key: cord-0031177-fa8df5ds authors: Cuervo-Cazurra, Alvaro; Grosman, Anna; Megginson, William L. title: A review of the internationalization of state-owned firms and sovereign wealth funds: Governments’ nonbusiness objectives and discreet power date: 2022-05-11 journal: J Int Bus Stud DOI: 10.1057/s41267-022-00522-w sha: 6f3e53278a17e1ec0762e1f7085698087ddb2094 doc_id: 31177 cord_uid: fa8df5ds We review and bridge the literature on the internationalization of state-owned firms and sovereign wealth funds to provide a novel understanding of how government ownership affects foreign investments in three ways. First, we explain how state-owned firms and funds behave differently from private ones because they need to balance governments’ nonbusiness objectives and firms’ business goals. This results in competing predictions on whether government ownership helps or hinders internationalization due to particular nonbusiness objectives. Second, building on the review, we provide suggestions on how to extend research topics and theories of the firm by incorporating these nonbusiness objectives in the internationalization decisions in four areas: home government’s endowments, characteristics, and attitudes; host-country expansion’s support, influence, and impact; home- and host-country relationship conflicts, mediation, and disguising; and management’s orientation, opacity, and arbitrage. Third, we capture how governments may use state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds to nudge host-country governments by introducing the concept of discreet power and the use of four strategies (recognition, values, development, and supremacy) to achieve it. This helps to outline the beginning of a unified approach to how governments use their foreign investments to achieve nonbusiness goals. SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION: The online version contains supplementary material available at 10.1057/s41267-022-00522-w. There has been a resurgence of state capitalism in international business, through which governments are increasingly becoming foreign investors. The 1980s and 1990s were a period of retrenchment for state capitalism as communist countries transitioned towards capitalism, and advanced and developing economies underwent deregulation and privatization (Megginson & Netter, 2001) . However, despite these processes, governments continue to be significant investors. On the one hand, state-owned firms continue to exist and have grown, even if governments are no longer the sole owners. Thus, among the 100 largest publicly traded firms, 25 are state-owned, accounting for USD4.3 trillion in total revenues (Fortune, 2020) . On the other hand, governments have increasingly created and funded sovereign wealth funds, which have undertaken a global investment spree. The top ten sovereign wealth funds have USD6.7 trillion in assets under management (Global SWF, 2020) . However, although governments own both stateowned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds and can coordinate their behavior, as illustrated in the opening quote, research has studied these firms separately, creating a theoretical gap. Studies on state-owned multinationals focus on their foreign direct investments, usually appear in international business journals, and tend to study country and entry mode selection (Cuervo-Cazurra & Li, 2021; Cuervo-Cazurra, Inkpen, Musacchio, & Ramaswamy, 2014) , while analyses of sovereign wealth funds focus on their foreign portfolio investments, are commonly published in finance and economics journals, and tend to study profitability (Bortolotti, Fotak, & Megginson, 2015; Dewenter, Han, & Malatesta, 2010) . Recent research has initiated a cross-fertilization, for example, analyzing the implication of state ownership on stock returns in multinationals (Karolyi & Liao, 2017) or country and entry mode selection of sovereign wealth funds (Bertoni & Lugo, 2013; Knill, Lee, & Mauck, 2012) . Despite this, most studies treat them as independent of one another, limiting the theorization on the role of governments as foreign investors. Hence, in this article, we bridge these two streams of research, which have operated in parallel, to provide a novel understanding of how governments act as foreign investors in three ways. First, we explain how state-owned firms and funds differ from private ones in their internationalization because they need to balance governments' nonbusiness objectives and firms' business goals. This results in competing arguments, with some discussing restrictions on foreign expansion, while others highlight support for foreign investments by influencing host-country governments. Second, building on the review, we provide suggestions on how to extend research topics and theories of the firm by incorporating these nonbusiness objectives in the internationalization decision in four areas: home government's endowments, characteristics, and attitudes; host-country expansion's support, influence, and impact; home-and host-country relationship conflicts, mediation, and disguising; and management's orientation, opacity, and arbitrage. Third, to capture how governments may use state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds to nudge host-country governments, despite their differences in the level of control over investee firms, we introduce the concept of discreet power as the beginning of a unified approach to how governments use their foreign investments to achieve nonbusiness goals. These ideas contribute to two lines of research: state ownership and internationalization. On the one hand, foreign investments by state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds question the traditional theoretical justifications for firms' state ownership as solving market imperfections and enabling development (Lawson, 1994) . Under this logic, governments should not invest abroad because addressing those imperfections is the task of host-country governments. Thus, the international expansion of state-owned firms and funds highlights the need to consider governments' nonbusiness objectives as complements to the traditional market imperfection explanations. On the other hand, governments' foreign investments question the focus on profitability as the ultimate driver of internationalization traditionally assumed (Buckley & Casson, 1985) , as state-owned entities also pursue nonbusiness objectives internationally (Cuervo-Cazurra et al., 2014) . This requires a rethinking of the theoretical predictions on the selection and management of foreign investments, as governments may use state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds as tools for achieving nonbusiness objectives abroad by exercising discreet power. This new concept of discrete power additionally contributes to the literature by providing a bridge between the soft and hard power concepts from political economy (Nye, 2004) . A Brief History of Governments as Investors State ownership and control of the economy have oscillated between reforms and reversals (Cuervo-Cazurra, Gaur, & Singh, 2019) . During much of the twentieth century, governments were active investors. The Great Depression and the Second World War led most governments in advanced countries to become active investors to facilitate reconstruction. In communist countries, state ownership expanded, driven by an ideology of state control of the means of production. Developing countries increased government ownership of industries considered necessary to facilitate industrialization. Governments created sovereign wealth funds to invest excess funds from natural resources (Aguilera, Capapé, & Santiso, 2016) , while some stateowned firms became multinationals (Vernon, 1979) . The economic crises of the 1970s questioned the effectiveness of government ownership and state control of the economy, resulting in large privatizations in the 1980s and 1990s. Even sectors considered to be the exclusive realm of the state, such as utilities or defense, underwent privatization. Studies explained the privatization objectives, decision, timing, and process (Megginson, Nash, Netter, & Poulsen, 2004) , as well as the performance of the newly privatized firms (Boubakri & Cosset, 1998) . However, many of these were partial privatizations, with governments retaining stakes in firms considered strategic. The 2000s led to another rethinking of state ownership. Governments in advanced markets responded to the Great Recession of 2007-2009 by supporting, and in some cases nationalizing, firms considered essential. Meanwhile, the success of the Chinese government in managing the recession and the foreign expansion of its state-owned firms showed that state capitalism was again a viable development model. Thus, the literature evolved from assuming that state ownership was harmful to considering its positive effects (Grosman, Okhmatovskiy, & Wright, 2016; Mazzucato, 2011; Wright, Wood, Musacchio, Okhmatovskiy, Grosman, & Doh, 2021) . Studies on state-owned multinationals analyzed recent phenomena, such as state ownership diversity (Cuervo-Cazurra et al., 2014; Inoue, Lazzarini, & Musacchio, 2013) . These processes generated a wide diversity of types of government ownership of firms, which Table 1 summarizes. We study the internationalization of two types of state-owned entities: state-owned firms and sovereign wealth funds. State-owned firms are enterprises over which the government has significant ownership and control; even minority stakes allow the government to influence decisions (Chen, Musacchio, & Li, 2019; Inoue et al., 2013) . They are created by the state or emerge from the nationalization of private firms, and they are sometimes grouped into state holding companies, such as SASAC in China and Temasek in Singapore. Sovereign wealth funds are government investment vehicles commonly funded by foreign exchange assets or natural resource wealth and managed separately from official reserves (Kimmitt, 2008) . They tend to invest in assets to obtain commercial returns (Balding, 2011) . Their small investment stakes do not typically provide control over the invested firms, but they can nevertheless exercise influence as active investors. We do not study public pension funds, whose main source of funds is pension contributions and whose objectives are social, even if they invest abroad and in some cases in private equity funds (Kimmitt, 2008; Preqin, 2017) . Governments at multiple levels can own both types of state entities. Among state-owned firms, most companies owned by lower-tier governments are not international, but some are, like the automobile manufacturer Volkswagen, which is partowned by the German state of Lower Saxony. Among sovereign wealth funds, the conventional view is that they are owned by the central government (hence the term sovereign), but lower-level governments also own them, like the Alaska Permanent Fund Corporation. There are significant differences in goals between state and private investors. At the core of the theory of the firm lies its objective function, which is maximizing profits or market returns (Friedman, 1988) and protecting shareholder rights (Shleifer & Vishny, 1997) . These goals also apply to stateowned entities. However, most state entities are charged with achieving additional nonbusiness goals that conflict with profit maximization. For state-owned firms, nonbusiness goals include politically motivated investments in innovation, employment, or social stability (Lazzarini, Mesquita, Monteiro, & Musacchio, 2020; Sun, Deng, & Wright, 2020) . For sovereign wealth funds, nonbusiness goals include diversification of domestic markets, stabilization, sustainable investments for social goals, and protection from corrupt elites (Bernstein, Lerner, & Schoar, 2013; Knill et al., 2012) . In Table 2 , we clarify these differences in goals between private and state-owned investors. Our view is that, rather than having a dichotomy of objectives, with private investors interested in business objectives and state-owned ones in nonbusiness objectives, they differ in the relative importance of the goals. Governments are not passive owners uninterested in performance, but rather active shareholders seeking multiple objectives. For example, sovereign wealth funds target strategic industries (Nowacki & Monk, 2017) and are used as part of governments' external investments (Truman, 2007) . State-owned entities follow hybrid governance. The governance practices of state-owned entities are usually considered deviations from the accepted standards for the governance of private firms (OECD, 2015a) , and the recommendation is to make the governance of state-owned entities resemble as much as possible the governance of private firms (Shleifer, 1998) . However, state-owned entities are hybrid organizations in their corporate governance, using elements of private corporate governance to enhance monitoring with elements of public administrative governance to enhance accountability. They use governance tools differently or employ additional instruments to develop a suitable corporate governance structure (Okhmatovskiy, Grosman, & Sun, 2021) . This hybrid governance is reflected in governance guidelines, board structures, and nontraditional governance mechanisms adopted by state-owned entities. Guidelines for state-owned firms and sovereign wealth funds reflect the particularities of government ownership. These differ in objectives from the codes of good governance for private firms, which are usually designed to address the separation of ownership and control (Aguilera & Cuervo-Cazurra, 2004) . State-owned firms can follow the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) guidelines (OECD, 2015b). If they are publicly traded, they must adhere to listing regulations, such as disclosure of ownership and executive compensation, board independence, and required board structures (OECD, 2013) . Sovereign wealth funds can follow corporate governance practices, commonly known as the Santiago The board of directors is a universal governance mechanism for advising and monitoring managers (John & Senbet, 1998) , but its composition and functions in state-owned entities differ from those in private firms. In state-owned entities, board nominations are usually the government's responsibility (OECD, 2013), resulting in appointments without transparent and competitive selection procedures. Boards are commonly composed of civil servants, tasked with pursuing the public interest, and are increasingly also composed of independent directors. However, although the latter have incentives to generate financial results (Grosman, Aguilera, & Wright, 2019) , they still have indirect affiliations to politicians pursuing noneconomic objectives (Menozzi, Gutiérrez Urtiaga, & Vannoni, 2012) . These boards undergo frequent replacements, mirroring election cycles rather than performance (Kuzman, Talavera, & Bellos, 2018) . Boards of state-owned firms perform their functions differently to reflect the requirements of state ownership. They monitor whether managerial actions are aligned both with the business goals and the public mission of state-owned firms . Their resource provision function differs because government support isolates them from financial pressure. Finally, their strategic function is fulfilled directly by the state (OECD, 2018), which is sometimes suboptimal because it is biased by political goals . State-owned entities sometimes employ governance mechanisms rarely used in private firms that enable the government to impose its preferences without securing the agreement of other shareholders. Okhmatovskiy et al. (2021) highlight four mechanisms. First, governments use performance contracts to establish expectations regarding outcomes that state-owned firms commit to deliver (OECD, 2015a). These contracts provide boards with greater autonomy in decision-making without sacrificing the goals of the government as a shareholder. Second, through loan agreements from state-owned banks, governments can pursue a politically driven industrial policy agenda. Third, state-owned firms are under informal influence from government officials in matters ranging from issuing permits to choosing suppliers for statefunded projects or providing support for internationalization. Finally, political elites influence managers of state entities through administrative mechanisms. For example, in China, the influence of the Communist Party permeates economic and social activities, leading Chinese state-owned entities to be called ''hybrid business-political actors'' (Lin & Milhaupt, 2013) . We study how these differences in objectives and governance of state and private investors affect internationalization, helping advance the theorization of international business and state ownership through cross-fertilization. By bringing insights from one topic to the other, we outline the beginning of a unified theory of how governments use their foreign investments to achieve nonbusiness goals. This complements previous studies that separately analyzed sovereign wealth funds (Aguilera et al., 2016; Megginson & Gao, 2020) and state-owned multinationals (Cuervo-Cazurra et al., 2014; Rygh, 2019) . The systematic review and analysis of the content of past studies on the internationalization of stateowned firms and sovereign wealth funds reveals new insights into the role of governments' nonbusiness objectives. Online Appendix A provides the research design and lists the articles reviewed. The internationalization of state-owned firms The literature on state-owned multinationals evolves through three phases. It starts in the 1970s and 1980s with a few theoretical and interview-based studies on the growing expansion of state-owned multinationals, usually from advanced economies (Aharoni, 1982; Mazzolini, 1979) . However, the extensive privatization processes of the 1990s redirect interest toward the privatization of state-owned multinationals (Dewenter & Malatesta, 2001; Djankov & Murrell, 2002) . In the 2000s, there is a rediscovery of the topic, and, by the late 2010s, there is a significant expansion in the number and variety of studies. There is also a change from studying only state-owned multinationals to comparing them to privately-owned multinationals, facilitating the identification of the uniqueness in their behavior. This evolution of the literature reflects the transformation of state-owned firms. Table 3 illustrates the evolution of state ownership in selected countries from 1970 to 2017. The general trend is a sharp decline in state ownership between 1970 and 1995 and an increase in the 2010s. The most notable drop is among transition economies, as expected from their move from communism to capitalism, but there is also a significant drop elsewhere. Table 4 presents the top 25 publicly traded state-owned firms. The list is dominated by Chinese firms, but there are state-owned firms from other countries, including advanced ones. Research on the internationalization of sovereign wealth funds is limited and recent, with studies on this topic only appearing in the 2010s. One reason is that, although some sovereign wealth funds were founded in the middle of the twentieth century, most were created only after 2000 (Aguilera et al., 2016) . They have expanded abroad in search of diversification, especially those from small economies unable to absorb surpluses. The investments have moved from passive to active ones as governments intervene in global financial markets to seek political, social, and financial objectives (Monk, 2011; Wood & Wright, 2015) . Although sovereign wealth funds were created more recently than state-owned firms, they have grown much faster. Table 5 provides statistics on sovereign wealth funds and public pension funds by country. China leads the ranking in terms of total assets under management, followed by Norway and Abu Dhabi. Their growth is driven by the accumulation of wealth from natural resources, especially oil, and foreign exchange reserves by central banks, especially after the 1998 East Asian financial crisis. Table 6 lists the 25 largest sovereign wealth funds, ranked by assets under management. The ranking is led by Norway's Government Pension Fund Global, China Investment Corporation, and the Abu Dhabi Investment Authority. The listing shows great variety in the country of origin, creation date, and size. Sovereign wealth funds are increasingly large investors in private equity, even if historically they held portfolios primarily composed of public equities and debt. Sixty-one percent of sovereign wealth funds directly hold private equity in their portfolios (Preqin, 2017) . This is driven by the search for higher returns and a growing sophistication of funds (Nowacki & Monk, 2017) . There are significant cross-country variations, however. Middle Eastern and Asian sovereign wealth funds account for the largest share of funds investing in private equity, while none of the Latin American sovereign wealth funds invest in private equity (Preqin, 2017) . Investing in private equity also helps sovereign wealth funds achieve the mission of developing their local economies. Some sovereign wealth funds were specifically created to coinvest in private equity to help domestic firms abroad or to attract long-term foreign capital into their home economies (e.g., Bahrain's Mumtalakat Holding). These two activities increasingly come together in bilateral partnerships in which investments support targeted industries' development (Nowacki & Monk, 2017) . As shown above, there is accelerating growth in the size and internationalization of both state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds. Our analysis suggests that national governments tend to specialize in the vehicles they use to internationalize investments. Small and wealthy emerging countries and advanced economies tend to invest in the rich world primarily through sovereign wealth funds. In contrast, large emerging economies seem to channel their international investments through state-owned firms to other emerging countries or occasionally advanced economies. China seems to be an exception, using both state-owned firms and sovereign wealth funds to invest everywhere. The internationalization of state-owned firms Most studies build on a variety of theories to explain the internationalization of state-owned firms. Among those studies that use a single theoretical approach, there appears to be a theoretical dichotomy in predictions, with some theories highlighting the advantage and others the disadvantage of stateness (Cuervo-Cazurra & Li, 2021; Musacchio, Monteiro, & Lazzarini, 2019) . On the one hand, studies using agency theory point out the additional costs that state-owned firms incur as a result of their multilevel agency problems, which hampers internationalization. Similarly, studies building on neo-institutional theory highlight how state-owned firms suffer from lower legitimacy in host countries that limits entry. On the other where V I is the country's state ownership score, while the V max and V min are set at 2.5 standard deviations above and below the average, respectively. We transformed the index so that 0 represents less state ownership and 10 represents more ownership (by subtracting 10 and multiplying the result by -1) hand, studies that draw on the resource-based view argue that state-owned firms can access state resources and thus internationalize more widely. There remains a need to increase the impact and sharpness of these arguments by clarifying the predictions of the theories on internationalization. More depth can be added by identifying the conditions, like the level of state ownership (Kalasin, Cuervo-Cazurra, & Ramamurti, 2019) , under which the arguments of one theory compensate for the predictions of another. Most studies on sovereign wealth funds focus on their rise and the influences on their investment strategies and returns, rather than on developing theory. Explanations are mainly based on principles of optimal portfolio allocation, attempting to identify whether sovereign wealth funds show biases in their investment decisions because they are state owned. One set of studies investigates how governments use foreign investments by sovereign wealth funds to promote national development (Haberly, 2014; Kamiń ski, 2017; Sun, Li, Wang, & Clark, 2014) . Another set with links to political economy focuses on the location choice of sovereign wealth funds' foreign investments, and how political relationships with host countries influence the location and amounts invested (Johan, Knill, & Mauck, 2013; Knill et al., 2012; Makhoul, Musacchio, & Lazzarini, 2020) . The few studies in management use a mix of theoretical foundations, like transaction costs, neo-institutional, or signaling theory (Aguilera et al., 2016; Vasudeva, Nachum, & Say, 2018) . The two research streams show a diversity of theoretical bases. In contrast to analyses of private investors, studies on governments as foreign investors tend to build links, sometimes implicitly, to political economy theory to explain the role that the government plays in decisions. They can extend theories by challenging some of the assumptions on which they have been built, namely private investors searching for returns, by incorporating nonbusiness objectives in the theorization. The internationalization of state-owned firms While the early literature analyzed European stateowned multinationals, recent studies usually focus on Chinese firms, with Brazilian firms coming in a distant second. One reason might be that the size and growth of these two economies helped their (Mazzolini, 1980) , but recent ones usually compare them to private firms (Li, Xia, & Lin, 2017) . Few analyses include state-owned firms from multiple countries, limiting our understanding of homecountry drivers of internationalization, such as the type of capitalism (Mariotti & Marzano, 2019) . Research on sovereign wealth funds tends to be dichotomous, analyzing either many sovereign wealth funds from multiple countries or only one. The former studies rely on publicly traded firms in which sovereign wealth funds have invested, and collect data on all available sovereign wealth funds regardless of country of origin. Some match investments by sovereign wealth funds and pension funds to understand the role of the government in investment decisions (Boubakri, Cosset, & Grira, 2016) . This may bias our view of their investment strategies, as we know little about investments in private equity and illiquid assets like real estate. The latter studies focus on investments by one fund, usually Norway's Government Pension Fund Global (Vasudeva, 2013; Vasudeva et al., 2018) or Singapore's Temasek (Gnabo, Kerkour, Lecourt, & Raymond, 2017; Phelps, 2007) , because these are transparent. The research databases used appear to bias the knowledge that we are gaining on governments as foreign investors. Most studies rely on datasets of publicly traded firms, which are only partially state owned. Future research can add novelty by using datasets of wholly state-owned firms and investments that are not publicly traded, and by extending the countries researched beyond Brazil and China in studies of state-owned multinationals and Norway and Singapore in analyses of sovereign wealth funds. The internationalization of state-owned firms The literature on the internationalization of stateowned firms has studied a wide variety of dimensions of internationalization and, with some exceptions (Aharoni, 1986) , seems to agree that the government plays a significant role in the foreign expansion of state-owned firms. However, the specifics of such influence are under debate. We separate the studies into categories based on the type of relationships on which they focus: internationalization motive, internationalization level, and the selection of country of destination and entry mode. The main lessons are that stateowned multinationals (1) have politically influenced nonbusiness motives; (2) select more challenging host countries and use more acquisitions, even if the market reactions are negative; and (3) show conflicting behavior on the level of internationalization, with some studies proposing a higher level and others a lower one (Cuervo-Cazurra & Li, 2021) . First, among studies on internationalization motives, some research argues that state-owned multinationals behave differently, although they do not compare them to private firms. These articles indicate that state-owned firms are driven to internationalize by political motives, such as the desire for governmental access to strategic assets and natural resources (Buckley, Cross, Tan, Xin, & Voss, 2008) . Other studies indicate that managers of state-owned firms drive internationalization in search of independence from government control (Choudhury & Khanna, 2014) . Other studies that compare state-owned and private firms find that the government influences both state and private firms, and that they pursue similar internationalization objectives (Ren, Manning, & Vavilov, 2019) . This conflict in arguments may result from the Chinese government's internationalization mandate and support to all firms (Luo et al., 2010) . For example, to facilitate cross-border investments by both state-owned and private firms, the Chinese government is establishing foreign trade agreements with host countries (Buckley, Clegg, Voss, Cross, Liu, & Zheng, 2018) . Second, state ownership seems to have a competing influence on the level of internationalization. Some studies argue that the agency problems of state-owned firms lead to less internationalization (Li, Xia, Shapiro, & Lin, 2018; Mazzolini, 1979) , while others propose that the provision of preferential resources to state-owned firms supports their internationalization (Luo et al., 2010) . The literature that compares state-owned and private firms shows conflicting patterns of findings. Some find that state-owned firms have more foreign investments thanks to their government support (Benito, Rygh, & Lunnan, 2016; Ramasamy, Yeung, & Laforet, 2012) , while others show that they have fewer investments due to home-country overdependence (Deng, Yan, & van Essen, 2018; Huang, Xie, Li, & Reddy, 2017) , and yet others indicate that they are similar to private firms (Hu & Cui, 2014) , especially state-owned firms with strong homecountry governance (Estrin, Meyer, Nielsen, & Nielsen, 2016) . A third group of articles investigates the selection of the country of investment and entry mode, acknowledging that governments' nonbusiness objectives affect the decisions. Governments direct stateowned firms to countries with good diplomatic relationships and that are similar to the home country in the weakness of their institutions (Zhang & He, 2014) , because they can influence the host country to support and protect their firms. Entry modes are influenced by state ownership, which helps to achieve more control over foreign operations (Dikova, Panibratov, & Veselova, 2019; Kalotay & Sulstarova, 2010) . Among entry modes, most studies analyze acquisitions. In this case, state-owned firms execute more acquisitions than private firms and gain full ownership thanks to their home-government support Meyer, Ding, & Li, 2014) . However, there are conflicting market reactions to acquisitions. Some propose adverse reactions to acquisitions because of the perceived higher inefficiency of state-owned firms (Chen & Young, 2010; Li et al., 2018) , while others argue for positive reactions from the preferential government treatment (Du & Boateng, 2015) . Some studies argue that state-owned firms prefer purchasing stand-alone assets instead of firms, and that their choices are similar to private firms when their home country has well-functioning institutions (Grøgaard, Rygh, & Benito, 2019) . Fewer studies have analyzed other dimensions of internationalization besides foreign direct investments, such as how state ownership affects offshore outsourcing, imports, or exports (Cuervo-Cazurra & Dau, 2009). One way to clarify the conflicting arguments on whether the government helps or hinders internationalization is to identify the conditions under which such relationships hold, such as the attitudes or types of governments, the level of development of the country, or the industry of operation. The sparse literature on the internationalization of sovereign wealth funds can be grouped into two sets: studies on their behavior, including investment portfolio strategy and decision making, and analyses that compare the investment performance of sovereign wealth funds to private funds. The general conclusion from these studies is that (1) sovereign wealth funds invest abroad in search of diversification and behave differently from private funds, and (2) they invest in better firms and countries with stronger investor protection. Sovereign wealth funds invest abroad to diversify their macroeconomic and political exposures by investing in global equities and debt, especially those of developed economy firms. This stream of research on portfolio selection unanimously finds that sovereign wealth funds behave differently, as they invest in firms in strategic industries (Boubakri et al., 2016; Haberly, 2011; Sun et al., 2014) , in countries with strong legal institutions and higher economic growth (Debarsy, Gnabo, & Kerkour, 2017) , and in large, profitable, international firms (Karolyi & Liao, 2017; Mietzner, Schiereck, & Schweizer, 2015) . Sovereign wealth funds from OECD countries invest differently from those from non-OECD countries (Avendaño & Santiso, 2011), use different target selection criteria, depending on whether or not the target is from an OECD country, and tend to re-invest in the same country (Candelon, Sy, & Arezki, 2011) . Some analyses explore how differences between the home and the host country affect investments. They indicate that sovereign wealth funds are used by their governments as tools to promote national economic development by investing abroad in priority sectors (Haberly, 2011; Kamiń ski, 2017; Sun et al., 2014) . Other studies find that investments through sovereign wealth funds' portfolio companies get the right level of managerial attention if these investments represent an important portion of the overall portfolio (Makhoul et al., 2020) . Sovereign wealth funds also seek to influence host-country governments. This influence can be achieved by providing money to campaign finance firms, where allowed, especially in industries with more restrictions on foreign investments (Calluzzo, Dong, & Godsell, 2017) , or by having representatives on the board in energy firms (Kamiń ski, 2017). Policy makers in host countries can also actively court sovereign wealth fund investments in local firms as long-term patient capital or to expand overseas market opportunities for these firms, and to politically reach out to sovereign wealth fundowning governments to advance their interests (Haberly, 2011 (Haberly, , 2014 Lavelle, 2017; Thatcher & Vlandas, 2016) . Bortolotti et al. (2015) and Bahoo, Alon, and Paltrinieri (2020) summarize research on the target selection and decision-making processes of sovereign wealth funds. Comparisons of sovereign wealth fund and private fund investment performance study their cross-border strategies to understand whether they behave differently in terms of choice (private or public equity investments), risk appetite, and returns. Particular attention is given to sovereign wealth funds' transparency and their target firms' performance (Bortolotti et al., 2015; Dewenter et al., 2010; Karolyi & Liao, 2017; Megginson, 2017) . It remains unclear why some sovereign wealth funds decide to remain opaque, even though they may face challenges and restrictions by doing so when investing overseas. Further, there is still a substantial gap in the literature on how macroissues, such as the characteristics of the governments or economies, or micro-factors, such as corporate governance, affect the internationalization motives of sovereign wealth funds. The arguments and findings of studies of governments as foreign investors confirm that they behave differently from private investors. State ownership appears to play a dual role in the internationalization of state-owned firms and sovereign wealth funds by constraining and supporting internationalization. This reflects the tension between the disadvantage and advantage of stateness (Cuervo-Cazurra & Li, 2021; Musacchio et al., 2019) . On the one hand, state-owned investors seem to have a lower tendency to go abroad because of governments' preference for domestic investments to gain political support, and because of the increased scrutiny and constraints that state-backed investments face in host countries. On the other hand, once they decide to invest abroad, they benefit from the government's financial and diplomatic support, targeting countries and projects that are too risky for private investors. Despite the significant progress made in our understanding of the government as a foreign investor, many areas can benefit from more research. Building on this review, we suggest several research avenues that integrate our understanding of the internationalization of state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds further. We organize them by topic and detail research questions in Table 7 . Home Government: Endowments, Characteristics, and Attitudes From the review, it is apparent that home-country characteristics drive the internationalization of both state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds. Sovereign wealth funds have been created in countries with strong economic growth and an excess of foreign exchange reserves and wealth accumulated through natural resources. State-owned multinationals have also been formed in interventionist states with a traditionally active role of the government, supporting the internationalization of home state-owned firms. We outline below what appear to be promising ideas. One fundamental question is the identification of how country endowments induce the creation of state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds. The level of home-country exposure to financialization (Wood & Wright, 2013) can affect the choice of organizational form of the investment vehicle (e.g., countries with developed financial markets are more likely to have sovereign wealth funds). National governments appear to specialize in the vehicles they use to internationalize investments, with small but affluent economies investing exclusively through sovereign wealth funds, while bigger, emerging countries channel most of their international investments through state-owned firms. This can help solve the question of why some governments set up sovereign wealth funds from natural resources windfalls, while others spend the windfalls subsidizing the welfare of the population. Attitudes towards savings and consumption may explain this. Home-country endowments can also affect the level of internationalization. For instance, state-owned firms in some emerging markets receive abundant state financing for internationalization. The characteristics of the political system of the home country is another interesting topic. Future research can analyze how political regimes and election cycles affect the international strategies of state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds. One way is to separate between authoritarian and democratic governments. In democratic systems, the rotation of parties in power with diverging attitudes towards state government control of the economy can lead to sharp changes in the internationalization strategy of state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds. Nondemocratic systems do not face such rotation, which may enable state-owned businesses to adopt longer-term strategies. It would also be interesting to analyze the buffers that state-owned entities can create to reduce disruption to their long-term strategies with changes in government. A new government may question the decisions taken by a previous one regarding foreign state-owned entities. Finally, there is room for analysis of the use of lobbyists and campaign donations by foreign state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds to influence host governments and their internationalization. Future research could benefit from a more structured analysis of the role of the home government's attitudes towards the internationalization of stateowned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds. For instance, research could use classifications of countries by the level of intervention in the economy (Wright et al., 2021) and identify patterns of foreign investments. This will reduce the criticism of the existing literature, especially on stateowned multinationals, as being based on a small set of countries, which limits generalization. Going deeper into the attitudes of the government towards its role in the economy, and not just the quality of institutions or the type of political system, can yield valuable insights. For example, one important question is why some governments control the foreign expansion of state-owned firms and sovereign wealth funds (e.g., China), while others give them autonomy (e.g., Norway). Politicians' view of their role in the economy and the level of trust or contract enforceability may drive these differences. Host Country Expansion: Support, Influence, and Impact How private multinationals make their selection of host countries and decide on the entry modes they use in these countries is well known (Rugman, 2009 ). In state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds, there are new issues to consider. One of the core insights on internationalization is how home-country governments play a dual role in internationalization: they constrain the foreign expansion of state-owned entities by directing them towards political objectives at home, but, once those firms go out abroad, they support their expansion with state resources. This support from the government enables them to undertake investments that are too risky for most private investors and mitigates some of the risks (Rose, 2009 ). Sovereign wealth funds can benefit from state support and alter their long-term investment strategies to become more exposed to riskier sectors in host countries in exchange for higher returns or greater influence. There might be some interesting coordination among firms in the same industry through investments by sovereign wealth funds and state-owned firms that reinforce state influence in that industry, not only at home but also abroad. Research can analyze whether and how corporate governance standards at the holding or portfolio levels diffuse to the next micro-level of the subsidiary or investee firms in host countries. Sovereign wealth funds could potentially become better monitors among institutional investors since they have long-term commitments in their investee firms and lack liquidity constraints. However, given the political and social priorities of sovereign wealth fund board representatives, it is unclear what the overall impact on the corporate governance processes of their investee firms would be, creating an opportunity for further research. We need more research on the management of foreign subsidiaries of state-owned multinationals and foreign portfolio firms of sovereign wealth funds, such as the acquisition and transfer of knowledge from host to home operations. There is also the issue of heterogeneity in the level of ownership in foreign investments and the varying degrees of government influence. Minority ownership, for example, is often considered a subtle but still influential method of government intervention (Inoue et al., 2013) . Another area of interest is how host countries manage the trade-offs between the economic benefits and political costs of investments by stateowned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds. There is a conflict between the technocratic analysis of the economic benefits of investments by state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds, and the politically driven discourse about the interference of home governments in hostcountry economies. State-owned multinationals can generate spillovers from investing in knowledge transfer and knowledge-intensive industries, such as high tech, and be proactive in such spillovers, instead of aiming to reduce them, as is the usual recommendation of the literature (Blomström & Kokko, 1998) . Investments by state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds can be used as rewards or punishments, but there is a need for a more subtle understanding of the differences between state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds as tools of foreign influence and power. Sovereign wealth funds usually have Table 7 Future research questions to answer in the study of state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds Suggested research questions Home Government: endowments, characteristics, and attitudes Endowments Which country characteristics lead to the creation and internationalization of a state-owned multinational/sovereign wealth fund? What country characteristics help a state-owned multinational/sovereign wealth fund work better in achieving business or nonbusiness objectives abroad? Which channels are the most effective for home-country governments in using state-owned multinationals/sovereign wealth funds to facilitate the development of the domestic economy through foreign expansion? How do international operating strategies of state-owned multinationals/sovereign wealth funds evolve over time/ with the level of economic development/in response to economic development in home countries? Characteristics How do a political regime and its change in the government affect the international strategies of state-owned multinationals/sovereign wealth funds? Attitudes Why do some governments exert control on the foreign expansion of state-owned multinationals/sovereign wealth funds, while others give them autonomy so that they internationalize like private firms? Host-country expansion: support, influence, and impact Support What is the effect of government ownership and support on the riskiness of foreign investments by sovereign wealth funds and state-owned multinationals? What are the coordination mechanisms among foreign investments from the same industry by sovereign wealth funds and state-owned multinationals that reinforce state influence in that industry abroad? How do industry characteristics of host countries (technological orientation, regulation, or level of competition) affect the internationalization and performance of state-owned multinationals/sovereign wealth funds? Influence How do governments as foreign investors affect host-country governments? How do state-owned multinationals/sovereign wealth funds address market imperfections abroad? How do the political and commercial expertise of the top management team and board affect the internationalization and performance of state-owned multinationals/sovereign wealth funds in comparison to private funds/ multinationals? How does CEO succession affect the internationalization strategy of state-owned multinationals/sovereign wealth funds? How does the ideology of the state-owned multinationals/sovereign wealth funds affect the behavior of managers of foreign subsidiaries/ foreign-invested firms? How do the political connections and ideology of top management teams affect the foreign strategy and performance of state-owned multinationals/sovereign wealth funds? How do the strategies of state-owned multinationals/sovereign wealth funds change industry characteristics in host countries? Impact How can host governments manage the trade-offs between the benefits of investments by state-owned multinationals/sovereign wealth funds and the costs of interference by the home government of state-owned multinationals/sovereign wealth funds? Home-and host-country relationships: conflicts, mediation, and disguising Conflicts How can governments use evaluations and other informal political restrictions to limit hostile governments' foreign investments? What are the institutional varieties in responses to foreign investments by state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds? Mediation How can state-owned multinationals/sovereign wealth funds reduce the negative impact of conflict between home and host countries? How do changes in bilateral relations between home and host countries affect the strategies and performance of state-owned multinationals/sovereign wealth funds? Disguising How do host-country governments or citizens react to state-owned multinationals/sovereign wealth funds entry? How do state-owned multinationals/sovereign wealth funds respond to these reactions? How do the different strategies of discreet power of home governments affect host countries? Management: orientation, opacity, and arbitrage Orientation How does the internationalization of state-owned multinationals affect the degree of their efficiency, budget constraints, and decision-making independence? How does the time horizon of state-owned multinationals/ sovereign wealth funds affect the time horizon of strategic decision-making of managers in foreign subsidiaries/ foreign target firms? Opacity How do sovereign wealth fund corporate governance characteristics lead to better foreign investment performance relative to private funds? fungible investments that can be more easily changed, but are less influential because of their smaller size. In contrast, state-owned firms have large stakes that grant firms greater influence, but reduce their ability to exit the host country quickly. The impact of the interactions between the host and the home country on the behavior of stateowned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds is a topic with ample potential for future research. The typical approach to the analysis of home and host connections is to identify the differences between home-and host-country settings and to study how these reduce international expansion and success (Berry, Guillén, & Zhou, 2010; Beugelsdijk, Kostova, Kunst, Spadafora, & van Essen, 2018) . The study of state-owned entities goes beyond these differences and into the quality of the relationships between countries, because what matters for state-owned entities is the relationship between home-and host-country governments. There are intriguing instances of state-owned entities addressing political conflicts between home and host countries. It would be interesting to investigate the institutional variety of responses to foreign government investments. For instance, some EU countries have proactively sought investments from sovereign wealth funds of countries with which they had strong political and trade links (Thatcher & Vlandas, 2016) . It is interesting to analyze host-country retaliation, that is, how countries can use evaluations and other informal political restrictions to limit hostile governments' foreign investments (Cuervo-Cazurra, 2018; Lavelle, 2017) . For example, the Committee on Foreign Investment in the United States limits foreign governments' influence through stateowned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds. However, government-owned entities do not have to be passive captives in conflicts between home and host governments. Instead, they could mediate relationships through informal channels to achieve their goals. Internationalization and financialization imply that financial markets contain power projection mechanisms, which governments can deploy via foreign investments of state-owned firms or sovereign wealth funds (Monk, 2011) . In addition to host-country governments, stateowned entities need to pay attention to the perceptions of host-country citizens. Host governments and citizens react differently to entry by state-owned entities. Whereas governments are aware of and have national security concerns about investment by foreign sovereign wealth funds or state-owned multinationals (Cuervo-Cazurra, 2018), citizens are often unaware of the state ownership of firms. Government-owned entities can respond to these reactions by disguising their influence. For example, state-owned multinationals may retain the brand names of local companies and products they purchase to disguise their foreignness, while sovereign wealth funds can use private equity funds to invest abroad indirectly. As to the management of state-owned entities, it would be interesting to understand how they are managed to balance the need to achieve business objectives and the requirement of politicians to pursue some nonbusiness objectives. A few critical issues worth considering are manager orientation, decision opacity, and investment arbitrage. Research on managerial behavior could illuminate the decision-making processes within state-owned multinationals' subsidiaries and sovereign wealth funds' investee firms. For example, future research could investigate whether the long-term orientation of the government impacts the strategic decision-making of managers in subsidiaries/investee firms in host countries. Additionally, future studies could focus on the effect of sovereign wealth fund shareholder activism on managerial behavior in investee firms (Wright & Amess, 2017) . Also important to study is investment-level heterogeneity in areas such as size, fit with the portfolio or holdings, and other influences on managerial attention and internationalization. One opportunity would be to study the determinants of sovereign wealth fund transparency and disclosure to find out why some sovereign wealth funds choose to remain opaque despite restrictions when investing abroad. Considering their opacity as a facilitator of money laundering and embezzlement, research could investigate the mechanisms that mitigate expropriation, especially since sovereign wealth funds are increasingly intertwined with the global financial markets through their foreign investments. Finally, further research is needed on the heterogeneity of state-owned multinational and sovereign wealth fund investments. Namely, research on the varying role of the state as a shareholder in stateowned multinationals relative to privately held multinationals in the valuation effects can be useful in understanding the motives behind international investments. Prior studies have shown that international corporate diversification enhances firm value in private multinationals (Errunza & Senbet, 1981; Gande, Schenzler, & Senbet, 2009 ), but further light can be shed on the effect of international diversification in stateowned vehicles, and how the latter arbitrage differences in legal forms of incorporation and corporate taxes across countries relative to private multinationals (Gande, John, Nair, & Senbet, 2020) . VIA CROSS-FERTILIZATION Complementing the analysis of new research avenues on the internationalization of state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds discussed in the previous section, we suggest another extension by refining theoretical explanations via cross-fertilization. We illustrate this by explaining how selected theories of the firm -agency, transaction cost economics, the resource-based view, resource dependence, and neo-institutional -can be advanced via the cross-fertilization of insights from one research area to the other. Table 8 summarizes these ideas. Agency theory is primarily concerned with how to align the interests of principals (owners) and agents (managers) to achieve desired goals (Jensen & Meckling, 1976) . State-owned firms suffer from unique agency problems in comparison to private firms. These firms are viewed as suffering from multilevel principal-agent problems which result in reduced competitiveness and performance relative to private firms (Grøgaard et al., 2019; Grosman et al., 2019; Musacchio & Lazzarini, 2014) . These conflicts among the goals of citizens (the nominal owners and ultimate principals), politicians (the agents of citizens), civil servants (the agents of politicians), and managers (the agents of politicians and civil servants) depend on the organizational distance between principals and agents. Some stateowned multinationals are directly influenced by their governments, while others, especially minority-owned ones, are more autonomous (Inoue et al., 2013 ). An interesting theoretical dilemma for stateowned firms is that greater managerial autonomy increases agency conflicts, but at the same time it reduces political interference in decisions. These insights can help extend research on sovereign wealth funds by discussing how divergence in objectives among citizens, politicians, and asset managers influence the behavior of sovereign wealth funds and their investee firms abroad. Another extension is analyzing state-ownership opacity and the expropriation of minority shareholders (Grosman et al., 2019; Sun, Hu, & Hillman, 2016) . Research on sovereign wealth funds can benefit from these insights, given that their opacity makes it easier to misappropriate funds (Rose, 2017) . Sovereign wealth fund research can help inform new agency approaches in state-owned multinationals. Agency problems are exacerbated when sovereign wealth funds invest indirectly through intermediaries like private equity or hedge funds (Wright & Amess, 2017) . Research on state-owned multinationals can incorporate more detailed analyses of multi-principal conflicts in firms and foreign subsidiaries with mixed ownership. Additionally, the autonomy and attention of sovereign wealth funds' managers vary with the size and type of investment (Makhoul et al., 2020) , which can inform studies of state-owned multinationals and their stakes in complex ownership pyramids. Transaction costs economics explains firm behavior based on reducing the cost of transactions in economic relationships among actors (Williamson, 1985) . State ownership has competing influences on transaction cost management. The negative view of government ownership argues that it increases the transaction costs by augmenting the risk that a firm may not fulfill contract obligations due to politically motivated interference. The positive view argues that it decreases transaction costs by reducing the risk of fraudulent behavior on behalf of firms. Which effect prevails depends on contingencies. For instance, state-owned multinationals are better able to manage global risks and institutional challenges from their experience in dealing with the uncertainty and risk of transacting with a government. This can be extended to the sovereign wealth fund literature to analyze how this experience helps them make better investments in countries with high government intervention. The literature on sovereign wealth funds uses transaction costs economics differently, proposing that sovereign wealth funds can deal with higher levels of investment risk due to the government's support. Recipient target firms and countries benefit from access to patient (long-term) capital and sovereign wealth fund home-country markets (Rose, 2009 ). The state-owned multinationals literature can benefit by incorporating these ideas to explain how the support of the home government helps state-owned multinationals reduce their transaction costs when investing in locations with a higher risk profile. The resource-based view explains how private firms develop and use resources and capabilities to satisfy customers' needs better than rivals (Barney, 1991) . From this viewpoint, state ownership provides an advantage from access to privileged funding, regulation, and support, thanks to the human and social capital of government officials appointed to the boards that also facilitates internationalization. Studies on sovereign wealth funds can use these ideas to explain how sovereign wealth funds gain an advantage from access to state resources, not only as capital but also from connections to government officials and their expertise in dealing with foreign investments and governments. The literature on sovereign wealth funds does not explicitly build on the resource-based view. Instead, it discusses how sovereign wealth funds mitigate the resource curse by reducing the negative consequences of natural resource wealth, reducing corruption from the misuse of wealth in emerging economies (Dixon & Monk, 2011) . Alternatively, sovereign wealth funds help home governments access resources abroad to promote national development (Haberly, 2011; Kamiń ski, 2017; Sun et al., 2014) . Studies of the building of state-owned multinationals can be cross-fertilized with these ideas to analyze their ability to reduce the resource needs of the home country via their foreign investments. Resource dependence analyzes power, which is driven by one actor influencing the behavior of another because the former controls something the latter needs (Pfeffer & Salancik, 1978) . State-owned firms depend on the government for resources and guidance, constraining their ability to pursue business objectives. This also limits their ability to invest abroad, as the dependence enables politicians to induce state-owned multinationals to invest at home (Deng et al., 2018; Okhmatovskiy, 2010) . This sometimes leads managers of stateowned firms to try to escape politicians' control via internationalization (Choudhury & Khanna, 2014; Rodrigues & Dieleman, 2018) . These ideas can inform the study of the constraining effects of government influence on sovereign wealth funds' capital allocation strategies (Vasudeva, 2013) and how politicians' preferences drive their investments. Studies on sovereign wealth funds do not explicitly build on a resource dependence approach, but they point out the challenges that some economies and sovereign wealth funds encounter from their dependence on natural resources as their primary sources of income in their asset allocation strategies (Balding & Yao, 2011) . Such dependence induces sovereign wealth funds to invest in a broader range of industries abroad to lessen dependence on the home government regulatory framework . State-owned multinationals research can use these insights to study how foreign expansion into diverse industries can reduce dependence on home-country institutions (Choudhury & Khanna, 2014) . Neo-institutional theory proposes that, to achieve legitimacy, firms imitate other companies in response to host-country regulatory, normative, and cognitive pressures. In the context of stateowned firms, it notes that these firms suffer from state ownership illegitimacy abroad. The effect of state ownership on internationalization switches from being negative in liberal market economies to positive in coordinated market economies at either extreme of the varieties of capitalism spectrum (Mariotti & Marzano, 2019) . Comparisons between minority and majority state ownership add another layer of complexity to the institutional moderation (Benito et al., 2016; Chen et al., 2019; Grøgaard et al., 2019; Mariotti & Marzano, 2019) . Research on sovereign wealth funds can study how their lower legitimacy abroad limits their investments, the ownership of noncontrolling positions, and investments under the disclosure thresholds in the host country. Sovereign wealth funds are efficient and powerful tools for the home governments to indirectly influence the legitimacy and perception of a country in which they invest (Vasudeva et al., 2018) . There is always a fear that, behind the seemingly rational financial investments, there is a political or social agenda, even if it promotes democratic values such as national welfare or global justice (Dixon & Monk, 2012; Monk, 2011) . These ideas can cross-fertilize research on state-owned multinationals by analyzing the political influence through their investments abroad, discussing how the political agenda of the home government modifies the perceptions of legitimacy. DISCREET POWER Finally, we complement the review and guidance on future research topics and theories with an additional suggestion for theoretical advancement by introducing the concept of discreet power. This concept encapsulates discussions in previous studies of the use of state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds or both as vehicles for influencing host-country governments. This is a suggestion for clarifying past insights and providing additional theoretical depth, which future research can refine. Power is the ability to influence others to follow one's desires. It is a relative concept in which one party can induce another to change its behavior according to the first party's preferences. In relations between countries, the traditional typology of power is the distinction between hard and soft power (Nye, 2004) . On the one hand, hard power is associated with one government influencing another through coercion. The latter acquiesces because it fears the potential retaliation in case of non-compliance. Hard power is usually tied to military and economic might (Robertson & Sin, 2017) . The retaliation threat can come from using military force and armed conflict to force alignment. It can also be driven by economic strength and the threat of loss of economic relations in cases of misalignment of behavior (Layne, 1997) . On the other hand, soft power is linked to one country influencing the behavior of another through co-optation, with the latter being attracted to the former and adopting the desired behavior voluntarily (Nye, 2004) . Co-optation can result from policies that the country adopts in its international relations and that benefit other countries, leading to their adoption. It can also be motivated by the political values espoused by the country through its foreign policy, which becomes a reference that other countries see as legitimate and emulate (Gill & Huang, 2006) . Finally, it can be led by the country's culture and values, which are perceived to be superior by others and are thus imitated (Watanabe & McConnell, 2008) . We suggest discreet power as a third option. With discreet power, the government aims to provide a subtle inducement for aligning behavior through nudging. A nudge is ''any aspect of the choice architecture that alters people's behavior […] without […] significantly changing their economic incentives'' (Thaler & Sunstein, 2008: p.6 ). Governments can nudge other countries toward their objectives with investments in the host country that follow the preferences of the government, with such investments being undertaken by state-owned companies or financed by state-owned banks and sovereign wealth funds. Thus, discreet power falls in between hard and soft power. It is neither the result of the first country forcing the second to adopt policies nor the second adopting the policies voluntarily, but rather part of a more subtle mutually beneficial relationship between the two countries. One example of discreet power via sovereign wealth funds is the global diffusion of values espoused by the Norwegian government through its use of Norway's Government Pension Fund Global (Rose, 2017; Vasudeva, 2013) by engaging in shareholder activism. State-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds can be used as mechanisms for achieving discreet power in two ways: as a reward that highlights the host-country's benefit for aligning interest, or as a punishment that points to the harm to the host country for not following expected behavior. On the one hand, the home government can follow a reward approach in its use of discreet power via state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds to nudge its political priorities abroad. The home government can guide its stateowned firms to build subsidized infrastructure in the host country, such as roads, railroads, or electricity distribution (Mwase, 1983) . These investments are highly visible to local politicians and populations and help improve relations with the host country, aligning interests in bilateral cooperation and gaining support in multilateral institutions (Dreger, Schüler-Zhou, & Schüller, 2017) . The home-country government can use the sovereign wealth funds to invest in preferred projects in the host country, so that these projects have the funding needed to become viable when commercial providers of funds would shy away from the costs or risks (Haberly, 2011) . Such investments can help improve political relationships with the host government and keep political preferences aligned (Beeson, 2009) . The reward approach is thus likely to be more efficient when there are affinities between the governments of home and host countries that foster existing political or trade relations further. On the other hand, the home government can use punishment through discreet power tactics via its state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds when political interests are not aligned. It can direct its state-owned firms to limit investments or reduce the purchases of imports from the host country (Yang, Zhang, & Terazono, 2019) , as was done, for example, when in 2021 China punished Australia's attempt to investigate how the COVID-19 virus emerged. Such actions can be a subtle message to the host country to nudge its political actions to align with the desires of the home government, given that a reduction in the purchase of imports has a quick and reversible impact. The government can also direct its sovereign wealth funds to divest from host-country firms to nudge the host-country government to align with political desires, as the opening quote illustrated. Such divestitures have expediency value, since the sale of stocks and bonds can be quickly reversed once the preferred political behavior is adopted. All countries can use state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds as mechanisms to implement discreet power, but their use is likely to vary across countries. We propose four types of nonbusiness strategies of state-owned entities as tools of discreet power: recognition, values, development, and supremacy. Table 9 illustrates the classification of discreet power strategies by whether they are used with a mostly social or economic goal, and whether the orientation is mostly inward or outward. These nonbusiness strategies complement the business strategies of the state-owned entities and their search for financial returns. The discreet power strategies evolve with changes in the political regime, ideology, or leadership. For example, under Prime Minister Justin Trudeau, the government of Canada used its sovereign wealth fund to promote the sale of oil and increase economic returns, rather than spread its social and ethical values to other countries, as was more the case previously. Nevertheless, they are likely to be used more or less intensively depending on the characteristics and attitudes of governments. A value strategy is the use of discreet power to spread home values in other countries. It is likely to be used by countries with democratic governments in market-oriented states. Strong institutions and the separation among powers in democratic systems limit the ability of politicians to force stateowned firms towards nonbusiness objectives. Thus, state-owned firms are likely to internationalize in pursuit of business objectives, as in the case with German automobile firm Volkswagen's global expansion, while sovereign wealth funds invest in pursuit of financial returns, as in the case of the Alaska Permanent Fund Corporation's mandate to obtain sustained, compelling returns for Alaskans. Their internationalization may be influenced by the desire to spread preferred values and ethical standards abroad, as occurred when Norway's Government Pension Fund Global became an instrument of the Norwegian government for spreading social norms and environmental practices (Vasudeva, 2013) . This strategy is likely to be most effective when the sovereign wealth fund coordinates with other investors to alter company values. The value strategy is most likely to be deployed through sovereign wealth funds, since most state assets in such countries are owned through them, although welfare states also deploy the value strategy through state-owned firms, as with Italian ENEL's push to develop sustainable power grids in emerging countries. A supremacy strategy is the utilization of discreet power to exert dominance abroad. It is more likely to be followed by interventionist countries with authoritarian regimes, where the dominant channel for discreet power is through state-owned firms. Table 9 Types of strategies of state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds to achieve discreet power Orientation Inward Outward The government uses state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds to improve the country's recognition by other countries The government uses state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds to spread its ethical and social values to other countries Economic Development The government uses state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds to facilitate the country's development The government uses state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds to achieve supremacy in other countries These countries have governments with limited checks and balances on the use of state-owned firms by politicians, who can induce state-owned firms to undertake the investments and activities that politicians deem useful for them. Politicians can direct state-owned firms to invest in preferred countries to achieve political goals, as when Russia's state-owned Gazprom invested in developing a pipeline to Germany that bypasses Ukraine. They can also use sovereign wealth fund investments to support political relationships despite dubious financial returns, as when Libya's sovereign wealth fund bought 25% of a $4 billion issuance of convertible bonds by Unicredit, Italy's secondlargest bank, and later became the largest shareholder (Bertoni & Lugo, 2013) . A development strategy is the use of discreet power in host countries to facilitate the home-country's development. It is likely to be employed by interventionist states with democratic governments, and primarily through state-owned firms. The checks and balances of the democratic government limit the use of state-owned firms to exert political influence abroad if this results in a misuse of funds. Politicians and civil servants can guide state-owned firms or funds to invest in international projects that facilitate access to needed technologies or markets, such as the Indian government mandating mineral-based state-owned firms to buy strategic lithium and cobalt assets overseas, as India aims to build an electric vehicle battery manufacturing capacity (Majumdar, 2018) . Finally, the recognition strategy is using discreet power to improve the home-country's standing abroad. It may be employed by entrepreneurial states with authoritarian political regimes, primarily through sovereign wealth funds. In these countries, the authoritarian nature of the governments reduces criticism. Political objectives can take preeminence over commercial ones in foreign investments as the government creates firms that strengthen its recognition abroad. An example is the sovereign wealth fund Investment Corporation of Dubai, which assumed the costs of hedging oil contracts for the United Arab Emirates' airline Emirates to help its growth, increasing Dubai's recognition in the region (Saleem, 2015) . The literature on state capitalism in international business has been ramping up in recent times, highlighting the importance of the phenomenon whereby governments seek ownership or control of foreign assets. However, separate theories of multinationals and institutional investors have been developed to explain the behavior of private firms. Hence, we need an extension to explain governments as foreign investors and to describe how their nonbusiness objectives affect the internationalization of state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds. This review explains how the government imposes nonbusiness objectives that alter the internationalization of state-owned firms and sovereign wealth funds, opening new topics and theorization opportunities. We outline suggestions for extending the literature in topics, theoretical cross-fertilization, and the concept of discreet power as a theoretical construct that encapsulates previous ideas. This article makes several significant contributions to our understanding of the role of the government as a foreign investor. The review clarifies the stateof-the-art on the topic, promoting the need to establish bridges between the study of the internationalization of sovereign wealth funds and stateowned firms and paying attention to the role of governments' nonbusiness objectives on foreign investments. We complement the independent reviews on sovereign wealth funds in the economics and finance literature (Bahoo et al., 2020; Megginson & Gao, 2020) and on state-owned multinationals in international business (Cuervo-Cazurra & Li, 2021; Cuervo-Cazurra et al., 2014) by clarifying how insights in each stream can help promote a better understanding of the other. The review highlights the importance of governments' nonbusiness drivers of internationalization and their strategic implications. Foreign investments by governments through state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds are subject to a balance between their business objectives as economic agents and their nonbusiness objectives as state-owned entities. This balancing results in a much more subtle impact of government ownership than the traditional negative view. Instead, there is a duality in state ownership, as it can harm some internationalization decisions while helping others. This duality view can help future researchers develop more sophisticated predictions by analyzing the conditions under which the helping hand may compensate the grabbing hand, and vice versa, not only in internationalization but also in other strategic decisions such as growth, diversification, or performance. The joint study of state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds helps advance theory in several ways. We suggest expanding theories of the firm by cross-fertilizing insights from one topic on the other. Additionally, we suggest the concept of discreet power to clarify the understanding of the government as a foreign investor. This is a new dimension of power that complements the traditional binary view of hard and soft power in international relations (Nye, 2004) . The notion of discreet power highlights the use of nudging as the mechanism by which governments can align the interests of other countries to their own, be it of a rewarding or a punishing nature. Our concept of discreet power is further calibrated by providing a typology of four strategies for using it based on whether its orientation is inward or outward and whether the type of desired goals is economic or social. Our categorization of uses of discreet power implicitly builds on the law and finance literature (Djankov, La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, & Shleifer, 2002) by bringing in the importance of politics, laws, and regulations on strategy. A better understanding of the discreet power of governments could further elucidate the institutional varieties of these economies. Further, the intensity of discreet power can be tested depending on the level of activity in foreign policy (Lavelle, 2017) . The study of discreet power can be extended to investments by private firms with the government supporting private national champions, with the view that some foreign ventures can contribute to improving relations and aligning interest with host-country governments. The literature on politically connected private companies usually considers firms using the government to achieve their objectives (Faccio, 2006) , and can also be extended by considering discreet power strategies. In sum, we offer a complementary view of the government exercising discreet power through state-owned entities in a symbiotic relationship. Our conceptual framework can help decision-makers better understand the role of governments in international business. There is much debate on the wisdom of opening to investments by state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds with the view that the governments behind them might use these firms to pursue their nonbusiness agendas (Cuervo-Cazurra, 2018) . We clarify when this might be the case and discuss the logic and mechanisms that enable their use to influence local governments. This does not mean that host-country governments should block all investments by state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds. On the contrary, these investors can bring much-needed technological and financial support for the firms in which they invest. The host country can analyze the strategy of discreet power behind the investment and adopt appropriate responses. Whereas governments from autocratic and institutionally weak economies might use state-owned multinationals and sovereign wealth funds to exert undue influence in host countries, those from democratic and institutionally strong economies can be used to bring superior governance and ethical standards. ABOUT THE AUTHORS Alvaro Cuervo-Cazurra is a Professor of International Business and Strategy at Northeastern University and co-editor of Global Strategy Journal. He studies the internationalization of firms, particularly emerging market multinationals, capability upgrading, focusing on technological capabilities, and governance issues, especially state ownership and corruption. He was elected a Fellow of AIB, received an Honorary Doctorate from Copenhagen Business School, and was awarded a PhD from MIT. Anna Grosman is a Reader (US eq. Professor) in Innovation and Entrepreneurship at Loughborough University London, UK. Her research falls at the intersection of international business, corporate governance, and corporate finance with a special emphasis on contemporary state capitalism, and corporate governance issues of state-affiliated organizations. Her regional focus is on Russia, CIS, and CEE. She was awarded a PhD from Imperial College, UK. William L. Megginson is Professor and Price Chair in Finance at the University of Oklahoma's Michael F. Price College of Business. His research interest has focused in recent years on the privatization of state-owned firms, sovereign wealth fund investments, energy finance, and investment banking principles and practices. He was awarded a PhD from Florida State University. Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/. Sovereign wealth funds: A strategic governance view. The Academy of Management Perspectives State-owned enterprise: An agent without a principal Evolution and management of state-owned enterprises Are sovereign wealth funds politically biased? A comparison with other institutional investors Sovereign wealth funds: Past, present and future A portfolio analysis of sovereign wealth funds Portfolio allocation for sovereign wealth funds in the shadow of commodity-based national wealth Special theory forum the resource-based model of the firm: Origins, implications, and prospects Comment: Trading places? China, the United States and the evolution of the international political economy The benefits of internationalization for state-owned enterprises The investment strategies of sovereign wealth funds An institutional approach to cross-national distance Testing the strategic asset allocation of stabilization sovereign wealth funds Cultural distance and firm internationalization: A meta-analytical review and theoretical implications Multinational corporations and spillovers The sovereign wealth fund discount: Evidence from public equity investments The financial and operating performance of newly privatized firms: Evidence from developing countries Sovereign wealth funds targets selection: A comparison with pension funds The economic theory of the multinational enterprise A retrospective and agenda for future research on Chinese outward foreign direct investment Historic and emergent trends in Chinese outward direct investment Sovereign wealth fund investments and the US political process Sovereign rating news and financial markets spillovers: Evidence from the European debt crisis A principals-principals perspective of hybrid leviathans: cross-border acquisitions by state-owned MNEs Cross-border mergers and acquisitions by Chinese listed companies: A principal-principal perspective Toward resource independence-Why state-owned entities become multinationals: An empirical study of India's public R&D laboratories Thanks but no thanks: State-owned multinationals from emerging markets and host-country policies Structural reform and firm exports Pro-market institutions and global strategy: The pendulum of pro-market reforms and reversals Governments as owners: State-owned multinational companies State ownership and internationalization: The advantage and disadvantage of stateness Sovereign wealth funds' cross-border investments: Assessing the role of country-level drivers and spatial competition Heterogeneity of political connections and outward foreign direct investment Firm values and sovereign wealth fund investments State-owned and privately owned firms: An empirical analysis of profitability, leverage, and labor intensity Investment motives, ownership advantages and institutional distance: An examination of Russian cross-border acquisitions What role for Sovereign Wealth Funds in Africa's development? Reconciling transparency and long-term investing within sovereign funds The regulation of entry Enterprise restructuring in transition: A quantitative survey Determinants of Chinese direct investments in the European Union State ownership, institutional effects and value creation in cross-border mergers & acquisitions by Chinese firms The effects of international operations on the market value of the firm: Theory and evidence Home country institutions and the internationalization of state owned enterprises: A cross-country analysis Politically connected firms The social responsibility of business is to increase its profits Taxes, institutions, and innovation: Theory and international evidence Valuation effects of global diversification Sources and limits of Chinese 'soft power Global SWF Launches a new data platform for sovereign wealth funds and public pension funds Understanding the decision-making process of sovereign wealth funds: The case of Temasek Bringing corporate governance into internalization theory: State ownership and foreign entry strategies Lost in translation? Corporate governance, independent boards and blockholder appropriation State control and corporate governance in transition economies: 25 Years on from 1989 Strategic sovereign wealth fund investment and the new alliance capitalism: A network mapping investigation White knights from the gulf: Sovereign wealth fund investment and the evolution of German industrial finance Outward foreign direct investment of publicly listed firms from China: A corporate governance perspective Does state ownership facilitate outward FDI of Chinese SOEs? Institutional development, market competition, and the logic of interdependence between governments and SOEs Leviathan as a minority shareholder: Firm-level implications of state equity purchases Sovereign wealth funds: Generally accepted principles and practices Determinants of sovereign wealth fund investment in private equity vs public equity Corporate governance and board effectiveness State ownership and international expansion: The S-curve relationship Kamiń ski, T. 2017. Sovereign Wealth Fund investments in Europe as an instrument of Chinese energy policy State capitalism's global reach: Evidence from foreign acquisitions by state-owned companies Saudi Arabia sells Canadian assets as dispute escalates Public footprints in private markets: Sovereign wealth funds and the world economy Bilateral political relations and sovereign wealth fund investment Politically induced board turnover, ownership arrangements, and performance of SOEs Sovereign wealth funds and foreign policy The theory of state-owned enterprises in market economies From preponderance to offshore balancing: America's future grand strategy Leviathan as an inventor: An extended agency model of state-owned versus private firm invention in emerging and developed economies Chinese exceptionalism or new varieties of state capitalism What do state-owned development banks do? Evidence from BNDES Cross-border acquisitions by stateowned firms: How do legitimacy concerns affect the completion and duration of their acquisitions? Institutional compatibility and the internationalization of Chinese SOEs: The moderating role of home subnational institutions We are the (national) champions: Understanding the mechanisms of state capitalism in China How emerging market governments promote outward FDI: Experience from China India readies its prospectors as hunt begins for lithium and cobalt mines abroad. The Economic Times Going the distance: The foreign investment strategies of sovereign wealth funds Varieties of capitalism and the internationalization of state-owned enterprises Government controlled enterprises: International strategic and policy decisions The international strategy of state-owned firms: An organizational process and politics perspective The entrepreneurial state: Debunking public vs. private sector myths Privatization, state capitalism, and state ownership of business in the 21st century Rise of the fiduciary state: A survey of sovereign wealth fund research The state of research on sovereign wealth funds The choice of private versus public capital markets: Evidence from privatizations From state to market: A survey of empirical studies on privatization Board composition, political connections, and performance in stateowned enterprises Overcoming distrust: How state-owned enterprises adapt their foreign entries to institutional pressures abroad The role of sovereign wealth funds as activist or passive fund managers Sovereignty in the era of global capitalism: the rise of sovereign wealth funds and the power of finance Reinventing State Capitalism: Leviathan in Business, Brazil and Beyond Stateowned multinationals in international competition The Oxford Handbook of Management in Emerging Markets The Tanzania-Zambia railway: The Chinese loan and the pre-investment analysis revisited Sovereign wealth funds and private equity Soft power: The means to success in world politics Professionalising boards of directors of state-owned enterprises: Stocktaking of national practices Performance implications of ties to the government and SOEs: A political embeddedness perspective Hybrid governance of state-owned enterprises The external control of organizations: A resource dependence perspective Gaining from globalization? State extraterritoriality and domestic economic impacts-the case of Singapore China's outward foreign direct investment: Location choice and firm ownership Does state ownership really matter? The dynamic alignment of China's resource environment and firm internationalization strategies Measuring hard power: China's economic growth and military capacity The internationalization paradox: Untangling dependence in multinational state hybrids Sovereign wealth fund investment in the shadow of regulation and politics Sovereign wealth funds and domestic political risk The Oxford handbook of international business Bureaucrats in international business: A review of five decades of research on state-owned mnes The changing strategies of international business: 49-69 Emirates reveals fuel contract details in U.S. airline subsidy claim riposte. Reuters Business News State versus Private Ownership A survey of corporate governance Partnering with Leviathan: The politics of innovation in foreign-host-state joint ventures The dark side of board political capital: Enabling blockholder rent appropriation China's sovereign wealth fund investments in overseas energy: The energy security perspective Nudge: Improving decisions about health, wealth, and happiness Overseas state outsiders as new sources of patient capital: Government policies to welcome sovereign wealth fund investment in France and Germany Sovereign wealth funds: The need for greater transparency and accountability Weaving together the normative and regulative roles of government: How the Norwegian sovereign wealth fund's responsible conduct is shaping firms' crossborder investments A Signaling theory of institutional activism: How Norway's sovereign wealth fund investments affect firms' foreign acquisitions The international aspects of state-owned enterprises Soft power superpowers: Cultural and national assets of Japan and the United States The economic institutions of capitalism An age of corporate governance failure?: Financialization and its limits Corporations and new statism: Trends and research priorities The Oxford handbook of sovereign wealth funds State capitalism in international context: Varieties and variations China tells companies to stop buying US agricultural goods. The Financial Times Economic nationalism and foreign acquisition completion: The case of China We are thankful for the constructive and insightful comments on previous versions of the article provided by Editor Lemma W. Senbet, three anonymous reviewers, Gabriel Benito, Luc Bernier, Bernardo Bortolotti, Veljko Fotak, Xuechen Gao, Birgitte Grøgaard, Omrane Guedhami, Maria Illieva, April Knill, Sergio Lazzarini, Summer Liu, Stefano Lugo, Asif Malik, Aldo Musacchio, Ilya Okhmatovskiy, Andrea Paltrinieri, Geoffrey Wood, and participants at the Academy of International Business conferences in 2019 and 2020. We are also grateful for the advice of Ilya Okhmatovskiy relating to cross-border acquisitions of stateowned enterprises and Diego Lopez and Daniel Brett of Global SWF relating to empirical evidence on sovereign wealth funds and public pension funds. Cuervo-Cazurra thanks the Lloyd Mullin Research Fellowship for financial support.