key: cord-0551985-ehsry8qa authors: Coculescu, Delia; Dandapani, Aditi title: Insiders and their Free Lunches: the Role of Short Positions date: 2020-12-01 journal: nan DOI: nan sha: 5c803d435816e5d4e56b3c4315bcc6d84c7b2b13 doc_id: 551985 cord_uid: ehsry8qa Given a stock price process, we analyse the potential of arbitrage by insiders in a context of short-selling prohibitions. We introduce the notion of minimal supermartingale measure, and we analyse its properties in connection to the minimal martingale measure. In particular, we establish conditions when both fail to exist. These correspond to the case when the insider's information set includes some non null events that are perceived as having null probabilities by the uninformed market investors. These results may have different applications, such as in problems related to the local risk-minimisation for insiders whenever strategies are implemented without short selling. Given a stock price process, we analyse the potential of arbitrage by insiders, when they chose not to sell short. Short-selling stocks when having access to a value-destroying event before it is known to the public leads to profits, but insiders that are already detaining the stocks may profit without engaging in selling short. Selling (and buying) of company shares by people who have special information because they are involved with the company is illegal in many jurisdictions, whenever the information is non-public and material. Insider trading scandals are nevertheless regularly on the front page of newspapers. For instance, the US justice department is currently investigating alleged insider trading by US lawmakers who sold stocks just before the coronavirus pandemic sparked a major market downturn. Rarely short selling is part of the insiders' strategies in these scandals. Short selling transactions receive additional attention from supervisory authorities in their attempt to detect abnormal trading activity and it is possible that many insiders refrain from such strategies for their trades to remain undetected. It is not clear nevertheless, from both a practical and purely theoretical perspective if an insider that does not detain the stock has the possibility to first buy and then sell the stock in a profitable manner, thus exploiting the informational advantage without selling short. The aim of this paper is to propose some first elements in tackling this question. For the notion of no arbitrage profits, we consider the setting of no free lunch with vanishing risks with short sales prohibitions (NFLVRS) introduced in Pulido [37] , a restriction of the classical notion of no free lunch with vanishing risks (NFLVR) by Delbaen and Schachermeyer [13] , [15] . Based on previous work by Jouini and Kallal [27] , Fritelli [19] , Pham and Touzi [34] , Napp [30] and Karatzas and Kardaras [28] , the paper by Pulido [37] establishes important properties of price processes under short sale prohibitions namely the equivalence between (NFLVRS) and the existence of an equivalent supermartingale measure for the price processes. Structure conditions for a price process under (NFLVRS) are provided in Coculescu and Jeanblanc [10] . Recently, Platen and Tappe [35] raised a similar question to the one we are analysing here, namely if exploiting arbitrages requires short-selling, however without insider information being specifically analysed. It is shown that without any possibility of selling short, it is not possible to exploit arbitrages. But at the difference of their paper, we allow the investor to borrow risk-free (that is equivalent selling short risk-free assets), and this assumption results in additional possibilities for exploiting possible arbitrages. Hence, the results in [35] do not apply to our framework. There is a very vast literature studying arbitrage possibilities and characterising no-arbitrage models, for different types of inside information and for different notions of arbitrage, sometimes weaker that no free lunch with vanishing risks. Usually, a model with respect to a given information set (filtration) is specified on a probability space, representing the financial market such as common investors perceive it, and the insider information is introduced as a strictly larger information set, via an enlargement of the original filtration. A fundamental question in this context is whether the additional information allows for arbitrage profits. We mention the early work by Grorud and Pontier [20] , Amendinger et al. [4] , Imkeller [24] and subsequent work by Hillairet [22] , Acciaio et al. [1] , Aksamit et al. [2] , Fontana et al [18] , Chau et al [9] , among athers. In a general setting, the situations where the additional information of an insider is insufficient for obtaining profits of arbitrage in the form of no free lunch with vanishing risk, were characterised in the literature and linked to the so-called (H) hypothesis holding between the asset price filtration and the larger filtration containing the additional information, under an equivalent martingale measure (see Blanchet-Scalliet and Jeanblanc [6] and Coculescu et al. [11] ). The present paper contributes to the literature on insider trading by studying specifically the short-sales restrictions. Within the two-filtration setting above described, with a filtration larger than the other, and where a stock price is an adapted process for both filtrations, we shall assume that no free lunch with vanishing risks prevails for the common investors having access only to the smallest filtration. We will then exclusively focus on the no arbitrage conditions in the larger filtration, that is, when considering the insider information. As mentioned above, the existence of a supermartingale measure for the stock price is equivalent to (NFLVRS) (Pulido [37] ). After we introduce the notion of minimal supermartingale measure, we analyse some of its connections with the minimal martingale measure. The results in Section 3 are actually general and do not depend on the two-filtration setting. In Section 4, a further analysis of the connections between the two measures is provided, specific to the the case of an insider, when assuming the smaller filtration has the predictable representation property with respect to a continuous martingale. The failure of both the minimal martingale measure and the minimal supermartingale measure to exist is obtained when the (H) hypothesis is satisfied under a probability measure such that the original one is absolutely continuous to it, but not equivalent. The additional null sets of the original measure belong to the inside information: they are not measurable in the smaller filtration that models the information of the common investors. Some new results on the importance of the (H) hypothesis may also be found in Section 4, in particular for the case where (NFLVRS) holds but (NFLVR) fails to hold. This corresponds to the case where the arbitrages cannot be exploited without selling the stock short. In the Conclusions section, we shall discuss some possible extensions and uses of our results. A probability space (Ω, G, P) is fixed, endowed with a right-continuous filtration F 0 = (F 0 t ) t≥0 . We denote by F = (F t ) t≥0 the augmentation of F 0 with the null sets of P, ensuring that F satisfies the usual assumptions. We consider a financial market where a risky asset (e.g. a stock) is traded, in addition to a risk-free asset and such that the price process, denoted by X = (X t ) t≥0 is adapted. To keep the message simple, we assume that the price of the risk-free asset is constant. Alternatively, one could consider the discounted asset price. Through this paper, we make the following assumption: Hypothesis 2.1. There exists an equivalent local martingale measure for X in the filtration F. Hypothesis 2.1 more precisely means: there exists a probability P * ∼ P on (Ω, F ∞ ) such that X is a (F, P * ) local martingale. We emphasise that it is only required the equivalence of these measures on F ∞ . Implicit to Hypothesis 2.1 is also that X is a locally bounded (F, P) semimartingale. We have thus a standard arbitrage free market in the sense of no free lunch with vanishing risks [13] , whenever the filtration F summarises the available information. We shall call common investors the F informed investors. We now take the point of view of a particular agent, that we name the insider. We assume that the insider has access to some information that can potentially impact the risky asset price, should this information be publicly released. Hence, the insider may have access to some forms or arbitrage, even under Hypothesis 2.1, as the asset price does not necessarily incorporate the extra information. In mathematical terms, there is a right continuous filtration G 0 strictly larger than F 0 , i.e., such that (1) We define G as the P augmentation of G 0 , so that G satisfies the usual assumptions. The insider is assumed to be able to use G adapted strategies in order to make investments in X and the risk-free asset. We do not assume any particular structure of the filtration G, except being strictly larger than F, in the sense of (1). The filtrations F 0 and G 0 will still play a role later on, as we consider probabilities to which P is only absolutely continuous. For now, the framework is that of the probability space (Ω, G, P) endowed with two filtrations F ⊂ G. Importantly, we shall assume a certain structure for the decomposition of the stochastic process X in the insider filtration G, namely: Hypothesis 2.2. The price of the risky asset X is a nonnegative (G, P) semimartingale of the form: for some (G, P) local martingale M and a (G, P) predictable process α. The process M , the sharp bracket of M, is the (G, P) dual predictable projection of the quadratic variation of M. For simplicity, and without loss of generality, we shall assume α to be constantly zero on the intervals where d M = 0. Before considering the question of whether the insider can have free lunches, one should clarify the available trading strategies for the insider. The insider is supposed to invest in the risky and risk free asset based on her information. We are interested here in two alternative situations: the one where the insider may sell short the risky asset and the one where she is constrained to have only long positions in the risky asset, i.e., short sales are prohibited. Consequently, we define the following sets for t ≥ 0: Obviously, we have that M t (G, P) ⊂ S t (G, P) t ≥ 0. 3 In this paper we intend to analyse from the insider's perspective the connections between arbitrages involving short selling the risky asset and arbitrages that exclude short selling the risky asset. The no arbitrage conditions we study are relative to the insider filtration G, and they are formally the following: (a) the no free lunch with vanishing risks (NFLVR) condition of Delbaen and Schachermayer [13] , in the case where short positions are permitted along with the long positions in the assets. In our setting, (NFLVR) is equivalent to: M(G, P) = ∅. (b) the no free lunch with vanishing risk under short sales prohibition (NFLVRS), a condition that was introduced in Pulido [37] . In our setting, by short sales prohibitions we mean that long positions in the risky asset are permitted, along with short and long in the risk-free asset, and in this case (NFLVRS) is equivalent to: S(G, P) = ∅ (cf. Theorem 3.9 in [37] ). , we use the following notation o,P Y stands for the optional projection of the process Y onto the filtration F, with respect to the measure P; whenever Y is increasing: Y o,P stands for its (F, P)-dual optional projection; Y p,P stands for its (F, P)-dual predictable projection; Some results will be established in the particular settings where the process X has continuous sample paths, or F enjoys the predictable representation property, that is, we have a complete F market. We label these particular settings as follows: (C) The stochastic process X has continuous sample path. F-(PRP) The filtration F is the natural filtration of the price process X. There is a (one dimensional) (F, P) local martingale m F,P such that m F,P satisfies the (F, P) predictable representation property, that is: any (F, P) local martingale vanishing at zero is equal to H · m F,P for a suitable F predictable process H. In the remaining of this section, we emphasise some implications of our modelling assumptions. The choice of assuming a decomposition of X as proposed in (2) is rooted in the result below: Proof. In the case where M(G, P) = ∅ holds, the decomposition in (2) is due to Ansel and Stricker [5] and Schweizer [41] for a G predictable process α. The same holds when S(G, P) = ∅, as proved by Coculescu and Jeanblanc [10] (note that should X be a discontinuous price process the decomposition above is not automatic). ✷ From Theorem 2.4, we may characterise a framework where the insider can have free lunches with vanishing risk without engaging in short sales: Corollary 2.5. Suppose that Hypothesis 2.1 and condition (C) hold. Then, if Hypothesis 2.2 is not satisfied, it follows that M(G, P) = ∅ and S(G, P) = ∅. In Coculescu and Jeanblanc [10] , examples are provided where the (G, P) decomposition of X fails to satisfy (2) , in the case where G is obtained by progressive enlargements of F with a random time. The corresponding arbitrage portfolios are also discussed. The current paper is intended to further analyse the question of (NFLVRS) within the frame of Hypothesis 2.2, that is, the representation (2) for the stock price holds. Finally, we can notice that implicit to Hypothesis 2.1 is also a (F, P) decomposition of the price process X, as follows: there is a (F, P) local martingale m F,P such that where we have (recall our notation) m F,P = o,P [m F,P ], that is the sharp bracket of the (F, P) local martingale m F,P . This decomposition follows by the same argument as in the proof of Theorem 2.4 (i), but applied to F instead of G. Given Hypotheses 2.1 and 2.2, it follows that m F,P is a (G, P) semimartingale that decomposes: Further analysis in Section 4 will again give rise to the representations (2) and (3) by means of Girsanov transformations. It is important to keep in mind that we assume that no free lunch with vanishing risk holds for common investors (that is in the smaller filtration F), and we analyse the properties of the price process when some additional information is available for an insider, that is, in the filtration G. In this section we introduce the concept of minimal supermartingale measure and establish some connections with the minimal martingale measure. We use the framework from the previous section, in particular the representation of the asset price in Hypothesis 2.2 is supposed to be verified. However, Hypothesis 2.1 is not used in establishing the results in this section, so that the results are general and still hold even if it is were not satisfied. We introduce the following (G, P) local martingales: We denote dQ M dP Gt = R t , 5 and if R is a strictly positive and uniformly integrable martingale, we have Q M ∈ M(G, P). and if R (+) is a strictly positive and uniformly integrable martingale we have Q S ∈ S(G, P) which can be checked using Girsanov's theorem. In general, Q M and Q S are signed measures. We recall below the notion of minimal martingale measure which first appeared in Schweizer [40] (see also Föllmer and Schweizer ([17] ) for a survey of this very rich topic). Definition 3.1. When R is a strictly positive and square integrable (G, P) martingale, we call Q M ∈ M(G, P) the (G, P) minimal martingale measure for X. Symmetrically, let us introduce the following definition: is a strictly positive and square integrable (G, P) martingale, we call Q S ∈ S(G, P), that is defined as in (6), the (G, P) minimal supermartingale measure for X. In what follows, we will skip the specification of the filtration and of the reference probability (G, P) and will be simply referring to Q M resp. Q S as the minimal martingale (resp. supermartingale) measure. It can be shown that when X has continuous sample paths, the minimal supermartingale measure can be characterised as the unique solution of a minimisation problem involving the relative entropy with respect to P, in a parallel manner to the result holding for the minimal martingale measure; in both cases the idea is to obtain a "minimal modification" of P that allows to reach the set of supermartingale versus martingale measures. The formal setting is given below. The relative entropy is interpreted as a directed divergence measure between two probabilities; it is nonnegative and H(Q|P) = 0 if and only if Q = P. Theorem 3.4. We assume that Hypothesis 2.2 and (C) hold. Assume also that Q S ∈ S T (G, P) and H(Q S |P) < ∞. Then, the measure Q S is the unique solution of over all supermartingale measures Q ∈ S T (G, P), satisfying the condition Note that the condition , for t ≥ 0. Further, by the Kunita-Watanabe decomposition, 6 In the above, N Q is a (G, P) local martingale orthogonal to M and β Q is a G predictable process. Under (G, Q) and for t ∈ [0, T ], X possesses the following decomposition: We use the notation {d M t > 0}, for the support of the random measure on B([0, T ]), associated with the nondecreasing process M . We have that Therefore, and where the min and max above are taken over the same set as in the problem (7); it can be checked that Q S belongs in this set. We have that min Q H(Q|Q S ) = 0; the minimal value of 0 is obtained if and only if Q = Q S . Also, in view of the inequality (9), E Q T 0 α + s (α s + β Q s )d X s ≤ 0 and we can check that the maximum value of this expected value is 0, obtained when taking β Q = −α + , that is, G Q = R (+) , or Q = Q S . This proves that (7) equals 0 and this value is attained if and only if Q = Q S . Let us now emphasise some first connections between Q M and Q S : Remark 3.6. Before we prove this result, let us illustrate the condition appearing in (b). We consider W is a Brownian motion with respect to (G, P), and let α := |W |. We obtain 1 1 |Wt|>0 = H t − 1 1 Wt=0 where H t := 1 1 |Wt|≥0 = 1. By Proposition 3.12 page 108 in [38] , the set {t : W (t) = 0} is a.s. closed, without any isolated points and has zero Lebesgue measure. Hence, H is a modification of the process 1 1 |Wt|>0 . As H is continuous, with null total variation, we conclude that for this example, the condition stated in Theorem 3.5 (b) is fulfilled. Alternatively, let us consider there is a (G, P) counting process N with càdlàg sample path and with finite explosion time. Let α := (−1) N . Then, the process α is càdlàg and has infinite total variation. In this case, the condition stated in Theorem 3.5 (b) is not fulfilled. Proof. (of Theorem 3.5) (a) We need to prove that if R is a strictly positive and square integrable (G, P) martingale then R (+) is a strictly positive and uniformly integrable (G, P) martingale. Let us introduce the following (G, P) local martingale, which is orthogonal to R (+) : so that: t . The processes R (+) and R (−) are strictly positive local martingales: they satisfy R = 1 and can become negative or null only after a jump, i.e., one at a time at most (as they do not have common jumps). In other words, the product R is strictly positive if and only if R (+) and R (−) are strictly positive. Then, one can show that R (+) is a uniformly integrable martingale, as a direct application of Proposition A.1 in Appendix A. We denote by H = (H t ) t≥0 a right-continuous modification of the process (1 1 αt>0 ) t≥0 , assumed of bounded variation. We can write R . The result then follows as an application of the Lemma A.2 in Appendix A. ✷ Another sufficient condition for Q S ∈ S(G, P) is the following: Lemma 3.7. We assume that the representation in Hypothesis 2.2 holds. Suppose that it exists Q ∈ S T (G, Proof. We use the same notation as in the proof of Theorem 3.4.; in particular the process L Q is a (G, P) local martingale with the Kunita Watanabe decomposition given in (8) . In order for X to be a (G, Q)-supermartingale, necessarily the process: is nonincreasing, in particular we need: (notice that {(ω, t)|α t (ω) > 0} is supposed to be included in the support of d M by Hypothesis 2.2). By assumption, E(L Q ) satisfies the Novikov condition. Hence, in view of the above inequality, R (+) is a uniformly integrable martingale satisfying the Novikov condition. ✷ In this section, assuming F-(PRP), we further analyse connections between the existence of Q M and Q S , in particular under the assumption that the (H) hypothesis under some probability measure on (Ω, G) holds true. Given two filtrations, F ⊂ G, the (H) hypothesis, also called the immersion property, is the property that all F martingales are also G martingales; the immersion property holds in relation to a reference probability measure. In the financial literature, the (H) hypothesis under an equivalent martingale measure for the asset prices is known as a classical no arbitrage condition whenever asset prices are F adapted, but agents may employ G-adapted strategies. The main result is due to Blanchet-Scalliet and Jeanblanc [6] (see Theorem 4.2 below), further results involving the (H) hypothesis and no arbitrage can be found in [11] . It is to be noted that both references [6] and [11] are focused on the particular case where the filtration G is obtained from F via a progressive enlargement with a random time, but some of their results are general (as we shall emphasize below). These results are investigating the link between (NFLVR) in G and (H), more precisely, when the G informed agent is able to sell short. We shall see that the immersion property is still a key condition for understanding (NFLVRS) in G. For the reader's convenience, let us first give a definition and recall some results that are needed later on. More about the immersion of filtrations can be found in [7] , [12] or [3] . See also [29] , [11] where changes of the probability measure are considered together with the immersion property. In general, the immersion property is not preserved by changes of the probability measure. Let us introduce the following notation for the set of probability measures that have the immersion property and are equivalent to P: We now state the result of Blanchet-Scalliet and Jeanblanc that was mentioned above. Even though in [6] the filtration G is defined as a progressive enlargement of F with a random time, the proof of their Proposition 1 -that corresponds to Theorem 4.2 below -holds actually in the generality of our definition for G, as one can easily verify; see also Corollary 4.6 in [11] for an alternative proof of this result. We want to understand if a potential of arbitrage is generated by the inside information, and the possible connections with the immersion property. To fully isolate this case of interest, no arbitrage for the common investors will be systematically assumed from now, in the form of Hypothesis 2.1. This way, any possible G arbitrage is necessarily arising from the exploitation of the inside information and is not accessible with F adapted strategies. With this extra requirement, we can be establish some stronger result than Theorem 4.2, in the form of Theorem 4.4 below. But before, let us also recall some well known financial implication of F-(PRP), namely the market is complete for the common investors. (i) P * ∼ P on F ∞ , and (ii) X is a (F, P * ) local martingale. This result is known under the name of second theorem theorem of asset pricing (see Harrison and Pliska [21] ). Furthermore, X has the (F, P * ) predictable representation property in the filtration F. Indeed, the predictable representation property is stable under equivalent changes of the probability measure (Theorem 13.12 in [23] ). One question is whether there are extensions of P * to the larger sigma-field G that can serve as equivalent martingale measures for the insider. Proof. -The implication (i) ⇒ (ii) follows from Theorem 4.2. -The implications (ii) ⇒ (iii) follows from Proposition 4.4 in [11] . We emphasize that this result holds in the generality of our setting for the filtrations F and G. We recall this result, for the reader's convenience: Given a reference probability measure P, if I(F, G, P) = ∅, then there is Q ∈ I(F, G, P) such that every (F, P) martingale is a (G, Q) martingale, that is, Q = P on F ∞ . This result means that if (ii) holds, then there exist equivalent probability measures that keep the F martingales unchanged and at the same time ensure the immersion property holds. We now take P * as a reference measure, where P * ∈ M(F, P), that is, X is a local martingale in the smaller filtration F under P * . Because P ∼ P * , it follows that I(F, G, P * ) = I(F, G, P). Thence (ii) is equivalent to: I(F, G, P * ) = ∅. Then, by Proposition 4.4 in [11] stated above, there is Q ∈ I(F, G, P * ) such that Q = P * on F ∞ , in particular X is a local martingale in both filtrations under Q. Hence (iii) holds. -The implication (iii) ⇒ (i) is obvious. -The equivalences with the last statement are also obvious: (iv) implies (ii) and also (iii) implies (iv), as if Q is a local martingale measure in filtration G, it is also a supermartingale measure in filtration G. can ensure for the (H) hypothesis to hold, when taken as a reference measure. Indeed, another formulation for the equivalence between (i) and (iv) is: We illustrate this situation by a simple example using honest times, inspired by the more general construction available in [31] . We refer to [18] for an analysis of arbitrages arising from knowledge of honest times (where short-sales restrictions are not studied). These references provide a general setting, surely also suitable for a more systematic study of the implications of short-sale restrictions in progressive enlargements of filtrations with honest times (that is beyond the scope here). Example. We assume the filtration G is the progressive enlargement of the filtration F with the last passage time of the stock price at its supremum level. More exactly let X = E(σW t ) where W is (F, P) Brownian motion. We notice that lim t→∞ X t = 0. Let S t = sup s≤t X s and We let G be the smallest filtration that satisfies the usual assumptions and so that g is a G stopping time. We thus assume the insider observes g when it occurs. The random time g is a last passage time within the filtration F and moreover the decomposition of the price process in the filtration G is given by (cf. Proposition 2.5 in [32] ): Where M = σ XdŴ corresponds to the local martingale in the decomposition (2) withŴ being a (G, P) Brownian motion. We now consider a finite horizon, that is t ∈ [0, T ], so that the process X is stopped at T . Then, there exists a minimal supermartingale measure and it satisfies dQ S = E(−σŴ T ∧g )·dP on G T . Indeed, Q S ∈ S T (G, P) as one can easily verify. However, there is no martingale measure in the filtration G: I T (G, P) = ∅ and M T (G, P) = ∅. Now, we want to shed some additional light on the connections between Q S and Q M , namely, we provide conditions under which both fail to be probability measures (in Theorem 4.8 below). As we shall only focus on a bounded time horizon [0, T ], we introduce the stopped filtrations F T = (F T ∧t ) and G T = (G T ∧t ), and we suppose that all stochastic processes are also stopped at T without introducing further notation. We also shall assume that F T P ֒→ G T , that is, so that our model is compatible with the (possible) failure of (NFLVR) in the filtration G (the terminal value of the portfolio will be nonnegative and strictly positive with positive probability). 11 Let us introduce the following set of probability measures: We have that I(F, G, P) ⊂ P ∞ (F, G, P). Absolutely continuous, but not equivalent, changes of measure may lead to arbitrage opportunities in the (NFLVR) sense, see e.g. Delbaen and Schachermayer [14] , Osterrieder and Rheinländer [33] , Ruf and Runggaldier [39] and Chau and Tankov [8] . Notation 4.6. Suppose that Q ∈ P T (F, G, P). We denote by V T (Q) the set of (G T , Q) local martingales that admit the representation (c + H 2 s d m s is locally integrable. As the immersion property holds for any Q ∈ P T (F, G, P), the stochastic integrals introduced above are well defined. In our next two results we will show that for Q M or Q S to be probabilities on G T , a certain subset of P T (F, G, P) plays a central role, namely Theorem 4.7. We assume that Hypothesis 2.1 and F-(PRP) hold. If p T (F, G, P) = ∅, then there exists a unique probability measure Q * that satisfies: The price process X is a (G T , Q * ) local martingale. Assume furthermore Hypothesis 2.2 and assumption (C) hold. Then: (iii) The process admits the (G T , Q * ) representation: It follows that Q * ∼ P on G T if and only if Q * = Q M ∈ M T (G, P). Proof. The set p T (F, G, P) contains equivalent probabilities and therefore we shall introduce Q * via a Girsanov transformation, relatively to an arbitrary element in p T (F, G, P). Let Q ∈ p T (F, G, P). Then there is a nonnegative (G T , Q) martingale E with dP = E T · Q on G T and a strictly positive (F T , Q) martingale e with dP = e T · Q on F T . If Hypothesis 2.1 together with F-(PRP) hold, there is a unique local martingale measure for the price process X and in the filtration F, that is, there is a unique (F, P) uniformly integrable martingale δ with δ being strictly positive δ 0 = 1, such that the process Xδ is (F, P) local martingale. Furthermore, δ admits a representation as (in line with the representation of the asset price given in (3)). Hence, an equivalent local martingale measure for the common (F informed) investors may be defined on G via dP * := δ ∞ · dP an G. We are after a probability Q * ∈ p T (F, G, P) that may potentially serve as an equivalent martingale measure for the insider, as the price process X is required to be a (G T , Q * ) local martingale, by statement (ii) of the theorem. We introduce Q * via: It can be checked that Q * ∼ Q and furthermore Q * concides with P * on F T : Consequently, Q * is a well defined change of measure on F T with the Radon-Nikodým density process (δ t e t ) being a strictly positive (F, Q) martingale. Finally, as the (H) hypothesis holds under Q, the process (δ t e t ) is also a (G, Q) martingale, so that the mesure Q * is well defined also on G T . One can see that Q * ∈ P T (F, G, P). This is the consequence of the fact that the immersion property is preserved under changes of measure using F ∞ measurable Radon-Nicodým derivatives (see Lemma 4.3 in [11] ). Indeed, we have F Q ֒→ G and dQ * dQ is F T measurable therefore F Q * ֒→ G and so that indeed Q * ∈ P T (F, G, P). We can now prove the statements of the theorem: (ii) Using Girsanov's theorem in the filtration F T , we obtain that the following is a (F T , Q * ) martingale: As F Q * ֒→ G, it follows that m F,Q * is also a (G T , Q * ) martingale, so that the (G T , Q * ) semimartingale decomposition of the asset price X is: that is a (G T , Q * ) martingale. (i) In view of (11), we only need to show that dP . We first provide (G T , Q) representations for the processes e and E. Because F-(PRP) holds and Q ∼ P on F T , it follows that in the filtration F the Q martingales also have the predictable representation property, with respect to the martingale [23] , Theorem 13.12]). Then, there exists an F predictable process h so that e = E hdm F,Q . As (H) holds under Q, m F,Q is also a Q martingale in the larger filtration G T . Then, e is also a (G T , Q) martingale, while E has the representation with N a (G T , Q) local martingale orthogonal to m F,Q , and where H is a G predictable process. This representation of E is Q − a.s. unique on the set [0, . This leads to the representation Moreover, the condition E Q [E t |F t ] = e t leads to a relation between H and h, (cf. Brémaud and Yor [7] , Proposition 1) namely Using all the above representations, we obtain: that proves the statement (i). We now assume Hypothesis 2.2 and (C) and prove the last statements. (iii) It is sufficient to prove the relation R = (D * ) −1 P a.s. Let us denote β : t is a (G, P) local martingale. Given the assumption (C), m F,Q * = M , that is, the quadratic variation. Consequently, we obtain the following (G, P) representation of X: If P and Q * are not equivalent on G T , it may still be the case that M T (G, P) = ∅. Indeed, one cannot exclude a priori the existence of a probability Q satisfying Q ∈ I(F, G, P) ( by Theorem 4.4 (ii) this is indeed equivalent to M T (G, P) = ∅). In such a case the measure Q m is not a probability, but there exist equivalent local martingale measures for the price process in G. In the next theorem we emphasise that quite strong relations between Q M and Q S exist whenever the reference measure P is a local martingale measure for the price process X, within the smaller filtration F (i.e., this situation is obtained for (a t ) ≡ 0 in (3), or, equivalently P = P * on F ∞ , where P * is as in Remark 4.3). 14 Theorem 4.8. We assume Hypotheses 2.1 and 2.2 together with conditions (C) and F-(PRP). In addition, we consider X is a (F, P) local martingale (in the representation (3) , the process (a t ) is taken to be null). Suppose p T (F, G, P) = ∅ and let Q * be such as in Theorem 4.7 . Then, the following hold: (a) If P and Q * are not equivalent on G T , then Q M / ∈ M T (G, P) and Q S / ∈ S T (G, P). (b) If P ∼ Q * on G T and dP dQ * | G T ∈ L 2 (Ω, G, Q * ), then Q S ∈ S T (G, P) and Q M ∈ M T (G, P). The proof of this theorem is postponed at the end of this section. In order to prove Theorem 4.8, we take as reference a probability space (Ω, G, Q * ), endowed with right-continuous filtrations F 0 ⊂ G 0 satisfying (1). We suppose that (H) hypothesis holds under Q * and our aim is to recover P form Q * with the help of a Girsanov transformation. The key properties of our initial model under P, in particular R and R (+) being or not strict local martingales, will appear as resulting from whether P is actually equivalent to Q * or only absolutely continuous (see Proposition 4.9 below). The filtrations F and G will be defined as completions with the null sets of P, as before. The assumptions that are going to be used below are the following: (A1) The filtration F 0 is the natural, Q * augmented filtration of a Q * -Brownian motion B. (A2) The filtrations F 0 and G 0 satisfy the condition (1) and furthermore F 0 Q * ֒→ G 0 . (A3) There is a nonnegative (G 0 , Q * ) martingale having the representation: where G is a G 0 predictable process satisfying E Q * [G t |F 0 t ] = 0 for all t ∈ [0, T ]. We now define the probability P as: where D * is the martingale defined in (14) . Proposition 4.9. We consider the probability space (Ω, G, Q * ) with the assumptions (A1)-(A3) and let P be defined as in (15) . The filtration F is defined as the usual augmentation of F 0 with the P null sets and similarly, the filtration G is defined as the usual augmentation of G 0 with the P null sets. Let X be a (F, Q * ) local martingale. The following hold: (a) The process X is a (F, P) local martingale and it is a (G, P) semimartingale with the Doob Meyer decomposition: for a (G, P) local martingale M and a G-predictable process α having a null (F, P) optional projection. Thus, X satisfies the Hypothesis 2. (c) If P ≪ Q * but P is not equivalent to Q * on G T , then both R and R (+) are strict (G T , P)local martingales. Proof. For simplicity, all processes are considered as stopped at T . Proof of claim in (a). The process X being an (F, Q * ) local martingale by assumption, there is an F-predictable process F such that We shall prove that the assumption (A4) implies: which then implies that all (F, Q * )-local martingales remain (F, P) local martingales, in particular X. The density process ( dP dQ * | Ft ) t∈[0,T ] is given by the (F, Q * ) optional projection of the process D * . The Brownian motion B being an (F, Q * ) and a (G, Q * ) local martingale (by assumption (A2)), we obtain (see [7] ): From assumption (A3), o,Q * G ≡ 0 and we obtain o,Q * D * ≡ 1, hence (18) holds true. Consequently, X is also a (F, P)-local martingale (by using Girsanov's theorem in the filtration F). In the larger filtration G however, using the Lenglart's extension of the Girsanov's theorem, we obtain that the following is a martingale under P: Because from (17) X = F 2 ds, we can write For all t ≥ 0: thus, α has a null (F, P) optional projection. The claim in (a) is thus proved. We write D * as product of orthogonal (G, Q * ) local martingales in 16 two different ways. First, we write D * = LZ with The following relations can be easily verified (using Ito's formula and the expression of the processes X and α in (16) resp (19) ): We denote: We notice that the processes L, L (+) , Z and Z (−) are such that the measure d L is singular with respect to the measure d Z and also the measure d L (+) is singular with respect to the measure d Z (−) . These local martingales being continuous, their constancy intervals are determined by the constancy intervals of their sharp bracket; hence L and Z do not co-move and L (−) and Z (+) do not co-move. Additionally the process D * , a nonnegative martingale, is absorbed at the level 0, once this level attained, and consequently the processes L, L (+) , Z and Z (−) are also stopped at T 0 . This shows that the following equalities hold Q * a.s.: We know that R t = 1 Lt . Therefore: and from this we deduce that -if Q * (τ < T ) > 0 we have E P [R T ] < 1 i.e., R is a strict (G, P)-local martingale. The strict inequality is justified using (23) . Indeed, these equalities imply that , R is a true (G, P)-martingale. Identical steps as above for R = 1 L can be used now for R (+) = 1 L (+) . Indeed, the characterisation of τ (+) in (24), can be used to prove the following: The claims (b) and (c) can now be proved using the above analysis and the fact that Q * (τ (+) < T ) > 0 if and only if Q * (τ < T ) > 0. For more clarity, the poof of this result is stated as a separate result below (Lemma 4.10). In particular, for (b): As D * is by assumption a square integrable (G, Q * )-martingale, using Proposition A.1, we deduce that, L, L (+) , Z and Z (+) are strictly positive and uniformly integrable (G, Q * )-martingales. We use Lemma 4.10 below together with the above analysis to conclude. For (c) we see that there is no need to have Z and Z (−) be true Q * martingales, so that no more constraints on the process D * are needed. ✷ Lemma 4.10. Recall the definitions of T 0 , τ and τ (+) in equations (20) , (21) and (22) , respectively. The following are equivalent: Proof. To begin with, we give an alternative characterisation of the sets {τ < T } and {τ (+) < T }, that uses the fact that the martingale L is constant on the set {(ω, t) : F t (ω) = 0}; while L (+) is constant on the set {(ω, t) : F t (ω) = 0, G t (ω) ≤ 0} (these properties can be easily seen from an inspection of their quadratic variation). Therefore, denoting by A := (1 1 T 0 1: We will now prove the stated properties for U; identical arguments hold for Z. We denote We notice that U T 2k = U T 2k−2 M (2k) ∞ and E[U T 2k |F T 2k−2 ] = U T 2k−2 M (2k) ∞ , therefore, for all k ≥ 1: = · · · = U 0 = 1. This proves that if T ∞ = +∞ a.s., i.e. (N t ) is finite, then (T 2k ) is a localising sequence for U. Therefore, whenever (N t ) is bounded, then U is a uniformly integrable martingale. ✷ Arbitrage of the first kind and filtration enlargements in semimartingale financial models On an optional semimartingale decomposition and the existence of a deflator in an enlarged filtration Enlargement of Filtration with Finance in View Additional logarithmic utility of an insider Lois de martingale, densités et décompositionde Föllmer Schweizer Hazard rate for credit risk and hedging defaultable contingent claims Changes of filtration and of probability measures Market models with optimal arbitrage Arbitrage and utility maximization in market models with an insider Some no-arbitrage rules under short-sales constraints, and applications to converging asset prices Default times, non arbitrage conditions and change of probability measures A propos du travail de Yor sur les grossissements des tribus A general version of the fundamental theorem of asset pricing Arbitrage possibilities in Bessel processes and their relations to local martingales The fundamental theorem for unbounded stochastic processes A simple counterexample to several problems in the theory of asset pricing Encyclopedia of Quantitative Finance On arbitrages arising with honest times Semimartingales and asset pricing under constraints Insider trading in a continuous time market model A stochastic calculus model of continuous trading: complete markets. Stochastic Processes and their Applications Comparison of insiders' optimal strategies depending on the type of side-information: Stoch Semimartingale Theory and Stochastic Calculus. Kexue Chubanshe Random times at which insiders can have free lunches The effect of trading futures on short sale constraints YOR: Nouveaux résultats sur le grossissement des tribus Arbitrage in securities markets with short-sales constraints The numéraire portfolio in semimartingale financial models A remark on default risk models The Dalang-Morton-Willinger theorem under cone constraints Enlargements of filtrations and path decompositions at non stopping times Doob's maximal identity, multiplicative decompositions and enlargements of filtrations Arbitrage opportunities in diverse markets via a non-equivalent measure change The fundamental theorem of asset pricing with cone constraints Exploiting arbitrage requires short selling Stochastic integration and differential equations The fundamental theorem of asset pricing, the hedging problem and maximal claims in financial markets with short sales prohibitions Continuous Martingales and Brownian Motion A systematic approach to constructing market models with arbitrage Hedging of options in a general semimartingale model Martingale Densities for General Asset Prices On the minimal martingale measure and the Föllmer-Schweizer decomposition Stochastic Analysis and Applications ZÜRICH 8032, SWITZERLAND. Email address: delia.coculescu@bf.uzh