key: cord-0044811-spihgbt0 authors: Bula, Inese title: On Uncertain Discontinuous Functions and Quasi-equilibrium in Some Economic Models date: 2020-05-16 journal: Information Processing and Management of Uncertainty in Knowledge-Based Systems DOI: 10.1007/978-3-030-50153-2_21 sha: c35dc31d03d793c27552f227efb27a8de1348a13 doc_id: 44811 cord_uid: spihgbt0 In the paper is studied some properties of uncertain discontinuous mappings, the so-called w-discontinuous mappings. Based on them, the existence of a quasi-equilibrium for a new economic model is proved. One of the basic assumptions in a mathematical modelling of the standard economic model is the continuity of the excess demand function involved. There are reasons to maintain that the necessity of this assumption is caused by the methods provided by mathematics. First of all the fixed points theorems of Brouwer and Kakutani have to be mentioned, since both require the continuity of the maps. They are the main tools for establishing the existence of an equilibrium. However, the necessity of the assumption of continuity has also some economic motivation: in a neoclassical exchange economy due to the strict convexity and strict monotony of the preferences of all consumers the excess demand function is continuous (s. [2] , Th. 1.4.4) . The paper offers a possibility to substitute the continuity of the excess demand function by the w-discontinuity of this function and therefore to deal, in some extent, with unstable economies. We will examine the properties of wdiscontinuous mappings and finally, under some additional conditions, we prove the existence of a generalized equilibrium. The concept w-discontinuity includes uncertainty about the deviation of a function from continuity. The classical microeconomic models have their origins mainly in the work of L. Walras [18] , (1954) , a wider discussion of them is presented by K. J. Arrow and G. Debreu [3] , (1954) and also by K.J. Arrow and F.H. Hahn [4] , (1991) . An extended description of the classical model can also be found in textbooks on are |a − b|-discontinuous (and for any w ≥ |a − b| also w-discontinuous) functions. If X, Y , V are real normed vector spaces the following properties of wdiscontinuous mappings are established (similar as for continuous mappings). For proofs see [7] . From the Definition 1, which makes sense also for w = 0, immediately follows that the 0-discontinuous mappings are exactly the continuous ones. Corollary 1. Suppose that f, g : X → Y , f is w -discontinuous and g is wdiscontinuous. Then f + g and f − g are w + w -discontinuous mappings. In particular, if one of the mappings (f or g) is continuous, then f ± g are wdiscontinuous (or w -discontinuous). Corollary 2. If f : X → Y is w-discontinuous and c is a constant then c · f is a |c|wdiscontinuous mapping. Proposition 2. Let f : domf → R and g : dom g → R be w -, w -discontinuous functions, respectively. Then the functions f ∧ g and f ∨ g are w + wdiscontinuous on domf ∩ dom g. In order to consider the product of mappings we need the notation of the product in a normed space. ). Let X, Y, Z be real normed vector spaces. A mapping π : X × Y → Z is called a product if it satisfies the following conditions: for all a, b ∈ X, u, v ∈ Y and λ ∈ R one has A simple example is given by X = Y = R n , Z = R and π((x, y)) = x, y -the Let V, X, Y, Z be real normed vector spaces and let π : X × Y → Z be a product. The product of the mappings f : domf ⊆ V → X and g : dom g ⊆ V → Y is understood pointwise, i.e., For the division we reconcile with simplified situation, where (X, d) is again a metric space. As a special case we get If the domain of definition for a continuous mapping is compact, then its range is also compact and, in particular, bounded. The boundedness of the range is guaranteed for w-discontinuous mappings as well, however, compactness may not hold. The function f is 1-discontinuous and its range ]0, 2[ is bounded, but not compact. The following essential result is proved by O. Zaytsev in [19] and can be considered as a generalization of the Bohl-Brouwer-Schauder fixed point theorem for w-discontinuous mappings. Let K be a nonempty, compact and convex subset in a normed vector space X. For every w-discontinuous mapping f : We give the description of a simple economic model E considered by Arrow and Hahn in [4] . Let there be n (n ∈ N) different goods (commodities) on the market: services and wares, and a finite number of economic agents: households and firms, where each household can be considered as a firm, and, vice versa, each firm can be considered as a household. Let x hi be the quantity of good i which is needed to the household h. If x hi < 0 then |x hi | denotes the quantity of good i which is supplied by the household h. If x hi ≥ 0 then x hi is the (real) demand of good i by h, including the zero demand. The summation over all households will be indicated by The quantity of good i that is supplied by the firm f will be denoted by y fi . Again, if y fi < 0 then |y fi | is the demand (input) of good i by f . If y fi ≥ 0 then y fi is the supplied quantity (output) of i by f , where the zero supply again is included. The summation over all firms will be indicated by y i = f y fi -the supply of good i, i = 1, . . . , n. The initially available amount (or resources) of good i in all households will be denoted by x i . Note that x i must be non-negative. A market equilibrium, which is one of the most important characteristics of any economy (see f. e. [1, 2, 4, 9, 11, 16] ), describes the economic situation that the total demand of each good in the economy is satisfied by its total supply. This fact is obviously expressed by saying that the difference between the total demand of each good and its total supply is less than or equal to zero. The total supply of good i is understood as the sum of the supply of the good i and the quantity of i which is already available, i.e. the total supply of the good i equals to y i +x i . The excess demand of good i is then defined as If economic agents at the market are faced with a system of prices, i.e. with a price vector p = (p 1 , . . . , p n ), where p i is the price of one unit of good i, then the quantities x hi , y fi and also x i , y i , x i depend on p. Now we denote the excess demand of the good i by z i (p), i.e. If prices are involved then an equilibrium price (a price system at which an equilibrium is reached) clears the markets. Further on we frequently make use of the natural order in R n introduced by the positive cone i.e. for two vectors x = (x 1 , . . . , x n ), y = (y 1 , . . . , y n ) we write x ≤ y iff x i ≤ y i for all i = 1, . . . , n, we write x < y iff x ≤ y and x i0 < y i0 for at least one index i 0 . The norm we will use in the space R n is defined as This norm is equivalent to the euclidean norm which is introduced by means of the scalar product x, y = n i=1 x i y i . Note that in economic publications the scalar product of two vectors x, y ∈ R n is usually written as x y. For the standard economic model the following four assumptions have to be met (see [4] ). Assumption 1. Let p = (p 1 , ..., p n ) be an n-dimensional price vector with the prices p i for one unit of good i as components, i = 1, 2, ..., n. For any p let the excess demand for i be characterized by a unique number z i (p) and so the unique vector z(p) = (z 1 (p), . . . , z n (p)) -the excess demand function with excess demand functions for i as components (i = 1, 2, ..., n) -is well defined. The Assumption 2 asserts that z is a homogeneous vector-function of degree zero. Economically this means that the value of the excess demand function does not depend on the price system if the latter is changed for all the goods simultaneously by the same portion. From the Assumption 2 follows that prices can be normalized (see [4] , p.20 or [9] , p.10). If for some price p one has z(p) = 0 then z(λp) = 0 for all prices of the ray {λp : λ > 0}. Therefore, further on we consider only prices from the We rule out the situations when all the prices are zero or some of them are negative. Note that Δ n is a compact and convex set in the space R n equipped with one of its (equivalent) norms. Walras' Law can be regarded as an attempt to have a model sufficiently truly reflecting rationally motivated activities of economic agents. According to Walras' Law all the firms and all the households both spend their financial resources completely [9] . It means that a small change of a price system will imply only a small change in the excess demand. As a consequence from continuity of z, the standard model can be used only for the description of economies with continuous excess demand functions. Sometimes they are called stable economies. In economies such prices are important at which the excess demand for each good is nonpositive, i.e. the total supply of each good satisfies at least its total demand. If p * is an equilibrium price then For the standard model of an economy with a finite number of goods and agents such prices always exist as is proved in the following theorem. If z is the excess demand function for a neoclassical exchange economy, then z is continuous on the set [2] ) is characterized by a finite set of agents, where each agent i has a non-zero initial endowment ω i and his preference relation i is continuous (a preference relation is continuous if, given a two sequences (x n ) ∞ n=1 , (y n ) ∞ n=1 with lim n→∞ x n = x, lim n→∞ y n = y and x n y n , n = 1, 2..., then x y), strictly monotone and strictly convex (on R n + ) or else his preference relation i is continuous, strictly monotone and strictly convex on interior of R n + , and everything in the interior is preferred to anything on the boundary and the total endowment ω = i ω i is strictly positive. If the preference relation i is continuous, strictly monotone and strictly convex then the corresponding utility function and the excess demand function are continuous on the set S. We will consider the situation with a discontinuous excess demand function. It is clear that in this case the properties of the preference relations differ from them in the neoclassical exchange economy. p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p For example, consider the preference relation on R 2 + that is represented by the utility function u(x, y) = max{x, y} and an initial endowment ω = (2, 2). The utility function is continuous, but it is not strictly monotone (for example, (2, 2) > (2, 1) but u(2, 2) = 2 = u(2, 1)) and it is not strictly concave, it is convex. The indifference curves for the values 1, 2, 3, 4 and 5 are illustrated in Fig. 1 . Let p = (α, 1−α) be a fixed price vector for some 0 < α < 1. We maximize the utility function u subject to the budget constraint αx+(1−α)y = 2α+2(1−α) = 2. This line goes through the point (2, 2) and intersects the axis in the points (0, 2 1−α ) and ( 2 α , 0). From Fig. 1 we see that the maximal vector of u over budget set (the dotted region in Fig. 1 ) is the point (0, 2 1−α ) if α > 1 2 and ( 2 α , 0) if α < 1 2 , respectively. If α = 1 2 then 2 1−α = 2 α and therefore we have two maximizing vectors. The demand function in this case is In the point ( 1 2 , 1 2 ) the demand multifunction is discontinuous. In [1] it is proved that in a neoclassical exchange economy the condition p n → p ∈ ∂S with (p n ) n∈N ⊂ S implies lim n→∞ ||z(p n )|| = ∞. It is also not our case (see Theorem 1). In [1] it is shown that a utility function u : X → R (Xtopological space) representing a continuous preference relation is not necessarily continuous. If we start with an arbitrary chosen discontinuous utility function then we have no mathematical tools for finding the corresponding demand function (in the classical situation an agent maximizes the utility function with respect to the budget constraint and uses the Lagrange multiplier method for finding demand function). We note that there exist preference relations which cannot be represented by a real-valued function, for example, the lexicographic preference ordering of R 2 (by definition (a, b) (c, d) if (1) a > c or (2) a = c and b > d) (see [10] , notes to chapt.4). The above situation inspires one to consider models without explicitly given preference relations. In which cases is the excess demand function discontinuous? Consider some good i and a fixed price system p. In the case that this good is, e.g. an aeroplane or a power station, its demand x i (p) is naturally an integer. A function like x i (p) = 30000 1+α , where [x] denotes the integer part of x, provides an example. Obviously, if the good is a piece-good (table, shoes, flower and other) then the demand for this good is an integer. Similarly, the supply of piece-goods is an integer. Therefore the demand and supply functions for piece-goods are discontinuous and consequently the excess demand function too. We will analyse some model of an economy with w-discontinuous excess demand functions. For the economies under consideration we keep the two first assumptions from the standard model and change the two last as follows. The w-discontinuity of the excess demand function makes our model available to describe some properties of an unstable economy as well. It is quite natural that for every price vector p ∈ Δ n there exist at least one good i with the price p i > 0 and such that the demand for them is satisfied, i.e. z i (p) ≤ 0. If for some economy E with the excess demand vectors z(p), p ∈ Δ n there holds the Walras' Law, i.e. p z(p) = 0 for any p ∈ Δ n , then for each p ∈ Δ n the inequality is satisfied. (We write further "z i (p) ≤ 0" instead of "i : z i (p) ≤ 0" and in similar cases.) Indeed, if for some p = (p 1 , . . . , p n ) ∈ Δ n there would be zi(p)≤0 would imply the existence of an index i 0 such that p i0 > 0 and z i0 (p) > 0, which hold then, because of n i=1 p i = 1, for some i 0 there must be p i0 > 0 and Walras' Law. Our next assumption requires the existence of a uniform lower bound for the sums It seems to be clear that it would be hard to find out why an equilibrium exists in our model. But it will be possible if we can estimate the unsatisfied aggregate demand. This leads to the concept of quasi-or k-equilibrium. The constant k ∈ R + as a numerical value of the maximally possible unsatisfied demand for a given price p * ∈ Δ n characterizes to what state the economy differs from the market equilibrium (Definition 3). We can prove now the following Theorem 4. Let E be an economy with n goods that satisfies the Assumptions 1, 2 and the Assumption 3' with some number γ > 0. Put w + = w + (n, γ) = 1 2n −(n + 1) + (n + 1) 2 + 8nγ . If now the Assumption 4' is satisfied with w ∈ [0, w + ), then the economy E possesses a k-equilibrium for each k ≥ nw 2 +(n+1)w 2γ−nw 2 −(n+1)w . Proof. For p ∈ Δ n define z + i (p) = max{0, z i (p)}, i = 1, ..., n, z + (p) = (z + 1 (p), . . . , z + n (p)), where e = (1, . . . , 1) denotes the vector of R n with all components equal to 1. Note that e = n. Define now a map T : Δ n → Δ n by T (p) = p+z + (p) p+z + (p),e , then T (p) = (t 1 (p), ..., t n (p)). Since 0 ≤ t i (p) ≤ 1 for each i and Now the particular maps which the map T consists of, possess the following properties. The identity map id on Δ n is continuous, by Assumption 4' the map z : Δ n → R n is w-discontinuous and by Corollary 3 so is z + . By Corollary 1 the map id + z + is w-discontinuous, what by Corollary 4 implies the w e -discontinuity, i.e. the nw-discontinuity of ν(p) = p + z + (p), e . Since ν : Δ n → [1, ∞) the function 1 ν is nw ν(p) -discontinuous as a consequence of Corollary 5. Finally, based on Proposition 3, the map T (p) = (p + z + (p)) 1 ν(p) is w 0discontinuous at a every point p ∈ Δ n , where (1) and so, the map T is also nw 2 + (n + 1)w-discontinuous on the set Δ n . Since Δ n is a convex and compact subset in the normed vector space R n and T (p) : Δ n → Δ n we conclude by means of Theorem 2 that there exists a vector p * ∈ Δ n satisfying the inequality T (p * ) − p * ≤ nw 2 + (n + 1)w. Using the norm in R n this yields p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p We make some remarks. 1. Let n and γ > 0 be fixed. Then w + = w + (n, γ) is defined as indicated in the theorem. For w ∈ [0, w + ) put k 0 (n, w) = nw 2 + (n + 1)w 2γ − nw 2 − (n + 1)w . The number k 0 (n, w) is non-negative as was shown above. Note that a sharper estimation (our estimation is based on the rough inequality ν(p) ≥ 1) in (1) would yield a smaller value of k 0 (n, w) and, therefore, would give a better result. In view of Theorem 2, however, an estimation has be obtained independently on p. 2. In Fig. 2 for n = 2 there is shown a situation without a classical equilibrium. It is clear that there is no p ∈ Δ 2 which satisfies the inequality z(p) = (z 1 (p), z 2 (p)) ≤ 0. The Assumptions 1, 2, 4' are obviously fulfilled. The Assumption 3' also holds. Indeed, represent p = (p 1 , p 2 ) ∈ Δ 2 as p = (1 − t)p + tp , t∈ [0, 1], then t ∈ [0, 1 2 ] implies z 1 (p) > 0, z 2 (p) < 0 and so γ p = p 2 and t ∈ ( 1 2 , 1] implies z 1 (p) = 0, z 2 (p) > 0 and so γ p = p 1 . In both cases we get γ p ≥ 1 2 which shows that the Assumption 3' holds with γ = 1 2 . Theorem 4 guarantees the existence of a k-equilibrium for k ≥ 2w 2 +3w 1−2w 2 −3w if w < − 3 4 + √ 17 4 . Note that Walras' Law is not satisfied. 3. The number w + (n, γ) is positive for each n and fixed γ > 0. If one takes w = 0 then k 0 (n, γ) = 0 and with k = 0 there is obtained the classical case. Observe that in this case it is not necessary to use the Walras' Law for establishing a classical equilibrium. 4. Note that in the classical situation it is impossible to carry out any quantitative analysis. On the contrary, the inequalities from Theorem 4 w < w + (n, γ) and k ≥ k 0 (n, w) give a chance to analyse the behaviour of an economy for different numerical values of the parameters n, w, γ included in our model. From 0 ≤ w + (n, γ) = −(n + 1) + (n + 1) 2 + 8nγ 2n < −(n + 1) + (n + 1) + √ 8nγ 2n = 2γ n it follows that lim n→∞ w + (n, γ) = +0. Since k 0 (n, 0) = 0, the positive number k can be chosen arbitrary small. This shows that the larger the number of goods the better the chance for a classical equilibrium. 5. It is reasonable to put k 0 (n, w + (n, γ)) = +∞. If for fixed n and γ the value w is sufficiently close to w + (n, γ), then k is very large. In such a case the existence of an k-equilibrium seems to be of low economic meaning. 6. The results of this paper have been developed in a collaboration with prof. M. R. Weber from the Dresden University of Technology [7] . 7. Other application of w-discontinuous mappings is to find a of quasiequilibrium in economic models that the author has developed in [6] in a collaboration with a student D. Rika. Problems in Equilibrium Theory Existence and Optimality of Competitive Equilibria Existence of an equilibrium for a competitive economy General Competitive Analysis On the stability of Bohl-Brouwer-Schauder theorem. Nonlinear Anal. Theory Arrow-Hahn economic models with weakened conditions of continuity On discontinuous functions and their application to equilibria in some economic model Towards the theory of continuity defect and continuity measure for mappings of metric spaces Introduction to the Use of General Equilibrium Analysis Theory of Value Analysis I A Course in Microecnomic Theory Microeconomic Theory. Basic Principles and Extensions. The Dryden Press General Equilibrium Theory: An Introduction Microeconomic Analysis Elements of Pure Economics On discontinuous mappings in metric spaces The left side of inequality (2) can be splitted into two sums zi(p * )≤0Using the triangle inequality we get the estimationand further the left hand side of (4) calculates asBy means of the equalities (3), (5) and the inequalities (2), (4) we obtain nowIt follows by means of the Assumption 3'where k satisfies k ≥ nw 2 +(n+1)w 2γ−nw 2 −(n+1)w . In order to have the number 2γ − nw 2 − (n + 1)w positive the value of w must belong to the interval [0, w + ), where w + is the positive root of the equation w 2 + n+1 n w − 2γ n = 0.