited extension g-en 
 by many recent economists " to the effects of division of 
 labour when they derive the whole of our present com- 
 m;:rcial organization directly from division of labour, and 
 think to characterize it sufficiently by caUing it, as they 
 commonly do, the " economy of divided labour." In this 
 they allow themselves to be guided by the opinion that in 
 their present form and method of action the most im- 
 portant economic phenomena are determined by division 
 of labour; that in the highly refined subdivision of trades 
 occasioned by it division of labour is, so to speak, the 
 skeleton supporting the economic organism, while trade 
 and commerce represent the ligaments and muscles that 
 hold it together and enable it to functionate like a great 
 living body. Commerce, however, they say, is occasioned 
 (':-ectly by division of labour; division of labour is its 
 ?. ase. 
 
 " Schmoller may again serve as an example: Grundriss, I. pp. 304 ff- 
 
h 
 
 III 
 
 304 
 
 DIVISION OF LABOUR. 
 
 Therein lies a great mistake. By i'^^self, division of 
 labour does not create trade. And iverscly, ii condition 
 of undivided labour may easily be inngiiied concurrent 
 with a relatively well-developed traf . 
 
 Let us elucidate the last sentence nrsi. \Vc nay recall 
 that peoples standing at the stage of private domestic 
 economy can have a relatively weli-developed exchange 
 of goods — for profit or otherwise, if smallness of the 
 household membership or extraordinar>- inequality in the 
 distribution o. the gifts of nature give occasion for it. 
 Each house and each worker produces, in a condition of 
 complete union of labour, everything that the natural ad- 
 vantages of the place of habitation permit of. Exchange 
 but fills up the gaps of home-produci.on; its objects are 
 merely surpluses of otherwise autonomous establishments. 
 The weaker the different households are numerically and 
 the oftener unfavourable seasons— dying of cattle, spoiling 
 of the stores, or sickness of members of the household — 
 threaten at particular points the satisfaction of their needs, 
 the more frequently will surplus ware be drawn from an 
 outside source in exchange for the excess commodity in 
 one's own sphere. 
 
 Thus tlie negro races of Central Africa have a great 
 number of weekly markets, which are usually held under 
 special peace protection in the midst of the primieval 
 forest. Yet among them there is scarcely a single in- 
 dustry carried on as a business; and every species of di- 
 vision of labour is lacking, save the separation of the 
 spheres of work according to sex. The same state of 
 things has been observed in different parts of Oceania. 
 Even in the countries of Western Europe a fairly 
 brisk market trade must seemingly be assumed for the 
 early Middle Ages, notwithstanding the complete absence 
 of a developed subdivision of labour. 
 
DIVISION OF LABOUR. 
 
 305 
 
 i 
 
 f 
 
 1 
 
 On the other hand, as aiready frequently remarked, 
 when the existence of slavery or serfdom calls into bemg 
 households numerically extensive, division of labour 
 can establish itself at the same stage of domestic work 
 without giving rise to exchange. On the estates of 
 wealthy Romans there were workmen of very different 
 grades of skill, perhaps even some who produced accord- 
 ing to the principle of subdivision of work; but exchange 
 neither united them with each other nor with the con- 
 sumers of their products. The power holding the-n to- 
 gether was the authority of the head of the family. Under 
 slavery this power lay in the ownership of the persons, 
 under serfdom, in the ownership of the soil. An establish- 
 ment thus organized is a permanent community for produc- 
 tion and consumption. What it produces it also consumes. 
 Indeed, division of labour really appears for it a welcome 
 means of avoiding exchange. 
 
 In such large households regular division of labour ac- 
 cording to employment paves the way for the succeeding 
 economic stage. It is the starting-point lor the formation 
 of trades. On the latter is baged the origin of special 
 economic life-vocations. It liberates a section of humanity 
 from the soil, on the possession of which its existence had 
 solely depended. It furnishes the burghe- s well as the 
 peasant with the means of livelihood. cialization in- 
 
 creases the number of opportunities for trade, it supplies 
 the framework within which higher mechanical skill is 
 developed. And at first division of production has no 
 other efTect. Formation of trades, specialization, and 
 division of production— all three together— are indeed 
 able of themselves to create an economy based upon di- 
 vided labour, but this economy is not at once national 
 economy. For, first of all. it still lacks the circulation 
 of goods. 
 
3o6 
 
 DiyiSION OF LABOUR. 
 
 The whole process of division of labour up to this point 
 proceeds, as we know, by the method of workers separat- 
 ing from the independent household of the proprietor of 
 the soil, and in the service of other households turning to 
 account any special skill in the form of wage-work. They 
 are, it is true, tradesmen living from the earnings of their 
 special trade; but the raw material that they work up is 
 owned by the person who will finally consume the product 
 in his own house. Now there are certain cases in which 
 several of such wage-workers must cooperate in one 
 process of manufacture if the commodity is to be com- 
 pletely finished; for example, in preparing bread, the 
 miller and the baker; in making a garment, the weaver, 
 the dyer, and the tailor. In the exercise of their technical 
 skill all these labourers engaged in independent trades 
 are united with one another through the product which 
 passes through their hands in different stages of its manu- 
 facture. The whole employment of the one is to con- 
 tinue the work of the other. Their economic coopera- 
 tion, however, is effected by the owner of the raw ma- 
 terial, who has himself generally produced it, and to whom 
 the finished product returns— that is, by the consumer. 
 The means, however, by which the same person attracts 
 to his service the various part-producers is the wage that 
 he pays to each. This payment, moreover, represents the 
 sole commercial act involved in this kind of division of 
 
 labour. 
 
 In b'lilding a house one employs successively on wage 
 the mason, the carpenter, the roofer, the glazier, the 
 joiner, the locksmith, and the decorators, and supplies 
 them with the material necessary for their work. Their 
 objective point of union they all find in the new structure; 
 their personal point of union they possess in the builder. 
 He unites them, so to speak, into a temporary community 
 
on SION OF LABOUR. 
 
 307 
 
 of production. J-ut their union is a loose and constantly 
 changing one. No permanent economic organization of 
 society arises fiom it. To-day they serve this builder, to- 
 morrow that. Division of labour makes the producers so- 
 cially dependent neither upon one another nor upon the 
 contractor. They remain " master workmen." 
 
 Nor is there much change in this regard when the wage- 
 worker rises to the position of craftsman and himself sup- 
 plies the raw material for his labour. A wagon, for in- 
 stance, is ordered from the wagon-maker, is ironed by the 
 smith, and painted by the painter. The wagon-maker fur- 
 nishes the wood, the smith the iron, the painte*- the paint. 
 The payment that they receive at this stage is a remunera- 
 tion for the labour and the material furnished by each. 
 But the one guiding the production is still, as ever, the 
 consumer of the commodity produced by divided labour. 
 
 Through all earlier forms of division of labour, as one 
 perceives, there runs an obvious endeavour to restrict the 
 number of commercial transactions evoked by it to 
 those absolutely necessary. In the midst of all trades 
 originatiii, in division of labour stands domestic work, 
 the mother of them all, with its primeval community of 
 labour dissolving but slowly. Alongside it, even through- 
 out the stage of town economy, the particular manufac- 
 turing establishments and professional workmen called 
 forth by formation of trades, specialization, and di- 
 vision of production continue to be firmly and clo«ely 
 united. From the customer's house they receive the com- 
 missions which tl.ey execute; and even then during the 
 performance of the work they frequently enter into a tem- 
 porary consuming community}' 
 
 In the stage of national economy the consumer with- 
 
 "[Comp. Chap. IV, remarks on i/iWraHO'— Ed.1 
 
3o8 
 
 DIVISION OF LABOUR. 
 
 iii 
 
 draws more and more from his century-old position as 
 director and uniter of divided production. These duties 
 now develop into a vocation. This vocation, however, 
 can be independently exercised by those alone in whose 
 hands the means of production — or at least the circulating 
 means of production — are at the same time found, that is, 
 by the capitalists. Because of the double duties that thus 
 fall to them — procuring capital and directing the produc- 
 tion — they are called business undertakers or entrepre- 
 neurs. 
 
 In their hands the division of labour undergoes a com- 
 plete transformation. In so far as it is division of produc- 
 tion each part-producer now disposes of the products of 
 his own raw material to his successor. They become for 
 each a source of profit, that is, circulating capital. Thus 
 arises along with the trade in certain classes of finished 
 wares, a series of exchanges of raw material or unfinished 
 goods with no other aim than to unite the various stages 
 of division of labour with each other. This exchanging 
 is in character quite unlike the one between the consumer 
 and the various producers in succession, which previously 
 held exclusive possession of the field. The earlier ex- 
 change, at least for the one acquiring the product, is pure 
 exchange for use, in which he is concerned with the com- 
 modity as an object of consumption. The later exchange is 
 for purchaser and seller always a business transaction in 
 which the utility of the object of exchange is of secondary, 
 and its character as capital — the profit to be gaine<l by it — 
 of primary, importance. The forms of division of labour, 
 displacement of labour, and subdivision of work now aris- 
 ing for the first time have by their mutual relationship the 
 effect of imparting the quality of capital to the fixed means 
 of product" n as well. The subdivision of work makes 
 necessary a permanently dependent labouring class. It 
 
DIVISION OF LABOUR. 
 
 309 
 
 alone gives to the method of capitalistic production its 
 full expansion. Although, on the other hand, it largely de- 
 stroys, in the department accessible to it, that which the 
 formation of trades and specialization had previously cre- 
 ated — the independence of the petty traders. 
 
 This new phase of division of laL- , accordingly, raises 
 commerce to a height unknown before. In trade, in trans- 
 portation, in credit negotiation, in insurance, it calls forth 
 numberless other phenomena of division of labour under 
 the shadow of the entrepreneur system, which lead in turn 
 to fresh commercial services of a manifold kind. But in 
 itself division of labour does not create this new com- 
 merce. The impelling and creative element in modem 
 national economy is not division of labour, but business 
 capital, and commerce is its spring of life. 
 
 The point at which capital in its primal form of money 
 first displayed its earning power was trade. From there 
 it has encroached upon production by enabling the trader 
 to take the consumer's place as director of production. 
 In this way that commission system first took its rise in 
 the world of industry in which the commission manufac- 
 turer enters into the same ouier relationship with wage- 
 worker and craftsman that the father of the household 
 formerly held. To the one he advances the raw material, 
 from the other he purchases the finished products made 
 from self-supplied material, with the object of further dis- 
 posing of them. Where a productive process falls into 
 different sections he guides the product from one to the 
 other, and finally places it on the market as finichcd war". 
 As a rule, he operates merely with circulating capital. 
 He has to do permanently with fixed capital only when it 
 becomes profitable to pass over from commission to fac- 
 tory production. While, however, in the provi.ice of 
 industry trading capital was merely a transforming agency, 
 
 .4 
 
3IO 
 
 DiyiSlON OF LABOUR. 
 
 m 
 
 ■■ 
 
 Bl 
 
 
 
 
 ■ 1 
 
 n^^^K 
 
 ii 
 
 w^m 
 
 ii 
 
 ^^B 
 
 1 
 
 HI 
 
 1 
 
 pvp 
 
 in the departments of banking, transportation, and in- 
 surance it has been creative. These departments of busi- 
 ness are really, when ve consider them from the side of 
 division of labour, only ramifications of trade. 
 
 Thus, it seems to us, we have to recognise capital as the 
 creative influence in modem national economy, and division 
 of labour as the medium through which it operates. Its 
 support and representative is the entrepreneur. 
 
 That the latter has been able to utilize this medium of 
 division of labour to much greater purpose than the head 
 of the household before him is plainly evident. To-day the 
 entrepreneur determines what we shall eat and drink, read 
 in the papers and see at the theatre^ how we shall lodge 
 and dress. That means everything. For a great part of 
 the goods we consume the right of self-determining is 
 taken away. And since uniform production on a large 
 scale is most advantageous to the manufacturer, there is 
 operative in the sphere of consumption an increasingly 
 active uniforming process. 
 
 In contrast with ihis the province of labour exhibits a 
 continually advancing differentiation. The field of work 
 of each individual is ever growing more restricted. It is 
 only when broken up on the basis of technique into 
 its parts, that labouring skill can furnish workable building 
 material for the task of the entrepreneur. Every business 
 establishment is a union of various fragmentary activities, 
 originating through division of labour, into an organic 
 whole. It unites workmen economically and technically 
 dependent into a permanent community of production. This 
 community of production, however, luis ceased to be at the 
 same time a community of consumption. On the contrary, its 
 members belong to distinct households which have been 
 freed from all the burdens of production, and which are in 
 
DIVISION OF LABOUR. 
 
 3" 
 
 no wise connected with one another or with the employer's 
 
 household. 
 
 In the formation of those communities of production 
 the entrepreneur's plan of action varies according to the 
 presence or absence of the earlier forms of division of 
 labour in the manufacture in which he wishes to place his 
 
 capital. 
 
 In the first case he absorbs into his undertaking all the 
 independent branches of business that up to that time had 
 to do with the wares to be produced. He specializes their 
 workers and permanently allots to them the performance, 
 side by side, of the part-tasks required by the business. As 
 an example, take the furniture-factory, in which joiners, 
 turners, wood-carvers, upholsterers, glaziers, painters, 
 and finishers are incorporated in a common productive 
 
 process. 
 
 In the second case he first organises the work according 
 to the principles of subdivision of labour, in the branch of 
 production concerned, and furnishes the business with a 
 comprehensive outfit of machinery. 
 
 In both instances there are in the fully-equipped busi- 
 ness, in addition to the entrepreneur, only subject part- 
 workmen whom the technical arrarpement of the work 
 renders dependent. In the one case they have been inde- 
 pendent craftsmen, and the task of the entrepreneur con- 
 sists in combining them into one industrial imit; in the 
 other the business unit already exists, and its component 
 parts are to be sought. Very soon the employees of 
 either origin are no longer to be distinguished from one 
 another. 
 
 Early handicraft had as a basis a few workmen of 
 similar training who, even though at different stages (ap- 
 prentices, journeymen, master workmen), worked side by 
 side. The qualifications of the groups so composed bear, 
 
312 
 
 DIVISION OF LABOUR. 
 
 from handicraft to handicraft, no resemblance to each 
 other. It is impossible for a transfer to be made from one 
 species of employment to another; for instance, the smith 
 cannot be wheelwright. The law recognises this by the 
 sharp dividing lines it dravvs between them. 
 
 Modern industrial activity unites workers difTering in 
 skill and strength into cooperative harmony within the 
 undertaking. Their grouping for business purposes fol- 
 lows the same principles of organization from branch to 
 branch of production: there are no sharp boundary lines 
 between industries. A distinction of vocations hardly oc- 
 curs among entrepreneurs, though to a certain extent it 
 exists among the workmen. As far as the entrepreneur's 
 functions are concerned, it is almost a matter of indiffer- 
 ence whether he manages a street-railway, iron-works, 
 or a weaving factory. Among the employees, on the con- 
 trary, in consequence of the continued subdivision of work, 
 there are now numerous specialists who are required in 
 very different branches of production. The locksmith, the 
 metal-turner, the moulder, the planer, and the cutter ap- 
 pear in all branches of well-ad\ iced metal industry, in 
 each special department of machine-construction, in rail- 
 way workshops, etc. Fireman and engineer are neces- 
 sary in every large establishment, whether it produces 
 cotton thread or illustrated papers. Joiners, tinsmiths, 
 coopers can be incorporated into or attached to under- 
 takings of the most varied type, and office-clerks, pattern- 
 artists, and engineers have a similarly varied usefulness. 
 To these is to be added the mass of unskilled labour that 
 is swallowed up by the large manufac curing establish- 
 ments. For many entrepreneurs almost the sole remain- 
 ing question is how to apportion and arrange these labour 
 elements in such a way that they may cooperate as a me- 
 chanical unit. 
 
^' 
 
 DiyiSION OF LABOUR. 
 
 ;i3 
 
 This cursory survey has taught us how at different 
 epochs division of labour has exerted an influence upon 
 the industry of peoples, and upon the existence of in- 
 dividuals, varying according to the organizing principles 
 dtDminating the different economic stages. 
 
 During the stage of independent household economy 
 there prevails either union of labour in the hands of the 
 father and mother of the family, or division of labour de- 
 veloped upon the basis of slavery or serfdom. In both 
 cases the household represents a permanent community 
 of production and consumption. The principle holds 
 good: who works with me shall eat with me. 
 
 In the stage of town economy specialization and division 
 of production predominate. The part-producers are per- 
 sonally free ; but the consumer of their wares, who unites 
 them under favourable circumstances into temporary com- 
 munities of production, determines in the main the nature 
 and time of their production. During the period of com- 
 mon production he often provides them with their keep. 
 
 During the stage of developed national economy the 
 entrepreneur controls the production of wares under di- 
 vision of labour. The part-producers are personally free 
 labourers. They are united by the employer into per- 
 manent communities of production. All other community 
 of living is excluded; and if perchance on occasion of a 
 business jubilee the entrepreneur gives a dinner to his 
 workmen, the newspapers report how he ate and drank 
 with them at the same table, and consider it a particular 
 condescension on his part. 
 
 These are different economic worlds, separated from 
 one another by a deep gulf. If there breathes in the prim- 
 itive union of labour of the home, and. in part, in the 
 eariier division of labour as well, a warm breath of social 
 fellowship, there surge through the modern division of 
 
 i 
 

 3»4 
 
 DiyiSION OF LABOUR. 
 
 labour the cold, cutting winds of calculation, contract, and 
 greed of gain. If the older division of labour was the 
 caryatid of economic independence, the modern is ever 
 forcing large masses ir o a condition of dependence. The 
 pressure of capital is making men's occupations increas- 
 ingly dissimilar; it is making the men, as consumers, ever 
 more alike. If in the olden time the individual's portion 
 of goods was shaped by his own hands and head, and was, 
 so to say, a component part of his being that had taken 
 objective form, the consumption goods surrounding us 
 to-day are the work of many hands and heads. As to 
 the workers, we are supremely indiflf erent ; and as to their 
 work, when once we have paid its last possessor the mar- 
 ket price, we for the most part reck but little. In the 
 narrow circle of a life-vocation the mind becomes nar- 
 rowed, frequently to obtuseness. In our sphere of activ- 
 ity we have lost in fulness of life, and the worker has not 
 the old joy in his work. Are we sufficiently compensated 
 for these losses by the variety of articles which it is ours 
 to use because thousands of hands labour for us, because 
 thousands of heads think for us? Or has division of labour 
 merely made life richer in pleasures, but poorer m real 
 joy? 
 
CHAPTER IX. 
 
 ORGANIZATION OF WORK AND THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL 
 
 CLASSES. 
 
 The economic processes involved in the organization 
 of work are processes of adaptation. Whether they fall 
 under the head of union of labour, of labour in common, 
 or of division of labour/ they all originate in the effort to 
 remove the disproportion perchance existing between the 
 labour to be performed at a given moment and the powers 
 of the individual labourers, and to bring them into agree- 
 ment with each other. They must accordingly react upon 
 the individual in compelling him to adapt, to accommo- 
 date himself mentally and physically to a definite work. 
 In this adaptation certain resistances on the part of human 
 nature are first to be overcome. Once vanquished, how- 
 ever, this negative element is, usually by virtue of con- 
 tinued practice, replaced by a positive one. The individual 
 
 ' It will assist to an understanding of the present and the two pre- 
 ceding chapters if we present here the various kinds and varieties of 
 labour organization in tabular survey. [Comp. Chapters VII and 
 VIII.— Edu] 
 
 A. Union of Labour. 
 
 B. Labour in Common. 
 
 I 
 
 C. Diviiion of Labour. • 
 
 I. Fraternal labour. 
 3. Labour aggregation. 
 3. Joint labour. 
 
 1. Formation of trades. 
 
 2. Specialization. 
 
 3. Division of production. 
 
 4. Subdivision of work. 
 
 5. Displacement of labour. 
 
 (a) Simple aggre- 
 gation. 
 
 {t) Concatenation 
 of labour. 
 
 3«5 
 
3i6 
 
 ORGANIZATION OF H^ORK AND 
 
 I 
 
 ^HlfO 
 
 ■ 1 
 
 ^^K,p 
 
 mi d. 
 
 
 i^^E^ '-^ 
 
 gains insight into the special character of his work; he 
 develops a particular dexterity for it; his mental powers 
 are directed continuously towards the same goal, and 
 therefore expand in a definite direction; in short, his 
 adaptation to the work becomes a part of his being and 
 distinguishes him from other individuals. 
 
 If, then, the class of work to which the workman de- 
 votes himself be of such a nature as to accentuate the 
 special character of the individual man in society, the 
 question naturally arises, how fai such individual charac- 
 teristics arising from work react upon the social life of the 
 species. More specifically stated, the question would be: 
 Is there a definite organization of society corresponding 
 to a definite organization of work; and what is the nature 
 of the influence exerted by the one upon the other? 
 
 The question is not so simple as it may perlKips at first 
 sight appear. Nothin/, for instance, seems easier than to 
 trace back the caste system of India to the hereditary 
 character of occupations, and accordingly to seek its 
 origin in division of labour. But we know positively that 
 the lower and the higher castes have different origins; 
 and many indications favour the view that place of resi- 
 dence and possts^ior of property have cooperated in the 
 genesis of that hi -^ecitar- str aification of society. Finally 
 we see that the --^^^f^r^zii^i na nrt- of the caste lay in purity 
 of hiooc and < --oil •rla.!onshi])s. Difference in caste 
 excindt ! eatrair n TEiJincn .-specially, although it does 
 nor ■'crr t< ni; e i-.^^-nTr- a similarity of occupation. 
 Ai; nis ^v«s j^.o«i ir^fiTSL for the assumption that the 
 sepamtim ai-cnrriinir t- ermlovments was only a result of 
 the fn^5??wi iTm- -a^-^ wftidi had ori.^inated in differences 
 in rz^t.- A srniiar course of development can be shown 
 for r-e ssiciai crosses c th* Middle Ages. 
 
 -^ ~e -^rTTSiSr "sir o:: pp. ;:.4 f?. regarding tribal indus- 
 
 tries «3vt at the 
 
THE FORMATION OF SOCI/tL CLASSES. 
 
 317 
 
 In considering tlie relations between economic activity 
 and society generally, it is never to be forgotten that they 
 are reciprocal, and that with them we can seldom deter- 
 mine with certainty action and reaction. Just as a 
 particular kind of organization of work, when it lays 
 hold of the individual for life, furnishes specially dif- 
 ferentiated men to society, so society on the other hand 
 has from its stratifications and its individuals to provide 
 the plastic material used by organization of work. Cer- 
 tain strata of society will favour distinct forms of labour 
 in common and division of labour, others will place ob- 
 stacles in the way of their operation. Slavery, for in- 
 stance, encourages the concatenation of labour; the pres- 
 ence of a numerous class of unpropertied wage-workers 
 promotes subdivision of work. But those social influences 
 alone are not able to produce these results; others of a 
 technical and a general civilizing nature must be assumed, 
 for instance, with subdivided labour, a highly specialized 
 equipment of instruments of production. 
 
 All these relationships are thus of an extraordinarily in- 
 tricate nature and demand the most circumspect treat- 
 ment. As a rule we can tell what features in the economic 
 and social world are found side by side, but it is seldom 
 that we can determine how they are mutually connected. 
 In attempting, then, to discover the social bearings of 
 organization of work in its various forms, we enter a field 
 as yet little investigated, in which each step aside from 
 the path leads into an impenetrable thicket of confused 
 ideas. 
 
 At first the oldest system of organization of work, 
 union of labour, seems to have been socially unimportant. 
 Its earliest appearance reaches back into the pre-economic 
 period where the individual Jias to perform all the labour 
 necessary to his maintenance. It is to be found more ex- 
 
3i8 
 
 ORGANIZATION OF IVORK AND 
 
 tensively, then, in the earlier stages of independent do- 
 mestic economy. The tools are simple and few, each 
 must serve the most varied purposes, and everyone must 
 be acquainted with their use. From work of such a type 
 the impulse to a division of society, to a formation of re- 
 lations of social dependence, manifestly cannot come. 
 Society, it appears, must consist of a uniform mass of indi- 
 vidual households; and such is its actual constitution as 
 long as collective ownership of the soil prevails. Within 
 the individual households, on the other hand, a separation 
 of male and female work can take place. But this is not 
 transferred to society; each household is in this respect 
 an exact replica of the other. If social differences never- 
 theless exist, their cause is to be sought in other con- 
 ditions. 
 
 Union of labour maintains this [socially trivial] charac- 
 ter in the higher stages of development even up to the 
 highest. To-day it is met nith almost exclusively in the 
 humbler spheres of economic life and in the lower strata 
 of society. Here it arises in most cases from the striving 
 for independence; it is the support, the stay, and the com- 
 fort of the common folk. Indeed, it can appear here even 
 as recoil from an excessive division of labour.' If it were 
 the sole active factor in the economic life of a people, it 
 would lead to a society of lifeless uniformity and render 
 a successful struggle from the lower to the higher im- 
 possible. 
 
 With labour in common it is different. To be sure, in its 
 loosest form of fraternal labou»- it exists between equals 
 only temporarily, and therefore can have scarcely any 
 effect upon the organization of society. At the most, it 
 can l)ut suggest it. The two forms of labour aggrega- 
 
 * Comp. our remarks in the Handwort. d. Staatswiss., IV, p. 377. 
 
THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 
 
 319 
 
 tion, on the contrary, become a means to the formation 
 of special groups; they create and maintain relations of 
 social dependence or, at least, assure their continuance 
 where they have been developed from other causes. The 
 same can be said, although not with equal definiteness, of 
 many forms of union of labour. In both cases cooperation 
 amongst a plurality of persons depends upon the extent 
 of the work to be performed as compared with the im- 
 perfect nature of the tools; and where those tasks are of 
 a permanent nature or, at least, are frequently repeated 
 in any one department of economic labour — for example, 
 in agriculture — they require for their stability permanent 
 social j^roupings secured by some controlling power. 
 
 On this rests, in large part, the long continuance of 
 slavery and serfdom, although it cannot be said that the 
 necessity for union of labour originally created these in- 
 stitutions. Nevertheless wherever property in man and 
 hereditary dependence of the labouring population have 
 existed, we notice in the early stages that master and slave 
 are distinguished but slightly from one another; that they 
 perform their work together; that the dependent class 
 is, in numbers, hardly stronger, .ndeed often weaker, than 
 the ruling one. But in the course of time this is changed; 
 the enslaved part of the population becomes more numer- 
 ous, though less through natural internal increase than 
 artificial augmentation from without by means of wars 
 of conquest, men-stealing, the slave trade, and misuse of 
 power against weaker freemen. At the same time the 
 class of propertied frc -nen is ever more sharply distin- 
 guished from that of ti unfree; labour becomes in the 
 eyes of the former a disgrace, while for the latter it de- 
 velops into a burden of constantly growing oppressive- 
 ness. A deep gulf rends society, and there is no means 
 of bridging it other than release from the condition 
 
ii'ii 
 
 320 
 
 ORGANIZATION OF U^ORK AND 
 
 of compulsory labour. Frequently even this does not 
 suffice, as is shown, for instance, by the sharp distinction 
 between freemen and freed men among the Romans. 
 
 The necessity for this graded progress lies in the tech- 
 nical conditions affecting the developed forms of labour 
 in common. The natural consequence of the imperfect 
 character of the implements * is that larger tasks can be 
 accomplished only through the application of combined 
 human labour on a large scale. Each advance of the 
 household economy thus necessarily presupposes an in- 
 crease in the number of its unfree workers. Each rise in 
 the standard of life of the ruling class involves a waste of 
 human material, which, according to our conceptions, is 
 monstrous. To realize an effective union of labour this 
 material must be organized and disciplined. 
 
 The necessity of working slaves in gangs has from time 
 immemorial been deduced from their unreliability and lazi- 
 ness which compelled the strict supervision of their work. 
 It is indeed true that these features everywhere character- 
 ize servitude. But not it alone; they are rather phenom- 
 ena incident to a half-developed culture in general, which 
 at such a stage may be found even among free people. 
 Moreover the slave-holder applies the system of division 
 of labour along with labour in common whenever this 
 can result in such an assignment of definite duties to the 
 individual workman that he can be made responsible for 
 the performance of them." But in the sphere of produc- 
 tion the allotment of particular tasks to the individual is 
 usually either impossible or inadvisable, because profitless. 
 
 'Comp. also A. Loria, Dit Sklaventuirtkschaft im modem. Amtrika 
 u. im turopiiisck. AUertum, in Ztschr. f. Sozial. u. WirthRchaftsgesch., 
 IV, pp. 68fl. 
 
 'This indeed takes place especially with housework and personal 
 •ervicei. See above, pp. 98, 99, 299, 300. 
 
THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 
 
 321 
 
 Thus at this stage we see labour in common assuming 
 extensive proportions and becoming by far the most 
 potent organizing principle of unfree labour. 
 
 David Hume long since remarked ' that slavery neces- 
 sitated a strict military discipline; and our investigations 
 are corroborative of this observation. 
 
 In early Egypt " each of the great administrative offices 
 possessed its own craftsmen and workmen. These were 
 divided into bands. We even meet with such a company 
 on the estates of the more prominent men of the ancient 
 empire, and notice how, led by their ensign, they draw 
 up on parade before the lord of the estate. The galley- 
 slaves of every larger ship likewise form a company, and 
 even the demons that nightly propel the ship of the sun 
 through the lower world bear this name. The craftsmen 
 of the temple and of the necropolis are similarly organized. 
 The Egyptian magistrate cannot think of these people of 
 lower rank otherwise than collectively; the individual 
 workman exists for him no more than the individual sol- 
 dier exists for our high army officers. Just as these free 
 or half-f.ee workers always appear in companies, so the 
 slaves of the temple and the necropolis and the unfree 
 peasants of the manors are duly organized in military 
 fashion and regarded as a part of the army." ^ 
 
 The large Roman slave estates exhibit like phe- 
 nomena. On the rural estates the unfree workers are 
 divided into groups according to their occupation; each 
 group falls again into trains of not more than ten men 
 under a " driver " ; the villicus is commander-in-chief over 
 all. Their day's work is performed with military discip- 
 line; at night they are lodged in barracks. In the 
 wealthiest homes the urban 'imily likewise exhibits such 
 
 * Essays, p. 252. 
 
 ' Erman. Aegypten und agyptisckes 
 
 .ibcn im Altertum, pp. 180-186. 
 
 

 322 
 
 ORGANIZATION OF IVORK AND 
 
 ordered gp'oups; in the Imperial household the separate 
 slave groups are expressly designated colleges or cor- 
 porations.* 
 
 We see here how the need for labour in common led 
 to permanent organizations among the unfree; and this 
 need was met in the same way by the agriculturalist of 
 later Roman times, by the manorial constitution of the 
 Middle Ages, and by the more modem servile tenure. In 
 each of these the labourers necessary for the large rural 
 estates were united into distinct corporate groups at- 
 tached to the soil, in order that they might always be 
 ready for seed-time and for harvest. One can really say 
 that manorial servitude, attachment to the soil, and per- 
 sonal subjection " owed their ascendancy to the necessity 
 of labour in common, and that their great extension and 
 long duration were conditioned by this necessity. 
 
 A reaction of labour in common upon the organization 
 of society is thus established beyond doubt, giving it not 
 merely a peculiar socio-judicial impress, but also deeply 
 influencing the mental disposition of the associated work- 
 ers. One of the keenest observers of agrarian conditions 
 in North Germany'** found as a prominent trait in the 
 character of the peasants " that they cling very closely to 
 
 •Thus mention is made of collegia {corpora) kctkariorum, taber- 
 Hoclariorum, cocorum, pragustatorum, decuriones or prapositi cvbiculario- 
 rum, velariorum, fricliniariorum, structorum, ministratorum, balntariorum, 
 UHctorum, etc. On all this comp. Marquardt, PrivatUben der Romer, pp. 
 144 ff., 154. The remarks in text do not contradict what was said above 
 on pp. 98, 9Q resarding division of labour in the slave family of the 
 Romans. This sprang from the necessity of having for each piece ol 
 work required by the household a responsible person — not from the 
 knowledge of the greater productivity of divided work — while labour 
 in common had its basis in technical considerations. 
 
 ' ilorigkeit, SchollenpAichtigkeit. Leibeigenschaft. 
 
 " Christian Garve, Utber d. Charakter d. Bauern u. ihr Verhattnis gegtn 
 d. Cutskerrn u. gegen d. Rtgierung (Breslau, 1786), pp. 14 ff. 
 
THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 
 
 323 
 
 each other." They live much more sociably among them- 
 selves than the ordinary citizens of the towns. They see 
 each other daily at each piece of demesne work, in summer 
 in the field, in winter in the barn and in the spinning-room. 
 Like soldiers, they constitute a corps, and like them gain 
 an esprit de corps. The same may be said of all unfree 
 conditions; uniformity and the disciplining of work create 
 uniform herd-like masses which become more dull and in- 
 dolent the more hopeless their condition. 
 
 This explains the small productiveness of their labour, 
 which in turn leads to inhumanly harsh treatment, re- 
 ducing the labourers to the level of the animal. Genera- 
 tion after generation of like labour perpetuates the same 
 way of thinking, the same feelings and sensations towards 
 the oppressors. The ruling race is now markedly distinct, 
 both intellectually and physically, from the subject one, 
 just as the vigorous tree in the forest stands out from the 
 weakling. But in this evolutionary process causes and 
 consequences are confused as in a tangled skein; one 
 perceives only a labyrinth of economic and social factors, 
 acting and reacting, and nowhere a thread to guide with 
 certainty the investigating eye. There are close relation- 
 ships existing between the two spheres; that is all that 
 we can with some measure of assurance determine. 
 
 The problem offered by the third primal form of or- 
 ganization of labour, division of labour, would seem rela- 
 tively much easier of solution. Moreover, each indi- 
 vidual in the world of to-day has a certain interest in it, 
 inasmuch as he is personally affected by it. For every- 
 one, if he does not wish to be a useless member of society, 
 has to accommodate himself to a particular task; and the 
 more completely he succeeds in this, the more diversified 
 do men themselves become in their every action and 
 thought. 
 
384 ORG/INIZATION OF U^ORK j4ND 
 
 The German census of occupations of 1895 recorded in 
 all 10,298 distinct trade designations. Now one may as- 
 sume that different names are current for many trades in 
 different parts of the country, and that a deduction is ac- 
 cordingly to be made for double counts. On the other 
 hand, one must also remember that very different kinds 
 of work, especially in the public service and the liberal 
 professions, are designated by the same name, and that 
 the numerous individual tasks which have arisen within 
 the separate industrial undertakings through division of 
 work and which have been transferred to special work- 
 men, can be but imperfectly taken into account in the re- 
 turns. Thus the census figures should rather be increased 
 than reduced. We have thus in round numbers 10,000 
 kinds of human activity, each of which can become in our 
 modern society a life-work, and subject the whole person- 
 ality to its sway. 
 
 New special trades, moreover, are being formed con- 
 tinually." Each new process of production, each advance 
 
 " From 1882 to 1895 the number of trade designations in the Ger- 
 man census of occupations has been increased by 4"9. The returns 
 
 were as follows: 
 
 Aceordias to the Ceniui 
 For the CtaM of Occupations. ol OccupmUont lor 
 
 iWa. •'95* 
 
 A. Agriculture, gardening, cattle-raising, forestry, 
 
 fisheries ••••• 35a 465 
 
 B. Mining and quarrying industry, and building 
 
 trades ^,661 5.406 
 
 C. Trade and commerce ••• L^is 2,216 
 
 D. Domestic services and wagework of varying kind. 75 8i 
 
 E. Military, court, civil, and ecclesiastical service, 
 
 liberal professions ^>^T^ *'°79 
 
 Total 6.179 10.398 
 
 How far this growth in figures is to be traced to an actual increase m 
 trades, how far to greater exactness in statistical census work, cannot 
 be determined. A part of the diflTerence, however, is certainly to be 
 attributed to increasing division of labour. 
 
t 
 f 
 
 THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 
 
 3*5 
 
 465 
 
 5.406 
 2,216 
 
 82 
 2,079 
 
 of technique and science, is subjected to the universal di- 
 vision of labour. Thinking and feeling men are thus 
 forced into the restricted field of trade interests of the 
 narrowest and pettiest sort. The time foreseen by Fer- 
 guson, when even thinking would become a special busi- 
 ness, has long since been reached.'* The scope of uni- 
 versal human interests grows narrower the greater the 
 divergence of the special interests of the numerous spheres 
 in life from one another, and the greater the severity of 
 the struggle for existence. 
 
 The differences among men due to nature and culture 
 without doubt assist this divergence in the most varied 
 spheres of life; yet, in our opinion, this is true to a much 
 smaller extent than is frequently assumed. Of course, as 
 everyone knows, a jockey must differ from a carrier, a 
 brewer from a tailor, a dancer from a singer, a poet from 
 a merchant, if he is to be competent for his vocation. But 
 what natural talents cause one man to appear destined to 
 be an inspector of diseased meat, another a bookbinder, 
 and a third a chiropodist, hosiery Vianufacturer, or tobac- 
 conist, will likely be as difficult to fix as to determine 
 beforehand the success of a particular individual in any 
 given liberal profession. 
 
 Although, then, many classes of occupations are 
 adapted to bringa particular talent to the highest develop- 
 ment, with many others the presence of such a talent will 
 he of no perceptible importance. All, however, through 
 continuous practice and use, will produce a certain 
 differentiation of the men devoting themselves to them; 
 
 " Most notoriously in politics, where the majority of men procure 
 their ideas ready made from some newspaper editorial. But also to no 
 inconsiderable degree in scientific circles, where on this account the 
 last is always right; for example, the reviewer of a book over the au- 
 thor. 
 
 ■-,Wi 
 
3a6 
 
 ORGANIZATION OF WORK AND 
 
 . I 
 
 certain organs will become enfeebled through lack of use, 
 while others, through constant exercise, will be developed 
 to greater perfection; according to his task the individual 
 will be attuned physically, intellectually, and morally, to 
 a definite key; through his occupation he will be given a 
 particular impress which will often be even externally dis- 
 cernible. This we all recognise when we come into con- 
 tact with strangers and involuntarily classify them to our- 
 selves according to callings. 
 
 With this personal differentiation, however, the eco- 
 nomic graduation is transferred also to society at large. 
 Similar occupations and views of life, similar economic 
 position and social habit lead to a new distribution of 
 social groups. They produce classes based on occupation 
 and a community of interests which dominate them even 
 in their most minute social ramifications, and are strong 
 enough to cover up inherited diflferences in position 
 due to birth, or to reduce them to insignificance. We 
 have even seen how these new social aggregations 
 reach out beyond the political boundaries, and how the 
 social interests and feelings of kinship resting on di- 
 vision into trades overtop those of nationality based upon 
 similarity of blood. 
 
 Under these circumstances we may raise the question, 
 which recent biology has brought into close connection: 
 whether, and to what extent, in a society with free choice 
 of occupation, the personal variations developed through 
 division of labour are hereditary, just as under the system 
 of castes and of classes according to birth such peculiar- 
 ities are transmissible. In this it is not merely a question 
 of natural capacities which may be utilized in one's occu- 
 pation and in which the possibility of hereditary transmis- 
 sion — though not more — is readily admitted. It is a 
 question rather of tlic whole physic.il and mental aptitude 
 
THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 
 
 327 
 
 for a vocation, of the skill gained through accommodating 
 oneself to a circumscribed task, of the intellectual plane 
 consequent upon such work, of the conception of life, and 
 the direction of the mind resulting from the character of 
 one's vocation. 
 
 From the latter point of view, ever since Shakespeare's 
 " Winter's Tale," the problem has frequently been treated 
 in literature. Generally this has been done by making 
 educational influences that counteract upon the character 
 and social position of the parents determine events. 
 Views as to the issue havt greatly changed in the course 
 of the last century. It would certainly be a profitable 
 undertaking for a literary historian to take up this prob- 
 lem of education and heredity, and investigate more 
 closely the dependence of literature upon the spirit of the 
 times and upon the position in life of the writers.*^ While 
 Lindau in Countess Lea makes the daughter of the 
 usurer develop, in spite of the paternal education, into a 
 paragon of nobleness, in a story by Arsene Houssaye (Les 
 trots Duchesses), of three children interchanged directly 
 after birth, the son of the peasant woman remains peasant 
 in understanding and in way of thinking, although edu- 
 cated as a prince; the daughter of the frivolous actress 
 becomes a courtesan, and the daughter of the duchess, 
 even in humble surroundings, displays the native eleva- 
 tion of her character. 
 
 The question has also been touched upon in numerous 
 ways in more serious literature. But a short time ago 
 W. H. Riehl, in his Culturgeschichtliche Characterk'dpfe, 
 drew a contrast between the " peasant youngsters with 
 limited capabilities " who had graduated from the gym- 
 
 "The latest treatment of this subject is to be found in Ludwig 
 Ganghofer's tale, Der Klosttrj'dger (Stuttgart, 1893). It is exception- 
 ally healthy and subtle. 
 
" IF 
 
 Si 
 
 I; 
 
 1:11 
 
 iil 
 
 Hit 
 
 3a8 
 
 ORGANIZATION OF tyORK AND 
 
 nasium with highest standing and the " intellectually 
 highly trained sons of cultured parents," between whom, 
 class for class, there arises an insurmountable wall. The 
 former, he believes, would develop at the university into 
 mediocre students, whom the " cultured son of cultured 
 parents," if he went to the university at all, would soon 
 overtake. Finally the former peasant youth becomes " a 
 very mediocre though clerically efficient civil servant." 
 What becomes of the son of the cultured parents, " who 
 has already been favoured by the manifold educational in- 
 terests of his parents' home," we are, unhappily, not in- 
 formed. 
 
 The first to discuss the subject with a claim of strict 
 scientific treatment,^* which, to be sure, is not made in 
 the above case, was Professor Gustav Schmoller, who, in 
 a very confident manner, rendered his decision that " the 
 adaptation of individuals to various activities, increased 
 through heredity during centuries and thousands of years, 
 has produced men of ever more individual and diverse 
 types." All higher social organizations, it is claimed, 
 rest upon continued differentiation produced by division 
 of labour. " The castes, the aristocracies of priests, of 
 warriors, of traders, the guild system, the whole constitu- 
 tion of labour to-day are but forms diflfering according to 
 the times, which division of labour and differentiation 
 
 "Schmoller has objected to this expression in his review of my 
 book in Jhrb. f. Gesetzg. Verw. und Volksw., XVII (1893). pp. 303 ff 
 He desires to have his remarks regarded as but " a kind of essay in 
 philosophical history." I can perceive in this characterization no re- 
 pugnancy to the expression used by myself. Nor can I discover that 
 the further remarks of Schmoller in the paper cited have furnished 
 proof that I have misunderstood him in essential points. I believe, 
 therefore, that I am acting most correctly in allowing the following 
 remarks to appear again word for word as they stood in the first edi- 
 tion, and in directing the attention of the reader to Schmoller's re- 
 marks on the same in the article indicated. 
 
 I'i 
 
THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 
 
 329 
 
 have imprinted upon society; and each individual has ar- 
 rived at his peculiar function not merely through indi- 
 vidual adroitness and fate, but also through his physical 
 and mental disposition, his nerves, and his muscles, which 
 rest upon hereditary tendencies and are determined by a 
 causal chain of many generations. The differences in social 
 rank and property, in social esteem, and in income are only a 
 secondary consequence of social differentiation." ^' 
 
 One will perhaps expect that the proof for these sur- 
 prising sentences has been attempted with the help of 
 biology. But, aside from cursory reference to biological 
 analogies, that path is avoided. Yet it would certainly 
 have been useful to pursue it further, because it must 
 have led inevitably to a point where the conception of 
 heredity must needs have been defined and its sphere 
 marked off from that of imitation and education." 
 
 On this account we also will have to avoid this path, 
 and enter upon an examination of the elaborate historical 
 and ethnographical material that Schmoller adduces for 
 
 his assertions. 
 
 Such historical proofs are of a nature peculiar to them- 
 selves. To the eye of one gazing backwards things get 
 shifted from their proper place. Cause and effect appear 
 equally near in point of time. One finds oneself in a posi- 
 
 " Comp. Schmoller's articles on the division of labour in his Jhrb., 
 XIII, pp. 1003-1074; XIV, pp. 45-105; and a short summary of his 
 conclusions in the Preuss. Jhrb., LXIX, p. 464. [See further his 
 Grundriss, pp. 395-411— Ed.]. 
 
 " Such an attempt, though indeed with but meagre results, is to be 
 found in Felix, Entwickelungsgesch. d. Eigenlhums, I, pp. 130 flf. Among 
 the more recent biologists this point in the problem of heredity i» 
 really no longer a matter of controversy; especially Weismann (The 
 Germ-plasm, Eng. ed., London. 1893) has decidedly contested the trans- 
 missibility of acquired characteristics. Comp. also Galton, A Theory 
 of Heredity, in Journal of Anthropolog. Institute, V, pp. 329 ff.; James, 
 The Principles of Psychology, II, 678. 
 
33° 
 
 ORG/INIZATIOS OF IVORK AND 
 
 tion similar to that of the man who looks away into ti:« 
 distance and sees a church steeple that really rises far 
 behind a group of houses apparently standing directly 
 over the nearest building. 
 
 After a similar fashion, we fear, SchmoUer in the critical 
 instances of his comprehensive investigations has viewed 
 the causal relationship of the historical processes in an in- 
 verted succession as regards reality. So far as th' ^e are 
 occurrences that do not reach back into epochs be- 
 yond the range of historical investigation, such as the 
 origin of castes, of the priesthood, of the oldest nobility, 
 we would venture to believe that one might unhesitatingly 
 reverse his surprising conclusion and say: the diversity of 
 possession and of income is not the result of division of 
 labour, but its chief cause. 
 
 For the past, in so far as it lies open to our eyes, this 
 can be demonstrated with absolute certainty. Inequality in 
 the extent and tenure of landed property forms among the 
 ancient Greeks and Romans, and even among our own 
 people from the early Middle Ages onward, the basis of 
 class organization. The noble, the peasant class, the class 
 of villeins and serfs are at first mere classes based on prop- 
 erty; it is only after a considerable time that they de- 
 velop into a species of classes based on occupation." 
 When in the Middle Ages along with the rise of the crafts- 
 man class the definite formation of trades sets in, it pro- 
 ceeds again from distribution of property. The demesne 
 servants, the landless villeins who h^ve learned an indus- 
 trial art, begin to turn their industrial skill to independent 
 account. The industrial process followed must adapt itself 
 to their poverty; it is pure wage-work, in which th" work- 
 
 "The presence of the unpropertied noble in the service of others 
 (Dienstadef) is a proof, not against, but for, this conception. It 
 would be inconceivable that the landed noble had not preceded him. 
 
 'H 1 
 
THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 
 
 33» 
 
 man receives the raw material from the customer. Only 
 later do we have a real division of production between 
 agriculturalist and craftsman. The latter acquires a busi- 
 ness capital of his own. But how trifling this is, is best 
 indicated by the circumstance that, as a rule, the crafts- 
 man works only on ordered piece-work, and that the 
 whole industrial process for liansforming the raw into the 
 finished product Hes usually in one hand." The industrial 
 undertakings were exclusively small undertakings. Where 
 the great extent of the sphere of production of a handi- 
 craft called for an increased supply of ccpital, men did not 
 turn to production on a large scale with subdivisi' n of 
 work, but to specialization which limited the demanc for 
 capital and kept the business small. 
 
 As one observes, each step taken by mediava! division 
 of labour in industry was conditioned by the possession of 
 wealth. It is the same with trade. The tradinp^ c isi of 
 the Middle Ages is derived from the class of ur m land- 
 owners, who had become, through the introduction of 
 rents on houses and the practice of rent-purchase>, pos- 
 sessors of movable capital. It is from this class c' • )ck- 
 holders and tradesmen that the present manufacturing 
 class has sprung since the seventeenth century. T) rough 
 
 "The longer the duration of the process of production th- aller 
 the business capital that the single producer requires, but th. gr -ater 
 the mass of labour which the completed product contains In he 
 Middle Ages, to cite a very familiar example, the shoemaker w.. re- 
 quently tanner as well. The whole process of industrial elaboration 
 from the raw hide to the finished footwear thus lay in one hand. Ai 
 suniing new that the tanning of the hide required 'lalf ihe time tha- 
 was necessary to its transformation into shoewarc, a shoenr kcr d' 
 siring to carry on tanning alone would have required thrte limes 
 much business capital as the tanner who at the same time mad, sho 
 But if he wished merely to make up into shoes leather already tanned, 
 his business capital must amount to one and a Naif times the former, 
 together with w.iges and profits. 
 
 ..tJ 
 
! I' 
 
 33J ORGANIZATION OF IVORK AND 
 
 the fertilizing of industry with their capital, the two new 
 forms of division of labour— subdivision and displacement 
 of labour— arise, and the division of production for the 
 first time realizes its full efficiency. Half-manufactured 
 products now wander in masses from workshop to 
 workshop; in each place they become capital, in each 
 they yield a return; from one department of pro- 
 duction to another fresh outlays in interest and other 
 charges are added, and through them profits on cap;- 
 tal are made.*» Subdivision of labour presupposes a 
 class of non-propertied wage-workers. This class comes 
 from that section of the aftsmen who, through the capi- 
 talistic character assume*, ay division of labour, have be- 
 come incapable of competing, and from the landless 
 peasant population. 
 
 In industry, indeed, the dependence of division of labour 
 upon possession of property becomes especially manifest. 
 In the Middle Ages each advance of industrial division of 
 labour augmented the number of urban " livelihoods," 
 because it diminished the business capital; at the present 
 time the progress of division of labour diminishes the num- 
 ber of independent existences since it increases either the 
 fixed or the business capital, or both. In the Middle Ages 
 the effort was made to keep each industrial product as 
 long as possible in one establishment in order to embody 
 in it as much labour as was feasible; nowadays, by di- 
 vision of work, the business capital is carried with the 
 utmost rapidity through the separate stages of production 
 in order to make the relation between interest expended 
 and profit realized the most favourable possible. In the 
 
 "The connection of capital with division of labour has been pre- 
 sented in a masterly manner by Rodbertus (Aus d. lilttf. ^<"*'f *■ "• 
 pp. 255 flf.); but in this he has not adequately distinguished the dif- 
 ferent kinds of division of labour. 
 
THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 
 
 333 
 
 Middle Ages dearth of capital led to specialization; in our 
 time abundance of capital imnels to subdivision of work 
 and displacement of labour. 
 
 Thus from the varied distribution of property have the 
 general features of our organization of society according 
 to occupation been developed historically; and on this 
 foundation, which our present industrial organization is 
 ever strengthening and solidifying, they continue to rest. 
 The latter is explained very simply from the following cir- 
 cumstance: I. Every vocation under our industrial or- 
 ganization yields an income; and only the propertied per- 
 son is in a situation to seek out for himself the more lucra- 
 tive positions within the universal organization of labour, 
 while the unpropertied person must be content with the 
 inferior positions."" 2. Property itself, by virtue of its cap- 
 italistic nature, furnishes an income to its owner, even 
 without work on his part, and transmits itself from gen- 
 eration to generation with this capability. In so far as 
 our propertied classes are also social classes according 
 to occupation, they are not such because their cccupation 
 creates property, but rather because property determines 
 the selection of a vocation, and because as a rule the in- 
 come that the calling yields is graded much the same way 
 as the property on which the vocation is founded. 
 
 True, there is no novelty in this statement. Each 
 of us acts conformably to this view. Daily experience 
 readily suggests it; and scientific political economy 
 has always recognised it. The whole wage-theory il'.elf 
 rests on the assumption that the son of the workman can 
 become nothing else than a workman. This is a conse- 
 
 •• This means, then. " that those whom poverty drives to seek a 
 profitable vocation are compelled by their very poverty to abandon 
 that vocation." Lotmar, Di* FrrihtH d. BtrufswaU (Leipzig. 1898). 
 p. 27- 
 
liiil; 
 
 ! I'lii: 
 
 ■if 
 
 334 
 
 ORGylNIZylTION OF fVORK AND 
 
 quence of his poverty, not of hereditary adaptation to his 
 trade. Must one then really prove now for the first 
 time that occupations whose inception and conduct re- 
 quire capital, or whose acquisition demands large outlays, 
 are as good as closed to those without capital? The 
 much-boasted " freedom of enterprise " thus exists only 
 within very narrow limits. In very exceptional cases 
 these indeed are now and then transgressed; but as a rule 
 it is not the particular vocation, but rather the general 
 vocational class ^* to which the individual is to belong in 
 society that is indicated for each person by the wealth of 
 the paternal house. The " social rank " that in popular 
 estimation is enjoyed by a particular class, however, can 
 hardly be maintained without corresponding financial 
 equipment — a proof that it also is not a secondary conse- 
 quence of social differentiation (resting upon division of 
 labour), but essentially a child of the rational union of 
 wealth and vocation. 
 
 No matter how many vocational classes may be dis- 
 tinguished in society, occupations of very diverse charac- 
 ter will still be represented in each, and between these 
 callings a rontinuous exchange of labour will take place. 
 This exchange extends as far as the classes of work de- 
 mand approximately the same equipment of wealth, and 
 as far. therefore, as they stand in the same " social rank "; 
 one might also say that it extends as far as people marry 
 among each other, or regularly associate with one an- 
 other, or as there is approximately the same plane of cul- 
 ture. All these things stand together in a mutual rela- 
 tionship. It is an every-day occurrence for a high public 
 
 " On this concept, in which we attempted to express the reciprocally 
 conditioned existence of property and vocation lonR before we were 
 ac(iuainted with Schmoller's wot';, compare my Btvolktnmg d. Kantons 
 Bastl-Sladt, p. 70. 
 
THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 
 
 335 
 
 I 
 I 
 
 1- 
 
 official to destine his son for agriculture in order, later on, 
 to purchase him an estate, for the son of a large land- 
 holder or manufacturer to enter upon an academic career, 
 for the son of a clergyman to become a civil engineer, 
 the son of the engineer a physician, the son of the physi- 
 cian a merchant, the son of the merchant a lawyer or an 
 architect. Just as easy and frequent is the transition 
 from peasant to schoolmaster or to brewer, from baker to 
 watchmaker, from blacksmith to bookbinder, from miner 
 to factory-hand, from farm-hand to station-hand or coach- 
 man, etc. We all look upon these transitions, in spite of 
 the great diflferences in labour skill, as socially proper and 
 industrially unobjectionable, although there can hardly be 
 men " differentiated " more widely through division of 
 labour than a statesman and a farmer, a manufacturer and 
 a professor, a merchant and an architect, and so forth. 
 When the son of the manufacturer in turn becomes 
 manufacturer, and the son of the peasant again a peasant, 
 we know that in many cases the financial means once 
 consonant with this vocation have dictated the occupation 
 without regard to the fitness or unfitness of the individual 
 for the role thrust upon him. 
 
 This glance at practical life must restrain us from con- 
 ceiving in too narrow a sense Schmoller's theory oi .h 
 hereditary transmission of personal differentiation conse- 
 quent upon division of labour. That the son of the shoe- 
 maker by virtue of inherited adaptation should be in a 
 better position to produce shoes than, let us say, picture- 
 frames; that the clergytnan's son. tliough his father had 
 been taken from him on the <lay i)f his birth, will, of all 
 classes of occupation, exhil)it the greater natural aptitude 
 for the clerical calling, cannot possibly be meant by that 
 theory, even if in the last-mentioned case the forefathers 
 of the clergyman during the previous two centuries had 
 
 ^ ntf^ 
 
it 
 
 336 
 
 ORGANIZATION OF (VORK AND 
 
 handed down the spiritual office to each other from gen- 
 eration to generation. For if we hold strictly to the bi- 
 ological idea the adaptation to occupation would neces- 
 sarily increase from age to age, and reveal itself in 
 continually improving performance of duties. It will, 
 however, hardly be seriously maintained that the numer- 
 ous clerical families of Protestant Germany, who are in 
 the position just described, furnish to-day relatively better 
 pulpit speakers and more efficient pastors than in the 
 seventeenth century. 
 
 In the domain of the guild handicraft of our towns, in 
 consequence of the jealous exclusiveness of the different 
 trades, the positions of master-craftsmen, with but few ex- 
 ceptions, have been actually passed down from father to 
 son from the sixteenth to the eighteenth century. The 
 technique, however, not only has not improved, but has 
 lamentably degenerated, and now languishes, as Schmol- 
 ler himself m an earlier treatise has shown.** Far from 
 augmenting the technical acquisitions of their fathers, the 
 sons have not even been able to maintain the standard of 
 professional aptitude reached by them. 
 
 We must therefore look upon the new theory, if we 
 would not be unjust to it, as referring to the inheritance 
 of bodily and intellectual characteristics by the members of 
 social classes grouped according to occupation. But these 
 classes arc, as a rule, likewise based upon property and 
 income, since the standard of their life, both material and 
 intellectual, is conditioned by property and income. Ac- 
 cordingly one must demand of the originator of the the- 
 ory to distinguish between the consequence of the charac- 
 ter of sustenance and education rendered possible for each 
 class by the possession of wealth, and the result of heredi- 
 
 "Znr Gfsck. d. deutsch. Kkingeucrhr im 19 Jhdt.. pp. 14. 667 AF. 
 
THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 
 
 337 
 
 i 
 
 -i 
 ■i 
 
 I 
 
 % 
 
 I 
 
 tary adaptation to occupation. If such a distinction of 
 the probable and possible causes is not undertaken, or if 
 without examination there is ascribed to division of labour 
 that which can be traced back with greater probability to 
 the apportionment of wealth, the whole theory must be 
 content in its undeniable weakness in " historical proof " 
 to be treated as an inexact Darwinian analogy, as a thesis 
 advanced without proof. 
 
 That within a whole social class of this kind a trans- 
 mission of the " bodily and intellectual constitution," of 
 the " nerves and muscles " takes place from one genera- 
 tion to another no one has as yet doubted. One may in- 
 deed term this heredity, but in this he must not overlook 
 that each fresh generation must be raised through theo- 
 retical and practical education to the inte'lectual and 
 moral level of the parents. Though in this the elements 
 of culture " fly to " them, to use Riehl's expressive 
 phrase,^' though the example of their surroundings in- 
 cites them to imitation, though much is appropriated 
 without trouble which under other conditions must first be 
 learned with effort, it is still a question of the acquired, 
 not of the innate. This holds to a certain extent even of 
 the bodily constitution — the "nerves and muscles" — so 
 far as it rests upon the character of sustenance and edu- 
 cation.'^ 
 
 Elements of adaptation to a vocation can certainly be 
 transferred by the indicated paths of " unconscious ab- 
 
 " AnHiegtn. 
 
 "Schiiffle, Bau u. Lthen d. sot. Korpers (i. Aufl.), II, p. aoi, desig- 
 nates that the physical side of pedagogy. He says: "The physical 
 education of each new generation and its schooling in the external 
 graces of the parents or ancestors cotnes as an immense additional task 
 to the procreative activity of the sexes. ... In this second act 
 physical adaptations are obtained that were unknown to the parents 
 themselves." 
 
 * 
 
li 
 
 ' ii 
 
 338 
 
 ORGANIZATION OF WORK AND 
 
 sorption " and imitation, just as well as other elements 
 of education. But this process is fundamentally different 
 from inheritance in the biological sense.'^" That which in 
 this sense is said to be hereditary must make its appear- 
 ance even when the offspring are completely removed at 
 the moment of birth from the influence of their pro- 
 genitors. 
 
 We know not whether there are people who consider 
 the physical and intellectual peculiarities constituting 
 the plane of culture of our six or eight vocational classes 
 in society as transmissable in the sense that they must ap- 
 pear among the descendants of each class even when 
 brought up within another class. It is only individual in- 
 stances of this kind that practical life is ever presenting; 
 and as yet no one has taken the trouble to collect them. 
 They are generally cases of children of the humbler classes 
 who are brought up or formally adopted by members of a 
 higher class. There will scarcely be anyone bold enough 
 to maintain that these persons, artificially united to social 
 groups of higher rank, are later on distinguishable from 
 the members of these groups by birth by reason of less 
 business ability or of a lower plane of culture. 
 
 A further series of observations of this nature is offered 
 by the instances in which descendants of one class have by 
 their own energy raised themselves into a higher class. 
 Everyone knows what difticulties the era of capitalistic 
 production opposes to such an attempt, and frequently 
 only too successfully. Everyone, too, can readily call up 
 the picture of the " upstart " who, with all the technical 
 
 "This latter is the real question with Schmollcr, as he plainly indi- 
 cates in Preuss. Jhrb.. Vol. 69. p. 464- The sociological conception of 
 inheritance which Schaffle has constructed in works cited (II. pp. 
 308 ff.) is not treated l>y Schtnolltr, tiiongli many of his remarks re- 
 call it. 
 
THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 
 
 339 
 
 ability he shows for his trade, is defeated in his effort to 
 reach the intellectual and moral level of his new class. 
 This serves again to illustrate the truth that the adapta- 
 tion to an occupation enjoined by division of labour — the 
 prime condition of business success — is accomplished by 
 each individually, and without too much difficulty. But 
 the moral and intellectual adaptation demanded by the 
 plane of culture of the class ripens slowly even amid 
 favourable surroundings, and comes to full maturity only 
 in the second or third generation. 
 
 A strict proof of the fallacy of SchmoUer's theory 
 of heredity cannot be adduced; but the proofs hitherto 
 advanced in favour of its accuracy fall equally short of 
 conclusiveness. Before venturing to dogmatize one 
 would perhaps have to pass in review the great men of a 
 nation and note the vocations of their parents, and the 
 number who have issued from classes of humble occupa- 
 tion. At the same t-me one would need to determine for 
 the dififerent classes the degree of probability of their 
 members attaining a prominent position in which they 
 alone could display high ability. Finally one would 
 have to ascertain what relation the number of promi- 
 nent men who have actually come forth from any given 
 class of tradesmen bears to the number obtained by the 
 calculation of probabilities. It does not need to be demon- 
 strated that for such an investigation all the data are lack- 
 ing. 
 
 But it may be maintained that the new theory contra- 
 dicts the belief of modern civilized people based, as it is, 
 upon the observation of many generations. 
 
 How often the complaint is made that so much talent 
 pines under the weight of adversity? If to this dictum 
 we oppose the other that real talent will always find a 
 way, wc may indeed offer a formula to (latter the egoism 
 
i1^: 
 
 .: 
 
 i i 
 
 340 
 
 ORG/tNlZATION OF fVORK AND 
 
 of successful competitors, though in reality it meets all 
 too rarely with confirmation. 
 
 Our whole socio-juridical development since the French 
 Revolution is based on the assumption that admission to 
 every free calling and to all public offices, which latter, 
 after all, we still regard as tJie pinnacle of class divisions, 
 shall be free to all. This principle of free choice of voca- 
 tion, whose recognition has been gained only after severe 
 struggles, would be a great mistake, and every endeavour 
 towards its realization lost labour, if beside the inequality 
 in distribution of wealth the hereditability of vocational 
 aptitudes likewise stood in the way of its establishment. 
 
 Even many of our oldest academic arrangements must, 
 in the light of this theory, necessarily appear funda- 
 mentally erroneous. To what a high degree the costli- 
 ness of preparation narrows admission to the favoured 
 positions of the business world is well known. From time 
 immemorial, however, a great peril to the efficiency of 
 the official and the scholastic class has likewise been per- 
 ceived; and an effort has been made to obviate this danger 
 through scholarships, free board, remission of fees, and 
 similar arrangements for rendering study possible to those 
 without means. The practical results of these arrange- 
 ments may be a subject of dispute. Yet in judging them 
 it is essential to remember that advancement in the voca- 
 tion enjoying popular esteem depends not only upon per- 
 sonal integrity, but also upon the social education of the 
 individual, upon his ability to make his own strength felt; 
 that in this imperfect world even the capable man who too 
 modestly holds back may all too easily be outdistanced by 
 the mediocre man who is boldly self-assertive; that he 
 who seeks to climb the social ladder from the lower rungs 
 will find it much more difficult to reach the top than the 
 man who starts halfway up. The German language has an 
 
THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 341 
 
 expression for denoting distinction in a line of business 
 which happily characterizes the importance of the personal 
 element in the achievement of success. It is sich hervortlnin 
 [literally, to do oneself forwardj. Thus it may indeed be 
 that the student sons of the peasant in Riehl's story failed 
 to distinguish themselves in their vocations because they 
 lacked capacity. It is none the less true that many of them 
 missed success because they did not know how to " do 
 themselves forward " in the right place, how to bring their 
 personality into play. , 
 
 In every social grouping in which the occupation exerts 
 an influence there is generally formed within the different 
 classes a community of feeling that turns instinctively 
 against the intruder, and in spite of all his talent frequently 
 dooms him to failure; while, on the other hand, it supports 
 and carries along weaklings belonging by birth to the 
 group in question. Thus, as concerns advancement in the 
 public service, which still bears in a preeminent degree the 
 sign manual of a class characterized purely by its voca- 
 tion, personal and family connections often play, along 
 with financial standing, a decisive part. Where these 
 become a cloak for nepotism they can indeed impress upon 
 it the characteristics of an hereditary class. In the broad 
 realm of labour, organized according to occupation and 
 extending beyond it, property will indeed remain, as long 
 as the present economic system lasts, the prime cause of 
 social class-formation. And just such an accessory im- 
 portance as fell in the stages of unfree labour to com- 
 munity of labour, will here attach to division of labour. If 
 the employment is inherited it is not because the adapta- 
 tion to the vocation has been inherited, but because the 
 property is transmitted by which membership in it is con- 
 ditioned. 
 
 The above theory of heredity consequently bears. 
 
 
:ilr 
 
 
 
 mi i ;i ■ 
 
 m 
 
 '" "1 
 
 f 
 
 342 ORGANIZATION OF f^ORK AND 
 
 though certainly unknown to its originator, the cheerless 
 lineaments of a social philosophy of beati poss^dentes It 
 calls to the man of humble birth who hinks he has m hmi 
 the power to occupy a higher position in life: Abandon 
 all hope- your physical and intellectual constitution, your 
 nerves, your muscles, the causal chain of many genera- 
 tions, hold you fast to the ground. For centuries your 
 ancestors have been serfs; yoar father and grandfather 
 were day-labourers, and you are destined for a l>ke posi- 
 tion " We need not recite how the consequences of this 
 new theory do violence to our moral consciousness, to 
 our ideal of social justice. 
 
 In the ^tate of improved thesis in which it at present 
 stands, the theory, in our opinion, falls to the ground from 
 the very fact that, as is frequently enough observed, in a 
 single generation the whole road from zero to the highest 
 point of modem culture, from the lowest to the highest 
 stage of division of labour, from the foot to the summit of 
 the social ladder is traversed, and vice versa. One must 
 indeed wonder that such a theory could originate among 
 a people who count among their intellectual heroes a 
 Luther the son of a miner, a Kant the son of a saddler, a 
 Fichte the son of a poor village weaver, a Winckelmann 
 the son of a cobbler, a Gauss the son of a gardener, not to 
 
 mention many others." , .u 1 j 
 
 There is an old anecdote of a cardinal whose father had 
 
 -Valerius Maximus wrote a chapter (III, 4). de humililoconatis, 
 aui clari evaserunt, that begins thus: " Sxpe even.t ut et hum.l. loco 
 Tati ad summam dignitatem consurgant et generosiss.marum 'naagmum 
 foetus in aliquod revoluti dedecus acceptam a majonbus lucem in 
 tenebras convertant."-In the most recent presentat.on of h.s theory, 
 which shows considerable modification, (Grundnss. pp. 396ff..) 
 SchmoUer rests the fact "that talents and great "^e", ^"^^ f^^") ^' 
 classes of a generally hishb cultured -rtety ' upon thf peculiar .« 
 fiuences of variation." But this explains nothmg. 
 
THE FORMATION OF SOCIAL CLASSES. 
 
 343 
 
 -A 
 
 tended swine, and a French ambassador filled with the 
 pride of noble birth. In a difficult negotiation in which 
 the cardinal represented the interests of the church with 
 adroitness and tenacity the ambassador was so carried 
 away that he taunted the other with his origin. The 
 cardinal answered: " It is true that my father tended 
 swine; but if your father had done so, you would be tend- 
 ing them too." 
 
 This little story has perhaps expressed better than a 
 long disquisition could have done what the observation 
 of many generations has established: that the virtues by 
 which the fathers rise are as a rule not handed down to 
 grandson and great grandson; that even if the occu- 
 pation is inherited, the ability to carry it on disappears. 
 Each aristocracy, be it aristocracy of property or of occu- 
 pation, degenerates in the course of time like the plant 
 growing in too fertile soil. In this it is not at all necessary 
 to think of a moral decay; it suffices if the physical and in- 
 tellectual powers decline, and procreation grows weak. 
 The introduction of uncorrupted blood, ascending from the 
 lower to the higher vocations, appears then a condition 
 fundamental to the healthy exchange of social material. 
 The great problem of the century, indeed, we have always 
 considered to be the ensuring that a gradual rise in the so- 
 cial scale is made pjossible; that a continuous regeneration 
 of the higher vocational classes takes place. -• the caste 
 system, which would be a necessary consequence of the 
 theory of heredity, we have ever seen the beginning, not 
 the end of the progress of civilization. 
 
 We will not allow ourselves to be led astray in this con- 
 ception. The solution of the problem just mentioned is 
 for modern civilized peoples a question of their very ex- 
 istence. For if history has taught anything with insistence 
 it is, that for a people that can no longer bt renewed 
 
I SI 
 
 hi 
 
 344 
 
 tyORK AND SOCIAL CLASSES. 
 
 from the fresh spring of pure physical and intellectual 
 strength flowing in the lower classes, the statement once 
 made by B. G. Niebuhr with regard to England and Hol- 
 land holds good: the marrow has departed fvoi;' their 
 bones, they are doomed to inevitable decay. 
 
 "Ml 
 
 I 
 
 ,.'! 
 
CHAPTER X. 
 
 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE GROWTH 
 OF TOWNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 
 
 All prehistoric investigation, as far as it relates to the 
 pJienomena of the animate world, necessarily rests upon 
 the hypothesis of migration. The distribution of plants, 
 of the lower animals and of men over the surface of the 
 earth; the relationships existing between the different 
 languages, religious conceptions, myths and legends, cus- 
 toms and social institutions; all these seem ir this one 
 assumption to find their common explanation. 
 
 In the history of mankind we have, to be sure, aban- 
 doned the view that nomad life is to be regarded as a 
 universal phase in the r rowth of civilization, which each 
 people necessarily traversed before making fix'^ settle- 
 ments, and which served, along with the taming of 
 domestic animals, as the " natural " pathway of a people 
 passing from the hunting stage to agriculture. Ethno- 
 graphic research has made it sufficiently clear that all 
 primitive peoples, whatever the economic foundations 
 of their existence, readily, often, indeed, for very insig- 
 nificant reasons, shift their habitations, and that they 
 exhibit an extraordinary number of stages intermediate 
 between nomadic and settled life.' The northern and 
 southern limits of the inhabited world are stiU peopled 
 
 Comp. Z. Dimti off. Die Geringschatsung d. menscklichcn Lebens u. 
 ihre Ursathen bei d. Naturvclk. (Leipzig, 1891), pp. 33 ff. 
 
 345 
 
u 
 
 
 346 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE 
 
 by races without fixed abode; and even in its midst there 
 are broad areas in which a condition of continual migra- 
 tion prevails. Most civilized peoples have proverbs or 
 other historic bequests from such a time. 
 
 In the German language this far-distant period of univer- 
 sal mobility has left distinct traces. The word for " healthy" 
 {gcsnnd) meant originally " ready for the road." « Gesmde, 
 signifying to-day household servants, is, in the olden 
 speech, a travelling retinue; companions (Gcfdhrtc and 
 Gefdhrtin) means, in the strictly literal sense, the fellow- 
 traveller. Ertahrmg (experience) is what one has ob- 
 tained on the journey {fahmi); and bcwandcrt (skilled) is 
 applied to the person who has wandered much. With 
 these the list of such expressions is far from ex 
 hausted. In the general significance attached to them 
 to-day the universality of the concrete range of concep- 
 tions and observations from which v ey originally sprang 
 
 finds expression. 
 
 It is natural to suppose that this condition of general 
 nomadic wandering, with its deep-rooted nomadic cus- 
 toms, did not suddenly cease; that, in all probability, 
 the wiiolc course of further development down to our own 
 day has been a gradual progress towards a settled condi- 
 tion and an ever-closer attachment of the man to the spot 
 
 wner* he was born. 
 
 Various indications support this view. Among our 
 forefathers the house is reckoned movable property; 
 and it is demonstrable that many settlements have within 
 historic times changed their locations. Despite the lack 
 of artificial roads and comfortable means of transporta- 
 tion.the individual appears in the Middle Ages much more 
 migratory than ac a later time. This is supported by the 
 
 * [From sendtn, meaning to go, to travel.— Ed.1 
 
GROIVTH OF TOH^NS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 347 
 
 numerous pilgrimages that extended as far as St. lago, in 
 Spain, by the crusades, by the great bands of travellers, 
 the migratory life of king and court, the rights of hospi- 
 tality of the marquisates and the developed system of 
 escorts. 
 
 Each fresh advance in culture commences, so to speak, 
 with a new period of wandering. The most primitive agri- 
 culture is nomadic, with a yearly abandonment of the cul- 
 tivated area; the earliest trade is migratory trade; the 
 first industries that free themselves from the household 
 husbandry and become the special occupations of separate 
 individuals are carried on itinerantly. The great founders 
 of reHgion, the earliest poets and philosophers, the musi- 
 cians and actors of past epochs are all great wanderers. 
 Even to-day, do not the inventor, the preacher of a 
 new doctrine, and the virtuoso travel from place to place 
 in search of adherents and admirers — notwithstanding the 
 immense recent development in the means of communi- 
 cating information? 
 
 As civilization grows older, settlement becomes more 
 permanent. The Greek was more settled than the Phoe- 
 nician, the Roman than the Greek, because one was al- 
 ways the inheritor of the culture of the other. Conditions 
 have not changed. The German is more migratory than 
 the Latin, the Slav than the (Jernian. The Frenchman 
 cleaves to his native soil; the Russian leaves it with a light 
 heart to seek in other parts of his broad Fatherland more 
 favourable conditions of living. Even the factory work- 
 man is but a periodically wandering peasant. 
 
 To all that can be adduced from experience in support 
 of the statement that in the course of history mankind 
 has been ever growing more settled, there comes a gen- 
 eral consideration of a twofold nature. In tlie first place 
 the extent of fixed capital g'ows with advancing culture; 
 
» \ 
 
 348 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE 
 
 the producer becomes stationary with his means of pro- 
 duction. The itinerant smith of the souther Slav coun- 
 tries and the Westphalian ironworks, the pack-horses of 
 the Middle Ages and the great warehouses of our cities, 
 the Thespian carts and the resident theatre mark the 
 starting and the terminal points of this evolution. In the 
 second place the modern machinery of transportation 
 has in a far higher degree facilitated the transport of 
 goods than of persons. The distribution of labour de- 
 termined by locality thereby attains greater importance 
 than the natural distribution of the means of production; 
 the latter in many cases draws the former after it, 
 where previously the reverse occurred. 
 
 To these statements there are, of course, some consider- 
 ations and facts opposed. First, the extent to which man 
 was by law tied to the soil in the earlier agrarian period — 
 the unfree nature of all his economic and legal relation- 
 ships in contrast with the modern freedom of person and 
 property. Further, and in part as a result of this, 
 we have in modem times the entire dependence of many 
 individuals upon movable capital or personal skill. Still 
 further, the growing ease of transfer of landed property 
 which to-day allows the peasant to convert house and land 
 into money and on the other side of the ocean to start 
 life anew; while the villein of the Middle Ages could at 
 most attach himself as an c.xtra-nuiral citizen to a ncigli- 
 bouring town whence he either contiimed to carr>- on his 
 work in the village personally, or leased it in some form 
 or other to a second person for a yearly rent. Finally. 
 the increase one observes in the flow of rural popula- 
 tion to the to\<ns which has been manifesting itself for 
 half a centurv in a remarkably rapid rise in nrhan. and 
 at some pc^ints in a stationary or even declining rural, 
 poi)ulation. \\ itli .ill these circuinstatv> ?s in mind, many 
 
GROIVTH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 349 
 
 consider themselves justified in speaking of the steadily 
 advancing mobility of society. 
 
 How are these two series of phenomena to be recon- 
 ciled? Is it a question of two principles of development 
 mutually opposed? Or is it possible that modern migra- 
 tions and those of past centuries are of essential!} diflferent 
 types? 
 
 One would almost be inclined to believe the latter The 
 migrations occurring at the opening of the history of 
 European peoples are migrations of whole tribes, a push- 
 ing and pressing of collective units from east tc; west which 
 lasted for centuries. The migrations of the Middle Ages 
 ever affect individual classes alone; the knights in the 
 crusades, the merchants, the wage craftsmen, the journey- 
 men hand-workers, the jugglers and minstrels, the villeins 
 seeking protection within the walls of a town. Modern 
 migrat'ons, on the contrary, are generally a matter of pri- 
 vate concern, the individuals being led by the most varied 
 motives. They are almost invarialily without organiza- 
 tion. The process repeating itself daily a thousand 
 times is united only throu}^!-]! the one characteristic, that 
 it is everywhere a question of change of locality by per- 
 sons seeking more favourable conditions of life. 
 
 Yet such a distinction would not be fully in accord with 
 the nature of either modern or media-val migrations. If 
 we would grasp their true importance in historical evolu- 
 tion we must fust thin out the tangled thicket of con- 
 fused contemporar) opinions that still surrounds the 
 whole subject ilespite all the ctTorts of statistics and politi- 
 cal economy. 
 
 Among all the phenomena of masses in sticial life suited 
 to statistical treatment there is without tloubt scarcely 
 one that appears to fall of itself so complett'Iy under the 
 general law of causality as migrations; and likeuisc hardly 
 
 til 
 
1' ' !" ^1 
 
 350 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE 
 
 one concerning whose real cause such misty conceptions 
 
 prevail. 
 
 Yet, not merely in popular circles and in the press, but 
 even in scientific works, migratory instincis are spoken of; 
 and thus those movements of men from place to place are 
 put without the pale of deliberate action. Indeed, a statis- 
 tician once entitled an article in the Journal of the Prus- 
 sian Statistical Bureau of 1873 "The Affection for the 
 Homestead and the Migratory Instinct of the Prussian 
 People," just as if home-keeping depended merely upon 
 natural disposition, and the abandoning of it upon an 
 irresistible instinctive impulse stronger with one race 
 
 than another! 
 
 In strange contradiction to this, to be sure, is the fact 
 that while the great bulk of official statistical compila- 
 tions remains unheeded by wider circles, the publication 
 of the emigration returns generally excites a most active 
 expression of public opinion. The rising and faUing of the 
 figures bring fear and hope, approbation and disapproba- 
 tion, editorial leaders and speeches in Parliament. Here 
 naturally we hear less about migrator>- instincts and the 
 love of home; people have avague feeling that behind those 
 Huctuating phenomena stand very concrete causes. Cut 
 how little they comprehend the nature of these causes 
 is evident when we recall, for example, that a few years 
 ago it was a matter of grave debate in the (lerman Reichs- 
 tag whether people emigrated because they were getting 
 along well or because they were not. 
 
 With regard to this jjfoblem one cannot say that as yet 
 statistics have succeeded in escaping from the turbid 
 -waters of confuse<l popular opinions to the firm conclti- 
 sions of exact observation. From the statistical stand- 
 point migration is above all an economic and social phe- 
 nomenon of masse>^; .iiul stritistin;.ns. in our opinion, have 
 
 W^. 
 
 awngyami lji.i: >*«» . 
 
GROU^TH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 35 » 
 
 been precipitate in abandoning the attempt to discover 
 with their peculiar machinery the causes of these migra- 
 tions and turning to investigation by inquiry before the 
 resources of the statistical method were exhausted. 
 
 A perusal of the perfunctory remarks that Quetelet' 
 devotes to the phenomenon of emigration will readily con- 
 vmce anyone that his exposition of the subject hardly rises 
 above the prosaic commonplace. True, one finds on go- 
 ing through the official publications of recent date that 
 detailed systematic interrogations on the " causes " and 
 " grounds " of emigration, which would not even perplex 
 the less intelligent of the communal officials consulted, are 
 by no means infrequent. But one immediately feels that 
 such suggestive (|uestions mean the substitution of a series 
 of subjective presumptions for the objective results of in- 
 vestigation. 
 
 Before resorting, however, to a means of information 
 that reads into the numbers only a strained interpre- 
 tation not following of itself, we should rather tr>' 
 to determine the phenomena of migrations themselves. 
 We should classify them according to numerical regu- 
 larity, and connect them with other mass-phenomena of 
 difTerent times and places accessible to statistics (for ex- 
 ample, the density of population, its division into trades, 
 the .listrihution oi landed property, the rate of labour 
 wages, the oscillation in food prices); that is, undertake 
 the statistical experiment of drawing up parallel lines of 
 isolated series of figures. 
 
 From even these first steps on the road to an exact 
 method we are. however, still far removed. The whole de- 
 partment of migrations has never yet undergone system- 
 atic statistical observation; exclusive attention has hith- 
 
 • D« systime social ft des lots qui It ri-gissent, pp. 186-190. 
 
!!■' V- p 
 
 3Si INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE 
 
 erto been centred upon remarkable individual occur- 
 rences of such phenomena. Even a rational classification 
 of migrations in accord with the demand of social science 
 is at the present moment lacking. 
 
 Such a classification would have to take as its starting- 
 point the result of migrations from the point of view of 
 population. On this basis they would fall into these 
 groups: — 
 
 1. Migrations with continuous change of locality. 
 
 2. " '■ temporary change of settlement. 
 3.' " " permanent settlement. 
 
 To the first i^roup belong gypsy life, peddling, the carry- 
 ing on of itinerant trades, tramp life; to the second, the 
 wandering of journeymen craftsmen, domestic servants, 
 tradesmen seeking the most favourable spots for tempo- 
 rary undertakings, officials to whom a definite office is 
 for a time entrusted, scholars attending foreign institu- 
 tions of learning; to the third, migration from place to 
 place within the same countr>' or province and to foreign 
 parts, especially across the ocean. 
 
 An intermediate stage between the first and second 
 group is found in the periodical migrations. To this stage 
 belong the migrations of farm labourers at harvest-time, 
 of the sugar labourers at the time of the campagne, of the 
 masons of Upper Italy and the Ticmo district, common 
 day-labourers, potters, chimney-sweeps, chestnut-roast- 
 ers, etc.. which recur at definite seasons. 
 
 In this division the influence of the natural and political 
 insulation of the different countries is. it is true, neglected. 
 It must not. however, be overlooked that in the era of 
 nationalism and protection of national labour political al- 
 lej^iance has a certain importance in connection with the 
 objective point of the migrations. It would, therefore, in 
 
 '-•v»!^Tr-Ear jz»:*wfe r /x. . .ta'n.*i"»r?n^». "wrj" 
 
CROIVTH OF TOfVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 353 
 
 our opinion, be more just to make another division, 
 taking as a basis the politico-geographical extent of the 
 migrations. From this point of view migrations would 
 fall into internal and foreign. 
 
 Internal migrations are those whose points of departure 
 and destination lie within the same national limits; for- 
 eign, those extending beyond these. The foreign may 
 again be divided into continental and extra-European 
 (generally transmaritime) emigration. One can, however, 
 in a larger sense designate all migrations that do not leave 
 the limits of the ODntinent as internal, and contrast with 
 them real emigration, or transfer of domicile to other parts 
 of the globe. 
 
 Of all these manifold kinds of migration, the trans- 
 maritime alone has regularly been the subject of official 
 statistics; and even it has been but imperfectly treated, as 
 every student of this subject knows. The periodic 
 emigrations of labour and the peddling trade have occa- 
 sionally been also subjected to statistical investigation — 
 mostly with the secondary aim of legislative restriction. 
 The Government of Italy alone has long been endeavour- 
 ing to clear up the subject of the periodic migration of a 
 part of her population to other European lands through 
 local investigations, exchange of tabulation-cards and 
 consular reports. 
 
 The migrations involving permanent and temporary 
 transfer of settlement between the different European 
 countries are but very imperfectly noticed in the publica- 
 tions of the population census by means of the returns of 
 births and of nationality. As for internal migrations, they 
 have only in rare instances met with serious consideration. 
 
 Yet these migrations from place to place within the 
 same country are vastly more numerous and in their con- 
 
 .i,'B'»»rei*sS5« 
 
f!'V 
 
 II i ii 
 
 354 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE 
 
 sequences vastly more important than all other kinds of 
 migration put together.* 
 
 Of the total population of the Kingdom of Belgium 
 there were, according to the results of the census of 31st 
 December, 1880, not less than 32.8 per cent, who were 
 born outside the municipality in which they had their tem- 
 porary domicile;' of the population of Austria (1890), 
 34.8 per cent. The actual population of Prussia on the 
 first of December, 1880, was divided as follows: — 
 
 No. of Per ct. of whole 
 PUcc of Birth. Peisona. Population. 
 
 1. In the municipality where enumerated 1S.721.S88 57-6 
 
 2. Elsewhere in census district (.Krtis) 4.S99.664 16.9 
 
 3. Elsewhere in enumerated province 4.556.124 i6.7 
 
 4. Elsewhere in Prussia 1,658,187 6.1 
 
 5. Elsewhere in Germany 526,037 1.9 
 
 6. In foreign parts under German flag 212,021 0.8 
 
 Of 27,279,111 persons, 11,552,033. or 42-4 per cent., 
 were born outside the municipality where they were domi- 
 ciled." More than two-fifths of the population had 
 changed their municipality at least once. Of the popula- 
 tion of Switzerland on the first of December, 1888, there 
 were born in the commune where then domiciled 56.4. in 
 another commune of the same canton 25.7. in another 
 canton 11. 5, in foreign parts 6.4 per cent.^ The commune 
 in this enumeration is an administrative centre, which in 
 many parts of the State embraces several places of resi- 
 dence. The figures here given thus exclude altogether 
 the numerous class of migrations from locality to locality 
 within the commune itself. 
 
 •Comp. now also G. von Mayr. Statistik m. GeselUckaftsUhre, II, pp. 
 
 li6fT. 354 ff- _^ 
 
 " \ntiuairt statist, de la Belgique. XVI (1885). p. 76. 
 •Ztschr d. k. preus^ statist, Bureaus, XXI (1881), Beilage I, pp. 
 
 46.47 
 
 ♦Statist. Jhrb. <! Schweiz. II (1892), p. 57. 
 
GROIVTH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 355 
 
 This latter class of internal migrations, as far as we are 
 aware, has been but once a subject of investigation. This 
 was in connection with the Bavarian birth statistics of 
 1871.* According to these the total actual population of 
 Bavaria was divided as follows: — 
 
 Place of Birth. No. of Pw ct. of whole 
 
 Penom. Population. 
 
 1. In the municipality where enumerated 2,975,146 61.2 
 
 2. Elsewhere in census district (Kreis) 143,186 3.0 
 
 3. Elsewhere in enumerated province 677,752 13.9 
 
 4. Elsewhere in Bavaria 944, loi 19.4 
 
 5. Elsewhere in Germany 78,241 1.6 
 
 6. In foreign parts 44,150 0.9 
 
 The Bavarian population of 1871 thus appears some- 
 what more settled than the Prussian of 1880 and the Swiss 
 of 1888, a circumstance perhaps due to the earlier year of 
 the census. Nevertheless, two-fifths of the inhabitants 
 (1,888,000 out of 4,863,000) were not native to the place 
 in which they were living; that is, had migrated thither 
 at some time or other. In the larger cities the number of 
 people not of local birth amounted to as much as 54.5 per 
 cent., in the small rural towns 43.2 per cent.; even in the 
 communes of the open country it sank to merely 35.6 per 
 cent. 
 
 These are colossal migrations that we are dealing with. 
 If one may venture an estimate, the data for which cannot 
 be. gfiven in detail here, we believe ourselves justified in 
 maintaining that the number of the inhabitants of Europe 
 owing their present place of domicile not to birth, but to 
 migration, reaches far over one hundred millions. How 
 small do the oft-cited figures of transmaritime emigration 
 appear in comparison! ® 
 
 ' Die bayerische Bevdlkerung nock d. Gebiirtigkeit. Bearbeitet von Dr. 
 
 G. Mayr (No. XXXII of Beitrdge s. Statistik d. Konigr. Bayem), p. 10. 
 
 *In the seventy years, 1821-1891, the United States of America re- 
 
W !'i 
 
 f *! 
 
 (:•<' 
 
 356 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE 
 
 That such enormous movements of population must 
 draw after them far-reaching consequences is obvious. 
 These consequences are chiefly economic and social. 
 
 The economic result of all kinds of migrations is a local 
 exchange of labour and, as people cannot be dissociated 
 from their economic equipment, a considerable transfer of 
 capital as well. Or we may say, since we must presume 
 that in these matters also men's actions have definite pur- 
 poses behind them, that they bring about more effective 
 distribution and combination of labour and capital 
 throughout the whole inhabited world. In this regard it 
 is indifferent whether labour follows capital or favourable 
 natural conditions, or capital seeks unemployed hands. 
 
 Their social result is great shiftings of the population, 
 which with an endless, undulatory motion seeks to pre- 
 serve the equilibrium between itself and existing advan- 
 tages for trade. These shiftings retard the increase in 
 population at certain points, and accelerate it at others,— 
 at once a thinning out and a concentration. The local 
 distribution of the population, which is ordinarily deter- 
 mined by natural organic increase, through surplus of 
 births over deaths, is broken through. 
 
 But in this very respect there is for the individual State 
 an important difference between internal migration and 
 
 emigration. 
 
 The immediate effect of emigration upon the mother 
 country shows itself in only one way: it thins out the pop- 
 ulation and gives elbow-room to the remainder. That at 
 the same time the settlement and development of thinly- 
 peopled colonial territories is accelerated only indirectly 
 affects the mother country when ultimately by the prac- 
 tice of agriculture on a virgin soil the emigrants create a 
 ceived from all countries of Europe 13.692.576 immigrants, v. Mayr, as 
 above, p. 344- 
 
CROIVTH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 357 
 
 dangerous competition for home agricultural products, or 
 by the transference of industrial skill and means of pro- 
 duction into foreign lands cut off the market of home in- 
 dustry. 
 
 The effects of internal migrations, on the other hand, 
 are always of two kinds: those displaying themselves 
 at the points of departure; those perceptible at the objec- 
 tive points. In the one case they reduce, in the other 
 they increase, the density of the population. They 
 thus cause, as it were, a division of the popula- 
 tion centres and districts into t'.iose producing and 
 those consuming human beings. Our producing centre" 
 are generally the country places and smaller towns; our 
 consuming centres, the large cities and industrial districts. 
 The latter increase in population beyond the natural rate 
 of the birth surplus, while the former remain noticeably 
 behind it. Taking a yearly average for the period of eigh- 
 teen years from 1867 to 1885, the total population of the 
 German Empire has increased by 0.86 per cent, of the 
 mean population." Yet when we look at the details we 
 see that the average yearly increase amounted: 
 
 In the large cities (pop. loo.cxn and over) to a.6 per cent. 
 " " medium-siied cities ( " 30,000 to 100,000) " 3.4 " " 
 " " small cities ( " 5,000" 30,000) " 1.8 " " 
 " " country towns ( " a.ooo •' s.ooo) " i.o " '• 
 " " villages (below 8,000) •' 
 
 But of course the phenomenon of inland migrations is 
 really not so simple and clear as this row of figures would 
 seem to indicate. It certainly vividly illumines the much- 
 talked-of " inHux to the cities." This expression, however, 
 tells only half the truth. It overlooks the great number of 
 internal migrations that counterbalance one another, and 
 
 "According to Schumann in Mayr's Allg. statist. Archiv., II (1890), 
 
 P- 518. 
 
MKIOCOnr RtSOUJTION TEST CHAtT 
 
 (ANSI and ISO TEST CHART No. 2) 
 
 A 
 
 /APPLIED IM/QE I 
 
 <6S3 Eoit Main Strnt 
 
 RochMttr, N«w Torh 1 4609 USA 
 
 ('!«) *82 - 0300 - Phon« 
 
 ("«) 2M- 5989 -Fo, 
 
;iil (r 
 
 358 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE 
 
 therefore find no expression in a change in the number 
 of inhabitants of individual localities. 
 
 If we take a collective view of the internal migrations 
 of a large country, without regard to their effect on the 
 distribution of the inhabitants over the surface, their 
 routes appear to us as a close variegated web in which the 
 interwoven threads cross and recross continually. Into 
 the rather simple warp stretched from the country places 
 and towns to the large cities and industrial centres is 
 woven a many-coloured woof whose threads run hither 
 and thither between the smaller centres of population. Or, 
 to use a different figure, the broad and majestically surg- 
 ing surface-current, which alone we see, is not the only 
 one; beneath it numerous lesser currents sport at will. 
 
 Up to the present these latter have received scarcely 
 any attention, certainly not so much as they deserve, even 
 in cases where they happen to have been statistically as- 
 certained. The Bavarian census of 1871 shows the follow- 
 ing situation: 
 
 Retidcnti native •>„_ 
 toLoc»lilyof pi^I^„ ToUl. 
 
 EnumeiatfoD. E^^'h^"- 
 
 In the self-governing cities ^. . 301, 494 361.899 663.393 
 
 In other places of over 2,000 population. 205,887 iS7.o<» 36^,887 
 
 Total 507,381 518,899 T j6,28o 
 
 In the rural municipalities 2,467,765 i.3S7.98l J,«-25,746 
 
 Grand total 3,975.146 1,876,880 4.852,026 
 
 From these figures it is plainly evident that the abso- 
 lute number of persons who during the last generation 
 migrated into rural municipalities is far more than twice 
 as great as the number who had migrated to the cities. 
 The same relation probably holds good for all larger 
 countries. 
 
 But the significant feature in this connection is not that 
 
CROU^TH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 359 
 
 the country places receive as well as give in this inter- 
 change of population; it lies in two other considerations. 
 The one is that they give out a larger population than 
 they receive; the other, that their additions are made 
 chiefly from the rural municipalities, while those leaving 
 them find their way in part to the more distant cities. The 
 excess of decrease over increase thus accrues to the bene- 
 fit of communities of higher order; so much of the popu- 
 lation enters into a sphere of life economically and socially 
 diflferent. 
 
 If we call the total population born in a given place 
 and domiciled anywhere within the borders of the coun- 
 try that locality's native population, then according to the 
 conditions of interchange of population just presented 
 the native population of the country places is greater than 
 their actual population, that of the cities, smaller. Thus 
 in Bavaria, according to the census of 187 1, the native 
 population of the rural municipalities amounted to 103.5 
 per cent, of the enumerated population, that of the cities 
 to only 61 per cent." In the Grand Duchy of Olden- 
 burg '* according to the census of December ist, 1880, 
 
 The influx from other places amounted in the citiei to 25,370 persons 
 
 The exodus to " " cities " io,ao8 " 
 
 The influx from " " " " " country " 57,366 " 
 
 The exodus to " " " •• " country "72,528 " 
 
 A balancing of the account of the internal migrations 
 thus gives the cities a surplus, and the country municipal- 
 ities a deficit, of 15,162 persons. In the economy of popu- 
 lation one is the complement of the other, just as in the 
 case of two brothers of different temperament, one of 
 whom regularly spends what the other has laboriously 
 
 " Mayr, as above, pp. 5.1, 54 of the introduction. 
 
 "Comp. Statist. Nachrickten iiber d. Grosch. Oldtnbwt, XIX, p. 64. 
 
:l 
 
 
 360 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE 
 
 saved. To this extent then we are quite justified from 
 the point of view of population in designating the cities 
 man-consuming and the country municipalities man-pro- 
 ducing social organisms. 
 
 But the total remaining loss of population of the coun- 
 try municipalities exceeds the surplus that they furnish 
 to the cities, even in the example here given from a small 
 State, by almost four times. And the amount that they 
 receive from one another is just as great. However large 
 this mutual exchange of population by the country places 
 may appear, only a relatively limited scientific interest 
 really attaches to it. For here we are dealing with a 
 species of migration which arises from the social limita- 
 tions of the rural places, and which accordingly gains in 
 importance the smaller the communities. In the whole 
 Grand Duchy of Oldenburg the number of persons not 
 bom where at the time residing amounted in: 
 
 Municipalities of less than 500 inhabitants to SS-of» 
 
 " " 500 to 1,000 " " 37-4% 
 
 " i.oooto i.soo " " 417% 
 
 " " 1,500 to 2,000 " " 40.4% 
 
 " 2,000 to 3,ooo " " 387% 
 
 " " 3,000 to 4.000 " " 22.2% 
 
 " " 4,000 to 5,000 " " ao.6% 
 
 « " over 5.000 " " 29-4% 
 
 From this we notice that in the smaller municipalities 
 (up to 4000 inhabitants), as the absolute size of the mu 
 nicipality increases the influx from other places decreases 
 relatively to the native population, while in the larger 
 places it increases. 
 
 Mayr has shown that the same holds for Bavaria. There 
 in the year 1871 in the lartjer rural municipalities (of 2000 
 and more inlubitants) the number of those resident in the 
 place of birth was 66.9 per cent., but in the smaller mu- 
 
GROWTH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 361 
 
 nicipalities only 64.4 per cent.,*^ while in the cities the 
 exact opposite was the case. For in the self-governing 
 cities 45.5 per cent, of the population were found to have 
 been born where enumerated, but in the other (smaller) 
 towns 56.8 per cent. Mayr accordingly sets up the prop- 
 osition that in the cities the proportion of persons born where 
 residing decreases with the sice of the place, while in the 
 rural municipalities, on the contrary, it increases}* 
 
 There is a very natural explanation for this condition 
 of affairs in the country. Where the peasant, on account 
 of the small population of his place of residence, is 
 much restricted in his local choice of help, adjoining com- 
 munities must supplement one another. In like man- 
 ner the inhabitants of small places will intermarry more 
 frequently than the inhabitants of larger places where 
 there is a greater choice among the native population. 
 Here we have the occasion for very numerous migrations 
 to places not far removed. Such migrations, however, only 
 mean a local exchange of socially allied elements. 
 
 This is again clearly shown by the "work, already fre- 
 quently referred to, on the native-born population of 
 Oldenburg. In it the foreign-born population of Wadde- 
 warden, Holle and Cappeln, three communities chosen at 
 
 "Die bayer. Bevolkerung nack d. Gebiirtigkeit. Introduction, p. 15. 
 
 "This proposition has been corroborated by the Austrian census of 
 1890. According to the excellent treatise on it by H. Rauchberg, Die 
 Bevolkerung Oesterreichs auf Grutid d. Ergebnisse d. Volkss. v. 31. Des. 
 iS<)0 (Vienna, 1895), p. 105, of every 100 persons bom where enumer- 
 ated there were in places: 
 
 Of less than 500 inhabitants 65.7% 
 
 SCO to 2,000 " 735% 
 
 2,000 to s.ooo " 69.9% 
 
 5,000 to 10,000 " SS-6% 
 
 10,000 to 20,000 " 46.4% 
 
 over 20.000 inhabitants 43-1% 
 
362 
 
 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE 
 
 Holle. 
 
 CappelD 
 
 1298 
 
 1423 
 
 445 
 
 388 
 
 267 
 
 324 
 
 60.1 
 
 83.5 
 
 178 
 
 64 
 
 39-9 
 
 16.5 
 
 544 
 
 387 
 
 490 
 
 33a 
 
 90.0 
 
 85.9 
 
 54 
 
 55 
 
 10. 
 
 14 I 
 
 random, is arrar.ged according to zones of distance from 
 the place of birth. The figures are as follows: *' 
 
 Waddewardea, 
 
 Total population 861 
 
 From other places 270 
 
 Of these latter there j ^^^^.^^^ „^^t,„ g 
 
 come from places upj p„ „„, ^5.6 
 
 to 9 miles distant ( " 
 
 _ • J- . i Absolute number 12 
 From greater distances j pg^ cent 4.4 
 
 Migrated to other places 400 
 
 Of those up to a dis- ( Absolute number 332 
 
 tance of 9 miles ( Per cent 83.0 
 
 Migrated to a greater j Absolute number 68 
 
 distance \ Percent 17.0 
 
 How entirely different are conditions in this regard 
 in the capital, Oldenburg, which with its 20,575 inhabi- 
 tants is after all to be looked upon as only a small city. 
 Of its total foreign-born population (13,364 persons, or 
 64.9 per cent.) there come: 
 
 From a Distance of— Persons. Per cent. 
 
 Less than 9 miles 2916 31.8 
 
 From 9-4S " 5625 42.1 
 
 Over 45 " 4823 36.1 
 
 Here the greater part of the influx of population is from 
 a distance; the entry of the stranger-born into a new 
 community means at the same time an entry into new 
 social and economical conditions; and this urban com- 
 munity does not give as many of its native inhabitants 
 to other districts as it receives from them.*® On the 
 contrary, it absorbs from a wide region round about the 
 surplus of emigration over immigration, and repays it 
 only in very small part. 
 
 ^^ Stati.t. Niuh.ichtai iibcr d. Grossh. Oldenburg, p. 65 [i Germati mile 
 is taken — 4.5 Ln^lish miles, although actually = 4.6. — EdI. 
 
 "The city of Oldenburg in the year 1880 received from other munici- 
 palities of the Grand Duchy 8,725 inhabitants, and gave up to them only 
 1,925. See, as above, p. 212. 
 
or 
 
 CROIVTH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. . 363 
 
 This is the characteristic of modem cities. If in our 
 consideration of this problem we pay particular attention 
 to this urban characteristic and to a like feature of the 
 factory districts — ^where the conditions as to internal mi- 
 grations are almost similar — we shall be amply repaid 
 by the discovery that in such settlements the result 
 of internal shiftings of population receives its clearest 
 expression. Here, where the immigrant elements are 
 most numerous, there develops between them and the 
 native population a social struggle, — a struggle for the 
 best conditions of earning a livelihood or, if you will, for 
 existence, which ends with the adaptation of one part to 
 the other, or perhaps with the final subjugation of the 
 one by the other. Thus, according to Schliemann,*" the 
 city of Smyrna had in the year 1846 a population of 80,000 
 Turks and 8,000 Greeks; in the year 1881, on the con- 
 trary, there were 23,000 Turks and 76,000 Greeks. Tlie 
 Turkish portion of the population had thus in 35 years 
 decreased by 71 per cent., while the Greeks had increased 
 nine-fold. 
 
 Not everywhere, to be sure, do those struggles take the 
 form of such a general process of displacement; but in 
 individual cases it will occur with endless frequency within 
 a country that the stronger and better equipped element 
 will overcome the weaker and less well equipped. 
 
 In the year 1871, for instance, there were, in round 
 numbers, 86,000 Bavarians living in Munich not born 
 in the city; and at the same time some 18,000 na- 
 tives of Munich were to be found in other places in 
 Bavaria. In the year 1890 55.3 per cent, of the popula- 
 tion of the twenty-six largest cities of Germany was found 
 to have been born in other places, while 22.3 per cent, of 
 
 J 
 
 " Reiit in d, Troas im Mai 1881, 
 
 pp. 29 
 
 aoff. 
 
ill' I ' 
 
 V 1 1 
 
 364 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE 
 
 their native population was living in other parts of the 
 empire.*^ Still more striking is the fact shown by the 
 English census of 188 1, that there were living in England 
 and Wales (outside of the metropolis) just about half as 
 many persons native to London as England and Wales 
 had supplied to that city.*" 
 
 Thus we have here a case similar to that occurring so fre- 
 quently in nature; on the same terrain where a more 
 highly organized plant or animal has no longer room 
 for subsistence, others less exacting in their demands take 
 up their position and flourish. The coming of the new 
 is in fact not infrequently the cause of the disappearance 
 of those already there and of their withdrawal to more 
 favourable surroundings. 
 
 This process need not, however, in the world of human 
 society necessarily be a process of displacement, a con- 
 sequence of the imperfect equipment of the native ele- 
 ments and of the superiority of the foreign ones. 
 
 The reverse will perhaps occur quite as frequently, and 
 in the examples cited is probably the rule. On account 
 of the endless differentiation of labour in modern national 
 
 "Comp. von Mayr, Statistik u. GeseUschaftslekre, II, pp. 122 flF. 
 
 "London had in i88i, 3,816,483 inhabitants. Of these there were 
 
 born: 
 
 D.—™.. P«' cent, of the 
 
 Penou. Population. 
 
 In London 2,401,955 62.9 
 
 In the immediate neighbourhood.. 384,871 lai 
 
 Elsewhere in England and Wales . . 787,699 ao.6 
 
 In Scotland 49-554 1.3 
 
 In Ireland 80,778 3.1 
 
 In other countries 111,626 a.9 
 
 On the other hand, 584,700 natives of London were counted in other 
 parts of England and Wales. For every 100 persons from these terri- 
 tories who had settled in London, 51 natives of London had left the 
 metropolis. — According to the Ztschr. des preuss. statist. Bureaus, 
 XXVI (j886), Statist. Correspondens, p, xviii. 
 
\- 
 
 GROIVTH OF TOfVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 3^5 
 
 economy it is the skilled labourers who experience most 
 trouble in finding suitable employment and compensation 
 for their labour where they live and have received their 
 training, because it is there that the competition is keen- 
 est. They emigrate and seek more favourable surround- 
 ings, better conditions of competition, while at these 
 points less highly qualified labour may at the same time 
 be in demand, which demand must be met by importation 
 of labour from outside places. This less skilled labour 
 may, on the other hand, however, form the stronger, bet- 
 ter equipped element in its own locality; and though it 
 may lack here the opportunity for a profitable utilization 
 of its skill, its departure may, nevertheless, leave a void 
 that it is impossible to fill. 
 
 Thus the emigration of more highly trained technical 
 labour from the cities was perhaps never greater than in 
 the period of the so-called industrial boom of the seventies. 
 At the same time, however, those same cities received an 
 immense influx of labouring population from the country; 
 and the departure of the latter again caused in the dis- 
 tricts of great landed estates a serious dearth of agricul- 
 tural labourers, an advance in wages, and in some places 
 a lamentable condition of agriculture. Here, in every case, 
 it was the relatively stronger that had emigrated, the rela- 
 tively weaker that had remained; there could be no ques- 
 tion at all of mutual displacement. 
 
 Still less is there ground for such a view with regard to 
 those internal migrations that have their origin not in 
 the effort to find a better place for carrying on work, but 
 in the search for more favourable conditions of living. The 
 pensioned civil servant or military man who leaves the 
 expensive metropolitan city for the country or a cheaper 
 rural town; the speculator who has become suddenly rich 
 and exchanged his fluctuating stocks for a solid country 
 
i H 
 
 \' t 
 
 4 ) 
 
 366 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE 
 
 estate; the Parisian shopkeeper who enjoys his more la- 
 boriously earned income in the quietude of his modest 
 country cottage; and also, on the other hand, the Jewish 
 cattle-dealer who has become wealthy and seeks the city 
 in order to speculate on the exchange; Fritz Reuter's ex- 
 cellently portrayed Mechlenburg " Fctthammcl " or rich 
 farmer, who after disposing of his farm will enjoy the 
 pleasures of city life; the poor clergyman's widow who 
 moves into the city in order to give her children a better 
 education and supplement her scant pension by keeping 
 boarders; — none of these in their new places of residence 
 enters into dangerous competition with the native labour- 
 ing population. 
 
 And yet at the objective points of the migration, even 
 where the danger of displacement cannot enter into the 
 question, there are innumerable struggles and endless fric- 
 tion, all originating in the process of social amalgamation 
 which is here always going on between the native popu- 
 lation and the new-comers. The stranger has to adapt 
 himself to his environment, to the peculiar local economic 
 methods, to customs, speech and the political, religious 
 and social institutions of his new abode. And the inhabi- 
 tants of the latter place again, however settled in char- 
 acter and peculiar in type cannot altogether escape 
 the influences that rush in upon them from without. 
 Though these influences often mean for them an increase 
 of working energy, an expansion of the horizon, a breeze 
 bringing freshness into corrupt local conditions, yet per- 
 haps much more frequently they result in a loss of good 
 old customs, of solid business qjalities, of interest in the 
 common weal, and, above all, of social characteristics. 
 
 Now there can be no doubt that these struggles for 
 mutual adaptation will take a vastly different form and 
 course when waged between similar and between diver- 
 
GROIVTH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 367 
 
 gent elements. For this verj' reason the division used in 
 municipal statistics for marking the distinction between 
 native and resident population does not suffice for more 
 exact socio-statistical investigations. 
 
 For if, for example, it has been ascertained that the 
 native-born inhabitants of the city of Munich in 1890 
 amounted to 36 per cent, of the whole, while in Hamburg 
 they consiituted 47.5 per cent., the mere fact that in the 
 former city there are 11.5 per cent, more citizens of extra- 
 mural birth is far from proving that the population of 
 Munich is to this extent more heterogeneous than that of 
 Hamburg, and that in the former the process of mutual 
 social adaptation is attended with more violent friction 
 and struggles than in the latter. In like manner the 
 fact that two cities — for example, Dresden and Frankfurt- 
 on-Main — show the same proportion of non-native to na- 
 tive-born citizens does not mean that this process takes 
 the same course in both. It is easy to conceive that the 
 strangers in one city may show a greater homogeneity of 
 customs and speech, economic energy and social habits 
 amongst themselves and with the native population on 
 account of coming from a neighbourhood more nearly 
 akin, while in the other city heterogeneous elements from 
 more distant localities are mingled together. 
 
 The final result of the mutual adaptation of non-native 
 and native population will be altogether different in each 
 of these cases. While in the former individuals and groups 
 of persons of approximately like economic equipment and 
 similar social character enjoy peacefully together the ex- 
 isting conditions for business, in the latter perhaps the 
 more robust, energetic, easily contented race will vanquish 
 the decrepit, weaker and more pretentious in its ancient 
 home, or at least eject it from the most favourable fields 
 of industry. Especially is it true that a lower standard 
 
1 l( 
 
 368 INTERN/tL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE 
 
 of living can give the incomers a superiority over the na- 
 tive labour in the competitive struggle, which involves 
 the latter in the most deplorable consequences. The im- 
 migration of the Polish labourers into the provinces on 
 their west, of the Italians into Switzerland and south Ger- 
 many, and of the Chinese into the cities of the North 
 American Union are well-known examples of this. 
 
 But even when the economic and social assimilation 
 takes place without severe struggles there may persist be- 
 tween incomers and natives differences that simply can- 
 not be removed, invading and disturbing the original 
 homogeneity of the population. We have especially 
 in mind differences of creed, of language and of political 
 allegiance. The two largest cities of Switzerland, Geneva 
 and Basel, both of which we are accustomed to look upon 
 as strongholds of Protestantism, have to-day, in conse- 
 quence of inKax from without, a population which over 
 a third is foreign. In Geneva about 20 per cent, of the 
 population have a mother tongue other than French. 
 Finally, since 1837 the Roman Catholics have increased in 
 Basel from 15 up to 30 per cent, of the population, while 
 in Geneva they have reached 42 per cent. Even he who 
 has no detailed knowledge of the internal history of these 
 small municipalities will be obliged to admit that such 
 differences are not void of danger. 
 
 If these considerations show that by no means the ma- 
 jority of internal migrations find their objective point in 
 the cities, they at the s;ame time prove that the trend 
 towards the great centres of population can in itself be 
 looked upon as having an extensive social and economic 
 importance. It produces an alteration in the distribution 
 of population throughout the State; and at its originating 
 and objective points it gives rise to difficulties which legis- 
 lative and executive authority have hitherto laboured. 
 
 ■*!! 
 
CROIVTH OF TOU^NS CONSIDERED HlSTORlC/iLLY. 369 
 
 usually with but very moderate success to overcome. It 
 transfers large numbers of persons almost directly from a 
 sphere of life where barter predominates into one where 
 money and credit exchange prevail, thereby affecting the 
 social conditions of life and the social customs of the 
 manual labouring classes in a manner to fill the philan- 
 thropist with grave anxiety. 
 
 This mighty flow of the country population into the 
 cities and the universally rapid rise of the latter in volume 
 is looked upon by many as an entirely modern phenom- 
 enon. In a certain sense this is true. The eighteenth cen- 
 tury knew nothing of it, at least in Germany. The famous 
 founder of population statistics, J. P. Sussmilch, did not 
 succeed in discovering any regular law governing the 
 movement of population in cities. He is of the opinion 
 that they rise and fall in size according to the will of 
 God.2° J jj Q yQj^ Justi deems it hardly possible that a 
 city should increase unless special privileges be granted 
 to the incoming settlers.** This is in accord with such 
 population statistics as we have been able to collect for 
 individual cities from the second half of the seventeenth 
 century to about 1820;" these show retrogression and 
 growth in irregular alternation. In France, on the other 
 hand, the modern movement seems to have begun about 
 one hundred and fifty years earlier; and men already spoke 
 
 " " Thus does the mighty ruler of the universe impart to states and 
 cities m ght, riches, and glory. He takes from them again and gives 
 to others according to his good will. He pulleth down the mighty 
 from their seat and exalteth them of low degree."— Co«/«cAe Ordnung, 
 II, § 546 (2d ed., pp. 477. 478). 
 
 " Grunds'dtst d. Polieeiwiss., 1 54. Comp. also Gesammelle polit. u. 
 Finansschriftcn, III, pp. 449^- 
 
 '" Much material relating to the subject has been collected by Inama- 
 Sternegg in the Handwort. d. Staatsw., II, pp. 433 ff. 
 
370 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE 
 
 IP 
 
 in the eighteenth century, according to familiar phrase- 
 ology, of the " depopulation of the open country." " 
 
 If on the other hand we go farther back into the history 
 of man in Europe we find two periods showing the same 
 phenomenon on a grand scale: ancient times, especially 
 the era of the Roman Empire; the later Middle Ages, in 
 particular, the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries. Between 
 them lie great epochs of quiescence, if not of retrogression 
 ar d decay. 
 
 How are these earlier periods of migration tc he cities 
 to be regarded from the standpoint of the history of their 
 evolution? Are they premature starts toward a goal 
 whose attainment was reserved for our own time and its 
 perfected means of communication? Or are they the out- 
 flow of other impulses than those behind the correspond- 
 ing movement of the present, and did they on that ac- 
 count also lead to other results? Above all, was their 
 influence upon population and their economic character 
 the same? 
 
 As concerns ancient times it would seem as if we must 
 assume, in spite of the uncertainty of the population record 
 handed down to us, that a consequence of the inHux of the 
 rural population was the inordinate growth of the cities.'* 
 But it must not be overlooked that only a part of that 
 population migrated of its own free will, namely, the free- 
 men. The remaining and much larger portion, the slaves, 
 were collected by their masters in the cities, or brought 
 thither by the slave trade. 
 
 " Evidence collected by LeRoyt, Du progrh des agglonUralions ur- 
 baines et r^migration rurale (Marseilles, 1870), pp. 8 flf, 
 
 " On what here follows compare particularly R. Polilmann. Die 
 Veberviilkerung d. antiken Grossstiidte im Zusammt'iange mil d. Gesamt- 
 entwick. stddlischer Civilisation (Leipzig, 1884); also Roscher, System 
 d. Volksw., III. Introduction, and Biicher, Die Aufstdnde d. unfrei. Ar- 
 beiter 143-1^9 ''• Chr. 
 
GROIVTH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 371 
 
 
 Where freemen moved in from the country they 
 usually came not because a better prospect of economic 
 advance in the cities beckoned them, but because they 
 were deprived of their lands through the growth of the 
 great slave estates. In the cities, it is true, they found 
 all the lucrative branches of tr^ '.e in the hands of slaves 
 and freedmen ; but they were here in less danger of starva- 
 tion, inasmuch as the proletarian masses of the cities in 
 whose midst they settled were supported by public and 
 private largesses. 
 
 The large cities of antiquity are essentially communities 
 for consumption. They owe their size to the political cen- 
 tralization which collected the surplus products of the ex- 
 tensive areas cultivated by individual husbandry at one 
 point where the governing class was domiciled. They are 
 imperial, or at least provincial, capitals. Accordingly they 
 first arise in the time of the successors of Alexander 
 and reach their height under the Roman Empire. The 
 capital, Rome, itself depends for its food-supply upon the 
 taxes in kind from the provinces; and the same is later on 
 true of Constantinople.^" It is a communistic and im- 
 perialistic system of provisioning, such as the world has 
 not seen a second time. The extortions of the ofiicials, 
 the farming of the revenues, the usurious practices, the 
 great estates of wealthy individuals worked by slaves, the 
 state-recognised obligation to supply largesses of bread, 
 meat and wino to the masses — all these placed the pro- 
 ductive labour of half a world at the service of the capital 
 city and left open to the private activity of its inhabitants 
 
 " Krakauer, Das I'erffiegungstvesen d. Stndt Rom i» d. sfiiter. Kaiser- 
 stit (Leipzig, 18-4). and E. Gebhardt, Studicn iiber d. I'ert^HcRungs- 
 wcsen von Rom u. Konstantinopel in d. spdter. Kaiserseit (Dorpit, i88i). 
 Also Rodbertus, Zur Gesch d. nm. Trtbutsteucrn in the Jhrb. f. N.-Oek. 
 Oek. u. SUt.. VIII, especially pp. 400 fT. 
 

 !N' 
 
 372 INTERNytL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE 
 
 nothing but the sphere of personal services. From what 
 we know of the larger provincial cities we may conclude 
 that in them similar conditions prevail.''® 
 
 A favourable market for free labour, a place for the 
 skilled production of goods on a large scale for export, 
 the ancient metropolitan city was not." Anything resem- 
 bling factory work rests, as does the extensive agricultural 
 production, upon slave labour. Accordingly among the 
 motives mentioned by the ancient writers as impelling the 
 free rural population toward the cities the very one that 
 is commonest to-day— the prospect of higher wages- 
 plays no part. " Consider this body of people," writes 
 Seneca" to his mother; "the houses of the immense 
 city are scarcely sufficient for them. From municipia and 
 colonies, in short from the world over, have they come 
 together. Some have been drawn hither by ambition, 
 some have come on public business, others as envoys, 
 others again have been attracted by luxurious tastes seek- 
 ing an apt and ample field for indulgence, others by fond- 
 ness for liberal studies, others by the shows; some have 
 been led by friendship, others by enterprise, which here 
 finds extended fields for displaying personal merit;" 
 some have brought their personal beauty for sale, others 
 their eloquence. There is no class of people which has 
 not streamed to the city, where the prizes are great for 
 virtue and vice alike." 
 
 "E. Kuhn. Die siddtische u. biirgcrliche Verfassung d. Rom. Reichs, 
 I. pp. 46 (T.. points lo an organization of the cura annona similar to that 
 in the capital. 
 
 " Frat.cotti-, i: Industrie dans la Crice ancicnne, I, esp. pp. 14Q-IS8. 
 has now established this fur the Greek cities. 
 
 "• Ad Hchiam. 6. ... 
 
 "Quosdam industria lalam ostendcndce virtuli ttacta matenam. It is 
 competition that is meant, not " industry." as Pohlmann, cited above, 
 p. 17, translates it. 
 
CROIVTH OF TOH^NS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 373 
 
 Quite different was it with the town-ward flow of popu- 
 lation in the Middle Ages. Taken as a whole, it is per- 
 haps not less voluminous than that at the time of the 
 Roman Empire. It did not result, however, in the forma- 
 tion of a few central points of consumption, but in the con- 
 struction of a large number of fortified places distributed 
 pretty evenly throughout the country, uniting within 
 their walls all the organized industrial activity of the na- 
 tion which was not attached to the soil. The mediaeval 
 towns are originally mere places of refuge for the sur- 
 rounding rural population;^*' their permanent inhabi- 
 tants are the burghers, or people of the burg. Everything 
 else — the market, the prosecution of trade, monetary 
 dealings, the personal freedom of the town inhabitants 
 and their special privileges before the law — is only a later 
 consequence of this extra-mural military relationship. The 
 defensive union became in course of time a territorially 
 circumscribed economic union, for which the town or city 
 was the trade centre and the seat of all specialized labour. 
 
 The mediaeval cities'* accordingly bear a great simi- 
 larity to each other in the social and economic organiza- 
 tion of their population, and differ, as far as we can see, 
 only slightly in the number of their inhabitants. At their 
 original founding the influx of the rural population 
 seems often to have been far from voluntary. Later on 
 the chief factor determining their growth was the greater 
 security of person and property and the more varied op- 
 portunities for earning a livelihood which they afforded 
 
 " Comp. above, pp. 1 16 flf. 
 
 " That is, so far as they really deserve the name. It is a peculiar in- 
 consistency to attempt to-day to demonstrate the character of the 
 mediaeval city by taking as examples places which never arrived at a 
 true city status and which can bring forward no better claim to the 
 name of city than that they were endowed with city privileges. 
 
■ I 
 
 374 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE 
 
 landless freemen and serfs. Their whole development, 
 economically and numerically, came t -n ^nd, however, 
 the moment all the handicrafts that the limited extent of 
 the city-market areas was capable of sustaining were rep- 
 resented and supplied with a sufficient number of master- 
 workmen. Up to this point the cities oflfered complete 
 freedom of movement and almost unimpeded access to 
 guild privileges and burgess rights, while the rural land- 
 owners, on the other hand, sought through limitations of 
 the right of removal to secure themselves against the loss 
 of their serfs. When, however, the cities were able to sup- 
 ply all branches of trade from the internal growth of their 
 population, they also exhibited a willingness to check ac- 
 cessions from without, and hence brought about those 
 numerous obstacles to settlement and to entry upon a 
 trade which have persisted into modern times. There arose 
 a sharp division between city and country. Migration to 
 and fro naturally continued to a certain extent, but it was 
 confined in the main to an exchange of labourers among 
 the cities themselves. City development had fallen, as it 
 were, into a condition of numbness from which it could be 
 roused only through transition to a new economic order. 
 
 We are in a position to prove statistically for a few 
 locaIit=-« Hie statement just made. There have been in- 
 stitii :haustive investigations into the origin of the 
 
 medi.-eval population of Frankfurt-on-Main,^^ a^j fg. 
 cently also regarding certain sections of the population 
 of Cologne." From these it appears that the majority 
 of the persons received by these two cities as burghers 
 
 « Biichcr, Beiolkcrung von Fr.. pp. 163 flf., 304 flF., 4" ff-. S2> A- SQi ff . 
 
 627 fi. 
 "A. Dorcn, Unlcrstichwigen :. Cesch. d. Kaufmannsguden d Mttlciiltcts 
 
 (in Schmoller's Forschungen, XII. 2), Appendix 1; and now aho H. 
 
 Bunfecr's Beitriige s. mittelalt. Topograph., Rechtsgeschich. u. Sozialstatishk. 
 
 d. Stadi Koln (Leipzig, 1896), Sec. 3. 
 
GROIVTH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 375 
 
 during the fourteenth and fifteenth centuries migrated 
 from the country. Of every loo new burghers there 
 came to: 
 
 In the Period. From Cities. ''™'",S»i" ""* 
 
 Cologne 1356- 1479 37-4 62.6 
 
 Frankfurt 1311-1400 28.2 71.8 
 
 " 1401-1500 43.9 56.1 
 
 We see from this that in the last two centuries of the 
 Middle Ages the movement of population from the coun- 
 try to the cities, though it continued, was on the wane, 
 while the admixture of town elements among the new 
 burghers increased. Thus as early as the fifteenth century 
 certain strata of the population of Frankfurt received their 
 chief increment through emigration from other cities. Of 
 the incoming Jews, for example, 90 per cent., and of the 
 members of a fraternity of journeymen metal-workers 79.3 
 per cent., came from cities. The material from which the 
 last percentage is deduced also covers, it should be said, 
 the first quarter of the sixteenth century. 
 
 Unfortunately, further figures regarding the sixteenth 
 and seventeenth centuries are not available. But for the 
 period from the beginning of the eighteenth till after the 
 middle of the nineteenth century we can offer some fig- 
 ures which serve to show that thee was an epoch when 
 the urban handicrafts received their workers almost ex- 
 clusively from other towns. The Frankfurt municipal 
 archives contain a number of books regarding the lodg- 
 ing-places of the bookbinders, in which are recorded the 
 names and places of origin ot all the journeymen of this 
 craft who came to Frankfurt between 1712 and 1867 
 (14,342 persons in all). Some years ago we worked over 
 this extremely valuable statistical material and found that 
 of every 100 incoming journeymen bookbinders there 
 came: 
 
'' 
 
 « Ijif \ 
 
 i 4*!- 
 
 376 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE 
 
 Periods. From Cities. ^™"h^i|S! "^ 
 
 1712-1750 97.5 2.5 
 
 1751-1800 94-3 5-7 
 
 1801-1835 89.2 10.8 
 
 1836-1850 36.0 14.0 
 
 1851-1867 81.3 18.8 
 
 We see here how, in a trade of a specifically urban char- 
 acter, within a period of rather more than a century and 
 a half, the proportion of workers drawn from the country 
 has continuously increased. Had it been possible to con- 
 tinue the investigation for the period from 1867 down to 
 the present time, we should undoubtedly have found that 
 the balance h^s inclined more and more in favour of the 
 journeymen from rural localities. 
 
 In the contemporary migrations to the cities a fusion 
 of town and country strongly resembling that established 
 by us for the fifteenth century seems to have set in.'* 
 Of every 100 of the inhabitants born in other places there 
 were in: 
 
 Year. Of City Birth. Of Country Birth. 
 
 Leipzig 188s 50.6 49.4 
 
 Basel 1888 23.5 76.S 
 
 As in the Middle Ages, the city element relatively in- 
 creas* s ^nd the country element decreases according to 
 the distance of place of birth from place of settlement. The 
 various classes of the population show but slight differ- 
 ences in this regard. Generally speaking those occupa- 
 tions that demand a special training have a stronger ad- 
 
 " Only the simplest results of these investigations can be given here. 
 Details may be found in my Beviilkerung d. Kantons Basel-Stadt am i, 
 Dez. 1888, pp. 62 flF. We may also refer to Hasse's Ergebnisse d. 
 Volkssdhlmg vom 1. Dez. 1885 in der Stadt Leipsig, Pt. II, pp. 7(T. The 
 higher figures in the rural accessions for Basel are explained by the 
 fact that in the above work the city limits are made to include only 
 3,000 inhabitants. 
 
 
CROl^TH OF TOMANS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 377 
 
 mixture o' city elements than the spheres of simple manual 
 
 labour. 
 
 It is greatly to be regretted that similar statistical in- 
 vestigations have not been carried out for a larger number 
 of modern cities. From the evidence at present to hand 
 we are apparently driven to conclude that the number 
 of incomers of city origin is relatively greater in the large 
 cities than in the medium-sized and smaller ones.^' The 
 explanation of this phenomenon is a simple one. A large 
 city exercises upon the population of the smaller cities the 
 same power of attraction that the latter have for the pop- 
 ulation of the country. In this way the transitions from 
 one social and economic sphere to another are rendered 
 less violent. ThUs a gradual elevation of the migrating 
 masses takes place, as also from generation to genera- 
 tion a continuous preparation for the demands of life in a 
 great city, which must render less violent the conflicts 
 inevitable to the process of mutual adaptation within the 
 
 new sphere. 
 
 But if the cities of to-day exhibit a process of redis- 
 tribution of population similar to that of their mediaeval 
 prototypes, the resemblance is only superficial. In the 
 fourteenth and fifteenth centuries we have to do with the 
 last stages of an evolution whose ultimate result was the 
 formation of numerous small autonomous spheres of 
 economic activity, each of which exactly resembled the 
 other in its harmonious development of production; in 
 the nineteenth rentury we have to deal with an increas- 
 ing differentiation of the individual centres of population, 
 
 •* Besides the work on Leipsig already mentioned, a later exhaustive 
 treatise on the accessions to, and losses of, population in Frankfurt-on- 
 Main in the year 1891, published by Dr. Bleicher in the Beitr. 2. 
 Stalislik d. SI. Frkf., II, pp. 29 ff., gives interesting information re- 
 garding this point. 
 
378 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE 
 
 
 in accord with the designs of a greater whole, namely, of 
 a state-regulated national economy. 
 
 This process begins with the development of the mod- 
 ern State and modern national administration. Hitherto 
 each city had developed within itself all the branches 
 of city life not forbidden by local conditions; now one 
 city bee* mes a permanent royal residence, others be- 
 come seats of district and provincial administrations, of 
 prisons, of higher educational institutions and of all kinds 
 of special branches of administration, while still others 
 become garrison cities, border fortresses, fair-towns, 
 watering-places, junction-points of commercial routes, 
 etc. They take over definite functions for the whole coun- 
 try and for all other places, though these functions are 
 not always specifically urban. The cities may also form 
 alliances with rural residence centres. This process has 
 been especially prominent since the fuller development 
 of city industry on a large scale and the extraordi- 
 nary increase and perfection of the means of communica- 
 tion. In this new national era the total national produc- 
 tion endeavours so to distribute itself over the territory 
 controlled by it that each of its branches may find the 
 location best suited to it. Factory and house-industry 
 districts arise, and separate valleys and whole regions take 
 on a semi-urban character. Certain cities develop special 
 branches of industry and trade reaching out far beyond 
 the local, and often even the national, demand. In others, 
 again, all industry and business life decline; they sink 
 down to the level of villages, so that the historical rights 
 of burgess that still attach +0 their name appear in striking 
 contrast with their position as places of trade and with 
 the number of their inhabitants. The distinctions between 
 city and country are blotted out. This happens in the 
 neighbourhood of rising industrial cities through the 
 
CROiyTH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 379 
 
 planting of factories and workmen's dwellings in the sub- 
 urbs and beyond; in the neighbourhood of the declining 
 " rural cities " through the approach of the latter to the 
 condition of surrounding country places, and through the 
 rise of populous industrial towns. On the whole, how- 
 ever, the number of centres of population and of objective 
 points for internal migrations is to-day relatively much 
 smaller than in the second half of the Middle Ages.^® 
 
 But in still another respect does the redistribution of 
 population resulting from the internal migrations of the 
 present time differ from that witnessed by our ancestors 
 from the tenth to the fifteenth centuries. In consequence 
 of the greater certainty of a living and of far-reaching 
 measures for the health of the people the increase in pop- 
 ulation is to-day more rapid than in mediaeval times. It 
 
 •* The German Empire had in 1890 a total of 2,285 " cities." Of 
 these there were 26 with more than 100,000 inhabitants, 22 with from 
 50,000 to 100,000, 104 with from 20,000 to 50.000, and 169 with between 
 10,000 and 20,000. Besides these there were 56 villages and suburban 
 municipalities with from 10,000 to 50,000 inhabitants, 11 of them with 
 more than 20,000. — In Prussia there were in that year 46 " cities " with 
 less than 1,000 inhabitants, 14 of these being in the Province of Posen, 
 12 in Silesia, 10 in Hesse-Nassau. 3 in Brandenburg, 2 each in West 
 Prussia and Westphalia, i each in Saxony, Hanover and the Rhine- 
 land (Schleiden with 515 inhabitants). Alongside these dwarflike 
 cities there were 37 rural municipalities with more than 10,000 inhabi- 
 tants. — How far some of the old cities have declined is shown by the 
 following figures for the Grand Duchy of Baden. There the census 
 of 1885 gave 114 " cities," only 63 of these having a population of over 
 2,000, and 9 with over 10,000. Of the remaining 51 " cities " 42 had from 
 1,000 to 2,000 inhabitants, 4 had from 500 to 1,000, and 5 below 500 
 (among these last being Kleinlaufenburg with 441, Neufreistett with 
 427, Blumenfeld with 349, Fiirstenberg with 341, Hauenstein with 157). 
 For every city there were on an average 14 villages. On the other 
 hand, there were altogether 129 municipalities with over 2,000 inhabi- 
 tants, 66 of these being " villages." Of the old cities only 55 are thus 
 cities according to the modern idea, and of the villages four per cent 
 are from the point of view of population to be reckoned in with the 
 cities. 
 
38o INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE 
 
 
 is safe from those heavy reverses so frequently resulting 
 in those ages from harvest failure, feuds and plague. 
 On that account the modern migrations into the large 
 cities and industrial districts in many cases absorb only 
 a surplus population that would not find sufficient room 
 for earning a livelihood in the places of its origin. 
 At these points tney retard or completely check the con- 
 gestion of population; while on the other hand at the 
 points of agglomeration no economic obstacles bar the 
 way to a continuous and rapid increase. 
 
 In mediaeval times, on the contrary, the migratory ac- 
 cession of population was distributed among a multitude 
 of walled places scattered at fixed intervals over the 
 whole country. The increase in many cases continued 
 only until the city was full. When once it had as many 
 inhabitants as it needed to man its walls and towers and 
 supply all the branches of industry, there was no room for 
 more. Extensions of the city limits often did take place 
 in mediaeval times, it is true; they are the result of the 
 increasing formation and subdivision of special trades. 
 But the Middle Ages developed no large cities; the 
 mediaeval economic and commercial system forbade it. 
 The country was often deprived of the population neces- 
 sary for the cultivation of the soil; yet even with such 
 accessions the frequency of extensive losses kept the city 
 populations stationary. 
 
 From these remarks it will indeed remain uncertain 
 whether or not the internal migrations that accompanied 
 the development of the industrial life of the mediaeval town 
 were relatively more extensive than the corresponding 
 territorial movements and shiftings of population that 
 result to-day from the more national character of settle- 
 ments. On the other hand, it cannot be doubted that the 
 attraction of the great cities of modern times for the pop- 
 
GROIVTH OF TOIVNS CONSIDERED HISTORIC/tLLY. 381 
 
 ulation of the smaller towns and the country is exerted 
 over greater expanses of territory than the mediaeval towns 
 held within the circle of their influence. One is not in a 
 position to say, however, that the recruiting territory for 
 the population of a city has expanded since the begin- 
 ning of modern times in direct ratio to the number of its 
 inhabitants. On the contrary, one is astonished to find 
 what a slight effect the perfecting of the means of com- 
 munication and the introduction of freedom of movement 
 have had upon the extent of the territory covered by the 
 regular internal migrations. 
 
 A few figures will make this clear. Of f.wtvy hundred 
 new settlers coming to Frankfurt, Oldenburg and Basel 
 the numbers according to distances are as f-^'' vs: 
 
 City. 
 
 Frankfurt . 
 II 
 
 Oldenburg. 
 Basel 
 
 Class of Population, 
 
 New citizens 
 
 II II 
 
 Metal workers 
 
 Citizens born in other 
 places 
 
 Citizens born in other 
 places 
 
 Journeymen craftsmen . . 
 
 Factory laborers 
 
 Period. 
 
 0-9 
 Miles. 
 
 9-45 
 Allies. 
 
 14th century 
 
 46.7 
 
 39-3 
 
 15th 
 
 23.1 
 
 52.7 
 
 iSthandi6th 
 
 
 
 centuries 
 
 2.7 
 
 45-0 
 
 1880 
 
 31.8 
 
 42.1 
 
 1888 
 
 16.7 
 
 50.2 
 
 1888 
 
 13.9 
 
 40.0 
 
 1888 
 
 17.1 
 
 59-6 
 
 Miles. 
 
 14.0 
 
 24. a 
 
 52.3 
 
 36.1 
 
 33.1 
 46.1 
 23-3 
 
 Of the three recruiting zones distinguished here the 
 outermost at present contributes more to the total popu- 
 lation and the inner less than in mediaeval times. The 
 reason probably is that to-day the population in the 
 more immediate neighbourhood of a city takes advantage 
 of the city's labour market without settling in the city 
 itself, whether it be that they go daily to their places of 
 work in the city by special workmen's trains or other con- 
 venient means of transportation, or that the great indus- 
 tries of the towns erect their workshops in neighbouring 
 
382 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE 
 
 places. The recruiting territory for journeymen has 
 rather contracted as compared with mediaeval times. 
 With this is linked the circumstance that at present three- 
 fourths of this class of workmen are drawn from the coun- 
 try, while at the close of the Middle Ages less than one- 
 quarter of them came from villages and hamlets. Of the 
 Frankfurt journeymen metal-workers in the fifteenth and 
 sixteenth centuries only 20.7 per cent, were born in the 
 country; of the Basel bakers and butchers in 1888, on the 
 contrary, 78.7 per cent, and of the journeymen of other 
 handicrafts 75.2 per cent, were of country birth. Even 
 to-day journeymen craftsmen still migrate in much larger 
 numbers and to greater distances than the typical work- 
 man class of the present, the factory hands. Of the 
 factory workingmen in Basel in 1888, 25.8 per cent, were 
 born in the city itself; of the handicraft journeymen, only 
 16.3 per cent. How many of them were bom and still 
 domiciled in the immediate neighbourhood the statistics 
 unfortunately do not show. But all modern industrial 
 development tends in the direction of producing a per- 
 manent labouring class, which through the custom of 
 early marriage is already much less mobile than the jour- 
 neymen of the early handicrafts, and which in future will 
 doubtless be as firmly attached to the factory as were the 
 servile labourers of the mediaeval manor to the glebe.^^ 
 If this is not very noticeable at present it is because the 
 majority of large industries have not yet attained their 
 growth, and because it is net. -ssary Tor them, as long as 
 they extend their works, to meet the increased demand 
 
 " The construction of workingmen's dwellings by the great man- 
 ufacturing establishments, whether these pass over into the possession 
 of the labourers or arc rented to them, is even now begetting a sort of 
 factory bondage, which has an appalling resemblance to the old bond- 
 age to the soil. Comp. my article on the Belgian social legislation in 
 Braun's Archiv. f. soz. Gesetzg. u. Stat, IV, pp. 484, 485. 
 
GROIVTH OF TOfVN^ CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 383 
 
 for labourers by drawing further upon the surplus popu- 
 lation of the rural districts. 
 
 These remarks point to the conclusion that we are not 
 justified in attributing a growing migratory character to 
 society as a result of the closer network of commercial 
 routes and the invention of perfected means of communi- 
 cation. Rather should we say that at present we are in 
 the midst of a transition period in which the yet un- 
 completed transformation of the town and territorial 
 economic structure into a national one involves a con- 
 tinuous displacement of the boundaries of division of 
 labour and ^''.e centres of the various branches of pro- 
 duction, and -.nsequently displacements of the labouring 
 population. 
 
 After a period of economic and social ossification ex- 
 tending over centuries, in which all sorts of limitations 
 upon migration and settlement held the population fast 
 to the original ancestral seats, it is not surprising that 
 many view with anxiety the great movements of popu- 
 lation which to-day extend over whole territories. It 
 seems almost as if the early times of universal migration 
 were returning. But in this they forget that it is only a 
 part — the rural part — of the population that has become 
 more migratory; that up to the early year:, of last 
 century a great number of these were bound to the soil. 
 The merchant, the craftsman and the scholar are to-day 
 much less mobile than, for instance, in the time of the 
 Reformation; and the industrial labourers move relatively 
 less often and to shorter distances than they did even a 
 century ago. Only their number has become much greater 
 and is still steadily increasing. This growth of in- 
 dustry displaces a part of the rural labouring population 
 from their usual places of abode, to which nothing now 
 holds them but the interests of those who profit by their 
 
IK. 
 
 384 INTERNAL MIGRATIONS OF POPULATION AND THE 
 
 helplessness. The further progress of this movement will 
 probably show, even in a few decades, that the human 
 race in the course of its evolution has on the whole be- 
 come more stationary. 
 
 We may thus say in conclusion: In this general influx 
 to the cities and their suburbs we are to-day undergoing 
 what our ancestors experienced in the second half 
 of the Middle Ages, the transition to a new economic 
 and social order and a fresh distribution of population. 
 At that time the movement inaugurated the period of 
 town economy and of sharp separation of town and 
 country; the movement in the midst of which we now 
 live is the outward sign that we have entered upon a new 
 period of development,— the period of organic distribu- 
 tion of population, the period of national division of 
 labour and of national satisfaction of wants, in which the 
 distinctions between city and country as places of abode 
 are being obliterated by numerous transitional forma- 
 tions. This fact has long since been recognised by statis- 
 ticians who have dropped the historico-juridical concep- 
 tion of city and substituted a statistical one in which 
 places are distinguished according t i the number of their 
 inhabitants. 
 
 Every transitional epoch has its inconveniences and its 
 suffering. But the modern movement of population, in 
 so far as it is expressed in the influx into the cities, will, 
 like that of mediaeval times, reach its goal and then sub- 
 side. This goal can be none other than to assign to 
 every individual capacity and to every local group of per- 
 sons that place and that role in the great national life 
 in which its endowments and the altered technical con- 
 ditions of economic activity best fit it to contribute to 
 the general welfare. 
 
 Thus from a consideration of internal migrations, de- 
 
GROH^TH OF TOl^NS CONSIDERED HISTORICALLY. 385 
 
 spite the fact that the conditions accompanying them 
 are often far from pleasant to contemplate, we may gain 
 the assurance that _they too mean, from the wider stand- 
 point, an advance towards higher and better forms of 
 social existence, both for the individual and for the race. 
 
mu 
 
INDEX. 
 
 Aboriginal man, no longer exist- 
 ing, 3 
 Acta diurna populi Roman!, aio, 
 
 220 
 
 Acta senatus, 219, aio 
 Adoption, 15 
 
 Advertising Bureaux, 240 
 Aged, exposure of the, 16 
 Agriculture, 4S, 255; savage .igri- 
 
 cuUuralists, 43 
 V. Ailzing, 236 
 Andree, 23, 26, 28. 37, 67, 73, 77, 
 
 266 
 Andrews, Alex., 232, 234 
 Animal sortD'ogy, 2 note. 
 Annuities, 133 
 Appun, 18 
 Art, 28, 29 note. 
 Artel, gs 
 Artifiters, 98 
 " Artistic Work," return t j, 208 
 
 Bank, evolution of, 138 
 
 BannrnfiU, 123 
 
 de Barthilemy, 233 
 
 .Ussier, 34, 264 
 
 Rastian. 24, 78 
 
 Battenberg. Frani Joseph von, 158 
 
 Peati fossidentts, philosophy of, 
 
 34a 
 
 Below, 126 
 
 lleti, 79 
 
 Ftunittn, 105 
 
 Hey, Fmin, 36 
 
 Itiilcicn Labour. Str Labour. 
 
 Hlcirhcr, 377 
 
 ni'ick, 283' 
 
 Itlmn, 157 
 
 noas, 28 
 
 Backcl, 266 
 
 Bos, 43 
 
 Botcher, botcher-hunt, 169 
 
 Bottiger, loi 
 
 Baun , 158 
 
 Btlcher, works cited, 19, 22, a8, 53, 
 87, 94, 96, 108, 130, 132, 154, 163, 
 171, 207, J54. »56. »63. sW), 267, 
 269, 273, 274. 298. 30'. 318. 334. 
 370, 374. 376. 382 
 
 Buchner, 24, 6$, 79, 93, iii 
 
 Buffalo herds, extermination of, 18 
 
 Buhl, l6i 
 
 Hunger, 374 
 
 Burg, 116, 373 
 
 Burgess rights, 116 119, 374. 37^ 
 
 Burgher, 116, 119, 13J, 373-375 
 
 Burner, 181 
 
 Hurton, 13, 21, 35. 263 
 
 Musiness Undertakers, 308 
 
 Cxsar, 218, 219 
 
 Camelots, 100 
 
 CamfagHt, 352 
 
 Capital, 112, 128, 129, 137, 143, 162, 
 
 173. >76. 309. 3«o. 333 
 
 Capitalists, 308 
 
 Cappeln, 361, 362 
 
 Casalis, 38, 78, 277 
 
 Casati, 72 
 
 Caste system, 343 
 
 Cattle-raising, 11, 45, 51 
 
 Cauwii, 250 
 
 Cecchi, 69 
 
 Census: Bavarian, 358 (T.; English, 
 364; Oldenburg, 359 ff. Sft Oc- 
 cupations, census of. 
 
 Cicero, loa, 219 
 
 Circulation of goods, ta8, 305 
 
 Cities: characteristic of modern, 
 363; in German Empire, 379 note; 
 in Middle Ages, 380. Set Towns. 
 
 Classes: rise of, 127; vocational, 
 334; labeurlnf, 38a 
 
 de Clercq, 28 
 
 S«7 
 
388 
 
 INDEX. 
 
 Colbert, 136. M^ ; Clbcrtism, 137 
 Columella, 300 
 Commerce, 303, 309 
 Commercial contrivances, 76, 145 
 Commission Work (Syr.tcm), 154. 
 
 171. 173. O'). 257 
 Common-houses of savages, 37- 
 
 .Vic Houses. 
 Common, Labour in. See Labour. 
 Communities: partial, 94; labour, 95 
 Community for I'rofiuction and 
 
 Consumption, 305, 3o<J. 3io. 372 
 Comprar, to sit down, 63 
 Conceptions of value of primitive 
 
 man 
 Consumption, 29. 192 
 Covetousness of the savage 
 <lc Coulanges, Fustel, 92 
 Couriers, 77 
 Cranz, 13 
 Credit, 129, 137. 145; Crc.lit-bal- 
 
 ances, 207 
 Crop-rotation, 47 
 
 Currency, national, 131. .SVf Money. 
 Custom-production, 170 
 Customs Duty, 80 
 
 Dampicr, 13 
 
 Defence, arrangements for, 14''> 
 I).-m.ind, conccniratinn of, 192 
 niensliiiiel, 33° "o'c- 
 Dipui'iK stick, 7, 11 
 Diinilruff, 345 
 
 Division of Labour. See Labour; 
 of Troduction. See Production. 
 Division of Use 'with tools\ 301 
 Domestic animals, laming of, 22, 
 
 27 
 Dorcn, 374 
 Drum, use of, 7S 
 Druzina, 95 
 Dualism in household. 55 
 
 F.conomic tivity, 2 
 F.conomic nature of man, I, 2, 3 
 " Kconomic piinriplr," the, I 
 r.conomic method, 14^; stai;c-<, R5. 
 
 See Stages. 
 Economy, 25, C). 3"'. 3'); m--^;I<M led 
 
 bv cthnogr.iiilu . n 
 " Economy ' 1 IKvi.l'-l I.;ibotir " 
 
 Fconomy. n.Tii' ■' ;!, "■ ■■ " , 3^ v •' '■■ 
 Stages. 
 
 Editorship, 240 
 
 Education, 146 
 
 Egoism of savage, 14, 21 
 
 Ehrenreich, 9. 11. 16, 23,28,32, 51, 
 
 61, 264 
 Ellis, loi 
 Embassies, 77 
 Endemann, 270, 277 
 Enfeoffment, 132 
 Engels, 4 
 
 Entrepreneur, 172, 17S, 308, 312 
 Erman, no, 263, 321 , 
 
 Exchange, genesis of, to; primi- 
 tive, 59, 65. 9". >c'6. I"?. •"/ 
 system of direct, 114. and divi- 
 sion of labour, 295, 301 
 Exner. 157, 158 
 Extra-mural jurisdiction, 124 
 
 171; districts, 37S; hands, 
 172, 
 
 Factory 
 
 3''2 
 Factory Work (SystenO, 154 
 
 173. 'i7f> 
 Fair Reports, 236 
 Fomilia tusti<a, 99; urbatta, 99, 
 
 300 
 Family, primitive, 10, 48, t5'r. of 
 
 Negritos, 8 note; Roman. 97 
 Fiiuihaber, 231 
 FebtfySy 38 
 Fcliit, 329 
 Felkin, 270 
 
 Ferguson, Adam, 2«3, 2S5, 326 
 Finsch, 5. 47. 67. if-. 79. 263. 269 
 Fire, use of, 3. '<• 26, 79 
 Fire-cabin, 38 
 Fishing, 49, 77 
 
 Food, separate preparation of. 32 - 
 38; procuring of, 42, 4». AuUse 
 Stage of Individual Search for. 
 Fof^li dCiivvisi, 226 
 Foresight, lack of by savage, 12, Si 
 Forester, I57 
 Forestry, 255 
 Francotte, 160, 372 
 "Freedom of luilerprisc," 334; 
 
 free choice of vocation, 340 
 Itil'ch, 9, 10. II, I'', -o, 21, ?.t. ""^ 
 3^'. 49 
 
 Gallon, 329 
 
 Gang. 27S 
 Ganphofer, 337 
 Garve, 322 
 
 w 
 
INDEX. 
 
 389 
 
 Gazetta (Gazette), 225; C^z.itanti, 
 
 327 
 Gebhardt, 371 
 Geiger, 4, 72 
 Gerland, 277 
 Gifts. See Presents. 
 Gioja, 250 
 Gorbunoff, 267 
 Gramich, 122 
 Grandke, 186 
 Grasshoif, 222, 224 
 Groos, 27 
 
 Grosse, 7, 28, 30, g2 
 Guilds, 168, 171, i32, igo, 374 
 
 Haberland, 62 
 Hack or Hoe System, 4*"'. 4S 
 Hahii. 43, 45 
 
 Handicraft (!land-work), 121, 150, 
 152, 168, 169, 171, 176. 1S2. 185. 
 311; displaceinent of, 192; sup- 
 planting, curtailment, incorpora- 
 tion, impoverishment, etc., of, 
 197-207 
 Handicraftsman (Craftsman), 
 
 modern, 151 
 Hansa. The. 138 
 Hansjakob, 163 
 Harar, 277 
 
 Hardness of heart of snv.ige, 14 
 Hasse, 376 
 
 Hatin, 221, 226, 232, 234 
 Haupt, 266 
 f/ausjieisz, 155 
 HeckcwL-lder, 17, nj, 23. 33. ''''■ 
 
 264 
 Heiiize. 2x3 
 Helmolt. 2S5 
 ileredity, 326. 335, 336 
 Hermann, 131, 250 
 Herodotus, 16 
 Heusler, t2g, 130 
 Higher primitive peoples, 29, 31) 
 Hildebrand, 86 
 Historical School, 84, 86 
 Hofsihulie, l?7 
 Holle, 361, 302 
 Holub, 80 
 Homer, 62 
 
 Home-work, ifi3. '''5. 'f>7. ''^7 
 llcirinutiii , 2(17 
 Hose, CIi.uIps, 32, 269 
 llospitaliiy, lilies of, (i2 
 Household, nt(;lccted by cthnoK 
 raphy, 39 
 
 House Industry (see Commission 
 Work), 154. i/i. 257. 2f'7 
 
 Houses, public social, 36 note, 205 
 
 Housework, 154. I55; i" Buko- 
 wina 153, 176 
 
 Houssaye, 327 
 
 Howitt, 63 
 
 HUbner, 218 
 
 Hudson, 234 
 
 HUgel, 64 
 
 Hume, 321 
 
 " Hunger-strap," il 
 
 Hunting, 49 
 
 Hwof, 67 
 
 Imitating, by savages, 27 
 
 Immermann, 157 
 
 Improvidence of savage, 17 
 
 Im Thurm, 64 
 
 Inama-Sternegg, 103, 369 
 
 Income, 112 note, 113, 131, 143 
 
 Individual econc my, 32 
 
 Individual Search for Food, staj c 
 
 of, 26, 27, 30, 39 
 Industrial Organizaliun. 54, 3'=. 
 
 peoples, 73 
 Industry, 52. 57. 5*. 144. i5f>- 255: 
 
 systems of, 154 
 Infanticide, 14, 15 
 
 Influx to the titles. 357 
 
 Insurance, 133 
 
 Interest, 132 
 
 Intermediaries, nlfici.il. 124 
 
 Iron smelting, 22, working. 159 
 
 Itinerancy, 162, lo-* 
 
 Itinerant, 162. i(.5-i69 
 
 Iwantschofl. 158 
 
 /?('(;;/:.;. 3O note. 
 
 Jacobsen, 79, 263 
 James, 329 
 
 Icllin,t;haus, 24 
 jentsch, 255 
 
 loest, 23 
 
 Jones, F. F:UHiy, 232 
 
 Jung, 21 
 
 Junker, 19, 72. '^lA 
 
 V. Justi, 369 
 
 K-iufiriann. 1 17 
 Klenim. 5 
 Kleinw.ichter, 245 
 Krakauer, 371 
 krejcsi, ir,S 
 
39° 
 
 INDEX. 
 
 Kubary. 34. 34. 38. 69. 107. «65. 269 
 Kuhn, 37a 
 
 Labour. 142. 3'°: aggregation. 2O2. 
 368. 371-273: bidden. 94. 2o3- 
 273; companionship. 262; conca- 
 tenation. 273; in common. 49. 93. 
 352. (extent) 259. 262. 280. 3«». 
 322; communities. 94. 95. 280; 
 displacement of. 390-394, 333; 
 distribution between sexes. 30- 
 37. 44. S4. 353: division of. (in- 
 terlocal) 71. 93. >44. «7t. 350-353. 
 284. 386, (defined) 389. 295. (so- 
 cial) 112. 128, 295. 299. (conse- 
 quences of) 302, 305. 310. 333. 
 331. 332; fraternal. 363. 318; in- 
 corporation of. 311; joint. 362, 
 378; social, 245; subdivision of, 
 286, 394, 333; union (combina- 
 tion) of, 344. 251. 253. 280, 317; 
 with a.iernate and with concur- 
 rent tfmfo, 274 
 
 Lamprecht, 103. 105. iii 
 
 Land in autonomous economy, 90 
 
 Landlord, landlady, 30 
 
 Landor, 66, 365 
 
 Latifundia. 98, 331 
 
 Laveliye. 93. 105 
 
 Laziness of savage, 30 
 
 " Least sacrifice, • principle of, I 
 
 Leber. 332 
 
 Leclerc, 3i8 
 
 Legoyt, 370 
 
 Leni, 67. 73 
 
 V. Leoprechting, 366 
 
 Liberalism, modern, 139 
 
 LieberkUbn. 3i8 
 
 Lindau. 327 
 
 Lippert. 4. 9. ". 14. «6. 18 
 List, 86, 346, 347. 250 
 Livingstone, 19. 24, 35. 3°. 37. 47. 
 
 48. 5«. 7». 79 
 Loaning. 61 
 Loria. 330 
 Lotmar. 333 
 Lduvois, 14s 
 '• Lower nomads," 9, 36 
 Lubbock. 3. 4. «3. '5. '7 49 
 Luther, 333, 343 
 
 Machines. I75. 29»; small power. 
 
 209 
 Mangold, 240 
 
 MangolJt. 2i4 
 
 Manor. 102 «., 126, 137. 383 
 
 Manufactory, 171 
 
 M -.rket-law. 120 
 
 Markets. 59, 66. 115, 373 
 
 Marquardt, 322 
 
 Martius. 10. 15. 16, 47. 49. 5i. 67. 
 
 78, 79 
 Marx Karl. 70 
 Material foresight and cultural 
 
 progress. 12 
 Maternal love. 10. 15. I7 
 Maurer, 103 
 
 V. Mayr, 354. 355. 359. 360. 364 
 Melancthon. 323. 324. 325 
 Meinecke, 3v6 
 Meitzen, 38o 
 
 Mercantile system, 136, 140 
 Meyer, 63, 98 
 Migration, 345; economic and 
 
 social results of, 356 ff., 377; 
 
 goal of modern, 384; kinds of, 
 
 349. 352. 353; periods of, 370, 
 
 373 , . 
 
 Migratory character of society, 
 
 383 
 Moha, 95 
 Mobility of society, query as to. 
 
 349 
 Momnistn, aiS 
 Money, 67ff., ii'-. 13. 143- ^" 
 
 also Currency. 
 Montesquieu. 233 
 Mciser. 186, 256 
 Mundt-Lautf. 4 
 
 Nachtigal, 5. 19. 35. 263,270 
 National economy (see Economy) 
 
 era, 134. 378 
 Nationality, principle of, 140 
 Natural peoples, 41, 43 note. 
 Nepotism. 341 
 News, communication of. 77". P""" 
 
 licatiun of, i39 
 News-letters. 232, 233 
 Newspaper, 3i6. 221 
 Ni-^buhr. 344 
 Nl .ad life, 16, 345, ^^i> 
 iVouvellauti, 217 
 ,\ouvtlUs <\ lit main, 233, 233 
 A\uvtllist(s, 232, 233 
 
 Occupations, German census of. 
 1 181. 260, 324 
 
 I 
 
INDEX. 
 
 39» 
 
 OHin husbandry, 97 
 
 One page prints, 235 
 
 Opel. 228, 231. 237 
 
 Ordinari ("ordinary messen- 
 gers), 222, 229; Ord. ZtitUHgtn, 
 230 
 
 Orth, 237 
 
 Ottino, 222 
 
 Paget, 158 
 
 Panckow, 23, 42, 47 
 
 Parkinson. 24. 33. 47. 69. 79. 93. »9 
 
 Pasz, 278 
 
 Pattrfamilias, 97 
 
 Paulitschke, 35. 270. 277 
 
 Peschel, 3, 4. 5. ". »3. ai 
 
 Petri, 158 
 
 Petronius, 98 
 
 V. Philippovich, 244, 289 
 
 Physiocrats, 87, I39 
 
 Piece-work, collective, 279 
 
 Play, 27, 28 
 
 Pliny, lie 
 
 Pogge, 10, 18, 24, 35, 47. Ji. «>5. 75. 
 77, 80, loi, 270 
 
 Pogio, 91 
 
 POhlmann, 370. 37» 
 
 Polygamy, 55. ^54 
 
 Popma, 98, 99 
 
 Population, Hutive, 359 
 
 Post, 15. 49. 79. 270. aSo 
 
 Postreuter, 236 
 
 Pottery, invention of, 22 
 
 Presents (gifts), 61. 6a note, 79. 81 
 
 Price-work, 169 
 
 Primitive man, 12 ff., 41 " ; Peo- 
 ples, classification of, 42 
 
 Printing, invention of, 234 
 
 Production, 196; division of. 280, 
 
 294, 331, 33' , 
 
 Productive powers, harmony ot, 
 
 347 
 Property, immaterial, 131 
 Pruti, 222, 227. 336, 237 
 Public administration, 76, 79, 140 
 
 Quetelet, 351 
 Quippus, 73 
 
 Rambangs, 265 
 
 Ratiel. 5. U. »5. 34. 47. 49. 51 
 
 Rau, 2S0 
 
 Raucbberg, 3^1 
 
 Ready-made goods, 19S 
 Recruiting territory for city, 381 
 Rtlationes semestraUs, 236 
 Rent, 112; purchases, 331 
 Repair trade, 198 
 Reuter, Fritr, 366 
 Ricardo, 83 
 
 Riedel, 269 
 
 Riegl, 157 
 
 Riehl, 327. 337. 341 
 
 Rodbertus, 96, 148. 33«. 37i 
 
 Rohlfs, 78 
 
 Romstorfer, 158 
 
 Roscher. 187. 245. 246. 37o 
 
 Rosegger, 163 
 
 Potu, 278 
 
 Sachau, 64 
 
 Sale-shop, 198 
 
 Salomon, Ludwig, 2i8 
 
 Sapper. 37, 58 
 
 Sarasin, 9 
 
 Schadenberg, 4. 8. 24. 38. 269, 277 
 
 Schaffle. 337. 338 
 
 Scheurl, 230 
 
 Schliemann, 363 
 
 Schloss, 279 
 
 Schmaler, 266 
 
 Schmeller, 278 
 
 Schmeltz, 28 
 
 Schmidt. A., 218 
 
 Schmoller, 87. 123. 136. 189. 289, 
 303. 328, 329. 330. 336-338. 342 
 
 Schiinberg, I3« 
 
 Schumann, 357 , 
 
 Schur'i, 23. 3*^. 58. 66. 67. 75. 76, 
 270 
 
 Schwarzkopf. 234. 237 
 
 Schweinfurth, 28. 37. 38, 47. 5J. 72. 
 
 '9 , . 
 Schweinitz, 263 
 
 Schwicker, 158 
 
 Seebohm, 280 
 
 Semon, 23, 76. 263 
 
 Seneca, 372 
 
 Serfdom, 95. 167. 280, 305, 322 
 
 Settegast, 272 
 
 Sexes, distribution of labour De- 
 
 tween, 30-37. 44. 54, 253 
 Shortland, 63 
 Sibree, 271 
 Sick, exposure of, by savages, 16 
 
 Sickel, 230 
 
 Sidenbladh, I57 
 
 Slavery, 55. 95. 280, 305. 3«7 
 
I't 
 
 39* 
 
 INDEX. 
 
 Smith. Adam. 87, 139. 151. 245-248, 
 
 282-290. 295-O, 303 
 Smiths, 72 
 Social differentiation {see Labour, 
 
 social). 290, 295, 329; rank, 334 
 Society, organization of. 7. 213, 
 
 3^(>. 333 
 Spedalhation, 287, 294, 305 
 
 Spencer, 13, 20 
 
 Spinning-rooms. 265-267 
 
 Spoken paper, 233 
 
 Stage of Individual Search for 
 Food (see Individual); of Inde- 
 pendent Household Economy. 
 89. 114. 142. 313; of Town Econ- 
 omy, 89, 114. 126, 313. 384; of 
 National Economy, 89, 134, I37i 
 
 141.313.383. „ ,. _ 
 
 Stages, not universally applicable, 
 
 12 
 
 Stanley. 34, 7Q, '^3 
 
 Staple, law of. 123 
 
 Starcke. 38 
 
 State, absolutist. 138; modern, 378. 
 
 See Economy, National. 
 Staudinger. 64 
 Steam, as motive power, 175 
 V. d. Steinen. 9, 23. 28. 31. 32, 5'. 
 
 61, 263 
 Steinhausen. 222, 229 
 Stellmacher, 267 
 Stieda, 123, 130 
 Stieve. 236 
 Stock, L., 212 
 
 Struggles for adaptation. 366 ff. 
 Sundt, IS7 
 SUssmilch, 3(19 
 Sweat-work, 197 
 Swetjolka, 267 
 
 Tacitus, 112, 220 
 Tarajanz, 158. 165. 166 
 Tax on land, 114; on general prop- 
 erty, 133 
 Teale, 4 
 
 ".Team-work," 279 
 Technical skill, development of. 28 
 Technique. 53 
 Telephonic contrivances, 78 
 Thaer. 272 
 Throwing-stick, 7 
 ThOnen, 88 
 Tiebe, 9I 
 Time, use of. 19 
 Tindall, 81 
 
 Town: constitution of, 126; simi- 
 larity of. 273; supremacy of, 133, 
 373. See Cities. 
 
 Trade, 59. 124. 125. 145, 206, 257, 
 
 309. 331. 373 
 Trades: division of. 287; formation 
 
 of. 290, 294 
 Trading peoples. 73 
 Trade-mark. 76 
 Transmission of knowledge among 
 
 savages. 22 
 Transportation, 77 
 Tree-dwelling, 4 
 Tscheta, 93 
 Turgot, 87 
 
 Uniformity, tendency towards, 
 
 194, 310 
 Usury, prohibition of, 113 
 Uten, no 
 
 Vadhmal, 109. 161 
 
 Valentinelli. 226 
 
 Valerius Maximus, 342 
 
 Value, conceptions of. among sav- 
 ages, 21 
 
 Verdinglichung, 91 
 
 Vierkandt, 42 
 
 Villenage. 91 
 
 Vocations: rise of, 127; free choice 
 of. 340 
 
 Vocational class. 334 
 
 Waddewarden. 361. 362 
 
 Wages. 132; of management, 132, 
 
 167 
 Wage-work, 154. 162, i63, 176 
 Wage-workers, class of, 332 
 Wagner, Adolf. 3 
 Waitz, 5, 16, 33. 37. 45. 59. 77. 78, 
 
 Si 
 Wallon, 160 
 v. Waltershausen, 61 
 Waterways, 77 
 Wealth, 131, 143 
 Weber, 96, 99 
 
 Weekly (newspaper). 236-238 
 Weiske, 120 
 Welsmann. 329 
 W Her. 235 
 We'sers. 230 
 Wiglitzsky, 158 
 Winckler. 322, 233 
 
INDEX. 
 
 393 
 
 Wissmann, lo, i8, 35. S^, 38. 47. SL 
 
 72. 74. 75. 77, 79. 80 
 
 Witzlebcn, 231 
 
 Wolf. 35 , ^.,. . 
 
 Work: principle of stability and 
 
 coniinuiiy of, 249; subdivision 
 
 of, 175. 3«7 
 
 Wiilkcr, 221 
 Wundl, KJ 
 
 Zadru^v!, 03. 105 
 
 Zell, 218 
 Zwingli -23