key: cord-0934547-or00s37n authors: Tori, Risa; Tanimoto, Jun title: A study on prosocial behavior of wearing a mask and self-quarantining to prevent the spread of diseases underpinned by evolutionary game theory date: 2022-03-31 journal: Chaos Solitons Fractals DOI: 10.1016/j.chaos.2022.112030 sha: 9103eb13cd2feab14fa49c107f3b58830136911f doc_id: 934547 cord_uid: or00s37n In the wake of COVID-19, mask-wearing practice and self-quarantine is thought to be the most effective means of controlling disease spread. The current study develops an epidemiological model based on the SEIR process that takes into account dynamic human behavior toward those two preventive measures. In terms of quantifying the effect of wearing a mask, our model distinguishes itself by accounting for the effect of self-protection as well as the effect of reducing a potential risk to other individuals in different formulations. Each of the two measures derived from the so-called behavior model has a dynamical equation that takes into account the delicate balance between the cost of wearing a mask/self-quarantine and the risk of infection. The dynamical system as a whole contains a social dilemma structure because of whether to commit to preventing measures or seek the possibility of infection-free without paying anything. The numerical result was delivered along the social efficiency deficit, quantifying the extent to which Nash equilibrium has been improved to a social optimal state. PACS numbers Theory and modeling; computer simulation, 87.15.Aa; Dynamics of evolution, 87.23.Kg The Spanish Flu (1918) , SARS (2003) , Swine Influenza (2009), and MERS (2013) underline the ongoing threat from global pandemics, which break out intermittently and jeopardize the safety and security of the modern social system and everyday lives. The COVID-19 pandemic has resulted in unprecedented experiences such as city lockdowns, massive quarantines, and social isolations, economic downturns, forced "social distancing," and the collapse of medical systems. At the early stage of the COVID-19 pandemic, since no effective vaccine was at our hands (e.g., [1] ), the only possible strategy for protecting people was the implementation of massive quarantines or systematic social isolation (e.g., [2] [3] [4] [5] ). These were primitive tools, similar to those described in Giovanni Boccaccio's 14th-century "Decameron," or those encountered in 17th-century London, where William Shakespeare wrote "King Lear" while theaters were closed due to a pandemic. Besides quarantine, the wake of COVID-19 drives us to learn and experience various preventing measures to mitigate the influence from an infection wave such as travel restrictions (e.g., [6, 7] ), social distancing as one of the most high-visibility words (e.g., [8, 9] ), and alteration of daily habits like washing-hands, gargling and wearing a mask (e.g., [10, 11] ). Those are still regarded as the most important, the public health authority has consistently emphasized, to limit a large-scale outbreak, even though vaccination is now available. Among those, without a doubt, the most highlighted intervention-measure as non-pharmaceutical as well as non-medical is wearing a mask, despite some social controversy, such as in the United States. One advantageous feature is that wearing a mask not only reduces infection risk to the wearer himself/herself, but it also reduces potential risk to others around him/her if he/she is infectious with a lack of self-consciousness, which is referred to as an asymptomatic state. In line with this motivation, we built a compartment-type epidemiological model based on the SEIR process before [12] . Following that, the current study reports a new model that takes into account both intervention effects from self-quarantine as another important nonpharmaceutical measure and wearing a mask, where a so-called behavior model (e.g., [13] [14] [15] ) is introduced to account the dynamics of how individual decision making to commit self-quarantine or not, and commit wearing a mask or not, is introduced. Our framework's comprehensive system is made up of a compartment model based on the SEIR process with some modifications and a part of two dynamical equations depicting individuals' compliance to commit self-quarantine or not and wearing a mask or not based on the behavior model concept. In our analysis, we quantify not only final epidemic size (FES) but also average social payoff (ASP) accounting infection, quarantine, and mask costs (e.g., [16] [17] [18] ). Subsequently, we explore whether the social dilemma structure works behind the dynamical system by quantifying social efficiency deficit (SED; e.g., [19, 20] ). The remaining part of this paper is organized as below. Section 2 contains our model configuration, which includes not only the ODE (ordinary differential equation) formulation of our SEIR process but also the definitions of ASP and SED. Section 3 follows the results and discussion of numerical simulations. Section 4 contains our concluding remarks. We presume a communicable disease spreading like COVID-19 and influenza, of which dynamics obey to an SEIR process. We introduce individuals' behaviors of self-quarantine and wearing a mask. The present model is schematically shown in Fig. 1 , of which formulation is given as below: where, Q, S, E, I Pre , I, and R are fractions of self-quarantine, susceptible, exposed (i.e., infected but not infectious), pre-infected, infected, and recovered individuals, respectively. Note that I Pre means infected and infectious, and its infectious capability is discounted by the fraction of q as compared with I. Namely, I Pre means an asymptomatic infected (and infectious) state. I M . S M , E M , I Pre M , I M , and R M are respective counterparts in mask-wearing states vis-à-vis those without subscript M. Thus, q M indicates a discounted infectious capability when one, wearing a mask, is pre-infected. Because of the mask's efficacy as opposed to without mask state, q M is less than q, i.e., q M /q ≤ 1. We throughout presume q = 0.9. Meanwhile, η indicates the effectiveness of masks in reducing the risk of infection. It is worth noting that q M , as opposed to q, suggests the benefit of wearing a mask to those around a mask wearer, whereas η indicates the benefit of wearing a mask to the mask wearer himself. We would like to address the fact that the current model distinguishes the social benefit of wearing a mask into two factors: to the mask wearer and other people around him. Parameters β and γ are disease transmission rate and recovering rate, which are mutually correlated by the basic reproduction number R 0 = β/γ. In the present study, we throughout presume R 0 = 2.5 and γ = 1/3 referring to the commonly agreed values for seasonal influenza (e.g., [16] [17] [18] ). Parameter ε is state transferring rate from selfquarantine to susceptible, which implies people's incompliancy. Parameters α and τ are state transferring rates from exposed to pre-infected, and from pre-infected to infected. Parameter κ indicates the discounted physical contact rate by a symptomatic infected individual with a susceptible one. Such a symptomatic infected one may stay home and does not wear a mask anymore. Presuming a precautionary approach in the present study, we set κ = 1 throughout the main text. Besides, to check the robustness of our conclusion, we also compare the results under κ = 0.5 and κ = 0 and presents the results in Appendix. We throughout presume α = 1/6 and τ = 1/6. Unlike models that deal with repeated seasons (e.g., [16] [17] [18] ), the current model uses the framework of evolutionary game theory combined with the concept of Fermi pairwise update rule to quantify the dynamics of an individual's decision-making process emulating whether committing or not both preventing measures would not be suitable to apply. Hence, obeying to the mile-stone precursors ( [13] [14] [15] ), we rely on the concept of behavior model, which accounts for the time-varying state transfer flux from susceptible (S) to quarantine (Q), denote by x Q , and one from S to S M , denoted by x M . Let us introduce the following two dynamical equations: where m Q and m M are inertial efficiencies for respective equations. We presumed a small initial value (x Q = x M = 0.01) for each of those two that is positive, so that time-evolved x Q and x M always stay in [0,1]. Parameter ξ means the relative sensitivity resulting from taking selfquarantine for reducing self-quarantine itself due to its cost C Q , as compared with the infection risk quantified by the product of infection cost C I , and visible infected population I + I M for boosting self-quarantine. We throughout presume C I = 1 to normalize other costs, wearing a mask as C M , and self-quarantining as C Q . Note that δ means the counterpart parameter to ξ, which affects the dynamical equation of wearing a mask. Eq. (3) considers the influence from people's conformity effect (e.g., [21, 22] ), in which the flux transferring to mask wearing increases if the total population of wearing a mask (S M + E M + I M Pre + I M + R M ) is larger than that without a mask (Q + S + E + I Pre + I + R), vice-versa. A positive parameter w confomity controls its balance. So-called FES in the present model is quantified as below: where, the argument ∞, indicates an equilibrium (let us call Nash equilibrium (NE)) t = ∞. Meanwhile, ASP NE , can be evaluated by This account the total accumulated cost of individuals only paying to wear a mask (the first term), all individuals having experience of selfquarantine (the second term), individuals who were infected despite wearing a mask (the third term), and individuals paying disease cost (the fourth term) who should be called failed free-rider in terms of commitment of wearing a mask. To quantify the social dilemma structure working behind the present social-dynamical system, we introduce SED (e.g., [18, 19] ), which accounts for a gap of ASP between observed at NE, i.e., ASP NE , and at SO, i.e., ASP SO , (hereafter, called SO), indicating how the system can be improved in terms of ASP from an evolutionary final state (NE) to a socially ideal situation to attain a maximal ASP (SO) that could be realized if both evolutional process for x Q and x M are optimally controlled. Namely, it is given as below: Social optimal state SO = ( It is worthwhile to confirm that zero SED implies no social dilemma working (because NE is consistent with SO), whereas a nonzero positive SED indicates a certain amount of social quandary lurking behind. That is to say, a total social benefit could be improved if an appropriate external commitment, such as governmental interventions, were introduced, preventing people from being drawn to NE, which is a relatively low payoff state when compared to SO. In the present study, we thoroughly presume q = 0.9, δ = 0.2, ξ = 0.8, α = 1/6, τ = 1/6, γ = 1/3, β = R 0 • γ = 2.5/3=0.833, and m Q = m M = 1/6. After confirming that time-series of respective compartments show fair dynamics (not shown here), we are concerned about each equilibrium state of each compartment when varying both costs C Q and C M to explore how efficiently self-quarantine and wearing a mask helps to confine disease spreading. Fig. 2 displays the result of the basic case, where we presumed q M /q = 0.5, η = 0.8, w conformity = 0.01, and ε = 0.01. The parameter set of those is defined as the standard setting to identify and discuss the respective sensitivities as discussed later. The first row shows the fraction of each compartment (except for E) and FES observed at NE (panels (a) to (f)). The second row shows those observed at social optimal (SO) (panels (g) to (l)). In the third row, panels (m) and (n) show x M for SO and x Q for SO , respectively. Panels (o) and (p) show ASP SO and ASP NE , respectively. Finally, panel (q) displays SED. Let us confirm that this particular set of presumed parameters brings a high FES. In fact, panel (f) is entirely red-yellow, because of relatively less infected mask wearers (panel (e)) combined with relatively higher infected nonmask wearers (panel (d)). Concerning the risk of infection for nonmask wearers (panel (d)), both plausible tendencies are observed, more infected with the increase in quarantine cost, and more infected with the increase in mask cost. When compared to what the real world is showing, those are quite plausible. Turning to SED (panel (q)), we should discuss the following four regions: regions (i) to (iv) highlighted by each black solid-line rectangle. Region (i), where a lower mask cost irrespective to quarantine cost except for extremely low C Q is presumed, shows higher SED, since quite high ASP SO could be possible (see the same region in panel (o)). It reveals that there is a serious social dilemma hidden behind this social dynamics, where NE poorly stumbles (see panel (p)) despite much higher SO being enabled. The main reason for such a large difference is that SO realizes a much higher fraction of mask wearers (see panels (i) SM and (k) RM), whereas NE realizes a much lower fraction of mask wearers (see panels (c) SM and (e) RM). This is quite ironic because the lower cost of wearing a mask allows people to avoid developing the habit of mask wearing. Such a phenomenon was commonly observed in the so-called Vaccination Game (e.g., [15] [16] [17] ), in which an individual tends to avoid committing a vaccination to 'free-ride' on herd immunity, which means a sort of 'public good' brought about by others' positive attitude toward vaccination. To summarize, the region I is in a serious social dilemma because the social dynamics brought about by our behavior model result in less compliancy with wearing a mask. Region (ii) is found as another parameter combination with relatively higher SED, in which quite low self-quarantine cost is presumed. This is brought by almost analogous structure observed in the region (i) mentioned in the previous paragraph. In fact, ASP SO , observed the same region in panel (o), is quite high, whereas ASP NE is not so much. Why higher ASP SO being possible is eloquently explained by the intensive commitment of self-quarantine proved by larger x Q for SO (see the same region in panel (n)). Like the social dilemma brought by the provision of wearing a mask, this dilemma, brought by the provision of committing self-quarantine, drives people to try to free-ride on the shelter-effect provided by others' commitment of self-quarantine, which is ironic because the cost of quarantining is quite low. Region (iii), opposed to the previous regions (i) and (ii), is featured with quite lower SED, close to zero, which implies this region approximates none dilemma, or say Trivial game structure. This is evident because there is less gap between ASP SO (see the same region in panel (o)) and ASP NE (see panel (p)). Yet, note that those two ASPs with almost comparable values do have completely different meanings from the physical point of view. First off, concerning ASP NE , FES showed in panel (f), and mask-wearer fraction, suggested by the sum of panels (c) and (e), reveal that such a lower ASP is brought by twofold factors. One is quite a lot total social cost for wearing a mask, which is brought by the nonzero fraction of mask wearing (panels (c) and (e)) and quite higher C M . Another is the higher social disease cost brought by larger FES (panel (f)). In the case of ASP SO , almost no mask wearer confirmed in panels (i) and (k) leads to a much larger outbreak (confirmed in panel (l)), implying extremely high social disease cost while no mask cost overall. One interesting fact is that SO in the region (iii) suggests doing nothing to increase the mask-wearing fraction and instead allowing disease to spread freely to maximize the ASP. It is because the mask cost is high, almost comparable to the disease cost, although the mask efficacy is insufficient to eliminate the risk of infection. As a result, the optimization process suggests not wearing masks but rather doing nothing and allowing disease to spread freely. Nonetheless, the human decision making modeled by our behavior model leads people to wear masks to some extent. Region (iv) is featured with slightly higher SED than the region (iii) but is still smaller than regions (i) and (ii). A lower bit for ASP NE (see the same region in panel (p)) than ASP SO (see panel (o)) can be attributed to nonezero mask-wearer fraction (see panels (c) and (e)) bringing quite a lot total social cost for wearing a mask and higher FES (see panel (f)) bringing higher social disease cost, which is the same mechanism of lower ASP NE in the region (iii). However, the mechanism of what extent of ASP SO being brought in the region (iv) is different from that in the region (iii) as above. In region (iv), SO favors all individuals wearing a mask (see panel (i)), which enables to complete remission of infection (see panel (l)), which makes possible bit higher ASP SO than ASP NE due to none of the social disease cost. Aforementioned result is obtained when κ = 1. To test the robustness of the conclusion, we vary κ and present the corresponding result in Figs. A1 and A2. Figs. A1 and A2 show heat maps in the same format with the same parameters value as in Fig. 2. Figs. A1 and A2 are obtained under κ = 0.5 and κ = 0, respectively. Basically, varying κ does not significantly alter the picture observed in Fig. 2 . Yet, it is noteworthy to note that the setting of discounted physical contact rate (κ = 0.5 and κ = 0) incurs less SED when presuming a quite low self-quarantine cost and a quite low mask-wearing cost. Fig. 2 . We vary relative mask benefit to others (remind q meaning the discount factor of the risk by I Pre compared with I), q M /q of 0.5 in basic case to q M /q = 0.9, which implies less mask benefit to other individuals than that of the basic case due to q M = 0.81 and q = 0.9. With being concerned on the dotted-line rectangle in panel (q), we note that SED is less than that in the basic case (see Fig. 2(q) ). Observing the same region (gray dotted-line rectangle) in FES of NE (panel (f)) and FES of SO (panel (l)), we could confirm that FES of SO in Fig. 3(l) is much and x Q realizing social optimal, of which color bar also ranges from 0 to 1. Panels (o) and (p) show ASP observed at social optimal and Nash equilibrium, of which color bar ranges from −1.5 to 0. Panel (q) displays SED, of which color bar ranges from 0 to 1.5. We assumed; q M /q = 0.5, η = 0.8, w conformity = 0.01, and ε = 0.01. This is basic case. Concerning other model parameters, we assumed; q = 0.9, δ = 0.2, ξ = 0.8, α = 1/6, τ = 1/6, γ = 1/3, β = R 0 • γ = 2.5/3=0.833, κ = 1.0, and m Q = m M = 1/6, which are fully shared with following cases as below. higher than that in Fig. 2(l) . It attributes to less ASP SO in Fig. 3 (o) than that of the basic case in Fig. 2 on the ground of higher disease cost. Whereas ASP NE in Fig. 3 is almost the same as that in Fig. 2 . The fact that all panels (a)-(f) in Fig. 3 are less different from those in Fig. 2 , suggests that less mask benefit to others does not change the picture of evolution resulting from individuals' decision-making process based on the behavior model. In contrast, less mask benefit to others does lower ASP SO , because SO favors less fraction of mask wearing even letting FES climb up. Consequently, less mask benefit to others incurs less SED. That is because the SO is lowered, whereas NE does not change so much. The tendency observed in Section 3.2 concerning q M /q becomes more significant. Namely, quite lower SED vis-à-vis basic case appears, just because ASP SO becomes much less than that in Fig. 3 . It is brought by the fact that SO favors much less fraction of mask wearing even letting FES climb up much more observed in Fig. 3 . Let alone, "mask benefit to a wearer" directly affects his payoff. In contrast, "mask benefit to others" indirectly affects a mask wearer's payoff. Fig. 2 . We assumed; q M /q = 0.9, η = 0.8, w conformity = 0.01, and ε = 0.01. This is the case of less mask benefit to others as compared with basic case. Other parameters are same as basic case. Fig. 4 . Heat-map of each property along quarantine cost; C Q , and mask cost; C M . Panel explanation is same as Fig. 2 . We assumed; q M /q = 0.5, η = 0.2, w conformity = 0.01, and ε = 0.01. This is the case of less mask effect to a mask wearer as compared with basic case. Other parameters are same as basic case. This mechanical difference lets SO in Fig. 4 favor less fraction of mask wearer. In other words, SO reflects more sensitively to the parameter of "mask benefit to a wearer own" than that of "mask benefit to others." Following to the previous sections, Fig. 5 only varies w conformity from 0.01 (basic case) to 0.1, while Fig. 6 varies ε from 0.01 (basic case) to 0.1. Fig. 5 just slightly differs from Fig. 2 . Thus, the sensitivity from the conformity affect implemented in one of the dynamical equations of our behavior model Eq. (3), is less significant. Observing panels in the first row in Fig. 6 , we note deteriorated FES (panel (f)) than basic case (Fig. 2(f) ). The time-constant rate (ε) of transferring from Q backing to S, does widen disease spreading. Such tendency is likely because a larger ε makes less self-quarantined people at a certain time. We developed an epidemiological model based on the SEIR process that takes into account dynamic human behavior by simulating whether or not to wear a mask and commit self-quarantining. Fig. 2 . We assumed; q M /q = 0.5, η = 0.2, w conformity = 0.1, and ε = 0.01. This is the case of more conformity pressure for wearing a mask as compared with basic case. Other parameters are same as basic case. Fig. 6 . Heat-map of each property along quarantine cost; C Q , and mask cost; C M . Panel explanation is same as Fig. 2 . We assumed; q M /q = 0.5, η = 0.2, w conformity = 0.01, and ε = 0.1. This is the case of a larger rate of transferring from Q to S as compared with basic case. Other parameters are same as basic case. Our main concern is whether a social dilemma is hidden behind this Intervention Game, in which wearing a mask and selfquarantine are introduced as disease-prevention measures rather than vaccination. Numerical results reveal that the analysis on SED teaches there are rich and complex dynamics depending on mask and quarantine costs. Different ASP observed at the SO state yields a different picture of SED. The main cause of this phenomenon is that SO strongly favors a true maximum payoff. Thus, SO, under certain conditions, prefers a situation in which no mask is worn at all, even if it means allowing people to become infected, because infection may be cost-comparable to doing nothing to prevent infection. In contrast, human decisions modeled by our behavior model, quantified by observed properties at NE, have a sort of "inertial effect," which lets individuals take preventing measures to oppress disease spreading to some extent. CRediT authorship contribution statement Risa Tori: Conceptualization, Methodology, Software, Data curation, Writingoriginal draft, Visualization, Investigation. Jun Tanimoto: Supervision, Validation, Writingreview & editing. None. This study was partially supported by Grant-in-Aid for Scientific Research from JSPS, Japan, KAKENHI (Grant No. JP 19KK0262, JP 20H02314 and JP 20K21062) awarded to Professor Tanimoto. We would like to express our gratitude to them. Fig. 2 . We assumed; κ = 0, q M /q = 0.9, η = 0.8, w conformity = 0.01, and ε = 0.01. This is the case of less mask benefit to others as compared with basic case. Other parameters are same as basic case. R. Tori and J. Tanimoto Chaos, Solitons and Fractals 158 (2022) 112030 The emerging pandemic of coronavirus: the urgent need for public health leadership Final and peak epidemic sizes for SEIR models with quarantine and isolation How quarantine and social-distancing policy can suppress the outbreak of novel coronavirus in developing or under poverty level countries: a mathematical and statistical analysis Based on mathematical epidemiology and evolutionary game theory, which is more effective: quarantine or isolation policy? Evolutionary game theory modelling to represent the behavioural dynamics of economic shutdowns and shield immunity in the COVID-19 pandemic An evolutionary game modeling to assess the effect of border enforcement measures and socio-economic cost: exportimportation epidemic dynamics Modelling importations and exportations of infectious diseases via travelers A novel social distance model reveals the sidewall effect at bottlenecks social distancing intentions to reduce the spread of COVID-19: the extended theory of planned behavior Do they really wash their hands? Prevalence estimates for personal hygiene behaviour during the COVID-19 pandemic based on indirect questions To mask or not mask: modeling the potential for face mask use by the general public to curtail the COVID-19 pandemic Prosocial behavior of wearing a mask during an epidemic: an evolutionary explanation Imitation dynamics predict vaccinating behaviour Evolutionary game theory and social learning can determine how vaccine scares unfold Evolutionary game theory and social learning can determine how vaccine scares unfold Sociophysics approach to epidemics Evolutionary games with sociophysics: analysis of traffic flow and epidemics Fundamentals of evolutionary game theory and its applications Social efficiency deficit deciphers social dilemmas Interplay between cost and effectiveness in influenza vaccination uptake: vaccination game approach How does conformity promote the enhancement of cooperation in the network reciprocity in spatial prisoner's dilemma games? Conformity enhances network reciprocity in evolutionary social dilemmas