key: cord-0018731-v3lgtoh8 authors: Hemel, Daniel J; Ouellette, Lisa Larrimore title: Innovation institutions and the opioid crisis(†) date: 2020-06-09 journal: J Law Biosci DOI: 10.1093/jlb/lsaa001 sha: edb2e7f1deef37c1aa8a024e27f57f10344b3da3 doc_id: 18731 cord_uid: v3lgtoh8 The US has recently—and belatedly—come to recognize opioid addiction as a public health crisis. What has gone mostly unrecognized is the degree to which this crisis is intertwined with US intellectual property law and related elements of US innovation policy. Innovation institutions—the legal arrangements that structure incentives for production and allocation of knowledge goods—encouraged the development and commercialization of addictive painkillers, restricted access to opioid antidotes, and (perhaps most importantly) failed to facilitate investments in alternative, nonaddictive treatments for chronic pain. Although innovation policy does not bear all the blame for the opioid wave that has washed over communities across the country, innovation institutions are bound up in the ongoing epidemic to a degree that so far has gone underappreciated. This article examines the proliferation of opioid use and abuse through the lens of innovation policy, and it envisions ways in which innovation institutions could help to contain the crisis. Along the way, it seeks to derive broader lessons for innovation policy scholarship as well as recommendations for institutional reform. The opioid crisis challenges the conventional understanding of IP law as a trade-off between allocative efficiency and dynamic efficiency; it highlights the potentially pernicious role of IP protection for addictive and habit-forming products; and it exposes deep flaws in the structure of federal subsidies for and regulation of prescription drugs. It also draws attention to the political and cultural factors that contribute to innovation policy failures. Ultimately, the opioid crisis underscores both the urgency and the limits of institutional change in the innovation policy domain. $500 billion annually. 8 Without a doubt, the opioid crisis is among the primary policy challenges facing the US today. Two dominant narratives have emerged in scholarly and popular commentary on the opioid crisis's causes. One narrative casts opioid abuse as a 'disease of despair'a by-product of poverty and lack of economic opportunity that has hit hardest in deindustrializing regions. 9 This account may capture some important social trends, but identifying causal mechanisms behind the growth in opioid overdoses has proven challenging. 10 Econometric evidence suggests that overdoses have more to do with the availability and cost of drugs than with regional economic trends. As one prominent health economist recently wrote, 'efforts to improve local economies, while desirable for other reasons, are not likely to yield significant reductions in overdose mortality.' 11 A second narrative-which we refer to as the 'disease of deception' accountemphasizes the role of pharmaceutical companies in hiding addiction risks from the public even as they aggressively marketed opioids for ever-broader uses. The chief antagonists in this narrative are members of the Sackler family that owned and ran Purdue Pharma, the maker of the now-infamous opioid drug OxyContin. 12 The diseaseof-deception narrative draws strong support from documents that have surfaced in litigation against Purdue Pharma revealing that company officials knew shortly after OxyContin's introduction in 1996 that the drug was being abused widely-yet concealed that information from the public. 13 Even Purdue Pharma's most withering critics do not allege that the company's coverup was the sole cause of the opioid crisis, however. Widespread OxyContin abuse was a front-page news story as early as 2001, when the opioid epidemic was still in its nascent stage. 14 ' [N] o prescription drug in the last 20 years has been so widely abused so soon after its release as OxyContin,' the New York Times reported in May 2001, citing articles/308156.php (Oct. 2, 2017). We are unaware of a study that measures the percentage of fentanyl users who began by abusing prescription opioids. officials at the federal Drug Enforcement Administration (DEA). 15 Talk radio host Rush Limbaugh drew greater attention to OxyContin in 2003 when he acknowledged on air that he had become addicted to prescription painkillers. 16 And in 2007, a full decade before the annual death toll from opioid abuse reached its peak, Purdue Pharma and three of its executives entered a widely publicized guilty plea to federal criminal charges of misbranding-charges related to the company's concealment of OxyContin's addictive properties. 17 None of this is to suggest that Purdue Pharma and other pharmaceutical companies that marketed prescription opioids are immune from blame for the current crisis. They are not. But deception alone cannot explain how opioids continued to inundate American medicine cabinets long after the addiction risks were widely publicized. How did opioids overwhelm a nation well aware of their addictive properties, claiming victims across the socioeconomic spectrum? To understand that, one must understand not only how opioid manufacturers aggressively marketed their wares and why physicians profligately prescribed these drugs but also why alternative pain management strategies failed to emerge and why opioid antidotes and abuse treatments were so much slower to spread. Purdue Pharma and 'pill mills' play a part in this story, 18 but so does Medicaid's 'best price' mandate and the National Institutes of Health's (NIH) allocation of research funding. Comprehending the origins and persistence of the crisis requires a deep dive into the organizations and policies that drove the opioid wave as well as those that failed to produce a robust response. This article takes up that task. We suggest that the opioid epidemic is, in important respects, a disease of design. By this, we do not mean to suggest that the opioid crisis is the outgrowth of any single person's grand plan. What we mean instead is that the design of institutions created conditions that allowed the crisis to arise and proliferate. We focus in particular on the design of innovation institutions-the legal arrangements that structure the production and allocation of knowledge goods. 19 These include not only intellectual property law (patents, trade secrets, trademarks, regulatory exclusivity, etc.), but also the regulatory structures of the Food and Drug Administration (FDA) that determine whether knowledge goods can reach the market and the public benefit programs like Medicare and Medicaid that subsidize access to knowledge goods. 20 )). The knowledge goods we have in mind here are, principally, pharmacological formulas and therapeutic methods for the treatment of addiction and pain. The design of innovation institutions enabled the opioid epidemic in a number of ways. First, US innovation institutions produced powerful incentives for pharmaceutical firms to develop and commercialize highly addictive prescription pain medicines while imposing weaker constraints on the rollout of new and more addictive products. Second, systems for allocating access to medical technologies promoted the use of addictive medicines while creating barriers to access for addiction treatments. Third, innovation institutions allowed-and indeed, encouraged-manufacturers of opioid antidotes to charge sky-high prices for products that, if more widely accessible, likely could have saved the lives of thousands of opioid overdose victims. Fourth, even while encouraging the rapid diffusion of addictive opioids, innovation institutions failed to sufficiently reward firms for formulating, refining, or popularizing alternative treatments for addiction or for the underlying problem of chronic pain. Again, no one sat down and designed the system to work this way. But a series of institutional design choices-some conscious, others unconscious-allowed a perfect storm to coalesce. Some of these design flaws are relatively familiar. Intellectual property (IP) is an innovation institution that relies on signals of social value generated by market mechanisms, and market-generated signals can yield inefficient allocations of goods in the presence of externalities. Addictive pain medications generate negative externalities, and overdose and addiction treatments produce positive externalities, so it is perhaps unsurprising that America ended up with too many addictive prescription opioids and too few overdose and addiction treatments. Furthermore, IP distorts investments in research and development toward patentable technologies like pharmaceuticals, 21 so it is no surprise that the patent-centric US innovation institutions resulted in a nation awash in pills but wanting for alternative pain treatments. In other respects, our examination of the role of innovation institutions in the opioid epidemic challenges traditional understandings of IP in particular and innovation institutions more broadly. The conventional view posits that IP policy's fundamental trade-off is between innovation and access, or what economists call dynamic efficiency and allocative efficiency. 22 IP incentivizes the development and commercialization of new and better products (the dynamic-efficiency benefit), but it also encourages IP holders to raise prices and restrict access (the allocative-inefficiency cost). The opioid epidemic presents a contrasting image of IP's potential consumption-expanding effects. Opioid patents induced investments in efforts to create demand for products that consumers did not previously believe they wanted. 23 This demand-creation effect was especially powerful because the patented product was habit-forming-Purdue's lower prices for OxyContin in the short term could thus raise consumption in the long Although pharmaceuticals are physical goods as well as knowledge goods, the primary value lies in the information underlying the product. 21 (1969) , optimal patent policy design has traditionally been framed as a trade-off between this benefit of providing incentives for the development of new technologies and the cost of deadweight loss from higher prices during the life of the patent.'). 23 The same is true for many non-opioid innovations, of course-which is part of why we think the story of opioid innovations has lessons for innovation policy more broadly. term. 24 And this problem was exacerbated by the effective cost often being lowered through prescription drug insurance. Although scholars typically view the increased use of patented technologies as a welfare gain, the example of prescription opioids illustrates that patents' consumption-expanding effects can be pernicious. Ideally, the government would counteract the biases embedded in the patent system through other innovation institutions, including regulations, taxes, and governmentdirected financial rewards such as grants and prizes. For example, market-based prizes in the form of insurance reimbursement policies appear to be a particularly promising intervention. 25 But in the context of pain treatment, the federal government's non-patent interventions exacerbated the skew toward prescription opioids and away from other pain management and mitigation strategies. At the same time, government policies created barriers that limited access to addiction treatments. Additionally, and paradoxically, the federal government's subsidies for opioid antidotes may have reduced access to these lifesaving products, challenging the view that demand-side subsidies are a solution to the patent system's pitfalls. Recognizing the role of America's innovation institutions in the opioid epidemic helps inform the search for paths out of the current crisis, but it is essential to emphasize that no magic-bullet policy will bring the opioid epidemic to an end. The proliferation of prescription opioids was both a function of incentives generated by the current innovation ecosystem and a response-misguided as it may have been-to the very real problem of chronic pain afflicting an estimated one in five US adults. 26 Any comprehensive effort to curtail opioid abuse will require interventions aimed at addressing chronic pain in ways that do not put patients at risk of addiction. The solution likely will involve regulated use of opioids by the populations for which they are justified as well as both existing and novel nonaddictive analgesics. 27 At the same time, wider access to existing non-pharmacological pain treatments such as acupuncture, physical therapy, exercise, meditation, and cognitive behavioral therapy may do as much to mitigate the overuse of prescription opioids as any pharmacological leap. 28 Moreover, any comprehensive national strategy to contain the opioid epidemic also will require interventions aimed at individuals already in the throes of addiction (medically known as 'substance use disorder' or 'opioid use disorder'). 29 Initiatives at the federal, state, and 24 As we will discuss, the economic literature has demonstrated that it is sometimes rational to price addictive products even below marginal cost. local levels suggest progress in this regard, though still on a scale far too small relative to the problem that they aim to solve. 30 This article is an attempt to understand how innovation institutions are bound up in the opioid crisis, how they might help to bring the crisis to an end, and what lessons the opioid crisis offers for innovation policy going forward. Part II investigates the relationship between innovation institutions and the sky-high rates of opioid use, abuse, and overdose. Part III draws on insights from the study of innovation policy and comparative institutional analysis to evaluate the ways in which innovation institutions can respond to the opioid epidemic. For example, distortions caused by patent law might be addressed through interventions in areas such as FDA regulation, tort law, and antitrust. And direct public support can address problems on both the incentive and allocation side of innovation policy. As we discuss, there are significant political hurdles to reform, although it is at least promising that opioid misuse is now being viewed as a public health problem. Finally, Part IV asks what lessons we can learn from the opioid crisis for innovation policy more broadly. Although a number of social, economic, and political factors have fueled the opioid epidemic, three phenomena in particular have contributed to the epidemic's spread and severity: (1) the proliferation of prescription opioids from the late 1990s onward, (2) restrictions on access to opioid antidotes and medication-assisted treatment for opioid use disorder, and (3) the limited availability of non-pharmacological treatments or studies on new uses of nonaddictive existing drugs for either chronic pain or addiction. Each of these phenomena involves the production and allocation of knowledge goods. This part highlights the role of America's innovation institutions in fueling these trends, while also recognizing the complexity of this history and the influence of other actors and structures. To illustrate how innovation institutions are bound up in the opioid crisis, we begin in Section II.A with the stories of three pharmaceutical knowledge goods that have affected different aspects of the epidemic: (1) OxyContin, a controlled-release form of an opioid called oxycodone, for treatment of chronic pain; (2) Suboxone, a treatment for opioid use disorder; and (3) Evzio, a device for injecting medicine to halt opioid overdoses. Of course, these three drugs capture only part of the story of the American opioid epidemic. For one thing, as we discuss in more detail below, OxyContin is just one of many opioids contributing to the overdose epidemic; Suboxone is just one among several drugs used to treat opioid use disorder; and Evzio is not the only delivery mechanism for overdose treatments. Nonetheless, the histories of OxyContin, Suboxone, and Evzio capture important aspects of the opioid epidemic's emergence and expansion, helping us show how America became awash in prescription opioids and not in the drugs needed to treat addiction and reverse overdoses. Sections II.B-D then relate these narratives to specific innovation institutions: intellectual property law (including patents, regulatory exclusivity, and their antitrust limits), institutions for ex ante and ex post drug regulation, and public benefit programs that subsidize access to pharmaceuticals and healthcare. All of these institutions are deeply intertwined with the opioid epidemic, though often in tangled ways. In Section II.E, we turn to the innovations that existing institutions failed to produce for treating both pain and opioid addiction. Opioids are not the only (and often likely not the best) way to treat chronic pain; pharmaceuticals may not be the only effective treatment for addiction; 31 and the Evzio injector is not the only way to halt an opioid overdose. Yet American innovation institutions failed to promote the development and commercialization of alternative treatments involving existing drugs or non-pharmacological interventions. This is-if not quite by conscious designnonetheless a by-product of the design of innovation institutions, which promote technologies that are amenable to IP protection but provide insufficient incentives for technologies that are not. And while non-IP policies potentially can offset some of the IP system's biases, the US federal government's non-IP interventions have often done the opposite-exacerbating rather than mitigating the failures of patent-centric innovation institutions. In the early 1990s, MS Contin, a controlled-release form of morphine sulfate, was generating millions of dollars in sales for Purdue Pharma. 32 But MS Contin no longer had IP-protected exclusivity, 33 and Purdue expected generic competition to eat into its profits. 34 The firm pivoted to a new pain treatment market strategy. In November 1993, the US Patent and Trademark Office (PTO) granted Purdue's application for Patent No. 5,266,331, which claimed a controlled-release form of the opioid oxycodone. 35 Just over 2 years later, in December 1995, the FDA approved Purdue's application to market OxyContin for treatment of chronic pain. 36 Purdue's strategy, according to its 1996 budget plan, was 'to switch patients who would have been started on MS [Contin] to OxyContin, as quickly as possible.' 37 The new drug would prove to be a commercial blockbuster. Purdue Pharma set the price of OxyContin at levels that put it within reach even of patients who lacked prescription drug coverage: $1.25 per 10-milligram tablet as of 2000. 38 The number of OxyContin prescriptions dispensed nationwide each year reached 6 million that year, bringing in over $1 billion in sales. 39 Thanks to its patent rights, Purdue Pharma controlled the entire controlled-release oxycodone market until 2005. 40 Due to a temporary patent litigation loss, generics briefly captured up to a third of the market in terms of number of prescriptions, but Purdue ultimately prevailed in litigation and forced competitors out of the market by 2010. 41 In 2010, Purdue also engaged in 'product hopping' 42 by replacing its original OxyContin formulation with a new 'abuse-deterrent' formulation, which is protected until 2030 by later-expiring patents. 43 (The new crush-resistant formulation seems to have been only moderately effective at deterring abuse. 44 ) By 2018, Purdue Pharma's all-time total OxyContin revenue topped $35 billion. 45 To be clear, OxyContin is just one of several prescription opioids that have contributed to America's overdose epidemic. In a recently released federal database, Purdue ranked fourth among prescription opioid manufacturers from 2006 to 2012, with just over 3 per cent of the market. 46 This small market share likely understates Purdue's role in the epidemic, however. OxyContin was for a time the 'drug of choice among abusers,' 47 and it still appears to be the most abused single-entity prescription 38 painkiller. 48 Approximately 14.1 per cent of adults who reported misuse of a prescription pain reliever in 2015 said they misused OxyContin specifically. 49 Moreover, there is some evidence to suggest that oxycodone is more prone to abuse than other common opioids. 50 A recent empirical study of cross-state variation in OxyContin exposure concluded that 'the recent heroin epidemic is largely due to the reformulation of OxyContin.' 51 Additionally, some of Purdue's efforts to promote controlled-release oxycodone may have had spillover effects on other opioid products. 52 Our focus on OxyContin should not be misinterpreted as a monocausal explanation for what is in fact an epidemic with multiple and converging root causes. Rather, its prominence makes it a useful example for illustrating the relationship between opioids and innovation institutions. But before we turn to this relationship, we introduce two other illustrative drugs-each of which might have done more to contain the epidemic had it been more widely distributed: Suboxone and Evzio. addictive drugs? Rising addiction to opioids such as OxyContin has been accompanied by growing business interest in drugs for treating individuals suffering from opioid use disorder, which are commonly described as medication-assisted treatments. The FDA has approved three drugs for treating opioid use disorders-buprenorphine, methadone, and naltrexone-which are available in various combinations and formulations. 53 Buprenorphine is a partial opioid agonist, meaning that it partially binds to opioid receptors to reduce cravings and to reduce the impact of other opioids taken while using the drug. Tables 170525 table 1 The buprenorphine market leader is Indivior, whose buprenorphine-naloxone combination drug Suboxone is, according to some studies, a more effective opioid substitution treatment than buprenorphine alone or the more familiar methadone. 55 Suboxone was introduced in 2002 as a sublingual (under the tongue) tablet subject to a 7-year period of exclusivity under the Orphan Drug Act. 56 The approaching end of Indivior's exclusivity period brought another example of product hopping. 57 The company developed and gained FDA approval for a sublingual film version of Suboxone, with patent protection extending until 2030. 58 As alleged in an antitrust suit brought by 35 states, Indivior then engaged in a campaign to shift patients from the tablet version to the film version, thus negating the threat of competition from generic tablets that could go on the market starting in 2009. 59 According to the states' complaint, Indivior's campaign took several forms. The company 'aggressively' promoted the superiority of the film version to physicians, pharmacists, and payors. 60 It priced the film version below the tablet version even though the film version is more expensive to produce. 61 And then in 2012, it followed Purdue's lead in protesting the safety of its own soon-to-be-generic product to remove it from the market. 62 Indivior announced that it would take the tablet form off the market due to a 'pediatric exposure safety issue' and petitioned the FDA to deny approval for generic versions of the Suboxone tablet due to purported safety concerns. 63 Because Indivior believed it would enjoy monopoly power over Suboxone film but would soon face competition from generic tablets, 64 the company apparently sought to cannibalize the tablet market and induce demand for a new product. Indivior's efforts to transition patients to the patented film version of Suboxone bore fruit: by 2013, 85 per cent of prescriptions for Suboxone were written for the film formulation, 65 and 12 • Innovation institutions and the opioid crisis Suboxone has consistently held over 50 per cent of the buprenorphine market. 66 But it did not come cheap-about $8.56 per dose as of early 2019 or slightly more than $500 per month for twice-a-day use. 67 Indivior's annual revenue from Suboxone topped $1 billion each year from 2014 to 2018. 68 While a lucrative business for Indivior, medication-assisted treatment continues to be underused in the US, reaching-by the National Academies' estimate-only about 20 per cent of patients who are estimated to need it. 69 Moreover, it is far from clear that Suboxone film carried any advantage over Suboxone tablets. The FDA has not found Indivior's claims regarding the dangers of Suboxone tablets to be supported by evidence, 70 and in 2019, Indivior was federally indicted for fraudulently marketing Suboxone film as safer than the tablet form. 71 3. The $4100 overdose treatment: why was the adoption of opioid inhibitors so slow? For patients underserved by addiction treatments, medications to halt the effects of an overdose are another evidence-supported intervention to reduce the human costs of the opioid crisis. One such drug is naloxone-the drug combined with buprenorphine in Suboxone-which binds to opioid receptors to block the effects of other opioids. It was first approved by the FDA in 1971 to reverse opioid overdose. 72 Naloxone is widely used for this purpose by medical professionals, but it has been difficult for lay people to use effectively. 73 To address this problem, the pharmaceutical company Kaléo developed a naloxone auto-injector, which was approved by the FDA in 2014. 74 Evzio's delivery mechanism resembles the much more familiar epinephrine auto-injector EpiPen, and the product has been described as 'an EpiPen for naloxone.' 75 A distinguishing feature of Evzio, however, is that each packet comes with an audio recording and visual cues that guide users through the injection process. That-plus the auto-injector format-is reported to give Evzio a significant ease-of-use advantage over other naloxone delivery mechanisms, including the nasal spray branded as Narcan. 76 Evzio's approval appears to have been based on relatively little R&D compared with most new therapeutics. In general, FDA approval of a new drug requires multiple clinical studies that examine the drug's effectiveness compared with a placebo or a different active drug in a large sample of patients who are observed over many months. 77 The direct costs of these trials are typically tens or hundreds of millions of dollars. 78 But given that naloxone had been used successfully since the 1970s and that Evzio's novelty was in the delivery system, the FDA did not require a new clinical efficacy study. Rather, it granted approval based simply on (1) demonstrated bioequivalence to existing naloxone products, (2) prior EpiPen studies showing the safety of auto-injectors, and (3) a human factor validation study showing that 30 out of 40 participants were able to adequately deliver naloxone to a dummy using the auto-injector without training or reading the accompanying package insert. 79 Kaléo claims that it 'has invested more than $100 million in the research, development and commercialization' of Evzio, 80 although a comparison with the firm's Securities and Exchange Commission filings suggests that much of this funding was on marketing rather than R&D. 81 Yet in spite of-or rather, because of-Evzio's relatively quick path to market, the drug enjoys a lengthy period of patent-protected exclusivity: Kaléo has declared that its product is protected by 31 patents, expiring as late as 2035. 82 (As with OxyContin and Suboxone, this exclusivity period has been extended through product hopping. 83 ) We say that this lengthy period of exclusivity is the result of the short R&D process because firms file for patents early in the process of developing a drug, well before the drug is approved by the FDA and available to consumers. 84 This means that drugs for which the 'time to market' is short enjoy longer periods of market exclusivity than drugs for 76 which the time to market is long, since long time-to-market drugs 'burn' much of their 20-year patent life during the R&D phase. 85 The relationship between time to market and length of exclusivity arguably leads to an upside-down system of incentives, where the financial rewards for easier-to-develop drugs are greater than the rewards for drugs that take years to fine-tune and test. 86 Evzio debuted in 2014 at a list price of $575 for a two-dose prescription. 87 Kaléo subsequently hiked the price per prescription to $750 in 2015, $3750 in 2016, and $4100 in 2017. 88 For comparison, the manufacturing cost for an Evzio unit is $52. 89 Fewer than 70,000 Evzio prescriptions were filled in the 12 months ending in January 2017. 90 These high prices have generated complaints from a number of potential purchasers, including state and local governments. 91 OxyContin, Suboxone, and Evzio are all protected by IP law-and in particular, by lengthy periods of patent exclusivity-so patent law is a logical culprit in the search for the opioid epidemic's cause. Indeed, Harvard Medical School researchers Ameet Sarpatwari, Michael Sinha, and Aaron Kesselheim have argued that 'non-rigorous patenting standards . . . played an important role in launching and prolonging the opioid epidemic.' 92 They focus specifically on OxyContin and Suboxone, both of which are covered by patents that-they say-should have been rejected by the PTO on grounds of obviousness. 93 Kesselheim, writing separately, has also assigned blame to patent law for limiting access to Evzio and other naloxone delivery devices. 94 Taken together, these claims about OxyContin, Suboxone, and Evzio present a puzzle. Sarpatwari, Sinha, and Kesselheim contend that patent protection led to the proliferation of OxyContin and the undersupply of Suboxone (and, according to Kesselheim, also the undersupply of Evzio). But why would patent protection result in more of the first drug and less of the latter two? The authors never note this tension or seek to resolve it. This section takes up that task. We first explain why patent protection plausibly contributed to OxyContin's deadly spread. We then explain why patent protection likely led to undersupply of Suboxone and Evzio. Finally, we consider how these cross-cutting claims can be reconciled and what that reconciliation might tell us about IP's role in the opioid crisis. The notion that patent law contributed to the proliferation of OxyContin cuts decidedly against the conventional wisdom about IP. The conventional view of patent law posits that patent monopolies lead to higher prices and lower quantities of patented products. 95 This is because patentees can maximize profits by pricing their products well above marginal cost (ie the cost of producing an additional unit), which means that some consumers who would have purchased the product in a perfectly competitive market choose not to when the price is marked up. 96 In mine-run cases, this reduction in quantity is considered to be a downside of patent protection, 97 but when the product in question is a potentially harmful drug, the reduction in quantity can increase social welfare. Christopher Cotropia and James Gibson have called this latter phenomenon 'the upside of intellectual property's downside' 98 : the quantity reduction resulting from patent protection is a feature, not a bug, when the relevant product is a detriment to society. Under this view, patent protection for OxyContin should have led to lower quantities of the drug being produced and sold. But the story of OxyContin did not play out as one might have expected: the drug became widely accessible even to consumers of modest means. Why did the trajectory of OxyContin play out so differently than the conventional view of patent law would suggest? We think at least two factors are likely to have played some role in OxyContin's proliferation: (a) the incentive IP provides to invest in demand creation and (b) the habitforming nature of the drug for both prescribing doctors and patients. These effects 95 complicate the conventional understanding of IP law's trade-offs between dynamic and allocative efficiency. We consider each in turn. a. Demand creation The first mechanism counteracting patents' quantity-limiting effect is that patents generate particularly strong incentives to invest in demand creation. If a firm is one of several purveyors of Honeycrisp apples, then it has a comparatively weak incentive to promote demand for Honeycrisps because the benefits of demand creation will spill over to other Honeycrisp purveyors. 99 If a firm is the sole purveyor of a patented product-whether it be a fruit variety 100 or a pharmaceuticalthen its demand-creation incentives are much stronger, as it can capture all of the benefits of its promotional efforts. Purdue Pharma invested enormous resources in creating demand for OxyContin, and while some of that investment might have occurred in the absence of patent protection, it is doubtful that the pharmaceutical company's outlays would have been on the same scale but for the additional IP impetus. OxyContin's selling points were several. First, Purdue sought to tap into the widespread belief that immediate-release oxycodone was an effective analgesic. 'The importance of the familiarity of physicians with oxycodone cannot be overstated,' Purdue officials wrote in an internal marketing plan. 101 'This familiarity is a principal factor that should lead to acceptance of OxyContin,' the officials added. 102 Purdue officials also emphasized OxyContin's convenience: the controlled-release formulation meant that patients would have to take the drug only once every 12 hours, as opposed to four-times-a-day dosing for the more common immediate-release versions of oxycodone then on the market. ' All of our market research indicates that the most important feature of OxyContin beyond oxycodone is the q12h dosing schedule,' according to Purdue materials. 103 Finally, Purdue highlighted the low risk of 'adverse events' even at high dosage levels. 104 At least with the benefit of hindsight, all of these claims now appear to be dubious at best. Rigorous evidence for oxycodone's analgesic efficacy is scant. One recent randomized controlled trial involving acute pain patients found no statistically significant difference in pain outcomes between patients who were administered oxycodone with acetaminophen and patients who were administered ibuprofen with acetaminophen. 105 (Acetaminophen is the generic name for Tylenol, and ibuprofen is available under brands such as Motrin or Advil.) Another year-long randomized study of patients with chronic back pain or with hip or knee osteoarthritis found no significant difference in pain-related function between patients receiving high doses of opioids (including oxycodone) and patients receiving non-opioid treatments. 106 Indeed, the non-opioid treatment group fared significantly better on a self-reported pain scale. 107 But of course, Purdue and other opioid manufacturers had little incentive to develop or disclose this kind of negative information about their products. 108 Instead, Purdue promoted OxyContin as a way for patients to 'gain control of [their] pain' after overthe-counter analgesics had failed. 109 As for the 12-hour dosing advantage, this too now appears to have been illusory. A study by researchers at Oklahoma University College of Medicine published in 2002 found that almost 9 in 10 patients prescribed OxyContin ended up taking the drug more frequently than twice a day. '[N]early every patient in the analysis reported perceived end-of-dose failure of analgesia as the reason for taking the medicine more frequently,' the researchers wrote. 110 A Los Angeles Times exposé collected stories from physicians and patients across the country attesting to 'OxyContin's 12-hour problem.' When the drug wears off before the 12-hour mark-as it often does-'patients can experience excruciating symptoms of withdrawal, including an intense craving for the drug,' the Times reported. 111 The high highs and low lows associated with 12-hour supra note 32 (noting on page 20 of Purdue's 1996 OxyContin budget plan that OxyContin had '[a]ll the analgesic efficacy of immediate-release oxycodone' with 'the ease of [twelve-hour] dosing').It is worth noting that the oxycodone-plus-acetaminophen treatment group in the Chang et al. study received relatively small doses of both drugs (5 milligrams of oxycodone and 325 milligrams of acetaminophen), while the ibuprofenplus-acetaminophen treatment group received much larger doses (400 milligrams of ibuprofen and 1000 milligrams of acetaminophen). Chang, supra; see also Josh Bloom, Advil Works as Well as Opioids for Acute Pain? Not So Fast, Am. Council on Sci. & Health (Nov. 7, 2017), https://www.acsh.org/news/2017/ 11/07/advil-works-well-opioids-acute-pain-not-so-fast-12089 (post on website of industry-funded group noting low oxycodone dosage in the Chang et al. study). Our main point here is not that there is evidence of the absence of oxycodone's efficacy, but that there is an absence of evidence of oxycodone's efficacy. dosing 'could be "the perfect recipe for addiction,"' the Times quoted a leading brain researcher as saying. 112 All the while, Purdue sought to persuade physicians and patients that addiction concerns were overblown. In that effort, Purdue relied heavily on a one-paragraph letter published in the New England Journal of Medicine in 1980-not a peer-reviewed study-which noted that among nearly 12,000 patients who had received at least one narcotic painkiller, 'there were only four cases of reasonably well documented addiction in patients who had no history of addiction.' 113 This letter was then heavily and uncritically cited as evidence that opioid addiction is rare, with later writers describing it as an 'extensive study' or a 'landmark report.' 114 By 2001, public health advocates were raising concerns about OxyContin's addiction risk and petitioning the FDA to recall the drug, and in July 2001, the FDA worked with Purdue to add stronger warnings about the potential for abuse to the OxyContin label. 115 But even then, Purdue argued that the warning was 'more of an exercise in graphic design' and that the real victims were 'legitimate patients' who would lose access to pain relief if OxyContin were restricted. 116 OxyContin sales continued to climb. 117 What made Purdue's demand-creation strategy remarkable-and remarkably successful-was not just the audacity of its claims but the intensity of its efforts. From 1996 to 2001, Purdue held over 40 all-expenses-paid conferences in Florida, Arizona, and California for over 5000 physicians, pharmacists, and nurses. 118 It distributed more than 14,000 videos claiming that less than 1 per cent of patients who took opioids would become addicted (a figure that-while dubious-is also less impressive than it sounds once one considers that 1 per cent of a third of US adults would still add up to nearly a million individuals suffering from substance abuse disorder). 119 In the absence of patent protection, would Purdue Pharma have had as strong an incentive to invest in creating demand for controlled-release oxycodone? Likely not. Purdue knew that if it persuaded physicians to prescribe controlled-release oxycodone to patients, then Purdue would capture the vast majority of resulting revenues. If it were easy for competitors to sell generic versions of OxyContin, however, then Purdue Pharma would have been less likely to invest so heavily in marketing efforts that would have largely benefitted its rivals. The example of Pfizer's drug Viagra is illustrative. Advertisements for Viagra, marketed as a treatment for erectile dysfunction, once dominated the airwaves, with celebrities such as former US Senator Bob Dole and Brazilian football legend Pelé among the drug's promoters. 122 Once a generic version of the drug became available in 2017, Pfizer's spending on Viagra ads sharply plummeted. 123 And Viagra is an especially noticeable example of what is a broader trend: IP-protected exclusivity and marketing expenditures are closely tied. Systematic empirical studies of the pharmaceutical market have found that, on average, marketing expenditures decline after patent expiration and that the resulting negative effect on consumption is equal to or even greater than the positive effect from increased competition and decreased price. 124 The relationship between patent protection and demand creation points to one way in which 'the upside of intellectual property's downside' may not be an upside after all. By that, we mean that patent protection for socially harmful products will not necessarily reduce the quantity consumed. This also means that when the relevant product generates positive externalities, the perceived downside of intellectual property in terms of allocative inefficiency may not be as much of a downside as traditional models suggest. That is, patent protection for positive externality-generating goods may encourage greater investment in demand creation-and ultimately, higher consumption-than if the same good had been unpatented. The overall welfare effect of the patent system will thus depend importantly on whether the system successfully distinguishes between-and offers differential rewards to-socially beneficial and socially harmful products. 125 b. Habit formation The prospect of market exclusivity interacted with OxyContin's addictive properties to generate especially strong incentives for the dissemination of OxyContin. The risk of addiction may have altered Purdue Pharma's profit maximization calculus, causing the company to adopt a pricing strategy that initially aimed at encouraging widespread consumption. If more people consume an addictive good in the present, then future demand for the good will be higher. As economists have recognized, a rational firm with market power may thus choose to lower the present price of its good to increase future demand. 126 If, for example, a tobacco company controls a significant share of the cigarette market, then the company is likely to profit from an additional smoker. If, by contrast, the company is one among a large number of players in a competitive cigarette market, then the likely benefit to the company of addicting an additional individual is smaller. Just as patent protection encourages firms to invest more heavily in marketing, it also may encourage manufacturers of addictive products to price more aggressively early in the patent term in order to hook new customers. Importantly, 'addiction' in this context refers to any mechanism through which consumption at one time generates demand at a later time. A drug may be addictive in this sense if patients develop a compulsion to continue using it (as in the case of substance use disorder) or if physicians can become habituated into prescribing it. 127 Studies of physicians' prescription practices show wide variation across doctors in the frequency of opioid prescriptions and the quantity of opioids prescribed-variation that does not appear to be a function of patient characteristics. 128 As the author of one of these studies hypothesizes, physicians may emulate their mentors' prescription 125 The net effect of patent law's incentives for demand creation will also inform proposals to enhance this commercialization incentive. practices to a large extent-in which case one physician's prescription behavior at one time may influence many more physicians' behaviors at later points in time. 129 If prescription behavior is propagated in this way, then firms with long-term market power over a drug have an even stronger incentive to boost present-period consumption. In the case of OxyContin, Purdue's pricing of the drug more or less conformed to what we might expect from a firm with market power over an addictive product. From 2000 to 2015, the (licit) retail price per tablet of 10-milligram strength OxyContin increased by nearly 60 per cent after adjusting for inflation, while the inflation-adjusted price of an 80-milligram tablet increased by more than 80 per cent. 130 But for Purdue's bankruptcy filing in 2019 and a tentative settlement with city and state governments, 131 we might have expected a continuing pattern of price increases as the firm's patent exclusivity with respect to OxyContin neared its end. (The tentative settlement restricts Purdue's marketing and sale of OxyContin, which may impede further profit maximization efforts-although there is evidence that the Sackler family's international affiliate is using similar tactics to promote OxyContin abroad. 132 ). Purdue's incentive to generate widespread demand for a highly addictive product can help explain why patents may not have had their conventional quantity-limiting effect in the case of OxyContin. We do not mean to suggest, however, that denying IP protection to OxyContin would have prevented the opioid crisis. As noted above, OxyContin constitutes just a small portion of the prescription opioid market. More importantly, it is difficult to know how the market would have evolved in the counterfactual in which Purdue did not have exclusivity with respect to controlled-release oxycodone. Based on the more systematic economic studies discussed above, it seems clear enough that Purdue would have invested far less in pushing the narratives that opioids are safe and effective treatments for chronic pain. But Purdue is not the only opioid producer that has pushed doctors to increase prescription rates in ways that crossed legal and ethical boundaries, 133 and it is plausible that had controlled-release oxycodone been available generically, even more people would have died. To be clear, none of this is to exonerate Purdue for its role in propagating a false narrative around opioids. Nor is it to exonerate IP law for its role in the opioid epidemic. But as we discuss below, IP's contribution to the crisis-while potentially profoundis also nuanced. OxyContin turns out to play a small part in a much more complicated narrative. The effect of IP law on the availability of our other two illustrative drugs-Suboxone and Evzio-looks on first glance like the more traditional tale of IP leading to high prices and restricted quantities. But again, first impressions can deceive, and the overall effect of IP on the use of opioid substitutes and antidotes turns out to be less obvious. Again, the conventional wisdom is that IP law-whatever its dynamic-efficiency effects-leads IP rightsholders to raise prices and thereby reduce quantities of IPprotected products. Consistent with this conventional story, Sarpatwari et al. blame patent law for Suboxone's high price and attribute the underutilization of Suboxone to that patent-induced pricing problem. 134 And as noted above, Evzio costs $4100 per two-dose prescription by 2017-nearly 80 times the unit manufacturing cost-leading to similar arguments that patents limited access. 135 If Suboxone and Evzio had not received lengthy IP protection, it is possible these products would have been developed anyway and that generic competitors would have entered the markets for buprenorphine-naloxone addiction treatments and for naloxone auto-injector overdose treatments, decreasing prices and increasing the number of patients with access to these products. On this account, Indivior and Kaléo could be portrayed as villains in the opioid story, using unnecessary patents, product hopping, and high prices to deprive patients of access to lifesaving medical treatments. But it is not obvious that long-lasting patent protection can be blamed for limiting access to Suboxone and Evzio. The two factors behind OxyContin's proliferation-IP-driven demand creation and habit formation-are present to at least some degree for Suboxone and Evzio as well. It is possible that without Indivior's and Kaléo's highpowered IP incentives to develop and promote demand for their products-including to encourage early use by consumers who would then be more likely to make repeat purchases-fewer patients would be using these products today. First, although Indivior and Kaléo did not spend as extravagantly on marketing as Purdue did, their long-lasting IP protection would seem to provide a similar incentive to increase demand for their products. ProPublica reports that Indivior has spent about $4 million on payments to physicians and lobbying since 2013, 136 and the company's annual reports describe its efforts to overcome the stigma of medical treatment for addiction. 137 Second, even if Suboxone and Evzio do not carry the same risk of medical addiction as OxyContin, demand does seem likely to be linked across time such that consumption today increases demand tomorrow. Suboxone is typically used for long-term maintenance therapy for opioid use disorder, with discontinuation linked to high rates of relapse. 141 Patients who begin Suboxone treatment are thus very likely to become repeat customers, even in the face of future price increases. And while naloxone has no risk of medical addiction, Evzio purchasers-including first responders, drug treatment centers, and businesses in neighborhoods where overdose is common-may become habituated to Evzio's ease of use. Commentators have noted that Kaléo has distributed over 180,000 free devices, apparently with the hope that some of these recipients would later become paying purchasers of the product. 142 And physicians may become routinized into prescribing Evzio as instructed by Kaléo's substantial sales force. It seems plausible that the markets for both Evzio and Suboxone were expanded by campaigns aimed at familiarizing doctors and patients with these products. The naloxone auto-injector was a novel approach to treating overdoses, so people who could benefit from Evzio-including first responders, people with opioid use disorder, friends and family members of those at risk of overdose, and those stocking first aid kits-did not know this was a product they needed. Suboxone faced a different hurdle. A 2019 National Academies report concludes that stigma toward opioid agonists like buprenorphine is a barrier to effective treatment 'grounded in the misperception that these medications are substituting one drug for another,' but that there is some evidence that 'as clinicians gain experience treating patients with [opioid use disorder] with buprenorphine, they gain more positive perceptions about the role of medications in effective treatment.' 143 As the sole provider of the leading buprenorphine product, Indivior arguably had stronger incentives to educate clinicians and patients than it pharmaceutical firm Alkermes for 'misbranding' the opioid addiction drug Vivitrol by failing to communicate the overdose risks associated with the drug. See Lev would have had in a market with generic competitors who could capture many of the benefits of these promotional efforts. What, then, can the stories of OxyContin, Suboxone, and Evzio tell us about the role of IP in the opioid crisis? It might seem that the answer is 'not much': IP's effects on quantity are ambiguous, making it difficult to attribute the spread of OxyContin or the scarcity of Suboxone and Evzio to patent protection or any other form of IP exclusivity. On further reflection, a few important lessons emerge. First, IP relies on markets, and so market failures are likely to result in IP failures too. Perhaps most obviously, OxyContin generates negative externalities (including, among others, the externality to family members and neighbors who are at increased risk of addiction when OxyContin appears in ever more medicine cabinets 144 ), and Suboxone and Evzio produce positive externalities (including the externality to individuals other than the prescription holder who may nonetheless be saved from overdose by a naloxone injection). 145 Markets tend to spawn socially supraoptimal quantities of products that yield negative externalities and suboptimal quantities of products that create positive externalities. It is in some ways unsurprising that America-reliant as it was on IP, a market institution, to allocate access-ended up with too much OxyContin and not enough Suboxone and Evzio. Second, and precisely because IP's effects on quantity are ambiguous, IP is too blunt a tool on its own to produce socially optimal quantities of externality-generating goods. Sarpatwari, Sinha, and Kesselheim suggest that without patent protection for OxyContin and Suboxone, we would have ended up with less of the former and more of the latter. 146 But while those counterfactual claims are plausible, it is also plausible that in a world without patent protection for OxyContin and Suboxone, we could have ended up with more of the former (because of lower prices) and less of the latter (because of lower investment in demand creation). Dialing IP protection down or up will have difficult-to-predict effects on welfare. Finally, and relatedly, reliance on market institutions to allocate access to externalitygenerating goods will lead to predictable pathologies unless policymakers use other tools-including ex ante regulation, ex post liability, and supply-and demand-side subsidies-to correct for market failures. In the remainder of this part, we consider how those tools were used and whether they succeeded. Institutions that regulate new knowledge goods-either in controlling whether and how the goods make it to market ex ante or in penalizing firms whose marketed goods turn out to be harmful ex post-play a key role in mediating IP's effect on welfare. Here, 144 we consider some of these institutions and how they interacted with IP throughout the opioid crisis. The FDA plays an important role in setting the IP incentives discussed in the prior section because FDA approval is typically accompanied by a period of regulatory exclusivity. 147 But the FDA also plays a direct role in drug regulation by deciding whether and under what conditions a new drug can reach the market. This regulatory power could be used to cause firms to internalize negative externalities of their products. For example, a 2017 National Academies report on pain management argues that the FDA should incorporate public health considerations into regulatory decisions, including drug approval and monitoring. 148 But even if the FDA aggressively took this social-welfare-based approach to drug approvals, it is not obvious that it would have reached a different outcome. The opioid crisis has had tremendous social cost, but so does chronic pain. Equally problematically, while the costs of opioids are now reasonably apparent, it would have been more difficult for the FDA to assess these costs prior to the height of the epidemic. Controlling the drug supply ex ante is a blunt policy tool that is difficult to wield. While the FDA does not currently consider broader public health considerations when deciding whether to approve new drugs, it has used its regulatory authority to address direct safety concerns with opioids. Since 2007, the FDA has had authority to impose a Risk Evaluation and Mitigation Strategy (REMS) requirement on drugs with serious associated risks, 149 though systematic studies have been unable to determine whether REMS affect prescribing and dispensing practices. 150 The agency also has encouraged opioid manufacturers to develop 'abuse-deterrent' versions of their products, and it has provided an abuse-deterrent designation for numerous brand-name opioids, starting with Purdue's OxyContin reformulation in 2010. 151 But this supplyside intervention may have backfired, at least in the short term: a recent economic study of cross-state variation in OxyContin exposure suggests that the reformulation in OxyContin-by cutting access to an easy source of highs-has accelerated the turn toward heroin as an alternative. 152 Of course, had the FDA required a tamper-resistant formulation from the outset, it would have avoided this problem-but that would have required the FDA to foresee OxyContin's abuse potential. Finally, we note that the FDA is not the only drug regulator. For example, another federal agency that plays an important role in ex ante drug regulation is the DEA within the Justice Department. Prescribing or dispensing buprenorphine (one of the active ingredients in Suboxone) requires a DEA waiver-a hurdle that is not required to prescribe OxyContin. Although this rule was motivated by a desire to prevent further abuse, it likely had the opposite effect. The 2017 report from the President's opioid commission recommended that all addiction patients have access to medicationassisted treatment including buprenorphine but noted that 47 per cent of counties nationwide and 72 per cent of the most rural counties did not have a physician who had received the required DEA waiver to prescribe this drug. 153 In other words, the DEA may have done more to restrict access to drugs that treat addiction than to drugs that cause it. Separate legal institutions for ex post drug regulation are the tort and criminal law system. A sprawling web of complex litigation is currently playing an important role in forcing Purdue and other opioid manufacturers to internalize some of the social costs of their products. 154 Purdue pled guilty to felony misbranding in 2007, 155 and in March 2019, it agreed to pay $270 million to settle claims brought by the state of Oklahoma. 156 In September 2019, it filed for bankruptcy and agreed to cede all of its assets to a public benefit trust. 157 The bankruptcy case is ongoing as of this writing, but certainly no one would predict that Purdue will emerge from the experience unscathed. The Sackler family that founded and controlled Purdue has pledged to pay $3 billion from their own fortune as part of a global settlement (though it is not clear whether that aspect of the deal will hold). 158 Why did the threat of tort liability not deter opioid manufacturers from aggressively hawking their wares? For one thing, we cannot say for sure that the ex ante effect of the threat of ex post liability was null. It may be (though it seems unlikely) that executives of Purdue and other pharmaceutical companies would have been even more unabashed in puffing up their products' virtues and concealing their vices if tort law had been off the table. We can, however, surmise several reasons why the shadow of ex post liability was short. The first set of reasons is internal to tort law. The framework of negligence liability-centering on the elements of duty, breach, causation, and damages-provides 153 an awkward fit for claims against opioid manufacturers. It was far from obvious that, for example, Purdue owed any duty to individuals who stole OxyContin from family members' medicine cabinets, crushed tablets to destroy the controlled-release feature, and then snorted or injected oxycodone. The fact that the FDA approved OxyContin and other prescription opioids would have made breach difficult to establish in court, and even if breach were shown, drawing a causal connection between a manufacturer's distribution of opioids and any given individual's overdose would require a fair amount of legal creativity. 159 As for damages, apportionment among manufacturers presents a factual and conceptual challenge. As a court in Connecticut said when dismissing a suit by the city of New Haven against Purdue, attempting to assign liability to a particular pharmaceutical company for a share of opioid crisis costs 'would inevitably require determining causation by conjecture.' 160 It would be, according to the court, 'junk justice.' 161 The Connecticut court's claim of 'junk justice' is certainly contestable. 'Junk justice,' one might fairly respond, is a tort system that allows opioid manufacturers to flood the country with addictive pills, conceal their risks, and escape scot-free. But supporters of the effort to hold opioid manufacturers accountable through tort law forthrightly acknowledged that the battle they were fighting was uphill. 162 The apparent settlement of claims against Purdue may be a victory on one front of that fight, but it is not an outcome that was clearly predictable ex ante. A second set of limits on the power of ex post tort liability is external to tort law. The limited liability structure of the corporation shields shareholders from the financial consequences of corporate wrongdoing. The corporation can always declare bankruptcy-an option that, as noted, Purdue has pursued-and it is difficult (though perhaps not impossible) for plaintiffs to claw back from shareholders the dividends that a corporation paid in solvent times. The Sacklers may prove to be the rare case of successful corporate veil piercing, but they stand out as an anomaly against the background of limited shareholder liability in American law. 163 Criminal law, meanwhile, may have a role to play in policing the most egregious abuses, but it is a small role in the overall scheme of the crisis. Obstacles to the use of serious criminal sanctions may be partly political-indeed, it was an intervention from the Bush administration that spared three Purdue executives from jail time in 2007 164 -but they are also legal and practical. Convincing 12 jurors that blame for the opioid crisis lies with individual corporate executives-executives whose companies were distributing drugs that also addressed post-surgical pain and other very real medical conditions-is not an easy task in any courtroom. Of course, our criminal justice system visits harsh consequences on street-level dealers of chemically similar substances on a daily basis, and the disparities in how we treat street-level drug dealers and high-ranking pharmaceutical executives are stark. But it is far from clear that treating the executive like the street-level drug dealer is the solution. And in any event, the task of criminal justice reform is one of the few that is even more daunting than the opioid epidemic. A broken criminal justice system is almost certainly not the opioid epidemic's fix. Demand-side subsidies are another set of institutions that perhaps could have but did not correct IP's flaws as the opioid crisis sprung up and spread. The largest government programs providing subsidies for prescription drugs are Medicare Part D and Medicaid, which are administered at the federal level by the Centers for Medicare & Medicaid Services (CMS). Medicare Part D is an opt-in federal benefit for people over 65 or with certain disabilities. 165 The formula for benefits is complex, but in 2019, Medicare Part D covers 75 per cent of brand-name costs up to an initial coverage limit of $3820, after a $415 deductible. 166 Medicaid is a joint federal-state program that provides healthcare coverage for low-income individuals. Medicaid beneficiaries receive full coverage for prescription drugs, with some states requiring a small co-pay. 167 Within these limits, Medicare and Medicaid have generally reimbursed the costs of prescription opioids such as OxyContin. Indeed, in 2016, opioids were provided to one-third of Medicare Part D beneficiaries (14.4 million individuals). 168 The nearly 164 170 In contrast, even though almost half of nonelderly adults with opioid use disorder are Medicaid beneficiaries, many states deny or limit coverage for medication-assisted treatments such as Suboxone, including by imposing barriers such as prior authorization requirements. 171 Part of the blame for the proliferation of opioids and the more limited spread of opioid addiction treatments may thus lie with the institutional design choices that led to subsidies for opioids and not for addiction treatments. This section provides an in-depth look at the role of Medicare and Medicaid in the opioid epidemic. First, we consider whether expanding access to healthcare contributed to the crisis. Next, we examine whether a particular aspect of Medicaid's approach to pharmaceutical pricing had the unintended consequence of limiting access to opioid antidotes. The claim that expanding access to healthcare made the crisis worse turns out to be tenuous at best. But as we seek to show in Section II.D.2, programmatic features of Medicaid may indeed have had pernicious effects for patients. Generally, demand-side subsidies for a product should result in lower out-of-pocket per-unit costs for subsidy recipients and higher consumption overall. That appears to be what happened with Medicare Part D. Economists Mark Duggan and Fiona Scott Morton have shown that for drugs with competitors in the same therapeutic class, the introduction of Medicare Part D led to substantial price declines and increases in utilization. 172 Subsequent studies have confirmed these findings in the opioid context: Part D coverage reduced the out-of-pocket cost of prescription opioids for newly insured seniors by roughly 40-50 per cent, and prescription opioid utilization among the covered population increased more or less commensurately. 173 While Medicare Part D appears to have contributed to the proliferation of prescription opioids, the same does not appear to have been the case for Medicaid. Rather, Medicaid-focused studies have found no statistically significant relationship between Medicaid expansion and opioid use. 174 The contrast between 169 Medicare Part D and Medicaid presents a puzzle with at least two potential answers. 175 First, Medicaid establishes limits on reimbursements to pharmaceutical manufacturers that are based on prices paid by non-Medicaid consumers such that Medicaid receives the 'best price' among purchasers. 176 This arrangement gives manufacturers an incentive to raise the prices that they charge to non-Medicaid consumers and thereby extract more revenue from the Medicaid program, and Duggan and Scott Morton have shown that an increase in the Medicaid market share is indeed associated with an increase in the average price of a prescription. 177 The result is that Medicaid coverage likely increases access among Medicaid beneficiaries but has the opposite effect on nonbeneficiaries. Since Medicare Part D prices are not explicitly tied to rates in the rest of the market, Medicare Part D does not create the same incentive for manufacturers to hike prices. But this is at most a partial explanation: Medicaid expansion failed to raise prescription opioid use in a statistically significant way not only at the state level, but also at the individual level among newly covered Medicaid beneficiaries. 178 The null result of Medicaid coverage on prescription opioid use is thus not simply a case of a positive effect on use among Medicaid beneficiaries being offset by a negative effect on use among others. A second plausible explanation for the Medicare/Medicaid contrast is that while Medicare Part D expanded prescription drug coverage among seniors who already had access to non-pharmaceutical care, Medicaid increased access to both pharmaceuticals and other forms of healthcare. In the pain relief context, healthcare and prescription painkillers may be substitutes, dampening the impact of increased opioid access. Thus, even while Medicaid provides a demand-side subsidy for prescription opioids, it also subsidizes certain forms of non-pharmaceutical care that serve to reduce demand for prescription opioids. In sum, demand-side subsidies do appear to have played a role in the proliferation of prescription opioids, but the story is not a straightforward one. 179 In particular, the contrast between Medicare Part D and Medicaid suggests that subsidies for prescription drugs and broader healthcare subsidies may have differential effects on opioid use. We return to this subject in Section III.B when we consider the implications of our analysis for potential healthcare access reforms. Like OxyContin, Evzio has been the beneficiary of demand-side subsidies. The federal government spent over $142 million on Evzio from its 2014 launch through August 2018, primarily through Medicare Part D and Medicaid. 180 Most of these expenditures occurred after Kaléo's sales force began urging prescribing doctors in 2016 to complete paperwork indicating that Evzio was 'medically necessary,' triggering coverage by both commercial and government plans. 181 In the first quarter of 2017, Medicare and Medicaid were responsible for 24% of the 2522 units sold but 75% of the $7.94 million in net sales. 182 When setting the price of Evzio, Kaléo sought advice from a number of industry consultants who offered widely varying recommendations. One consultancy suggested a price of $125 per device, or $250 for a double-dose packet. 183 Another firm advised Kaléo to price its packets in the $300-$350 range. 184 A third recommended a target price per packet of $575, which is where Evzio started out in 2014. 185 Two Chicago-based consultants, Todd Smith and Benjamin Bove, were hired in 2015 and offered up a very different strategy, which Kaléo ultimately adopted. 186 Under the distribution model urged by Smith and Bove, Kaléo promised to cover the copays of patients who received Evzio. 187 These patients would receive Evzio in the mail, bypassing the traditional pharmacy channel. 188 Kaléo would charge sky-high prices (in the several thousands of dollars) to commercial insurers, apparently with the expectation that some would not pay but others would. 189 The strategy was described to 60-minutes journalists by former Kaléo employees as 'a legal shell game to bilk insurance companies.' 190 Kaléo's shell game hit a number of roadblocks. Two of the three major US pharmacy benefit managers (PBMs), 191 generally considered to be less user-friendly than Evzio. 193 Kaléo responded by terminating rebate agreements with the PBMs and with CMS, allowing it to earn a higher profit per device. 194 Kaléo received more than $140 million in payments from Medicare Part D and Medicaid, but even so, according to a Senate subcommittee report, Kaléo had not turned a profit on Evzio as of 2018. 195 Meanwhile, state and local governments-which were not the beneficiaries of Kaléo's zero co-pay pledge-struggled to afford the $4100 drug. 196 Ultimately-though only after significant pressure from a Senate investigation and critical news articles 197 -Kaléo began offering Evzio to first responders for $180 in April 2018, 198 and in December 2018, Kaléo announced that a subsidiary will sell an authorized generic version for $178. 199 One way to describe Kaléo's strategy is as a failed effort at price discrimination. If successful, price discrimination-charging different prices to different consumerscould alleviate the allocative inefficiencies of patent protection. As long as a firm can charge each consumer less than her willingness to pay, then no one's access will be limited, even if prices are well above marginal cost for consumers whose willingness to pay is high. 200 But a number of factors stood in the way of Kaléo's price discrimination gambit. For one, drug manufacturers do not typically interact directly with consumers-hence Kaléo's effort to establish independent relationships through specialty pharmacies and bypass traditional distribution channels. For another, federal law places some limits on price discrimination. Drug manufacturers seeking Medicaid coverage typically enter rebate agreements with CMS, with the rebate size guaranteeing Medicaid the 'best price' among purchasers. 201 Specifically, Medicaid receives a minimum rebate of 23.1 per cent off the average manufacturer price, and if any private purchaser (or some public purchasers, including local governments) receives more than this discount, Medicaid receives that 'best price.' 202 This mandate made it unattractive for Kaléo to negotiate discounts with individual PBMs. 203 And even after Kaléo ended its rebate agreements, it could (and did) receive Medicaid and Medicare Part D payments when doctors certified Evzio as 'medically necessary,' 204 but these payments could not be higher than 'usual and customary charges to the general public,' 205 again limiting incentives to negotiate individual discounts. 206 Under typical accounts of the patent system-including our own previous work 207 -demand-side subsidies like Medicaid are viewed as a solution to allocative inefficiencies. And there are indeed substantial demand-side subsidies for Evzio through Medicaid and Medicare Part D. But they are not playing the role they play in the classic story; instead, they appear to be exacerbating the allocative problem. If the limits on charging CMS more than the 'best price' or the 'usual and customary charges' did not exist, Kaléo might well have reached agreements with individual purchasers such as cash-strapped local governments or patients without insurance that preserved patient access to Evzio (thereby lowering deadweight loss). But with these limits in the background, Kaléo had less incentive to strike deals with private purchasers that would have reduced what it could charge the federal government. 208 The Kaléo story thus confirms and challenges our view of patent law. It confirms the view that monopoly power can, under certain conditions, lead to supracompetitive prices and suboptimal output. It challenges the view of demand-side subsidies as an easy solution to the problem. This is not to say that demand-side subsidies could not address the allocative problem here. It is, instead, to illustrate that the design details of those subsidies are critically important and that non-patent policies can magnify as well as mitigate the patent system's pathologies. E. Where were the alternative pain and addiction treatments? Thus far, this part has illustrated the history of the opioid crisis through a tale of three drugs. But why is it a tale of three drugs? Here, we explain how the US patent system helped lead to the current opioid epidemic not only through its incentives to commercialize prescription pain treatments, but also through its failure to provide incentives for alternative non-pharmacological pain and addiction treatments. There are, of course, important differences between the problem of treating chronic pain and the problem of treating those addicted to opioids, including the differential role of politics, which we turn to in Section III.C. We think it is worth emphasizing, however, the common institutional distortions that affected the market for innovations in both contexts. The patent system is designed to mitigate the problem of underinvestment in innovation. Knowledge goods present a classic public goods problem: producers underinvest because knowledge goods often benefit persons other than the producer (nonrivalry) who are hard to exclude from their benefits (nonexcludability), and rational firms do not account for these benefits in their investment decisions. 209 Patent law addresses this problem by making many knowledge goods more excludable. But as Amy Kapczynski and Talha Syed have explained, this system creates a skew in research toward innovations that can be excluded through patents, such as pharmaceuticals. 210 Many solutions to chronic pain are not easily patentable. Even within the pharmaceutical space, it is difficult to patent (or to enforce patents on) new uses of existing drugs. 211 Information that corrects misinformation about existing drugs is also difficult to patent or commodify. 212 Recent randomized controlled trials have suggested that opioids may be no more effective than certain non-opioids at treating both acute and chronic pain. 213 Why were these studies not conducted before opioid misuse became a national crisis? Why are these non-opioid treatment strategies not being aggressively promoted even now? A substantial part of the answer is likely the inability to patent or commodify these findings: no one firm can capture the significant public benefit of correcting misinformation about opioid efficacy. Patents are even less effective at incentivizing pain treatment research that is not related to a commodifiable pill. The 2017 National Academies report on pain management stressed the importance of additional research on non-pharmacological interventions that may be more effective than medications, including acupuncture, physical therapy and exercise, cognitive behavioral therapy, and mindfulness meditation. 214 But even if firms could overcome the legal hurdles to patenting improvements to these methods of pain management, 215 it would be difficult to monitor the dispersed use of these knowledge goods and to enforce these legal rights. Ideally, these patent law failures could be corrected by government-set incentives such as increased grant spending on alternative pain treatments and increased subsidies to expand the market for resulting interventions. But while CMS generally reimbursed the costs of prescription opioids, it did not reimburse the costs of many non-opioid pain treatments such as acupuncture or behavioral programs. 217 This coverage choice makes non-pharmacological treatments more expensive to patients, even if they are more costeffective overall. Worse yet, CMS may have inadvertently pushed physicians to rely more heavily on prescription opioids through its use of pain management questions on patient satisfaction surveys. 218 Specifically, the Hospital Consumer Assessment of Healthcare Providers and Systems (HCAHPS) survey-introduced by CMS in 2006 and administered to patients after discharge 219 -asked in its now-controversial Question 14: 'How often did the hospital or provider do everything in their power to control your pain?' 220 Providers anecdotally observed that patients who received opioid prescriptions were more likely to provide favorable survey responses. 221 The stakes for hospitals were reputational as well as financial. Starting in 2007, hospitals receiving payments from Medicare for inpatient stays were required to collect and submit HCAPHS data, which was then made publicly available. 222 The rewards for high HCAPHS scores increased after the Affordable Care Act explicitly tied hospital reimbursements in part to a hospital's HCAHPS performance. 223 Hospitals were effectively rewarded (or, at least, believed they were being rewarded 224 ) for alleviating short-term pain with opioids and were not subsequently punished when their patients or their patients' relatives started abusing the drugs. In short, instead of offsetting the patent system's skew toward addictive pharmacological pain treatments, other federal policies amplified patent law's flaws. The patent system is only one among a complex of innovation institutions that can balance each other's biases, but here, non-patent innovation institutions did more to exacerbate than to equilibrate the tilt toward prescription opioids. As we discuss in the parts that follow, the failures of non-patent innovation institutions in the opioid crisis inform potential near-term policy responses to the ongoing epidemic as well as long-term efforts at innovation policy reform. While the design of US innovation institutions created conditions that allowed the opioid crisis to develop, these institutions also can play an important role in helping resolve (or at least contain) the epidemic. The causes of opioid addiction and overdose are manifold, but knowledge goods (or the lack thereof) play a critical role at each step along the way. Greater access to affordable nonaddictive pain treatment alternatives would stem the spread of prescription opioids in the first place. Technologically assisted early interventions can halt transitions from opioid use to opioid abuse. Medicationassisted treatments can put patients with opioid abuse disorders on the path to discovery. And widespread availability of opioid antidotes such as naloxone can avert catastrophic outcomes when earlier efforts fail. In prior work, we have drawn a distinction between the incentives that innovation institutions provide to producers of knowledge goods and the allocation mechanisms that innovation institutions establish to govern access to knowledge goods. 225 Here, we apply this framework to the challenges presented by the opioid epidemic. Section III.A considers ways in which innovation institutions can spur the development of technologies that reduce addiction and overdose risks. Section III.B examines policies that can ensure broader access to knowledge goods that fight the opioid epidemic. Finally, Section III.C places these potential policy responses within a broader political and social context. To some degree, the failures of innovation institutions during the opioid crisis reflect underlying inequalities and political pathologies that innovation policy reform is unlikely to solve. In still other respects, however, the crisis was precipitated and perpetuated by policy mistakes that can be corrected, even though the human and economic costs of past mistakes cannot be erased. A. Incentivizing pain-and addiction-related innovation 1. Intellectual property and market incentives Conventionally, innovation scholars have focused on patent law as the main policy tool to increase production of new knowledge goods. 226 Patents, at least in theory, leverage private information from market actors about the value and viability of potential projects and provide strong incentives for investments in promising ideas. 227 But as emphasized in Section II.B, these same features of the patent system encouraged the development and commercialization of prescription opioids. Given the patent system's pro-pharmaceutical skew-and, in particular, its bias toward addictive goods-one natural response might be to write off patents as a potential solution to a problem that, in many respects, is a product of too many pills. We think that would be a mistake. As awareness grows among physicians and patients about the addiction risk associated with prescription opioids, demand for nonaddictive pain treatments will increase too. The patent system will generate strong 225 financial incentives for pharmaceutical and biotech firms to invest in the development of non-opioid painkillers, 228 abuse-resistant opioids, ,229 drugs that can be used to treat addiction, 230 and easier delivery methods for the overdose antidote naloxone. 231 (Indeed, many firms already have. 232 ) There is, to be sure, something unseemly about the very firms that fueled the spread of prescription opioids also profiting from the problem they helped create. Many Americans were thus understandably outraged to learn that Purdue Pharma has filed for a patent on a drug that could 'help wean addicts from opioids,' given that Purdue had helped to hook some of those same people on opioids in the first place. 233 It would be an even crueler irony, though, if the patent system failed to reward investments in innovations that could bring the opioid epidemic under control and thereby encouraged the proliferation of prescription opioids but not the development of solutions to addiction. Of course, these powerful patent incentives still may be subject to the same distortions described in Part II. Patents also skew research toward treatments that require repeated use-and thus generate steady streams of revenue-rather than preventatives which are effective after a single administration. 234 Patent law may therefore be more helpful, for example, in encouraging the development of nonaddictive painkillers than in the development of anti-addiction vaccines. 235 Patent law likewise will do little to facilitate research and development directed at ideas that are difficult for a single firm to commodify-for example, reducing the default number of pills per prescription, 236 informing doctors when their patients overdose, 237 or encouraging the use of alternative pain treatments such as physical or behavioral therapy. 238 Patents are also ineffective incentives for non-pharmaceutical addiction recovery tools such as mobile phone reminders that track the number of days that a patient has remained substancefree, 239 for creative ideas like using reverse motion detectors in clinic bathrooms (ie devices that detect lack of motion) to prevent fatal overdoses, 240 and for research on the comparative value of supervised drug use clinics 241 or different drug court protocols or streamlined ER-to-outpatient transfers for preventing relapse. 242 Episodes such as Indivior's effort to undermine the tablet form of Suboxone 243 highlight the need to consider broad changes to patent law and its interactions with FDA regulatory law, antitrust law, tort law, and other institutions that might cabin its pathologies. 244 These changes, however, may take years to formulate and implement. In the meantime, the opioid epidemic's daily death toll reminds us of 'the fierce urgency of now.' 245 While patents may play a role in promoting the development and commercialization of opioid alternatives, antidotes, and addiction treatments, we think it is clear enough that America will not patent its way out of the opioid crisis. Policymakers will need to look elsewhere for solutions. Patents, fortunately, are not the only choice in the innovation policy toolkit. Another major innovation lever is direct government R&D spending through grants, contracts, and national laboratories, which collectively account for about one-quarter of the $500 billion spent on US R&D each year. 246 Government-set rewards can encourage innovation in areas where patent law fails (eg where welfare-enhancing ideas are difficult to commodify). 247 But government-set rewards are, as we discuss below, vulnerable to pathologies of their own. The US already does provide direct funding for research related to opioids and alternatives, mostly at federal level through the NIH. In 2017, the NIH spent $516 million on pain-related research and $1.6 billion on all forms of substance abuse (of which opioids are only one fraction). 248 In fiscal year 2018, Congress nearly doubled NIH funding for research on opioid addiction with an additional $500 million. 249 Yet these investments, while nontrivial, are on a scale too small for a problem whose economic costs likely top $500 billion annually. 250 For example, opioid-related research funding is less than the $3 billion the NIH provides each year for HIV/AIDS research, 251 even though in 2016, there were over 10 times more Americans abusing prescription pain relievers than living with HIV, 252 and more Americans now die from opioid overdoses than died from the AIDS epidemic at its peak. 253 The 2017 National Academies report recommended that the US invest more heavily in research on pain and on opioid use disorder. 254 We agree, and we think understanding the failures of innovation institutions that contributed to the present crisis can help policymakers direct this funding to where it is most needed. For example, although patent law is likely to incentivize investment in new nonaddictive pharmaceutical pain treatments, it is less likely to encourage research on non-pharmaceutical (and in most cases unpatentable) pain treatments such as acupuncture, physical therapy and exercise, cognitive behavioral therapy, and mindfulness meditation. 255 And while patent law potentially rewards firms for developing opioid antidotes such as Evzio and pharmacological addiction treatments such as Suboxone, it does much less to encourage research into other addiction management mechanisms (eg counseling as a complement to medication-assisted treatment 256 ). Grantmaking agencies should consider the patent system's skews when allocating funds so that their dollars can do the most good-which likely means that resources should be directed at precisely the areas that the patent system leaves untouched. In making these recommendations, we are cognizant that in the real world of federal grants and contracts, politics as well as policy considerations shape outcomes. For example, one study finds that each additional member on the House subcommittee that oversees the NIH's budget is associated with a roughly 9 per cent increase in NIH grants to public universities in that member's state 257 -suggesting that grant allocations may not be based purely on the merits of potential projects. Universities spend many millions of dollars each year lobbying Congress and federal agencies for more grant money, 258 and certainly some of this spending can be fairly characterized as rent-seeking. Increasing the amount of federal spending on opioid-related research will likely increase the social cost of competition among politicians and potential grantees for funds. Yet these rent-seeking costs pale in comparison to the costs of patent litigation 259 and seem rather trivial when compared with the magnitude of the crisis that opioid-related R&D addresses. That the federal R&D grant process remains far from perfect is, we think, both undeniably true and also not a compelling argument against dramatic increases in opioid-related grantmaking. Government grants-ie direct, ex ante public funding for research and developmentare both familiar and popular, with polling suggesting that 8 in 10 US adults think government investments in medical research 'usually pay off in the long run.' 260 Less well recognized-at least outside the innovation policy literature 261 -is that the government can also choose to reward specific technologies ex post through prize systems. Because ex post rewards are only given to successful researchers, they can provide stronger incentives for ingenuity and effort, at least as long as researchers can acquire necessary bridge financing until their ideas reach fruition. 262 Innovation inducement prizes are a small but growing portion of US innovation institutions, 263 including in the opioid context. The NIH is offering $2.5 million for five challenges related to developing open-source databases, algorithms, and biological assays to streamline development of treatments for pain, opioid use disorder, and opioid overdose. 264 Other prize competitions offer financial awards for developing the most promising solutions for tackling a broad portion of the opioid problem, without specifying a particular technological goal. 265 For example, the federal Health Resources and Services Administration, an agency within the US Department of Health and Human Services (HHS), is offering up to $375,000 for innovations that address any 'barriers that limit access to quality treatment . . . for those with Opioid Use Disorder (OUD), including pregnant women and new moms.' 266 And the HHS two-day Opioid Code-a-Thon distributed three $10,000 prizes for 'data-driven solutions to combat the opioid epidemic.' 267 Several states have launched prize competitions of their own. For example, an Ohio prize competition awarded $200,000 in 2018 to each of 12 winners working on technologies to address drug abuse and addiction. 268 And most recently, a New York state prize competition focused on novel solutions to the opioid epidemic awarded a grand prize of $10,000 to a team developing a new intranasal naloxone patch in January 2019. 269 Many opioid-related prize competitions offer funding at such a small scale that they seem unlikely to overcome financial barriers to addressing the epidemic-although prizes can have effects beyond direct monetary rewards. Economists Petra Moser and Tom Nicholas have demonstrated that prizes also encourage innovation through publicity, independent from the inducement effect of financial incentives. 270 As a possible illustration of this effect, the FDA ran a prize competition for opioid-related medical devices that came with no cash prize-winners received only 'enhanced interactions with FDA review divisions' and 'Breakthrough Device designation.' 271 Despite the lack of direct financial reward, the competition generated significant interest, with 250 applications, from which 8 winners were selected. 272 Where innovation inducement prizes are explicitly financial, moreover, they need not be structured as offering a fixed amount of money for a particular technological development. The prize can also be tied to some market outcome, with larger prizes corresponding to greater use of the resulting technology by consumers. For example, rather than offering $100 million for creation of a new vaccine, a prize sponsor could offer $50 per person actually inoculated-an intermediate solution between governmentset fixed prizes and market-set patent rewards. 273 This kind of market-based prize has been used to incentivize distribution of pneumococcal vaccines. 274 But such a structure is not limited to small demonstration projects: demand-side government subsidies for certain technologies, such as through insurance programs like Medicare and Medicaid, bear some similarities to market-based prizes 275 (though they may also introduce new distortions, as discussed above 276 ). The federal government has offered some targeted subsidies focused on relieving the opioid crisis. Most notably, the US Substance Abuse and Mental Health Services Administration (SAMHSA) distributed over $1 billion in State Opioid Response Grants, focused on 'increasing access to medication-assisted treatment using the three [FDA] approved medications for the treatment of opioid use disorder, reducing unmet treatment need, and reducing opioid-overdose-related deaths through the provision of prevention, treatment, and recovery activities for opioid use disorder.' 277 If firms expect this kind of demand-side subsidy to expand the market for a particular medical intervention, the subsidy can enhance incentives to develop technologies in that area in the first place. Grants administered at the state level also provide some opportunity to learn from state experimentation with opioid abuse treatment models-policy variation is important in the face of uncertainty about which policies are most effective. 278 Indeed, SAMHSA grants explicitly include funding for 'identify[ing] which system design models will most rapidly and adequately address the gaps in their systems of care.' 279 Some learning has already occurred from state-level responses: for example, Virginia's 2017 increase in Medicaid reimbursement rates to addiction treatment providers seems to have reduced opioid-related emergency department visits by expanding the supply of (and thus access to) addiction treatment services. 280 To encourage policy experimentation, federal policymakers should consider ways to reward states that use SAMHSA grants or other funding sources to develop innovative approaches that are adopted by other states. To the extent the results of state-level innovation are patentable, states could internalize some out-of-state benefits from their innovation. 281 But while this benefit-internalization approach might work for some technologies such as medical devices, most state-level opioid-related innovations are less likely to generate financial rewards commensurate with their social value, making the need for federal innovation incentives all the more acute. 282 The overall efficacy of the SAMHSA grant program is yet to be seen, but a recent investigative report into the District of Columbia's execution of its grants raises an important cautionary note. 283 The District won $4 million through the grant program, but 'many programs the city said it would launch never materialized,' and '[o]fficials at the clinic contracted by the District with most of its federal funds said not a single patient has been referred to them for addiction treatment.' 284 This story serves as another reminder that non-market solutions are not a panacea: failures of the political market can be just as devastating, and comparisons of innovation institutions must consider the imperfections of each policy choice. We return to these political concerns in Section III.C. The opioid epidemic stems in part from our failure to develop and refine nonaddictive pain treatments, addiction prevention technologies, and successful therapies for substance abuse. But the opioid crisis is not only a crisis of innovation; it is also a crisis of access. In some cases, expensive but effective patent-protected technologies remain out of patients' reach. In other instances, non-patent-protected treatments are available at reasonable cost, but public and private sector health insurance plans fail to cover them or regulatory barriers limit patient access. In this section, we consider a combination of interventions that would expand access to technologies that can avert, treat, and contain the consequences of opioid addiction. Importantly, as we have explained, these allocation choices can be largely separated from the choice of innovation incentive, and increasing access does not necessarily imply a decreased reward for the innovator. 285 But questions of incentives and allocation are not hermetically sealed off from one another. In some cases, access-related policy levers should be used to decrease the reward to the innovator, such as when a product that generates negative externalities is subjected to a Pigouvian tax. In other cases, access-related policies can be used to increase rewards to innovation, as when firms expect demand-side subsidies to boost their profits from new products. Policymakers should remain attentive to the incentive effects of their real-world allocational choices while also understanding the possibility of disaggregating rewards and access. The benefit of expanding access to innovations that will address the opioid crisis should be obvious: stemming the enormous human cost of chronic pain and addiction. But should policymakers be concerned about losing some of the informational value of proprietary pricing? As Glen Weyl and Jean Tirole have explained, market prices often serve a useful screening function: when consumers are willing to pay higher prices for a new product, it signals that they assign a high value to that product relative to any substitutes. 286 But there are a host of reasons that the screening function of proprietary pricing fails in the context of pain-and addiction-related innovations. These problems largely mirror the shortcomings of patent incentives in these contexts. As noted above, market value does not reflect social value in the presence of the externalities and internalities that beset markets for addictive products. These markets have also been plagued with misinformation that further misaligns economic rewards and social value. 287 Additionally, even if detailed information about relative clinical efficacy were available, those suffering from opioid use disorder and perhaps some pain patients probably are not operating at full rationality. 288 It is hard for lay people and even doctors 289 to understand the complex statistical evidence needed to evaluate medical information, and it seems implausible that the choice between two treatment options for addiction will typically be grounded in a full understanding of their comparative value. Just as market prices can fail to accurately signal social value when consumers lack relevant information, they also can fail when consumers are not the ones paying the patent owner's price, such that consumption signals little about the relative value of innovations. Allocation of medical technologies in the US-and most other countries-is far from a pure user-pays system. As previously discussed, the federal government subsidizes access to new medical technologies through programs like Medicare and Medicaid, which have generally covered prescription opioids. 290 All of these factors suggest that the value of proprietary pricing is more attenuated in markets for pain and addiction treatments than in many other contexts, lessening concerns about some of the policy options discussed below. Sky-high sticker prices for pharmaceutical products such as Evzio are, we have argued, in part a product of unintended consequences of federal reimbursement policiesand in particular, the limits on charging CMS more than the 'best price' or the 'usual and customary charges' for other payers. 291 These rules discourage pharmaceutical companies from offering discounts to private health insurance plans and PBMs because those discounts will reduce the amount that the companies can charge the government. Limits on CMS payments aspire to serve the noble purpose of protecting the federal fisc from predatory pharmaceutical pricing. In the case of Evzio, however, these laws appear to have had the unintended consequence of keeping the drug out of many private health plans and PBM formularies while still leaving the government with an enormous bill. Fortunately, policymakers are not without tools to address the problem. Specifically, the Affordable Care Act authorizes the Secretary of HHS to waive the Medicaid bestprice mandate, among other restrictions, when testing 'payment and service delivery models' that 'address[] a defined population for which there are deficits in case leading to poor clinical outcomes.' 292 This authority at least arguably allows the Secretary to create a carveout from the best-price mandate for sales of naloxone products to health plans in the areas hit hardest by the opioid epidemic. 293 Exercise of that waiver authority would encourage Kaléo and its leading competitor, Adapt Pharma's naloxone nasal spray Narcan, to strike deals with private health plans that are currently unwilling to cover the drugs at their list prices. A bolder approach than a Medicaid best-price carveout would be for the federal government to offer to buy the family of Evzio-related patents from Kaléo and then to place those patents in the public domain. 294 One potential concern with buyouts is that they remove the patent holder's incentive to invest in commercialization-though by this point, the publicity surrounding the naloxone auto-injector may already have accomplished much of what marketing efforts can achieve. Another, more daunting, 290 challenge is how to set the price for such a buyout. Academics have proposed auction systems to place some market bound on patent buyout prices, but perhaps the most straightforward approach for a one-time buyout is for Congress to appropriate a specific amount, in effect making a take-it-or-leave-it offer to the manufacturer. Given that Kaléo does not appear to be turning a profit from Evzio yet, 295 it is not crazy to think that the firm would say yes. Optional patent buyouts are attractive if the optimal buyout price is higher than the patentee's expected market return, which may be the case in the Evzio context given both the product's positive externalities and Kaléo's apparent financial struggles. For unwilling sellers, the government has legal options to effectively force patent buyouts. If all the relevant patents were created under federal grants, the government has a license to practice the invention and can also exercise 'march-in' rights to grant additional licenses if 'action is necessary to alleviate health or safety needs which are not reasonably satisfied' by the patentee. 296 And for any patent, 28 U.S.C. § 1498 allows the government and its contractors to manufacture and use the invention 'by or for the United States' in exchange for monetary damages based primarily on the patentee's riskadjusted research and development costs. 297 These statutory mechanisms potentially allow the government to address the problem of 'over-reward,' although the government has shown reluctance to embrace this authority in other contexts. 298 As discussed in Part II, Medicare and Medicaid generally provided reimbursements for prescription opioids but not for non-opioid pain treatments such as acupuncture or behavioral programs, exacerbating the patent-related distortion toward drugs as opposed to less excludable interventions. Coverage of non-pharmacological treatments through private insurers has been similarly limited. 299 In addition to incentivizing additional research into these alternative pain treatments, the government should address this bias by requiring or subsidizing coverage for these interventions. Moreover, Part II explained how insufficient insurance coverage has presented a barrier to access not only for non-opioid pain treatments, but also for pharmaceutical addiction treatments such as Suboxone. 300 Of course, as with government-set innovation incentives, government interventions on the allocation side raise the risk of political failures, including rent-seeking and mismanagement. 301 Ideally, government interventions in the innovation ecosystem should counteract the patent system's biases. But as illustrated throughout this article, the federal government's actual interventions in the allocation system for pain treatment likely compounded the problems that facilitated the current crisis. The opioid crisis dramatically illustrates deep flaws with linking biomedical innovation incentives to patent-based rewards, but it exposes inadequacies of non-patent innovation institutions as well. So far, this article has illustrated how much purchase we can get on these problems through a law-and-economics analysis, but we are cognizant that the study of innovation institutions is about more than financial incentives. The failure of America's innovation institutions to encourage the development and dissemination of nonaddictive pain treatments arose not only from errors of institutional design but also from deficiencies of political will-deficiencies that non-patent institutions came to reflect. To put the point in public choice terms, the diffuse individuals who bear the costs of underinvestment in nonaddictive pain management-including chronic pain patients and members of communities ravaged by opioid abuse-lacked the social and political capital to influence resource allocation that other, better organized interest groups enjoy. The opioid epidemic has had the most devastating impact in rural, poor communities with high unemployment 302 (although, as noted, the causal connection between higher unemployment and higher rates of opioid abuse is difficult to substantiate empirically 303 ). And the stigma of addiction further limited the political capital of those hardest hit. 304 If addiction had not been a taboo subject and if the first people hit were children of congressmen rather than politically marginalized groups, there likely would have been far more political traction to address these problems early on. Although political institutions could have done far more to forestall the present crisis, it is at least promising that drug misuse is now being viewed as a public health problem, at least in the opioid context. In October 2017, President Trump declared the opioid crisis to be a national public health emergency, 305 and the ensuing President's Commission on Combatting Drug Addiction and the Opioid Crisis issued a comprehensive report on addiction prevention and treatment. 306 In contrast, the rise of heroin addiction in the 1970s and crack cocaine addiction in the 1980s and 1990s were largely viewed as criminal justice problems rather than public health problems, leading to mass incarceration rather than mass medical care. 307 The difference may reflect racial and class politics; the press has typically portrayed opioid users as sympathetic white suburbanites, compared with urban black and Latino heroin users. 308 But perhaps greater empathy for those fighting opioid addiction will help the public and policymakers view those suffering from other forms of addiction through a public health lens. 309 Of course, even when opioids began to gain policymakers' attention, government interventions were often too small or were misdirected, as illustrated in Part II. Many of the most significant hurdles to effective policymaking continue to be political and cultural, such as concerns that many addicts are to blame for their own plight and thus less worthy of publicly funded assistance, that scientifically supported medicationassisted treatment is inferior to abstinence-based programs, and that treatment clinics will simply attract more heroin users and crime. 310 It is not enough to recommend that policymakers fix innovation institution failures. Innovation institutions are themselves politically produced, and one reason they failed was because politicians did not have sufficient incentives to design them otherwise. These problems illustrate the need for research not just on the science of treating pain and addiction, but also on the science of communicating this knowledge in ways that overcome existing cultural hurdles. 311 Analogies to other health policy movements may prove instructive. For example, the AIDS movement is partly a story about patent law incentivizing innovations like novel antiretroviral medications, but it is also a story about changing norms and political power. 312 Innovations in cancer therapy require not just scientific advances but also the political support to fund those research efforts-compare the amazing success of the pink ribbon movement for breast cancer research 313 with the low funding rates for stigmatized lung cancer, 314 even though lung cancer is the deadliest cancer, killing more Americans than breast cancer, prostate cancer, and colon cancer combined. 315 As opioid deaths have become higher profile and overdose victims acquire the faces of friends and family members rather than statistics, there has already been progress. In the end, the story of the opioid crisis is to a significant extent an account of failures of institutional design, but it is also a narrative in which the pathological politics of pain and addiction prevented design changes that could have helped address the problem. This may be a dispiriting diagnosis: problems of institutional design are ones that legal scholars can solve, and our analysis suggests that the roots of the opioid crisis are not so easy to snip. More optimistically, recognizing the political and cultural determinants of innovation policy failures will move us incrementally further toward ensuring that those failures are not relived. But it will no doubt be a long and hard journey. While our primary focus in this article is on the ways in which America's innovation institutions have contributed to the opioid crisis and can hasten its end, the opioid epidemic also yields lessons for innovation scholars that apply to other areas of public health and scientific knowledge. The stories of OxyContin, Suboxone, and Evzio confirm some truths that we have long known about the IP system. IP is an effective innovation incentive for aggregating dispersed information about consumers' willingness to pay for new knowledge goods-but when markets fail, so too will IP. 316 Two familiar reasons why markets fail to produce socially optimal outcomes are (1) the externalization of harms and (2) the externalization of benefits. OxyContin is an example of a product that generates negative externalities, and-unsurprisingly-we ended up with too much OxyContin. Suboxone and Evzio are examples of products that generate positive externalities, and-unsurprisingly-we have ended up with too little of these drugs. America's apparent underinvestment in non-pharmacological pain treatments likewise fits into our existing mental models. Non-pharmacological pain treatments such as yoga and acupuncture are almost inevitably nonexcludable and ineligible for patent protection. Our innovation ecosystem is well designed to reward patentable technologies, such as pharmaceuticals, and poorly structured to support the development of processes and practices such as checklists, cognitive behavioral therapy, and alternative medicine. 317 Yet in other ways, our study of the opioid crisis has challenged our beliefs about innovation policy and led us toward new insights. In this final part, we highlight five lessons from the opioid context for innovation policy more broadly: First, we think that the traditional view of IP as a trade-off between dynamic efficiency and allocative efficiency is less accurate than we once believed. 318 In the case of OxyContin, patent protection appears to have encouraged Purdue Pharma's extraordinary investment in demand creation. Aggregate data on the consumption of patented and post-patent pharmaceuticals suggest that the OxyContin story is not an outlier in this regard. 319 Especially when a pharmaceutical manufacturer follows a relatively standard pricing strategy (such that the product is available to Medicaid and Medicare beneficiaries and is included in most private health plan formularies), abovemarginal-cost pricing seems less likely to prevent the vast majority of US patients from gaining access than conventional IP models suggest. Second, and relatedly, the fact that IP encourages demand creation should affect our view of IP's overall welfare effects. Do we want to encourage patentees to create demand for products for which demand does not currently exist? There are, perhaps, cases in which the answer is yes-for example, Eli Lilly's promotion of Prozac arguably generated greater attention toward untreated depression. 320 But we should be aware that the patent system creates incentives for firms to promote products that consumers did not know they wanted (and indeed might not have needed). 321 Third, the interaction between IP and addiction can be particularly pernicious. As we sought to illustrate in Section II.B.1, firms have an especially strong incentive to promote habit-forming products-perhaps by initially charging below-marginal-cost prices-if they anticipate that they can maintain a medium-to long-term monopoly over that product. When the habit-forming nature of a product generates negative externalities, as is the case for medical addiction, the combination of this effect with the more general demand-creation incentives can have devastating social consequences. It is possible that this misalignment of IP rewards with social welfare could be addressed by reforms internal to IP. For example, Michael Risch has called for a revitalization of patent law's utility requirement to deny patents on inventions from which society reaps no benefit (even if the innovator can reap significant profits). 322 Margo Bagley has suggested legislative restrictions on patentable subject matter to revive moral utility doctrine and move away from the US's current (and distinctively American) 'patent first, ask questions later' approach. 323 As another example, Ted Sichelman suggests that patent law remedies should be reformed to better reflect the social value, not market value, of an invention. 324 But, non-IP innovation institutions also have an importantand perhaps paramount-role to play in correcting the IP system's biases. 325 A fourth lesson from the opioid crisis for other areas of innovation policy is that the notion that government subsidies can promote access to IP-protected products turns out to be less than clear-cut. Medicaid's best-price mandate incentivizes pharmaceutical firms to charge higher prices to the private sector, and as the number of patients covered by Medicaid increases, so too does the incentive for firms to set private sector prices with Medicaid in mind. This is not an argument against Medicaid expansion, and removing the best-price mandate without creating an alternative means to control government drug spending would lead to different (and perhaps worse) pathologies. But, it does suggest that government subsidies should be designed with attention to their impact on private pharmaceutical pricing. Indeed, in a world without Medicaid's best-price mandate or other limits on incentives to offer discounts to some purchasers, pharmaceutical firms might seek to maximize profits through price discrimination (ie seeking to ensure that every consumer who values a product at more than its marginal cost will be charged her willingness to pay and no more). Perfect price discrimination entails no deadweight loss. Medicaid changes the incentive to engage in price discrimination, however, because the lowest price charged to other purchasers becomes the ceiling for Medicaid reimbursement. The limit on charging CMS more than the 'usual and customary charges to the general public' has a similar effect. 326 In such cases, IP does lead to serious allocative inefficiencies, but the inefficiencies are because of the way IP interacts with other government policies. To be sure, perfect price discrimination will almost never be possible, and deadweight loss in the IP system is inevitable. But the opioid crisis illustrates that subsidies can do as much to increase deadweight loss as to reduce it. Finally, and notwithstanding our criticisms of the IP system, we again emphasize that non-IP innovation incentives and allocation mechanisms are imperfect. In the case of the opioid epidemic, CMS created powerful non-IP incentives for hospitals to prescribe more opioids. 327 That turned out to be a disaster. The root causes of this particular policy failure are unclear, but we should be cognizant in our critique of certain aspects of market-based IP policies that the grass is not always greener on the non-market side. See Canadian Agency for Drugs & Technologies in Health, Rapid Response Report: Summary with Critical Appraisal-Suboxone versus Methadone for the Treatment of Opioid Dependence: A Review of the Clinical and Cost-Effectiveness See supra note 42 and accompanying text at * 3; Patent and Exclusivity for N022410, US Food & Drug Admin WL 3967911, at * 4. The district court has denied defendants' motion to dismiss, id. at * 24, and has certified two classes in the litigation The FDA has recently announced draft guidance that would give them greater authority to deny these petitions. Citizen Petitions and Petitions for Stay of Action Subject to Section 505(q) of the Federal Food, Drug, and Cosmetic Act Indivior is now fighting a challenge from rival Dr. Reddy's to the patents on the film version of Suboxone. See Indivior Inc. v. Dr. Reddy's Labs America's Best Weapon in the Opioid Epidemic Just Got Cheaper Indivior started as the buprenorphine division of Reckitt Benckiser in 1994 and was spun off into a separate company in 2014 Indicted for Fraudulently Marketing Prescription Opioid The district court denied Indivior's motion to dismiss. United States v Navin Ariyaprakai & Faizan H Arshad, Assessment of the Safety and Ease of Use of the Naloxone Auto-Injector for the Reversal of Opioid Overdose, 7 Open Access Emergency Med The EpiPen is a fascinating story of innovation institutions in itself On the implications for patent policy of time-to-market differentials, see generally Benjamin N. Roin, The Case for Tailoring Patent Awards Based on Time-to-Market Combatting the Opioid Crisis: The Price Increase of an Opioid Overdose Reversal Drug and the Cost to the U.S. Health Care System Some sources indicate that the 2017 price was as much as $4500. See Shefali Luthra, The $4500 Injection to Stop Heroin Overdoses The 'unit cost' is $174, including $29 in overhead and $93 in 'obsolescence supra note 8, at 77 ('[P]rice increases of the various forms of naloxone continue to create affordability issues, preventing state and local governments, as well as community organizations, from stocking naloxone at the levels necessary to rescue more people from overdose Opioid Epidemic, Some Cities Strain to Afford OD Antidote The Opioid Epidemic: Fixing a Broken Pharmaceutical Market (arguing that patent abuse and related strategies limited generic entry for Suboxone and helped maintain high prices, which 'limited the volume of drugs purchased See Wang & Kesselheim, supra note 81 Pain Management and the Opioid Epidemic: Balancing Societal and Individual Benefits and Risks of Prescription Opioid Use Implementing a Public Health Perspective in FDA Drug Regulation, 73 Food & Drug L The Political Economy of the Opioid Epidemic, Yale L. & Pol'y Rev. (forthcoming) (noting that unlike cigarettes, which 'were never reviewed and sanctioned for sale in advance by the federal government The Role of Litigation in the Fight Against Prescription Drug Abuse, 116 W. Va. L. Rev. 1117, 1165 (2014) (advocating for the pursuit of civil remedies but acknowledging that 'the overall effectiveness of civil litigation in this area is highly questionable Litigation is Critical to Opioid Crisis Response The Law's Responses to the Opioid Epidemic: Legal Solutions to a Unique Public Health, Criminal law, and Market-Related Crisis, in Confronting Our Nation's Opioid Crisis: A Report of the Aspen Health Strategy Group See 60 Minutes: Evzio: The Overdose-Reversal Drug with a $4000+ Price Tag, supra note 190 (showing reporter Lesley Stahl struggling to administer Narcan but exclaiming that Evzio is Permanent Subcomm. on Investigations See supra note 91 and accompanying text See Staff of S. Permanent Subcomm. on Investigations, supra note 87; see, eg, 60 Minutes: Evzio: The Overdose-Reversal Drug with a $4000+ Price Tag This Drug Saves Americans from Opioid Overdoses. Its Price Has Been Hiked 600 Percent USP) Auto-Injector Now Available to Patients in Select States Without a Prescription Through Kaléo's New Virtual Standing Order Pilot Program and to Government Agencies at a Direct Purchase Price Maker of $4,100 Overdose Antidote, Authorizes a Generic Version for Just $178 The deadweight loss imposed by a monopolist can be mitigated, and possibly eliminated, if the monopolist can discriminate on price One ripple effect of guaranteeing the best price for Medicaid is that it weakens the leverage of private commercial payers and PBMs in negotiations with manufacturers, in effect setting a floor under prices. Private payers argue that they would be able to negotiate even lower prices for patients if manufacturers were not obliged to offer the same price to all 50 state Medicaid programs Medicare Part D paid over $45 million and Medicaid paid over $5 million for Evzio) at 1 (describing sales efforts focused on getting doctors to sign 'paperwork indicating that EVZIO was medically necessary, which ensured the drug would be covered by government programs like Medicare and Medicaid') This regulation was renumbered from § 447.331 in 2007. See 72 Fed. Reg. 39,142 There is relatively little discussion in case law or legal commentary about the effect of this 'usual and customary' limit on pharmaceutical prices because most firms voluntarily enter rebate agreements with CMS, but the inability to charge CMS more that the 'usual and customary charges to the general public' has limited price discrimination in other pharmaceutical contexts as the closest example in the US to 'matching' of an IP innovation incentive with a non-IP allocation mechanism to reduce allocative inefficiencies) mandate does permit a variety of novel pricing arrangements, including pay-forvalue models Are Pain Management Questions in Patient Satisfaction Surveys Driving the Opioid Epidemic, 106 Am How Good Intentions Contributed to Bad Outcomes: The Opioid Crisis, 93 HCAHPS Fact Sheet Doctors' salary and professional advancement are tied to how well patients rate them on "patient satisfaction surveys Whether high rates of opioid prescription actually boosted HCAHPS scores is a subject of some ambiguity. See Jay S. Lee, Hsou M. Hu & Chad M. Brummett, Postoperative Opioid Prescribing and the Pain Scores on Hospital Consumer Assessment of Healthcare Providers and Systems Survey Drugmakers including Pfizer Inc, Eli Lilly and Co, Regeneron Pharmaceuticals Inc and Teva Pharmaceutical Industries Inc have been packing their pipelines with potential solutions to the crisis and there are 120 non-opioid drugs under FDA review this year, up some 650 per cent since FDA-approved abuse-deterrent opioids, none of which have generic alternatives, are listed at Abuse-Deterrent Opioid Analgesics, US Food & Drug Admin ) (search for the product name and then click on the ' Appl No' and 'Patent and Exclusivity Information'); see also Orexo AB v See supra note 82 and accompanying text supra note 8, at 88; Nic Fleming, The Search for the Perfect Painkiller For examples of recent patents on devices for treating pain through neural stimulation, see US Patent The Man Who Made Billions of Dollars from OxyContin is Pushing a Drug to Wean Addicts off Opioids The idea of Purdue and the Sacklers swooping in with the cure for an epidemic they have profited from, with a new product that will make them even richer, however, feels like the darkest form of capitalist absurdity-and like maybe it's time to make a corporate version of the Son of Sam laws ) (unpublished manuscript); see also Michael Kremer & Christopher M. Snyder, Preventatives Versus Treatments, 130 i8/Vaccines-against-addictive-drugs-push.html Association of Lowering Default Pill Counts in Electronic Medical Record Systems with Postoperative Opioid Prescribing Opioid Prescribing Decreases After Learning of a Patient's Fatal Overdose See supra notes 214-217 and accompanying text Can a Phone App's Warnings to Avoid Risky Friends and Places Prevent Opioid Addiction Relapses? See Macy, supra note 118 Somerville Mayor Plans to Open a Supervised Consumption Site Next Year See Macy, supra note 118 Eng'g, & Med., supra note 148, at 410-14 (arguing that the FDA should incorporate public health considerations into regulatory decisions suggesting legal changes to cabin extensions of exclusivity with limited public health benefits); infra notes 322-324 (discussing potential doctrinal changes to patent law's utility requirement and remedies rules to incorporate broader social welfare concerns) I Have a Dream, Speech Delivered at the Lincoln Memorial See Hemel & Ouellette, supra note 19 Price II, Grants, 34 Berkeley Tech Estimates of Funding for Various Research, Condition, and Disease Categories (RCDC), Nat'l Insts Helping to End Addiction Over the Long-Term: The Research Plan for the NIH HEAL Initiative See supra note 8 and accompanying text See Estimates of Funding for Various Research, Condition, and Disease Categories (RCDC), supra note 248 supra note 48, at 170525 table 1.97A (eleven million), with HIV in the United States and Dependent Areas See supra note 3 and accompanying text Eng'g, & Med., supra note 148 See supra note 214 and accompanying text finding no statistically significant difference on effectiveness measures between patients receiving Suboxone and patients receiving Suboxone plus cognitive behavioral therapy) See Hemel & Ouellette, supra note 19 See Hemel & Ouellette, supra note 259 We have argued that prize competitions may be particularly effective for this kind of computational challenge, where capital constraints typically are not binding. See Hemel & Ouellette, supra note 259 See generally Jason Reinecke, General Innovation Competitions, 21 Stan Addressing Opioid Use Disorder in Pregnant Women and New Moms: Timeline Publicity and Patents: Non-Monetary Awards as a Mechanism to Encourage Innovation The competition was broadly open to any opioidrelated devices, including devices related to 'diagnostics to identify patients at increased risk for addiction, treatments for pain that eliminate the need for opioid analgesics (such as opioid-sparing or replacement therapies for acute or chronic pain), treatments for opioid use disorder or symptoms of opioid withdrawal, as well as devices or technologies that can prevent diversion of prescription opioids describing this evaluation problem). And while rewards are not directly financial, they may be indirectly so. For example, Breakthrough Device designation may help manufacturers obtain FDA approval at a quicker clip-thus bringing the product to market sooner and increasing total profits over the device's life. See Breakthrough Devices Program See Hemel & Ouellette, supra note 19 Intellectual Property Versus Prizes: Reframing the Debate, 81 U. Chi See supra Section II HHS Awards Over $1 Billion to Combat the Opioid Crisis See Lisa Larrimore Ouellette, Patent Experimentalism, 101 Va State Opioid Response Grants For a description of another innovative state program, see German Lopez, I Looked for a State That's Taken the Opioid Epidemic Seriously. I Found Vermont at 550 (referring to this combination of innovation policies as 'layering,' or 'the use of different policies at different jurisdictional levels, such as using non-IP innovation incentives and allocation mechanisms at the domestic level within an international legal system See generally Yair Listokin, Learning Through Policy Variation F]ree-rider problems, failure to internalize benefits to other jurisdictions from innovation, network externalities, and spillovers may reduce policy variation in multi-jurisdictional systems to a level far below optimality Pure Incompetence Market Power Screens Willingness-to-Pay, 127 See, eg supra notes 109-116 and accompanying text Medicine Residents' Understanding of the Biostatistics and Results in the Medical Literature See supra note 195 and accompanying text To be sure, march-in rights alone will be of little use when a product is also covered by private sector patents. See Rachel Sachs, March-In Rights Alone Won't Solve Our Drug Pricing Problems )); see also Letter from Kim Treanor, Knowledge Ecology Int'l, to Kellyanne Conway, Counselor to the President, and James Carroll, Acting Director, Office of Nat'l Drug Control Pol'y The Bayh-Dole Act and Public Rights in Federally Funded Inventions: Will the Agencies Ever Go Marching in? Coverage of Nonpharmacologic Treatments for Low Back Pain Among US Public and Private Insurers, 1 JAMA Network Open e183044 § 300gg-26, and its extension through the Affordable Care Act, 42 U.S.C. § 18031(j) Trump Opioid Plan Writes in Favoritism to Single Company's Addiction Medication Understanding the Rural-Urban Differences in Nonmedical Prescription Opioid Use and Abuse in the United States, 104 Am See supra note 11 and accompanying text See generally Macy, supra note 115, at 8 (explaining how retracing the epidemic across the Appalachians allowed her to 'understand how prescription pill and heroin abuse was allowed to fester, moving quietly and stealthily across this country Locking Up Our Own: Crime and Punishment in Black America 147 (2017) (arguing that crack cocaine addiction should have been labeled 'a public health disaster' rather than Another proffered explanation is the demographics of prescription drug users: the epidemics of the 1980s and 1990s affected mainly low-income, African Americans (crack cocaine) and low-income, rural whites (methamphetamine), whereas the opioid epidemic includes a large representation of middle-class, white individuals with more political and social capital.'). Racial biases may also have been responsible for shielding nonwhite communities from the brunt of the opioid crisis: nonwhite patients are less likely to be prescribed opioids for comparable reported pain. See Diana Jill Burgess et al., Patient Race and Physicians' Decisions to Prescribe Opioids for Chronic Low Back Pain But this is just a silver lining to a broader problem of racial and ethnic disparities in healthcare-including, in this case, the undertreatment of pain. See generally Inst How Trump Unexpectedly Garnered Bipartisan Support for Criminal Justice Reform See Macy, supra note 118, at 216, 281, 288; Nat'l Acads. of Scis Needle Exchanges Help Combat the Opioid Crisis. So Why Was the One in Orange County Shut Down? See generally The Oxford Handbook of the Science of Science Communication The History of AIDS Exceptionalism The Politics Behind the Pink Ribbon Stigma Lingers for Deadliest Cancer See generally Hemel & Ouellette, supra note 19 See generally Kapczynski & Syed, supra note 21 See supra notes 22, 95-98 and accompanying text See supra note 124 and accompanying text Positive Spillovers and Free Riding in Advertising of Prescription Pharmaceuticals: The Case of Antidepressants, 126 Well-Being Analysis vs. Cost-Benefit Analysis, 62 Duke L Reinventing Usefulness Effectively addressing social problems would likely require a more dynamic utility requirement because many social downsides do not surface until long after patent filing Bagley's focus is social concerns with patents grounded in morality rather than negative externalities Patentable Subject Matter and Nonpatent Innovation Incentives, 5 UC Irvine L. Rev. 1115 Purging Patent Law of "Private Law" Remedies, 92 Tex Using validity doctrines such as utility to weed out socially harmful patents would be both administratively challenging for patent examiners and would not help with inventions that create negative externalities but have a net social benefit. And tailoring remedies may be difficult as well; for example, Mark Lemley called Sichelman's proposal 'a perfectly correct statement of aspirations, but nothing that could ever be operationalized without perfect knowledge.' Mark Lemley, Taking the Regulatory Nature of IP Seriously, 92 Tex See supra notes 205-206 and accompanying text See supra notes 218-224 and accompanying text Subsequent events have tragically illustrated that lessons from the last public health crisis will have to be applied-or relearned-in short order Driving a Decade of Change: HIV/AIDS, Patents and Access to Medicines for All, 14 The Access to Knowledge Mobilization and the New Politics of Intellectual Property, 117 Yale L supra note 297, at 303 (describing the government's threat of importing generic versions of the drug under 28 U.S.C. § 1498 Says Bayer Will Cut Cost of Its Anthrax Drug On Language: A Terrible Thing to Waste, N.Y. Times Mag The opioid epidemic is not the first public health crisis that has exposed flaws in innovation institutions. 328 The global AIDS crisis drew the world's eyes toward high prices for patented antiretroviral therapies and highlighted ways in which international IP law limited the ability of low-income countries to respond to health emergencies. The episode resulted in the World Trade Organization issuing its Doha Declaration in 2001, which in turn led to the loosening of restrictions in low-and middle-income countries on access to generic versions of lifesaving drugs. 329 Around the same time as the Doha Declaration, the anthrax attacks in the US also placed a spotlight on patent law's allocative inefficiencies and resulted in Bayer AG, the manufacturer of the anthrax medicine Cipro, cutting prices steeply. 330 A crisis-as Nobel laureate economist Paul Romer once said-is a terrible thing to waste, 331 and innovation policy scholars and reformers did not let these earlier crises meet that fate.Crisis-based policymaking raises the obvious concern that lawmakers and bureaucrats will sacrifice sense for speed. Yet the opioid epidemic, like AIDS but unlike the anthrax scare, is a crisis whose timeline is marked in months and years rather than hours or days. An optimistic scenario is that the crisis's comparatively slow movement will allow for the sort of careful contemplation that crisis-based policymaking often lacks, while the crisis's magnitude will overcome the legislative inertia that often stands in the way of innovation policy change. We ourselves lack the political predictive powers to say whether institutional reform will be the ultimate outcome or whether instead legislative interest in the subject will wane.What we can say with confidence is that close consideration of the interaction between innovation institutions and the opioid epidemic has the potential to reveal important aspects of each. This is not to say that the opioid epidemic is entirely attributable to innovation policy or that the flaws of the innovation system are all at work in the opioid crisis. It is to say, however, that one cannot fully comprehend the causes of the opioid epidemic without understanding the role that innovation institutions played in it, and one's understanding of innovation institutions will almost certainly be enhanced by attention to opioid problem. The epidemic already has wasted far too many lives and laid waste to communities across the country. Hopefully the opportunities for reflection and reform that can come from the crisis will not be squandered as well.