Antonello Eugenio Scorcu University of Bologna and The Rimini Centre for Economic Analysis, Italy Roberto Zanola University of Eastern Piedmont and The Rimini Centre for Economic Analysis, Italy THE ‘RIGHT’ PRICE FOR ART COLLECTIBLES. A QUANTILE HEDONIC REGRESSION INVESTIGATION OF PICASSO PAINTINGS Copyright belongs to the author. Small sections of the text, not exceeding three paragraphs, can be used provided proper acknowledgement is given. The Rimini Centre for Economic Analysis (RCEA) was established in March 2007. RCEA is a private, nonprofit organization dedicated to independent research in Applied and Theoretical Economics and related fields. RCEA organizes seminars and workshops, sponsors a general interest journal The Review of Economic Analysis, and organizes a biennial conference: The Rimini Conference in Economics and Finance (RCEF) . The RCEA has a Canadian branch: The Rimini Centre for Economic Analysis in Canada (RCEA- Canada). Scientific work contributed by the RCEA Scholars is published in the RCEA Working Papers and Professional Report series. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors. No responsibility for them should be attributed to the Rimini Centre for Economic Analysis. The Rimini Centre for Economic Analysis Legal address: Via Angherà, 22 – Head office: Via Patara, 3 - 47900 Rimini (RN) – Italy www.rcfea.org - secretary@rcfea.org WP 01_10 mailto:secretary@rcfea.org 1 The ‘right’ price for art collectibles. A quantile hedonic regression investigation of Picasso paintings* A.E. Scorcu+ and R. Zanola° ABSTRACT Different art objects are likely to be priced by means of different systems of hedonic characteristics; more precisely, different evaluation procedures for high and low price items are often postulated. However, the empirical evidence on this point is scant. The main purpose of this paper is to fill this gap by using the quantile hedonic regression approach. The empirical evidence, based on a data set of 716 Picasso paintings sold at auction worldwide, highlights the critical role of the price classes in determining the evaluation criteria of art items. JEL Classification: D49 Key Words: hedonic price; auction; quantile regression; painting; Picasso. * A first version of this paper was completed while the second author was visiting at University of York. Thanks are due to Andrew Jones, Guido Candela, Roberto Cellini and Simone Giannerini. The usual disclaimers apply. + University of Bologna, Department of Economics, Italy and Rimini Center for Economic Analysis (RCEA), Italy, antonello.scorcu@unibo.it ° University of Eastern Piedmont, Department of Public Policy and Public Choice, Italy and Rimini Center for Economic Analysis (RCEA), Italy, roberto.zanola@unipmn.it 2 1. Introduction The price determinants of collectibles has often raised the interest of scholars of the field. Surveying the relevant empirical literature, Ginsburgh et al. (2006) noted that analyses often use the hedonic regression approach, with the price of an art item explained by a number of hedonic characteristics (author, genre, technique, dimension, etc.), market variables (auction house, city of sale, provenance of the object, etc.) and time dummies. The sign and the size of these price determinants emerge from an hedonic regression, and the corresponding market price index can be obtained from the estimated time dummy coefficients. Empirical investigations often analyze the specification of the regression, or the stability of the estimated coefficients over time, as the collectors’ preferences and the evaluation of the hedonic characteristics might evolve, exogenously or in relation to market booms and slumps. In any case, an implicit (albeit restrictive) assumption is that in given market and period, a single evaluation system is shared by low- and high-price art items. Although there is an extensive literature on the hedonic approach [e.g. Candela and Scorcu, 1997; Locatelli-Biey and Zanola, 2005; Zanola, 2007; Collins et al., 2007, 2009], it seems that one basic point has been neglected, namely, the possible existence of a segmentation in the art market with respect to the market value of the items. One could hardly be surprised to learn that a different criterion is used in the appraisal of a masterpiece valued several million dollars and another one in the evaluation of a painting whose price might be a few hundred dollars. In fact art item characteristics evaluations can change across the sectional distribution of art prices, because those who bid for expensive items are likely to differ from those who buy relatively inexpensive items [Malpezzi, 2003]. Moreover, even the same collector might appreciate differently the characteristics in low- and high price items. Finally, paintings that reach an extraordinary evaluation within a group, the top lots, seem to behave differently from other items [Pesando, 1993; Mei and Moses, 2002]. The purpose of this paper is to analyze the existence of different hedonic models for cheap and expensive paintings. To this aim, an hedonic quantile regression framework is used, which allows the impact of art item characteristics to differ across price distribution. More precisely, by using a dataset of 716 Picasso 3 paintings sold at auctions worldwide during the period 1988-2005, we address two questions: • Is the assumption of homogeneous effects of covariates on prices, implicitly determined by the estimation of average effects, justified; or do effects differ at different quantiles of the price distribution? • How do time-invariant and time-variant characteristics affect the returns from paintings? The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 defines the model to be used. Data and functional form are presented in Section 3. The empirical evidence is discussed in Section 4. Section 5 concludes. 2. Theoretical framework The hedonic OLS regression is commonly used in the analysis of the art market to determine the relationship between a set of characteristics of collectibles and their corresponding (hammer) prices. Such an approach relies upon the mean of conditional distribution of the dependent variable. However, to the extent that characteristics are expected to be valued differently across a given distribution of selling prices, the exogenous variables influence the parameters of the conditional distribution of the dependent variable differently. Neglecting this possibility might undermine the reliability of the results [Koenker and Bassett, 1978; Zietz et al., 2007]. Unlike OLS, quantile regression models allow for a full characterization of the conditional distribution of the dependent variable. The standard OLS hedonic regression minimizes the sum of the squared residuals: { } ,min 2 0 , 0 ∑ ∑        − == i k j ijji xyk jj β β (1) where yi is the dependent variable at observation i; xj,i is the j regressor variable at observation i; and βj the parameter of the implicit price of the j characteristic. By contrast, quantile model involves instead the minimization of a weighted sum of the absolute deviations in a median-regression context: 4 { } ,min 0 , 0 ∑ ∑ = − = i i k j ijji hxyk jj β β (2) where the weight hi is defined as hi = 2q if the residual for the ith observation is strictly positive or as hi = 2-2q if the residual for the ith observation is negative or zero. The variable q (0 F F Prob > F F Prob > F F Prob > F Dimension 0.97 0.3257 0.84 0.3606 0.69 0.4074 0.57 0.4505 Style 1.74 0.1091 1.73 0.1106 1.73 0.1124 1.73 0.1107 Media 3.81 0.0100 3.82 0.0100 3.82 0.0099 3.86 0.0094 Salerooms 1.48 0.2074 1.45 0.2166 1.41 0.2280 1.40 0.2324 Period 2.89 0.0001 2.80 0.0002 2.68 0.0004 2.65 0.0005 15 Table 4. Adjacent year regression indexes Percentile Full sample .20 .40 .60 .80 .95 d88 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00 d89 179.10 172.25 246.25 170.70 166.60 162.26 d90 120.58 123.62 143.39 95.05 81.17 156.05 d91 67.11 72.64 82.79 49.91 46.92 48.82 d92 39.07 41.68 45.38 34.39 39.36 50.26 d93 31.85 20.74 58.61 35.54 32.10 37.42 d94 53.73 38.02 56.57 36.18 58.25 88.43 d95 52.63 44.55 55.43 37.53 55.30 82.20 d96 45.34 43.98 58.70 34.44 45.88 75.73 d97 77.51 59.36 81.50 65.93 85.69 117.23 d98 47.24 42.80 63.93 43.30 53.69 56.44 d99 70.29 51.82 81.82 61.66 89.33 102.33 d00 83.30 67.51 90.74 79.22 81.35 125.86 d01 67.78 63.83 72.38 50.95 47.59 120.32 d02 54.52 43.12 79.81 46.71 46.84 134.45 d03 71.56 75.85 88.33 55.94 53.14 76.95 d04 104.82 89.92 123.04 91.08 103.19 116.53 d05 118.79 117.94 149.87 91.66 106.83 198.18 16 Table 5. 5-year return return (full) return (0.2) return (0.4) return (0.6) return (0.8) return (0.95) 1988-92 39.07 41.68 45.38 34.39 39.36 50.26 1989-93 17.78 12.04 23.80 20.82 19.27 23.06 1990-94 44.56 30.76 39.45 38.06 71.76 56.67 1991-95 78.42 61.33 66.95 75.20 117.86 168.37 1992-96 116.05 105.52 129.35 100.15 116.57 150.68 1993-97 243.36 286.21 139.05 185.51 266.95 313.28 1994-98 87.92 112.57 113.01 119.68 92.17 63.82 1995-99 133.56 116.32 147.61 164.30 161.54 124.49 1996-00 183.72 153.50 154.58 230.02 177.31 166.20 1997-01 87.45 107.53 88.81 77.28 55.54 102.64 1998-02 115.41 100.75 124.84 107.88 87.24 238.22 1999-03 101.81 146.37 107.96 90.72 59.49 75.20 2000-04 125.83 133.20 135.60 114.97 126.85 92.59 2001-05 175.26 184.77 207.06 179.90 224.48 164.71 15 Figure 2. Adjacent year regression indexes 0.00 50.00 100.00 150.00 200.00 250.00 d88 d89 d90 d91 d92 d93 d94 d95 d96 d97 d98 d99 d00 d01 d02 d03 d04 d05 Index (full) Index (.20) Index (.40) Index (.60) Index (.80) Index (.95) 1 Figure 3. Average return and standard deviation of 5-year returns full samp le 0.6 quant 0.2 quant 0.8 quant .95 quant 0.4 quant 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 105 110 115 120 125 130 average 5-year return st d d ev ia tio n on 5 -y ea r re tu rn