key: cord-119626-qb6fea06 authors: Cruz-Aponte, Mayte'e; Caraballo-Cueto, Jos'e title: Balancing Fiscal and Mortality Impact of SARS-CoV-2 Mitigation Measurements date: 2020-06-02 journal: nan DOI: nan sha: doc_id: 119626 cord_uid: qb6fea06 An epidemic carries human and fiscal costs. In the case of imported pandemics, the first-best solution is to restrict national borders to identify and isolate infected individuals. However, when that opportunity is not fully seized and there is no preventative intervention available, second-best options must be chosen. In this article we develop a system of differential equations that simulate both the fiscal and human costs associated to different mitigation measurements. After simulating several scenarios, we conclude that herd immunity (or unleashing the pandemic) is the worst policy in terms of both human and fiscal cost. We found that the second-best policy would be a strict policy (e.g. physical distancing with massive testing) established under the first 20 days after the pandemic, that lowers the probability of infection by 80%. In the case of the US, this strict policy would save more than 239 thousands lives and almost $170.8 billion to taxpayers when compared to the herd immunity case. During the COVID-19 pandemic, many policymakers are usually facing two separated sources of information: economic models that usually predict an economic collapse [15] and epidemic models that focus on death counts [12] . However, both the economic and mortality figures are key policy variables during a pandemic but few articles integrate both approaches [9, 16] . In particular, no research (to our knowledge) has analyzed both the fiscal and mortality impact of different mitigation measurements. In this article we strive to fill that gap by approximating the impact of physical distancing and patient care on the death toll and government budget, in a attempt to find the optimal conditions to balance it all. Vaccination or therapeutics can eradicate epidemics from the population, like the case of smallpox [2, 3] but when a newly discovered virus hits the population, the entire world is at risk because everyone is susceptible as in the case of the novel SARS-CoV-2 that is impacting us in 2020 [13] . In the case of an imported infection (i.e. not an endemic epidemic), the first-best strategy would be to control borders, identify, treat and isolate infected individuals. This occurred in the U.S. with the Ebola virus, which never became an epidemic [7] . But when a virus is already circulating in a territory and there is no antidote or massive testing and contact tracing available, social or physical distancing is an alternative to mitigate a pandemic and provide the scientific community time to research and find alternative measures such as an effective treatment or a vaccine. Also, physical distancing measure gives fragile healthcare systems the leverage to take care of chronically ill patients without saturation of existing capacity. What are the fiscal and human costs of all these measurements in the short and long run? Thus, two research questions drive this study: What is the optimal physical distancing policies in a country and what are the implications of these policies for both the government budget and loss-of-life? We constructed an enhanced mathematical SIR (Susceptible, Infected, Recovered) epidemic model [5] to simulate the COVID-19 epidemic in the US in an attempt to estimate the fiscal impact and the optimal conditions to mitigate this ongoing pandemic. We found that a policy of no physical distancing or a race towards herd immunity is not the optimal policy choice when both human and fiscal costs are considered. In Section 2 we lay out our methodology. In Section 3 we show the dynamics associated to our calibrated system of differential equations. In Section 4 we discuss our results and in Section 5 we conclude and recommend public policies. We first describe a simple economy with three sectors; businesses, government, and a household sector with two actors. In the second part of this section we describe our epidemic model. In this economy, the household sector is mobile within the country and is composed of L workers and U individuals that are not working. Thus, employment is less than full. This characterization allows us to consider the supply shocks associated to the COVID-19 pandemic [10] , where laborers are impeded to work fully because of lock-downs or infections affecting members of the household sector. Firms produce goods and services i, which require X amount of L. A fixed amount of total output y is predetermined to be produced in period t=0 and is given by, y = X i * L i . However, firms are able to adjust its output when external changes hit the labor stock. The total output that considers the impact of such external changes is observed in, Y t = yH t where H t = dL/dt. We hold the following assumptions over H: • if physical distancing is implemented at t=1, H t = −0.3 during the physical distancing. When the physical distancing ends in t=n, and H t=n = 0.1 This setting let us capture the V-shape growth that is being projected [11] in the post-COVID-19 period. • if no physical distancing is implemented, the pandemic ends in t=n+j, H t=n+j+1 = 0, and H t