key: cord-0785481-pdlw3qzg authors: Hosseini-Motlagh, Seyyed-Mahdi; Nami, Nazanin; Farshadfar, Zeinab title: Collection disruption management and channel coordination in a socially concerned closed-loop supply chain: a game theory approach date: 2020-09-18 journal: J Clean Prod DOI: 10.1016/j.jclepro.2020.124173 sha: dddef7d532e637849dc88e8d7f6debdf3b23a8cc doc_id: 785481 cord_uid: pdlw3qzg Uncertainty in real-world situations disrupts operations, including the collection process in closed-loop supply chains (CLSCs). A collection disruption is more critical in the pharmaceutical sector since pharmaceutical leftovers contain chemicals that threaten the environment and human health. This paper revolves around the challenges of a real pharmaceutical case that implements circular economy principles through a closed-loop system design, takes sustainability issues into account, and seeks for effective management of collection disruption. The case includes a manufacturer, who invests in green research and development (R&D), and two retailers competing on corporate social responsibility (CSR) efforts to boost the collection amount and market demand. This competitive environment raises conflict of interests and complicates the interactions between members, which need to be neutralized by an appropriate coordination plan. This paper proposes an analytical scenario-based coordination model that resolves channel conflicts and pays dividends to the involving members through augmenting their social, economic, and environmental performance. We show that the coordination plan could be a practical policy to increase the system’s adaptability to disruption. Under the coordinated model, by increasing a retailer’s collection disruption, the other one invests more in CSR efforts to compensate for its competitor’s lower collection, preventing loss for the whole channel. We also demonstrate that the proposed model maintains the chain’s balance and prevents loss in case of a highly competitive CSR-based collection and boosts the collection amount, market demand, and the whole chain’s profitability simultaneously. coordination contract with the Tsuchiya factory, an electric switch producer . Toyota Motor Corporation, and an Indian holding company, TATA group, take advantage of the trade credit coordination contract to their dealerships . This paper studies a real CLSC in the pharmaceutical industry, namely DG (the company's name is abbreviated to ensure confidentiality) that produces "Tolidin" in plastic containers and distributes its products through duopolistic competing retailers under a decentralized setting. DG tends to promote the sustainability level of the system via reusing its plastic medication containers and investing in research and development (R&D) activities with an eco-friendly perspective (green R&D). Green issues have gained strong worldwide attention (Safarzadeh et al., 2020a, Safarzadeh and Rasti-Barzoki, 2019a) , and R&D investment is a significant decision variable in the pharmaceutical sector. In the United States, the ratio of R&D investment to sales revenue in the pharmaceutical industry is five times more than the average in all sectors (Nouri et al., 2018) . The retailers assume the collection responsibility and boost the return amount by participating in CSR activities. Meanwhile, the above-mentioned CLSC faces substantial challenges, such as (i) aligning the conflict of interests and managing the complex interactions between the involved parties; (ii) acting in a competitive environment; and (iii) facing uncertainty of the collection process, caused by disruption, which frustrate the chain's performance. While supply, demand, and production disruptions have been widely studied in the literature (Guo et al., 2019 , Huang and Wang, 2018 , Han et al., 2017 , Chen and Xiao, 2009 , Giri and Sarker, 2016 , Li et al., 2015 , collection disruption is neglected by the previous researchers. However, collection disruption highly affects the performance of the CLSCs, since the successful performance of these systems depends on the effective management of the collection process and the reverse flow (Hosseini-Motlagh et al., 2019c) . Contributing to the previous literature investigating disruptions in CLSCs, this study evaluates the performance of such systems in the face of collection disruptions. When the collection process is disrupted, (i) the retailers (collectors) collect lower items and lose some profit, and (ii) the manufacturer receives lower resources and incurs an extra cost. Therefore, in such a case, not only the retailers' profit is affected, but also the manufacturer's performance is exacerbated. In the literature, various promotional offers, such as purchase price (Bulmuş et al., 2014) , reward-penalty (Wang et al., 2017) , discount offer , economic incentives (Hosseini-Motlagh et al., 2020c) , collection investment (Sabbaghnia and Taleizadeh, 2020) , and acquisition price (Hosseini-Motlagh et al., 2020a) , have been proposed to augment the collection amount of used products, while CSR participation has not been studied in this regard. We contribute to this literature and investigate the case where two competitive retailers exert CSR as an incentive policy to raise the consumers' willingness to return their plastic containers, which also affects the demand for new products. Accordingly, these efforts determine both the raw material supply (derived from collected products) and the sales amount (demand) of the J o u r n a l P r e -p r o o f pharmaceutical manufacturer. As a result, the manufacturer's performance depends also on the retailers' decisions (Hosseini-Motlagh et al., 2020c) . CSR participation of retailers causes competition between them and complicates the interactions within the chain. Besides, the DG Company tends to invest in green R&D efforts to produce more environmentally friendly products. Green R&D efforts influence the customer's tendency to buy the manufacturer's products and thus influence the retailers' demand in the investigated market (from a theoretical viewpoint, such impacts of these efforts are also addressed by the previous literature such as Levin and Reiss (1989) ). Due to such interrelations between the members' decisions, it is of high importance to implement a practical coordination mechanism to deal with CLSC challenges and manage the interactions between the members (Chen and Xiao, 2015) . This study analytically explores the role of coordination models in enhancing the performance of such systems dealing with competition in both forward and reverse channels and facing disruptions. It is worth mentioning that such a scenario might occur in many companies and industries, and the proposed models are generalizable to any production system with similar attributes. The primary purpose of this paper is to develop an analytical model for tackling the abovementioned challenges of the investigated case, generalizable to similar production systems. To this end, the paper develops a scenario-based coordination model for tackling collection disruption, R&D efforts, and competitive CSR activities of two retailers in both forward and reverse channels. The model is investigated in the decentralized system, which indicates the current situation of the case. Since DG and the retailers determine their decisions individually, this setting leads to locally optimal solutions and frustrates the efficiency of the system. Afterwards, the centralized decision-making structure is modeled, which gives a benchmark for measuring the best performance of the system. However, centralization is not acceptable for all members, since it maximizes the objective of the whole system and neglects the benefit of individual members. Therefore, to coordinate the system and ensure the members' participation in the centralization, a profit-sharing mechanism is proposed, and the fairness of the profit-sharing is guaranteed by a simple Nash-bargaining model. Overall, the main contributions of this study are as follows: • The present paper analytically analyzes collection disruption as a source of uncertainty in a pharmaceutical closed-loop supply chain (PCLSC). • This study proposes competitive CSR participation of retailers as an incentive strategy to boost the collection volume and market demand of the PCLSC in forward and reverse channels, respectively. • We develop a model for simultaneous coordination of competitive CSR efforts, collection disruption, and green R&D, implementing a profit-sharing contract and Nash-bargaining game model to ensure the fairness of the coordination scheme. J o u r n a l P r e -p r o o f • Last but not least, this study revolves around a real pharmaceutical case and tries to manage the significant challenges of the case effectively. However, the proposed models are generalizable to any production system with similar attributes. The rest of this study is arranged as follows. Section 2 contains the related literature review. Section 3 describes the investigated problem. Section 4 represents the objective functions under the scenario-based decentralized, centralized, and coordinated systems alongside the optimal R&D investment and competitive CSR efforts. Sections 5 and 6 demonstrate analytical and numerical results of a real case study in detail, respectively. Finally, Section 7 includes concluding remarks, managerial insights, and future research directions. All proofs are available in the Online Supplementary Appendix. In this section, we review the literature related to this paper. To this end, four research streams, i.e. (i) CLSCs and collection strategies in CLSCs, (ii) competition in CLSCs and channel coordination, (iii) CSR, and (iv) disruption management in supply chains and supply chain coordination are reviewed in separate sub-sections. Finally, research gaps and contributions of the study are explained. Sustainability issues being widely noticed (Safarzadeh and Rasti-Barzoki, 2020, Safarzadeh and Rasti-Barzoki, 2019b), many companies have decided to design a CLSC. In recent literature, various promotional offers have been proposed to augment the collection amount of used products by increasing the consumers' willingness to return used products . For instance, Bulmuş et al. (2014) used purchase price as a customer incentive to increase the return rate. Additionally, Wang et al. price as incentives for customers to return more items. Besides, some papers suggest that the incentive policies could not only raise the return quantity of used products but also affect the market demand for new products. For example, Das and Dutta (2013) illustrated that a product exchange plan applied to a CLSC improves the collection amount of used products as well as the total demand. However, to the best of our knowledge, CSR as an incentive plan has not been noticed in the literature, while it is currently applied in practice. In the pharmaceutical sector, Ritchie et al. (2000) revealed the benefits of pharmaceutical reverse logistics for 28 hospitals in the UK, having the potential for considerable financial savings. Likewise, Khan and Subzwari (2009) stated that developments in the reverse channels saved at least 10% of costs in the studied pharmaceutical system in Pakistan. The whole pharmaceutical supply chain benefits from J o u r n a l P r e -p r o o f medicines procurement associated with reverse logistics (Xie and Breen, 2014) . However, improper coordination and collaboration between the involving parties are identified as the major hindrances in pharmaceutical CLSCs (Viegas et al., 2019 , Ding, 2018 Many researchers have investigated competition as a factor that dramatically affects the performance of CLSCs. For example, Jena and Sarmah (2014) investigated the competition on new product demand and the return rate of used products. They concluded that the channel achieves its best performance under a cooperative system. Qiang (2015) analyzed the effects of competition on the manufacturers' market share. Fallah et al. (2015) investigated the Stackelberg competition on the retail prices and customer incentives between two CLSCs. Wang et al. (2018) considered two types of competition: (i) competition between collectors and (ii) competition between new and remanufactured products. Afterward, He et al. links. It is found that implementing supply chain coordination is remarkably useful in the presence of competing members (De Giovanni, 2018) . However, the simultaneous effects of competition on both forward and reverse channels have not been adequately noticed in the channel coordination literature (Fallah et al., 2015) . CSR activities are becoming increasingly important in recent decades. Many scholars have investigated the effects of CSR efforts in supply chains. For instance, Nematollahi et al. (2017) implemented a collaborative mechanism to coordinate CSR investment decisions in a supply chain. Moreover, Panda et al. (2017) examined the effects of CSR in a CLSC. They demonstrated that channel coordination is a practical policy to share CSR costs between members and enhance the CSR performance level. The effect of different game structures in a socially responsible supply chain is studied by Seyedhosseini et al. (2019) . Raj et al. (2018) coordinated greening and CSR activities and showed that sustainability is beneficial for companies. Raza (2018) coordinated a supply chain with price-CSR dependent demand in both deterministic and stochastic conditions. In addition, Hosseini-Motlagh et al. Non-CSR strategies are better to be adopted. Disruption as a result of uncertainty in the real cases damages the whole CLSC performance, and the research depth of this field is increasing in the literature. For instance, Jabbarzadeh et al. (2016) presented J o u r n a l P r e -p r o o f a supply chain resilient to supply, demand, and facility disruptions using a robust-stochastic optimization model. Moreover, Guo et al. (2019) investigated the probability of supply disruption and government subsidy in a CLSC. Likewise, Giri and Sharma (2016) studied uncertain demand and return rate in a hybrid CLSC. Then, a CLSC with remanufacturing cost disruption is developed by Wu et al. (2018) . Besides, Li et al. (2016) studied the non-delivery penalty and financing assistance strategies for supply disruption in a supply chain. Song (2019) proposed an adjusted revenue-sharing contract to hedge against demand disruption in a closed-loop supply chain. To the best of our knowledge, disruption occurrence regarding the collection process, which is a significant issue in both theory and practice, has not been studied in the literature. Coordination plans are good means of improving the supply chain profitability and balance the including parties' conflict of interests (Yan et al., 2017) . Therefore, many papers utilize this approach to manage disruptions in production systems. Here are some papers using coordination schemes to deal with disruptions in supply chains: Xiao and Qi (2008) managed cost and demand disruptions applying two different modified quantity discount contracts. Chen and Xiao (2009) also coordinated a supply chain under demand disruption by a linear quantity discount model. Then, Cao et al. (2013) used an improved revenue-sharing contract to deal with demand and cost disruption. Additionally, Mohammadzadeh and Zegordi (2016) coordinated a supply chain under supply disruption and uncertain market demand. Buyback and revenue-sharing contracts with production disruption are examined by Giri and Sarker (2017) . A transshipment contract is developed by Aslani and Heydari (2019) in order to coordinate a supply chain under disruption probability. Although there are numerous papers that have coordinated a chain under disruptions, they neglect the important issue of CSR competition in both forward and reverse channels of their network and also, they lack the issue of collection disruption in their reverse channel, which is a critical hindrance to companies' performance. The above-reviewed studies illustrate the main contributions of this study as follows. First, different from the previous studies (Guo et al., 2019 , Huang and Wang, 2018 , Han et al., 2017 , Chen and Xiao, 2009 , Giri and Sarker, 2016 , Li et al., 2015 , Song, 2019 , which have considered disruption regarding supply, demand, and production, this study is the first to investigate disruption occurring in the collection process in the channel coordination context. Second, while many papers have investigated competition on various decisions, such as acquisition price (Bulmuş et al., 2014) , retail price, and customer incentive (Fallah et al., 2015) , in either forward or reverse channels of a supply chain, studies on competition in both the forward and reverse channels are scarce (Fallah et al., 2015) . However, to the best of our knowledge, this paper is the first to evaluate the effects of competitive CSR efforts on both the market demand and collection amount, as important practical and theoretical issues, in the context of supply chain coordination. Third, the previous studies in the CLSC coordination literature usually consider the J o u r n a l P r e -p r o o f collection amount to be dependent on incentives, such as discounts or acquisition prices, while in this paper, we propose the CSR participation as the factor influencing the collection rate. Besides, according to Campos et al. (2017) , studies in the field of product reuse in the pharmaceutical industry are scarce, while the current paper suggests reusing products and green R&D as strategies toward achieving sustainability in the pharmaceutical sector. Moreover, it analyzes the effects of green R&D on market demand. Furthermore, this study implements a profit-sharing contract to coordinate the interactions of the mentioned elements in a two-echelon PCLSC, and the Nash-bargaining game model is applied to ensure the fairness of the coordination scheme. A real PCLSC related to the DG Company (the pharma-manufacturer) and its retailers is investigated in this paper. DG provides the medications in plastic containers and seeks to collect plastic containers from the customer zone in order to reuse them. To this end, DG assigns the collection responsibility to the retailers. The retailers try to motivate customers to return their empty plastic containers by doing CSR activities, such as raising public awareness about the detrimental effects of pharmaceutical leftovers on the environment. Moreover, the retailers compete on collecting the plastic containers by improving their CSR attempts. Thus, the collection function of retailer ( ) can be formulated as , 1, 2; where is the CSR investment level of retailer ( ), is the initial amount of plastic containers collected by retailer ( ), is the intrinsic CSR efforts elasticity coefficient of each retailer's collection function, and is the cross-CSR efforts elasticity coefficient of each retailer's collection function. The total return quantity for DG is obtained by ∑ . The retailers inspect the collected items, deliver them to DG, and receive a collection fee per item returned. Afterward, the items go through inspection, cleaning, and disinfection processes before entering the production line at DG's site. CSR participation, such as increasing customer environmental awareness, not only affects the collection amount but also boosts the market demand of the retailers. Therefore, the retailers' CSR competition arises in either forward channel or reverse channel of the PCLSC. Moreover, DG applies green R&D (e.g., considering environmental issues in drug formulation, manufacturing, and packaging) as an eco-friendly policy that affects Coordination with contract Sustainable chain Collection disruption Competition in forward channel Competition in reverse channel Closed-loop supply chain CSR activities as an incentive for collection J o u r n a l P r e -p r o o f the market demand, as well. The demand function for retailer ( ) is formulated as , 1, 2; where is DG's green R&D efforts level, is the initial demand of each retailer, is the intrinsic CSR efforts elasticity coefficient of each retailer's demand function, and is the cross-CSR efforts elasticity coefficient of each retailer's demand function. The total demand of DG is obtained by ∑ . Note that due to health policies, the retail price and wholesale price of pharmaceutical products are under the control of the government, and therefore, the mentioned parameters are considered exogenous in this problem, which cannot be changed. The collection process, as a significant aspect of the mentioned PCLSC, is prone to disruptions that could be caused by numerous unexpected incidents. Collection disruption occurrence lessens the return quantity, which in turn endangers the PCLSC objectives. Let 0 < < 1 be the probability that retailer ( ) faces disruption during the collection process. In such a case, retailer ( ) is unable to collect and deliver plastic containers, and DG incurs an extra cost. To analyze the problem, four scenarios are considered based on disruption occurrence (Giri and Sarker, 2016) : • Scenario (3): Retailer (2) faces collection disruption, and no disruption occurs at retailer (1) • Scenario (4): The collection disruption happens for both retailers. Overall, the DG Company seeks ways to: improve the collection amount of the used products, manage the competitive environment, deal with the uncertainty of the collection process, find the optimal R&D and CSR investment levels, and manage the interactions between the involved parties. Therefore, the current study aims to find the optimal green R&D level and CSR investment decisions in a competitive CLSC system under different disruption scenarios. Moreover, this paper evaluates the channel coordination approach as a strategy to manage the interactive effects of DG's green R&D efforts, the retailers' competitive CSR practices, and disruption in the collection process. The scenario-based decentralized model of the investigated problem is developed under the Stackelberg game, considering the manufacturer as the leader, and the retailers as its followers. Afterward, the centralized decision-making system is devised as a benchmark for the best performance of the system, and then, a profit-sharing coordination scheme is proposed to coordinate the members' decisions and ensures their benefit. The Nash-bargaining game is applied as the profit-allocation plan. Note that these scenarios may occur in various industries, and the proposed models are generalizable to any reverse channel with similar attributes. Figure In this section, we explain the important assumptions considered in the proposed model. Intrinsic CSR efforts elasticity coefficients of each retailer's demand and collection functions are greater than the cross-CSR efforts elasticity coefficient ones. Besides, the manufacturer sells the products to the retailer with a higher price than production cost, and the retailer sells the products to the customers at a higher price than the wholesale price (the retailer's purchasing cost). Cost efficiency coefficient of the manufacturer's green effort In this paper, the methodology of supply chain coordination with the profit-sharing contract is implemented. In a supply chain, there are two decision-making structures: 1. Decentralized: under the decentralized decision-making structure, each member makes decisions to optimize its benefit regardless of the other members' profit. This individual decision-making model results in inefficient, locally optimal solutions. The reservation level of profits for each party is derived in the decentralized decision-making structure. 2. Centralized: the centralized decision-making structure is associated with the integrational management of members where the decisions are determined so as to maximize the total supply chain profit. Thus, the centralized decision-making structure leads to globally optimal solutions. Accordingly, the centralized structure as a benchmark reaches the best performance of the channel. Supply chain coordination induces individual members to decide based on the centralized decision-making structure instead of their local decisions. To achieve the optimal decisions of the entire chain, a coordination mechanism places the centralized decisions into the objective functions that the individual parties have in the decentralized setting. This method guarantees to enhance the supply chain profit up to that of the centralized one (achieving channel coordination) while it simultaneously improves the profitability of each member compared to that of the decentralized structure. Since the Stackelberg game is played between the members, the backward J o u r n a l P r e -p r o o f induction method is applied to determine the decentralized optimal decisions. Hence, considering the manufacturer as the leader and the retailers as the followers, first, the retailers determine their CSR investment levels, and then the manufacturer determines the green R&D investment level considering the retailers' best responses. Disruption occurrence in the collection process lessens the return quantity collected by the retailers and affects DG's performance, as well. Four different possible scenarios are presented in the following. The . $ / . 1 ( hold, respectively. Moreover, we define a random variable to illustrate the effect of disruption as follows: 5 is the proportion of collected items that are delivered to the manufacturer by retailer ( ) with respect to the collection disruption possibility. Accordingly, retailer ( )'s scenario-based profit can be formulated as Eq. (2): The first term in Eq. (2) shows the retailer's earned revenue from selling the collected plastic containers to DG. The second term is the disruption cost which is related to the additional time to handle the disruption and resume the collection process (Mark et al., 2008) . The third term indicates the profit of selling medicines to the end customers in the forward channel, and the cost of CSR investment. Eq. (3) represents the manufacturer's expected profit under the four disruption scenarios. The first term in Eq. (3) denotes the obtained revenue from selling new products, without using returned plastic containers. The second term indicates the gained revenue from selling new products using returned plastic containers of retailer (1) and (2). Finally, the last term shows the cost of investment in green activities. In the next subsections, the decentralized, centralized, and coordinated structures are investigated. In the decentralized structure, members determine their decisions regardless of the PCLSC benefit. To be more specific, the manufacturer (DG) determines the green R&D level, and each retailer optimizes his CSR investment level, individually. Thus, for calculating the optimal values of decision variables, each member's profit function is separately optimized. In the following sub-sections, we derive the members' scenario-based decentralized profit function. Since the Stackelberg game is played between the members, the optimal green R&D level and competitive CSR efforts are obtained, subsequently, using the backward induction method. Note that in this study, the decentralized optimal solutions are represented using the superscript *, and the decentralized profit is indicated by superscript B $. The retailers collect empty plastic containers and sell the medications to the customers. The collection amount and the market demand depend on the CSR investment level of the retailers. If the CSR investments grow, the retailers can benefit more from selling the plastic containers to the manufacturer and selling the medications to customers; but their costs increase as well. According to Eq. (2), the expected profit of retailer ( ) is as Eq. (4): In order to obtain the optimal value of retailer ( )'s decision variable, we optimize Eq. (4) with respect to and , simultaneously, and the following lemma is proposed. of retailer (j) under the decentralized structure is obtained by Eq. (5): J o u r n a l P r e -p r o o f The manufacturer uses the returned amount in his production system in addition to the first handed plastic containers to satisfy the demand. Since the production cost decreases by using the returned items, the collection volume of retailers affects the production cost of the manufacturer. In other words, CSR participation of the retailers affects not only the manufacture's sales amount bus also his production costs. The manufacturer also invests in green R&D to produce more eco-friendly products and boost the market demand. The manufacturer's expected profit is modeled using Eq. (3) as follows: Note that Eq. (5) shows that the retailers' decisions, * , depend on the manufacturer's decision, , and they are the followers of the Stackelberg game. According to the backward induction method, we replace the retailers' best responses from Eq. (5) in the expected profit of the manufacturer. Then, to obtain the optimal value of the manufacturer's decision variable that maximizes Eq. (6) the following lemma is proposed. Note that the retailers' decentralized CSR investment is obtained by replacing the manufacturer's final decision (Eq. (7)) into the retailers' best response (Eq. (5)) Lemma 2. The manufacturer's profit function is concave with respect to under the decentralized structure, and the optimal green R&D efforts level is obtained by Eq. (7): The decentralized solutions are locally optimum determined by the including parties. Hence, to achieve the best system efficiency, the centralized model is proposed, where the decisions are made based on the whole system performance. In the centralized system, the supply chain is considered as a single unit, and the decision variables (i.e., green effort and CSR levels) are optimized from an integrated viewpoint . In the previous literature on supply chain coordination, it is shown that shifting to the centralized system improves the performance of the entire chain (Heydari and Mosanna, 2018) . The expected centralized profit function is the summation of the members' scenario-based profit. Thus, the expected profit of the investigated supply chain is formulated as Eq. (8) (Chen and Xiao, 2015) : J o u r n a l P r e -p r o o f We can simplify Eq. (8) using Eqs. (2) and (3) as follows: To find the centralized optimal variables of the PCLSC objective function, the following lemma is proposed. Note that in this study, the centralized optimal solutions are represented using superscript **, and the centralized profit is denoted by superscript $ ^. Lemma 3. The PCLSC profit function is concave with respect to , , and , and the optimal values of the decision variables under the centralized structure are obtained by Eqs. (10) and (11) In the centralized model, the system is optimized as a unified whole, the conflict of interests between actors is neutralized, and the disruption risk is mitigated through sharing with all supply chain members. Although the PCLSC achieves its best performance under the centralized structure, the benefit of each participant is not guaranteed. Consequently, centralization is usually inapplicable in practice, and a motivational plan is needed to encourage the reluctant members to make decisions based on the centralized setting (Choi and Liu, 2019). Coordination strategies are employed to ensure all parties' profitability and induce them to change their decentralized optimal solutions to the centralized ones. In our problem, three scenarios may occur after centralization: (1) the manufacturer benefits from centralization, while the retailers incur loss, (2) the retailers benefit under the centralized model, but the manufacturer incurs loss, and (3) all three members benefit from centralization, although the profit surplus is not fairly shared among them. Accordingly, a mechanism is needed to not only ensure profitability for all members but also fairly divide the profit surplus between all parties. To this end, in the current paper, a profit-sharing mechanism is proposed to coordinate the manufacturer's green R&D efforts and the retailers' competitive CSR practices along with the Nash-bargaining game model to ensure fairness. The profit-sharing contract is practically easy to implement and useful to channel coordination (Leng and Parlar, 2009 ). According to this mechanism, each member earns a proportion of the PCLSC profit under the centralized model. Let 0 ≤ 0 ≤ 1 be the proportion of PCLSC profit given to retailer ( ), which leaves (1 ∑ 0 ) for the manufacturer's share. Accordingly, applying the profit-sharing contract, the members' profit in the coordinated model is obtained as Eqs. (12) Note that in our paper, superscript $dd indicates the coordinated profit. The members' coordinated profits must be greater than the decentralized ones to persuade the actors to accept the coordination. Therefore, the following conditions must be satisfied under the coordinated system. Eqs. (15) and (16) Accordingly, Lemmas 4 and 5 represent the lower bounds of 0 and 0 , which are acceptable for retailer (1) and retailer (2), respectively. Note that retailer ( ) determines the minimum amount of 0 and any values of 0 lower than that is not acceptable, since it will not be beneficial to the retailers in the coordination plan. Let q be the feasible range of 0 and 0 based on the above-mentioned conditions (Eqs. (18) to (20)). Hence, for any (0 , 0 ) inside q, the coordination scheme is applicable. In such a case, not only the PCLSC achieves its best performance, but also the manufacturer and the retailers gain benefits. There are various methods to determine a fixed optimum solution for the contract parameters (0 , 0 ) in the previous literature (Nouri et al., 2018) . The significant point is to fairly share the profit gained by the centralization between the members (Ebrahimi et al., 2017) . The Nash-bargaining game model (Nash Jr, 1950) has been applied as the profit-allocation plan in different coordination contracts, such as profit-sharing (Yan, 2011) , cooperative advertising (Li et al., 2002) , and quantity discounts (Kohli and Park, 1989) . The Nash bargaining cooperative game maximizes an objective function defined as the product of the bargainers' profit (Panda et al., 2015) . Moreover, each bargainer's profit is the difference between the profit under the decentralized decision-making system and that of the coordinated one (Panda et al., 2015) . The Nash bargaining solution reconciles efficiency and fairness in profit division. 1 In this study, to calculate the exact optimum values of 0 and 0 , a simple Nashbargaining model is applied that guarantees a fair profit division between the members under the profit-sharing coordination mechanism. It is assumed that all three members are risk-neutral (Li et al., 2009 ). Lemma 7 states that the optimum values of 0 and 0 are obtained by solving Eq. (21), through the Nash-bargaining cooperative game model. The optimum values of 0 and 0 are derived by solving the following Nash-bargaining cooperative game model as the profit-allocation scheme: To go deeper into the proposed model, this section provides an analytical sensitivity analysis on the coordinated and decentralized scenarios. We investigate how the variables of each setting behave when significant parameters of the model change. The results are presented in Propositions 1 to 4. According to Proposition 1, under the decentralized scenario, by increasing the probability of disruption occurring in the collection process of one retailer, the other retailer's CSR investment level decreases, as well. This is because, when one retailer is weaker due to the collection disruption occurrence, its competitor is confident of its superiority and is not motivated to invest more in CSR. Moreover, by increasing the fraction of acceptable items in each retailer's collection amount, the collection process is more beneficial, and thus, the retailer tends to invest more in CSR efforts and collect more items. This means that the retailer becomes a stronger competitor, which leaves the other retailer no choice but to participate more in the CSR activities and collect more items due to the competitive environment. Besides, a higher collection fee paid by the manufacturer improves the retailers' revenue and their ability to invest more in CSR efforts. In such a case, more CSR activities are performed, customers are encouraged to return more empty plastic containers, and the collection amount is improved. Additionally, increasing the wholesale price raises the retailers' costs and makes it more difficult for them to invest in CSR activities. In the decentralized structure, the manufacturer's marketing strategy (e.g., the wholesale price and the collection fee) has a direct influence on its green R&D activities. For instance, when the retailers receive a higher collection fee, they participate more in CSR activities (see Proposition 1), which in turn augments the manufacturer's revenue and its green activities. Furthermore, when the customers' sensitivity to green efforts is high, the manufacturer enhances its green efforts level to improve the demand and profitability of the chain. Likewise, when the customers are more sensitive to the CSR efforts, the sales amount, and the return quantity increase, the manufacturer's revenue improves, and it can invest more in green R&D. Meanwhile, increasing the manufacturer's reverse operational costs, decreasing the collection sensitivity to the retailers' CSR efforts, and increasing the probability of disruption in the collection process reduce the retailers' CSR participation and the collection amount. Thus, to compensate for the associated loss, the manufacturer invests more in R&D activities and increases the demand. According to Proposition 3, as opposed to the decentralized structure, by increasing the probability of collection disruption at each retailer, the other retailer's centralized CSR investment level increases to compensate for the reduction of the collected amount from the chain's perspective. Moreover, by growing one retailer's acceptance rate, the other one participates less in the CSR activities and collects fewer items to maintain the balance in the PCLSC. Therefore, the coordination mechanism keeps the PCLSC in balance when the probability of disruption and the fraction of acceptable items changes. Moreover, reducing the retailers' J o u r n a l P r e -p r o o f selling price decreases their CSR activities at a lower rate compared to the decentralized one. Accordingly, channel coordination is an effective strategy to prevent loss in case of changing the selling price in the pharmaceutical market. Note that in the pharmaceutical market, while the demand is not sensitive to the selling price for the pharmaceuticals are regarded as essential goods (Guennif and Ramani, 2012) , the price is often determined by the government or health organizations. Therefore, the PCLSC should be prepared to prevent the probable loss in case of decreasing the selling price by the government. Unlike the decentralized structure, increasing the selling price positively affects the manufacturer's ability to invest in green efforts under the coordinated model. In both the decentralized and coordinated models, by increasing the reverse operational costs and the probability of collection disruption, the manufacturer invests more in green R&D activities to compensate for the associated loss and increase the demand. However, in the coordinated system, this increasing rate is higher than that of the decentralized one. In other words, channel coordination helps the manufacturer to adapt himself in case of disruption in a more effective way compared to the decentralized setting. By improving the green R&D investment level, the PCLSC's environmental sustainability improves, which is another achievement of the coordination strategy toward sustainability. Overall, the above-mentioned propositions discuss how the coordination and decentralized optimal decisions behave with respect to the changes in the main parameters of the model. We conclude that compared to the decentralized structure, coordination (i) lessens the negative effects and strengthens the positive effects of changing model parameters on the PCLSC performance, and (ii) is a reasonable means of simultaneously moving toward the economic, environmental, and social goals of sustainability. This section numerically examines the developed models using the collected data from the DG Company. However, some parameters are estimated based on the opinion of DG's experts, since they are difficult to be accurately measured. In fact, the intrinsic CSR efforts elasticity coefficient of each retailer's demand, cross-CSR J o u r n a l P r e -p r o o f efforts elasticity coefficient of each retailer's demand, manufacturer's green R&D efforts elasticity coefficient of demand, intrinsic CSR efforts elasticity coefficient of each retailer's collection function, and cross-CSR efforts elasticity coefficient of each retailer's collection function are designed to be consistent with the model assumptions and the experts' opinions. The DG Company implements a closed-loop system, invests in green R&D, and seeks for effective management of the system under collection disruption. The DG Company produces "Tolidin" in plastic containers and distributes them through duopolistic competing retailers. The two retailers compete on CSR efforts to boost the collection amount and market demand. The plastic containers are collected by the retailers and delivered to DG to re-enter the production line. The manufacturing cost is $ % 5 $/unit using first handed plastic containers. DG sells Tolidin to the retailers with the wholesale price of # 15 $/unit, and the retailers sell it with the selling price of " 30 $/unit to the customers. DG tends to promote the sustainability level of the system via reusing its plastic medication containers and investing in green R&D. DG invests in the green R&D with the cost of a 140 $/unit and boosts the demand with the rate of 10. Besides, the two retailers assume the collection responsibility and increase the return amount by participating in CSR with the rate of 60. The retailers' CSR efforts boost the demand with the rate of 82, as well. Moreover, the retailers face disruption in their collection process with the probability of 0.5 and 0.4 for retailers (1) and (2) The results of running the proposed model are indicated in Table 3 . Under the centralized structure, the PCLSC achieves its best sustainability performance, since the profitability of the entire channel, CSR activities, green R&D investment, and collection amount are enhanced, simultaneously. To be more specific, the chain profit increases from 43063.6 to 45817.4, CSR participation level of retailer (1) enhances from 3.67 to 7.75, CSR investment level of retailer (2) improves from 3.71 to 7.81, and DG's green efforts level increases from 0.75 to 2.45 after centralization. As a consequence, the total market demand is changed from 1986.71 to 2609.94, and the total collection amount is increased from 724.22 to 1133.3. Along with these remarkable achievements, DG's profit is enhanced from 19976.8 to 25909 by shifting to the centralized model. However, after centralization, retailer (1)'s profit reduces from 11478. to 9894.71, and retailer (2)'s profit reduces from 11608.8 to 10013.6. Therefore, to convince the retailers to make globally optimal decisions, an incentive policy is needed. Using the profit-sharing mechanism along with the Nash-bargaining profit-allocation scheme, all members benefit from centralization, and the profit surplus is shared fairly between them. In other words, after coordinating the channel, DG's profit increases from 19976.8 to 20894.7, retailer (1)'s profit increases from 11478. to 12395.9, and retailer (2)'s profit improves from 11608.8 to 12526.7. Hence, all parties are willing to participate in the coordination plan. The developed mechanism (i) advances the economic performance of the PCLSC, as well as each member; (ii) improves the sustainability performance of the PCLSC through enhancing CSR investment level and green efforts; and (iii) enhances the market demand and collection amount, simultaneously. Insight 2. The coordination plan is capable of dealing with competitive CSR-based demand. The impacts of changing the probability that retailer (1) faces disruption during the collection process ( ) on the model are indicated in Figure 5 . When increases, retailer (1) faces a higher risk of disruption, which lessens the retailer's collection amount under all decision-making models. In such a case, retailer (1), and the whole PCLSC incur loss. Nevertheless, for any logical values of , retailer (1)'s collection amount and profit, as well as the PCLSC profit in the coordinated system, are more than those of the decentralized one. Furthermore, in the coordinated structure, by increasing , retailer (2) increases its collection amount to compensate for the lower collection amount of the other retailer and maintain the PCLSC sustainability performance (see also Proposition 3). This augmentation rate is higher in the coordinated model compared to the decentralized one. Therefore, the coordination scheme is able to decrease the adverse effects of collection disruption on the PCLSC and each member's performance. According to Figure 5 , retailer (1)'s centralized profit is less than that of the decentralized one, which means that it will not participate in the centralization without an appropriate incentive plan. After implementing the coordination mechanism, however, the retailer's profit improves compared to the decentralized system, which verifies applicability of the model. It is noteworthy that the influences of changing on the model is similar to those of . Besides, the model is always robust with respect to the effects of changing , since in the feasible interval of , i.e., [0, 1] , the performance of the proposed coordination model is considerably better compared to the decentralized one. This is because the negative effects of collection disruption on the system are minimized, and the chain enjoys a higher benefit alongside a higher social and environmental performance for any disruption possibility. Figure 6 indicates the effects of changing demand sensitivity to DG's green efforts ( ) on the PCLSC profit, market demand, and DG's green efforts. By increasing , customers' sensitivity to green efforts has a more substantial positive effect on market demand. As a result, DG is motivated to invest more in the green R&D activities, which consequently augments the market demand and the PCLSC profit in all decision-making structures. Additionally, in the coordinated model, the market demand, DG's green efforts, and the PCLSC profit, as well as their augmentation rates, are higher than those of the decentralized one for any values of . Figure 6 shows that the developed coordination model is more efficient regarding the environmental and economic aspects of sustainability compared to the decentralized one. Additionally, it is noteworthy that the proposed model is robust with respect to , since the coordinated system is of higher environmental and economic performance compared to the decentralized structure. J o u r n a l P r e -p r o o f . decreases the manufacturer's profit from reusing the products. In the coordinated model, this reduction affects the retailers' CSR efforts and collection amount, since reusing the products is less beneficial from the economic viewpoint. However, even for high values of $ ) . , the coordinated model improves the chain's sustainability performance. Furthermore, although the PCLSC profit decreases in all scenarios, the PCLSC profit in the coordinated model is greater than that of the decentralized one. Moreover, the model's robust interval with respect to $ ) . is considered [0, 7.3], since for any values of $ ) . beyond 7.3, the decentralized profits are negative, and the system incurs loss. However, the coordinated system performs better than the decentralized one, even for production costs higher than 7.3. In other words, the proposed coordination scheme is particularly useful and prevents loss when the production cost is high. J o u r n a l P r e -p r o o f Augmenting " enhances the revenue of the retailer and manufacturer. Consequently, the retailer's profit and collection amount and the green R&D level improve. However, under the decentralized structure, the manufacturer's green R&D is independent of the selling price (see also Proposition 2). Moreover, shifting to the centralized optimal decisions with the help of the proposed coordination mechanism leads to a remarkable increase in the retailer's profit, collection amount, and green R&D activities for any feasible values of ", in comparison with the decentralized system. Besides, if the government reduces the selling price due to the health policies, the retailer loses its profitability and collection amount under the decentralized structure. However, shifting to the coordination strategy makes the PCLC safe to the changes in the selling price. Therefore, the coordination plan can be a useful strategy in the pharmaceutical sector to prevent loss in case of reducing the selling price due to the health policies. It is noteworthy that the influences of changing " on the retailer (2)'s profit and collection are similar to those of retailer (1). Furthermore, the model is robust with respect to " within J o u r n a l P r e -p r o o f the interval [9, 32] . This is because the retailers' decentralized profits are negative for any values of " lower than 9, and the retailers' decentralized profits are higher than the coordinated ones for any values of " higher than 32. However, for rational values of the selling price, the proposed coordination model is of higher sustainability performance compared to the decentralized structure. Figure 8 . The influences of changing " on the model Insight 8. When 0 is equal to its maximum level, retailer ( )'s coordinated profit is maximum, and when ∑ 0 is equal to its maximum, the manufacturer's coordinated profit is minimum. Figure 9 indicates the effects of changing the profit-sharing factors (0 , 0 ) on the profit division among the three members. Using the data of Table 2 Reverse supply chain managers can hedge against the negative effects of collection disruption on the system performance by an appropriate coordination scheme. Under the coordinated model, the system is more adaptable to disruption probability and can deal with the collection disruption more effectively in comparison with the decentralized structure. Under the coordinated model, if the probability of collection disruption occurrence for a retailer increases, the other one invests more in CSR efforts to compensate for its competitor's lower collection amount as well as preventing loss for the PCLSC. Reverse supply chain managers can prevent loss and maintain balance in case of a highly competitive CSR-based collection by an appropriate coordination mechanism. Implementing the coordination plan is necessary for retailers, especially in highly competitive environments. This is because the coordination scheme reduces the negative impacts of competition on demand, CSR investments, and members' profits. Moreover, under the decentralized, structure changing one retailer's CSR investment level is retailer's acceptance rate decreases, its opponent will participate more in the CSR activities and collect more items to maintain the balance in the PCLSC. Accordingly, the coordinated structure effectively keeps the PCLSC in balance when the retailer's acceptance rate changes. Managers of production systems can move toward achieving the sustainability goals through an appropriate coordination model. Implementing the coordination plan increases the sustainability performance of the PCLSC through enabling the PCLSC members to invest more in their sustainability efforts, including CSR investment level and green efforts, and also enhances the market demand and collection amount, at the same time. Overall, these achievements ensure sustainability through improving the economic, social, and environmental performance of the supply chain. In other words, the coordination plan is capable of protecting the environment from detrimental impacts of discarded pharmaceutical plastic containers, increasing the customers' willingness to return empty plastic containers, as well as ensuring profitability for the PCLSC and its members. Similar to any other operations in the real world, the retailers' collection process is prone to disruption. This issue is of more significance in the pharmaceutical sector since pharmaceutical leftovers contain chemicals that threaten the environment and human health. Meanwhile, growing social and environmental concerns have forced companies to take sustainability issues into account in their decisions (Safarzadeh et al., 2020b) . This study analyzes a real PCLSC that reuses its plastic containers, considering disruption in its collection process. The case includes a pharmaceutical company, namely DG, and two competitive retailers. However, the proposed models are generalizable to any production system with similar attributes. Following a new approach, we assume that the retailers competitively exert CSR to increase the customers' tendency to return their used products, which simultaneously influence the market demand and the return quantity of empty plastic containers transferred to DG. Hence, when retailers participate less in CSR efforts, DG receives fewer products, which may lead to a shortage of resources. Moreover, DG performs green R&D activities, which boosts the market demand. Due to such interrelations between the members' decisions, the interactions of the members' decisions need to be coordinated to achieve an efficient system. The problem is analytically investigated in three decentralized, centralized, and coordinated decisionmaking structures, through developing scenario-based mathematical models. The PCLSC members are coordinated, employing a profit-sharing mechanism, and fairness is guaranteed using a simple Nash-bargaining J o u r n a l P r e -p r o o f model. In addition, we analytically explore the circumstances that reusing plastic containers is beneficial for all parties, from both economic and environmental aspects. The current paper reveals that when the probability of disruption of a retailer grows under the coordinated model, the other one makes more CSR efforts to compensate for its competitor's lower collection, which prevents loss for the PCLSC. Accordingly, the system is more adaptable to disruption compared to the decentralized structure. Moreover, the coordination scheme reduces the negative impacts of competition on demand, CSR investments, and members' profits. It also maintains the system in balance when the retailer's acceptance rate changes. The coordination plan increases the sustainability performance of the PCLSC through enabling the PCLSC members to invest more in their sustainability efforts, including CSR investment level and green efforts, and also enhances the market demand and collection amount, at the same time. Similar to other studies, this study is not without limitations. For example, this paper assumes that the operational costs, green efforts costs, and CSR investment costs are known to all parties. However, in many real situations, the supply chain members usually do not share these types of information with other parties. Hence, further studies could develop the investigated model considering asymmetric information. Also, since extra transportation regarding the collection process could harm the environment, the effects of transportation on environmental sustainability is an attractive issue to study in the context of supply chain coordination. Further studies may also consider an innovative distribution function for the collection disruption, as well. For example, they can assume that the probability of disruption occurrence is a function of facility boosting investment that protects the chain from potential disruptions. Transshipment Contract for Coordination of a Green Dual-Channel Supply Chain under Channel Disruption Optimal core acquisition and pricing strategies for hybrid manufacturing and remanufacturing systems Reverse logistics for the endof-life and end-of-use products in the pharmaceutical industry: a systematic literature review', Supply Chain Management Coordination of a supply chain with one manufacturer and multiple competing retailers under simultaneous demand and cost disruptions Analyses of the reward-penalty mechanism in green closedloop supply chains with product remanufacturing Demand disruption and coordination of the supply chain with a dominant retailer Outsourcing strategy and production disruption of supply chain with demand and capacity allocation uncertainties Optimal advertisement budget allocation and coordination in luxury fashion supply chains with multiple brand-tier products The mean-variance approach for global supply chain risk analysis with air logistics in the blockchain technology era A system dynamics framework for integrated reverse supply chain with three way recovery and product exchange policy Cradle-to-cradle stewardship of drugs for minimizing their environmental disposition while promoting human health. II. Drug disposal, waste reduction, and future directions A joint maximization incentive in closed-loop supply chains with competing retailers: The case of spent-battery recycling Pharma Industry 4.0: literature review and research opportunities in sustainable pharmaceutical supply chains Proposing a delay in payment contract for coordinating a two-echelon periodic review supply chain with stochastic promotional effort dependent demand Competitive closed-loop supply chain network design under uncertainty' Circular economy strategies for mitigating critical material supply issues', Resources, Conservation and Recycling The economics of cell phone reuse and recycling Competitive green supply chain network design model considering inventory decisions under uncertainty: a real case of a filter company Coordinating a two-echelon supply chain under production disruption when retailers compete with price and service level Improving performance by coordinating a supply chain with third party logistics outsourcing under production disruption Optimal production policy for a closed-loop hybrid system with uncertain demand and return under supply disruption Reverse logistics and closed-loop supply chain: A comprehensive review to explore the future Explaining divergence in catching-up in pharma between India and Brazil using the NSI framework Optimal strategies for the closed-loop supply chain with the consideration of supply disruption and subsidy policy Collection channel and production decisions in a closedloop supply chain with remanufacturing cost disruption Competitive collection under channel inconvenience in closed-loop supply chain Reverse and closed loop supply chain coordination by considering government role Coordination by quantity flexibility contract in a two-echelon supply chain system: Effect of outsourcing decisions Coordination of a sustainable supply chain contributing in a causerelated marketing campaign Sustainable supply chain coordination under competition and green effort scheme Supply Chain Coordination through Lead Time Crashing in a Socially Responsible Supply Chain Considering Transportation Modes and Carbon Emissions Tax Coordination of dual-function acquisition price and corporate social responsibility in a sustainable closed-loop supply chain A collaborative model for coordination of monopolistic manufacturer's promotional efforts and competing duopolistic retailers' trade credits Drug recall management and channel coordination under stochastic product defect severity: a game-Theoretic analytical study Coordinating economic incentives, customer service and pricing decisions in a competitive closed-loop supply chain Reverse Supply Chain Systems Coordination Across Multiple Links With Duopolistic Third Party Collectors Improving corporate social responsibility in a supply chain through a new revenue sharing contract Demand disruptions, pricing and production decisions in a closed-loop supply chain with technology licensing' Designing a supply chain resilient to major disruptions and supply/demand interruptions Price competition and co-operation in a duopoly closed-loop supply chain Bi-level credit period coordination for periodic review inventory system with price-credit dependent demand under time value of money An evolutionary game theoretic model for analyzing pricing strategy and socially concerned behavior of manufacturers Reverse logistics in pharmaceutical industry Reverse logistics in Pakistan's pharmaceutical sector A cooperative game theory model of quantity discounts Corporate reputation through strategic corporate social responsibility: Insights from service industry companies Lead-time reduction in a two-level supply chain: Non-cooperative equilibria vs. coordination with a profit-sharing contract Cost-reducing and demand-creating R&D with spillovers Supply chain coordination and decision making under consignment contract with revenue sharing Cooperative advertising, game theory and manufacturer-retailer supply chains Remanufacturing and pricing decisions with random yield and random demand Penalty and financial assistance in a supply chain with supply disruption Disruption management in a constrained multi-product imperfect production system The cost of interrupted work: more speed and stress Investigating structure of a two-echelon closed-loop supply chain using social work donation as a Corporate Social Responsibility practice Coordination in a triple sourcing supply chain using a cooperative mechanism under disruption Game-theoretic analysis of cooperation among supply chain agents: Review and extensions The bargaining problem Coordination of social responsibility and order quantity in a two-echelon supply chain: A collaborative decision-making perspective Coordinating manufacturer's innovation and retailer's promotion and replenishment using a compensationbased wholesale price contract Channel coordination and profit distribution in a social responsible three-layer supply chain Coordinating a socially responsible closedloop supply chain with product recycling The closed-loop supply chain network with competition and design for remanufactureability' Designing supply contracts for the sustainable supply chain using game theory Pricing and coordination strategies of a dual-channel supply chain considering green quality and sales effort Supply chain coordination under a revenue-sharing contract with corporate social responsibility and partial demand information The benefits of reverse logistics: the case of the Manchester Royal Infirmary Pharmacy Quality, buyback and technology licensing considerations in a two-period manufacturing-remanufacturing system: a closed-loop and sustainable supply chain A game theoretic approach for assessing residential energyefficiency program considering rebound, consumer behavior, and government policies A game theoretic approach for pricing policies in a duopolistic supply chain considering energy productivity, industrial rebound effect, and government policies A duopolistic game for designing a comprehensive energyefficiency scheme regarding consumer features: Which energy policy is the best? A review of optimal energy policy instruments on industrial energy efficiency programs, rebound effects, and government policies A game theoretic approach for the duopoly pricing of energy-efficient appliances regarding innovation protection and social welfare Reverse logistics and social sustainability Social pricesensitivity of demand for competitive supply chain coordination Managing product returns to achieve supply chain sustainability: an exploratory study and research propositions Effects of sourcing structure on performance in a multiple-product assemble-to-order supply chain Research on Coordination of Closed-Loop Supply Chain Revenue Sharing Contract Under Disruption Modeling and solving a sustainable closed loop supply chain problem with pricing decisions and discounts on returned products Concepts and definitions of CSR and corporate sustainability: Between agency and communion Reverse flows within the pharmaceutical supply chain: A classificatory review from the perspective of end-of-use and end-of-life medicines Hybrid closed-loop supply chains with competition in recycling and product markets Reward-penalty mechanism in a closed-loop supply chain with sequential manufacturers' price competition Production and coordination decisions in a closed-loop supply chain with remanufacturing cost disruptions when retailers compete Price competition, cost and demand disruptions and coordination of a supply chain with one manufacturer and two competing retailers Who cares wins? A comparative analysis of household waste medicines and batteries reverse logistics systems Three-level supply chain coordination of fresh agricultural products in the Internet of Things Managing channel coordination in a multi-channel manufacturer-retailer supply chain', Industrial Marketing Management Closed-loop supply chain coordination strategy for the remanufacture of patented products under competitive demand J o u r n a l P r e -p r o o f Collection disruption management and channel coordination in a socially concerned closed-loop supply chain: a game theory approach HIGHLIGHTS:• The paper coordinates a two-echelon pharmaceutical closed-loop supply chain• The collection process of the retailers may be subject to disruptions• Two retailers compete on exerting corporate social responsibility ☒ The authors declare that they have no known competing financial interests or personal relationships that could have appeared to influence the work reported in this paper.☐The authors declare the following financial interests/personal relationships which may be considered as potential competing interests: J o u r n a l P r e -p r o o f