key: cord-0963705-4w9pa0vz authors: Hsiao, Cody Yu-Ling; Morley, James title: Debt and financial market contagion date: 2021-06-11 journal: Empir Econ DOI: 10.1007/s00181-021-02077-5 sha: a940e2ac6c41c6924cb745cf47dc242fc75234b9 doc_id: 963705 cord_uid: 4w9pa0vz We empirically investigate why financial crises spread from one country to another. For our analysis, we develop a new multiple-channel test of financial market contagion and construct indices of crisis severity in equity markets in order to examine how the transmission of shocks across countries can be related to direct linkages between countries or to common characteristics. Based on network analysis with our proposed multiple-channel test for crises between 2007 and 2021, we find that the Great Recession is the most pervasive across countries, followed by the European sovereign debt crisis and the recent COVID pandemic, with the subprime mortgage crisis being the least pervasive. Our main finding is that similar public, private and external debt characteristics are particularly helpful in explaining the transmission of financial shocks during crises. Fiscal deficits appear more important than current account deficits, while stage of economic development matters more than regional linkages, but none of these indicators is as important as debt. ies have investigated financial market contagion (King and Wadhwani 1990; Forbes and Rigobon 2002; Bae et al. 2003; Fry et al. 2010; Keddad and Schalck 2020; Niţoi and Pochea 2020) , although the exact definition and measurement of contagion varies considerably across studies. The most commonly used definitions of financial market contagion are those proposed by King and Wadhwani (1990) and Forbes and Rigobon (2002) , who focus on a comparison of the linear dependence structure across markets in non-crisis and crisis periods. However, instead of focusing on the correlation of returns, other researchers have considered alternative measures such as higher-order co-moments or tail dependencies to capture contagion. For instance, Favero and Giavazzi (2002) explore outlier tests, Bae et al. (2003) develop the co-exceedance approach based on extreme value theory, Pesaran and Pick (2007) and Finta et al. (2019) propose the threshold tests of contagion, Rodriguez (2007) and Silvapulle et al. (2016) study tail dependence using copulas, Fry et al. (2010) introduce the co-skewness change tests, and Fry-McKibbin and Hsiao (2018) developed the co-kurtosis and co-volatility change tests. This literature examines contagion by focusing primarily on single-channel tests, which may not capture all relevant dependencies across financial markets. Moreover, as we show, single-channel tests based on changes in correlation (Forbes and Rigobon 2002) , co-skewness (Fry et al. 2010) , or co-kurtosis and co-volatility (Fry-McKibbin and Hsiao 2018) have some size distortions when the sample period for a crisis episode is relatively short compared to non-crisis periods. The most closely related paper is Fry-McKibbin et al. (2021) who study the entropy theory through second-and higher-order co-moments, but focus on measuring market interdependence rather than contagion. Instead of just focusing on a single-channel test of contagion, we introduce a new multiple-channel test for which the effects of a financial crisis can be identified not only through a change in correlation, but also through changes in higher-order comoments. 1 Following Forbes and Rigobon (2002) , we define contagion as a significant change in a co-moment relative to what would be expected given heteroskasticity. However, our proposed test enables us to capture changes in various aspects of dependency across asset returns, specifically correlation (how the mean return in one country depends on the return in another), co-skewness (how the volatility in one country depends on the return in another) and co-volatility (how the volatility in one country depends on the volatility in another). Our formal test is based on a Lagrange multiplier statistic constructed under the hypothesis of no change in co-moments relative to what would be expected given heteroskasticity and we derive its distribution allowing for the presence of a non-normal multivariate return distribution, as is appropriate for financial time series. In addition to providing a more comprehensive test for contagion that captures linear, asymmetric and tail dependencies simultaneously, we also directly consider why financial crises spread across countries. Several possible explanations have been investigated in the literature, including trade linkages ( Van Rijckeghem and Weder 2001; Kali and Reyes 2010; Ters and Urban 2018 , financial linkages (Ahlgren and Antell 2010), regional proximity to the market in which the crisis originates (Glick and Rose 1999) , comparably stage of economic development (Fry-McKibbin et al. 2014) , external and internal imbalances (Caramazza et al. 2004; Ehrmann et al. 2009; Bekaert et al. 2011) , as well as government debt (Reinhard and Rogoff 2011; Forbes (2012) ) and fiscal conditions (Dioikitopoulos 2018; Niemann and Pichler 2020). We focus on which similar pre-crisis characteristics, including levels of different types of debt, regional linkages and stage of development, are the most important in explaining the likelihood of contagion. 2 The importance of these characteristics is determined by grouping countries by characteristic and comparing a measure of crisis severity in terms of frequency of significant contagion from a crisis for each country grouping. Our main results can be summarized as follows: First, among the four financial crises from 2007 to 2021 (the subprime mortgage crisis, the Great Recession crisis, the European sovereign debt crisis and the coronavirus disease (COVID) crisis), the crises associated with Great Recession seems from our proposed multiple-channel test and network analysis to have been the most pervasive across countries, followed by the European sovereign debt crisis and the COVID pandemic, with the subprime mortgage crisis being the least pervasive. Second, debt conditions (public, private and external debt) were the most important determinants in explaining the transmission of financial shocks during crises. The current account balance did not necessarily alter crisis transmission, while the evidence indicates that government fiscal balance was only somewhat correlated with contagion during the crises. Third, compared with stage of development, regional linkages were a weak predictor of contagion during the financial crises. Only the European sovereign debt and, to some extent, the COVID crises had evidence of regional contagion, as might be expected, but contagion with the subprime mortgage crisis and the Great Recession crisis did not seem at all to be regionally determined. The rest of this paper proceeds are follows. Section 2 describes the single-and multiple-channel tests of contagion considered in our analysis and considers their finite-sample properties. The tests are then applied in Sect. 3 to investigate financial market contagion during the four crises from 2007 to 2021. Section 4 concludes. This section provides details of the Lagrange multiplier tests of contagion used in our analysis. Following the work of Fry et al. (2010) and Fry-McKibbin and Hsiao (2018) , the bivariate generalized exponential family of the distribution for the two random variables r 1,t and r 2,t at time t is where h t specified as bivariate normal distribution through the first-to the fourth-order co-moments gives and η t is the normalizing constant The distribution in (1) is an extension of the univariate generalized distribution by Cobb et al. (1983) and Lye and Martin (1993) . The choice of h t corresponds to polynomials and cross-products of standard scores for the two random variables r 1 and r 2 . The parameter ρ controls the degree of linear dependence (correlation), the parameters θ 4 and θ 5 control the asymmetric dependencies (co-skewness) and the parameter θ 6 control the extremal dependencies (co-volatility). In a special case, the distribution in (1) reduces to a bivariate normal distribution if θ 4 , θ 5 and θ 6 in ( 2) are equal to zero. We develop a Lagrange multiplier statistic to test joint co-moments. Giving a sample of size T , the log-likelihood function corresponding to (1 ) is of the form where = (θ 1 , ..., θ K ) is a finite number K of the unknown parameters. The hypothesis to be tested is specified as H 0 : θ 1 = 0, ..., θ p = 0; p ≤ K . The Lagrange multiplier test statistic is given by where represent the maximum likelihood estimator of under the null hypothesis and S is the score function evaluated at given by and I is the asymptotic information matrix evaluated at , which is derived by Fry et al. (2010) , given by Under the null hypothesis, the Lagrange multiplier test statistic is asymptotically distributed as χ 2 p , where p is the number of constraints imposed under the null hypothesis. The advantage of using this test is that the Lagrangian multiplier test does not require the estimation of the unrestricted model as the distribution in (1) is nested in the bivariate normal distribution by setting the restrictions θ 4 = θ 5 = θ 6 = 0. The existing contagion literature using Lagrange multiplier tests includes the co-skewness statistics of Fry et al. (2010) , the co-kurtosis and co-volatility statistics of Fry-McKibbin and Hsiao (2018) and joint statistics of co-skewness, co-kurtosis and co-volatility of Fry-McKibbin et al. (2019) . The full derivations behind our multiple-channel test statistic for correlation, co-skewness and co-volatility are given in Appendix B and Appendix C. In developing our test of contagion, the following notation is used. The pre-crisis period is denoted as x, and the crisis period is denoted as y . The sample sizes of the pre-crisis and crisis periods are T x and T y , respectively. The correlation between the two asset returns is denoted as ρ x (pre-crisis) and ρ y (crisis). The source crisis market is denoted as i, and the recipient market is denoted as j. Finally, μ i x , μ j x , μ iy and μ j y are the sample means of the asset returns for markets i and j during the two periods, and σ i x , σ j x , σ iy and σ j y are the sample standard deviations of the asset returns for markets i and j during the two periods. The existing contagion tests in the literature tend to focus on individual channels for contagion. Four types of single-channel tests are considered here. The first is the Forbes and Rigobon (2002) correlation change test where it is based on changes in correlation. The second and third are Fry et al. (2010) co-skewness change tests where they are based on changes in co-skewness. The final is Fry-McKibbin and Hsiao (2018) co-volatility change test based on changes in co-volatility. The first type of single-channel contagion test developed by Fry et al. (2010) extends early forms of the correlation contagion tests of Forbes and Rigobon (2002) . The test statistic is based on significance change in the adjusted crisis period correlation ν y|x i compared to a pre-crisis period correlation ( ρ x ) given by where ν y|x i is the heteroskedasticity adjusted correction coefficient derived by Forbes and Rigobon (2002) given by The standard error for (8) is presented in Fry et al. (2010) , where The second and third single-channel tests are the co-skewness tests proposed by Fry et al. (2010) . The tests are based on the significance change in the crisis co-skewness coefficient ( ψ y ) compared to the pre-crisis period co-skewness coefficient ( ψ x ) given as where two forms of co-skewness moments during the pre-crisis (x) and crisis (y) periods be where a = 1, b = 2 is the first form of co-skewness and a = 2, b = 1 is the second form of co-skewness. The first form of ST 1:2 is a test for contagion through new spillover from the level returns of the source country i to the squared return of the recipient country j. The second form of ST 2:1 is a test for contagion through new spillover from the squared returns of the source country i to the level returns of the recipient country j. The final single-channel test is the co-volatility contagion test developed by Fry-McKibbin and Hsiao (2018) . The test is based on the significance change in the crisis co-volatility coefficient ( ξ y r 2 i , r 2 j ) compared to the pre-crisis co-volatility coefficient ( ξ x r 2 i , r 2 j ) given by where The new contagion test developed in this paper involves a more general statistic, as it is designed to identify contagion through changes in multiple channels of correlation, both forms of co-skewness and co-volatility. The statistic (MT ) is designed to test for contagion from country i to country j (see Appendix C for details): where ν y|x i is the heteroskedasticity adjusted correction coefficient in equation (9), a = 1, b = 2 is the first form of co-skewness, and a = 2, b = 1 is the second form of co-skewness during the pre-crisis and crisis periods in equations (12 ) and (13), and a = 2, b = 2 is the co-volatility during the two periods in equations (15) and (16). The statistic MT consists of four components capturing correlation, both forms of co-skewness and co-volatility simultaneously. Under the null hypothesis of no contagion, the test statistic in (17) is asymptotically distributed as MT d −→ χ 2 4 , where the number of degrees of freedom is determined by the number of restrictions imposed on (2) under the null hypothesis which for this class of tests is ρ = θ 4 = θ 5 = θ 6 = 0. Table 1 summarizes the different single-and multiple-channel tests. We study the finite-sample properties of the single-and multiple-channel tests in the context of a relatively large pre-crisis sample size but relatively short crisis sample size, which is the standard setting for most financial market crises. To investigate this issue, the finite-sample distribution properties of the contagion tests under the null hypothesis of no contagion are conducted through simulations. The data generating process is based on the bivariate generalized normal distribution in (1), setting that the population means and variances at μ = 0, and σ 2 = 1, as well as the null hypothesis of no contagion is ρ = θ 4 = θ 5 = θ 6 = 0. The joint density function is where η is the normalizing constant such that f (r 1 , r 2 )dr 1 dr 2 = 1. To allow for varying crisis period sample sizes, nine experiments are conducted, with the non-crisis sample size set to 500 days (T x ) and the crisis period sample size varying from 30 to 500 days (T y = 30, 60, 90, 120, 150, 200, 300, 400, 500) . The pre-crisis sample size is T x = 500. The empirical size of the ST 1:1 , ST 1:2 , ST 2:1 and ST 2:2 tests is based on the 5% asymptotic χ 2 1 critical values with 1 degree of freedom and the MT test is based on the 5% asymptotic χ 2 4 critical values with 4 degrees of freedom. The results are based on 50,000 replications Table 2 reports results for the empirical size of the contagion tests as the duration of the crisis period T y is decreased from 500 to 30 days. The duration of the precrisis period is set to T x = 500 days. The number of replications is 50,000 for all simulations in order to minimize the effect of any simulation error on our inferences. 3 The empirical size for the ST 1:1 , ST 1:2 , ST 2:1 and ST 2:2 tests is based on the 5% asymptotic χ 2 1 distribution critical value, but for the MT test is based on the 5% asymptotic χ 2 4 distribution critical value. The results show that given a relatively large pre-crisis sample size (T x = 500), but relatively short crisis period sample size (T y = 30), the proposed MT test provides a good approximation of the finite-sample distribution among the five contagion tests, with the empirical size being close to the nominal size of 5%. Given larger crisis period sample sizes, the remaining tests (ST 1:1 , ST 1:2 , ST 2:1 and ST 2:2 ) exhibit the correct size of 5%. However, if the crisis sample size is short (T y = 30), the ST 1:2 , ST 2:1 and ST 2:2 tests are slightly undersized with values of 3.8%, 3.9% and 1.9%, respectively, but the ST 1:1 test is slightly oversized with value of 8.0%. To investigate the impact of the four financial crises on equity markets of different countries around the world, we consider daily equity price indices for 44 countries during the 2005 to 2021 period collected from Datastream and Bloomberg database. 4 3 Results would be mostly the same to three decimals given only 25,000 simulations. 4 The equity indices, expressed in US dollars, are collected from Datastream. The mneumonics are: Argentina -Argentina Merval price index; Australia -ASX200 price index; Austria -MSCI Austria price index; Belgium -BEL20 price index; Brazil -MSCI Brazilian price index; Bulgaria -Bulgaria Se Sofix price index; Canada -S&P Composite price index; Chile -Chile Santiago Se General price index; China -Shanghai Se A Share price index; Colombia -Colombia IGBC price index; Denmark -OMX Copenhagen price index; Finland -OMX Helsinki price index; France -CAC40 price index; Germany -MDAX The 44 countries are classified into four regions: Africa, Americas, Asia and Europe, which we consider to investigate contagion through the regional linkages. 5 Daily percentage equity returns (R l,t ) for the lth market are calculated as where P l,t is the equity index in market l at time t. Our sample period starts on January 1, 2005, and ends on March 17, 2021, which covers four episodes of financial crisis: (i) the subprime mortgage crisis, (ii) the Great Recession, (iii) the European debt crisis and iv) the recent COVID pandemic. 6 According to Fry-McKibbin et al. (2014) , the pre-crisis period is from January In order to avoid arbitrary selection of the pre-crisis and crisis periods, we consider Bai and Perron (2003) structural break tests to identify the non-crisis and crisis dates. These tests support the dates specified in , which is the most recent period available at the time of writing. 8 The crisis source for the subprime mortgage crisis and the Great Recession crisis is assumed to be the USA (Chan et al. 2019) . For the European debt crisis, the crisis source is assumed to be Greece (Beirne and Fratzscher 2013; Samarakoon 2017) , and for the COVID pandemic, the crisis source is assumed to be China (Akhtaruzzaman et al. 2021) . Table 3 summarizes the dates for each crisis episode and its crisis source. All returns are plotted in Fig. 1 , showing that the returns volatility changes dramatically around the world during the crisis periods compared with the pre-crisis periods. To highlight changes in the behavior of equity returns between pre-crisis and crisis periods, Table 4 reports descriptive statistics of the own-moments of the mean, standard deviation, skewness and kurtosis of equity returns in each country during Footnote 7 continued Fry-McKibbin et al. (2014) . We also perform the sensitivity analysis by taking the dates as one-month before and after the structural break on July 25, 2007 for robustness. These structural break and robustness test results are provided in Appendix D. 8 We filter the data in the same way as in Forbes and Rigobon (2002) . Before conducting the contagion tests, a vector autoregressive (VAR) model is used to control for market fundamentals (country-specificand the pre-crisis (January 1, 2005 to July 25, 2007) and crisis (September 15, 2008 to December 31, 2009 periods. The first and second moments show that average returns (mean) decrease while volatility (standard deviation) increase during the crisis period compared with the pre-crisis period. Inspection of the third and fourth moments of each returns suggests a change in the returns distributions from negative skewness in the pre-crisis period to either smaller negative skewness or positive skewness in the crisis period in most cases. Not surprisingly, kurtosis rises during the crisis period. Table 5 reports the co-moment statistics of the equity returns between the US and the 43 selected markets during pre-crisis and crisis periods. As expected, the correlation between the US and the selected market (except for Colombia) increases during the crisis period, indicating that equity returns between markets are strongly correlated in the crisis period. Both forms of co-skewness, which measures the relationship between expected returns and volatility, switch from left-to right-skewed in most cases during the crisis period. Co-volatility, which measures the correlation between volatilities, increases during the crisis period. The higher value of co-volatility in the crisis period implies that return volatility is high in both markets, thus increasing contagion risk in the crisis period. Tables 6, 7, 8, and 9 present the empirical results of single-and multiple-channel tests of contagion during the four financial crises of 2007-2021 (the subprime mortgage crisis, the Great Recession crisis, the European debt crisis and the COVID pandemic). Under the null hypothesis of no contagion, the single-channel test statistics for the ST 1:1 , ST 1:2 , ST 2:1 and ST 2:2 are distributed asymptotically as χ 2 1 where the 5% critical value is 3.84, and the multiple-channel test statistic for the MT is distributed asymptotically as χ 2 4 where the 5% critical value is 9.49. Table 6 presents the single-and multiple-channel tests of contagion based on changes in correlation, co-skewness and co-volatility during the subprime mortgage crisis with the source country specified to be the USA. Inspection of Table 6 reveals that among the Footnote 8 continued cross market relationships that always exist) and address any serial correlation. The VAR model is given by where R t = [x t , y t ] is a transposed vector of returns across a set of equity markets during the non-crisis (x t ) and crisis (y t ) periods; φ (L) is a vector of lags, and u t is a vector of the residual terms. In order to deal with equity markets open in different time zones, two-day rolling average returns are used in the VAR model. The residuals u t are treated as financial shocks and are used in the calculation of the correlation contagion statistic in (8), the co-skewness contagion statistics in (10) and (11), the co-volatility contagion statistic in (14), and the multiple-channel test of contagion statistic in (17). To conduct the contagion tests during the three episodes of financial crises from 2007 to 2013, the VAR model with 5 lags is estimated based on the sample period of 2005 to 2013. As for testing contagion during the COVID pandemic, a VAR model with 5 lags is estimated based on the sample period of 2019 to 2021. The co-moment statistics of equity returns between the USA (i) and selected market ( j) include correlation (r 1 it , r 1 jt ), co-skewness 12 (r 1 it , r 2 jt ), co-skewness 21 (r 2 it , r 1 jt ) and co-volatility (r 2 it , r 2 jt ), which are computed as four regions, the Americas region is the most affected by the subprime mortgage crisis, followed by the Asian and European regions, with the African region the least affected by the crisis based on single-and multiple-channel tests. In particular, all countries especially those located in the Americas region are more exposed to contagion risk through either single channel or multiple channel of correlation, co-skewness and covolatility. In terms of single channel tests, the correlation channel (ST 1:1 ) seems to be the most dominant in detecting contagion from the equity returns of the USA to the equity returns of the other North and South American equity markets, followed by the co-volatility channel (ST 2:2 ), where the contagion effect is detected from the square returns of the US equity markets to squared returns of the other North and South American equity markets. Compared with correlation and co-volatility, co-skewness channels (ST 1:2 and ST 2:1 ) are weaker in detecting contagion between the returns of the US equity market and the squared returns of the other North and South American equity markets. In terms of multiple channel test, all joint co-moments of correlation, co-skewness and co-volatility (MT ) are affected by contagion from the US equity market to the other North and South American equity markets during the subprime mortgage crisis. Table 7 presents the empirical results of the single-and multiple-channel tests of contagion during the Great Recession crisis of 2008-2009, with the source market is again specified to be the USA. The results show that contagion effects are widespread from the US equity market to the selected equity markets in four regions including Africa, Americas, Asia and Europe during the Great Recession. Among these regions, the European regions are most affected by the crisis from the US equity market since all equity markets in the European region experienced a dramatic change in joint correlation, co-skewness and co-volatility with the US equity market in the crisis period compared with the non-crisis period. This result also anticipates the fact that after the end of the Great Recession, the European region faced its own financial crisis, namely the European sovereign debt crisis due to the problem of refinancing government debt (Fry-McKibbin and Hsiao 2018) . Besides Europe, the African, Asian and Americas regions are also exposed to contagion risk during the Great Recession as evident by financial market contagion between the US and selected equity markets through either single channel or multiplier channel of correlation, co-skewness and co-volatility. Table 8 presents the empirical results of the single-and multiple-channel tests of contagion during the European debt crisis of 2010-2013, with the source market specified to be Greece. Table 8 reveals significant evidence of contagion from Greece to selected equity markets in four regions through either single or multiple-channel of correlation, co-skewness and co-volatility during the European debt crisis. Not surprisingly, among the four regions, the European region is the most affected region by the crisis, with all equity markets except for Bulgaria affected by the crisis in at least two transmission channels. The African, Americas and Asian regions are also affected by the European debt crisis, but the contagion effect is not so strong as for the European region. Table 9 presents the empirical results of contagion tests during the COVID pandemic of 2019-2021, with the source market specified to be China. Table 9 shows significant evidence of contagion from China's equity market to selected markets in the Americas and Asian and European regions during the COVID pandemic through the single channels of correlation, co-skewness or co-volatility. Among the four regions, the Asian region is the most affected by contagion from China, followed by the Americas, with no contagion from China to the African region during the COVID pandemic. (10 ) and (11), ST 2:2 is the co-volatility contagion test in (14), MT is the joint test of correlation, co-skewness and co-volatility in (17). * denotes the significance of contagion at the 5% level (10 ) and (11), ST 2:2 is the co-volatility contagion test in (14), MT is the joint test of correlation, co-skewness and co-volatility in (17). * denotes the significance of contagion at the 5% level The results for the multiple channel test reveal that contagion effects are widespread from China's equity market to the Americas' equity markets (Argentina, Colombia and Peru), Asian equity markets (Australia, Hong Kong, Korea, Singapore, Taiwan and Thailand) and European equity markets (Bulgaria, Greece and Ireland) through joint channels of correlation, co-skewness and co-volatility. Overall, the results indicate that among the four episodes of crises from 2007 to 2021, the Great Recession seems to be the most pervasive crisis in leading to contagion between the US equity market and the selected equity markets in four regions, followed by the European debt crisis and the COVID pandemic, with the subprime mortgage crisis being the least pervasive. When considering which single channel of contagion is most important, the co-volatility channel is the most dominant, followed by the correlation channel, with the co-skewness channels the least important in the financial market contagion. The results are consistent with the fact that co-volatility, one of the tail dependence, can better detect contagion than the correlation and co-skewness (10 ) and (11), ST 2:2 is the co-volatility contagion test in (14), MT is the joint test of correlation, co-skewness and co-volatility in (17). * denotes the significance of contagion at the 5% level channels, especially when the crisis corresponds to the worst event occurring in one market given that the worst event occurred in another market (Garcia and Tsafack 2011). It is interesting to investigate not only the contagion effect spreading from the US, Greece or China to other countries, but also possible contagion effects between other countries. We plot network diagrams using the proposed multiple-channel test ( (17). If the node is colored in dark red and is larger, it reveals that all 43 recipient countries are affected by the source node, while if the node is colored in orange and is smaller, it suggests that no country is affected by crisis. Figure 2 reveals that among the four crises, the networks for the COVID pandemic are the most connected, as evident by more than 30 countries acting as the main nodes in the network. Perhaps surprisingly, among the 44 countries, China is not found to be an important node in spreading the shocks to the overall system; however, Bulgaria, Colombia, Canada, Ireland, Norway, Thailand and the UK appear as nodes affecting up to 40 countries in the network during the COVID pandemic. The Great Recession also displays a more interconnected system than the European debt crisis. In particular, more than 14 European countries shows the dark red node during the Great Recession, suggesting that European region has more linkages with other regions in equity markets. The results are consistent with the fact that the European region faced its own financial crisis during the period of 2010 to 2013. Similarly, among the four (10 ) and (11), ST 2:2 is the co-volatility contagion test in (14), MT is the joint test of correlation, co-skewness and co-volatility in (17). * denotes the significance of contagion at the 5% level (17). If the node is colored in dark red, it reveals that all 43 recipient countries are affected by the source node, while if the node is colored in orange, it shows that no country is affected regions, the European countries are the most dominant the source node in the network during the European debt crisis. Among the four crises, the connections are not strong during the subprime mortgage crisis, as evident by the total number of links and density being the lowest. Financial crisis indicators can provide important tools for both academics and policymakers in understanding the determinants of crisis transmission (Giordano et al. 2013) . A number of papers analyze the ability of such indicators to anticipate financial crisis and assess the impact of financial crisis future vulnerabilities. Crisis indicators that have been studied in the literature include those related to equity and debt inflows (Didier et al. 2010) , terms of trade (Forbes 2012) , financial conditions (Dungey and Martin 2007; Matsuyama 2007; Cipriani et al. 2013; de Haas and van Horen 2013; and Morley 2016) , regional proximity (Glick and Rose 1999; Dungey et al. 2009 ) and development comparability (Fry-McKibbin et al. 2014) . In this paper, we mainly focus on the following conditions: (i) debt levels include public, private and external debts, (ii) fiscal and current accounts, (iii) regional proximity and (iv) stage of economic development. The crisis indicators are further analyzed in Appendix E. In order to test whether the crisis indicators discussed above can be treated as an important predictor in explaining contagion, a crisis severity index is constructed with two groups such as high-debt and low-debt. There are several steps to compute the crisis severity index (C I t ). First, taking the pre-crisis (T 1,x = 661) period as fixed, the crisis period is defined on a rolling sample basis using a window length of 30 days, where the crisis period shifts forward by one day between each rolling sample. Second, all test statistics (MT t ) in equation (17) can be computed for each rolling sample. Finally, the crisis severity index (C I t ) can be computed by using capitalization-weighted index of indicator variable. If the multiple-channel test statistic (MT t ) at time t is greater than the critical value 9.49, the indicator (I (i→ j), j,t ) at time t takes a value of 1, indicating market contagion from source country i to a recipient country j at the 5% significant level, such that Then, the crisis severity index (C I t ) at time t is given by where C W j is the market capitalization (cap) weight for the recipient country j. The index is constructed in terms of market cap value, so that the countries with large market cap value will carry more weight in the calculation of the index. 9 To understand why some countries are more affected by the crisis than others, we conduct a difference-in-means t test for different country groupings. Taking the debt-to-GDP ratio as an example, if a country's debt ratio is above the 80th percentile of its distribution, the country will be classified in the "high-debt" group, while if a country's ratio is below the 20th percentile, the country will be classified in the "low-debt" group. 10 In this case, the crisis severity index of the n 1 high-debt countries is calculated as while the crisis severity index for the the n 2 low-debt countries is given by The independent two sample t test statistic is given by where Here, μ C I 1 and μ C I 2 are the sample means of crisis severity index for high-debt and low-debt groups in equations (22) and (23), σ 2 C I 1 and σ 2 C I 2 are the sample variances of the crisis severity index for two groups, and σ C I 12 is the pooled standard deviation. The null and alternative hypotheses of no difference of crisis transmission between the high-debt and low-debt groups are Under the null hypothesis of no crisis transmission through the link arising from the similar debt conditions, the t statistic is asymptotically distributed as T n 1 +n 2 −2 . Figure 3 displays results for crisis severity indices related to economic conditions during the three episodes of financial crises of 2007 to 2013. The first row of Figure 3 shows the percentage of countries affected by contagion in terms of the debt conditions (the public, private and external debt) over the three episodes of crisis from 2007 to 2013. The solid (black) line presents the 30 day indicator of contagion for the highdebt countries in (22), and the dotted (red) line for the low-debt countries in (23). As the public debt panel shows, the subprime mortgage crisis and the Great Recession crisis affect nearly 10% of low-debt and high-debt countries; while the European debt crisis affect more on high-debt countries (40%) than the low-debt countries (10%). For the private debt panel, the results reveal that the crisis severity index for the highdebt countries are much higher than that for the low-debt countries during the three crises. As for external debt panel, the results show that the crisis severity index for the high-debt countries is quite identical to the low-debt countries during the three crises. The second row of Figure 3 shows crisis severity indices related to fiscal and current account balances. The solid (black) line presents the 30-day indicator of contagion for the weak-account countries in (22), and the dotted (red) line for the strong-account countries in ( 23). As the fiscal account panel shows, the European debt crisis affected fiscally weak countries (40%) more than strong countries (10%), while the subprime mortgage crisis and the Great Recession crisis tend to affect a small number of fiscal weak or strong countries. Compared with the role of fiscal account balance in detecting contagion, the current account is less likely to be correlated with crisis transmission during the three financial crises, with little difference of incidence of crisis severity between fiscally strong and weak countries. For both account balances, only the European debt crisis affects weak countries (40%) more than strong countries (10%), but the crisis severity index is quite similar for both of groups during the US-sourced crises. The last row of Fig. 3 show the percentage of countries affected by contagion in terms of regional proximity (Americas, Asia, Africa and Europe) and development comparability (developed and emerging) over the three episodes of crisis. For the regional panel, the countries most affected by contagion are located in the European region (40%), followed by the Asian and Americas regions (20%). Turning to the development comparability panel, the results show that developed and emerging countries in North and South America show similar crisis rates during the subprime mortgage crisis and the Great Recession, suggesting little support for development comparability in driving crisis transmission. However, the results are different from the European debt crisis, where the crisis affects the developed European countries (20%) more than the emerging countries (5%). Table 10 presents difference-in-means test results for different country groupings based on the eight economic indicators for crisis transmission during the three financial crises from 2007 to 2013. The results reveal that the debt conditions play an important role in explaining the crisis transmission for three episodes of financial crises of 2007 to 2013. In particular, among the three types of debt, private debt is the most important indicator, followed by public and external debts during the three financial crises. Not only are debt conditions important, but so is the fiscal account balance, as is evident by crisis severity index for weak-balance countries being significantly larger than for strong-balance countries at a 5% significance level. Compared with the role of fiscal account balance, the current account balance appears not to be an important indicator in explaining the crisis transmission, as there is no significant evidence of crisis transmission for both weak-and strong-balance countries during the entire crisis period of 2007 to 2013. In terms of regional linkages, the results of Table 10 suggest that the European debt crisis displayed evidence of regional contagion, but the subprime mortgage crisis and the Great Recession crisis did not. In particular, it is evident that the mean of crisis severity index for the European countries is significantly higher than other countries in African, Americas and Asian regions at the 5% significance level. Regarding to similar levels of development, the results suggest that development comparability plays an In this paper, we have developed a new test of financial market contagion to identify why financial shocks spread across international markets. Contagion is defined as a significant changes in second and higher-order co-moments including correlation, coskewness and co-volatility for two markets between a non-crisis and a crisis period. Our proposed test enables us to simultaneously capture these various channels of contagion (i) from mean returns of the source market to mean returns of the recipient market; (ii) from the mean returns of the source market to return volatility of the recipient market; (iii) from return volatility of the source market to mean returns of the recipient market; and (iv) from return volatility of the source market to return volatility of the recipient market. In deriving a new multiple-channel test of contagion, we considered a bivariate generalized exponential distribution and employed a Lagrange multiplier test. In comparison with existing single-channel tests, our proposed test appears to provide a good approximation of the finite-sample distribution given the relatively large sample period of the non-crisis but the relatively short sample period of the crisis. The 44 selected countries are classified into two groups using 80th percentile. The first group is for high-debt, weak account or developed countries; and the second group is for low-debt, strong account or emerging countries The t statistic in (24) is to test whether the mean of the crisis severity index for the first group is significantly larger than the second group. pvdenotes p-values with the significance of transmission channel at the 5% level. The debt stock, fiscal and current account balances for selected 44 countries are reported in Tables 13 to 16 Our new test is applied to investigate financial market contagion in equity markets during the four episodes of financial crisis from 2007 to 2021. The results suggest widespread contagion from the US to global equity markets during the subprime mortgage crisis and the Great Recession, from Greece to global equity markets during the European debt crisis and from China to global equity markets during the COVID pandemic. Among the four financial crises, the Great Recession crisis seems to have been the most pervasive, followed by the European debt crisis and the COVID pandemic, with the subprime mortgage crisis the least pervasive. Using network analysis where all possible contagion effects are considered, it is evident that the networks for the COVID pandemic are the most connected, followed by the Great Recession and the European debt crisis, while the connections are not strong for the subprime mortgage crisis. In investigating possible reasons for contagion, including levels of different types of debt, regional proximity and stage of development, we constructed crisis severity indices and found that, for the crises between 2007 and 2013, similar debt characteristics played the main role in explaining the transmission of a crisis from one country to another. Among the three types of debt that we consider, private debt is the most important. However, public debt is also an important indicator in driving crisis, especially for the European debt crisis. This result is consistent with the results in Rogoff (2011a, 2011b) that public debts rise markedly as a sovereign debt crisis draws near. Of course, the importance of regional linkages is also important during the European sovereign debt crisis. The following results are used to derive the information matrix for the test statistic of joint correlation, co-skewness and co-volatility. Consider the following bivariate normal distribution with higher-order co-moments We take the expectations of the first and second conditions of the distribution with respect to the parameters (μ 1 , μ 2 , σ 2 1 , σ 2 2 , ρ, θ 4 , θ 5 and θ 6 ) in (25) under the null hypothesis of independent bivariate normality, then the following elements of the information matrix at observation t are Let the parameters of (26) to be = μ 1 , μ 2 , σ 2 1 , σ 2 2 , θ 4 , θ 5 , θ 6 . By taking the log function of (26), the log likelihood function at time t is given by Using (5) and the results of Appendix B, the information matrix under the null hypothesis (H 0 : ρ = 0, θ 4 = 0, θ 5 = 0, θ 6 = 0) is where the elements of I i, j at observation t are shown in Appendix B. Replacing the unknown population parameters by consistent estimators under the null hypothesis, the inverse asymptotic information matrix is Evaluating the gradients for ρ, θ 4 , θ 5 and θ 6 under the null hypothesis gives The score function under H 0 is given as The Lagrange multiplier statistic is obtained by substituting (30 ) and (31) into (5), gives As contagion tests are conditional on a state of nature, the dating of a crisis period is an essential component of understanding contagion. We perform structural break tests (Bai and Perron 2003) to identify the non-crisis and crisis dates for sensitivity analysis. Table 11 shows structural break dates for residual returns and squared returns for 44 equity markets using the Bai and Perron (2003) test. The residuals are filtered by a VAR (5) (Fry-McKibbin et al. 2014) . In order to perform a further robustness check, we conduct sensitivity analysis by taking the dates as one-month before and after the break dates on July 25, 2007. Table 12 shows empirical results of contagion tests, given the pre-crisis period from January 1, 2005 to June 25, 2007 (Panel A) and from January 1, 2005 to August 25, 2007 (Panel B) . The results reveal that among the three crises from 2007-13, the Great Recession seems to be the most pervasive crisis, followed by the European debt crisis, with the subprime mortgage crisis the least pervasive crisis. The results are consistent with the results in Tables 6, 7 and 8. This appendix provides the discussion of financial crisis indicators used in this paper. Four types of crisis indicators include (i) debt levels, (ii) fiscal and current accounts, (iii) regional proximity and (iv) stage of economic development. Structural break dates for residual returns and squared returns of 44 equity markets filtered by a VAR(5) from January 12, 2005 to December 31, 2013 The first crisis indicators that we consider are related to debt conditions. There are actually three types of debt that we consider: (i) public, (ii) private and (iii) external debt. Our hypothesis is that high-debt countries should be more affected by a crisis than low-debt countries (see also Masson 1999; Briguglio et al. 2009; Rogoff 2010, 2011a, b) . Tables 13 and 14 summarize the percentile of the gross public debt, domestic private credit, and external debt for 44 countries in 2006 and 2009, respectively. To investigate whether the debt is an important determinant in driving crisis, the selected 44 countries are classified into two groups of high-debt and lowdebt using the threshold of 80th percentile. 11 Table 13 shows that if the gross public debt is selected as a crisis indicator, then high-debt countries (Japan, Greece, Italy, Belgium, Singapore, India, Argentina and Canada) will be more affected by contagion than the low-debt countries (Chile, Russia, Australia, Romania, China, New Zealand, Bulgaria and Ireland) during the subprime mortgage crisis and the Great Recession. The second crisis indicator that we consider is related to fiscal and current account balances. We hypothesize that, if a country has a larger either fiscal deficit or current account deficit, the probability it will suffer from a crisis will be higher (see also Burnside 2004; Edward, 2006; Rose and Spiegel 2012; and Manasse and Zavalloni 2013) . Tables 15 and 16 present the percentile of the fiscal account balance, current account balance and both account balance for 44 countries in 2006 and 2009, respectively. To investigate whether fiscal and current account balances can be treated as an early warning indicator of financial crisis, the selected 44 countries are also classified into two groups of weak and strong using threshold of the 80th percentiles. Table 15 shows that if the fiscal account balance is selected as a facilitator of contagion, then countries with weak fiscal account balance (Hungary, India, Greece, Portugal, Japan, Poland, Brazil and Italy) will be more affected by contagion than the countries with strong account balance (Norway, Russia, Chile, Singapore, Denmark, New Zealand, Hong Kong and Finland) during the subprime mortgage crisis and the Great Recession. The data for gross government debt is collected from IMF, World Economic Outlook Database. The data for domestic credit and external debt is collected from Datastream The data for gross government debt is collected from IMF, World Economic Outlook Database. The data for domestic credit and external debt is collected from Datastream The third crisis indicator that we consider is related to regional linkages. If a country's location has an economically relevant form of geographically proximity to the country in which the crisis originates, then we hypothesize that the country would be more likely affected by the crisis than others (see also Fry-McKibbin et al. 2014) . Therefore, it is expected that the North and South American countries should be more affected by the US-sourced crises (subprime mortgage crisis and the Great Recession crisis) and European countries more affected by the Greek-sourced crisis (European debt crisis). The last crisis indicator that we consider is related to a country's level of economic development. If there is a crisis in a developed/emerging country, it is hypothesized that other developed/emerging countries should be more likely to experience contagion than others. The development comparability indicator reflects similar characteristics for countries with similar market fundamentals, political environment and financial liberalization to the country in which the crisis originates (Goldstein 1998; Fry-McKibbin et al. 2014) . To investigate whether development comparability indicator can be treated The data is collected from IMF, World Economic Outlook Database. Both account balance consists of fiscal and current account balance as an early warning indicator of financial crisis, the selected 44 countries are classified into two groups of developed and emerging countries. 12 The market capitalization (cap) weight is summarized in Table 17 in order to calculate the crisis severity index. The table shows the percentages of total market cap for 43 countries in 2006 and 2009 (prior to the crisis) and illustrates that the crisis severity index is mainly dominated by Japan (14.67%), the UK (11.78%) and France (7.54%) in 2006, and mainly dominated by the USA (33%), China (10.96%) and Japan (7.39%) in 2009. Stock market linkages and financial contagion: a cobreaking analysis Financial contagion during COVID-19 crisis Computation and analysis of multiple structural change models A new approach to measuring financial contagion The pricing of sovereign risk and contagion during the European sovereign debt crisis Global crises and equity market contagion Economic vulnerability and resilience: concepts and measurements Currency crises and contingent liabilities International financial contagion in currency crises A regime switching skew-normal model of contagion Financial contagion in the laboratory: the cross-market rebalancing channel Estimation and moment recursion relations for multimodal distributions of the exponential family Running for the exit? International bank lending during a financial crisis What explains stock markets' vulnerability to the 2007-2008 crisis? In: Policy research working paper 5224 Are financial crises alike? Unravelling financial market linkages during crises The US current account deficit: gradual correction or abrupt adjustment? What has made the current financial crisis truly global? In: ECB working paper Is the international propagation of financial shocks non-linear? Evidence from the ERM Time-varying contemporaneous spillovers during the European debt crisis The Big C: identifying contagion No contagion, only interdependence: measuring stock market co-movements A new class of tests of contagion with applications Extremal Dependence Tests of Contagion Joint Tests of Contagion with Applications Measuring financial interdependence in asset markets with an application to eurozone equities Contagion and Global Financial Crises: Lessons from Nine Crisis Episodes Dependence structure and extreme comovements in international equity and bond markets Pure or Wake-up-call Contagion? Another Look at the EMU Sovereign Debt Crisis Contagion and trade: why are currency crises regional? The Asian financial crisis: causes, curses and systemic implications, policy analysis in international economics Detecting Shift-Contagion in Currency and Bond Markets Financial contagion on the international trade network Evaluating sovereign risk spillovers on domestic banks during the European debt crisis Transmission of volatility between stock markets Robust estimation, non-normalities and generalized exponential distributions Sovereign contagion in Europe: evidence from the CDS Market Contagion: macroeconomic models with multiple equilibria Credit traps and credit cycles Macro-finance linkages Rev Econ Dyn (forthcoming) Niţoi M, Pochea MM (2020) Time-varying dependence in European equity markets: a contagion and investor sentiment driven analysis Econometric issues in the analysis of contagion Growth in a time of debt From financial crash to debt crisis A decade of debt Measuring financial contagion: a copula approach Cross-country causes and consequences of the 2008 crisis: early warning Contagion of the Eurozone debt crisis Determinants of sovereign bond yield spreads and contagion in the peripheral EU countries Intraday dynamics of credit risk contagion before and during the euro area sovereign debt crisis: evidence from central europe Sources of contagion: is it finance or trade? Publisher's Note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations Acknowledgements We thank Yu-wei Luke Chu, Alan King, Robert Kirkby, Ilan Noy, Anella Munro, Yigit Saglam, Benjamin Wong and participants of the Brown Bag Seminar Series at Victoria University of Wellington, University of Otago, the Reserve Bank of New Zealand, the Society of Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics 23rd annual symposium, and the Society for Computational Economics and Finance 21st international conference. Hsiao and Morley acknowledge funding from the Macau SAR Government Higher Education Fund and ARC Grant DP130102950.The total market capitalization are reported as millions of US dollars. The data is collected from the World Bank of world development indicator. The US and Greece are not listed for the weight of market capitalization because they are selected as the country in which the crisis originates Conflict of interest The authors declare that they have no conflicts of interest.Ethical approval This article does not contain any studies with human participants or animals performed by any of the authors. This appendix contains four sections. Section B presents the results of information matrix derivations used for test statistic of joint co-moments. Section C presents the details of derivation for test statistic of joint co-moments. Section D conducts the sensitivity analysis of contagion tests by using Bai and Perron (2003) structural break tests to identify the pre-crisis and crisis dates. Section E provides the discussion of financial crisis indicators used in this paper. Consider the following bivariate normal distribution with higher-order co-moments given aswhereand h in (25).The multiple-channel test of contagion based on changes in correlation, coskewness and co-volatility in equation (12) is based on the null hypothesisUnder the null hypothesis of independence and bivariate normality, the maximum likelihood estimators of the unknown parameters are simply The data is collected from IMF, World Economic Outlook Database. Both account balance consists of fiscal and current account balance