key: cord-0771142-0jagirzl authors: Espinoza, Baltazar; Marathe, Madhav; Swarup, Samarth; Thakur, Mugdha title: Asymptomatic individuals can increase the final epidemic size under adaptive human behavior date: 2021-10-05 journal: Sci Rep DOI: 10.1038/s41598-021-98999-2 sha: 5735761a1d3f4fe4d6d82af29d2cf7935013d12f doc_id: 771142 cord_uid: 0jagirzl Infections produced by non-symptomatic (pre-symptomatic and asymptomatic) individuals have been identified as major drivers of COVID-19 transmission. Non-symptomatic individuals, unaware of the infection risk they pose to others, may perceive themselves—and be perceived by others—as not presenting a risk of infection. Yet, many epidemiological models currently in use do not include a behavioral component, and do not address the potential consequences of risk misperception. To study the impact of behavioral adaptations to the perceived infection risk, we use a mathematical model that incorporates the behavioral decisions of individuals, based on a projection of the system’s future state over a finite planning horizon. We found that individuals’ risk misperception in the presence of non-symptomatic individuals may increase or reduce the final epidemic size. Moreover, under behavioral response the impact of non-symptomatic infections is modulated by symptomatic individuals’ behavior. Finally, we found that there is an optimal planning horizon that minimizes the final epidemic size. Since the model is not amenable to an analytic solution, we numerically explore the implications of adaptive behavior and risk misperception on the epidemic dynamics and on the attack rate. We assume per-contact utility to be independent of health status and use the single peaked utility function u t = bC h t − (C h t ) 2 ν , where C h t represents the contact rate of a typical individual with health status h at time t, and where the maximum number of contacts available per time (b) and the utility function shape parameter ( ν ), are fixed over time. Therefore, u(h, C h t ) represents the immediate utility a typical individual in health class h obtains by making C contacts at time t. Since preferences are single-peaked each individual has a unique most preferred contact rate and, although the utility function is symmetric around the optimal contact rate C * = b/2 , we restrict behavior adaptations to reductions in the contact rate. In Appendix C we explore the impact of changes in the utility function on the adaptive behavior produced. In the absence of appropriate behavioral data, we assumed individuals make an average of b = 48 contacts per day and that future utility is discounted at the rate of 5% per year ( δ = 0.99986 ), and the utility function parameter value is assumed to be ν = 0.1 27, 29 . We explore the impact of variations in these parameter values in Supplementary Appendix C. We calibrate the behavior model by letting the basic reproductive number of the constant contact rates model to be consistent with early disease dynamics of the COVID-19 pandemic. Exposed www.nature.com/scientificreports/ individuals are assumed to exhibit a 5 days latency period ( κ = 1/5 ) with a reduced infectiousness of ρ = 0.25 4, 36 . Infected individuals recover and cannot infect others on average after 9 days ( γ = 1/9 ) of symptoms onset 37 . For our baseline parameters we assume 50% ( σ = 0.5 ) of the infections become asymptomatic with relative infectiousness of ǫ = 0.4 10 , and all symptomatic individuals to be non-compliant ( l = 1 ). These baseline parameters with a per-contact likelihood of infection β = 0.01324 , generate a basic reproductive number of 2.4, 38, 39 . The set of parameters used in our numerical experiments, unless otherwise indicated, are collected in Table 1 . We now use model (1) with varying contact rates to study the impact of susceptible and non-symptomatic individuals' behavior on the transmission dynamics and on the attack rate. Risk misperception has the potential to increase the attack rate. Figure 1 shows selected simulations for disease dynamics under constant contact rates (dashed curves), and under adaptive behavior (solid curves). It reports two scenarios: in panel (a) 30% ( σ = 0.3 ) of all infections are asymptomatic, and in panel (b) 60% ( σ = 0.6 ) of all infections are asymptomatic. In panel (a), behavioral adaptation reduces the contact rates of susceptible and non-symptomatic individuals (C S t ) down to 50%, while in panel (b), there is a weaker behavioral response, reducing the susceptible and non-symptomatic contact rates to 80%. While adaptive behavioral responses to disease risk reduce the contact rates in both cases, our numerical experiments show that the level of contacts reduction is sensitive to the proportion of infections that are asymptomatic. Specifically, the previous simulations show the impact of risk misperception to silent infections. In the scenario of σ = 0.3 , the epidemic is mainly driven by symptomatic transmission, in consequence the perceived risk associated to the symptomatic individuals prevalence produce a strong behavioral response. In counterpart, in the scenario of σ = 0.6 the epidemic is mostly driven by asymptomatic transmissions. In this scenario, the perceived risk associated to the symptomatic individuals prevalence, produce a weaker behavioral response compared to the scenario of σ = 0.3. (a) (b) Figure 1 . Disease dynamics under adaptive behavior (thick curves) and constant contact rates (dashed curves). The scenarios where 30% (a) and 60% (b) of cases become asymptomatic show differential behavioral response (C S t ) as a function of the risk perception, impacting the attack rate. Parameters τ = 14, ν = 0.1, ǫ = 0.4, C I = max C t , l = 1 and ρ = 0.25. www.nature.com/scientificreports/ We now explore the impact of the asymptomatic individuals' relative infectiousness on the attack rate. Figure 2 shows that the impact of silent infections depends upon the relative infectiousness of asymptomatic individuals. Our simulations show that under low infectiousness of asymptomatic individuals ( ǫ = 30% ), the attack rate decreases as the proportion of asymptomatic cases increases. However, if asymptomatic individuals are relatively highly infectious, ( ǫ = 60% ), the attack rate increases as the proportion of asymptomatic cases increases. Intuitively, the non-monotonic dynamics of the attack rate for the adaptive behavior model reflects the balance between the reduced infectiousness of non-symptomatic infectious individuals (exposed and asymptomatic) and the behavioral response of susceptible and non-symptomatic individuals. Our simulations show that risk misperception to silent transmissions increases the attack rate when the epidemic is mainly driven by asymptomatic infections. The lower the risk of infection perceived (via the disease prevalence level), the weaker the behavioral response. We found that there is a trade off between the proportion of asymptomatic cases, the reduced infectiousness of asymptomatic individuals and, the behavioral response produced on susceptible and non-symptomatic individuals. In Fig. 3 we explore all the potential scenarios where the attack rate is a function of both the proportion of infections that are asymptomatic ( σ ), and their relative infectiousness ( ǫ ). Panel (a) shows the attack rate for the constant contact rates model, and panel (b) shows the attack rate for the adaptive behavior model. We take the case where there are no asymptomatic infections ( σ = 0 ) as the baseline scenario (gray plane), for each model. Panel (a) shows that under the constant contact rates model, regardless of asymptomatic individuals' relative infectiousness, an epidemic driven by both symptomatic and asymptomatic cases ( σ > 0 ), leads to a lower attack rate than an epidemic solely driven by symptomatic cases. That is, under the constant contact rates model the attack rate attained for all (σ , ǫ) scenarios, is lower than the attack rate for the baseline scenario, ( σ = 0). www.nature.com/scientificreports/ Panel (b) shows as expected, that the attack rate in the absence of asymptomatic infections under behavioral response (σ = 0) , is lower than the corresponding one under constant contact rates. Interestingly, under the adaptive behavior model, the attack rate shows a non-monotonic behavior to the presence of asymptomatic infections. For scenarios where asymptomatic individuals' infectiousness is high ( ǫ > 0.6 ), behavioral response leads to an increased attack rate, relative to the baseline scenario (σ = 0) . In counterpart, for scenarios where asymptomatic individuals' infectiousness is low ( ǫ < 0.4 ), behavioral response leads to a reduced attack rate, compared to the baseline scenario. Notice that for intermediate levels of asymptomatic individuals' infectiousness, the impact of adaptive behavior on the attack rate depends upon the trade-off between the proportion of asymptomatic cases (σ ) and their relative infectiousness (ǫ). In summary, the set of presented simulations suggest that under adaptive behavior the trade off between the proportion of asymptomatic individuals and their relative infectiousness, defines a threshold. The presence of relatively highly infectious asymptomatic individuals, in conjunction with risk misperception produced by silent transmission, has the potential to generate more cases than the analogous epidemic composed purely by symptomatic transmissions. Our next set of experiments tested the effect of symptomatic individuals' activity level on the attack rate produced for scenarios varying asymptomatic cases ratio and their relative infectiousness. Specifically, we explored the impact of behavioral responses on the attack rate as the contact rate of infected (but still socially active) individuals varies. We found the attack rate in the presence of asymptomatic cases is modulated by the contact rate of symptomatic but still socially active individuals. Since it is expected that some symptomatic infected individuals comply with health authorities recommendations, we assume that variations in the contact rate of infected individuals are determined by both the ratio of compliant to non-compliant infected individuals (l) and the contact rates reduction of compliant individuals ( u C ). The higher the compliance rate, the lower the contact rate. Figure 4 shows the impact on the attack rate, of the proportion of asymptomatic cases ( σ ) and their relative infectiousness ( ǫ ), for scenarios where symptomatic infected individuals exhibit contact rates of C I t = 100%, 75% and 50% . Our simulations show that, in general, the attack rate of the epidemic decreases as the contact rate of symptomatic individuals falls, an intuitive result. Moreover, Fig. 4 shows two effects on the attack rate as symptomatic contact rates decreases: (i) the impact of non-symptomatic infections increases as the symptomatic individuals are less socially active, increasing the attack rate over the baseline scenario, (ii) the higher the level of compliance (the reduction in the symptomatic individuals' contact rate), the lower the levels of asymptomatic cases and the relative infectiousness ( σ , ǫ ) at which the attack rate exceeds the baseline scenario ( σ = 0 ). In other words, the (σ , ǫ) values that lead to an increased final epidemic size over the base case decrease as symptomatic compliance increases. Furthermore, for the scenarios at which the attack rate in the presence of asymptomatic individuals exceeds the baseline scenario (the no asymptomatic cases scenario), the impact on the attack rate increases as the symptomatic individuals compliance increases. The intuition behind our result is that by reducing symptomatic individuals activity level, the infection risk perception decreases. However, risk misperception towards non-symptomatic individuals leads silent transmissions to play a preponderant role as mixing occurs mainly between susceptible and non-symptomatic infectious individuals. Moreover, due to the reduced infection risk perception, the mixing between susceptible and nonsymptomatic infectious individuals tend to occur at high contact rates, as seen in Fig. 1b. Optimal planning horizon minimizing the attack rate. Finally, we considered the impact of the planning horizon of susceptible and non-symptomatic individuals on the attack rate. In the proposed adaptive behavior model the planning horizon is the period over which individuals anticipate the costs and benefits of (a) (b) (c) Figure 4 . Attack rate as a function of the proportion of asymptomatic infections ( σ ) and their relative infectiousness ( ǫ ), for different contact rates of symptomatic individuals under adaptive behavior model. In panel (a) we assume symptomatic individuals maintain the privately optimal contact rate ( C I t = max C t ), in panel (b) we assume symptomatic individuals reduce their contact rate to 75% ( C I t = 0.75 max C t ), and in panel (c) we assume a contact rate reduction to 50% ( C I t = 0.5 max C t ). Compliance with recommended precautionary measures by infectious individuals moderates the impact of non-symptomatic infections. The lower the symptomatic individuals' contact rate, the greater the impact of non-symptomatic infections on the attack rate. Parameters τ = 14, ν = 0.1 , and ρ = 0.25. www.nature.com/scientificreports/ contact decisions. During the planning horizon individuals assume the disease prevalence to be constant. It may be thought of as the period over which individuals have confidence that the state of the epidemic will remain unchanged. We investigated the sensitivity of the attack rate to variations in the length of the planning horizon as the proportion of asymptomatic infections, and their infectiousness, change. We found the attack rate to be sensitive to the length of the planning horizon. Indeed, our simulations suggest there exists a planning horizon that minimizes the impact of the epidemic. Figure 5a shows the attack rate as a function of the length of the planning horizon for the scenarios of 30% ( σ = 0.3 ), 50% ( σ = 0.5 ) and 70% ( σ = 0.7 ) of asymptomatic cases, with relative infectiousness of ǫ = 0.4 . Figure 5b shows the attack rate as a function of the length of the planning horizon for the scenarios where asymptomatic individuals have a relative infectiousness of 70% ( ǫ = 0.7 ), 50% ( ǫ = 0.5 ) and 30% ( ǫ = 0.3 ), for a proportion of asymptomatic cases of σ = 0.5 . Our selected simulations show that the attack rate is minimized for a planning horizon between 20 and 25 days regardless of the proportion of asymptomatic cases and their relative infectiousness. Figure 5c ,d, show the attack rate attained as a function of the planning horizon, for all possible scenarios of asymptomatic ratios and relative infectiousness, respectively. Our numerical experiments show that the existence of the optimal planning horizon is robust to variations on the asymptomatic subpopulation characteristics. That is, the optimal planning horizon is a consequence of the proposed adaptive behavioral response model. The previous simulations suggest that while the projection of the benefits and costs of making contacts over long planning horizons is beneficial, the assumption of constant prevalence may deviate risk assessments leading to high attack rate values. Moreover, we found the optimal planning horizon to be sensitive to the disease basic reproductive number and, to the expected utility loss related to the infectious compartments u(I, C * t )/u(S, C * t ) . Intuitively, the planning horizon length producing the minimal attack rate is the one at which the expected utility appropriately weights the utility loss while infected. Specifically, short planning horizons underweight the expected utility losses of being infected, by potentially missing individuals' transitions across disease health classes. In counterpart, long planning horizons tend to overweight the expected utility obtained after have gone over the whole disease progression, that is, while recovered. Figure 6 summarizes the methodology components of our adaptive behavior model and our key results. The starting point for this analysis is the finding that adaptive behavior by susceptible and non-symptomatic individuals responding to the perceived infection risk alters epidemic dynamics by dynamically modifying the structure of contacts 40 . In this paper we focused on an important feature of the COVID-19 pandemic: that a large proportion of infected individuals are asymptomatic or have symptoms at a level that allows continued social interaction. Absent testing, infected with mild symptoms and asymptomatic individuals may both behave and be treated by others as if they are susceptible. On the other hand, absent enforcement of health authority recommendations, symptomatic individuals experiencing only mild effects may continue to engage with others. www.nature.com/scientificreports/ To uncover the importance of the non-symptomatic proportion of the infected population we considered the impact of behavioral responses to the risks and rewards of contact with others, assuming variable levels of compliance with health authority recommendations on the part of infected individuals. Taking the case where non-symptomatic individuals do not make any attempt to mitigate the risks to themselves or others as the base case, we considered how the inclusion of behavioral responses may be expected to alter disease dynamics. We supposed that individuals do not have perfect knowledge of either their own health class or the health class of others, and that they make decisions based on observable cues-symptoms of disease. A study using data from New York City, New York and Austin, Texas, found that the attack rate in the first wave of the pandemic had depended on the proportion of asymptomatic infections but not on the infectiousness of asymptomatic individuals 41 . Consistent with this study, we found that while the inclusion of behavioral responses generally reduces the final epidemic size relative to the base case, the effect was highly sensitive to the proportion of the infected population that was asymptomatic. However, we also found the final epidemic size to be highly sensitive to both the infectiousness of the asymptomatic population and to the compliance with health authority recommendations of the symptomatic but socially engaged population. The higher the proportion of the infected population that is asymptomatic, and the greater the infectiousness of asymptomatic individuals, the greater the final epidemic size. Particularly, if there are asymptomatic infections, Fig. 4 shows that there is a threshold determined by the proportion of asymptomatic cases and their relative infectiousness, for which the final epidemic size is larger than would occur if there were no asymptomatic infections. It also shows that the greater the rate of compliance with health authority recommendations by symptomatic individuals, the greater the likelihood that asymptomatic infections will lead to a final epidemic size larger than would occur absent asymptomatic infections. The evidence to date on both the proportion of infections that are asymptomatic and the relative infectiousness of asymptomatics is mixed. The New York/Austin study reported that 56% of infections were estimated to be asymptomatic 41 . This result is consistent with other studies outside China 42 , but is higher than was found in studies focused on the original outbreak in Wuhan. A study of Japanese evacuees from Wuhan, for example, found the asymptomatic ratio to be 30.8% 12 . Evidence on the relative infectiousness of symptomatic and asymptomatic individuals indicates that asymptomatic infections may well be increasing the final epidemic size. Most studies have found viral loads in symptomatic and asymptomatic individuals to be similar 43 , but even where viral loads have been found to be lower in asymptomatic individuals, a period of viral shedding has been observed 44 . Modelling exercises have shown that differences in the generation-interval distribution of asymptomatic and symptomatic transmission matter, and can significantly bias estimates of the basic reproduction number 45 . The first quantitative study of asymptomatic transmission found a total infection rate of 6.15%, with 6.30% and 4.11% for symptomatic and asymptomatic individuals respectively 46 . The implication is that the relative infectiousness of asymptomatic individuals is such that the final epidemic size is increasing in the proportion of asymptomatic infections. Absent large scale random testing there is no way to generate precise estimates of the size of the infected and infectious asymptomatic population, and in consequence no way to generate reliable estimates of the disease reproduction number. However, by investigating changes in observable contact and associated attack rates it may be possible to infer the size and the impact of the infected asymptomatic and pre-symptomatic populations. The framework we use to model individuals' adaptive behavior during an epidemic focuses on the private benefits and costs of contacts. The individuals does not consider the impact that their behavior would have on others. The individual does not internalize the external costs and benefits of their behavior. The social costs of private behavior are instead reflected in health authority recommendations on, for example, social distancing measures or the use of personal protective equipment. We explore the consequences of variations in infected individuals' willingness to comply with such recommendations. Another critical aspect on the model is the uni-dimensional and single peaked utility function. This allows us to focus on the costs and benefits of contact decisions alone, but neglects other factors that may influence individual decisions. The population in health states S, E, A, R are assumed to be homogeneous. The population in health state I is divided between those who choose to comply with health authority recommendations, and those who do not. They balance the costs and benefits of contact over that horizon assuming no change in prevalence. The benefits of being forward-looking in some state are constrained by the speed at which that state is changing. www.nature.com/scientificreports/ While these assumptions allow us to explore the role of human behavioral responses during an epidemic, we recognize that take no account of the many other factors influencing decision-making in the current epidemic. Politicization of the epidemic is partially reflected in the parameter describing compliance with health authority recommendations, but we cannot, for example, capture the very different constraints faced by individuals in manufacturing and services, or the limited capacity to respond by those on low incomes. However, our goal is to capture the interactive evolution of human behavioral adaptation and epidemic dynamics, by using a simple but insightful mechanistic model. The proposed model assumes susceptible and non-symptomatic (exposed and asymptomatic) individuals are aware of the disease prevalence at each time step, but do not have perfect knowledge of either their own health class or the health class of others. In reality, risk perception depends upon the region-specific level of testing, where the perceived prevalence (the combination of symptomatic and asymptomatic individuals detected) is a fraction of the true epidemic size. In such a scenario, risk misperception not only arises due to asymptomatic individuals but also due to testing limitations. The challenge is exacerbated in regions where testing is very limited and where infectious individuals continue engaging in social interactions. Economic stress and the lack of reasonable alternatives are some of the factors leading the population to risk the dangers of COVID-19 47, 48 . On the other hand, our simulations shown some potential impacts of reducing symptomatic individuals contact rates, for instance due to detection and quarantine or isolation. The modification of the contact structure by reducing symptomatic individuals' activity has the potential to be balanced, if not overcame, by the increasing contact rates of pre-symptomatic and asymptomatic individuals, producing a comparable or a worse epidemic scenario. Therefore, an effective control measure intended to reduce secondary cases by isolating or quarantining infectious individuals should enforce compliance as well as mass testing, so that an epidemic is not driven by silent transmissions produced due to infection risk misperceptions. Mathematical model. Our model focuses on infected individuals who are capable of social interaction, i.e., infected individuals who have no symptoms or mild symptoms. Since our goal is to study the impact of the behavior of infectious exposed and asymptomatic individuals on the disease dynamics, we neglect individuals with severe symptoms, since these do not interact with the rest of the population. The potential impact of nosocomial outbreaks has been analyzed in the context of SARS, pneumonia and other diseases 49 . Our model of disease transmission is composed of susceptible (S), pre-symptomatic infectious exposed individuals (E), infected individuals with symptoms or testing positive (I), infectious but asymptomatic individuals (A), and recovered individuals (R). We suppose that only individuals in I know themselves to be infected either through observation of symptoms or through a positive test result. During the ongoing COVID-19 pandemic, it has been shown that infected individuals carry the highest viral load on or before symptom onset 50 . Due to the lack of adequate data on the specific infectiousness of exposed individuals, we assume this subpopulation to be less infectious than symptomatic individuals, ρ = 0.25 . We explore the impact that changing the exposed individuals' infectiousness produce on the evolution of the disease transmission and on the attack rate (the proportion of finally infected individuals), in the Supplementary Appendix C section. We assume that on average, 1/κ days after infection, a proportion σ of exposed individuals remain asymptomatic, while the rest develop symptoms. To capture the fact that only a fraction of the infected population will adopt pro-social precautionary behavior, we stratify the infected population into those who reduce their infectious potential by complying with health authority recommendations ( I S ), and those who do not ( I C ) 51 . We assume the fraction l of symptomatic individuals do not follow health authority recommendations, while the proportion 1 − l do it. Individuals may be non-compliant for many different reasons: they may have no reasonable alternative to interact with others, they may be compelled to continue interacting with others, they may be non-compliant for political or ideological reasons, or they may simply be careless. For our purposes all that matters is that a proportion of those known to be infected do not comply with health authority recommendations. The adoption of precautionary measures by the symptomatic population I S is assumed to reduce their infectious potential by a factor η < 1 . All other symptomatic individuals not following precautionary recommendations maintain their infectious potential. Finally, we assume a similar infectious period of 1 γ days for asymptomatic and symptomatic individuals. Our model for disease progression is sketched in Fig. 7and mathematically described by the system of equations (1). We determine the contact choices made by individuals at each time step, by finding the contact rate that maximize their expected utility V t (h) in each of the possible health state h ∈ {S, E, I S , I C , A, R} , over a given planning horizon, τ . At each time step, the system's current state (population distribution among health states and their respective contact choices) is assumed to remain constant during the planning period. The expected utility V t (h) comprises the potential benefit obtained by making the optimal contact choice at each future time step during the planning horizon. The expected utility comprises the immediate net benefits of contact (which depends only on the individual's perceived health status), and the expected net benefits of future contacts (which depend on all possible future health states and transitions probabilities). We assume that the utility of making C contacts at time t is described by a concave single peaked utility function u t = u(C t ) . Individuals obtain positive marginal net benefit from additional contacts up to C * t , after which additional contacts diminish the net benefits. Following the work by Morin et al. 29 , we assume a utility function of the particular form u t = bC h t − (C h t ) 2 ν , where b is the maximum number of contacts possible, ν is the utility function shape parameter, and C h t is the contact rate of a typical individual with health status h. Therefore, u(h, C h t ) is the utility a typical individual in health class h obtains by making C contacts at time t. We assume that individuals get similar per-contact utility regardless of health status, except symptomatic infected individuals who gets no utility during the infectious period. The number of daily contacts maximizing the immediate utility is given by C * = b/2. To solve the optimization problem, we define a system of Bellman's equations which are then numerically solved using dynamic programming methods. Non-symptomatic individuals behavior. In the absence of symptoms, we assume exposed and asymptomatic individuals are not aware of their infectious status, perceiving themselves to be susceptible. In consequence, we suppose that non-symptomatic individuals in all three health classes-susceptible, exposed and asymptomaticchoose their contact rates in the same way. All non-symptomatic individuals choose the contact rate that maximizes expected utility over the planning horizon [t, t + τ ] . This is done by weighing current and the expected future benefits of contact against the risk of infection. Expected benefits are conditioned on the probability of future infection, and potential recovery. We model the optimization problem as a dynamic programming problem, the solution to which generates the privately optimal contact rate [27] [28] [29] . Formally, the dynamic programming problem by which susceptible individuals assess the daily optimal contact rate is given by the Bellman's equation (1) S = −βS ρE + εA + ηI S + I C N , E = βS ρE + εA + ηI S + I C N − κE, www.nature.com/scientificreports/ where V t (S) is the expected utility of susceptible individuals at time t, V t+1 (S) ( V t+1 (E) ) is the expected utility being susceptible (exposed) at time t + 1 , and is the probability of being infected at time t. The maximization problem in Eq. (4) accounts for the individual's immediate utility ( u(S, C S t ) ), plus the expected future utility discounted at rate δ . The susceptible individual's expected future utility comprises the expected utility of remaining susceptible with probability 1 − P I and, the expected utility of being infected (progressing to the E compartment) with probability P I . Notice that in order to solve Eq. (4), the expected utility of exposed individuals is required, which is given by Eq. (6) where P E = 1 − e −κ stands for the probability of moving from the E health class to either A, I S or I C health classes, with probabilities defined by our constant contact rates model. Similar to Eq. (4), V t (E) sums the immediate utility of currently being exposed ( u(E, C S t ) ) and the discounted expected future utility of progressing to possible future health states. The future expected utility while exposed comprises the expected utility of remaining in the exposed compartment with probability (1 − P E ) or progressing out of the exposed compartment with probability P E . The future expected utility for exposed individuals progressing to a different health class comprises the future expected utilities of being asymptomatic, infected compliant or infected non-compliant, with probabilities P E σ , P E (1 − σ )(1 − l) and P E (1 − σ )l , respectively. Finally, the expected utility of asymptomatic ( V t (A) ), infected compliant ( V t (I S ) ) and infected non-compliant ( V t (I C ) ), comprise the immediate utility and the discounted future expected utility when recovered ( V t (R) ). The Bellman's equations for individuals in these health states are, respectively: where P R = 1 − e −γ is the probability of recovery. Notice that the assumption that non-symptomatic individuals are unaware of their health status implies that the current utility ( U(h, C S t ) for h ∈ {E, A} ), is computed choosing a contact rate similar to individuals in the susceptible health state. That is, the contact rates used in the terms u(E, C S t ) and u(A, C S t ) in Eqs. (6) and (7), respectively, are driven by individuals' own health status perception. A variation to the modeling framework proposed in Refs. [27] [28] [29] . Symptomatic infected individuals. We suppose that symptomatic infected individuals divide into two subclasses: a fraction 1 − l of symptomatic individuals comply with health authority recommendations for the mitigation of population level disease risk ( I S ), while the rest of symptomatic individuals do not comply with those recommendations ( I C ). We suppose that all individuals in I S and I C , develop symptoms and are aware that they are infected and infectious. The solution to the Bellman's equation for symptomatic infected individuals generates the privately optimal contact rate for individuals in that health class. However, we also suppose that individuals in I S are willing to reduce their contact rate below the privately optimal level in compliance with health authority recommendations 52 . Particularly, we suppose that compliant infected individuals are willing to accept a reduction in the utility they gain from contacts, so long as utility does not fall below the minimum acceptable level, u c . In this respect, our approach differs from the framework proposed in Refs. [27] [28] [29] . Note that expected utility in (8) and (9) depends on the average recovery period. We therefore derive the following explicit expression for non-compliant I C individuals' expected utility where C I C * t ≤ C * t . The first term of (10) corresponds to the expected utility obtained while infected, and the second term corresponds to the expected utility obtained while recovered, during the planning horizon. By contrast, compliant individuals reduce their contact rate subject to a level consistent with securing a minimal utility, solving the problem (4) V t (S) = max C S t {u(S, C S t ) + δ[(1 − P I )V t+1 (S) + P I V t+1 (E)]}, (5) P I = 1 − exp −βC S t S C E t ρE + C A t εA + C I S t ηI S + C I C t I C C S t S + C E t E + C A t A + C I S t I S + C I C t I C + C R t R www.nature.com/scientificreports/ The critical utility value for compliant individuals is a free parameter that allow us to calibrate the model for different scenarios of compliance. Notice that Eq. (11) comprises only the infectious period, since an infected individual is assumed to stop this behavioral regime when recovered. Taking into account the contact rates of compliant and non-compliant individuals, we let the expected contact rate of symptomatic individuals to be given by weighting the non-compliant and compliant individuals with their respective contact rates: C I t = l(C I C ) + (1 − l)C I S t . We assume there is no incentive for recovered individuals to behave strategically, since our model does not consider potential reinfections. Therefore, we let recovered individuals make the daily number of contacts that maximizes the net benefits of contact. The recovered individuals Bellman's equation is given by Asymptomatic humans transmit dengue virus to mosquitoes Asymptomatic infection and unrecognised Ebola Virus Disease in Ebola-affected households in Sierra Leone: A cross-sectional study using a new non-invasive assay for antibodies to Ebola virus The implications of silent transmission for the control of COVID-19 outbreaks Evidence supporting transmission of severe acute respiratory syndrome coronavirus 2 while presymptomatic or asymptomatic A systematic review of asymptomatic infections with COVID-19 Substantial undocumented infection facilitates the rapid dissemination of novel coronavirus (SARS-CoV-2) The contribution of asymptomatic SARS-CoV-2 infections to transmission on the Diamond Princess cruise ship Quantifying SARS-CoV-2 transmission suggests epidemic control with digital contact tracing Epidemiology and transmission dynamics of COVID-19 in two Indian states Mathematical modeling of COVID-19 in 14.8 million individuals in Bahia, Brazil What the data say about asymptomatic COVID infections Estimation of the asymptomatic ratio of novel coronavirus infections (COVID-19) False negative tests for SARS-CoV-2 infection-challenges and implications Estimating the extent of true asymptomatic COVID-19 and its potential for community transmission: Systematic review and meta-analysis COVID-19: What proportion are asymptomatic Towards an accurate and systematic characterisation of persistently asymptomatic infection with SARS-CoV-2 Estimating the asymptomatic proportion of coronavirus disease 2019 (COVID-19) cases on board the Diamond Princess cruise ship Relative infectiousness of asymptomatic SARS-CoV-2 infected persons compared with symptomatic individuals: a rapidscoping review Asymptomatic and symptomatic SARS-CoV-2 infections in close contacts of COVID-19 patients: A seroepidemiological study Prevalence of asymptomatic SARS-CoV-2 infection: A narrative review The behavioural immune system and the psychology of human sociality Behavioural change models for infectious disease transmission: A systematic review (2010-2015) Modelling the influence of human behaviour on the spread of infectious diseases: A review Individual and collective behavior in public health epidemiology The economic consequences of social-network structure The impact of social structure on economic outcomes Adaptive human behavior in epidemiological models Merging economics and epidemiology to improve the prediction and management of infectious disease SIR dynamics with economically driven contact rates Coupled contagion dynamics of fear and disease: Mathematical and computational explorations The spread of awareness and its impact on epidemic outbreaks Game theory of social distancing in response to an epidemic Mask-wearing and control of SARS-CoV-2 transmission in the USA: a cross-sectional study Rational use of face masks in the COVID-19 pandemic Impacts of game-theoretic activation on epidemic spread over dynamical networks Transmission dynamics and control of severe acute respiratory syndrome Virological assessment of hospitalized patients with COVID-2019 Effective control of SARS-CoV-2 transmission in Wanzhou, China Preliminary estimation of the basic reproduction number of novel coronavirus (2019-nCoV) in China, from 2019 to 2020: A data-driven analysis in the early phase of the outbreak Economic considerations for social distancing and behavioral based policies during an epidemic The impact of asymptomatic COVID-19 infections on future pandemic waves Asymptomatic patients as a source of COVID-19 infections: A systematic review and meta-analysis Asymptomatic cases with SARS-CoV-2 infection Viral dynamics in asymptomatic patients with COVID-19 The time scale of asymptomatic transmission affects estimates of epidemic potential in the COVID-19 outbreak Asymptomatic and pre-symptomatic cases of COVID-19 contribution to spreading the epidemic and need for targeted control strategies As virus surges in Europe, resistance to new restrictions also grows. N. Y. Times Oct As the coronavirus surges, a new culprit emerges: Pandemic fatigue Some simple nosocomial disease transmission models Temporal dynamics in viral shedding and transmissibility of COVID-19 Modeling behavioral change and COVID-19 containment in Mexico: A trade-off between lockdown and compliance Changes in risk perception and self-reported protective behaviour during the first week of the COVID-19 pandemic in the United States The authors would like to thank members of the Biocomplexity COVID-19 Response Team and the Network Systems Science and Advanced Computing (NSSAC) Division for their thoughtful comments and suggestions related to epidemic modeling and response support. We thank members of the Biocomplexity Institute and Initiative, University of Virginia, for useful discussion and suggestions. We also thank Dr. Charles Perrings The authors declare no competing interests. The online version contains supplementary material available at https:// doi. org/ 10. 1038/ s41598-021-98999-2.Correspondence and requests for materials should be addressed to B.E. Publisher's note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http:// creat iveco mmons. org/ licen ses/ by/4. 0/.