key: cord-0057418-0r7wvyi3 authors: Metelli, Luca; Natoli, Filippo title: The International Transmission of US Tax Shocks: A Proxy-SVAR Approach date: 2021-03-15 journal: IMF Econ Rev DOI: 10.1057/s41308-021-00136-6 sha: 7541fb40c84fdd65804cffb659d13684d01f2b47 doc_id: 57418 cord_uid: 0r7wvyi3 We investigate the international propagation of tax rate shocks originating in the USA using a global vector error correction model. We identify shocks to corporate and personal income tax rates by using narrative series as external instruments, following the proxy-SVAR methodology. The main results are the following: (1) In terms of fiscal multiplier, domestic effects of corporate tax shocks are stronger than those of personal income tax shock; (2) spillovers are in most cases positive and significant, albeit of small size; (3) the boost to exports in recipient economies, stimulated both by stronger US demand and, to a lesser extent, by real exchange rate depreciation, is the main transmission channel; and financial channels (through long-term interest rates) also play a role. Since the Great Recession, the discussion on the role of fiscal policy has gained traction, as discretionary fiscal measures have started afresh to serve as policy tools in advanced economies. During the global financial crisis, the US administration implemented a sizable fiscal stimulus, which supported the recovery in the USA; in contrast, during the Euro area debt crisis many countries in Europe introduced tax increases and spending cuts as a way to restore confidence in the sustainability of public debt. More recently, the US Congress has adopted a major overhaul of the tax US output stimulates demand for imports without significant exchange rate variations (expenditure boosting or quantity effect). In our results, this latter propagation mechanism seems to dominate quantitatively on the former. Moreover, financial channels (through interest rates and equity prices) also play a role in the international transmission, although a smaller one than the trade channel. Foreign longterm interest rates generally increase following the US fiscal shocks, acting as a drag on economic growth; only in a few cases, they fall on impact reinforcing expansionary effects. Concerning equity markets, a US fiscal expansion may lead to an increase in foreign equity prices, generating positive wealth effects which, in principle, could support consumption and investment; in our framework, we find equity prices reacting significantly to fiscal shocks only in some cases, suggesting that wealth effects are of minor importance in channeling fiscal shocks across the board. This paper contributes to the recently growing literature on fiscal spillovers in several ways. First, it is one of the first studying empirically the international transmission of fiscal shocks originating in the USA, in particular for what concerns tax shocks. As we model the world economy in a single framework, we are able to take into account the indirect effect of shocks arising from the economic linkages among recipient countries (third-party effects) and obtain more accurate spillover estimates than those delivered by widely used bilateral models (such as two-country VARs or local projections à la Jorda 2005) , as highlighted by Georgiadis (2017) . Second, the paper highlights the differences in the international propagation among the implemented tax policy tools, i.e., personal and corporate income tax policies. Third, it is the first paper quantifying spillovers in terms of fiscal multipliers for each type of tax shocks and at different points in time. Fourth, fiscal policy shocks in the US are identified using narrative series, which allow for the identification of tax rate shocks, as opposed to the more endogenous measure of tax revenues usually adopted in the literature on fiscal spillovers. As far as we know, this is also the first time that a proxy-SVAR identification strategy is employed in a GVAR framework. The paper draws on different strands of literature. First, it relates to the literature analyzing international fiscal spillovers, in particular to the very scant literature analyzing tax spillovers. The closest papers to ours are Blagrave et al. (2018) and Christofzik and Elstner (2018) . Blagrave et al. (2018) investigate spillovers stemming from a global fiscal shock (both spending shock and tax revenue shock), aggregated across five advanced economies; by running the local projection estimates of Jorda (2005) on the GDP of each recipient economy separately, the paper finds that spillovers depend on the monetary policy response (in particular at the zero lower bound) and on the degree of economic slack in source and recipient countries. Although it addresses the relevant issue of the state dependency of fiscal policy effectiveness, Blagrave et al. (2018) focus on the more endogenous variable tax revenues instead of tax rate shocks. Moreover, they do not concentrate on the transmission mechanism of fiscal shocks, which is instead our focus. Christofzik and Elstner (2018) analyze the spillover effect of tax rate shocks, identified as in our case through the methodology of Mertens and Ravn (2013) . They find positive but small spillovers on German output, also considering the reaction of the German fiscal variables. This study, contemporaneous to ours, is also the closest. However, it focuses only on the German economy, neglecting the whole international dimension. Aside from these two papers, most of the literature on fiscal spillovers concentrates on government spending. Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2013) estimate government spending spillovers in a panel of OECD countries; they find, in line with Blagrave et al. (2018) , positive effects on foreign output. Bussiere et al. (2017) use a three-country specification of the Global Integrated Monetary and Fiscal (GIMF) model of the IMF to simulate different types of budget-neutral spending policies in the USA; they find positive domestic and spillover effects that can be amplified in case of a coordinated action across countries, and a trade-off between growth and distributional consequences. Faccini et al. (2016) estimate spillovers from a US government spending shock in a factor model, finding positive and sizable effects on foreign output operating mainly through a financial channel, i.e., a reduction of real interest rates abroad. This paper follows some theoretical and empirical papers claiming that expectations of future spending reversals, triggered by fiscal rules on debt, are such that the effect of expansionary shocks on domestic interest rates, positive in standard models, is instead negative and acts as the main driver of fiscal expansion in the medium run. 2 According to this literature, spillovers are mainly determined by the evolution of the foreign interest rates determined by international financial linkages (Corsetti et al. 2010 (Corsetti et al. , 2012 Corsetti and Muller 2013; Ong 2018) . While we find some negative impacts on long rates in the case of corporate tax shocks, in our paper the international transmission goes mainly through the trade channel. In this respect, our results are more in line with those of papers that investigate fiscal spillovers indirectly, i.e., by studying the reaction of those domestic variables that can influence foreign output dynamics, such as the exchange rate (e.g., Auerbach and Gorodnichenko 2016; Forni and Gambetti 2016) , the trade balance (e.g., Kim and Roubini 2008) , or the terms of trade (Monacelli and Perotti 2010; Enders et al. 2011) . In general, the literature on fiscal spillovers is not particularly large; it focuses only on specific country groups and mainly on spending shocks, neglecting the tax side. 3 Second, our paper is related to the strand of the literature analyzing the domestic effects of fiscal policy, specifically for the USA (e.g., Blanchard and Perotti 2002; Ramey 2011; Romer and Romer 2010; Mountford and Uhlig 2009; Mertens and Ravn 2013; Ilzetzki et al. 2013) . We are closer to those empirical studies using proxy-SVAR methods and the narrative approach as identification scheme, in particular Mertens and Ravn (2013) . The latter is one of the papers that develops the proxy-SVAR methodology, together with Stock and Watson (2008) ; 4 also, Mertens 2 As also noted in Blagrave et al. (2018) , in a standard Mundell-Fleming-Dornbusch framework a fiscal expansion puts upward pressure on interest rates, appreciates the nominal exchange rate and increases domestic prices. 3 A set of papers investigate fiscal spillovers within the Euro area, see, for instance, Beetsma et al. (2008) , Beetsma and Giuliodori (2011) and, more recently, Dabla-Norris et al. (2017) . 4 Indeed, the methodology of Mertens and Ravn (2013) builds on the precedent work by Stock and Watson (2008) presented in a 2008 NBER summer school, and later applied in Stock and Watson (2012) . and Ravn (2013) construct the exogenous narrative tax rate series that we use in the estimation, both for the corporate tax and the personal income tax. They moreover quantify the effects of tax rate shocks, finding a large multiplier in the case of personal income tax rate shocks, while they cannot provide such estimate for the corporate tax measure, as the response of tax revenues in this case is not significant. In our paper, we follow the Mertens and Ravn (2013) methodology and we embody it in the GVAR. As in Mertens and Ravn (2013) , we find quantitatively similar effects on US output but, differently from them, also significant effects on tax revenues following both tax shocks. This allows us to calculate fiscal multipliers in both cases finding that, in the post-1980 sample, corporate income tax cuts are more output enhancing than cuts in personal income tax rates. Finally, our paper draws on the GVAR methodology, introduced in the two seminal papers by Pesaran et al. (2004) and Di Mauro et al. (2007) . The GVAR framework has been widely used to assess the international transmission of shocks; however, also in the GVAR literature, the topic of fiscal spillovers has been underinvestigated. Caporale and Girardi (2013) and Hebous and Zimmermann (2013) study the propagation of non-identified fiscal disturbances originated in the Euro area, while Favero et al. (2011) investigate the effects of contemporaneous fiscal policy shocks at the global level. 5 None of these studies aims at quantifying the output effect of an identified fiscal shock stemming from the USA on the rest of the world. In our paper, we aim at filling this gap. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the GVAR methodology, the proxy-SVAR methodology and the identification strategy, while Sect. 3 discusses the data and the specification adopted in the paper, focusing also on the cross-border transmission mechanism of fiscal shocks. Section 4 reports the results obtained. Finally, Sect. 5 concludes. The GVAR model is a multi-country framework which explicitly allows for interdependencies among countries and markets. The model is particularly useful to investigate the transmission channels of shocks across countries and to quantify the magnitude of such spillovers. The GVAR modeling strategy consists of two steps. In the first step, each country i is modeled separately in a single-country VAR model augmented with exogenous variables (VARX). In each VARX, the endogenous variables are domestic only ( X i,t ), while country-specific foreign variables X * i,t , constructed as averages of all other countries' variables, serve as a proxy for common unobserved factors. In this way, each country is affected by its domestic developments and by the rest of the world. Each country model is estimated separately, conditional on the 5 Other studies which employ the GVAR methodology to investigate fiscal shocks among Euro area countries are Ricci-Risquete and Ramajo-Hernandez (2015) and Dragomirescu-Gaina and Philippas (2015) . foreign variables, in error correction form. In the second step, the country-specific VARX's are stacked together and linked using a matrix of cross-country linkages W, building in this way the global model. Consider N+1 countries, indexed by i = 0, 1, 2, … N . Each country is modeled through a VARX(K i , P i ) of the following form: where X i,t is the vector of country i's domestic variables and ∑ K i k=1 i,k are the corresponding lagged coefficients; X * i,t−p is the vector of country i's foreign variables and ∑ P p=0 Λ i,p the associated coefficients; a i,0 and a i,1 are, respectively, the vector of intercepts and the vector of the coefficients of the deterministic time trend. u i,t is the vector of country-specific residuals, which is assumed to be distributed as a white noise process, i.e., u i,t ∼ i.i.d.(0, Σ u i ) . The vector X * i,t plays a crucial role in the GVAR framework, and it is defined in the following way: where w i,j represents the trade share of country j for country i, i.e., the countryspecific weight of country j in the total trade of country i. Moreover, w i,i = 0 and ∑ N j=0 w i,j = 1 . Equation (2.1) can be consistently estimated assuming that X * i,t is weakly exogenous with respect to the other variables in the system. In words, this means that each country is considered as a small open economy with respect to the rest of the world and therefore that Eq. (2.1) can be estimated on a country-by-country basis. 6 Di Mauro et al. (2007) show that Eq. (2.1) can be rewritten in error correction (EC) form, thus allowing for cointegration both within X i,t and between X i,t and X * i,t ; the model in EC form can be estimated with the Johansen procedure, modified to take into account the exogenous variables (Harbo (1998) ; Pesaran et al. (2000) ). After the estimation of each country-specific VARX, these are combined and stacked in order to form the global model. For the ease of exposition, we assume that a VARX(1,1) is estimated for each country: In "Appendix 1" of the paper, we test such exogeneity assumption, reporting the results of the test in Table 8 . Equation (2.3) can be written as: where The trade weights w i,j are then used to define the link matrix W i and obtain the identity: , the vector collecting all the country-specific endogenous variables of the model. Substituting 2.7 in Eq. (2.5), we obtain: Now, the country-specific models given by Eq. 2.8 are stacked to generate the global model for X t : where With G 0 non-singular matrix, depending on the trade weights and the estimated parameters, we obtain: 2.10) represents the GVAR model and can be solved recursively. The variance-covariance matrix of the global model is computed directly from the countryspecific reduced form residuals v i,t and is represented by the following: where Σ v i ,v j is the sample covariance matrix between country i and country j and Σ v i is the covariance matrix of country i. In order to identify shocks in the GVAR, one needs to specify a matrix P 0 that premultiplies Eq. (2.10) yielding where P 0 is and is the vector of identified structural shocks, with covariance matrix Σ : We are interested in identifying shocks originating from the USA only, chosen on i = 0 ; therefore, we need to make specific assumptions on P 0,0 (to identify the US model) and then on the other matrices within P 0 . We take up these issues in the following two paragraphs. Identifying US fiscal shocks using external instruments In order to identify fiscal shocks in the US model, we rely on the proxy-SVAR methodology. Restrictions on the P 0,0 matrix are obtained by using proxies for the latent shocks. In each of the two GVAR models we estimate, following Mertens and Ravn (2013) , we assume that a narrative measure, denoted by m t , is a proxy for the unobserved structural fiscal shock of interest f ,t , with E(m t ) = 0 ; in addition, denoting the other non-fiscal US shocks as nf ,t , the methodology assumes that the defined proxy satisfies the following conditions In other words, m t is correlated with the unobserved fiscal policy shock of interest and orthogonal with the remaining shocks. Assuming that the fiscal variable is ordered lth in the US model, the proxy-SVAR method provides the restrictions to be placed on the lth column of the matrix P 0,0 . To obtain those restrictions, one must follow a two-step procedure: • Run two-stage least squares (2SLS) estimates of all non-fiscal residuals in the US model, v nf ,t , on the fiscal residual v f ,t , using each time m t as an instrument for v f ,t ; the estimated coefficients represent each variables' restrictions up to a scale factor; • Impose covariance restrictions to identify each element in the lth column of P 0,0 . Details on the proxy-SVAR procedure are reported in Mertens and Ravn (2013) . Narrative measures of fiscal policy changes are constructed from historical sources, and as suggested by Mertens and Ravn (2013) , they can be viewed as imperfectly correlated with linear combinations of the latent structural policy shocks. 7 In order to validate the use of narrative series as instruments for the latent shocks, one should test the relevance of the proxy by constructing the reliability test statistic of Mertens and Ravn (2013) that is based on the hypothesis of linear random measurement errors. The reliability test statistic represents the fraction of the variance of the measured variable that is explained by the latent variable; it lies between 0 and 1, with large values indicating a high correlation between the proxy and the true underlying tax shock. Imposing cross-country restrictions After having imposed restrictions on P 0,0 , we have to impose restrictions on the other elements of P 0 . Provided that we are not interested in identifying shocks in other countries, we assume that all the other matrices on the diagonal of P 0 are identity matrices. Concerning off-diagonal matrices, we impose all cross-country correlations between model residuals to be zero. Indeed, correlations between the residuals of the GVAR may occur both within countries (i.e., among variables of a country-specific model) but also across countries (i.e., among variables in different countries). While the first type of correlations is taken care of through the identification procedure described in the previous paragraph, residuals can still be contemporaneously correlated across countries, creating concerns about reverse spillover effects. Although, having conditioned domestic models on foreign variables, cross-country correlations are generally very small, the case of significant correlations with specific foreign variables cannot be ruled out, giving rise to possible identification issues. Given the central role of the US economy, it is reasonable to assume that it does not react within the quarter to foreign developments. This restriction is crucial to complete identification in GVAR models, although it is not always stressed in the GVAR literature. By imposing such correlations to be zero, we obtain a block-diagonal P 0 matrix. Therefore, the resulting P 0 matrix is For the dynamic analysis of shocks, the GVAR literature largely relies on generalized impulse response functions (GIRFs) (Koop et al. 1996; Pesaran and Shin 1997) that in our case take the form of structural GIRFs (SGIRFs) as our model is identified. The response of variable j at time t + n to a one standard error shock at time t given to variable l is given by the jth element of: where e l = (0;0; … ;0;1;0; … ;0) is a selection vector with unity as the lth element; G 0 is defined as in Eq. (2.9); A n is We specify two GVAR models using quarterly data. 8 Each model encompasses 25 economy-specific VARX models, where the included economies account for about 90 percent of world GDP. 9 Subject to data availability, we consider the same set We use the GVAR toolbox developed by Smith and Galesi (2014 of variables for each economy except for the USA. For non-US economies, domestic variables are real GDP y i,t , consumer price inflation i,t , real exchange rate r i,t (defined as the nominal exchange rate e i,t minus domestic CPI, following Di Mauro et al. 2007) , the 3-month interest rate i s i,t , the 10-year government bond yield i l i,t , the real equity price index q i,t (the equity index deflated by domestic CPI) and real exports of goods and services x i,t . 10,11 Foreign variables, constructed as tradeweighted averages of variables in all other economies, are the following: foreign real GDP y * i,t , foreign consumer price inflation * i,t , foreign real equity price q * i,t and the foreign 3-month short-rate i s * i,t . The real exchange rate is not included in the set of foreign variables of non-US models to avoid multicollinearity. The US model is slightly different for a number of reasons. First, as our aim is to study the effect of a fiscal policy expansion in the USA on the rest of the world, we include, as domestic variables, US fiscal variables, both on the spending and on the tax side. Government spending and tax variables are constructed following previous works on US fiscal shocks (Blanchard and Perotti 2002; Mertens and Ravn 2013, among others) . On the spending side, we include real government expenditure to take into account the possible reaction of spending variables following the tax shock; on the tax side, we include the average personal income and corporate tax rates, together with their respective tax bases (net of transfers and interest payments). 12 Second, we include real imports among the domestic variables in the USA for a more in-depth study of the trade channel of fiscal policy, as we explain in Sect. 4. Concerning the instruments for personal and corporate tax rate shocks, we rely on the legislated tax liability changes categorized by Mertens and Ravn (2013) from the total tax liabilities changes recorded by Romer and Romer (2010) . Regarding foreign variables, we only include the real exchange rate in the US model. This implies that the USA is considered as a closed economy in our framework. Table 1 summarizes the domestic and foreign variables included in the US and non-US models. We estimate two GVAR models: one to study the effects of personal income tax shocks and one for corporate income tax shocks 13 • In GVAR #2, the US model is augmented with the corporate income tax rate, the corporate income tax base and government expenditure; The GVAR models are estimated over the period 1979 Q2-2006 Q4 because of data availability issues: observations before 1979 Q2 are not available for all countries, while the available tax instruments data end in 2006 Q4. "Appendixes A1.1 and A1.2" contain more details regarding the data sources and the specifications chosen, in particular for what concerns the selection of lag length and the number of cointegrating relationships in each country model. Before describing the results of the paper, it is useful to summarize the main transmission channels through which fiscal policy shocks in the USA may affect real variables in the rest of the world. The first channel operates through trade, in particular through the so-called expenditure boosting effect. Following a fiscal expansion that increases US output, US demand for imports increases as well, to an extent depending on the marginal propensity to import, both of the public and of the private sector. Output in foreign countries can thus rise through higher export demand. This direct channel can be reinforced via third-party effects, i.e., through the aforementioned mechanism working in all the foreign countries experiencing a boost in output. The second channel is represented by the real exchange rate. The US fiscal expansion is expected to increase domestic interest rates and to appreciate the US dollar, improving price competitiveness for all goods and services produced abroad and stimulating foreign exports and output (expenditure switching effect). A fiscal shock can also impact foreign GDP through the financial channel. A loose fiscal policy stance in the USA affects domestic interest rates, which in turn can impact foreign financial variables through financial linkages. The direction in which variables can be affected is not straightforward. On the one hand, in a standard portfolio balance model, the financial channel should cause both domestic and foreign interest rates to rise, putting a drag on the magnitude of spillovers on foreign output. On the other hand, an expansionary fiscal policy in the USA might generate the opposite effect, putting downward pressure on domestic and foreign interest rates. Faccini et al. (2016) and Corsetti and Muller (2013) obtain falling interest rates by making the assumption of a subsequent reversal of the fiscal shock; alternative explanations suggest that lower taxes may either expand aggregate supply or increase firms' savings more than investments, in both cases putting downward pressures on prices and interest rates. Fiscal spillovers might also be transmitted by an equity price channel: Expected profits of foreign exporting firms may rise, and depending on whether there is no offset from discount rates (which rise due to foreign central bank reactions), they put upward pressure on equity prices. This produces wealth effects for portfolio investors that could support consumption and investment. Overall, the magnitude of fiscal spillovers is an empirical question. The relative importance of the aforementioned channels depends on the strength of trade and financial linkages among the source and recipient countries, and to a smaller extent, among recipient countries themselves. Finally, it might also depend on the composition of the fiscal shock, i.e., whether the fiscal expansion is implemented through spending increases or tax reductions, and also on the particular type of spending or tax instrument. In this section, we describe our main results. In order to compare the effects of the two shocks, we comment on the results of the two GVAR models together, divided between domestic and spillovers effects; then, we construct domestic and international fiscal multipliers. The shocks of interest are: shock to average personal income tax rate (PITR henceforth) and shock to corporate income tax rate (CITR henceforth). Last, we discuss the main transmission channels. Reliability tests ensure the relevance of the chosen tax instruments in our settings. In GVAR #1, the reliability test on the adopted instrument shows a statistic Table reports the variables included in the non-US models (for each country (i) and in the US model. Variables are: real GDP y i , consumer price inflation i , real exchange rate r i (defined as the nominal exchange rate e i minus domestic CPI), the 3-month interest rate i s i , the 10-year government bond yield i l i , the real equity price index q i (the equity index deflated by domestic CPI), real exports of goods and services x i and real imports for the US m US . gcgi US is government spending, taxrev US are net tax revenues, pitr US ( citr US ) is personal (corporate) income tax rate, and pitb US ( citb US ) is personal (corporate) income tax base Non-US model US model All GVARs: of 0.8, and in GVAR #2, of 0.6. These values are in the good-quality range for tax models reported in Mertens and Ravn (2013) and Mertens and Ravn (2014) , validating the adopted identification procedures. Impulse response functions (IRFs), standardized to obtain comparable results, are shown in Figs. 1, 2 , 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8 and 9. Regarding their interpretation, we highlight the following points. First of all, all impulse responses can be interpreted as reactions to a shock of -1 percentage point size in the tax rate. Second, the impulse response functions show a permanent behavior, both for the shocked and the response variables. Such behavior is driven by the fact that the model is estimated in error correction form and, therefore, takes into account the existing cointegrating relationships among variables, as outlined in Sect. 2. Finally, the IRFs display the median estimates along one standard deviation confidence bands, calculated through the bootstrap procedure. 14,15 Figure 1 displays the domestic response to a -1 p.p. shock to US PITR and CITR. In both cases, the output response is positive and significant, showing a persistent behavior that is similar to that of the shocked variable, i.e., the tax rate. The timing of the response is slightly different across the two shocks, with GDP increasing on impact following the PITR shock, while reacting with a lag to the CITR shocks. In terms of magnitudes, GDP in percentage changes increases more in the case of PITR shocks than CITR shocks, similarly to what Mertens and Ravn (2013) find. However, in order to correctly quantify the impact on output, we rely on fiscal multipliers, as we clarify later. Short-and long-term interest rates react significantly, despite following opposite dynamics. Indeed, they increase in response to the personal income tax shock, while they fall after the corporate tax shock. 16 A similar pattern can also be noted for inflation. Such results suggest a different propagation mechanism for the two types of shocks. In the case of personal income tax shock, demand-side effects seem to dominate, with the central bank reacting to higher demand and inflation raising interest rates and dampening the positive effect of the tax cut on growth. At the opposite, in the case of corporate tax rate shock supplyside effects prevail, reinforcing the positive impact given by the fiscal expansion. In order to properly compare the quantitative effects of the two different shocks, we report the results in terms of their implied multipliers, i.e., the dollar increase 14 In order to bootstrap the GVAR model as in 2.10, we need to resample the estimated residuals, to obtain: The resampling procedure is carried out by making random draws with replacement from the residual vector [v 1 ,v 1 , … ,v T , ] , and impulse responses are recomputed at each draw. (4.1) We adopt one standard deviation confidence bands as uncertainty surrounding international spillover effects is considered higher than that around domestic effects. Other papers in the GVAR literature adopting one-standard deviation bands are, for example, Caporale and Girardi (2013) and Inoue et al. (2015) . 16 Murphy and Walsh (2020) noted a similar behavior after government spending shocks. in GDP following a one dollar decrease in tax revenues, see Table 2 . 17 One year after the shock, both tax rate shocks yield multipliers greater than one, with the one related to the personal income tax equal to 1.4 and the multiplier related to the corporate income tax equal to 3.9. The high value of the corporate tax multiplier partly relates to the negative response of the long-term interest rate, which reinforces the effect of fiscal policy on output, instead of dragging down growth. Two years after the shock, tax multiplier reaches 2.5 in case of a personal income tax shock while cannot be calculated in case of corporate tax rate shock, as tax revenues become not significant. 18 While we cannot directly compare our multipliers with Mertens and Ravn (2013) , as they can calculate such statistics only for personal income tax rate shocks 19 , our results are in line with tax revenues multipliers reported in Mountford and Uhlig (2009) . Tax rate shocks have positive and statistically significant, albeit relatively small, international output spillovers. For the sake of brevity, we focus on the main economic partners of the USA, i.e., the Euro area, China, Japan, the UK and Canada, for which we detail the main transmission channels; for other emerging economies, we only discuss the overall effect of shocks on economic growth. Effects on GDP Spillovers on foreign GDP are reported in Figs 3, 4 and 5. Output spillovers are significant in most of the main advanced economies. In particular, they are strongest in Canada and of comparable size in the Euro area, China and the UK. The shapes of foreign GDP responses follow those of US GDP: Spillovers from PITR shocks are slightly more front-loaded, while those from CITR shocks are more gradual. The effect of fiscal policy on emerging countries is on average less significant than that on advanced economies (Fig. 5) . Among EMEs, they are stronger in Mexico and South East Asia than in Latin America, and never significant in India. 20 International fiscal multipliers Tables 3 and 4 quantify the effect of fiscal shocks on GDP in recipient economies in terms of fiscal multipliers. International fiscal multipliers are here defined as the dollar increase in foreign GDP following a one 18 After the 2-year horizon, it is not possible to calculate anymore the fiscal multiplier in neither case, as tax revenues become all insignificant. 19 The main difference between our results and those of Mertens and Ravn (2013) is that, in the latter, the response of tax revenues following a CITR shock is never significant. In fact, such difference is explained by the different sample we adopt, i.e., 1979:Q2-2006:Q4 instead of 1955Q1-2006Q4. Indeed, when re-estimating Mertens and Ravn's model in the sample 1979:Q2 -2006:Q4, we find that tax revenues are in line with the domestic responses we obtain in our GVAR framework. 20 South East Asia is the GDP-weighted aggregation of Indonesia, Philippines and Thailand, while Latin America is the aggregation of Argentina, Brazil, Chile and Peru. 17 The response of tax revenues t periods after the shock ( t = 0, … , n ) is constructed by combining the dynamics of the shock with the response of the tax base, following Mertens and Ravn (2013) where T is the tax rate of type i = PITR, CITR , T i is the mean average tax rate, and b is the appropriate tax base; hats denote impulse responses, and lower case letters denote logged variables. tr t =T i t ∕T i +b i t dollar decrease in US tax revenues. The fiscal multiplier of country i, M i , observed t periods after the shock ( t = 0, … , N ) and referred to a US fiscal instrument FI us , is given by the following: ΔFI us is the response of the fiscal instrument and ΔY i that of GDP in country i. 21 Empirically, international multipliers are computed as follows. Defining the elasticity of GDP to the fiscal instrument at period t as the ratio of the impulse response of GDP over that of the fiscal instrument, i.e., (2016), we report cumulated multipliers given by In order to compute international multipliers, we calculate the ratio FI/Y in Eq. (4.4) as the average FI/Y ratios throughout the estimation period for each economy. 22 The tables below summarize the estimates of the international fiscal multipliers for the two types of tax rate shocks, both in terms of the 1-year and 2-year multipliers (Tables 3 and 4 ). In general, international fiscal multipliers are small, ranging between 0 and 0.4. There is substantial variation across countries: multipliers are small in China, while strongest in the Euro area and the UK. Moreover, multipliers are larger in case of CITR shocks than PITR shocks, consistently with the stronger domestic effect of corporate tax cuts. All in all, the aforementioned results suggest that US fiscal policy does affect economic activity in foreign economies, but its impact is limited. Transmission channels Figs. 6, 7, 8 and 9 are illustrative in order to shed some light on the international transmission channels of the US fiscal shocks. Although such results are mainly suggestive, we believe they provide useful information on the propagation mechanism. The trade channel appears to be the dominant propagation mechanism. This result is partly driven by the fact that, in the model, international financial markets are also linked by trade weights, so the pure financial spillovers from the USA to the rest of the world may be underestimated. However, other estimates we made with our GVAR assigning higher weights to US financial variables in foreign economies confirm the dominance of the trade channel. 23 The two propagation mechanisms lying behind the trade channel, i.e., the expenditure switching and the expenditure boosting effects, affect the various economies in different ways. As Fig. 6 shows, following a personal income tax cut in the USA, real exchange This procedure can lead to a bias when significant trends in this ratio are present (Ramey 2016) . We also computed the ratio using end-of-sample values, and multipliers do not change significantly. 23 In order to evaluate whether financial spillovers are able to fully counteract trade spillovers, in a robustness analysis we make the extreme assumption that US short-term rates, long-term rates and equity prices influence foreign financial variables with unitary weights, leaving third-party financial spillovers equal to zero. We simulate a new GVAR with mixture of trade and (unitary) financial weights for PITR shocks, for which a stronger, positive reaction of foreign interest rates could, in principle, mute the positive trade effects on foreign output. Estimates, available upon request, show that spillovers are still positive, confirming the dominance of the trade channel on the financial channel. rates vis-à-vis the US dollar depreciate for China, Japan, UK and Canada, making their exports cheaper. However, as the responses are barely or even not significant, it is difficult to imagine that these countries benefit from a large expenditure switching effect. Regarding CITR shocks, the picture is specular. Real exchange rates appreciate in foreign countries, but also in this case the responses are mainly not significant. Such opposite behavior of the real exchange rate following PITR and CITR shocks is consistent with the domestic effects of the two shocks in the US, which generate opposite reactions in interest rates and prices, as already commented in the previous section. As real exchange rate responses are subdued, the expenditure switching channel does not seem to play a prominent role. On the other hand, Fig. 7 reports the response of real exports, which rise even when the real exchange rate does not depreciate. This fact suggests that exports receive a boost from stronger import demand in the USA, confirmed by the behavior of US real imports in Figs. 1 and 2 , hinting at the presence of a powerful expenditure boosting mechanism. An important transmission mechanism is also represented by financial channels. Such channels point to the response of long-term interest rates and equity prices as vehicles for the transmission of fiscal shocks abroad, as explained in Sect. 3. 24 Overall, the effect of financial channels on growth is ambiguous. As regards longterm rates, they increase following the two types of US shocks (Fig. 8) . 25 However, such increase is more relevant in the case of PITR shocks, while in the case of CITR shocks the response is generally less significant and pronounced and, in some cases, even negative. For what concerns equity prices, Fig. 9 reports the results. In the case of PITR shocks, they do not seem to play a major role, as their response is basically null, both at the domestic and foreign levels. 26 In case of CITR shocks, the effects are positive and significant, representing a possible amplification mechanism. Although it is difficult to evaluate the quantitative relevance of financial channels, it seems plausible that, in the case of corporate income tax shocks, such channels do not significantly contribute to dampen the real effects of fiscal policy across the board. For personal income tax shocks, instead, the responses of interest rates and equity prices seem to represent a drag on GDP growth. In this paper, we investigate the international dimension of fiscal policy, analyzing the spillover effects of tax rate shocks originating in the USA. We study different subcategories of tax shocks, focusing on the international propagation mechanisms and quantifying the size of multipliers. The main finding is that fiscal spillovers are positive and statistically significant, albeit of a relatively small size. This result suggests some relevant policy insights. First, the potential benefits of a fiscal expansion in the US, from the point of view of recipient countries, are generated via the trade channel, which includes an expenditure boosting and, to a lesser extent, an expenditure switching effect. Second, the international spillovers of US fiscal policy seem to be more relevant for advanced countries than for emerging ones. This is in contrast with the effects of US monetary policy, which is considered as a driver of international capital flows and a source of major concern for developing countries. In this paper, we do not address the question of nonlinearity of fiscal policy spillovers, which still deserves further research. The set of variables common to all GVAR models are taken from Mohaddes and Raissi (2018) . The database contains data for real GDP y i , consumer price inflation i , real exchange rate r i (defined as the nominal exchange rate e i minus domestic CPI), the 3-month interest rate i s i , the 10-year government bond yield i l i , the real equity price index q i (the equity index deflated by domestic CPI). Exports and imports are taken from the IMF IFS database. For what concerns the fiscal variables in the USA, we used the following sources. Nominal government spending (gcgi) is taken from the NIPA tables of the Bureau of Economic Analysis and consists of both government consumption and investment. Nominal variables are then deflated using the CPI index. The personal income tax rate and tax base, as well as corporate income tax rate and tax base, are taken from the dataset provided by Mertens and Ravn (2013) . The narrative series used to identify tax shocks are taken from Mertens and Ravn (2013) . Here, we summarize our model specification in terms of the number of cointegrating relationships and lags chosen. First of all, we conducted the augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test to check for the presence of unit root for the variables included in the GVAR. At the 5% significance level, we find that most of the domestic variables are integrated of order 1, i.e., I(1), with the exception of some variables, mainly interest rate variables, being I(0) or near I(1). The fact that almost all variables show a unit root behavior motivated our choice to proceed in the estimation of the N + 1 single-country models using the error correction form. In order to recover the cointegrating relationships among variables, we followed the standard Johansen cointegrating procedure (see Table 5 for the results); in some cases, we had to reduce the number of cointegrating relationships found by the Johansen test to guarantee the stability of the model, as in Cesa-Bianchi (2013) . Concerning the choice of lags in each country model, we followed the Schwarz criterion for the domestic variables, while we impose one lag only for the foreign variables. Table 6 reports the results. We also calculated the optimal number of lags following the Akaike criterion, which is less parsimonious. Table 7 reports the number of lags chosen by this criterion, while Figs. 12 and 13 in "Appendix 3" plot the IRFs calculated using such Fig. 2 US tax rate shocks, domestic effects. Impulse responses from a −1 percentage point shock to US corporate income tax rate (CITR). IRFs are in percent for all variables, except for inflaton and interest rates, which are in percentage points. Bootstrap median estimates with 68% confidence bands Fig. 3 Personal tax rate shock, spillover effects. Impulse responses of real GDP rate from a −1 percentage point shock to US personal income tax rate (PITR). IRFs are in percent. Bootstrap median estimates with 68% confidence bands specification. Finally, in Table 8 we also report the results of the weak-exogeneity test, along the lines of Harbo (1998) . Results show that the economies included in our GVAR can be considered weakly exogenous with respect to the rest of the world, at least in the long run, validating the estimation framework given by Eq. 2.1 (See Tables 5, 6, 7 and 8). Corporate tax rate shock, spillover effects. Impulse responses of real GDP rate from a −1 percentage point shock to US corporate income tax rate (CITR). IRFs are in percent. Bootstrap median estimates with 68% confidence bands Fig. 5 Spillovers to EMEs. Impulse responses of real GDP from a −1 p.p. shock to US personal income tax rate (PITR) and US corporate income tax rate (CITR). IRFs are in percent. Latin America is the GDP-weighted aggregation of Argentina, Brazil, Chile and Peru. South East Asia is the GDP-weighted aggregation of Indonesia, Philippines and Thailand. Bootstrap median estimates with 68% confidence bands Table 3 International fiscal multipliers, one year after the shock Output spillovers from fiscal policy Effects of fiscal shocks in a globalized world The effects of government purchases shocks: review and estimates for the EU The effects of public spending shocks on trade balances and budget deficits in the European Union Cross-border transmission of fiscal shocks: The role of monetary conditions. IMF working papers An empirical characterization of the dynamic effects of changes in government spending and taxes on output Can fiscal budget-neutral reforms stimulate growth? Model-based results The analytics of SVARs: A unified framework to measure fiscal multipliers How do US credit supply shocks propagate internationally? A GVAR approach Housing cycles and macroeconomic fluctuations: A global perspective International spillover effects of U.S. tax reforms: Evidence from Germany Cross-border spillovers from fiscal stimulus Fiscal stimulus with spending reversals Multilateral Economic Cooperation and the International Transmission of Fiscal Policy Fiscal spillovers in the euro area: Letting the data speak Exploring the international linkages of the euro area: A global VAR analysis Strategic interactions of fiscal policies in Europe: A global VAR perspective How do fiscal and technology shocks affect real exchange rates? New evidence for the United States International fiscal spillovers Country heterogeneity and the international evidence on the effects of fiscal policy Government spending shocks in open economy VARs To bi, or not to bi? differences between spillover estimates from bilateral and multilateral multi-country models Asymptotic inference on cointegrating rank in partial systems Estimating the effects of coordinated fiscal actions in the euro area How big (small?) are fiscal multipliers? The impact of China's slowdown on the Asia Pacific region: an application of the GVAR model. Policy research working paper series 7442 Estimation and inference of impulse responses by local projections Twin deficit or twin divergence? Fiscal policy, current account, and real exchange rate in the U.S Impulse response analysis in nonlinear multivariate models The dynamic effects of personal and corporate income tax changes in the united states A reconciliation of SVAR and narrative estimates of tax multipliers Compilation, revision and updating of the global VAR (GVAR) database 1979Q2-2016Q4 Fiscal policy, the real exchange rate and traded goods What are the effects of fiscal policy shocks Government spending and interest rates Do fiscal spending news shocks generate financial spillovers? Modeling regional interdependencies using a global error-correcting macroeconometric model Generalised impulse response analysis in linear multivariate models. Cambridge working papers in economics 9710 Structural analysis of vector error correction models with exogenous I(1) variables Identifying government spending shocks: It's all in the timing Macroeconomic shocks and their propagation. NBER working papers 21978 Chapter 9 in Evolution or Revolution: Rethinking macroeconomic policy after the great recession Macroeconomic effects of fiscal policy in the European union: a GVAR model The macroeconomic effects of tax changes: Estimates based on a new measure of fiscal shocks GVAR toolbox 2 Disentangling the channels of the 2007-2009 recession Recent Developments in structural VAR modeling. Presented at the National Bureau of Economic Research Summer Institute Minicourse: What's new in econometrics: Time series Acknowledgemets We thank Maria Grazia Attinasi, Pietro Catte, Valerio Ercolani, Laurent Ferrara, Andrea Finicelli, Alessandro Galesi, Andrea Gazzani, Ethan Ilzetzki, Daniele Siena, Vanessa Smith and seminar participants at the European Central Bank for their helpful comments and suggestions. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Bank of Italy. All the remaining errors are ours. Publisher's Note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.Luca Metelli is senior economist at the Bank of Italy Advanced Economies and International Finance Division. He holds a Ph.D. in Economics from the London School of Economics. He has been a visiting scholar at the Banque de France.Filippo Natoli is senior economist at the Bank of Italy Advanced Economies and International Finance Division. He holds a Ph.D. in Economics from LUISS University. Prior to joining the Bank of Italy he has been working as junior economist at the European Central Bank and in the finance department of two private banks. He has been a visiting scholar at the World Bank.