key: cord-0824363-9ma2y34a authors: Sato, Hitoshi title: Industrialization of Developing Economies in the Global Economy with an Infectious Disease date: 2021-05-06 journal: Dev Econ DOI: 10.1111/deve.12280 sha: 8aafe25f7d906e1156fd101197ea661ddd5d49b3 doc_id: 824363 cord_uid: 9ma2y34a Manufacturing has long been the center of industrialization strategies for poor developing countries. This article first investigates the effects of labor supply constraints on industrialization, which may have been caused by the coronavirus disease 2019 (COVID‐19). Then, it examines how manufacturing automation could affect industrialized developing economies based on the premise that manufacturers may accelerate production automation in response to the COVID‐19 pandemic. The model predicts declines in developing economies' manufacturing competitiveness and a heterogeneous pattern of recovery from the COVID‐19 recession. In comparison, developing economies with large manufacturing bases would recover relatively quickly, whereas those with weaker manufacturing bases would suffer from a long‐term decline and manufacturing contraction trends (undesirable deindustrialization). Manufacturing automation can enhance economic welfare, causing a contraction in the unproductive nontradable good (service) sector. However, with low labor mobility, the welfare effect is ambiguous, thereby widening the wage gap between skilled and unskilled labor. T HE coronavirus disease 2019 has forced drastic changes in our economic activities, causing serious health, economic, and social crises. Private firms reconsider how they could operate their business safely in the global economy, which is riskier than previously thought. Governments have struggled to balance controlling the spread of the COVID-19 while keeping I would like to thank two anonymous referees for constructive comments and suggestions. In addition, I am grateful to Kyoji Fukao and other seminar participants at IDE-JETRO for insightful discussions. Responsibility for opinions and errors lie with the author. their economies alive. As in many other difficult times, the highest costs fall on those least prepared to bear them, which is particularly true in developing economies. How would the COVID-19 pandemic affect the industrialization of developing economies? Manufacturing has long been the center of industrialization strategies for poor developing countries, but their performance seems to be dichotomous. That is, some countries (mainly in Asia) have successfully developed manufacturing sectors, whereas others have been sluggish and remained in nonindustrial states. The main goal of this article is to shed light on this industrialization heterogeneity and potential effects of the pandemic on industrialization. To address this issue, this article proposes a small open economy model with multiple sectors, based on Rodríguez-Clare (1996) . This article first considers conditions for industrialization of developing economies in an open economy setting. Then, we examine how the pandemic would affect the identified conditions while focusing on labor supply constraints, which is one of the most evident difficulties caused by the pandemic through social distancing. The novelty of the model is twofold. First, a nontradable final good (service) sector is introduced. The majority of the workers in developing economies are informal employment, which is largely engaged in nontradable final goods and services. Hence, the introduction of the nontradable sector enables us to examine the potential effect of the pandemic on one of developing economies' remarkable traits. 1 Second, the supply of skilled labor is endogenous. Unskilled workers may become skilled by taking costly education (or vocational training), which is the model's other fundamental ingredient: separating labor supply constraints into those over total labor supply and over skilled labor supply. We model a small country with three final consumption sectors: two tradable sectors and one nontradable sector. The first tradable sector is unskilled labor intensive, referred to as the agricultural sector. The other tradable sector, which is referred to as the manufacturing sector, is characterized by productivity growth with increasing varieties of intermediate inputs. Such inputs are nontradable and skilled labor intensive. The nontradable consumption good sector is unskilledlabor intensive and its sole difference from the agricultural sector is that the product demand is constrained by the size of the home market. In this framework, trade openness requires a minimum scale of the local intermediate good sector for industrialization (i.e., the threshold size of the manufacturing base). As the intermediate good sector exhibits increasing returns to scale, the threshold size of the manufacturing base leads to multiple equilibria; that is, an industrialization equilibrium and a nonindustrial equilibrium. Thus, the model shows that developing economies may be trapped in a nonindustrial state even though they can potentially reach a Pareto-superior industrialized state, which is a common property in the big push literature exemplified by Murphy, Shleifer, and Vishny (1989) . Given the possibility of the "industrialization trap," this article first investigates the effects of labor supply constraints on industrialization, which may have been caused by the COVID-19 pandemic. Then, the article examines how manufacturing automation could affect industrialized developing economies, based on the premise that manufacturers may accelerate production automation in response to the incremental labor supply constraints due to the COVID-19 pandemic. Automation is not exceptional in developing countries. Indeed, long before the pandemic, manufacturing automation had begun mainly in multinational plants even in poor developing economies (e.g., Seric and Winkler 2020) . To investigate automation consequences, the model is extended to include international capital flows (i.e., machine imports), which allow manufactures to replace unskilled labor input with capital. The main findings of this article are as follows. First, labor supply constraints may have a critical impact on industrialization, weakening the manufacturing competitiveness of developing economies in the world market. Nonindustrial developing economies face more restrictive industrialization conditions, and worse, industrialized developing economies may be back to the nonindustrial state if their manufacturing base drops below their industrialization thresholds. Thus, the model predicts that although developing economies with relatively large manufacturing bases may recover quickly from the current recession, those with weaker manufacturing bases will suffer from long-term decline and manufacturing contraction trends (undesirable deindustrialization). Second, manufacturing automation will expand the intermediate good sector by increasing manufacturing productivity and cause a contraction of the unproductive nontradable final good (service) sector, resulting in a positive impact on aggregate productivity. Thus, manufacturing automation is expected to mitigate the negative economic effect of the pandemic. However, the ability of manufacturing automation to enhance economic welfare crucially depends on high labor liquidity, not only in inter-sectoral mobility (horizontal mobility) but also in skill upgrading (vertical mobility). With low labor liquidity, automating manufacturing production will expand the nontradable final sector and enlarge the wage gap between skilled and unskilled. Therefore, the direction of economic welfare change is ambiguous. Hence, policies for increasing labor mobility, including enhancing education systems, become more important under the COVID-19 crisis. Although the economics literature on COVID-19-related issues has been rapidly expanding, to my best knowledge, apart from descriptive policy briefs such as Hartwich and Isaksson (2020) , formal analyses on the effect on industrialization and economic development are still limited. Developing a simple model of a small open economy with endogenous skill accumulation, this article provides a formal analysis on the potential effects of the COVID-19 pandemic on the industrialization of developing countries through the lens of constrained labor supply (skilled and unskilled) and manufacturing automation. A large body of literature points out that whereas only a limited number of developing countries succeeded in catching up with developed economies through industrialization, many developing countries failed to do so and even experienced declines in their manufacturing goods. Rodrik (2016) , referring to this phenomenon as "premature deindustrialization," claims that terms-of-trade deterioration owing to the rapid growth of China and technological progress in the rest of the world have disturbed developing countries' industrialization. Eichengreen, Park, and Shin (2014) empirically find that fast-growing middle-income countries tend to experience growth slowdowns, but those with relatively rich human capital accumulation or high-technology products tend to escape from growth slowdowns. This article's predictions are consistent with their findings. However, contrary to Rodrik (2016) , I stress the role of labor mobility including skill formation. In the trade-and skill-formation literature, Atkin (2016) recently investigates Mexican data and finds that less-skilled manufacturing exports slow down the country's skill accumulation. Using a panel of 102 countries and 45 years, Blanchard and Olney (2017) find the evidence that skill-intensive exports encourage educational attainment. This article, primarily theoretical, incorporates endogenous skill formation and argues that a country's comparative advantage affects its skill accumulation. Furthermore, this article aims to examine the potential impact of the COVID-19 pandemic on industrialization and to derive related policy implications. Rodríguez-Clare (1996) and Rodrik (1996) are the two closest to this article in the sense that both studies present coordination failure problems in comparative advantage formation. Rodríguez-Clare (1996) primarily focuses on multinationals' creation of backward linkage in developing economies. Rodrik (1996) discusses policy measures, such as minimum wages to avoid the coordination failure problem. Both studies lack endogenous skill formation and nontradable sectors, which are highlighted in this article. Venables (2017) examines a dichotomous feature of developing countries' industrialization by explicitly modeling a nontradable sector. However, although Venables (2017) stresses the role of urbanization as a prerequisite for industrialization, this article focuses on endogenous skill formation and the role of manufacturing automation. The remaining part of this article is as follows. The next section introduces a simple open economy model with a nontradable sector and endogenous skill formation. Then, Section 3 discusses conditions for industrialization, and Section 4 considers the potential impacts of the COVID-19 pandemic on developing economies' industrialization, focusing on labor supply constraints and manufacturing automation. Section 5 concludes. We consider a small open economy populated with L individuals, each of which inelastically supplies one unit of unskilled labor. A representative individual consumes a unit interval of sectors indexed by j with the following Cobb-Douglas utility function: where q j represents consumption of sector j. Following Epifani and Gancia (2009) , we assume that sectors are sorted into three categories: tradable manufacturing goods (M), nontradable goods (services) (N), and tradable agricultural goods (A). For analytical simplicity, subintervals for each category are exogenous, and we assign intervals θ > 0 and η > 0 for the manufacturing and nontradable goods, respectively. Assuming that θ + η < 1, the remaining interval is assigned to the agricultural goods. The embedded idea of the specification of the nontradable good (service) sector is that trade costs for interval η are prohibitively high. We view recent globalization as a decrease in η; that is, as trade costs decline, goods and services that were nontradable become tradable (e.g., online consulting services). By sectoral symmetry, the utility function can be rewritten as where q i stands for consumption of good i = {M, N, A} and θ and η are distribution parameters that determine the importance of the three goods. The agricultural good is a numéraire in the model, and its price is normalized to unity. Utility maximization yields the following demand for each good: where p M is the manufacturing price that is exogenously determined in the world market, p N is the endogenous price of nontradable good, and E is the economy's aggregate income. By choosing ζ appropriately, the indirect utility is given as All the three final consumption goods are perfectly competitive and produced with constant returns to scale technologies. The production of the agricultural good requires only unskilled labor, and its labor productivity is normalized such that the unskilled wage w is 1 as long as the agricultural good is produced. Denoting the output of the agricultural good by y A , the unskilled labor demand from this sector is simply The nontradable good (service) also requires only unskilled labor. Denoting output by y N , the production function is y N = ψ N L N , where ψ N > 0 stands for labor productivity and L N is unskilled labor input in the nontradable final sector. The price of nontradable good is p N = w/ψ N . Using market-clearing condition, y N = q N , the unskilled labor demand from this sector is The manufacturing good employs the following Cobb-Douglas technology: where L X is the input of unskilled labor and X is a composite of intermediate goods. The composite of intermediate goods is specified by the following CES function: where σ > 1 is the elasticity of substitution between any two varieties of the intermediate goods and n is the mass of varieties of the intermediate goods. This specification of manufacturing production indicates that final manufacturing production is constant returns to scale while the production of the composite of intermediate goods exhibits increasing returns to scale. 2 Hence the access to a 2 To see this convexity and symmetry among x(i) in equation (4), ensure that final firms use the same quantity of all available intermediate goods, thereby denoting this usage level by x for all Hence, as input n x increases, X increases more than proportionally. wider range of inputs enhances manufacturing productivity, which can be interpreted as the division of labor as a source of increased productivity (Ethier 1982) . As β increases, the productivity-enhancing effect by the division of labor becomes more powerful. Each intermediate variety is produced with skilled labor under increasing returns and monopolistic competition. The stock of skilled labor is endogenous. It is assumed that to acquire skills necessary for intermediate production, each household must incur an iceberg-type education (or job training) cost measured in units of unskilled labor. Specifically, each household can provide either one unit of unskilled labor or 1/t units of skilled labor, where t (>1) measures costly education. Given that the manufacturing sector is active in the economy, households must be indifferent between becoming skilled and remaining unskilled, which implies that the skilled wage, w s , just compensates the education cost: The total amount of skilled labor required for quantity x(i) of intermediate good i is given by l s (i) = ψx(i) + f, where ψ is the marginal requirement of skilled labor. Profit maximization leads to the standard markup pricing. Choosing the unit of skilled labor such as ψ = (σ À 1)/σ, we have p(i) = w s for all varieties. 3 Using this result, the monopoly profits are expressed by π(i) = [p(i) À ψw s ]x(i) À fw s = [x(i)/σ À f]w s . Free entry drives the monopoly profits down to zero, which ensures that each intermediate firm produces a fixed amount of x σf in equilibrium. Hence, the firm-level skilled labor requirement is also fixed at To derive unskilled labor requirement from the direct input in manufacturing, final producers' cost minimization yields where P X is the price index of a continuum of intermediate goods, which is expressed as where equation (5) is used. As x i ð Þ ¼ x for all i, equations (4), (5), and (7) suggest that P X X ¼ ntw x . Substituting this into equation (6), we obtain unskilledlabor demand in the manufacturing sector as follows: Considering that the total demand of skilled labor for intermediate production is n x, the aggregate labor demand in the manufacturing sector in units of unskilled labor is expressed as which is proportional to the mass of intermediate varieties, n. Furthermore, else equal, L M is increasing in the training cost t, but decreasing in the intermediate intensity β. The intuition is straightforward. As education for skill acquisition is more costly, unskilled labor demand increases for given n. By contrast, an increase in the intensity of intermediate goods enhances productivity and saves labor input. To close this section, labor productivity in manufacturing increases as more intermediate varieties become available to the final producers. Defining labor productivity by y M /L M , we obtain Hence, as the availability of intermediate varieties increases (n"), the manufacturing productivity improves, which can be interpreted as a welldeveloped manufacturing base increases manufacturing productivity, leading to enhanced manufacturing competitiveness in the world market. Education efficiency is also transmitted to manufacturing productivity because inefficient education (t") requires more labor input to produce the same amount of output. The production possibilities frontier with respect to the two tradable goods is linear. 4 Thus, the economy perfectly specializes in either one of the two tradable sectors, depending on the economy's comparative advantage, which is determined by the ratio of unit costs of the manufacturing and agricultural goods, c M /c A , and the terms of trade. Letting p A denote the price of the agricultural good, if holds, then complete specialization in the agricultural good occurs. Otherwise, the economy perfectly specializes in the manufacturing goods. The unit production costs of the manufacturing and agricultural goods are given by c M ¼ w 1Àβ P β X and c A = w, respectively. Using equation (7), the relative production cost is which is infinitely high when n is very low and monotonically decreases as n increases. Noting that p A = 1, the thresholdn at which the ratio of unit cost equals p M is expressed aŝ If the mass of intermediate varieties that the economy can produce is greater thann , then the economy can be industrialized. Otherwise, the economy can never be industrialized. To understand this point from the view of the labor market, it is useful to consider the wage rate that firms in the manufacturing sector can offer (payable wages). If the manufacturing sector is active, then p M = c M holds. Applying equation (7) to c M , the payable unskilled wage is expressed by an increasing function of n: By definition, wn ð Þ ¼ 1, which equals the unskilled wage that the agricultural and the nontradable final sectors offer. Thus, no manufacturing firms cannot attract workers unless more thann varieties of intermediate goods are available. We start with the case that the economy perfectly specializes in the agricultural and nontradable goods (nonindustrial equilibrium). The unskilled wage equals the agricultural price: w = 1. Given free labor mobility across the two sectors, the same wage prevails in the nontradable sector, which leads to p N = 1/ψ N . At this price, the demand for the nontradable good is q N = ψ N ηL, which equals the output level. The sector's unskilled labor requirement is ηL and the remaining is allocated to the agricultural sector, which leads to L A = y A = (1 À η)L. As wages are the sole source of income, economic welfare (per capita) is The economy hosts only constant returns to scale sectors, and thus population size (L) does not affect welfare. Welfare increases due to either decreases in p M (terms-of-trade gain) or increases in ψ N (productivity growth in nontradable goods). To complete the description of the nonindustrial equilibrium, the agricultural good is the economy's export good. Domestic consumption of the agricultural good is q A = (1 À θ À η)L. Hence, the export volume is given by EX u = y A À q A = θL. The balanced trade condition gives the volume of manufacturing imports, IM u = θL/p M . We now turn to an industrialization equilibrium, in which the economy has the manufacturing and nontradable final sectors. As the nonindustrial case, the economy's aggregate income is still given by E = wL because the skill premium just compensates labor supply depreciation for education. The labor market clearing condition is L = L M + L N . Substituting equations (3) and (8) into this condition, the mass of intermediate varieties in equilibrium is derived such that Comparative statics on n* is straightforward. The mass of equilibrium intermediate varieties, n*, is proportional to the economy's population size L. As the size of the nontradable sector, η, increases, n* declines. 5 In addition, as education quality declines (t"), n* also declines. 6 Applying equation (13) to equation (11), the equilibrium unskilled wage is expressed as Using this result, per capita welfare is expressed by In equilibrium, n* >n. Given that wn ð Þ ¼ 1 and w is increasing in n, w* must be greater than 1. Thus, compared with V u in equation (12), industrialization unambiguously raises per capita economic welfare. These results are recorded in the following proposition. PROPOSITION 1. Industrialization raises per capita economic welfare by fostering the manufacturing sector that productivity grows with a range of specialized intermediate inputs. With a larger population and an efficient education for skill formation, the economy has a wider range of specialized inputs, resulting in a larger and more productive manufacturing sector. Trade impediments may increase the range of nontradable consumption goods (η"). Equation (13) suggests that the range of intermediate varieties decreases. Consequently, the manufacturing sector decreases in terms of output share and employment share ("deindustrialization"). 7 The effect of deindustrialization on 5 Parameter η represents the size of the nontradable sector in terms of both employment and income shares. To see this, from equation (3) economic welfare is somewhat complicated. Equation (14) suggests that as long as ψ N < w*, deindustrialization would unambiguously decrease economic welfare through the following: (i) increasing the weight of low productive industries in the economy (composition effect) and (ii) decreasing the wages with reducing gains from division of labor in the manufacturing (n*#). This "undesirable" deindustrialization is likely to occur in economies with relatively unproductive nontradable sectors. This observation is consistent with Rodrik's (2016) "premature deindustrialization" of developing countries, which means that manufacturing shares in output and employment decrease before reaching a sufficiently high income level. Although nontradable consumption goods are always domestically produced, the manufacturing good is not necessarily because the small economy faces the infinite import supply at the world price p M . The necessary condition for the economy to be industrialized is n* ≥n . Using equations (10) and (13), this condition is expressed as This inequality tends to be reversed when: 1. the economy size is small (L#), 2. the education (training) cost for acquiring skills is high (t " ), 3. the size of the nontradable sector is large (η"), and 4. the terms of trade deteriorate (p M #). All these results are intuitive. For industrialization, the economy must foster a competitive manufacturing sector. Competitiveness critically depends on the range of specialized intermediate inputs. The availability of labor resources for intermediate production is crucial. The economy size, education efficiency, and labor demand from the nontradable final sector affect labor available to intermediate production. Figure 1 illustrates the industrialization condition in equation (15) with two gross profit schedules in intermediate production (more precisely, they express the gross return rates of skilled labor input. See Appendix A.1 for the derivation of these schedules). 8 A schedule labeled as π g H satisfies the industrialization condition. As the number of intermediate varieties increases, π g H monotonically decreases, and the intersection with a horizontal line of f gives the equilibrium level of intermediate varieties, where n * H >n. In any of the adverse shocks in L, t, and η, the gross profit schedule shifts leftward. The schedule labeled as π g L is located far left relative to π g H , and the equilibrium mass of varieties n * L does not satisfy the condition for industrialization. In such a case, the economy cannot be industrialized and must stay at the nonindustrial stage. PROPOSITION 2. An economy with a larger population, an efficient education for skill formation, and a smaller nontradable final sector tends to have a comparative advantage in manufacturing and a larger possibility of industrialization. The industrialization condition of equation (15) is a necessary condition because the model has two equilibria even if n* >n is satisfied. Industrialization and nonindustrial equilibria are stable. To observe this, in the nonindustrial state (n = 0), the payable manufacturing wage is 0, and thus the sector cannot attract workers who obtain w = 1 in the other sectors. Hence, this nonindustrial equilibrium is stable. However, Figure 1 shows that once the economy somehow acquiresn of intermediate varieties (and the economy has a sufficiently large production capacity), firm entry occurs, and the economy can reach n * H . Thus, the industrialization equilibrium is also stable. The economy has an "industrialization trap" stemming from a coordination failure problem in the manufacturing sector. Suppose that a relatively small private coordination, n min 0, ∂n=∂t > 0, and ∂n*/∂t < 0 are straightforward. Thus, labor constraints decrease the economy's realizable size of intermediate good sector n*, while leaving the threshold size of the intermediate good sectorn intact. Costly education decreases n* and increasesn. The model suggests that economies are unindustrialized due to either their too small intermediate good sector (n * n is not sufficient for industrialization). Decreases in L or increases in t makes industrialization tougher for nonindustrial economies: decreasing n* and/or increasingn may enlarge the gap between n* andn for economies with n * 0.5 to warrant the model's solution. 17 As expected, the equilibrium number of varieties increases relative to the one without the labor replacement with capital (see equation 13). The small economy can exploit more gains from the division of labor, and economic welfare increases. The results of capital introduction are summarized in the following proposition. PROPOSITION 5. In the small economy, manufacturing automation that replaces unskilled labor with capital borrowed from the international market leads to a contraction of the nontradable good sector and an expansion of the manufacturing sector with increased skill-intensive intermediate good varieties. Thus, economic welfare increases. 17 Thus, the manufacturing sector must be intermediate goods intensive to a certain degree when the economy borrows all the necessary capital from the world market. This restriction can be relaxed either by assuming a positive home capital endowment or allowing to run a current account deficit. Thus, the condition β > 0.5 is not so restrictive as appeared. The model highlights that introducing machines (capital use in the model) to the manufacturing sector in replacement of unskilled labor yields various benefits to the economy: human capital accumulation, a richer industry base (a wider range of intermediate varieties and advanced division of labor), contraction of the relatively unproductive nontradable sector, and wage increases. It is well known that workers in the informal sector are more likely to be exposed to the infection risk of COVID-19 because the provision of their services tends to require face-to-face interactions. Many anecdotes and reports illustrate that COVID-19 has reduced informal employment and income more severely than the formal counterparts (e.g., World Bank 2020). In the model, it is reasonable to assume that workers in the nontradable good (service) sector are more susceptible to the disease, and labor supply constraints are more severe than those in the manufacturing sector. When the economy uses imported capital, the employment share in the nontradable good (service) sector is expressed as Since the counterpart employment share in case of no capital use is η, the employment share in the nontradable good (service) sector unambiguously declines by using capital (see the Appendix A.3 for derivation). Hence, machine introduction contributes to making the economy not only more productive (i.e., n * < n * k ) but also less vulnerable to the COVID-19 pandemic, reducing employment more susceptible to the disease and relaxing labor supply constraints due to the pandemic. In developing countries, nontradable sectors largely coincide with informal sectors. Thus, the contraction of the nontradable sector presented here may be good news for policymakers in such countries. However, notably, the predictions illustrated here depend on the flexibility of labor mobility in terms of skills and sectors. In the real world of developing countries (and to a lesser extent in developed countries), this may be one of the most difficult problems to be resolved. What if manufacturing automation occurs with slow labor adjustments? I illustrate this issue in the following section. To make the problem of slow labor adjustments crystal clear, I consider it an extreme case: The supply of skilled labor is perfectly inelastic. Suppose that the small open economy with the manufacturing sector cannot increase the number of skilled workers from the initial level. Then, the international capital market becomes available, and the manufacturing firms start to use capital instead of unskilled labor as before. Two points are immediate. First, the wage equation (5) is not applicable because no labor upgrading from unskilled to skilled occurs. As a result, the wage gap increases (more than just compensating the training cost). Second, all unskilled workers who were formerly employed in manufacturing move to the nontradable good sector. Thus, the nontradable good sector expands, and the unskilled wage declines. As the model is easy to solve, I summarize the equilibrium with stagnant labor mobility. The labor market-clearing condition of equation (16) is still applicable by just applying n* in equation (13). Substituting equation (13) to equation (16) leads to the equilibrium labor allocation to the nontradable sector: which is greater than the size without capital inflows L N = ηL. As shown in the Appendix A.4, the ratio of the skilled wage to unskilled wage is expressed as Recall that the wage gap before the capital introduction is w s /w = t. Hence, the wage gap unambiguously increases. Intuitively, although the skilled wage increases because of the unskilled labor replacement, the unskilled wage must decrease because the unskilled workers released from the manufacturing sector enter the nontradable final good sector. Skilled workers are better off because p N falls. Unskilled workers are worse off because their wage w decreases. Thus, on average, real income per capita may fall, depending on the share of unskilled workers. 18 If the economy has a relatively small manufacturing base (a low number of specialized inputs), the economy is likely to suffer from a real income decrease. PROPOSITION 6. If the cost for skill accumulation is prohibitively high, then manufacturing automation expands the nontradable good (service) sector. Consequently, the wage gap between skilled and unskilled labor grows. Gains from automation are ambiguous. The proposition emphasizes that skill accumulation is crucial to obtain gains from automation. Given that the COVID-19 pandemic is likely to cause education disruption, our results stress that improving education systems (particularly for supplying workers contributing manufacturing bases) is more important. In addition, financial globalization does not always generate good economic performances, such as high economic growth. Some expositions have been proposed (Rodrik and Subramanian 2009 ). However, nonbeneficial financial globalization is still an open question (Kose et al. 2010) . Highlighting the role of flexible social mobility, in particular workers' skill-upgrading, our model provides an account on why financial globalization is not always promising for economic development: high cost for skill acquisition and low social mobility in developing economies. The COVID-19 pandemic has not only generated the deepest world recession in our living memory but also convinced us about future pandemic's recurring, which almost assures long-lasting effects on economies. Long before the pandemic, automation and digital technologies and trade and production networks have evolved hand in hand, forming two dominant world trends. The COVID-19 pandemic seems to strengthen these trends with some alternations from health and risk concerns. I have argued in this paper that these trends are important from the point of view of the industrialization of developing economies, proposing a simple open economy model with the development trap. The following findings are emphasized. First, the pandemic may cause the reversal of comparative advantage by imposing labor supply constraints through curtailing worker mobility (social distancing) and degrading education systems. In particular, education systems can be easily damaged for several reasons, including school closures, poor access environments for remote learning, public financial shortages, and household income falls by the recession. If a reversal of comparative advantage does not occur, then a developing economy will recover to the original state. However, if the reversal of comparative advantage is the case, then the original state turns to be an unstable equilibrium and the economy will be trapped in a nonindustrial equilibrium. Hence, the negative impact will be long-term. Second, manufacturing automation supported by international capital inflows improved the economy's welfare by enhancing the manufacturing base and making the (relatively) unproductive nontradable sector smaller. Human capital accumulation (increases in skilled labor) will increase. However, exploiting the benefits of automation, labor mobility, and specifically smooth acquisition of skills is critical. Otherwise, as the model suggests, manufacturing automation may lead to an expansion of the nontradable sector, and thus, the wage gap between skilled and unskilled labor will grow, thereby lowering economic welfare. Thus, this paper emphasizes that enhancing social mobility (i.e., labor mobility across sectors and skill acquisition) becomes more important in the era of global pandemic risks. The model's predictions are intuitive, and their logic is clear. However, empirical validation is desirable to make them more useful for policy practitioners. In addition, although this paper's model is deliberately kept simple to highlight the major logic, some extensions, including endogenous sector size and more general preferences, are also desirable to make the model a base for empirical studies. These agendas are left for future work. Labor constraints in an industrialized economy are expressed as where L N is the labor demand from the nontradable sector. For labor requirements from intermediate good production, t is multiplied to convert units from skilled to unskilled. Applying L X = (1 À β)nt/β to equation (1.1) and factoring with respect to x, x ¼ β 1 À β þ βψ L À L N nt À f : ð1:2Þ Using equation (1.2), the gross profits π g = w s x/σ can be expressed by π g n ð Þ ¼ βw s σ À β L À L N nt À f : Equivalently, in the return rate of skilled labor, which is decreasing in n. New firm entry continues until the return rate decreases until f. It is immediate that π g /w s schedule shifts leftward by a higher training cost (t " ) or a larger nontradable sector (L N "). The labor market clearing is now given by equation (16). Solving it with respect to n, n k ¼ L À L N t x : ð2:1Þ Substituting L N in equation (18) into equation (2.1), K is given by equation (19). Endogenous Skill Acquisition and Export Manufacturing in Mexico Supply Chain Contagion Waves: Thinking Ahead on Manufacturing 'Contagion and Reinfection' from the COVID Concussion Globalization and Human Capital Investment: Export Composition Drives Educational Attainment The Macroeconomic Effects of Automation and the Role of COVID-19 in Reinforcing Their Dynamics Global Supply Chains in the Pandemic How Many Jobs Can Be Done at Home? Growth Slowdowns Redux That's Good for the U.S., Bad for Poor Countries Openness, Government Size and the Terms of Trade National and International Returns to Scale in the Modern Theory of International Trade The Effects of Trade Policy Managing COVID-19: Why Poorer Countries May Drop Out of Industrialization. Vienna: United Nations Industrial Development Organization 2018. Women and Men in the Informal Economy: A Statistical Picture Financial Globalization and Economic Policies Trade Policies in Developing Countries Complementarities and Cumulative Processes in Models of Monopolistic Competition Industrialization and the Big Push Multinationals, Linkages, and Economic Development Coordination Failures and Government Policy: A Model with Applications to East Asia and Eastern Europe Why Did Financial Globalization Disappont? COVID-19 Could Spur Automation and Reverse Globalisation-To Some Extent Policy Brief: Education during COVID-19 and Beyond Breaking into Tradables: Urban Form and Urban Function in a Developing City South Asia Economic Focus, Fall 2020: Beaten or Broken? Informality and COVID-19 where n k is given by equation (2.4). Capital input isð2:6ÞAggregate income is expressed as Without borrowing capital from the international capital market, manufacturing output is expressed asWhen capital (machines) is introduced, manufacturing output iswhere equation (2.6) is used. Without imported capital, the output of nontradable good is simply expressed asSince the employment in the N sector is ηL, the employment share is simplyWhen the economy uses imported capital in the manufacturing sector,The corresponding employment isSince 2β À 1 < β À (1 À β)η , η < 1, L N declines when the economy uses capital in the manufacturing sector. 1ÞTotal expenditure is E ¼ w s n * x þ wL N À r * K: Market clearing of the nontradable good (service) sector isPerfect competition implies thatEquation (4.5) determines w s :Comparing to the skilled wage before capital introduction, w s in equation (4.6) increases because r* < w by assumption.Using equations (4.3) and (4.4) and eliminating E, we obtainFurther substituting equations (4.1), (4.2), and n* in equation (13) into equation (4.7), we obtain the ratio of skilled to unskilled wages (i.e., skill premium) such that w s w ¼ 1 À β þ η βη t:Since 1 À β + η > βη is immediate, the wage gap increases compared to the one before capital introduction.With w and L N , equation (4.4) gives E. Then, equation (4.3) gives K. Thus, the model is solved.