key: cord-0916312-b63bc0v5 authors: Funke, Michael; Terasa, Raphael title: Has Germany’s Temporary VAT Rates Cut as Part of the COVID-19 Fiscal Stimulus Boosted Growth? date: 2022-03-30 journal: J Policy Model DOI: 10.1016/j.jpolmod.2022.03.008 sha: f364159db693d10e4d1072fc988750cde15d8bf6 doc_id: 916312 cord_uid: b63bc0v5 On 3 June 2020, the German government announced a EUR 130 billion fiscal stimulus package to stimulate market demand and jumpstart the economy in the wake of the COVID-19 pandemic lockdown in the spring of 2020. The most prominent measure of this package is an unconventional fiscal policy in the form of a temporary VAT rates cut for six months, from 1 July to 31 December 2020. Employing a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) framework, we study the efficiency of the VAT tax rates cut for ameliorating the consequences of the pandemic recession. The simulation of the calibrated DSGE model yields a tax policy-induced real GDP increase of about 0.3 percentage points for 2020. The global economic landscape has changed dramatically since the turn of the year from 2019 to 2020. In December 2019, respiratory illness clusters due to a novel coronavirus emerged in Wuhan, the capital city of the mainland Chinese Hubei Province. The World Health Organization (WHO) named the disease 1 SARS- . In addition to the global health crisis, the COVID-19 pandemic has led to an extraordinary disruption in economic activity and has transformed the fiscal outlook. 1 The incentives to act quickly in the wake of this crisis have been substantial. Fiscal policy has been highlighted as the best available policy response tool (Baldwin and Weder di Mauro, 2020) . To ensure that firms can weather the storm without going into bankruptcy, governments rolled out easier borrowing terms and credit guarantees, collateral-free credit to small companies, supply-chain finance schemes, a suspension of tax payments, and/or provided direct financial assistance where needed. Furthermore, the job retention scheme ('Kurzarbeitergeld') has been a key component. Conceptually, 'Kurzarbeit' allows workers to remain formally with the firm even if not currently working. 2 After these initial emergency aid programmes, the question of how to rebound economies and stimulate aggregate demand has taken centre stage. Overturning years of fiscal orthodoxy and the so-called 'black zero' policy, the German government announced on 3 June 2020 a stimulus package worth EUR 130 billion. This followed a EUR 123 billion supplementary budget passed in March 2020. The centrepiece of the policy was a temporary VAT tax rates cut for six months, from 1 July to 31 December 2020. The regular VAT rate was reduced from 19 percent to 16 percent, and the reduced VAT rate from 7 percent to 5 percent. 3 The aim was to create a future path for increasing VAT taxes by stimulating aggregate demand today. 4 Upon what does the effect of the adopted VAT tax measure depend? First of all, the economic impact depends on the extent to which the VAT rates cut was passed on to consumers, thereby increasing their real income. The empirical literature shows that the tax incidence varies from sector to sector (Benedek et al., 2019; Benzarti and Carloni, 2019) . Moreover, the effect of VAT tax rate variations appears to be asymmetric. In particular, reductions in VAT tax rates are passed on to consumers to a lesser extent than increases (Benzarti et al., 2020) . On 1 January 2012 the VAT rate for restaurants and catering services in Sweden was reduced from 25 to 12 percent. The Swedish National Institute for Economic Research (2015) then determined an associated price pass-through of roughly 50 percent. Matching this, Falkenhall et al. (2020) employed register data from Swedish firms to show that the VAT tax rate reduction had a positive effect on restaurant turnover, employment, and profit margins. The first empirical study on the pass-through of the VAT tax rate reduction in the German fuel market was conducted by Montag et al. (2020) . They employed a dataset containing the universe of price changes at petrol stations in Germany and France for June and July 2020, and a difference-in-differences modelling strategy. The econometric results reveal that, depending on the type of fuel and the degree of 1 For further information on the global economic fallout of the COVID-19 pandemic and GDP forecasts for 2022 and 2023, see https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WEO/Issues/2021/10/12/world-economic-outlook-october-2021. 2 Most countries have relied on such labour market toolkits intended to help firms adjust working time and preserve jobs. See the IMF Policy Response Tracker on COVID-19 at https://www.imf.org/en/Topics/imf-and-covid19/Policy-Responses-to-COVID-19. For economic policy responses to the pandemic, see Taylor (2021) . 3 In addition to the regular tax rate, there is a reduced tax rate for basic necessities (Section 12 and Annex 2 UStG). 4 For the theoretical underpinnings of unconventional fiscal policies, see Correia et al. (2013) . competition, between 40 and 80 percent of the tax reduction was passed on to consumers. Fuest et al. (2020) observed an average price decline of about 2 percent in German supermarkets. These results indicate that the temporary reduction in VAT tax rates at supermarket checkouts was almost entirely passed on to consumers. Both aforementioned studies dealt with selected consumer goods. The first assessment of all goods and services in the CPI basket was presented by the Deutsche Bundesbank (2020, pp. 57-59) . According to this, 60% of the temporary VAT tax rates cut has been passed on to consumers. Furthermore, the efficiency of temporary tax rate cuts also depends on the strength of the substitution effect. Provided that the temporary measure is credible, consumers may bring forward their consumption (Feldstein, 2002; Christofzik et al., 2020) . 5 In this case, a larger effect could be expected for consumer durables (D'Acunto et al., 2016 (D'Acunto et al., , 2020 Büttner and Madzharova, 2019) . The empirical evidence on the temporary VAT rate reduction in the UK between 2008 and 2009 has revealed a resulting short-term economic stimulus, followed by a decline after the measure ended (Blundell, 2009; Crossley et al., 2014) . This is compatible with the postulated intertemporal shift in consumption. Our work relates to recently published dynamic economic models analysing the effects of the fiscal response to the pandemic, including those of Faria-e-Castro (2020) using a two-agent DSGE model and Bayer et al. (2020) using a Heterogeneous Agent New Keynesian (HANK) model framework. The Ifo Institute in Munich expected that the temporary German VAT rate reduction to increase GDP by 0.2 percentage points in 2020. 6 The German Council of Economic Advisors (Sachverständigenrat zur Begutachtung der gesamtwirtschaftlichen Entwicklung, 2020, pp. 114-117) has briefly summarised work examining the macroeconomic impact of the overall German stimulus package using an estimated DSGE, in the spirit of Drautzburg and Uhlig (2015) . In this analysis, the growth-enhancing effect of the VAT tax rates cut amounts to 0.3 percentage points in 2020. None of these works, however, models the temporary German VAT rate cut in such a multifaceted way as our study. Against this background, the reminder of the paper is organised as follows. Section 2 describes the DSGE modelling framework. Section 3 puts forward the calibration, while Section 4 presents the numerical model evaluation. Section 5 concludes with final thoughts and suggestions for further research. Isolating the effect of tax policies from complementary policies or other economic developments constitutes a significant challenge and requires cautious interpretations. To address this difficulty, a 5 Feldstein (2002) and Hall (2011) introduced the notion of unconventional fiscal policy measures at times of liquidity traps. Among several possible interventions, Feldstein (2002) proposed a series of pre-announced increases in VAT to generate consumer price inflation, and thus increase private spending via intertemporal substitution. 6 See https://www.bundestag.de/resource/blob/702942/2220ad3cf44aa03bafe4e9847e49ca21/Prof-Dr-Dr-h-c-Clemens-Fuest-data.pdf. J o u r n a l P r e -p r o o f growing strand of the literature employs DSGE modelling frameworks. Given their micro foundation and forward-looking nature, while also preserving the transparency of any resulting policy analysis, DSGE models present a useful tool for policy analysis generally and unconventional fiscal policy analysis in particular. For this reason, this section models the temporary German VAT rate reduction using a DSGE framework. Doing so can facilitate the design and activation of countercyclical policies dampening the pandemic's negative consequences. Time is discrete, quarterly, and infinite. The economy is populated by a representative household that chooses consumption and hours worked in order to maximise its discounted lifetime utility according to the constant relative risk aversion (CRRA) utility function: (1) Where > 0 determines two attributes: it is the coefficient of relative risk aversion and also determines the intertemporal elasticity of substitution, given by 1 ⁄ . If is big, then the household is said to be risk averse. If is zero, then the household is said to be risk-neutral. The larger the value of , the more intense the household's interest in maintaining a smooth consumption profile. ∈ (0,1) is the discount factor, is the inverse Frisch elasticity, is the labour disutility parameter, and is an intertemporal preference shock. 7 The parameter 0 < ℎ < 1 measures the degree of habit formation. Habit persistence captures intertemporal complementarity in consumption, which strengthens the smoothing motive relative to the time-separable CRRA case. The representative household maximises the utility function subject to the inter-temporal budget constraints: where denotes the consumption bundle of retail goods, denotes the price index for retail goods, is the capital stock, is the labour income, is the real gross return on capital, Ψ represents the profits of the production sector of the economy, and are lump-sum taxes. Note that since households own firms, they receive firm profits. Finally, as in many simple New Keynesian models, we assume that there exists a single financial asset each period, a one-period riskless nominal debt instrument, the interest rate on which is also the central bank's policy instrument. Furthermore, investment decisions are subject to convex capital adjustment costs and thus capital accumulates according to the law of motion: Where ∈ (0,1) is the capital depreciation rate, is the investment adjustment cost parameter, and = ( / −1 ) denotes the growth rate of investment. The first-order conditions of the optimisation problem with respect to , , , and are: Where denotes the Lagrange multiplier associated with the budget constraint, while is the Lagrangian multiplier associated with the capital stock and represents the shadow price of capital (Tobin's ). Furthermore, = / −1 denotes the inflation rate. Following Voigts (2017) , the household consumption bundle is composed of differentiated retail good varieties ( ). Varieties are imperfect substitutes and are aggregated with the standard Dixit-Stiglitz (1977) aggregator: Where is the elasticity of substitution between retail varieties. The associated demand function for retail goods is: Where ( ) is the price of retail variety and is the aggregate retail price index (11) The assumed production process is composed of three distinct sub-processes. The first stage consists of monopolistically competitive intermediate good producers who sell the intermediates to representative final consumption good producers in the second stage. Following Voigts (2017) and in contrast to conventional DSGE models, a further third production stage exists beyond that. At this final production stage, retail firms repackage the homogeneous consumer goods and thus convert the homogeneous consumer goods into differentiated retail goods. The resulting imperfect competition on the retail goods market then allows for the modelling of different degrees of pass-through for the VAT tax rates cuts by the firms to the consumers. 8 Intermediate goods firm ∈ [0,1] produces its differentiated intermediate good ( ) using capital ( ) and labour ( ) through a Cobb-Douglas technology: Where denotes the stochastic total factor productivity, and (1 − ) represents the share of capital (labour) in the production function. The first-order conditions for capital and labour imply Where marginal cost is Intermediate good firms are subject to a Calvo-pricing mechanism (1983), i.e., only a share (1 − ) of firms are allowed to re-adjust prices each period (the green-light-red-light approach). A firm that is randomly allowed to re-adjust prices maximises the expected sum of discounted profit: Where Λ is the stochastic discount factor. The optimal intermediate good price ( ) * is given by the first order condition of the following maximisation problem: Equation (17) implies that the optimal intermediate good firm price ( ) * is a mark-up over the marginal cost. J o u r n a l P r e -p r o o f Stiglitz (1977) aggregator: Where determines the elasticity of substitution between intermediate goods. The cost-efficient bundling of intermediates goods is: Where is the aggregate price index for the final good: The retail firms ∈ [0,1] buy the homogenous final goods and repackage them. Subsequently, they sell the created differentiated goods with a mark-up on the price: In accordance with the German VAT legislation, we introduce a tax-inclusive value added tax levied upon retail firms. 9 A tax-inclusive system means that the tax liability is included in the tax base. The implication is that a retail firm ∈ [0,1] only receives after-tax revenues of the following per unit: Analogously to intermediate goods firms, retailers are also subject to a Calvo (1983) pricing mechanism in which only a share 1 − of randomly chosen retailers can optimally re-adjust prices each period. When deciding on the mark-up , re-adjusting retail firms solves the maximisation problem: Plugging in ( ) = (1 + ( )) yields the first-order condition of the optimisation problem for the optimal mark-up * : Where is the elasticity of substitution between retail varieties, implying that the market power of retail The associated aggregate retail price index is given in equation (11) above. Profits of the monopolistically competitive intermediate firms and retail firms are paid out to households. Aggregate profits are given by: The balance of the first three terms provides the profits of the intermediate goods firms. The final term provides the profits of the retail firms. The government issues risk-free one period bonds that return the interest rate . In order to finance public spending and debt service −1 expenditures, the government raises a value added tax and lump sum taxes . Thus, the fiscal authority's period-by-period budget constraint has the following form: J o u r n a l P r e -p r o o f Following Coenen et al. (2012) and Born et al. (2013) , among others, the fiscal instruments are assumed to follow the prescriptions of simple feedback rules, with the feature that taxation responds to deviations of government debt from its steady-state level in an effort to stabilise public debt. 10 It is in this regard that the government is assumed to follow the requirements of the debt brake. 11 In particular, the following rule applies: Where −8 /4 −8 denotes the lagged debt-to-GDP ratio, denotes the steady-state level of lump sum taxes, and > 0 denotes the responsiveness of the tax rule to deviations in the debt-to-GDP ratio. 12 Note, however, that the method of financing government spending, at least in the short term, does not have significant effects. This is because taxation does not respond on impact and otherwise evolves slowly. The VAT tax rate is calculated as the weighted average of the standard rate and the reduced rate on products deemed necessities of life. The overall VAT tax rate is thus given as: where (1 − ) represents the share of consumption goods taxed with the standard rate (reduced rate). As is standard in the New Keynesian literature, we assume that the central bank adheres to an inflation targeting policy in the spirit of Taylor (1993) . Thus, monetary policy reacts to deviations of inflation and output from their respective steady states according to: Where is the monetary policy rate, is the inflation rate, is output, is the interest rate smoothing parameter, and and are the responsiveness parameters for inflation and the output gap, respectively. 13 The instantaneous interest rate reaction reflects the fact that monetary policy is enacted with ease and immediacy. Finally, the log of the technology shock and the demand shock are assumed to follow first-order autoregressive, or AR(1), processes. where ~(0, 2 ) and ~(0, 2 ). The final goods market is in equilibrium when the supply side of the economy is equal to the demand side of the economy, which implies that the final good production is equal to aggregate consumption , aggregate investment , and aggregate public spending . The above toolbox provides the theoretical underpinnings for this study's quantitative evaluation of the temporary VAT reduction. The model can now be employed to investigate the immediate, transitional, and long-term effects of the German government's efforts to stimulate the economy after the COVID-19 shock. 13 In view of the fact that the zero lower bound has been reached in many countries, the interest rate in the monetary policy response function can also be interpreted as the shadow short rate, reflecting the joint influence of conventional and unconventional monetary policy measures. See https://sites.google.com/view/jingcynthiawu/shadow-rates. J o u r n a l P r e -p r o o f The baseline model parameter values in Table 1 were chosen to match their empirical counterparts and to be consistent with the quarterly frequency. Where possible, an attempt has been made to define parameters specific to the German economy. For the most part, we employ standard parameters as found in the literature, and thus our discussion can be brief. Following Drygalla et al. (2020) , the intertemporal elasticity of substitution is set to 1. The habit persistence parameter ℎ is set to 0.68 following the estimates of Pytlarczyk (2005) (2015) in order to match a steady-state mark-up for retail firms of 1.1. Both shock persistence parameters are set at 0.33, implying a pandemic shock persistence of about six quarters. The model calibration is thus guided by the assumption that the pandemic will lead to a -type recession. Alternatively, it could be said that the calibration is motivated by the anticipation of progressively effective pharmaceutical interventions for the pandemic from mid-2021 onwards. Turning to the fiscal side, the German sovereign debt-to-GDP ratio /4 is set to 0.62, and the steady state government consumption-to-GDP ratio / is set to 0.203. In the case of the tax responsiveness parameter , we follow the European Commission's target under the excessive deficit procedure. This requires that a debt-to-GDP ratio above 60% be reduced by one twentieth each year. According to this narrative, we assume = 1 80 = ⁄ 0.0125. The regular VAT rate is set to 0.19 and the reduced VAT rate is set to 0.07, matching the prevailing tax rates prior to the 2020 temporary tax cut. The share of goods subject to the regular VAT tax rate is set to = 0.865 following Bach and Isaak (2017). Finally, the chosen monetary policy parameters are = 1.5, = 0.125, and = 0.8, respectively. This ensures adherence to the Taylor principle. This means that while inflation targeting is the main objective, output fluctuations (and the level of the output gap) also feature in monetary policy decisions. Armed with our modelling framework in the New Keynesian tradition, we now turn to the policy evaluation. The temporary VAT rate reduction is modelled as a non-anticipated measure. On the contrary, the end of the measure is assumed to be known and credible. Since the New Keynesian model is inherently forward-looking, we employ the perfect foresight rational expectations solution method. The basic idea is that agents have perfect foresight of the path of the VAT rate and of all shocks until an arbitrary point in time. This feature makes it suitable for the announced duration of the tax reduction, J o u r n a l P r e -p r o o f limited to six months. After reverting to the initial tax rates, all the shocks are zero and the solution method is standard. 15 Therefore, the system can be solved backwards from this point. The algorithm takes into consideration the special structure of the Jacobian matrix in dynamic models with forwardlooking agents. The details of the algorithm can be found in Juillard (1996) . Figure 1 plots the impulse responses of key model variables in response to the temporary VAT rate cut. Specifically, a simultaneous decrease of 15.7% of the regular VAT rate and 28% of the reduced VAT rate for six months is assumed. Due to perfect foresight, agents presume that the VAT rate cut is temporary and that the VAT rate will return to initial levels after six months. Figure 1 illustrates the isolated effect of the VAT rate cut in the German stimulus package. The responses are broadly intuitive, with a lower VAT rate inducing positive consumption, investment, and labour supply responses, which, in turn, increase output by 0.3 percentage points in 2020. The CPI inflation rate initially decreased and then increased again. Furthermore, it is evident that firms also benefitted from the temporary VAT rate tax cut and thus stimulated demand. Finally, the increase in public debt is rather long-lasting, as the resulting increase in lump-sum taxation occurs with a lag of eight quarters. In terms of magnitude, the reactions are comparable with existing estimates. The Ifo Institute in Munich has predicted that the temporary German VAT tax rates reduction will increase GDP by 0.2 percentage points in 2020, while the German Council of Economic Advisers has estimated that the tax stimulus will increase German GDP by 0.3 percentage points in 2020. 16 An critical question is whether and to what extent the model predicts an intertemporal pull-forward effect in consumption. In other words, will the temporary VAT tax rates cut incentivise households to bring consumption forward, jump-starting and helping the economy to exit the COVID-19 recession? Does the baseline model support this conjecture? Figure 1 reveals that in the baseline model calibration, such a response is hardly visible. In other words, an intertemporal shift in consumption is quantitatively of minor importance. 17 Section 4.2 below offers a detailed sensitivity analysis of this transmission channel. 15 Thus, this paper relates to the literature on foresight and anticipation in fiscal policy. Amongst others, important contributions include Leeper et al. (2012) and Mertens and Ravn (2012) . To ensure that a perfect foresight solution exists, the DSGE model has to be stable under perfect foresight. See, e.g., Boucekkine (1995) . 16 There are well-founded reasons to believe that these steady-state deviations represent a lower limit. Numerous studies indicate that expansionary fiscal policy shocks unfold greater effects during recessions (see, e.g., Berg, 2019 and Gechert and Rannenberg, 2018) . 17 This finding is certainly no surprise. Non-expert household surveys from the GfK consumer research association (https://www.gfk.com/en-gb/home) in summer 2020 have revealed that only a limited number of consumers planned to bring forward purchases. See https://www.gfk.com/de/presse/29-prozent-der-deutschen-planengroessere-anschaffungen-vorzuziehen. An analogous conclusion results from the SAFE Leibniz Institute for Financial Research 'Household Crisis Barometer', providing representative in-depth insights into the purchasing behaviours and expectations of German consumers. See https://safefrankfurt.de/fileadmin/user_upload/editor_common/Policy_Center/SAFE_Policy_Letter_87_final.pdf. Note: Impulse responses are reported as percentage deviations from the non-stochastic steady state with the exception of the inflation rates, which are reported as annualised percentage-point deviation. The evidence presented in Figure 1 brings more clarity to the debate on the effectiveness of the temporary VAT tax rates cut. Despite existing reservations, the impulse response functions demonstrate that the temporary tax policy measure has mitigated the consequences of the pandemic. A natural follow-up question is to ask how a longer-term VAT rate reduction would work as compared to the six-month measure. While the impressive German real GDP turnaround in 2020:Q3 was a welcome rebound, further waves of the pandemic left Germany's economy vulnerable to setbacks. 18 Against this background, Figure 2 plots the impulse responses following a temporary VAT tax rates cut with a length of 2, 4 and 6 quarters, respectively. All other parameters are unaltered. In particular, three lessons can be learnt from this policy experiment. First, if the tax cuts had been implemented over a longer period of time, then the growth in consumption would be longer lasting and thus more expansionary overall. Second, in the case of more permanent tax cuts, the consumption impact would occur with a time lag. As is intuitively reasonable, in the case of a short-lasting VAT tax rate reduction, agents squeeze in their expenditures while the VAT tax rate cut exists. Third, due to the convex adjustment costs, a longer time span for the tax measure would lead to a more pronounced increase in investment. In the interest of a swift recovery after the initial pandemic lockdown in spring 2020, a prolongation of the tax measure would thus have been associated with drawbacks. In a nutshell, the guiding principle can be summarised with the phrase 'make hay while the sun shines'. Note: The figures plot the impulse responses following a temporary VAT rate cut with a length of two quarters (solid red lines), four quarters (dashed blue lines), and six quarters (solid black lines), respectively. Impulse responses are reported as percentage deviations from the non-stochastic steady state with the exception of the inflation rates, which are reported as annualised percentage-point deviation. As a third exercise within the model, we consider the joint impact of the initial COVID-19 shock and the temporary VAT tax rates cut. This requires the introduction of the pandemic shock into the DSGE model. The COVID-19 shock has specific characteristics. Whether the COVID-19 pandemic is primarily a demand or supply shock is one of macroeconomics' ongoing questions. In response to the COVID-19 pandemic, governments around the world used non-pharmaceutical interventions and lockdowns which led to disruptions in international supply chains and the shutdown of entire sectors of the global economy. At the same time, consumers voluntarily reduced their consumption of goods and services involving high levels of physical contact with other people. This, combined with uncertainty about the evolution of the pandemic, has led to a reduction in demand for goods and services across the board. For this reason, most economists agree that the economic effects of the pandemic combine aspects of aggregate supply and aggregate demand shocks (Baldwin and Weder di Mauro, 2020) . Using survey-based forecast revisions to resolve the identification problem for the structural shocks, Bekaert et al. (2020) have attributed two thirds of the decline in US GDP in 2020:Q1 to a negative shock to aggregate demand. In contrast, regarding the staggering decline in US GDP in 2020:Q2, they have estimated two thirds of that decline were due to a reduction in aggregate supply. Balleer et al. (2020) have investigated planned price changes among German firms to infer the relative importance of supply and demand shocks during the COVID-19 pandemic. The micro data used are from the Ifo Business Climate Survey database. All in all, the results suggest that demand and supply shocks account for a significant share of the fall in GDP. However, the demand shocks exhibit a somewhat greater significance. 19 A contributing factor to this difference has been the declining demand for contact-intensive goods and services due to individuals' responses to the COVID-19 risk. Headline CPI inflation and core inflation (excluding energy and food) in Germany took a recession-induced nosedive. 20 When the lockdown measures in spring were eased, inflation recovered somewhat but remained below the pre-pandemic level. This points to the relevance of demand shocks. Thus, we assume that the downturn has been triggered by demand and supply shocks at a ratio of 70:30. 21 Figure 3 shows the exercise of simulating the pandemic-induced recession. The weighted sum of both structural shocks leads to a 5.1% percentage point decline of German GDP, as predicted by the Sachverständigenrat zur Begutachtung der gesamtwirtschaftlichen Entwicklung (2020) for the year 2020. The exercise also sheds light on the amplification and transmission processes during the economic downturn as well as the subsequent recovery. 22 In the following, we will use this simulated benchmark COVID-19 recession as the reference allocation in the welfare analysis. Note: The impulse responses are reported as percentage deviations from the non-stochastic steady state with the exception of the inflation rates, which are reported as annualised percentage-point deviation. In this section, we look at how the response of the economy to the temporary VAT tax rates cut varies when considering different values of certain parameters. The different parameters we take a closer look at are the household's intertemporal elasticity of substitution 1 ⁄ , the Calvo parameter of retail firms , and the habit formation parameter ℎ. All other parameters conform to their respective baseline calibrations. The intertemporal decision theory outlined above implies consumption smoothing over the consumer's life cycle. To illustrate the dependence on key model parameters, Figure 4 provides the impulse responses for different intertemporal elasticities of substitution 1 ⁄ . The recent literature has underlined the considerable uncertainty regarding the estimation of the elasticity of intertemporal substitution. Calibrations greater than 1.0 are inconsistent with the bulk of the empirical evidence. Note: The figures depict the impulse responses for an intertemporal elasticity of substitution 1 = 1 1.5 = 0.67 ⁄ ⁄ (solid black lines), the baseline calibration 1 = 1 1 = 1 ⁄ ⁄ (dashed blue lines), and 1 = 1 0.5 = 2 ⁄ ⁄ (solid red lines). The impulse responses are reported as percentage deviations from the nonstochastic steady state with the exception of the inflation rates, which are reported as annualised percentage-point deviation. A comparison of the different model calibrations in Figure 4 clearly illustrates that the intertemporal elasticity of substitution characterises the consumer's willingness to preor postpone consumption. Consumers with a high elasticity of intertemporal substitution are more willing to substitute consumption over time in view of the temporary VAT tax rate cut. One objective of the temporary tax policy measure was to create a future path of higher VAT tax rates, and thus stimulate more immediate aggregate demand. The sensitivity of the consumption dynamics on preferences apparent in Figure 4 poses the question of what a reasonable model calibration actually is. Unfortunately, the elasticity of intertemporal substitution is a parameter which is notoriously difficult to estimate. A thorough meta-analysis of the elasticity of intertemporal substitution estimates across 104 countries has been carried out by Havranek et al. (2015) . One of their main conclusions was that, in representative agent models, it is difficult to argue against values for 1⁄ that are below one. For Germany, too, values 1 < 1 ⁄ are ascertained. This suggests that the parameter 1 = 1 ⁄ in the baseline specification actually constitutes an upper bound. Conversely, this means that unconventional fiscal policy is ineffective for bringing consumption forward. A closely-related question is that of habit formation significance, which is governed by the habit formation parameter ℎ ∈ [0,1]. A consumer with more pronounced habit formation is less willing to substitute consumption over time. We calibrated the model for ℎ = 0.5, ℎ = 0.6, and ℎ = 0.68, respectively. 23 The associated impulse response functions are presented in Figure 5 . As expected, consumers with a less pronounced habit persistence attitude are more willing to substitute consumption over time in view of the temporary tax cut. Note: The figure depicts the impulse responses for ℎ = 0.5 (solid red lines), ℎ = 0.6 (dashed blue lines), and the baseline specification ℎ = 0.68 (solid black lines). The impulse responses are reported as percentage deviations from the non-stochastic steady state with the exception of the inflation rates, which are reported as annualised percentage-point deviation. As another example of how the model works, we consider the VAT pass-through in more detail. In the model, retail firms set prices in a staggered fashion. Complementing the solution of the baseline model, Figure 6 provides a sensitivity analysis regarding the retail sector Calvo parameter. Given the short-term nature of the VAT tax rates cut, this is especially relevant for the fiscal policy transmission process. As a result of Calvo pricing in the New Keynesian model, only 1 − percent of firms can optimally adjust prices in each period. The imminent consequence is that the pass-through degree and the retail sector Calvo parameter are inversely related. In other words, larger parameters initially diminish the expansionary consumption impact of VAT policy; after the change-back to the higher VAT tax rates from January 2021 onwards, the expansionary effects will be more persistent for smaller Calvo parameters . These two opposing effects are clearly visible in Figure 6 . As in the other graphs, there are also numerous general equilibrium feedback effects. Note: The figures depict the impulse responses for the baseline parameter = 0.4 (solid red lines), = 0.6 (dashed blue lines), and = 0.6 (solid black lines). The impulse responses are reported as percentage deviations from the non-stochastic steady state with the exception of the inflation rates, which are reported as annualised percentage-point deviation. In closing, one can say that, like any other model simulation, these sensitivity analyses are challengeable. However, they do illustrate the locations of the most neuralgic points. In order to compare welfare under different scenarios, both a welfare criterion and a reference scenario are required. We chose the pandemic recession scenario in Figure 3 as our reference allocation. The metric that we use is the consumption equivalent change in welfare of the representative household. Formally, Table 2 reports the value of that solves the following: The resulting welfare gains/losses over different horizons are given in Table 2 . Time, measured in quarters, is given in the first column. In each case, we report the welfare losses/gains in percentages conditional upon the pandemic-induced crisis scenario in Figure 3 . This allows us to get a sense of the welfare gains of the unconventional VAT tax cut policy compared to the total losses of the crisis. The net welfare losses in the third column are the difference between the first and second columns. Table 2 provides two findings in particular. First, we see that the welfare losses of the pandemic-induced recession were substantial. 24 Second, the calculations show the positive welfare effect of the unconventional temporary VAT tax measure. This paper provides insight into how the temporary VAT tax policy measure affected the German economy. What message does the policy experiment offer for other countries? The modelling exercise indicates that the unconventional temporary reduction in VAT increased German GDP by 0.3 percentage points in 2020. We have also uncovered differing economic adjustment processes as a result of different model calibrations. How realistic is this VAT tax policy evaluation? From a modelling perspective, two reservations can be made. First, the modelling framework assumes rational expectations on the part of all decision makers, which enhances the effectiveness of state-dependent fiscal policies. Yet the grounds for assuming rational expectations may be questionable. 25 Since the triggering pandemic marks uncharted territory, one can doubt whether agents have rational expectations as a result of learning from experience. Second, the VAT tax is highly regressive. Therefore, a VAT rate reduction favours lower-and middle-income households and thus has income distribution effects. A model theoretical analysis of such distributional effects would require a HANK model framework (see, e.g., Cantore and Freund, 2020) . In such a model, the response of consumption to the pandemic and the temporary fiscal shock would depend on three key dimensions of households' heterogeneity: their portfolios, their exposure to aggregate fluctuations, and their marginal propensities to consume. We leave such model extensions adding further heterogeneity on the household side to future research. Inflation Persistence and Price-Setting Behaviour in the Euro Area -A Summary of the IPN Evidence Consumer Responses to the COVID-19 Crisis: Evidence from Bank Account Transaction Data (S)Cars and the Great Recession Banks, Sovereign Risk and Unconventional Monetary Policies Economics in the Time of COVID-19: A New eBook, www.VoxEU.org Demand or Supply? Price Adjustment during the Covid-19 Pandemic The Coronavirus and the Great Influenza Pandemic: Lessons from the 'Spanish Flu' for the Coronavirus Potential Effects on Mortality and Economic Activity The Coronavirus Stimulus Package: How Large Is the Transfer Multiplier? Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Effects of COVID-19: A Real-time Analysis Estimating VAT Pass Through Who Really Benefits from Consumption Tax Cuts? Evidence from a Large VAT Reform in France What Goes Up May Not Come Down: Asymmetric Incidence of Value-Added Taxes Business Uncertainty and the Effectiveness of Fiscal Policy in Germany Assessing the Temporary VAT Cut Policy in the UK Fiscal News and Macroeconomic Volatility An Alternative Methodology for Solving Nonlinear Forward-Looking Models Unit Sales and Price Effects of Pre-Announced Consumption Tax Reforms: Micro-Level Evidence from European VAT Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework Workers, Capitalists, and the Government: Fiscal Policy and Income (Re)distribution Tracking the COVID-19 Crisis with High-Resolution Transaction Data Macroeconomic Effects of the Anticipation and Implementation of Tax Changes in Germany: Evidence from a Narrative Account Fiscal Policy and the Great Recession in the Euro Area What Can Survey Forecasts Tell Us About Information Rigidities? Information Rigidity and the Expectations Formation Process: A Simple Framework and New Facts Unconventional Fiscal Policy at the Zero Bound Using a Temporary Indirect Tax Cut as a Fiscal Stimulus: Evidence from the UK Unconventional Fiscal Policy to Exit the COVID-19 The Effect of Unconventional Fiscal Policy on Consumption Expenditure Price and Volume Effects of VAT Increase on 1 Wirkung der vorübergehenden Mehrwertsteuersenkung auf die Verbraucherpreise Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity Fiscal Stimulus and Distortionary Taxation The Effects of Fiscal Policy in an Estimated DSGE Model: The Case of the German Stimulus Packages During the Great Recession Direct Impact of Changes in Administered Prices and Indirect Taxes on Euro Area HICP Developments The Impact of Developments in Indirect Taxes and Administered Prices on Inflation Impact of VAT Reform on Swedish Restaurants: A Synthetic Control Group Approach Supply and Demand in Disaggregated Keynesian Economies with and Application to the Covid-19 Crisis Fiscal Policy during a Pandemic The Role for Discretionary Fiscal Policy in a Low Interest Rate Environment Die Preiseffekte der Mehrwertsteuersenkung in deutschen Supermärkten: Eine Analyse für mehr als 60 000 Produkte Which Fiscal Multipliers are Regime-Dependent? A Meta-Regression Analysis Macroeconomic Implications of COVID-19: Can Negative Supply Shocks Cause Demand Shortages? The Long Slump Cross-Country Heterogeneity in Intertemporal Substitution The Ifo DSGE Model for the German Economy Dynare: A Program for the Resolution and Simulation of Dynamic Models with Forward Variables Through the Use of a Relaxation Algorithm What Drives the German Current Account? And How Does it Affect Other EU Members States? Quantitative Effects of Fiscal Foresight Scarred Consumption Empirical Evidence on the Aggregate Effects of Anticipated and Unanticipated US Tax Policy Shocks Indebted Demand Are Temporary Value-Added Tax Reductions Passed on to Consumers? Evidence from Germany's Stimulus An Estimated DSGE Model for the German Economy within the Euro Area Sachverständigenrat zur Begutachtung der gesamtwirtschaftlichen Entwicklung (2020) Jahresgutachten 2020/21: Corona-Krise gemeinsam bewältigen, Resilienz und Wachstum stärken Short and Long Run Effects of Reduced VAT for the Restaurant Industry Discretion Versus Policy Rules in Practice The Impact of the Coronavirus on Economic Policy and the Economy Intertemporal Substitution in Consumption: A Literature Review Estimating Mark-Ups and the Effect of Product Market Regulations in Selected Professional Services Sectors: A Firm Level Analysis Revisiting the Effect of VAT Changes on Output: The Importance of Pass-Through Dynamics