key: cord-0799219-do0lkl25 authors: Chudik, Alexander; Mohaddes, Kamiar; Pesaran, M. Hashem; Raissi, Mehdi; Rebucci, Alessandro title: A counterfactual economic analysis of Covid-19 using a threshold augmented multi-country model() date: 2021-08-30 journal: J Int Money Finance DOI: 10.1016/j.jimonfin.2021.102477 sha: ee1a1764d0207c1a0ee3b1a61c84cd6f844c6db6 doc_id: 799219 cord_uid: do0lkl25 This paper develops a threshold-augmented dynamic multi-country model (TGVAR) to quantify the macroeconomic effects of the Covid-19 pandemic. We show that there exist threshold effects in the relationship between output growth and excess global volatility at individual country levels in a significant majority of advanced economies and several emerging markets. We then estimate a more general multi-country model augmented with these threshold effects as well as long term interest rates, oil prices, exchange rates and equity returns to perform counterfactual analyses. We distinguish common global factors from trade-related spillovers, and identify the Covid-19 shock using GDP growth projection revisions of the IMF in 2020Q1. We account for sample uncertainty by bootstrapping the multi-country model estimated over four decades of quarterly observations. Our results show that, without policy support, the Covid-19 pandemic would cause a significant and long-lasting fall in world output, with outcomes that are quite heterogenous across countries and regions. While the impact on China and other emerging Asian economies are estimated to be less severe, the United Kingdom, and several other advanced economies may experience deeper and longer-lasting effects. Non-Asian emerging markets stand out for their vulnerability. We show that no country is immune to the economic fallout of the pandemic because of global interconnections as evidenced by the case of Sweden. We also find that long-term interest rates could temporarily fall below their pre-Covid-19 lows in core advanced economies, but this does not seem to be the case in emerging markets. economy. For an extensive survey of the latest theoretical developments in GVAR modelling and the numerous empirical analyses, see and Chapter 33 of Pesaran (2015) . Our counterfactual results show that the pandemic could reduce the world real GDP by 3 percent below its modelgenerated path without the shock by the end of 2021. While China and other emerging Asian economies are estimated to be less severely affected, the United Kingdom, and several other advanced economies may experience deeper and longerlasting effects. Among non-Asian emerging market economies, however, the economic impact of Covid-19 varies substantially, depending on domestic factors (economic structures, health preparedness, and the scale of lockdowns) as well as external disturbances (plunging trade, collapsing tourism, volatility in capital flows, and fluctuations in commodity prices). There is a significant degree of uncertainty around all these counterfactual outcomes which we try to quantify (while abstracting from the large-scale fiscal support that followed later in 2020). Importantly, our findings underscore the role of spillovers which we quantify for the case of Sweden considering its different approach toward the pandemic (i.e., a less stringent strategy). We show that no country is immune to the economic fallout of the pandemic because of interconnections. We also estimate that the Covid-19 pandemic would lower long-term interest rates temporarily by about 100 basis points below their historical lows in core advanced economies. In contrast, the impact on long-term interest rates in emerging markets has a wide range, including significant upside risks. Our paper also relates to a rapidly growing literature that investigates the macroeconomic effects of Covid-19. McKibbin and Fernando (2020) explore the global macroeconomic effects of different scenarios of how Covid-19 might evolve sing a hybrid DSGE/CGE model. They underscore the importance of spillover effects and show that even a contained outbreak could significantly impact the global economy in the short run. Bonadio et al. (2020) study the impact of Covid-19 on output growth in 64 countries and investigate the contribution of global supply chains to these adverse effects. Ludvigson et al. (2020) quantify the macroeconomic impact of Covid-19 in the United States using a VAR framework and a gauge of the magnitude of the Covid-19 shock in relation to past costly disasters. Baqaee and Farhi (2020) consider possible non-linearities in response to the Covid-19 shock in a multi-sectoral model. They develop a disaggregated structural model with input-output linkages, as well as downward nominal wage rigidities and a zero lower bound constraint on nominal policy rate to study the effects of supply and demand shocks associated with Covid-19. They demonstrate how these shocks are amplified or mitigated by nonlinearities, and quantify their effects using disaggregated data from the United States. Another paper which highlights the importance of nonlinearity is Céspedes et al. (2020) . They build a threshold macroeconomic model of a pandemic and show how such a shock can have large magnification effects. Finally, Milani (2020) uses a GVAR model to underscore the importance of countries' interconnections in the evolution of Covid-19 and its unemployment effects. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 highlights the importance of threshold effects in the growth-global volatility relationship. Section 3 develops the threshold-augmented dynamic multi-country (TGVAR) model. Section 4 quantifies the macroeconomic effects of Covid-19 under uncertainty using TGVAR. Finally, Section 5 offers some concluding remarks. Additional results are provided in three appendices. Threshold effects have been used in the literature primarily in the context of autoregressions pioneered by Tong (1990) . These models are known as threshold autoregressions (TAR) and allow the parameters of the autoregressive model to switch between two or more values. Extension of TAR models to multi-variate systems has been considered by Tsay (1998) . Hansen (2011) provides a recent review of TAR models, and discusses their empirical applications in economics in areas such as growth dynamics, stock return volatility and forecasting. Given the global nature of Covid-19, and to capture its non-linear economic effects, we focus on a global measure of realized volatility, and consider its possible impact on country-specific output growth. To measure global volatility, we use the following where w $ i is the PPP-GDP weight of country i, we index countries as i ¼ 0; 1; . . . ; n, and rve it is the country-specific realized volatility of equity returns during quarter t, computed from daily observations: where r it s ð Þ is the equity return during day s in quarter t in country i; r it ¼ D À1 t P Dt s¼1 r it s ð Þ, and D t is the number of trading days in quarter t. The country-specific realized volatility measures, rve it , have been used in the literature to investigate the effects of uncertainty on growth. Here we focus on a global volatility measure, as opposed to country-specific ones, to better capture the effects of global uncertainty, which is more akin to Covid-19. One could use other measures of global volatility as well. For example, instead of averaging country-specific realized volatilities, we could first take the average of equity returns across countries and then compute the realized volatility of global equity. Let r gt s ð Þ be the global daily equity return defined by using PPP-GDP weights as before. Then realized volatility of global equity returns is given by A widely-used alternative measure of global volatility in the literature is the option-implied volatility, or VIX. While the VIX captures the stock market's expectation of volatility based on S&P 500 index options and is only available from 1990, our preferred measure of global volatility, grve t , is based on realized equity returns for a large number of countries and is available for the last four decades. Note that the correlation of grve t and VIX is 89.8%, therefore, grve t seems to follow the VIX index well but not too closely (see Fig. 1 ), thus capturing, to some degree, some of the volatilities that originate from emerging economies. Appendix B systematically compares these three measures of global volatility and shows that grve t is superior to other measures in terms of fit. 1 Therefore, in what follows, we report the results based on the grve t measure of global volatility. We begin our econometric analysis with the following simple multi-country threshold-augmented dynamic output growth model: for i ¼0; 1; 2; . . . ; n; and t ¼ 1; 2; . . . ; T; where Dgdp it ¼ gdp it À gdp i;tÀ1 , is the first difference of the logarithm of real GDP for country i during quarter t, and Þis the global volatility threshold variable, I A ð Þ is an indicator variable that takes the value of unity if event A occurs and zero otherwise, grve t is the global realized volatility defined by (1), and c is a threshold parameter, assumed to be the same across countries under consideration. e it is the idiosyncratic error assumed to be serially uncorrelated with a zero mean. The above specification only allows for intercept shifts in output growth equations, thus treating the threshold variable, z tÀ1 c ð Þ, as another common factor, with the threshold parameter estimated by pooling across countries. Modelling other forms of threshold effects, including country-specific thresholds, will unduly complicate the modelling exercise and is beyond the scope of the present paper. We model the threshold effects with respect to lagged values of the realized volatility variable, and rely on standard common factor analysis to capture possible simultaneity between output growths and volatility. See Section 3. The results of estimating Eq. (4) for advanced and emerging economies are summarized in Table 1 . In addition to reporting the estimates of c and u i , we also report the estimate of the proportion of times that the threshold is exceeded, denoted by p. The threshold parameter, c, is estimated by grid search and is allowed to take different values for advanced and emerging economies. The estimate of c for advanced economies at 0:156 is slightly larger than the value of 0:129 estimated for emerging economies. Given these estimates, the global volatility threshold variable is statistically significant in 15 out of the 19 (80%) advanced economies in our sample. But the results are much weaker for emerging economies, with only 4 statistically significant effects out of the 14 emerging economies in our sample. Nevertheless, all statistically significant threshold affects were negative, suggesting that excessive global volatility is generally associated with lower output growth subsequently. There are a numbers of channels through which excessive global financial market volatility can adversely affect economic growth. They include higher precautionary savings by households, lower or delayed investment by firms due to increased uncertainty and weaker demand prospects, and a higher cost of raising capital owing to higher funding costs in a volatile environment. See, for example, Cesa-Bianchi et al. (2020) and the references therein. In normal conditions where global volatility is low (below the threshold c), financial markets are able to price the volatility risk, and therefore weaken the relationship between output growth and the volatility factor. But during periods of heightened volatility, that occur very rarely, it is difficult to price the volatility risk properly and it is thus more likely for excess volatility to show up as statistically significant in output growth equations. Overall, while we manage to detect threshold effects in the output growth-global volatility relationship in many advanced economies (80 percent of cases), similar results for emerging markets are less pervasive (with threshold effects being statistically significant in 30 percent of cases) for the following reason. Compared to advanced countries, exposure to global equity markets is lower in emerging market economies (that is, they have less developed capital markets and rely more on the banking sector for credit intermediation). Nonetheless, in these countries output growth could well be non-linearly affected by localized events (e.g., natural disasters; banking, currency and sovereign crises) or external shocks (e.g., commodity price 1 See in particular Fig. B .1 in the Appendix, which compares the average Mean Square Errors (MSE) of the threshold-augmented dynamic output growth (1), and c is the threshold parameter. The estimation sample is 1979Q2 to 2019Q4. Statistical significance is denoted by à ; y and à , at 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. volatility and capital flow reversals), and be exacerbated by country-specific characteristics (internal and external imbalances). However, these types of threshold effects will not be captured by our econometric specification that focuses on the global realized volatility of equity returns that is more reflective of developments in advanced economies. 2 The above findings underscore the importance of allowing for threshold effects in studying the macroeconomic consequences of Covid-19-which, considering its unprecedented nature, generated a sharp tightening in global financial conditions (Fig. 1) . Specifically, global equity markets sold off sharply through mid-March 2020 as the pandemic spread across the world. From end-2019 to trough, the S&P 500 index in the United States fell 30 percent. Stock prices in other major economies experienced declines of similar magnitude and flight to safety resulted in sharp capital outflows from emerging market economies. Notwithstanding the improvement in global risk sentiment since March amid large-scale liquidity injections by major central banks and a gradual relaxation of lockdowns in many countries, output recovery is expected to be gradual with GDP growth in many economies expected to be negatively affected by the previous bout of financial market volatility (Fig. 2) . In what follows, we study the implications of Covid-19 for the global economy. In doing so we build on the GVAR literature and develop a threshold-augmented dynamic multi-country framework, which we refer to as Threshold-augmented GVAR, or TGVAR for short. The proposed modelling framework takes into account both the temporal and cross-sectional dimensions of the data; real and financial drivers of economic activity; interlinkages and spillovers that exist between different regions/countries; and the global common factors, as well as network effects (e.g., through trade linkages). This is crucial as the impact of shocks (and importantly that of Covid-19) cannot be reduced to a single country but rather involves multiple regions/countries, and this impact may be amplified or dampened depending on the degree of openness of the countries (both trade and financial) and their economic structures. Informed by the results in Section 2, we also allow for threshold effects in the output growth equation arising from global financial market volatility. Moreover, in contrast to the standard GVAR models that rely on trade-weighted averages to capture both local and global effects, we treat these effects separately. Before describing our model specification, we provide a short exposition of the methodology and data. We consider a world economy composed of n þ 1 interconnected countries. Our focus is to model output growth and its responses to common shocks, either directly or indirectly through equity and bond markets. Specifically, for each economy i, we include the logarithm of real GDP (gdp it ), nominal long-term interest rate (lr it ), the logarithm of real equity prices (eq it ), and the logarithm of the real exchange rate (the nominal exchange rate deflated by the consumer price index), ep it . Data on these variables are obtained from the updated GVAR data set which includes 33 countries and covers the period 1979Q2 to 2019Q4. For a detailed description of data sources and related transformations see Mohaddes and Raissi (2020) . To avoid highly persistent variables we work with first-differences and denote the endogenous country-specific variables by The U.S. economy is denoted by i ¼ 0, with the remaining economies indexed by i ¼ 1; 2; . . . ; n, in no particular order. For estimation we suppose that y it is available over the period t ¼ 1; 2; . . . ; T, although the bond and equity variables, Dlr it and Deq it , are not available for some of the countries in our dataset. Therefore, the dimension of y it , which we denote by k i , differs across countries. Let k ¼ P n i¼0 k i , and collect all country-specific variables in a single k  1 vector Given the focus of our analysis, we augment the standard GVAR model with observed and unobserved external common factors. We consider changes in log oil prices, Dpoil t , and global volatility, grve t , as common observed factors and include them in the 2  1 vector In addition, we use the weighted cross-sectional averages of the following four variables to capture unobserved common factors: where gdp i is the PPP-GDP weight of country i, and similarly lr One could also apply the principal component analysis (PCA) to y t , but that would involve estimating 2 As a robustness check, we are able to detect the presence of threshold effects in a larger number of economies if we start the sample from 1990Q1. See Appendix B for the estimation results and other details. To link the global aggregates to the country-specific variables, we introduce a k  k weights matrix, W $ , and define it such thatỹ In addition to global aggregates, we also allow for transmission of shocks through the trade channel and consider countryspecific trade-weighted averages are the trade weights, j ¼ 0; 1; . . . n; w ii ¼ 0, and P n j¼0 w ij ¼ 1.For empirical application, the trade weights are computed as three-year averages: 3 where T ijt is the bilateral trade of country i with country j during a given year t and is calculated as the average of exports and imports of country i with j, and T it ¼ P n j¼0 T ijt (the total trade of country i) for t ¼ 2014; 2015 and 2016, in the case of all countries. A similar procedure is followed for the construction of Dlr à it ; Deq à it , and Dep à it . As it is well known in the GVAR literature, the country-specific aggregates y à it relate to y t through the following links where W i is the k i  k matrix of trade weights for country i. The main difference between the two sets of aggregates,ỹ t and y à it , for i ¼ 0; 1; . . . ; n, is the weights used in their construction. These two variables are likely to be highly correlated contemporaneously. The reason for considering both aggregates (cross-section averages) is to distinguish the effects of global factors from local (trade related) effects, captured by countryspecific trade linkages. Also to avoid multi-collinearity and related identification problems, we include only lagged countryspecific cross-section averages, y à i;tÀ1 , and rely on global cross-section averages,ỹ t , to capture contemporaneous effects of global factors. We specify the following equations for g t andỹ t 3 As an additional robustness check, we also re-estimated the model using weights based on data on a longer period from 1990-2016 and obtained very similar results. These results are not reported here but available upon request. Let f t ¼ g 0 t ;ỹ 0 t À Á 0 , and write (11) and (12) as where is the vector of reduced form global shocks, with We consider the following country-specific threshold-augmented models: The country-specific models in (14) are intended to capture the individual country VAR dynamics as well as common factors, f t , and local effects, y à i;tÀ1 . We have also confined the threshold variable, z tÀ1 c i ð Þ, to affect the intercepts only, but we do allow for these effects to vary across countries. These are pragmatic choices that we had to make to keep the model sufficiently parsimonious so that to obtain reasonably reliable estimates of the unknown parameters. We expect the threshold event, namely periods where grve tÀ1 > c i , to be quite rare and therefore to be most important in terms of its direct effect on output growth, which is best characterized by a shift in the intercept term. The possible effects of such rare events on growth persistent is likely to be of second order importance. Moreover, we limited the heterogeneity in c i by estimating only two threshold values, one pooled value for advanced economies and one for emerging markets. We allow the country-specific error vectors, u it , to be cross-sectionally weakly correlated. Adding non-granular (local) cross-section averages, of the dependent variables, y à i;t , also known as spatial lags, to the right side of (14) is common in the spatial literature, where the contemporaneous correlation (after controlling for lags and common factors) is fully parametrized by introducing spatial lags, which, if specified correctly, would then identify geographical origins of the shocks. We do not attempt to fully parametrize the cross sectional correlation of u it . For this reason, we only include lagged values of y à it in the country-specific models. Another important reason for why we do not include y à it as a regressor is the fact that, for a number of countries, some trading partners have a large weight in country-specific trade-weighted averages y à it . For example, U.S. is the dominant trading partner of Canada, with its trade weight exceeding 70 percent of the total. In such cases, we would expect that contemporaneous values of y à it to be correlated with u it , even if n ! 1. Including non-granular contemporaneous cross-section averages of the dependent variable in (14), would consequently result in inconsistent least squares estimation, owing to correlation between u it and the non-granular cross-sectional averages (spatial lags) even when n is large, and a full maximum likelihood or GMM type estimation will be required. Eqs. (11) and (12) are specifications for global variables and global aggregates. Eq. (14), for i ¼ 0; 1; . . . ; n, relates to country specific models. Eq. (15) links the threshold indicator with the vector of global variables. Moreover, we have two additional linking equations. Eq. (8) links global aggregatesỹ t with y t , and links the vector of country-specific trade-weighted averages y à t ¼ y Ã0 0;t ; y Ã0 1t ; y Ã0 2t ; . . . ; y Ã0 n;t 0 to the full k  1 vector of endogenous variables, y t , and Substituting (13) for f t in (14), we obtain Note that the substitution of the global model (13) for f t in the country-specific models (14) avoids the possibility of the rank-deficiency problem discussed in Section 4.1 of . In addition, it allows for an error structure that explicitly features common and idiosyncratic shocks. Our approach differs from the earlier GVAR models in the literature that only rely on the conditional country-specific equations in (14) and the marginal equation for the observed common variables g t in (11). In contrast, (17) utilizes the Eq. (12) forỹ t as well. This approach is also adopted by Cesa-Bianchi et al. (2020) and Chudik et al. (2020) . Stacking (17) for i ¼ 0; 1; 2; . . . ; n, we obtain where d ¼ d vector of threshold indicators, and Substituting identity (16) for y à tÀ1 in (18 ), we have and substituting (8) forỹ t , we obtain Substituting identity (8) forỹ tÀ1 in equations for g t in (11), we have Stacking (19) and (20), we obtain the following TGVAR representation for the full set of observables, the k þ 2 ð Þ 1 vector where c ¼ d where e t is a vector of reduced form shocks, composed of global (v t ) and idiosyncratic shocks (e t ). Given our focus on the output effects of the Covid-19 shock, and to keep the analyses empirically manageable, we consider the effects of the threshold variable on the output growth variables only, and accordingly set k y;i ¼ k Dgdp;i ; 0; 0; 0 À Á 0 . Without loss of generality, we identify advanced economies by i ¼ 0; 1; . . . ; n a and the emerging market countries by i ¼ n a þ 1; n a þ 2; . . . ; n. Moreover, currently available time series observations do not allow for the estimation of countryspecific threshold effects which capture rare events. Thus, we can only estimate two threshold parameters, distinguishing between advanced and emerging economies: Identifying the economic effects of Covid-19 is not a straightforward task as our historical sample is not informative about such a shock. Also considering the truly global nature of the pandemic, it is not possible to compare economic outcomes from countries affected by Covid-19 with a control group that has not been buffeted by the Covid-19 shock. At best, we could compare economic outcomes across countries that followed different strategies to mitigate the spread of the pandemic. This approach is also limited as most countries have followed very similar approaches (for example, lockdowns) with just a few exceptions (such as Sweden which we consider below), and they differ mainly in terms of the timing of the implemented social distancing policies (for example, Germany and the United Kingdom). Here we adopt a historical country-specific approach and identify the Covid-19 shock by comparing the IMF's GDP projections for Q1 to Q4 of 2020 formed at the end of 2019-before the spread of the pandemic and when no one (including the IMF) could have predicted the global economic disruption that was brought about by the pandemic-to the same projections prepared in April 2020. We attribute the IMF's GDP projection revisions in 2020Q1 to the Covid-19 shock. In effect, we assume that the short-term IMF projections at the end of 2019 were free from systemic bias and can be used as potential outcomes in the absence of the Covid-19 shock. We believe this is a reasonable identifying assumption, in view of the unprecedented nature of the Covid-19 pandemic. Accordingly, we assume that up to 2019Q4 (t ¼ 1; 2; . . . ; T), e t is given by (23), but for Q1 to Q4 of 2020, it is given by e Tþq ¼ x Tþq þ Cv Tþq þ e Tþq ; for q ¼ 1; 2; 3; 4; ð26Þ where x Tþq corresponds to the Covid-19 shock in the period T þ q. We assume x t ¼ 0 for t 6 T, but it is nonzero for To identify x Tþq we will use the size of IMF's projection revisions at the end 2020Q1. April i;Tþq be the April 2020 IMF World Economic Outlook (WEO) GDP growth projections for country i in quarters q ¼ 1; 2; 3; 4 of 2020, and Dgdp Jan i;Tþq be the associated January 2020 IMF WEO projections. We compute the April-January projection revisions as j i;q ¼ Dgdp April i;Tþq À Dgdp Jan i;Tþq ; for q ¼ 1; 2; 3; 4; and i ¼ 0; 1; 2; . . . ; n. Assuming that developments surrounding Covid-19 were the only dominant developments behind the projection revisions, we use j q ¼ j 1;q ; j 2;q ; . . . ; j n;q À Á 0 , for q ¼ 1; 2; 3; 4 to infer x Tþq . Note that growth outturns in 2020 were subsequently affected by the massive scale-up of policy actions by governments (for example, global fiscal support was increased from $3.3 trillion in April 2020 to $16 trillion in April 2021). To the extent possible, we try to abstract from these factors in our counterfactual analysis to identify the Covid-19 shock from policy responses to mitigate its effects. For this reason and as expected, the actual growth outturns in 2020 (reported in Table 2 ) were somewhat different from the April 2020 growth projections of the IMF that served as our baseline. 4 Let us define S as the matrix that selects all output growth variables from the vector x t , namely Sx t ¼ Dgdp t ¼ Dgdp 0t ; Dgdp 1t ; . . . :; Dgdp nt ð Þ 0 : We set individual elements of x Tþ1 that correspond to GDP to be given by the corresponding j i;1 , and use the historical correlations of the reduced form errors to estimate the remaining elements. This yieldŝ x Tþq for q ¼ 2; 3; 4 are computed recursively aŝ In (27) and (28), we infer the sequence of shocksx Tþq ; q ¼ 1; 2; 3; 4, using revisions in the IMF projections for the paths of GDP and the corresponding predictions of our global model. Specifically, we define the Covid-19 effects by the difference where x c Tþh is a counterfactual realization of the global economy after the Covid-19 shock hit the economy, namely x Tþj ¼x Tþj È É 4 j¼1 , and x 0 Tþh ¼ E x Tþh jI T ð Þis the conditional expectation of global economy without the Covid-19 shock, conditioning on the information I T ¼ x T ; x TÀ1 ; . . . Our model includes 33 economies, which together cover more than 90% of world GDP, see Table 3 . For presentation of our results, we create a euro area block comprising 8 of the 11 countries that initially joined the Euro in 1999: Austria, Belgium, Finland, France, Germany, Italy, Netherlands, and Spain. The time series data for the euro area are constructed as crosssectionally weighted averages of the domestic variables, using Purchasing Power Parity GDP weights, averaged over the 2014 to 2016 period. In addition to the euro area we also consider a further seven regions, see Table 3 . comes given the constellation of shocks experienced over the past four decades. Note that the median impulse responses for 2020Q1-Q4 match the April 2020 growth projections of the IMF by design. Uncertainty around these projections are pervasive because of the severity and duration of the Covid-19 pandemic, global spillovers, financial market volatility, the efficacy of policy actions to protect firms and households, and the success of pharmaceutical interventions to contain the spread of the virus. Overall, the Covid-19 pandemic would leave the 2021 GDP about 3 percentage points lower than the model-generated forecast of global GDP in the absence of Covid-19. The adverse impact on Advanced Economies is particularly large-ranging from 2 percentage points below pre-crisis path of GDP by the end of 2021 in the euro area to 6.5 percentage points in the United States. 6 Among emerging markets, however, the economic impact of Covid-19 varies substantially. In addition to domestic shocks (health crisis and lockdowns), these countries faced a range of external shocks in early 2020 as well (plunging trade, collapsing tourism, capital outflows, falling commodity prices), albeit to varying degrees, and have different economic structures (those relying heavily on certain sectors are naturally more vulnerable to the adverse macroeconomic effects of the pandemic). China appears to be an exception largely because most of the country had reopened by early April and its lower size of inward spillovers. Emerging Asia excluding China is expected to be less affected by Covid-19 than Latin America. This is partly due to higher commodity dependence of the latter and tighter financing conditions initially, as well as being less successful is containing the pandemic. Fig. 4 reports the results of our counterfactual exercise for real GDP of Sweden under two scenarios: (i) growth shock in all 33 countries in our sample arising from the Covid-19 pandemic and (ii) growth shock in all countries except for Sweden. Comparing the two sets of results highlights the importance of spillovers through disruptions in global supply chains, travel, and tourism. The results in Fig. 4 illustrate that no country can shield itself from the adverse economic effects of Covid-19 by following less stringent lockdowns. Figs. 5 and 6 report the results of our counterfactual exercise for the evolution of real GDP following the Covid-19 shock relative to the 2019Q4 output levels rather than the model-generated forecasts of real GDP in the absence of Covid-19. In other words, we assess how long it will take for different countries/regions to return to their 2019Q4 real GDP levels following the Covid-19 shock. Informed by the April 2020 vintage of the IMF growth projections and our counterfactuals, global activity is estimated to trough in the second quarter of 2020, recovering thereafter. The estimated recovery in global activity is mainly driven by Asian economies (most notably China) while the United States and the United Kingdom are less likely to recuperate income losses by the end of 2021 (that is, their GDP is projected to end 2021 below 2019Q4 levels by about 2 and 1.5 percent with high probability, respectively). Consistent with the results in Fig. 3 , China's real GDP is expected to recover rapidly the lost ground, while non-Asian emerging economies are likely to take longer to achieve a full recovery. In all cases, there is a significant amount of uncertainly around the counterfactual GDP paths. See also Table 4 for likely growth outcomes. Note that these growth outcomes will be significantly worse if one were to use the updated projection revisions of the IMF in June 2020 to gauge the size of the shock rather than the April vintage (see Appendix C for details). This is because in June, the IMF updated its GDP projections based on more information about the pathway of the pandemic and the intensity and efficacy of containment efforts. The IMF, therefore, downgraded its projections of growth in the first half of 2020 and portrayed a more gradual recovery thereafter than previously projected. Global public debt is expected to reach its highest recorded level (about 100 percent of global GDP and higher than the post-World War II peaks) partly driven by the massive fiscal response to the Covid-19 pandemic (9.2 percent of 2020 GDP in additional spending and foregone revenue globally as of April 2021). At the same time, the 10-year government bond yields are at their historical lows and negative in several advanced economies (Fig. 7) . To the extent that borrowing costs stay at low levels, they make it easier to service public debt. Fig. 8 reports the results of our counterfactual exercise for long-term interest rates between 2020Q1 and 2021Q4. For advanced economies (especially those that are perceived to be safe havens), long-term interest rates are estimated to temporarily fall even below their pre-Covid levels as the crisis raises precautionary savings and dampens investment demand. However, the same cannot be said about emerging market economies where borrowing rates can increase rapidly as shown by the upper range of our counterfactual exercise in Fig. 8 . Among safe havens, Japan appears to be an exception possibly driven by Bank of Japan's policy of yield-curve control. These predictions are largely borne out by actual data. For example, in the first half of 2020, 10-year government bond yields in the United States, the United Kingdom, and Germany fell by 111, 44, and 10 basis points, respectively, and that of Japan increased by 10 basis points-all within our counterfactual ranges displayed in Fig. 8 . Among emerging markets, South Africa experienced a 137 basis points increase in its 10-year government bond yields during the first half of 2020again within our prediction ranges. The Covid-19 pandemic has been a shock like no other, initiating simultaneous demand and supply disruptions. In addition, it led to a sharp tightening in global financial market conditions during the first quarter of 2020. Using quarterly data over the past four decades, we first showed that global financial market volatility (beyond certain thresholds) can adversely affect economic growth in a significant majority (80 percent) of advanced countries and for several emerging market economies. We then developed a threshold-augmented dynamic multi-country model, or TGVAR for short, to study the global macroeconomic effects of Covid-19. We identified the country-specific Covid-19 shocks by comparing IMF's GDP projections for Q1 to Q4 of 2020 formed at the end of 2019 (before the spread of the pandemic) to the same projections prepared in April 2020. Finally, using the TGVAR model we quantified the range of likely macroeconomic outcomes following the Covid-19 shock. Our results showed that the Covid-19 pandemic could lead to long-lasting declines in world real GDP with varied effects across regions/countries. The impact of Covid-19 on the UK, and several other advanced economies could be particularly severe, while China and other emerging Asian economies are estimated to fare better. We also estimated that the Covid-19 pandemic can temporarily lower long-term interest rates below their pre-Covid-19 lows in core advanced economies, but the reverse outcome is predicted for emerging markets, with implications for debt servicing costs. Our findings highlighted the importance of policy interventions to restore the normal functioning of financial markets, as well as adopting other measures (fiscal and liquidity) that can limit bankruptcies of viable firms and support incomes of households. These measures would likely limit the amount of scarring. Note that the pandemic resurfaces in waves-that is, with every easing of social distancing restrictions, the infection rates rise again, requiring the re-imposition of local restrictions, as we saw in Europe and the US in late 2020 and India latelydampening economic activity and confidence. Appendix C shows how more up-to-date information about the pathway of the pandemic (considering its rarity) can affect our predictions. Data available in data repository at https://data.mendeley.com/datasets/5kp6h6ttx3. 4. Steps 1 À 3 are repeated for r ¼ 1; 2; . . . ; R. Mean of x 0 Tþh is estimated as This appendix provides additional results on the choice of the global volatility measure (Section B.1) and and on the robustness of the threshold effects to the choice of the sample period (Section B.2). In addition to our preferred measure of global volatility, or grve t -given by (1)-, we consider the realized volatility of the global equity returns, or rvge t -given by (3)--, and the VIX index, vix t (http://www.cboe.com/vix). The VIX index is available on the CBOE website from 1990. 9 To differentiate among these measures, we compute the average of squared residuals (MSE) of the threshold-augmented dynamic output growth models Dgdp it ¼ c i þ q i Dgdp itÀ1 þ u i z tÀ1 c ð Þ þ e it . We plot the minimized MSE for different values of the threshold parameter (c). We consider indicator-specific grids of thresholds defined by the set S p;T ¼ j=T; p min < j=T < p max f g ; namely, the indicator-specific grid of thresholds is given by 1 À p ð Þquantiles of the given indicator, p 2 S p;T . The results clearly show that the grve t measure performs best in terms of MSEs in all cases considered, and is preferred over the other two measures. Note that the underlying regression models contain the same number of estimated parameters and as a result the MSE outcomes across the three measures are comparable. Therefore, we conclude that data speaks in favor of grve t , which happened to be our choice based on our a priori arguments spelled out in the paper. We also investigate the robustness of our threshold effects to the choice of time period. To this end we consider the subsample 1990Q1-2019Q4 which excludes the 1987 stock market crash whose macroeconomic impact was rather short lived, avoids breaks in error variances due to the so called ''Great Moderation", and better captures the trade and financial market globalization of emerging economies that gathered pace post 1990. The results, in Table B .1, show that in 16 advanced economies and 5 emerging markets (out of 19 and 14 countries in each income group, respectively), global volatility (grve t ) (i.e., beyond the threshold c) is associated with lower output growth subsequently. While the estimate of c remains unchanged, we are able to detect the presence of threshold effects in a larger number of economies. 9 Historical VIX data can be downloaded from here: https://www.cboe.com/tradable_products/vix/vix_historical_data/. This data is subject to a change in methodology that occured in September 22, 2003. Appendix C. Counterfactual analysis using June-January IMF projection revisions The IMF revised its growth projections down for most countries in June as the extent of the Covid-19 shock and its economic fallout became clearer. In this appendix, we use these updated projections to gauge the size of the GDP shock arising from the Covid-19 pandemic. Let Dgdp June i;Tþq be the June 2020 IMF World Economic Outlook (WEO) GDP growth projections for country i in quarters q ¼ 1; 2; 3; 4 of 2020, and Dgdp Jan i;Tþq be the associated January 2020 IMF WEO projections. We compute the June-January projection revisions as j i;q ¼ Dgdp June i;Tþq À Dgdp Jan i;Tþq ; for q ¼ 1; 2; 3; 4; and i ¼ 0; 1; 2; . . . ; n. Assuming that developments surrounding Covid-19 were the only dominant developments behind the projection revisions, we use j q ¼ j 1;q ; j 2;q ; . . . ; j n;q À Á 0 , for q ¼ 1; 2; 3; 4 to infer x Tþq and repeat the counterfactual analysis in Section 3. The results are reported in Figs. C.1,C.2,C.3 and Table C.1. While the new estimates are qualitatively similar to those reported in the main text, they indicate worse growth outcomes and longer recoveries quantitatively. Notes: Our threshold-augmented dynamic output growth model is given by Dgdp it ¼ c i þ q i Dgdp itÀ1 þ u i z tÀ1 c ð Þ þ e it , where Dgdp it is the first difference of the logarithm of real GDP in country i during quarter t and zt ¼ I grve t > c ð Þ .I A ð Þ is an indicator variable that takes the value of unity if event A occurs and zero otherwise. grve t is a measure of global volatility defined by (1), and c is the threshold parameter. The estimation sample is 1990Q1 to 2019Q4. Statistical significance is denoted by à ; y and à , at 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. 2. MSE Objective Functions Using the 1990Q1-2019Q4 Subsample. Notes: This chart shows average MSE of the threshold-augmented dynamic ð Þ þ eit estimated for the grid of threshold values (x-axis) for three choices of volatility measures: grve t (solid blue line), rvge t (dotted orange line) and vixt Nonlinear Production Networks with an Application to the Covid-19 Crisis. CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP14742 Modelling Global Trade Flows: Results from a GVAR Model. Globalization and Monetary Policy Institute Working Paper 119 Understanding and Avoiding the Oil Curse in Resource-Rich Arab Economies Fair Weather or Foul? The Macroeconomic Effects of El Niño China's Slowdown and Global Financial Market Volatility: Is World Growth Losing Out? Emerging Markets Rev The Differential Effects of Oil Demand and Supply Shocks on the Global Economy Uncertainty and Economic Activity: A Multicountry Perspective China's Emergence in the World Economy and Business Cycles in Latin America A Multi-country Approach to Forecasting Output Growth Using PMIs Covid-19 Fiscal Support and its Effectiveness Infinite Dimensional VARs and Factor Models Theory and Practice of GVAR Modeling Identifying Global and National Output and Fiscal Policy Shocks Using a GVAR The Macroeconomics of a Pandemic: A Minimalist Model Exploring the International Linkages of the Euro Area: A Global VAR Analysis The GVAR Handbook: Structure and Applications of a Macro Model of the Global Economy for Policy Analysis Fiscal Policies for a Transformed World Threshold Autoregressions in Economics The Rate of Return on Everything Impulse Response Analysis in Nonlinear Multivariate Models The Global Macroeconomic Impacts of COVID-19: Seven Scenarios COVID-19 Outbreak, Social Response, and Early Economic Effects: A Global VAR Analysis of Cross-Country Interdependencies Country-Specific Oil Supply Shocks and the Global Economy: A Counterfactual Analysis Oil Prices and the Global Economy: Is it Different this Time Around? The U.S. Oil Supply Revolution and the Global Economy Compilation, Revision and Updating of the Global VAR (GVAR) Database, 1979Q2-2019Q4 Time Series and Panel Data Econometrics Forecasting Economic and Financial Variables with Global VARs Modelling Regional Interdependencies using a Global Error-Correcting Macroeconometric Model Non-linear Time Series: a Dynamical System Approach. Oxford Statistical Science Series Testing and Modeling Multivariate Threshold Models This appendix provides technical details on the estimation and simulation of the threshold-augmented GVAR (TGVAR) model. Section A.1 describes how we estimate the model, while Section A.2 explains the bootstrapping procedure we use to capture the uncertainty of the parameter estimates. Sections A.3 and A.4 outline how we simulate x 0Tþh and x c Tþh , respectively. Let p min ¼ 1% and p max ¼ 20%. 7 We set S p;T ¼ j=T; p min < j=T < p max f g , and our grid set for c is given bywhere q grve a ð Þ is a quantile of grve 1 ; grve 2 ; . . . ; grve T f g , and grve t is the global volatility measure for quarter t, defined by (1).ðA:2Þ is estimated by least squares. For a given c s 2 S c , we set c i ¼ c s for all i belonging either to advanced and emerging economies, and estimate 8ðA:3Þ by least squares. Estimates of (A.2) and (A.3) are used to obtain the GVAR representation forðA:4Þwhere I adv is the index set of advanced economies, and I eme is the index set of emerging economies. Given the estimatesĉ adv andĉ eme , we setĉ i ¼ĉ adv if economy i belongs to the group of advanced economies andĉ i ¼ĉ eme if economy i belongs to the group of emerging economies. Then (A.3) is re-estimated usingĉ adv orĉ eme (depending on the country grouping). We have excluded the threshold variable from countries wherek Dgdp;i > 0. The corresponding GVAR model is then estimated and solved based on (A.2) and (A.3). In particular, using hats to denote the corresponding estimates, we haveGx tÀ1 þKz tÀ1ĉ ð Þ þê t ;ê t ¼Ĉv t þê t : This section describes how we generate bootstrap replications ofĉ; b G;K;Ĉ;v t andê t , denoted asĉ r